58
Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More Contagious? What is the Historical Evidence on Contagion? Michael D. Bordo Rutgers University and NBER Antu Panini Murshid Rutgers University and World Bank August 14, 2000 This paper is based on an earlier paper, “The International Transmission of Financial Crises before World War II: Was there Contagion?” prepared for the ADB/IMF/World Bank conference on “International Financial Contagion,” Washington D.C., February, 2000. The authors are indebted to the conference participants for their valuable comments and criticisms. The authors are also indebted to Debajyoti Chakrabarty, Simon Evenett and Peter Montiel for constructive criticisms and comments, as well as Larry Neal and Jong Woo Kim for suggestions about data sources and help obtaining data. Finally we are deeply indebted to Jean Skidmore for patient research assistance and to Patricia Kerster for data work.

Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    0

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More Contagious? What

is the Historical Evidence on Contagion?

Michael D. Bordo

Rutgers University and NBER

Antu Panini Murshid

Rutgers University and World Bank

August 14, 2000

This paper is based on an earlier paper, “The International Transmission of Financial Crises before World War II: Was there Contagion?” prepared for the ADB/IMF/World Bank conference on “ International Financial Contagion,” Washington D.C., February, 2000. The authors are indebted to the conference participants for their valuable comments and criticisms. The authors are also indebted to Debajyoti Chakrabarty, Simon Evenett and Peter Montiel for constructive criticisms and comments, as well as Larry Neal and Jong Woo Kim for suggestions about data sources and help obtaining data. Finally we are deeply indebted to Jean Skidmore for patient research assistance and to Patricia Kerster for data work.

Page 2: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

2

Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More Contagious? What is the

Historical Evidence on Contagion?

Abstract

The scope and severity of the recent series of financial crises to hit Latin America and East Asia has helped

to crystalli ze a belief, that in this new era of global economic markets, "good health," in the sense of sound

economic policies, can no longer ensure a nation's immunity from crises. Yet from a historical perspective,

the recent spate of crises, as measured by their scope and severity, is nothing new. In the century and a half

preceding World War II, there were numerous financial crises, some of which dwarfed the recent batch in

both severity and scope.

In this paper we examine the evidence of contagion during episodes of volatilit y during the pre-World War

I period as well as, the interwar and contrast our findings with evidence from the recent crises in Asia and

Latin America.

Using weekly data on bond prices and interest rates, we investigate the extent to which bilateral cross-

market correlations rise following the onset of a crisis. After correcting for heteroscedasticity, ala Forbes

and Rigobon (1998, 1999), we find littl e evidence of significant increases in cross-market correlations in

either the earlier regimes or in the more recent period. Moreover, there is no indication that financial crises

are any more contagious today than in the past.

We then shift our focus away from contagion stemming from specific crises and ask the more general

question, Is the overall extent of comovement greater during turbulent periods? We use principle

components analysis to assess the extent of comovement across all markets as well as within various

groups of markets, prior to, and after the onset of a crisis. Countries are grouped into regions, as well as

into advanced and emerging countries. There is little evidence to suggest that cross-country linkages are

tighter during more turbulent periods for the recent period. There is, however, some evidence of stronger

comovement during periods of instabilit y in earlier regimes.

Page 3: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

3

1. Introduction

The recent series of f inancial crises in the emerging markets, the Mexican crisis of 1994-

95 and the Asian crisis of 1997-98, closely followed by the devaluations of the Ruble and

the Real, have been decried for their virulence and their far-reaching effects beyond their

epicenters. Certainly these recent batch of crises have been particularly severe.1 Yet,

that crises can spread across international borders should not, of its own accord, be

surprising; it is merely a reflection of the interdependence of cross-country fortunes in the

presence of real and identifiable channels of transmission. Moreover, in the face of

macroeconomic imbalances and or structural weaknesses, crises, when they arrive,

should not be surprising, rather they are a reflection of the unsound economic policies

and ineff iciencies fostered in an underdeveloped financial infrastructure. However, as

the October 1997 crash on the Hong Kong Exchange demonstrated, good fundamentals

alone cannot insulate a country from the effects of f inancial contagion.2 Moreover, the

sharp drops on the Brazili an exchange and the eventual devaluation of the Real,

following the Russian crisis are diff icult to attribute to bad fundamentals or cross-country

linkages. 3

These recent crises have led to the view that financial crises can spread across

international borders like a contagious disease, unless curtailed by heavy lending by the

international financial institutions. Indeed the scope and severity of the recent batch of

crises is such, that it has helped crystalli ze a belief that financial crises, in this new era of

1 Bordo and Eichengreen (1999) assess the severity of the recent financial crises and compare them to crises in the prewar and interwar periods. They find the average drop in output following a crisis, in a sample of ten emerging countries, in the post Bretton Woods period, to be greater than the average drop in output following a crisis in any other period this century. 2 That Hong Kong was not insulated from the effects of the Asian crisis is a reflection of intra-regional ties, however, unlike many of its neighbors, there was littl e evidence of the type of corruption and cronyism that have often been associated with the Asian crisis. By contrast the regulatory supervision over the banking system was much stricter. Moreover, government budgets in Hong Kong were conservative. 3 Whereas we can attribute Hong Kong’s woes to regional ties, it is diff icult to establish any real li nkages that can justify the events that transpired in Brazil as an implication of the crisis in Russia. The heavy losses inflicted on a handful of highly leveraged investors following the Russian crisis, causing some of them to liquidate their positions in Brazil , is one possible channel of transmission. However, it is not clear that this alone could explain why the Brazili an stock market plummeted and eventually forced the government to devalue the currency. In a recent study of the contagion from Russia to Brazil , Baig and Goldfajn (1999), conclude that, “ the data does not seem to reflect a compensatory liquidation of assets

Page 4: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

4

globalization, are becoming increasingly more contagious.4 Yet from an historical

perspective the recent spate of international financial crises is nothing new. In the

century and a half preceding World War II there were numerous international financial

crises, some of which dwarfed the recent batch in both severity and scope.

In this paper we assess the evidence of contagion in the pre-World War II period and

contrast this with our findings for the more recent period. Using weekly data on the price

of sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

– the Baring Crisis in 1890 and the US banking crisis in 1893.5 The earlier of these two

episodes of instabilit y, had its origins in the financial crisis in Argentina early in 1890.

The events there had ramifications for the House of Baring, which triggered a financial

crisis in London that eventually fed back to Latin America. We examine the interesting

dynamics of that year, by focusing on the first half and the latter half of that year

separately. That is we first investigate the extent of contagion stemming from the earlier

Argentine crisis, and then examine the contagion following from the troubles of Baring

Brothers later that year.

For the interwar, we utili ze weekly data on bond prices of foreign government bonds that

were traded on the NYSE. 6 Specifically, we focus on the contagion stemming from the

crash on the NYSE in 1929, from the UK following the devaluation of sterling in 1931,

and from the US following the devaluation of the dollar in 1933. For the recent period

we examine the two recent crises to hit Latin America and East Asia. Specifically, we

focus on the episodes of volatilit y following the devaluation of the peso in December,

1994, and the devaluation of baht in July, 1997. For this period, we utili ze a weekly data

set on short-term interest rates. Our coverage is varied. For the six-month period piror to

story by international investors.” They conclude that if there was contagion from Russia to Brazil , the most likely source of this contagion was from the offshore Brady market. 4 Following the recent series of financial crises, the volatile nature of private capital flows has become evident. This has led many to propose policy safeguards against sudden reversals of capital flows. Some have gone further and questioned the long terms benefits of capital flow liberalization. Jagdish Bhagwati (1998) argued that the case for fully-fledged capital flow liberalization was not as strong as for trade liberalization. 5 The countries in our sample are Argentina, Belgium, Brazil , Canada, Chile, France, the Netherlands, the UK and the US. Source: The Economist, Weekly Commercial Times, various issues.

Page 5: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

5

and after the collapse of the peso, our data spans 15 countries.7 This number increases to

23, for the period spanning the devaluation of the baht.8

In section 2 of this paper, we provide an historical account of numerous international

financial crises in the nineteenth and twentieth centuries and attempt to identify the

possible channels of transmission that could have dictated the spread of these crises. We

identify several key channels of transmission, which include linkages through

international trade, through lending from the core to the peripheral countries, through

arbitrage in short-term securities markets, and through gold flows. With this narrative as

background, combined with the aid of a chronology of f inancial crises (banking and

currency crises) for 21 countries,9 both advanced and emerging, in section 3, we examine

the empirical evidence on contagion by examining the behavior of the correlation

coeff icient in the period surrounding a crisis.

In section 4, we change our perspective from specific episodes of volatilit y and the

contagion stemming from specific countries, and focus instead on the extent of

comovement across markets during periods of volatilit y in general. That is we ask the

question, Do financial variables across markets exhibit greater comovement during

turbulent periods? Hence we are less interested in whether markets exhibited higher

correlations with Thailand following the crisis there, or with Mexico following the peso's

collapse, and more concerned with the extent of comovement, across all markets, during

periods of volatilit y. We use principle components analysis to analyze this issue. Our

analysis reveals evidence of significant comovement across markets during both periods

of turmoil and periods of relative stabilit y. We then take this analysis one step further

6 The countries in our sample are: Argentina, Belgium, Brazil , Canada, Chile, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Italy, the Netherlands, Sweden, Switzerland, the U.K. and the U.S. Source: Commercial and Financial Chronicles, various issues. 7 The countries in our sample are Australia, Canada, Denmark, France, Germany, Hong Kong, Indonesia, Japan, Malaysia, Portugal, Singapore, Thailand, the U.K. and the U.S. Source: Reuters. 8 The countries in our sample are Australia, Brazil , Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hong Kong, Indonesia, Italy, Japan, Malaysia, Mexico, Phili ppines, Portugal, Singapore, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, Thailand, the U.K. and the U.S. Source: Reuters. 9 The chronology of crisis, by Bordo and Eichengreen (1999), was constructed for the following countries: Argentina, Australia, Belgium, Brazil , Canada, Chile, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Italy, Japan, Netherlands, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, U.K., USA. The countries in our sample are a subset of these 21 countries for which we were able to obtain weekly data on bond price movements.

Page 6: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

6

and examine the evidence of comovements within various groups of countries. Countries

are grouped into regional clusters and into advanced and emerging. We use principle

components analysis in order to investigate the extent of comovement within these

various clusters. For the interwar, we find some evidence of greater comovement

following the sterling and dollar devaluations. However, for the recent period, the

evidence of tighter cross-market linkages, within various regions of countries or within

the set of advanced or the set of emerging countries, is weak. Section 5 concludes.

Page 7: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

7

2. Historical Perspectives on the International Transmission of Financial Crises

2.1 The Incidence of International Financial Crises

The recent series of crises in emerging markets, the Mexican crisis of 1994-95 and the

“ tequila spill overs” to Latin American and other countries, the Asian crisis of 1997-98

and its “spill overs” to Brazil and Russia, has led to the view that financial crises (both

currency and banking crises) tend to spread across countries like a contagious disease

unless they are curtailed by vigorous international intervention. From an historical

perspective the recent spate of international financial crises is nothing new. In the

century and a half preceding World War II there were numerous international financial

crises, some of which dwarfed the recent batch in both severity and scope. Below we

discuss their incidence and evolution.

The nineteenth century had periodic international financial crises in virtually every

decade since 1825. Kindleberger (1986a) Appendix B presents a chronology going back

to the seventeenth century. His focus was primarily on showing a common incidence of

crises in the core countries of Europe and the U.S. Morgenstern (1959) displays a

chronology of stock market panics for European countries and the U.S. from 1880-1939

showing a high degree of cross-country coherence. Thorp’s (1926) Business Annals is

also a source showing common patterns of banking panics, stock market crashes, and

financial stress in 17 countries. Bordo (1986) focused on 4 European countries (U.K.,

France, Germany, Sweden) and the U.S. and Canada 1870-1939. His chronologies of

financial crises, banking panics, and stock market crashes highlighted the international

coincidence of these events and of several empirical measures of f inancial stress under

the classical gold standard and gold exchange standards. Recently Bordo and

Eichengreen (1999) compiled a chronology of banking and currency crises based on

historical narratives and a currency crisis index for 21 countries from 1880-1973. (See

Figure 1). This chronology is complemented with measures of the economic impact of

crises. Again a pattern of recurrent international crises is evident.

Page 8: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

8

From this literature we learn that there were periodic financial crises in a large number of

countries over the past century and a half. The key crisis years before World War II were

the following: 1825, 1837-38, 1847, 1857, 1866, 1873, 1890-93, 1907-1908, 1914, 1920-

21, and 1929-33. In the postwar Bretton Woods regime, although there were currency

crises in advanced countries associated with adherence to the adjustable peg exchange

rate regime, there were no banking crises and the crises observed had relatively minor

economic effects. For the period beginning in 1880 for which we have suff icient data to

assess the economic impact of crises, the evidence from Bordo and Eichengreen (1999)

suggests that the severity of crises in emerging countries before 1914 may not have been

as great as that observed in today’s emerging countries and that it is the incidence of twin

currency and banking crises today that may account for the different experiences.

2.2 Patterns of Transmission

From the historical lit erature we can discern a number of explanations for the

international transmission of crises. These include linkages through international trade,

through lending from the core to peripheral countries, through arbitrage in short-term

securities markets, stock markets, and commodities markets between advanced countries,

and through gold flows and the money supply and psychological factors independent of

the other channels.

All of the pre-World War II crises occurred under variants of the gold standard. This has

two important implications. First, most countries adhering to gold convertibilit y after

1880 were tightly linked to each other by the fixed exchange rates of their gold parities

and the absence of serious impediments to the flow of goods and capital. This facilit ated

the transmission of shocks, including financial crises, between countries. Second, these

international crises often occurred in periods of deflation when, under the self-regulating

operation of the commodity theory of money which in the long-run drives the price level

for the gold standard world, an excess demand for monetary gold created an environment

Page 9: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

9

of monetary stringency and financial distress (Bordo and Wheelock 1998, Bordo,

Duekker, Wheelock 1999).

Within this context the record suggests a number of geographical patterns of crisis

transmission. The dominant mechanism was between the advanced countries of Europe,

with crises often originating in Great Britain, the center of the international financial

system, and from the core to the periphery countries of North America, Latin America,

and the rest of the world. However, crises also originated in the periphery and especially

in the U.S., which spread to Europe and then back to the periphery. Below we document

some of the more important episodes.

2.3 Episodes of International Financial Crises

1825. The crisis of 1825 is often viewed as the first international financial crisis. The

liberation of Latin America in the early 1820s led to a massive inflow of capital from

Britain to finance the exploitation of gold and silver mines and of sovereign loans to the

newly independent republics. It also led to an export boom. These foreign influences

combined with the rapid growth of the new industries of the industrial revolution and

liberal monetary expansion in the years after the Napoleonic wars led to a speculative

mania on the London Stock Exchange (Gayer, Rostow, and Schwartz 1953, Neal 1998,

Bordo 1998). A growing trade imbalance and a drain on the Bank of England’s gold

reserves led the Bank to raise its discount rate in the summer. A stock market crash in

October triggered a banking panic in December, which spread to the continent. The

Bank, concerned over its own reserves, did not act quickly enough to allay the panic,

which resulted in numerous bankruptcies and a recession. The crisis spread to Latin

America as the overseas loans were cut off , a decline in investment and exports reduced

tax revenues and led to sovereign debt defaults across the region. It took three decades

before the debts were renegotiated and capital flows in Latin American resumed

(Marichal 1989).

1836-38. This crisis was primarily an Anglo-American affair. In 1836, the Bank of

England began raising Bank rate in response to an external gold drain caused by poor

Page 10: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

10

corn harvests and capital flows to the U.S. to finance a boom in cotton lands. The

resultant stock market crash in December 1836, spread to Paris. The effects on the U.S.

were dramatic. A reduction in lending to cotton factors in New Orleans sparked a

banking panic there that spread through the correspondent banking system to New York.

The resultant nationwide panic led to suspension of specie payments in May 1837 that

lasted close to a year. The crisis was transmitted through capital market linkages and

through specie outflows and their effects on money supply (Temin 1969, Levy-Leboyer

1982, Huffman and Lothian 1984).

1847. This crisis, primarily a European affair, was triggered by the collapse of a

speculative boom in rail road shares in London. As in earlier episodes, the British balance

of trade turned negative. The Bank reacted to declining gold reserves by raising its

discount rate. This ended the boom, caused prices to fall and triggered a major banking

panic, which ended only with an announcement that the Chancellor of the Exchequer had

signed a letter temporarily suspending the Bank Charter Act, thereby allowing the Bank

to issue more notes than would be covered by its gold reserves (Clapham 1945,

Dornbusch and Frenkel 1984). According to Kindleberger (1986a), the crisis spread to

Germany and Holland in the next year through international banking channels.

1857. This crisis began in the U.S. A rail road stock boom fueled by the recently

discovered gold fields in Cali fornia and British capital, collapsed in August 1857. This

led to the banking panic of 1857 with widespread bank failures. This crisis spread to

England in the fall and, li ke the 1847 event, was ended in November by a Treasury letter.

From England the crisis spread to the continent, with a serious panic in Hamburg in

December. According to Kindleberger, the crisis was also felt in South America, South

Africa and the Far East.

1873. The crisis of 1873 is viewed as a major international crisis. The run-up to the

crisis was a lending boom in Latin America to finance rail roads fueled from England and

the continent, and a speculative land boom in Germany and Austria fueled by the French

gold indemnity paid to Prussia after the Franco-Prussian war. The Austrian, German

Page 11: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

11

boom collapsed in a spectacular stock market crash in Vienna in May. Stock markets in

Amsterdam and Zurich also crashed. In the U.S. a banking panic in September followed

the collapse of a stock market boom in New York with the failure of Jay Cook, a major

financier and President of the Union Pacific rail road. According to Kindleberger, the

German crisis contributed to the U.S. event as capital flow was cut off despite the fact

that the dollar was floating in this period which would have negated the price specie flow

channel of transmission. This crisis had serious repercussions in Latin America. The

downturn in the European economy ushered in by the crises and the turnaround in world

prices from inflation to deflation in this period reduced exports, tax revenues (trade taxes

were the principal form of taxation in Latin America), and debt service leading to a new

wave of defaults (Marichal 1989).

1890. The Baring crisis of 1890 triggered an international crisis in England and Latin

America that has resonance for today. The crisis culminated a major lending boom from

England and the continent in the 1880s to Argentina and Uruguay to finance rail roads and

other infrastructure. Many of the loans went to the Argentine provincial banks, that were

not financially sound, fueling a monetary expansion and their collapse. The international

crisis erupted when the House of Baring (a major investment bank in London that held

the unsaleable paper of the Buenos Aires Water Supply and Drainage Company) declared

itself to the Bank of England to be insolvent on November 8, 1890. The Bank prevented

a panic by arranging a li feboat operation to re-capitalize Barings with the aid of other

major London financial institutions and a temporary rescue loan from the Banque de

France and the Russian central bank. The crisis spread back to Latin America with the

cessation of British lending to Argentina, Uruguay, and Brazil . According to

Kindleberger the 1890 crisis was also linked to a major bank failure in Paris in 1889 and

was the foundation for a later series of crises in 1893.

1893. Major crises in the U.S. and Australia in 1893 have been linked to the earlier

Baring crisis and to a general downturn in the world price level. The U.S. panic of 1893

is generally associated with the Sherman Silver Purchase Act, a filli p to the Free Silver

Movement, which led investors fearing that the issue of silver certificates would force the

Page 12: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

12

U.S. off the gold standard, to flee the U.S., hence precipitating a gold outflow and

monetary contraction. The proximate cause of the massive banking panic in the summer

of 1893 was a stock market collapse and increase in commercial failures that awakened

fears about the solvency of commercial banks.

The Australian crisis was preceded by a land boom, which was in large part financed by

domestic bank lending. The immediate cause of the panic was falli ng export prices,

which made it diff icult for the pastoral sector to repay its loans. The trigger was the

closure of three banks. The crisis was aggravated by a withdrawal of British deposits and

loans. Retrenchment by the surviving banks in turn precipitated a long depression (Bordo

and Eichengreen 1999).

1907. The 1907 crisis had many of the attributes of the earlier crisis but in terms of its

international scope and its virulence it was probably the worst of the gold standard era.

According to the chronology in Bordo and Eichengreen, 9 out of their 21 countries were

hit by crises. The trigger is said to have been the Bank of England, which began raising

its discount rate in 1906 from 3.5 percent to 6 percent to counter a gold drain. This action

had the effect of reversing the flow of gold to the U.S. and severely tightening U.S.

money market conditions. A stock market crash occurred in early 1907, and economic

activity began to decline. In October, depositor runs on trust companies spread to the

commercial banks. The money stock declined precipitously, banks suspended cash

payments, and the economy entered a sharp recession. According to Kindleberger

(1986a) the crisis spread from England via France to Italy, which had been undergoing a

speculative boom. The connection was by Paris clearing its decks of London securities

and both centers stopped lending to Italy and other peripheral countries (Bonnelli 1982).

1914. The outbreak of World War I precipitated a massive international financial crisis

across the world. In the Bordo-Eichengreen (1999) sample of 21 countries, 15 countries

had currency crises, banking crises, or both. This crisis, unlike the others, did not spread

from the core to the periphery but occurred virtually simultaneously in all countries as the

belli gerents scrambled to liquidate foreign assets. This led to panics in all asset markets

Page 13: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

13

and a scramble for high-powered money. Banking panics in the U.S., U.K., and other

countries were allayed by timely lender-of-last-resort intervention.

1920-22. The post war deflation and recession, triggered by monetary authorities in the

U.S., U.K., and other countries in an attempt to roll back the wartime inflation and post

war commodity boom and to restore price levels to their prewar gold standard levels,

were associated with both banking and currency crises in a number of countries

(Denmark, Italy, Finland, Netherlands, and Norway). However, unlike the crises of the

nineteenth century there was no clear pattern of international transmission.

1929-33. The stock market crash on Wall Street in October of 1929 ushered in the

greatest worldwide contraction of all time. The collapse in world output from 1929-33

was heralded by a collapse in commodity prices in the emerging countries. The stock

market boom in New York by 1928 choked off U.S. capital flows to central Europe and

Latin America and precipitated currency crises in a number of countries (Australia,

Argentina, Uruguay, and Brazil ) early in 1929 (Kindleberger 1986a). The Wall Street

crash precipitated by tightening Federal Reserve policy was instantly reflected in stock

market crises around the globe.

The story of the international propagation of the Great Depression is well known

(Eichengreen 1992, Kindleberger 1986b, Friedman and Schwartz 1963). The U.S.

downturn in 1929 turned into a depression in 1930 and 1931 after the Federal Reserve

failed to allay a series of banking panics. The resultant collapse in prices and output

worldwide forced sovereign borrowers to cut back on servicing their debts and then to

default, precipitating a collapse of foreign lending in 1931. At the same time the U.S.

induced depression and deflation precipitated banking and currency crises in central

Europe, forcing the U.K. to abandon gold in 1931. Transmission occurred through gold

flows, the money supplies, and capital flight. Adherence to gold for most countries acted

as “golden fetters” preventing monetary authorities from following expansionary

monetary policy (Eichengreen 1992).

Page 14: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

14

3. Correlations Analysis

Recent studies, such as Baig and Goldfajn (1998, 1999), Forbes and Rigobon (1998),

have tested for contagion in financial markets by examining the behavior of the

correlation across countries, in financial market variables, such as securities prices,

interest rates and exchange rates. Whereas high correlations across countries is not in

itself evidence of contagion, as this may merely reflect historic cross-country

dependence, significant increases in the correlation coeff icient are typically interpreted as

evidence of contagion. The idea underlying such tests is the view that the strength of

cross-country linkages is state dependent. The occurrence of a bad state, in particular a

crisis, excites otherwise dormant channels of transmission, radically changing the nature

of the linkages between countries, thus ampli fying the cross-border impact of a shock,

which shows up as an increase in the correlation coeff icient.

However, cross-country correlations are highly volatile, whether during turbulent periods

or periods of relative tranquilit y, which makes this type of analysis sensitive to the choice

of crisis windows. Moreover, as Forbes and Rigobon (1998, 1999) have shown, this

volatilit y is not necessarily a reflection of the changing patterns in cross-country linkages.

Rather this type of instabilit y may be the outcome of the heteroscedastic nature of the

shocks impacting on the markets.10 Specifically, if x and y are two series such that yt =

βxt + ut, where ut is a disturbance, the correlation between x and y is given by

, y)(x,y

x

σσβρ = where , xσ is the variance of x and , yσ is the variance of y. Now to the

10 Unfortunately the Forbes and Rigobon (1998, 1999) result is occasionally misinterpreted. Some have interpreted the result as saying that the sample correlation coeff icient is a biased estimator of the population correlation coeff icient, when heteroscedasticity is present. As elementary statistics has taught us, this is not true. The sample correlation coeff icient is indeed biased, in small samples, but the size of this bias depends not on the stochastic properties of the parent populations, but rather on the sample size, and the true value of the population correlation coeff icient. See Fisher (1915), Gayen (1951) and Ruben (1966). The point that Forbes and Rigobon are making is that if two series x and y are linearly related according to the equation yt = βxt + ut, then an increase in the variance of x can lead to an increase in the correlation between x and y, even though the value of β has remained unchanged. This point is made by means of a very cute example involving a coin tossing game in two stages, in Forbes and Rigobon (1999). We have made a stand here and directed the reader to Forbes and Rigobon (1999), as well as numerous seminal contributions in the statistics literature governing the distribution of the sample correlation coeff icient, before this confusion spreads through the literature in aptly contagious fashion.

Page 15: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

15

extent that the ratio of the variances , y

x

σσ

is changing the correlation between x and y will

also be changing.

In this section, we examine the evidence of increases in correlations following a financial

crisis in three periods of our history. Given the frequency of our data, in order to allow

suff icient degrees of freedom, we examine the evidence of changes in correlations in six-

month windows of time.11 We present the results of our correlation analysis in two ways:

(1) in a set of tables that reports pre-crisis and post-crisis correlations, as well as the

increase in correlations in the post-crisis period, where increases in correlations that are

significant after adjusting for heteroscedasticity are shaded; (2) in a second set of tables

that report the average pre-crisis and post-crisis correlations between the crisis countries

and the emerging countries and between the crisis countries and the advanced countries.

3.1 The Pre World War I Period

In order to compare correlations in the pre-crisis period with those of the crisis period, it

was necessary to have some additional information regarding the timing of crises than

could be obtained from an annual chronology such as that reported in Bordo and

Eichengreen (1999). In each period of instabilit y we discuss the chain of events that

culminated in a financial crisis. Other than providing an explanation of the proximate

causes of each crisis, this discussion provides clues as to the timing of the events. Since a

crisis, banking or currency, however defined, is never so precise as to present an obvious

demarcation of a period of tranquilit y from a period of crisis, the eventual choice of crisis

windows is somewhat subjective. Moreover, since crises often occur sequentially across

countries, the contagion stemming from a turbulent period typically cannot be attributed

to any single event. These caveats need to be kept in mind when interpreting an analysis

based on pre- and post-crisis correlations.

Page 16: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

16

The Baring crisis in 1890 erupted on November 8, 1890, when the House of Baring

declared itself to be insolvent to the Bank of England. The crisis had its roots in the

lending boom from the UK to Latin America. Though a successful rescue package

arranged by the Bank of England limited the fallout from the crisis in London, the effects

of the crisis were felt in Latin America for several years. The acute financial crisis and

monetary instabilit y in Argentina, which began in March of 1890 continued well i nto

1894 (Thorp 1926). A revival from this depression did not begin until 1895.

Attracting between 40 and 50 per cent of all Briti sh funds invested abroad, Argentina in

the 1880s was the single most important destination of British capital (Eichengreen

1997). Following the earlier episodes of default in the 19th century, Argentina’s return to

the international capital market reflects a combination of both monetary reforms and low

interest rates in London.

The inflows of foreign capital fueled a speculative bubble in real estate prices. The

bubble eventually burst at the end of the decade, with real estate prices falli ng in excess

of 50% (Batchelor 1986). As a result of its speculative activity, the Banco de la Nacion

(one of the two national banks of Argentina), found itself unable to make its dividend

payments, triggering a run on the whole banking system. By April of that year, the

Argentine government found itself unable to make its interest payments. Despite initial

attempts to reschedule loans and the negotiation of a 10 milli on pound loan from London,

government finances collapsed.

The crisis spread to London when Baring Brothers declared their insolvency to the Bank

of England. A rescue package arranged in secret helped minimize the fall out from the

crisis. The effects of the crisis were not solely restricted to Latin America, as countries as

far a field as Australia and New Zealand found it diff icult to raise external finance.

11 Our data for the prewar period covers two non-adjacent years – 1890 and 1893. Since the crises we consider often occurred in the last quarter the post-crisis windows are typically taken to be the last quarter of each year.

Page 17: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

17

The origins of the banking crisis in the US in 1893 can be traced to the enactment of the

Sherman Silver Purchase Act, which was passed on July 14, 1890. The act which

stipulated that the Treasury should step-up the purchase of silver to 4.5 milli on ounces

per month (Friedman and Schwartz, 1963), introduced fears that this purchase of silver

would produce an inflation that would force the US of gold. These fears were re-ignited

when a series of runs on trust companies in New York, including the Knickerbocker

Trust Company in October 1893, introduced doubts about the solvency of the banking

system. A banking panic ensued.

Table 1, which is divided into three parts, reports the unadjusted pre- and post-crisis

correlations along with the increases in correlations in the post-crisis period. An asterix

denotes that the increases are significant at 10%, while a double asterix indicates

significance at 5%.12 Shaded entries are significant after adjusting for heteroscedasticty.

Tables 1 a) and 1 b) examine the correlations in crisis and pre-crisis periods during the

Baring crisis. Specifically, Table 1 a) focuses on the contagion stemming from the crisis

in Argentina, which can be traced to the troubles of the Banco de la Nacion in March.

The period of tranquilit y is thus defined as the six-month window prior to this event. The

period of crisis is defined as the six-month window after the start of the crisis in

Argentina.

Table 1 b) focuses on the contagion following from the insolvency of Baring Brothers.

Even though Barings disclosed its financial diff iculties in November, the crisis window is

defined to start in the first week of October. The reason for this has to do with data

constraints. Taking the crisis-period one-month back allows more degrees of freedom

with which to estimate post-crisis correlations.

12 The distribution of the sample correlation coeff icient is complicated. However, a simple transformation, known as the Fisher z transformation, brings the distribution close to normality (Fisher 1915). In order to test the null hypothesis that two samples of size n1 and n2 are from two independent bivariate normal populations with correlation coeff icients ρ1 and ρ2 such that ρ1= ρ2, we employ the following test statistic:

( )( ) ( )[ ]3131 21

21

−+−−=

nnzzU , where zi = tanh-1(ri), where ri is the sample correlation

coeff icient.

Page 18: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

18

Table 1 c) examines the impact of the October 1893 banking panic in the US. The crisis-

period is defined to start in the first week of October. The period of tranquilit y is taken to

be the six-month window prior to this.

Tables 2 a), 2 b) and 2c) report the average pre-crisis and post-crisis correlations between

the crisis affected country and the emerging countries as a group and the advanced

countries as a group.

Table 1 a) shows that in the pre-crisis period movements in Argentine bond prices were

correlated with movements in bond prices in the Netherlands. Negative correlations are

observed with Brazil and Chile. Interestingly, the correlation with the UK is highly

negative despite the fact that the UK was the largest supplier of capital to Argentina.

In the post-crisis period, we observe that, with the exception of Canadian bonds, price

movements of Argentine Cedula bonds were correlated with those of all other foreign

bonds. In particular, we observe a high correlation between the Argentine and Dutch

bond markets. High correlations are also seen to exist between Argentina and Chile, as

well as with the core European nations and the US. The two sharpest increases in

correlations are between Argentina and Chile and Argentina and the UK. However, only

the increase in correlations with UK are significant at 5%, and these increases remain

significant at 5% even after correcting for heteroscedasticty. There thus seems to be

evidence of contagion from Argentina to the UK.

The sharp increase in correlation between the UK and Argentina is consistent with the

spread of the crisis to London. Figure 2 plots the price of Argentine and UK bonds over

time. In the period prior to the crisis, the two series can be seen to be moving in opposite

directions. However, from April onwards, one month after the crisis in Argentina was

well under way, the movements in the two series are correlated with each other.

Table 2 a) reports the average correlations between Argentina and the emerging countries

in our sample, as well as the advanced countries. The Table suggests that in the pre-crisis

Page 19: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

19

period, the correlation between Argentina and the emerging countries was significantly

higher than the correlation between Argentina and the advanced countries. In the post-

crisis period, correlations with both advanced and emerging countries rise strongly.

However, if we exclude the UK from the set of advanced countries, then correlations with

the two remaining advanced countries in our sample are seen to decrease in the crisis

period.

In Table 1 b) we switch our attention to the behavior of cross-market correlations in the

period following the announcement of the insolvency of Baring Brothers. Several

patterns are apparent. We see that in the pre-crisis period, the UK displays high

correlations with all the countries in our sample. In particular, we observe high

correlations between the UK and Canada and the UK and the US. These high

correlations may reflect the importance of trade linkages. In particular, the UK was the

second most important export market for Canada. We also observe a high correlation

between the UK and Chile. This may reflect Chile’s openness and strong reliance on its

exports of nitrates to the European nations. Interestingly, the correlation between France

and the UK is small .

In the post-crisis period, we observe that with the exception of the Netherlands and

Argentina, the correlations between the UK and the other nations in our sample turn

sharply negative. Interestingly, the correlation between the UK and the other Latin

American countries with the exception of Argentina are negative. The analysis seems to

suggest that there may have been contagion from the UK to Argentina in the immediate

aftermath of the Baring crisis, even though the increase in correlations between the two

nations is not significant. In part, this may have to do with the proximity of the crisis in

Argentina and the later crisis in London. Since correlations between the UK and

Argentina had already increased following the turbulent events their, we would expect to

observe fairly high correlations between the two countries in the pre-Baring crisis period.

There is no evidence of contagion from UK to any other country. In fact, all other

correlations decrease in the crisis period. Table 2 b) summarizes this finding. We see

Page 20: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

20

that even though pre-crisis correlations between the UK and the advanced as well as the

emerging countries are on average positive, in the post-crisis period they are negative.

Table 1 c) shows that prior to the crisis, US bond price movements were highly correlated

with bond price movements in Belgium, Brazil , Chile, France, the Netherlands, and the

UK. On average, we see that correlations between the US and the advanced countries are

higher in the pre-crisis period, see Table 2 c). Interestingly the correlations between the

US and Canada are small , even though these countries have traditionally shared strong

trade linkages. In the crisis period the correlations between the US and several countries

increase, both advanced and emerging, see Table 2 c). In particular, we observe sharp

increases in correlations with the UK, France, Brazil and Chile. However, correlations

between the US and Canada still remain fairly weak. Though we observe increases in

correlations between the US and several countries, none of these increases are significant,

even before we adjust for heteroscedasticity. Thus, though there may have been greater

comovement between bond markets, we cannot verify this to be statistically significant.

In summary our evidence for the pre World War I period suggests that correlations

between countries often increased during periods of turbulence. There is convincing

evidence of contagion in the aftermath of the Argentine crisis to both the UK and Chile.

However, the evidence of contagion following the Baring crisis on London is not as

compelli ng. Furthermore, the increases in correlations that we observe in the period

following the US banking panic in 1893, are not suff iciently strong to withstand

statistical scrutiny.

3.2 The Interwar Period

As can be seen from Figure 1, the years between 1929-1933 were the most heavily

polluted with crises. We focus on the contagion stemming from the onset of three

financial crises; the stock market crash of October 1929, the devaluation of sterling on

September 21, 1931, and the devaluation of the dollar following the enactment of the

Thomas Amendment in May 1933.

Page 21: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

21

The crash of October 1929, though arguably symptomatic of the decline in economic

activity that was already underway, is seen by many as the trigger behind the sequence of

events that led to the onset of the Great Depression and that helped to pull apart the

already fragile international monetary system. On October 21, margin calls led to heavy

selli ng on the NYSE with the volume of sales exceeding 6 milli on shares. By October

29, this number had reached 16.4 milli on, which by today’s standard would imply a

trading volume in excess of one billi on shares. See Malkiel (1996). However, the crash

is viewed, there is no doubt that it served only to deepen the slump in the US.

Moreover, the drop in economic activity in the US sparked a precipitous decline in the

terms of trade in several primary exporting nations at the periphery, in particular those in

Latin America. The negative shock to the terms of trade and the decline in capital

imports from New York caused a large outflow of reserves, that led many Latin

American countries to either impose exchange controls, or suspend convertibilit y

altogether and issue a moratorium on external debt service (Diaz Alejandro). By the end

of 1929, Argentina and Uruguay had already limited gold convertibilit y (Eichengreen

1996). Between 1930 and 1934, several Latin American countries allowed their

exchange rates to slip below off icial parities. The sequential impact of the crash was not

restricted to Latin America or the periphery. Australia and New Zealand imposed

exchange controls, while Canada sealed off the gold outflow by imposing an embargo on

gold exports (Eichengreen 1996).

Despite the shockwave emanating from the wake of the 1929 stock market crash, there

were few crises in that year relative to 1931. 1931 was by and far the "year of crises."

Altogether 18 countries in our sample of 21 experienced crises. With a banking crisis

well underway in the US, in May 1931, Austria suffered a severe banking crisis following

the failure of the Kreditanstalt, Austria’s largest private bank (Friedman and Schwartz

1963). Within a month the crisis had spread to Germany. In an effort to stem the outflow

of gold, the Austrian and German governments were forced to suspend gold

convertibilit y. The instabilit y soon spread to the continent and the UK.

Page 22: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

22

From the onset of the restoration of convertibilit y at the pre-World War I parity in 1925,

the UK was plagued with balance of payments deficits. During the six years that the UK

was on the gold standard, these deficits progressively worsened. The global slowdown in

demand and increasingly protectionist policies caused a slump in export earnings.

Moreover default on debt by several Latin American countries had a deleterious effect on

the external balance. By 1931, the crisis-ridden countries of Austria and Germany were

forced to impose exchange controls and place a freeze on interest payments. These

events served to accelerate the outflow of gold reserves. Moreover, within a backdrop of

depressed economic activity and high unemployment, rises in the Bank rate were no

longer viewed as a credible policy (Eichengreen and Jeanne 1998). On September 21,

1931, Britain was forced to abandon gold convertibil ity.

The UK’s departure from gold set the stage for several countries to break off their ties to

gold. Countries with close ties to the UK through trade linkages, as well as those that

relied on the London financial markets, followed sterling off gold and pegged their

currencies to the pound, thus forming the sterling area (Eichengreen 1996). Other

countries that followed the UK off gold, but that did not join the sterling area, included

Japan, who competed with the UK in the textiles industry, and Canada, who depreciated

her currency to a lesser extent than sterling (Eichengreen 1996). In all some 25 countries

followed Britain off gold within a year of the sterling devaluation (Friedman and

Schwartz 1963).

The Thomas Amendment to the Agricultural Adjustment Act was enacted into law on

May 12, 1933. The Amendment empowered President Roosevelt to reduce the gold

content of the dollar by as much as one half of it’s original content. Though coming after

a period of sustained instabilit y in the US, culminating in the massive banking panic of

1933, the devaluation of the dollar had ramifications on an international scale. The

devaluation triggered another round of devaluations at the periphery, in particular in

Latin America.

Page 23: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

23

Despite the severity and the international nature of the financial crises from this period,

that there was contagion in financial market variables is not necessarily so. The

sequential dethroning of gold convertibilit y over the period, is to a large extent a

reflection of the underlying weaknesses of the interwar gold exchange standard, which

helped to both foster and perpetuate shocks across international borders. The channels of

transmission of these shocks, have been well documented by Eichengreen (1992). Below

we test the evidence of contagion in bond markets. Our data for the interwar is more

comprehensive than for the pre-World War I period, providing coverage over a larger

number of countries for a larger number of years. We proceed as above by estimating the

correlations of weekly changes in bond prices for both crisis and non-crisis periods.

Tables 3 a), b) and c) report the pre- and post-crisis correlations in the periods prior to

and after the onset of the three crises, along with the increases in correlations in the post-

crisis periods. In particular, Tables 3 a) and 3 c) report the correlations between the US

and the other countries in our sample, while Table 3 b) reports the correlations between

the UK and the other countries.

From Table 3, some patterns are apparent that suggest the importance of linkages through

international trade, which are consistent with the predictions of standard gravity equation

models, see Eichengreen and Irwin (1998). For instance in the period of tranquilit y prior

to the stock market crash of 1929, or the devaluation of the dollar in 1933, we observe

positive correlations between the US and Canada that are consistent with historically

strong ties between the two nations through international trade. Moreover, we see that

prior to the devaluation of sterling in 1931, UK bond prices are highly correlated with

several European countries, including the core countries, France and Germany. In

particular, we observe strong correlations between the UK and Denmark, reflecting

linkages between these two countries through international trade.

These patterns are less pronounced in the post-crisis periods. For instance, from Table 3

a), we see that correlations between US and Canadian bond prices decrease sharply

following the stock market crash. In the aftermath of the crisis, the US bond market lined

Page 24: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

24

up with the European markets. Yet prior to the crash the majority of the European

countries displayed negative correlations with the US. In fact the countries that depicted

positive correlations in the period of tranquilit y prior to the stock market crash, typically

show negative correlations in the aftermath of the crash. We observe a similar pattern

after the devaluation of the dollar. For a large number of countries showing positive

correlations with the US in the period of “ tranquilit y,” correlations decrease in the

aftermath of the crisis. However during the sterling crisis, we observe that correlations

between UK bond prices and the majority of the European nations remain positive in the

post-crisis period. Indeed the patterns that we observe in the post-crisis period are

sharper. We see the UK is strongly correlated with the core European countries – France

and Germany – as well as with Canada and the US, reflecting the importance of trade-

based channels of transmission.

From Table 3 a), we detect littl e evidence of contagion from the US bond market, in the

period following the stock market crash. Although correlations are seen to increase in the

post-crisis period, none of these increases are seen to be statistically significant. Some of

the increases in correlations may reflect the operation of channels of transmission on both

the capital and current accounts. The rise in correlations between the US and Brazil and

the US and Chile reflects the transmission of instabilit y to Latin America, which was

harshly affected by both the deterioration in the terms of trade and the sharp decline in

capital imports from the core, forcing many Latin American countries to impose

exchange controls and or suspend debt servicing.

Interestingly correlations between Argentina and the US are seen to decline in the crisis

period. This may reflect the early suspension of convertibilit y in Argentina, which halted

the decline in money supply that started a year earlier. Indeed M2 in Argentina and

Uruguay, which had both imposed exchange controls, increased between 1929 and 1930

(Diaz Alejandro), while M2 in the US decreased sharply over the same period. By

contrast, between 1929 and 1930, M2 fell by 4.5% in Brazil (Diaz Alejandro), and by

15% in Chile (Bordo and Schwartz 1996). The suspension of convertibilit y or the

Page 25: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

25

imposition of exchange controls, however, eventually halted the decline in money supply

in these economies as well .

Table 3 b) suggests sharper increases in correlations following the sterling crisis than that

was observed following the crash in 1929. From column 3 of Table 3 b), we observe that

6 of these increases are significant at 10%. However, after correcting for

heteroscedasticity, we find that none of these increases are significant. This suggests that

a large proportion of the increase in correlations that we observe can be attributed to

greater volatilit y in the UK bond market.

From Table 3 c) we observe some evidence of increases in correlations following the

devaluation of the dollar. For instance, the correlations between the US and Finland, as

well as the US and Greece rise sharply. Indeed these increases are significant at 1%.

Moreover, they continue to be significant after we correct for heteroscedasticity. We also

observe smaller increases in correlation between the US and Canada as well as the US

and Chile. These are, however, not significant. Even though we see that correlations

with the US do not increase for many countries, we do observe sharp increases that

suggest that there could have been contagion from the US to Finland and from the US to

Greece. Interestingly, we observe littl e evidence of contagion from the US to the Latin

American countries, even though the devaluation of the dollar sparked another series of

devaluations and crises in these countries.

An interesting finding that emerges from our analysis is that typically the correlations

with the four emerging countries in our sample are low during tranquil periods, but are

often seen to increase sharply in the aftermath of a crisis. For instance prior to the stock

market crash, with the exception of Chile, the correlation between the US and the

emerging countries in our sample are either weak or negative. In the aftermath of the

crash, correlations with Brazil , Chile and Greece increase. We observe a similar pattern

following the sterling and dollar devaluations.

Page 26: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

26

Table 4 summarizes these findings. Typically we observe that the average pre-crisis

correlations with emerging countries are lower than the average pre-crisis correlations

with the advanced countries. Moreover, the average post-crisis correlations with the

emerging countries are greater than the average post-crisis correlations with the advanced

countries following the stock market crash and the dollar devaluation. In each episode

the average increase in correlations with the emerging countries exceeded the average

increase in correlations with the advanced countries. Though this evidence is not

forceful, it is suggestive. The emerging countries were possibly more exposed to shocks

from the center countries.

In summary, we see higher correlations during turbulent periods. However few of these

increases can be verified to be statistically significant. Typically when we observe

increases in correlations, as we do in the aftermath of sterling crisis, these increases wash

out after we correct for heteroscedasticity. There is some evidence that seems to suggest

that disturbances often spread from the core to the periphery, with the emerging countries

depicting sharper increases in correlations on average. We also observe some evidence

of patterns that reflect the importance of trade-based channels of transmission. These

patterns are, however, typically more diff icult to discern in the aftermath of a crisis.

3.3 The Recent Period

Tables 5 a) and 5 b) report the correlations in the periods prior to and after the Mexican

and Thai crises, as well as the post-crisis increases in correlations. While Tables 6 a) and

6 b) report the average pre-crisis and post-crisis correlations with advanced and emerging

countries as a group, as well as the average increases in correlations.

From Table 5 a) we can discern patterns in the pre-crisis period, which, as was the case

for the interwar, suggest the importance of regional li nkages, as well as trade-based

channels of transmission. For instance prior to the crisis, Mexico is strongly correlated

with Canada and displays positive, though slightly weaker correlations, with the US,

Page 27: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

27

which suggests the importance of regional ties. Mexico is also positively correlated with

several of the East Asian countries in our sample, in particular, with Hong Kong. After

the crisis, we observe that several of these correlations increase. In particular,

correlations with Thailand and Portugal increase significantly. The correlation between

Mexico and Denmark also increases significantly, however, the two countries are still

weakly correlated in the post-crisis period. After correcting for heteroscedasticity, we see

that none of the increases in correlations are significant at 5%, though the increase in

correlations between Mexico and Denmark is significant at 10%.

Table 6 a) reveals that on average correlations with advanced countries decreased in the

aftermath of the peso’s devaluation, suggesting that they were largely insulated from the

crisis in Mexico. Correlations with the emerging countries, however, increased sharply,

suggesting that if there was contagion, the emerging countries were more likely affected.

Table 5 b) reveals clear evidence of regional patterns. We observe that prior to the baht

devaluation, Thai interest rates were positively correlated with all the other Asian

countries. The correlations with the other emerging countries were either weak or

negative. Correlations with the advanced countries were in general negative, see Table 6

b). In the aftermath of the crisis, the correlations with several countries rise. Moreover,

there is still strong evidence of regional ties. Correlations with Hong Kong, Indonesia,

Japan, Malaysia, and Singapore are positive in the post-crisis period. Of these, the

correlations between Thailand and Indonesia and Thailand and Malaysia increase in the

turbulent period following the devaluation. This increase may reflect the onset of the

crisis in those countries. However, these increases are very small .

Correlations with the other emerging countries are seen to increase dramatically, see

Tables 5 b) and 6 b). Although none of these increases are significant at 5%, the rise in

correlations with Brazil and Mexico are significant at 10%. After correcting for

heteroscedasticity, we find that the increase in correlations with Brazil remains

significant at 10%.

Page 28: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

28

From Table 6 b) we see that in the post-crisis period, on average, correlations with the

advanced countries increase. However, even after this increase, these correlations remain

weak. An exception is the correlation between Thailand and the US, which remains

significant at 5% even after correcting for heteroscedasticity.

Looking at Table 6 b), we observe that, unlike the interwar, or during the Mexican crisis,

the average increase in correlations with the advanced countries following the Asian

crisis were substantially higher than the average increase in correlations with the

emerging countries. However, even after this increase, post-crisis correlations with the

advanced countries, on average, are still negative. Whereas post-crisis correlations with

the emerging countries, were on average quite high.

In summary, there is some evidence of contagion in the aftermath of the recent Mexican

crisis to Denmark, and in the aftermath of the Thai crisis to Brazil . Correlations between

the US and Thailand are also seen to increase significantly in the aftermath of the crisis.

However, this evidence of contagion is not strong. Though we observe several increases

in correlation, these increases may, to a large extent, be attributed to greater volatilit y in

financial markets.

4. Are Linkages Tighter in General During Turbulent Periods?

Cross-market correlations, whether during periods of turmoil , or periods of relative

tranquilit y, are highly volatile. An analysis based on a comparison of correlations, in two

windows of time, is therefore sensitive to how we demarcate a period of turmoil from a

period of relative stabilit y. Moreover, since crises can spread rapidly across international

borders, it is easy to muddle the effects of contagion from various crises. Our choice of

crisis dates, whether arbitrary, or following from some meaningful scientific

methodology, can thus crucially impact on the eventual conclusions that we draw.

Moreover, though cross-country correlations can be suggestive, such a methodology

cannot account for the complex inter-relationships that exist between countries and

cannot disentangle the effects of a shock in one country on another. That we observe

Page 29: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

29

strong correlations between two countries, or a significant rise in correlations during

crises periods, may be by virtue of a complex chain of transmission and feedback effects

of which we are largely ignorant. Hence a rise in correlations between two markets

suggests but does not necessarily imply transmission from one market to the other.

Given these concerns, in this section we move away from the issue of contagion

stemming from specific countries and from the analysis of bilateral correlations, and

instead we ask the broader question, In general do markets display greater comovement

with each other during periods of volatilit y? Put another way, are turbulent periods more

conducive to the propagation of shocks than periods of greater stabilit y?13

We use principle components analysis to examine the evidence of stronger comovement

across markets during turbulent periods in all three regimes. Principle components

analysis, allows us to shed some light on this issue by, in effect, collapsing the

dimensionality of the data. Principle components analysis, is a statistical technique that

linearly transforms a set of correlated variables into a smaller subset of uncorrelated

variables, in a manner that aims to capture most of the variation in the data. For any

given p variables, it is possible to extract p principle components, assuming that none of

these variables are perfectly correlated with each other. These p principle components

are just an orthogonal li near combination of the original variables spanning the same

space.

The basic statistics that emerge from principle components analysis are the p variances

(latent roots) of the principle components, and the associated p variable weight-vectors

(latent vectors) that serve as the basis for the transformation of the original variables.

The ith latent root, tells us what fraction of the variation in the original data is explained

by the ith principle component, while the sum of the first i latent roots, tells us how much

of the variation is explained by the first i principle components.

13 Bordo and Murshid (1999) use VAR analysis to examine whether comovement was greater following periods of financial instabilit y during the interwar. They find evidence to suggest that cross-market linkages were tighter during these periods.

Page 30: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

30

In order to compare the comovement in tranquil periods with that in turbulent periods, in

Figures 3 a), 3 b) and 3 c) we graph, for all three regimes, the cumulative variation in the

data that is captured by the first i principle components, for i=1,..,p, for both pre-crisis

and post-crisis periods. If there is greater comovement during turbulent periods, then the

graph of the post-crisis variation should be above the graph of the pre-crisis variation.

From Figure 3 a) we can see that there is some evidence of an increase in the

comovement in bond prices across all markets following the Baring crisis, however, there

is littl e evidence of greater comovement following the earlier Argentine crisis. We also

see evidence of excess comovements across markets following the US banking panic in

1893.

There is also evidence of tighter cross-market linkages in turbulent periods during the

interwar. In particular, bond prices are seen to show considerably more comovement in

the aftermath of Britain’s departure from gold in 1931. By contrast the evidence that

bond prices were more strongly correlated following the devaluation of the dollar, is

considerably weaker. Moreover, there is no indication of stronger comovement in bond

prices in the aftermath of the 1929 stock market crash.

For the recent period, the evidence of greater comovement during crisis periods is much

weaker. There is littl e suggestion that the overall extent of comovement was greater

following the Mexican crisis. Moreover, we observe that there was lower comovement

across countries in the aftermath of the devaluation of the baht.

The above analysis provides mixed evidence with regard to the overall extent of

comovement following a crisis. In particular, though we observe evidence that bond

prices were more correlated in the aftermath of a crisis in the pre World War I period and

the interwar, this is not the case for the recent period. This is not an altogether surprising

finding. During the earlier regimes, countries were tightly linked to each other through

the fixed exchange rates of their gold parities, which facilit ated the transmission of

Page 31: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

31

shocks between countries. This needs to be contrasted to the current managed floating

regime based on fiat money, which is arguably less open to macro shocks.14

If some countries are relatively insulated from the fallout emanating from a crisis, then

we would not necessarily expect to observe stronger cross-market ties across all

countries. However, it may be reasonable to expect to observe greater comovement

within various groups or clusters of countries in the post-crisis period.

The analysis in section 3 revealed patterns in cross-country correlations that could serve

to provide a means by which to separate countries into various groups, in particular

regional ties were often seen to be important. Thus we divide the countries into regional

groups and examine the extent of within-group comovement in the pre-crisis and post-

crisis periods. Moreover, one of the stylized facts of the analysis in section 3 above has

been that average correlations with advanced countries decrease in the post-crisis period,

or at least increase to a lesser extent than correlations with emerging countries. This

seems to imply that advanced countries may be more insulated from the impacts of

international shocks than emerging countries and thus suggests that a division along the

lines of emerging and advanced countries may be revealing.

In Figures 4 a) and 4 b) we graph, for the various crises during the interwar and the recent

period, 15 the intra-regional variation in the data that is explained by successively

increasing numbers of principle components. Similarly, in Figures 5 a) and 5 b) we

graph the variation within the group of advanced and emerging countries.

From both Figure 4 and Figure 5, we see that the evidence of stronger comovement

within various groups of countries following the onset of a crisis is mixed. There is some

evidence of stronger cross-market linkages following the sterling and dollar devaluations

during the interwar. This evidence is weaker for recent period. There is, however, some

14 This of course needs to be quali fied by the effects of increasing open capital markets, which offset the insulation properties of floating exchange rates. Also it should be noted that within the rubric of the managed float regime, many of the countries in our sample at various times have pegged their currency to the dollar or other dominant currencies.

Page 32: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

32

indication of an increase in comovement following the devaluation of the peso within the

set of advanced countries as well as within the set of emerging countries.

From Figure 4 a) we observe evidence of a strong increase in the comovement in bond

prices between the European countries following the onset of the sterling devaluation.

Moreover, Figure 5 a) suggests that the extent of comovement between the set of

advanced countries, which includes several European countries in our sample increased

sharply in the aftermath of the sterling crisis. There is somewhat weaker evidence of

stronger comovment between the Latin and North American countries following the

stock market crash of 1929. And there is littl e suggestion of an increase in intra-regional

comovement following the devaluation of the dollar.

For the recent period there is some evidence of stronger linkages following the onset of

the Mexican crisis. In particular, we observe evidence of an increase in comovement

between the set of advanced countries as well as the set of emerging countries. The

evidence of greater comovement within the Latin and North American region is weak.

However, this evidence must be interpreted liberally, since this group consists of only

three countries, namely the US, Canada and Mexico.

Interestingly there is littl e indication that cross-country ties were greater within any

region other than Europe, following the devaluation of the baht. For all other regions,

including the Pacific rim, we observe a decrease in the overall extent of comovement.

This is interesting, since many of Pacific rim nations were affected by the fall out from

the Thai devaluation.

In summary, we find some evidence during the earlier regimes of tighter cross-market

linkages across all markets during periods of turmoil , but littl e evidence of this for the

recent crises. There is some evidence of greater market comovements within groups of

countries during periods of f inancial instabilit y in the interwar. This evidence is much

15 Since our data for prewar era covers only nine countries, we omit the analysis of this period.

Page 33: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

33

weaker for the recent period, though there is a suggestion that cross-market linkages may

have strengthened in the period following the peso’s devaluation.

5 Conclusion

In this essay, we have examined seven particularly severe instances of f inancial

instabilit y, spanning 108 years and three regimes, each significantly distinct from the

other. Yet from each episode, several underlying themes have emerged. We find that

periods of turbulence are typically characterized by higher cross-market correlations.

The volatile nature of f inancial markets means that correlations between markets are

always changing, however, this inherent instabilit y in the correlation coeff icient is not

necessarily a reflection of continuously changing cross-market linkages. Rather these

complex dynamics may be a consequence of the heteroscedastic nature of disturbances

impacting upon these markets. After adjusting for heteroscedasticity, we find that very

few of the increases in correlations can be verified to be statistically significant,

suggesting that the dynamics of the correlation coeff icient reflect greater volatilit y rather

than instabilit y in cross-market relationships. Nevertheless there is some evidence of

isolated cases of contagion between specific countries, during all three regimes that we

have examined.

The volatilit y in the correlation coeff icient blurs the underlying relationships between

markets. Even so, in each episode we have been able to discern regional patterns in

correlations that may suggest the importance of trade-based channels of transmission.

Although during periods of f inancial instabilit y these patterns are occasionally more

diff icult to discern.

Principle components analysis has revealed that the extent of comovement across markets

is often unchanged in the aftermath of a crisis. Given stronger correlations between some

countries, this evidence suggests higher variance in cross-market correlations during

periods of instabilit y. Dividing countries into various regional groups, or along the lines

of advanced and emerging, has, however, suggested some tendency of stronger

Page 34: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

34

comovement within various groups of countries, particularly during the interwar. By

contrast, the evidence of stronger intra-regional or intra-group variation during periods of

instabilit y for the recent period, is far weaker.

In summary, despite some evidence that correlations increase during turbulent periods,

and of stronger intra-regional comovement during the interwar, we have not been able to

establish a strong case for contagion, especially for the recent period. The increases in

correlations that withstand statistical scrutiny are often diff icult to justify on the basis of

traditional channels of transmission. This very small number of significant increases

could support the idea of contagion, or they could merely be spurious. From a

perspective of weeks rather than days, the evidence on contagion is sporadic, and can

only be convincingly identified in a discrete number cases. Yet these are the exceptions

to the rule that have commanded our attention. Our evidence suggests that the emphasis

on contagion in the recent literature is clearly overblown and hence the case for an

international crisis manager or an international lender of last resort to deal with contagion

is not transparent.

Page 35: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

35

References

Baig, Taimur and Ilan Goldfajn (1998), "Financial Market Contagion in the Asian

Crisis," International Monetary Fund Working Paper, WP/98/155.

____________ (1999), "The Russian Default and the Contagion to Brazil ," Prepared for

the ADB/IMF/World Bank conference on “ International Financial

Contagion,” in Washington D.C on February 3-4, 2000.

Batchelor, Roy A (1986),"The Avoidance of Catastrophe: Two Nineteenth Century

Banking Crises," in Forrest Capie and Geoffrey E. Wood (eds.) Financial

Crises and the World Banking System. London: Macmillan, pp41-73.

Bhagwati, Jagdish (1998), “The Capital Myth.” Foreign Affairs 77(3): 77-92.

Bonelli , Franco (1982), "The 1907 Financial Crisis in Italy: A Peculiar Case of Lender of

Last Resort in Action," in Charles P. Kidleberger and Jean Pierre

Laffarugue, (eds.), Financial Crises : Theory History and Policy. New

York: Cambridge University Press, pp. 51-65.

Bordo, Michael D., (1986), "Financial Crises, banking Crises, Stock Market Crashes and

the Money Supply: Some International Evidence, 1870-1933," in Forest

Capie and Geoffrey E. Wood (eds.), Financial Crises and the World

Banking System. London : MacMill an, pp. 190-248.

Bordo, Michael D., and Anna J. Schwartz (1996), “The Operation of the Specie Standard:

Evidence for Core and Peripheral Countries, 1880-1990,” in Jorge Braga

de Macedo, Barry Eichengreen and Jamie Reis (eds.) Currency

Convertibility: The Gold Standard and Beyond. New York: Routledge,

pp. 11-83.

____________ (1998), "Comment on Larry Neal ' The Bank of England's First Return to

Gold and the Stock Market Crash of 1825," Federal Reserve Bank of St.

Louis Review, Vol. 79 (May/June), pp. 77-82.

Bordo, Michael D. and David C. Wheelock (1998), "Price Stabilit y and Financial

Stabilit y: the Historical Record," Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Review, Vol. 80(5), pp. 41-62.

Page 36: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

36

Bordo, Michael D., Michael Duekker and David C. Wheelock (1999), "Inflation Shocks

and Financial Distress: An Historical Analysis." Paper presented at the

EHA Meetings, Baltimore, Maryland.

Bordo, Michael D. and Barry Eichengreen (1999), Is Our Current International Economic

Environment Unusually Crisis Prone?" Reserve Bank of Australia

Conference on Private Capital Flows. Sydney, Australia.

Bordo, Michael D. and Antu P. Murshid (1999), “The International Transmission of

Financial Crises before World War II : Was there Contagion?” Prepared

for the ADB/IMF/World Bank conference on “ International Financial

Contagion,” in Washington D.C on February 3-4, 2000.

Clapham, Sir John (1945), The Bank of England. London: MacMill an.

Diaz Alejandro, Carlos F ( ), “Stories of the 1930s for the 1980s,”

Dornbusch, Rudiger and Jacob A. Frenkel (1984), "The Gold standard and the Bank of

England in the Crisis of 1847," in Michael D. Bordo and Anna J. Schwartz

(eds.), A Retrospective of on the Classical Gold Standard, 1821-1931.

Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 233-271.

Eichengreen, Barry (1992), Golden Fetters; The Gold Standard and the Great

Depression, 1929-1933. New York: Oxford University Press.

__________ (1996), Globalizing Capital:A History of the International Monetary

System. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

__________ (1997), “The Baring Crisis in a Mexican Mirror. Mimeo, University of

Cali fornia, Berkeley.

Eichengreen, Barry and Olivier Jeanne(1998),”Currency Crisis and Unemployment:

Sterling in 1931.” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper

#6563.

Eichengreen, Barry and Douglas Irwin (1998)

Fisher, Robert A. (1915), :"Frequency Distribution of the Values of the Correlation

Coeff icient in Samples from an Indefinitely Large Population,"

Biometrika, Vol. 10(3), pp. 507-521.

Forbes, Rigobon (1998), "No Contagion, Only Interdependence: Measuring Stock Market

Co-Movements," Mimeograph, Massachusetts Institute of Technology.

Page 37: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

37

____________ (1999). "Measuring Contagion: Conceptual and Empirical Issues,"

Prepared for the ADB/IMF/World Bank conference on “ International

Financial Contagion,” in Washington D.C on February 3-4, 2000.

Friedman, Milton and Anna J. Schwartz (1963), A Monetary History of the United States,

1867-1960. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Gayen, A. K. (1951), "The Frequency Distribution of the Product Moment Correlation

Coeff icient in Random Samples of Any Size Drawn from Normal

Universes," Biometrika, Vol. 38(3), pp. 219-247.

Gayer, Arthur D. and Walter W. Rostow and Anna J. Schwartz (1953), The Growth and

Fluctuation of the British Economy, 1790-1850. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

Huffman, Walker E. and James R. Lothian (1984), "The Gold Standard and the

Transmission of Business Cycles, 1833-1932," in Michael D. Bordo and

Anna J. Schwartz (eds.), A Retrospective of on the Classical Gold

Standard, 1821-1931. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Kindlebereger (1986a), Manias, Panics and Crashes: A History of Financial Crises.

Third Edition. New York: John Wiley and Sons.

Kindlebereger (1986a), The World in Depression, 1929-1939. Berkeley: University of

Cali fornia Press.

Levy-Leboyer, Maurice (1982), "central Banking and Foreign Trade: the Anglo-

American Cycle in the 1830s," in Charles P. Kidleberger and Jean Pierre

Laffarugue, eds. Financial Crises : Theory History and Policy. New

York: Cambridge University Press, pp. 66-110.

Malkiel, Burton G. (1996), A Random Walk Down Wall Street. Sixth Edition. New

York: W. W. Norton.

Marichal, Carlos (1989), A Century of Debt Crises in Latin America: From Independence

to Depression, 1870-1930. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Morgenstern, Oskar (1959), International Financial Transactions and Business Cycles.

New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.

Neal, Larry (1990), The Rise of Financial Capitalism: International Capital Markets in

the Age of Reason. New York: Cambridge University Press.

Page 38: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

38

____________ (1998), The Bank of England's First Return to Gold and the Stock Market

Crash of 1825," Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, Vol. 79

(May/June), pp. 53-76.

Rigobon, Roberto, "On the Measurement of the International Propagation of Shocks,

NBER Working Paper No. W7354.

Ruben, Harold (1966), "Some New results on the Distribution of the Sample Correlation

Coeff icient," Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, Vol. 28(3), pp. 513-

525.

Temin, Peter (1969), The Jacksonian Economy. New York: W. W. Norton.

Thorp, Will ard (1926), Business Annals. New York: National Bureau of Economic

Research.

Page 39: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

39

��������� ����� � �� ���� ��� ������� ����� ����� ���� ����������� � "!#%$&''( )*+*,

-�./012 34 .05 .675 89 1: 27; 0227< =>>>?

18

80

18

81

18

82

18

83

USA

18

84

18

85

Arg

entin

aD

enm

ark

Gre

ece

18

86

18

87

Chi

le1

88

81

88

9B

razil

18

90

Arg

entin

aB

razil

18

91

Arg

entin

aB

razil

Can

ada

Ital

yPo

rtu

gal

USA

18

92

USA

18

93

Aus

tral

iaC

anad

aIt

aly

18

94

Ital

yU

SA1

89

51

89

61

89

7B

razil

Den

mar

kSw

eden

18

98

Bra

zilC

anad

aC

hile

Den

mar

k1

89

91

90

0B

razil

Finl

and

Japa

n1

90

1B

razil

Japa

n1

90

21

90

31

90

4Ja

pan

19

05

19

06

19

07

Can

ada

Ital

yJa

pan

Swed

enU

SA1

90

8A

rgen

tina

Can

ada

Ital

yJa

pan

19

09

19

10

19

11

19

12

19

13

19

14

Arg

entin

aB

razil

Can

ada

Den

mar

kFi

nlan

dG

reec

eIt

aly

Nor

way

UK

USA

Page 40: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

40

@A�BCDEFGH GI�JCKL DA EMNOO EPL EQRSIDA MEM%TO DJUVW VUXY EJOZFI�JCKL DA EM%TF[F[ \]^_^

`�abcde fg ach aijh kl dm ejn ceejo ]^^^p

19

19

19

20

Port

ugal

Spai

n

19

21

Can

ada

Den

mar

kFi

nlan

dIt

aly

Japa

nN

eth

Nor

way

19

22

Den

mar

kN

orw

aySp

ain

19

23

Bra

zil

Can

ada

Fran

ceN

eth

Nor

way

Port

ugal

Spai

n

19

24

Bel

gium

19

25

Bel

gium

Chi

le

19

26

Bel

gium

Fran

ce

19

27

Japa

n

19

28

19

29

Arg

entin

aC

anad

a

19

30

Arg

entin

aB

razi

lFr

ance

Ital

yU

SA

19

31

Arg

entin

aB

elgi

umB

razi

lC

anad

aC

hile

Den

mar

kFi

nlan

dFr

ance

Ger

man

yG

ree

ceIt

aly

Japa

nN

orw

ayPo

rtug

alSp

ain

Swed

enU

KU

SA

19

32

Aus

tral

iaFr

ance

Gre

ece

Japa

nPo

rtug

alSw

eden

USA

19

33

Aus

tral

iaSw

itz

USA

19

34

Arg

entin

aB

elgi

umG

erm

any

19

35

Bel

gium

Ital

yN

eth

19

36

Fran

ceIt

aly

Swit

z

19

37

Fran

ce

19

38

Bel

gium

19

39

Bel

gium

Finl

and

Net

hSw

itz

Page 41: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

41

qsrutwvyxyz|{~}|��x�twz�����r��sz����s�������|���s����xr��yz����������¡ 

¢¤£¦¥�§©¨«ª­¬®¨�§°¯©¨�±³²µ´ ¶¸·¹¨�±»º¼£¡¬�½�§¿¾¡ÀÂÁ�ÃwÄÆÅ

ÇÈÊÉËÍÌÎyÏÐ�ÑÒyÓÔyÕ

Ö�×ÙØ Ö�ÚÛØÝÜÖ

Ö®ÞßØ Ö × ØàÜÖ

Ößá�Ø Ö × ØÝÜÖ

ÖáØ Þ Ü ØàÜÖ

Ö Ú Ø Þãâ ØàÜÖ

Ö�äÙØ Þ ÚÛØÝÜÖ

Ö â Ø Þ× ØàÜÖ

åçæyèêéë è ëå

ìí�îàïð îàñì

ì ñ îêïò îÝñì

ïì îêï ï îàñ

ì

ï ï îì í îàñ

ì

ïó î ìð îÝñì

ô�õö÷øùú ø÷û�üøý þõú"ÿ÷�

���������������������������������������������� �����

������ �������

����� �!#"%$'&�()�)* +-,/.�021�3)45.76�89,/.7:<; =>1�?@0

Page 42: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

42

Argentine Crisis, 1890

ACB#D E F9GIH J#H JLK�MNGOHQPSRUT>V%PLWLMYX-ZOM[G�\^]`_babc`d'efPghM#ZOGjibkbG lm\@\n]`_baoc`dqp�rCPIJ[e s t9uIv w9v wUx�y[uIvQzS{U| }U~��bu[tN���I}��b�o�`�'�fz�m�#� �S�9�b�/�b�`�b�o�`�

�C�#� � ���O� �9� ����S�#�j�9 Q¡b¢£�¤�S¥o� ¦C�I�[¢ § ���O� �9� ����S�#�j�9 Q¡b¢£�¤�S¥o� ¨O©bª[«#¬[­L®N¬¯Q©�°�±S«j«#¬#²³­^´�¯¤±S©o®µ·¶#¸U¹�ºf» ¼ ½@¾ ½o¿ ÀqÁ³Âoà À@Á Ä/ÅÆ�ÇoÈnÇbÉnÇ Ê À@Á ÀnÃ Ê ÀqÁ Ànà À@Á À@ÀÆÌË@Í�Î³Ï Ê À@ÁQÂSÐ ÑqÒ Ó`Ô Ñ@Ò Õ@ÕÖh×jØoÙbÚ9Û Ñ@Ò Ñ�Ü ÑqÒ³ÜSÝ Ñ@ÒQÜbÞßáà^â³ãNä å@æ çÌè åqæ é/ç ê å@æQë>ìíî ï ð@ñ òoó ôqõ³ön÷ øqù ú�û/üqüýþ ÿ�� ÿ�� ÿ������ ÿ�� ÿ�

��� ��������� �� ��� ������� � !#"%$&!' (��)�`ÿ*+ ,! - .' �� ��� � /0!' ��1�32�4�56/7 ��98�� �:��)�`ÿ<;9��þ0! /7;1!#"%$&!' �=7>,�:�?)�`ÿ��@*+���'; - A'B&C D�C D E0F'B�C1G3H�I JLK@A�M9G�N&F'BPO J:Q�R�S:T<M9G

U FVA�F#W<N&F'B�XZY,J:Q�R�S[T\+B,F ] ^�B�C D�C DP^�G3B,B F,_�`�MaC�G3b�D \+G�D'M ] ^�B&C D�C DP^�G3B,BcF�_�`�MaC1G3b�D d&b�A'B,F'` DeFPC�bf^�G3BcB,F,_�`?M�C1G3b�D

g B�hiF'b�MaC�bj` T�k�Q�O T�k l�X T�k mLRn�B,`�oLC9_ T�k�QLY ] T�k T�p ] T�k X�m^�`�bj`�Hj` T�k X6T ] T�k X:l ] T�k O�l^6q�C�_�F T�k mLO ] T�k�Q�R ] T�k l�XrsBc`�b�A�F T�k�Q�m ] T�k�Q�R ] T�k m6QUut M�Aeq T�k�Q?R T�k�Q�l ] T�k T�mvPw T�k miQ ] T�k m6Q ] T�k�p3X

xPy{z�|�}�~���}�������� ��� ���:��������+�,� � ����� ��� ���0�'�����3�����i�0������� �:�������{�1��y0� �7�9�#�<�&�'�7�:�3�:�������L���+���'� � ����� ��� � �0�'���1�3�������,�1���&�'���,�[���������9�

� �V���#�<�&�'�7�:�3�:��������+�,� � ����� �,� �P���3�c�,�,��|?���1�3}�� �s����� � ����� �,� �P���3�c�,�,��|?���1�3} � �&}��'�c�e| �e�P�1}f���3�,�,�,��|?���1�3}��

�+���i�'}��a��}j| � ��� �j� � ���  [� � ���  [�z��,� �0�9¡ � ��� ��� ��� �j  ��� ���z��,|�¢L�9� ��� ��  ��� ��� ��� �����|�}j|��j| ����� � ������� � ��� �� �6£������ ������� ��� �[� ��� �L�¤s�c|�}���� ��� ��� ��� �:¥ ��� �L�¦§����£?�'����|�}j��� ��� ��¨ � ��� �?� � ��� ���xP© ��� �j� ��� ¨[� ��� �6��ª

«�¬7­0®�¯ °i± ²³±µ´u¶i·�·�¸j¹3º¼»e½�¶i¾s¿ÁÀ½�»eÃIJŷ Ƨ¸�¾u»e½'¾ÇºÉÈ{·�½�¶�·Ê»Ë¶Êº�¾%ÌŲÎÍL»3¸�·Ê»eÃ%¸ÏÑÐ+Ò6ÓÕÔ%Ö0×ØÔeÙ%ÓÛÚÅÜ Ý§Ó�ÐÛÔeÞ'Ð<Óàß+Ü�Þ&Ò�Þ&Ò�á§â0ãZä�å

æ�çZè0é�ÓÊâiê ë�êìß{Ö�Ü�Ü�Ó�é3ç¼Ô#Þ�ÖiÐ+ÒÁí Þ�ÔeÙîÔeÙ%Óðïfñóò{Ü�Þ�Ö�ÜàÔ3ÖàçLÐ%ôÉÚÎ×�Ô3Ó�ÜàÔeÙ%Ó³ÏÑÐ+Ò[Ó�Ô<Ö0×Ô#Ù%Ó�ë�ç:Ü�Þ'ÐZÝóß+Ü�Þ&Ò�Þ&Ò�á§â0ãZä�å

æ�ç7è0é�ÓÊâiê'ß%êìß{Ö�Ü�Ü�Ó�é3ç¼Ô#Þ�ÖiÐ+ÒÁíÂÞ�ÔeÙõÔeÙ öø÷uùÊú{û�ü�ýiûÊþ3ý ÿ ������� þ3ö�û þ��%ö ��� öÕþfý � ��������������������! #"�$%�'&(�'&*),+!-!.0/

Page 43: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

43

13254*6(7(8�9�2;:=<*>(75?A@'BC9ED FHGJI�KMLONCPQLSR=T*U(P5VAK'NCIEWXJY*I�K[Z[L\I*]!K[I ^ _`KQN W[N WOZ(a5Y*Z(P(_`I�a ^ b5c b�d b5cCdfeXJY*I�K[Z[L\IhgHTQW�V ^ R=K'N W`N WiR=TjK[KkI`lCZ(VmNATjPfW b5c npo b5c o�bXJY*I�K[Z[L\Ihq'P(_`K[I�ZjW�IrNAP;R=TjK[K[I[lCZ(VmNCTjPfW b5c nhs b5cCdjt

X3a5Y*Z(P(_�I�a;R=T*U(P5VAK'NCIEW FHGJI�KMLONCPQLSR=T*U(P5VAK'NCIEWXJY*I�K[Z[L\I*]!K[I ^ _`KQN W[N WOZ(a5Y*Z(P(_`I�a b5cCdvu b5c npoXJY*I�K[Z[L\IhgHTQW�V ^ R=K'N W N WiR=TjK[KkI`lCZ(VmNATjPfW ^ b5c bwn ^ b5c bpuXJY*I�K[Z[L\Ihq'P(_`K[I�ZjW�IrNAP;R=TjK[K[I[lCZ(VmNCTjPfW ^ b5cCdpx ^ b5c n%t

X3a5Y*Z(P _�I�a;R=T*U(P5VAK'NCIEW FHGJI�KMLONCPQLSR=T*U(P5VAK'NCIEWXJY*I�K[Z[L\I*]!K[I ^ _`KQN W[N WOZ(a5Y*Z(P(_`I�a b5cCdfs b5c bpuXJY*I�K[Z[L\IhgHTQW�V ^ R=K'N W`N WiR=TjK[KkI`lCZ(VmNATjPfW b5c oyn b5cCdpxXJY*I�K[Z[L\Ihq'P(_`K[I�ZjW�IrNAP;R=TjK[K[I[lCZ(VmNCTjPfW b5cCdpx b5cCd5d

z|{r}O~f�����h���������%��{(��� ���=�5�=�5�j�����w�\�H�������v���O�v�����*�,�5�������3� ����¡¢��£���¤������O¥¦¨§J©pªp«�¬=­=§¯®�°�±\«�²�³5´w­�µ�ªp«�§¢²·¶�­�¸H­�²�°O¹Hº�»¼­%³*½�´�«r½#®�°�±\«�²·³%´w­hµ�¾�³5´w°=³¨²¿°¨ªp«�§

¦�¹�²j­5³¨²�¶�­À�«Hµ�­�²�°O¹�²�¶�­�¦�³*½,­5«�²�´�«�­®�³%´'µ(´'µ*Á,Â!Ã!ÄÆÅ

Ç ªrÈOÉfÊ�Ë�Ì=Í,Ì�¦�©�Ê%³�ª(½�Ê®�°=³5³=Ê5Éjª�²�Îw°\«Hµ�Í�Ê�²vÏ�ÊOÊv«Ð²·¶�Ê�Ñ|ÒÓª�«�§¢²�¶�Ê�¸�Ê�²�°O¹¦¨§J©pªp«�Ô=Ê=§¯®�°�±\«�²�³5ÎwÊ�µ�ªp«�§¢²·¶�Ê�¸HÊ�²�°O¹Hº�»¼Ê%³*½�Î�«r½#®�°�±\«�²·³%ÎwÊhµ�¾�³5Îw°=³¨²¿°¨ªp«�§

¦�¹p²jÊ%³�²�¶�ÊÀ,«�µÕÊÖ²;°=¹�²�¶�Ê�Í�ªh³5Î�«r½×®H³5Î'µ(Î'µwÁ�Â!ØrÄ�Å

Ç ªrÈOÉfÊ�Ë0Ì�®�Ì�¦�©�Ê5³Õª(½,Ê®�°=³5³=Ê5Éjª�²�Îw°\«Hµ�Í�Ê�²vÏ�ÊOÊv«Ù²�¶�Ê�Ñ�¸Úªp«�§Û²�¶�Ê�¸HÊ�²�°O¹¦¨§J©pªp«�Ô=Ê=§¯®�°�±\«�²�³5ÎwÊ�µ�ªp«�§¢²·¶�Ê�¸HÊ�² °O¹Hº�»¼Ê%³*½�Î�«r½#®�°�±\«�²·³%ÎwÊhµ�¾�³5Îw°=³¨²¿°¨ªp«�§

¦�¹�²jÊ5³¨²�¶�ÊÀ�«Hµ�Ê�²�°O¹�²�¶�Ê�Ñ�¸�Í�ª�«0Ü�Î�«r½#®�³5Î'µyÎ'µ*Á,Â!Ø!Ä0Ý

Page 44: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

44

Þ!ßáà'â�ãÖäå(æ�ãwç`ßhè=ækåjéEêjëhìjí5î%íï æ[ç ð â`æQñ é`ñ é*òOç�æQñAàjówôQõÕòOæ'ñáöfî\÷'ëhìjí5î%í�ßáà�ø�â[ßAàwù'ç�æ�ì(ú*ëhìjívî%í�û ï àQé�ß ð â`æQñ é`ñ éwòOç�æQñCàjówô5øüâ`ßáàwù'ç�æ=îhý*ë�ìjívî%í�ßáà!õ\òOæQñMö�ì(újë�ìjí%þ�ÿ

ï æ[ç ð è=æQñ é`ñ éiè=àjæ[æ[ç[ö åyßmñCà � é ï àQé`ß ð è=æQñ é[ñ éiè=àjækæ[ç[ö åyßMñAà � é � � â�æ[ç�å*é�çiñ � è=àjækæ[ç[ö åyßMñAà � éõ3æ��\ç � ßMñ � å ÿ5ûCì�� ð ÿ5û ÿvý ð ÿ5ûCìjí� ç`ö �Oñ�� ð ÿ5û î�ÿ ð ÿ5û ÿp÷ ÿ5ûCì��� æ[å ��ñMö ð ÿ5û ÿfí ÿ5û ÿ(þ ÿ5ûCì¿îè=å � åfóvå ÿ5û þÕì ð ÿ5û ÿ(þ ð ÿ5û þ��èÕê%ñáöCç ÿ5û ÿfí ÿ5û þ5þ ÿ5û î����ç � Jåfæ`ã ð ÿ5û î�ÿ ÿ5ûCìv÷ ÿ5û þ�÷� ñ � ö å � ó ÿ5û �hì ð ÿ5û î=ì ð ÿ5û ÷jî� æ[å � â�ç ð ÿ5û ÿfí ð ÿ5ûCì¿î ð ÿ5û ÿ(þ������������� � �! "$# � �! �&% �! �(') �+*-,-�/.10�*�324.(56� �! ��# � �! 7"98 � �! #:"���;�/��<=� � �! >?� �! �?" �! >@"A ,-�CB � � �! �(' �! �(' �! 7"��D�EGFHE�I J!K7L�J J!K J�M N J!K J?LOQP=RTS(P�U3VTE�I(W�X N J!K7L(Y N J!K Z�[ N J!K J&\]H^1_�`(_/a b!c b�d b!c b�d b!c b!b]H^feg7h+_�i3jTk�a(` b!c7l m n b!c7l!l n b!c o�p

]qg-_�i3jea3rts:i3e u=e uwv�l9d+m@lx i;_ n y�i6e u=e u zH_�i3e{9`�|6}~k�i�y/��o&b9v�l9d�m@l�g-{�]H_ zqg_����6_�i�l!l3v�l d+m@l�c x {3u�g n y�i6e u=e u zH_�i3e{9`�| ]H_ zqg-_����6_�i�l�� v�l9d+m@lfg{�}~k�i=y���l!l3v�l d+mCo

x i�_ n s:i3e u=e u�s:{9i�i�_�j7k�gwe7{9a�u x {3u=g n s:i3e u�e u�s:{9i;i�_�jTkCg�e{9a�u �6a�y=i�_�k9u/_�ea�s:{9i�i�_�jTkCgwe7{9a�u�fi�r4_�a!g�ea k b!c b�m n b!c b�o n b+c b(�� _=j rHe��� b!c b!� b!cT� d b!c ��l?�+�� i�k h?e�j b!c7l�b b!c �+b b!c p+b@�s:k�a(k�`(k b!c b!� b!c �+b b!c p�o��s@�+e-j7_ n b!c b�o b!c p+b b!c p�o����_�a���k�i=� b!c o+d b!c p!� b+cTl��� ea+jTk�a(` b!c o:l b!c7l�� n b+c b(p� i�k�a�y�_ b!c7l!l b!cT��m b!c ��o��+���_�i���k�a�� b!c m:� b!c pCm b+c b����i;_/_�y=_ b!c b&� b!c m!m b+c o4��$g-kCj � b!c p@� b!c ��o b c b(�� kGzHk�a b!c o+d n b!c b(� n b+c m��� _=gT�(_�i3jTk�a(`�u n b!c b�o b!c7l m b+cTl��]H^1_�`(_/a n b!c7l�p b!c o+d b!c pCmH�]H^feg7h+_�i3jTk�a(` b!c b�� b!c o+d b+c o�m� a+e-g-_/`1]�gkCg_�u n b!c b?l b!c o4� b+c o4�

�� q¡H¢�£¥¤�¦�§¨¦ª©¬«:­!­:£!¢9 �®/¯�«4°�±³²´¯!®�µ¶®/µ�£¸·¬¹»º�­!¯�«:­»®$«» �°�¼½§¥¾?® ¿!À»Á/Â�¿ÄÃ�Á$Å�Æ+ÇÉÈËÊ?À�Ç�¿ÌÁÍ�À&Ê:Î�Â�ÏÑÐ&Ò�Ó�Ò

Ô�Ê�ÕHÖ�¿¥×�Ø4ÙQØÚͬÅ4À+À:¿(Ö9ÊÛÁ/Ü�Å4Ý1ÎßÞàÜ!Á/¶Á�Â�¿¸á�âäã�À!Ü�Å:À»Á$Å»Ê�Ý�å æ¥ç?Á9¿!À»Á/Â�¿ÄÃ�Á$¿+À(Ö�Ü�Ý�èäÍ1À!Ü6ÎCÜ6Î ÏÐ@Ò�×fÐ

Page 45: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

45

é�ê�ë-ëTì�í:é�î=ï ì(ë7ð�ìCñ�òê9ó9ô�õ9ö+÷+÷

ø í î ù ú�í6ò û=ò û üHî�í3òê9ý�þ3ÿ4üHí3ò�ë?õ�� ô&õ9ö+÷!÷�ñ-ê���ú�ñ-ê��6î/í��6ô�õ9ö+÷+÷� ø ê3û�ñ ù ú=í3ò û=ò û üHî�í3òê9ý�þ��ú�ñê��6î�í�õ ÷�ô�õ9ö+÷!÷�ñêqÿ4üHí3ò�ë��6ô&õ9ö+÷��ø í�î ù �:í3ò û=ò û �:ê9í�í�î�ë7ì�ñwò7ê9ó�û ø ê3û�ñ ù �:í3ò û=ò û��:ê9í�í�î�ëTìCñ�òê9ó�û �6ó�ú=í�î�ì9û/î�òó��:ê9í�í�î�ëTìCñwò7ê9ó�û

ÿ�í��4î�ó!ñwò7ó(ì ��� ��� �� �� ù �� ��÷� î�ë �Hò-ð�� ��� ÷�� ù �� �� ù �� ���� í�ì��?ò-ë ��� ÷�� �� ��� ù � � � ��:ì�ó(ì�ý(ì ���Tõ!� �� ��� ��7õ!���"!ò�ëTî ù ���Tõ!õ �� �� ��7õ#�é�î�ó!�fì�í%$ ��� �� ��Tõ ö ù �� � �& òó+ëTì�ó(ý ù ��� � � �� ��� �� ��ö('�'& í;ì�ó�ú=î ��� �� �� ��õ ù �� ��)�î�í%�fì�ó+* ù ���Tõ ÷ ù ��Tõ�÷ �� ��)�í�î�î�ú�î ù ��� �C÷ �� ÷+÷ ��,�!� '�'�6ñ-ì(ë * ��� ��� �� �� ù �� ��- ì üqì�ó ��� ��� �� �?÷ ù ��7õ9ö. î=ñ/"Cî�í3ë7ì�ó(ý�û ��� �� �� ��� ù �� ���021 î�ý(î�ó ��� � � �� ÷#� �� ��021�ò-ñ3�+î�í3ë7ì�ó(ý ù ��� ��� ù �� ��� ù ��7õ ÷4 ó+òñ-î�ý�5�ò7ó6�4ý(ê7� ��� ��� ù �� ��õ ù �� ���

8:9<;2=�>@?BADC�AECGFIHHI>=J9�KDL�FNMPORQSLK+TUKDTV>XWGY[Z\HL�FIH[K]F[9�MV^`_@aKJ>H[KDTV>cbS>Bd�9=�e�9�KDL�FNMfF2agKDTV>bhFN=i=J9 H!jlk�mn?o?

Page 46: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

46

October 1929 Stock market crash

pPqr�s�t!uiv%q�wIx�y�tz,{6|}v�~ ����v%{��2|}t6��wIx�y!tz,{6|}v�~p�r�v {�s���v��P{�v � wI{7| ~i| ~ wIxJ{�{�vi�/s!z�|}xJt�~ ��� ���2��� � ��� �!����p�r�vD{�si�Nv��Px6~%z � wI{6| ~i| ~�wIxJ{�{�v��3s�z�|}xJt�~ � �� �� �!� �� �����!�p�r�v%{�s��Nv �7t!ui{�v%sJ~%v<|}t�wIxJ{�{�v��/s!z�|/xJt�~ � �� ���6��� ��/��!��

� z v { �,|/t6�:�\vir�s��}y�s�z�|/xJtJ� �������

pPqr�s�t!uiv%q�wIx�y!tz}{6|}v�~ ����v%{��2|}t6��wIx�y!tz,{6|}v�~p�r�v%{�s��Nv���{�v � wI{6| ~i| ~�wIxJ{�{�v��3s�z�|}xJt�~ ��3�!���#� �� �#�� �p�r�v%{�s���v��Px6~%z � wI{6| ~i| ~ wIxJ{�{�v��/s!z�|/xJt�~ �� �����#� �� ������p�r�vD{�si�Nv��7t!u%{�v%s�~Dv |/t�wIxJ{�{�v��3s�z�|}xJt�~ �� ������ �� � ����

�\x��,�3s!{I�\vir�s#�/y!s�z�|}xJtJ� �J�����pPqr�s�t!uiv%q�wIx�y�tz,{6|}v�~ �P��v%{��2|}t6��wIx�y�tz,{6|}v�~

p�r�v%{�s���v��P{�v � wI{7| ~i| ~ wIxJ{�{�vi�/s!z�|}xJt�~ ��� � ����� ��� ��!��p�r�vD{�si�Nv��Px6~%z � wI{6| ~i| ~�wIxJ{�{�v��3s�z�|}xJt�~ ���3������ ���3�]�<��p�r�v%{�s��Nv �7t!ui{�v%sJ~%v<|}t�wIxJ{�{�v��/s!z�|/xJt�~ � ��3�J�(��� ���3������

�:�<�2 �¡£¢¥¤§¦¥¤R¨�¡�©���ªl¡¬«\­I©©2¡# J�n®D¯�­�°P±³²¥¡�®#´l¡I¡°µ®D¶V¡X·G¸E�°V¹º®D¶V¡¥¸P¡�®V­2»¼¤[¹�¨��°V½N¡2¹«\­�¾N°³®+©�¯�¡ ±g�°¿¹h®D¶V¡¥¸�¡B®V­2»PÀcÁ¡©�ªV¯%°(ªÃ«\­�¾N°³®D© ¯�¡ ±cÄ\©¯�­I©[®J­Å��°V¹@¤@»�®J¡�©Å®D¶V¡¥¸�®J­o½�Æ

Ç � ©�Æ¿¡�®G«�©��I±!¶BÈlÉ�Ê�Ë�Ê

�:�<�2 �¡£¢@²�¦¥¤R¨�¡�©���ªl¡¬«\­I©©I¡ J�n®+¯�­N°P±³²¥¡�®#´c¡2¡°µ®D¶V¡X·�ÌÍ�°V¹º®D¶V¡¥¸P¡�®V­2»¼¤[¹�¨��°V½N¡2¹«G­�¾�°³®D©¯�¡�±g��°V¹º®D¶V¡¥¸P¡B®V­2»PÀcÁf¡�©�ª¿¯%°<ªÃ«\­�¾N°G®D©¯�¡�±cÄ\©¯�­I©Å®J­Å�°V¹`¤@»®J¡©[®D¶V¡

ÎS¡B¨�� �¾���®D¯�­N°f­2»V¸�®J¡©# �¯%°<ªPÈlÉ�Ê�Ï�É

�:�<�2 �¡£¢E«V¦Ð¤R¨�¡�©��!ª�¡¬«\­I©©I¡ J��®D¯�­N°P±³²g¡B®#´c¡2¡#°U®+¶V¡X·³¸E��°V¹h®+¶V¡¥¸P¡B®V­2»¼¤[¹�¨���°V½I¡I¹«G­�¾�°³®D©¯�¡�±g��°V¹º®D¶V¡¥¸P¡B®V­2»PÀcÁf¡�©�ª¿¯%°<ªÃ«\­�¾N°G®D©¯�¡�±cÄ\©¯�­I© ®J­Å�°V¹`¤@»®J¡©[®D¶V¡

ÎS¡o¨��� �¾��n®+¯�­N°f­2»g®D¶V¡cÎS­N i J�©!ÈlÉ�Ê�ÏoÏ

Page 47: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

47

ÑPÒ�ÓDÔ�ÕIÖ6× Ói× Ó�Ø�Ù\Ò+ÚiÒ�ÛVÜ7Ò%Ö�ÝJÞ!Ø�ÝJÞÞß

ÑPÖ�Ò à ÕIÖ6× Ói× Ó ÕIÔJÖ�Ö�Ò�á/â!ã�×/ÔJä�Ó ÑPÔ6Ó%ã à ÕIÖ7× Ói× Ó ÕIÔJÖ�Ö�Òiá/â!ã�×}ÔJä�Ó å7ä!Ú%Ö�Ò%â�ÓDÒ�Ó<×}ä�ÕIÔJÖ�Ö�Ò�á3â�ã�×}ÔJä�Óæ�ç Ó%ã,Ö�â�á,×/â èé ê#Þ è�é èë à èé ê�ÝÕIâ!ä#â!ì#â èé ß Ý è�é ê�í à èé èëÙGÒDä!Û�â!Ö%î à è�é êê è�é èë èé ß ÝïðPÖ�â!ä!ÚiÒ à è�é3Ý#ñ è�é íIÝ è é êIòó ÒDÖiÛ�â!ä+ô à è�é3Ý�ê à èé/ÝÝ èé è�íõ�öJ÷6ø\ù¼öJ÷6ø úû ü�ú ý�þ ÿ�� ����������� ��������� � ��� ��� ��� ��� ��� ����! #"$ &% '�(�)�* + ,�- ,!. / ,�- 0�1243�56387�9�:�3 ;�<�=?> ;�<6=A@ B ;�< ;C=DFE�GIHKJMLON�P Q�R Q!S Q�R T�U V�W X�YOZ�Z[]\�^`_Oa8b$c�dMe f g�h iCg f g�h jlk g�h g�mnpo�q�rKs6q&t�u v w�x w�y w�x y�w w�x y�yOz�z{}| ~ ���6��� ~ ��� ��� ��������}��� ������� � ��� ��� � ��� �C�

�������C�l�`� ��� �K���!��� ��� ��¡�� ¢�£�£$¤¥F�M¦ § �l�`� ��� �]�l¨��M�M¦M���&©ª��¨���� ¥F¨`�«© § �l�`� ��� �]�l¨��M�M¦M�6��©ª��¨���� ¬�­&®�¯M°«±�²³°�²µ´�­·¶l¸�¯M¯M°M¹�±&ºª´�¸�­�²

»�¼ ²«º½¯M±�¹½´�± ¾ ¿�À Á�Á ¾ ¿�À ¿� ¿�À�Ã?ÄÅÇÆMÈÊÉCË½Ì Í Î�Ï Ð Ñ Î�Ï�Ò�Ó Î�Ï Ñ ÒCÔÕ È&Ö�È&×�È Í Î�Ï ØCÙ Í Î�Ï Î!Ó Î�Ï ØÚÒÛÝܳÞ&ß�à&á«â ã ä�å æ�ç ã ä�å ä�è ä�å é!êë�ì�í�î6ï&í�ð ñ ò�ó ò�ô ñ ò�ó ò!õ ñ ò�ó ò�öëF÷Mï&í&ø�ù ñ ò�ó úCû ñ ò�ó6ü&ý ò�ó þ!ýÿ���������� � �� ��� � �� ��� � �� ���ÿ���������� � �� ��� �� ���� �� ���� � �"!$# � �"! �� �%� �� ��&� � �� �(') ��* � ����+�,-� �� ��.� �� ��� �� �/')&0 ��1 � �� 2��� �� ��� �� �%�3 �546��� � �� 2�/� �� ���� �� ���7 ��1 �8�+�,-� �� 9�9 �� 9:� �� ���;=<8>:?2@�A B C�D2E�C C�D F�G C�D H�GJIKML�?ONO? PQPR?�S�<�T C�D�E�E B C�D C�U B C�D2E�VKWAYX[Z]\�^`_�N C�D C�U B C�D C�V B C�D C�ab ?�S"^`_8P6AYX�< C�D FcU C�D C.G B C�D2E�Vb P6_�?-S B C�D2E�E B C�D C�a C�D C�UdJeMf�g�f�h i j�k2l&m i j�k j�n j�k j.odJeWpOq2r�f�s"t�u.h�g j�k j%l i j�k2l�v i j�k2l%wxzy i j�k j�{ j�k j%l j�k j/vx d/| i j�k n�o j�k�l}n j�k {.mR~/~

���R�6�.������� ���`���(���Y�����Q�`����������������� �Q¡`�£¢$���Q�`�¤�Y�=�%�¦¥�§�¨/�Y���=���©�«ª¬�®­/�/�.¯z����Q�`�°�6¨±�²©³µ´¶³c·:¸�¹«º:»®»½¼

¾�¿ À6Á.Â�Ã£Ä ÅÇÆ$È(É�É(Â�ÁYÊ�ËÌQÈ`ÍWÎ�Ï�Ì�Ë�ÐÒÑ�Ð�ÊcÌ�ÁYÊ/Í©Ó�Ô$É�ÌQÈ(É=ËYÈ=Ê%Í©Ó�Õ�Ö%Ë&Â�ɤËЩ«׬®Ø/Ê/Á.ÙzÊ�Ë�ÌQÈ:ÍÚÈ(ÖÛ�Ü©Ý Þ ß%ÜàÛ8áãâ:äåäàæ

Page 48: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

48

çWè�é�ê�ë(ì"í é�í é]î.ï$èð�è�ñ©òóè�ì ôYõ�î�ôYõ�õ%ö

÷Wø�ùQú.û�ü�ý�øÿþ����.û�����-ý� �� ���������������������������� "!����$#$�%�'&(�$� ) ���*� �+� �,���-�$�.�+/0#��1���-�2� 354 3�687�3 ) 354 3�6:92; �!<�=�.#+�:�'&(���� ) ���� �+� �>���-�$�$�$/?#@�����-�2� 354 3�683A; 3�4 B8;�C'7 "!����$#$�:�8D*��E+�$��#-���F���G���-�$�$�$/0#��1�0�-�2� ) 3�4 353'H�I 3�4 B'7J9-B

KML #A�J���� �+� ��N2O'�A/ P"B8�AQ-N89-C5C�H

(Q�!<#2��E+��QG���������������� �( "�=�1������R���������������� "!����$#$�:�8&(�$� ) ���� �$� �,���-�.�$�$/?#@�����-�2� ) 3�409-CAB:I 3�4 357ASJI �!<���$#+�:�'&(���� ) ���� �+� �,���-�$�$�$/?#@�1�0�-�2� ) 3�4 3<B8S53 3�4?9<6TS@6 "!����$#$�:�'D��E+�$��#��=�,�0�G���-�$�.�+/0#��1���-�2� 3�4?9�IJH�I 3�4 3�;�C�H

UWVFX�Y2Z\[^]`_a]cb'Z�d'V@efZhgji:d5d�ZAY-Vlk=m<i:nporqsZtk@ufZ�Z�nwvxZ5yMm<z�i{VJn}|~k=��Zs�pZtk�i���]�|"bTVJn}z�Z�|�j���%�r�=���<�'�^�T�����=���s�(�t�����(�����5���}���F�������:�j�=���<�'�������<���{�-�{�J�������J�-�����=� �

 ¡�M¢T�T£2�>�l�=�<�%�¤���^�=���R�s�'�'�'¥f¦'§M§�¨

©W�Fª�£2�\«�¬�­s�c¢'�5�'�@�f�h����������£-�l�®�<�:�(�r¬s�>�A¯�������©����J��£-�J�����J�����=���s�(�>���������"¢T�J��° ����j���%�r�=���<�'�^�T�����=���s�(�t�����(�����5���}���F�������:�j�=���<�'�������<���{�-�{�J�������J�-�����=���

 ¡�t¢T�J£2�>���=�<�:�����^�=����¬f�8�r��¥f¦'§M§j±

Page 49: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

49

²®³0´�µ�¶ · ¸�¹A¸�º+¶ »®¼2½+¸�¶ ´?¾-¿À´?³ · ´�¶ · ¸�¹2· ¹�¶ »®¼$Á�´�¶ ´�Â�´ ÃĶ Å�³�¼0Æ�Ç�ÈJ¶ »®¼.²®· ³?É�¶�¹Ê+Ë Ì Í=Î?Ì Ï$Ð Ñ-Ò�Ó�ÔÏÓ�Í=Ñ Í�Õ Ö ×1ØË Ù$Ñ Í�Õ Ì Í=Ñ-Ò®Ë Ì Ö Ì Ö Ú+Û0Ü�ÝÀÞ

ßà á âã ä åæ ç èé ê ëì í îï ð ñò ó ôõ ö ÷ø ù úû

û ü ý þ ÿ � � ���� ��� �� ��� � ��� � ��� ���� ����� �� ��� ���� � � � �� �

!"#$% &'&( ) "!% "$% &'* +,- "%'./

0�1 2 3 4�1 5 6 5 67�8 9 : ; <�= > 9 > 9

?A@�B�C�D E F�GHF�IJD KALNMJFOD B�PRQ�B�@ E B�D E F�GNE GSD KALUTVB�D BXW�B YZD [�@�L�\X]�^_D KAL`?AE @�a�D�GbJc d egf�d hUi jRk�l�mnhnl�egj e�o p q�rUs�c d e�tukAc d p d p vJw�x�y�z

{

{ | }

{ | ~

{ | �

{ | �

{ | �

{ | �

{ | �

{ | �

{ | �

}

} ~ � � � � � ���� ��� � ��� ����� � ��� � ��� ����� ����� ��� ��� ����� � � � ��� �

� �����  ¡ ¢ £��� ���  ¡¤ ¥¦§ �� ¡¨©

ª�« ¬ ­ ®�« ¯ ° ¯ °ª�± ° ² ­ ®�« ¯ ° ¯ °

³gc�s�f�o d l�e´l�µUo ¶AjV·JlOo s�iZ¸�s�c d s�o d l�eNd eSo ¶AjU¹Vs�o sXk�s hZo º�c�j�»Rr�¼_o ¶Aj`³Ad c�p�o�e½J¾ ¿ ÀgÁ ¿ ÂUà ÄZÅJÆ�Ç`ÂnÆ�ÀgÄ À�È É ÊUËJÌXÍUÎ À�Ï�¿ À�ÐuÅA¾ ¿ É ¿ É ÑJÒ�Ó�Ô�Õ

Ö

Ö × Ø

Ö × Ù

Ö × Ú

Ö × Û

Ö × Ü

Ö × Ý

Ö × Þ

Ö × ß

Ö × à

Ø

Ø Ù Ú Û Ü Ý Þ ß àá�â ãgä å æ�ç è�é�æ ê ë�ì ê í�î å�ï�ç ã�í�ç ë�å ë�ð ñ�ò�å ð ó ê ë�å ô

õ ö÷øùú ûüûý þ÷öú ÷ùú ûüÿ ��� ÷ú ü��

��� � �� � � ��� � �� � �

��������������� �!�#"$��� % &('*),+-),+/.1032!4657+98 : ;=<?>,@->,@A;$B�CDBFE G?CDG*HJIK>LHNM6BOH3P!Q$<*>SROG @�TURV<�B7@?@�TXWYW[Z]\^<?_3G�I`@SabQ$<�G c dfe�gVhjikml^npo

Page 50: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

50

qsr�tvuxw y zv{Vzx|Yw }s~j�Yz�w t�����t�r y txw y zv{jy {*w }s~��-txw t��Lt ��w �xr�~����x�1w }s~`qsy r���w�{�Y� � ����� ��� ���L�x�����v��� �L� � �� s� ��� � � �x¡V¢£�¥¤�¦�� §�¦x� � �v��¨Y© ª�«s©

¬¬ ­ ®¬ ­ ¯¬ ­ °¬ ­ ±¬ ­ ²¬ ­ ³¬ ­ ´¬ ­ µ¬ ­ ¶®

® ¯ ° ± ² ³ ´ µ ¶ ® ¬ ® ® ® ¯ ® ° ® ± ® ² ® ³ ® ´·�¸ ¹Lº » ¼¥½ ¾�¿�¼ À Á� À Ã�Ä »�Åv½ ¹xÃx½ Á�» Á�Æ ÇvÈ¥» Æ É À Á�» Ê

Ë ÌÍÎÏÐ ÑÒÑÓ Ô ÍÌÐ ÍÏÐ ÑÒÕ Ö×Ø ÍÐ ÒÙÚ

Û�Ü Ý Þ ß�Ü à á à áÛ�â á ã Þ ß�Ü à á à á

äs��¦v�x� � �v�V�xåY� æs�jçY��� ¦���è�¦�� � ¦x� � �v�j� �*� æs��¢-¦x� ¦��L¦ ��� §x����é�êxë1� æs�`äs� �������ìYí î ï�ð î ñ�ò ó�ôLõxö�ñ�õvï�ó ïL÷ ø ù�ús÷ õ�ð ûjü^ý�í ûsóx÷Yôsí�ý�ø þ¥ÿ��������

�� � � � � � �� � �� � � � �� � �� � �� � �

� � � � � � � � � � ���� ��� � ��� ����� � �! � "!# �%$&� ��"�� �!� �!' (&)�� ' * � �!� +

, -./01 2324 5 .-1 .01 236 789 .1 3:;

<�= > ? @!= A B A B<�C B D ? @!= A B A B

EGF%HJILKLMONQPLRJPTSUKLM V WXKYF[Z\F[Z^]`_bacSedfZfg V WXKhF[ZiF[ZTWUdLjkdmlnMYjkMh_ogpF�_qRedr_bacSUKhFtsuMnZwvxsyKLdzZYZwv {�{}|�~��Y���������X���o���Y���U~��

���!���&� � �&�y����� ���\����� �!� �%�!� � ��� � �&��� �Y� ���¢¡\��� ��£�� ¤ � ¥����!¦�§�¨©� �����ª� ��«����¬�� � �ª� � ¤¢� ��£���­�¤®�&�ª� ��� « ¯�¡\��� � ����¡y��°���� ¥%��� � �&�%±�²�³%´�´

µµ ¶ ·µ ¶ ¸µ ¶ ¹µ ¶ ºµ ¶ »µ ¶ ¼µ ¶ ½µ ¶ ¾µ ¶ ¿·

· ¸ ¹ º » ¼ ½ ¾ ¿ · µ · · · ¸ · ¹ · º · » · ¼ · ½À�Á Â�Ã Ä Å�Æ Ç�È!Å É Ê!Ë É Ì�Í Ä%Î�Æ Â&Ì�Æ Ê!Ä Ê�Ï Ð&Ñ�Ä Ï Ò É Ê!Ä Ó

Ô ÕÖ×ØÙ ÚÛÚÜ Ý ÖÕÙ ÖØÙ ÚÛÞ ßàá ÖÙ Ûâã

ä�å æ ç è!å é ê é êä�ë ê ì ç è!å é ê é ê

Page 51: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

51

íbî%ïñðuòôóOõQöp÷GöùøUòôó ú ÷}òhî[û\î[û^ü©ýbþÿø��zû�� ú ���������� ��� ������������������� �� �"!����$#��%'&(#)�* +,'&.-/-10324�,56�7�8:9<;=�*#������

>@?BADCFE G HFI)HDJ/E K@L�M/HNE ABOQPRAB? G ASE G HFITG I�E K@LVU�ASE A:W�A XQE YD?ZLB[:\S]4E K@L8>^G ?`_ZEaIb/c d e^f`d gVh ikj�lDmngnlFe^i e�o p qSbniBp`lQrsiRt uBh vRuSo d lFeRw/x`ySyRz

{

{ | }

{ | ~

{ | �

{ | �

{ | �

{ | �

{ | �

{ | �

{ | �

}

} ~ � � � � � � � } { } } } ~ } � } � } ��a� ��� � �D� �`�B� � �B� � �Z� �R�Z� �F�S� �B� �Z� �F�S� � � � �B� �

� �����  ¡ ¢ £��� ���  ¡¤ ¥¦§ �� ¡¨©

ª`« ¬ ­ ®B« ¯ ° ¯ °ª`± ° ² ­ ®B« ¯ ° ¯ °

³@cBuDfFo d lFe)lD´/o µ@i�¶/lNo uBhQ·RuBc d uSo d lFeTd e�o µ@iVr�uSo u:j�u gQo vDcZiB¸:¹Sº4o µ@i8³^d c`pZoae»/¼ ½ ¾^¿`½ ÀVÁ ÂkÃ�ÄDÅnÀnÄF¾^ ¾�Æ Ç ÈVÉ^ÊNËB½RÌsÂRÍ ËBÁ ÎRËSÆ ½ ÄF¾RÏ/Ð`ÑSÑ�Ò

Ó

Ó Ô Õ

Ó Ô Ö

Ó Ô ×

Ó Ô Ø

Ó Ô Ù

Ó Ô Ú

Ó Ô Û

Ó Ô Ü

Ó Ô Ý

Õ

Õ Ö × Ø Ù Ú Û Ü Ý Õ Ó Õ Õ Õ Ö Õ × Õ Ø Õ Ù Õ Ú Õ Û Õ Ü Õ Ý Ö Ó Ö Õ Ö Ö Ö ×Þaß à�á â ãDä å`æBã ç èBé ç êZë âRìZä àFêSä èBâ èZí îFïSâ í ð ç èBâ ñ

ò óôõö÷ øùøú ûôó÷ ôö÷ øùü ýþÿ ô÷ ù��

��� � � ��� ��� � � ���

Page 52: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

52

�������� � ��������� ��������� �� "!#��� � ��� � ����� �$� ���&%'��� �)(*� +,� -��.��/)0�12� ���3 �� ��4.�5�6�� � �7��� +& �"(*��89+9���7� �*� 4 :#;�� �5� <�=>��� <�����(�����4 �@? ACBCA

DD E FD E GD E HD E ID E JD E KD E LD E MD E NF

F G H I JO5P Q*R S TCU V�W.T X Y�Z X [�\ S#]�U Q�[�U Y�S Y�^ _�`CS ^ a X Y�S b

c defgh ijik l edh egh ijm nop eh jqr

s�t u v w�t x y x ys�z y { v w�t x y x y

�������� � ��������� ��������� �� "!#��� � ��� � ����� �$� ���&%'��� �)(*� +,� -��.��/)0�12� ���3 �� ��4.�5�6�� � �7��� +& �"(*��89+9���7� �*� 4 :#;�� �5� <�=>��� <�����(�����4 �@? ACBCA

DD E FD E GD E HD E ID E JD E KD E LD E MD E NF

F G H I J K L M N F D F FO5P Q*R S TCU V�W.T X Y�Z X [�\ S#]�U Q�[�U Y�S Y�^ _�`CS ^ a X Y�S b

c defgh ijik l edh egh ijm nop eh jqr

s�t u v w�t x y x ys�z y { v w�t x y x y

�������� � ��������� ��������� �� "!#��� � ��� � ����� �$� ���&%'��� �)(*� +,� -��.��/)0�12� ���3 �� ��4.�5�6�� � �7��� +& �"(*��89+9���7� �*� 4 :5;�� ��� � ��|�%}�C~��� -#��� � ���#��? A#��?

DD E FD E GD E HD E ID E JD E KD E LD E MD E NF

F G H I JO5P Q*R S TCU V�W.T X Y�Z X [�\ S#]�U Q�[�U Y�S Y�^ _�`CS ^ a X Y�S b

c defgh ijik l edh egh ijm nop eh jqr

s�t u v w�t x y x ys�z y { v w�t x y x y

���#�����������>��������� � ���$���}�����2����������� �  ¢¡$£�¤'£�¤� ¦¥¨§©¥«ª­¬$§©¬�®°¯±£*®³²�¥¨®�´�µ�¡$£·¶�¬>¤°²¹¸»º�¬·¼½£·¥¨®¿¾�À·®°¯"¬Á¡¿Â�Ã>¡

Ä�Å�Æ�Ç�È É Ê�Ë�Ê�Ì�È Í�Î�Ï�Ê�È Æ�Ð"Ñ#Æ�Å É Æ�È É Ê�Ë�É Ë$È Í�Î&Ò'Æ�È Æ)Ó*Æ Ô,È Õ�Å.Î�Ö)×�Ø2È Í�Î3Ä�É Å�Ù.È5ËÚ�Å É Ë7Ç�É Ô&Ð Î"Ó*Ê�Û9Ô9Ê�Ë7Î Ë*È Ù Ü5Ý�È Î�Å Ð É Ë�Þ�Ò}ÎCß�Æ�Ð Õ#Æ�È É Ê�Ë#à�á â#ã�á

ää å æä å çä å èä å éä å êä å ëä å ìä å íä å îæ

æ ç è é ê ë ì í î æ ä æ æï5ð ñ*ò ó ôCõ ö�÷.ô ø ù�ú ø û�ü ó#ý�õ ñ�û�õ ù�ó ù�þ ÿ��Có þ � ø ù�ó �

� ���� �� �� �� �� ��� � ���

��� � � ��� � � � ���� � � � ��� � � � �

�! #"%$'&( )&+*-,/.102"%3547698:0;$=<> ?A@1B1CED7F

G!H#I%J'K(H)K+L-M/C1B2I%N5O7P9F:B;J=Q>H

?A@1B1CED7F

Page 53: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

53

RTS�U�VXW Y Z�[\ZX]^W _T`ba^ZcW U�dEefU�S Y UXW Y Z�[bY [:W _T`hgiUXW Ukj'U lmW nXSo`�pkqXr)W _T`sRTY S�toWu[v^S Y [%V Y lhd `mj^ZXwslxZ�[%` ['W t yzgiZXd d U�S^g{`f| U�d nfUXW Y Z�[f}^~��f�z�

�� � �� � �� � �� � �� � �� � �� � �� � �� � ��

� � � � ��u� �'� � �z� ���o� � ��� � ��� �f��� �X�X� ��� ��� ���z� � � � ��� �

  ¡¢£¤¥ ¦§¦¨ © ¢¡¥ ¢¤¥ ¦§ª «¬­ ¢¥ §®¯

°�± ² ³ ´�± µ ¶ µ ¶°�· ¶ ¸ ³ ´�± µ ¶ µ ¶

RTS�U�VXW Y Z�[\ZX]^W _T`ba^ZcW U�dEefU�S Y UXW Y Z�[bY [:W _T`hgiUXW Ukj'U lmW nXSo`�pkqXr)W _T`sRTY S�toWu[v^S Y [%V Y lhd `mj^ZXwslxZ�[%` ['W t yzgiZXd d U�S^g{`f| U�d nfUXW Y Z�[f}^~��f�z�

�� � �� � �� � �� � �� � �� � �� � �� � �� � ��

� � � � � � � � � � � � ��u� �'� � �z� ���o� � ��� � ��� �f��� �X�X� ��� ��� ���z� � � � ��� �

  ¡¢£¤¥ ¦§¦¨ © ¢¡¥ ¢¤¥ ¦§ª «¬­ ¢¥ §®¯

°�± ² ³ ´�± µ ¶ µ ¶°�· ¶ ¸ ³ ´�± µ ¶ µ ¶

¹+ºf»½¼1¾1¿ÁÀÃÂ>ÄÅÂÁÆǾ1¿ È Éʾ:ºÌË{ºÌËÎÍ)Ï+Ð-ÆÒÑÃËÔÓ È ÉÕ¾:ºÌËiºÌËÁÉÖÑØ×9ÑÚÙÛ¿:×9¿\ÏÜÓݺ'Ï/ÞÒÑØÏ+Ð-ÆǾ:º=ß1¿>ËÜÞ#àâáÅ¿=»ãº=ÑØÏåäÊæ=ÏÜÓE¿;¾åçÇÍ>¾

è Í#Ó%º'Ï(Í)Ï+Ð-é/Ñ1¾2Ó%ê5Ä7×9¿:¾;º=ß>Í

ëA¼1¾1ÑEì7¿

Page 54: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

54

íTî�ï�ðXñ ò ó�ô\óXõ^ñ öT÷bø^ócñ ï�ùEúfï�î ò ïXñ ò ó�ôbò ô:ñ öT÷hûiïXñ ïkü'ï ýmñ þXîo÷�ÿ����)ñ öT÷síTò î��oñuô�^î ò ô%ð ò ýhù ÷Eü'ó��xýxó�ô%÷ ô'ñ � ��x÷� óEû{÷���ï�ù þfïzñ ò ó�ô ��������

�� � �� � �� � �� � �� � �� � �� � �� � �� � ��

� � � � � � ���� "! # $�% &�'($ ) *+ ) ,- #./% �,�% *# *0 1/2�# 0 3 ) *# 4

5 6789: ;<;= > 76: 79: ;<? @AB 7: <CD

E�F G H IF J K J KE�L K M H IF J K J K

íTî�ï�ðXñ ò ó�ô\óXõ^ñ öT÷bø^ócñ ï�ùEúfï�î ò ïXñ ò ó�ôbò ô:ñ öT÷hûiïXñ ïkü'ï ýmñ þXîo÷�ÿ����)ñ öT÷síTò î��oñuô�^î ò ô%ð ò ýhù ÷Eü'ó��xýxó�ô%÷ ô'ñ � ��x÷� óEû{÷���ï�ù þfïzñ ò ó�ô ��������

�� � �� � �� � �� � �� � �� � �� � �� � �� � ��

� � ���� "! # $�% &�'($ ) *+ ) ,- #./% �,�% *# *0 1/2�# 0 3 ) *# 4

5 6789: ;<;= > 76: 79: ;<? @AB 7: <CD

E�F G H IF J K J KE�L K M H IF J K J K

NPOQSRUTUVXWZY\[]YX^_TUV ` abTcOedfOedhgjiPkl^nmZdpo ` aqTcOedrOedXasm\tumwvxVctuVyizo{O"i|[nm\iPkl^_TcO~}UV�dz[�����V~Q�O~m\i�����VU}UVyizo�^nV�TcO~m�k

íTî�ï�ðXñ ò ó�ô\óXõ^ñ öT÷bø^ócñ ï�ùEúfï�î ò ïXñ ò ó�ôbò ô:ñ öT÷hûiïXñ ïkü'ï ýmñ þXîo÷�ÿ����)ñ öT÷síTò î��oñuô�^î ò ô%ð ò ýhù ÷Eü'ó��xýxó�ô%÷ ô'ñ � ��x÷� óEû{÷���ï�ù þfïzñ ò ó�ô ��������

�� � �� � �� � �� � �� � �� � �� � �� � �� � ��

� � � � ���� "! # $�% &�'($ ) *+ ) ,- #./% �,�% *# *0 1/2�# 0 3 ) *# 4

5 6789: ;<;= > 76: 79: ;<? @AB 7: <CD

E�F G H IF J K J KE�L K M H IF J K J K

�]�Z�y�����~�S����� �]�����"���j�P�l�|�U�����  ¡�u¢c���~���

£¥¤ �U�§¦¡¢

Page 55: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

55

¨ª©«/¬�­ ® ¯/°y¯�±�­ ²ª³µ´�¯¶­ «�·§¸«�© ® «�­ ® ¯/°µ® °c­ ²ª³�¹r«�­ «�º"« »¼­ ½�©(³¾�¿�Àj­ ²ª³Á¨ª® ©�Â(­�°

à © ® °�¬�® »�· ³§º"¯�Ä�»�¯/°�³ °"­  Å�´�²¶«®¹f³Æ «· ½«�­ ® ¯/°jÇ È�È�É

ÊÊ Ë ÌÊ Ë ÍÊ Ë ÎÊ Ë ÏÊ Ë ÐÊ Ë ÑÊ Ë ÒÊ Ë ÓÊ Ë ÔÌ

Ì Í Î Ï Ð Ñ Ò ÓÕ�Ö ×"Ø Ù Ú�Û Ü�Ý(Ú Þ ßà Þ áâ Ùã/Û ×�á�Û ßÙ ßä å/æ�Ù ä ç Þ ßÙ è

é êëìíî ïðïñ ò ëêî ëíî ïðó ôõö ëî ð÷ø

ù�ú û ü ýú þ ÿ þ ÿù�� ÿ � ü ýú þ ÿ þ ÿ

¨ª©«/¬�­ ® ¯/°y¯�±�­ ²ª³µ´�¯¶­ «�·§¸«�© ® «�­ ® ¯/°µ® °c­ ²ª³�¹r«�­ «�º"« »¼­ ½�©(³¾�¿�Àj­ ²ª³Á¨ª® ©�Â(­�°Ã © ® °�¬�® »�· ³§º"¯�Ä�»�¯/°�³ °"­  Å�´�²¶«®¹f³Æ «· ½«�­ ® ¯/°jÇ È�È�É

ÊÊ Ë ÌÊ Ë ÍÊ Ë ÎÊ Ë ÏÊ Ë ÐÊ Ë ÑÊ Ë ÒÊ Ë ÓÊ Ë ÔÌ

Ì Í Î ÏÕ�Ö ×"Ø Ù Ú�Û Ü�Ý(Ú Þ ßà Þ áâ Ùã/Û ×�á�Û ßÙ ßä å/æ�Ù ä ç Þ ßÙ è

é êëìíî ïðïñ ò ëêî ëíî ïðó ôõö ëî ð÷ø

ù�ú û ü ýú þ ÿ þ ÿù�� ÿ � ü ýú þ ÿ þ ÿ

���������� ����������� � ������������ ��!"�$#��&% � �'����(�����)#�*+#-,.��*+�/�0%1�2�3�$#���!"����54��6�0�87:9;�5�<�5#��>=?9;��4��/�0%@�$�A��5#8!

¨ª©«/¬�­ ® ¯/°y¯�±�­ ²ª³µ´�¯¶­ «�·§¸«�© ® «�­ ® ¯/°µ® °c­ ²ª³�¹r«�­ «�º"« »¼­ ½�©(³¾�¿�Àj­ ²ª³Á¨ª® ©�Â(­�°Ã © ® °�¬�® »�· ³§º"¯�Ä�»�¯/°�³ °"­  Å�´�²¶«®¹f³Æ «· ½«�­ ® ¯/°jÇ È�È�É

ÊÊ Ë ÌÊ Ë ÍÊ Ë ÎÊ Ë ÏÊ Ë ÐÊ Ë ÑÊ Ë ÒÊ Ë ÓÊ Ë ÔÌ

Ì Í Î Ï Ð Ñ Ò Ó Ô Ì Ê Ì ÌÕ�Ö ×"Ø Ù Ú�Û Ü�Ý(Ú Þ ßà Þ áâ Ùã/Û ×�á�Û ßÙ ßä å/æ�Ù ä ç Þ ßÙ è

é êëìíî ïðïñ ò ëêî ëíî ïðó ôõö ëî ð÷ø

ù�ú û ü ýú þ ÿ þ ÿù�� ÿ � ü ýú þ ÿ þ ÿ

����4/�CBD�549E�F* G��8%H�2�I� ��!"J3#�K%HLNMO*+��A�546�

PQ���#SRO�

Page 56: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

56

TVUXWZY\[ ] ^Z_/^\`F[ aVbdcF^e[ W�fSg�W�U ] W\[ ] ^Z_d] _�[ aVbCh(W\[ Wji2W kl[ m\UnbXojp\q [ aVbrTV] U�sn[t_

u U ] _HY ] kCf bSi2^\vDkD^Z_Hb _2[ s wtxV[ ^tY ydz6WXU yVb\[FiVUXWXs a {F|�}\~�}

�� � �� � �� � �� � �� � �� � �� � �� � �� � ��

� � � � � � � � � � � � � � � � ��t� �2� � ��� ���n� � �X� � �X� ���Z� �\�\� �X� �X� �Z��� � � � �X� �

�  ¡¢£¤ ¥¦¥§ ¨ ¡ ¤ ¡£¤ ¥¦© ª«¬ ¡¤ ¦­®

¯�° ± ² ³X° ´ µ ´ µ¯�¶ µ · ² ³X° ´ µ ´ µ

TVUXWZY\[ ] ^Z_/^\`F[ aVbdcF^e[ W�fSg�W�U ] W\[ ] ^Z_d] _�[ aVbCh(W\[ Wji2W kl[ m\UnbXojp\q [ aVbrTV] U�sn[t_u U ] _HY�] kCf bSi2^\vDkD^Z_Hb _2[ s w�xV[ ^tY ydz6WXU yVbZ[FiVUXWXs a | }�~�}

�� � �� � �� � �� � �� � �� � �� � �� � �� � ��

� � � ��t� �2� � ��� ���n� � �X� � �X� ���Z� �\�\� �X� �X� �Z��� � � � �X� �

�  ¡¢£¤ ¥¦¥§ ¨ ¡ ¤ ¡£¤ ¥¦© ª«¬ ¡¤ ¦­®

¯�° ± ² ³X° ´ µ ´ µ¯�¶ µ · ² ³X° ´ µ ´ µ

TVUXWZY\[ ] ^Z_/^\`F[ aVbdcF^e[ W�fSg�W�U ] W\[ ] ^Z_d] _�[ aVbCh(W\[ Wji2W kl[ m\UnbXojp\q [ aVbrTV] U�sn[t_u U ] _HY�] kCf bSi2^\vDkD^Z_Hb _2[ s wtxV[ b�U f ] _\¸/h�b�¹�W�f m�W\[ ] ^Z_ {F| }�ºV|

�� � �� � �� � �� � �� � �� � �� � �� � �� � ��

� � � � � � � � � � � � � � � � ��t� �2� � ��� ���n� � �X� � �X� ���Z� �\�\� �X� �X� �Z��� � � � �X� �

�  ¡¢£¤ ¥¦¥§ ¨ ¡ ¤ ¡£¤ ¥¦© ª«¬ ¡¤ ¦­®

¯�° ± ² ³X° ´ µ ´ µ¯�¶ µ · ² ³X° ´ µ ´ µ

»½¼�¾¿�À�ÁQÂKÃ.Ä;ÃÆÅ�À�Á Ç È'À�¼�É(¼�ÉEÊ Ë<Ì;Å$Í�É&Î Ç È�ÀA¼�É(¼�É�È�Í�ÏÐÍ-Ñ.ÁAÏÐÁ�Ë0Î1¼2Ë3Ò$Í�Ë<Ì;Å�À�¼5Ó�Á.É0Ò8ÔÕÄNÌÖÑ×Ê Ë<Ó�Á�ÌØÊ×Ë�Ì�ÙÚÏÐÁAÀj¾<¼2ËÛ¾È�Í8¿�Ë0ÎVÀA¼5Á6É5Ü?ÝdË0ÎSÁ�ÀßÞ�Ê6À

àVáXâZã\ä å æZç/æ\èFä éVêdëFæeä â�ìSí�â�á å â\ä å æZçdå ç�ä éVêCî(â\ä âjï2â ðlä ñ\ánêXòjó\ô ä éVêràVå á�õnätçöFá å çHã�å ðCì êSï2æ\÷DðDæZçHê ç2ä õ øtùVä ê�á ì å ç\ú/î�ê�û�â�ì ñ�â\ä å æZç�üFý þ�ÿVý

�� � �� � �� � �� � �� � �� � �� � �� � � � �

� � � �� � ��� � ��� ����� � ��� � ��� � �!� �"�"� ��� ��# $!%�� # & � ��� '

( )*+,- ./.0 1 *)- *,- ./2 345 *- /67

8�9 : ; <�9 = > = >8�? > @ ; <�9 = > = >

ÄNÌÖÑ×Ê×Ë�Ó�Á Ì ÙÚÏ+Á�Àj¾�¼2Ë&¾

ÄNÌÖÑ×Ê×Ë�Ó�Á Ì

ÙÚÏ+Á�Àj¾�¼2Ë&¾

Page 57: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

57

ACB�D!E"F G H!IJH"KLF MCNPOLHQF D�RTS D�B G D"F G H!IPG IUF MCNWVXD"F DZY�D [\F ]"B�N�^Z_"`aF MCNbACG B�c�F IdLB G IeE G [WR N\YLH"fb[gH!IeN I�F c h�VXH"R R D�BLViN j D�R ] D"F G H!I kLl�m n�n

oo p qo p ro p so p to p uo p vo p wo p xo p yq

q r s t u v w x y q o q q q r q sz { |�} ~ ��� ����� � ��� � ��� ~ �!� |"�"� ��~ ��� �!��~ � � � ��~ �

� ����� ���� � ��� ��� ��� ��� �� ���

���   ¡ ¢�� £ ¤ £ ¤��¥ ¤ ¦ ¡ ¢�� £ ¤ £ ¤

ACB�D!E"F G H!IJH"KLF MCNPOLHQF D�RTS D�B G D"F G H!IPG IUF MCNWVXD"F DZY�D [\F ]"B�N�^Z_"`aF MCNbACG B�c�F IdLB G IeE G [WR N\YLH"fb[gH!IeN I�F c h�VXH"R R D�BLViN j D�R ] D"F G H!I kLl�m n�n

oo p qo p ro p so p to p uo p vo p wo p xo p yq

q r s tz { |�} ~ ��� ����� � ��� � ��� ~ �!� |"�"� ��~ ��� �!��~ � � � ��~ �

� ����� ���� � ��� ��� ��� ��� �� ���

���   ¡ ¢�� £ ¤ £ ¤��¥ ¤ ¦ ¡ ¢�� £ ¤ £ ¤

§©¨ ª¬«®­®¯±°³²µ´¶²¸·¹­®¯ º »¼­U¨¾½X¨¾½À¿aÁö·ÅÄƽÈÇ º »É­Ê¨¾½X¨¾½Ë»¹Ä®ÌÍÄÏε¯ÊÌͯUÁÐÇѨ�ÁÓÒÅÄÔÁö·¹­U¨ÖÕÔ¯µ½ÐÒØ×Ù´ÚÂÛÎÜ¿aÁÃÕ®¯®ÂÝ¿ÜÁÞÂËßàÌͯʭZªÃ¨�Á᪻¹ÄØ«ÔÁÐÇC­Ê¨Ö¯â½ÖãåäPÁÐÇT¯U­ç湿â­

´ÚÂÛÎÜ¿ÜÁÞÕÔ¯è ßàÌé¯U­ZªÞ¨�ÁȪ

Page 58: Are Financial Crises Becoming Increasingly More ...econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo/contagion.pdfof sovereign debt for nine countries, we focus on two crises from the pre-World War I era

58

êLë�ì�í î ï ð"ñÊð"ò\î ó�ôJõgðeî ì�öÖ÷Cì�ë�ï ìQî ï ð"ñiï ñaî óLôgøJìQî ìPùLì úÖî û"ë!ô"üPý þÔî óLô¾êLï ë�ÿ�îQñ

����� ����� � � ����������������� � ������������������ !��� � ���!"�#�$�$&%

'

( ) *

+ , -

. / 0

1 2 3

4 5 6

7 8 9

: ; <

= > ?

@ A B

C

C D E F G H I JK�L M�N O P!Q R�STP U V�W U X�Y O�ZTQ M!X!Q V�O VT[ \�]�O [ ^ U V�O _

` abcde fgfhibae bde fgj klm be gno

p�q r s t�q u vw�x y z { |T} ~

�&���T��� � �T������� �&������� �����!��� � ��� � �T��� ��� �&������� ����� ��� ������������� �&���&� ���������� �  �¡ � ¢�£ ¤�¥�¦�§¢¦T �¤  �¨ © ª!�¤�© ¦�«¬¤®­�¯�£ °!¯®¨ � ¦T !±�²�³�³�´

µ

¶ · ¸

¹ º »

¼ ½ ¾

¿ À Á

 à Ä

Å Æ Ç

È É Ê

Ë Ì Í

Î Ï Ð

Ñ

Ñ Ò Ó Ô Õ Ö ×Ø�Ù Ú�Û Ü Ý®Þ ß�à�Ý á â�ã á ä�å Ü!æTÞ Ú�ä�Þ â�Ü â�ç èTé®Ü ç ê á â�Ü ë

ì íîïðñ òóòô õîíñ îðñ òóö ÷øù îñ óúû

ü�ý þ ÿ ��ý � � � ���� � � � � � � � �

�������� � ��������� ��������� �� "!#��� � ��� � ����� �$� ���&%'��� �)(*� +,� -��.��/)0�12� ���3 �� ��4.�5�6�7 8 9;:�8 <&= >"?*@�AB<B@�9;> 9*C D E&F;G�H�8#IJ>#K H�= L#HMC 8 @�92N OMO�P

QR S TU V WX Y Z[ \ ]^ _ `a b cd e fg h ij k lm

m n o p q r s t l m j m m m nu5v w*x y zM{ |�}.z ~ ��� ~ ��� y#��{ w���{ ��y ��� ���My � � ~ ��y �

� ����� ���� � ��� ��� ��� ��� �� ���

��� � � ��� � � � ���  � ¡ � ��� � � � �

¢¤£#¥§¦©¨©ª¬«®­°¯±­³²´¨©ª µ ¶¸·$¹»ºJ¹»º½¼2¾¤¿ÁÀÃÂĺÆÅ Ç ÈÊÉ$Ë»Ì'˻̳ÈÎÍ°ÏÐÍÒÑÔÓ$ÏÐÓ�Õ×ÖØË*ÕÚÙÃÍ°Õ¤ÛÁÜ´É$ËÞÝ©ÓßÌ×ÙáàãâäÛåÑçæ2դݰÓèÛäæ2Õ¤ÛêéëÏÐÓ$É)ì¤Ë*ÕÆìíÎîáïñð×ò;ó$ôÞõÔö)÷ùøúõèû°õ$ðÎòùüÃõ$ó$ôÞîáý

þ�ÿ������ � ������� �� ������ ��������ÿ � ��� � ����� ��� �� ������ ����� ��� �ÿ! �"�#�$%� �� 3þ�� ÿ�&!�'�(�ÿ � �)��� ��� �����*+�+���) ��� & ,��)�������- �. ��� ��/� � ���%0 1/1�2

3

3 4 5

3 4 6

3 4 7

3 4 8

3 4 9

3 4 :

3 4 ;

3 4 <

3 4 =

5

5 6 7 8 9 : ; < = 5 3 5 5>'? @�A B C/D E�F!C G H�I G J�K B�L�D @�J�D H�B H�M N�O/B M P G H�B Q

R STUVW XYXZ [TSW TVW XY\ ]^_ TW Y`a

b�c d e f�c g h g hb�i h j e f�c g h g h

k ýmlonçð¤û°õèý prqÐõ$ó�s¤ô*ðts

k ýmlonçð¤û°õèý

prqÐõ$ó�s¤ô*ðts