US Climate Change Policy Options

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/11/2019 US Climate Change Policy Options

    1/26

    0

    US Climate Change Policy Approaches

    Author: Charles Laffiteau

  • 8/11/2019 US Climate Change Policy Options

    2/26

    1

    Introduction

    The Obama administrations environmental policy team, as well as members of the US

    Congress and their staff, need to urgently consider implementing new climate change policies

    and making changes to existing climate change policies like those favoring biofuels.

    Although some skeptics remain, most political leaders agree that climate change, which

    most scientists agree is due to man-made carbon emissions from the burning of fossil fuels, is a

    global environmental problem which will eventually require the worlds nations to negotiate with

    one another in order to implement regulatory policies that will reduce the rising levels of CO2in

    the earths atmosphere. Yet almost two decades of intense international negotiations have still

    not produced any effective global climate change agreements.

    There are a range of issues which make a deal difficult including the complexity of the

    issues at play and the growing economic weight and carbon emissions of large developing

    countries such as Brazil, Russia, India and China. But the nations with the largest per capita

    carbon emissions are the United States (US) and its fellow members of the Organization for

    Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), so no global agreement will be reached until

    the US and other OECD nations take the lead in carbon emission reductions. However the US

    Congress remains deeply divided on the appropriate policy responses and the existing policy

    literature does not explain why US policies have diverged from those of other OECD countries.

    Much like the discovery of the health risks associated with ozone depletion, large scale

    climate change due to man-made CO2emissions only emerged as an international environmental

    concern within the past thirty years. Antonio Cassese explains that; Before, the problem was not

    felt, for three main reasons. First, industrial developments had not spawned pollution and

    damage to the environment on a very large scale. Second, States still took a traditional approach

    to their international dealings: they looked upon them as relations between sovereign entities,

    each pursuing its self-interest..and unmindful of general or community amenities. Third,

    public opinion was not yet sensitive to the potential dangers of industrial and military

    developments to a healthy (global) environment.1

    But the initial reluctance of the US and other developed countries to take effective action

    with respect to environmental issues is what led to the formation and growth of environmental

    non-governmental organizations (NGOs), to lobby public officials in national governments, as

    1Antonio CasseseInternational Law (Oxford UK: Oxford University Press, 2001): 375

  • 8/11/2019 US Climate Change Policy Options

    3/26

    2

    well as policy makers within international institutions, for policies that are environmentally

    sensitive. Indeed, environmental NGOs were initially successful pressuring the US and other

    OECD nations to sign an international agreement to deal with governance of the global issue of

    ozone depletion. Environmental NGO Friends of the Earth U.K. ran an aggressive campaign

    through 1987, culminating in a boycott threat against twenty specific CFC-aerosol products.2

    The environmental NGOs then followed up on this success by pushing for another international

    treaty designed to govern man-made CO2emissions at the United Nations Conference on

    Environment and Development (UNCED), aka the 1992 Earth Summit, in Rio de Janeiro.

    The successful negotiation of the ozone treaty was also due, at least in part, to the success

    of the World Trade Organization (WTO) in reducing international trade barriers during the latter

    half of the 20th

    century. Jan Aart Scholte notes that, thanks to economic globalization and the

    effectiveness of the WTO as an institution of global governance increasing trade and economic

    ties between the worlds nations, we have also developed some potentials for global governance

    of environmental matters. In this respect the ozone regime established through the 1985 Vienna

    Convention and the 1987 Montreal Protocol has proved particularly successful.3

    At the 1992 Earth Summit in Rio de Janeiro, it was environmental NGOs who galvanized

    public opinion worldwide, thus putting pressure on the worlds political leaders. Donald Kettle

    writes; These organizations are powerful engines for organizing and driving policy change, and

    their influence has been impressive. At the 1992 Earth Summit in Rio de Janeiro, they raised

    public pressure for governments to commit to reducing greenhouse gases.4

    These treaty negotiations culminated in the development of the 1997 Kyoto Protocol, an

    international treaty designed to deal with the threat of catastrophic climate change caused by

    man-made CO2emissions. The resulting United Nations Framework Convention on Climate

    Change (UNFCCC) became the worlds first international environmental treaty specifically

    designed to achieve stabilization of greenhouse gas (GHG) concentrations in the atmosphere at

    a level that would prevent dangerous anthropogenic interference with the climate system. Such a

    level should be achieved within a time-frame sufficient to allow ecosystems to adapt naturally to

    climate change, to ensure that food production is not threatened and to enable economic

    2Edward Parson Protecting the Ozone Layer in Peter Haas, Robert Keohane and Marc Levy(eds.)Institutions for the Earth:Sources of Effective International EnvironmentalProtection(Cambridge MA: MIT Press): 433Jan Aart Scholte. Globalization. A critical introduction, (New York: St. Martins Press, 2000): 2124Donald Kettl. The Transformation of Governance: Globalization, Devolution, and the Role of Government Public

    Administration Review, (Vol. 60, No. 6, 2000): 491

  • 8/11/2019 US Climate Change Policy Options

    4/26

    3

    development to proceed in a sustainable manner.5It should also be noted that the CO2 emissions

    regulated by the Kyoto Protocol, were in addition to the chlorofluorocarbon (CFC) GHG

    emissions nations had previously agreed to reduce under the terms of the Montreal Protocol.

    Although a safe or acceptable level of global temperature increase has never been

    established, the general consensus of climate scientists both then and now was that an average

    global temperature rise of more than 1.5-2

    C would cause substantial damage to ecosystems

    around the world. Nicholas Stern also notes that; because many greenhouse gases, including

    carbon dioxide (CO2), stay in the atmosphere for more than a century and the effects on climate

    come through with a lag, temperature and sea level will continue to rise during the twenty-

    second century, even if we stabilise emissions soon. Most of the damaging consequences of

    climate change are associated with water in some shape or form, including droughts, floods,

    storms, and sea level rise.6Given the fact that scientists could demonstrate that the world had

    already experienced close to a 0.7C rise in global temperatures, the overall objective of the

    Kyoto Protocol was to reduce four types of GHG emissions (of which CO2was by far the largest

    contributor) 5.2 per cent from their 1990 benchmark levels by the year 2012. Many climate

    scientists as well as environmentalists also hoped that a 5.2 per cent reduction in GHG emissions

    would represent the first step to deal with climate change that would lead to further reductions in

    GHG emissions, thus preventing the world from warming more than the 1.5-2C that most

    scientists believed would damage local ecosystems around the world. John Grace writes that

    effective CO2reduction policies are urgently needed because, At best, a 5.2% reduction would

    merely mark the start of a large-scale and long-running set of international negotiations aimed at

    stabilizing the atmospheric greenhouse gas content. In principle, to bring the carbon cycle back

    to equilibrium the world needs to reduce its emissions to match the natural sink strength.7

    Since the worlds wealthier, more industrialized nations like the US also bore the

    responsibility for emitting the majority of the atmospheres existing CO2gases, it was also

    agreed that these nations would agree to take the lead in reducing their GHG emissions and agree

    to meet specific GHG emission reduction targets. Paul Harris writes that this agreement was

    based on the international legal principle of Common but Differentiated Responsibility. As

    5United Nations. Article 2. The United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change. (1997)6Nicholas Stern What is the Economics of Climate Change? World Economics(Vol. 7, No. 2, 2006): 27John Grace Presidential Address: Understanding and Managing the Global Carbon Cycle Journal of Ecology, (Vol. 92, No. 2,2004):197

  • 8/11/2019 US Climate Change Policy Options

    5/26

    4

    such Harris says that; while all countries must join in efforts to reduce emissions of greenhouse

    gases that contribute to climate change, the developed countries are required by the Climate

    Convention to take the lead.8Furthermore, the economic development needs of developing

    countries necessitated some increase in GHG emissions and their historical GHG emissions, as

    well as their per capita GHG emissions, were also much lower than those of more industrialized

    countries. Therefore, in contrast to the GHG emissions reductions mandated for the US and the

    other industrialized nations of the OECD, developing countries like Brazil, Russia, India and

    China were allowed to wait to set their own GHG emissions reduction targets in conjunction

    with negotiations for a 2012 successor treaty to the Kyoto Protocol.

    However, since China, India and Brazil were among the worlds largest emitters of GHG

    gases but were not required to set reduction targets, the then newly elected US President,

    Republican George Bush (the US at the time was also the OECDs largest GHG emitter),

    subsequently refused to agree to the Kyoto Protocols 7% GHG emission reduction target for the

    US even though the US at the time was the worlds largest GHG emitter.9

    The US President and

    US Senates subsequent refusal to ratify the Kyoto Protocol underscores the fact that, in contrast

    to the political challenge of dealing with atmospheric ozone depletion, the political complexity of

    the problem of climate change (caused primarily by fossil fuel CO2emissions) poses a profound

    challenge to contemporary forms of both national and international political governance.

    Effectively dealing with climate change will also entail the use of new environmental

    policy instruments (NEPI) and different types of economic decision making criteria by

    governments, as well as the inclusion of non-state actors like businesses and third sector

    organizations in the policy making process with the objective of achieving environmental

    outcomes that are both economical and sustainable. The complexity of the network of potential

    stakeholders in any decision and the absence of a set of prior decisions and policies in this area

    has also meant that initial policy-making was quite varied in its outputs. Since the US is the

    worlds largest emitter of CO2that is why the Obama administrations environmental policy

    team, as well as members of the US Congress and their staff, need to urgently consider

    implementing new policies and making changes to the USs existing GHG emissions policies.

    8Paul Harris Common But Differentiated Responsibility: The Kyoto Protocol and United States Policy New York UniversityEnvironmental Law Journal(Vol. 7, 1999):309Diana M. Liverman. Conventions of climate change: constructions of danger and the dispossession of the atmosphere Journalof Historical Geography(Vol. 35, 2009): 291-192

  • 8/11/2019 US Climate Change Policy Options

    6/26

    5

    Overview of Current US Climate Change Policies

    Over the past thirty years the US has implemented some policies designed to mitigate the

    negative effects of GHG emissions. Following is a brief summary of the direct regulation and

    other types of policies that are currently being utilized to address the issue of climate change.

    Direct Regulation

    Restrictions followed by a ban on the production of CFCs that lead to ozone depletion

    and an increase of global GHG emissions.

    Increasing fuel economy standards for cars & trucks.

    Regulations mandating the percentage of ethanol mixed in gasoline.

    EPA regulation of air pollution standards and the types of gasoline mixtures required for

    all of the USs major urban regions.

    EPA regulation of pollutants (i.e. soot and nitrous oxides that lead to acid rain) produced

    by US factories and electricity providers.

    Government Grants, Subsidies and Import Tariffs

    Subsidies for US corn farmers and ethanol producers to encourage the production and use

    of low CO2emissions ethanol made from corn.

    Import tariffs on ethanol made from less energy intensive sources such as sugar cane.

    Subsidies to encourage the development of alternative sources of non-CO2emitting

    energy sources (i.e. solar panels & wind turbines).

    Subsidies for mass transit systems in various urban areas throughout the US.

    Grants for research on carbon sequestration (i.e. clean coal), hydrogen fuel cells & other

    types of clean energy technologies.

    But of all of these climate change related policies, the most prominent public policy

    specifically designed to reduce CO2 emissions in the US as well as many other OECD nations is

    encouraging the production and use of ethanol and other biofuels made from agricultural corn,

    soybeans, palm oil, rapeseed, and sugar cane. US government support for the production and use

    of biofuels has included direct regulation by mandating the percentage of ethanol mixed in

    gasoline as well as government subsidies for US corn farmers and import tariffs to protect US

    ethanol producers. However, in a world with almost one billion undernourished inhabitants, is

    the use of food crops and agricultural land to provide the raw materials for biofuels also the best

    use of scarce arable land and water resources?

  • 8/11/2019 US Climate Change Policy Options

    7/26

    6

    Although the concept of turning food crops into atmosphere friendly biofuels such as

    ethanol initially appeared to have some positive effect on reducing CO2emissions, many climate

    scientists have now concluded that increasing the production of biofuels is more harmful to the

    earths atmosphere than the continued burning of fossil fuels like coal and oil is. Climate

    scientist Joe Fargione explains how this misconception came to pass by noting that; Previous

    conclusions that biofuels reduce greenhouse gases were based on incomplete analyses. They did

    not include the effect that biofuels can have on the conversion of natural ecosystems to crops.

    Adding energy production to our current and growing demand for food production inevitably

    requires more land to be converted to agriculture, whether or not the biofuel is grown directly on

    that land. Some of this land comes from natural ecosystems, and the conversion of these natural

    ecosystems to cropland releases carbon to the atmosphere and contributes to global warming.10

    The current controversy surrounding the production and use of biofuels and its impact on

    the worlds food supplies is pertinent because until fairly recently this was the only policy

    designed to reduce CO2emissions that had gained wide acceptance in the US and other

    developed countries. However as a recent article in the Economist notes, According to William

    Cline of the Peterson Institute for International Economics in Washington, DC, at least 4% of the

    worlds grain is used to make ethanol for fuel. Most of this is doing little good for the global

    environment, and stopping subsidies for such fuels would boost the supply of grain for feeding

    people on a scale similar to the hit that the past three decades of warming have provided.11Yet

    in spite of the abundant evidence that shows using grain to produce biofuels has at best a

    marginal impact on reductions in overall CO2emissions and a decidedly negative impact on food

    supplies and prices, biofuel policies persist. However, although some OECD members have now

    changed their biofuel policies, other OECD countries like the US continue to embrace them.

    Regardless of the environmental efficacy of producing biofuels as an alternative to

    burning fossil fuels, in and of themselves, biofuels were never going to lead to substantial

    reductions in CO2emissions because they were really only viable as a substitute for oil as a

    transportation fuel. Biofuels were never envisaged as a substitute for the much more substantial

    CO2emissions that result from coal used in generating electricity, natural gas used for heating or

    as a replacement for oil as a source of petrochemicals and plastics. The rapid increase in grain

    10Joe FargioneInterview with nature.org(February 2008)11Hindering Harvests.The Economist.(Vol. 399 No. 8732, 7 May 2011): 74

  • 8/11/2019 US Climate Change Policy Options

    8/26

    7

    prices and food shortages experienced in many developing countries between 2007 and 2008 was

    fueled by droughts in grain producing countries in 2006 as well as a spike in oil prices. But these

    events also underscored the fragility of the worlds food supplies and called into question the

    wisdom of using agricultural land and food crops to develop biofuels. As a consequence, since

    most of the US and other OECD nations had initially promoted and even subsidized the

    production of biofuels as a way to reduce their CO2carbon emissions, their political leaders and

    policy makers have now been forced to face the fact that achieving reductions in their CO2

    emissions is actually going to be a much more complex, difficult and costly undertaking than

    they had at first believed. Figure 1illustrates the complexity of the problem of reducing GHG

    emissions due to the numerous different economic sectors and end user activities that are both

    dependent on fossil fuels and are also the sources of almost all of the worlds GHG emissions.

    Figure 1

    Given the negative impacts the production of biofuels has on food supplies, many

    environmental organizations such as the Sierra Club have now started to argue that a more

    sensible course of action is for national governments to levy carbon taxes on the goods and

    services produced by the use of fossil fuels. Carl Pope, Sierra Clubexecutive director says [a

  • 8/11/2019 US Climate Change Policy Options

    9/26

    8

    carbon tax] will be more effective [than a cap-and-trade system] if people know that in year X

    they will pay this much.12Many economists also agree saying that carbon taxes would increase

    the costs of fossil fuel energy, thus providing an economic incentive for both businesses and

    consumers to reduce their use of fossil fuels in favor of alternative energy sources that reduce the

    earths uptake of CO2gases. For instance Marc Chupka, a leading energy economist, notes that a

    carbon tax would provide; a continual incentive to reduce the costs of carbon abatement,13

    Jonathan Zasloff also notes that a carbon tax is precisely the policy instrument that many

    economists say is the best form of regulation, but is routinely dismissed as politically

    unfeasible.14

    Advocates of carbon taxes also point out that an additional benefit governments

    could realize through the imposition of carbon taxes, is that these taxes could also provide more

    tax revenues national governments could then use to fund climate change mitigation and

    adaptation strategies.

    But unlike their counterparts in Europe, most US political leaders as well as the US

    general public have thus far been reluctant to embrace the use of carbon taxes to address climate

    changes national and global negative externalities; i.e. the concept that ecological damage (i.e.

    climate change due to man-made fossil fuel CO2emissions) that results from the way something

    is produced (i.e. energy and fuel), but is not taken into account in establishing the market prices

    of the goods and services involved (i.e. plastic products, electricity and transportation). Elected

    politicians in the US are justifiably concerned about adverse voter reactions from both businesses

    and consumers towards CO2emissions reduction policies that raise the costs of the goods

    produced through the use of fossil fuels and or the prices businesses and consumers currently pay

    for fossil fuel derived energy (electricity, heat, petrol, etc.) as well as the thousands of other

    carbon based products they use such as agricultural fertilizers, petro-chemicals and plastics.

    Furthermore some business lobbies in the US have argued that carbon taxes will put them

    at a competitive disadvantage, compared to producers in emerging economies that are not subject

    to Kyoto targets, such as Brazil Russia, India, Indonesia and China. With respect to exports,

    Harry Clarke writes that similar arguments by businesses in Australia were not without merit and

    that these companies exports face a competitive disadvantage in international markets simply

    12Juliet Eilperin and Steven Mufson Tax on Carbon Emissions Gains Support Washington Post(April 1, 2007)13Marc Chupka, Carbon Taxes and Climate Change,Encyclopedia of Energy, (Volume 1, 2001).14Jonathan Zasloff. Judicial Carbon Tax: Reconstructing Public Nuisance and Climate Change. The Symposium: ChangingClimates: Adapting Law and Policy to a Transforming World UCLA Law Review (Vol. 55 No.1 October 2007): 1829

  • 8/11/2019 US Climate Change Policy Options

    10/26

    9

    because globally desirable carbon mitigation objectives are being pursued.15

    Consequently, given the concerns of the industrialized democracies of the OECD, as well

    as the concerns of poorer developing countries about climate change policies adversely affecting

    their parochial economic development interests, formulating politically acceptable national, as

    well as international environmental policies that account for domestic economic interests, is a

    complicated task for public policy practitioners. As a result, climate policies that balance global

    environmental and national economic interests, present a unique political conundrum for all

    government policymakers, but particularly for the policy makers of the OECD member states

    democratic political governance regimes. Although some OECD political leaders and policy

    makers may have initially been confused about the effectiveness of biofuels in reducing global

    CO2emissions, there is no such confusion about a variety of other policies that would be much

    more effective than biofuels in reducing CO2 emissions. So why has the US failed to embrace

    other climate change policies such as nuclear power, or the use of New Environmental Policy

    Instruments (NEPI) like eco-carbon taxes, eco labeling, tradable CO2emission permits and

    industry wide environmental management systems? Furthermore, why does the US continue to

    promote and subsidize the production of coal, oil and gas and, in some cases, the continued

    production of biofuels at the expense of the global food supply as well as the environment?

    Since most16of the Kyoto Protocols Annex 1 nations (which are committed to reduce

    their CO2emissions) including the US are also members of the OECD, the wealthier more

    technologically developed nations of the OECD were expected to take the lead in reducing their

    CO2emissions. Therefore, in contrast to the CO2emission policies of China, India and other

    large developing nations with high levels of GHG emissions, the vast majority of the OECDs

    member nations (except the US and Canada) also agreed to meet specific GHG emission

    reduction targets agreed to in the Kyoto Protocol by 2012. While there were no financial

    penalties for Annex 1 nations that failed to meet their 2012 emission reduction targets, there was

    still widespread acceptance on the part of these OECD nations, that their failure to meet these

    CO2reduction targets would undermine their bargaining position with respect to future

    UNFCCC negotiations over the CO2emission reductions targets that they would want faster

    15Harry Clarke Some Basic Economics of Carbon Taxes CCEP working paper 4.(10, October 2010): 8-916Mexico, South Korea, Chile and Israel are the only OECD nations that are not Annex 1 nations while the former Communistnations of Belarus, Bulgaria, Croatia, Latvia, Lithuania, Romania, Ukraine and the Russian Federation as well as the Europeanprincipalities of Liechtenstein and Monaco are the only Annex 1 nations that are not members of the OECD.

  • 8/11/2019 US Climate Change Policy Options

    11/26

    10

    growing developing countries like Brazil, Russia, India and China (BRICs) to adopt.

    The extent of divergence between the US and other OECD members policies and the

    explanation for the policy divergence in climate change related environmental policies is a

    puzzle because the self-declared aim of the OECD states is to cooperate and harmonize policies

    among its members in order to help governments foster prosperity and fight poverty through

    economic growth and financial stability. We (also) help ensure the environmental implications of

    economic and social development are taken into account.17

    The US and other members of the OECD also share many characteristics as a group,

    which are widely seen in the literature as variables leading towards policy convergence in a

    range of policy areas. They are all high-income, economically developed, democratic nations

    that have relatively (compared to wider global comparators) similar socio-economic profiles. In

    contrast, the G77 group of developing countries varies much more significantly in their socio-

    economic profiles and they also vary widely in terms of their consumer cultures, levels of

    income inequality, education levels, as well as the structure of their economic systems.

    Finally, it should be noted that it was climate scientists residing in the US and the more

    technologically advanced OECD nations who were the first to raise the alarm about the

    damaging impact man made chlorofluorocarbons were having on the earths ozone, and to

    discover the role man-made GHG emissions were playing in raising global air and water

    temperatures, thus leading to adverse climate changes in ecosystems worldwide.

    US critics of implementing new CO2emission reduction policies have cited the lack of

    CO2emission reduction targets for China, the worlds largest GHG emitter and second largest

    economy, as a justification for not ratifying the emission reduction targets set for the US in the

    Kyoto Protocol. While more economically advanced countries like China are unlikely to be

    granted the same exemption from GHG emission reductions as the poorer developing countries

    in Africa and Asia in future climate change treaty negotiations, China and Indias counter-

    argument that their per capita CO2emissions are still a fraction of those in countries like the US

    is not without merit. Setting aside the ethical argument that the US and more developed nations

    are also the nations most responsible for the excessive levels of GHG emissions that are already

    in the earths atmosphere, the US cannot realistically expect developing countries to reduce their

    own carbon emissions until after the US takes the lead in doing so and shows the developing

    17Organization for Economic Development and Co-operation. What We Do and How. Online at www.oecd.org

  • 8/11/2019 US Climate Change Policy Options

    12/26

    11

    countries how to reduce carbon emissions without hurting their own economic development.

    The aforementioned arguments were repeated many times during negotiations between

    the US, European nations and members of the G77 group of developing countries in the months

    leading up to the 2009 Copenhagen Climate Change Conference. The lack of substantive

    progress in Copenhagen as regards a successor agreement to the Kyoto Protocol, has resulted in

    an impasse for now, but there is also little argument by the nations of Europe or the developing

    worlds G77, that it is still the responsibility of the more technologically advanced nations like

    the US to lead the way in reducing GHG emissions.

    The lack of tangible progress at the 2009 Copenhagen Climate Conference was also due

    to several factors which were years in the making. The 2008 financial crises has had a deeper

    and longer lasting effect on the economies of the US and Europe than it had on the economies of

    developing countries. As a result, the US and many OECD states in Europe had economies that

    were still suffering from the effects of the global economic recession in 2009, 2010 and 2011. So

    in addition to the US, with some of their economies still in shambles many European nations are

    less willing to sign up for the deeper and more difficult to achieve cuts in their carbon emissions

    envisaged as a part of a new climate change treaty that would succeed the Kyoto Protocol.

    As a result, the terms of the debate shifted noticeably in the months following the 2009

    Copenhagen Climate Conference. Whereas the initial goal of the carbon reduction strategies of

    the OECD countries had been to prevent a global temperature rise of more than 1.5-2C; the lack

    of any real progress during the preceding decade by many OECD nations in meeting their 2012

    Kyoto Protocol targets led to the tacit abandonment of this objective at the 2010 Cancun Climate

    Conference. Furthermore, instead of adopting 2C as a new target, the goal of the climate change

    negotiations in Cancun shifted to mitigating the worst effects of climate change by keeping the

    global temperature increase under 3C. As a result, most climate change discussions are now

    focused on mitigation and adaptation strategies to cope with the consequences of climate change,

    instead of trying to prevent climate change. But once again, because the wealthier OECD nations

    are more technologically advanced than their developing country brethren, they are not only

    more likely to lead the way in terms of reducing their carbon emissions and developing low

    carbon emission alternatives, but will also lead the way in terms of adapting to or coping with the

    negative consequences of climate change. Therefore, the initiative for policy action stills lies

    with the US and other developed countries. No one expects a global deal without a significant

  • 8/11/2019 US Climate Change Policy Options

    13/26

    12

    shift in the policy position of more developed countries - in particular the US, so the chances of

    making any real impact on reducing the worlds GHG emissions are becoming ever more

    dependent on the climate change policies adopted by the US.

    Literature Review

    Most of the environmental policy literature dealing with climate change focuses on the

    global nature of the problem instead of individual nations policies to deal with it. To that end,

    Jacob Park, Ken Conca, Matthais Finger and their collaborators, focus particular attention on

    Rios flawed and outmoded governancemodel.18

    With respect to the factors that influence

    nations to implement environmental protection policies, Tews, Busch and Jorgens concluded that

    the adoption of environmental policy innovations is more likely if these policy innovations

    figure prominently on the global political agenda.19

    They also concluded that the special

    features of a policy innovation can either facilitate of hinder its widespread adoption.20In other

    words, while international institutional support does have an impact on environmental policy

    diffusion, the nature of the environmental policies themselves also has a substantial affect on

    whether a country actually adopts a specific environmental policy. Tews et altherefore

    considered national factors as crucial for answering the question of why nations adopt policy

    innovations at an earlier stage, at a later stage or even resist them altogether.

    Jordan, Wurzel and Zito note that since governance theory regards regulation as the very

    essence of government, they used the adoption and implementation of NEPIs to assess how these

    particular environmental policy responses impact governments regulatory domain. The authors

    used comparative research to investigate whether or not governance of the environment has

    eclipsed the role of government in eight industrialized OECD states and the EU. Jordan et al

    focused on how the use of NEPIs impacted the governance of environmental issues by looking at

    the levels of support they found for four types of NEPIs in eight industrialized OECD nations

    and within the EU. Like Tews et al, they cite the importance of national factors and attribute

    differences in levels of support to national-level factors such as deeply engrained national

    policy styles, industry opposition and the absence of effective champions.21Their research also

    18Jacob Park et al. The death of Rio environmentalism. In Jacob Park, Ken Conca and Matthais Finger, Editors. The Crisis ofGlobal Environmental Governance. (New York: Routledge. 2008): 919Kerstin Tews, Per-Olaf Busch and Helge Jorgens. The diffusion of new environmental policy instruments.European Journalof Political Research(Vol. 42 No. 3, 2003): 57220Tews et al: 57321Andrew Jordan, Rdiger K. W. Wurzel and Anthony Zito. The Rise of New Policy Instruments in Comparative Perspective:Has Governance Eclipsed Government?Political Studies. (Vol. 53, 2005): 491

  • 8/11/2019 US Climate Change Policy Options

    14/26

    13

    suggests that NEPIs such as tradable carbon emission permits are not viewed as a replacement

    for existing regulation of CO2emissions; rather they are being used to plug the gaps that exist in

    some national environmental policy systems or to respond to new, high profile problems such as

    climate change. Based on the results of their study, Jordan et alconclude that Broadly speaking,

    our nine jurisdictions (all of them are members of the OECD) have, on balance, shifted from a

    position of government to one of governance with respect to their use of (new environmental)

    policy instruments.22

    Overall, the environmental politics literature suggests that complex interactions between

    a number of different elements influence environmental policy at the global level. Authors like

    Young, Schofer and Hironaka contend it is international institutions that have a substantial

    impact on improving environmental policy outcomes while others like Princen and Finger say it

    is the influence of environmental NGOs. On the other hand, Hajer and Whitman cite the public

    discourse of societal elites while Jordan et aland Tews et alargue that state level national factors

    are more crucial in the development of global environmental policies than the influence of

    international institutions or environmental NGOs.

    Tews et alalso cite the influence of regional ties, due at least in part to cultural

    similarities, in their analysis of policy diffusion writing that the nearly simultaneous policy

    adoption of energy/carbon taxes in the Scandinavian countries had been co-ordinated by the

    Nordic Council.23Andrea Lenschow, Duncan Liefferink and Sietske Veenmans paper, When

    the birds sing: A framework for analysing domestic factors behind policy convergence, was the

    only significant policy convergence study in the environmental politics and policy literature that

    used culture as a determinant of the likelihood that countries would adopt certain types of new

    environmental policies. The authors argue that although these factors may have different degrees

    of importance given the goals of the policy, culture as well as institutions and economy are the

    three domestic factors that underlie policy diffusion and convergence.

    Lenschow et al concluded that new ideas, principles and goals impinge first and

    foremost on national culture. Therefore, countries that share important aspects of their cultural

    foundations might be expected to more quickly adopt similar ideas, principles and goals than

    22Jordan et al: 47749623Tews et al: 586

  • 8/11/2019 US Climate Change Policy Options

    15/26

    14

    countries that are culturally less close to each other.24Based on my review of the environmental

    policy literature and surveys of cultural values conducted by Geert Hofstede 25it appears that the

    differences that exist between the individualistic cultural values of the US and the more

    collectivist cultural values of most European countries best explains why the US has not yet

    adopted the GHG emissions reductions policies implemented by many European countries.

    However, the other explanation most often heard is that the US is waiting for new

    technologies such as geoengineering to develop that will address the problem. Geoengineering

    schemes run the gamut from deploying millions of solar panels in space to more prosaic

    proposals like painting all rooftops white. While most of these engineering ideas are still in their

    infancy one of the more plausible ones is a solar radiation management (SRM) scheme that

    simulates the cooling effects of volcanic eruptions by spraying millions of tons of sun-reflecting

    particles into the upper reaches of the earths atmosphere. While not much is known about the

    overall risks and long term costs of these geoengineering schemes we must begin to investigate

    them immediately. Scott Barrett observes Should our efforts to limit (GHG) concentrations fail,

    or should rapid climate change occur despite emissions being curtailed sharply, geoengineering

    may seem worth the risk. Either way, it would seem prudent to be prepared for these possible

    futures, which is why R&D into geoengineering should begin now.26

    Unfortunately, literature dealing with the economic costs and benefits of different types

    of GHG emission reduction policies is also relatively immature. However, separate studies that

    have been done by William Nordhaus and Gilbert Metcalf, have concluded that the long term

    costs of waiting for new technologies before adopting new GHG emission reduction policies far

    exceeds the short term and overall costs of acting now. While reducing the GHG emissions that

    underlie climate change is a global problem that will require global cooperation, there will be no

    real cooperation on a global scale until the worlds wealthiest nation undertakes its own policies.

    As Gerald Metcalf notes, Without the participation and leadership of the world's richest country

    and one of the leading emitters of greenhouse gases, it is difficult to imagine how the world can

    ever make meaningful progress on slowing and eventually stopping global warming. 27

    24Andrea Lenschow, Duncan Liefferink and Sietske Veenman. When the birds sing: A framework for analysing domesticfactors behind policy convergence. Journal of European Public Policy(Vol. 12 No. 5, 2005): 81025Geert Hofstede, Culture's Consequences: comparing values, behaviors, institutions & organizations across nations (ThousandOaks, CA: Sage 2001)26Scott Barrett. The Coming Global Climate-Technology Revolution The Journal of Economic Perspectives, (Vol. 23, No. 2Spring, 2009): 7327Gilbert E. Metcalf. Market-based Policy Options to Control U.S. Greenhouse Gas EmissionsJournal of Economic

  • 8/11/2019 US Climate Change Policy Options

    16/26

    15

    US Climate Change Policy Options

    Since the costs and risks associated with geoengineering schemes are unknown at this

    time, this paper will focus on the policy options that have been proposed for the US and have

    already been implemented in other countries. Following is a brief summary of specific types of

    direct regulation and incentive policy options which have been proposed to reduce GHG

    emissions in order to mitigate some of the negative impacts of climate change as well as the pros

    and cons and economic, political and societal impacts associated with each policy alternative.

    Direct Regulation

    1) A GHG/CO2emissions target is established for each polluting firm and industry so the

    burden of reducing emissions cant be shifted to firms that can more easily achieve them.

    2) Major advantage is the cost to comply with GHG/CO2emissions regulations is born

    directly by the polluting firms and indirectly by consumers of those firms products and

    services through higher prices that reflect the fact that firms are no longer free riders.

    3) Major disadvantage is command and control regulations are inflexible and do not

    encourage polluting firms to go beyond their regulatory emissions targets and cut their

    GHG emissions more than they are required to.

    4) A carbon tax is a form of carbon pricing that levies an environmental tax on the carbon

    content of fuels, electricity and other goods produced from fossil fuels.

    5) Major advantage is carbon taxes address the problem of GHG/CO2emitters who are free

    riders since they dont pay for the negative externalities or social costs of their actions.

    6) Economists prefer a carbon tax because it is explicit, not hidden, it is efficient,

    minimizing collateral damage to the economy, and it is effective, raising the price of

    greenhouse gas emissions and encouraging alternatives.

    7) Major disadvantage is regressive nature of tax adversely impacts budgets of poor citizens.

    Incentive Policies

    Emissions trading or cap-and-trade is a market-based approach used to control pollution

    by providing economic incentives for polluting firms to reduce GHG emissions.

    Major advantage is incentive is designed to achieve the greatest amount of GHG

    emissions reductions at the most efficient and economically effective cost.

    Perspectives(Vol.23, No. 2, Spring 2009): 25

  • 8/11/2019 US Climate Change Policy Options

    17/26

    16

    A cap and trade of CO2emissions permits is also one of the new climate change policy

    options that has already been adopted by many countries in Europe and the OECD.

    Major disadvantage centers on price fluctuations and government policies that give away

    permits to industrial polluters as opposed to policies that auction government permits.

    Direct regulation has been used successfully by many governments, including the US, to

    address local, state and national environmental problems such as air and water pollution as well

    as international pollutants that affect other countries such as acid rain. Direct regulation was also

    used by the US and other developed countries to address the global environmental problem of

    ozone depleting CFC chemicals. But reducing GHG CO2emissions involves many different

    industries and a much greater number of polluting firms, not to mention consumers who own

    cars and other GHG emitting products, so it is difficult to imagine a direct regulation scheme that

    will effectively target all polluters in proportion to their contribution to GHG emissions.

    Therefore due to the complexities of regulating so many producers and consumers of fossil fuels,

    no new direct regulation policies beyond those governing CFCs and or tweaks to existing EPA

    policies governing fuel economy standards and ethanol mixtures will be considered.

    Many European countries such as the United Kingdom (UK) have imposed a carbon tax

    based on the estimated carbon content and GHG emissions of fuel and energy products.

    According to a recent Bloomberg news report about Australias new carbon tax, the Australian

    government expects to raise $24.7 billion in four years from the carbon tax that will take effect

    on July 1 2012. The tax on Australias biggest sources of GHG emissions starts at $23 per ton of

    carbon and rises by 2.5 percent in real terms in each of the following two fiscal years. The

    Australian Treasury projects the price will reach $29 a ton in 2015-16, when the mechanism

    moves to a price set by the market. The tax is also expected to increase consumer prices by 0.7

    percentage point in the 12 months starting July 1 2012.28

    The European Union Emission Trading Scheme (or EU ETS) is the largest multi-

    national, GHG/CO2cap and trade emissions trading scheme with a market value of $120bn in

    2010. It is one of the EU's central policy instruments used since 2005 by 25 of 27 EU members

    to meet their Kyoto Protocol emissions targets. New Zealand also introduced an Emissions

    Trading Scheme in 2008. However, the World Bank says the international market in carbon

    28Garfield Reynolds.Australia Predicts $24.7 Billion Carbon Revenue.Bloomberg(May 9 2012)

  • 8/11/2019 US Climate Change Policy Options

    18/26

    17

    credits suffered an almost total collapse in 2010 with only $1.5bn of credits traded, the lowest

    amount since the market first opened in 2005. Furthermore, the price of carbon emission permits

    has swung widely and is currently around $10 per ton which is widely considered to be too low a

    price to encourage firms and consumers to reduce their GHG emissions.

    US Climate Change Policy Cost Benefit Analysis and Policy Recommendations

    Figure 2represents the decision matrix that was used to identify climate change related

    policy alternatives and the rationale that was used in deciding which climate change related

    policies to recommend over the other climate change policy alternatives that were rejected.

    Figure 2

    Revenue-Benefits Decision Matrix

    Policy Options Polluting Firm Benefits Government Benefits

    No Mitigation Policy YES (No added costs free riders) NO (Pays costs of free riders)

    Cap & Trade Emissions Permits YES (Profit from trading permits) NO ( Yes if permits auctioned)

    Carbon Tax NO YES

    Based on his in-depth economic analysis of the price of carbon emissions, Richard Tol

    observes that The price of carbon dioxide emission permits in the European Union was $78 per

    ton of carbon in January 2009 and although the United States has no federal policy specifically to

    reduce carbon emissions, many utilities apparently factor in the likelihood of a carbon tax of $15

    per ton of carbon in their investment decisions. This pattern also suggests that the European

    Union may be placing too high a price on carbon emissions, while the United States is placing

    too low a price on such emissions.29

    Figure 3is a cost benefit analysis that shows the dollar value of implementing a new

    climate change mitigation policy and continuing with the status quo of no new climate change

    policies. As such, it comparesthecost of a carbon tax CO2mitigationpolicy through 2035

    beginning with aninitial tax of $10 per ton of carbon (rising to $33 per ton in 2035) with no

    mitigation policy through 2035. Losses are figured in discounted Global World Product (GWP)in billions of dollars. US GDP is approximately 25% of GWP so US losses are 20-25% of figures

    shown. Annual losses (and gains) are discounted back to 2005. IN means impossible now;

    temperature target cannot be reached by any mitigation policy initiated in 2005. IL means

    29Richard Tol. The Economic Effects of Climate Change.Journal of Economic Perspectives(Vol. 23, No. 2, Spring 2009): 46

  • 8/11/2019 US Climate Change Policy Options

    19/26

    18

    impossible later; temperature targets could not be achieved by any adjustments in 2035 to

    mitigation policies initiated in 2005. Since the current price of carbon emissions permits is

    around $10 per ton of carbon, the very conservative cost benefit analysis illustrated in Figure 3

    uses this price instead of the $15 price used by US electric utilities or the $78 EU carbon price.

    Figure 3

    Cost Benefit Analysis of Carbon Tax vs. Status Quo (No CO 2Mitigation Policy)

    DISCOUNTED ADJUSTMENT COSTS($) GIVEN AN INITIAL CARBON TAX OF $10

    Temperature targetClimate Sensitivity (degrees)

    (degrees) 2 2.5 3 3.5

    1.5 $0 $0 $0 $0

    2 $2 $1 $0 $03 $4 $3 $1 $04 IL $6 $2 $05 IL $12 $3 $06 IN IL $4 $17 IN IL $6 $38 IN IL $9 $59 IN IL $12 $9

    DISCOUNTED ADJUSTMENT COSTS($) GIVEN NO MITIGATION THROUGH 2035

    Temperature targetClimate Sensitivity (degrees)

    (degrees) 2 2.5 3 3.5

    1.5 $32 $11 $3 $02 $38 $22 $16 $43 $180 $29 $18 $224 IL $60 $24 $245 IL $142 $25 $256 IN IL $27 $287 IN IL IL $34

    8 IN IL IL $359 IN IL IL $38

    Figure 3sdollar value analysis shows the cost of status quo is much higher and the value

    is based on the DICE model used by William Nordhaus who notes that The DICE baseline

    temperature projections are in the lower-middle end of the IPCC Fourth Assessment Reports

  • 8/11/2019 US Climate Change Policy Options

    20/26

    19

    best estimate of the global mean temperature increase of between 1.8 and 4.0C from 1980-2099.

    The DICE baseline yields a global mean temperature increase of 2.2C over this same period.30

    Figure 4 illustrates the economic effect of carbon tax and cap and trade of emissions.

    Figure 4

    In Figure 4, the intersection of the supply and demand curves for GHG-emitting

    products, point A, will generate emissions equal to Q0, and the price will be P0. There are two

    climate change policies either of which the government can use to reduce the quantity to Q1.

    Carbon tax: if a carbon tax is added into the price the supplier's price will be the old

    price plus the amount of the tax, and the supply curve will shift up to S*. The new equilibrium is

    at point B, the quantity is the target Q1, and the price will increase to P1.

    Cap-and-trade: if government restricts emissions to a level consistent with Q1the new

    supply curve S* is vertical and no matter how high the price goes, supply will remain fixed at Q1.

    The new equilibrium is B, the quantity is determined by the cap at Q1, and price will rise to P1.

    is the green area which represents the difference between the price the consumers pay

    at B and what it costs suppliers to produce at Q1. In the case of the carbon tax, that money goes

    to the government to help pay for the costs of climate change disasters. But if output is capped at

    30William Nordhaus.A Question of Balance: Weighing the Options on Global Warming Policies. (New Haven: Yale UniversityPress, 2008): 199

  • 8/11/2019 US Climate Change Policy Options

    21/26

    20

    Q1, that difference is pure profit since a permit to produce one unit of output allows its owner

    to collect a rent equal to the difference between the selling price and the cost of production. 31

    Figure 5illustrates the economic impact carbon taxes and a cap and trade of emissions

    permits has on two firms; one with high GHG emissions and one with lower GHG emissions

    Figure 5

    With a carbon tax, the high cost polluting firm will abate to e* (right to left) and suffer

    abatement costs of K and pay a tax bill to the government equal to B + C + F + G. The low cost

    firm will abate to e* (left to right) and suffer abatement costs of C + G and pay a tax bill to the

    government equal to J + K. The efficient abatement level is achieved: e* The abatement cost to

    the polluting firms, C + G + K, is minimized and Government revenue = B + C + F + G + J + K.

    With cap and trade schemes, the abatement cost to the low abatement cost firm is equal to

    area C. The abatement cost to the high abatement cost firm is D + F + G + K. If it recognizes that

    its marginal abatement cost is higher than the marginal abatement cost of the low cost firm it

    could propose a trade. In effect, the blue line over area D, F and G is a demand curve for permits

    and the green line is a supply curve for permits. Anywhere in between the blue and green line is

    a permit price that is mutually agreeable between both firms. A competitive permit market will

    result in a permit price equivalent to the efficient carbon tax. Trading reduces overall abatement

    costs by area D + F. The efficient abatement level is achieved: e* and the abatement cost to the

    31StephenGordon. Carbon Taxes vs Cap and Trade.The Economists View(June 3, 2008)

  • 8/11/2019 US Climate Change Policy Options

    22/26

    21

    polluting firms, C + G + K, is minimized. However, the drawback is that there is no revenue for

    the government that it can use to pay for costs of negative externalities of climate change.32

    Conclusions

    Compared to other types of direct government regulation command and control schemes,

    both carbon taxes and carbon cap-and-trade permits could achieve the same level of increased

    efficiency by achieving the optimal GHG/CO2emissions abatement levels at the minimum cost.

    However, even though the economics graphs in Figure 4 andFigure 5show that the economic

    impacts of a direct carbon tax and a cap and trade of emissions permits are equivalent, they will

    in fact only be roughly equivalent if the cap and trade emissions permits are auctioned off to the

    highest bidders by the government. But if the GHG emissions permits are simply given to

    existing GHG emitters, then all permit trading profits are pocketed by the polluting firms.

    However, if the permits are auctioned off, the price will be bid up to an equilibrium

    market price for carbon (probably somewhere between the $10 per ton of carbon used in the cost

    benefit analysis, US electric utilities $15 per ton estimate and the EUs carbon permit price of

    $78 per ton). The polluting firms could still earn profits from future trading of emissions permits

    while the US government would receive some money right away to use to pay for the costs of

    climate change related negative externalities. Unfortunately, US politicians have long expressed

    a preference for hidden taxes. Given the current anti-tax political climate that all Congressional

    Republicans now have to operate within, it is much more likely that they will support a cap-and-

    trade of emissions permits, which private firms can profit from. Since a carbon tax would not be

    a hidden tax, Congress is unlikely to approve of it even though it would also provide the federal

    government with an ongoing revenue stream to pay for climate change related costs.

    Given the multifaceted number of contributors to the earths GHG emissions I believe a

    multifaceted policy approach will also be necessary to effectively address the problem. To that

    end, the US government should take action on the following policy fronts; 1) Increase

    conservation and replanting of forests that absorb CO22) Increase the energy efficiency of the

    US electric grid and electric appliances, 3) Stop underwriting government insurance of homes on

    beaches & flood plains, 4) Increase the federal gasoline tax to pay for rebuilding road and water

    infrastructure, 5) Implement a carbon tax on electricity per kilowatt hour to fund climate change

    adaptation, 6) A Cap & Trade of emissions permits for industries that make goods from carbon.

    32Carbon Tax vs. Cap-and-TradeEnvironmental Economicsat http://www.env-econ.net/

  • 8/11/2019 US Climate Change Policy Options

    23/26

    22

    Overhanging the debate about what steps we should take to deal with climate change is

    the fact that the quality and quantity of research on the economic impacts of climate change is in

    no way commensurate with the expected costs of mitigating the worst effects of climate change

    or adapting to it. While numerous polls have consistently shown that approximately two thirds of

    Americans believe that man made emissions are causing climate change, there is no consensus

    on what policies should be adopted to address the problem because so little is known about the

    short and long term economic impacts. As Richard Tol notes Politicians are proposing to spend

    hundreds of billions of dollars on green house gas emission reduction, and at present, economists

    cannot say with confidence whether this investment is too much or too little.33

    Richard Lind poses another interesting question that policy makers need to consider when

    doing any kind of cost benefit analysis; If we invest successfully in new technologies that will

    substantially reduce the costs of abatement in ten years, can we wait and more cost-effectively

    reach the same level of total abatement by starting later and doing it more efficiently?34

    Mr.

    Lind has a valid point here, particularly in regard to evaluating the costs and benefits of the

    geoengineering schemes that are now being discussed. However, many climate change skeptics

    use this same rationale to argue that since the eminent threat of climate change doesnt appear to

    be as great, we also need to wait until we are more certain about precisely how and to what

    degree man-made GHG emissions are negatively affecting our national and global environment.

    But the Economist responds to those skeptics by noting that :Some scientists are now

    arguing that man-made climate change is not quite so bad a threat as it appeared to be and that

    the planets climate sensitivitythe amount of warming from a doubling in the carbon-dioxide

    levelmay not be as high as was previously thought. So if the world has a bit more breathing

    space to deal with global warming, that will be good. But breathing space helps only if you

    actually do something with it35Furthermore, Gary Yohe, Natasha Andronova and Michael

    Schlesingers offer an insightful response to those who want to use uncertainty or the lack of new

    technologies as an excuse to wait when they write that; Uncertainty is the reason for acting in

    the near term, and that uncertainty cannot be used as a justification for doing nothing.36

    33Richard Tol. The Economic Effects of Climate Change.Journal of Economic Perspectives(Vol. 23, No. 2, Spring 2009): 4634Robert Lind. Intergenerational equity, discounting, and the role of cost-benefit analysis in evaluating global climate policy.

    Energy Policy(Vol. 23, No. 45 1995): 38835Economist Global warming; Apocalypse perhaps a little later.The Economist(Vol. 407 No. 8828, 30 May 2013)36Gary Yohe, Natasha Andronova and Michael Schlesinger. To Hedge or Not Against an Uncertain Climate Future? Science(Vol. 306 October 15 2004): 416-417

  • 8/11/2019 US Climate Change Policy Options

    24/26

    23

    BibliographyBarrett, Scott. The Coming Global Climate-Technology Revolution The Journal of Economic

    Perspectives, Vol. 23, No. 2 (Spring, 2009), pp. 53-75

    Carbon Tax vs. Cap-and-TradeEnvironmental Economicsat http://www.env-econ.net/

    Cassese, Antonio.International Law (Oxford UK: Oxford University Press, 2001)

    Chupka,Marc. Carbon Taxes and Climate Change.Encyclopedia of Energy, (Volume 1, 2001).

    Clarke, Harry. Some Basic Economics of Carbon Taxes. Centre for Climate Economics &

    Policy Crawford School of Economics and Government, The Australian National

    University, CCEP working paper 4(10 October, 2010): 1-23

    Economist. Hindering Harvests.The Economist(Vol. 399 No. 8732, 7 May 2011)

    Economist Global warming; Apocalypse perhaps a little later.The Economist(Vol. 407 No.

    8828, 30 May 2013)Eilperin, Juliet and Steven Mufson. Tax on Carbon Emissions Gains Support. Washington Post

    (April 1, 2007)

    Fargione, Joe.Interview with nature.org(February 2008)

    Grace, John. Presidential Address: Understanding and Managing the Global Carbon

    Cycle.Journal of Ecology(Vol. 92, No. 2, 2004.): 189-202

    Gordon, Stephen. Carbon Taxes vs Cap and Trade.The Economists View(June 3, 2008)

    Hofstede, Geert. Culture's Consequences: comparing values, behaviors, institutions &

    organizations across nations(Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage 2001)

    Jordan, Andrew, Rdiger K. W. Wurzel and Anthony Zito. The Rise of New Policy

    Instruments in Comparative Perspective: Has Governance Eclipsed Government?

    Political Studies. (Vol. 53, 2005)

    Kettl, Donald The Transformation of Governance: Globalization, Devolution, and the Role of

    Government. Public Administration Review(Vol. 60, No. 6, 2000)

    Lenschow, Andrea, Duncan Liefferink and Sietske Veenman. When the birds sing: A

    framework for analysing domestic factors behind policy convergence. Journal of

    European Public Policy(Vol. 12 No. 5, 2005)

    Lind, Robert. Intergenerational equity, discounting, and the role of cost-benefit analysis in

    evaluating global climate policy.Energy Policy(Vol. 23, No. 45 1995): 379389

    Liverman, Diana M. Conventions of climate change: constructions of danger and the

  • 8/11/2019 US Climate Change Policy Options

    25/26

    24

    dispossession of the atmosphere.Journal of Historical Geography(Vol. 35, 2009)

    Metcalf, Gilbert. Market-based Policy Options to Control U.S. Greenhouse Gas Emissions

    Journal of Economic Perspectives(Vol.23, No. 2, Spring 2009): 5-27

    Nordhaus, William.A Question of Balance: Weighing the Options on Global Warming Policies.

    (New Haven: Yale University Press, 2008)

    Nordhaus, William D. Economic aspects of global warming in a post-Copenhagen

    environment Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences(Vol. 107, No. 26, June

    29, 2010): 11721-11726

    Nordhaus, William D. Why the Global Warming Skeptics Are Wrong. The New York Review

    of Books(March 22, 2012)

    Organization for Economic Development and Co-operation. What We Do and How. Can be

    accessed online at www.oecd.org

    Park, Jacob et al. The death of Rio environmentalism. In Jacob Park, Ken Conca and Matthais

    Finger, Editors. The Crisis of Global Environmental Governance. (New York: Routledge.

    2008): 1-12

    Parson, Edward. Protecting the Ozone Layer in Peter Haas, Robert Keohane and Marc

    Levy(eds.)Institutions for the Earth: Sources of Effective International Environmental

    Protection(Cambridge MA: MIT Press)

    Reynolds, Garfield.Australia Predicts $24.7 Billion Carbon Revenue.Bloomberg(May 9 2012)

    Scholte, Jan Aart. Globalization: A critical introduction(New York: St. Martins Press, 2000)

    Smith, Joel, Jason Vogel and John Cromwell. An Architecture for Government Action on

    Adaptation to Climate Change. Climatic Change (Vol. 95 No. 1-2, 2009): 53-61

    Stern, Nicholas. What is the Economics of Climate Change? World Economics(Vol. 7, No. 2,

    2006)

    Tews, Kersten, Per-Olaf Busch and Helge Jorgens. The diffusion of new environmental policy

    instruments.European Journal of Political Research(Vol. 42 No. 3, 2003)

    Tol, Richard. The Economic Effects of Climate Change.Journal of Economic Perspectives

    (Vol. 23, No. 2, Spring 2009): 2951

    United Nations. Article 2. The United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change.

    (1997)

  • 8/11/2019 US Climate Change Policy Options

    26/26

    Yohe, Gary. Natasha Andronova and Michael Schlesinger. To Hedge or Not Against an

    Uncertain Climate Future? Science(Vol. 306 October 15 2004): 416-417

    Zasloff, Jonathan. Judicial Carbon Tax: Reconstructing Public Nuisance and Climate Change.

    The Symposium: Changing Climates: Adapting Law and Policy to a Transforming World

    UCLA Law Review(Vol. 55 No.1 - October 2007)