135
Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random Regimes Actuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 / 36

Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    1

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models WithRandomized Regimes

James G. Bridgeman, FSA

University of Connecticut

Actuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 1

/ 36

Page 2: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Introduction

Work in progress on cash �ow testing interest rate models

Empirical Work In Valuation Actuary Practice (1990�s):

Unconstrained lognormal models have too much tailMean-reverting ones have too little shoulderRandomizing the reversion target �xes itTrial and error calibration2001 Valuation Actuary Symposium Proceedings

Theoretical Work (2006):

Closed form calibration for the mean-reverting lognormalA surprising drift formula for the mean-reverting lognormalCouldn�t get closed form calibration with randomized targetsARCH 2007.1

More Recent Results (2007):

Asymptotic closed form calibration with randomized targetsInteresting probability results/techniquesARCH 2008.1

This year? Numerical examples and extensions

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 2

/ 36

Page 3: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Introduction

Work in progress on cash �ow testing interest rate modelsEmpirical Work In Valuation Actuary Practice (1990�s):

Unconstrained lognormal models have too much tailMean-reverting ones have too little shoulderRandomizing the reversion target �xes itTrial and error calibration2001 Valuation Actuary Symposium Proceedings

Theoretical Work (2006):

Closed form calibration for the mean-reverting lognormalA surprising drift formula for the mean-reverting lognormalCouldn�t get closed form calibration with randomized targetsARCH 2007.1

More Recent Results (2007):

Asymptotic closed form calibration with randomized targetsInteresting probability results/techniquesARCH 2008.1

This year? Numerical examples and extensions

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 2

/ 36

Page 4: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Introduction

Work in progress on cash �ow testing interest rate modelsEmpirical Work In Valuation Actuary Practice (1990�s):

Unconstrained lognormal models have too much tail

Mean-reverting ones have too little shoulderRandomizing the reversion target �xes itTrial and error calibration2001 Valuation Actuary Symposium Proceedings

Theoretical Work (2006):

Closed form calibration for the mean-reverting lognormalA surprising drift formula for the mean-reverting lognormalCouldn�t get closed form calibration with randomized targetsARCH 2007.1

More Recent Results (2007):

Asymptotic closed form calibration with randomized targetsInteresting probability results/techniquesARCH 2008.1

This year? Numerical examples and extensions

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 2

/ 36

Page 5: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Introduction

Work in progress on cash �ow testing interest rate modelsEmpirical Work In Valuation Actuary Practice (1990�s):

Unconstrained lognormal models have too much tailMean-reverting ones have too little shoulder

Randomizing the reversion target �xes itTrial and error calibration2001 Valuation Actuary Symposium Proceedings

Theoretical Work (2006):

Closed form calibration for the mean-reverting lognormalA surprising drift formula for the mean-reverting lognormalCouldn�t get closed form calibration with randomized targetsARCH 2007.1

More Recent Results (2007):

Asymptotic closed form calibration with randomized targetsInteresting probability results/techniquesARCH 2008.1

This year? Numerical examples and extensions

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 2

/ 36

Page 6: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Introduction

Work in progress on cash �ow testing interest rate modelsEmpirical Work In Valuation Actuary Practice (1990�s):

Unconstrained lognormal models have too much tailMean-reverting ones have too little shoulderRandomizing the reversion target �xes it

Trial and error calibration2001 Valuation Actuary Symposium Proceedings

Theoretical Work (2006):

Closed form calibration for the mean-reverting lognormalA surprising drift formula for the mean-reverting lognormalCouldn�t get closed form calibration with randomized targetsARCH 2007.1

More Recent Results (2007):

Asymptotic closed form calibration with randomized targetsInteresting probability results/techniquesARCH 2008.1

This year? Numerical examples and extensions

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 2

/ 36

Page 7: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Introduction

Work in progress on cash �ow testing interest rate modelsEmpirical Work In Valuation Actuary Practice (1990�s):

Unconstrained lognormal models have too much tailMean-reverting ones have too little shoulderRandomizing the reversion target �xes itTrial and error calibration

2001 Valuation Actuary Symposium Proceedings

Theoretical Work (2006):

Closed form calibration for the mean-reverting lognormalA surprising drift formula for the mean-reverting lognormalCouldn�t get closed form calibration with randomized targetsARCH 2007.1

More Recent Results (2007):

Asymptotic closed form calibration with randomized targetsInteresting probability results/techniquesARCH 2008.1

This year? Numerical examples and extensions

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 2

/ 36

Page 8: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Introduction

Work in progress on cash �ow testing interest rate modelsEmpirical Work In Valuation Actuary Practice (1990�s):

Unconstrained lognormal models have too much tailMean-reverting ones have too little shoulderRandomizing the reversion target �xes itTrial and error calibration2001 Valuation Actuary Symposium Proceedings

Theoretical Work (2006):

Closed form calibration for the mean-reverting lognormalA surprising drift formula for the mean-reverting lognormalCouldn�t get closed form calibration with randomized targetsARCH 2007.1

More Recent Results (2007):

Asymptotic closed form calibration with randomized targetsInteresting probability results/techniquesARCH 2008.1

This year? Numerical examples and extensions

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 2

/ 36

Page 9: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Introduction

Work in progress on cash �ow testing interest rate modelsEmpirical Work In Valuation Actuary Practice (1990�s):

Unconstrained lognormal models have too much tailMean-reverting ones have too little shoulderRandomizing the reversion target �xes itTrial and error calibration2001 Valuation Actuary Symposium Proceedings

Theoretical Work (2006):

Closed form calibration for the mean-reverting lognormalA surprising drift formula for the mean-reverting lognormalCouldn�t get closed form calibration with randomized targetsARCH 2007.1

More Recent Results (2007):

Asymptotic closed form calibration with randomized targetsInteresting probability results/techniquesARCH 2008.1

This year? Numerical examples and extensions

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 2

/ 36

Page 10: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Introduction

Work in progress on cash �ow testing interest rate modelsEmpirical Work In Valuation Actuary Practice (1990�s):

Unconstrained lognormal models have too much tailMean-reverting ones have too little shoulderRandomizing the reversion target �xes itTrial and error calibration2001 Valuation Actuary Symposium Proceedings

Theoretical Work (2006):Closed form calibration for the mean-reverting lognormal

A surprising drift formula for the mean-reverting lognormalCouldn�t get closed form calibration with randomized targetsARCH 2007.1

More Recent Results (2007):

Asymptotic closed form calibration with randomized targetsInteresting probability results/techniquesARCH 2008.1

This year? Numerical examples and extensions

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 2

/ 36

Page 11: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Introduction

Work in progress on cash �ow testing interest rate modelsEmpirical Work In Valuation Actuary Practice (1990�s):

Unconstrained lognormal models have too much tailMean-reverting ones have too little shoulderRandomizing the reversion target �xes itTrial and error calibration2001 Valuation Actuary Symposium Proceedings

Theoretical Work (2006):Closed form calibration for the mean-reverting lognormalA surprising drift formula for the mean-reverting lognormal

Couldn�t get closed form calibration with randomized targetsARCH 2007.1

More Recent Results (2007):

Asymptotic closed form calibration with randomized targetsInteresting probability results/techniquesARCH 2008.1

This year? Numerical examples and extensions

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 2

/ 36

Page 12: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Introduction

Work in progress on cash �ow testing interest rate modelsEmpirical Work In Valuation Actuary Practice (1990�s):

Unconstrained lognormal models have too much tailMean-reverting ones have too little shoulderRandomizing the reversion target �xes itTrial and error calibration2001 Valuation Actuary Symposium Proceedings

Theoretical Work (2006):Closed form calibration for the mean-reverting lognormalA surprising drift formula for the mean-reverting lognormalCouldn�t get closed form calibration with randomized targets

ARCH 2007.1

More Recent Results (2007):

Asymptotic closed form calibration with randomized targetsInteresting probability results/techniquesARCH 2008.1

This year? Numerical examples and extensions

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 2

/ 36

Page 13: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Introduction

Work in progress on cash �ow testing interest rate modelsEmpirical Work In Valuation Actuary Practice (1990�s):

Unconstrained lognormal models have too much tailMean-reverting ones have too little shoulderRandomizing the reversion target �xes itTrial and error calibration2001 Valuation Actuary Symposium Proceedings

Theoretical Work (2006):Closed form calibration for the mean-reverting lognormalA surprising drift formula for the mean-reverting lognormalCouldn�t get closed form calibration with randomized targetsARCH 2007.1

More Recent Results (2007):

Asymptotic closed form calibration with randomized targetsInteresting probability results/techniquesARCH 2008.1

This year? Numerical examples and extensions

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 2

/ 36

Page 14: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Introduction

Work in progress on cash �ow testing interest rate modelsEmpirical Work In Valuation Actuary Practice (1990�s):

Unconstrained lognormal models have too much tailMean-reverting ones have too little shoulderRandomizing the reversion target �xes itTrial and error calibration2001 Valuation Actuary Symposium Proceedings

Theoretical Work (2006):Closed form calibration for the mean-reverting lognormalA surprising drift formula for the mean-reverting lognormalCouldn�t get closed form calibration with randomized targetsARCH 2007.1

More Recent Results (2007):

Asymptotic closed form calibration with randomized targetsInteresting probability results/techniquesARCH 2008.1

This year? Numerical examples and extensions

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 2

/ 36

Page 15: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Introduction

Work in progress on cash �ow testing interest rate modelsEmpirical Work In Valuation Actuary Practice (1990�s):

Unconstrained lognormal models have too much tailMean-reverting ones have too little shoulderRandomizing the reversion target �xes itTrial and error calibration2001 Valuation Actuary Symposium Proceedings

Theoretical Work (2006):Closed form calibration for the mean-reverting lognormalA surprising drift formula for the mean-reverting lognormalCouldn�t get closed form calibration with randomized targetsARCH 2007.1

More Recent Results (2007):Asymptotic closed form calibration with randomized targets

Interesting probability results/techniquesARCH 2008.1

This year? Numerical examples and extensions

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 2

/ 36

Page 16: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Introduction

Work in progress on cash �ow testing interest rate modelsEmpirical Work In Valuation Actuary Practice (1990�s):

Unconstrained lognormal models have too much tailMean-reverting ones have too little shoulderRandomizing the reversion target �xes itTrial and error calibration2001 Valuation Actuary Symposium Proceedings

Theoretical Work (2006):Closed form calibration for the mean-reverting lognormalA surprising drift formula for the mean-reverting lognormalCouldn�t get closed form calibration with randomized targetsARCH 2007.1

More Recent Results (2007):Asymptotic closed form calibration with randomized targetsInteresting probability results/techniques

ARCH 2008.1

This year? Numerical examples and extensions

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 2

/ 36

Page 17: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Introduction

Work in progress on cash �ow testing interest rate modelsEmpirical Work In Valuation Actuary Practice (1990�s):

Unconstrained lognormal models have too much tailMean-reverting ones have too little shoulderRandomizing the reversion target �xes itTrial and error calibration2001 Valuation Actuary Symposium Proceedings

Theoretical Work (2006):Closed form calibration for the mean-reverting lognormalA surprising drift formula for the mean-reverting lognormalCouldn�t get closed form calibration with randomized targetsARCH 2007.1

More Recent Results (2007):Asymptotic closed form calibration with randomized targetsInteresting probability results/techniquesARCH 2008.1

This year? Numerical examples and extensions

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 2

/ 36

Page 18: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Introduction

Work in progress on cash �ow testing interest rate modelsEmpirical Work In Valuation Actuary Practice (1990�s):

Unconstrained lognormal models have too much tailMean-reverting ones have too little shoulderRandomizing the reversion target �xes itTrial and error calibration2001 Valuation Actuary Symposium Proceedings

Theoretical Work (2006):Closed form calibration for the mean-reverting lognormalA surprising drift formula for the mean-reverting lognormalCouldn�t get closed form calibration with randomized targetsARCH 2007.1

More Recent Results (2007):Asymptotic closed form calibration with randomized targetsInteresting probability results/techniquesARCH 2008.1

This year? Numerical examples and extensionsBridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random Regimes

Actuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 2/ 36

Page 19: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Example: 55 Years of the 10-year Treasury Rate

 10 YEAR TREASURY RATE 1953­2007 (monthly data)

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 3

/ 36

Page 20: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

The Distribution of those Interest Rates

FREQUENCY OF 10 YEAR RATES

0.00

0.02

0.04

0.06

0.08

0.10

0.12

0.14

0.16

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24

DATA LOGNORMAL

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 4

/ 36

Page 21: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Lognormal 4th Moment Is Just Too High (6th too)

FREQUENCY OF 10 YEAR RATES

0.00

0.02

0.04

0.06

0.08

0.10

0.12

0.14

0.16

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24

DATA LOGNORMAL

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 5

/ 36

Page 22: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

55 Years of Changes in the 10 Year Treasury Rate

MONTHLY LOG­CHANGE IN 10 YEAR RATE

­0.2

­0.15

­0.1

­0.05

0

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 6

/ 36

Page 23: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

What is the Distribution of Those Changes?

FREQUENCY OF MONTHLY LOG­CHANGE IN 10 YEAR RATES

0

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04

0.05

0.06

0.07

0.08

DATA GAUSSIAN

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 7

/ 36

Page 24: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

For Rate Changes, Lognormal 4th Moment Too Low

FREQUENCY OF MONTHLY LOG­CHANGE IN 10 YEAR RATE

0

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04

0.05

0.06

0.07

0.08

DATA GAUSSIAN

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 8

/ 36

Page 25: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

The Fix: Randomize the Reversion Target

50 YEAR SAMPLE PATH (A DANGEROUS ONE)

0

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04

0.05

0.06

0.07

0.08

0.09

0.1PATH TARGET

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 9

/ 36

Page 26: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Lognormal Models

Unconstrained:

d ln (r t )=Dtdt + σpdtNt

d ln(rt ) = Dtdt + σdWt

Mean-reverting:

d ln (r t )=h1� (1� F )dt

i[ln(T0)� ln(rt�dt )]

+ (1� F )dt Dtdt + (1� F )dt σpdtNt

actuarial folklore (circa 1970)d ln(rt ) = f� ln (1� F ) [ln(T0)� ln(rt )] +Dtg dt + σdWtBlack-Karasinski (1991)

With Randomized Reversion Target

d ln (r t )=h1� (1� F )dt

i " ∞

∑j=0

1[j,j+1)(t) ln(Tj )� ln(rt�dt )#

+ (1� F )dt Dtdt + (1� F )dt σpdtNt , where 1[j,j+1) (t) is

the indicator for t to be in a random interval�tj, tj+1

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 10

/ 36

Page 27: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Lognormal Models

Unconstrained:

d ln (r t )=Dtdt + σpdtNt

d ln(rt ) = Dtdt + σdWt

Mean-reverting:

d ln (r t )=h1� (1� F )dt

i[ln(T0)� ln(rt�dt )]

+ (1� F )dt Dtdt + (1� F )dt σpdtNt

actuarial folklore (circa 1970)d ln(rt ) = f� ln (1� F ) [ln(T0)� ln(rt )] +Dtg dt + σdWtBlack-Karasinski (1991)

With Randomized Reversion Target

d ln (r t )=h1� (1� F )dt

i " ∞

∑j=0

1[j,j+1)(t) ln(Tj )� ln(rt�dt )#

+ (1� F )dt Dtdt + (1� F )dt σpdtNt , where 1[j,j+1) (t) is

the indicator for t to be in a random interval�tj, tj+1

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 10

/ 36

Page 28: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Lognormal Models

Unconstrained:

d ln (r t )=Dtdt + σpdtNt

d ln(rt ) = Dtdt + σdWt

Mean-reverting:

d ln (r t )=h1� (1� F )dt

i[ln(T0)� ln(rt�dt )]

+ (1� F )dt Dtdt + (1� F )dt σpdtNt

actuarial folklore (circa 1970)d ln(rt ) = f� ln (1� F ) [ln(T0)� ln(rt )] +Dtg dt + σdWtBlack-Karasinski (1991)

With Randomized Reversion Target

d ln (r t )=h1� (1� F )dt

i " ∞

∑j=0

1[j,j+1)(t) ln(Tj )� ln(rt�dt )#

+ (1� F )dt Dtdt + (1� F )dt σpdtNt , where 1[j,j+1) (t) is

the indicator for t to be in a random interval�tj, tj+1

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 10

/ 36

Page 29: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Lognormal Models

Unconstrained:

d ln (r t )=Dtdt + σpdtNt

d ln(rt ) = Dtdt + σdWt

Mean-reverting:

d ln (r t )=h1� (1� F )dt

i[ln(T0)� ln(rt�dt )]

+ (1� F )dt Dtdt + (1� F )dt σpdtNt

actuarial folklore (circa 1970)d ln(rt ) = f� ln (1� F ) [ln(T0)� ln(rt )] +Dtg dt + σdWtBlack-Karasinski (1991)

With Randomized Reversion Target

d ln (r t )=h1� (1� F )dt

i " ∞

∑j=0

1[j,j+1)(t) ln(Tj )� ln(rt�dt )#

+ (1� F )dt Dtdt + (1� F )dt σpdtNt , where 1[j,j+1) (t) is

the indicator for t to be in a random interval�tj, tj+1

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 10

/ 36

Page 30: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Lognormal Models

Unconstrained:

d ln (r t )=Dtdt + σpdtNt

d ln(rt ) = Dtdt + σdWt

Mean-reverting:

d ln (r t )=h1� (1� F )dt

i[ln(T0)� ln(rt�dt )]

+ (1� F )dt Dtdt + (1� F )dt σpdtNt

actuarial folklore (circa 1970)

d ln(rt ) = f� ln (1� F ) [ln(T0)� ln(rt )] +Dtg dt + σdWtBlack-Karasinski (1991)

With Randomized Reversion Target

d ln (r t )=h1� (1� F )dt

i " ∞

∑j=0

1[j,j+1)(t) ln(Tj )� ln(rt�dt )#

+ (1� F )dt Dtdt + (1� F )dt σpdtNt , where 1[j,j+1) (t) is

the indicator for t to be in a random interval�tj, tj+1

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 10

/ 36

Page 31: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Lognormal Models

Unconstrained:

d ln (r t )=Dtdt + σpdtNt

d ln(rt ) = Dtdt + σdWt

Mean-reverting:

d ln (r t )=h1� (1� F )dt

i[ln(T0)� ln(rt�dt )]

+ (1� F )dt Dtdt + (1� F )dt σpdtNt

actuarial folklore (circa 1970)d ln(rt ) = f� ln (1� F ) [ln(T0)� ln(rt )] +Dtg dt + σdWtBlack-Karasinski (1991)

With Randomized Reversion Target

d ln (r t )=h1� (1� F )dt

i " ∞

∑j=0

1[j,j+1)(t) ln(Tj )� ln(rt�dt )#

+ (1� F )dt Dtdt + (1� F )dt σpdtNt , where 1[j,j+1) (t) is

the indicator for t to be in a random interval�tj, tj+1

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 10

/ 36

Page 32: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Lognormal Models

Unconstrained:

d ln (r t )=Dtdt + σpdtNt

d ln(rt ) = Dtdt + σdWt

Mean-reverting:

d ln (r t )=h1� (1� F )dt

i[ln(T0)� ln(rt�dt )]

+ (1� F )dt Dtdt + (1� F )dt σpdtNt

actuarial folklore (circa 1970)d ln(rt ) = f� ln (1� F ) [ln(T0)� ln(rt )] +Dtg dt + σdWtBlack-Karasinski (1991)

With Randomized Reversion Target

d ln (r t )=h1� (1� F )dt

i " ∞

∑j=0

1[j,j+1)(t) ln(Tj )� ln(rt�dt )#

+ (1� F )dt Dtdt + (1� F )dt σpdtNt , where 1[j,j+1) (t) is

the indicator for t to be in a random interval�tj, tj+1

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 10

/ 36

Page 33: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Lognormal Models

Unconstrained:

d ln (r t )=Dtdt + σpdtNt

d ln(rt ) = Dtdt + σdWt

Mean-reverting:

d ln (r t )=h1� (1� F )dt

i[ln(T0)� ln(rt�dt )]

+ (1� F )dt Dtdt + (1� F )dt σpdtNt

actuarial folklore (circa 1970)d ln(rt ) = f� ln (1� F ) [ln(T0)� ln(rt )] +Dtg dt + σdWtBlack-Karasinski (1991)

With Randomized Reversion Target

d ln (r t )=h1� (1� F )dt

i " ∞

∑j=0

1[j,j+1)(t) ln(Tj )� ln(rt�dt )#

+ (1� F )dt Dtdt + (1� F )dt σpdtNt , where 1[j,j+1) (t) is

the indicator for t to be in a random interval�tj, tj+1

�Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random Regimes

Actuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 10/ 36

Page 34: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Lognormal Models

Mean-reverting:

d ln (r t )=h1� (1� F )dt

i[ln(T0)� ln(rt�dt )]

+ (1� F )dt Dtdt + (1� F )dt σpdtNt

actuarial folklore (circa 1970)d ln(rt ) = f� ln (1� F ) [ln(T0)� ln(rt )] +Dtg dt + σdWtBlack-Karasinski (1991)

With Randomized Reversion Target

d ln (r t )=h1� (1� F )dt

i " ∞

∑j=0

1[j,j+1)(t) ln(Tj )� ln(rt�dt )#

+ (1� F )dt Dtdt + (1� F )dt σpdtNt , where 1[j,j+1) (t) is

the indicator for t to be in a random interval�tj, tj+1

�d ln(rt ) = � ln (1� F )

"∞

∑j=0

1[j ,j+1)(t) ln(Tj )� ln(rt )#dt

+Dtdt + σdWt

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 11

/ 36

Page 35: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Lognormal Models

Mean-reverting:

d ln (r t )=h1� (1� F )dt

i[ln(T0)� ln(rt�dt )]

+ (1� F )dt Dtdt + (1� F )dt σpdtNt

actuarial folklore (circa 1970)

d ln(rt ) = f� ln (1� F ) [ln(T0)� ln(rt )] +Dtg dt + σdWtBlack-Karasinski (1991)

With Randomized Reversion Target

d ln (r t )=h1� (1� F )dt

i " ∞

∑j=0

1[j,j+1)(t) ln(Tj )� ln(rt�dt )#

+ (1� F )dt Dtdt + (1� F )dt σpdtNt , where 1[j,j+1) (t) is

the indicator for t to be in a random interval�tj, tj+1

�d ln(rt ) = � ln (1� F )

"∞

∑j=0

1[j ,j+1)(t) ln(Tj )� ln(rt )#dt

+Dtdt + σdWt

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 11

/ 36

Page 36: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Lognormal Models

Mean-reverting:

d ln (r t )=h1� (1� F )dt

i[ln(T0)� ln(rt�dt )]

+ (1� F )dt Dtdt + (1� F )dt σpdtNt

actuarial folklore (circa 1970)d ln(rt ) = f� ln (1� F ) [ln(T0)� ln(rt )] +Dtg dt + σdWtBlack-Karasinski (1991)

With Randomized Reversion Target

d ln (r t )=h1� (1� F )dt

i " ∞

∑j=0

1[j,j+1)(t) ln(Tj )� ln(rt�dt )#

+ (1� F )dt Dtdt + (1� F )dt σpdtNt , where 1[j,j+1) (t) is

the indicator for t to be in a random interval�tj, tj+1

�d ln(rt ) = � ln (1� F )

"∞

∑j=0

1[j ,j+1)(t) ln(Tj )� ln(rt )#dt

+Dtdt + σdWt

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 11

/ 36

Page 37: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Lognormal Models

Mean-reverting:

d ln (r t )=h1� (1� F )dt

i[ln(T0)� ln(rt�dt )]

+ (1� F )dt Dtdt + (1� F )dt σpdtNt

actuarial folklore (circa 1970)d ln(rt ) = f� ln (1� F ) [ln(T0)� ln(rt )] +Dtg dt + σdWtBlack-Karasinski (1991)

With Randomized Reversion Target

d ln (r t )=h1� (1� F )dt

i " ∞

∑j=0

1[j,j+1)(t) ln(Tj )� ln(rt�dt )#

+ (1� F )dt Dtdt + (1� F )dt σpdtNt , where 1[j,j+1) (t) is

the indicator for t to be in a random interval�tj, tj+1

�d ln(rt ) = � ln (1� F )

"∞

∑j=0

1[j ,j+1)(t) ln(Tj )� ln(rt )#dt

+Dtdt + σdWt

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 11

/ 36

Page 38: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Lognormal Models

Mean-reverting:

d ln (r t )=h1� (1� F )dt

i[ln(T0)� ln(rt�dt )]

+ (1� F )dt Dtdt + (1� F )dt σpdtNt

actuarial folklore (circa 1970)d ln(rt ) = f� ln (1� F ) [ln(T0)� ln(rt )] +Dtg dt + σdWtBlack-Karasinski (1991)

With Randomized Reversion Target

d ln (r t )=h1� (1� F )dt

i " ∞

∑j=0

1[j,j+1)(t) ln(Tj )� ln(rt�dt )#

+ (1� F )dt Dtdt + (1� F )dt σpdtNt , where 1[j,j+1) (t) is

the indicator for t to be in a random interval�tj, tj+1

d ln(rt ) = � ln (1� F )"

∑j=0

1[j ,j+1)(t) ln(Tj )� ln(rt )#dt

+Dtdt + σdWt

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 11

/ 36

Page 39: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Lognormal Models

Mean-reverting:

d ln (r t )=h1� (1� F )dt

i[ln(T0)� ln(rt�dt )]

+ (1� F )dt Dtdt + (1� F )dt σpdtNt

actuarial folklore (circa 1970)d ln(rt ) = f� ln (1� F ) [ln(T0)� ln(rt )] +Dtg dt + σdWtBlack-Karasinski (1991)

With Randomized Reversion Target

d ln (r t )=h1� (1� F )dt

i " ∞

∑j=0

1[j,j+1)(t) ln(Tj )� ln(rt�dt )#

+ (1� F )dt Dtdt + (1� F )dt σpdtNt , where 1[j,j+1) (t) is

the indicator for t to be in a random interval�tj, tj+1

�d ln(rt ) = � ln (1� F )

"∞

∑j=0

1[j ,j+1)(t) ln(Tj )� ln(rt )#dt

+Dtdt + σdWt

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 11

/ 36

Page 40: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Drift Compensation and Calibration: plain mean-reversion

It would be intuitive to have:

E [rt ] = r(1�F )t0 T

[1�(1�F )t ]0

To �nd out what drift Dt will ensure it, you can integrate d ln(rt ) :

ln(rt ) = ln(r0) (1� F )tdt dt + σ

pdt

tdt

∑s=1

Nt�(s�1)dt (1� F )sdt

+ ln(T0)h1� (1� F )dt

i tdt

∑s=1(1� F )(s�1)dt (= notice geom. series

+dt

tdt

∑s=1

Dt�(s�1)dt (1� F )sdt which simpli�es to:

ln(rt ) = ln(r0) (1� F )t + σpdt

tdt

∑s=1

Nt�(s�1)dt (1� F )sdt

+ ln(T0)�1� (1� F )t

�+ dt

tdt

∑s=1

Dt�(s�1)dt (1� F )sdt , which is

Gaussian.

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 12

/ 36

Page 41: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Drift Compensation and Calibration: plain mean-reversion

It would be intuitive to have:

E [rt ] = r(1�F )t0 T

[1�(1�F )t ]0

To �nd out what drift Dt will ensure it, you can integrate d ln(rt ) :

ln(rt ) = ln(r0) (1� F )tdt dt + σ

pdt

tdt

∑s=1

Nt�(s�1)dt (1� F )sdt

+ ln(T0)h1� (1� F )dt

i tdt

∑s=1(1� F )(s�1)dt (= notice geom. series

+dt

tdt

∑s=1

Dt�(s�1)dt (1� F )sdt which simpli�es to:

ln(rt ) = ln(r0) (1� F )t + σpdt

tdt

∑s=1

Nt�(s�1)dt (1� F )sdt

+ ln(T0)�1� (1� F )t

�+ dt

tdt

∑s=1

Dt�(s�1)dt (1� F )sdt , which is

Gaussian.Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random Regimes

Actuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 12/ 36

Page 42: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Drift Compensation and Calibration: plain mean-reversion

Since ln(rt ) is Gaussian, E [rt ] = eµ+ 12 σ2where the µ and σ2 are

some mess determined by the constants in the expression for ln(rt ).

If you work that mess out and set it equal to r (1�F )t

0 T[1�(1�F )t ]0 ,

and require that it be true for all t, you can arrive at what the driftcompensation function Dt must be to deliver the intuitive E [rt ] :

Dt = � 12σ2(1�F )dt

1+(1�F )dth1+ (1� F )2t�dt

i, or

Dt = � 14σ2h1+ (1� F )2t

iin the continuous case

There is a similar closed form for the variance of rt based onE�r2t�= e2µ+ 1

2 (2σ)2which can help calibrate the model to historical

variance F = 1�n1� σ2obsdt

ln(Vobs+T 2)�ln(T 2)

o 12dt

Practical work with the randomized reversion target model all butrequires you to know similar closed forms for drift compensation andvariance, but now when you integrate no geometric series appears.

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 13

/ 36

Page 43: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Drift Compensation and Calibration: plain mean-reversion

Since ln(rt ) is Gaussian, E [rt ] = eµ+ 12 σ2where the µ and σ2 are

some mess determined by the constants in the expression for ln(rt ).

If you work that mess out and set it equal to r (1�F )t

0 T[1�(1�F )t ]0 ,

and require that it be true for all t, you can arrive at what the driftcompensation function Dt must be to deliver the intuitive E [rt ] :

Dt = � 12σ2(1�F )dt

1+(1�F )dth1+ (1� F )2t�dt

i, or

Dt = � 14σ2h1+ (1� F )2t

iin the continuous case

There is a similar closed form for the variance of rt based onE�r2t�= e2µ+ 1

2 (2σ)2which can help calibrate the model to historical

variance F = 1�n1� σ2obsdt

ln(Vobs+T 2)�ln(T 2)

o 12dt

Practical work with the randomized reversion target model all butrequires you to know similar closed forms for drift compensation andvariance, but now when you integrate no geometric series appears.

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 13

/ 36

Page 44: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Drift Compensation and Calibration: plain mean-reversion

Since ln(rt ) is Gaussian, E [rt ] = eµ+ 12 σ2where the µ and σ2 are

some mess determined by the constants in the expression for ln(rt ).

If you work that mess out and set it equal to r (1�F )t

0 T[1�(1�F )t ]0 ,

and require that it be true for all t, you can arrive at what the driftcompensation function Dt must be to deliver the intuitive E [rt ] :

Dt = � 12σ2(1�F )dt

1+(1�F )dth1+ (1� F )2t�dt

i, or

Dt = � 14σ2h1+ (1� F )2t

iin the continuous case

There is a similar closed form for the variance of rt based onE�r2t�= e2µ+ 1

2 (2σ)2which can help calibrate the model to historical

variance F = 1�n1� σ2obsdt

ln(Vobs+T 2)�ln(T 2)

o 12dt

Practical work with the randomized reversion target model all butrequires you to know similar closed forms for drift compensation andvariance, but now when you integrate no geometric series appears.

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 13

/ 36

Page 45: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Drift Compensation and Calibration: plain mean-reversion

Since ln(rt ) is Gaussian, E [rt ] = eµ+ 12 σ2where the µ and σ2 are

some mess determined by the constants in the expression for ln(rt ).

If you work that mess out and set it equal to r (1�F )t

0 T[1�(1�F )t ]0 ,

and require that it be true for all t, you can arrive at what the driftcompensation function Dt must be to deliver the intuitive E [rt ] :

Dt = � 12σ2(1�F )dt

1+(1�F )dth1+ (1� F )2t�dt

i, or

Dt = � 14σ2h1+ (1� F )2t

iin the continuous case

There is a similar closed form for the variance of rt based onE�r2t�= e2µ+ 1

2 (2σ)2which can help calibrate the model to historical

variance F = 1�n1� σ2obsdt

ln(Vobs+T 2)�ln(T 2)

o 12dt

Practical work with the randomized reversion target model all butrequires you to know similar closed forms for drift compensation andvariance, but now when you integrate no geometric series appears.

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 13

/ 36

Page 46: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Drift Compensation and Calibration: plain mean-reversion

Since ln(rt ) is Gaussian, E [rt ] = eµ+ 12 σ2where the µ and σ2 are

some mess determined by the constants in the expression for ln(rt ).

If you work that mess out and set it equal to r (1�F )t

0 T[1�(1�F )t ]0 ,

and require that it be true for all t, you can arrive at what the driftcompensation function Dt must be to deliver the intuitive E [rt ] :

Dt = � 12σ2(1�F )dt

1+(1�F )dth1+ (1� F )2t�dt

i, or

Dt = � 14σ2h1+ (1� F )2t

iin the continuous case

There is a similar closed form for the variance of rt based onE�r2t�= e2µ+ 1

2 (2σ)2which can help calibrate the model to historical

variance F = 1�n1� σ2obsdt

ln(Vobs+T 2)�ln(T 2)

o 12dt

Practical work with the randomized reversion target model all butrequires you to know similar closed forms for drift compensation andvariance, but now when you integrate no geometric series appears.

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 13

/ 36

Page 47: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Drift Compensation and Calibration: plain mean-reversion

Since ln(rt ) is Gaussian, E [rt ] = eµ+ 12 σ2where the µ and σ2 are

some mess determined by the constants in the expression for ln(rt ).

If you work that mess out and set it equal to r (1�F )t

0 T[1�(1�F )t ]0 ,

and require that it be true for all t, you can arrive at what the driftcompensation function Dt must be to deliver the intuitive E [rt ] :

Dt = � 12σ2(1�F )dt

1+(1�F )dth1+ (1� F )2t�dt

i, or

Dt = � 14σ2h1+ (1� F )2t

iin the continuous case

There is a similar closed form for the variance of rt based onE�r2t�= e2µ+ 1

2 (2σ)2which can help calibrate the model to historical

variance F = 1�n1� σ2obsdt

ln(Vobs+T 2)�ln(T 2)

o 12dt

Practical work with the randomized reversion target model all butrequires you to know similar closed forms for drift compensation andvariance, but now when you integrate no geometric series appears.

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 13

/ 36

Page 48: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Drift Compensation & Calibration: random mean-reversion

ln(rt ) = ln(r0) (1� F )t + σpdt

tdt

∑s=1

Nt�(s�1)dt (1� F )sdt

+h1� (1� F )dt

i tdt

∑s=1

∑j=01[j,j+1)(sdt) ln(Tj ) (1� F )t�sdt (ugly

+dt

tdt

∑s=1

Dt�(s�1)dt (1� F )sdt

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 14

/ 36

Page 49: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Drift Compensation & Calibration: random mean-reversion

ln(rt ) = ln(r0) (1� F )t + σpdt

tdt

∑s=1

Nt�(s�1)dt (1� F )sdt

+h1� (1� F )dt

i tdt

∑s=1

∑j=01[j,j+1)(sdt) ln(Tj ) (1� F )t�sdt (ugly

+dt

tdt

∑s=1

Dt�(s�1)dt (1� F )sdt , but switch the order of summation:

ln(rt ) = ln(r0) (1� F )t + σpdt

tdt

∑s=1

Nt�(s�1)dt (1� F )sdt

+ ln(T0)h(1� F )(t�t1)+ � (1� F )t

i+

∑j=1ln(Tj )

h(1� F )(t�tj+1)+ � (1� F )(t�tj )+

i(=after telescoping

+dt

tdt

∑s=1

Dt�(s�1)dt (1� F )sdt , so rt 6= lognormal, = log-log-gamma?

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 15

/ 36

Page 50: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Drift Compensation & Calibration: random mean-reversion

ln(rt ) = ln(r0) (1� F )t + σpdt

tdt

∑s=1

Nt�(s�1)dt (1� F )sdt

+h1� (1� F )dt

i tdt

∑s=1

∑j=01[j,j+1)(sdt) ln(Tj ) (1� F )t�sdt (ugly

+dt

tdt

∑s=1

Dt�(s�1)dt (1� F )sdt , but switch the order of summation:

ln(rt ) = ln(r0) (1� F )t + σpdt

tdt

∑s=1

Nt�(s�1)dt (1� F )sdt

+ ln(T0)h(1� F )(t�t1)+ � (1� F )t

i+

∑j=1ln(Tj )

h(1� F )(t�tj+1)+ � (1� F )(t�tj )+

i(=after telescoping

+dt

tdt

∑s=1

Dt�(s�1)dt (1� F )sdt , so rt 6= lognormal, = log-log-gamma?Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random Regimes

Actuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 15/ 36

Page 51: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Condition on the Times When Regimes Switch

ln(rt ) = ln(r0) (1� F )t + σpdt

tdt

∑s=1

Nt�(s�1)dt (1� F )sdt

+ ln(T0)h(1� F )(t�t1)+ � (1� F )t

i+

∑j=1ln(Tj )

h(1� F )(t�tj+1)+ � (1� F )(t�tj )+

i+dt

tdt

∑s=1

Dt�(s�1)dt (1� F )sdt

Conditioning on the tj random variables and using a lognormal model(reasonable) for the random targets Tj (so each ln(Tj ) is Gaussian)we again have a (messy) Gaussian for the conditional ln(rt ). Canthat help in calculating an unconditioned E [rt ] and variance?

The answer is "Yes" ... up to an approximate expansion.

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 16

/ 36

Page 52: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Condition on the Times When Regimes Switch

ln(rt ) = ln(r0) (1� F )t + σpdt

tdt

∑s=1

Nt�(s�1)dt (1� F )sdt

+ ln(T0)h(1� F )(t�t1)+ � (1� F )t

i+

∑j=1ln(Tj )

h(1� F )(t�tj+1)+ � (1� F )(t�tj )+

i+dt

tdt

∑s=1

Dt�(s�1)dt (1� F )sdt

Conditioning on the tj random variables and using a lognormal model(reasonable) for the random targets Tj (so each ln(Tj ) is Gaussian)we again have a (messy) Gaussian for the conditional ln(rt ). Canthat help in calculating an unconditioned E [rt ] and variance?

The answer is "Yes" ... up to an approximate expansion.

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 16

/ 36

Page 53: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Condition on the Times When Regimes Switch

ln(rt ) = ln(r0) (1� F )t + σpdt

tdt

∑s=1

Nt�(s�1)dt (1� F )sdt

+ ln(T0)h(1� F )(t�t1)+ � (1� F )t

i+

∑j=1ln(Tj )

h(1� F )(t�tj+1)+ � (1� F )(t�tj )+

i+dt

tdt

∑s=1

Dt�(s�1)dt (1� F )sdt

Conditioning on the tj random variables and using a lognormal model(reasonable) for the random targets Tj (so each ln(Tj ) is Gaussian)we again have a (messy) Gaussian for the conditional ln(rt ). Canthat help in calculating an unconditioned E [rt ] and variance?

The answer is "Yes" ... up to an approximate expansion.

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 16

/ 36

Page 54: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Edgeworth Expansion for the Unconditioned Moments

We expect the tails of ln(rt ) to be supressed in favor of the shoulders.That suggests that E [rt ], and higher moments as well, might beapproximated e¢ ciently by an Edgeworth expansion for ln(rt ). Itworks out to be surprisingly simple:

Eh(rt )

li� e lµ+ 1

2 (lσ)2n1+ l4

4!

�µ4 � 3σ4

�oHere σ2 and µ4 stand for central moments of ln(rt ) and µ is itsmean.

� e lµ+ 12 (lσ)

2n1+ l4

4!

�µ4 � 3σ4

� �1� 3

4! (lσ)2�+ l6

6!

�µ6 � 15σ6

�o=

e lµ+12 (lσ)

2

(1+ limN!∞

N∑j=2

l2j(2j)!

hµ2j � (2j)?σ2j

i N�j∑n=0

(�1)n(2n)?(2n)! (lσ)2n

)where (2n)? = (2n� 1) (2n� 3) � � � (1)Conditional Gaussian ensures that odd higher moments vanish.

The problem now is to calculate µ, σ2, and the µ2j

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 17

/ 36

Page 55: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Edgeworth Expansion for the Unconditioned Moments

We expect the tails of ln(rt ) to be supressed in favor of the shoulders.That suggests that E [rt ], and higher moments as well, might beapproximated e¢ ciently by an Edgeworth expansion for ln(rt ). Itworks out to be surprisingly simple:

Eh(rt )

li� e lµ+ 1

2 (lσ)2n1+ l4

4!

�µ4 � 3σ4

�o

Here σ2 and µ4 stand for central moments of ln(rt ) and µ is itsmean.

� e lµ+ 12 (lσ)

2n1+ l4

4!

�µ4 � 3σ4

� �1� 3

4! (lσ)2�+ l6

6!

�µ6 � 15σ6

�o=

e lµ+12 (lσ)

2

(1+ limN!∞

N∑j=2

l2j(2j)!

hµ2j � (2j)?σ2j

i N�j∑n=0

(�1)n(2n)?(2n)! (lσ)2n

)where (2n)? = (2n� 1) (2n� 3) � � � (1)Conditional Gaussian ensures that odd higher moments vanish.

The problem now is to calculate µ, σ2, and the µ2j

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 17

/ 36

Page 56: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Edgeworth Expansion for the Unconditioned Moments

We expect the tails of ln(rt ) to be supressed in favor of the shoulders.That suggests that E [rt ], and higher moments as well, might beapproximated e¢ ciently by an Edgeworth expansion for ln(rt ). Itworks out to be surprisingly simple:

Eh(rt )

li� e lµ+ 1

2 (lσ)2n1+ l4

4!

�µ4 � 3σ4

�oHere σ2 and µ4 stand for central moments of ln(rt ) and µ is itsmean.

� e lµ+ 12 (lσ)

2n1+ l4

4!

�µ4 � 3σ4

� �1� 3

4! (lσ)2�+ l6

6!

�µ6 � 15σ6

�o=

e lµ+12 (lσ)

2

(1+ limN!∞

N∑j=2

l2j(2j)!

hµ2j � (2j)?σ2j

i N�j∑n=0

(�1)n(2n)?(2n)! (lσ)2n

)where (2n)? = (2n� 1) (2n� 3) � � � (1)Conditional Gaussian ensures that odd higher moments vanish.

The problem now is to calculate µ, σ2, and the µ2j

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 17

/ 36

Page 57: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Edgeworth Expansion for the Unconditioned Moments

We expect the tails of ln(rt ) to be supressed in favor of the shoulders.That suggests that E [rt ], and higher moments as well, might beapproximated e¢ ciently by an Edgeworth expansion for ln(rt ). Itworks out to be surprisingly simple:

Eh(rt )

li� e lµ+ 1

2 (lσ)2n1+ l4

4!

�µ4 � 3σ4

�oHere σ2 and µ4 stand for central moments of ln(rt ) and µ is itsmean.

� e lµ+ 12 (lσ)

2n1+ l4

4!

�µ4 � 3σ4

� �1� 3

4! (lσ)2�+ l6

6!

�µ6 � 15σ6

�o

=

e lµ+12 (lσ)

2

(1+ limN!∞

N∑j=2

l2j(2j)!

hµ2j � (2j)?σ2j

i N�j∑n=0

(�1)n(2n)?(2n)! (lσ)2n

)where (2n)? = (2n� 1) (2n� 3) � � � (1)Conditional Gaussian ensures that odd higher moments vanish.

The problem now is to calculate µ, σ2, and the µ2j

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 17

/ 36

Page 58: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Edgeworth Expansion for the Unconditioned Moments

We expect the tails of ln(rt ) to be supressed in favor of the shoulders.That suggests that E [rt ], and higher moments as well, might beapproximated e¢ ciently by an Edgeworth expansion for ln(rt ). Itworks out to be surprisingly simple:

Eh(rt )

li� e lµ+ 1

2 (lσ)2n1+ l4

4!

�µ4 � 3σ4

�oHere σ2 and µ4 stand for central moments of ln(rt ) and µ is itsmean.

� e lµ+ 12 (lσ)

2n1+ l4

4!

�µ4 � 3σ4

� �1� 3

4! (lσ)2�+ l6

6!

�µ6 � 15σ6

�o=

e lµ+12 (lσ)

2

(1+ limN!∞

N∑j=2

l2j(2j)!

hµ2j � (2j)?σ2j

i N�j∑n=0

(�1)n(2n)?(2n)! (lσ)2n

)where (2n)? = (2n� 1) (2n� 3) � � � (1)

Conditional Gaussian ensures that odd higher moments vanish.

The problem now is to calculate µ, σ2, and the µ2j

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 17

/ 36

Page 59: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Edgeworth Expansion for the Unconditioned Moments

We expect the tails of ln(rt ) to be supressed in favor of the shoulders.That suggests that E [rt ], and higher moments as well, might beapproximated e¢ ciently by an Edgeworth expansion for ln(rt ). Itworks out to be surprisingly simple:

Eh(rt )

li� e lµ+ 1

2 (lσ)2n1+ l4

4!

�µ4 � 3σ4

�oHere σ2 and µ4 stand for central moments of ln(rt ) and µ is itsmean.

� e lµ+ 12 (lσ)

2n1+ l4

4!

�µ4 � 3σ4

� �1� 3

4! (lσ)2�+ l6

6!

�µ6 � 15σ6

�o=

e lµ+12 (lσ)

2

(1+ limN!∞

N∑j=2

l2j(2j)!

hµ2j � (2j)?σ2j

i N�j∑n=0

(�1)n(2n)?(2n)! (lσ)2n

)where (2n)? = (2n� 1) (2n� 3) � � � (1)Conditional Gaussian ensures that odd higher moments vanish.

The problem now is to calculate µ, σ2, and the µ2j

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 17

/ 36

Page 60: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Edgeworth Expansion for the Unconditioned Moments

We expect the tails of ln(rt ) to be supressed in favor of the shoulders.That suggests that E [rt ], and higher moments as well, might beapproximated e¢ ciently by an Edgeworth expansion for ln(rt ). Itworks out to be surprisingly simple:

Eh(rt )

li� e lµ+ 1

2 (lσ)2n1+ l4

4!

�µ4 � 3σ4

�oHere σ2 and µ4 stand for central moments of ln(rt ) and µ is itsmean.

� e lµ+ 12 (lσ)

2n1+ l4

4!

�µ4 � 3σ4

� �1� 3

4! (lσ)2�+ l6

6!

�µ6 � 15σ6

�o=

e lµ+12 (lσ)

2

(1+ limN!∞

N∑j=2

l2j(2j)!

hµ2j � (2j)?σ2j

i N�j∑n=0

(�1)n(2n)?(2n)! (lσ)2n

)where (2n)? = (2n� 1) (2n� 3) � � � (1)Conditional Gaussian ensures that odd higher moments vanish.

The problem now is to calculate µ, σ2, and the µ2j

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 17

/ 36

Page 61: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Expected Value Easy

Remember,

ln(rt ) = ln(r0) (1� F )t + σpdt

tdt

∑s=1

Nt�(s�1)dt (1� F )sdt

+ ln(T0)h(1� F )(t�t1)+ � (1� F )t

i+

∑j=1ln(Tj )

h(1� F )(t�tj+1)+ � (1� F )(t�tj )+

i+dt

tdt

∑s=1

Dt�(s�1)dt (1� F )sdt and condition on the tj

So µ = E[ ln(rt )] is given by

ln(r0) (1� F )t + ln(T0)n

Eh(1� F )(t�t1)+

i� (1� F )t

o+µTE

"∞

∑j=1

h(1� F )(t�tj+1)+ � (1� F )(t�tj )+

i#

+dt

tdt

∑s=1

Dt�(s�1)dt (1� F )sdt where µT = E [ln(Tj )]

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 18

/ 36

Page 62: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Expected Value Easy

Remember,

ln(rt ) = ln(r0) (1� F )t + σpdt

tdt

∑s=1

Nt�(s�1)dt (1� F )sdt

+ ln(T0)h(1� F )(t�t1)+ � (1� F )t

i+

∑j=1ln(Tj )

h(1� F )(t�tj+1)+ � (1� F )(t�tj )+

i+dt

tdt

∑s=1

Dt�(s�1)dt (1� F )sdt and condition on the tj

So µ = E[ ln(rt )] is given by

ln(r0) (1� F )t + ln(T0)n

Eh(1� F )(t�t1)+

i� (1� F )t

o+µTE

"∞

∑j=1

h(1� F )(t�tj+1)+ � (1� F )(t�tj )+

i#

+dt

tdt

∑s=1

Dt�(s�1)dt (1� F )sdt where µT = E [ln(Tj )]Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random Regimes

Actuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 18/ 36

Page 63: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Expected Value Easy

So µ = E[ ln(rt )] is given by

ln(r0) (1� F )t + ln(T0)n

Eh(1� F )(t�t1)+

i� (1� F )t

o+µTE

"∞

∑j=1

h(1� F )(t�tj+1)+ � (1� F )(t�tj )+

i#

+dt

tdt

∑s=1

Dt�(s�1)dt (1� F )sdt where µT = E [ln(Tj )]

Telescoping,= ln(r0) (1� F )t + ln(T0)

nEh(1� F )(t�t1)+

i� (1� F )t

o+µT

n1�E

h(1� F )(t�t1)+

io+dt

tdt

∑s=1

Dt�(s�1)dt (1� F )sdt

Eh(1� F )(t�t1)+

iturns out to be a Laplace transform that we can

calculuate (later).

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 19

/ 36

Page 64: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Expected Value Easy

So µ = E[ ln(rt )] is given by

ln(r0) (1� F )t + ln(T0)n

Eh(1� F )(t�t1)+

i� (1� F )t

o+µTE

"∞

∑j=1

h(1� F )(t�tj+1)+ � (1� F )(t�tj )+

i#

+dt

tdt

∑s=1

Dt�(s�1)dt (1� F )sdt where µT = E [ln(Tj )]

Telescoping,= ln(r0) (1� F )t + ln(T0)

nEh(1� F )(t�t1)+

i� (1� F )t

o+µT

n1�E

h(1� F )(t�t1)+

io+dt

tdt

∑s=1

Dt�(s�1)dt (1� F )sdt

Eh(1� F )(t�t1)+

iturns out to be a Laplace transform that we can

calculuate (later).

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 19

/ 36

Page 65: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Expected Value Easy

So µ = E[ ln(rt )] is given by

ln(r0) (1� F )t + ln(T0)n

Eh(1� F )(t�t1)+

i� (1� F )t

o+µTE

"∞

∑j=1

h(1� F )(t�tj+1)+ � (1� F )(t�tj )+

i#

+dt

tdt

∑s=1

Dt�(s�1)dt (1� F )sdt where µT = E [ln(Tj )]

Telescoping,= ln(r0) (1� F )t + ln(T0)

nEh(1� F )(t�t1)+

i� (1� F )t

o+µT

n1�E

h(1� F )(t�t1)+

io+dt

tdt

∑s=1

Dt�(s�1)dt (1� F )sdt

Eh(1� F )(t�t1)+

iturns out to be a Laplace transform that we can

calculuate (later).

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 19

/ 36

Page 66: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Higher Moments Hard

Remembering that the even central moments of std normal are(2n)? = (2n� 1) (2n� 3) � � � (1), the even central moments ofln(rt ) are E

hfln(rt )�E [ln(rt )]g2n

i= (2n)?E

248<:σ2dt

tdt

∑s=1(1� F )2sdt + σ2T

∑j=1e2j

9=;n35

= (2n)?E

"(σ2dt (1� F )2dt 1�(1�F )

2t

1�(1�F )2dt+ σ2T

∑j=1e2j

)n#

σ2T is the common variance of the ln(Tj ) Gaussians

ej =n(1� F )(t�tj+1)+ � (1� F )(t�tj )+

ofor each j

The fgn part can be expanded binomially, but that still leaves termslike...

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 20

/ 36

Page 67: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Higher Moments Hard

Remembering that the even central moments of std normal are(2n)? = (2n� 1) (2n� 3) � � � (1), the even central moments ofln(rt ) are E

hfln(rt )�E [ln(rt )]g2n

i= (2n)?E

248<:σ2dt

tdt

∑s=1(1� F )2sdt + σ2T

∑j=1e2j

9=;n35

= (2n)?E

"(σ2dt (1� F )2dt 1�(1�F )

2t

1�(1�F )2dt+ σ2T

∑j=1e2j

)n#σ2T is the common variance of the ln(Tj ) Gaussians

ej =n(1� F )(t�tj+1)+ � (1� F )(t�tj )+

ofor each j

The fgn part can be expanded binomially, but that still leaves termslike...

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 20

/ 36

Page 68: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Higher Moments Hard

Remembering that the even central moments of std normal are(2n)? = (2n� 1) (2n� 3) � � � (1), the even central moments ofln(rt ) are E

hfln(rt )�E [ln(rt )]g2n

i= (2n)?E

248<:σ2dt

tdt

∑s=1(1� F )2sdt + σ2T

∑j=1e2j

9=;n35

= (2n)?E

"(σ2dt (1� F )2dt 1�(1�F )

2t

1�(1�F )2dt+ σ2T

∑j=1e2j

)n#σ2T is the common variance of the ln(Tj ) Gaussians

ej =n(1� F )(t�tj+1)+ � (1� F )(t�tj )+

ofor each j

The fgn part can be expanded binomially, but that still leaves termslike...

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 20

/ 36

Page 69: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Higher Moments Hard

Remembering that the even central moments of std normal are(2n)? = (2n� 1) (2n� 3) � � � (1), the even central moments ofln(rt ) are E

hfln(rt )�E [ln(rt )]g2n

i= (2n)?E

248<:σ2dt

tdt

∑s=1(1� F )2sdt + σ2T

∑j=1e2j

9=;n35

= (2n)?E

"(σ2dt (1� F )2dt 1�(1�F )

2t

1�(1�F )2dt+ σ2T

∑j=1e2j

)n#σ2T is the common variance of the ln(Tj ) Gaussians

ej =n(1� F )(t�tj+1)+ � (1� F )(t�tj )+

ofor each j

The fgn part can be expanded binomially, but that still leaves termslike...

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 20

/ 36

Page 70: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Still Need To Evaluate Terms Like

... E

" ∞

∑j=1e2j

!m#where the

ej =n(1� F )(t�tj+1)+ � (1� F )(t�tj )+

ofail to be independent and

are each complicated in their own right.

But they do have a uniform correlation property

Lemma: Ehe2a1j1 � � � e2akjk

i= ρa1,...,akE

he2a1j1

i� � �E

he2akjk

iindependent of fj1, ..., jkg for distinct fj1, ..., jkgρa1,...,ak can be computed using Laplace transforms and there�s even arecursive relationship ρa1,...,ak = ρa1,a2+...+ak ρa2,...,akHow does that help?

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 21

/ 36

Page 71: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Still Need To Evaluate Terms Like

... E

" ∞

∑j=1e2j

!m#where the

ej =n(1� F )(t�tj+1)+ � (1� F )(t�tj )+

ofail to be independent and

are each complicated in their own right.

But they do have a uniform correlation property

Lemma: Ehe2a1j1 � � � e2akjk

i= ρa1,...,akE

he2a1j1

i� � �E

he2akjk

iindependent of fj1, ..., jkg for distinct fj1, ..., jkgρa1,...,ak can be computed using Laplace transforms and there�s even arecursive relationship ρa1,...,ak = ρa1,a2+...+ak ρa2,...,akHow does that help?

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 21

/ 36

Page 72: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Still Need To Evaluate Terms Like

... E

" ∞

∑j=1e2j

!m#where the

ej =n(1� F )(t�tj+1)+ � (1� F )(t�tj )+

ofail to be independent and

are each complicated in their own right.

But they do have a uniform correlation property

Lemma: Ehe2a1j1 � � � e2akjk

i= ρa1,...,akE

he2a1j1

i� � �E

he2akjk

iindependent of fj1, ..., jkg for distinct fj1, ..., jkg

ρa1,...,ak can be computed using Laplace transforms and there�s even arecursive relationship ρa1,...,ak = ρa1,a2+...+ak ρa2,...,akHow does that help?

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 21

/ 36

Page 73: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Still Need To Evaluate Terms Like

... E

" ∞

∑j=1e2j

!m#where the

ej =n(1� F )(t�tj+1)+ � (1� F )(t�tj )+

ofail to be independent and

are each complicated in their own right.

But they do have a uniform correlation property

Lemma: Ehe2a1j1 � � � e2akjk

i= ρa1,...,akE

he2a1j1

i� � �E

he2akjk

iindependent of fj1, ..., jkg for distinct fj1, ..., jkgρa1,...,ak can be computed using Laplace transforms and there�s even arecursive relationship ρa1,...,ak = ρa1,a2+...+ak ρa2,...,ak

How does that help?

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 21

/ 36

Page 74: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Still Need To Evaluate Terms Like

... E

" ∞

∑j=1e2j

!m#where the

ej =n(1� F )(t�tj+1)+ � (1� F )(t�tj )+

ofail to be independent and

are each complicated in their own right.

But they do have a uniform correlation property

Lemma: Ehe2a1j1 � � � e2akjk

i= ρa1,...,akE

he2a1j1

i� � �E

he2akjk

iindependent of fj1, ..., jkg for distinct fj1, ..., jkgρa1,...,ak can be computed using Laplace transforms and there�s even arecursive relationship ρa1,...,ak = ρa1,a2+...+ak ρa2,...,akHow does that help?

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 21

/ 36

Page 75: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

For Example

E

24 ∞

∑j=1e2j

!235 = E

"∞

∑j=1e4j +

∑j=1e2j

( ∞

∑i=1e2i

!� e2j

)#

So E

24 ∞

∑j=1e2j

!235 = E

"∞

∑j=1e4j

#+

ρ1,1

8<:

E

"∞

∑j=1e2j

#!2� E

"∞

∑j=1e2j E

he2ji#9=; using monotone

convergence to run expectations across ∞ sums

It gets complicated fast

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 22

/ 36

Page 76: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

For Example

E

24 ∞

∑j=1e2j

!235 = E

"∞

∑j=1e4j +

∑j=1e2j

( ∞

∑i=1e2i

!� e2j

)#

So E

24 ∞

∑j=1e2j

!235 = E

"∞

∑j=1e4j

#+

ρ1,1

8<:

E

"∞

∑j=1e2j

#!2� E

"∞

∑j=1e2j E

he2ji#9=; using monotone

convergence to run expectations across ∞ sums

It gets complicated fast

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 22

/ 36

Page 77: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

For Example

E

24 ∞

∑j=1e2j

!235 = E

"∞

∑j=1e4j +

∑j=1e2j

( ∞

∑i=1e2i

!� e2j

)#

So E

24 ∞

∑j=1e2j

!235 = E

"∞

∑j=1e4j

#+

ρ1,1

8<:

E

"∞

∑j=1e2j

#!2� E

"∞

∑j=1e2j E

he2ji#9=; using monotone

convergence to run expectations across ∞ sums

It gets complicated fast

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 22

/ 36

Page 78: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

For m=3

E

24 ∞

∑j=1e2j

!335=E

26666666664

∑j=1e6j + 3

∑j=1e4j

( ∞

∑i=1e2i

!� e2j

)

+∞

∑j=1e2j

8>>>><>>>>:

∑i=1e2i

" ∞

∑k=1

e2k

!� e2i � e2j

#!

�e2j

" ∞

∑k=1

e2k

!� e2j

#+ e4j

9>>>>=>>>>;

37777777775=E

"∞

∑j=1e6j

#+ 3ρ2,1E

"∞

∑j=1e4j

#E

"∞

∑j=1e2j

#

��3ρ2,1 � ρ1,1,1

�E

"∞

∑j=1e4j E

he2ji#+ρ1,1,1

8<:

E

"∞

∑j=1e2j

#!3

�3E"

∑j=1e2j

#E

"∞

∑j=1e2j E

he2ji#

+E

"∞

∑j=1e2j�

Ehe2ji�2#)

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 23

/ 36

Page 79: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Complicated, but each piece is simpler

Now all you need to be able to evaluate are terms like

E

"∞

∑j=1e2nj

n∏k=1

�Ehe2kji�nk#

, where ∑nk=1 knk � m� n

In fact, we will develop a calculation that includes the odd powers

too, E

"∞

∑j=1enj

n∏k=1

�Ehekji�nk#

Some notation: to save ink later let ν(x) stand for xnn∏k=1

E�xk�nk so

our expression abbreviates to E

"∞

∑j=1

ν (ej )

#

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 24

/ 36

Page 80: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Complicated, but each piece is simpler

Now all you need to be able to evaluate are terms like

E

"∞

∑j=1e2nj

n∏k=1

�Ehe2kji�nk#

, where ∑nk=1 knk � m� n

In fact, we will develop a calculation that includes the odd powers

too, E

"∞

∑j=1enj

n∏k=1

�Ehekji�nk#

Some notation: to save ink later let ν(x) stand for xnn∏k=1

E�xk�nk so

our expression abbreviates to E

"∞

∑j=1

ν (ej )

#

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 24

/ 36

Page 81: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Complicated, but each piece is simpler

Now all you need to be able to evaluate are terms like

E

"∞

∑j=1e2nj

n∏k=1

�Ehe2kji�nk#

, where ∑nk=1 knk � m� n

In fact, we will develop a calculation that includes the odd powers

too, E

"∞

∑j=1enj

n∏k=1

�Ehekji�nk#

Some notation: to save ink later let ν(x) stand for xnn∏k=1

E�xk�nk so

our expression abbreviates to E

"∞

∑j=1

ν (ej )

#

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 24

/ 36

Page 82: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

The Set-Up

Let d1,d2, ...,dj , ...be i.i.d inter-arrival intervals with common law d

De�ne�d0 by the relationships 0 ��d0 � d1 and�d0 ' (d1 ��d0)Let�d stand for the common law of�d0 and (d1 ��d0), the equilibriumdistribution of dThe density f�d (x) =

P[d�x ]E[d]

De�ne�d1 = d1 ^ (�d0 + t)��d0, so we begin at a random point in the�rst i.i.d. interval

Set t0 = 0, t1 =�d1, ... , tj =�d1 + d2 + ...+ djLet J=min fj : tj � tg (a "stopping regime")De�ne random indicators f1j<Jgj�1 by 1j<J = 0 for j � J and1j<J = 1 for j < JSet�dJ = t � tJ�1 and�dJ+1 = tJ � tSo t =�d1 + d2 + ...+ dJ�1 +�dJ

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 25

/ 36

Page 83: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

The Set-Up

Let d1,d2, ...,dj , ...be i.i.d inter-arrival intervals with common law dDe�ne�d0 by the relationships 0 ��d0 � d1 and�d0 ' (d1 ��d0)

Let�d stand for the common law of�d0 and (d1 ��d0), the equilibriumdistribution of dThe density f�d (x) =

P[d�x ]E[d]

De�ne�d1 = d1 ^ (�d0 + t)��d0, so we begin at a random point in the�rst i.i.d. interval

Set t0 = 0, t1 =�d1, ... , tj =�d1 + d2 + ...+ djLet J=min fj : tj � tg (a "stopping regime")De�ne random indicators f1j<Jgj�1 by 1j<J = 0 for j � J and1j<J = 1 for j < JSet�dJ = t � tJ�1 and�dJ+1 = tJ � tSo t =�d1 + d2 + ...+ dJ�1 +�dJ

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 25

/ 36

Page 84: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

The Set-Up

Let d1,d2, ...,dj , ...be i.i.d inter-arrival intervals with common law dDe�ne�d0 by the relationships 0 ��d0 � d1 and�d0 ' (d1 ��d0)Let�d stand for the common law of�d0 and (d1 ��d0), the equilibriumdistribution of d

The density f�d (x) =P[d�x ]

E[d]

De�ne�d1 = d1 ^ (�d0 + t)��d0, so we begin at a random point in the�rst i.i.d. interval

Set t0 = 0, t1 =�d1, ... , tj =�d1 + d2 + ...+ djLet J=min fj : tj � tg (a "stopping regime")De�ne random indicators f1j<Jgj�1 by 1j<J = 0 for j � J and1j<J = 1 for j < JSet�dJ = t � tJ�1 and�dJ+1 = tJ � tSo t =�d1 + d2 + ...+ dJ�1 +�dJ

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 25

/ 36

Page 85: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

The Set-Up

Let d1,d2, ...,dj , ...be i.i.d inter-arrival intervals with common law dDe�ne�d0 by the relationships 0 ��d0 � d1 and�d0 ' (d1 ��d0)Let�d stand for the common law of�d0 and (d1 ��d0), the equilibriumdistribution of dThe density f�d (x) =

P[d�x ]E[d]

De�ne�d1 = d1 ^ (�d0 + t)��d0, so we begin at a random point in the�rst i.i.d. interval

Set t0 = 0, t1 =�d1, ... , tj =�d1 + d2 + ...+ djLet J=min fj : tj � tg (a "stopping regime")De�ne random indicators f1j<Jgj�1 by 1j<J = 0 for j � J and1j<J = 1 for j < JSet�dJ = t � tJ�1 and�dJ+1 = tJ � tSo t =�d1 + d2 + ...+ dJ�1 +�dJ

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 25

/ 36

Page 86: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

The Set-Up

Let d1,d2, ...,dj , ...be i.i.d inter-arrival intervals with common law dDe�ne�d0 by the relationships 0 ��d0 � d1 and�d0 ' (d1 ��d0)Let�d stand for the common law of�d0 and (d1 ��d0), the equilibriumdistribution of dThe density f�d (x) =

P[d�x ]E[d]

De�ne�d1 = d1 ^ (�d0 + t)��d0, so we begin at a random point in the�rst i.i.d. interval

Set t0 = 0, t1 =�d1, ... , tj =�d1 + d2 + ...+ djLet J=min fj : tj � tg (a "stopping regime")De�ne random indicators f1j<Jgj�1 by 1j<J = 0 for j � J and1j<J = 1 for j < JSet�dJ = t � tJ�1 and�dJ+1 = tJ � tSo t =�d1 + d2 + ...+ dJ�1 +�dJ

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 25

/ 36

Page 87: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

The Set-Up

Let d1,d2, ...,dj , ...be i.i.d inter-arrival intervals with common law dDe�ne�d0 by the relationships 0 ��d0 � d1 and�d0 ' (d1 ��d0)Let�d stand for the common law of�d0 and (d1 ��d0), the equilibriumdistribution of dThe density f�d (x) =

P[d�x ]E[d]

De�ne�d1 = d1 ^ (�d0 + t)��d0, so we begin at a random point in the�rst i.i.d. interval

Set t0 = 0, t1 =�d1, ... , tj =�d1 + d2 + ...+ dj

Let J=min fj : tj � tg (a "stopping regime")De�ne random indicators f1j<Jgj�1 by 1j<J = 0 for j � J and1j<J = 1 for j < JSet�dJ = t � tJ�1 and�dJ+1 = tJ � tSo t =�d1 + d2 + ...+ dJ�1 +�dJ

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 25

/ 36

Page 88: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

The Set-Up

Let d1,d2, ...,dj , ...be i.i.d inter-arrival intervals with common law dDe�ne�d0 by the relationships 0 ��d0 � d1 and�d0 ' (d1 ��d0)Let�d stand for the common law of�d0 and (d1 ��d0), the equilibriumdistribution of dThe density f�d (x) =

P[d�x ]E[d]

De�ne�d1 = d1 ^ (�d0 + t)��d0, so we begin at a random point in the�rst i.i.d. interval

Set t0 = 0, t1 =�d1, ... , tj =�d1 + d2 + ...+ djLet J=min fj : tj � tg (a "stopping regime")

De�ne random indicators f1j<Jgj�1 by 1j<J = 0 for j � J and1j<J = 1 for j < JSet�dJ = t � tJ�1 and�dJ+1 = tJ � tSo t =�d1 + d2 + ...+ dJ�1 +�dJ

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 25

/ 36

Page 89: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

The Set-Up

Let d1,d2, ...,dj , ...be i.i.d inter-arrival intervals with common law dDe�ne�d0 by the relationships 0 ��d0 � d1 and�d0 ' (d1 ��d0)Let�d stand for the common law of�d0 and (d1 ��d0), the equilibriumdistribution of dThe density f�d (x) =

P[d�x ]E[d]

De�ne�d1 = d1 ^ (�d0 + t)��d0, so we begin at a random point in the�rst i.i.d. interval

Set t0 = 0, t1 =�d1, ... , tj =�d1 + d2 + ...+ djLet J=min fj : tj � tg (a "stopping regime")De�ne random indicators f1j<Jgj�1 by 1j<J = 0 for j � J and1j<J = 1 for j < J

Set�dJ = t � tJ�1 and�dJ+1 = tJ � tSo t =�d1 + d2 + ...+ dJ�1 +�dJ

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 25

/ 36

Page 90: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

The Set-Up

Let d1,d2, ...,dj , ...be i.i.d inter-arrival intervals with common law dDe�ne�d0 by the relationships 0 ��d0 � d1 and�d0 ' (d1 ��d0)Let�d stand for the common law of�d0 and (d1 ��d0), the equilibriumdistribution of dThe density f�d (x) =

P[d�x ]E[d]

De�ne�d1 = d1 ^ (�d0 + t)��d0, so we begin at a random point in the�rst i.i.d. interval

Set t0 = 0, t1 =�d1, ... , tj =�d1 + d2 + ...+ djLet J=min fj : tj � tg (a "stopping regime")De�ne random indicators f1j<Jgj�1 by 1j<J = 0 for j � J and1j<J = 1 for j < JSet�dJ = t � tJ�1 and�dJ+1 = tJ � t

So t =�d1 + d2 + ...+ dJ�1 +�dJ

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 25

/ 36

Page 91: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

The Set-Up

Let d1,d2, ...,dj , ...be i.i.d inter-arrival intervals with common law dDe�ne�d0 by the relationships 0 ��d0 � d1 and�d0 ' (d1 ��d0)Let�d stand for the common law of�d0 and (d1 ��d0), the equilibriumdistribution of dThe density f�d (x) =

P[d�x ]E[d]

De�ne�d1 = d1 ^ (�d0 + t)��d0, so we begin at a random point in the�rst i.i.d. interval

Set t0 = 0, t1 =�d1, ... , tj =�d1 + d2 + ...+ djLet J=min fj : tj � tg (a "stopping regime")De�ne random indicators f1j<Jgj�1 by 1j<J = 0 for j � J and1j<J = 1 for j < JSet�dJ = t � tJ�1 and�dJ+1 = tJ � tSo t =�d1 + d2 + ...+ dJ�1 +�dJ

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 25

/ 36

Page 92: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

The Result

E

"∞

∑j=1

ν (ej )

#=

Kn

Ehν�(1� F )�d^t

�i�P [�d �t] ν

�(1� F )t

�o E[ν(1�(1�F )d)]1�E[ν((1�F )d)]

+Ehν�1� (1� F )�d^t

�i�P [�d �t] ν

�1� (1� F )t

Where K = 1�E

��Ehν�(1� F )d

�i�J�2j J > 1

�= 1� (1� G )t E[(1�G )�

�d^t ]�P[�d�t ](1�G )�t

E[(1�G )�d^t ]�P[�d�t ](1�G )t

And G is de�ned by (1� G ) = expn�L�1d (E

hν�(1� F )d

�i)o,

Ld being the Laplace transformMeaningEh(1� G )d

i= Ld

nL�1d (E

hν�(1� F )d

�io= E

hν�(1� F )d

�i

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 26

/ 36

Page 93: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

The Result

E

"∞

∑j=1

ν (ej )

#=

Kn

Ehν�(1� F )�d^t

�i�P [�d �t] ν

�(1� F )t

�o E[ν(1�(1�F )d)]1�E[ν((1�F )d)]

+Ehν�1� (1� F )�d^t

�i�P [�d �t] ν

�1� (1� F )t

�Where K = 1�E

��Ehν�(1� F )d

�i�J�2j J > 1

�= 1� (1� G )t E[(1�G )�

�d^t ]�P[�d�t ](1�G )�t

E[(1�G )�d^t ]�P[�d�t ](1�G )t

And G is de�ned by (1� G ) = expn�L�1d (E

hν�(1� F )d

�i)o,

Ld being the Laplace transformMeaningEh(1� G )d

i= Ld

nL�1d (E

hν�(1� F )d

�io= E

hν�(1� F )d

�i

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 26

/ 36

Page 94: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

The Result

E

"∞

∑j=1

ν (ej )

#=

Kn

Ehν�(1� F )�d^t

�i�P [�d �t] ν

�(1� F )t

�o E[ν(1�(1�F )d)]1�E[ν((1�F )d)]

+Ehν�1� (1� F )�d^t

�i�P [�d �t] ν

�1� (1� F )t

�Where K = 1�E

��Ehν�(1� F )d

�i�J�2j J > 1

�= 1� (1� G )t E[(1�G )�

�d^t ]�P[�d�t ](1�G )�t

E[(1�G )�d^t ]�P[�d�t ](1�G )t

And G is de�ned by (1� G ) = expn�L�1d (E

hν�(1� F )d

�i)o,

Ld being the Laplace transform

MeaningEh(1� G )d

i= Ld

nL�1d (E

hν�(1� F )d

�io= E

hν�(1� F )d

�i

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 26

/ 36

Page 95: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

The Result

E

"∞

∑j=1

ν (ej )

#=

Kn

Ehν�(1� F )�d^t

�i�P [�d �t] ν

�(1� F )t

�o E[ν(1�(1�F )d)]1�E[ν((1�F )d)]

+Ehν�1� (1� F )�d^t

�i�P [�d �t] ν

�1� (1� F )t

�Where K = 1�E

��Ehν�(1� F )d

�i�J�2j J > 1

�= 1� (1� G )t E[(1�G )�

�d^t ]�P[�d�t ](1�G )�t

E[(1�G )�d^t ]�P[�d�t ](1�G )t

And G is de�ned by (1� G ) = expn�L�1d (E

hν�(1� F )d

�i)o,

Ld being the Laplace transformMeaningEh(1� G )d

i= Ld

nL�1d (E

hν�(1� F )d

�io= E

hν�(1� F )d

�iBridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random Regimes

Actuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 26/ 36

Page 96: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Asymptotically

limt!∞ E

"∞

∑j=1

ν (ej )

#=

E[ν((1�F )�d)]E[ν(1�(1�F )d)]

1�E[ν((1�F )d)]+E

hν�1� (1� F )�d

�i

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 27

/ 36

Page 97: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Everything Is Closed Form

Everything is now of the form P [�d � t] and E [xv] for v one of therandom variables d, �d and�d^ t

E [xv] = Lv [� ln (x)], where Lv is the Laplace transform of vIf, for example, we take the interarrival distribution d forregime-switches to be gamma(α, β), then

Ld(x) = (1+ βx)�α, L�1d (y) = 1β

�y�

1α � 1

�,

L�d (x) = 1αβx

h1� (1+ βx)�α

i, L�d^t (x) =

1αβx

n1� e�xt

h1� Γ

�α; tβ

�i� (1+ βx)�α Γ

�α; (

1+βx )tβ

�o+e�xt

n1� Γ

�α+ 1; tβ

�� t

αβ

h1� Γ

�α; tβ

�io,

P [�d � t] = 1� Γ�

α+ 1; tβ

�� t

αβ

h1� Γ

�α; tβ

�i

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 28

/ 36

Page 98: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Everything Is Closed Form

Everything is now of the form P [�d � t] and E [xv] for v one of therandom variables d, �d and�d^ tE [xv] = Lv [� ln (x)], where Lv is the Laplace transform of v

If, for example, we take the interarrival distribution d forregime-switches to be gamma(α, β), then

Ld(x) = (1+ βx)�α, L�1d (y) = 1β

�y�

1α � 1

�,

L�d (x) = 1αβx

h1� (1+ βx)�α

i, L�d^t (x) =

1αβx

n1� e�xt

h1� Γ

�α; tβ

�i� (1+ βx)�α Γ

�α; (

1+βx )tβ

�o+e�xt

n1� Γ

�α+ 1; tβ

�� t

αβ

h1� Γ

�α; tβ

�io,

P [�d � t] = 1� Γ�

α+ 1; tβ

�� t

αβ

h1� Γ

�α; tβ

�i

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 28

/ 36

Page 99: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Everything Is Closed Form

Everything is now of the form P [�d � t] and E [xv] for v one of therandom variables d, �d and�d^ tE [xv] = Lv [� ln (x)], where Lv is the Laplace transform of vIf, for example, we take the interarrival distribution d forregime-switches to be gamma(α, β), then

Ld(x) = (1+ βx)�α, L�1d (y) = 1β

�y�

1α � 1

�,

L�d (x) = 1αβx

h1� (1+ βx)�α

i, L�d^t (x) =

1αβx

n1� e�xt

h1� Γ

�α; tβ

�i� (1+ βx)�α Γ

�α; (

1+βx )tβ

�o+e�xt

n1� Γ

�α+ 1; tβ

�� t

αβ

h1� Γ

�α; tβ

�io,

P [�d � t] = 1� Γ�

α+ 1; tβ

�� t

αβ

h1� Γ

�α; tβ

�i

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 28

/ 36

Page 100: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Everything Is Closed Form

Everything is now of the form P [�d � t] and E [xv] for v one of therandom variables d, �d and�d^ tE [xv] = Lv [� ln (x)], where Lv is the Laplace transform of vIf, for example, we take the interarrival distribution d forregime-switches to be gamma(α, β), then

Ld(x) = (1+ βx)�α, L�1d (y) = 1β

�y�

1α � 1

�,

L�d (x) = 1αβx

h1� (1+ βx)�α

i, L�d^t (x) =

1αβx

n1� e�xt

h1� Γ

�α; tβ

�i� (1+ βx)�α Γ

�α; (

1+βx )tβ

�o+e�xt

n1� Γ

�α+ 1; tβ

�� t

αβ

h1� Γ

�α; tβ

�io,

P [�d � t] = 1� Γ�

α+ 1; tβ

�� t

αβ

h1� Γ

�α; tβ

�i

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 28

/ 36

Page 101: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Even Those Uniform Correlation Coe¢ cients

ρa,b =1D

nEh(1� F )2(a�b)�d^t

i�P [�d � t] (1� F )2(a�b)t

o

where D =n

Eh(1� F )2a�d^t

i�P [�d � t] (1� F )2at

o�n

Eh(1� F )�2b�d^t

i�P [�d �t] (1� F )�2bt

oand ρa1,...,ak = ρa1,a2+...+ak ρa2,...,ak recursively

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 29

/ 36

Page 102: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Even Those Uniform Correlation Coe¢ cients

ρa,b =1D

nEh(1� F )2(a�b)�d^t

i�P [�d � t] (1� F )2(a�b)t

owhere D =

nEh(1� F )2a�d^t

i�P [�d � t] (1� F )2at

o�n

Eh(1� F )�2b�d^t

i�P [�d �t] (1� F )�2bt

o

and ρa1,...,ak = ρa1,a2+...+ak ρa2,...,ak recursively

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 29

/ 36

Page 103: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Even Those Uniform Correlation Coe¢ cients

ρa,b =1D

nEh(1� F )2(a�b)�d^t

i�P [�d � t] (1� F )2(a�b)t

owhere D =

nEh(1� F )2a�d^t

i�P [�d � t] (1� F )2at

o�n

Eh(1� F )�2b�d^t

i�P [�d �t] (1� F )�2bt

oand ρa1,...,ak = ρa1,a2+...+ak ρa2,...,ak recursively

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 29

/ 36

Page 104: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Where Does the Edgeworth Come From?

De�ne the Fourier Transform f̂ (t) =Z ∞

�∞e�itx f (x) dx

Let W have mean 0 and variance 1 and let φ be std normal density

Write cfW (t) = hcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)�i bφ (t) and Taylor expand the bracket

cfW (t) =(

∑n=0

1n!

hcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)�i(n)

t=0tn) bφ (t)

So fW (w) =∞

∑n=0

1n!

hcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)�i(n)

t=0i�nφ(n) (w) and use Leibniz�s

rulehcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)�i(n)

t=0=�

1bφ(t)�(n)t=0

+n

∑j=1

n!j !(n�j)!

cfW(j) (0) � 1bφ(t)�(n�j)t=0

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 30

/ 36

Page 105: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Where Does the Edgeworth Come From?

De�ne the Fourier Transform f̂ (t) =Z ∞

�∞e�itx f (x) dx

Let W have mean 0 and variance 1 and let φ be std normal density

Write cfW (t) = hcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)�i bφ (t) and Taylor expand the bracket

cfW (t) =(

∑n=0

1n!

hcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)�i(n)

t=0tn) bφ (t)

So fW (w) =∞

∑n=0

1n!

hcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)�i(n)

t=0i�nφ(n) (w) and use Leibniz�s

rulehcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)�i(n)

t=0=�

1bφ(t)�(n)t=0

+n

∑j=1

n!j !(n�j)!

cfW(j) (0) � 1bφ(t)�(n�j)t=0

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 30

/ 36

Page 106: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Where Does the Edgeworth Come From?

De�ne the Fourier Transform f̂ (t) =Z ∞

�∞e�itx f (x) dx

Let W have mean 0 and variance 1 and let φ be std normal density

Write cfW (t) = hcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)�i bφ (t) and Taylor expand the bracket

cfW (t) =(

∑n=0

1n!

hcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)�i(n)

t=0tn) bφ (t)

So fW (w) =∞

∑n=0

1n!

hcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)�i(n)

t=0i�nφ(n) (w) and use Leibniz�s

rulehcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)�i(n)

t=0=�

1bφ(t)�(n)t=0

+n

∑j=1

n!j !(n�j)!

cfW(j) (0) � 1bφ(t)�(n�j)t=0

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 30

/ 36

Page 107: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Where Does the Edgeworth Come From?

De�ne the Fourier Transform f̂ (t) =Z ∞

�∞e�itx f (x) dx

Let W have mean 0 and variance 1 and let φ be std normal density

Write cfW (t) = hcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)�i bφ (t) and Taylor expand the bracket

cfW (t) =(

∑n=0

1n!

hcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)�i(n)

t=0tn) bφ (t)

So fW (w) =∞

∑n=0

1n!

hcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)�i(n)

t=0i�nφ(n) (w) and use Leibniz�s

rulehcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)�i(n)

t=0=�

1bφ(t)�(n)t=0

+n

∑j=1

n!j !(n�j)!

cfW(j) (0) � 1bφ(t)�(n�j)t=0

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 30

/ 36

Page 108: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Where Does the Edgeworth Come From?

De�ne the Fourier Transform f̂ (t) =Z ∞

�∞e�itx f (x) dx

Let W have mean 0 and variance 1 and let φ be std normal density

Write cfW (t) = hcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)�i bφ (t) and Taylor expand the bracket

cfW (t) =(

∑n=0

1n!

hcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)�i(n)

t=0tn) bφ (t)

So fW (w) =∞

∑n=0

1n!

hcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)�i(n)

t=0i�nφ(n) (w) and use Leibniz�s

rule

hcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)�i(n)

t=0=�

1bφ(t)�(n)t=0

+n

∑j=1

n!j !(n�j)!

cfW(j) (0) � 1bφ(t)�(n�j)t=0

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 30

/ 36

Page 109: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Where Does the Edgeworth Come From?

De�ne the Fourier Transform f̂ (t) =Z ∞

�∞e�itx f (x) dx

Let W have mean 0 and variance 1 and let φ be std normal density

Write cfW (t) = hcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)�i bφ (t) and Taylor expand the bracket

cfW (t) =(

∑n=0

1n!

hcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)�i(n)

t=0tn) bφ (t)

So fW (w) =∞

∑n=0

1n!

hcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)�i(n)

t=0i�nφ(n) (w) and use Leibniz�s

rulehcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)�i(n)

t=0=�

1bφ(t)�(n)t=0

+n

∑j=1

n!j !(n�j)!

cfW(j) (0) � 1bφ(t)�(n�j)t=0

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 30

/ 36

Page 110: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Where Does the Edgeworth Come From?

So fW (w) =∞

∑n=0

1n!

hcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)�i(n)

t=0i�nφ(n) (w) and use Leibniz�s

rule

hcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)�i(n)

t=0=�

1bφ(t)�(n)t=0

+n

∑j=1

n!j !(n�j)!

cfW(j) (0) � 1bφ(t)�(n�j)t=0

0 =hbφ (t) � 1bφ(t)

�i(n)t=0

=�

1bφ(t)�(n)t=0

+n

∑j=1

n!j !(n�j)!

bφ(j) (0) � 1bφ(t)�(n�j)t=0hcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)

�i(n)t=0

=n

∑j=1

n!j !(n�j)!

�cfW(j) (0)� bφ(j) (0)�� 1bφ(t)�(n�j)t=0hcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)

�i(n)t=0

=n

∑j=3

n!j !(n�j)!

�cfW(j) (0)� bφ(j) (0)�� 1bφ(t)�(n�j)t=0

because W is mean 0 variance 1

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 31

/ 36

Page 111: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Where Does the Edgeworth Come From?

So fW (w) =∞

∑n=0

1n!

hcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)�i(n)

t=0i�nφ(n) (w) and use Leibniz�s

rulehcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)�i(n)

t=0=�

1bφ(t)�(n)t=0

+n

∑j=1

n!j !(n�j)!

cfW(j) (0) � 1bφ(t)�(n�j)t=0

0 =hbφ (t) � 1bφ(t)

�i(n)t=0

=�

1bφ(t)�(n)t=0

+n

∑j=1

n!j !(n�j)!

bφ(j) (0) � 1bφ(t)�(n�j)t=0hcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)

�i(n)t=0

=n

∑j=1

n!j !(n�j)!

�cfW(j) (0)� bφ(j) (0)�� 1bφ(t)�(n�j)t=0hcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)

�i(n)t=0

=n

∑j=3

n!j !(n�j)!

�cfW(j) (0)� bφ(j) (0)�� 1bφ(t)�(n�j)t=0

because W is mean 0 variance 1

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 31

/ 36

Page 112: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Where Does the Edgeworth Come From?

So fW (w) =∞

∑n=0

1n!

hcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)�i(n)

t=0i�nφ(n) (w) and use Leibniz�s

rulehcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)�i(n)

t=0=�

1bφ(t)�(n)t=0

+n

∑j=1

n!j !(n�j)!

cfW(j) (0) � 1bφ(t)�(n�j)t=0

0 =hbφ (t) � 1bφ(t)

�i(n)t=0

=�

1bφ(t)�(n)t=0

+n

∑j=1

n!j !(n�j)!

bφ(j) (0) � 1bφ(t)�(n�j)t=0

hcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)�i(n)

t=0=

n

∑j=1

n!j !(n�j)!

�cfW(j) (0)� bφ(j) (0)�� 1bφ(t)�(n�j)t=0hcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)

�i(n)t=0

=n

∑j=3

n!j !(n�j)!

�cfW(j) (0)� bφ(j) (0)�� 1bφ(t)�(n�j)t=0

because W is mean 0 variance 1

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 31

/ 36

Page 113: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Where Does the Edgeworth Come From?

So fW (w) =∞

∑n=0

1n!

hcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)�i(n)

t=0i�nφ(n) (w) and use Leibniz�s

rulehcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)�i(n)

t=0=�

1bφ(t)�(n)t=0

+n

∑j=1

n!j !(n�j)!

cfW(j) (0) � 1bφ(t)�(n�j)t=0

0 =hbφ (t) � 1bφ(t)

�i(n)t=0

=�

1bφ(t)�(n)t=0

+n

∑j=1

n!j !(n�j)!

bφ(j) (0) � 1bφ(t)�(n�j)t=0hcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)

�i(n)t=0

=n

∑j=1

n!j !(n�j)!

�cfW(j) (0)� bφ(j) (0)�� 1bφ(t)�(n�j)t=0

hcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)�i(n)

t=0=

n

∑j=3

n!j !(n�j)!

�cfW(j) (0)� bφ(j) (0)�� 1bφ(t)�(n�j)t=0

because W is mean 0 variance 1

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 31

/ 36

Page 114: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Where Does the Edgeworth Come From?

So fW (w) =∞

∑n=0

1n!

hcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)�i(n)

t=0i�nφ(n) (w) and use Leibniz�s

rulehcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)�i(n)

t=0=�

1bφ(t)�(n)t=0

+n

∑j=1

n!j !(n�j)!

cfW(j) (0) � 1bφ(t)�(n�j)t=0

0 =hbφ (t) � 1bφ(t)

�i(n)t=0

=�

1bφ(t)�(n)t=0

+n

∑j=1

n!j !(n�j)!

bφ(j) (0) � 1bφ(t)�(n�j)t=0hcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)

�i(n)t=0

=n

∑j=1

n!j !(n�j)!

�cfW(j) (0)� bφ(j) (0)�� 1bφ(t)�(n�j)t=0hcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)

�i(n)t=0

=n

∑j=3

n!j !(n�j)!

�cfW(j) (0)� bφ(j) (0)�� 1bφ(t)�(n�j)t=0

because W is mean 0 variance 1

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 31

/ 36

Page 115: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

But derivatives of Fourier transforms evaluated at 0 are just momentsso

hcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)�i(n)

t=0=

n

∑j=3

n!(n�j)?j !(n�j)! i

�j �E �Wj�� j?

�and

fW (w) = φ (w) +∞

∑n=0

1n!

n

∑j=3

n!(n�j)?j !(n�j)! i

�n�j �E �Wj�� j?

�φ(n) (w)

=

φ (w) + limN!∞

N

∑j=3

1j !

�E�Wj�� j?

� b N�j2 c∑n=0

(2n)?(2n)! (�1)

n+j φ(2n+j) (w)

But

φ(2n+j) (w) =

24n+b j2 c∑k=0

(2n+j)!(2k )?(2n+j�2k )!(2k )! (�1)

2n+j�k w2n+j�2k

35 φ (w)

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 32

/ 36

Page 116: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

But derivatives of Fourier transforms evaluated at 0 are just momentssohcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)

�i(n)t=0

=n

∑j=3

n!(n�j)?j !(n�j)! i

�j �E �Wj�� j?

�and

fW (w) = φ (w) +∞

∑n=0

1n!

n

∑j=3

n!(n�j)?j !(n�j)! i

�n�j �E �Wj�� j?

�φ(n) (w)

=

φ (w) + limN!∞

N

∑j=3

1j !

�E�Wj�� j?

� b N�j2 c∑n=0

(2n)?(2n)! (�1)

n+j φ(2n+j) (w)

But

φ(2n+j) (w) =

24n+b j2 c∑k=0

(2n+j)!(2k )?(2n+j�2k )!(2k )! (�1)

2n+j�k w2n+j�2k

35 φ (w)

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 32

/ 36

Page 117: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

But derivatives of Fourier transforms evaluated at 0 are just momentssohcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)

�i(n)t=0

=n

∑j=3

n!(n�j)?j !(n�j)! i

�j �E �Wj�� j?

�and

fW (w) = φ (w) +∞

∑n=0

1n!

n

∑j=3

n!(n�j)?j !(n�j)! i

�n�j �E �Wj�� j?

�φ(n) (w)

=

φ (w) + limN!∞

N

∑j=3

1j !

�E�Wj�� j?

� b N�j2 c∑n=0

(2n)?(2n)! (�1)

n+j φ(2n+j) (w)

But

φ(2n+j) (w) =

24n+b j2 c∑k=0

(2n+j)!(2k )?(2n+j�2k )!(2k )! (�1)

2n+j�k w2n+j�2k

35 φ (w)

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 32

/ 36

Page 118: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

But derivatives of Fourier transforms evaluated at 0 are just momentssohcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)

�i(n)t=0

=n

∑j=3

n!(n�j)?j !(n�j)! i

�j �E �Wj�� j?

�and

fW (w) = φ (w) +∞

∑n=0

1n!

n

∑j=3

n!(n�j)?j !(n�j)! i

�n�j �E �Wj�� j?

�φ(n) (w)

=

φ (w) + limN!∞

N

∑j=3

1j !

�E�Wj�� j?

� b N�j2 c∑n=0

(2n)?(2n)! (�1)

n+j φ(2n+j) (w)

But

φ(2n+j) (w) =

24n+b j2 c∑k=0

(2n+j)!(2k )?(2n+j�2k )!(2k )! (�1)

2n+j�k w2n+j�2k

35 φ (w)

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 32

/ 36

Page 119: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

But derivatives of Fourier transforms evaluated at 0 are just momentssohcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)

�i(n)t=0

=n

∑j=3

n!(n�j)?j !(n�j)! i

�j �E �Wj�� j?

�and

fW (w) = φ (w) +∞

∑n=0

1n!

n

∑j=3

n!(n�j)?j !(n�j)! i

�n�j �E �Wj�� j?

�φ(n) (w)

=

φ (w) + limN!∞

N

∑j=3

1j !

�E�Wj�� j?

� b N�j2 c∑n=0

(2n)?(2n)! (�1)

n+j φ(2n+j) (w)

But

φ(2n+j) (w) =

24n+b j2 c∑k=0

(2n+j)!(2k )?(2n+j�2k )!(2k )! (�1)

2n+j�k w2n+j�2k

35 φ (w)

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 32

/ 36

Page 120: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Where Does the Edgeworth Come From?

Finally, if Y = σW+ µ a change of variables gives the Edgeworthexpansion

fY (y) = 1σ φ�y�µ

σ

�+ limN!∞

N

∑j=3

1j !

�µjσj� j?

� b N�j2 c∑n=0

(2n)?(2n)! (�1)

n �

n+b j2 c∑k=0

(2n+j)!(2k )?(2n+j�2k )!(2k )! (�1)

k�y�µ

σ

�2n+j�2k1σ φ�y�µ

σ

�where µj is the j-th central moment of YFor Esscher (aka Saddlepoint) Expansion, Taylor expandhcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)

�iaround a di¤erent point than 0

For something even more �exible, use a di¤erent function than φ; trylogistic, gamma, inverse gamma or inverse logistic

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 33

/ 36

Page 121: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Where Does the Edgeworth Come From?

Finally, if Y = σW+ µ a change of variables gives the Edgeworthexpansion

fY (y) = 1σ φ�y�µ

σ

�+ limN!∞

N

∑j=3

1j !

�µjσj� j?

� b N�j2 c∑n=0

(2n)?(2n)! (�1)

n �

n+b j2 c∑k=0

(2n+j)!(2k )?(2n+j�2k )!(2k )! (�1)

k�y�µ

σ

�2n+j�2k1σ φ�y�µ

σ

where µj is the j-th central moment of YFor Esscher (aka Saddlepoint) Expansion, Taylor expandhcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)

�iaround a di¤erent point than 0

For something even more �exible, use a di¤erent function than φ; trylogistic, gamma, inverse gamma or inverse logistic

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 33

/ 36

Page 122: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Where Does the Edgeworth Come From?

Finally, if Y = σW+ µ a change of variables gives the Edgeworthexpansion

fY (y) = 1σ φ�y�µ

σ

�+ limN!∞

N

∑j=3

1j !

�µjσj� j?

� b N�j2 c∑n=0

(2n)?(2n)! (�1)

n �

n+b j2 c∑k=0

(2n+j)!(2k )?(2n+j�2k )!(2k )! (�1)

k�y�µ

σ

�2n+j�2k1σ φ�y�µ

σ

�where µj is the j-th central moment of Y

For Esscher (aka Saddlepoint) Expansion, Taylor expandhcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)�iaround a di¤erent point than 0

For something even more �exible, use a di¤erent function than φ; trylogistic, gamma, inverse gamma or inverse logistic

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 33

/ 36

Page 123: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Where Does the Edgeworth Come From?

Finally, if Y = σW+ µ a change of variables gives the Edgeworthexpansion

fY (y) = 1σ φ�y�µ

σ

�+ limN!∞

N

∑j=3

1j !

�µjσj� j?

� b N�j2 c∑n=0

(2n)?(2n)! (�1)

n �

n+b j2 c∑k=0

(2n+j)!(2k )?(2n+j�2k )!(2k )! (�1)

k�y�µ

σ

�2n+j�2k1σ φ�y�µ

σ

�where µj is the j-th central moment of YFor Esscher (aka Saddlepoint) Expansion, Taylor expandhcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)

�iaround a di¤erent point than 0

For something even more �exible, use a di¤erent function than φ; trylogistic, gamma, inverse gamma or inverse logistic

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 33

/ 36

Page 124: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

Where Does the Edgeworth Come From?

Finally, if Y = σW+ µ a change of variables gives the Edgeworthexpansion

fY (y) = 1σ φ�y�µ

σ

�+ limN!∞

N

∑j=3

1j !

�µjσj� j?

� b N�j2 c∑n=0

(2n)?(2n)! (�1)

n �

n+b j2 c∑k=0

(2n+j)!(2k )?(2n+j�2k )!(2k )! (�1)

k�y�µ

σ

�2n+j�2k1σ φ�y�µ

σ

�where µj is the j-th central moment of YFor Esscher (aka Saddlepoint) Expansion, Taylor expandhcfW (t) � 1bφ(t)

�iaround a di¤erent point than 0

For something even more �exible, use a di¤erent function than φ; trylogistic, gamma, inverse gamma or inverse logistic

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 33

/ 36

Page 125: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

How Do You Get The Moments?

E�rlt�= E

hel ln(rt )

i= E

�elY�=

∞Z�∞

e ly fY (y) dy

Substitute the Edgeworth expression, complete the square to integratejust as if you were integrating for the lognormal, and expand thebinomials that occur when you change variables and you wind up with

E�rlt�=

e lµ+12 (lσ)

2

8<:1+ limN!∞

N

∑j=3

l jj !

�µj � j?σj

� b N�j2 c∑n=0

(2n)?(2n)! (�1)

n (lσ)2n �

�n+b j2 c

∑m=0

(2n+j)!(2n+j�2m)! (lσ)

�2mm

∑k=0

(2k )?(2(m�k ))?(2k )!(2(m�k ))! (�1)

k

9=;Remarkably,

m

∑k=0

(2k )?(2(m�k ))?(2k )!(2(m�k ))! (�1)

k = 0 when m > 0

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 34

/ 36

Page 126: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

How Do You Get The Moments?

E�rlt�= E

hel ln(rt )

i= E

�elY�=

∞Z�∞

e ly fY (y) dy

Substitute the Edgeworth expression, complete the square to integratejust as if you were integrating for the lognormal, and expand thebinomials that occur when you change variables and you wind up with

E�rlt�=

e lµ+12 (lσ)

2

8<:1+ limN!∞

N

∑j=3

l jj !

�µj � j?σj

� b N�j2 c∑n=0

(2n)?(2n)! (�1)

n (lσ)2n �

�n+b j2 c

∑m=0

(2n+j)!(2n+j�2m)! (lσ)

�2mm

∑k=0

(2k )?(2(m�k ))?(2k )!(2(m�k ))! (�1)

k

9=;Remarkably,

m

∑k=0

(2k )?(2(m�k ))?(2k )!(2(m�k ))! (�1)

k = 0 when m > 0

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 34

/ 36

Page 127: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

How Do You Get The Moments?

E�rlt�= E

hel ln(rt )

i= E

�elY�=

∞Z�∞

e ly fY (y) dy

Substitute the Edgeworth expression, complete the square to integratejust as if you were integrating for the lognormal, and expand thebinomials that occur when you change variables and you wind up with

E�rlt�=

e lµ+12 (lσ)

2

8<:1+ limN!∞

N

∑j=3

l jj !

�µj � j?σj

� b N�j2 c∑n=0

(2n)?(2n)! (�1)

n (lσ)2n �

�n+b j2 c

∑m=0

(2n+j)!(2n+j�2m)! (lσ)

�2mm

∑k=0

(2k )?(2(m�k ))?(2k )!(2(m�k ))! (�1)

k

9=;

Remarkably,m

∑k=0

(2k )?(2(m�k ))?(2k )!(2(m�k ))! (�1)

k = 0 when m > 0

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 34

/ 36

Page 128: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

How Do You Get The Moments?

E�rlt�= E

hel ln(rt )

i= E

�elY�=

∞Z�∞

e ly fY (y) dy

Substitute the Edgeworth expression, complete the square to integratejust as if you were integrating for the lognormal, and expand thebinomials that occur when you change variables and you wind up with

E�rlt�=

e lµ+12 (lσ)

2

8<:1+ limN!∞

N

∑j=3

l jj !

�µj � j?σj

� b N�j2 c∑n=0

(2n)?(2n)! (�1)

n (lσ)2n �

�n+b j2 c

∑m=0

(2n+j)!(2n+j�2m)! (lσ)

�2mm

∑k=0

(2k )?(2(m�k ))?(2k )!(2(m�k ))! (�1)

k

9=;Remarkably,

m

∑k=0

(2k )?(2(m�k ))?(2k )!(2(m�k ))! (�1)

k = 0 when m > 0

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 34

/ 36

Page 129: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

How Do You Get The Moments?

Why? 0 =hbφ (t) � 1bφ(t)

�i(2m)t=0

=m

∑k=0

(2k )?(2(m�k ))?(2k )!(2(m�k ))! (�1)

k

Finally, E�rlt�=

e lµ+12 (lσ)

2

8<:1+ limN!∞

N

∑j=3

l jj !

�µj � j?σj

� b N�j2 c∑n=0

(2n)?(2n)! (�1)

n (lσ)2n

9=;

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 35

/ 36

Page 130: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

How Do You Get The Moments?

Why? 0 =hbφ (t) � 1bφ(t)

�i(2m)t=0

=m

∑k=0

(2k )?(2(m�k ))?(2k )!(2(m�k ))! (�1)

k

Finally, E�rlt�=

e lµ+12 (lσ)

2

8<:1+ limN!∞

N

∑j=3

l jj !

�µj � j?σj

� b N�j2 c∑n=0

(2n)?(2n)! (�1)

n (lσ)2n

9=;

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 35

/ 36

Page 131: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

What About the Main Results?

Proofs were inspired by techniques in Decoupling: From Dependenceto Independence, by de la Peña and Giné

Essential lemmata are:

As joint distributions fJ,�dJg ' fJ,�d1g and�dJ '�d1 '�d^ tConditional on J = j 0 > 1 the following are each independentsets:fJ,�d1g,

��d1,d2, ...,dj 0�1, �d2, ...,dj 0�1,�dj 0 and fJ,�dJgThis is enough independence to get a geometric series inside the main

expectation E

"∞

∑j=1

ν (ej )

#and to pull apart the two sides of the

correlation expectation for ρa,b , leaving a common term involving�d1and�dJ which can be evaluated by writing�d1 = t� (�dJ + dJ�1 + ...+ d2)

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 36

/ 36

Page 132: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

What About the Main Results?

Proofs were inspired by techniques in Decoupling: From Dependenceto Independence, by de la Peña and Giné

Essential lemmata are:

As joint distributions fJ,�dJg ' fJ,�d1g and�dJ '�d1 '�d^ tConditional on J = j 0 > 1 the following are each independentsets:fJ,�d1g,

��d1,d2, ...,dj 0�1, �d2, ...,dj 0�1,�dj 0 and fJ,�dJgThis is enough independence to get a geometric series inside the main

expectation E

"∞

∑j=1

ν (ej )

#and to pull apart the two sides of the

correlation expectation for ρa,b , leaving a common term involving�d1and�dJ which can be evaluated by writing�d1 = t� (�dJ + dJ�1 + ...+ d2)

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 36

/ 36

Page 133: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

What About the Main Results?

Proofs were inspired by techniques in Decoupling: From Dependenceto Independence, by de la Peña and Giné

Essential lemmata are:

As joint distributions fJ,�dJg ' fJ,�d1g and�dJ '�d1 '�d^ t

Conditional on J = j 0 > 1 the following are each independentsets:fJ,�d1g,

��d1,d2, ...,dj 0�1, �d2, ...,dj 0�1,�dj 0 and fJ,�dJgThis is enough independence to get a geometric series inside the main

expectation E

"∞

∑j=1

ν (ej )

#and to pull apart the two sides of the

correlation expectation for ρa,b , leaving a common term involving�d1and�dJ which can be evaluated by writing�d1 = t� (�dJ + dJ�1 + ...+ d2)

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 36

/ 36

Page 134: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

What About the Main Results?

Proofs were inspired by techniques in Decoupling: From Dependenceto Independence, by de la Peña and Giné

Essential lemmata are:

As joint distributions fJ,�dJg ' fJ,�d1g and�dJ '�d1 '�d^ tConditional on J = j 0 > 1 the following are each independentsets:fJ,�d1g,

��d1,d2, ...,dj 0�1, �d2, ...,dj 0�1,�dj 0 and fJ,�dJg

This is enough independence to get a geometric series inside the main

expectation E

"∞

∑j=1

ν (ej )

#and to pull apart the two sides of the

correlation expectation for ρa,b , leaving a common term involving�d1and�dJ which can be evaluated by writing�d1 = t� (�dJ + dJ�1 + ...+ d2)

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 36

/ 36

Page 135: Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes · Regime-Switching Interest Rate Models With Randomized Regimes James G. Bridgeman, FSA University of Connecticut Actuarial

What About the Main Results?

Proofs were inspired by techniques in Decoupling: From Dependenceto Independence, by de la Peña and Giné

Essential lemmata are:

As joint distributions fJ,�dJg ' fJ,�d1g and�dJ '�d1 '�d^ tConditional on J = j 0 > 1 the following are each independentsets:fJ,�d1g,

��d1,d2, ...,dj 0�1, �d2, ...,dj 0�1,�dj 0 and fJ,�dJgThis is enough independence to get a geometric series inside the main

expectation E

"∞

∑j=1

ν (ej )

#and to pull apart the two sides of the

correlation expectation for ρa,b , leaving a common term involving�d1and�dJ which can be evaluated by writing�d1 = t� (�dJ + dJ�1 + ...+ d2)

Bridgeman (University of Connecticut) Random RegimesActuarial Science Seminar Jan. 29, 2008 36

/ 36