16
Investment Opportunities as Real Options: Getting Started on the Numbers by Timothy A. Luehrman Harvard Business Review Reprint 98404

Investment Opportunities as Real Options: Getting …people.stern.nyu.edu/adamodar/pdfiles/articles/Investmentsas... · Investment Opportunities as Real Options: Getting Started

  • Upload
    hakhanh

  • View
    212

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Investment Opportunities as Real Options: Getting …people.stern.nyu.edu/adamodar/pdfiles/articles/Investmentsas... · Investment Opportunities as Real Options: Getting Started

Investment Opportunities asReal Options: Getting Startedon the Numbers

by Timothy A. Luehrman

Harvard Business Review Reprint 98404

Page 2: Investment Opportunities as Real Options: Getting …people.stern.nyu.edu/adamodar/pdfiles/articles/Investmentsas... · Investment Opportunities as Real Options: Getting Started

JULY– AUGUST 1998

Reprint Number

HarvardBusinessReviewTHE END OF CORPORATE IMPERIALISM 98408

LEADERSHIP WHEN THERE IS NO ONE TO ASK: 98402AN INTERVIEW WITH ENI’S FRANCO BERNABE

WELCOME TO THE EXPERIENCE ECONOMY 98407

THE PROMISE – AND PERIL – OF INTEGRATED 98403COST SYSTEMS

PUTTING THE ENTERPRISE INTO THE 98401ENTERPRISE SYSTEM

HOW HARDWIRED IS HUMAN BEHAVIOR? 98406

HBR CASE STUDYHOW DO YOU MANAGE AN OFF-SITE TEAM? 98405

ideas at workANOTHER LOOK AT HOW TOYOTA INTEGRATES 98409PRODUCT DEVELOPMENT

manager’s tool kitINVESTMENT OPPORTUNITIES AS REAL OPTIONS: 98404GETTING STARTED ON THE NUMBERS

perspectivesCONNECTIVITY AND CONTROL IN THE YEAR 2000 98411AND BEYOND

BOOKS IN REVIEWWHAT DRIVES THE WEALTH OF NATIONS? 98410

c.k . Prahalad ANDKenneth Lieberthal

Linda hill andSuzy wetlaufer

B. joseph pine I I andJames h. Gilmore

Robin Cooper and Robert s. kaplan

Thomas h. davenport

Nigel Nicholson

Regina fazio Maruca

Durward k . Sobek i i ,Jeffrey k. liker, and Allen C. ward

Timothy A . Luehrman

introduction by richard l . nolan

DAVID Warsh

Page 3: Investment Opportunities as Real Options: Getting …people.stern.nyu.edu/adamodar/pdfiles/articles/Investmentsas... · Investment Opportunities as Real Options: Getting Started

he analogy between financialoptions and corporate invest-

ments that create future opportuni-ties is both intuitively appealing andincreasingly well accepted. Execu-tives readily see why investing todayin R&D, or in a new marketing pro-gram, or even in certain capital ex-penditures (a phased plant expansion,say) can generate the possibility ofnew products or new markets tomor-row. But for many nonfinance man-agers, the journey from insight to action, from the puts and calls offinancial options to actual invest-ment decisions, is difficult and deeplyfrustrating.

Experts do a good job of explainingwhat option pricing captures thatconventional discounted-cash-flow(DCF) and net-present-value (NPV)analyses do not. Moreover, simpleoption pricing for exchange-traded

puts and calls is fairly straightfor-ward, and many books present thebasics lucidly. But at that point,most executives get stuck. Their in-terest piqued, they want to knowHow can I use option pricing on myproject? and How can I use this withreal numbers rather than with steril-ized examples? Unfortunately, how-to advice is scarce on this subjectand mostly aimed at specialists,preferably with Ph.D.’s. As a result,corporate analyses that generate realnumbers have been rare, expensive,and hard to understand.

The framework presented herebridges the gap between the practi-calities of real-world capital projects

and the higher mathematics associ-ated with formal option-pricing the-ory. It produces quantitative output,can be used repeatedly on many proj-ects, and is compatible with theubiquitous DCF spreadsheets thatare at the heart of most corporatecapital-budgeting systems. What thisframework cannot supply is absoluteprecision: when a very precise num-ber is required, managers will stillhave to call on technical expertswith specialized financial tools. Butfor many projects in many compa-nies, a “good enough” number is notonly good enough but considerablybetter than the number a plain DCFanalysis would generate. In such cases, forgoing some precision in ex-change for simplicity, versatility, andexplicability is a worthwhile trade.

We’ll begin by examining a gener-ic investment opportunity – a capi-tal budgeting project – to see whatmakes it similar to a call option.Then we’ll compare DCF with theoption-pricing approach to evaluat-ing the project. Instead of lookingonly at the differences between thetwo approaches, we will also look forpoints of commonality. Recognizingthe differences adds extra insight to the analysis, but exploiting thecommonalities is the key to makingthe framework understandable andcompatible with familiar techniques.In fact, most of the data the frame-work uses come from the DCFspreadsheets that managers routine-ly prepare to evaluate investmentproposals. And for option values, theframework uses the Black-Scholesoption-pricing table instead of com-plex equations. Finally, once we’vebuilt the framework, we’ll apply it toa typical capital-investment decision.

Mapping a ProjectOnto an OptionA corporate investment opportunityis like a call option because the cor-poration has the right, but not theobligation, to acquire something –let us say, the operating assets of a

harvard business review July–August 1998 Copyright © 1998 by the President and Fellows of Harvard College. All rights reserved.

InvestmentOpportunities as

Real Options:Getting Startedon the Numbers

by Timothy A. Luehrman

Timothy A. Luehrman is a professor of finance at Thunderbird, the AmericanGraduate School of International Management, in Glendale, Arizona. He isthe author of “What’s It Worth: A General Manager’s Guide to Valuation,”HBR May–June 1997.

T

Here’s a way to apply option pricingto strategic decisions without

hiring an army of Ph.D.’s.

M A N A G E R ’ S T O O L K I T

Page 4: Investment Opportunities as Real Options: Getting …people.stern.nyu.edu/adamodar/pdfiles/articles/Investmentsas... · Investment Opportunities as Real Options: Getting Started

NPV = (value of project assets) 2 (expenditure required)

This is S. This is X.

So: NPV = S 2 X.

Here, we must decide “go” or “no go.”

new business. If we could find a calloption sufficiently similar to the in-vestment opportunity, the value ofthe option would tell us somethingabout the value of the opportunity.Unfortunately, most business oppor-tunities are unique, so the likeli-hood of finding a similar option islow. The only reliable way to find asimilar option is to construct one.

To do so, we need to establish acorrespondence between the proj-ect’s characteristics and the fivevariables that determine the value of a simple call option on a share ofstock. By mapping the characteris-tics of the business opportunity ontothe template of a call option, we canobtain a model of the project thatcombines its characteristics withthe structure of a call option. Theoption we will use is a Europeancall, which is the simplest of all op-tions because it can be exercised on

only one date, its expiration date.The option we synthesize in thisway is not a perfect substitute forthe real opportunity, but becausewe’ve designed it to be similar, it isindeed informative. The diagram“Mapping an Investment Opportu-nity onto a Call Option” shows thecorrespondences making up the fun-damental mapping.

Many projects involve spendingmoney to buy or build a productiveasset. Spending money to exploitsuch a business opportunity is anal-ogous to exercising an option on, for example, a share of stock. Theamount of money expended corre-sponds to the option’s exercise price(denoted for simplicity as X). Thepresent value of the asset built or ac-quired corresponds to the stock price(S). The length of time the companycan defer the investment decisionwithout losing the opportunity cor-

4 harvard business review July–August 1998

investment opportunities as real optionsM A N A G E R ’ S T O O L K I T

Conventional NPV and option value are identical when the investment decision can nolonger be deferred.

Call Option

Mapping an Investment Opportunity onto a Call Option

Investment Opportunity

Stock price

Exercise price

Time to expiration

Risk-free rate of return

Variance of returnson stock

When Are Conventional NPV and Option Value Identical?

Option Value

When t = 0, s 2 and rƒ donot affect call option value.Only S and X matter.

At expiration, call optionvalue isS 2 X or 0, whichever is greater.

Here, it’s “exercise“ or “not.”

Conventional NPV

Present value of a project’s operating assets to be acquired

Expenditure required to acquire the project assets

Length of time the decisionmay be deferred

Time value of money

Riskiness of the project assets

responds to the option’s time to ex-piration (t). The uncertainty aboutthe future value of the project’s cashflows (that is, the riskiness of theproject) corresponds to the standarddeviation of returns on the stock (s ).Finally, the time value of money isgiven in both cases by the risk-freerate of return (rƒ). By pricing an op-tion using values for these variablesgenerated from our project, we learnmore about the value of the projectthan a simple discounted-cash-flowanalysis would tell us.

Linking NPV And Option ValueTraditional DCF methods would as-sess this opportunity by computingits net present value. NPV is the dif-ference between how much the op-erating assets are worth (their pres-ent value) and how much they cost:

NPV = present value of assets – required capital expenditure.

When NPV is positive, the corpora-tion will increase its own value bymaking the investment. When NPVis negative, the corporation is betteroff not making the investment.

When are the project’s optionvalue and NPV the same? When a final decision on the project can nolonger be deferred; that is, when thecompany’s “option” has reached itsexpiration date. At that time, either

the option value = S – X

or the option value = 0

whichever is greater. But note that

NPV = S – X

as well, because we know from ourmap that S corresponds to the pres-ent value of the project assets and Xto the required capital expenditure.To reconcile the two completely, weneed only observe that when NPV is negative, the corporation will notinvest, so the project value is effec-tively zero (just like the optionvalue) rather than negative. In short,both approaches boil down to thesame number and the same decision.(See the diagram “When Are Con-ventional NPV and Option ValueIdentical?”)

Variable

S

X

t

s 2

Page 5: Investment Opportunities as Real Options: Getting …people.stern.nyu.edu/adamodar/pdfiles/articles/Investmentsas... · Investment Opportunities as Real Options: Getting Started

This common ground betweenNPV and option value has great prac-tical significance. It means that cor-porate spreadsheets set up to com-pute conventional NPV are highlyrelevant for option pricing. Anyspreadsheet that computes NPV al-ready contains the information nec-essary to compute S and X, whichare two of the five option-pricingvariables. Accordingly, executiveswho want to begin using option pric-ing need not discard their currentDCF-based systems.

When do NPV and option pricingdiverge? When the investment deci-sion may be deferred. The possibilityof deferral gives rise to two additionalsources of value. First, we would al-ways rather pay later than sooner, allelse being equal, because we canearn the time value of money on thedeferred expenditure. Second, whilewe’re waiting, the world can change.Specifically, the value of the operat-ing assets we intend to acquire maychange. If their value goes up, wehaven’t missed out; we still can ac-quire them simply by making the in-vestment (exercising our option). Iftheir value goes down, we might de-cide not to acquire them. That alsois fine (very good, in fact) because, by waiting, we avoid making whatwould have turned out to be a poorinvestment. We have preserved theability to participate in good out-comes and insulated ourselves fromsome bad ones.

For both of these reasons, beingable to defer the investment decisionis valuable. Traditional NPV missesthe extra value associated with de-ferral because it assumes the deci-sion cannot be put off. In contrast,option pricing presumes the abilityto defer and provides a way to quan-tify the value of deferring. So tovalue the investment, we need to de-velop two new metrics that capturethese extra sources of value.

Quantifying Extra Value: NPVq.The first source of value is the inter-est you can earn on the required cap-ital expenditure by investing laterrather than sooner. A good way tocapture that value is to suppose youput just enough money in the banknow so that when it’s time to invest,that money plus the interest it has

So instead of expressing modifiedNPV as the difference between S andPV(X), let’s create a new metric: S di-vided by PV(X). By converting thedifference to a ratio, all we are doing,essentially, is converting negativevalues to decimals between zero andone.1 We’ll call this new metricNPVq, where “q” reminds us thatwe are expressing the relationshipbetween cost and value as a quotient:

NPVq = S ÷ PV(X).

Modified NPV and NPVq are notequivalent; that is, they don’t yieldthe same numeric answer. For exam-ple, if S = 5 and PV(X) = 7, NPV = 22but NPVq = 0.714. But the differencein the figures is unimportant be-cause we haven’t lost any informa-tion about the project by substitut-ing one metric for another. Whenmodified NPV is positive, NPVq willbe greater than one; when NPV isnegative, NPVq will be less thanone. Anytime modified NPV is zero,NPVq will be one. There is a perfectcorrespondence between them, asthe diagram “Substituting NPVq forNPV” shows.

Quantifying Extra Value: Cumu-lative Volatility. Now let’s move onto the second source of additionalvalue, namely that while we’re wait-ing, asset value may change and af-fect our investment decision for thebetter. That possibility is very im-portant, but naturally it is more dif-ficult to quantify because we are notactually sure that asset values willchange or, if they do, what the futurevalues will be. Fortunately, ratherthan measuring added value directly,

investment opportunities as real options M A N A G E R ’ S T O O L K I T

We can rank projects on a continuum according to values for NPVq, just as we wouldfor NPV. When a decision can no longer be deferred, NPV and NPVq give identical investment decisions, but NPVq has some mathematical advantages.

When time runs out, projects here are rejected (option is not exercised).

When time runs out, projects here areaccepted (option is exercised).

NPVq = S 4 PV(X)NPVq < 1 NPVq > 1

1.0

NPV

NPVq

NPV = S 2 XNPV < 0 NPV > 0

0.0

Substituting NPVq for NPV

earned is sufficient to fund the re-quired expenditure. How muchmoney is that? It is the discountedpresent value of the capital expendi-ture. In option notation, it’s the pres-ent value of the exercise price, orPV(X). To compute PV(X), we dis-count X for the requisite number ofperiods (t) at the risk-free rate of re-turn (rƒ):

PV(X) = X ÷ (1 + rƒ)t.

The extra value is the interest rate(rƒ) times X, compounded over how-ever many time periods (t) are in-volved. Alternatively, it is the differ-ence between X and PV(X).

We know that conventional NPVis missing that extra value, so let’sput it in. We have seen that NPV canbe expressed in option notation as:

NPV = S – X.

Let’s rewrite it using PV(X) insteadof X. Thus:

“modified” NPV = S – PV(X).

Note that our modified NPV will begreater than or equal to regular NPVbecause it explicitly includes inter-est to be earned while we wait. Itpicks up one of the sources of valuewe are interested in.

Modified NPV, then, is the differ-ence between S (value) and PV(X)(cost adjusted for the time value ofmoney). Modified NPV can be posi-tive, negative, or zero. However, itwill make our calculations a lot eas-ier if we express the relationship be-tween cost and value in such a waythat the number can never be nega-tive or zero.

harvard business review July–August 1998 5

Page 6: Investment Opportunities as Real Options: Getting …people.stern.nyu.edu/adamodar/pdfiles/articles/Investmentsas... · Investment Opportunities as Real Options: Getting Started

dollars or percentage points, where-as variance is denominated insquared dollars or squared percent-age points, which are not intuitive.Since we are going to work with re-turns instead of values, our unitswill be percentage points instead ofdollars.

To make these refinements to ourmeasure of total uncertainty, we dothe following:

First, stipulate that s 2 denotes thevariance of returns per unit of timeon our project.

Second, multiply variance per pe-riod by the number of periods (t) toget cumulative variance (s 2t).

Third, take the square root of cu-mulative variance to change units,expressing the metric as standard deviation rather than variance. Let’scall this last quantity cumulativevolatility (s =+t ) to distinguish itfrom cumulative variance.

Valuing the Option. Together, ourtwo new call-option metrics, NPVqand s =+t, contain all the informa-tion needed to value our project as a European call option using theBlack-Scholes model. They capturethe extra sources of value associatedwith opportunities. And they arecomposed of the five fundamentaloption-pricing variables onto whichwe mapped our business opportu-nity. NPVq is actually a combina-tion of four of the five variables: S, X,rƒ, and t. Cumulative volatility com-bines the fifth, s, with t. (See the dia-gram “Linking Our Metrics to theBlack-Scholes Model.”) By combin-ing variables in this way, we get towork with two metrics instead offive. Not only is that easier for mostof us to grasp, it also allows us toplot two-dimensional pictures,which can be helpful substitutes forequations in managers’ discussionsand presentations. Finally, each ofthe metrics has a natural businessinterpretation, which makes option-based analysis less opaque to non-finance executives.

The graph “Locating the OptionValue in Two-Dimensional Space”shows how to use NPVq and s=+t toobtain a value for the option. NPVqis on the horizontal axis, increasingfrom left to right. As NPVq rises, sodoes the value of the call option.

we can measure uncertainty insteadand let an option-pricing modelquantify the value associated with agiven amount of uncertainty. Onceagain, we’ll go through two steps.First, we’ll identify a sensible way to measure uncertainty. Then we’ll express the metric in a mathemati-cal form that will be easier for us touse but will not cause us to lose anypractical content.

The only way to measure uncer-tainty is by assessing probabilities.Imagine that the project’s futurevalue is to be drawn from an urncontaining all possible future values,weighted according to their likeli-hood of occurring. That is, if a valueof $100 were twice as likely as $75or $125, there would be twice asmany $100 balls in the urn as $75balls or $125 balls.

How can we quantify this uncer-tainty? Perhaps the most obviousmeasure is simply the range of allpossible values: the difference be-tween the lowest and the highestpossibilities. But we can do betterthan that by taking into account the relative likelihood of values be-tween those extremes. If, for exam-ple, very high and very low valuesare less likely than “medium” or“average” values, our measure of un-certainty should reflect that. Themost common probability-weightedmeasure of dispersion is variance,often denoted as sigma squared (s 2).Variance is a summary measure ofthe likelihood of drawing a valuefar away from the average value inthe urn. The higher the variance, themore likely it is that the valuesdrawn will be either much higher or much lower than average. In otherwords, we might say that high-vari-ance assets are riskier than low-vari-ance assets.

Variance is an appealing measureof uncertainty, but it’s incomplete.We have to worry about a time di-mension as well: how much thingscan change while we wait dependson how long we can afford to wait.For business projects, things canchange a lot more if we wait twoyears than if we wait only twomonths. So in option valuation, wespeak in terms of variance per period.Then our measure of the total

6 harvard business review July–August 1998

investment opportunities as real optionsM A N A G E R ’ S T O O L K I T

amount of uncertainty is varianceper period times the number of peri-ods, or s 2t.

This sometimes is called cumula-tive variance. An option expiring intwo years has twice the cumulativevariance as an otherwise identicaloption expiring in one year, giventhe same variance per period. Alter-natively, it may help to think of cu-mulative variance as the amount ofvariance in the urn times the num-ber of draws you are allowed, whichagain is s 2t.

Cumulative variance is a goodway to measure the uncertainty as-sociated with business investments.Now we’ll make two modifications,again for mathematical conve-nience, that won’t affect the abilityof the variable to tell us what wewant to know about uncertainty.First, instead of using the variance ofproject values, we’ll use the varianceof project returns. In other words,rather than working with the actualdollar value of the project, we’llwork with the percentage gained (orlost) per year. There is no loss of con-tent because a project’s return iscompletely determined by the proj-ect’s value:

return = (future value – present value)

present value.

The probability distribution of pos-sible values is usually quite asym-metric; value can increase greatlybut cannot drop below zero. Re-turns, in contrast, can be positive ornegative, sometimes symmetricallypositive or negative, which makestheir probability distribution easierto work with.

Second, it helps to express uncer-tainty in terms of standard devia-tion rather than variance. Standarddeviation is simply the square rootof variance and is denoted by s. Ittells us just as much about uncer-tainty as variance does, but it has theadvantage of being denominated inthe same units as the thing beingmeasured. In our business example,future asset values are denominatedin units of currency – say, dollars –and returns are denominated in per-centage points. Standard deviation,then, is likewise denominated in

Page 7: Investment Opportunities as Real Options: Getting …people.stern.nyu.edu/adamodar/pdfiles/articles/Investmentsas... · Investment Opportunities as Real Options: Getting Started

Locating the Option Value in Two-Dimensional Space

s=+t

What causes higher values of NPVq?Higher project values (S) or lowercapital expenditures (X). Note fur-ther that NPVq also is higher when-ever the present value of X is lower.Higher interest rates (rƒ) or longertime to expiration (t) both lead tolower present values of X. Any ofthese changes (lower X or higher S,rƒ, or t) increases the value of a Euro-pean call.

Cumulative volatility is on thevertical axis of the graph, increasing

from top to bottom. As s =+t in-creases, so does call value. Whatcauses higher values of s =+t?Greater uncertainty about a project’sfuture value and the ability to defer a decision longer. Either of thesechanges (higher s or t) likewise in-creases the value of a European call.

Plotting projects in this two-dimensional space creates a visualrepresentation of their relative op-tion values. No matter where youstart in the graph, call value increases

Our two new metrics together contain all five variables in the Black-Scholes model.Combining five variables into two lets us locate opportunities in two-dimensional space.

lowervalues

NPVq

lowervalues

Call option valueincreases in thesedirections.

highervalues

highervalues1.0

s=

+t

NPVq

Call Option

Linking Our Metrics to the Black-Scholes Model

Investment Opportunity

Present value of a project’s operating assets to be acquired

Expenditure required to acquire the project assets

Length of time the decisionmay be deferred

Time value of money

Riskiness of the project assets

Variable Option ValueMetrics

Variance of returns on stock

Risk-free rateof return

Time to expiration

Exercise price

Stock price

We can locate investment opportunities in this two-dimensional space.

s 2

t

X

S

investment opportunities as real options M A N A G E R ’ S T O O L K I T

harvard business review July–August 1998 7

Page 8: Investment Opportunities as Real Options: Getting …people.stern.nyu.edu/adamodar/pdfiles/articles/Investmentsas... · Investment Opportunities as Real Options: Getting Started

when you move down, to the right,or in both directions at once. Proj-ects in the lower-right corner of thegraph are high on both NPVq ands=+t metrics and their option valueis high compared with projects in theupper-left corner.

Locating various projects in thespace reveals their value relative toone another. How do we get absolutevalues? That is, how can we get anumber? Having gotten this far, wefind that getting a number is easy.Because NPVq and s=+t contain allfive Black-Scholes variables, we canfill in a table with Black-Scholes callvalues that correspond to every pairof NPVq and s=+t coordinates. I callthis “pricing the space,” and thetable does it for us.

The exhibit “Using the Black-Scholes Option-Pricing Model to‘Price the Space’” shows part of thefilled-in Black-Scholes table. Each

number expresses the value of a spe-cific call option as a percentage ofthe underlying project’s (or asset’s)value. For example, for a projectwhose NPVq equals 1.0 and s =+tequals 0.5, the value given in thetable is 19.7%. Any European calloption for which NPVq is 1.0 ands=+t is 0.5 will have a value equal to0.197 times S. If the assets associatedwith a particular project have avalue (S) of $100, then the projectviewed as a call option has a value of$19.70. If S were $10, the call optionvalue would be $1.97, and so forth.Option values in the table are ex-pressed in relative terms, as percent-ages of S, rather than in absolute dol-lars, to enable us to use the sametable for both big and small projects.It’s also convenient not to have tomanipulate the Black-Scholes equa-tion every time we want to value aproject. The Black-Scholes model is

used once, to generate the table it-self.2 After that, we need only locateour project in the table and multiplyby a factor of S.

Why is the option value $19.70less than the asset value of $100?We’ve been analyzing sources of ex-tra value associated with being ableto defer an investment. The key is toremember that extra refers to a com-parison between option value andnet present value (NPV), not to acomparison between option valueand present value (S). In this exam-ple, we are not expecting the optionvalue to be greater than S; we are ex-pecting it to be greater than NPV,which is S minus capital expendi-tures (X). S equals $100 here, but wedidn’t say what X was. Since NPVqequals 1.0 in this example, X must infact be greater than $100; otherwiseNPVq would be greater than 1.0. Forconcreteness, suppose that this is a

8 harvard business review July–August 1998

investment opportunities as real optionsM A N A G E R ’ S T O O L K I T

Using the Black-Scholes Option-Pricing Model to “Price the Space”

NPVq

Black-Scholes value of a European call option, expressedas a percentage of underlying asset value.

Each number in the table givesthe value of a European call forspecified values of NPVq and s=+t,as a percentage of S, the value ofproject assets.

Example:

Suppose S = $100

X = $105

t = 1 year

rƒ = 5%

s = 50% per year

then NPVq = 1.0

and s=+t = 0.50.

The table gives a value of 19.7%.

Interpretation:

Viewed as a call option, theproject has a value of:

Call value = 0.197 ´ $100 = $19.70.

Compare this to its conventionalNPV:

NPV = S 2 X

= $100 2 $105

= $25.

s=

+t

0.80 0.82 0.84 0.86 0.88 0.90 0.92 0.94 0.96 0.98 1.00 1.02 1.04 1.06 1.08

0.05 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.3 0.6 1.2 2.0 3.1 4.5 6.0 7.5

0.10 0.0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.5 0.8 1.2 1.7 2.3 3.1 4.0 5.0 6.1 7.3 8.6

0.15 0.5 0.7 1.0 1.3 1.7 2.2 2.8 3.5 4.2 5.1 6.0 7.0 8.0 9.1 10.2

0.20 1.5 1.9 2.3 2.8 3.4 4.0 4.7 5.4 6.2 7.1 8.0 8.9 9.9 10.9 11.9

0.25 2.8 3.3 3.9 4.5 5.2 5.9 6.6 7.4 8.2 9.1 9.9 10.9 11.8 12.8 13.7

0.30 4.4 5.0 5.7 6.3 7.0 7.8 8.6 9.4 10.2 11.1 11.9 12.8 13.7 14.6 15.6

0.35 6.2 6.8 7.5 8.2 9.0 9.8 10.6 11.4 12.2 13.0 13.9 14.8 15.6 16.5 17.4

0.40 8.0 8.7 9.4 10.2 11.0 11.7 12.5 13.4 14.2 15.0 15.9 16.7 17.5 18.4 19.2

0.45 9.9 10.6 11.4 12.2 12.9 13.7 14.5 15.3 16.2 17.0 17.8 18.6 19.4 20.3 21.1

0.50 11.8 12.6 13.4 14.2 14.9 15.7 16.5 17.3 18.1 18.9 20.5 21.3 22.1 22.9

0.55 13.8 14.6 15.4 16.1 16.9 17.7 18.5 19.3 20.1 20.9 21.7 22.4 23.2 24.0 24.8

0.60 15.8 16.6 17.4 18.1 18.9 19.7 20.5 21.3 22.0 22.8 23.6 24.3 25.1 25.8 26.6

0.65 17.8 18.6 19.3 20.1 20.9 21.7 22.5 23.2 24.0 24.7 25.3 26.2 27.0 27.7 28.4

0.70 19.8 20.6 21.3 22.1 22.9 23.6 24.4 25.2 25.9 26.6 27.4 28.1 28.8 29.5 30.2

0.75 21.8 22.5 23.3 24.1 24.8 25.6 26.3 27.1 27.8 28.5 29.2 29.9 30.6 31.3 32.0

0.80 23.7 24.5 25.3 26.0 26.8 27.5 28.3 29.0 29.7 30.4 31.1 31.8 32.4 33.1 33.8

0.85 25.7 26.5 27.2 28.0 28.7 29.4 30.2 30.9 31.6 32.2 32.9 33.6 34.2 34.9 35.5

0.90 27.7 28.4 29.2 29.9 30.6 31.3 32.0 32.7 33.4 34.1 34.7 35.4 36.0 36.6 37.3

19.7

Page 9: Investment Opportunities as Real Options: Getting …people.stern.nyu.edu/adamodar/pdfiles/articles/Investmentsas... · Investment Opportunities as Real Options: Getting Started

Recognizing the Option

ditures in the third year are large –three times the initial investment.

Step 1 is to recognize the optionand describe it. It takes practice torecognize the options that may beburied in conventional projects.However, there are at least two easyways to see the option in our exam-ple. The first is simply to look be-yond the numbers and examine theproject’s description. It surely sayssomething about the two-phased

one-year option – that is, suppose wecan defer the decision for one year –and that the risk-free rate of return(rƒ) is 5%. Then for NPVq to equal1.0, X must be $105 Recall that:

NPVq = S ÷ PV(X) = $100 ÷ ($105 ÷ 1.05).

Thus the conventional NPV is actu-ally negative:

NPV = S – X= $100 – $105 = –$5.

And an option value of $19.70 reallyis substantially greater than conven-tional NPV.

Using the Framework: An Example in Seven Steps To illustrate how to apply the frame-work, consider this example of a hy-pothetical, but representative, capi-tal investment. Division managers ata company we’ll call Franklin Chem-ical are proposing a phased expan-sion of their manufacturing facilities.They plan to build a new, commer-

cial-scale plant immediately to ex-ploit innovations in process tech-nology. And then they anticipatefurther investments, three years out,to expand the plant’s capacity and toenter two new markets. The initialinvestment is obviously strategic be-cause it creates the opportunity forsubsequent growth. Yet executivesresponsible for the company’s capi-tal budget are unimpressed by theproject because its NPV is essentiallyzero. (Cash flow projections andNPV calculations for the projectedinvestment are shown in the table“Franklin Chemical’s Initial Calcu-lations for a Proposed Expansion.”)In fact, in the annual jockeying forfunds, this program may not beat outcompeting alternatives. Its champi-ons are frustrated and feel sure thatthe company’s conventional NPVapproach is missing something.

They are right.This project has considerable op-

tion value because the initial expen-diture of $125 million buys the rightto expand (or not) three years later.This is important because the expen-

investment opportunities as real options M A N A G E R ’ S T O O L K I T

Discounted-cash-flow valuation: conventional NPV is our starting point.

Franklin Chemical’s Initial Calculations for a Proposed Expansion

large,discretionaryinvestments

routinespending

initialinvestments

0 1 2 3 4 5 6

routinespending

$mill

ion

s$m

illio

ns

capital expendituresincrease in NWC

Patterns in the total cash flows and/orin expenditure items such as capitalexpenditures and investments in networking capital provide clues aboutthe structure of the option.

harvard business review July–August 1998 9

0 1 2 3 4 5 6

lumpy cash flows

Year 0 1 2 3 4 5 6

Operating projections

revenues 455.0 551.0 800.0 1080.0 1195.0 1255.0

2cost of good sold 341.3 414.9 596.0 811.1 893.9 941.3

= gross profit 113.8 136.1 204.0 268.9 301.1 313.8

2SG&A expense 110.4 130.0 219.2 251.6 280.3 287.4

= operating profit 3.3 6.1 -15.2 17.3 20.8 26.3

Cash flow calculation

EBIT (1-tax rate) 2.2 4.0 -10.0 11.5 13.7 17.4

+ depreciation 19.0 21.0 21.0 46.3 48.1 50.0

2capital expenditures 100.0 8.1 9.5 307.0 16.0 16.3 17.0

2increase NWC 25.0 4.1 5.5 75.0 7.1 8.0 9.7

= free cash flow, assets -125.0 9.0 10.0 -371.0 34.7 37.5 40.7

+ terminal value, assets (perpetuity value with 5% per year growth) 610.3

Discount to present value

´ discount factor (12%) 1.000 0.893 0.797 0.712 0.636 0.567 0.507

= PV (by year) -125.0 8.0 8.0 -264.1 22.0 21.3 329.8

NPV (sum of all years) 0.1

Figures are in $millions and have been rounded.

Spending PatternsYear

350.0

300.0

250.0

200.0

150.0

100.0

50.0

0.0

Free-Cash FlowYear

100.0

0.0

2100.0

2200.0

2300.0

2400.0

Page 10: Investment Opportunities as Real Options: Getting …people.stern.nyu.edu/adamodar/pdfiles/articles/Investmentsas... · Investment Opportunities as Real Options: Getting Started

How to EstimateCumulative Volatility

The variable in our option-pricing model that managersare least accustomed to estimating is variance (s 2), orstandard deviation (s ), which we used to get our metricfor cumulative volatility (s=+t ). For a real option, s can-not be found in a newspaper or in a financial statement,and most people do not have highly developed intuitionabout, say, the annualized standard deviation of returnson assets associated with entering a new market. In theexample given in the text, we assume s is 40% per year. Isthat reasonable? Here are several sound approaches to cre-ating or judging estimates of s :

Take a(n educated) guess.Assets to which you would as-sign higher hurdle rates becauseof their higher-than-average sys-tematic risk are also likely tohave higher values of s. Howhigh is “high” for standard devi-ation? Returns on broad-basedU.S. stock indexes had a stan-dard deviation of approximately20% per year for most of the past15 years; exceptions (upwardspikes) were associated withevents like the 1987 stock-mar-ket crash and the 1990–1991Persian Gulf crisis. Individualstocks generally have a higherstandard deviation than themarket as a whole; returns onGeneral Motors’ stock, for ex-ample, have a s of about 25% peryear. Individual projects withincompanies can be expected tohave a still higher s. When Iwork with manufacturing assetsand have no specific informa-tion at all about s, I begin by ex-amining a range: from 30% to60% per year.

Gather some data.For some businesses, we can es-timate volatility using histori-cal data on investment returnsin the same or related indus-tries. Alternatively, we mightcompute what is called impliedvolatility using current prices ofoptions traded on organized ex-

changes. The idea is to observe amarket price for an optionwhose parameters are all knownexcept for s. We then use a modellike Black-Scholes to figure outwhat s must be given all theother variables. Today we canget implied volatility for sharesof a very large number of compa-nies in many industries. Often itis possible to use implied vola-tilities from options on stocks toinfer s for assets in correspond-ing industries. The quality andavailability of such data haveimproved enormously in thepast ten years.

Simulate s.Spreadsheet-based projectionsof a project’s future cash flows,together with Monte Carlo sim-ulation techniques, can be usedto synthesize a probability dis-tribution for project returns.Once you have the synthesizeddistribution, the computer canquickly calculate the corre-sponding standard deviation.Simulation software packagesfor desktop computers are com-mercially available and workwith the same popular spread-sheet applications that generateyour company’s DCF models.These tools also have becomefar more widely available andmuch easier to use in recentyears.

nature of the program by way of jus-tifying the large outlays in year 3.The other is to examine the patternof the project cash flows over time.The cash flows in the chart are veryuneven: two figures are an order ofmagnitude larger than the other five,and both of these are negative. Agraph of the capital-expendituresline would clearly show the spike inspending in year 3. Such a large sumis almost surely discretionary. Thatis, the company can choose not tomake the investment, based on howthings look when the time comes.This is a classic expansion option,sometimes called a growth option.(See the graphs “Recognizing theOption.”)

Franklin’s project has two majorparts. The first part is to spend $125million now to acquire some operat-ing assets. The second part is an op-tion to spend an additional sum,more than $300 million, three yearsfrom now to acquire the additionalcapacity and enter the new markets.The option here is a call option,owned by the company, with threeyears to expiration, that can be exer-cised by investing certain amountsin net working capital (NWC) andfixed assets. Viewing the project inthis way, we want to evaluate thefollowing: NPV (entire proposal) =NPV (phase 1 assets) + call value(phase 2 assets).

Phase 1 refers to the initial invest-ment and the associated cash flows.It can be valued using NPV as usual.Phase 2 refers to the opportunity toexpand, which may or may not beexploited in year 3. To value phase 2,we will use the framework outlinedabove to synthesize a comparablecall option and then value it.

Step 2 is to map the project’s char-acteristics onto call option variables.This mapping will create the syn-thetic option we need and indicatewhere in the DCF spreadsheet weneed to go to obtain values for thevariables. The value of the underly-ing assets (S) will be the presentvalue of the assets acquired whenand if the company exercises the op-tion. The exercise price (X) will bethe expenditures required to acquirethe phase 2 assets. The time to expi-ration (t) is three years, according to

10 harvard business review July–August 1998

investment opportunities as real optionsM A N A G E R ’ S T O O L K I T

Page 11: Investment Opportunities as Real Options: Getting …people.stern.nyu.edu/adamodar/pdfiles/articles/Investmentsas... · Investment Opportunities as Real Options: Getting Started

the projections given in the DCFanalysis, although we might want toquiz the managers involved to deter-mine whether the decision actuallycould be made sooner or later. Thethree-year risk-free rate of interest(rƒ) is 5.5% (which is the market rateof interest on a three-year U.S. gov-ernment bond). Note for comparisonthat the risk-adjusted discount ratebeing applied in the spreadsheet is12%. Finally, the standard deviationof returns on these operating assets(s ) is not given anywhere in thespreadsheet. For now, we’ll assumethat figure is 40% per year, a valuethat is neither particularly high norlow. The insert “How to EstimateCumulative Volatility” explainsways to obtain values for s in caseslike these.

Step 3 is to rearrange the DCF pro-jections for two purposes: to sepa-rate phase 1 from phase 2 and to iso-late values for S and X. I generallyfind it easier to work on S and X first.That requires making a judgmentabout what spending is discre-tionary versus nondiscretionary orwhat spending is routine versus ex-traordinary. It also requires making asimilar judgment about which cashinflows are associated with phase 1as opposed to phase 2.

In this project, expenditures onnet working capital and fixed assetsobviously are lumpy. The very largesums in year 3 clearly are discre-tionary and form part of the exerciseprice (X). The smaller sums in otheryears are plausibly routine and maybe netted against phase 2 cash in-flows, ultimately to be discountedand form part of S, the value of thephase 2 assets.

Sometimes it is easy to separatephase 1 cash flows from phase 2 cashflows because whoever prepared theDCF analysis built it up from de-tailed, phase-specific operating pro-jections. When that’s the case, as itis in our example, all we have to do isuse the disaggregated detail underly-ing the summary DCF analysis, andthe table “Franklin’s Projections Re-arranged” presents this informationfor our example. At other times, wehave to allocate cash flows to eachphase. A common expedient is sim-ply to break out the phase 1 cash in-

flows and terminal value. Then,phase 2 cash inflows and terminalvalue are whatever is left over. Notethat when we discount cash flowsfor the two phases separately, we ob-tain the same NPV as before.

Step 4 is to establish a benchmarkfor phase 2’s option value based onthe rearranged DCF analysis. Havingseparated phases 1 and 2, we can geta conventional discounted-cash-flow NPV for each, which can beseen in the table showing FranklinChemical’s rearranged calculations.This table shows that phase 1 alonehas a positive NPV of $16.3 millionwhile phase 2’s NPV is 2$16.2 mil-lion. The sum of the two is the sameNPV, $0.1 million, that we obtainedoriginally. Already, we have a quan-titative option-related insight. Thevalue of the whole proposal must be

at least $16.3 million because theoption value of phase 2, whatever itturns out to be, cannot be less thanzero. In fact, if the option value ofphase 2 is significant, the project as awhole will have a much higher valuethan $16.3 million, to say nothing ofthe $0.1 million we started with.This insight is available only whenwe separate the project’s two phasesand realize that we will have a choiceabout whether or not to undertakephase 2.

Our first DCF benchmark forphase 2 is 2$16.2 million. Actually,though, phase 2’s conventional NPVis worse than that, and it’s worth adigression to see why. The DCF val-uation contains a common mistake.It discounted the discretionaryspending in year 3 at the same 12%risk-adjusted rate that had already

The DCF projections have been rearranged to separate phases 1 and 2 and isolate S and X.

Franklin’s Projections Rearranged

investment opportunities as real options M A N A G E R ’ S T O O L K I T

harvard business review July–August 1998 11

Year 0 1 2 3 4 5 6

Phase 1

cash flow 0.0 9.0 10.0 11.0 11.6 12.1 12.7

+ terminal value 191.0

2investment -125

´ discount factor (12%) 1.000 0.893 0.797 0.712 0.636 0.567 0.507

= PV (each year) -125.0 8.0 8.0 7.8 7.3 6.9 103.2

NPV (sum of years) 16.3 This is the conventional NPV of phase 1.

Phase 2

cash flow 0.0 23.1 25.4 28.0

+ terminal value 419.3

2investment -382

´ discount factor (12%) 0.712 0.636 0.567 0.507

= PV (each year) -271.9 14.7 14.4 226.6

NPV (sum of years) -16.2 This is the conventional NPV of phase 2.

Phases 1 and 2

cash flow 0.0 9.0 10.0 11.0 34.7 37.5 40.7

+ terminal value 610.3

2investment -125 -382

´ discount factor (12%) 1.000 0.893 0.797 0.712 0.636 0.567 0.507

= PV (each year) -125.0 8.0 8.0 -264.1 22.0 21.3 329.8

NPV (sum of years) 0.1 This is the same conventional NPV we got previously.

Figures are in $millions and have been rounded.

Page 12: Investment Opportunities as Real Options: Getting …people.stern.nyu.edu/adamodar/pdfiles/articles/Investmentsas... · Investment Opportunities as Real Options: Getting Started

Getting the Right Benchmark

produce in the fourth year and be-yond. The same table shows that tobe $255.7 million. The other option-pricing variables have already beenmentioned: t is 3 years, rƒ is 5.5%,and s is 40% per year.

Step 6 is to combine the five op-tion-pricing variables into our twooption-value metrics: NPVq ands=+t. In this case:

NPVq = S ÷ PV(X) =$255.7

= 0.786382 ÷ (1.055)3

And

s =+t = 0.4 ´ =+3 = 0.693.

The exhibit “Deriving the Option-Value Metrics for Franklin’s Project”shows how all five variables were de-rived and how they combine to formour two metrics.

12 harvard business review July–August 1998

investment opportunities as real optionsM A N A G E R ’ S T O O L K I T

Most companies overdiscount future discretionary spending (in steps 2 and 3, we used 12%).If we discount phase 2 spending at 5.5% instead, we get a new (lower) benchmark.

been applied to the project’s cashflows. That rate is almost certainlytoo high because such expendituresare rarely subject to the same oper-ating and product-market forcesthat make the project’s cash flowsrisky. Construction costs, for exam-ple, may be uncertain, but they areusually much more dependent onengineering factors, weather condi-tions, and contractors’ performancethan on customers’ tastes, competi-tive conditions, industry capacityutilization, and such. Overdiscount-ing future discretionary spendingleads to an optimistically biased estimate of NPV. To see the mag-nitude of this effect, discount theyear 3 expenditures of $382 millionat 5.5% instead of 12% (again, it’s asif we were putting investment fundsinto treasury bonds between now

and year 3). Then, phase 2 has a con-ventional DCF value of 2$69.6 mil-lion, not 2$16.2 million, and theNPV for the whole project goes from$0.1 million to 2$53.4 million, avery substantial difference (See thetable “Getting the Right Bench-mark.”)

Step 5 is to attach values to the option-pricing variables. Having re-formulated the DCF spreadsheet,we can now pull values for S and Xfrom it. X is the amount the com-pany will have to invest in networking capital and fixed assets(capital expenditures) in year 3 if itwants to proceed with the expan-sion: $382 million. S is the presentvalue of the new phase 2 operatingassets. In other words, it’s the DCFvalue now (at time zero) of the cashflows those assets are expected to

Year 0 1 2 3 4 5 6

Phase 1

cash flow 0.0 9.0 10.0 11.0 11.6 12.1 12.7

+ terminal value 191.0

2investment -125

´ discount factor (12%) 1.000 0.893 0.797 0.712 0.636 0.567 0.507

= PV (each year) -125.0 8.0 8.0 7.8 7.3 6.9 103.2

NPV (sum of years) 16.3 This is the conventional NPV of phase 1.

Phase 2

cash flow 0.0 23.1 25.4 28.0

+ terminal value 419.3

2investment -382

´ discount factor (12%) 0.712 0.636 0.567 0.507

´ discount factor (5.5%) 0.852

= PV (cash flows 12%) 0.0 14.7 14.4 226.6

= PV (investment 5.5%) -325.3

NPV (sum of years) -69.6 This is a revised DCF benchmark for phase 2.

Phases 1 and 2

cash flow 0.0 9.0 10.0 11.0 34.7 37.5 40.7

+ terminal value 610.3

2investment -125 -382

´ discount factor (12%) 1.000 0.893 0.797 0.712 0.636 0.567 0.507

= PV (each year) -125.0 8.0 8.0 7.8 22.0 21.3 329.8

= PV (investment 5.5%) -325.3

NPV (sum of years) -53.4 This is a revised DCF benchmark for theproject as a whole.

Figures are in $millions and have been rounded.

The sum of thesepresent values is S.

This is t.

This is X.

This is rƒ.

Year 0 1 2 3 4 5 6

Phase 2

cash flow 0.0 23.1 25.4 28.0

terminal value 419.3

investment -382

discount factor (12%) 0.712 0.636 0.567 0.507

discount factor (5.5%) 0.852

PV (cash flows 12%) 0.0 14.7 14.4 226.6

PV (investment 5.5%) -325.3

NPV -69.6 This is a revised DCF benchmark for phase 2.

Page 13: Investment Opportunities as Real Options: Getting …people.stern.nyu.edu/adamodar/pdfiles/articles/Investmentsas... · Investment Opportunities as Real Options: Getting Started

Step 7 is to look up call value as apercentage of asset value in ourBlack-Scholes option-pricing table.The table does not show values thatcorrespond exactly to our computedvalue for NPVq and s=+t, but by in-terpolating we can see that the valueof our synthesized call option isabout 19% of the value of the under-lying assets (S). Accordingly, the dol-lar value of the option is 0.19 times$255.7 million, which equals $48.6million. Recall the value of the en-tire proposal is given by: NPV (entireproposal) = NPV (phase 1 assets) +call value (phase 2 assets). Filling inthe figures gives: NPV (entire pro-posal) = $16.3 million + $48.6 mil-lion = $64.9 million.

Our final estimate of $64.9 mil-lion is a long way from the originalfigure for NPV of $0.1 million andeven further from 2$53.4 million.Yet the option-pricing analysis usesthe same inputs from the samespreadsheet as the conventionalNPV. What looks like a marginal-to-terrible project through a DCF lensis in fact a very attractive one. This

seems especially so when we com-pare $64.9 million with the requiredinitial investment of $125 million;the value associated with the optionto expand the plant in year 3 is fullyhalf again as much as the initial in-vestment. Few projects look so good.

What should you do next? All thethings you would usually do whenevaluating a capital project. Performsensitivity analyses. Check and up-date assumptions. Examine particu-larly interesting or threatening sce-narios. Compare and interpret theanalysis in light of other historical orcontemporary investments andtransactions. In addition, now thatyou’ve begun pricing synthesizedreal options, you may want to con-sider adding a few other items toyour list. Some are discussed furtherin the insert “How Far Can You Ex-tend the Framework?” They includechecking for project features thatwould make it more suitable to usean American rather than a Europeanoption. They also include checkingfor clear disadvantages associated

with deferring investment, such ascompetitive preemption, whichwould offset some or all of thesources of value associated withwaiting. Some of these concerns canbe handled by straightforward mod-ifications to the framework. Othersrequire more sophisticated model-ing than either this framework aloneor conventional NPV generally canprovide. Even in those cases, though,a naïvely formulated option valuewill augment whatever insight maybe drawn from a DCF treatmentalone. Remember that simply byrecognizing the structure of theproblem we gleaned an importantinsight about the value of the projectin our example (that it had to be atleast $16.3 million) before we actu-ally priced the option.

Does the framework really work?Yes. Even though we have takensome liberties, we know more aboutour project after using it than we didbefore. And if it seemed worthwhile,we could further refine our initial es-timate of option value. But the keyto getting useful insight from option

Deriving the Option-Value Metrics for Franklin’s Project

S

X

t

s

The present value ofthe project assets asso-ciated with phase 2.

Spending required inyear 3 to obtain thephase 2 assets.

Length of time phase 2spending may bedeferred.

Time value of money atsame horizon (t) asoption.

Standard deviation peryear on phase 2 assets.

Separate phase 1 from phase 2cash flows; compute the DCFvalue of phase 2 alone.

Identify large discretionaryportions of capital expendituresand net-working-capital spendingassociated with phase 2 only,in year 3.

Appears in spreadsheet to bethree years; check with managers.

Obtain market rate of interest onthree-year U.S. government bond,assumed here to be 5.5%.

Not in DCF spreadsheet; obtainfrom similar traded assets, fromimplied volatilities on tradedoptions, or try a range. Assume40% per year to start.

Value

NPVq = $255.7 = 0.786$3824(1.055)3

s =+t = 0.4 ´ =+3 = 0.693

Variable

$255.7

$382

3 years

5.5%

40%per year

MetricSource in DCF SpreadsheetProject Characteristic

investment opportunities as real options M A N A G E R ’ S T O O L K I T

harvard business review July–August 1998 13

Page 14: Investment Opportunities as Real Options: Getting …people.stern.nyu.edu/adamodar/pdfiles/articles/Investmentsas... · Investment Opportunities as Real Options: Getting Started

14 harvard business review July–August 1998

investment opportunities as real optionsM A N A G E R ’ S T O O L K I T

How Far Can You Extend the Framework?

Real corporate projects will present immediatechallenges to some of the simplifications underly-ing this framework. Can the framework be soupedup to handle more complex problems? Or does itsvery simplicity present insurmountable limita-tions? When might it generate seriously misleadinginformation?

Bells and whistles can be added to the frameworkfairly easily, although they require extra data, andthe details are beyond the scope of this article. Forexample, the framework assumes that the amountand timing of a project’s capital expenditures (X) arecertain. But what if they are not? That’s usually thecase with business opportunities. The frameworkcan be adapted to handle those circumstances, butthe adaptation helps only if we can describe the un-certainty. Specifically, we need to know the proba-bility distribution of X and the joint probability dis-tribution of S and X. That is, it matters whether Xtends to be high when S tends to be high; whetherthe opposite is true (that is, X tends to be high whenS is low and vice versa); or whether they are both notonly uncertain but also unrelated.

As another example, suppose the uncertainty (orvariance) associated with a project changes overtime. That’s fairly common, and it makes sense thatit should affect our estimate of cumulative volatility.Once again, if we know how the variance changesover time, or if we can make plausible guesses, theframework can be adapted without much trouble.The insert “Where to Find Additional Help” citessome readings that address how such real-worldproblems affect option values.

Both of these examples describe situations inwhich the real limitation is not the framework butrather the data or our knowledge of the project’s pa-rameters. Even when we know that we lack neces-sary data, the framework can help by showing uswhat the effect on value would be if the data wereone thing or another. We might conclude that it’sworthwhile to gather or create better data.

Some other real-world complications arethornier. The framework does a good job of captur-ing the extra value associated with deferring an in-vestment decision. But what if there are particularcosts associated with deferral? For example, compa-nies trying to be first to market with the next gener-ation of a hot product will incur large costs if defer-ral allows a competitor to preempt them. Anytime

there are predictable costs to deferring, the option todefer an investment is less valuable, and we wouldbe foolish to ignore those costs. If such additionalcosts were the only issue, we could easily handlethem in our framework as long as we knew whenthe decision to invest or not to invest finally wouldbe made. But in the real world, we often don’t know.Companies may not be compelled to invest at a cer-tain moment, but rather may have discretion totime their investments. So the problem is to decidenot only whether to invest but also when.

In effect, many real options are American ratherthan European. American options can be exercisedat any time prior to expiration; European optionsmay be exercised only at expiration. The option-pricing table embedded in this framework prices Eu-ropean options. American options are more valu-able than European options whenever the costsassociated with deferral are predictable. Whenthat’s the case, I recommend using the frameworkto set the lower boundary of the option value andthen supplementing that figure with another tableor a spreadsheet-based algorithm to convert Euro-pean option values to the corresponding Americanoption values. That is not quite as easy as merelyrewriting the pricing table because it would take athree-dimensional or possibly four-dimensionaltable to accommodate the extra variables needed.But it can be set up in a spreadsheet. In short, thecombination of costs associated with deferral and acompany’s ability to time investments calls forsome added analysis. But the framework needs to beaugmented, not scrapped.

Finally, the Black-Scholes option-pricing modelthat generated the numbers in the table makessome simplifying assumptions of its own. They in-clude assumptions about the form of the probabilitydistribution that characterizes project returns. Theyalso include assumptions about the tradability ofthe underlying project assets; that is, about whetherthose assets are regularly bought and sold. And theyinclude assumptions about the ability of investorsto continually adjust their investment portfolios.When the Black-Scholes assumptions fail to hold,this framework still yields qualitative insights butthe numbers become less reliable. Consequently, itmay be worthwhile to consult an expert about alter-native models to improve the quantitative esti-mates of option value.

Page 15: Investment Opportunities as Real Options: Getting …people.stern.nyu.edu/adamodar/pdfiles/articles/Investmentsas... · Investment Opportunities as Real Options: Getting Started

pricing sooner rather than later is tobuild on, rather than abandon, theDCF-based NPV analysis your com-pany already uses. Had we set out tovalue the option from scratch, itwould have been more difficult andtaken longer. It also would havebeen hard to tell how well we haddone and when to stop working on it.Option pricing should be a comple-ment to existing capital-budgetingsystems, not a substitute for them.The framework presented here is away to start where you are and getsomewhere better.

1. There are other mathematical advantages,beyond the scope of this article, associatedwith using the quotient instead of the differ-ence. Also, students of economics will recog-nize the similarity between NPVq and the fa-mous “Tobin’s q,” which measures the ratio ofthe value of an asset to its replacement cost.

2. This form of option-pricing table is nearly asold as the Black-Scholes model itself. I first raninto it as an M.B.A. student using RichardBrealey and Stewart Myers’s text, Principles ofCorporate Finance (New York: McGraw-Hill,1981).

In the September–October 1998 issue ofHBR, Timothy Luehrman extends theframework presented here. In “Strategyas a Portfolio of Real Options,” he ex-plores how managers can use optionpricing to improve the way they makedecisions about the sequence and timingof strategic investments.

Reprint 98404To place an order, call 1-800-988-0886.

harvard business review July–August 1998 15

investment opportunities as real options M A N A G E R ’ S T O O L K I T

Where to Find Additional Help

Graduate-level corporate-finance textbooks cover the basics ofoption pricing, beginning from first principles:

Zvi Bodie and Robert C. Merton, Finance(Upper Saddle River, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 1998).

Richard A. Brealey and Stewart Myers,Principles of Corporate Finance, fifth edition(New York: McGraw-Hill, 1996).

Stephen A. Ross, Randolph W. Westerfield, and Jeffrey Jaffe,Corporate Finance, fourth edition(Chicago: Richard D. Irwin, 1996).

Other books go beyond the basics to treat specialized problemsand present more advanced models for option pricing.Well-known titles include:

John C. Hull, Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives,third edition (Upper Saddle River, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 1997).

David G. Luenberger, Investment Science(New York: Oxford University Press, 1998).

Paul Wilmott, Jeff Dewynne, and Sam Howison, Option Pricing(Oxford, England: Oxford Financial Press, 1993).

A few books focus on real options in particular. Each takes a some-what different approach to modeling corporate opportunities:

Martha Amram and Nalin Kulatilaka,Real Options: Managing Strategic Investment in anUncertain World (Boston, Mass.: Harvard Business SchoolPress, forthcoming 1998).

Avinash K. Dixit and Robert S. Pindyck,Investment Under Uncertainty(Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1994).

Lenos Trigeorgis, Real Options: Managerial Flexibility and Strategy in Resource Allocation (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1996).

Shorter readings on selected related topics include:

Avinash K. Dixit and Robert S. Pindyck, “The Options Approach to Capital Investment,” HBR May–June 1995.

W. Carl Kester, “Today’s Options for Tomorrow’s Growth,”HBR March–April 1984.

Timothy A. Luehrman, “What’s It Worth? A GeneralManager’s Guide to Valuation,” HBR May–June 1997.

Lenos Trigeorgis, ed., Real Options in Capital Investment:Models, Strategies, and Applications(Westport, Conn.: Praeger, 1995).

Finally, expanded versions of the option-pricing table publishedin this article are available in the Brealey and Myers text citedabove and in Luehrman, “Capital Projects as Real Options: AnIntroduction,” HBS case no. 295-074.

Page 16: Investment Opportunities as Real Options: Getting …people.stern.nyu.edu/adamodar/pdfiles/articles/Investmentsas... · Investment Opportunities as Real Options: Getting Started

Harvard Business ReviewHARVARD BUSINESS REVIEWSUBSCRIPTION SERVICE

United States and Canada Phone: 800-274-3214Rates per year: United States, $85; Canada, U.S.$95

International and MexicoPhone: 44-1858-435324Fax: 44-1858-468969Rates per year: international, U.S.$145; Mexico, U.S.$95Orders, inquiries, and address changes: Harvard Business ReviewTower House, Sovereign ParkLathkill Street, Market HarboroughLeicestershire le16 9efEngland

International customer service E-mailaddress: [email protected]

Payments accepted: Visa, MasterCard, American Express; checks at current exchange rate payable to Harvard Business Review. Bills and other receipts may be issued.

CATALOGS

Harvard Business School PublishingMedia CatalogThis 32-page, full-color catalog features morethan 40 management development video andinteractive CD-ROM programs.

Harvard Business School PressThis latest full-color catalog features books for the fast-paced business world where youlive and work.

Harvard Business School Publishing Catalog of Best-Selling Teaching MaterialsThis collection of teaching materialscontains those items most requested byour customers.

Harvard Business School PublishingCatalog of New Teaching MaterialsDesigned for individuals looking for thelatest materials in case method teaching.

CASE STUDIES AND HARVARD BUSINESS REVIEWARTICLE REPRINTS

Many readers have asked for an easy way to order case studies and article reprints or toobtain permission to copy. In response, wehave established a Customer Service Team to grant permission, send rush copies in paperform, deliver files in Acrobat (PDF) formatelectronically (Harvard Business Reviewarticles only), or customize collections.

Please contact the Customer Service Team:

Phone: 617-496-1449United States and Canada: 800-668-6780(8 A.M. – 6 P.M. weekdays, voice mail after hours)Fax: 617-496-1029 (24 hours, 7 days a week)E-mail: [email protected](24 hours, 7 days a week)Web Site: http://www.hbsp.harvard.edu

Prices (minimum order, $10):

Harvard Business Review Reprints(Discounts apply to multiple copies of thesame article.)

1–9 copies $5 each10–99 $4100–499 $3.50Electronic $3.50 each

Harvard Business School Case Studies$5 each

For quantity estimates or quotes on customized products, callFrank Tamoshunas at 617-495-6198.Fax: 617-496-8866

PERMISSIONS

For information on permission to quote or translate Harvard Business SchoolPublishing material, contact:

Customer Service DepartmentHarvard Business School

Publishing Corporation60 Harvard WayBoston, MA 02163

Phone: 617-496-1449United States and Canada: 800-668-6780Fax: 617-495-6985E-mail: [email protected]