An Economic History of Twentiet - Enrique Cardenas

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin AmericaVolume 3: Industrialization and the State in Latin America: The Postwar YearsE. Cardenas; J. Ocampo; R. ThorpISBN: 9780230595682DOI: 10.1057/9780230595682Palgrave Macmillan

    Please respect intellectual property rightsThis material is copyright and its use is restricted by our standard site license terms and conditions (see palgraveconnect.com/pc/info/terms_conditions.html). If you plan to copy, distribute or share in any format, including, for the avoidanceof doubt, posting on websites, you need the express prior permission of PalgraveMacmillan. To request permission please contact [email protected].

  • Edited by Enrique Crdenas,Jos Antonio Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp

    An Economic History ofTwentieth-Century Latin

    America

  • St Antonys Series General Editor: Richard Clogg (1999 ), Fellow of St Antonys College, Oxford

    Recent titles include:

    Enrique Crdenas, Jos Antonio Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp (editors)

    AN ECONOMIC HISTORY OF TWENTIETH-CENTURY LATIN AMERICA

    Volume 1: The Export Age

    Volume 2: Latin America in the 1930s

    Volume 3: Industrialization and the State in Latin America

    Jennifer G. Mathers

    THE RUSSIAN NUCLEAR SHIELD FROM STALIN TO YELTSIN

    Marta Dyczok

    THE GRAND ALLIANCE AND UKRAINIAN REFUGEES

    Mark Brzezinski

    THE STRUGGLE FOR CONSTITUTIONALISM IN POLAND

    Suke Wolton

    LORD HAILEY, THE COLONIAL OFFICE AND THE POLITICS OF RACE AND

    EMPIRE IN THE SECOND WORLD WAR

    The Loss of White Prestige

    Junko Tomaru

    THE POSTWAR RAPPROCHEMENT OF MALAYA AND JAPAN, 194561

    The Roles of Britain and Japan in South-East Asia

    Eiichi Motono

    CONFLICT AND COOPERATION IN SINO-BRITISH BUSINESS, 18601911

    The Impact of the Pro-British Commercial Network in Shanghai

    Nikolas K. Gvosdev

    IMPERIAL POLICIES AND PERSPECTIVES TOWARDS GEORGIA, 17601819

    Bernardo Kosacoff

    CORPORATE STRATEGIES UNDER STRUCTURAL ADJUSTMENT IN ARGENTINA

    Responses by Industrial Firms to a New Set of Uncertainties

    Ray Takeyh

    THE ORIGINS OF THE EISENHOWER DOCTRINE

    The US, Britain and Nassers Egypt, 195357

    Derek Hopwood (editor)

    ARAB NATION, ARAB NATIONALISM

    Judith Clifton

    THE POLITICS OF TELECOMMUNICATIONS IN MEXICO

    Privatization and StateLabour Relations, 192895

    10.1057/9780230595682 - An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin America, Edited by Enrique Cardenas, Jose A. Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp

    Copy

    right

    mat

    eria

    l fro

    m w

    ww

    .pa

    lgra

    vec

    on

    nec

    t.com

    - lic

    ense

    d to

    Q4

    Push

    - Pa

    lgra

    veC

    onne

    ct -

    2010

    -12-

    06

  • Ccile Laborde PLURALIST THOUGHT AND THE STATE IN BRITAIN AND FRANCE, 190025

    Craig Brandist and Galin Tihanov (editors) MATERIALIZING BAKHTIN

    C. S. NichollsTHE HISTORY OF ST ANTONYS COLLEGE, OXFORD, 19502000

    Anthony Kirk-Greene BRITAINS IMPERIAL ADMINISTRATORS, 18581966

    Laila Parsons THE DRUZE BETWEEN PALESTINE AND ISRAEL, 194749

    M. K. FlynnIDEOLOGY, MOBILIZATION AND THE NATION The Rise of Irish, Basque and Carlist Nationalist Movements in the Nineteenth and Early Twentieth Centuries

    Karina Sonnenberg-Stern EMANCIPATION AND POVERTY The Ashkenazi Jews of Amsterdam, 17961850

    Shane ORourke WARRIORS AND PEASANTS The Don Cossacks in Late Imperial Russia

    Azar Gat BRITISH ARMOUR THEORY AND THE RISE OF THE PANZER ARM Revising the Revisionists

    St Antonys Series Series Standing Order ISBN 0333711092 (outside North America only)

    You can receive future titles in this series as they are published by placing a standing order. Please contact your bookseller or, in case of difficulty, write to us at the address below with your name and address, the title of the series and the ISBN quoted above.

    Customer Services Department, Macmillan Distribution Ltd, Houndmills, Basingstoke, Hampshire RG21 6XS, England

    10.1057/9780230595682 - An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin America, Edited by Enrique Cardenas, Jose A. Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp

    Copy

    right

    mat

    eria

    l fro

    m w

    ww

    .pa

    lgra

    vec

    on

    nec

    t.com

    - lic

    ense

    d to

    Q4

    Push

    - Pa

    lgra

    veC

    onne

    ct -

    2010

    -12-

    06

  • An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin America Volume 3

    Industrialization and the State in Latin America: The Postwar Years

    Edited by

    Enrique Crdenas Professor of Economics and Rector Universidad de las Amricas-Puebla

    Jos Antonio Ocampo Executive Secretary United Nations Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean (CEPAL/ECLAC)

    and

    Rosemary Thorp Reader in the Economics of Latin America St Antonys College Oxford

    in association with St Antonys College, Oxford

    10.1057/9780230595682 - An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin America, Edited by Enrique Cardenas, Jose A. Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp

    Copy

    right

    mat

    eria

    l fro

    m w

    ww

    .pa

    lgra

    vec

    on

    nec

    t.com

    - lic

    ense

    d to

    Q4

    Push

    - Pa

    lgra

    veC

    onne

    ct -

    2010

    -12-

    06

  • Editorial matter, selection and Chapter 1 Enrique Crdenas, Jos Antonio Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp 2000 Chapter 7 Enrique Crdenas 2000 Chapter 9 Jos Antonio Ocampo and Camilo Tovar 2000 Chapters 26, 8, 10, 11 Palgrave Publishers Ltd 2000

    All rights reserved. No reproduction, copy or transmission of this publication may be made without written permission.

    No paragraph of this publication may be reproduced, copied or transmitted save with written permission or in accordance with the provisions of the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988, or under the terms of any licence permitting limited copying issued by the Copyright Licensing Agency, 90 Tottenham Court Road, London W1P 0LP.

    Any person who does any unauthorised act in relation to this publication may be liable to criminal prosecution and civil claims for damages.

    The authors have asserted their rights to be identified as the authors of this work in accordance with the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988.

    First published 2000 by PALGRAVE Houndmills, Basingstoke, Hampshire RG21 6XS and 175 Fifth Avenue, New York, N. Y. 10010 Companies and representatives throughout the world

    PALGRAVE is the new global academic imprint of St. Martins Press LLC Scholarly and Reference Division and Palgrave Publishers Ltd (formerly Macmillan Press Ltd).

    ISBN 0333633423

    This book is printed on paper suitable for recycling and made from fully managed and sustained forest sources.

    A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library.

    Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data An economic history of twentieth-century Latin America / edited by Enrique Crdenas, Jos Antonio Ocampo, and Rosemary Thorp.

    p. cm. Includes bibliographical references and index. Contents: v. 1. The export age / edited by Enrique Crdenas, Jos Antonio Ocampo, and Rosemary Thorp v. 2. Latin America in the 1930s : the role of the periphery in world crisis / edited by Rosemary Thorp v. 3. Industrialization and the State in Latin America : the postwar years / edited by Enrique Crdenas, Jos Antonio Ocampo, and Rosemary Thorp. ISBN 0333913043 (v. 1 : cloth) ISBN 0333633415 (v. 2 : cloth) ISBN 0333633423 (v. 3 : cloth) 1. Latin AmericaEconomic conditions. 2. Latin AmericaEconomic

    conditions1918 I. Crdenas, Enrique. II. Ocampo, Jos Antonio. III. Thorp, Rosemary.

    HC125 .E37365 2000

    330.98'0033dc21

    00040449

    10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 09 08 07 06 05 04 03 02 01 00

    Printed and bound in Great Britain by Antony Rowe Ltd, Chippenham, Wiltshire

    10.1057/9780230595682 - An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin America, Edited by Enrique Cardenas, Jose A. Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp

    Copy

    right

    mat

    eria

    l fro

    m w

    ww

    .pa

    lgra

    vec

    on

    nec

    t.com

    - lic

    ense

    d to

    Q4

    Push

    - Pa

    lgra

    veC

    onne

    ct -

    2010

    -12-

    06

  • For Carlos Daz Alejandro

    10.1057/9780230595682 - An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin America, Edited by Enrique Cardenas, Jose A. Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp

    Copy

    right

    mat

    eria

    l fro

    m w

    ww

    .pa

    lgra

    vec

    on

    nec

    t.com

    - lic

    ense

    d to

    Q4

    Push

    - Pa

    lgra

    veC

    onne

    ct -

    2010

    -12-

    06

  • This page intentionally left blank

    10.1057/9780230595682 - An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin America, Edited by Enrique Cardenas, Jose A. Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp

    Copy

    right

    mat

    eria

    l fro

    m w

    ww

    .pa

    lgra

    vec

    on

    nec

    t.com

    - lic

    ense

    d to

    Q4

    Push

    - Pa

    lgra

    veC

    onne

    ct -

    2010

    -12-

    06

  • Contents

    List of Tables and Figures ix

    Foreword to An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin America xii

    Notes on the Contributors xiii

    1 Introduction 1

    Enrique Ca rdenas, Jose Antonio Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp

    2 Technological Learning, Institution Building and the

    Microeconomics of Import Substitution 36

    Jorge Katz and Bernardo Kosacoff

    3 ECLA and the Theory of Import Substituting Industrialization

    in Latin America 58

    E.V.K. FitzGerald

    4 The Influence of International Financial Institutions on ISI 98

    Richard Webb

    5 The Industrialization of Chile during Protectionism, 194082 114

    Ricardo Ffrench-Davis, Oscar Munoz, Jose Miguel Benavente

    and Gustavo Crespi

    6 Import Substitution and Growth in Brazil, 1890s1970s 154

    Marcelo de P. Abreu, Afonso S. Bevilaqua and Demosthenes

    M. Pinho

    7 The Process of Accelerated Industrialization in Mexico, 192982 176

    Enrique Ca rdenas

    8 Industrialization in Venezuela, 193683: The Problem of

    Abundance 205

    Pablo Astorga

    9 Colombia in the Classical Era of `Inward-Looking Development',

    193074 239

    Jose Antonio Ocampo and Camilo Tovar

    10 Import-Substituting Industrialization in Argentina, 194080:

    Its Achievements and Shortcomings 282

    Jorge Katz and Bernardo Kosacoff

    vii

    10.1057/9780230595682 - An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin America, Edited by Enrique Cardenas, Jose A. Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp

    Copy

    right

    mat

    eria

    l fro

    m w

    ww

    .pa

    lgra

    vec

    on

    nec

    t.com

    - lic

    ense

    d to

    Q4

    Push

    - Pa

    lgra

    veC

    onne

    ct -

    2010

    -12-

    06

  • viii Contents

    11 Import Substitution, Economic Integration and the Development

    of Central America 195080 314

    Isaac Cohen

    Index 335

    10.1057/9780230595682 - An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin America, Edited by Enrique Cardenas, Jose A. Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp

    Copy

    right

    mat

    eria

    l fro

    m w

    ww

    .pa

    lgra

    vec

    on

    nec

    t.com

    - lic

    ense

    d to

    Q4

    Push

    - Pa

    lgra

    veC

    onne

    ct -

    2010

    -12-

    06

  • List of Tables and Figures

    Tables

    1.1 World economic growth 7

    1.2 Export growth rate 24

    3.1 The external constraint according to ECLA 85

    3.2 Aggregate capital, labour and output ratios in Latin

    America, 195094 86

    3.3 Rates of accumulation (GFCF/GDP) 86

    3.4 The fiscal structure in Latin America 88

    3.5 Fiscal incidence in Latin America 89

    5.1 Chile: rate of growth of GDP 115

    5.2 Chile: rate of gross fixed investment 116

    5.3 Chile: productivity of capital 116

    5.4 Chile: sectoral growth of GDP and share of industry 119

    5.5 Chile: average growth rate of value added per industrial worker 124

    5.6 Chile: value added per worker in Chile and the US, 197094 124

    5.7 Chile: percentage and average expenditure on research and

    development by institutional sectors, 196592 129

    5.8 Chile: cost per dollar of imports, in real terms 137

    6.1 Brazil: coffee price regressions, 18801960 159

    6.2 Brazil: GDP and industrial output growth rates, 193080 162

    6.3 Brazil: GDP shares (%), 191080 162

    6.4 Brazil: distribution of industrial value added, 191959 163

    6.5 Brazil: percentage share of coffee and manufactured

    exports in total exports, 193080 169

    6.6 Brazil: life expectancy at birth, in years, 194080 171

    7.1 Mexico: sources of industrial growth, 192939 181

    7.2 Mexico: sources of economic growth of industry 185

    7.3 Mexico: sources of industrial demand growth 188

    7.4 Mexico: sources of financing of the economy, 195070 196

    7.5 Mexico: position of the 10 most important industrial

    branches, 196081 200

    8.1 Venezuela: shares of selected industries in manufacturing 214

    8.2 Venezuela: GDP by economic sectors: annual average growth

    and shares 221

    9.1 Colombia: composition of economic activity 241

    9.2 Colombia: external trade ratios and composition 243

    ix

    10.1057/9780230595682 - An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin America, Edited by Enrique Cardenas, Jose A. Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp

    Copy

    right

    mat

    eria

    l fro

    m w

    ww

    .pa

    lgra

    vec

    on

    nec

    t.com

    - lic

    ense

    d to

    Q4

    Push

    - Pa

    lgra

    veC

    onne

    ct -

    2010

    -12-

    06

  • x List of Tables and Figures

    9.3 Colombia: evolution of infrastructure 249

    9.4 Colombia: composition of industrial GDP 251

    9.5 Colombia: sources of growth in the manufacturing sector 253

    9.6 Colombia: sources of corporate financing 255

    9.7 Colombia: trade policy indicators 259

    9.8 Colombia: effective protection according to ISIC classification 261

    9.9 Colombia: growth of agricultural sector 264

    9.10 Colombia: main educational and health indicators 274

    9.11 Colombia: quality of housing 275

    9.12 Colombia: average wages for selected sectors 277

    10.1 Argentina: the expansion of manufacturing industry, 193049 283

    10.2 Argentina: the participation of labour in domestic GDP 287

    10.3 Argentina: the expansion of metalworking and chemical

    production in the 1950s and 1960s 289

    10.4 Argentina: average annual growth rates of industrial value

    added 292

    10.5 Argentina: industrial output during the 1970s plateau

    (1970 = 100) 295

    10.6 Argentina: capital flight (in US$ millions) 295

    10.7 Argentina: structure of industrial value added, 1974 and 1990 296

    10.8 Argentina: raw material processing plants erected during the

    final stages of the ISI process 297

    10.9 Argentina: flow of foreign private capital to Argentine

    manufacturing according to the legal regime 298

    10.10 Argentina: foreign private capital by industry, 195461 299

    10.11 Argentina: export of `pure' technology by Argentine firms

    under the form of turnkey production facilities sold in

    Latin America 309

    11.1 Central America: total GDP and per capital real growth rates 316

    11.2 Central America: GDP composition 317

    11.3 Central America: income distribution by households 324

    11.4 Central America: the share of intraregional trade in total trade 326

    Figures

    1.1 GDP growth and composition 17

    1.2 Convergence patterns 18

    1.3 Relative living standard index (relative to USA) 21

    1.4 Exports as % of GDP 23

    1.5 Net transfer of resources as % of 1980 real GDP 27

    2.1 Technological learning and improvements in production

    during the import substitution process 47

    10.1057/9780230595682 - An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin America, Edited by Enrique Cardenas, Jose A. Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp

    Copy

    right

    mat

    eria

    l fro

    m w

    ww

    .pa

    lgra

    vec

    on

    nec

    t.com

    - lic

    ense

    d to

    Q4

    Push

    - Pa

    lgra

    veC

    onne

    ct -

    2010

    -12-

    06

  • List of Tables and Figures xi

    5.1 Chile: Chilean balance of trade pattern 122

    5.2 Chile: net trade balance by subsections 123

    7.1 Mexico: exchange rate overvaluation and the import coefficient 188

    7.2 Mexico: evolution of key real public prices for industry 191

    7.3 Mexico: evolution of industrial structure, 196081 199

    8.1 Venezuela: value added in manufacturing, 193689 212

    8.2 Venezuela: real exchange rate, 192086 223

    8.3 Venezuela: labour productivity by sectors, 192090 224

    8.4 Venezuela: in support of industrialization 225

    9.1 Colombia: fixed investment in machinery and equipment 244

    9.2 Colombia: terms of trade vs real import exchange rate 254

    9.3 Colombia: Colombian industrial prices/international prices 262

    10.1 Argentina: total production of grain in Argentina, 191084 288

    10.2 Argentina: performance of the industrial sector, 196474 308

    10.3 Argentina: total exports, industrial exports and

    manufacturing exports of industrial origin, 1964 and 1974 308

    10.1057/9780230595682 - An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin America, Edited by Enrique Cardenas, Jose A. Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp

    Copy

    right

    mat

    eria

    l fro

    m w

    ww

    .pa

    lgra

    vec

    on

    nec

    t.com

    - lic

    ense

    d to

    Q4

    Push

    - Pa

    lgra

    veC

    onne

    ct -

    2010

    -12-

    06

  • Foreword to An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin America

    The three volumes of this mini-series reflect a collaborative effort that began in

    1982, when a group of economists and economic historians met to consider the

    effect of the 1929 Depression on Latin America, and the explanation of the

    continent's rapid recovery. Carlos Daz Alejandro was the leading light of the

    group until his premature death in 1985. This initial group effort led to the

    study Latin America in the 1930s, published in 1984. Subsequent collaboration

    was made possible by the inspiration of Enrique V. Iglesias, President of the

    Inter-American Development Bank, whose idea it was to fund a major project

    to write an economic history of Latin America for the twentieth century,

    accessible to a wide audience but based on the best Latin American scholarship.

    His invitation to me to lead the project and write the overview volume gave me

    the most stimulating 16 months of my academic career. New friends joined the

    group, and we came together in the course of 1997 in a series of workshops

    organized to support the project. These workshops resulted in the books

    published here as Volumes 1 and 3. Volume 2 is a reprint of the 1930s

    study. The overview volume was published by the IDB in 1998 as Progress,

    Poverty and Exclusion: An Economic History of Latin America in the Twentieth

    Century (available in English, Spanish, French and Portuguese from IDB book-

    store, www.iadb.org/pub, and in English through Johns Hopkins University

    Press, www.press.jhu.edu.).

    My thanks for the opportunity to lead this stimulating project go first and

    foremost to Enrique Iglesias himself, to the Inter-American Development Bank

    and to the European Union for funding. Tim Farmiloe was our enthusiastic and

    patient editor. I owe a particular vote of thanks to my co-editors, who made

    themselves available against exceptional pressures and were remarkable part-

    ners. Margaret Hancox, Catalina Sanint and Elvira Ryan bore the huge burden

    of the final editing and processing.

    ROSEMARY THORP

    Latin American Centre

    Oxford University and St Antony's College

    xii

    10.1057/9780230595682 - An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin America, Edited by Enrique Cardenas, Jose A. Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp

    Copy

    right

    mat

    eria

    l fro

    m w

    ww

    .pa

    lgra

    vec

    on

    nec

    t.com

    - lic

    ense

    d to

    Q4

    Push

    - Pa

    lgra

    veC

    onne

    ct -

    2010

    -12-

    06

  • Notes on the Contributors

    Marcelo de Paiva Abreu is Professor of Economics at the Department of

    Economics, Catholic University of Rio de Janeiro, and former Director for the

    Department, 199097.

    Pablo Astorga has a DPhil in Economics from the University of Oxford. He is a

    Research Fellow at St Antony's College, Oxford, and attached to IESA, Caracas,

    Venezuela.

    Jose Miguel Benavente has a BA in Industrial Engineering and an MSc in

    Economics from the University of Chile, and an MSc in Economics for Devel-

    opment from the University of Oxford. He is Lecturer in Economics, Depart-

    ment of Economics, University of Chile, and senior consultant for ECLAC,

    Ministry of Economics and CORFO in Chile.

    Alfonso S. Bevilaqua is a member of the Department of Economics, Catholic

    University of Rio de Janeiro (PUC-Rio), Brazil. He has a PhD in Economics from

    the University of California, Berkeley.

    Enrique Cardenas is Professor of Economics and Rector of Universidad de las

    Americas-Puebla, since 1985.

    Isaac Cohen was director of the Washington office of the United Nations

    Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean (ECLAC) and is

    now a private consultant based in Washington, DC.

    Gustavo Crespi is Lecturer in Economics at the University of Chile and senior

    consultant for ECLAC Ministry of Economics in Chile.

    Ricardo Ffrench-Davis is Principal Regional Adviser of ECLAC, and Professor

    of Economics at the University of Chile. He is a former Director of Policies of

    the Central Bank of Chile and Director of the Centre for Economic Research on

    Latin America.

    E.V.K. FitzGerald is Reader in International Economics and Finance at Oxford

    University and a Professorial Fellow of St Antony's College, Oxford.

    Jorge Katz, previously Professor of International Economics at the University

    of Buenos Aires, is currently Regional Adviser on Industrial and Technical

    Development at ECLAC in Santiago, Chile.

    Bernardo Kosacoff obtained a BA in Economics at the University of Buenos

    Aires in 1972; he was a Visiting Senior Fellow, St Antony's College, Oxford, UK.

    xiii

    10.1057/9780230595682 - An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin America, Edited by Enrique Cardenas, Jose A. Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp

    Copy

    right

    mat

    eria

    l fro

    m w

    ww

    .pa

    lgra

    vec

    on

    nec

    t.com

    - lic

    ense

    d to

    Q4

    Push

    - Pa

    lgra

    veC

    onne

    ct -

    2010

    -12-

    06

  • xiv Notes on the Contributors

    (1995); Senior Economist, United Nations Economic Commission for Latin

    America and the Caribbean, Buenos Aires (since 1983); Professor of Industrial

    Organization and Political Economy at the University of Buenos Aires (since

    1984) and the National University of Quilmes (since 1993).

    Oscar Munoz is an economist, formerly President of CIEPLAN, and presently

    Executive Secretary of the Forum for Economic Development, Ministry of

    Economic Affairs in Chile, and a Professor at the University of Chile.

    Jose Antonio Ocampo is currently the Executive Secretary of the United

    Nations Economic commission for Latin America and the Caribbean (CEPAL/

    ECLAC). He is a former Finance Minister of Colombia, Director (Minister) of

    the National Planning Department of Colombia and Minister of Agriculture of

    Colombia. He has also been the Director of research centres in Colombia

    (FEDESARROLLO and CEDE).

    Demosthenes M. Pinho is attached to the Central Bank of Brazil. He has a PhD

    in Economics from the University of California, Berkeley.

    Rosemary Thorp is Reader in the Economics of Latin America at the University

    of Oxford, Fellow of St Antony's College and Director of the Latin American

    Centre. She is also a member of Queen Elizabeth House, Oxford.

    Camilo Tovar is currently Adviser to the Executive Secretary of the United

    Nations Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean (CEPAL/

    ECLAC). Previously, he served as Adviser to the Finance Minister and to the

    Director of the National Planning Department of Colombia.

    Richard Webb recently co-authored a history of the World Bank published by

    the Brookings Institution and is currently President of Banco Latino in Peru.

    10.1057/9780230595682 - An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin America, Edited by Enrique Cardenas, Jose A. Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp

    Copy

    right

    mat

    eria

    l fro

    m w

    ww

    .pa

    lgra

    vec

    on

    nec

    t.com

    - lic

    ense

    d to

    Q4

    Push

    - Pa

    lgra

    veC

    onne

    ct -

    2010

    -12-

    06

  • 1 Introduction Enrique Cardenas, Jose Antonio Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp

    In the 1990s, `protection', `import substitution' and `intervention' have

    become dirty words, part of the `leyenda negra' of Latin American development

    in the postwar period. Like most `black legends', it is at once both true and

    false. This book attempts a deeper and as far as possible dispassionate look at

    the controversial years between the end of the Second World War and the point

    when almost everywhere in Latin America, although at varying dates in differ-

    ent countries, a discontinuity occurs in which the postwar `style of develop-

    ment' ceased to play a central role in the economic evolution of the region. As

    we well know, this process eventually led to a new stage in which `the market'

    assumed the predominant role in the development strategy.

    The analysis is based on seven case studies covering 11 countries. These

    studies were discussed in two workshops, in Oxford in September 1996 and in

    Paipa, Colombia, in May 1997.1 The guiding concepts that emerged in the

    debate are developed in two conceptual chapters which open the book. On

    the micro side, as Katz and Kosakoff in Chapter 2 make clear, the crucial

    concept is the `evolutionary' or `maturing process' which characterizes the

    development of both technological capabilities and institutions. On the

    macro side, Fitzgerald explores in Chapter 3 the issue of accumulation by

    the private and public sectors, and its relation both to postwar industrialization

    and the `fiscal crisis' of the state. This provides a `positioning' of the theorizing

    of ECLAC, (the UN Economic Commission for Latin America and the Carib-

    bean), the work of which is at its strongest a theory of capital accumulation. A

    closing chapter by Webb presents a historical perspective on the thinking of

    multilateral financial institutions at the time.

    The book tries to answer several questions: what are the distinguishing

    features of the `style of development' which characterized this period? Is it

    adequately captured by the common concept of `import-substituting industria-

    lization' (ISI)? Do the different national experiences give rise to a single stereo-

    type? What external and internal forces shaped development patterns? What

    1

    10.1057/9780230595682 - An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin America, Edited by Enrique Cardenas, Jose A. Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp

    Copy

    right

    mat

    eria

    l fro

    m w

    ww

    .pa

    lgra

    vec

    on

    nec

    t.com

    - lic

    ense

    d to

    Q4

    Push

    - Pa

    lgra

    veC

    onne

    ct -

    2010

    -12-

    06

  • 2 Introduction

    was the role of ideas, and particularly what role did ECLAC's thinking play?

    Given existing constraints, what were the real alternatives to inward-looking

    industrialization? What were the benefits and costs of the path adopted? To

    what extent were the debt crisis and adjustment problems of the 1980s a

    reflection of such costs? Were such problems a result of the internal contra-

    dictions of the development model followed, or rather of political instability,

    macroeconomic financial mismanagement or exogenous reasons? As we will

    see, the answers to these questions vary by country and subperiod, and are in

    fact less neat than generally assumed.

    The following section of this introduction explores the core topic of the

    volume. We then elaborate the context, both national and international, to

    which postwar industrialization was responding, and finally review the overall

    results for Latin America.

    The topic of the volume

    Our subject is the period of accelerated industrialization that followed the

    Second World War in large and medium-sized Latin American countries, with

    `echo' effects in the smaller countries. In many cases, the postwar development

    pattern had clear continuities with the 1930s and even before, a fact which is

    brought out in several of the case studies. This period has typically been

    referred to as `import substituting industrialization', but this is not a very

    helpful label, since it is as much about a new and expanded role of the state

    as it is about import substitution. In addition, modern manufacturing first

    appeared in several countries of the region in a significant scale in the late

    nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, as a response to the expansion and

    integration of domestic markets induced by increasing integration into the

    international economy. For obvious reasons, that first spurt of industrialization

    was largely stimulated by the substitution of goods hitherto imported, mostly

    consumer goods, and so qualifies as `import substituting industrialization'.

    Moreover, in several cases (Brazil, Chile, Colombia and Mexico being notable

    examples), protection actually promoted such domestic linkages during the

    export age, in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, indeed as part

    of a stylized international practice at the time (see the introduction and coun-

    try cases in the companion volume on the export age).

    `Import substitution' is an imperfect label for many additional reasons. In the

    postwar years the export sector continued to play a fundamental role, although

    increasingly as a source of the foreign exchange required to finance the imports

    of capital and intermediate goods which were not produced domestically. In

    most mineral export economies most notably Venezuela throughout the

    period of analysis mineral rents were a major source of capital accumulation.

    Moreover, in many, particularly small, countries industrialization did not

    10.1057/9780230595682 - An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin America, Edited by Enrique Cardenas, Jose A. Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp

    Copy

    right

    mat

    eria

    l fro

    m w

    ww

    .pa

    lgra

    vec

    on

    nec

    t.com

    - lic

    ense

    d to

    Q4

    Push

    - Pa

    lgra

    veC

    onne

    ct -

    2010

    -12-

    06

  • Enrique Cardenas, Jose Antonio Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp 3

    totally replace but was actually superimposed on the primary export model,

    which continued to dominate development trends, as the chapter by Cohen on

    Central America in this volume makes clear. In some medium and large coun-

    tries, export promotion was introduced as an essential component of the

    development strategy at some stage of the industrialization process, which in

    these cases thus became a `mixed model' that combined import substitution

    with export promotion. The model was also `mixed' in several countries at

    different times in the sense that it actively promoted, with similar instruments

    to those used to encourage industrialization, several agricultural activities,

    which served to generate export income or produced foodstuffs for a growing

    urban population or inputs for the manufacturing sector. On top of that,

    despite protectionism, there was often no net import substitution during the

    process and import substitution was not always or consistently over time the

    leading source of growth, even in new industries, whereas domestic demand

    generally played a more consistent role.

    Therefore, the essence of the period covered in this volume is best expressed

    as `state-led industrialization' or `accelerated industrialization',2 a process

    accompanied by a thorough transformation of the particular economies and

    societies. Indeed, accelerated industrialization was only possible through the

    integration of domestic markets, and a greater and more ubiquitous role of the

    state. It developed together with urbanization and an increasing role of labour

    unions, entrepreneurial associations and state enterprises. It included a whole

    range of governmental support through fiscal, trade and exchange rate policies.

    Although many of these policies first appeared during the 1930s as a consequence

    of the Great Depression and some even predated it (see the two previous volumes

    in this series), it was only in the postwar period that more conscious policies were

    developed and implemented to speed up industrialization.

    These policies were pushed up to the point variable among countries

    where the diminishing returns from their use became evident. As we have

    pointed out, this led in some cases to a rationalization of the development

    strategy towards a `mixed model', maintaining, nonetheless, high levels of

    state intervention. The old forms of intervention were kept but were detached

    increasingly in many countries from a development strategy of any sort, as the

    short-term management of booms and crises came to dominate totally the

    economic scene. This was increasingly true in the years following the first oil

    shock. In this sense, the strategy of `accelerated industrialization' was effect-

    ively abandoned in many countries in the early or mid-1970s, even though its

    policy manifestations maintained an inertia of their own. Throughout this

    process, there was a gradual shift in policy-making ideology away from protec-

    tion and towards openness and belief in the value of exposure to international

    competitive pressures. However, the Chilean case aside, the new ideology

    became dominant only in the second half of the 1980s and, particularly, in

    10.1057/9780230595682 - An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin America, Edited by Enrique Cardenas, Jose A. Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp

    Copy

    right

    mat

    eria

    l fro

    m w

    ww

    .pa

    lgra

    vec

    on

    nec

    t.com

    - lic

    ense

    d to

    Q4

    Push

    - Pa

    lgra

    veC

    onne

    ct -

    2010

    -12-

    06

  • 4 Introduction

    the 1990s. Thus, a long period elapsed in many countries between the effective

    end of the era of state-led industrialization and its replacement by the new,

    market-oriented strategy.

    The process of accelerated industrialization must thus be viewed together

    with the transformation of the state and society which accompanied it. The

    political economy dimension, by which new actors appeared, such as entrepre-

    neurial organizations, labour unions, peasant movements and technocrats, as

    well as the transformation of political parties and movements to which these

    processes led, grew in depth and complexity. Major social conflicts built up in

    several countries: the Cuban revolution accelerated this process, but it was

    probably only in the 1970s that social conflict became the dominant feature,

    to the point of seriously undermining investor confidence in several countries.

    External and internal forces shaping development

    The external context

    The outstanding characteristic of the postwar scene was the new dominance of

    the USA. While European countries had suffered terrible destruction, the pro-

    ductive capacity of the USA had increased 50 per cent during the war and in

    1945 produced more than half the worldwide total of manufacturing goods,

    and was capable of quickly converting productive capacity from war to peace-

    time production. Still more significant, the USA owned half of the world supply

    of shipping, compared with only 14 per cent in 1939, and supplied one-third of

    world exports while taking only one-tenth of world imports (Ashworth, 1987,

    p. 266).

    The USA also had a relatively clear agenda. Whereas in the interwar years the

    signals pointing to the need for change in the international system were

    there but were weak and conflicting, as the Second World War drew to a close

    the international system was clearly perceived to have broken down and to

    require major institutional change. Led by the USA, talks had gone on at many

    levels during the war itself to prepare to build the peace. The economic agenda

    comprised: (i) institutional developments to ensure stable and expanding trade

    and capital flows; (ii) the use of those institutions to reduce discriminatory

    controls; and (iii) a sufficiently rapid recovery of the main trading nations to

    complement the institutional renewal of the international system. The agenda

    shaped the Bretton Woods agreement of 1944, which saw the creation of the

    International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the World Bank (IBRD), specifically

    aiming at a return to a system of stable exchange rates and to an assured supply

    of long-term capital, with a progressive liberalization of the European econo-

    mies. The `dollar shortage' made that process a very gradual one, leading to

    practices which, for many years, continued to be far more protectionist than

    10.1057/9780230595682 - An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin America, Edited by Enrique Cardenas, Jose A. Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp

    Copy

    right

    mat

    eria

    l fro

    m w

    ww

    .pa

    lgra

    vec

    on

    nec

    t.com

    - lic

    ense

    d to

    Q4

    Push

    - Pa

    lgra

    veC

    onne

    ct -

    2010

    -12-

    06

  • Enrique Cardenas, Jose Antonio Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp 5

    the theory.3 As it became clear that these actions alone would not be enough to

    kick-start the European economies, a more radical US role was conceived with

    the Marshall Plan in 1947. Lengthy negotiations eventually added the General

    Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), signed in 1947 in Geneva by 23

    nations (including Argentina, Chile and Cuba), but failed to add the Interna-

    tional Trade Organisation (ITO).4

    What was only to become clear with time was how far down the US agenda

    was the position of Latin America in the early postwar years. The embodiment

    of this was the series of conferences which began with Chapultepec in 1945

    before the war ended. The eighth Inter-American Conference in Chapultepec

    was a disillusion, in that economic issues were mostly postponed to a confer-

    ence to deal with them specifically. Nonetheless, at least Latin America

    appeared to be on the agenda, and it was possible to sign pious statements

    about free trade while reserving the right to make just about any specific

    exceptions they should see fit to make. On the issue of most concern to the

    USA conditions for direct foreign investment the Latin Americans were

    rather interested in responding. But then the economic conference was post-

    poned so often that Rabe (1978) christened it the `elusive' conference. By the

    ninth Inter-American Conference in Bogota in 1948, after the invention of the

    Marshall Plan and audacious suggestions that the time was ripe for a similar

    effort in Latin America, General Marshall's chief preoccupation was to persuade

    the Latin American nations that the USA had too much on its shoulders as a

    reconstructor of world peace and security to be considered a major source of

    finance for the rest of the hemisphere.5 The corollary was that, therefore, the

    essential thing was to put in place good solid guarantees so that private capital

    could come and do the job. The clashes over the `Calvo doctrine' on the lack

    of resident aliens' rights to appeal to their home government were such that

    thereafter the US private sector strongly counselled the abandonment of a

    conference and the concentration on bilateral negotiations on direct foreign

    investment legislation (Rabe, 1978, p. 289). This is what happened.

    A further characteristic of the postwar period was the emerging consensus

    that industrialization of developing countries provided both interesting invest-

    ment opportunities and good sales of machinery and equipment. Meanwhile,

    on the Latin American side, the ample foreign exchange reserves in place as the

    war finished vanished sooner than anyone thought possible, and provoked an

    abrupt resort to import quotas. When foreign firms found that they were

    completely excluded from the market through quotas, this produced a strong

    incentive to move to local production, as it became suddenly the only option.

    So, the early building of the postwar boom and the shaping of Latin

    America's mode of insertion went hand in hand. As Webb indicates, the

    World Bank was quite tolerant of protectionism in developing countries not

    so with respect to Europe preferring a mix of export promotion and `efficient'

    10.1057/9780230595682 - An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin America, Edited by Enrique Cardenas, Jose A. Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp

    Copy

    right

    mat

    eria

    l fro

    m w

    ww

    .pa

    lgra

    vec

    on

    nec

    t.com

    - lic

    ense

    d to

    Q4

    Push

    - Pa

    lgra

    veC

    onne

    ct -

    2010

    -12-

    06

  • 6 Introduction

    import substitution; it also quietly favoured protectionism in the specific

    industries which the Bank or the International Financial Corporation were

    financing. It was also less influential in policy formulation than it became

    later on. In its earlier years and even decades the IMF also did not altogether

    dislike protection, and indeed viewed it as a useful complementary instrument

    to correct payments imbalances.

    In due time, of course, Latin America became more central to US policy. As

    had been true in the early postwar years, this was intimately associated with

    how important the region was in the struggle against communism. Early Latin

    American initiatives to create a regional development bank initially found no

    support from the USA. In 1958, at the meeting of the Inter-American Economic

    and Social Council, the USA announced that it would support the initiative,

    and the 1959 Cuban revolution gave a new urgency to the initiative. An

    announcement to establish the Inter-American Development Bank (IDB), and

    within it the Social Progress Trust Fund, specifically designed to lend to sectors

    neglected by existing financial organizations education, health, agriculture,

    and so on was signed in 1960. This was soon followed by a more ambitious

    initiative, the Alliance for Progress which, under the leadership of President

    Kennedy, came formally into existence with the Charter of Punta del Este in

    August 1961. This initiative also became closely interlinked with the postwar

    patterns of state intervention. The key themes were integration, planning, tax

    reform, agrarian reform and modernization, and investment in the social

    sectors, many of them central to the agenda which the United Nations Eco-

    nomic Commission for Latin America (ECLA6) had been pushing forward since

    the 1950s. Many initiatives in these areas were put in place, the flow of outside

    funds increased and the IDB was able to direct financing to the neglected

    sectors. But the flow of funds was less than promised, and the tied character

    of US aid and the condition that it had to be spent on US goods, `additional' to

    what would have been bought anyway, became a source of significant friction.

    By the end of the 1960s, it was clear that expectations unleashed at the start of

    the decade by the Alliance for Progress had not been fulfilled.

    Meanwhile, the world economy had entered a period of unprecedented

    prosperity. The depressed conditions of the 1930s followed by the wartime

    stimulus to innovation had left a backlog of technology waiting to be applied.

    These opportunities, the rapid success of European reconstruction, the gradual

    but steady return to freer trade and the successful application of macroeco-

    nomic stabilization tools, among other factors, helped to unleash the century's

    fastest economic growth in the world industrial centres. The growth of the

    welfare state and, in many countries, of state enterprises, led to a large-scale

    expansion of the state in developed market economies, which was accompan-

    ied in parallel by the expansion of centrally-planned economies. In 195073,

    the economic growth of the industrialized countries accelerated, not only with

    10.1057/9780230595682 - An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin America, Edited by Enrique Cardenas, Jose A. Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp

    Copy

    right

    mat

    eria

    l fro

    m w

    ww

    .pa

    lgra

    vec

    on

    nec

    t.com

    - lic

    ense

    d to

    Q4

    Push

    - Pa

    lgra

    veC

    onne

    ct -

    2010

    -12-

    06

  • Enrique Cardenas, Jose Antonio Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp 7

    Table 1.1 World economic growth

    187013 191350 195073

    GDP GDP GDP GDP GDP GDP

    growth growth growth growth growth growth

    (%) per capita (%) per capita (%) per capita

    (%) (%) (%)

    Western Europe 2.1 1.3 1.4 0.9 4.7 3.9

    Western offshoots 3.9 1.8 2.8 1.6 4.0 2.4

    Southern Europe 1.5 1.1 1.3 0.4 6.3 4.9

    Eastern Europe 2.4 1.0 1.6 1.2 4.7 3.5

    Latin America 3.3 1.5 3.4 1.5 5.3 2.5

    Asia 1.1 0.6 1.0 0.1 6.0 3.8

    Africa 1.1 0.4 3.0 1.0 4.4 2.0

    World 2.1 1.3 1.9 0.9 4.9 2.9

    Source: Maddison (1995).

    respect to the interwar period but also with respect to the previous period of

    rapid expansion, 18701913. Moreover, this was part of and largely propelled

    an unprecedented, generalized world economic expansion. As Table 1.1

    makes clear, annual world economic growth reached 4.9 per cent in 195073

    vs 2.1 per cent in 18701913, according to Maddison's estimates (1995). This

    was also accompanied by the most rapid expansion of world trade in history:

    real world exports grew at an annual rate of 7 per cent in 195073 vs 3.4 per

    cent in 18701913 (see Maddison, 1995, table I-4). Indeed, the growth of trade

    continued to be very rapid even after growth in the industrialized economies

    and the world economy at large decelerated, after the first oil shock. The

    growth of multinational corporations was also part of this process. The growth

    of trade and direct investment was finally accompanied, with a lag, by the

    reconstruction of an international financial system, which had been severely

    hit by the crisis of the 1930s.

    By the early 1970s, when the era of `state-led industrialization' in Latin

    America was coming to an end, the international economy had experienced

    significant changes with respect to what had been typical in the early postwar

    years. A dynamic economy had replaced the crippled world economy of the

    interwar period and the international trade and financial systems had been

    rebuilt. Multinational corporations had become a major agent in the interna-

    tional economy. The state had become a central player in market economies

    and obviously the central player in non-market ones but one of the oldest

    forms of state intervention, protectionism, was undergoing a gradual process of

    negotiated erosion. The Bretton Woods institutions, GATT, the United Nations

    organizations and several regional bodies most importantly those supporting

    10.1057/9780230595682 - An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin America, Edited by Enrique Cardenas, Jose A. Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp

    Copy

    right

    mat

    eria

    l fro

    m w

    ww

    .pa

    lgra

    vec

    on

    nec

    t.com

    - lic

    ense

    d to

    Q4

    Push

    - Pa

    lgra

    veC

    onne

    ct -

    2010

    -12-

    06

  • 8 Introduction

    European integration had become well-established, bringing a presence of

    state intervention to a more global level.

    Rapid growth had `trickled down' to the developing countries through both

    trade and investment channels. The expansion of world trade was largely

    concentrated in transactions among industrialized nations, and tariff reduc-

    tions maintained a structure that discriminated against the imports of light

    manufactured and some agricultural products. However, the expansion opened

    windows of opportunity for exports from the periphery, which were rapidly

    taken advantage of by some countries in the developing world particularly in

    East and Southeast Asia. Also, the growth of the international financial system

    concentrated largely on financial transactions among developed countries, but

    since the late 1960s, at least, it began to offer large-scale opportunities for

    external financing as an alternative to multilateral banks and bilateral agencies.

    The developing countries underwent, as a result, their own phase of rapid

    expansion, as Table 1.1 indicates, and Latin America was certainly part of that

    story. However, with some notable exceptions, GDP per capita grew less in the

    `periphery' than in the `core' of the world economy. Thus, income gaps tended

    to increase in the world economy during its `golden age'. New mechanisms

    were designed to enhance the diffusion of progress, both at an international

    that is, the Generalized System of Preferences and commodity agreements or

    regional (that is, the Alliance of Progress) level, but they were generally per-

    ceived to be insufficient. The call for a `new international economic order', a

    central debate of the mid-1970s, was a clear reflection of that fact.

    The call also demonstrated how far from the international agenda were the

    ideas of economic liberalization as the engine of progress of the developing

    world at the end of our period of analysis. These ideas had made some headway,

    both in economic thinking and in national practice in some countries, but by

    the standards of the late 1990s the classic treatise of the time that argued for the

    reduced use of protectionism as a development tool (Little et al., 1970), could

    be read today as a defence of moderate state intervention! Indeed, it could

    be viewed as further from current ideas than from Rau l Prebisch's report

    to UNCTAD a few years earlier (Prebisch, 1964). As Webb argues in his

    chapter, the World Bank continued to defend, up to the late 1970s, the ideas

    that industrialization was essential to economic development, and that

    protectionism was an essential stage in the process of industrialization,

    ideas which were clearly exposed by its most influential thinker at the time,

    Hollis B. Chenery.

    The internal context

    There have been several attempts to classify the different stages of industrial-

    ization. In Chenery's well-known classification, emphasis is placed on whether

    the process relies on production for the domestic market vs exports inward vs

    10.1057/9780230595682 - An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin America, Edited by Enrique Cardenas, Jose A. Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp

    Copy

    right

    mat

    eria

    l fro

    m w

    ww

    .pa

    lgra

    vec

    on

    nec

    t.com

    - lic

    ense

    d to

    Q4

    Push

    - Pa

    lgra

    veC

    onne

    ct -

    2010

    -12-

    06

  • Enrique Cardenas, Jose Antonio Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp 9

    outward orientation and on when specific industries appear in the process of

    industrialization `early' vs `late' manufactures (see, for example, Chenery et

    al., 1986). The latter classification is associated to the idea, which was wide-

    spread in the period we are analysing, that there was a first `easy' phase of

    import substitution during which mostly non-durable consumer goods were

    produced, and later phases in which import substitution `deepened' producing

    non-durable consumer as well as intermediate and some capital goods. Based

    on our case studies, four stages in the evolution of industrialization in Latin

    America can be differentiated.

    The first stage came as a natural byproduct of export expansion. The expan-

    sion and integration of domestic markets, as a result of rising export revenues

    and the development of modern transportation networks, was combined with

    that of modern monetary systems, capital and wage labour markets. As we have

    pointed out, in several countries state protection actually encouraged the

    `domestic linkages' of the dynamic export sectors, as well as their linkages to

    domestic agriculture.

    The second was an `empirical' stage of state-led industrialization, in which

    policy-makers followed their intuition and external conditions created the

    appropriate price structure to stimulate domestic rather than external demand.

    The 1930s and the Second World War provide a good example of this stage, but

    the First World War had been an important precedent. The collapse of com-

    modity prices and capital flows in the 1930s led to a wave of devaluations and

    protectionism which shifted relative prices in favour of domestic industries and

    agricultural production. Indeed, exchange controls, protectionism and the

    proliferation of bilateral trade agreements, which enhanced the complexity of

    tariff structures, became such widespread practices in the industrialized nations

    in the 1930s that it seemed natural and even necessary to practice them under

    the circumstances. In particular, bilateral trade agreements introduced direct

    controls of foreign trade operations to guarantee bilateral trade equilibria,

    practices which were unknown before.

    This led to the development of direct import controls at a more general level.

    On the other hand, in all cases but Mexico, the Second World War isolated

    national economies, forcing them to exploit existing capacity, and to produce

    or create the plans to produce a wider variety of products which were not

    available given war shortages. The concept that some `essential' or `strategic'

    industries should be encouraged was, thus, a natural byproduct of the war.

    After the experience of the 1930s and the Second World War, protectionism,

    tariff discrimination, direct trade controls, import substitution in manufactur-

    ing and agriculture, and plans to encourage `essential industries' became fairly

    widespread practices, but they were more a byproduct of the deficient func-

    tioning of the international economic system than a `development strategy' of

    any sort.

    10.1057/9780230595682 - An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin America, Edited by Enrique Cardenas, Jose A. Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp

    Copy

    right

    mat

    eria

    l fro

    m w

    ww

    .pa

    lgra

    vec

    on

    nec

    t.com

    - lic

    ense

    d to

    Q4

    Push

    - Pa

    lgra

    veC

    onne

    ct -

    2010

    -12-

    06

  • 10 Introduction

    The end of the war reopened the possibility of importing all kinds of goods,

    expanding output even further, and saw the gradual evolution of the third

    stage. Rising commodity prices supported this process; but the repressed

    demand was soon manifested in an avalanche of imports. Dollar foreign

    exchange reserves evaporated and most countries reacted by imposing or hard-

    ening trade restrictions and exchange controls. Inconvertibility in European

    countries was an additional constraint on the way adjustments operated in the

    early postwar period for those countries for which Europe was the main export

    market. Following the experience of the `empirical phase', early postwar bal-

    ance of payments crises now established a pattern by which each crisis

    increased the previous levels of protection. Now, however, a more conscious

    industrialization strategy came into existence, the so-called ISI model, based on

    tariff and non-tariff protection of industry and some agricultural activities,

    changes in the internal terms of trade against traditional primary exports, the

    design of development banks to support these activities, strong public sector

    investment in infrastructure and in `strategic' sectors, including energy and

    other raw materials, and the rationing of foreign exchange, with multiple

    exchange rates to channel it preferentially to the imports of non-competitive

    intermediate and capital goods. An essential characteristic of the model was

    that new layers of protection, to promote new sectors, were imposed on older

    layers associated with previous import substitution phases. It should be noted

    that, even at the time, the model was not exempt from criticism, not even from

    ECLAC which was instrumental in justifying and rationalizing the strategy. At

    all times, there were voices of warning on the limits of the strategy, particularly

    on the rising costs of new industries being promoted, which affected older

    industries adversely, and on the diminished capacity to reach the explicit

    goal of reducing import dependence. This `classic' stage of inward-looking

    development `desarrollo hacia adentro' dated from the late 1940s to the

    early 1960s in most medium and larger economies.

    Finally came the `mature' stage. During this stage, countries differed substan-

    tially in the relative weight of two different strategies. The first was to give more

    emphasis to export promotion, generating what we have called a `mixed'

    model. It was characterized by the imposition of a new layer of in some

    cases, very high export incentives on old layers of protection, generally

    accompanied by a moderate rationalization of the latter. The second was to

    further deepen import substitution in intermediate and capital goods. Among

    the countries covered in this volume, Argentina, Chile and, particularly,

    Colombia were closer to the first, Mexico and Venezuela closer to the second

    supported in the 1970s by rising oil revenues in both cases whereas Brazil

    very actively mixed both up to the eve of the debt crisis. Mexico had followed a

    more `mixed' strategy in its own classic period, 194862, as the chapter by

    Cardenas in this volume make clear, and effectively moved backwards to a

    10.1057/9780230595682 - An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin America, Edited by Enrique Cardenas, Jose A. Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp

    Copy

    right

    mat

    eria

    l fro

    m w

    ww

    .pa

    lgra

    vec

    on

    nec

    t.com

    - lic

    ense

    d to

    Q4

    Push

    - Pa

    lgra

    veC

    onne

    ct -

    2010

    -12-

    06

  • Enrique Cardenas, Jose Antonio Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp 11

    more traditional emphasis on import substitution in its mature phase. Among

    the countries not covered in this volume, Peru is another example of such a

    backward shift. Central America effectively never moved into the advanced

    stages of import substitution and, rather, followed still another `mixed stra-

    tegy': import substitution at the subregional level, superimposed on the prim-

    ary export model.

    As we have pointed out so far, at some point short-term macroeconomics

    totally replaced long-term strategies in many countries, and/or the latter were

    swamped by rising social conflicts which then became the dominant force

    determining social as well as economic events. However, the Chilean case

    aside, the older layers of high protection and the more recent of export promo-

    tion in those countries where they were fully developed survived up to the

    liberalization period which took off in the mid-1980s and speeded up in the

    region in the 1990s. Although deeply defended by their beneficiaries, they were

    increasingly detached from a real development strategy of any sort.

    The process of industrialization went hand in hand with other major changes

    occurring in Latin American societies and economies. The restructuring that

    took place in the 1930s (see the previous volume) continued during and after

    the war. The state had acquired a number of policy instruments, such as

    monetary discretion, and a more diverse tax base, while the abandonment of

    the gold standard had left financial authorities free to manoeuvre the exchange

    rate. In some cases, this led to the illusion that money creation was one and the

    same as wealth creation. The state had also taken on its shoulders the respon-

    sibility for promoting economic development. It did so by enlarging economic

    infrastructure in some instances or by establishing state enterprises, either for

    defence purposes as in Argentina under Peron or to assure domestic supplies of

    certain `strategic' inputs, as in Brazil, Mexico and many other countries. It also

    created public sector commercial and development banks, or encouraged new

    private financial institutions and forced all of them to channel funds to priority

    sectors. The role of the state was also enlarged to incorporate new entrepren-

    eurs, often actually `creating' them under the umbrella of large government

    contracts related to the construction of roads, public utilities, dams and so on,

    which therefore implied a certain working relationship that often surpassed the

    business component and entered the political sphere.

    In several countries, the postwar period witnessed an acceleration of popula-

    tion growth caused by the decline of infant mortality rates. Within a few years,

    that implied a corresponding increase in the labour force, creating enormous

    pressures for the economy to grow. The Latin American population increased

    from 126 million in 1940 to 210 million twenty years later, and 139 million

    more were added in the 1960s and 1970s. Due to falling mortality rates and a

    lagged transition in fertility, population growth peaked at an average level of

    2.72.8 per cent a year from the mid-1950s to the mid-1960s, with over 3 per

    10.1057/9780230595682 - An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin America, Edited by Enrique Cardenas, Jose A. Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp

    Copy

    right

    mat

    eria

    l fro

    m w

    ww

    .pa

    lgra

    vec

    on

    nec

    t.com

    - lic

    ense

    d to

    Q4

    Push

    - Pa

    lgra

    veC

    onne

    ct -

    2010

    -12-

    06

  • 12 Introduction

    cent in several countries. Indeed, Latin America and Africa faced the strongest

    population pressures, a fact which probably contributed to depressed growth in

    per capita GDP (see Table 1.1). Cities also multiplied in size, creating increasing

    demands on public utilities, schools, hospitals and the like. The rate of urban-

    ization was 41.6 per cent in 1950, but had already reached 5673 per cent in the

    four `success stories' of the export age (Argentina, Chile, Cuba and Uruguay).

    By 1970, 57.7 per cent of the population lived in urban areas (75 to 82 per cent

    in Argentina, Chile, Uruguay and Venezuela) and most Latin American capitals

    had become large, sophisticated metropolitan areas.7 This was accompanied, as

    we will see, by significant improvements in human development and the

    incorporation of a proportion of the population into the benefits of a modern

    economy, but also by the persistence of high levels of inequality in the dis-

    tribution of income and assets.

    The role of ECLAC

    A consensus among participants in the workshops is that the role of ECLAC has

    been exaggerated in the mythology of ISI unfortunately in part because for

    some in the US State Department and elsewhere Prebisch became paradox-

    ically, given his rather conservative background identified as the spokesman

    for ideas coming out of Moscow and Prague, and thus a victim of Cold War

    paranoia.8 In fact, as we have seen, the development of many of the building

    blocks of strong state intervention took place as a spontaneous process during

    the `empirical' phase of import substitution and even during the export age,

    and corresponded to international practice at the time. Thus, all clearly pre-

    dated the creation of ECLAC in 1948. Large governments were also not an

    innovation of ECLAC or Latin America, either, but rather a widespread inter-

    national practice in the postwar period.

    However, the wider importance of ECLAC is undoubted. It helped to bring

    about almost the first glimmerings of continental self-awareness, in particular

    by providing theoretical and empirical support to the evolution of a regional

    identity.9 It played a significant role in spreading modern economic analysis

    and statistical techniques, and in developing institutions such as schools of

    public administration and planning ministries. In due course, it was important

    in developing the notion of protection at the regional level, and it thus played

    a central role in the design of the Latin American Free Trade Association

    ALALC, according to its Spanish abbreviation, later Latin American Integration

    Association the Andean Group and, most notably, the Central American

    Common Market, as the chapter by Cohen makes clear. It also helped to press

    for reforms in the social area, many of which set the stage for the Alliance for

    Progress in the 1960s.

    At the conceptual level, ECLAC gave a logic to and helped to rationalize the

    strategy of development which had been springing up in the region. It built

    10.1057/9780230595682 - An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin America, Edited by Enrique Cardenas, Jose A. Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp

    Copy

    right

    mat

    eria

    l fro

    m w

    ww

    .pa

    lgra

    vec

    on

    nec

    t.com

    - lic

    ense

    d to

    Q4

    Push

    - Pa

    lgra

    veC

    onne

    ct -

    2010

    -12-

    06

  • Enrique Cardenas, Jose Antonio Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp 13

    upon a theory of capital accumulation, not a theory of static efficiency. Indus-

    trial development was primarily seen as the mechanism to transfer technical

    progress to peripheral countries in the face of the slow growth in primary

    commodity markets. Capital accumulation, structural changes associated

    with industrialization and the transfer of technological innovations from the

    centre were, thus, seen as three facets of a unique process. It was also seen as a

    mechanism to absorb labour displaced from rural areas and to manage macro-

    economic constraints associated with foreign exchange scarcity. As Fitzgerald

    makes clear, these ideas on industrialization were different from the infant

    industry argument, as well as from those associated with the role of dynamic

    scale economies in more recent theories of trade and growth. Tariff protection

    was seen as a way to guarantee a stable demand for new sectors and public

    sector investment as the way to guarantee the provision of skills and infra-

    structure. The problems of this strategy were also recognized, and some policies

    were designed to overcome them regional integration, the `mixed' strategy

    but others were seen as intrinsic to peripheral industrialization.

    The institution also played a negative role at the level of ideas and percep-

    tions. Most important, it never developed, during our period of analysis, the

    ideas of protection as a time-bound instrument and the need to tie incentives

    to performance; the latter played an important role in rapid East Asian indus-

    trialization, according to some interpretations. It was thus lenient on the

    `geological' layer over layer pattern which protection adopted and the

    inefficiencies and political economy which it generated. It also tended to

    view new developments in international trade with a pessimistic lens. None-

    theless, it shifted gradually in the 1960s and, particularly, in the 1970s, to a

    favourable view of export promotion (Bielschowsky, 1998). Several times it

    manifested distrust for relative price adjustments and, particularly, for active

    foreign exchange rate policies, which were certainly instrumental in encour-

    aging structural diversification (see below).

    However, it should be emphasized again that ECLAC's views on industrializa-

    tion, protection and state intervention agreed with contemporary wisdom.

    Moreover, in the regional debate it always remained in the centre, more mod-

    erate than the more radical dependency school visions that sprang from its

    work, as well as Marxist thinking. Its character as an intergovernmental institu-

    tion certainly determined that.

    What were the alternatives?

    A distinct conclusion of the project, which comes clearly from the previous

    sections, is that it is hard to imagine countries choosing other than they did in

    the early postwar years. On the one hand, at the time, and despite favourable

    short-term trends, continued reliance on primary exports did not look like a

    good alternative in the light of past trends and instability in the terms of trade.

    10.1057/9780230595682 - An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin America, Edited by Enrique Cardenas, Jose A. Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp

    Copy

    right

    mat

    eria

    l fro

    m w

    ww

    .pa

    lgra

    vec

    on

    nec

    t.com

    - lic

    ense

    d to

    Q4

    Push

    - Pa

    lgra

    veC

    onne

    ct -

    2010

    -12-

    06

  • 14 Introduction

    Indeed, after the mid-1950s the renewed downward trend of commodity prices

    generated a new wave of balance of payments crises, which further encouraged

    regional protectionist trends. The coexistence of GATT with renewed agricul-

    tural protectionism was an additional argument, particularly for those coun-

    tries which exported temperate zone agricultural products. The export of

    manufacturing products from developing countries was a very distant alternat-

    ive, although the Mexican experience during the war had made a first start.

    High levels of protection were still the rule in the industrialized countries and it

    was clearly necessary to undergo a long period of continuous growth in inter-

    national trade to convince countries and authorities which had lived through

    its collapse to regard it as a reliable alternative. The failure of the International

    Trade Organization was also a wrong signal, as well as that of the other institu-

    tions Keynes had envisaged as accompanying the familiar Bretton Woods cre-

    ations, including a commodity buffer fund and a soft aid facility through the

    United Nations. A further reality in the early postwar years was inconvertibility,

    as a reflection of the `dollar shortage'. Sterling export earnings, in particular,

    could not be converted into dollars to buy US machinery.

    On the other hand, the option for industrialization had already been made de

    facto in the larger countries, in an unmistakable sense since the 1930s, and this

    was clearly reflected in the positions of emerging industrial groups in Latin

    America and in their growing political weight. Politically, also, urban growth

    and continuing migration were making industrialization crucial. During the

    Second World War, the USA backed the push for expanded state involvement in

    economic affairs and even a direct role in industry. After the war, the official US

    line, and the framework for the new Bretton Woods institutions, was to pull

    back from state involvement but, as Webb's chapter reveals, the international

    financial institutions were not hard on that line, at least with respect to devel-

    oping countries. As we have seen, the multinationals' views on protection

    changed rapidly as they began to perceive the extent of the profits to be

    made in `tariff-hopping'. Under Truman's Four Point Plan, launched in 1949,

    the industrialization of the developing world was an important policy object-

    ive, and the technical missions that followed were intended to design devel-

    opment plans including the devising of foreign exchange controls and tariffs

    (Maxfield and Nolt, 1990). Finally, as we have seen, economic ideas at the time

    and indeed for a long period continued to favour state intervention, and

    indeed, in this regard as well as in practice, probably the real option was central

    planning that is, more rather than less state involvement.

    A difficult part of the assessment of alternatives concerns the role of external

    pressures. Was the enthusiasm for protection among Latin American adminis-

    trators mainly a result of exclusion from the financial aid available for postwar

    reconstruction, rather than a response to endogenous forces within Latin

    America? Fitzgerald argues in his contribution to this volume that there was a

    10.1057/9780230595682 - An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin America, Edited by Enrique Cardenas, Jose A. Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp

    Copy

    right

    mat

    eria

    l fro

    m w

    ww

    .pa

    lgra

    vec

    on

    nec

    t.com

    - lic

    ense

    d to

    Q4

    Push

    - Pa

    lgra

    veC

    onne

    ct -

    2010

    -12-

    06

  • Enrique Cardenas, Jose Antonio Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp 15

    marked willingness to conform to free trade rules as long as it seemed that even

    a Marshall Plan for Latin America was not beyond the pale. But by Havana it

    was clearly beyond the pale, and countries rapidly changed their tune and,

    more to the point, their practice.

    The situation had, of course, changed considerably by the 1960s when the

    international economy did start to offer an alternative in a real sense. Indeed,

    the shift to what we have called a `mixed model' indicates that many Latin

    American countries did not ignore it. The country studies provide, indeed,

    many instances of this change of direction. Chile was the first to introduce

    the crawling peg in 1965, and combined this with an extensive set of policies

    developed over the next few years, including tax rebates, tariff reductions and

    rationalization of the tariff structure. CORFO was active in these years with

    programmes that laid the basis for subsequent exports in fishery, forestry and

    fresh fruits. Colombia had adopted in the late 1950s and early 1960s a series of

    export incentives that were rationalized in 1967, when the crawling peg was

    introduced and wide-ranging institutional reforms in the foreign trade and

    exchange regimes were adopted. Mexico actually introduced its maquiladora

    programme in the same year as Taiwan (1965). The introduction of the crawl-

    ing peg in Brazil in 1968 had been preceded by export incentives since 1965.

    Venezuela had certainly not ignored her opportunities in oil throughout. At

    the same time, in the smaller countries, the opportunities in more traditional

    commodity markets had not been ignored, and exports of coffee, bananas and

    cotton were generating export dynamism in Central America from the mid-

    1950s. This is also true of some South American countries not included in the

    case studies Ecuador, in particular. Indeed, as we will see, there was a sense of a

    `golden age' in many Latin American countries towards the end of our period of

    analysis, from some year around the mid-1960s to the first oil shock.

    Examples abound, however, in which senior advisers recommended devalu-

    ations, tax reforms or other policy measures in circumstances where, with

    hindsight, the institutional conditions and macro/micro relations would have

    allowed successful policy alternatives, but the options were rejected for polit-

    ical reasons. Many individual examples can also be quoted concerning the

    pushing of import substitution programmes when it was already clear that

    market size could not sustain them. Obviously, the very ambitious industrial

    investment plans of Brazil, Mexico and Venezuela following the first oil shock

    are the most remarkable examples, although some actually partly paid off in

    the long term, even in terms of export expansion. Outside our case studies, Peru

    is probably the most outstanding example of a country which opted for a more

    inward-oriented policy in the late 1960s, against regional and international

    trends and without adequate export backing, and failed. Decisions to plan

    import substitution at a subregional level by a political allocation of the pro-

    duction of certain goods to specific countries, in the Andean Group and the

    10.1057/9780230595682 - An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin America, Edited by Enrique Cardenas, Jose A. Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp

    Copy

    right

    mat

    eria

    l fro

    m w

    ww

    .pa

    lgra

    vec

    on

    nec

    t.com

    - lic

    ense

    d to

    Q4

    Push

    - Pa

    lgra

    veC

    onne

    ct -

    2010

    -12-

    06

  • 16 Introduction

    Central American Common Market, were definite failures. But the most frus-

    trating experience was, obviously, the resistance to liberalizing competitive

    imports in regional and subregional integration agreements the Central

    American Common Market aside. It is a historical paradox that the great

    invention of ECLAC to rationalize import substitution, regional integration,

    succeeded only when fully-fledged trade liberalization was undertaken in the

    1990s, that is, when import substitution as a development strategy had

    been abandoned! It is, indeed, a double paradox, as orthodox thinking pushing

    for trade liberalization considered integration agreements to be close to an

    aberration.

    More generally, the major problem was the reduced flexibility that built up

    during the years of state-led industrialization. This is closely associated with the

    political economy which characterized the process. As we have pointed out, a

    remarkable feature was the absence of the ideas of protection as a time-bound

    instrument and the need to tie incentives to performance. This was obviously

    supported by the political economy that characterized the process, in which

    protection to a specific sector was a permanent conquest. The pessimistic

    export lens was also a feature, although decreasingly so in most countries. An

    interesting counterfactual exercise would be to ask whether, in the absence of

    the oil shock and the `macro mess' which followed, the model would have

    evolved in a different direction as a result, for example, of the success which

    the `mixed model' was starting to show in some countries. Nonetheless, by that

    time macroeconomics and politics were taking over the scene. We will return to

    this analysis later on.

    The overall results10

    The benefits (with some qualifications)

    Latin American economic performance during the three decades that followed

    the Second World War was remarkable, inducing a widespread transformation

    of society. On the one hand, continental GDP grew at 5.6 per cent per year in

    194574, or 2.7 per cent per capita.11 This was unparalleled for Latin America,

    just as the developed country record was the fastest in recorded time. In the

    intermediate period between this phase of long-term growth and the debt

    crisis, growth was only slightly slower 5 and 2.5 per cent, respectively12

    though it was more than two percentage points lower than the peak rate of

    growth of 196874 (see below). The manufacturing sector was the engine

    of growth, growing 6.8 per cent a year in 194574, reaching a peak share of

    GDP of 26 per cent in 1973, 7 percentage points more than in 1945. Sectoral

    behaviour is vividly summarized in Figure 1.1b, where industry gains at the

    expense of primary production, as also occurred in most developing areas in

    the world.

    10.1057/9780230595682 - An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin America, Edited by Enrique Cardenas, Jose A. Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp

    Copy

    right

    mat

    eria

    l fro

    m w

    ww

    .pa

    lgra

    vec

    on

    nec

    t.com

    - lic

    ense

    d to

    Q4

    Push

    - Pa

    lgra

    veC

    onne

    ct -

    2010

    -12-

    06

  • % o

    f GDP

    at 1

    980s

    con

    stan

    t pric

    es

    1939

    1939

    1941

    3%

    26%

    25%

    24%

    23%

    22%

    21%

    20%

    19%

    18%

    17%

    16%

    Figure 1.1 GDP growth and composition Source: ECLAC.

    The temporal pattern of GDP growth was a very rapid recovery in the early

    postwar period, which was interrupted by a series of balance of payments crises

    in the late 1940s and early 1950s. Growth then stabilized for the region as a

    whole around a rate somewhat above 5 per cent. In the late 1960s and early

    1941

    1943

    1945

    1947

    1949

    1951

    1953

    1955

    1957

    1959

    1961

    1963

    1965

    1967

    1969

    1971

    1973

    1975

    1943

    1945

    1947

    1949

    1951

    1953

    1955

    1957

    1959

    1961

    1963

    1965

    1967

    1969

    1971

    1973

    1975

    1977

    1979

    1981

    1983

    1985

    1%

    1%

    3%

    5%

    7%

    9%

    Current growth rate Three years centred moving average

    1939-45 Latin Amrica six largest economies Three years centred moving average L.A. (6)

    17Enrique Cardenas, Jose Antonio Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp

    10.1057/9780230595682 - An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin America, Edited by Enrique Cardenas, Jose A. Ocampo and Rosemary Thorp

    Copy

    right

    mat

    eria

    l fro

    m w

    ww

    .pa

    lgra

    vec

    on

    nec

    t.com

    - lic

    ense

    d to

    Q4

    Push

    - Pa

    lgra

    veC

    onne

    ct -

    2010

    -12-

    06

  • 18 Introduction

    1970s there were clear signs of acceleration (see Figure 1.1a), and the period Pe

    r cap

    ita G

    DP g

    rowt

    h, 1

    945

    74 (%

    ) ended in a `golden age' with peak rates of growth in 196874 7.2 per cent

    a year, or 4.2 per cent per capita. This reflected a fairly broad pattern of growth

    acceleration. There was also a discernible reduction in the volatility of

    growth in the last phases of the postwar boom.

    Growth was not uniform among countries, either. A certain `convergence'

    was achieved due to the fact that the three `success stories' of the export age

    (Argentina, Chile and Uruguay) grew at a slower rate. This is also true if the

    fourth `success story' of the export age, Cuba, was added to the picture, but no

    comparable long-run GDP series for this country exists.13 These cases aside,

    however, there was no clear convergence pattern. Very fast growth was experi-

    enced by both countries with low initial per capita GDP, notably Brazil, but also

    by countries which started with a medium-level per capita GDP, particularly

    Mexico and Venezuela. On the other hand, Bolivia, Honduras, Paraguay and,

    particularly, Haiti constitute a sample of countries with low initial per capita

    GDP which grew at slow rates and, thus, performed contrary to convergence

    patterns (Figure 1.2).

    Along with growth came labour productivity gains, which translated into

    higher real wages of those employed, and a stronger labour union movement.

    Labour productivity increased at an annual rate of 3.4 per cent in 195073,

    which exceeded that of the USA but was below those typical in the most

    dynamic developed market economies and the Asian NICs.14 This reflected

    4.5

    4.0

    3.5

    3.0

    2.5

    2.0

    1.5

    1.0

    0.5

    0.0