9
Research Article Asymptotic Analysis of Shout Options Close to Expiry G. Alobaidi 1 and R. Mallier 2 1 Department of Mathematics, American University of Sharjah, Sharjah, UAE 2 Department of Mathematics and Statistics, York University, Toronto, ON, Canada M3J 1P3 Correspondence should be addressed to G. Alobaidi; [email protected] Received 14 November 2013; Accepted 9 January 2014; Published 17 February 2014 Academic Editors: R. V. Roy and E. Skubalska-Rafajlowicz Copyright Β© 2014 G. Alobaidi and R. Mallier. is is an open access article distributed under the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited. We use an asymptotic expansion to study the behavior of shout options close to expiry. Series solutions are obtained for the location of the free boundary and the price of the option in that limit. 1. Introduction Since the seminal work of Black and Scholes [1] and Merton [2] on the pricing of options appeared forty years ago, there has been a dramatic growth in both the role and complexity of financial contracts. e world’s first organized options exchange, the Chicago Board of Options Exchange (CBOE), opened in 1973, the same year as [1, 2] appeared in print, and trading volumes for the standard options traded on exchanges such as the CBOE exploded in the late 1970’s and early 1980’s. Around the same time as the growth in standard options, financial institutions began to look for alternative forms of options, termed exotic options, both to meet their needs in terms of reallocating risk and also to increase their business. ese exotics, which are usually traded over-the-counter (OTC), became very popular in the late 1980’s and early 1990’s, with their users including big corporations, financial institu- tions, fund managers, and private bankers. One such exotic, which is the topic of the current study, is a shout option [3, 4]. is option has the feature that it allows an investor to receive a portion of the pay-off prior to expiry while still retaining the right to profit from further upsides. In order to use this feature, the investor must shout, meaning exercise the option, at a time of his choosing, and this leads to an optimization problem wherein the investor must decide the best time at which to shout, which in turn leads to a free boundary problem, with the free boundary dividing the region where it is optimal to shout from that where it is not. In practice, shouting should of course only take place on the free boundary. is sort of free boundary problem is of course common in the pricing of options with American-style early option features, and this aspect of vanilla American options has been studied extensively in, for example, the recent studies of [5–13], although American-style exotics have received somewhat less attention. In the present study, we will use a technique developed by Tao [14–22] for the free boundary problems arising in melting and solidification; such problems are termed Stefan problems. Tao used a series expansion in time to find the location of the moving surface of separation between two phases of a material, and, in almost all of the cases he studied, he found that the location of the interface was proportional to 1/2 , being the time from when the two phases were first put in contact. Although, like all equity options, shout options obey the Black-Scholes-Merton partial differential equation [1, 2], it is straightforward to use a change of variables [8, 23] to transform this into the heat con- duction equation studied by Tao, along with a nonhomoge- neous term, and, once this transformation has been made, it is straightforward to apply Tao’s method. is approach has been taken for vanilla American options in the past [5, 6, 8, 12]. Before starting our analysis, which is presented in Section 2, we should first mention earlier work on shout options, much of which has been numerical, although as with other options involving a free boundary and choice on the part of an investor, some standard numerical techniques such as the forward-looking Monte Carlo method are problematic because of difficulties handling the optimization component Hindawi Publishing Corporation ISRN Applied Mathematics Volume 2014, Article ID 920385, 8 pages http://dx.doi.org/10.1155/2014/920385

Research Article Asymptotic Analysis of Shout Options Close ...Research Article Asymptotic Analysis of Shout Options Close to Expiry G.Alobaidi 1 andR.Mallier 2 Department of Mathematics,

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    2

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • Research ArticleAsymptotic Analysis of Shout Options Close to Expiry

    G. Alobaidi1 and R. Mallier2

    1 Department of Mathematics, American University of Sharjah, Sharjah, UAE2Department of Mathematics and Statistics, York University, Toronto, ON, Canada M3J 1P3

    Correspondence should be addressed to G. Alobaidi; [email protected]

    Received 14 November 2013; Accepted 9 January 2014; Published 17 February 2014

    Academic Editors: R. V. Roy and E. Skubalska-Rafajlowicz

    Copyright Β© 2014 G. Alobaidi and R. Mallier. This is an open access article distributed under the Creative Commons AttributionLicense, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properlycited.

    We use an asymptotic expansion to study the behavior of shout options close to expiry. Series solutions are obtained for the locationof the free boundary and the price of the option in that limit.

    1. Introduction

    Since the seminal work of Black and Scholes [1] and Merton[2] on the pricing of options appeared forty years ago, therehas been a dramatic growth in both the role and complexityof financial contracts. The world’s first organized optionsexchange, the Chicago Board of Options Exchange (CBOE),opened in 1973, the same year as [1, 2] appeared in print, andtrading volumes for the standard options traded on exchangessuch as the CBOE exploded in the late 1970’s and early 1980’s.Around the same time as the growth in standard options,financial institutions began to look for alternative forms ofoptions, termed exotic options, both to meet their needs interms of reallocating risk and also to increase their business.These exotics, which are usually traded over-the-counter(OTC), became very popular in the late 1980’s and early 1990’s,with their users including big corporations, financial institu-tions, fund managers, and private bankers.

    One such exotic, which is the topic of the current study, isa shout option [3, 4].This option has the feature that it allowsan investor to receive a portion of the pay-off prior to expirywhile still retaining the right to profit from further upsides.In order to use this feature, the investor must shout, meaningexercise the option, at a time of his choosing, and this leadsto an optimization problemwherein the investor must decidethe best time at which to shout, which in turn leads to afree boundary problem, with the free boundary dividing theregion where it is optimal to shout from that where it is not.In practice, shouting should of course only take place on thefree boundary.

    This sort of free boundary problem is of course commonin the pricing of options with American-style early optionfeatures, and this aspect of vanilla American options hasbeen studied extensively in, for example, the recent studiesof [5–13], although American-style exotics have receivedsomewhat less attention. In the present study, we will use atechnique developed by Tao [14–22] for the free boundaryproblems arising inmelting and solidification; such problemsare termed Stefan problems. Tao used a series expansion intime to find the location of the moving surface of separationbetween two phases of a material, and, in almost all of thecases he studied, he found that the location of the interfacewas proportional to 𝜏1/2, 𝜏 being the time from when thetwo phases were first put in contact. Although, like all equityoptions, shout options obey the Black-Scholes-Merton partialdifferential equation [1, 2], it is straightforward to use achange of variables [8, 23] to transform this into the heat con-duction equation studied by Tao, along with a nonhomoge-neous term, and, once this transformation has beenmade, it isstraightforward to apply Tao’s method. This approach hasbeen taken for vanilla American options in the past [5, 6, 8,12].

    Before starting our analysis, which is presented inSection 2, we should first mention earlier work on shoutoptions, much of which has been numerical, although as withother options involving a free boundary and choice on thepart of an investor, some standard numerical techniques suchas the forward-looking Monte Carlo method are problematicbecause of difficulties handling the optimization component

    Hindawi Publishing CorporationISRN Applied MathematicsVolume 2014, Article ID 920385, 8 pageshttp://dx.doi.org/10.1155/2014/920385

  • 2 ISRN Applied Mathematics

    of shout options. In [24], a Green’s function approach wasused. With this approach, it was assumed that early exercisecould only occur on a limited number of fixed times 𝑑 < 𝑑

    1<

    𝑑2

    < β‹… β‹… β‹… < π‘‘π‘›βˆ’1

    < 𝑑𝑛

    = 𝑇, so that the option was treatedas Bermudan-style or semi-American rather than American-style, and then the value of the option at time 𝑑

    π‘šwas used

    to compute the value at time π‘‘π‘šβˆ’1

    , which in turn was usedto compute the value at time 𝑑

    π‘šβˆ’2and so on. The value at

    time π‘‘π‘šβˆ’1

    was computed by using an integral involving theproduct of the Green’s function with the value at time 𝑑

    π‘š,

    with this integral being evaluated numerically.More standardnumerical methods, such as finite differences, have also beenapplied to shout options [25]. One analytical study was [4]which used partial Laplace transforms to study the freeboundary.

    Finally in this section, we should mention that, in addi-tion to shout options themselves, the shout feature can also befound embedded in several other financial contracts, someof which are offered to retail investors. One such contractis a segregated fund, sold by life insurance companies inCanada, which allows investors to lock in their profits priorto maturity. Some of these contracts have multiple shoutingopportunities, although in this analysis, we assume that theholder can shout only once so that there is only one freeboundary whose location must be optimized: with multipleshouting opportunities, there would be multiple free bound-aries.

    2. Analysis

    As with any equity option, the price 𝑉(𝑆, 𝑑) of a shout optionis governed by the Black-Scholes-Merton partial differentialequation (PDE) [1, 2]

    πœ•π‘‰

    πœ•π‘‘

    +

    𝜎2𝑆2

    2

    πœ•2𝑉

    πœ•π‘†2+ (π‘Ÿ βˆ’ 𝐷) 𝑆

    πœ•π‘‰

    πœ•π‘†

    βˆ’ π‘Ÿπ‘‰ = 0, (1)

    where 𝑆 is the price of the underlying and 𝑑 < 𝑇 is thetime, with 𝑇 being the expiry time. The parameters in thisequation are the risk-free rate, π‘Ÿ, the dividend yield, 𝐷, andthe volatility, 𝜎, all of which are assumed constant here.Merton [26] observed that this same PDE (1) governs theprice of many different securities, and it is the boundary andinitial conditions which differentiate the securities, not thePDE. For the shout options considered here, the pay-off for anoption held to maturity without shouting is max(𝑆 βˆ’ 𝐸, 0) fora call andmax(πΈβˆ’π‘†, 0) for a put, where𝐸 is the original strikeprice of the shout option; these pay-offs are the same as forvanilla European and American options. In addition, a shoutoption gives the holder the right to cash in some of the gainsprior to expiry, and a shout call can be exchanged at any timefor the excess of the current stock price 𝑆 over the strike price𝐸 together with a European call with a new strike price equalto the current stock price, provided the stock price is greaterthan the original exercise price. Obviously, the price of sucha European call can be written down using the Black-Scholesoption pricing formula, whichmeans that, upon shouting, the

    holder of a call receives a package consisting of cash togetherwith a European call with a total value of

    𝑉𝑓(𝑆, 𝜏) = 𝑆 βˆ’ 𝐸 +

    π‘†π‘’βˆ’π·πœ

    2

    erfc[βˆ’(π‘Ÿ βˆ’ 𝐷 + 𝜎

    2/2)√𝜏

    √2𝜎

    ]

    βˆ’

    π‘†π‘’βˆ’π‘Ÿπœ

    2

    erfc[βˆ’(π‘Ÿ βˆ’ 𝐷 βˆ’ 𝜎

    2/2)√𝜏

    √2𝜎

    ] .

    (2)

    Obviously, this leads to the constraint that the value of ashout option cannot be less than the proceeds from shoutingimmediately, so that, for the call, 𝑉 β‰₯ 𝑉

    𝑓for 𝑆 β‰₯ 𝐸, where

    𝑉𝑓is the pay-off from shouting. Similarly, a shout put can be

    exchanged at any time for the deficit of the current stock price𝑆 below the strike price 𝐸 together with a European put witha new strike price equal to the current stock price, providedthe stock price is less than the original exercise price. Uponshouting, therefore, the holder of a put receives a packageconsisting of cash together with a European put with a totalvalue of

    𝑉𝑓(𝑆, 𝜏) = 𝐸 βˆ’ 𝑆 βˆ’

    𝑆

    2

    π‘’βˆ’π·πœ erfc[

    (π‘Ÿ βˆ’ 𝐷 + 𝜎2/2)√𝜏

    √2𝜎

    ]

    +

    𝑆

    2

    π‘’βˆ’π‘Ÿπœ erfc[

    (π‘Ÿ βˆ’ 𝐷 βˆ’ 𝜎2/2)√𝜏

    √2𝜎

    ] ,

    (3)

    and for a put we have the constraint that 𝑉 β‰₯ 𝑉𝑓for 𝑆 ≀

    𝐸. In both (2) and (3), erfc denotes the complementary errorfunction.

    As with American options, the possibility of β€œshouting”leads to a free boundary where it is optimal to shout. Severalproperties of this free boundary are known. Firstly, we knowthe value of the option at the free boundary, namely,𝑉

    𝑓, given

    by (2) and (3) above, and also the value of the option’s delta,or derivative of its value with respect to the stock price, at thefree boundary, where it is equal to (πœ•π‘‰

    𝑓/πœ•π‘†), which for a call

    is

    𝑉𝑓(𝑆, 𝜏) + 𝐸

    𝑆

    , (4)

    while for a put it is

    𝑉𝑓(𝑆, 𝜏) βˆ’ 𝐸

    𝑆

    . (5)

    The condition on the delta, (πœ•π‘‰/πœ•π‘†), comes from requiringthat the delta is continuous across the boundary and isessentially the β€œhigh contact” or β€œsmooth-pasting” condition,which was first proposed by Samuelson [27] for Americanoptions.

    Secondly, we know that the location of the free boundaryat expiry 𝜏 = 0 is 𝑆

    𝑓(0) = 𝐸, which can be deduced intuitively

    because the pay-off for early exercise is so sweet for shoutoptions. In our terms, 𝜏

    𝑓(𝐸) = 0. We also know that the

    optimal exercise boundary moves upwards (or at worst is

  • ISRN Applied Mathematics 3

    flat) as we move away from the expiration date for a call anddownwards (or again at worst is flat) for a put.

    To analyze this equation, we will use an expansion whichis essentially along the lines of those used by Tao [14–22].An approach very similar to this has previously been appliedto American options [5, 6, 8, 12]. To apply Tao’s method tothe Black-Scholes-Merton PDE (1), it is necessary to make achange of variables to transform (1) into a more standard dif-fusion equation together with a forcing term.Wewill proceedalong the same lines as [5, 6, 8, 12] and make the change ofvariables 𝑆 = 𝐸𝑒π‘₯, 𝑑 = 𝑇 βˆ’ 2𝜏/𝜎2, and 𝑉(𝑆, 𝑑) = 𝑉

    𝑓+ 𝐸V(π‘₯, 𝜏),

    which leads us to the diffusion-like PDEπœ•Vπœ•πœ

    =

    πœ•2V

    πœ•π‘₯2+ π‘˜2

    πœ•Vπœ•π‘₯

    βˆ’ π‘˜1V + 𝑓 (π‘₯, 𝜏) , (6)

    where π‘˜1= 2π‘Ÿ/𝜎

    2 and π‘˜2= 2(π‘Ÿβˆ’π·)/𝜎

    2βˆ’1 and the nonhomo-

    geneous term for the call is

    𝑓 (π‘₯, 𝜏) = π‘˜1+ (1 + π‘˜

    2βˆ’ π‘˜1) 𝑒π‘₯

    βˆ’

    𝑒π‘₯βˆ’π‘˜1𝜏

    2

    Γ— (

    π‘’βˆ’π‘˜2

    2𝜏/4

    βˆšπœ‹πœ

    + (π‘˜2+ 1) erfc [βˆ’π‘˜2

    √𝜏

    2

    ]) ,

    (7)

    while for the put it is

    𝑓 (π‘₯, 𝜏) = βˆ’ π‘˜1βˆ’ (1 + π‘˜

    2βˆ’ π‘˜1) 𝑒π‘₯

    βˆ’

    𝑒π‘₯βˆ’π‘˜1𝜏

    2

    Γ— (

    π‘’βˆ’π‘˜2

    2𝜏/4

    βˆšπœ‹πœ

    βˆ’ (π‘˜2+ 1) erfc [π‘˜2

    √𝜏

    2

    ]) .

    (8)

    Equation (6) is valid for 𝜏 > 0 and must be solved togetherwith the payoff at expiry, 𝜏 = 0, which is V(π‘₯, 0) = max(1 βˆ’π‘’π‘₯, 0) for a call and V(π‘₯, 0) = max(𝑒π‘₯ βˆ’1, 0) for a put, while on

    the free boundary, we have

    V =πœ•Vπœ•π‘₯

    = 0. (9)

    At expiry the free boundary starts at 𝑆 = 𝐸 or equivalentlyπ‘₯ = 0. In the analysis that follows, strictly speaking (6) is validonly where it is valid to hold the option, so that at expiry, wecan only impose the initial condition on π‘₯ ≀ 0 for the call andon π‘₯ β‰₯ 0 for the put.

    To tackle (6) and associated boundary and initial condi-tions, we will follow Tao [14–22] and seek a series solution ofthe form

    V (π‘₯, 𝜏) =∞

    βˆ‘

    𝑛=1

    πœπ‘›/2

    𝑉𝑛(πœ‰) , (10)

    where πœ‰ = π‘₯/2√𝜏 is a similarity variable, while we assumethat the free boundary is located at π‘₯ = π‘₯

    𝑓(𝜏) which we also

    write as a series as follows:

    π‘₯𝑓(𝜏) =

    ∞

    βˆ‘

    𝑛=1

    π‘₯π‘›πœπ‘›/2

    . (11)

    In our analysis, we substitute the assumed form for V(π‘₯, 𝜏)(10) in the PDE (6) and group powers of 𝜏. To abbreviate thepresentation, we introduce the operator

    𝐿𝑛≑

    1

    4

    𝑑2

    π‘‘πœ‰2+

    1

    2

    𝑑

    π‘‘πœ‰

    βˆ’

    𝑛

    2

    . (12)

    2.1. The Call. For the call, at the first few orders, we find thefollowing equations for the various 𝑉

    𝑛:

    𝐿1𝑉1=

    1

    2βˆšπœ‹

    ,

    𝐿2𝑉2= βˆ’

    π‘˜2

    2

    𝑉

    1βˆ’

    π‘˜2+ 1

    2

    +

    πœ‰

    βˆšπœ‹

    ,

    𝐿3𝑉3= βˆ’

    π‘˜2

    2

    𝑉

    2βˆ’ π‘˜1𝑉1+ (2π‘˜1βˆ’ π‘˜2βˆ’ 1) πœ‰

    +

    πœ‰2βˆ’ (π‘˜1/2) + (3π‘˜

    2

    2/8) + (π‘˜

    2/2)

    βˆšπœ‹

    ,

    𝐿4𝑉4= βˆ’

    π‘˜2

    2

    𝑉

    3βˆ’ π‘˜1𝑉2+ (2π‘˜1βˆ’ 1 βˆ’ π‘˜

    2) πœ‰2

    βˆ’

    1

    2

    π‘˜1(π‘˜2+ 1)

    +

    (2πœ‰3/3) + (π‘˜

    2βˆ’ π‘˜1+ (3π‘˜2

    2/4)) πœ‰

    βˆšπœ‹

    ,

    (13)

    with similar equations for the higher orders, and it isstraightforward to write the solutions to (13) which satisfy theinitial condition that V(π‘₯, 0) = max(1 βˆ’ 𝑒π‘₯, 0) for π‘₯ ≀ 0 orequivalently 𝑉

    𝑛→ βˆ’(2πœ‰)

    𝑛/𝑛! as πœ‰ β†’ βˆ’βˆž. The solutions for

    the first few orders are

    𝑉1= βˆ’2πœ‰ βˆ’

    1

    βˆšπœ‹

    + 𝐢1[

    π‘’βˆ’πœ‰2

    βˆšπœ‹

    + πœ‰ erfc (βˆ’πœ‰)] ,

    𝑉2= βˆ’ 2πœ‰

    2βˆ’

    2πœ‰

    βˆšπœ‹

    βˆ’

    π‘˜2+ 1

    2

    + 𝐢2[

    2πœ‰π‘’βˆ’πœ‰2

    βˆšπœ‹

    + (2πœ‰2+ 1) erfc (βˆ’πœ‰)]

    βˆ’ 𝐢1π‘˜2[

    πœ‰π‘’βˆ’πœ‰2

    βˆšπœ‹

    + πœ‰2 erfc (βˆ’πœ‰)] ,

    𝑉3=

    βˆ’8 + 12π‘˜1βˆ’ 12π‘˜

    2βˆ’ 3π‘˜2

    2βˆ’ 24πœ‰2

    12βˆšπœ‹

    βˆ’

    πœ‰

    3

    (4πœ‰2+ 3π‘˜2+ 3)

    + 𝐢3[(1 + πœ‰

    2)

    π‘’βˆ’πœ‰2

    βˆšπœ‹

    + (πœ‰3+

    3πœ‰

    2

    ) erfc (βˆ’πœ‰)]

  • 4 ISRN Applied Mathematics

    + 2𝐢2π‘˜2[

    π‘’βˆ’πœ‰2

    βˆšπœ‹

    + πœ‰ erfc (βˆ’πœ‰)]

    βˆ’ 𝐢1[(π‘˜1+

    3

    4

    π‘˜2

    2)

    π‘’βˆ’πœ‰2

    βˆšπœ‹

    + πœ‰ (π‘˜1+ π‘˜2

    2) erfc (βˆ’πœ‰)] ,

    𝑉4=

    πœ‰ (βˆ’8πœ‰2+ 12π‘˜

    1βˆ’ 12π‘˜

    2βˆ’ 8 βˆ’ 3π‘˜

    3

    2)

    6βˆšπœ‹

    βˆ’

    2πœ‰4

    3

    βˆ’ (π‘˜2+ 1) πœ‰

    2βˆ’

    (π‘˜2+ 1)2

    4

    +

    π‘˜1(π‘˜2+ 1)

    2

    + 𝐢4[

    [

    (5πœ‰ + 2πœ‰3) π‘’βˆ’πœ‰2

    3βˆšπœ‹

    + (

    4

    3

    πœ‰4+ 4πœ‰2+ 1) erfc (βˆ’πœ‰)]

    ]

    βˆ’ 𝐢3π‘˜2[

    [

    (πœ‰ + πœ‰3) π‘’βˆ’πœ‰2

    βˆšπœ‹

    + (

    3

    2

    πœ‰4+ πœ‰2) erfc (βˆ’πœ‰)]

    ]

    + 𝐢2[

    [

    ((4π‘˜1βˆ’ 5π‘˜2

    2) πœ‰ + (4π‘˜

    1βˆ’ 2π‘˜2

    2) πœ‰3) π‘’βˆ’πœ‰2

    3βˆšπœ‹

    + (

    2

    3

    (2π‘˜1βˆ’ π‘˜2

    2) πœ‰4+ 2 (π‘˜

    1βˆ’ π‘˜2

    2πœ‰2))

    Γ— erfc (βˆ’πœ‰)]

    ]

    + 𝐢1π‘˜2[((

    3

    4

    π‘˜2

    2+ 1) πœ‰ +

    π‘˜2

    2πœ‰3

    3

    )

    π‘’βˆ’πœ‰2

    βˆšπœ‹

    + ((π‘˜2

    2+ π‘˜1) πœ‰2+

    π‘˜2

    2πœ‰4

    3

    ) erfc (βˆ’πœ‰) ] ,

    (14)

    where the 𝐢𝑛are constants that must be found by applying

    the conditions (9) at the free boundary.To apply the conditions (9) at the free boundary, we

    reconstitute the series (10) using the expressions (14) forthe 𝑉𝑛and then substitute the assumed form (11) for π‘₯

    𝑓(𝜏)

    and again group powers of 𝜏. The solution of the resultingequations will yield the coefficients π‘₯

    𝑛and 𝐢

    𝑛.

    Proceeding in thismanner, at leading order, we obtain thepair of equations for π‘₯

    1and 𝐢

    1:

    𝐢1[

    π‘’βˆ’π‘₯2

    1/4

    βˆšπœ‹

    +

    π‘₯1

    2

    erfc(βˆ’π‘₯12

    )] βˆ’ π‘₯1βˆ’

    1

    βˆšπœ‹

    = 0,

    𝐢1

    2

    erfc(βˆ’π‘₯12

    ) βˆ’ 1 = 0,

    (15)

    so that π‘₯1must satisfy the equation

    erfc(βˆ’π‘₯12

    ) = 2π‘’βˆ’π‘₯2

    1/4, (16)

    with 𝐢1then given by

    𝐢1=

    2

    erfc (βˆ’π‘₯1/2)

    = 𝑒π‘₯2

    1/4. (17)

    These expressions ((16) and (17)) are similar to but notidentical to their counterparts for the American call withπ‘Ÿ > 𝐷 given in [5, 8]; the analysis of the American call withπ‘Ÿ ≀ 𝐷 is rather different and involves logarithms. As with[5, 8], (16) and (17) must be solved numerically, and we find

    π‘₯1= 1.030396155,

    𝐢1= 1.303990345.

    (18)

    At the next order on the free boundary, we obtain the pair ofequations

    𝐢2

    𝐢1

    [2 +

    π‘₯1

    βˆšπœ‹

    + π‘₯2

    1] βˆ’

    π‘˜2

    2

    [1 +

    π‘₯1

    βˆšπœ‹

    + π‘₯2

    1]

    βˆ’

    1

    2

    [1 +

    2π‘₯1

    βˆšπœ‹

    + π‘₯2

    1] = 0,

    𝐢2

    𝐢1

    [4π‘₯1+

    1

    βˆšπœ‹

    ] βˆ’ π‘˜2[2π‘₯1+

    1

    βˆšπœ‹

    ] βˆ’ [2π‘₯1+

    2 βˆ’ π‘₯2

    βˆšπœ‹

    ] = 0,

    (19)

    which have a solution

    π‘₯2=

    2πœ‹π‘₯1(1 + π‘˜

    2) + βˆšπœ‹ (2 βˆ’ π‘₯

    2

    1(π‘˜2+ 2)) βˆ’ π‘₯

    1(π‘˜2+ 2)

    βˆšπœ‹ (2 + π‘₯2

    1) + π‘₯1

    = 0.5516261066π‘˜2+ 0.6496056829,

    𝐢2=

    𝐢1

    2

    [

    βˆšπœ‹ (1 + π‘˜2) (1 + π‘₯

    2

    1) + π‘₯1(2 + π‘˜

    2)

    βˆšπœ‹ (2 + π‘₯2

    1) + π‘₯1

    ]

    = 0.4730258268π‘˜2+ 0.5770676475.

    (20)

    If we continue the analysis to higher orders, it is straightfor-ward to show that

    π‘₯3= 0.292207785π‘˜

    2

    2+ 0.893808684π‘˜

    2

    βˆ’ 0.3950836719π‘˜1+ 0.610198033,

    π‘₯4= 0.203979819π‘˜

    3

    2+ 0.9698633439π‘˜

    2

    2

    + 1.452965717π‘˜2βˆ’ 0.8345732085π‘˜

    1π‘˜2

    βˆ’ 0.9203954739π‘˜1+ 0.6875373101,

    π‘₯5= 0.1638998310π‘˜

    4

    2+ 1.037819212π‘˜

    3

    2

    + 2.400660126π‘˜2

    2+ 2.386097546π‘˜

    2

    βˆ’ 1.469136768π‘˜1π‘˜2

    2βˆ’ 3.178694724π‘˜

    1π‘˜2

    βˆ’ 1.768309502π‘˜1+ 0.4855736529π‘˜

    2

    1

    + 0.8593396200,

    (21)

  • ISRN Applied Mathematics 5

    with

    𝐢3= 0.2474229510π‘˜

    2

    2βˆ’ 0.1188463797π‘˜

    2

    + 0.5304417776π‘˜1+ 0.7375354641,

    𝐢4= 0.00318404397π‘˜

    3

    2+ 0.2473130714π‘˜

    2

    2

    + 0.5280891544π‘˜2βˆ’ 0.3593239715π‘˜

    1π‘˜2

    βˆ’ 0.4660110242π‘˜1+ 0.2730318578,

    𝐢5= 0.04939807173π‘˜

    4

    2βˆ’ 0.02503076966π‘˜

    3

    2

    + 0.1638363804π‘˜2

    2βˆ’ 0.00645471784π‘˜

    2

    + 0.1970541793π‘˜1π‘˜2

    2βˆ’ 0.08183232660π‘˜

    1π‘˜2

    + 0.03734886087π‘˜1+ 0.09802891395π‘˜

    2

    1

    + 0.1461511036.

    (22)

    In (10), (14), (18), (20), and (22), we have an expression for thevalue of a shout call close to expiry, with the location of thefree boundary given by (11), (18), (20), and (21).

    2.2. The Put. The analysis for the put is very similar to thatfor the call, but with a different nonhomogeneous term anddifferent initial condition. Once again using the operator 𝐿

    𝑛

    defined in (12), at the first few orders, we find

    𝐿1𝑉1=

    1

    2βˆšπœ‹

    ,

    𝐿2𝑉2=

    π‘˜2

    2

    𝑉

    1+

    π‘˜2+ 1

    2

    +

    πœ‰

    βˆšπœ‹

    ,

    𝐿3𝑉3= βˆ’

    π‘˜2

    2

    𝑉

    2βˆ’ π‘˜1𝑉1+ (π‘˜2+ 1 βˆ’ 2π‘˜

    1) πœ‰

    +

    πœ‰2βˆ’ (π‘˜1/2) + (3π‘˜

    2

    2/8) + (π‘˜

    2/2)

    βˆšπœ‹

    ,

    𝐿4𝑉4= βˆ’

    π‘˜2

    2

    𝑉

    3βˆ’ π‘˜1𝑉2+ (π‘˜2+ 1 βˆ’ 2π‘˜

    1) πœ‰2

    +

    1

    2

    π‘˜1(π‘˜2+ 1) +

    (π‘˜2βˆ’ π‘˜1+ (3π‘˜2

    2/4)) πœ‰ + (2πœ‰

    3/3)

    βˆšπœ‹

    .

    (23)

    Not surprisingly, (23) for the put are very similar to those(13) for the call, differing only in the signs of variousnonhomogeneous terms. Once again, it is straightforward towrite the solutions to (23) which satisfy the initial condition,which for the put is V(π‘₯, 0) = max(𝑒π‘₯ βˆ’ 1, 0) for π‘₯ β‰₯ 0 orequivalently 𝑉

    𝑛→ (2πœ‰)

    𝑛/𝑛! as πœ‰ β†’ +∞. The solutions for

    the first few orders are

    𝑉1= 2πœ‰ βˆ’

    1

    βˆšπœ‹

    + 𝐢1[

    π‘’βˆ’πœ‰2

    βˆšπœ‹

    βˆ’ πœ‰ erfc (πœ‰)] ,

    𝑉2= 2πœ‰2βˆ’

    2πœ‰

    βˆšπœ‹

    +

    π‘˜2+ 1

    2

    βˆ’ 𝐢2[

    2πœ‰π‘’βˆ’πœ‰2

    βˆšπœ‹

    βˆ’ (2πœ‰2+ 1) erfc (πœ‰)]

    βˆ’ 𝐢1π‘˜2[

    πœ‰π‘’βˆ’πœ‰2

    βˆšπœ‹

    βˆ’ πœ‰2 erfc (πœ‰)] ,

    𝑉3=

    βˆ’8 + 12π‘˜1βˆ’ 12π‘˜

    2βˆ’ 3π‘˜2

    2βˆ’ 24πœ‰2

    12βˆšπœ‹

    +

    πœ‰

    3

    (4πœ‰2+ 3π‘˜2+ 3)

    βˆ’ 𝐢3[(1 + πœ‰

    2)

    π‘’βˆ’πœ‰2

    βˆšπœ‹

    βˆ’ (πœ‰3+

    3πœ‰

    2

    ) erfc (πœ‰)]

    βˆ’ 2𝐢2π‘˜2[

    π‘’βˆ’πœ‰2

    βˆšπœ‹

    βˆ’ πœ‰ erfc (πœ‰)]

    βˆ’ 𝐢1[(π‘˜1+

    3

    4

    π‘˜2

    2)

    π‘’βˆ’πœ‰2

    βˆšπœ‹

    βˆ’ πœ‰ (π‘˜1+ π‘˜2

    2) erfc (πœ‰)] ,

    𝑉4=

    πœ‰ (βˆ’8πœ‰2+ 12π‘˜

    1βˆ’ 12π‘˜

    2βˆ’ 8 βˆ’ 3π‘˜

    3

    2)

    6βˆšπœ‹

    +

    2πœ‰4

    3

    + (π‘˜2+ 1) πœ‰

    2+

    (π‘˜2+ 1)2

    4

    βˆ’

    π‘˜1(π‘˜2+ 1)

    2

    βˆ’ 𝐢4[

    [

    (5πœ‰ + 2πœ‰3) π‘’βˆ’πœ‰2

    3βˆšπœ‹

    βˆ’ (

    4

    3

    πœ‰4+ 4πœ‰2+ 1) erfc (πœ‰)]

    ]

    βˆ’ 𝐢3π‘˜2[

    [

    (πœ‰ + πœ‰3) π‘’βˆ’πœ‰2

    βˆšπœ‹

    βˆ’ (

    3

    2

    πœ‰4+ πœ‰2) erfc (πœ‰)]

    ]

    βˆ’ 𝐢2[

    [

    ((4π‘˜1βˆ’ 5π‘˜2

    2) πœ‰ + (4π‘˜

    1βˆ’ 2π‘˜2

    2) πœ‰3) π‘’βˆ’πœ‰2

    3βˆšπœ‹

    βˆ’ (

    2

    3

    (2π‘˜1βˆ’ π‘˜2

    2) πœ‰4+ 2 (π‘˜

    1βˆ’ π‘˜2

    2πœ‰2)) erfc (πœ‰) ]

    ]

    βˆ’ 𝐢1π‘˜2[((

    3

    4

    π‘˜2

    2+ 1) πœ‰ +

    π‘˜2

    2πœ‰3

    3

    )

    π‘’βˆ’πœ‰2

    βˆšπœ‹

    βˆ’ ((π‘˜2

    2+ π‘˜1) πœ‰2+

    π‘˜2

    2πœ‰4

    3

    ) erfc (πœ‰) ] ,

    (24)

    which differ from their counterparts (14) for the call only inthe signs of various terms.

  • 6 ISRN Applied Mathematics

    To apply the conditions (9) at the free boundary, weproceed as for the call, and at leading order, we obtain thepair of equations for π‘₯

    1and 𝐢

    1,

    𝐢1[

    π‘’βˆ’π‘₯2

    1/4

    βˆšπœ‹

    βˆ’

    π‘₯1

    2

    erfc(π‘₯12

    )] + π‘₯1βˆ’

    1

    βˆšπœ‹

    = 0,

    𝐢1

    2

    erfc(π‘₯12

    ) βˆ’ 1 = 0,

    (25)

    so that π‘₯1obeys

    erfc(π‘₯12

    ) = 2π‘’βˆ’π‘₯2

    1/4, (26)

    with 𝐢1given by

    𝐢1=

    2

    erfc (π‘₯1/2)

    = π‘’βˆ’π‘₯2

    1/4, (27)

    which can be solved numerically to give

    π‘₯1= βˆ’1.030396155,

    𝐢1= 1.303990345.

    (28)

    The coefficient 𝐢1is the same as for the call but the sign of π‘₯

    1

    is changed.At the next order, we have

    𝐢2

    𝐢1

    [2 βˆ’

    π‘₯1

    βˆšπœ‹

    + π‘₯2

    1] +

    π‘˜2

    2

    [1 βˆ’

    π‘₯1

    βˆšπœ‹

    + π‘₯2

    1]

    +

    1

    2

    [1 βˆ’

    2π‘₯1

    βˆšπœ‹

    + π‘₯2

    1] = 0,

    𝐢2

    𝐢1

    [4π‘₯1βˆ’

    1

    βˆšπœ‹

    ] + π‘˜2[2π‘₯1βˆ’

    1

    βˆšπœ‹

    ] + [2π‘₯1+

    π‘₯2βˆ’ 2

    βˆšπœ‹

    ] = 0,

    (29)

    with a solution

    π‘₯2=

    βˆ’2πœ‹π‘₯1(1 + π‘˜

    2) + βˆšπœ‹ (2 βˆ’ π‘₯

    2

    1(π‘˜2+ 2)) βˆ’ π‘₯

    1(π‘˜2+ 2)

    βˆšπœ‹ (2 + π‘₯2

    1) βˆ’ π‘₯1

    = 0.5516261066π‘˜2+ 0.6496056829,

    𝐢2=

    𝐢1

    2

    [βˆ’

    βˆšπœ‹ (1 + π‘˜2) (1 + π‘₯

    2

    1) + π‘₯1(2 + π‘˜

    2)

    βˆšπœ‹ (2 + π‘₯2

    1) βˆ’ π‘₯1

    ]

    = βˆ’ 0.4730258268π‘˜2βˆ’ 0.5770676475,

    (30)

    with π‘₯2the same as for the call but the sign of 𝐢

    2reversed.

    For the higher orders, we find

    π‘₯3= βˆ’ 0.292207785π‘˜

    2

    2+ 0.893808684π‘˜

    2

    βˆ’ 0.3950836719π‘˜1βˆ’ 0.610198033,

    π‘₯4= 0.203979819π‘˜

    3

    2+ 0.9698633439π‘˜

    2

    2

    + 1.452965717π‘˜2βˆ’ 0.8345732085π‘˜

    1π‘˜2

    βˆ’ 0.9203954739π‘˜1+ 0.6875373101,

    π‘₯5= βˆ’ 0.1638998310π‘˜

    4

    2βˆ’ 1.037819212π‘˜

    3

    2

    βˆ’ 2.400660126π‘˜2

    2βˆ’ 2.386097546π‘˜

    2

    + 1.469136768π‘˜1π‘˜2

    2+ 3.178694724π‘˜

    1π‘˜2

    + 1.768309502π‘˜1βˆ’ 0.4855736529π‘˜

    2

    1

    βˆ’ 0.8593396200,

    (31)

    with

    𝐢3= βˆ’ 0.2474229510π‘˜

    2

    2+ 0.1188463797π‘˜

    2

    βˆ’ 0.5304417776π‘˜1βˆ’ 0.737535464,

    𝐢4= βˆ’ 0.00318404397π‘˜

    3

    2+ 0.2473130714π‘˜

    2

    2

    βˆ’ 0.5280891544π‘˜2+ 0.3593239715π‘˜

    1π‘˜2

    + 0.4660110242π‘˜1βˆ’ 0.2730318578,

    𝐢5= βˆ’ 0.04939807173π‘˜

    4

    2+ 0.02503076966π‘˜

    3

    2

    βˆ’ 0.1638363804π‘˜2

    2+ 0.00645471784π‘˜

    2

    βˆ’ 0.1970541793π‘˜1π‘˜2

    2+ 0.08183232660π‘˜

    1π‘˜2

    βˆ’ 0.03734886087π‘˜1βˆ’ 0.09802891395π‘˜

    2

    1

    βˆ’ 0.1461511036,

    (32)

    with (31) and (32) differing from their counterparts for the call((21), (22)) only in the sign of various terms. In (10), (24), (28),(30), and (32), we have an expression for the value of a shoutput close to expiry, with the location of the free boundarygiven by (11), (28), (30), and (31).

    3. Discussion

    In the previous section, we used the method of Tao [14–22]to study the behavior of shout options close to expiry, thesebeing exotic options which allow the investor to receive aportion of the pay-off prior to expiry while still retaining theright to further upside participation, because of which thepay-off for early exercise is sweeter than for vanilla Americanoptions. Perhaps surprisingly, the behavior close to expiryis slightly different for shouts than for vanilla Americans, andwe can attribute a large part of this difference to the richnessof the pay-off for early exercise. For vanilla Americans [5–13],

  • ISRN Applied Mathematics 7

    the behavior of the free boundary has a strong dependenceon the relative values of the risk-free interest rate π‘Ÿ and thedividend yield 𝐷 on the underlying stock. For the Americancall with 0 ≀ 𝐷 < π‘Ÿ and the American put with𝐷 > π‘Ÿ β‰₯ 0, thefree boundary started at π‘ŸπΈ/𝐷 at expiry, with𝐸 as the exerciseprice of the option, and had the usual 𝜏1/2 behavior close toexpiry, meaning that, as 𝑑 β†’ 𝑇, the free boundary behavedlike 𝑆 ∼ 𝑆

    0exp[π‘Ž(𝑇 βˆ’ 𝑑)1/2]; this was the 𝜏1/2 behavior which

    Tao found in themajority of the physical problems he consid-ered. For the American call with𝐷 > π‘Ÿ β‰₯ 0 and the Americanput with 0 ≀ 𝐷 < π‘Ÿ, the free boundary started at 𝐸 at expiryand behaved like 𝑆 ∼ 𝑆

    0exp[π‘Ž(βˆ’(𝑇 βˆ’ 𝑑) ln(𝑇 βˆ’ 𝑑))1/2]; this

    behavior is somewhat unusual in that Tao did not encounterthis sort of behavior in his studies. For shouts, we foundin Section 2 that, although the coefficients in the expansiondepended on π‘Ÿ and 𝐷, the qualitative behavior of the freeboundary did not: regardless of the values of π‘Ÿ and 𝐷, thefree boundary for a shout always starts from 𝐸 at expiry andalways has the usual 𝜏1/2 behavior close to expiry. Regardlessof the values of π‘Ÿ and 𝐷, the free boundary close to expiryfor shout options seems to be less steep than that for vanillaAmericans, and it would seem likely that this is because earlyexercise is more likely for a shout than a vanilla Americanon the same underlying with the same strike, simply becausethe rewards for early exercise are greater for a shout thanan American. For an American, early exercise involves atrade-off between receiving the pay-off earlier and receivingbenefits from any further upside, while with a shout earlyexercise results in receiving a portion of the pay-off earlierwhile still benefitting from further upsides. Because of this, itwould appear paradoxically that, although shout options aremore complex contracts than vanilla Americans, the analysisof shouts is actually a little simpler than that of Americans,primarily because logs are not present for the shouts.

    Finally, we note that the behavior of shout puts and callsclose to expiry is very similar, suggesting that there is somesort of put-call symmetry for shout options, perhaps alongthe lines of that for vanilla Americans [28, 29], and it wouldbe interesting to find the exact forms of this symmetry forshouts and other American-style exotics.

    Conflict of Interests

    The authors declare that there is no conflict of interestsregarding the publication of this paper.

    References

    [1] F. Black and M. Scholes, β€œThe pricing of options and corporateliabilities,” Journal of Political Economy, vol. 81, pp. 637–659,1973.

    [2] R. C. Merton, β€œTheory of rational option pricing,” The BellJournal of Economics and Management Science, vol. 4, pp. 141–183, 1973.

    [3] B. Thomas, β€œSomething to shout about,” Risk, vol. 6, pp. 56–58,1993.

    [4] G. Alobaidi, R. Mallier, and S. Mansi, β€œLaplace transforms andshout options,” Acta Mathematica Universitatis Comenianae,vol. 80, no. 1, pp. 79–102, 2011.

    [5] G. Alobaidi and R. Mallier, β€œAsymptotic analysis of Americancall options,” International Journal of Mathematics and Mathe-matical Sciences, vol. 27, no. 3, pp. 177–188, 2001.

    [6] G. Alobaidi and R. Mallier, β€œOn the optimal exercise boundaryfor an American put option,” Journal of Applied Mathematics,vol. 1, no. 1, pp. 39–45, 2001.

    [7] G. Barles, J. Burdeau, M. Romano, and M. Samsoen, β€œCriticalstock price near expiration,”Mathematical Finance, vol. 5, no. 2,pp. 77–95, 1995.

    [8] J. N. Dewynne, S. D. Howison, I. Rupf, and P. Wilmott, β€œSomemathematical results in the pricing of American options,”European Journal of Applied Mathematics, vol. 4, no. 4, pp. 381–398, 1993.

    [9] J.D. Evans, R.Kuske, and J. B. Keller, β€œAmerican options of assetswith dividends near expiry,” Mathematical Finance, vol. 12, no.3, pp. 219–237, 2002.

    [10] C. Knessl, β€œA note on amoving boundary problem arising in theAmerican put option,” Studies in Applied Mathematics, vol. 107,no. 2, pp. 157–183, 2001.

    [11] R. E. Kuske and J. B. Keller, β€œOptimal exercise boundary for anAmerican put option,”AppliedMathematical Finance, vol. 5, no.2, pp. 107–116, 1998.

    [12] R. Mallier and G. Alobaidi, β€œThe American put option close toexpiry,”ActaMathematicaUniversitatis Comenianae, vol. 73, no.2, pp. 161–174, 2004.

    [13] R. Stamicar, D. Ševčovič, and J. Chadam, β€œThe early exerciseboundary for the American put near expiry: numerical approx-imation,” The Canadian Applied Mathematics Quarterly, vol. 7,no. 4, pp. 427–444, 1999.

    [14] L. N. Tao, β€œThe Stefan problem with arbitrary initial andboundary conditions,” Quarterly of Applied Mathematics, vol.36, no. 3, pp. 223–233, 1978.

    [15] L. N. Tao, β€œFree boundary problems with radiation boundaryconditions,” Quarterly of Applied Mathematics, vol. 37, no. 1, pp.1–10, 1979.

    [16] L. N. Tao, β€œOn solidification problems including the densityjump at the moving boundary,” The Quarterly Journal ofMechanics and Applied Mathematics, vol. 32, no. 2, pp. 175–185,1979.

    [17] L.N. Tao, β€œOn free boundary problemswith arbitrary initial andflux conditions,” Zeitschrift für Angewandte Mathematik undPhysik, vol. 30, no. 3, pp. 416–426, 1979.

    [18] L. N. Tao, β€œThe analyticity of solutions of the Stefan problem,”Archive for Rational Mechanics and Analysis, vol. 72, no. 3, pp.285–301, 1980.

    [19] L. N. Tao, β€œOn solidification of a binary alloy,” The QuarterlyJournal of Mechanics and Applied Mathematics, vol. 33, no. 2,pp. 211–225, 1980.

    [20] L. N. Tao, β€œThe exact solutions of some Stefan problems withprescribed heat flux,” Journal of Applied Mechanics, vol. 48, no.4, pp. 732–736, 1981.

    [21] L. N. Tao, β€œThe Stefan problem with an imperfect thermalcontact at the interface,” Journal of Applied Mechanics, vol. 49,no. 4, pp. 715–720, 1982.

    [22] L. N. Tao, β€œThe Cauchy-Stefan problem,” Acta Mechanica, vol.45, no. 1-2, pp. 49–64, 1982.

    [23] P. Wilmott, Paul Wilmott on Quantitative Finance, John Wiley& Sons, Chichester, UK, 2000.

    [24] P. P. Boyle, A. W. Kolkiewicz, and K. S. Tan, β€œValuation ofthe reset option in segregated fund contracts using quasi-Monte Carlo,” Research Report 99-10, Institute of Insurance andPension Research, University of Waterloo, 1999.

  • 8 ISRN Applied Mathematics

    [25] H. Windcliff, P. A. Forsyth, and K. R. Vetzal, β€œShout options: aframework for pricing contracts which can be modified by theinvestor,” Journal of Computational and Applied Mathematics,vol. 134, no. 1-2, pp. 213–241, 2001.

    [26] R. C. Merton, β€œOn the problem of corporate debt: the riskstructure of interest rates,” The Journal of Finance, vol. 29, pp.449–470, 1974.

    [27] P. A. Samuelson, β€œRational theory of warrant pricing,” IndustrialManagement Review, vol. 6, pp. 13–31, 1965.

    [28] M. Chesney and R. Gibson, β€œState space symmetry and two fac-tor option pricing models,” Advances in Futures and OperationsResearch, vol. 8, pp. 85–112, 1993.

    [29] R. McDonald and M. Schroder, β€œA parity result for Americanoptions,” Journal of Computational Finance, vol. 1, pp. 5–13, 1998.

  • Submit your manuscripts athttp://www.hindawi.com

    Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

    MathematicsJournal of

    Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

    Mathematical Problems in Engineering

    Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com

    Differential EquationsInternational Journal of

    Volume 2014

    Applied MathematicsJournal of

    Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

    Probability and StatisticsHindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

    Journal of

    Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

    Mathematical PhysicsAdvances in

    Complex AnalysisJournal of

    Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

    OptimizationJournal of

    Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

    CombinatoricsHindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

    International Journal of

    Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

    Operations ResearchAdvances in

    Journal of

    Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

    Function Spaces

    Abstract and Applied AnalysisHindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

    International Journal of Mathematics and Mathematical Sciences

    Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

    The Scientific World JournalHindawi Publishing Corporation http://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

    Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

    Algebra

    Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society

    Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

    Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

    Decision SciencesAdvances in

    Discrete MathematicsJournal of

    Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com

    Volume 2014 Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

    Stochastic AnalysisInternational Journal of