22
Modeling Dynamics of Oil Supply – Demand Shock Effects on Stock Market Returns Hassan Nojumi (author for all correspondence) Department of Mathematical Sciences Sharif University of Technology, Tehran, Iran P.O.Box 11365-9415, Azadi Street, Tehran, Iran E-Mail: [email protected] [email protected] Mobile: 0912 5937563 Tel: (+9821) 6616-5640 Fax: (+9821) 6600-5117 , Amirreza Shafaat, Hamidreza Golmakani, Hossein Salimi Department of Industrial Engineering Amir Kabir University of Technology, Tehran, Iran 0

Prob lem Definitionsharif.edu/~nojumi/pubfiles/mdosdsesmr.doc  · Web viewOn the other hand, the resulting transfer of wealth from industrialized nations to less developed oil-producing

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    1

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Prob lem Definition

Modeling Dynamics of Oil Supply – DemandShock Effects on Stock Market Returns

Hassan Nojumi (author for all correspondence)

Department of Mathematical Sciences

Sharif University of Technology, Tehran, Iran

P.O.Box 11365-9415, Azadi Street, Tehran, Iran

E-Mail: [email protected]

[email protected]

Mobile: 0912 5937563

Tel: (+9821) 6616-5640

Fax: (+9821) 6600-5117

, Amirreza Shafaat, Hamidreza Golmakani, Hossein Salimi

Department of Industrial Engineering

Amir Kabir University of Technology, Tehran, Iran

Modeling Dynamics of Oil Supply – Demand

Shock Effects on Stock Market Returns

Hassan Nojumi*, Amirreza Shafaat**, Hamidreza Golmakani**, Hossein Salimi**

* Department of Mathematical Sciences, Sharif University of Technology, Tehran, Iran

** Department of Industrial Engineering, Amir Kabir University of Technology, Tehran, Iran

Abstract

Throughout the industrial world, prices of financial products are continually affected by various factors and events. One of these significant factors is price of oil and oil products. This papers aims at investigation of this connection through mathematical modeling using stochastic analysis.

1. Introduction

Financial press has long asserted that stock prices and stock market returns are affected by the oil price volatility. The Asian financial crisis of 1997, the recession of 2001, and the depreciation of the Dollar against the Euro in recent times can all be read directly in the historical price of oil.

On the other hand, the resulting transfer of wealth from industrialized nations to less developed oil-producing countries has had a measurable effect on the financial system: From 2002 to 2003, the revenues accrued to the OPEC 10 members from sales jumped from $180 billion to $240 billion, as the price of WTI averaged $31.10/bushel (an increase of 30% from the previous year).

These revenues (the so-called petrodollars) have the potential to move currencies, stocks and interest rates. For instance, the market capitalizations of most Persian Gulf stock exchanges doubled between January 2003 and September 2004, following the oil price increase. As an illustration, Figure 1 plots the returns of major equity indexes in the Persian Gulf, with the base set on January 1, 2003 and their correlation to the oil price. As it can be seen, stock indexes of oil producing countries in are positively affected by oil price growth.

Stock markets of 18 major countries (in local currencies) and 33 emerging markets have been analyzed in [6], in which, using regression analysis, the stock price data with various oil price indexes (Brent crude, WTI and Dubai ) have been compared to see if there is any correlation. It turns out there is; in 12 of the 18 countries, changes in oil price have significantly predicted future market returns on a lagging monthly basis. Not surprisingly, rise in oil price suggests a lower stock market and a drop in oil price infers rise in stock prices. The magnitude of the oil price shift is also carried over into the magnitude of the expected increase/decrease in stock prices.

As empirical studies have shown [10], we assume that there are logical interconnections between stock market returns and oil price volatility. With this assumption, what is sought is to model the interconnections to capture and better estimate the behavior of stock markets.

The paper continues by describing our model. A review of related literature is presented in section 3. We model the two country world in section 4; first with the world modeled in simple form when market is complete and there are no jumps, then with the jumps being incorporated. In both parts we consider a portfolio which is risk neutral to non-oil effects, with price movement rela6ed to oil volatility and shocks.

2. Model Description

We will model the oil supply-demand shock effects on stock market returns in the form of system dynamics and stochastic differential equations.

First we divide the world in to two parts: oil producers and oil consumers. In these two categories the effect of oil price volatility and jumps are opposite each other (see [10], [6]). A simple two-country model is then developed. Using this model, stock and oil prices are jointly determined.

The model identifies interconnections among crud oil price and stock markets, and characterizes their joint dynamic as a multi-factor model. These factors describe the international financial equilibrium model and the interconnections between its components (oil price and stock indexes). The model also contains factors of oil supply and demand shocks for determining responses of stock markets to these shocks.

We have assumed that crude oil price and stock indexes follow Levy processes such as CGMY, Variance Gamma (VG), Normal Inverse Gaussian (NIG), Log-Stable (LS) or some combined models such as EJP, Bates and etc [4], [5].

Thus the conceptual system can be defined as follows:

Empirical validity of our model’s implications can be tested in several dimensions. For this purpose one should run the model with real data of some creditable financial markets such as NYMEX, WTI, Brent Crude, Dubai Stock Exchange, London Stock Exchange, etc. Then the results should be compared with the effects of oil price volatility and jumps on stock market returns of both oil producer and consumer in the real world.

3. Related Literatures

Various types of mathematical and statistical tests have been used by analysts in determining the effective elements on an international financial network.

Oil has important role in international finance and economy. Also, stock market returns are affected by oil price volatility, especially when the oil price trends include upward or downward jumps [10], [6].

It has been shown [12] that oil price increases have been at least partly responsible for every post-World War II US recession except the one in the 1960’s. These basic findings have been tested using alternative data and estimation procedures [11], [2], [19]. In the early 1990s the focus of research was on the role that asymmetric oil price shocks have on the economy [20], [21], [17], [9].

In sharp contrast to the volume of work investigating the link between oil price shocks and macroeconomic variables, there has been relatively little work done on the relationship between oil price shocks and financial markets. Two notable exceptions are [14] and [3].

In [9] quarterly data was used to test whether the reaction of international stock markets to oil shocks could be justified by current and future changes in real cash flows and/or changes in expected returns. Using a standard cash-flow dividend valuation model (see [3]), it was discovered that the reaction of Canadian and US stock prices to oil price shocks can be completely accounted for by the impact of these shocks on real cash flows. The results for Japan and the UK are, however, not as strong.

A Vector Auto Regression (VAR) approach was used in [14] to investigate the relationship between daily oil futures returns and daily US stock returns. It was learned that oil futures returns do lead to some individual oil company stock returns but oil future returns do not have much impact on broad-based market indices like the S&P 500.

Using quarterly data from 1947 to 1991, it was found that oil prices do have an effect on aggregate stock returns [16]. In contrast, daily data from 1979 to 1990 were used and no evidence was found of a relationship between oil futures prices and aggregate stock returns [14].

The dynamic interaction between oil prices and other economic variables were examined in [23] using VAR approach. Results were presented for oil price shocks, asymmetric oil price shocks, oil price volatility shocks and asymmetric oil price volatility shocks. It was found that oil price shocks have asymmetric effects on the economy. In addition, it was found that the dynamics of oil price shocks have changed across time. It was also found that oil price shocks had a significant impact on real stock returns although this impact was stronger after 1986.

The issue of asset pricing, in general, is controversial in relation to equities. The development of alternative multi-factor models, such as the Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT), was a response to the failure of traditional models, such as the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM), to adequately explain cross-sectional variation in equity returns. Within this context, researchers have sought to examine the sensitivity of equity returns to economic factors.

For example, in [1] a two-factor version of the APT, using a market and an oil price change factor was investigated. Based on a sample of 29 NYSE-listed oil companies covering the period 1970–1978, it was found that the oil price risk premium was highly unstable. Specifically, in the period immediately following the OPEC oil price shock of 1973, equity returns of domestic oil producers and large multinationals were associated with a significant ex ante oil risk premia. While this investigation of the asset pricing issue in the context of a small sample of oil companies served the narrow purpose of this study, the question was left open of how pervasive the oil price factor is across all sectors. Similarly, in [16] an APT-type model was used in which fundamental variables were augmented by an oil price change variable.

Sensitivity of Australian industry equity returns to an oil price factor over the period 1983–1996 was investigated in [8] using the two-factor APT model. The followings were the key findings. First, a degree of pervasiveness of an oil price factor, beyond the influence of the market, was detected across some Australian industries. Second, it was proposed and found that significant positive oil price sensitivity existed between the Oil and Gas, and Diversified Resources industries. Similarly, significant negative oil price sensitivity was found in the paper and packaging, and transport industries. Generally, it was found that long-term effects persist, although we hypothesize that some firms have been able to pass on oil price changes to customers or hedge the risk.

More recently, using an error-correcting representation of a VAR macroeconomic model and using a monthly data for Greece for the period January 1989–June 1999, it was concluded that oil prices are important in explaining stock price movements [22].

In [13] the spillover effects, day effects and dynamic relationships among five S&P 500 oil sector stock indices and five oil prices was examined for the U.S. oil markets using daily data for the available period July 17, 1995 to October 10, 2001. It was found that: (1) the oil price systems have common trends, suggesting little potential for long-run portfolio diversification. (2) In the S&P 500 oil sectors stock index system, the five indices are not co-integrated, suggesting no index integration and strong opportunities for gains from diversification. (3) On a daily basis, none of the oil industry stock indices explains the future movements of the NYMEX oil futures prices, while these prices can explain the movements of independent oil companies engaged in exploration, refining, and marketing; confirming the results that the oil exploration companies and refiners take their cues from the oil market. (4) The autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity (ARCH)/GARCH analysis suggests that the oil futures market has a matching resonant or volatility-echoing effect on the stocks of the oil exploration, production, and domestic integrated companies, and a volatility-dampening effect on the stocks of oil international integrated and oil and gas refining and marketing companies. (5) The day effect with oil volatility transmission suggests that Friday has a calming effect on the volatility of the oil stocks. The policy implication is that, at times of oil volatility, traders should choose the trading day and the S&P 500 sectors that match their tolerance for volatility and use the right financial derivative to profit from this volatility.

Although oil price is the considerable factor in international finance, there is no idea what its real effect is and why the financial markets react so slowly to the oil price volatility [10]. There has been little attempt to compare the effect of oil price volatility on both oil producing and oil consuming countries simultaneously, in which the oil price behavior and jump models are considered. This has motivated the researchers to model the co-movement among stock market prices and oil prices within a multi-factor two-country dynamic equilibrium in which oil price jumps are considered. The oil price effects on financial markets can then be explicitly determined. This is the purpose of this paper.

4. Modeling the Two Country World

4.1. Market Is Complete and There are No Jumps

Suppose that the process followed by country i oil output is geometric Brownian motion [18]:

d Yi(t)/ Yi(t) = µi(t).dt +σi(t).dωi(t) (4.1)

where µi(t) and σi(t) >0 are arbitrary adapted processes, Yi is country i oil output and

)

(

t

i

w

is Brownian motion.

Now if there are just two countries in world, one oil producer (i=1) and the other oil consumer (i=2), then the total oil output in the world will be:

å

å

=

=

þ

ý

ü

î

í

ì

+

÷

ø

ö

ç

è

æ

-

=

=

2

1

2

2

1

)

(

2

exp

)

0

(

)

(

)

(

i

i

i

i

i

i

i

i

Total

t

t

Y

t

Y

t

Y

v

s

s

m

(4.2)

This is equal to oil total consumption, and we have

i

i

i

i

i

i

i

i

i

i

i

Total

d

Y

dt

Y

t

dY

Y

d

t

dY

w

s

m

å

å

å

å

=

=

=

=

+

=

=

=

2

1

2

1

2

1

2

1

)

(

)

(

)

(

)

(

(4.3)

It is assumed that oil price is dependent only on

)

(

t

Y

Total

and t, in other words it is dependent only on

1,2

i

,

)

(

=

t

Y

i

and t. Therefore equation (4.4) shows process of the oil price:

i

i

i

d

s

mdt

O

dO

w

å

=

+

=

2

1

(4.4)

Where O is the oil price, m is the expected return from oil,

i

d

w

i=1, 2 are the same as equation (4.1) and

2

,

1

i

,

=

i

i

d

s

w

are the components of the risk of return attributable to Yi,

i =1, 2. Thus it can be shown that

i

i

i

s

r

m

å

=

=

-

2

1

l

(4.5)

where r is risk free interest rate and λi is the market price of risk for Yi.

Assume that the market index uncertainty in each of the consumer and producer countries is separated to oil effects and non-oil effects parameters. Thus we have:

P

P

i

i

i

P

P

P

p

d

S

d

S

dt

M

I

dI

w

w

¢

¢

+

+

=

å

=

2

1

,

C

C

i

i

i

C

C

C

C

d

S

d

S

dt

M

I

dI

w

w

¢

¢

+

+

=

å

=

2

1

,

(

)

0

)

,

(

and

0

,

>

<

O

I

COV

O

I

COV

P

C

(4.6)

where Ip is stock market index of the oil producer country, and similarly IC is stock market index of the oil consumer country, MP and MC are expected returns of indexes,

i

d

w

i=1, 2 are the same as equations (4.1) and (4.4),

2

,

1

i

,

=

i

i

d

S

w

are the components of the risk of return attributable to Yi, i =1, 2 and

C

,

P

k

,

=

¢

¢

K

K

d

S

w

are the components of the risk of return attributable to non-oil effects.

Now consider the portfolio

P

p

¢

which consists of all financial assets Ai i=1, 2,…, m in market index of oil producer country with the same weight as in market index which has the following property:

(

)

0

,

=

O

A

COV

i

(4.7)

Thus the uncertainty of this portfolio just refers to non-oil effects and the process followed by

P

p

¢

is:

P

P

P

d

S

dt

M

d

P

P

w

p

p

p

p

¢

+

=

¢

¢

¢

¢

(4.8)

One can make the portfolio

P

p

risk neutral to non-oil effects by combining

P

S

p

¢

units of IP and -

P

S

¢

units of

P

p

¢

. This portfolio stochastic movement just refers to oil price volatility so that one could analyze the oil effects on stock market of oil producer country. Similarly, by making portfolios

C

p

¢

and

C

p

risk neutral, one can do the same analysis for stock market of consumer country. Note that stochastic movements of portfolios

C

p

and

P

p

must be the same and in opposite directions; in other words,

(

)

1

,

-

=

C

P

Corr

p

p

.

Thus we have criteria and measures (

C

and

p

p

P

) for analyzing oil supply-demand shock effects on stock market returns of each of oil producer and consumer country.

4.2. Market Is Complete and There are Jumps

Sometimes in the real world, because of unpredictable events, oil supply or demand changes are high. Hence it is more accurate to model processes with jumps so that equation (4.1) changes as follows, where dJi’s are jump process which can follows CGMY, VG, NIG and other Levy processes:

d Yi(t)/ Yi(t) = µi(t).dt +σi(t).dωi(t)+

i

a

dJi (4.9)

And world total oil output dynamics is then:

EMBED Equation.3

å

å

å

å

å

=

=

=

=

=

+

+

=

=

=

2

1

2

1

2

1

2

1

2

1

)

(

)

(

)

(

)

(

i

i

i

i

i

i

i

i

i

i

i

i

i

i

Total

dJ

d

Y

dt

Y

t

dY

Y

d

t

dY

a

w

s

m

(4.10)

Again if it is assumed that oil price is dependent only on

)

(

t

Y

Total

and t, then oil price dynamics change to:

å

å

=

=

+

+

=

2

1

,

2

1

i

i

O

i

i

i

i

dJ

d

s

mdt

O

dO

a

w

(4.11)

leading to market index processes as follows:

P

P

i

i

P

i

P

P

i

i

i

P

P

P

p

J

d

dJ

d

S

d

S

dt

M

I

dI

¢

¢

+

+

¢

¢

+

+

=

å

å

=

=

a

a

w

w

2

1

,

2

1

,

C

C

i

i

C

i

C

C

i

i

i

C

C

C

C

J

d

dJ

d

S

d

S

dt

M

I

dI

¢

¢

+

+

¢

¢

+

+

=

å

å

=

=

a

a

w

w

2

1

,

2

1

,

(

)

0

)

,

(

and

0

,

>

<

O

I

COV

O

I

COV

P

C

(4.12)

Where

i

dJ

and

2

,

1

i

,

=

i

i

d

S

w

are the components of the risk of return attributable to Yi, i =1, 2 and,

K

J

d

¢

and

C

,

P

k

,

=

¢

¢

K

K

d

S

w

are the components of the risk of return attributable to non-oil effects.

Now again consider the portfolio

P

p

¢

which consists of all financial assets Ai i=1, 2,…, m in market index of oil producer country with the same weight as in market index which has the property (4.7). This portfolio’s uncertainty just refers to non-oil effects and the process followed by

P

p

¢

is:

P

P

P

P

J

d

d

S

dt

M

d

P

P

P

¢

+

¢

+

=

¢

¢

¢

¢

¢

p

p

p

a

w

p

p

(4.13)

Now if the ratio of Brownian changes in

P

I

and

P

p

¢

is equal to ratio of jumps in

P

I

and

P

p

¢

,

÷

÷

ø

ö

ç

ç

è

æ

¢

=

¢

¢

¢

P

P

P

P

S

S

p

p

a

a

, then we can make the portfolio risk neutral to non-oil effects

P

p

by combining

P

S

p

¢

units of IP and -

P

S

¢

units of

P

p

¢

. Similarly we can make same portfolio

C

p

for consumer country. All the conditions mentioned in section 4.1 for

C

and

p

p

P

are also confirmed here.

5. Conclusion

In recent times, oil price shocks and energy price crises have had a big role in international finance; thus financial analysts should make more sophisticated instruments for modeling these phenomenon. Here we introduced a criterion for measuring and analyzing the impact of oil supply-demand shocks on stock market returns of both oil producer and consumer countries. Possible extensions of this model include extension into a multi-country model, and extension by describing the jumps more clearly and with more details.

Acknowledgements

The authors thank The Department of Mathematical Sciences of Sharif University of technology, and The Department of Industrial Engineering of Amir Kabir University, for their academic and financial support.

References

1. Al-Mudhaf, A., and Goodwin, T. H., Oil shocks and oil stocks: Evidence from the 1970s, Applied Economics, 25(1993), 181–190.

2. Burbidge, J., and Harrison, A., Testing for the effects of oil-price raises using vector auto regressions, International Economy Review, 25(1984), 459-484.

3. Campbell, J.Y., A variance decomposition for stock returns, Economy Journal, 101(1991), 157-179.

4. Carr, P., H., Geman, D., Madan, M., Yor., The fine structure of asset returns: An empirical investigation, Journal of Business, 75(2002), 305-332.

5. Carr, P., and Wu, L., The finite moment log stable process and option pricing, Journal of Finance, 58(2003), 753-777.

6. Driesprong, G., Jacobsen, B., and Maat, B., Striking oil: Another Puzzle? , EFA 2005 Moscow Meetings paper, 2005.

7. Eraker, B., Johannes, M., and Polson, N., The impact of jumps in equity index volatility and returns, Journal of Finance, 58(2003), 1269-1300.

8. Faff, R. W., and Brailsford, T. J., Oil price risk and the Australian stock market, Journal of Energy Finance and Development, 4(1999), 69–87.

9. Ferderer, J., Oil price volatility and the macro economy, Journal of Macro Economy, 18(1996), 1-26.

10. Geman, H., Commodities and Commodity Derivatives: Modeling and Pricing for Agriculturals, Metals and Energy, John Wiley & Sons, 2005.

11. Gisser, M., and Goodwin, T.H., Crude oil and the macro economy: tests of some popular notions. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 18(1986), 95-103.

12. Hamilton, J.D., Oil and the macro economy since World War II., Journal of Political Economy, 92(1983), 228-248.

13. Hammoudeh, S., Dibooglu, S., and Aleisa, E., Relationships among U.S. oil prices and oil industry equity indices, International Review of Economics and Finance, 13(2004), 427–453.

14. Huang, R.D., Masulis, R.W., and Stoll, H.R. Energy shocks and financial markets, Journal of Futures Market, 16(1996), 1-27.

15. Hull, John C., Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, Prentice Hall, Fifth Edition, 2003,

16. Jones, C.M., and Kaul, G., Oil and the stock markets, Journal of Finance 51(1996), 463-491.

17. Lee, K., Ni, S., and Ratti, R.A., Oil shocks and the macro economy: The role of price variability, Energy Journal, 16(1995), 39-56.

18. Lucas, R. E., Interest rates and currency prices in a two-country world, Journal of Monetary Economics, 10 (1982), 335–359.

19. Loungani, P., Oil price shocks and the dispersion hypothesis, Review of Economy Statistics, 68(1986), 536-539.

20. Mork, K.A., Oil and the macro economy when prices go up and down: An extension of Hamilton’s results, Journal of Political Economy 97(1989), 740-744

21. Mork, K.A., Olsen, O., and Mysen, H.T., Macroeconomic responses to oil price increases and decreases in seven OECD countries, Energy Journal, 15(1994), 19-35.

22. Papapetrou, E., Oil price shocks, stock market, economic activity and employment in Greece, Energy Economics, 23(2001), 511–532.

23. Sadorsky, P., Oil price shocks and stock market activity, Journal of Energy Economics, 21(1999), 449-469.

Figure1.Persian Gulf stock indexes and oil price

Figure2.Conceptual system for two-country model

� Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries

� West Texas Intermediate

� In this paper recent fall in Persian Gulf stocks has not been considered.

� Most of these18 countries are oil consumers.

� These models are made by combination of stochastic volatility model, and jump models

� One can ask how increasing oil output could increase oil price. This occurs because in the model it is assumed that world total oil output is equal to world total oil consumption

� For more information about market price of risk, see [15]

PAGE

0

_1192127443.unknown
_1192129784.unknown
_1202464720.unknown
_1202465400.unknown
_1192130967.unknown
_1192131860.unknown
_1192129294.unknown
_1192129319.unknown
_1192128758.unknown
_1192129011.unknown
_1192129039.unknown
_1192128990.unknown
_1192128285.unknown
_1192127666.unknown
_1192128049.unknown
_1191709420.unknown
_1191709507.unknown
_1191920710.unknown
_1191919298.unknown
_1181334347.unknown
_1191706576.unknown
_1191707448.unknown
_1191708678.unknown
_1191709336.unknown
_1181335754.unknown
_1181687147.unknown
_1181335069.unknown
_1181335658.unknown
_1181334370.unknown
_1181329479.unknown
_1181329576.unknown
_1181329714.unknown
_1181329532.unknown
_1181329245.unknown
_1181329266.unknown
_1181329413.unknown
_1180872632.unknown
_1180872703.unknown
_1180870543.unknown