Lecture Notes 7 Exchange Rate Overshooting · PDF file7.7 Dornbusch (1976) ... 4 LECTURE NOTES 7. EXCHANGE RATE OVERSHOOTING run value. This is intended to capture the common-sense

  • Upload
    docong

  • View
    221

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • Lecture Notes 7

    Exchange Rate Overshooting

    International Economics: Finance Professor: Alan G. Isaac

    7 Exchange Rate Overshooting 1

    7.1 Overshooting: Core Considerations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3

    7.1.1 Covered Interest Parity with Regressive Expectations . . . . . . . . . 4

    7.1.2 Liquidity Effects and Overshooting . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8

    7.1.3 The Algebra of Overshooting . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10

    7.2 Implied Real Changes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12

    7.2.1 CIPRE : Real Version . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12

    7.2.2 Liquidity Effects and Non-Neutrality of Money . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15

    7.3 The Long Run In Sticky-Price Models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17

    7.3.1 The Real Interest Differential Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19

    7.4 Money Market Considerations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23

    7.4.1 Overshooting with Sticky Prices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25

    7.5 Simple Empirical Considerations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30

    7.5.1 Can We See the CIPRE Relationship? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30

    1

  • 7.5.2 Forward Rates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 31

    7.5.3 VAR Analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32

    7.6 Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33

    Terms and Concepts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34

    Problems for Review . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34

    7.7 Dornbusch (1976) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35

    7.7.1 Regressive Expectations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35

    7.7.2 Rational Expectations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37

    7.7.3 Unanticipated Policy Shocks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 41

    7.7.4 Anticipated Shocks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 43

    Bibliography 45

  • 2 LECTURE NOTES 7. EXCHANGE RATE OVERSHOOTING

    In chapter 3, our development of the monetary approach to flexible exchange rates relied

    on two key ingredients: the Classical model of price determination, and an exogenous real

    exchange rate. We found that the monetary approach had some notable early empirical

    successes. But we also found that as data accumulated under the new flexible exchange rate

    regimes, the simple monetary approach appeared increasingly unsatisfactory. The present

    chapter considers whether the problem lies in attempting to use the monetary approach

    model, which has a long-run orientation, to describe short-run exchange-rate movements.

    The widespread adoption of floating exchange rates in the early 1970s brought unexpected

    volatility of the nominal exchange rate. The large movements of the nominal exchange rate,

    coupled with the relative inertia of the price level, produced large fluctuations in the real

    exchange rate (and therefore large deviations from purchasing power parity). The monetary

    approach model of chapter 3 treats such real exchange rate movements as exogenous, but it

    is clearly desirable to explain them.

    Increasing the scope of our models seldom comes without costs, and our attempt to

    endogenize the real exchange rate is no exception. The most popular models of short-run

    real-exchange-rate movements abandon the simplifying Classical assumption of perfectly

    flexible prices. These models treat the price level as sticky in the short run. This chapter

    develops such a sticky-price exchange-rate model. We find we must therefore abandon

    two key simplifying assumptions of the monetary approach model: the exogeneity of the

    real interest rate, and the exogeneity of the real exchange rate. Our sticky-price model will

    predict large short-run deviations from purchasing power parity, such as those described in

    chapter 5.

    In sticky-price models, monetary policy influences real interest rates and the real exchange

    rate. When prices are sticky, any change in the nominal money stock becomes a change

    in the real money stock, which will generally imply a change in the interest-rate. Similarly,

    short-run nominal-exchange-rate fluctuations will imply corresponding real exchange rate

    fluctuations. There is an immediate benefit for our exchange rate models: we are no longer

    2015 Alan G. Isaac

  • 7.1. OVERSHOOTING: CORE CONSIDERATIONS 3

    forced to treat persistent deviations from purchasing power parity, such as those we discussed

    in chapter 5, as purely exogenous. Instead our explanation short-run nominal-exchange-rate

    movements becomes an explanation of short-run real-exchange-rate movements. Sticky-price

    models also offer new insights into the sources of exchange-rate volatility. In particular, they

    offer an explanation of why exchange rates may be much more volatile than monetary policy.

    7.1 Overshooting: Core Considerations

    Suppose an economy is disturbed by an unanticipated exogenous change, which we call a

    shock . This might be a change in monetary or fiscal policy, but it need not be policy

    related. We say the endogenous variable exhibits overshooting in response to this shock if

    its short-run movement exceeds the change in its steady-state value.

    For example, given the long-run neutrality of money, a one-time, permanent increase in

    the money supply will eventually lead to a proportional depreciation of the steady-state value

    of the currency. If the short-run depreciation is more than proportional, then the short-run

    depreciation of the spot rate is greater than the depreciation of its steady-state value. We say

    such an economy exhibits exchange-rate overshooting in response to money-supply shocks.

    Popular models of such exchange rate overshooting have three key ingredients: covered

    interest parity, regressive expectations, and a liquidity effect of money supply changes. You

    are already familiar with the covered interest parity relationship: it is just the requirement

    that domestic assets bear the same rate of return as fully hedged foreign assets. This means

    that i = i + fd . If we decompose the forward discount on the domestic currency into

    expected depreciation and a risk premium, then we can write this as i = i + se + rp.

    Once again we see that we must deal with exchange-rate expectations if we wish to

    discuss the determination of exchange rates. Instead of the rational-expectations assumption,

    this chapter will adopt the slightly more general regressive-expectations assumption.

    Expectations are regressive when the exchange rate is expected to move toward its long-

    2015 Alan G. Isaac

  • 4 LECTURE NOTES 7. EXCHANGE RATE OVERSHOOTING

    run value. This is intended to capture the common-sense idea that if you think that the

    exchange rate is currently overvalued, then you also expect it to depreciate toward its long-

    run value.

    The final key ingredient is that monetary policy has a liquidity effect in the short run.

    This means, for example, that expansionary monetary policy lowers the real interest rate

    in the short run. These three ingredientscovered interest parity, regressive expectations,

    and short-run liquidity effectscan be combined to illustrate why the exchange rate may

    overshoot in response to monetary policy changes.

    7.1.1 Covered Interest Parity with Regressive Expectations

    The first ingredient in our exchange-rate overshooting models is covered interest parity. In

    chapter 2 we saw that covered interest parity is implied by perfect capital mobility in the

    assets markets. Recall that covered interest parity is just the requirement of equivalent

    returns on equivalent assets. This is the first core ingredient of overshooting models.

    i i rp = se (7.1)

    Here i is the domestic nominal interest rate, i is the foreign interest rate, rp is the expected

    excess return on the domestic asset, and se is the expected rate of depreciation of the

    spot exchange rate. Note the presence of the expected rate of depreciation. As with the

    simple monetary approach model, this makes consideration of exchange rate expectations

    unavoidable. Holding all else constant, covered interest parity implies that the domestic

    interest rate must be higher when expected depreciation is higher. This implied positive

    correlation between interest rates and expected depreciation is summarized in figure 7.1.

    The second ingredient in our exchange-rate overshooting models is regressive expectations.

    Expectations formation is called regressive when a variable is expected to close any gap

    between its current level and its long-run equilibrium level. So if exchange-rate expectations

    2015 Alan G. Isaac

  • 7.1. OVERSHOOTING: CORE CONSIDERATIONS 5

    se

    i

    0

    i + rp

    CIP

    Figure 7.1: Covered Interest Parity

    are regressive, a spot rate that is above its long-run equilibrium level is expected to fall

    towards that level. The expected rate of real depreciation depends on the gap between the

    current exchange rate and its long-run equilibrium level.1

    se = (S/S) (7.2)

    Here S is the full-equilibrium value of the spot rate, which we will discuss more below. The

    function determines the expected speed of adjustment of the real exchange rat