20
Firm-Specific Assets and the Link Between Exchange Rates and Foreign Direct Investment By BRUCE A. BLONIGEN* Foreign direct investment (FDI) theory and empirical studies have generated mixed support for a link between exchange rates and FDI. This paper argues that exchange rate movements may affect acquisition FDI because acquisitions involve firm-specific assets which can generate retums in currencies other than that used for purchase. Using data on Japanese acquisitions in the United States across 3-digit SIC industries from 1975-1992, maximum-likelihood estimates from discrete dependent variable models support the hypothesis that real dollar depreciations make Japanese acquisitions more likely in U.S. industries, partic- ularly those which more likely have firm-specific assets. (JEL F21, F23, F31) Foreign direct investment flows from other industrialized countries into the United States in the last two decades have been marked by substantial swings, most notably in FDI via acquisitions of U.S. firms. While traditional theories concerning FDI may explain the in- creasing investment flows into the United States in the long run, they offer little expla- nation for short-run movements in FDI. Until the late 197O's, trade theorists and others were content to write off FDI as mainly a phenom- enon of comparative costs, specifically arising where trade did not equalize factor prices. This theory came out of a world where the majority of multinational firms were from the United States and a significant share of their invest- ment was into less developed countries with significantly lower costs. However, the large share of FDI between only industrialized countries turned attention to another theory: internalization. Based on transactions cost lit- erature, this theory predicts FDI will occur where there are high transactions costs in- * Department of Economics, 1285 University of Oregon, Eugene, OR 97403. The author thanks George Bittlingmayer, Severin Borenstein, Robert Feinberg, Stephen Haynes, Peter Lindert, Joe Stone, Deborah Swenson, two anonymous referees, and especially Robert Feenstra for valuable comments and discussion. The paper also benefitted from seminars at the University of Oregon, the University of Virginia, Georgia Institute of Technol- ogy, the University of Califomia-Davis, and the U.S, In- temational Trade Commission, All errors or omissions are the responsibility of the author. volved in exporting or licensing a product to another country. In these cases, the firm may choose to internalize the transaction and set up operations in the other country. However, the experience of the United States in the 198O's and 199O's presents a dif- ficult question for theories of comparative costs and internalization. Figure 1, panel A, shows the number of U.S. acquisitions by all foreign countries and the multilateral ex- change rate, while panel B presents Japanese acquisitions in the United States and the dollar-yen real exchange rate, which are the focus of this paper's empirical work.' Both panels show substantial short-run swings in U.S. inward acquisition FDI and beg the question whether these swings could be the manifestation of corresponding changes in comparative costs and/or transactions costs between the United States and other industri- alized countries. For example, how can these traditional theories explain why foreign ac- quisitions can double in one year? It seems unlikely that comparative costs between the United States and foreign countries fell enough or transactions costs of exporting or licensing to the United States rose enough to account for this. Given the inefficacy of traditional and gen- eral theories to answer these questions, a ' While Figure 1 graphs numbers of foreign acquisi- tions, aggregate dollar values of acquisition FDI from all foreign countries and from Japan follow a similar pattern. 447

Firm-Specific Assets and the Link Between Exchange Rates and Foreign Direct Investmentpages.uoregon.edu/bruceb/Firm_Specific_Assets.pdf · 2015. 5. 6. · By BRUCE A. BLONIGEN* Foreign

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    1

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Firm-Specific Assets and the Link Between Exchange Rates and Foreign Direct Investmentpages.uoregon.edu/bruceb/Firm_Specific_Assets.pdf · 2015. 5. 6. · By BRUCE A. BLONIGEN* Foreign

Firm-Specific Assets and the Link Between Exchange Ratesand Foreign Direct Investment

By BRUCE A. BLONIGEN*

Foreign direct investment (FDI) theory and empirical studies have generatedmixed support for a link between exchange rates and FDI. This paper arguesthat exchange rate movements may affect acquisition FDI because acquisitionsinvolve firm-specific assets which can generate retums in currencies other thanthat used for purchase. Using data on Japanese acquisitions in the United Statesacross 3-digit SIC industries from 1975-1992, maximum-likelihood estimatesfrom discrete dependent variable models support the hypothesis that real dollardepreciations make Japanese acquisitions more likely in U.S. industries, partic-ularly those which more likely have firm-specific assets. (JEL F21, F23, F31)

Foreign direct investment flows from otherindustrialized countries into the United Statesin the last two decades have been marked bysubstantial swings, most notably in FDI viaacquisitions of U.S. firms. While traditionaltheories concerning FDI may explain the in-creasing investment flows into the UnitedStates in the long run, they offer little expla-nation for short-run movements in FDI. Untilthe late 197O's, trade theorists and others werecontent to write off FDI as mainly a phenom-enon of comparative costs, specifically arisingwhere trade did not equalize factor prices. Thistheory came out of a world where the majorityof multinational firms were from the UnitedStates and a significant share of their invest-ment was into less developed countries withsignificantly lower costs. However, the largeshare of FDI between only industrializedcountries turned attention to another theory:internalization. Based on transactions cost lit-erature, this theory predicts FDI will occurwhere there are high transactions costs in-

* Department of Economics, 1285 University ofOregon, Eugene, OR 97403. The author thanks GeorgeBittlingmayer, Severin Borenstein, Robert Feinberg,Stephen Haynes, Peter Lindert, Joe Stone, DeborahSwenson, two anonymous referees, and especially RobertFeenstra for valuable comments and discussion. The paperalso benefitted from seminars at the University of Oregon,the University of Virginia, Georgia Institute of Technol-ogy, the University of Califomia-Davis, and the U.S, In-temational Trade Commission, All errors or omissions arethe responsibility of the author.

volved in exporting or licensing a product toanother country. In these cases, the firm maychoose to internalize the transaction and set upoperations in the other country.

However, the experience of the UnitedStates in the 198O's and 199O's presents a dif-ficult question for theories of comparativecosts and internalization. Figure 1, panel A,shows the number of U.S. acquisitions by allforeign countries and the multilateral ex-change rate, while panel B presents Japaneseacquisitions in the United States and thedollar-yen real exchange rate, which are thefocus of this paper's empirical work.' Bothpanels show substantial short-run swings inU.S. inward acquisition FDI and beg thequestion whether these swings could be themanifestation of corresponding changes incomparative costs and/or transactions costsbetween the United States and other industri-alized countries. For example, how can thesetraditional theories explain why foreign ac-quisitions can double in one year? It seemsunlikely that comparative costs between theUnited States and foreign countries fellenough or transactions costs of exporting orlicensing to the United States rose enough toaccount for this.

Given the inefficacy of traditional and gen-eral theories to answer these questions, a

' While Figure 1 graphs numbers of foreign acquisi-tions, aggregate dollar values of acquisition FDI from allforeign countries and from Japan follow a similar pattern.

447

Page 2: Firm-Specific Assets and the Link Between Exchange Rates and Foreign Direct Investmentpages.uoregon.edu/bruceb/Firm_Specific_Assets.pdf · 2015. 5. 6. · By BRUCE A. BLONIGEN* Foreign

448 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW JUNE 1997

Numbar of•cqulaltlon*

Panel A: Acquisition FDIin the United States

Real exchangerala index1980=100

Panel B: Japanese Acquisitionin the United States

i exchange

1975 1876

FIGURE 1. NUMBERS OF ACQIHSITIONS IN THt UNITED STATES BY ALL FOREIG.N OJUNTRIKS AND BY JAPAN, 1975-1992

Notes; The multilateral real exchange rate is a trade-weighted index of foreign currencies to the dollar. The dollar-yenreal exchange rate was constructed using the nominal exchange rate and consumer price indexes.Sources; Numbers of acquisitions were tabulated from U.S, Department of Commerce, Intemational Trade Administration,Foreign Direct Investment in the United State.^: Transactions. The multilateral real exchange rate, the nominal dollar-yen exchange rate and U.S. consumer price index come from the Economic Report of the President, 1995, while theJapanese consumer price index comes from the Japan Statistical Yearbook, various issues.

number of recent papers have turned toexchange rate movements for an empiricalexplanation. While Figure 1 suggests theexchange rate levels may have substantial ex-planatory power for FDI flows, empiricalstudies have had only limited success estab-lishing this connection.^ This may not be sur-prising since the traditional view is thatexchange rate levels should not affect invest-ment incentives. Specifically, if exchangerates are a random walk and an asset's pur-chase price and retum on an asset (such as abond) are in the same currency, the relativevaluation of domestic versus foreign firms foran asset will remain unchanged.

This paper presents a new hypothesis whichcomes from the observation that firm-specificassets do not fit this standard analysis. If for-eign and domestic firms have equal opportu-

^ Kenneth A. Froot and Jeremy C, Stein (1991) providea theoretical connection between exchange rates and FDI,which will be discussed below. Many empirical studies ofFDI into the United States have included the exchange rateas a regressor, with mixed results. These studies includeRichard E. Caves (1989), Edward J, Ray (1989), Frootand Stein (1991), Steven Martin (1991), Guy V. G.Stevens (1992), and Deborah L, Swenson (1994).

nity to purchase firm-specific assets in thedomestic market, but different opportunities togenerate retums on these assets in foreign mar-kets, then ctirrency movements may affect rel-ative valuations. While both firms pay in thesame currency, unlike bond-like assets theymay generate retums in different currencies.In the case where the domestic firm does nothave equal access to the foreign market, thisasymmetry means that the relative level of for-eign firm acquisitions of these assets may beaffected by exchange rate movements. As asimple example to illustrate this, suppose thereare two prospective acquiring firms of a U.S.target firm: a Japanese firm and a U.S. firm.The markets are completely segmented, so thatboth firms have production and sales solely intheir own country. A U.S. target firm has aninnovation (a firm-specific asset) which willmake an acquiring firm's assembly line 10-percent more productive (i.e., it gets 10-percent more output for the same level of in-puts). For the U.S. acquiring firm, achange inthe exchange rate makes no difference in itsvaluation of the target firm, since its gains willbe denominated in dollars, as will be the priceit must pay for the target firm. However, theJapanese firm's gains will be denominated inyen, since its production and sales are in Japan,

Page 3: Firm-Specific Assets and the Link Between Exchange Rates and Foreign Direct Investmentpages.uoregon.edu/bruceb/Firm_Specific_Assets.pdf · 2015. 5. 6. · By BRUCE A. BLONIGEN* Foreign

VOL. 87 NO. 3 BLONIGEN: FIRM-SPECIFIC ASSETS 449

wbile if it wins tbe bid it must pay for thetarget firm in dollars. Therefore, a depreciationof the dollar relative to the yen will raise theJapanese firm's reservation bid, while leavingthe U.S. firm's bid unchanged, and presum-ably make it more likely that the Japanese firmwill acquire the asset.

The next section quickly reviews the liter-ature on possible links between exchange ratemovements and FDI. The second section de-tails this paper's idea more formally. It pres-ents a stylized model which shows why it isplausible that real dollar depreciations in-crease acquisitions involving firm-specificassets by foreign firms. Next, an empiri-cal section tests the relationship betweenexchange rate movements and acquisitionFDI predicted by the model using a paneldata set of Japanese acquisitions across 3-digit Standard Industrial Classification (SIC)industries in the United States from 1975through 1992. Because this paper's model istoo stylized to generate a complete empiricalspecification for Japanese acquisition pattemsin the United States, other traditional deter-minants of acquisition FDI are included in theregressions in addition to the exchange rate.Controlling for these other determinants, it isfound that real depreciations of the dollar tothe yen lead to substantial increases in acqui-sition FDI in industries that more likely havefirm-specific assets, while no such relation-ship is found in Japanese acquisition activityin other U.S. industries. In addition, there isno similar differential exchange rate effectacross industries with respect to Japanesenew plant FDI. Some evidence is found for asimilar exchange rate effect on West Germanacquisition.s in the United States as well.These resuUs suggest an explanation for whyprevious empirical studies of the effect ofexchange rate movements on overall FDIflows have been largely inconclusive.

I. A Link Between Exchange RateMovements and FDI?

One potential explanation for short-run fluc-tuations in FDI flows is movements in theexchange rate. Casual empiricism of exchangerate movements of the dollar in the 198O's re-veals possible correlation between a depreci-ating dollar and boom periods of FDl into the

United States, especially acquisition FDI. Theobservation that acquisition FDI may be cor-related with exchange rate movements tendsto support a "common wisdom" belief thatforeign firms are able to purchase U.S. assetsand technology "cheaply" when the dollar isweak. In addition, a number of empirical stud-ies, including Caves (1989), Froot and Stein(1991), Swenson (1994), and Michael W.Klein and Eric S. Rosengren (1994), havefound correlation between dollar depreciationsand increased FDI in the United States. Otherstudies have found little support for exchangerate movements on FDI, including Ray(1989), Stevens (1992), and Paul M. Healyand Krishna G. Palepu (1993). However, withthe exception of Froot and Stein (1991) dis-cussed below, no one has offered an explana-tion for why a weak dollar would be correlatedunambiguously with increases in inward FDI.At the same time, most economists have re-jected any link between exchange rates andFDI flows for a seemingly good reason. Themain argument is that the price of U.S. assetsshould not matter, only their rate of return \when the dollar depreciates relative to anothercountry's currency, not only the price, but thenominal retum of the U.S. asset in the foreigncurrency, will go down. Thus, as RachelMcCulloch (1989 p. 188) states, the tradi-tional theory maintains that:

If a U.S. asset is seen as a claim to afuture stream of dollar-denominatedprofits, and if profits will be convertedback into the domestic currency of theinvestor at the same exchange rate, thelevel of the exchange rate does not affectthe present discounted value of theinvestment.

McCulloch goes on to note that this argu-ment must be modified if a U.S. asset engagesin export or import activities, but because ex-porting and importing activities lead to oppos-ing exchange rate exposure, the effect ofexchange rates on the value of U.S. assets isambiguous. Froot and Stein (1991), however,present an unambiguous connection betweenexchange rate levels and FDI when capitalmarkets are imperfect. Specifically, Froot andStein analyze a financial environment wherelenders do not have perfect information and

Page 4: Firm-Specific Assets and the Link Between Exchange Rates and Foreign Direct Investmentpages.uoregon.edu/bruceb/Firm_Specific_Assets.pdf · 2015. 5. 6. · By BRUCE A. BLONIGEN* Foreign

450 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW JUNE 1997

thus charge a premium for monitoring costs.In this environment, firms which have moreassets in an appreciating currency and expe-rience relative wealth gains can finance moreof an investment internally, and avoid thepremium-laden external financing.

Froot and Stein (1991) provide an importantfirst step in linking exchange rate movementsto FDI flows, but still leave some important is-sues unresolved. First, while their wealth effectneed not distinguish the effect of exchange ratemovements on different types of FDI, their em-pirical findings present evidence that variousforms of FDI respond differently to theexchange rate changes. Second, it may be em-pirically difficult to distinguish relative wealthgains from currency movements compared toother factors affecting firm wealth. For exam-ple, with respect to Japanese FDI in the UnitedStates, did Japanese firms experience largerwealth gains in the late 198O's from exchangerate movements or from the speculative bubblein the Japanese stock market and real estatemarkets?

This paper presents perhaps an even moreapparent flaw in the argument against any linkbetween exchange rates and FDI: the tradi-tional argument implicitly assumes that the as-sets connected with FDI are similar to bondsor other assets for which the price and nominalretum are in the same currency, regardless ofthe investor. This need not be the case withrespect to acquisition FDI, because the assetsof a target firm can often be in the form offirm-specific assets, which can generate re-tums simultaneously in a variety of marketsand currencies, without involving any foreigncurrency transactions.^ The next section de-tails how this may lead to an unambiguous re-lationsbip between exchange rates andacquisition FDI.

'Elhanan Helpman (1984), James R, Markusen(1984), and Ignatius J. Horstmann and Markusen (1989)are examples of papers that have used the unique propertyof firm-specific assets to be essentially costlessly trans-ferrable across a firm's various operations to derive inter-esting economic conclusions in the analysis of FDi. Thecentral idea of this paper goes one step further, by notingthat transfer of intangible assets across intemational bor-ders need not involve currency transactions.

II. A Model of Foreign Demand for Firm-Specific Assets via Acquisitions

This section provides a simple stylized ex-ample involving a representative foreign firmand U.S. firm bidding for a U.S. target firmwith firm-specific assets to show how realexchange rate depreciations of the dollar canplausibly increase foreign acquisitions of thesetarget firms. For the sake of intuitive clarity,the example is not a fully specified model inmany ways, but the discussion identifies im-portant conditions which are necessary for theproposed relationship to hold, including devi-ations from the law of one price (LOP) andsome degree of market segmentation.

To begin, I assume that each firm has pro-duction and sales solely in its own country, andI focus on the foreign firm. Assume the objectiveof a representative foreign firm is to maximizeprofit subject to available technology:

(1) Max Ilf =

(2) yr

subject to

where 11̂ ^ is the foreign firm's restricted profit(ignoring payment to fixed factors), yp is firmoutput, \F and Z are vectors of variable andfixed inputs, respectively, and p * and w* arethe exogenous output price and vector of ex-ogenous variable input prices in the foreigncurrency, respectively. TTie foreign firm cansolve this problem by first choosing variableinputs, X/r, to minimize costs subject to the pro-duction constraint in equation (2) and thenchoosing yp to maximize

(3)

where C(yF; w*, Z ) is the minimum cost fora chosen y^. The vector, Z, includes such fixedinputs as various forms of capital, includingfirm-specific assets. Given an initial Z, Z",output price, and variable input prices, the for-eign firm will solve equation (3) to obtain itsrestricted profit Ii;^ = \\F(P*, W*, Z " ) , whereII" is homogeneous of degree one in (/>*, w*)and valued in the foreign currency.

Now suppose that the foreign firm has theopportunity to obtain a firm-specific asset viaan acquisition of a U.S. target firm. Acquisi-tion of the firm (and hence, the asset) would

Page 5: Firm-Specific Assets and the Link Between Exchange Rates and Foreign Direct Investmentpages.uoregon.edu/bruceb/Firm_Specific_Assets.pdf · 2015. 5. 6. · By BRUCE A. BLONIGEN* Foreign

VOL 87 NO. 3 BLONIGEN FIRM-SPECIFIC ASSETS 451

increase the firm's stock of fixed capital fromZ" to Z ' , such that F(x,r, Z ' ) > F{XF, Z " )for all values of X/r. Profit-maximizing behav-ior means Iljr = \\F{P*, W*, Z ' ) > Ihip*,w*, Z") = 11^ Define the difference AII^ =III - Ilf- > 0. Because it is linear in Iljr andII", Allf̂ has similar properties to Ilf, includ-ing homogeneity of degree one in (p*, w*)and valuation in the foreign currency. Let edenote the bilateral exchange rate between theUnited States and the foreign country ex-pressed in dollars per foreign currency, Rf de-note the foreign firm's reservation price indollars, and p the rate of retum the firm wouldreceive by investing the funds in a relatively"safe" investment over a similar time period.The foreign firm's reservation price in dollarscan be expressed as

I* '

(4)

For ease of comparison, assume that the U.S.bidding firm has the same production technol-ogy and an identical fixed capital stock as theforeign firm. However, the U.S. firm maxi-mizes in dollars and faces a vector of dollar-denominated prices, (p, w). Similar to theforeign firm's problem, the U.S. firm's reser-vation bid in dollars is

(5)

-P

\+p

Equations (4) and (5) show that a permanentdollar depreciation {e increases) raises theforeign firm's reservation price relative to theU.S. firm's reservation price, ceteris paribus.However, LOP implies that prices acrosscountries will adjust to offset nominalexchange rate changes. In the context of thismodel, this means that the foreign firm mustexpect to realize a return before LOP-relatedprice movements completely offset the nomi-nal exchange rate change."* This may not be

•* For ease of analysis, I do not model expectations for-mally, but clearly the likelihood of observing changes in

a restrictive condition, since the empiricalevidence shows that LOP is a long-run phe-nomenon at best.^ Thus, a depreciation(appreciation) of the industry-specific realexchange rate will increase (decrease) the for-eign firm's dollar-denominated reservation bidfor the U.S. firm-specific assets relative to theU.S. firm's reservation bid, provided the realexchange rate does not adjust to its originallevel before the foreign firm realizes a retum.

The direct implication is that real dollar de-preciations lead to a greater likelihood of for-eign acquisition of the U.S. asset, ceterisparibus. The exchange rate effect on the for-eign firm's retum from an acquisition occursbecause the firm-specific assets accompanyingthe acquisition yield a nominal retum in theforeign currency [All,, in equation (3) or(4) ] , yet do not involve a currency transac-tion, as does the initial purchase of the asset(R/e). Seen in another way, firm-specificassets are not location-specific like other assetssuch as bonds. With bonds, the price and cou-pon retum are denominated necessarily in thesame currency. However, acquisition assetsare not location-speeific in the sense that theprice is in one currency, but the nominal retumnfay occur in a variety of currencies. However,the investors in this model may be location-specific (unlike the bond example), becausein order to generate a retum in a certain cur-rency, the investor must have access to thatmarket.

This last point is an important one. Theabove analysis suggests that any investor thatsells in the foreign market (i.e., faces foreignprices) may benefit from the acquisition ofU.S. firm-specific assets. It is easy to show thata U.S. multinational firm that had productionand sales in the foreign country similar to the

relative reservation prices from exchange rate changes de-pends on firms' expectations and risk preferences. It is notclear what foreign firms' expectations involving LOP cor-rections would be, but the sooner they expect a correctionto occur, the less their reservation price changes relativeto the U,S, firm, ceteris paribus. In addition, the more riskadverse the foreign firm, the less its expected profit and,hence, reservation price changes as well, (See David O,Cushman, 1985,)

' For empirical evidence on LOP, see Pier G, Ardeni(1989), Bany K. Goodwin et al. (1990). and Michael M.Knetter (1994). For related evidence on purchasing powerparity, see Mark F, Taylor (1995),

Page 6: Firm-Specific Assets and the Link Between Exchange Rates and Foreign Direct Investmentpages.uoregon.edu/bruceb/Firm_Specific_Assets.pdf · 2015. 5. 6. · By BRUCE A. BLONIGEN* Foreign

452 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW JUNE 1997

foreign firm would experiettce a similar in-crease in its reservation bid for a dollar depre-ciatioti, m which case a real dollar depreciationwould not tiecessarily increase the likelihoodof foreign acquisition. However, if there issome degree of market segmentation to the ex-tent that access to the foreign market is limitedfor the U.S. firm relative to the foreign firm,then exchange rate movements can affect thelikelihood of foreign acquisition.*"

The importance of a goods market imperfec-tion for this paper's hypothesis contrasts withFroot and Stein {1991), who find that capitalmarket imperfections can lead to a link betweenexchange rate movements and FDI. An addi-tional difference, however, is that while theFroot and Stein effect is applicable to poten-tially many forms of FDI, this paper's hypoth-esis concems only acquisition FDI that involvesfirm-specific assets. Acquisitions comprise alarge portion of FDI activity for the UnitedStates and many of these acquisitions may haveincluded firm-specific assets, since a wide va-riety of assets have firm-specific properties,including process technology, product innova-tion, and managerial skills.^

m. Empirical Test: Japanese Acquisitionsin the United States

To test the theory linking exchange rates toforeign acquisitions, I focus primarily on Jap-anese acquisitions in the United States from1975 to 1992. This paper's hypothesis relies ona couple of important conditions that are par-ticularly applicable to the Japanese-U.S. inter-national market structure. First, the linkbetween acquisition FDI and exchange ratemovements relies on some degree of marketsegmentation, in the sense that domestic firmshave litnited access to the foreign market rela-

*" One way to show this in the above model is to imposea quantitative restriction on the U.S. firm's sales to theforeign market at the level before the acquisition. In thiscase it is easy to show that exchange rate movementswould have no effect on the U.S. firm's reservation bid,despite presence in the foreign market. Proof is availablefrom author on request.

' Klein and Rosengren (1994) found that acquisitionsas a percent of all FDI inflows into the United Statesranged from 60 to 89 percent from 1979-1991 —see theirTable 2. p. 377.

tive to the foreign firm. In this respect, a num-ber of papers (see BelaBalassa [1986]; RobertZ. Lawrence [1991, 1993]; Dennis J.Encamation [1992]; Marcus Noland [1997])have demonstrated that the Japanese market hasbeen particularly insulated from foreign importpenetration and FDI, which has given Japanesefirms a larger presence in their own market rel-ative to foreign firms than perhaps any otherindustrialized country in the world. While therehas been an intense debate over whether thelow levels of foreign investment and tradeare due to artificial barriers (see Gary R.Saxonhouse, 1986; Saxonhouse and Robert M.Stem, 1989), all agree that the levels are low.Second, a link between acquisifion FDI andexchange rates depends on the condition thatacquisitions involve firm-specific assets. In thisregard, there is evidence that Japanese acqui-sition FDI into the United States is strongly mo-tivated by the intent to access technology andother firm-specific assets. A number of empir-ical studies, including Bruce Kogut and Sea JinChang (1991) and Hideki Yamawaki (1993),have found evidence that Japanese U.S. acqui-sitions are motivated by the desire to accesstechnology. In this sense, the literature has in-dicated that the Japanese are interested intechnology-related, firm-specific assets, whichsuggests high research and development(R&D) manufacturing industries as an area thatshould be more likely to support my hypothesisin the case of the Japanese investors. Finally,Knetter (1994) gives evidence that LOP doesnot hold well with respect to Japan, which makesit more likely that Japanese firms will have ade-quate time to reahze a retum from a U.S. ac-quisition after a real exchange rate change.

While the model presented above is too styl-ized to suggest a full empirical specificafion,it suggests that given certain conditions, theprobability of a foreign firm acquiring a U.S.target firm is a function of the reservationprices in equations {4) and (5), which implies

(6) Prob(foreign acquisition) =/(RER;,),+

where RER,, = e,p*/p,,, is the real exchangerate for bidding firms in industry ( in year f .**

** Specification of a nominal exchange rate (conditionalon industry prices) yielded almost identical results as a

Page 7: Firm-Specific Assets and the Link Between Exchange Rates and Foreign Direct Investmentpages.uoregon.edu/bruceb/Firm_Specific_Assets.pdf · 2015. 5. 6. · By BRUCE A. BLONIGEN* Foreign

VOL. H7 NO. 3 BLONIGEN: FIRM-SPECIFIC ASSETS 453

If firm-specific assets are involved with eachobserved acquisition, then both reservationprices will be nonzero and an assumption ofnegligible U.S. access to the Japanese marketallows an unambiguous expected sign on thereal exchange rate variable. To the extent thatU.S. firms have significant market presence inJapan or acquisitions do not involve firm-specific assets, it is less likely that coefficientsigns will be correct and/or have statisticalsignificance.

Modifications of equation (6) are necessaryto make the testing equation appropriate foravailable data. While equation (6) specifiesthe probability of foreign acquisition at thefirm level, typical sources of FDI data reportat very aggregated levels.' This paper usesdata published by the Intemational Trade Ad-ministration (ITA) of the U.S. Department ofCommerce in its annual publication. ForeignDirect Investment in the United States: Trans-actions. This ITA publication contains a com-piled list of FDI transactions reported in publicsources during the year, including the type ofinvestment, the foreign investor and country,and the industry ofthe U.S. investment. How-ever, since dollar values of FDI, including ac-quisitions, are not necessarily a matter ofpublic record, dollar values for acquisitionsare missing for over one-third of the obser-vations. Therefore, I specify the dependentvariable as the number of Japanese acquisi-tions into the United States in 3-digit SIC in-dustry (• in year r (where t = 1975-1992). Inorder to correspond to these data considera-tions, equation (6) is modified to yield the fol-lowing testing specification:

(7) Prob (number of foreign acquisition)

real exchange rate specification in all regressions, and iike-lihood ratio tests indicated that the restriction.s implied byconstructing a real cxehange rate were appropriate. Sta-tionarity issues, however, argue for using the realexchange rate, since it more likely tends to a long-rynequilibrium.

' The most wideiy known source of FDI data, the an-nual article in the U.S. Department of Commerce's ^Mrvcyof Current Business (SCB), reports dollar values on onlyvery aggregate FDI flows to avoid revealing dollar valuesthat can be traced to specific firms and transactions. Inaddition, ihe SCB articles do not separately list acquisitionFD! from other forms of FDi by industry.

where RER,, represents the industry-specificreal exchange rate, and IH,, and *„ representcharacteristics of industry (' in year / that con-trol for the U.S. supply of, and foreign demandfor, U.S. target firms available for acquisition,respectively. While equation (6) specifies theprobability that a foreign firm will purchase aU.S. target firm, equation (7) indicates theprobability that the number of total foreign ac-quisitions in an industry will take some non-negative integer value. A common way tospecify this type of discrete probability func-tion is as a Poisson or negative binomialmodel. These specifications model the integerproperty of the dependent variable explicitlyand include " 0 " ohservations as natural out-comes. Initial estimates are with maximum-likelihood estimates from a standard negativebinomial specification. However, a major con-cern is that a standard negative binomialmodel does not take into account the panel na-ture of the data used here. Accounting for het-erogeneity can be very important in panelmodels, since controlling for it can reduce asignificant amount of apparent serial correla-tion. In a linear, least-squares context, fixedeffects and random effects models are oftenemployed to address these concerns. JerryHausman et al. (1984) derive negative bino-mial models which account for cross-sectionalvariation in a manner analogous to the fixedand random effects models in the linear con-text, and I use the random effects specification(random NEGBIN) in results reported be-low.'" The Appendix provides a brief descrip-tion of the Hausman et al. (1984) randomeffects negative binomial model used forestimation.

'" Hausman et al. (1984) point out that their randomeffeets negative binomial model achieves asymptoticallymore efficient estimators than their fixed effects model.However, if the industry-specific effects are correlatedwith the regressors, the random effects' estimates are notnecessarily consistent, A Hausman test indicated that therandom effects model estimates are consistent for thesedata, and thus 1 report only the more efficient random ef-fects model estimates.

Page 8: Firm-Specific Assets and the Link Between Exchange Rates and Foreign Direct Investmentpages.uoregon.edu/bruceb/Firm_Specific_Assets.pdf · 2015. 5. 6. · By BRUCE A. BLONIGEN* Foreign

454 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW JUNE 1997

TABLE 1—NUMBER OF JAPANESE ACOUISITIONS IN THE UNITED STATES, 1975-1992

Year

1975

1976

1977

1978

1979

1980

1981

1982

1983

1984

1985

1986

1987

1988

1989

1990

1991

1992

Total

to

1

4

7

5

14

23

13

9

29

33

63

95

101

151

156

107

39

Numtjer of Japanese acquisitions in the United States'

Nonmanufacturing

5

0

I

3

4

8

6

5

2

11

14

27

36

35

77

89

58

19

Total

5

I

3

4

1

6

17

8

7

18

19

36

59

66

74

67

49

20

Manufacturing

High R&D Low R&D

3

0

I

4

0

4

9

3

4

7

10

24

38

37

50

45

35

16

2

1

2

0

1

2

8

5

3

11

9

12

21

29

24

22

14

4

rvtalexchange

rate"

84.7

87.7

95.8

121.8

108.7

100.0

97.6

83.7

86.6

84.6

118.0

135.7

147,9

132.8

123.3

129,9

136.7

154,0

Source: Same as Figure 1." Nonmanufacturing industries are Standard Industrial Classification (SIC)Ol 1 -179 and

401 -899; manufacturing industries are SIC 200-399; high R&D manufacturing industriesare industries that are at or above the meati in terms of R&D expenditures as a percent ofsales in 1991 (National Science Foundation) and comprise SIC 281-289. 351-359, 365-367, 371-372, 376, and 381-389; low R&D industries are alt other manufacturingindustries.

'' The real exchange rate of the dollar and yen using the nominal exchange rate andconsumer price indexes with base year 1980 = 100.

A. Data separate totals for manufacturing and nonman-ufacturing. It also breaks down manufacturing

My dependent variable is taken from the ITA totals into industries with high R&D expendi-publication mentioned above. Table I lists tbe tures and tbose witb low R&D, as well as re-number of annual Japanese acquisitions in the ports an economywide real excbange rateUnited States from 1975 to 1992, including between tbe dollar and yen. Tbese data are

Page 9: Firm-Specific Assets and the Link Between Exchange Rates and Foreign Direct Investmentpages.uoregon.edu/bruceb/Firm_Specific_Assets.pdf · 2015. 5. 6. · By BRUCE A. BLONIGEN* Foreign

VOL 87 NO. 3 BLONIGEN EIRM-SPECIFIC ASSETS 455

much more aggregate than the data used for thedependent variable, but it shows that the latel980's correspond to a substantial increase inJapanese acquisitions across all these industrygroupings, as well as a real dollar depreciation.By itself this may mean very little, since it canbe argued that a number of different forces mayhave affected Japanese acquisitions in the late198O's, as discussed below. However, Table 1shows that years in which the real exchange rateis relatively high correspond to years where theratio of high R&D acquisitions to total manu-facturing (column 4 divided by column 3) islarge. A greater proportion of high R&D ac-quisitions during periods of a real dollar depre-ciation lends support to this paper's hypothesis,in the sense that these manufacturing industriesshould have more firm-specific assets.

The vector of explanatory variables used forestimation are based on equation (7), and a de-tailed Data Appendix is available upon request.Annual industry-specific real exchange ratesare constructed using the dollar-yen nominalexchange rate and roughly 2-digit SIC price in-dexes for the United States and Japan. An in-crease in the industry-specific real exchangerate variable represents a real depreciation ofthe dollar relative to the yen; thus, a positivecorrelation between the real exchange rate andJapanese acquisitions is expected. To captureindustry supply characteristics, il,,, I include aregressor indicating the number of acquisitionsof U.S. target firms by other U.S. firms in in-dustry i during year t, which was compiled bythe author from various issues (1975 -1993) ofMergers and Acquisitions. Domestic acquisi-tions are the largest portion of U.S. acquisifionseach year, and their distribution across indus-tries should be representative of the overall ac-tivity and target firm supply for each industryand year. Thus, the number of foreign acqui-sitions in an industry should be positively cor-related with this supply variable. To control forJapanese demand for U.S. target firms, I includea variable that captures the share of Japanesevalue added in industry /, constructed from Ja-pan's census of manufactures, and the annualreal growth of Japanese GDP, which I expectto have posifive correlations.

I also control for alternative explanationsthat may account for movements in Japaneseacquisition FDI, especially the large increasein the late 198O's. First, I include an industry-

specific U.S. protection variable constructedfrom the SMART software developed by thetrade division of the World Bank, since onetraditional reason for FDI which may be mostapplicable to Japan during this period is estab-lishing production in the protected market toavoid protectionism. A second theory relevantto Japanese FDI in the United States is that theboom in Japanese acquisitions of U.S. firms inthe late 198O's and early 199O's was an out-growth ofthe speculative "bubble" economyof Japan during those years. Edward M.Graham and Paul R. Krugman {1995) discussthis possibility and casual observation of mydata showed support for such a speculativebubble, which was potentially highly corre-lated with exchange rate movements in the latel980's. Thus, I include the annual growth inthe Tokyo Stock Price Index (TOPIX) as aregressor and expect it to have a positive sign.I also include a time trend.

B. Empirical Results

Columns 1 and 2 of Table 2 report negativebinomial and random NEGBIN estimates ofthe determinants of Japanese acquisitions inthe United States across a balanced panel of361 industries (both manufacturing and non-manufacturing) and the years 1975-1992."Many of the coefficients are the expected signand are statistically significant across the twospecifications. The level of U.S. domestic ac-quisitions in an industry are positively corre-lated with the level of Japanese acquisitions.This corresponds with the assumption thatsupply shocks should similarly affect the equi-librium number of acquisitions by Japaneseand U.S. firms in an industry. Likewise, vari-ables to control for demand-side factors,Japanese GDP growth, and the Japanese in-dustry's share of total value added positivelyaffect the probability of Japanese acquisitionsas predicted.

As for other theories of Japanese FDI in theU.S., there is strong evidence that growth pe-riods in the Japanese stock market index arehighly correlated with increased Japanese

'' All samples used for estimation in this paper are bal-anced panels. Financial sectors, SIC 60-67. were not in-cluded because there is no value-added data for theseindustries.

Page 10: Firm-Specific Assets and the Link Between Exchange Rates and Foreign Direct Investmentpages.uoregon.edu/bruceb/Firm_Specific_Assets.pdf · 2015. 5. 6. · By BRUCE A. BLONIGEN* Foreign

456 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW JUNE 1997

TABLE 2—DETERMINANTS OF NUMBER OP JAPANESE AcguisiTioNs IN THL UNITED STATES. 1975-1992: SEPARATEESTIMATES FOR ALL iNDtJSTRiES. NONMANUPACTURING, AND MANUFACTURING

Variables

Constant

Real exchange rate

Domestic acquisitions

Industry value-addedshare

Japan real GDPgrowth

Japan stock maricet

U.S. protection

Time trend

Alpha

a

b

Dependent variable:

All industries

Negativebinomial

-6.948***(0.328)

0,219**(0,570)

0.068***(0.008)

1,086***(0.196)

0.174***(0,046)

0.779***(0,292)

0.159(0.332)

0.193***(0.014)

4,592***(0.311)

RandomNEGBIN

-4.559***(0.346)

0.851*(0,480)

0.017***(0.002)

2,334***(0.397)

0.140***(0.039)

0,900***(0.283)

0.688(0.519)

0.188***(0.012)

4.333***(0,671)

0.458***(0.057)

Japanese acquisitions in ihe United States, 1975-1992

Nonmanufacturing

Negativebinomial

-7.252***(0,562)

0,382(1,124)

0.059***(0.018)

0,737(0.449)

0,236***(0.073)

0,719(0,535)

-0.807(10.801)

0.226***(0,023)

11,381***(1.096)

RandomNEGBIN

-4.718***(0.642)

0,385(0,802)

0.009*(0.0O6)

1,235*(0.736)

0,200**(0.088)

0.534(0,542)

0,124(13.339)

0.206***(0.023)

3.753***(0.778)

0.390***(0.067)

Manufacturing

Negativebinomial

-6.431***(0,425)

2.292***(0.692)

0,079***(0,009)

0.316***(0.046)

0.120*(0.067)

0,785*(0.415)

-0.230(0.227)

0.158***(0,016)

1.182***(0.213)

RandomNEGBIN

-3.272***(0,758)

1,548**(0.657)

0.042***(0.008)

0,526***(0.117)

0,129***(0.046)

0.761**(0,307)

-0,180(0.281)

0.164***(0.015)

18,762(12,180)

1.009***(0.249)

Log-likelihood(LogL)

Restricted LogL^

Likelihood ratio test''

Observations

-1900,9

-3020.1

2238.4

6498

-1676,5

-2441.3

1529,6

6498

- 8 7 L5

-1501,2

1259.4

3978

-754,2

-1237.1

965.8

3978

-949.7

-1464,3

1029.2

2520

-894,4

-1204.2

619,6

2520

Note: Standard errors are in parentheses and ***, **. and * denote ( statistics at the 99-percent, 95 percent, and 90-percent confidence level, respectively,

^ The coefficients are restricted to slopes equal to zero and intercept equal to Ihe mean of the dependent variable. Forthe random effects model, I also restrict a and 6 to be equal to one.

" Likelihood ratio tests have 9 and 11 degrees of freedom for the negative binomial and random NEGBIN model,respectively. All ;7-values for the likelihood ratio iests are less than 0,001.

acquisition activity. Evidence for tariff-jumping is lacking, however. There are a num-ber of potential explanations for M/hy this maybe true. First, this sample tests for the effect ofprotection over time, but FDI flows may be

affected by protection only around the time theprotection is put into place. Second, U.S. pro-tection may be highest in those industrieswhere other factors make FDI less likely. Sen-sitivity tests showed a strong negative effect

Page 11: Firm-Specific Assets and the Link Between Exchange Rates and Foreign Direct Investmentpages.uoregon.edu/bruceb/Firm_Specific_Assets.pdf · 2015. 5. 6. · By BRUCE A. BLONIGEN* Foreign

VOL 87 NO. 3 BLONIGEN: FIRM-SPECIFIC ASSETS 457

between FDI and protected sectors in textiles,apparel, and steel. High labor costs may detertextiles and apparel FDI into the United States,despite high levels of protection, while plant-level scale economies may severely limit FDIin steel industries.

Column I of Tahle 2 also reports an esti-mated alpha parameter for the negative bino-mial model. Unlike a Poisson specification,this parameter allows the variance of the dis-tribution to differ from the mean. The positive,statistically significant alpha parameter inTable 2 suggests that overdispersion in thedata (i.e., a greater variance than mean) andthat the negative binomial model, therefore, isa better specification than a Poisson model.''In addition, the shape parameters for the ran-dom NEGBIN model (see Appendix), a andb, are estimated with precision. While it is dif-ficult to measure goodness of fit in these non-linear models, the null hypothesis that theslopes are zero is strongly rejected by the like-lihood ratio test for both models.

Of particular interest, the real exchange ratevariable is statistically significant and has thecorrect sign across both models. Thus, withoutcontrolling for the conditions connected withthe paper's hypothesis (market presence andfirm-specific assets), there is support for a linkbetween exchange rate movements and Japa-nese acquisition FDI in the United States.However, hecause the conditions have notbeen controlled for. it is impossible to distin-guish from these initial estimates whether thepredicted coefficient on the exchange rate vari-able is due to this paper's hypothesis effect orthe Froot and Stein {1991) wealth effect dis-cussed earlier. The rest of the empirical sectionis intended to separately identify this paper'shypothesis in the data from other altemativeexplanations, particularly that of Froot andStein (1991).

Froot and Stein's (1991) effect does notnecessarily predict a difference in howexchange rate movements affect different

'̂ In addition, regression-based tests suggested by A,Colin Cameron and Pravin K, Trivedi (1990) confirm sig-niticant overdispersion, Poisson estimates yielded verysimilar results for all regressions, suggesting that the re-ported results presented are not biased by misspecificationerrors in the negative binomial models used for analysis.

forms of FDI across different industries; thispaper predicts an exchange rate effect for ac-quisition FDI, particularly for industries inwhich firm-specific assets are important. As afirst cut on the data, I test the model separatelyon manufacturing and nonmanufacturing sam-ples, reported in columns 3-6 in Table 2.While most of the coefficients across the twosamples are similar, the coefficient on the realexchange rate is statistically insignificant forthe nonmanufacturing industries (which in-clude services, wholesale and retail trade, andagricultural production) and only one-fourthto one-sixth as large as the real exchange ratecoefficient for manufacturing industries. Thisdifference is not predicted by Froot and Stein(1991), but supports this paper's hypothesisto the extent that firm-specific assets may hemore important in manufacturing industries.

I next focus on manufacturing acquisitionsand test whether industries with higher R&Dexpenditures experience a larger real exchangerate effect on foreign acquisitions than lowR&D manufacturing industries. As discussedabove, a number of papers have found evidencethat Japanese firms may be particularly inter-ested in technology-related, firm-specific assetsin the United States. Thus, I predict theexchange rate effect on Japanese acquisitionbehavior should be strongest in high R&D man-ufacturing industries. Using the National Sci-ence Foundation publication. Selected Data onResearch and Development in Industry: 1991,I classify industries that are at or above the av-erage R&D as a percentage of sales as highR&D and all other manufacturing industries aslow R&D. Columns 1-4 of Table 3 detail es-timates for these samples from both a negativehinomial and the random NEGBE^ specifica-tion for the years 1975-1992. The differencebetween these high R&D and low R&D man-ufacturing industries is even more striking thanthat between manufacturing and nonmanufac-turing. In the negative binomial model, the co-efficient on the real exchange rate variable isinsignificant for the low R&D sample and onlyone-eighth as large as for high R&D industries.In addition, a Wald test rejects the hypothesisthat the coefficients are equal at the 99-percentconfidence level. Despite less precision, therandom NEGBIN specification yields qualita-tively similar results. The real exchange rate co-efficient for both the high and low R&D

Page 12: Firm-Specific Assets and the Link Between Exchange Rates and Foreign Direct Investmentpages.uoregon.edu/bruceb/Firm_Specific_Assets.pdf · 2015. 5. 6. · By BRUCE A. BLONIGEN* Foreign

458 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW JUNE 1997

T A B L E 3—DETERMINANTS O F NUMBER OF JAPANESE ACQUISITIONS IN THE UNITED STATES: SEPARATE ESTIMATES

FOR HIGH R&D AND Low R&D MANUFACTURING, FOR SAMPLE YEARS 1975-1992 AND 1975-1984

Variables

Constant

Real exchangerate

Domesiicacquisitions

Industry value-added share

Japan real GDPgrowth

Japan stockmarkel

U.S, protection

Time trend

Alpha

a

b

Dependent variable: Japanese acquisitions,1975-1992

High R&Dmanufacturing

Negalivebinomial

-6,496***(0.753)

4,036***(1,177)

0.057***(0.011)

0,150**(0.057)

0,114(0,096)

0.325(0.611)

0,158(0,437)

0,160***(0,021)

0,930***(0.248)

RandomNEGBIN

-4.126***(1,400)

2,562**(!,252)

0,038***(0.013)

0,147(0,233)

0.140**(0.070)

0,385(0,627)

0,863(1.456)

0.172***(0.030)

9.681(9.377)

1,727(1,158)

Low R&Dmanufacturing

Negalivebinomial

-6,266***(0,563)

0.490(1.117)

0,083***(0,01.5)

0.501***(0.108)

0,117(0.095)

1,414**(0.604)

-0.340(0,324)

0.187***(0,031)

1.045***(0.324)

RandomNEGBIN

-3,898***(0.755)

0.143(1.261)

0.080***(0,016)

0.543**(0.199)

0,116(0,103)

1.237*(0,713)

-0.423(0,617)

0,187***(0,029)

13,887*(8,130)

1.575**(0.640)

Dependent variable: Japanese acquisitions,1975-1984

High R&Dmanufacturing

Negativebinomial

-4,906***(1,876)

9.787***(2.017)

0.045**(0,022)

0,025(0,145)

-1,100**(0.439)

6,553(4,329)

t.536(1.393)

0,110(0,141)

0,013(0,607)

RandomNEGBIN

-5,168**(2,404)

11,327**(4,901)

0.051*(0-031)

-0.008(0,254)

-1,107(0,679)

6,449(6,710)

2,133(4.243)

0.177(0.160)

9,011(19,048)

3.406(11,093)

Low R&Dmanufacturing

Negativebinomial

-4,841**(1,910)

-0,163(3,244)

0,112***(0.039)

0,327(0,201)

-0.228(0,405)

0,223(4,637)

0,361(0.746)

0,211(0,157)

0-679(0,748)

RandomNEGBIN

-3,307(3.366)

0,963(4,308)

0,121*(0.073)

0.307(0.380)

-0,180(0.4.14)

0,421(5.952)

0.518(0.875)

0,233(0,208)

9,755(9,437)

0,840(1.066)

Log-likelihood(LogL)

RestrictedLogL"

Likelihoodratio test"

Observations

-392,6

-622.3

459.4

522

-374,

-460,

171.

522

-529.7 -506,0 -98,9 -101, -131,7

-622.3 -460,0 -683,4 -744,2 -119.4 -145.8

307.4 476,4

1998 1998

41.0

290

89.4

290

-128.2

-158.5 -341,

53.6 427.2

1110 1110

Note: Standard errors are in parentheses and ***, **, and * denote /-statistics at the 99-percent. 95-percent, and 90-percent confidence level.respectively,

' The coefficients are restricted to slopes equal to zero and intercept equal to the mean of the dependent variable. For the random effectsmodel, I also restrict a and A to be equal to one,

*• Likelihood ratio tests have 9 and 11 degrees of freedom for the negative binomial and random NEGBIN model, respectively. All p-vaiues for the likelihood ratio tests are less than 0,001,

samples is lower, but the difference in the realexchange rate coefficients between the twosamples is statistically significant at the 90-percent confidence level.

One critique with the above analysis is thatR&D expenditures may be a proxy for othercharacteristics of an industry that would makea Japanese firm more likely to acquire in that

Page 13: Firm-Specific Assets and the Link Between Exchange Rates and Foreign Direct Investmentpages.uoregon.edu/bruceb/Firm_Specific_Assets.pdf · 2015. 5. 6. · By BRUCE A. BLONIGEN* Foreign

VOL. 87 NO. 3 BLONIGEN: FIRM-SPECIFIC ASSETS 459

industry when the dollar depreciates. Perhapshigh R&D industries are also the ones that arerelatively more capital intensive. The Frootand Stein (1991) capital market story maysuggest that exchange rate depreciations willbenefit capital-intensive industries proportion-ally more. I create a capital intensity variableby dividing an industry's current-cost grossstock of fixed private capital by the industry'svalue added (both reported annually in theSurvey of Current Business). I then sample therelatively high capital-intensive industries(those above the mean of 1,715) and find thereal exchange rate effect for these high capital-intensive industries is negative and insignifi-cant for both model specifications (resultsomitted for brevity). This suggests that myhigh R&D/low R&D distinction is not proxy-ing for capital intensity.

Another critique may suggest that becausethe depreciation of the dollar in the late 1980' soccurred at the same time that the Japaneseeconomy was experiencing significantly lowercosts of capital (see Jeffrey A. Franket, 1991;David M. Meerschwam, 1991) and a possiblespeculative bubble, the correlation of in-creased acquisition activity with exchange ratemovements may be spurious.'^ To a large ex-tent, these criticisms are controlled for in theabove regressions. First, neither altemative ex-planation predicts differential effects acrossmanufacturing and nonmanufacturing andhigh R&D and low R&D manufacturing. Sec-ond, the Japanese stock market growth vari-able controls for the speculative bubble and ispositive as expected, and the real exchangerate effect for capital-intensive industriesshows no relationship. However, I also run es-timates for high R&D and low R&D industriesfor sample years from 1975-1984, and reportthese in column 5-8 of Table 3. While theestimates are less precise, the same qualitativedifferences emerge in the real exchange ratecoefficient estimates between high and lowR&D manufacturing for this pre-1985 sampleof years.

In addition to these specification tests, I nextrun a similar equation for new plant manufac-turing FDI, as opposed to acquisition manu-facturing FDI. This provides an importantcomparison because, first of all, this paper'sproposition does not predict any exchange rateeffect for new plant FDI: a foreign firm cannotgain new firm-specific assets by building itsown plant. The Froot and Stein (1991) effectdoes not necessarily make a distinction be-tween new plant FDI and acquisition FDI inpredicting an exchange rate effect. Second, theabove specification tests simply may not cap-ture some unobservable factor that causes theJapanese to invest (through all forms of FDI)in high R&D industries. Thus, I test the deter-minants of Japanese new plant FDI in theUnited States using the same specification asused to test Japanese acquisition FDI, with theexception of the U.S. domestic acquisition re-gressor.''' This testing equation is similar toprevious studies of determinants for varioustypes of FDI, including new plant FDI. (Seefor example, Ray, 1989; Martin, 1991.) Table4 shows separate estimates for Japanese newplant FDI in the United States for manufactur-ing, high R&D manufacturing, and low R&Dmanufacturing from 1975-1992.

Columns 1 and 2 of Table 4 show that thereis evidence that Japanese new plant FDI is pos-itively affected by real exchange rate depre-ciation and display coefficients that are similarin magnitude to the Japanese acquisition FDIestimates. However, columns 3-6 show thatthere is no differential impact of the realexchange rate on Japanese new plant FDIacross high and low R&D manufacturing in-dustries, as was true with Japanese acquisi-tions. Thus, while there seems to be a positiveeffect of real dollar depreciations on JapaneseFDI in general (which could be due to a num-ber of explanations, including the Froot andStein [1991] effect), the differential impact onhigh R&D and low R&D manufacturing in-dustries is large and specific to acquisitionFDI, as predicted by this paper's hypothesis.

'̂ Another potential explanation for inward FDI intothe United States over this period is U.S. tax law changesin 1986, as suggested by Myron S. Scholes and Mark A.Wolfson (1990), which may have increased the Japanesedemand for U.S, assets. However. Alan J, Auerbach andKevin A, Hassett (1993) dispute this conclusion.

'* There is no a priori belief that domestic acquisitionactivity should affect new plant FDI. In addition, inclusionof the domestic acquisition variable has no qualitative ef-fect on the results.

Page 14: Firm-Specific Assets and the Link Between Exchange Rates and Foreign Direct Investmentpages.uoregon.edu/bruceb/Firm_Specific_Assets.pdf · 2015. 5. 6. · By BRUCE A. BLONIGEN* Foreign

460 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW JUNE 1997

TABLE '1—DETERMINANTS OF NUMBER OF JAPANESE NEW PLANT FDI IN THE UNITED STATES, ]975-!992: SEPARATEESTIMATES FOR MANUFACTURING. HIGH R&D MANUFACTURING, AND LOW R&D MANUFACTURING

Variables

Constant

Real exchange rate

Industry value-addedshare

Japan real GDP growth

Japan stock market

U,S, protection

Time trend

Alpha

a

-ft

Log-likelihood

Restricted LogL''

Likelihood ratio test*"

Observations

Dependent variable: Japanese new plant FDI,

Manufacturing

Negativebinomial

-5,055***(0.353)

2.596***(0.591)

0.565***(0.045)

-0,020(0.058)

2.254**'(0.422)

-0.626**(0,245)

0.111***(0.015)

1.190***(0.216)

-1119,7

-1655.8

1072.2

2520

RandomNEGBIN

-2,928***(0,590)

1.840***(0.662)

0.390***(0,107)

0.061(0,055)

1,151***(0.344)

-0.227(0.419)

0,109***(0,012)

9.539**(4.752)

1.133***(0.265)

-1026.8

-1302.6

551,6

2520

High R&D manufacturing

Negativebinomial

-3.425***(1.974)

1,974**(1,006)

0.312***(0.059)

-0,082(O.iO7)

2,439***(0,770)

0,636(0.663)

0.093***(0,022)

0,595***(0,190)

-444,6

-688.2

487.2

522

RandomNEGBIN

-2,076(1,580)

1.240(1.567)

0.257(0.214)

0,031(0.102)

1.374**(0.569)

0,377(1.100)

0.088***(0.019)

9.152(13,109)

1,992*(1,075)

-418,5

-487.6

138.2

522

1975-1992

Low R&D manufacturing

Negativebinomial

-5,819***(0,496)

1.943**(0.879)

0.704***(0.098)

0.051(0,073)

2,086***(0.527)

-0.835***(0.294)

0,147***(0.026)

1.045***(0.347)

-631.1

-785,5

308,8

1998

RandomNEGBIN

-3.464***(0,760)

1,968*(1.066)

0.543**(0,212)

0.077(0.074)

1.402**(0.570)

-0.630(0.667)

0,145***(0.026)

11.610(7.671)

1.002***(0.314)

-587.4

-814,9

455.0

1998

Note: Standard errors are in parentheses and ***, **, and * denote r-statistics at the 99-percent, 95-percent, and 90-percent confidence level, respectively,

" The coefficients are restricted to slopes equal to zero and intercept equal to the mean of the dependent variable. Forthe random effects model, I also restrict a and 6 to be equal to one.

" Likelihood ratio tests have 9 and II degrees of freedom for the negative binomial and random NEGBIN model,respectively. All p-values for the likelihood ratio tests are less than 0,001,

How large is the effect of the real exchangerate on Japanese acquisitions in the United Statesfrom 1975-1992? In a highly nonlinear settingsuch as this, perhaps the best way to estimatethese magnitudes is through simulations. Table

5 reports results from a simulation where I in-crease the real exchange rate by 10 percentacross all years and industries and estimate itseffect on the yearly prediction of total Japaneseacquisitions. In addition to determining the eco-

Page 15: Firm-Specific Assets and the Link Between Exchange Rates and Foreign Direct Investmentpages.uoregon.edu/bruceb/Firm_Specific_Assets.pdf · 2015. 5. 6. · By BRUCE A. BLONIGEN* Foreign

VOL. 87 NO. 3 BLONIGEN: FIRM-SPECIFIC ASSETS 461

TABLE 5—SIMULATED EPTECTS or- IO-PERCKNT INCRKA.SE IN EXCHANGE RATE ON NUMBEROF JAPANESE AcyuisiTioNs IN THE UNITED STATES, 1975-1992

Year

1975

1976

1977

1978

1979

1980

1981

1982

1983

1984

1985

1986

1987

1988

1989

1990

1991

1992

ActualFDI

6

0

1

6

2

7

19

10

5

17

22

40

57

66

76

67

50

20

Manufacturing industries

PredictedFDI

1,6

3,0

4,4

7,3

8.7

6.7

9.3

8.6

11,9

20.0

31.0

55,1

60.2

99,0

65.6

66,6

46.3

33.0

Predicted FDiafter 10-percenlexchange rate

increase

1.8

3.4

4.9

8.4

10.0

7.6

10,4

9.5

13.1

22.1

34.0

62.3

69,1

115.5

75,8

75.7

53,2

38,2

Percentchange

12.2

11.9

12J

15.4

14.3

12.6

12.4

10.3

10.4

10.3

9.9

13.1

14.9

16.6

15.5

13.6

14.9

15.9

ActualFDI

4

0

1

5

0

5

9

5

2

7

12

21

35

34

46

41

34

14

High R&D manufacturing industries

PredictedFDI

1.1

1.7

2.4

5.1

5.7

3.6

4.9

3.6

5,2

7.7

11,0

23.9

29.7

49.5

36.9

33,0

29,4

23,4

Predicted FDIafter 10-percentexchange rate

increase

1,4

2.1

3.0

6.8

7.4

4.5

6.2

4.3

6.3

9.2

13,0

29.8

38.0

65.1

47.5

41.4

37,4

30.2

Percentchange

26.8

25.0

25.9

32.3

29.8

25.1

24.4

19.7

19.7

19.4

18.4

24.5

27.9

31.6

28.9

25.1

27.2

29.0

nomic significance of the real exchange rate onJapanese acquisitions, comparing predicted toactual FDI helps indicate the fit of the model ingeneral. I run these simulations using the esti-mated coefficients for the manufacturing andhigh R&D samples, where the real exchange rateeffect is largest and stafistically significant. Ona final note, I use the negafive binomial modeland its estimates for the simulations, because un-like the random NEGBIN, the predicted valueshave a closed-form solution.

Table 5 shows that for both the manufacturingand high R&D manufacturing samples the pre-dicted FDI totals match the actual totals fairly

well, lending further support of the goodness offit of the model. Second, the simulations capturehow much the predicted Japanese acquisitionschange each year for a 10-percent increase in thereal exchange rate (or similarly, a 10-percent in-crease in the nominal exchange rate, holdingprices constant). For the manufacturing sample,a 10-percent real exchange rate depreciation ofthe dollar generates a 10-16-percent increase intotal Japanese acquisitions across the years in thesample. The effect of a 10-percent increase inthe exchange rate on Japanese acquisition activ-ity in high R&D manufacuiring is even larger,ranging from 18 percent to over 32 percent.

Page 16: Firm-Specific Assets and the Link Between Exchange Rates and Foreign Direct Investmentpages.uoregon.edu/bruceb/Firm_Specific_Assets.pdf · 2015. 5. 6. · By BRUCE A. BLONIGEN* Foreign

462 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW JUNE 1997

6—DETERMINANTS OF NUMBER OF GERMAN ACQUISITION FDI IN THE UNITED STATES, 1975-1990: SEPARATE

ESTIMATES FOR MANUFACTURING, HIGH R&D MANUFACTURING, AND LOW R&D MANUFACTURING

Variables

Cotistant

Real exchange rate

Domestic acquisitions

Industry value-addedshare

German real GDP growth

U.S. protection

Time trend

Alpha

a

b

Log-likelihood (LogL)

Restricted LogL^

Likelihood ratio tes^

Observations

Dependent variable; German acquisition FDI,

Manufacturing

Negativebinomial

-5.160***(0.576)

3.236*»*(0.847)

0.090***(0.010)

0.156***(0.055)

0.016(0.054)

-0,488(0.377)

0.011(0.022)

n,70i***(0.449)

-645.1

-780.7

271.2

2240

RandomNEGBIN

-3.605***(0.610)

3.640***(0.882)

0.072***(0.012)

0.270***(0.071)

0.021(0.059)

-0.452(0.722)

0.018(0.019)

9.193**(4.625)

1.300***(0.411)

-629.9

-856.5

453,2

2240

High R&D manufacturing

Negativebinomial

-4.231***(0.867)

3.269***(L217)

0.052***(0.012)

0.063(0.071)

0.015(0.070)

-0.494(0.805)

0.033(0.030)

1.103***(0.405)

-303.2

-342.2

78.0

464

RandomNEGBIN

-3.328**(1.254)

3.434**(1.727)

0.053***(0.015)

0.062(0,095)

0,035(0,089)

-0,401(2,910)

0,039(0,027)

8,378(7,129)

2.644(1.669)

-298.6

-333.9

70.6

464

1975-1990

Low R&D manufacturing

Negativebinomial

-5.192***(0.751)

2.520***(L137)

0.106***(0.021)

0,032(0,243)

0.029(0,080)

0,110(0,455)

0,004(0.031)

1,298(0,968)

-318.2

-348.6

60.8

1776

RandomNHGBIN

-2.995***(0.874)

2.448**(1.223)

0.088***(0.028)

0.082(0.191)

0,037(0,089)

-0.466(0,710

0,009(0,036)

21.787(20.981)

2,555(2,028)

-318,4

-422,6

208.4

1776

Note: Standard errors are in parentheses and ***, **, and * denote r-statistics at the 99-percent. 95-percent, and 90-percent confidence level, respectively,

' The coefficients are restricted to slopes equal to zero and intercept equal to the mean of the dependent variable. Forthe random effects model, I also restrict a and fe to be equal to one.

^ Likelihood ratio tests have 8 and 10 degrees of freedom for the negative binomial and random NEGBIN model,respectively. All p-values for the likelihood ratio tests are less than 0,001,

C. Extension: Empirical Test of WestGerman Acquisitions in the United States

While I have suggested that this paper'stheory linking exchange rate movements is

particularly appropriate for examining Jap-anese acquisitions in the United States, itmay apply to other countries' acquisition be-havior in the United States as well. Tahle 6presents results for West German acquisi-

Page 17: Firm-Specific Assets and the Link Between Exchange Rates and Foreign Direct Investmentpages.uoregon.edu/bruceb/Firm_Specific_Assets.pdf · 2015. 5. 6. · By BRUCE A. BLONIGEN* Foreign

VOL 87 NO. 3 BLONIGEN: FIRM-SPECIFIC ASSETS 463

tions in the United States from 1975 -1990. ' ̂All regressors are tbe West Geraian equiv-alent to tbe Japanese acquisition FDI esti-mates in Tables 2 or 3 (and described in theData Appendix, available upon request), ex-cept the stock market growth index is omit-ted because there is no a priori belief thatWest Germany experienced a speculativebubble. Data sources are similar as well, ex-cept the West German statistical yearbookwas used for German industry-level price in-dexes and value-added shares. Like Japaneseacquisition behavior, the real exchange ratehas a positive and significant effect on allWest German manufacturing acquisitions. Inaddition, when the manufacturing sample issplit into high R&D and low R&D, the pointestimates show approximately a 30-percenthigher coefficient for the high R&D sample.The evidence for a differential relationshipbetween the high and low R&D samples isweaker than the case of Japan, however, be-cause there is no statistical difference in thereal exchange rate coefficient across the twosamples. The weaker West German resultsmay reflect that certain conditions of the the-ory are not as appropriate for the WestGermany-U.S. international relationship;e.g., perhaps the U.S. finns have a greatermarket presence in West Germany thanJapan.

IV. Conclusion

The inadequacy of traditional theories of FDIto explain the U.S. experience in inward FDIover the last 20 years has caused a new searchfor explanations that can naturally account forsubstantial short-run fluctuations in FDI flows.While both anecdotal and empirical evidencehas supported a link between FDI and exchangerate movements, few formal theories for thislink have been presented and previous empiri-cal evidence has been mixed. This paper at-tempts to shed light on the relationship betweenexchange rate movements and FDI. Specifi-cally, a theoretical connection betweenexchange rate movements and acquisition FDI

" The sample leaves out 1991 -1992 because the reuni-fication of Germany made data consistency with the restof the sample problematic for these years.

can be found, provided that acquisitions in-volve firm-specific assets and goods-marketimperfections prevent investors from havingequal access to all markets. The data on Japa-nese acquisitions in the United States from1975-1992 display a strong correlationbetween periods of a weaker dollar and higherlevels of Japanese acquisition FDI in the UnitedStates for industries which more likely involvefirm-specific assets. Postregression simulationsfind that a 10-percent lower dollar increasesJapanese acquisition FDI activity in high R&Dmanufacturing sectors from 18 to 32 percent.In addition, this effect does not display itself inJapanese new plant FDI, where acquisition offirm-specific assets is not involved.

APPENDIX ; RANDOM EFFECTS NEGATIVEBINOMIAL MODEL

To develop a random effects negative bi-nomial model, Hausman et al. (1984) beginwith a standard Poisson distribution and as-sume that the Poisson parameter, \y,, followsa gamma distribution with shape parameters,(•y, 6). As is standard, we can parameterize yto be an exponential function of the indepen-dent variables, X,,, such that y,, = exp(X,/3).Then, to introduce variation across industries,they assume that each industry (/) has its own6,, which are randomly distributed across the((•) industries. To accomplish this, Hausman etal. assume that the ratio 6, /(1 -F 6,) is distrib-uted as a beta random variable with shape pa-rameters {a, b). Using this beta density theyderive the joint probability of an industry's ac-quisitions over the panel years to be

X I I I1)

where v,, denotes the dependent variable. Therandom effects negative binomial (NEGBIN)model thus has two "shape" parameters, aand b, to estimate, in addition to our coeffi-cient vector, /3.

Page 18: Firm-Specific Assets and the Link Between Exchange Rates and Foreign Direct Investmentpages.uoregon.edu/bruceb/Firm_Specific_Assets.pdf · 2015. 5. 6. · By BRUCE A. BLONIGEN* Foreign

464 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW JUNE 1997

REFERENCES

Ardeni, Pier G. "Does the Law of One PriceReally Hold for Commodity Prices?"American Journal of Agricultural Econom-ics, August 1989, 77(3), pp. 661-69.

Auerbach, Alan J. and Hassett, Kevin A. * 'Tax-ation and Foreign Direct Investment in theUnited States: A Reconsideration of theEvidence," in Alberto Giovanini, R.Glenn Hubbard, and Joel Slemrod, eds..Studies in international taxation. Cbi-cago: University of Chicago Press, 1993,pp. 119-44.

Balassa, Bela. "Japan's Trade Policies." Welt-wirtschaftliches Archiv, October 1986,722(4), pp. 745-90.

Cameron, A. Colin and Trivedi, Pravin K."Regression-Based Tests for Overdisper-sion in the Poisson Model." Journal ofEconometrics, December 1990, 46(3), pp.347-64.

Caves, Richard E. "Exchange-Rate Movementsand Foreign Direct Investment in the UnitedStates," in David B. Audretsch and MichaelP. Claudon, eds.. The internationalization ofU.S. markets. New York: New York Uni-versity Press, 1989, pp. 199-228.

Cushman, David O. ' 'Real Exchange Rate Risk,Expectations, and the Level of Direct In-vestment." Review of Economics and Sta-tistics, May 1985, 67(2), pp. 297-38.

Economic Report of the President. Washington,DC: U.S. Govemment Printing Office, Feb-ruary 1995.

Encarnation, Dennis J. Rivals beyond trade:America versus Japan in global competi-tion. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press,1992.

Frankel, Jeffrey A. "Japanese Finance in the198O's: A Survey," in Paul R. Krugman,ed.. Trade with Japan: Has the door openedwideri Chicago: University of ChicagoPress, 1991, pp. 225-68.

Froot, Kenneth A. and Stein, Jeremy C."Exchange Rates and Foreign Direct In-vestment: An Imperfect Capital MarketsApproach." Quarterly Journal of Econom-ics, November 1991, 706(4), pp. 1191-1217.

Goodwin, Barry K.; Grennes, Thomas andWohlgenant, Michael K.' 'Testing the Law ofOne Price Wheti Trade Takes Time." Jour-

nal of Intemationai Money and Finance,March 1990, 9( 1), pp. 21-40.

Graham, Edward M. and Krugman, Paul R. For-eign direct investment in the United States.Washington, DC: Institute for IntemationaiEconomics, 1995.

Hausman, Jerry; Hall, Bronwyn H. and Griliches,Zvi. "Econometric Models for Count Datawith an Application to the Patents-R & DRelationship." Fconometrica, July 1984,52(4), pp. 909-38.

Healy, Paul M. and Palepu, Krishna G. "Inter-national Corporate Equity Associations:Who, Where, and Why?" in Kenneth A.Froot, ed.. Foreign direct investment. Chi-cago: University of Chicago Press, 1993,pp. 231-50.

Helpman, Elhanan. "A Simple Theory of In-temationai Trade with Multinational Cor-porations." Journal of Political Economy,June 1984, 92(3), pp. 451-71.

Horstmann, Ignatius J. and Markusen, James R."Firm-Specific Assets and the Gains fromDirect Foreign Investment." Economica,February 1989, 56( 221), pp. 41 -48 .

Japan Statistical Yearhook. Tokyo: Japan Statis-tical Association, various issues.

Klein, Michael W. and Rosengren, Eric S. ' 'TheReal Exchange Rate and Foreign Direct In-vestment in the United States: RelativeWealth vs. Relative Wage Effects." Jour-nal of International Economics, May 1994,i 6 ( 3 - 4 ) , pp. 373-89.

Knetter, Michael M. "Why Are Retail Prices inJapan So High?: Evidence from GermanExport Prices." National Bureau of Eco-nomic Research (Cambridge, MA) Work-ing Paper No. 4894, October 1994.

Kogut, Bruce and Chang, Sea Jin. "Technolog-ical Capabilities and Japanese Foreign Di-rect Investment." Review of Economics andStatistics, August 1991, 75(3), pp. 4 0 1 -13.

Lawrence, Robert Z. ' 'Efficient or Exclusionisl?The Import Behavior of Japanese CorporateGroups." Brookings Papers on EconomicActivity, 1991, ( l ) , p p . 311-41.

"Japan's Low Levels of Inward In-vestment: The Role of Inhibitions on Ac-quisi t ions," in Kenneth A. Froot, ed..Foreign direct investment. Chicago: Uni-versity of Chicago Press, 1993, pp. 8 5 -107.

Page 19: Firm-Specific Assets and the Link Between Exchange Rates and Foreign Direct Investmentpages.uoregon.edu/bruceb/Firm_Specific_Assets.pdf · 2015. 5. 6. · By BRUCE A. BLONIGEN* Foreign

VOL 87 NO. 3 BLONIGEN: FIRM-SPECIFIC ASSETS 465

Markusen, James R. "Multinationals, Multi-plant Economies, and the Gains fromTrade." Journal of Intemationai Econom-ics, May 1984, 76(3-4) , pp. 205-26.

Martin, Stephen. "Direct Foreign Investment inthe United States." Journal of EconomicBehavior and Organization, December1991, 76(3), pp. 283-93.

McCulloch, Rachel. "Japanese Investment inthe United States," in David B. Audretschand Michael P. Claudon, eds.. The interna-tionalization of U.S. markets. New York:New York University Press, 1989, pp. 171 -97.

Meerschwam, David M. "The Japanese Finan-cial System and the Cost of Capital," inPaul R. Krugman, ed.. Trade with Japan:Has the door opened wider'? Chicago: Uni-versity of Chicago Press, 1991, pp. 191-220.

Mergers and Acquisitions. Philadelphia, PA:MLR Publishing Company, various issues,1975-1993.

National Science Foundation. Selected data onresearch and development in industry:1991, NSF 93-322. Arlington, VA: Na-tional Science Foundation, October 1993.

Noland, Marcus. "Public Policies, Private Pref-erences, and the Japanese Trade Pattem,"Review of Economics and Statistics, 1997(forthcoming).

Ray, Edward J. "The Determinants of ForeignDirect Investment in the United States,1979 -85 , " in Robert C. Feenstra, ed..Trade policies for intemationai competi-tiveness. Chicago: University of ChicagoPress, 1989. pp. 53-77.

Saxonhouse, Gary R. "Japan's Intractable TradeSurpluses in a New Era." World Economy,September 1986, 9(3), pp. 239-58.

Saxonhouse, Gary R. and Stern, Robert M.' 'Dif-ferentiated Products, Economies of Scale,and Access to the Japanese Market," inRobert C. Feenstra, ed.. Trade policies forinternational competitiveness. Chicago:University of Chicago Press, 1989, pp. 145-74.

Scholes, Myron S. and Wolfson, Mark A. "TheEffects of Changes in Tax Laws on Corpo-rate Reorganization Activity." Joumal ofBusiness, J a n u a r y 1 9 9 0 , 63{\I2), p p .S141-64.

Stevens, Guy V. G. "Exchange Rates and For-eign Direct Investment: A Note." Intema-tionai Finance Paper No. 444, Board ofGovemors of the Federal Reserve System,Washington, DC, 1992.

Swenson, Deborah L. "Impact of U.S. TaxReform on Foreign Direct Investment inthe United States ." Journal of PublicEconomics, June 1994, 54(2) , pp. 2 4 3 -66.

Taylor, Mark P. ' The Economics of ExchangeRates." Joumal of Economic Literature,March 1995, i i ( 1), pp. 13-47.

U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Eco-nomic Analysis. Survey of current bu.siness.Washington, DC: Bureau of EconomicAnalysis, various issues.

U.S. Department of Commerce, InternationalTrade Administration. Foreign direct in-vestment in the United States: Transactions.Washington, DC: Intemationai Trade Ad-ministration, various issues.

Yamawaki, Hideki. "Intemationai Competitive-ness and Choice of Entry Mode: JapaneseMultinationals in the U.S. and EuropeanManufacturing Industries." Working paper,Universite Catholique de Louvain, Louvain-la-Nueve, Belgium, 1993.

Page 20: Firm-Specific Assets and the Link Between Exchange Rates and Foreign Direct Investmentpages.uoregon.edu/bruceb/Firm_Specific_Assets.pdf · 2015. 5. 6. · By BRUCE A. BLONIGEN* Foreign