17
7/25/2019 Endogenous Product Cycles Economic Journal 1991 http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/endogenous-product-cycles-economic-journal-1991 1/17 The Economic Journal,  ioi  {September  1991), 1214-1229 Printed  in  Great Britain ENDOGENOUS PRODUCT CYCLES Gene  M.  Grossman and Elhanan tJelpman The product cycle features prominently  in  trade between  the  Northern developed economies  and the  Southern newly industriahsing economies.  In a much-celebrated article, Vernon (1966) described  the  'life cycle'  of a  typical manufactured product. Invention  and  initial manufacturing  of  new products occur  in  the North,  he  argued, because R&D capabilities  are  well developed there,  and  because proximity  to  large, high-income markets facilitates innovation. After  a  while, production methods may become more standardised. Then, technology transfer  or  imitation  by  Southern firms takes place, whereupon  the  bulk  of  production migrates  to the  low-wage South. Interregional trade  in  manufactured goods involves exchange  of the  latest, innovative goods, produced only  in the  North,  for  older, more established goods, produced predominantly  or  entirely  in the  South. The first attempt  at  formal modelling of this phenomenon was carried out by Krugman (1979).  He  posited  an  exogenous rate,  g  our  notation),  of introduction  of  new products  in the  North,  and an  exogenous rate,  /*, of technology transfer  to the  South.  By  hypothesis, then,  the  totai number  of products known  to the  world evolves according  to  ri/n = g,  while  the  number of products that  the  South  is  able  to  produce evolves according  to  n^  =  /m^ where  n^,  is  the number of products  in  which the North temporarily maintains exclusive productive capacity. These exogenous processes ensure the existence of  a  steady state  in  which  the  share  of the  North  in the  total number  of products, 0 ,^  =  «,v/«, is ec|ual to  g/ g  +  /i)- Adding some economic structure  to the model, Krugman finds  a  positive relationship between  the  relative wage paid to Northern labour  w^./Wf^)  and  g/fJ- and  an  inverse relationship betwee the relative wage  and the  relative size  of  the Northern labour force. Krugman's work  has  been extended  by  Dollar (1986)  and  Jensen  and Thursby (1986, 1987). Dollar maintains Krugman's assumption  of an exogenous rate  of  product innovation,  but  relates  the  rate  of  technology transfer  to  the North-South terms of trade, albeit  in an  entirely  ad hoc  manner. Jensen  and  Thursby (1986) attempt  to  capture  the  resource costs  of  product development and technology transfer, and the decision processes that determine these expenditures,  but  they assume that  all  innovation  is  carried  out by a single entrepreneur in the North, and that the allocation of resources to reverse engineering  in  the South  is  made  by a  social planner. Their later (1987) paper does allow  for a  fixed number (perhaps greater than one)  of  innovators  in the

Endogenous Product Cycles Economic Journal 1991

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Endogenous Product Cycles Economic Journal 1991

7/25/2019 Endogenous Product Cycles Economic Journal 1991

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/endogenous-product-cycles-economic-journal-1991 1/17

The Economic Journal,  ioi  {September

  1 9 9 1 ) , 1 2 1 4 - 1 2 2 9

Printed  in Great Britain

ENDOGENOUS PRODUCT CYCLES

Gene

 M.

  Grossman and Elhanan tJelpman

The product cycle features prominently

  in

  trade between

  the

  Northern

developed economies and the Sou thern newly indu striahsing econom ies.  In a

much-celebrated article, Vernon (1966) described

  the

 'life cy cle'

 of a

  typical

manufactured product. Invention  and initial ma nufacturing  of new produc ts

occur

 in

  the North,

 he

 argued, because R& D capabilities

 are

  well developed

there,

  and

  because proximity

  to

  large, high-incom e m arkets facilitates

innovation. After

 a

 while, production method s may become more standard ised.

Then, technology transfer

  or

  imitation

  by

  Sou thern firms takes place,

whereupon  the  bulk  of  production migrates  to the  low-wage South.

Interregional trade

  in

  ma nufac tured goods involves exch ange

  of the

  latest,

innovative goods, produced only

  in the

 Nor th,

  for

  older, mo re established

goods, produced predominantly  or entirely  in the South.

The first attempt

 at

 formal mo delling of this pheno me non was carried out by

Krugman (1979).  He  posited  an  exogenous rate,  g  our  notation) ,  of

introduction

  of

  new products

  in the

  North,

  and an

  exogenous rate,

  /*, of

technology transfer

  to the

 South.

  By

 hypothesis, then,

  the

  totai n um ber

 of

products known

  to the

 world evolves ac cord ing

  to

 ri/n = g ,  while

 the

 number

of products that

  the

 South

  is

 able

  to

 prod uce evolves accord ing

  to n^

  = /m^

where  n^, is the n um ber of products in which the No rth tem porarily ma intains

exclusive productive capacity. These exogenous processes ensure the existence

of  a  steady state  in  which  the share  of the  North  in the  total num ber of

products, 0 ,^

 =

 «,v/«, is ec|ual to g/ g + /i)-  Adding some economic structure

 to

the model, Krugman finds

  a

  positive relationship between

  the

 relative wage

paid to Northern labour  w^./Wf^)  and g/fJ- and an  inverse relationship betwee

the relative wage

 and the

 relative size

 of

 the No rthern labo ur force.

Krugman's work  has  been extended  by  Do llar (1986)  and Jensen and

Thursby (1986, 1987). Dollar maintains Krugman's assumption

  of an

exogenous rate  of  product innovation,  but  relates  the  rate  of  technology

transfer

  to

 the Nort h-S ou th terms of trade, albeit

 in an

 entirely ad hoc  manner .

Jensen

  and

 Th ursby (1986) attem pt

  to

 capture

  the

 resource costs

 of

 product

development and technology transfer, and the decision processes that determine

these expenditures,

  but

  they assume tha t

  all

  innovation

  is

  carried

  out by a

single entrepreneur in the North, and that the allocation of resources to reverse

engineering

 in

 the S outh

 is

 made

 by a

 social plan ner. T he ir later (1987) p ap er

does allow

 for a

  fixed number (perhaps greater than one)

 of

 innovators

 in the

Page 2: Endogenous Product Cycles Economic Journal 1991

7/25/2019 Endogenous Product Cycles Economic Journal 1991

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/endogenous-product-cycles-economic-journal-1991 2/17

[ S E P T .  I99 1] ENDOGENOUS PRODUCT CYCLES I2 15

imitation. Moreover, their analysis in both papers is partial equilibrium in

nature, inasmuch as they take the interest rate as given.^

In this paper we build upon our earlier work on product development and

international trade (1989^, 1990) to construct a model ofthe product cycle

featuring endogenous innovation and endogenous technology transfer. In our

model, competitive entrepreneurs in the North expend resources to bring out

new products whenever the expected present discounted value of subsequent

oligopoly profits exceeds current product development costs. Each Northern

oligopolist continuously faces the risk that its product will be copied by a

Southern imitator, at which time its profit stream comes to an end. Thus the

length o fthe initial ph ase in the life cycle of each p rod uct (i.e. wh en pro du ction

occurs in the North) is rand om . In the South, entrep reneu rs m ay devote

resources to learning the production processes that have been developed in the

North. There too, costs (of reverse engineering) must be covered by a

subsequent .stream of operating profits. In all this, interest rates are determined

endogenously so as to equate saving.s and investment.

Our approach enables us to study the determinants of the long-run rate of

grow th ofth e w orld economy an d the long-run rate of technological diffusion.

We find steady-state values for

  g

  and

  /i

and relate these to underlying

structural characteristics of the world economy (the sizes of the two trading

blocs,

  the productivities of resources in their various uses, and the nature of

dem and for the differentiated ma nufactured goods), and to the comm ercial

and industrial policies enacted by the two governments. Also, we provide an

analysis o fth e effects of exogenous events and of public policy on re lative w age

rates in the two regions, and find that Krugman s (1979) results derived for the

case of ^ and /^ exogenous m ay in fact be m isleading. For e xam ple, when we

allow for the changes in the steady-state rates of innovation and imitation that

are induced by variations in the two labour forces, we find that the direction

of movem ent in relative w ages in th e .steady state is exactly the opposite of th at

predicted by Krugman.

The remainder ofthis paper is organised as follows. We develop our model

ofthe product cycle in the next section. In Section II we solve for the steady-

state equilibrium and discuss its dependence on structural features ofthe world

economy. Section III contains policy analysis. We analyse the long-run effects

of subsidies to innovation in the North, of subsidies to reverse engineering (or

learning) in the South, and of trade policies in both regions. The concluding

section provides a summary of the findings.

I. A M O D E L O F T H E P R O D U C T CY C L E

We study a world economy com prising two regions, denoted by N o rt h and

  South . The regions differ only in their abilities to innovate. The North enjoys

absolute (and comparative) advantage in developing new products and

Page 3: Endogenous Product Cycles Economic Journal 1991

7/25/2019 Endogenous Product Cycles Economic Journal 1991

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/endogenous-product-cycles-economic-journal-1991 3/17

I 2 l 6 THE ECONOMIC JOURN AL [SEPTEMB ER

bringing them to ma rket. Indeed , we shall assume that So uthern productivity

in pro du ct innovation is sufficiently low tha t the Sou th performs none of this

activity in a trade equilibrium.

W e consider a world of symm etrically d ifferentiated prod ucts. Th ere exists

a continuum of potential goods that are desirable to consumers, but only a

subset of th es e (of finite mea sure) a re produ ced at any one time. Before an y

pro du ct can be ma nufactu red and sold to consum ers, resources must be devoted

to 'dev elo pin g' the prod uct ; that is, the good must be designed, the p roduction

techniques perfected, and so on.

Households worldwide share identical preferences for the differentiated

products. Each household seeks to maximise the time-separable intertemporal

utility function

r 7 ) ] r f r , (I)

w h e r e   p  is t h e s u b j e c t i v e d i s c o u n t r a t e a n d  u{-) is  t h e i n s t a n t a n e o u s s u b - u t i l i t y

f u n c t i o n g i v e n b y

r

  fn   l l / a

U {

=

  x{(o)

da)\ ,

  o<oc<i .

  ( 2 )

Uo J

In (2), .v(w) denotes cons um ption of differentiated pro du ct w, and   n   (a function

of

  T)

  is the number (measure) of varieties available on the market.

The representative consumer maximises (i) subject to an intertemporal

budget constraint

r

 3

where  R{t)  is the cumulative interest factor from time o to time / that the

consumer faces on the local capital market; £(7) and   Y{T) are his spending and

factor income at time T,  respectively; and  A{1)  represents the value of his asset

holdings at  t.   Our results concerning the steady state do not hinge on whether

capital is traded internationally or not; but for ease of exposition we shall

assume that all agents face the same interest rate.

As is well known (see, for example, Grossman and Helpman (19896)), the

solution to the intertemporal maximisation problem requires

R-p,  (4)

while (2) generates an instantaneous demand for variety   o)  given by

^^ ^ ^ £ , (5)

Page 4: Endogenous Product Cycles Economic Journal 1991

7/25/2019 Endogenous Product Cycles Economic Journal 1991

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/endogenous-product-cycles-economic-journal-1991 4/17

EN DO GE NO US PR OD UC T CYCLES 2 7

random. But all risks are idiosyncratic, so tbat households can earn a safe

retu rn by holding well-diversified portfolios of equities. Th en arb itrag e ensures

that, in equilibrium, the return to such a portfolio of Northern firms equals the

riskless interest rate, which in turn equals tbe (certain) return on a share of any

Southern firm.

The production sector comprises two distinct activities. Before a firm can

begin to manufacture any variety, it must learn the production technique

specific to that variety . If the pro duc t is a new one (i.e. not previously ava ilable

in the marketplace), then this learning represents

  innovation.

  If, in.stead, the

product already exists on the market, then the learning represents

  imitation.

  In

either case, tbe learning activity requires an expenditure of resources by the

entrepreneur (presumably more for innovation than for imitation), with

productivity parameters that vary by region. After a production technique has

been mastered, the firm can manufacture the chosen product according to a

constant-returns-to-sca e production function.

We suppose that the regions are endowed with a single primary input, which

we call labour. Consider first the manufacturing activity. Production of any

variety of consumer good in either country requires

  a^

 units oflabo ur per unit

of output. Hence the marginal cost of any good produced in country

  i

 is

  w^a^,

where  f  is the wage there, for  i = S  (South) and A (N orth) . At any pa rticu lar

moment, the set of available products and the number of firms in either

location able to produce every product is given by history. The producers

behave as Bertrand competitors, taking the prices of other firms' products and

the level of aggregate spending as fixed. They maximise profits by setting

marginal revenue equal to marginal cost.

A Northern firm with the unique ability to produce some variety faces,

according to (5) and our assumptions about market structure, a demand curve

with constant elasticity equal to

  e

Such a firm maximises profits by setting

a price

 p^

  that is a fixed mark-up over marginal cost, or

P N   =

  "^^flx/a- (6)

The producer earns instantaneous profits given by

 r •

  = {i-cc PsXs^

  (7)

where

  x^^

  is the equilibrium output level, calculated from (5). If two Northern

firms happ ene d to be capab le of produ cing a variety in comm on (e.g. if one h ad

imitated the innovation ofthe other), then as Bertrand competitors they would

each set a price equal to marginal cost and earn zero profits. It follows that no

Northern entrepreneur can recoup the fixed costs of imitation, so none of this

activity takes place in the North.

The equilibrium wage rate in the South is assumed to be less than that ofthe

North.^ We rule out the possibility that a Southern firm will have exclusive

Page 5: Endogenous Product Cycles Economic Journal 1991

7/25/2019 Endogenous Product Cycles Economic Journal 1991

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/endogenous-product-cycles-economic-journal-1991 5/17

I2l8

  THE

  ECONOMIC JOURNAL [SEPTEMBER

preneurs. This implies that  all   innovation occurs   in the   North,   and  that

knowledge acqui.sition

  in the

 South

  is

 confined

  to

 imitation.

  If two

 Southern

firms have copied

  the

 same variety

  of

 consumer good, these

  two

 will

 set

 prices

equal

  to

  their marginal costs

  and

  earn zero profits.

  So the

  second

  of the

imitators could never justify bearing

  the

 cost

 of

 reverse engineering. Therefore,

the only market structure that

  we

 need

  to

 consider

  for

 Southern producers

 is

one where

 a

 single firm

 (an

 imitator) competes with

 a

 single Northern firm

  (the

innovator)

  in the

 market

  for

 some variety.

Two outcomes

 may

 result from this competition, depending

 on the

 size ofthe

gap between Northern

  and

  Southern wages.

 If the gap is

 large,

  the

 Southern

firm can charge

 its

 monopoly price without regard

 for the

 competition from

  the

Northern innovator. This price  for   Southern products prevails whenever

Wf^a^/aL

  (the

  monopoly price) falls short

  of the

  marginal cost

  of

  Northern

production, w^aj^,

 or

 when w_^

 ^  aw^. We

 shall refer

 to

 this

 as the

 wide-gap cas

If relative wages

 in the

 South

  are

 somewhat higher,

  a

 Southern firm charging

its monopoly price would

  be

 undercut

  by its

 Northern rival.

  In

  this narrow-gap

case^

  the

  Southern firm prices just below

  the

  marginal cost

  of the

  Northern

producer, thereby capturing

  the

  entire market. Thus,

 we

 have

.s =  Wgd^/a  if Wg ^  aw; ,  {8a

Ps

 ~ ^N^x  if

 Ws

 ^

  ccw^.

  (8i)

The instantaneous profits ofa Southern firm are

where

 x^

 represents

 the

 firm s sales (calculated from

  (5)).

 Notice that,

 in

 either

case,,  the

  Southern firm uses

  its

  cost advantage

  to

  capture

  the

  entire

  sub-

market. Northern firms make

  no

 further sales once their varieties have been

copied abroad. This feature ofthe model captures

  the

 migration

 of

 production

from North  to  South,   as first described  by Vernon   (1966}.

We turn next

  to the

 learning activities.

 As in

 Romer (1990)

  and

 Grossman

and Helpman (1990, 1991),

 we

 assume that

  the

 resources devoted

  to

 industrial

research generate

 two

 sorts of outputs. First, when

 an

 entrepreneur hires labour

for purposes of  innovation   or imitation,   he  derives  an  appropriable output   in

the form  ofa   blueprint for producing  a  particular variety. This blueprint  is

the entry ticket into

  the

 product market,

  and

 carries

  the

 reward

  ofa

  stream

of oligopoly profits.

 At the

 same time,

 the

 development activity

 (in the

 North)

and

  the

 imitation activity

  (in the

  South) create non-appropriable benefits

  in

the form

 of

 additions

 to

 general knowledge. Such knowledge includes scientific

and technical information that

  has

  widespread appHcability,

  and

  that

contributes

 to the

 productivity

 of

 subsequent learning efforts.

  We

 assume that

the stocks of  industrial knowledge are  specific   to the  regions  in which they have

Page 6: Endogenous Product Cycles Economic Journal 1991

7/25/2019 Endogenous Product Cycles Economic Journal 1991

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/endogenous-product-cycles-economic-journal-1991 6/17

1990 ENDOGENOUS PRODUCT CYCLES I219

must devote ajjK   units of labour  to the task, w here aj is a fixed produc tivity

parameter  ( / for imitation)  and

 K^

 is the stock  of disembodied knowledge

capital  in the South.  We take  the stock  of knowledge  to be proportional  to

cumulative experience in  the learning sector in  the South, and choose units so

that

 K^

 =

  R5,

 where ^5 is the num ber of varieties th at have been imitated

  in the

past. Under this specification,^

ri^ = rif-LjIa,,

  (10)

where L,  represents labour employed  in  reverse engineering in the South.

Entry into imitation can  be  financed by bond issue or by an equ ity offering.

If this activity ever were to offer a  pure profit, incipient entry by entrepreneurs

would generate excess demand   for  Southern labour.  It  follows that,  in an

equilibrium with some labour devoted   to im itation  in the South,  the present

value

  of

 Sou thern profits from m anu factu ring just eq uals

  the

 cost

 of

 reverse

engineering, or

Differentiating this break-even condition with respect  to /, we  find

Equation  (ii) expresses a  no-arbitrage condition, equating  the sum of the

instantaneous profit rate (first term

  on the

 left-han d side)

  and the

  rate

 of

capital gain (second term   on the left-hand side)  to the instantaneo us interest

rate.  The capital-gain term reflects the fact that the value of a Southern firm

equals  the cost of imitation,  and so varies positively with  the wage rate and

negatively with productivity  in  the learning activity.

A potential Northern innovator faces  a  similar, though som ewhat more

complex decision problem. The development of a new variety requires a^/K^

units  of  labour, where  a , is  another productivity param eter  ( Z) for

development)  and A ;^. represents the level of scientific knowhow  in the N orth.

We assume that each development project contributes

 a

  similar amount

  to the

stock  of knowledge  in the North,  so that

  K^^

 is proportional  to  cumulative

experience   in innov ation. Units are chosen so that

  K^.

 =

 n.

 Then  the m easure

of the set of available products grows according to

fi

 =

 nLJao,

  (12)

where

 L^

 is the aggreg ate am oun t of labou r hired for product development. A

Northern innovator who brings out a new product  at time

 t

 faces thereafter a

positive probability that  the  pro duc t will  be  targeted  by a  Southern

* Some alternative specifications may be equally plausible. First, productivity  in imitation m ight depen d

on both imitation experience

  and

  knowledge areumu lated

  in the

 No rth. This specification would ap ply

 if

iiirormation dis.seminated internationally,  and if the knowledge generated  in the course of innovation were

Page 7: Endogenous Product Cycles Economic Journal 1991

7/25/2019 Endogenous Product Cycles Economic Journal 1991

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/endogenous-product-cycles-economic-journal-1991 7/17

1220

  THE

 ECONOMIC JOURNAL [SEPTEMBER

entrepreneur

 for

 imitation.

 If

 the product

 is

 copied

 at

 time

  T., the

 innovator's

stream

 of

 monopoly profits ends at T. In that event,

  the

 innovator earns, in

total, a

 sum

 whose present discounted value at /

 is

At

  the

 time that

 a

 particular product

 is

 developed,

  the

 date

  T at

 which

imitation will occur is unknown. However,  as we noted before, shareholders

can diversity away this product-specific risk

 by

 holding a portfolio of Northern

shares. Thus  the individual firm maximises  its stock market value by

maximising

  the

 expected present discounted value

 of

 the stream

 of

 monopoly

profits less innovation costs. We will assume that Northern agents have rational

expectations. Letting F(/,

  T

denote the cumulative distribution function

 for

 T

for a product developed at t (i.e.

 the

 probability that monopoly power wili

 be

lost to a Southern imitator before time  T), we can write the expected present

value

 of

 profits

 for

 a time-/ innovator

 as

Since we allow free entry by Northern entrepreneurs into product development,

a positive rate

 of

 innovation implies

V{t =wM<^o/n[t .

  13)

The evolution of imitation activity in the South after time / determines the

distribution of the terminal date Tfor

 a

 product developed

 at

 /. Since Southern

entrepreneurs choose their targets

 at

 random, each existing Northern monopoly

faces

  the

 same risk of being imitated.

  The

 instantaneous rate of imitation,

li{T =n_^{T ln {T ,

  gives

  the

 hazard rate

 for F(/, 7 ),

 or F>p/{i

 —F .

  This

Fit, T = i-t-r/i[T]dT.  14)

Using (14),

 and the

 definitions of

 V{t

and n(/,

 7 ),

 we

 calculate

(15)

Now, differentiating

  (13)

 with respect

  to t, and

 using (15),

 we

 find

Equation

  (16)

  expresses

  a

  no-arbitrage relationship similar

  to (n) . It

equates

  the sum of

 the instantaneous profit rate (first term

 on the

 left-hand

side)

 and the

 capital gain (second term on

 the

 left-hand side)  to

 the

 risk-

adjusted interest rate.

 The

 capital gain here

 is the

 increase in

 the

 value

 of a

typical Northern firm, which equals

  the

 rate

 of

 increase in Northern wages

Page 8: Endogenous Product Cycles Economic Journal 1991

7/25/2019 Endogenous Product Cycles Economic Journal 1991

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/endogenous-product-cycles-economic-journal-1991 8/17

I O

  ENDOGENOUS PRODUCT CYCLES

  I I

clearing conditions.

 In

 each region, lab ou r is employed

 in

 both ma nufacturing

and learning activities. Letting  X^ = ^^.v,, denote aggregate output in region i,

I = , S and /,; denote the exogenous labour supply there, we equ ate labo ur

supply and demand  in  each region in  the following equations:

iaj/ns ns

 +

 a^Xs = Lsl

  17)

{aj,/n n-\-a^X^

  = L .

  18)

The equations that  we have derived  in  this section fully de term ine the

evolution

  of

 the world econom y from any initial con ditions (i.e. nu m bers

 of

goods produced  in the No rth an d Sou th), provided that we choose an initial

level of spending, £ (0), consistent with long-run convergence to

 a

 steady state.

We proceed now

 to

 exam ine the steady-state properties ofth e model.

II.

  DETERMINANTS OF IMITATION AND INNOVATION IN THE LONG

RUN

In the steady state, the number of varieties grows

 at

  Me constant rate ^, and

Southern firms imitate  at the  constant rate  //. We are  interested  in the

determ inants ofthese long-run rates of innovation and imitation. We are also

concerned with growth of log   U { T ,  since this measures instantaneous utility in

our model. But it is easy to show that t/fiog  u{T ]/dt = (i  a) g/a, so the factors

that affect the long-run rate of innovation similarly influence the steady-state

growth in utility.

We normali.se nominal prices so that

  w^ = n.

  With this choice of numeraire,

all prices and wages grow

 at

  the common rate g

 in

  the steady state,

 as

 does

nominal spending  E.  Then

  4)

 implies

(19)

In the steady state, the share ofthe North in  the total number of varieties,

^.\  = «A-/ > is constant and equal  to g/{g  fi .  Using this fact, and substituting

(6),

  7) and

 (ig ) into (16), we find

^

  20)

Now we combine (18)

 and

 (20)

  to

 derive

where h = L ja^

 is the

 'effectiv e' lab ou r force

 of

 the N orth, measured

 in

terms of productivity

  in

  innovation.

Equation (21) expresses

 a

  steady-state relationship between g  and ji.

  We

depict this relationship  by the  curve  NN in Fig. i.* The curve shows

combinations

  of

  steady-state rates

  of

  innovation

  and

  imitation that

 are

consistent with labour-market clearing

  in

  the North

  and a

  profit rate there

Page 9: Endogenous Product Cycles Economic Journal 1991

7/25/2019 Endogenous Product Cycles Economic Journal 1991

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/endogenous-product-cycles-economic-journal-1991 9/17

1222  THE ECONOMIC JOURNAL [SEPTEMBER

into

 the

 learning sector, thereby decreasing aggregate output

 in the

 North,

 and

hence the sales base over which mark-up profits

 are

 earned. Second,

 an

 increase

in

 g

 raises

 the

 share

 of

 Northern products

 in the

 total number

 of

 varieties,

 and

thus lowers

  the

 output

  per

 Northern firm

  for a

 given

 n and X . At the

 same

time, an

 increase

 in the

 rate of innovation raises

 the

 interest rate,

 ceteris paribus

So

 an

 increase

 in g

 opens

 a

 positive

 gap

 between

 the

 risk-adjusted interest rate

and

  the

 profit rate.

 An

 increase

  in the

 rate

  of

 imitation

  is

 needed, then,

  to

restore equality between

  the two. The

 increase

 in fi

 raises

 the

 risk premium,

thereby exacerbating

  the

 disequilibrium,

 but it

 also raises

 the

 profit rate.

 As

can

  be

  seen from

  21), the

  effect

  on the

  profit rate

  the

  left-hand side)

dominates.

 The

 effect

  of/< on the

 Northern profit rate stems from

  the

 implied

reduction

  in a   and

 thus

 the

 increase

 in

 sales

 for

 each Northern firm

 at

 given

n

 and

  X .

To derive  a  second relationship between  g and //, we must brirtg  in the

equilibrium conditions for the South. The nature  of this second relationship

varies according to the size ofthe  gap between Northern and Southern wages.

We take up the wide-gap  and  narrow-gap cases in  turn, discussing  in each

instance  the determinants of  steady-state) g and {i.

The Wide-gap Case

R eca l l t ha t , when

  w_^/w^

 < a, a S ou t he r n i m i t a t o r cha r ges

  the

 mo nopo l y p r i ce

wi thout f ear

  of

  com pet i t ion f rom

  the

  o r i g ina l No r t he r n deve l ope r

  of

  t h a t

va r i e t y .  In  this case,  we sub s t i tute 8f l) ,  9a) and 19) in to  the  n o - a r b i t ra g e

cond i t i on

  for

 So uthe rn f irms ,

  11),

 wh ich gives

{i a axXs  =

 aa,{g

p .  22)

N ow

  we use the

  l abo u r - m ar ke t c l ea r i ng cond i t ion

  for the

  S o u t h ,

  17), to

subs t i tu te

  for X  in  22).

 R ecogn i s i ng t ha t

  the

 n u m b e r

  of

 S o u t h e r n p r o d u c t s

mus t g row

 at the

 r a te

 ^ in a

  s t eady s t a te ,

 we

 have

g= [\-a. hs-CLp,  23)

where h^

 =

 Z-s/fl/ represents

 the

 effective labour force ofthe South measured

 in

terms of its productivity  in imitation.

Page 10: Endogenous Product Cycles Economic Journal 1991

7/25/2019 Endogenous Product Cycles Economic Journal 1991

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/endogenous-product-cycles-economic-journal-1991 10/17

EN DO GE NO US PRO DUC T CYCLES 223

We represent equation (23) by the horizontal line labelled   SS  in Fig. i. The

steady-state rates of innovation and imitation for the wide-gap case are given

by the intersection ofthe curves  .S and  V.V in the figure.^ Of course, the wide -

gap case applies only if

 li;

 ^  aw^-  is implied by the point of intersection. (More

on this point below.)

We note first the effects of international trade on long-run growth in the two

regions. The North's autarky rate of innovation is found at the intersection of

th e  NN  curve and the horizontal axis, where  fi = o. Since the  A iV curve slopes

upward, the North innovates faster in the steady state of a wide-gap

equilibrium than it does in the absence of trade. Imitation causes resources to

be released from the Northern manufacturing sector, which find their way into

the research laboratory. This reallocation of resources is mediated by an

increase in the profit rate, which results when, at given   n a  smaller number of

firms competes in the Northern labour market. In autarky, the South would be

forced to develop its own varieties from scratch. The resource requirements for

this surely would exceed those needed for assimilating and adapting Northern

technologies. To the extent that this is true, the opportunities for imitation

contribute to a more rapid pace of technological progress in the South. In

particular, the region's autarky rate of learning is given by an equation like

(23), except that  aj is replaced by a pa ram ete r reflecting S outhern productivity

in

  innovation

say aj^g As long as a^s >   ^i^  the South also grows faster with trade

than without.

In the steady state ofa wide-gap equilibrium, the growth rate is proximately

determined by economic forces in the South. An expansion in the North's

labo ur force or a rise in the produ ctivity of N orthe rn lab our in the resea rch

laboratory shifts the  NN  curve upward. This reduces the rate of Southern

imitation a nd hence the steady-state share of produc ts manufac tured by the

South, but it has no effect on the steady-state growth rate.* The explanation for

this lies in the determination of a Southern firm's profit rate,, which in the

steady state must equal

  g-\-p.

  Consider a shock in the North that alters the

derived demand for Southern labour, hence the equilibrium relative wage

Wff/w^ . S ince the prices of S outh ern goods in the wid e-gap case are a fixed

mark-up over production costs there, the change in  w^/wy  alters profits per

variety and the cost of imitation equ iprop ortion ately . T he shock in the N orth

also may ch ange the fraction of produc ts m anufactured in the S outh. But given

aggregate So uthern o utput of manufactures  X^ a change in  n,y  affects similarly

the profits of a given variety and productivity in itnitation. So, by either

channel, the net effect on the profit  r te  in the South is nil. It follows that the

* If the

  SS

  curve lies everywhere above the A^^ curve, then th e narrow -gap case, rathe r than the wide-

gap case, applies. If the .55  curve lies everywhere below the A'A'curve, then there can be no steady slaie with

a positive rate of imitation in the South, Instead, the South imitates for a while, then produces a fixed set

of goods. An equilibrium with ongoing imitation requires that the

  A'JV

 curve em anate s from a point on the

Page 11: Endogenous Product Cycles Economic Journal 1991

7/25/2019 Endogenous Product Cycles Economic Journal 1991

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/endogenous-product-cycles-economic-journal-1991 11/17

1224 ^^^ ECONOMIC JOURN AL [SEPTEMB ER

initial values of ^ and .^5 contin ue to satisfy the con dition s for a stea dy -state

equil ibr ium.

An Improvement in productivity at manufacturing, a^, has no effect on   SS,

hence no effect on the steady -state values of// o r^ . But an expansion of effective

labour in the South, precipitated either by an increase in   L,, or a decline in  a,,

causes the  SS  curve to shift upward, and generates an increase in the steady-

state rates of imitation and innovation. The impact effect entails a rise in the

rate of imitation. In the North this raises the risk premium for product

deve lopm ent, but also boosts profits for each surviving mo nopo ly, as ou tpu t per

Northern brand expands. As we mentioned before, the latter effect dominates,

so innovation responds positively.

W e close ou r discussion ofth e w ide-gap case by considering the de term ina nts

ofthe relative wage. We evaluate {5) at the equilibrium prices given in (6) and

{8a),  an d then take the ratio of ou tpu ts per variety in the N orth and Sou th, to

derive

K^2

Substituting for ^^7X5 using (20) and (22), and noting

  IT^

  =  g/{g +  /f-), we find

  pj

The right-hand side of (24) is increasing in  and dechning in   g  and in  g/{i.

An expansion ofthe labour force in the North alters the right-hand side of

(25(7) only via its effect on /*. We see, therefore, that this shock causes   Wg/w^

to fall. A larger labour force in the South., on the other hand, implies

acceleration of both innovation and imitation, but a fall in the ratio   ol g   to  /i

(the slope of a ray from the origin to   E   falls as we move up along a given  NN

curve), hence a larger value of

  W^/K'^J-

  We conclude that the relative wage of

either region varies directly with the size of that region.

The response of relative wages to the productivity parameters is similar. An

improvement in the productivity of Northern researchers reduces the steady-

state rate of imitation, and also has a direct negative effect on the right-hand

side of (250), so the relative wage of the South falls in response. An

improvem ent in Southern prod uctivity iu imitation raises//, depresses^//*, and

directly increases the right-hand side of (25a), and so cau.scs   Wg/w^  to rise.

Our results on the relationship between labour supplies and relative wages

stand in sharp contrast to those reported by Krugman (1979). The sources of

the difference can be seen in the equation

Page 12: Endogenous Product Cycles Economic Journal 1991

7/25/2019 Endogenous Product Cycles Economic Journal 1991

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/endogenous-product-cycles-economic-journal-1991 12/17

EN DO GE NO US PR OD UC T CYCLES 225

nu m ber of differentiated goods, an expansion of a region's labou r force

increases the relative supply of a typical good m anu facture d there relative to

the supply of a good man ufactured abro ad. T his exerts dow nw ard pressure on

the relative price of goods em an atin g from the expa nd ing region, and so the

relative wage ofthe region tends to fall. But (256) points to two additional

channels through which a change in labour supply might affect relative wages

in the long run. First, the endowment change might induce a reallocation of

resources between manufacturing and re.search in each country. If the steady-

state size ofthe research sector exp and s in both regions (i.e. if^ rises), resources

must be drawn from manufacturing in each one. This tends to increase the

relative wage of the North, because the per-unit labour requirements for

research are greater there in relation to the size of the region's labour force.'

Secondly, the expanding region captures in the long run an increased share of

the total num ber of differentiated prod ucts. Th at is,

 cr ^

 varies directly with  L^,

bu t inversely with Z, ., reflecting the fact th at p rod uc ts accum ula te relatively

faster along the transition path to a new steady state in the region that has

experienced the endowment growth. With relatively more goods to produce,

the expanding region sees growth in the relative demand for its labour.

Evidently, these latter effects dominate. In a sense, labour supply creates its

own (long-run) demand in the research laboratory.

Tke Narrow-gap Case

In Fig. 2 we have reproduced the

  A''JV

 curve (equation (21)), which c ontinues

to apply. We find a second relationship between the long-run values of/i and

g  for the narrow-gap case by substituting the equilibrium prices in (6) and  {8b)

into (5), taking the ratio of aggregate outputs in the North and South, and

using the result together with (17) and (18). This gives

^   ~—71 r~ - (26)

^

  [fi-g]

  g ^

We plot the com binations of and   fi   that satisfy (26) as  XX   in Fig. 2. This

curve gives the rates of innovation and imitation that are consistent with

simultaneous clearing of the labour markets and product markets in each

region. It is easy to show that the  XX   curve slopes upward, once we recall that

.s > A.v is requ ired for the ex istence of a steady -state eq uilib rium with a

positive rate of imitation. We prove in our working paper (Grossman and

H clpm an , 1989(2) that the XA curve must be steeper tha n the A ^A ' curve at any

point of intersection, and that the curves intersect exactly once. This

intersection (at  Q)  represents the unique narrow-gap equilibrium, provided

that the relative wage associated with that point satisfies  Wf^/w^  > a.^

Fig. 2 can be used to study the relationship between the effective sizes ofthe

Page 13: Endogenous Product Cycles Economic Journal 1991

7/25/2019 Endogenous Product Cycles Economic Journal 1991

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/endogenous-product-cycles-economic-journal-1991 13/17

1226

THE ECONOMIC JOURNAL

[SEPTEMBER

Fig. J The narrow-gap case.

two regions and the long-run rates

 of

 imitation and innovation.

 To

 conserve

space, we refer the interested reader to our (1989  a working paper, and present

here only  the  results  of the  analysis.  We  find that  the  long-run rate of

innovation rises

 in

 response

 to an

 expansion

 in

  the size of either labour force,

or

  a

  reduction

  in the

 labour requirements

  for

 learning new technologies

 in

either region. The rate of imitation, on the other hand, varies directly with tbe

effective size of tbe S ou th, b ut inversely w ith tbe size of the N ortb . As in tbe

narrow-gap case, tbe relative wage of a region increases with the relative size

of that region's labour force.

I I I .  TRADE AND INDUSTRIAL POLICIES

Nations often contemplate tbe use of policies to speed their growtb

 or to

  slow

the rate of

 loss

  of markets to foreign competitors. We can use our model of tbe

product cycle

  to

 study the effects

  of

 policy

 on

 long-run rates

 of

 growtb and

imitation,  and on relative wages in  tbe steady state. In  tbis section we sbal

consider subsidies  to the learning activities and protective trad e policies. We

limit

  our

 analysis here

  to

  positive issues; G rossm an

  and

 He lpm an (1991)

contains

  a

  complete welfare analysis

  for a

  small country witb

  an

 economic

structure similar

  to

 tbe one described here.

We let I — Aj, i

 = S, N^

 represe nt tbe fraction of learn ing costs borne by tb

government in country

 i

We assume that subsidies are financed by lump-sum

taxes. Since Ricardian neutrality applies in our model, we need not specify the

intertemporal pattern of the tax collections, so long as tbe present value of tbe

government's casb flow

 is

 zero.

The subsidies to learning alter tbe private incentives for researcb, hence the

no-arbitrage conditions tbat apply in eacb region

 in

 tbe long-run equilibrium

Witb these policies in place, we need to multiply the rigbt-band side of (21)  by

Page 14: Endogenous Product Cycles Economic Journal 1991

7/25/2019 Endogenous Product Cycles Economic Journal 1991

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/endogenous-product-cycles-economic-journal-1991 14/17

199^] ENDOGENOUS PRODUCT CYCLES I22 7

to tbe left, wbile leaving tbe  curve in place. Tbis policy reduces the long-run

rate of imitation and boosts the steady-state share of varieties produced in the

North, but has no effect on tbe long-run growtb rate. Using a modified version

of

 (25(1),

 it is easy to see that tbe Northern government's intervention raises ihe

relative wage of its workers in the steady state.

A subsidy to imitation or to technology adaptation in the South shifts the 

curve ofthe wide-gap case upward. The growth rate and the imitation rate rise,

as does tbe sbare of varieties produced in tbe South. Like an improvement in

productivity in imitation, this serves to raise tbe Soutb's relative wage in the

long run. The positive effect on the growth rate should be well understood by

now. Although tbe speeding of the product cycle directly reduces the

profitability of product development, tbis effect is more tban offset by the

expansion of sales for Northern products tbat survive. So the incentive to

innovate is strengthened by faster imitation in tbe South.

In the narrow-gap case, a subsidy to imitation serves only to alter relative

wages {see Grossman and Helpman, 19890). As before, tbe relative wage ofthe

South rises when its gov ernm ent subsidises learnin g. An R D subsidy in tbe

Nortb causes tbe growtb rate and tbe rate of imitation both to increase. The

subsidy also serves to increase tbe relative wage of tbe North in tbe long

run.

We turn now to trade policy. For the wide-gap case, the analysis is quite

simple. An  ad v lorem  tariff or export subsidy imposed by either country does

not affect tbe elasticity of demand perceived by producers of any nationality.

The refore, it does not affect tbe prices charg ed by them . T b e profit rates do not

change with trade policy, nor do tbe no-arbitrage conditions. Of course, the

labour-market-clearing conditions, (17) and (18), continue to apply. It follows

that trade policies in either country do not affect the  A JV or the  of the wide-

ga p case, and therefore tbey do not alter the steady -state rates of inno vation or

imitation.

The conclusion for the narrow-gap case turns out the same. Tbe reader is

referred to our (19890) working paper for tbe details. In our model with only

one production sector, trade policies (and production incentives more

generally) do not affect tbe long-run allocation of resources to the learning

activity, because tbeir effect on investment incentives is fully offset by an

induced change in factor rewards. We should note, however, that tbe

conclusion would b e different In an ex tended version of ou r model tba t

included a second ma nufacturing sector, a second prim ary factor of prod uction ,

and different factor intensities in the various economic activities.

I V . C O N C L U S I O N S

Tbe product cycle describes an ever-evolving pattern of Inter-regional trade.

Page 15: Endogenous Product Cycles Economic Journal 1991

7/25/2019 Endogenous Product Cycles Economic Journal 1991

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/endogenous-product-cycles-economic-journal-1991 15/17

1228 THE ECONOMIC JOUR NAL [SEPTEMB ER

average length of the cycle and the speed with which new products are

introduced to the market are both determined endogenousiy. We have used our

model to study tbe determinants of the long-run rates of imitation and

innovation, and the long-run distribution oflabour income.

As in previous studies of technology-driven growth (e.g. Romer (1990),

Grossman and Helpman (198913)), we found that tbe size ofthe resource base

and the productivity of resources in tbe learning activities are important

determinants of tbe steady-state growtb rate. Long-run growtb is faster tbe

larger is tbe resource base of the South, and the more productive are its

resources in learning the production processes for products originally developed

in the North. This is surprising, perbaps, because faster imitation by the South

means on average a shorter period over which a Northern firm can earn

monopoly profits. But profits during the monopoly phase are higher when a

smaller num ber of No rthe rn firms compete for resources in the m anufa cturing

sector. We found that the latter effect dominates, so faster imitation by the

South uhimately strengthens the incentive to innovate in tbe Nortb.

Steady-state growtb also increases witb the effective size of tbe North,

provided tbat the gap between wages in the North and South is not too large

(what we have called the 'narrow-gap case'). An increase in the North's

effective labour force always slows the rate of imitation (hence the average

length of tbe first stage of tbe product cycle) and raises tbe steady-state sbare

of varieties produced in the North. An increase in tbe effective labour force of

tbe South has jus t tbe opposite effect on the im itation rate an d on pro duc t

shares in the long run.

Perbaps surprisingly, we find tbat the relative wage in the Nortb rises when

tbe effective size of tbe North expands in relation to the effective size of the

South. Tbis result, which contradicts one derived by Krugman (1979) in his

product-cycle model with exogenous rates of innovation and imitation, stems

ultima tely from the increasing-returns na ture of tbe tecbnologies for pro duc tion

of goods and knowledge.

In comparing tbe product-cycle equilibrium to one witb autarky in eacb

region, we find that international trade always contributes to faster growth in

botb regions. Tbe migration of some products from North to South frees

Northern resources for use in product development. In the steady-state

equilibrium witb trade, Nortbern firms bave a greater incentive to undertake

R D th an in au tark y, because eacb earns a bigher profit ra te, albeit for a

shorter period of time. Th e South grows faster w itb trade tban witbo ut, because

tbe resources needed for learning and adapting Northern technologies are far

fewer tban those needed for developing new products from scratch.

We studied the long-run effects of two types of policies. Subsidisation of tbe

learning activities (innovation in tbe North or imitation in tbe South) tends to

boost long-run rates of growth. The only exception to this occurs for subsidies

Page 16: Endogenous Product Cycles Economic Journal 1991

7/25/2019 Endogenous Product Cycles Economic Journal 1991

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/endogenous-product-cycles-economic-journal-1991 16/17

199^] ENDOGENOUS PRODUC T CYCLES 1229

policies serve only to alter relative wages and the steady-state levels of real

spending in tbe two regions. This finding, which is perhaps reminiscent of

similar results tha t app ly in neoclassical models of grow th, rehes strongly on the

two-sector structure of our regional economies. If, instead, we were to allow a

second manufacturing activity in each country in a manner that preserved the

existence of a steady state, trade policy would indeed play a role in determining

tbe long-run growth rate.

Princeton University

Tel Aviv University

Date of  receipt  of final typescript: Octob er iggo

REFERENCES

Dollar, D. (1986). 'Technological innovation, capital mobility, and the product cycle in the North-South

t r a d e '  merican Economic  Review vol, 76 (March), pp. 177-90.

Grossman, G. M. and Helpman, B, (1989a). 'Endogenous product cycles.' National Bureau of Economic

Research Working Paper No. 2913, Cambridge MA.

(1989*)-  'Product development and international trade. '

  Journat 0/ Potilical Econom y

vol. 97

(December), pp, 1261-83.

(1990).  'Comparative advantage and long-run growth.'  mencan Economic Review vol, 80 (September),

pp.  796-815.

(1991).  Growth and welfare in a small open economy ,' In  International Trade an d Trade Poticy [cd. E.

Helpman and A. Razin). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, Torthcoming.

Jrn.scn, R. and Th ursb y, M . (1986), A strategic appro ach to the product life cycle.'  Journal

  of

 International

Economics voi. 21 (November), pp. 269-84,

('987)- 'A decision theoretical model of innovation, technology transfer and trade,' Review

  of Economic

Studies

vol. 54 [October), pp. 631-49,

Kru gm an, P. R. (1979). 'A model oi innovation, technology transfer, and th e world distribution of income.

Joumat of

 Potilicat  Economy vol. 87 [April), pp, 253-66,

Romer, P .M . (1990), 'Endogenous technical change.'  Journal 0/Potilicat  Economy vol. 98 [October),

pp.  S71-S102,

Segerstrom, P. S., Anant, T. C. A, and Dinopoulos, E.  [1987}.  'A Schumpeterian model ofthe product life

cycle.' Econometrics and Economic Theory Paper No, 8fio6, Michigan Stale University,

Vernon, R. (1966). 'International investment and international trade in the product cycle.'  Quartetty

 Joumat

of

 Economics

vol. 80 (May), pp, 190—207.

Page 17: Endogenous Product Cycles Economic Journal 1991

7/25/2019 Endogenous Product Cycles Economic Journal 1991

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/endogenous-product-cycles-economic-journal-1991 17/17