Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    1/47

    A conditional characteristics model of stock returns

    Malcolm Baker Harvard Business School and NBER

    [email protected]

    Jeffrey Wurgler NYU Stern School of Business

    [email protected]

    August 25, 2003

    Abstract

    Traditional asset pricing models maintain that differences in expected returns across

    securities reflect differences in systematic risk. We develop a model in which cross-sectional differences in expected returns reflect the pattern of mispricing created by timevariation in investor sentiment and cross-sectional variation in the difficulty of valuationand arbitrage As predicted we find that when investor sentiment is high stocks whose

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    2/47

    and arbitrage As predicted we find that when investor sentiment is high stocks whose

    I. Introduction

    Traditional asset pricing models attribute cross-sectional differences in expected returns

    to differences in systematic risk. As in Markowitz (1959), investors are assumed to care about

    the mean and variance of their portfolio, and think about individual securities in statistical terms,

    as how their respective expected returns, variances, and covariances affect the portfolio return.

    Sharpe (1964), Merton (1973), Ross (1976), and Breeden (1979) show that in an equilibrium of

    diversified or Markowitz-type investors, individual securities are priced so that their expected

    returns depend only on their systematic risks, i.e. their covariances with relevant market

    aggregates or state variables.

    The systematic risk view is elegant, but its empirical relevance remains uncertain. Market

    beta does not explain cross-sectional differences in expected returns, while firm characteristics,

    such as size and book-to-market, have robust effects (Banz (1981), Basu (1983), and Fama and

    French (1992)). Fama and French (1993) suggest that these characteristics proxy for covariances

    with systematic risk factors, but Daniel and Titman (1997) find that they have cross-sectional

    explanatory power that is separate from the covariance structure of returns. Recent research has

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    3/47

    which they are claims, as bundles of salient investment characteristics, not as variances and

    covariances; that investor sentiment varies over time; and that securities vary cross-sectionally in

    the difficulty of valuation and arbitrage. These ingredients lead to a conditional characteristics

    model in which expected returns reflect predictable corrections of mispricing, not compensation

    for systematic risk. In particular, the model predicts that when sentiment is optimistic, stocks

    whose salient characteristics can sustain optimistic valuations, especially those that are difficult

    to arbitrage, are relatively overpriced and hence have low expected returns. Conditional on low

    sentiment, the same stocks are predicted to be relatively underpriced, and have high expected

    returns. We motivate the approach and these specific predictions with a discussion of historical

    bubbles and crashes, as well as theoretical and psychological considerations.

    To test these predictions, we gather a set of investor sentiment proxies to use as time

    series conditioning variables. We use the closed-end fund discount, NYSE turnover, the volume

    and first-day returns on IPOs, the equity share, the dividend premium, and a composite index

    based on the common variation in these variables. To reduce the likelihood that these proxies are

    connected to systematic risks, we orthogonalize them to a range of macroeconomic variables.

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    4/47

    higher on young stocks than older stocks, unprofitable stocks than profitable ones, and nonpayers

    than dividend payers. When sentiment is high, however, these patterns completely reverse. Thus,

    variables that do not have any unconditional explanatory power actually reveal a striking sign-

    flip pattern, in the predicted direction, conditional on sentiment.

    The sorts also reveal U-shaped conditional patterns involving salient characteristics of

    growth opportunities and distress. When sentiment is low, expected returns are high on both

    highest- and lowest-sales growth deciles relative to firms in between. These extreme deciles

    represent ultra-growth stocks and distressed stocks with contracting sales, respectively. When

    sentiment is high, this U-shaped pattern flips upside down, so both ultra-growth and distressed

    stocks now expect lower returns relative to those in the middle. There are U-shaped conditional

    patterns in external finance and book-to-market as well. These patterns are consistent with the

    prediction that hard-to-value firms are particularly prone to underpricing (overpricing) when

    investors are pessimistic (optimistic). Again, note that these U-shaped conditional patterns, like

    the monotonic conditional patterns involving age, profitability, and dividend payment, are

    averaged away in unconditional studies.

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    5/47

    conclusion. We directly test, and reject, the basic systematic risk alternative explanation in which

    the conditionally varying expected returns of young, small, unprofitable, nonpaying, etc. firms

    are tied to conditionally varying covariances with the stock market or consumption growth. Also,

    we find evidence of conditional patterns in returns around earnings announcements that roughly

    match those in the sorts, indicating that at least a portion of those results are due to the correction

    of too-optimistic or too-pessimistic expectations.

    The results have broad implications, which we highlight at the end of the paper. Here we

    point out that the conditional characteristics model builds upon and ties together several themes

    in the recent literature. Lettau and Ludvigson (2001) study conditional systematic risks, much as

    we condition on sentiment. Daniel and Titman (1997) introduce a firm characteristics model for

    expected returns. We extend this approach and give it a specific, conditional motivation. Shleifer

    (2000) reviews early research on sentiment and limited arbitrage, two key ingredients in the

    model. Barberis and Shleifer (2003) and Barberis, Shleifer, and Wurgler (2003) develop and test

    models of category-level trading. Conditional shifts in demand for groups of securities with the

    same salient characteristics are at the core of the model.

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    6/47

    [ ] 11211 '' ++= it t it it T a R E xbxb (1)

    where i indexes firms or securities, t is time, x is a vector of firm or security characteristics, and

    T is a time series conditioning variable. Formally, this model adds conditional effects to the

    unconditional characteristics model of Daniel and Titman (1997).

    In the remainder of this section, we argue that Eq. (1) is appropriate for capturing the

    correction of mispricings that result from broad fluctuations in investor sentiment, i.e. optimism

    or pessimism, in the presence of cross-sectional differences in the difficulty of valuation and

    arbitrage. We motivate more specific aspects of Eq. (1) with historical observations, economic

    considerations, and psychological considerations. We summarize the discussion with empirical

    predictions regarding appropriate characteristics and conditioning variables.

    B. Historical motivation

    Descriptions of historical market bubbles and crashes offer a number of useful insights.

    Kindleberger (2001) draws general lessons from bubbles that have occurred over the past few

    hundred years, while Brown (1991), Dreman (1979), Malkiel (1990, 1999), Shiller (2000), and

    Siegel (1998) focus more specifically on recent U.S. stock market episodes. These accounts help

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    7/47

    boom came back to earth in 1962 Growth stocks took the brunt of the decline, falling much

    further than the general market (p. 54 - 57). Dreman (1979, p. 70) confirms this account.

    The next widely noted episode of speculation occurred in 1967 and 1968. Brown writes

    that scores of franchisers, computer firms, and mobile home manufactures seemed to promise

    overnight wealth. [while] quality was pretty much forgotten (p. 90). Malkiel and Dreman

    also note this pattern a focus on firms with strong earnings growth or potential, while an

    avoidance of the major industrial giants, buggywhip companies, as they were sometimes

    contemptuously called (Dreman 1979, p. 74-75). Another characteristic viewed as out of favor

    was dividends. According to the New York Times , during the speculative market of the late

    1960s many brokers told customers that it didnt matter whether a company paid a dividend

    just so long as its stock kept going up (9/13/1976). However, after 1968, as it became clear

    that capital losses were possible, investors came to value dividends (10/7/1999).

    Anecdotal accounts describe the early 1970s as a bear market, with general investor

    sentiment at a low level. The only stocks with notably high valuations were a set of old, large,

    stable, consistently profitable stocks known as the nifty fifty. Brown, Malkiel, and Siegel

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    8/47

    and 78. Ritter (1984) studies the hot issue market of 1980, finding greater initial returns on

    IPOs of natural resource start-ups than on larger, mature, profitable offerings. Of 1983, Malkiel

    (p. 74-75) writes that the high-technology new-issue boom of the first half of 1983 was an

    almost perfect replica of the 1960s episodes The bubble appears to have burst early in the

    second half of 1983 the carnage in the small company and new-issue markets was truly

    catastrophic. Brown confirms this account. Of the mid-1980s, Malkiel suggests that What

    electronics was to the 1960s, biotechnology became to the 1980s. new issues of biotech

    companies were eagerly gobbled up. having positive sales and earnings was actually

    considered a drawback (p. 77-79). By 1987 and 1988, however, market sentiment had changed

    from an acceptance of an exciting story to a desire to stay closer to earth with low-multiple

    stocks that actually pay dividends (p. 79).

    The late 1980s and early 1990s are not viewed as remarkable by these sources. The

    mid- through late-1990s bubble in Internet and technology stocks will be familiar. By all

    accounts, investor sentiment was generally high before the bubble popped in 2000. This episode

    is analyzed in detail by Ofek and Richardson (2002). Malkiel draws parallels to episodes in the

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    9/47

    of generally high sentiment appear to have been associated with a tendency for firms with

    characteristics such as small size, young age, no dividends, low or negative current profits, and

    apparently strong growth potential to be overpriced relative to firms with the opposite

    characteristics. Conditions of low sentiment, on the other hand, are associated with the opposite

    pattern in relative prices.

    C. Economic motivation

    Economic considerations tend to reinforce the historical impression that mispricings are

    more frequent and severe in young, small, unprofitable, nonpaying, and/or high perceived-

    growth firms. The first is that the characteristics of no earnings history and apparently unlimited

    growth opportunities combine to allow unsophisticated investors to plausibly defend a wide

    range of valuations, from (objectively) much too low to much too high. In bubble periods, the

    same characteristics allow investment bankers or, worse, swindlers, to plausibly defend the

    higher range in selling securities. Thus, stocks with these characteristics are naturally more

    sensitive to sentiment swings. By contrast, the valuation of a mature firm, with an earnings

    history and high dividends, is less arbitrary.

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    10/47

    D. Psychological motivation

    Financial economists have tended to view firm characteristics as merely proxies for

    deeper fundamentals, but some psychological principles suggest that investor demands may be

    based directly on firm characteristics. To see how, some comments on the cognitive process of

    categorization may be useful. 2 Psychologists suggest that an objects category is determined by a

    set of essential features, or characteristics, that are shared by the members of the category. As a

    result, categorization is useful for making inferences. For example, for the category birds some

    of the defining characteristics include can fly, has wings, and has feathers. Knowing that

    an object has two of these features allows it to be categorized as a bird; and then one can

    reasonably infer the third feature.

    In this spirit, and the spirit of Lancaster (1966, 1971), we propose that typical investors

    view individual securities as bundles of salient investment characteristics for example no

    earnings, young age, or high dividends. We hypothesize that typical investors determine the

    merit of investing in a security by processing its salient characteristics. Investors may evaluate

    the salient characteristics directly. More interestingly, they may use characteristics to categorize

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    11/47

    suggested above, this will be true even if there is an intervening process of categorization and

    even if all trading is done at the category level, so long as psychologists are correct that

    categories are defined by a common bundle of characteristics. It is also empirically convenient to

    be able to boil categories down to their defining characteristics. This allows us to study such

    episodes as the 1968 growth stocks bubble and the late-1990s Internet bubble in terms of a

    roughly similar set of characteristics. The meaning of specific category labels, on the other hand,

    are often ephemeral casual observation suggests that the connotation of Internet stocks

    changed drastically from 1999 to 2001.

    E. Predictions

    This discussion helps to flesh out a predictive model of the form of Eq. (1). Both

    historical and economic considerations imply that in conditions of general investor optimism

    (call it high sentiment, a bubble, or a bull market), firms whose salient characteristics suggest an

    opportunity for extreme capital gains are more likely to be overpriced relative to firms with the

    opposite characteristics. The reverse applies when investors are more pessimistic (low sentiment,

    a crash, a bear market). In addition, psychological considerations suggest that investor demand

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    12/47

    III. Data

    A. Firm characteristics and returns

    The firm-level data is from the merged CRSP-Compustat database. The sample includes

    all common stock (share codes 10 and 11) of nonfinancial firms (excluding SIC code 6) between

    1962 through 2001. We match accounting data for fiscal year-ends in calendar year t -1 to

    (monthly) returns from July t through June t +1.

    Table 1 shows summary statistics. Panel A summarizes returns variables. Following

    common practice, momentum MOM is defined as the cumulative raw return for the eleven-

    month period between 12 and two months prior to the observation return. We will consider

    momentum as a control or robustness variable, not as a salient firm characteristic.

    The remaining panels summarize the firm and security characteristics that we consider.

    The discussion of the previous section points us directly to several variables. To that list, we add

    a few more characteristics that, by introspection, seem likely to be salient to investors. Overall,

    we roughly group characteristics as most directly pertaining to firm size and age, profitability,

    dividends, growth opportunities, and distress.

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    13/47

    items (Item 18) plus income statement deferred taxes (Item 50) minus preferred dividends (Item

    19), if earnings are positive; book equity ( BE ) is shareholders equity (Item 60) plus balance sheet

    deferred taxes (Item 35). E> 0 is a dummy variable for profitable firms.

    Panel D summarizes dividend payment characteristics. Dividends to equity D/BE is

    dividends per share at the ex date (Item 26) times Compustat shares outstanding (Item 25)

    divided by book equity. D>0 is a dummy for a firm with positive dividends per share by the ex

    date. The decline in the percentage of firms paying dividends is noted by Fama and French

    (2001) is apparent. As they point out, this is partly explained by the increasing proportion of

    unprofitable firms.

    Panel E summarizes characteristics that could serve as salient indictors of growth

    opportunities, distress, or both. The elements of book-to-market equity BE/ME are defined

    above. External finance activity EF/A is defined as the change in assets (Item 6) minus the

    change in retained earnings (Item 36) divided by assets. Sales growth ( GS ) is the change in net

    sales (Item 12) divided by prior-year net sales. We measure and report sales growth GS/10 as the

    decile of the firms sales growth in the prior year relative to NYSE firms decile breakpoints.

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    14/47

    market timing motives are important to external finance, that variable could serve as a generic

    misvaluation indicator as well.

    In Panels C, D, and E, the accounting data for fiscal years ending in t -1 are matched to

    monthly returns from July of year t through June of year t +1. To reduce the influence of outliers

    and data errors, all characteristics variables, plus momentum, are Winsorized each year at their

    0.5 and 99.5 percentiles.

    B. Investor sentiment

    Prior research suggests a number of plausible proxies for investor sentiment to use as

    time-series conditioning variables. We consider six proxies the average closed-end fund

    discount, NYSE share turnover, the number and average first-day returns on IPOs, the equity

    share in new issues, and the dividend premium as well as a composite sentiment index that

    takes the first principal component of these proxies. Each variable is measured annually from

    1962 through 2000.

    To isolate the sentiment component of these proxies from any business cycle

    components, we orthogonalize each of them with respect to several macroeconomic variables.

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    15/47

    difference between the net asset value of closed-end fund shares and their market prices. Prior

    work suggests that the discount is inversely related to investor sentiment. Zweig (1973) uses the

    closed-end discount to forecast reversion in Dow Jones stocks, and Lee, Shleifer, and Thaler

    (1991) examine several attributes of the discount. We take the value-weighted average discount

    on closed-end stock funds for 1962 through 1993 from Neal and Wheatley (1998), for 1994

    through 1998 from CDA/Wiesenberger, and for 1999 and 2000 from turn-of-the-year issues of

    the Wall Street Journal .

    NYSE share turnover is based on the ratio of reported share volume to average shares

    listed from the NYSE Fact Book . Baker and Stein (2002) motivate turnover (and more generally

    liquidity) as a sentiment index. In a market with short-sales constraints, irrational investors

    participate and add liquidity only when they are optimistic, and hence high liquidity

    coincides with overvaluation. Consistent with this interpretation, Jones (2001) finds that high

    turnover forecasts low market returns. Turnover displays an exponential positive trend over our

    period, however, and the May 1975 elimination of fixed commissions have a visible effect. As a

    partial solution, the raw turnover ratio TURN is detrended by the five-year moving average

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    16/47

    non-sentiment explanations for why IPO volume and underpricing vary over time, but they do

    not imply predictive relationships in the cross-section of stock returns.

    The share of equity issues in total equity and debt issues is another measure of financing

    activity that may capture an aspect of investor sentiment. Baker and Wurgler (2000) find that

    when the equity share is in its bottom (top) historical quartile, the next years equal-weighted

    market return averages 27% (-8%). The equity share is defined as gross equity issuance divided

    by gross equity plus gross long-term debt issuance using data from the Federal Reserve Bulletin .

    The equity share S is adjusted for the apparent regime change in debt issues in the early 1980s,

    which coincided with the emergence of junk debt markets and the drop in inflation. 3

    While both measures reflect equity issuance, the number of IPOs and the equity share

    have some important differences. The equity share includes SEOs, has strong predictive power

    for market returns, and scales by total external finance to isolate the composition of finance from

    the overall level. On the other hand, the IPO variables may better reflect demand for certain

    regions of the cross-section including young firms, small firms, and extreme-growth firms

    that Section II suggests may be particularly sensitive to sentiment.

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    17/47

    relationships, which raises the possibility that different variables may reflect sentiment sooner or

    later. For instance, Ibbotson and Jaffe (1975) and Lowry and Schwert (2002), and Benveniste,

    Wilhelm, Ljungqvist, and Yu (2003) find that IPO volume lags the first-day returns on IPOs. A

    natural interpretation is that sentiment is in part behind the high first-day returns, and this in turn

    attracts additional IPO volume with some lag. Put more generally, one suspects that sentiment

    measures involving firm supply responses ( S or NIPO ) are likely to lag sentiment measures that

    are based directly on stock prices or investor behavior ( RIPO, P D-ND , TURN , and CEFD ).

    We form a composite sentiment index SENTIMENT in order to capture the common

    factor in the sentiment proxies and to help us identify the most effective timing of the individual

    proxies. The process is as follows. We start by estimating the first principal component of the six

    sentiment proxies and their lags. This gives us a first-stage index with twelve loadings, one for

    each of the current and lagged proxies. We then compute the correlation between the first-stage

    index and the current and lagged values of each of the proxies. We then construct SENTIMENT

    as the first principal component of six terms the lead or lag of each proxy, whichever has the

    higher correlation with the first-stage index. This leads to the final, more parsimonious index:

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    18/47

    variables. We will make use of this pattern in the subsequent analysis, i.e. we will condition on

    the first predetermined value of CEFD , NIPO , S , and SENTIMENT , and the lag of the first

    predetermined value of TURN , RIPO , and P D-ND .

    Figure 1 shows that the sentiment proxies line up well with anecdotal accounts of

    investor sentiment. Most of the proxies point to low sentiment in the first few years of the sample

    (which follow a 1961 crash in growth stocks) the closed-end fund discount and the dividend

    premium are relatively high, and turnover and equity issuance-related variables are low. Each

    variable identifies a spike in sentiment in 1968 and 1969, matching anecdotal accounts.

    Sentiment then tails off until, by the mid-1970s, it is low by most measures, although for the

    turnover this pattern is confounded by deregulation. The late 1970s through mid-1980s sees

    generally rising sentiment, and according to the composite index, sentiment has not dropped

    below a medium level since 1980. In 1999, the peak of the Internet bubble, sentiment peaks

    again by most proxies.

    This correspondence with anecdotal accounts is encouraging. It confirms, to the extent

    possible, that the proxies capture the intended variation. Also noteworthy is that cleaning the

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    19/47

    IV. Empirical tests

    A. Sorts

    Table 3 gives a simple, nonparametric look at the conditional characteristics model. We

    place each monthly returns observation into a bin according to the decile rank that a given

    characteristic takes at the beginning of that month, and then according to the level of a sentiment

    proxy from the beginning of that year. We then compute the average monthly return for that bin

    and look for patterns. We report sorts on CEFD in Table 3a and SENTIMENT in Table 3b. To be

    clear, in light of the timing discussion above, we condition returns from calendar year t on the

    December of year t -1 values of CEFD and SENTIMENT . Also, to keep the meaning of the

    deciles relatively constant over time, we define them based on NYSE firms only. The tradeoff is

    that there is not a smooth distribution of firms across bins in any given month.

    For brevity, we omit sorts on the five other sentiment proxies. They give similar results,

    which are available upon request, and they are broken out separately in all other tables, where

    they fit more compactly. But it seems worth showing results for CEFD alongside the overall

    index, however, because CEFD is the cleanest general sentiment indicator. It is not

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    20/47

    The first rows of Table 3 show the effect of size conditional on sentiment. They reveal

    that the cross-sectional size effect exists in low-sentiment conditions only, i.e. when CEFD is

    positive or when SENTIMENT is negative (a final reminder that here, and in all subsequent

    tables, the sentiment proxies are net of macroeconomic effects and standardized). Specifically,

    Table 3b shows that when SENTIMENT is negative, returns average 2.59 percent per month for

    the bottom ME decile and 0.84 for the top decile. This pattern puts some already known results

    into a broader perspective, namely that the size effect is largely a January effect (Keim (1983),

    Blume and Stambaugh (1983)), and that the January effect is in turn stronger after a period of

    low returns (Reinganum (1983)), which is precisely when sentiment is likely to be low.

    As an aside, the average returns across the first two rows of Table 3 show that expected

    returns tend to be higher across the board when sentiment is low. This is consistent with prior

    results that the equity share and turnover, for example, forecast market returns. More generally, it

    supports our premise that investor sentiment broadly affects stocks, and so the existence of richer

    conditional patterns in the cross-section should not be entirely surprising.

    The conditional cross-sectional effect of Age is even more striking. Investors demand

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    21/47

    of favor when SENTIMENT is low they earn huge subsequent returns of 3.04 percent per

    month. However, as with ME , the cross-sectional effect of Sigma appears only in low sentiment

    conditions. This suggests that the two effects are closely related.

    The next rows examine profitability and dividends. The simplest and perhaps most salient

    comparison for investors is between profitable and unprofitable ( E< 0) firms and between payers

    and nonpayers ( D=0 ). These contrasts are summarized in the extreme right columns of Table 3,

    where we average returns across profitable firms and payers and compare them to unprofitable

    firms and nonpayers, respectively. They again demonstrate a conditional sign-flip pattern. Table

    3b shows that when SENTIMENT is positive, monthly returns are 0.33 percent higher on

    profitable firms than unprofitable firms and 0.42 percent higher on payers. When it is negative,

    however, returns are 1.08 percent per month lower on profitable firms and 0.95 percent lower for

    payers. The leftmost column shows that this pattern is driven mostly by variation in the returns

    of unprofitable and nonpaying firms. Since these firms are hard to value and hard to arbitrage, it

    is not surprising that they are especially sensitive to swings in sentiment.

    The remaining variables book-to-market, external finance, and sales growth also

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    22/47

    sentiment reverses, this actually flips to an upward U shape. As a result, the difference between

    high and low sentiment regimes becomes a pronounced inverted U. Similar conditional U

    patterns are apparent, but somewhat less striking, in EF/A and BE/ME . Their shape suggests that

    investors are more willing to demand both high growth and distressed firms when they are

    optimistic, while they avoid these extremes when they are pessimistic. This may reflect the

    notion that extremely fast-growing or shrinking firms are hardest to value, and therefore most

    sensitive to sentiment.

    Overall, the sorts suggest that the cross-section of expected stock returns is highly

    sensitive to investor sentiment. The directions are roughly consistent with theoretical predictions

    and historical accounts. A highly stylized summary is as follows. When investors are optimistic,

    firms with salient characteristics that cause them to be particularly hard to value and same time

    hard to arbitrage young age, high volatility, no profits, no dividends, extreme growth or

    distress are more likely to be overpriced in relative terms. They therefore have lower expected

    returns. Likewise, firms with these characteristics are prone to being relatively underpriced when

    investors are pessimistic. They earn higher subsequent returns at such times. The conditional

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    23/47

    As a baseline, we start by estimating the unconditional predictive ability of each

    characteristic. Each month, we run cross-sectional univariate predictive regressions:

    it it t it X ba R ++= 1 , (3)

    where X is a given characteristic. As earnings and dividends characteristics, we simply consider

    the profitability and payer dummies, as the sorts suggest that these will capture the main effects.

    Figure 2 reports the time series of the coefficients, and Panel A of Table 4 reports the average

    monthly coefficient and t-statistics based on the standard deviation of the coefficients. The

    results confirm prior evidence that size, book-to-market, profitability, and external finance have

    univariate, unconditional predictive power. High volatility and low sales growth are, on average,

    also associated with higher returns. These mean effects are apparent in Figure 2.

    Panel B runs multivariate cross-sectional regressions to distinguish novel unconditional

    effects from the known effects of size, book-to-market, and momentum:

    ( ) ( ) it it t it t it t it t it MOM m ME BE h ME s X ba R +++++= 1111 loglog , (4)

    where X denotes the characteristic of interest. (There is no X variable when we consider size and

    book to market themselves ) We find that age is modestly significant while the unconditional

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    24/47

    columns regress coefficients from (3) on each of the sentiment proxies; the last column regresses

    coefficients from (4) on the composite index:4

    t t t dSENTIMENT cb ++= 1 . (5)

    To be clear, the monthly coefficients from cross-sectional regressions in calendar year t are

    regressed on the December of year t -1 value of CEFD , NIPO , S , and the overall SENTIMENT

    index, and the December of t -2 value of TURN , RIPO , and P D-ND . The sentiment proxies are

    standardized. Standard errors are bootstrapped to correct for the bias induced if the

    autocorrelated sentiment proxies have innovations that are correlated with innovations in the

    coefficients, as in Stambaugh (1999).

    The results confirm the sorts. The first rows show that as sentiment increases (lower

    CEFD or P D-ND or higher TURN , NIPO , RIPO , S , or SENTIMENT ), expected returns tend to

    decrease on small firms, young firms, firms with volatile returns, unprofitable firms, and non-

    dividend-paying firms. In all cases the results are in the expected direction, and those using IPO

    volume as the sentiment proxy are particularly strong. The last column shows that the connection

    between the cross sectional effect of these variables and SENTIMENT can often be distinguished

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    25/47

    Like the sorts, the regressions show that the cross-sectional effects of book-to-market,

    external finance, and sales growth do not have a strong linear relationship with sentiment. To

    capture their U-shaped conditional effects, we re-run (3) and (4) for these characteristics but

    limit the sample to observations within the top or bottom seven deciles of these variables. 5 The

    idea is to bite off separate sides of the U. For instance, the GS (1-7) row examines how the cross-

    sectional effect of sales growth varies with sentiment among firms in the lower range of sales

    growth, where a marginal increase may predominantly reflect a marginal decrease in distress, not

    an increase in growth opportunities. The GS (4-10) row examines the cross-sectional effect of

    sales growth in a range where the most salient effect of a marginal increase is an increase in

    growth opportunities, not a decrease in distress. Effectively, this procedure views GS (1-7) and

    GS (4-10) as if they were distinct characteristics. Figure 2 plots the cross-sectional coefficient

    from these regressions, which indeed suggests that these characteristics have different cross-

    sectional effects in the bottom and top of their ranges.

    This procedure brings out the U-shaped conditional effects in book-to-market, external

    finance, and sales growth. As in the sorts, expected returns on stocks with characteristics of

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    26/47

    low values. We have just seen that the average payer, for example, earns higher returns than the

    average nonpayer when sentiment is high, so sentiment must forecast a long-short portfolio

    formed on dividend payment. But it is useful to show explicitly how sentiment affects portfolios

    like SMB and HML, for example, because a large literature has used them as proxies for

    systematic risks. Also, the portfolio method is less parametric than the regressions for individual

    stocks, so to the extent it delivers similar results it indicates that the results are not driven by

    changes in the cross-sectional distribution of firm characteristics.

    The first several columns of Table 6 use individual sentiment proxies to predict long-

    short portfolios: 6

    it t t Low X t Hig h X dSENTIMENT c R R it it ++= == 1,, . (6)

    So the dependent variable is the monthly return on a long-short portfolio, such as SMB, and these

    monthly returns from January through December of t are regressed on the December t -1 value of

    SENTIMENT or a sentiment proxy. The last column again separates novel comovement effects

    from known ones using a multivariate prediction:

    sSMBRMKTdSENTIMENTcRR +++=

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    27/47

    ME stocks that is separate from returns on HML. HML is constructed to isolate the difference

    between high- and low- BE/ME portfolios.7

    For profitability and dividend payment status, the coefficients from the portfolio

    approach are identical to those for the individual stock approach by construction. The other

    results are very similar (the sign for predicting SMB is opposite to the earlier ME sign). Both

    SMB and HML are significantly related to sentiment in some specifications. But for HML, as

    with long-short portfolios formed on external finance and sales growth, the more interesting

    story is the U-shaped conditional effect. We separate growth opportunities and distress effects by

    constructing High, Medium, and Low portfolios for these characteristics based on the top three,

    middle four, and bottom three NYSE decile breakpoints, respectively. Using sentiment to

    forecast the High-Medium portfolio for sales growth, for example, is analogous to using it to

    predict the cross-sectional effect of GS (4-10).

    D. Systematic risk

    The conditional characteristics effects are unlikely to be compensation for systematic

    risk, for a number of reasons. First, the sentiment variables have been orthogonalized with

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    28/47

    nonpaying firms, and are recognized as such by the marginal investor. This is counterintuitive.

    Sixth, the effects seem large. This is clearest in the sorts, which hint that conditional expected

    returns on (clearly risky) stocks are around zero or even negative for extreme combinations of

    characteristics and sentiment.

    Table 7 investigates the systematic risk explanation directly, asking whether sentiment

    coincides with time-variation in market betas in a way that would at least qualitatively reconcile

    the results with a conditional asset pricing model. Specifically, we predict returns on the

    characteristics portfolios:

    ( ) it t t t t Low X t Hig h X RMRF fSENTIMENT edSENTIMENT c R R it it ++++= == 11,, . (8)

    The systematic risk hypothesis predicts that the composite coefficient f , reported in Table 7,

    will be of the same sign as the estimates of d in Table 6. A quick comparison of these tables

    shows, however, that when the coefficient f is statistically significant, it is usually the wrong

    sign. We have repeated this analysis with RMRF replaced by aggregate consumption growth.

    Similar results obtain, i.e. when the composite coefficient is significant, it is typically of the

    wrong sign for a systematic risk interpretation A table is available upon request

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    29/47

    This methodology has only limited power to detect how expectational errors affect our

    results, however, because the essential feature of our results is the correlated correction of

    mispricing. A firms announcement event returns, on the other hand, pick up the expectational

    corrections that occur only to it alone and within its own announcement window. A quote from

    Malkiel (1999) illustrates the problem: The music slowed drastically for the conglomerates on

    January 19, 1968. On that day, the granddaddy of the conglomerates, Litton Industries,

    announced that earnings for the second quarter of that year would be substantially less than

    forecast. the announcement was greeted with disbelief and shock. In the selling wave that

    followed, conglomerate stocks declined by roughly 40 percent (p. 67). And so while an

    analysis of announcement event returns will capture the idiosyncratic corrective effect of Litton

    Industries announcement on its own stock, it will capture none of its broader effects, which are

    important to our main results.

    This limitation notwithstanding, we gather quarterly earnings announcement dates from

    the merged CRSP-Compustat file, which are available beginning in 1971. For each firm-calendar

    quarter observation, we compute the cumulative abnormal return over the value-weighted market

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    30/47

    percentage points) in 10 of the 82 corresponding portfolios. The intersection of these strong

    results is 6 cells, and the signs agree in all cases. Among the 5 cells that are strong in Table 3b

    but insignificant in Table 8, 4 have matching signs. Likewise, among the 6 significant results in

    Table 8 that are not associated with especially large conditional differences in Table 3b, 5 are of

    the same sign. The clear anomaly is the significantly negative coefficient on the oldest firms;

    perhaps one such anomaly is a chance outcome of so many comparisons. Overall, these results

    suggest that at least a portion of our results appears to reflect the correction of conditional errors

    in earnings expectations.

    V. Summary and implications

    We develop and test a conditional characteristics model of the cross-section of expected

    returns. In a nutshell, it is an empirical framework that captures the corrections of mispricing that

    arise in a world in which investors view stocks as bundles of salient investment characteristics,

    are prone to time-varying sentiment, and trade stocks that vary cross-sectionally in the difficulty

    of valuation and arbitrage. This approach ties together several important strands in the recent

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    31/47

    distinct from well-known cross-sectional patterns. The approach thus helps us to identify several

    new conditional patterns in the cross-section that leave no unconditional trace, because their signdepends on sentiment conditions.

    Several aspects of the results indicate that they do not reflect compensation for bearing

    systematic risk. For instance, we directly consider, and reject, a connection between the

    conditional patterns in expected returns and conditional patterns in covariance with market

    returns or aggregate consumption growth. In addition, we find some conditional patterns in

    earnings announcement returns, which suggests that at least a component of the basic results can

    be directly attributed to expectational errors.

    If the conditional characteristics model and our interpretation are correct, the implications

    for finance are significant. For corporate finance, one implication is the relevance of dividends.

    Black and Scholes (1974) view the unstable cross-sectional effect of dividends as evidence that

    dividends are irrelevant to market value, as in the efficient markets setup of Miller and

    Modigliani (1961). Our results suggest that this conclusion is incorrect. While the cross-sectional

    effect of dividends is indeed unstable, its sign is predictable from prevailing sentiment. This

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    32/47

    being orthogonalized to macroeconomic conditions, can predict the factor portfolios of the Fama

    and French (1993) three-factor model. The results also suggest that stock returns are difficult to properly interpret without some appreciation of historical stock market bubbles and crashes.

    More research will help to determine whether the systematic risk model should, as an empirical

    matter, be replaced by the conditional characteristics model.

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    33/47

    References

    Amihud, Yakov, and Haim Mendelson, 1986, Asset pricing and the bid-ask spread, Journal of Financial Economics , 17, 223-49.Baker, Malcolm, and Jeremy Stein, 2002, Market liquidity as a sentiment indicator, NBER

    Working Paper Series, No. 8816. Baker, Malcolm, and Jeffrey Wurgler, 2000, The equity share in new issues and aggregate stock

    returns, Journal of Finance 55, 2219-57.Baker, Malcolm, and Jeffrey Wurgler, 2002, A catering theory of dividends, Journal of Finance ,

    forthcoming.

    Banz, Rolf, 1981, The relationship between return and market value of common stocks, Journal of Financial Economics 9, 3-18.Barberis, Nicholas, and Andrei Shleifer, 2003, Style investing, Journal of Financial Economics ,

    forthcoming.Barberis, Nicholas, Andrei Shleifer, and Jeffrey Wurgler, 2003, Comovement, University of

    Chicago working paper.Basu, Sanjoy, 1983, The relationship between earnings yield, market value, and return for NYSE

    common stocks: Further evidence, Journal of Financial Economics 12, 129-156.Benveniste, Lawrence M., Alexander P. Ljungqvist, William J. Wilhelm, Jr., and Xiaoyun Yu,

    2003, Evidence of information spillovers in the production of investment bankingservices, Journal of Finance 58, 577-608.

    Black, Fischer, and Myron S. Scholes, 1974, The effects of dividend yield and dividend policyon common stock prices and returns, Journal of Financial Economics 1, 1-22.

    Blume, Marshall, and Robert Stambaugh, 1983, Biases in computed returns: An application tothe size effect, Journal of Financial Economics 12, 387-404.

    Breeden, Douglas T., 1979, An intertemporal asset pricing model with stochastic consumptionand investment opportunities, Journal of Financial Economics 7, 265-296.

    Brennan, Michael J., 1970, Taxes, market valuation and corporate financial policy, National Tax Journal 23: 417-427.

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    34/47

    Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French, 2001, Disappearing dividends: Changing firmcharacteristics or lower propensity to pay?, Journal of Financial Economics 60, 3-44.

    Greenwood, Robin, and Nathan Sosner, 2002, Trade and the comovement of stock returns:Evidence from Japan, Harvard University working paper.Ibbotson, Roger, and Jeffrey F. Jaffe, 1975, Hot issue markets, Journal of Finance 30, 1027-42.Ibbotson, Roger, Jody Sindelar, and Jay Ritter, 1994, The market's problems with the pricing of

    initial public offerings, Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 7, 66-74.Jones, Charles, 2001, A century of stock market liquidity and trading costs, Working paper,

    Columbia University. Keim, Donald, 1983, Size-related anomalies and stock return seasonality: Further empirical

    evidence, Journal of Financial Economics 12, 13-32.Keim, Donald, 1985, Dividend yields and stock returns: Implications of abnormal Januaryreturns, Journal of Financial Economics 14, 473-489.

    Kindleberger, Charles, 2001, Manias, Panics, and Crashes , Wiley.La Porta, Rafael, Josef Lakonishok, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert Vishny, 1997, Good news for

    value stocks: Further evidence on market efficiency, Journal of Finance 52:859-74. Lee, Charles, Andrei Shleifer, and Richard Thaler, Investor sentiment and the closed-end fund

    puzzle, Journal of Finance 46, 75-109.Lettau, Martin, and Sydney Ludvigson, 2001, Consumption, aggregate wealth, and expected

    stock returns, Journal of Finance 56, 815-49.Lettau, Martin, and Sydney Ludvigson, 2001, Resurrecting the (C)CAPM: A cross-sectional test

    when risk premia are time-varying, Journal of Political Economy 109, 1238-87.Lewellen, Jonathan, and Stefan Nagel, 2003, The conditional CAPM does not explain asset-

    pricing anomalies, MIT working paper.Litzenberger, Robert H., and Krishna Ramaswamy, 1979, The effect of personal taxes and

    dividends on capital asset prices, Journal of Financial Economics 7, 163-195.Ljunqvist, Alexander and William Wilhelm, 2003, IPO pricing in the dot-com bubble, Journal of

    Finance , forthcoming.Loughran, Tim and Jay Ritter, 1995, The new issues puzzle, Journal of Finance 50, 23-51.

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    35/47

    Ofek, Eli and Matthew Richardson, 2002a, DotCom Mania: The rise and fall of internet stocks, Journal of Finance , forthcoming.

    Ofek, Eli, and Matthew Richardson, 2002b, The valuation and market rationality of internetstock prices, NYU working paper.Reinganum, Marc R., 1983, The anomalous stock market behavior of small firms in January:

    Empirical tests for tax-loss selling effects, Journal of Financial Economics 12, 89-104.Ritter, Jay, 1984, The 'hot issue' market of 1980, The Journal of Business 57, 215-40.Ritter, Jay, 1991, The long-run performance of initial public offerings, Journal of Finance 46, 3-

    27.Rosch, Eleanor, 1978, Principles of categorization, in Eleanor Rosch and Barbara B. Lloyd, eds.:

    Cognition and Categorization (Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, Hillsdale, NJ).Ross, Stephen A., 1976, The arbitrage theory of capital asset pricing, Journal of EconomicTheory 13, 341-360.

    Sharpe, William F., 1964, Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under conditionsof risk, Journal of Finance 19, 425-442.

    Shiller, Robert, 2000, Irrational Exuberance , Princeton University Press.Shleifer, Andrei, 2000, Inefficient Markets , Oxford University press.Shleifer, Andrei, and Robert W. Vishny, 1997, The limits of arbitrage, Journal of Finance 52,

    35-55.Siegel, 1998, Stocks for the Long Run , McGraw-Hill.Speiss, D. Katherine, and John Affleck-Graves, 1995, Underperformance in long-run stock

    returns following seasoned equity offerings, Journal of Financial Economics 38, 243-267.

    Spiess, Katherine, and John Affleck-Graves, 1999, The long-run performance of stock returnsfollowing debt offerings, Journal of Financial Economics 54, 45-73.

    Stambaugh, Robert F., 1999, Predictive regressions, Journal of Financial Economics 54, 375-421.

    Stigler, George J., 1964, Public regulation of the securities markets, Journal of Business 37, 117-142.

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    36/47

    Figure 1. Investor Sentiment. The first panel shows the year-end, value-weighted average discount on closed-endmutual funds. The data on prices and net asset values (NAVs) come from Neal and Wheatley (1998) for 1962through 1993; CDA/Wiesenberger for 1994 through 1998; and turn -of-the-year issues of the Wall Street Journal for 1999 and 2000. The second panel shows detrended log turnover. Turnover is the ratio of reported share volume toaverage shares listed from the NYSE Fact Book. We detrend using the past five-year average. The third panel showsthe annual number of initial public offerings. The fourth panel shows the average annual first-day returns of initial

    public offerings. Both series come from Jay Ritter, updating data analyzed in Ibbotson, Sindelar, and Ritter (1994).The fifth panel shows gross annual equity issuance divided by gross annual equity plus debt issuance from Baker and Wurgler (2000). We adjust the series for the one-time change in the share from 1983 to 1984. The sixth panelshows the year-end log ratio of the value-weighted average market-to-book ratios of payers and nonpayers fromBaker and Wurgler (2003). The dashed line is raw data. We regress each measure on the growth in industrial

    production, the growth in durable, nondurable and services consumption, the growth in employment and a flag for NBER recessions. The solid line is the residuals from this regression. The final panel presents a first principalcomponent index of the six measures. In the index, turnover, the average annual first-day return, and the dividend

    premium are lagged one year relative to the other three measures.

    Panel A. Closed-end fund discount %

    -15

    -10

    -5

    0

    5

    10

    15

    20

    25

    30

    1962 1967 1972 1977 1982 1987 1992 1997

    -20

    -15

    -10

    -5

    0

    5

    10

    15

    Panel B. Turnover %

    -15

    -10

    -5

    0

    5

    10

    15

    20

    25

    1962 1967 1972 1977 1982 1987 1992 1997

    -15

    -10

    -5

    0

    5

    10

    15

    Panel C. Number of IPOs

    0

    200

    400

    600

    800

    1000

    1200

    1962 1967 1972 1977 1982 1987 1992 1997

    -600

    -400

    -200

    0

    200

    400

    600

    Panel D. Average first-day return

    -10

    0

    1020

    30

    40

    50

    60

    70

    80

    1962 1967 1972 1977 1982 1987 1992 1997

    -30

    -20

    -100

    10

    20

    30

    40

    50

    60

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    37/47

    Figure 2. Average Annual Coefficients. Average annual coefficients from monthly univariate regressions of returns on firm characteristics X .

    it it t t it e X ba R ++= 1

    The firm characteristics are size, age, total risk, indicator variables for profitable firms and dividend payers, book-to-market ratio, external finance over assets,and sales growth decile. Size is the log of market equity. Market equity (ME) is price times shares outstanding from CRSP. Age is the number of years since thefirms first appearance on CRSP. Total risk is the annual standard deviation in monthly returns from CRSP. Earnings (E) is defined as income beforeextraordinary items (Item 18) plus income statement deferred taxes (Item 50) minus preferred dividends (Item 19). The book-to-market ratio is the log of the ratioof book equity to market equity. Book equity (BE) is defined as shareholders equity (Item 60) plus balance sheet deferred taxes (Item 35). External finance (EF)is equal to the change in assets (Item 6) l ess the change in retained earnings (Item 36). When the change in retained earnings is not available we use net income(Item 172) less common dividends (Item 21) instead. Sales growth decile is formed using NYSE breakpoints for sales growth. Sales growth is the percentagechange in net sales (Item 12). For the last three characteristics, we analyze the top (solid) and bottom (dashed) seven deciles separately.

    Panel A. log(ME)

    -1.5

    -1.0

    -0.5

    0.0

    0.5

    1.0

    1 9 6 3

    1 9 6 5

    1 9 6 7

    1 9 6 9

    1 9 7 1

    1 9 7 3

    1 9 7 5

    1 9 7 7

    1 9 7 9

    1 9 8 1

    1 9 8 3

    1 9 8 5

    1 9 8 7

    1 9 8 9

    1 9 9 1

    1 9 9 3

    1 9 9 5

    1 9 9 7

    1 9 9 9

    2 0 0 1

    Panel B. Age

    -0.10

    -0.08

    -0.06

    -0.04

    -0.02

    0.00

    0.02

    0.04

    0.06

    0.08

    1 9 6 3

    1 9 6 5

    1 9 6 7

    1 9 6 9

    1 9 7 1

    1 9 7 3

    1 9 7 5

    1 9 7 7

    1 9 7 9

    1 9 8 1

    1 9 8 3

    1 9 8 5

    1 9 8 7

    1 9 8 9

    1 9 9 1

    1 9 9 3

    1 9 9 5

    1 9 9 7

    1 9 9 9

    2 0 0 1

    Panel C. Total Risk

    -20

    -10

    0

    10

    20

    30

    40

    50

    1 9 6 3

    1 9 6 5

    1 9 6 7

    1 9 6 9

    1 9 7 1

    1 9 7 3

    1 9 7 5

    1 9 7 7

    1 9 7 9

    1 9 8 1

    1 9 8 3

    1 9 8 5

    1 9 8 7

    1 9 8 9

    1 9 9 1

    1 9 9 3

    1 9 9 5

    1 9 9 7

    1 9 9 9

    2 0 0 1

    Panel D. E>0

    -5.0

    -4.0

    -3.0

    -2.0

    -1.0

    0.0

    1.0

    2.0

    3.0

    1 9 6 3

    1 9 6 5

    1 9 6 7

    1 9 6 9

    1 9 7 1

    1 9 7 3

    1 9 7 5

    1 9 7 7

    1 9 7 9

    1 9 8 1

    1 9 8 3

    1 9 8 5

    1 9 8 7

    1 9 8 9

    1 9 9 1

    1 9 9 3

    1 9 9 5

    1 9 9 7

    1 9 9 9

    2 0 0 1

    Panel E. D>0

    -5.0

    -4.0

    -3.0

    -2.0

    -1.0

    0.0

    1.0

    2.0

    3.0

    1 9 6 3

    1 9 6 5

    1 9 6 7

    1 9 6 9

    1 9 7 1

    1 9 7 3

    1 9 7 5

    1 9 7 7

    1 9 7 9

    1 9 8 1

    1 9 8 3

    1 9 8 5

    1 9 8 7

    1 9 8 9

    1 9 9 1

    1 9 9 3

    1 9 9 5

    1 9 9 7

    1 9 9 9

    2 0 0 1

    Panel F. log(BE/ME)

    -1.5

    -1.0

    -0.5

    0.0

    0.5

    1.0

    1.5

    2.0

    2.5

    1 9 6 3

    1 9 6 5

    1 9 6 7

    1 9 6 9

    1 9 7 1

    1 9 7 3

    1 9 7 5

    1 9 7 7

    1 9 7 9

    1 9 8 1

    1 9 8 3

    1 9 8 5

    1 9 8 7

    1 9 8 9

    1 9 9 1

    1 9 9 3

    1 9 9 5

    1 9 9 7

    1 9 9 9

    2 0 0 1

    Panel G. EF/A

    -20.0

    -15.0

    -10.0

    -5.0

    0.0

    5.0

    10.0

    1 9 6 3

    1 9 6 5

    1 9 6 7

    1 9 6 9

    1 9 7 1

    1 9 7 3

    1 9 7 5

    1 9 7 7

    1 9 7 9

    1 9 8 1

    1 9 8 3

    1 9 8 5

    1 9 8 7

    1 9 8 9

    1 9 9 1

    1 9 9 3

    1 9 9 5

    1 9 9 7

    1 9 9 9

    2 0 0 1

    Panel H. GS/10

    -8.0

    -6.0

    -4.0

    -2.0

    0.0

    2.0

    4.0

    6.0

    1 9 6 3

    1 9 6 5

    1 9 6 7

    1 9 6 9

    1 9 7 1

    1 9 7 3

    1 9 7 5

    1 9 7 7

    1 9 7 9

    1 9 8 1

    1 9 8 3

    1 9 8 5

    1 9 8 7

    1 9 8 9

    1 9 9 1

    1 9 9 3

    1 9 9 5

    1 9 9 7

    1 9 9 9

    2 0 0 1

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    38/47

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    39/47

    Table 1. Summary Statistics, 1963-2001. Panel A summarizes the returns variables. Returns are measured monthly. Momentum (MOM) is defined as thecumulative return for the eleven-month period between 12 and two months prior to t . Panel B summarizes the size, age, and risk characteristics. Size is the log of market equity. Market equity (ME) is price times shares outstanding from CRSP in the June prior to t . Age is the number of years between the firms firstappearance on CRSP and t . Total risk ( ) is the annual standard deviation in monthly returns from CRSP for the 12 months ending in the June prior to t . Panel Csummarizes profitability variables. The earnings-price ratio is defined for firms with positive earnings. Earnings (E) is defined as income before extraordinaryitems (Item 18) plus income statement deferred taxes (Item 50) minus preferred dividends (Item 19). Book equity (BE) is defined as shareholders equity (Item60) plus balance sheet deferred taxes (Item 35). Panel D reports dividend variables. Dividends (D) are equal to dividends per share at the ex date (Item 26) timesshares outstanding (Item 25). Panel E reports variables used as proxies for growth opportunities and distress. T he book-to-market ratio is the log of the ratio of

    book equity to market equity. External finance (EF) is equal to the change in assets (It em 6) less the change in retained earnings (Item 36). When the change inretained earnings is not available we use net income (Item 172) less common dividends (Item 21) instead. Sales growth decile is formed using NYSE breakpointsfor sales growth. Sales growth is the percentage change in net sales (Item 12). In Panels C through E, accounting data from the fiscal year ending in t -1 arematched to monthly returns from July of year t through June of year t +1. All variables are Winsorized at 99.5 and 0.5 percent.

    Full Sample Subsample Means

    N Mean SD Min Max 1960 s 1970s 1980s 1990s 2000-1

    Panel A. Returns

    R t (%) 1,398,432 1.38 18.70 -97.37 2400.00 1.06 1.59 1.24 1.45 1.19MOM t -1 (%) 1,398,432 13.44 60.32 -86.00 359.40 21.45 12.51 14.85 12.11 11.95

    Panel B. Size and AgeME t -1 ($M) 1,398,432 576 2,152 1 21,623 392 238 371 805 1,411

    Age t (Years) 1,398,432 13.68 13.89 0.03 69.17 15.91 12.97 13.80 13.65 14.06

    t- 1 (%) 1,396,198 14.39 9.07 0.00 64.00 9.20 12.62 13.69 15.28 21.53

    Panel C. Profitability

    E+/BE t -1 (%) 1,398,432 10.62 10.32 0.00 67.48 12.14 12.10 11.29 9.28 9.08

    E>0t -1 1,398,432 0.76 0.42 0.00 1.00 0.96 0.91 0.77 0.68 0.63

    Panel D. Dividend Policy

    D/BE t -1 (%) 1,398,432 1.96 2.96 0.00 17.61 4.42 2.72 1.98 1.36 1.05

    D>0t -1 1,398,432 0.45 0.50 0.00 1.00 0.78 0.65 0.48 0.30 0.24Panel E. Growth Opportunities and Distress

    BE/ME t -1 1,398,432 0.93 0.86 0.02 5.78 0.70 1.35 0.92 0.72 0.81

    EF/A t -1 (%) 1,365,115 11.70 24.99 -69.00 131.18 7.09 6.34 10.72 14.77 19.16

    GS t -1 (Decile) 1,349,463 5.94 3.19 1.00 10.00 5.66 5.66 5.97 6.12 5.91

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    40/47

    Table 2. Investor Sentiment. Means, standard deviations, and correlations for measures of investor sentiment. The first measure (CEFD) is the year-end, value-weighted average discount on closed-end mutual funds. The data on prices and net asset values (NAVs) come from Neal and Wheatley (1998) for 1962 through1993; CDA/Wiesenberger for 1994 through 1998; and turn-of-the-year issues of the Wall Street Journal for 1999 and 2000. The second measure (TURN) isdetrended log turnover. Turnover is the ratio of reported share volume to average shares listed from the NYSE Fact Book. We detrend using the past five-year average. The third measure (NIPO) is the annual number of initial public offerings. The fourth measure (RIPO) is the average annual first-day returns of initial

    public offerings. Both IPO series come from Jay Ritter, updating data analyzed in Ibbotson, Sindelar, and Ritter (1994). The fifth measure (S) is gross annualequity issuance divided by gross annual equity plus debt issuance from Baker and Wurgler (2000). We adjust the series for the one-time change in the share from1983 to 1984. The sixth measure (P D-ND ) is the year-end log ratio of the value-weighted average market-to-book ratios of payers and nonpayers from Baker andWurgler (2003). Turnover, the average annual first-day return, and the dividend premium are lagged one year relative to the other three measures. The index isthe first principal component of the six measures. In the first panel, we present raw data. In the second panel, we regress each measure on the growth in industrial

    production, the growth in durable, nondurable and services consumpt ion, the growth in employment and a flag for NBER recessions. The adjusted measures arethe residuals from these regressions. The sentiment index is the first principal component of the six measures. a, b, and c denote statistical significance at 1%,5%, and 10%.

    Correlations

    Mean SD Min Max Index CEFD TURN NIPO RIPO S PD-ND

    Panel A. Raw data

    CEFD t 8.87 8.12 -10.41 23.70 -0.51a 1.00

    TURN t -1 5.21 7.94 -11.60 18.66 0.62a -0.30 c 1.00

    NIPOt 358.41 262.76 9.00 953.00 0.74a -0.57 a 0.38 b 1.00

    RIPO t -1 16.94 14.93 -1.67 69.53 0.73a -0.42 a 0.50 a 0.35 b 1.00

    St 28.97 10.08 11.15 50.03 0.78a -0.31 c 0.31 c 0.77 a 0.33 b 1.00

    Pt -1D-ND 0.20 18.67 -33.17 36.06 -0.85 a 0.53 a -0.50 a -0.56 a -0.58 a -0.67 a 1.00

    Panel B. Controlling for macroeconomic conditions

    CEFD t 0.00 6.14 -18.31 9.27 -0.51a 1.00

    TURN t -1 0.00 6.73 -11.31 11.45 0.65a -0.28 c 1.00

    NIPOt 0.00 226.30 -435.98 484.15 0.82a -0.46 a 0.39 b 1.00

    RIPO t -1 0.00 14.31 -23.55 46.54 0.76a -0.46 a 0.53 a 0.44 a 1.00

    St 0.00 9.47 -22.17 18.78 0.80a -0.18 0.35 b 0.77 a 0.37 b 1.00

    Pt -1D-ND 0.00 16.89 -43.20 35.96 -0.85 a 0.28 c -0.60 a -0.46 a -0.68 a -0.61 a 1.00

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    41/47

    Table 3a. Two-way Sorts: Closed-End Fund Discount and Firm Characteristics. For each month, we form ten portfolios according to the NYSE breakpointsof firm size (ME), age, total risk, earnings-book ratio for profitable firms (E/BE), dividend-book ratio for dividend payers (D/BE), book-to-market ratio(BE/ME), external finance over assets (EF/A), and sales growth (GS). We also calculate portfolio returns for unprofitable firms and nonpayers. We then reportaverage portfolio returns over months where the closed-end fund discount is positive, negative, and the difference between the two averages.

    Closed- End Fund Discount Decile Overall

    0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 10-1 10-5 5-1>0- 0

    ME Positive 2.40 1.93 1.81 1.79 1.83 1.63 1.62 1.49 1.38 1.31 -1.08

    Negative 0.46 0.21 0.36 0.24 0.53 0.33 0.45 0.55 0.46 0.38 -0.08

    Difference 1.94 1.73 1.46 1.56 1.29 1.30 1.17 0.94 0.92 0.93 -1.00

    Age Positive 1.97 1.99 2.05 1.94 2.02 2.01 1.57 1.67 1.63 1.48 -0.49

    Negative -0.23 0.50 0.67 0.47 0.62 0.64 0.66 0.65 0.58 0.72 0.95

    Difference 2.20 1.49 1.38 1.46 1.40 1.37 0.91 1.01 1.05 0.76 -1.44

    Positive 1.20 1.39 1.43 1.52 1.55 1.68 1.72 1.80 1.98 2.86 1.66

    Negative 0.57 0.50 0.54 0.50 0.50 0.48 0.48 0.26 0.13 0.60 0.03Difference 0.64 0.89 0.90 1.02 1.05 1.20 1.24 1.54 1.85 2.26 1.62

    E/BE Positive 2.48 2.21 2.08 2.11 1.92 1.79 1.95 1.90 1.88 1.77 1.87 -0.34 -0.61

    Negative 0.25 0.53 0.65 0.89 0.53 0.46 0.49 0.38 0.50 0.48 0.36 -0.17 0.23

    Difference 2.23 1.68 1.43 1.22 1.38 1.32 1.46 1.52 1.38 1.29 1.51 -0.18 -0.84

    D/BE Positive 2.35 2.08 1.90 1.92 1.77 1.71 1.59 1.53 1.47 1.44 1.38 -0.70 -0.63

    Negative 0.12 0.60 0.51 0.73 0.47 0.58 0.68 0.76 0.70 0.70 0.81 0.21 0.52

    Difference 2.23 1.48 1.39 1.19 1.30 1.13 0.91 0.77 0.77 0.74 0.56 -0.91 -1.16

    BE/ME Positive 1.47 1.72 1.78 1.86 1.87 1.93 2.12 2.12 2.33 2.58 1.11 0.71 0.40

    Negative -0.27 0.09 0.35 0.38 0.56 0.67 0.67 0.77 0.89 0.94 1.21 0.38 0.83Difference 1.74 1.63 1.43 1.48 1.31 1.26 1.45 1.35 1.45 1.64 -0.10 0.33 -0.43

    EF/A Positive 2.52 2.18 2.08 1.98 1.82 1.89 1.88 1.80 1.92 1.66 -0.87 -0.17 -0.70

    Negative 0.76 0.75 0.84 0.77 0.75 0.63 0.38 0.38 0.24 -0.46 -1.23 -1.21 -0.02

    Difference 1.76 1.43 1.25 1.22 1.08 1.27 1.50 1.42 1.67 2.12 0.36 1.05 -0.68

    GS Positive 2.37 2.04 1.97 1.79 1.82 1.88 1.98 2.08 1.90 1.81 -0.56 -0.01 -0.54

    Negative 0.66 0.61 0.58 0.65 0.62 0.67 0.68 0.56 0.34 -0.41 -1.07 -1.03 -0.04

    Difference 1.71 1.43 1.39 1.15 1.20 1.21 1.31 1.52 1.57 2.22 0.51 1.02 -0.51

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    42/47

    Table 3b. Two-way Sorts: Sentiment Index and Firm Characteristics. For each month, we form ten portfolios according to the NYSE breakpoints of firmsize (ME), age, total risk, earnings-book ratio for profitable firms (E/BE), dividend-book ratio for dividend payers (D/BE), book-to-market ratio (BE/ME),external finance over assets (EF/A), and sales growth (GS). We also calculate portfolio returns for unprofitable firms and nonpayers. We then report average

    portfolio returns over months where the sentiment index is posit ive, negative, and the difference be tween the two averages.

    Sentiment Index Decile Overall

    0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 10-1 10-5 5-1>0- 0

    ME Positive 0.89 0.74 0.80 0.75 0.96 0.86 1.05 1.00 1.01 1.01 0.12

    Negative 2.59 1.91 1.80 1.73 1.76 1.45 1.29 1.25 1.02 0.84 -1.75

    Difference -1.70 -1.17 -0.99 -0.98 -0.80 -0.59 -0.24 -0.25 -0.01 0.17 1.87

    Age Positive 0.34 0.89 1.03 0.97 1.23 1.32 1.04 1.13 1.05 1.07 0.73

    Negative 2.01 2.06 2.11 1.82 1.75 1.64 1.41 1.43 1.43 1.32 -0.69

    Difference -1.67 -1.16 -1.08 -0.85 -0.52 -0.32 -0.37 -0.30 -0.38 -0.26 1.42

    Positive 0.97 0.99 0.95 0.88 0.85 0.88 0.82 0.63 0.59 1.13 0.17

    Negative 0.92 1.09 1.23 1.42 1.49 1.61 1.75 1.91 2.09 3.04 2.12

    Difference 0.04 -0.10 -0.28 -0.55 -0.63 -0.73 -0.93 -1.28 -1.50 -1.91 -1.95

    E/BE Positive 0.60 0.78 0.99 0.92 0.94 0.94 0.94 0.92 1.04 1.03 0.89 0.12 0.33

    Negative 2.89 2.54 2.18 2.54 1.92 1.68 1.93 1.78 1.70 1.54 1.76 -0.78 -1.08

    Difference -2.29 -1.77 -1.19 -1.62 -0.99 -0.74 -0.98 -0.86 -0.66 -0.51 -0.87 0.90 1.42

    D/BE Positive 0.63 1.02 0.98 1.15 0.92 1.06 1.02 1.09 1.09 1.11 1.01 -0.01 0.42

    Negative 2.55 2.11 1.83 1.82 1.68 1.53 1.49 1.39 1.26 1.20 1.34 -0.77 -0.95

    Difference -1.92 -1.09 -0.85 -0.66 -0.76 -0.47 -0.46 -0.30 -0.17 -0.09 -0.32 0.77 1.36

    BE/ME Positive 0.13 0.69 0.88 1.00 1.11 1.15 1.18 1.19 1.33 1.46 1.33 0.34 0.99

    Negative 1.63 1.56 1.63 1.62 1.65 1.78 2.02 2.08 2.32 2.53 0.90 0.89 0.02

    Difference -1.51 -0.88 -0.75 -0.62 -0.54 -0.63 -0.84 -0.89 -1.00 -1.08 0.43 -0.54 0.97

    EF/A Positive 1.29 1.19 1.37 1.28 1.21 1.19 1.07 0.89 0.77 0.06 -1.23 -1.15 -0.08

    Negative 2.51 2.15 1.86 1.78 1.62 1.64 1.56 1.67 1.88 1.79 -0.72 0.17 -0.89

    Difference -1.22 -0.96 -0.49 -0.50 -0.41 -0.45 -0.49 -0.78 -1.11 -1.73 -0.51 -1.32 0.80

    GS Positive 1.00 1.21 1.20 1.13 1.20 1.18 1.19 1.09 0.89 0.18 -0.81 -1.02 0.20

    Negative 2.59 1.79 1.69 1.60 1.53 1.67 1.82 1.98 1.78 1.89 -0.70 0.37 -1.06

    Difference -1.59 -0.58 -0.49 -0.48 -0.33 -0.49 -0.63 -0.89 -0.88 -1.71 -0.12 -1.38 1.26

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    43/47

    Table 4. Baseline Regressions, Monthly Returns. Average coefficients and t-statistics from monthly regressions of returns on firm characteristics (X), size(log(ME)), book-to-market (log(BE/ME)), and momentum (MOM).

    ( ) ( ) it it t it t it t it t t it e MOM m ME BE h ME s X ba R +++++= 1111 loglog We only report the average of b t . The firm characteristics are firm size (log(ME)), age (log(Age)), total risk ( ), an indicator variable for profitable firms (E>0)and dividend payers (D>0), book-to-market ratio (log(BE/ME)), external finance over assets (EF/A), and sales growth decile (GS). The first panel showsunivariate results. The second panel includes book-to-market, size, and momentum as control variables. Standard errors are equal to the time series standarddeviation of b t divided by the number of months.

    ME Age E >0 D>0 BE/ME EF/A GS/ 10

    s t(s) b t(b) b t(b) b t(b) b t(b) h t(h) b t(b) b t(b)

    Panel A. Univariate

    -0.17 [-3.3] 0.03 [0.4] 8.28 [4.5] -0.26 [-1.3] -0.17 [-0.8] 0.47 [6.5] -1.63 [-6.8] -0.59 [-4.6]

    Panel B. Controlling for Book-to-Market, Size, and Momentum

    -0.18 [-3.3] 0.08 [2.3] 0.32 [4.5]

    0.02 [0.4] 9.24 [5.3] 0.51 [8.8]

    -0.16 [-3.3] -0.05 [-0.4] 0.35 [4.9]

    -0.16 [-3.5] 0.05 [0.4] 0.34 [5.1]-0.14 [-2.4] 0.51 [6.7]

    -0.16 [-3.0] 0.26 [3.9] -1.16 [-6.8]

    -0.15 [-2.8] 0.32 [4.4] -0.26 [-2.7]

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    44/47

    Table 5. Time Series Regressions, Monthly Returns Coefficients. Two-stage regression. In the first stage, we compute coefficients from monthly regressionsof returns on firm characteristi cs (X), size (log(ME)), book-to-market (log(BE/ME)), and momentum (MOM).

    ( ) ( ) it it t it t it t it t t it e MOM m ME BE h ME s X ba R +++++= 1111 loglog The firm characteristics are firm size (log(ME)), age (log(Age)), total risk ( ), an indicator variable for profitable firms (E>0) and dividend payers (D>0), book-to-market ratio (log(BE/ME)), external finance over assets (EF/A), and sales growth decile (GS). When we analyze growth opportunities, we exclude the top(bottom) three deciles for book-to-market ratio (external finance, sales growth). When we analyze distress, we exclude the bottom (top) three deciles for book-to-market ratio (external finance, sales growth). In the second stage, we regress the monthly coefficients b t on measures of investor sentiment, each standardized tohave unit variance.

    t t t udSENTIMENT cb ++= 1

    Coefficients are matched to the closed-end fund discount (CEFD), the number of IPOs (NIPO), and the equity share (S) for the calendar year one year before t .Coefficeints are matched to detrended log turnover (TURN), the average annual first-day return (RIPO), and the dividend premium (P D-ND ) for the calendar year two years before t . The first seven columns show univariate results. The last column includes size, book-to-market, and momentum as control variables in thefirst-stage regression and uses the sentiment index in the second stage. Bootstrap p -values are in braces.

    CEFD t -1 TURN t -2 NIPO t -1 RIPO t -2 S t -1 P t -2 D-ND

    Sentiment Index

    Controlling for Size, B/M, and

    MOM

    d p(d) d p(d) d p(d) d p(d) d p(d) d p(d) d p(d) d p(d)ME -0.2 [.00] 0.1 [.06] 0.2 [.00] 0.2 [.01] 0.1 [.03] -0.1 [.13] 0.2 [.01] 0.2 [.00]

    Age -0.2 [.02] 0.1 [.11] 0.3 [.00] 0.2 [.01] 0.2 [.00] -0.1 [.21] 0.2 [.00] 0.1 [.15] 6.4 [.00] -3.9 [.06] -7.2 [.00] -5.2 [.01] -5.3 [.03] 4.0 [.09] -7.0 [.00] -3.9 [.04]

    E>0 0.7 [.01] -0.5 [.03] -0.9 [.00] -0.7 [.00] -0.7 [.01] 0.6 [.03] -0.9 [.00] -0.5 [.00]

    D>0 -0.8 [.00] 0.5 [.03] 1.0 [.00] 0.7 [.00] 0.8 [.00] -0.5 [.09] 0.9 [.00] 0.5 [.00]

    BE/ME -0.0 [.68] 0.1 [.48] 0.1 [.19] 0.1 [.55] 0.1 [.13] -0.0 [.89] 0.1 [.28] 0.2 [.02]

    EF/A 0.6 [.02] -0.2 [.52] -0.6 [.02] -0.5 [.06] -0.7 [.02] 0.2 [.52] -0.6 [.05] -0.4 [.08]

    GS 0.2 [.16] -0.1 [.40] -0.3 [.06] -0.3 [.04] -0.4 [.03] 0.2 [.34] -0.3 [.05] -0.2 [.22]

    BE/ME (1-7) -0.1 [.31] 0.1 [.15] 0.2 [.01] 0.1 [.12] 0.3 [.02] -0.1 [.27] 0.2 [.03] 0.3 [.01]EF/A (4-10) 1.8 [.00] -0.8 [.11] -1.9 [.00] -1.6 [.01] -1.5 [.01] 1.0 [.11] -1.8 [.01] -0.9 [.01]

    GS (4-10) 0.1 [.00] -0.1 [.01] -0.1 [.00] -0.1 [.00] -0.1 [.00] 0.1 [.04] -0.1 [.00] -0.1 [.00]

    BE/ME (4-10) 0.1 [.30] -0.1 [.17] -0.1 [.21] -0.1 [.31] -0.1 [.24] 0.2 [.07] -0.2 [.10] 0.0 [.64]

    EF/A (1-7) -2.1 [.00] 1.1 [.11] 2.4 [.00] 1.9 [.01] 1.7 [.03] -1.6 [.04] 2.4 [.00] 1.1 [.01]

    GS (1-7) -0.1 [.02] 0.1 [.03] 0.1 [.01] 0.1 [.05] 0.1 [.09] -0.1 [.09] 0.1 [.01] 0.0 [.09]

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    45/47

    Table 6. Time Series Regressions, Portfolios. Regressions of long-short portfolio returns on measures of sentiment (S), each standardized to have unit variance,the market risk premium (RMRF), the Fama-French factors (HML and SMB), and a momentum factor (UMD).

    t t t t t t t low X t high X umUMDhHML sSMB RMRF dSENTIMENT c R R it it ++++++= == 1,,

    The long-short portfolios are formed based on firm characteristics (X): firm size (ME), age, total risk ( ), profitability (E), dividends (D), book-to-market ratio(BE/ME), external finance over assets (EF/A), and sales growth decile (GS). High is defined as a firm in the top three NYSE deciles; low is defined as a firm inthe bottom three NYSE deciles; medium is defined as a firm in the middle four NYSE deciles. Monthly returns are matched to the closed-end fund discount(CEFD), the number of IPOs (NIPO), and the equity share (S) for the calendar year one year before t . Monthly returns are matched to detrended log turnover

    (TURN), the average annual first-day return (RIPO), and the dividend premium (PD-ND

    ) for the calendar year two years before t . The first seven columns showunivariate results. The last column includes RMRF, SMB, HML, and UMD as control variables. Bootstrap p-values are in braces.

    CEFD t -1 TURN t -2 NIPO t -1 RIPO t -2 S t -1 P t -2 D-ND

    Sentiment Index

    Controlling for RMRF,SMB, HML,and UMD

    d p(d) d p(d) d p(d) d p(d) d p(d) d p(d) d p(d) d p(d)

    ME SMB 0.4 [.02] -0.2 [.26] -0.6 [.00] -0.4 [.05] -0.4 [.05] 0.2 [.21] -0.5 [.01] -0.4 [.02]

    Age High-Low -0.6 [.01] 0.4 [.09] 0.9 [.00] 0.6 [.00] 0.7 [.00] -0.3 [.20] 0.8 [.00] 0.3 [.01]

    High-Low 0.8 [.00] -0.6 [.04] -1.0 [.00] -0.6 [.02] -0.8 [.01] 0.6 [.08] -1.0 [.00] -0.3 [.09]E >0 0 =0 -0.8 [.00] 0.5 [.03] 1.0 [.00] 0.7 [.00] 0.8 [.00] -0.5 [.09] 0.9 [.00] 0.4 [.00]

    BE/ME HML -0.2 [.41] 0.1 [.58] 0.2 [.18] 0.2 [.15] 0.2 [.22] 0.1 [.60] 0.2 [.38] 0.1 [.75]

    EF/A High-Low 0.2 [.12] -0.1 [.43] -0.3 [.01] -0.2 [.06] -0.4 [.00] 0.2 [.15] -0.3 [.02] -0.2 [.06]

    GS High-Low 0.1 [.27] -0.1 [.59] -0.2 [.09] -0.2 [.05] -0.2 [.05] 0.1 [.39] -0.2 [.10] -0.2 [.16]

    BE/ME Low-Medium -0.1 [.23] 0.2 [.20] 0.3 [.01] 0.2 [.17] 0.3 [.01] -0.1 [.34] 0.3 [.06] 0.2 [.14]

    EF/A High-Medium 0.4 [.01] -0.3 [.03] -0.5 [.00] -0.4 [.00] -0.5 [.00] 0.4 [.01] -0.5 [.00] -0.3 [.00]

    GS High-Medium 0.4 [.00] -0.3 [.02] -0.5 [.00] -0.4 [.00] -0.4 [.00] 0.3 [.03] -0.5 [.00] -0.3 [.00]

    BE/ME High-Medium 0.1 [.41] -0.1 [.43] -0.1 [.26] -0.1 [.43] -0.1 [.36] 0.1 [.09] -0.1 [.18] -0.1 [.45]EF/A Low-Medium -0.2 [.00] 0.2 [.01] 0.2 [.00] 0.2 [.02] 0.2 [.07] -0.2 [.02] 0.3 [.01] 0.2 [.00]

    GS Low-Medium -0.3 [.01] 0.2 [.03] 0.3 [.00] 0.2 [.05] 0.2 [.09] -0.2 [.08] 0.3 [.01] 0.1 [.17]

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    46/47

    Table 7. Conditional Market Betas. Regressions of long-short portfolio returns on the market risk premium (RMRF) and the market risk premium interactedwith measures of sentiment (S) , each standardized to have unit variance.

    ( ) t t t t t low X t high X u RMRF fSENTIMENT edSENTIMENT c R R it it ++++= == 11,,

    The long-short portfolios are formed based on firm characteristics (X): firm size (ME), age, total risk ( ), profitability (E), dividends (D), book-to-market ratio(BE/ME), external finance over assets (EF/A), and sales growth decile (GS). High is defined as a firm in the top three NYSE deciles; low is defined as a firm inthe bottom three NYSE deciles; medium is defined as a firm in the middle four NYSE deciles. Monthly returns are matched to the closed-end fund discount(CEFD), the number of IPOs (NIPO), and the equity share (S) for the calendar year one year before t . Monthly returns are matched to detrended log turnover

    (TURN), the average annual first-day return (RIPO), and the dividend premium (PD-ND

    ) for the calendar year two years before t . T-statistics are heteroskedasticityrobust.

    CEFD t -1 TURN t -2 NIPO t -1 RIPO t -2 S t -1 P t -2 D-ND Sentiment Index

    f t( f) f t( f) f t( f) f t( f) f t( f) f t( f) f t( f)

    ME SMB -0.01 [-0.2] -0.02 [-0.6] -0.03 [-0.8] 0.02 [0.5] -0.10 a [-2.6] 0.05 [1.4] -0.04 [-1.1]

    Age High-Low -0.02 [-0.5] -0.13 b [-2.9] 0.01 [0.3] -0.13 b [-2.7] -0.01 [-0.3] 0.15 b [3.0] -0.10 b [-2.1]

    High-Low 0.01 [0.2] 0.08 [1.6] -0.03 [-0.7] 0.11 b [2.1] -0.03 [-0.7] -0.07 [-1.4] 0.05 [0.9]

    E >0-0-

  • 7/28/2019 Condition Characteristic Model (via Sentiments)

    47/47

    Table 8. Announcement Effects. For each calendar quarter, we form ten portfolios according to the NYSE breakpoints of firm size (ME), age, total risk,earnings-book ratio for profitable firms (E/BE), dividend-book ratio for dividend payers (D/BE), book-to-market ratio (BE/ME), external finance over assets(EF/A), and sales growth (GS). We also calculate average announcement effects for unprofitable firms and nonpayers. We then regress the average quarterlyearnings announcement effects for each portfolio on lagged values of the sentiment index.

    t t t ubSENTIMENT a R ++= 1

    We report b . Quarterly average announcement effects are matched to the sentiment index for the calendar year one year before t . T-statistics areheteroskedasticity robust.

    Decile

    0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

    ME -0.20 -0.06 -0.03 -0.08 -0.06 -0.05 -0.01 -0.05 0.00 -0.02

    [-2.21] [-0.97] [-0.42] [-0.92] [-0.95] [-0.72] [-0.13] [-0.79] [0.08] [-0.41]

    Age -0.06 -0.02 -0.09 -0.12 -0.17 0.01 0.03 -0.06 -0.03 -0.16

    [-0.49] [-0.14] [-1.22] [-1.43] [-2.12] [0.09] [0.56] [-0.90] [-0.48] [-3.10]

    -0.04 -0.04 -0.03 0.00 -0.03 -0.01 -0.04 -0.01 -0.08 -0.27

    [-0.71] [-0.88] [-0.58] [0.06] [-0.59] [-0.18] [-0.56] [-0.20] [-0.91] [-2.49]

    E/BE -0.38 -0.24 0.06 0.14 -0.17 -0.17 -0.06 -0.03 0.02 -0.02 0.13[-3.26] [-2.22] [0.66] [1.16] [-1.73] [-1.88] [-0.66] [-0.35] [0.33] [-0.31] [1.99]

    D/BE -0.18 -0.02 -0.10 -0.06 0.00 -0.10 0.00 -0.09 -0.12 0.03 -0.05

    [-2.11] [-0.30] [-1.36] [-0.77] [0.04] [-1.59] [0.05] [-1.53] [-2.11] [0.45] [-0.65]

    BE/ME -0.08 0.01 0.04 -0.03 -0.03 0.02 -0.13 -0.01 -0.14 -0.21

    [-1.21] [0.19] [0.61] [-0.50] [-0.43] [0.28] [-1.74] [-0.07] [-1.64] [-1.77]

    EF/A -0.08 -0.06 0.00 -0.06 0.01 -0.07 -0.13 -0.03 -0.14 -0.04

    [-0.75] [-0.73] [-0.05] [-0.84] [0.15] [-1.02] [-1.96] [-0.39] [-1.99] [-0.48]

    GS -0.29 -0.06 -0.12 -0.02 -0.02 0.04 -0.05 0.01 -0.04 -0.04

    [-2.68] [-0.66] [-1.51] [-0.27] [-0.39] [0.58] [-0.79] [0.14] [-0.65] [-0.46]