34
Banks, their Balance Sheets and Optimal Monetary Policy David Aikman a,* , Matthias Paustian b a Bank of England, Threadneedle Street, London, EC2R 8AH, UK b Center for European Integration Studies (ZEI B), Walter-Flex-Str. 3, 53113 Bonn, Germany Abstract We incorporate financial constraints in a standard dynamic new Keynesian model. These constraints are derived endogenously from two moral hazard problems in financial markets: Unobservable project choice of entrepreneurs generates a role for entrepreneurial net worth in financial contracts, while unobservable monitoring by commercial banks gives rise to bank capital as a determinant in aggregate lending. We study the transmission of shocks to monetary policy and bank capital and total factor productivity. Furthermore, we analyze optimal monetary policy. It is shown that interest rate rules should not respond to asset prices or loan supply. Optimal monetary policy does not fully stabilize the inflation rate in response to shocks. However, the optimal amount of volatility in the inflation rate is extremely small. Key words: Banks; moral hazard; financial market imperfections; Ramsey JEL classification: E44; E32; E52 1 Introduction A number of empirical studies have identified an important role of banks for real economic activity. Samolyk (1994) examines the relationship between banking conditions and economic performance at the U.S. state level and shows how regional banking conditions can affect local economic activity by impacting on a region’s ability to fund local investments. Peek and Rosengren (2000) focus on real estate lending of Japanese banks in U.S. states following * Corresponding author Email addresses: [email protected] (David Aikman), [email protected] (Matthias Paustian).

Banks, their Balance Sheets and Optimal Monetary Policy · 2021. 1. 11. · Banks, their Balance Sheets and Optimal Monetary Policy David Aikmana;⁄, Matthias Paustianb aBank of

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    2

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • Banks, their Balance Sheets and Optimal

    Monetary Policy

    David Aikman a,∗ , Matthias Paustian baBank of England, Threadneedle Street, London, EC2R 8AH, UK

    bCenter for European Integration Studies (ZEI B), Walter-Flex-Str. 3, 53113Bonn, Germany

    Abstract

    We incorporate financial constraints in a standard dynamic new Keynesian model.These constraints are derived endogenously from two moral hazard problems infinancial markets: Unobservable project choice of entrepreneurs generates a role forentrepreneurial net worth in financial contracts, while unobservable monitoring bycommercial banks gives rise to bank capital as a determinant in aggregate lending.We study the transmission of shocks to monetary policy and bank capital and totalfactor productivity. Furthermore, we analyze optimal monetary policy. It is shownthat interest rate rules should not respond to asset prices or loan supply. Optimalmonetary policy does not fully stabilize the inflation rate in response to shocks.However, the optimal amount of volatility in the inflation rate is extremely small.

    Key words: Banks; moral hazard; financial market imperfections; RamseyJEL classification: E44; E32; E52

    1 Introduction

    A number of empirical studies have identified an important role of banksfor real economic activity. Samolyk (1994) examines the relationship betweenbanking conditions and economic performance at the U.S. state level andshows how regional banking conditions can affect local economic activity byimpacting on a region’s ability to fund local investments. Peek and Rosengren(2000) focus on real estate lending of Japanese banks in U.S. states following

    ∗ Corresponding authorEmail addresses: [email protected] (David Aikman),

    [email protected] (Matthias Paustian).

  • the Japanese banking crisis. They find that reduced real estate lending byJapanese banks was not compensated by increased lending of domestic banksand had a significant and sizeable impact on real construction projects. Har-rison et al. (1999) analyze the relationship between economic growth and costof bank monitoring using U.S. state level data. They find an inverse, albeitsmall, relationship between state per-capita income and the cost of banking- suggesting a feedback between real and financial development. Gambacortaand Mistrulli (2004) analyze a sample of Italian banks and show that bankcapital matters in the propagation of different types of shocks, owing to theexistence of regulatory capital constraints and imperfections in the market forbank fund-raising.

    Despite the rich empirical literature on the role of banks, there is only a smallnumber of theoretical macroeconomic models linking the banking sector tothe macroeconomy. 1 Friedman (1991) notes: “Traditionally, most economistshave regarded the fact that banks hold capital as at best a macroeconomic ir-relevance and at worst a pedagogical inconvenience.”The lack of a tractablemacroeconomic model that provides a meaningful role for banks in intermedia-tion has left several important questions unanswered: Do variations in banks’net worth significantly affect macroeconomic outcomes? Does incorporatingbanks into a standard business cycle model change the propagation of busi-ness cycle shocks? Are there implications for the conduct of monetary policyarising from an explicit focus on bank loan supply?

    The contribution of this paper is to provide a small quantitative general equi-librium model in which banks serve a meaningful role in intermediation anduse it for policy analysis. Its virtue is that it shares essential features with theworkhorse models for business cycle analysis: The real business cycle modeland its successor, the new Keynesian sticky price model. We build on the foun-dation of Chen (2001), who in turn builds on Holmstrom and Tirole (1997). Inthat model two moral hazard problems in the market for loans and depositsimply an important role for firms’ net worth and for bankcapital in incentivecompatible financial contracts: Unobservable project choice of entrepreneursgenerates a role for entrepreneurial net worth in financial contracts, while un-observable monitoring by commercial banks gives rise to bank capital as adeterminant in aggregate lending. We add to this moral hazard setup variablelabour supply, aggregate capital accumulation, concave preferences over con-sumption, monopolistic competition and sticky prices to be able to analyzemonetary policy questions.

    Two papers are closely related. The first is Meh and Moran (2004). These

    1 See Holmstrom and Tirole (1997), Bolton and Freixas (2001), Ennis (2001), Chen(2001), Van den Heuvel (2002) and Meh and Moran (2004) for a non exhaustive listof theoretical models on banks with some reference to the macroeconomy.

    2

  • authors also build a general equilibrium model with a banking sector on thefoundations of Holmstrom and Tirole (1997). However, their paper does notexplore the implications of credit market imperfections for the conduct ofoptimal monetary policy as is the focus of this paper. Furthermore, theirpaper differs in a number of modeling choices from this one. 2 The secondone is Collard and Dellas (2005). They analyze optimal monetary policy ina model with quadratic costs to price adjustment, a monetary friction andtax distortions. They show that optimal monetary policy tolerates only smalldepartures from complete price stability, thereby confirming the case for pricestability made by Goodfriend and King (2001). The present paper analyzeswhether credit market imperfections give rise to more substantial deviationsfrom stabilizing inflation.

    We first show that incorporating a dual moral hazard problem in credit exten-sion significantly affects the response of macroeconomic variables to businesscycle shocks. Credit constraints bring about an amplified response of macro-economic variables to technology and monetary shocks relative to the casewhere moral hazard in financial markets is absent. The amplification is dueto the fact that the net worth of both entrepreneurs and banks serves to ame-liorate moral hazard problems and is affected by market prices. Variationsin the price of physical assets therefore feed back into the economy via thecollateral effects stressed in Kiyotaki and Moore (1997). We then show thatthe contribution of banks’ net worth to amplifying and propagating businesscycle fluctuations in this model is relatively small. The reason is that firms’net worth and banks’ own funds are substitutes in the determinant of aggre-gate credit extension. In any reasonably calibrated model however, banks networth is likely to be an order of magnitude smaller than the net worth ofentrepreneurs. Therefore variations in banks own funds are only a small por-tion of total net worth and must be large to significantly impact on aggregateoutcomes.

    We then turn to how monetary policy should optimally be conducted in thismodel. To what extent do distortions in the credit markets give rise to a de-parture from full price stability? This question is addressed in two parts. First,it is asked whether interest rate rules should include a response to financialvariables such as asset prices or loan supply. It is shown that a mechanicalresponse to asset prices or loan supply can be quite costly in welfare terms,leading to welfare losses equivalent to up to one per cent of period consumptionin per period.

    2 First, Meh and Moran (2004) assume intra-period loan contracts contrary to theinter-period contracts used here. Second, they base the moral hazard problem in theinvestment good sector whereas our model assumes moral hazard in intermediategood production. Third, they utilize a limited participation assumption to introducea role for monetary policy, whereas we use a sticky price framework.

    3

  • Second, we search numerically within a broad family of rules for the optimalmonetary policy rule that maximize household’s expected utility . Optimalmonetary policy does not fully stabilize the price level in response to shocksto bank’s net worth. Rather, it takes a slightly counter-cyclical stance andsmooths some of the inefficient fluctuations stemming from the exogenousshocks to banks net worth. Quantitatively, the amount of inflation inducedby optimal monetary policy is very small and roughly comparable to what isfound by Collard and Dellas (2005) for the case of tax distortions.

    This paper is organized as follows. Section 2 introduces the model set up.Section 3 explains the structure of financial contract. Section 4 discusses ag-gregation and equilibrium conditions. In section 5, we discuss the conditionsthat imply a role for bank capital and firms net worth in intermediation. Sec-tion 6 contains the calibration. Section 7 explains the internal propagationmechanism in this model via impulse responses. Section 8 analyzes optimalmonetary policy. Finally, section 9 concludes.

    2 Structure of the model

    There are three agents with distinct preferences and access to production tech-nologies: Households, bankers and entrepreneurs. The production structurefor the final output good has two layers. Intermediate goods production takesplace at the initial layer. Both households and entrepreneurs can produce in-termediate goods from capital goods, but have access to different productiontechnologies. Households marginal product of capital is decreasing, whereasthat of entrepreneurs is constant. In the steady state of our model, due tocredit constraints, households hold too much capital relative to the surplusmaximizing allocation which equates the marginal product of capital of thetwo agents. Intermediate goods as well as labour are an input in the productionof a continuum of slightly differentiated goods at the second layer of produc-tion. Imperfect competition at this layer allows us to introduce nominal pricerigidities. A competitive bundler then aggregates the differentiated goods intofinal output.

    The final output good can be either consumed or be used as investment intoaugmenting the aggregate capital stock. Investment takes place in a compet-itive sector that uses output as material input and combines it with rentedexisting capital stock to produce new capital goods. At the end of a periodafter intermediate good production has taken place, the owners of existingcapital rent out their capital stock to the investment good sector and receivetheir rental rate. 3

    3 Note that both production of intermediate goods and subsequent rental of the

    4

  • 2.1 Households

    We utilize a money in the utility function framework. Households are infi-nitely lived, their period utility is separable in consumption and leisure. Theirobjective is to maximize

    E0

    ∞∑

    t=0

    βt

    (cht

    )1− 1σ

    1− 1σ

    1 + ψ(1− nt)1+ψ + H (mt)

    . (1)

    Here, mt are real money balances. In every period, households choose theirconsumption cht , how much labour nt to supply, how much deposits dt to makeand how much capital goods kht to purchase. The relative price of capitalgoods in terms of the final consumption goods is qt and the relative price ofintermediate goods is vt. Households receive real wage income w

    rt nt, rental

    income Zkt from renting their capital holdings to the investment good sector,lump sum profits from the monopolistic retailer Πt, the revenue from thesales of home production vtG

    (kht−1

    )and of last period’s capital stock as well

    as the real gross return from yesterdays deposits rdt−1dt−1. The central bankadjusts nominal monetary transfers trt to households in order to support itspolicy instrument rnt , the nominal interest rate. Households face the followingperiod-by-period budget constraint in real terms:

    qt(kht − (1− δ̃)kht−1

    )+ dt + c

    ht + mt =

    rdt−1dt−1 + wrt nt + vtG

    (kht−1

    )+ Zkt (1− δ̃)kht−1 + Πt + trt +

    mt−1πt

    .

    Here, δ̃ is the rate of depreciation of the physical capital used in householdproduction of intermediate goods and πt ≡ Pt/Pt−1, where Pt is the aggregateprice index. The first order conditions with respect to kht , dt and nt are:

    qt(cht

    )− 1σ = βEt

    (cht+1

    )− 1σ

    [(1− δ̃)(qt+1 + Zkt+1) + vt+1G

    ′ (kht

    )], (2)

    (cht

    )− 1σ = βEt

    rdtπt+1

    (cht+1

    )− 1σ , (3)

    χ(1− nt)ψ = wrt(cht

    )− 1σ . (4)

    Since monetary policy follows an interest rate rule, we omit the first-ordercondition for money holdings. In this model, the first-order condition for real

    capital stock occur within one period. The same unit of capital can therefore beused for production of intermediate goods and subsequent rental to the investmentgood sector.

    5

  • money balances merely serves to back out the money supply that supports agiven interest rate.

    2.2 Entrepreneurs

    There exists a continuum of risk neutral entrepreneurs. Entrepreneurs have aconstant probability πe of surviving to the next period. 4 Dying entrepreneursare replaced by new entrepreneurs as to keep the population size constant.They derive utility from consuming goods ce and enjoying private benefitsB ∈ {0, b, B} per unit of capital they purchase. Entrepreneur i maximizes theintertemporal objective function:

    E0

    T̃∑

    t=0

    βt (ceit + Bkeit) . (5)

    0 < β < 1 is a constant discount factor, T̃ is the stochastic time of death andkei denotes entrepreneur i’s holdings of physical capital.

    Entrepreneurs optimize subject to the following period-by-period budget con-straint:

    qtkeit = wit + l

    dit − ceit. (6)

    where wit is the entrepreneur’s net worth in period t, and ldit is the entrepre-

    neur’s demand for loans from the banking sector in period t.

    At the beginning of each period, an entrepreneur can choose between threeproduction technologies. In case of success, each technology yields a total netreturn of R intermediate goods per unit of capital invested as well as (1−δ) ofthe capital stock which is rented to the investment good sector at rate Zkt andthen sold at price qt. If the project fails, it yields no output and the capitalstock is lost as well. The return is verifiable by all agents in the economyat zero cost. Projects differ both in their probability of success and in theprivate benefits 5 per unit of capital they offer to the investing entrepreneur,as described in the box below:

    4 The purpose of this assumption is to preclude the possibility that the entre-preneurial sector will eventually accumulate sufficient net worth to become self-financing (see Carlstrom and Fuerst (1997), and Bernanke et al. (2000) for furtherdiscussion). An often-used alternative would be to assume that entrepreneurs dis-count the future at a higher rate than households. See Carlstrom and Fuerst (2001)for a discussion of the differing macroeconomic implications of each assumption.5 Private benefits capture the idea that the entrepreneur gets some kind of non-monetary return from some projects. A common interpretation is that they captureeffort. Lower effort is clearly a benefit to the entrepreneur, but leads to a lowerprobability of success.

    6

  • project probability of success private benefits

    ‘good’ pH 0

    ‘bad’ pL b

    ‘rotten’ pL B

    The “good” project has a high probability of succeeding, pH , but offers noprivate benefits; the “bad” project has a low probability of succeeding, pL(pH − pL ≡ ∆p > 0), and private benefits, b, per unit of capital invested;finally, the “rotten” project shares the same low probability of succeeding,pL , but offers higher private benefits, B, per unit of capital invested (B > b).Notice that this implies that in the absence of monitoring, entrepreneurs willalways prefer the rotten project to the bad one. This simple two outcome-threeaction principal-agent set-up is taken from Holmstrom and Tirole (1997).

    We assume that only the good project has a positive expected net presentvalue:

    pHEt[vt+1R + (1− δ)(qt+1 + Zkt+1)

    ]− rtqt > 0 (7)

    0 > pLEt[vt+1R + (1− δ)(qt+1 + Zkt+1)

    ]+ B − rtqt

    where r is the opportunity cost of funds.

    Households are unable to verify the flow of private benefits to entrepreneurs atany cost. This is the source of the model’s first moral hazard problem: entre-preneurs may be tempted to deliberately reduce the probability of a projectsucceeding in order to enjoy private benefits. Given (7), however, only thegood project can be chosen in equilibrium. We therefore require an incentiveconstraint to induce entrepreneurs to implement this outcome:

    pHEt(vt+1R + (1− δ) (qt+1 + Zkt+1)− fit)ket ≥ (8)pLEt(vt+1R + (1− δ)(qt+1 + Zkt+1)− fit)keit + Bkeit

    Here, fit is the portion of the per unit project return that is pledged to anoutside financier. The following constraint limits the due repayment fit thatany entrepreneur can promise to repay without destroying incentives

    fit ≤ Et[vt+1R + (1− δ)(qt+1 + Zkt+1)

    ]− B

    ∆p(9)

    Since the per unit repayment is independent of entrepreneur specific variableswe henceforth use the symbol Ft. This simply states that the entrepreneur’sexpected return from carrying out the good project must exceed the expectedreturn from the rotten project. The entrepreneur cannot credibly commit torepay more than Ft per unit of capital.

    7

  • With linear preferences, the entrepreneur only cares about the present dis-counted value of her consumption. In the neighbourhood of the steady state,the agency problem implies that the expected rate of return from accumulatingcapital exceeds the discount factor. 6 The entrepreneurs problem has a simplesolution: the net present value of consumption will be maximized by postpon-ing consumption and accumulating wealth until the period in which she re-ceives a signal to exit the economy. She will then consume her entire resourcesbefore exiting. In every period, the entrepreneur receives an endowment of ee

    units of the final good. 7 Thus, aggregate entrepreneurial consumption andnet worth, respectively, are given by:

    Cet = (1− πe) pH[vtR + (1− δ)(qt + Zkt )− Ft−1

    ]Ket−1, (10)

    Wt =πepH

    [vtR + (1− δ)(qt + Zkt )− Ft−1

    ]Ket−1 + e

    e. (11)

    2.3 Banks

    Banks play a distinct role in the model because they have a monitoring technol-ogy. By spending a certain amount of resources c proportional to the projectscale under their supervision, they can distinguish rotten projects from theothers. Monitoring is assumed to imply a strong enough punishment on theentrepreneur such that rotten projects will not be chosen by the entrepreneursin a monitoring equilibrium. Their incentive constraint can be relaxed to:

    Ft ≤ Et[vt+1R + (1− δ)(qt+1 + Zkt+1)

    ]− b

    ∆p(12)

    Ceteris paribus, the entrepreneur can now pledge a higher repayment to bankersand therefore achieve higher leverage.

    Banks also face a moral hazard problem in that depositors cannot observewhether this monitoring has actually taken place. For monitoring to occur, asecond incentive constraint must be satisfied, regulating the share of the duerepayment that must be paid to the bank, 0 < Rbt < 1:

    pHRbtFtk

    ejt − ckejt ≥ pLRbtFtkejt. (13)

    6 To see this define, Ωt ≡ vt+1R+(1−δ)(qt+1 +Zkt+1)−Ft In the aggregate, rate ofreturn on entrepreneurial capital is EtΩtK

    et

    πeΩt−1Ket−1+eeWithout special assumptions on

    the distribution of the shocks, this expression is not guaranteed to always exceed thediscount factor. Calibrating πe

  • Solving for Rbt yields:

    Rbt ≥c

    ∆pFt. (14)

    The intuition is identical to the case for the entrepreneur: in order to beinduced to carry out costly monitoring, the bank must be given a sufficientlyhigh financial stake in the outcome of the project. This required payment tothe bank lowers the entrepreneur’s leverage.

    For monitoring to exist in equilibrium, it must be the case that the gains fromintermediary finance in terms of reduced opportunity costs of not shirkingoutweigh the delegation costs of providing the bank with the necessary incen-tives to monitor. 8 Depending on the model’s parameters both a monitoringequilibrium (indirect finance) and an equilibrium without monitoring (directfinance) are possible. We calibrate the model such that in the steady banksmonitor and analyze small perturbations around the steady state.

    The formal problem of a banker in a monitoring equilibrium can be describedas follows. Denote by kej the stock of entrepreneurial capital under bank j’ssupervision.

    Banks are assumed to be risk neutral and face a constant probability πb ofsurviving to the next period. A typical bank j maximizes the following lifetimeutility:

    E0

    T̃∑

    t=0

    βt(cbjt − ckejt

    ) . (15)

    where cbj is bank j’s consumption.

    Bank j uses its net worth net of monitoring costs, ajt − ckejt, and its depositsfrom households dj to finance loans l

    sjt to entrepreneurs:

    lsjt = ajt − ckejt + djt. (16)

    The agency cost problem again implies that the rate of return from investingexceeds the discount factor β and the bank will find it optimal to postponeconsumption and accumulate net worth until the period in which it exits theeconomy. We again assume that the banker can consume the accumulated networth just before death. Banks receive an endowment eb of the final good ineach period. Once the signal to die realizes, a fraction 1−πb of bankers consume8 We implicitly make the assumption that project returns within a bank’s loanportfolio are perfectly correlated. As Diamond (1984) shows, with perfectly diver-sified loan portfolios (the opposite extreme), the delegation costs of involving anintermediary asymptotically fall to zero as the number of projects being monitoredrises and the bank can be induced to monitor without holding any own capital.

    9

  • their net worth. Consumption and aggregate net worth at the beginning ofthe next period are given by:

    Cbt =(1− πb

    ) [pHFt−1Ket−1 − rdt−1Dt−1

    ], (17)

    At = πb[pHFt−1Ket−1 − rdt−1Dt−1

    ]+ ee. (18)

    2.4 The final goods sector and price setting

    There is a continuum of imperfectly competitive firms indexed by z with unitmass, producing slightly differentiated wholesale products Yt(z). A competitivebundler uses these varieties Yt(z) as inputs into production of a homogeneousfinal good Y . The production function of the bundler is given by the Dixit-Stiglitz index:

    Yt =[∫ 1

    0Yt(z)

    ²−1² dz

    ] ²²−1

    . (19)

    where ² > 1. Each wholesale firm z uses intermediate goods Mt(z) and labourNt(z) to produce output according to

    Yt(z) = TtMt(z)γNt(z)

    1−γ (20)log Tt = ρ log Tt−1 + vt (21)

    Cost minimization of firm z gives rise to these first-order conditions

    wrt =Xt (1− γ)Tt(

    Mt(z)

    Nt(z)

    )γ, (22)

    vt =Xt γTt

    (Mt(z)

    Nt(z)

    )γ−1. (23)

    Here Xt denotes real marginal cost. Since all firms optimize against the samevector of input prices, marginal cost is equal across firms.

    We introduce price stickiness following the widely used approach of Calvo(1983). In any given period, there is a constant probability 1−θ of receiving asignal that allows the firm to reset its price. Is the random signal not received,the firm carries on the price posted in the last period and satisfies any demandat that price. The problem of a firm that receives a signal to change its price inperiod t is to maximize expected profits as valued by the households’ marginalutility of consumption in those states of the world where the price remainsfixed. The firm’s problem can be written as

    maxP ∗t (z)

    Et∞∑

    i=0

    (θβ)i(Cht

    )− 1σ

    [P ∗t (z)Pt+i

    ]1−²Yt+i −Xt+i

    [P ∗t (z)Pt+i

    ]−²Yt+i

    (24)

    10

  • The optimal price P ∗t can then be expressed as

    P ∗t =²

    ²− 1Et

    ∑∞i=0(θβ)

    i(Cht+i

    )− 1σ Xt+iP

    ²t+iYt+i

    Et∑∞

    i=0(θβ)i(Cht+i

    )− 1σ P ²−1t+i Yt+i

    (25)

    As is well known, with Calvo (1983) pricing, the consumption based priceindex Pt evolves as

    Pt =[θP 1−²t−1 + (1− θ) (P ∗t )1−²

    ] 11−² . (26)

    2.5 The investment good sector

    The end of period capital stock K̃t−1 = (1−δ)pHKet−1+(1−δ̃)Kht−1 is combinedwith consumption goods as material input to produce new capital goods. Theproduction function is concave in material input. This gives rise to a price ofcapital - henceforth asset price - that is increasing in the investment to capitalratio, as in Tobin’s q. Existing capital and newly produced capital are perfectsubstitutes, so they sell at the same price. The production function for newphysical capital goods of firm j is

    Y kt,j = µIφt,jK̃

    1−φt−1,j (27)

    Here, 0 < φ < 1, and µ is a constant chosen such that the steady state price ofnew capital is unity. Capital producing firms maximize their profits, qtY

    kt,j −

    Zkt K̃t−1,j − It,j, through choice of It,j and K̃t−1,j. The first-order conditionsare:

    1 = φqtµ

    (It,j

    K̃t−1,j

    )φ−1, (28)

    Zkt = (1− φ)qtµt(

    It,j

    K̃t−1,j

    )φ. (29)

    Due to the linear homogeneity of the production function, all firms choose thesame ratio of investment to capital, which allows to drop the subscript j andmove to aggregate variables. The evolution of the aggregate capital stock is

    Kt = µIφt K̃

    1−φt−1 + K̃t−1, (30)

    11

  • 3 The financial contract and monetary policy

    In order to keep the model tractable, we follow Carlstrom and Fuerst (1997)by assuming that there exists enough anonymity between agents that only oneperiod contracts are feasible. The contract specifies the division of the projectreturn amongst the parties providing finance, contingent on the two possibleproject outcomes.

    As Holmstrom and Tirole (1997) and Chen (2001) demonstrate, one optimalcontract in this setting will involve the entrepreneur and bank investing alltheir net worth, w and a respectively, and households putting up the difference(q + c) ke − w − a. If the project succeeds, the net per unit return is dividedso that the incentive constraints (12), (14) bind:

    Ft = Et[vt+1R + (1− δ)(qt+1 + Zkt+1)

    ]− b

    ∆p(31)

    Rbt =c

    ∆pFt. (32)

    If the project fails, no one is paid anything.

    We assume that the central bank sets the nominal interest rate following asimple rule:

    rnt =

    (1

    β

    )1−ρr (rnt−1

    )ρrπ

    (1−ρr)(1+κ)t e

    ut . (33)

    In loglinear form, rules of this type have been employed in a number of studies.ρr parameterizes the degree of inertia in the rule, (1 + κ) gives the long runresponse of the nominal interest rate to inflation and ut represents a monetarypolicy shock. We link the nominal interest rate with the real interest rate ondeposits via the Fisher equation, rnt = Etr

    dt πt+1.

    9 The reason we specify de-posit contracts in real terms is that we later analyze to what extent monetarypolicy should depart from full price stability. Sticky nominal goods prices arethe only relative price that is affected by inflation in this setup. Therefore,it is easy to identify the channel through which inflation affects real activitywhich would be more difficult with multiple nominal contracts.

    9 Specifying the interest rate policy via the Fisher equation is a shortcut for a moreexplicit modeling of policy manipulating the nominal rate on other assets such asbonds.

    12

  • 4 Equilibrium

    Aggregation is straightforward here, because entrepreneurs obtain the sameamount of capital per unit of net worth. Despite the heterogeneity of net worthacross entrepreneurs and banks, all that matters is the aggregate quantity ofeach type. We use upper-case letters to denote economy-wide aggregate quan-tities. The model is closed with market clearing conditions for consumptiongoods, capital goods, intermediate goods and credit.

    Market clearing for physical capital goods requires:

    Ket + Kht = Kt. (34)

    The market clearing condition for bank credit is given by the aggregation of(6) and (16):

    Ldt = qtKet −Wt = At + Dt − cKet = Lst . (35)

    Market clearing for intermediate goods requires:

    Mt = pHRKet−1 + G(K

    ht−1). (36)

    Market clearing for the final good requires:

    Yt + eb + ee − cKet = Cet + Cbt + Cht + It. (37)

    Free entry into the market for banks implies that banks earn only the minimalamount of informational rents inducing them to monitor. Therefore, the rateof return on Dt real units of deposits is given by:

    rdt Dt = pH(1−Rbt)FtKet (38)

    An individual bank may be faced with all their projects under supervisionfailing. In order to make this consistent with a safe return on householdsdeposits, we assume as in Carlstrom and Fuerst (1997) a mutual fund thatpools households savings and diversifies the idiosyncratic risk. 10 Aggregaterisk cannot be diversified. One can therefore not fully exclude the possibilitythat due to unexpectedly low market prices vt+1 and qt+1, even the successfulentrepreneurs cannot repay their loans. However, the fact that entrepreneurscan only credibly commit to repay a fraction of the value of a successfulproject implies that the unpledged portion of the project return acts as abuffer against aggregate shocks. In our calibration entrepreneurs can crediblepledge less than half of the project value, therefore even very large shocks are

    10 Recall that each bank faces a perfectly correlated loan portfolio. Then in caseall projects fail, an individual bank will not be able to service its obligations todepositors.

    13

  • unlikely to cause default of successful entrepreneurs and the deposit returncan indeed be viewed as safe. 11

    We end the discussion of equilibrium with an aggregate production function.As first pointed out by Yun (1996), the following relation between aggregatefactor inputs Mt, Nt and aggregate output Yt holds.

    Yt ≡[∫ 1

    0Yt(z)

    ²−1² dz

    ] ²²−1

    =Tt

    P̃tMγt N

    1−γt . (39)

    Here P̃t is a price dispersion terms that captures the efficiency costs of pricedispersion across producers due to sticky prices. It evolves as:

    P̃t = (1− θ)(

    P ∗tPt

    )−²+ θ

    (Pt−1Pt

    )−²P̃t−1 (40)

    General equilibrium in this model are sequences{Pt, P

    ∗t , P̃t, Z

    kt , wt, qt, vt, r

    dt , r

    nt

    }∞t=0

    as well as{Xt, Yt, Nt, Mt, It, C

    ht , C

    et , C

    bt , Dt, R

    et , R

    bt , Kt, K

    et , K

    ht , At, Wt

    }∞t=0

    that

    satisfy the following equations:(2) - (4), (10), (11), (17), (18), (22), (23), (25) -(40), the Fisher equation and a transversality condition for household’s capitalholding.

    We define two key financial variables and analyze its cyclical variation in laterparts of the analysis: Firms’ leverage qtK

    et /Wt and banks’ capital to asset

    ratios At/(Lt + cKet ).

    5 When are bankcapital and firms’ net worth essential?

    Combining (38) with (35) and (31)-(32), we find a relation linking equilibriumpurchases of capital by entrepreneurs to the sum of entrepreneurial and banknet worth – the key equation in the model:

    KEt =Wt + At

    Zt. (41)

    where the variable Zt is defined as follows:

    Zt ≡ qt + c− (rdt )−1pHFt(1−Rbt) (42)11 Since households’ labour income is risky, a state contingent return on households’deposits that is negatively correlated with the labour income would dominate thenon-contingent pay-off of deposits used here. Such a contract would be feasible giventhe large size of entrepreneurial net worth. We do not pursue it here, since depositcontracts observed in practice are typically non-contingent.

    14

  • Zt must be positive for there to be a role for net worth. To see this, notethat Zt is the difference between the per-unit cost of investing – equal to thecurrent price of capital qt plus the monitoring resource cost c – and the maxi-mum discounted expected return that can be promised to depositors withoutdestroying incentives. Were Zt to be negative, depositors funds would be suffi-cient to finance the entire project without the need for entrepreneurs’ or banks’capital. When Zt goes up, more resources must be devoted to deterring moralhazard, implying less investment and a greater role for net worth.

    Two types of equilibria can therefore emerge in this framework. In the first,total returns generated by the project are high relative to the overall projectcost and credit constraints do not bind. High project returns make it possibleto pay the entrepreneur and bank sufficiently well to ensure that they havethe right incentives, while maintaining a sufficiently high rate of return fordepositors to entice them to participate in the funding of the project. In thissituation, entrepreneurs are able to borrow enough to buy the entire capitalstock, and the most efficient level of output will be achieved. In this equilib-rium, the economy will behave as if all agents had perfect information.

    What happens if total project returns are not large enough to offer depositors asufficient rate of return once the required payment to entrepreneurs and bankshas been subtracted? In this case, the credit constraint binds. And depositorswill ask both the entrepreneur and the bank to invest their own funds in theproject, thereby sharing the burden of its financing cost. Depositors, in thiscase, will not in general make deposits that are sufficient to fund entrepreneurs’desired borrowing needs. And as a result, entrepreneurs will not own the entirecapital stock. The remaining capital stock will be owned by the less productivedepositors. Output is therefore below its optimal level.

    This equilibrium provides a clear role for both entrepreneurial net worth andbank capital. Capital, net worth and deposits can be thought of as comple-ments for the financing of projects in this situation: better capitalized bankswill be able to attract more deposits and higher net worth firms will be ableto borrow more.

    6 Functional forms and calibration

    The functional form we choose for households production function is G(kht ) =λε

    (kht−1

    )ε. We take one period to be a quarter, and set β to 0.99, consistent

    with a gross real interest rate of 1.04. The depreciation rate of entrepreneurialcapital δ is set to 0.025. Households capital depreciates at a slightly higher rate

    15

  • such that (1− δ)pH = 1− δ̃. 12 Household utility is taken to be logarithmic inleisure and consumption, implying that ψ = −1 and σ = 1. This assumptiontogether with a steady state labour supply of 1

    3as governed by χ yields a

    Frisch elasticity of labour supply −1−NψN

    = 2. The capital share γ is set at 0.35.ρ is set at the standard value 0.9. The standard deviation of the innovationto total factor productivity is also standard, σu = 0.007.

    As in Bernanke et al. (2000) we require firms’ leverage to be roughly 2 inthe steady state. The fraction of total capital held by entrepreneurs in thesteady state is set to 0.5. Bank’s capital to asset ratio is taken to be 10 percent. Steady state monitoring costs per dollar of extended credit amount toroughly 6 cents. This is in line with the findings of Harrison et al. (1999),who report average costs of. 5.85 cents for banks in 48 U.S. states for theperiod 1982-1994. The annualized return to bank capital is calibrated to be10 per cent. To match these features, we set ε at 0.5, c at 0.03 and λ at 1, theper-unit net return R at 22.5 and b = 0.35 . We follow Carlstrom and Fuerst(1997) and set the quarterly failure rate at 1 per cent, requiring pH = 0.99.The difference in success probabilities, ∆p, is taken to be 0.35. We choose φsuch that the elasticity of the price of physical capital with respect to theinvestment to capital ratio is 0.75. This is in line with empirical estimates forOECD countries obtained by Eberly (1997) ranging from 0.51 to 1.51.

    We calibrate ² = 7, implying a markup of 16.66 per cent, roughly consistentwith the evidence in Basu and Fernald (1993) for U.S. manufacturing. Theaverage duration of price contract is calibrated to 2 quarters, i.e. θ = 1

    2. This

    in line with the evidence in Bills and Klenow (2004), who find an averagefrequency of price adjustment of roughly 6 months when excluding temporarysales. Finally, inertia in the monetary policy rule ρr is set to 0.9 and theinflation response 1 + κ = 1.5.

    7 Model analysis: Impulse responses

    To illustrate the working of the model, we plot impulse response functions toshocks to bank capital and monetary policy. To identify how the moral hazardproblems influence the business cycle dynamics, we also plot the response ofthe variables in an economy without any financial frictions. 13 We start witha shock to bank capital.

    12 This simplifies the law of motion for capital and as well the computation of theno moral hazard reference model.13 This frictionless reference model is sketched in our technical appendix. All deepparameters are identical to the moral hazard model, we only assume that monitoringand project choice are observable and contractable.

    16

  • 7.1 Bank Capital shock

    We consider an exogenous shocks to bank capital, impulse responses are dis-played in Figure 1. A fall in bank capital that is not brought about endoge-nously by movements in the economy could represent international factors.The Japanese banking crisis for instance had an influence on the loan sup-ply of U.S.-based Japanese banks as shown in Peek and Rosengren (1997).More generally, we consider such a shock in order to isolate the role of thebanking sector for business cycle dynamics. In particular, we consider a 25 %fall in banks net worth. For the baseline calibration the capital-asset ratio ofbanks is 10 %, so for constant loan supply, this corresponds to a decline of thecapital-asset ratio to 7.5%.

    Note that a shock to bank capital would not have any effects on aggregateactivity in a frictionless benchmark economy as households would be willingto increase deposits. In the economy with agency costs in the banking sector,the fall in bank capital requires that banks cut back their lending as indicatedby (41). With less own funds at stake, banks can only be induced to monitor ifthey extend a smaller loan. Given that entrepreneurs will be able to hold lesscapital, households must be induced to buy extra capital to clear the market.The required fall in the asset price lowers the return on the entrepreneursprojects and this effect decreases entrepreneurial net worth.

    Entrepreneurs’ incentive constraints are affected by two opposing movementsin relative prices: The price of intermediate goods rises as the redistributionof capital holdings reduces total supply of intermediate goods. A rise in theprice of intermediate goods increases the incentive to choose the good project,the fall in the asset price adversely influences incentives. The former effectdominates and entrepreneurs can credibly pledge to repay a larger amountper unit of his capital holdings. That effect ameliorates the adverse impact ofthe fall in banks net worth on aggregate activity, but cannot offset it.

    The dynamics of output are also affected by the response of labour. Laboursupply falls as the drop in intermediate good production decreases labour’smarginal product and therefore the real wage. Note that a one time fall inbank net worth induces a considerable amount of endogenous persistence intothe dynamics of a number of variables. Although the shock only lasts for oneperiod, it takes about 10 quarters for the effect on output to die away.

    It should be noted that large variations in bank capital are necessary to gen-erate sizeable fluctuations in other macroeconomic variables. To understandthis result consider (41). What matters for aggregate credit extension is onlythe sum of entrepreneurs’ and bankers’ net worth. Broadly consistent with thedata, we have calibrated the leverage ratio of entrepreneurs to be 2 and the

    17

  • 1 20

    −0.5

    0output

    no frictionsfrictions

    1 20

    −0.2

    −0.1

    0labor

    1 20−1.5

    −1

    −0.5

    0Intermediate goods

    1 20−0.2

    −0.1

    0household consumption

    1 20

    −1.5

    −1

    −0.5

    0entrepreneurs net worth

    1 20

    −20

    −10

    0banks net worth

    1 20

    −1.5

    −1

    −0.5

    0entrepreneur capital

    1 20

    −0.15−0.1

    −0.05

    0asset price

    1 200

    0.5

    due repayment

    1 20

    −0.5

    0return to banker

    1 20

    −3

    −2

    −1

    0loans

    1 20−20

    −10

    0capital−asset−ratio

    1 20−1.5

    −1−0.5

    0

    leverage

    1 200

    0.01

    0.02

    nominal interest rate

    1 20

    −0.1

    −0.05

    0

    real interest rate

    Fig. 1. Response to a bankcapital shock

    capital-to-asset ratio of banks to be 10 per cent. It follows that entrepreneurshold 10 times as much as net worth as banks. Therefore modest shocks tobanks net worth constitute only a small variation in overall net worth andaccording to (41) have only a small impact on the capital holdings of thehigh productive entrepreneurs. See Aikman and Vlieghe (2004) for a furtherdiscussion of the importance of the bank capital channel.

    7.2 Monetary policy shock

    Next, we consider the reaction of key variables to an expansionary monetarypolicy shock, displayed in Figure 2.

    The expansionary monetary policy shock increases nominal aggregate demand.Given that some firms cannot adjust their prices, inflation erodes their markupand they increase production. That strongly boosts labour demand and in turnthe marginal product of the intermediate goods. The initial increase in theprice of intermediate goods contributes to an increase in asset prices (as thephysical capital is used to produce intermediate goods) and therefore the networth of banks and entrepreneurs. Given increased net worth, larger loans can

    18

  • 1 20

    1

    2

    3

    output

    no frictionsfrictions

    1 200

    2

    4

    labor

    1 200

    2

    4

    Intermediate goods

    1 20

    0.51

    1.52

    2.5household consumption

    1 200

    5

    entrepreneurs net worth

    1 200

    5

    banks net worth

    1 200

    5

    entrepreneur capital

    1 200

    1

    2

    asset price

    1 200

    0.5

    1

    due repayment

    1 20

    −1

    −0.5

    0

    return to banker

    1 200

    2

    4

    6

    loans

    1 20

    −6

    −4

    −2

    0

    capital−asset−ratio

    1 20

    −0.4

    −0.2

    0leverage

    1 20

    −0.3

    −0.2

    −0.1

    nominal interest rate

    1 20

    −1.5

    −1

    −0.5

    real interest rate

    Fig. 2. Response to a monetary policy shock

    be supplied while still satisfying incentive constraints. The increased extensionof loans to the high productive entrepreneurs implies that a the supply ofintermediate goods increases strongly. The output of final goods thereforeincreases much more than in the world where capital market imperfectionsare absent. There is a strong supply side of the monetary expansion.

    The output effect of the monetary shock is both amplified and more persistent(as measured by the half life) in the economy with financial frictions relativeto the economy without moral hazard. Half of the initial impact on output hasceased one period after the shock in the moral hazard world, whereas it takestwo periods in the economy with moral hazard. Part of the stronger outputresponse is explained through the increase in labour. Clearly, the amplificationof shocks due to credit market imperfections hinges partly on the labour supplyelasticity.

    7.3 Technology shock

    We end the exposition of the working of the model by discussing the impulseresponses to an adverse shock to total factor productivity Tt, displayed in Fig-

    19

  • ure 3. For ease of exposition, we shut off price stickiness by specifying completeprice stability as an implicit monetary policy rule. The internal mechanism for

    1 20−1.4−1.2

    −1−0.8−0.6−0.4−0.2

    output

    no frictionsfrictions

    1 20−0.08

    −0.06

    −0.04

    −0.02

    labor

    1 20

    −1

    −0.5

    0Intermediate goods

    1 20

    −1.2−1

    −0.8−0.6−0.4−0.2

    household consumption

    1 20

    −1.5

    −1

    −0.5

    0entrepreneurs net worth

    1 20

    −1.5

    −1

    −0.5

    0banks net worth

    1 20

    −1.5

    −1

    −0.5

    0entrepreneur capital

    1 20−1.2

    −1−0.8−0.6−0.4−0.2

    asset price

    1 20−2

    −1

    0due repayment

    1 200

    1

    2

    return to banker

    1 20

    −3

    −2

    −1

    loans

    1 200

    2

    capital−asset−ratio

    1 20−1

    −0.5

    0leverage

    1 20−0.4

    −0.2

    0

    nominal interest rate

    1 20−1

    0

    1inflation

    Fig. 3. Response to a technology shock

    propagation of technology shocks is similar as for the aforementioned shocks.The decrease in technology lowers directly the demand for intermediate goods,as their marginal product becomes smaller. This lowers the return from theentrepreneurial projects and therefore their net worth. In turn, the decreasednet worth of firms leads to smaller credit extension. A larger fraction of thecapital stock is therefore held by less productive households and as a secondround effect intermediate good output falls sharply. That effect accounts forthe additional fall in output from period 2 onwards. Again credit constraintsserve to propagate the effects of exogenous shocks via their effect on net worthof banks and entrepreneurs.

    8 How should monetary policy be conducted?

    It has been shown that introducing moral hazard in credit extension can sig-nificantly change the transmission and propagation of business cycle shocks.Large and variable deviations between the allocation under moral hazard andthe efficient allocation absent moral hazard give rise to a potential role for

    20

  • monetary policy. 14 Due to sticky prices, monetary policy can influence realeconomic activity in this model. It may be beneficial (in terms of a modelconsistent welfare measure) for monetary policy to smooth some of the ineffi-cient fluctuations arising from credit constraints. While monetary authoritiescannot directly influence the origins of the moral hazard problems it may ad-dress them indirectly. For instance, when negative technology shocks hit theeconomy, asset prices and net worth are low and credit constrained agents canobtain less outside finance. This further contributes to the fall in aggregateoutput above what would happen in a first best economy. Monetary policyhas the ability to stimulate aggregate demand and may to some extent offsetthe fall in asset prices thereby ameliorate the second round effects of creditconstraints on aggregate activity. However, stimulating demand comes at acost, as inflation implies that the bundler in (19) demands the varieties in away that is socially inefficient. The welfare cost of this inefficient allocation ofvarieties in the bundler is captured by the price dispersion term P̃tin (39).

    The literature on welfare based monetary policy in models with sticky priceshas made a case for price stability. Khan et al. (2003) analyze a monetarymodel in a cash-credit good set-up, staggered price setting and no capitalaccumulation. They show that optimal monetary policy tolerates only verysmall departures from full price stability in an environment with several dis-tortions. Collard and Dellas (2005) have analyzed a monetary model with taxdistortions and capital accumulation and confirmed the case for price stabilityin their model. Here, we analyze whether large cyclical variations in the inef-ficiency gap - the gap between actual and efficient levels of real activity - thatare induced by moral hazard in financial contracts give rise to more significantdepartures from price stability than found in the aforementioned studies.

    To study this question we proceed in two steps. First, we analyze the welfareeffects of simple monetary policy rules that respond to financial variables inaddition to inflation. Second, we find the optimal interest rate rules within aparticular family of rules. 15

    We compute welfare using the numerical solution techniques described inSchmitt-Grohé and Uribe (2004b) and Collard and Juillard (2001). That tech-nique is based on a second-order Taylor approximation of the models equationaround the deterministic steady state and has been shown to give rise to ac-curate welfare comparisons. 16 Welfare effects of policy rules are compared

    14 Our monetary policy analysis focuses on interest rate policy. We believe thereis little role for governmental regulation of capital-asset ratios in this model. Themarket required capital-asset ratios present a second best solution with little roomfor government regulation.15 We do not consider here, whether random monetary policy as in Dupor (2003)could improve upon price stability.16 The technical appendix briefly describes the method and some accuracy checks

    21

  • as percentage points of equivalent variation in the consumption process. Letmonetary policy rule A yield welfare of V A and let the sequences of consump-

    tion and labour supply under that rule be denoted with{CAt , N

    At

    }∞t=0

    . The

    required percentage variation ξ of the consumption sequence under monetarypolicy rule A that makes the household as well off as some alternative mone-tary policy rule yielding welfare of V B is defined by the relation

    V B = E0∞∑

    j=0

    [(1 + ξ)CAt+j

    ]1− 1σ

    1− 1σ

    1 + ψ

    (1−NAt+j

    )1+ψ(43)

    For the log utility specification in this paper, we have V B = log(1+ξ)1−β + V

    A It

    follows that ξ = exp((1− β)(V B − V A))− 1.

    8.1 Simple targeting rules

    In this section we analyze the welfare effects of simple monetary policy rulesof the following loglinear form

    r̂nt = (1− α0)(α1π̂t +J∑

    j=2

    αj ĝjt) + α0r̂nt−1 (44)

    Here, gjt are additional variables that the central bank responds to on top ofinflation. A prominent question in the literature is whether monetary policyshould respond to financial variables such as asset prices or credit aggregates.While Bernanke and Gertler (2001) or Gilchrist and Leahy (2002) argue thata response to asset prices in an interest rate rule is not warranted, no formalanalysis of the welfare performance of such rules has been conducted. In ourmodel movements in asset prices feed back to the real economy, because theyinfluence the net worth of credit constraint agents and therefore their abilityto obtain loans. We therefore include the growth of asset price and the growthrate of loan supply into the reaction function. Working with levels instead ofgrowth rates gave similar conclusions as the ones presented below.

    Figure 4 plots −100ξ as a function of the response of the interest rate tocredit growth and asset price growth, i.e it expresses welfare as the percentagegain over full price stability. That is, our reference level V B is welfare undercomplete price stability.

    Given the choice of the other parameters of the policy rule, responding tocredit growth and or asset price growth does not increase welfare relative to a

    applied to our model. We use the log transformation as our change of basis function.That is we express the log deviations of the model’s endogenous variables as aquadratic function of the log deviations of the state variables.

    22

  • −5

    0

    5

    −5

    0

    5

    −1.2

    −1

    −0.8

    −0.6

    −0.4

    −0.2

    asset price growth

    Welfare effects

    credit growth

    wel

    fare

    Fig. 4. Welfare effects of responding to credit and asset price growth

    policy of full price stability. On the contrary, mechanically responding to thesefinancial variables has a considerable adverse effect on welfare. The welfare lossstems from the dispersion of output across producers of differentiated goods asindicated by (39). Our formal welfare analysis therefore supports the positiontaken by Gilchrist and Leahy (2002) that central banks should not augmentsimple interest rate rules with a response to asset prices. We next move to amore systematic analysis of optimal monetary policy rules.

    8.2 Optimal interest rate rules

    We next search numerically for the optimal rule within a simple family of mon-etary policy rules. We consider the family of interest rate rules that respondlog-linearly to all state variables. Since in linearized rational expectations mod-els all endogenous variables are linear functions of the states, our approach isquite general and similar to Collard and Dellas (2005). 17

    17 These authors also allow to react to crossproducts of the states. We have alsoexperimented with crossproducts in our model and further lags of states. Only avery small gain in welfare was achieved by additionally including crossproducts orfurther lags. To save on computational time we chose to exclude them. In our setup,we optimize for each shock a new rule, whereas Collard and Dellas (2005) lookedfor one rule that maximizes welfare in face of several shocks. In that case, allowingfor crossproducts becomes crucial.

    23

  • The optimal rule maximizes the welfare measure numerically through of choiceof coefficients in an interest rate rule of the following log-linear form:

    r̂nt = c0π̂t +J∑

    j=1

    cjŜj,t−1 + cJ+1et (45)

    According to this rule the nominal interest rate reacts to current period infla-tion, to all endogenous state variables Sj,t−1 and to the current period exoge-nous shock et.

    18 The response to inflation is added to ensure determinacy andfor numerical stability. While the choice of the family of rules to consider issomewhat arbitrary, a restriction must be placed to limit the function space.

    For all computed welfare measure we study a decomposition into mean andvariance based on the following second-order Taylor approximation to ex-pected utility of households:

    E {U(Ct, Nt)} = a1E(C)− a2VAR(C)− a3E(N)− a4VAR(N) +O(||ξ||3)

    Here aj, j = 1, ..., 4 are coefficients and O(||ξ||3) denotes constants and termsof higher than second order in the amplitude of the exogenous shocks. Wedecompose welfare into means and variances of consumption and labour, as inCollard and Dellas (2005) and compute welfare for 3 monetary policy rules:Full price stability (henceforth FPS), our baseline monetary rule (BMR) -equation (33) without any monetary policy shocks - and the numerically op-timized monetary rule (OMR).

    The following table depicts the welfare effects of shocks to banks net worthand to technology under the three aforementioned monetary policy rules. 19

    We also plot the standard deviation (SDV) of inflation in order to measurethe departure from full price stability. The last column expresses the welfaregain relative to a policy of full price stability and as a fraction of one per centof period consumption.

    The first conclusion emerging from the table is that the simple baseline rule(BMR) yields a very similar level of welfare as the rule that completely stabi-lizes inflation (FPS). This is in line with findings of Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe

    18 We do not let the optimization routine choose c0, but rather impose c0 = 10in order to avoid determinacy problems and to ensure that the optimization isinitialized in a promising region of the parameter space. This is not a restrictionas the optimization routine is free to undo a too strong response to inflation bychoosing higher reactions to the states.19 Bank capital shocks are modeled as an innovation to (18) with standard deviation0.007. This calibration implies that output is largely driven by technology shocks,only 5 per cent of the forecast error variance decomposition is due to bank networth shocks. Financial variables such as are more strongly affected by this shock.Roughly 12 per cent of forecast error variance is due to the net worth shock.

    24

  • case SDV(C) SDV(N) E(C) E(N) SDV(π) −100ξbank net worth shock

    BMR 0.00229 0.00060766 1.0442545 0.3228945 0.00086 -0.0007

    FPS 0.00304 0.00071266 1.0442657 0.32289514 0 0

    OMR 0.00283 0.00065809 1.0442736 0.32289759 0.00035 0.0002

    technology shock

    BMR 0.022147 0.00063566 1.0444055 0.32289436 0.0036 -0.0143

    FPS 0.024036 0.00034722 1.0445947 0.32289365 0 0

    OMR 0.024051 0.00045403 1.0446017 0.32289759 0.00025 0.0002

    (2004a) who report that targeting inflation strongly or weakly has small ef-fects on welfare as long as the equilibrium remains determinate. Consideringthe optimized monetary policy rule (OMR) shows that one can improve uponfull price stability but that the gain from doing so is small. The above tableshows that it is crucial to account for the effects of increases in average levelsof consumption E(C) and labour E(N) to capture the welfare effects of mon-etary policy rules. For shocks to bank capital, both BMR and OMR inducea smaller standard deviation of consumption and labour relative to full pricestability. However, it is the fact the optimal rules increases the average level ofconsumption and the baseline rule decreases the average level of consumptionthat accounts for the welfare ranking.

    To further characterize optimal policy, we plot impulse response functions toa shock to banks’ net worth under the optimized rule. Figure 5 shows that theoptimal monetary policy response to the bank capital is to induce a very mod-est amount of inflation on impact. Due to sticky prices, that boosts demandand implies a significantly smaller fall in employment relative to full pricestability. Output, consumption and asset prices also fall by slightly less. Thesmaller fall in asset prices implies that the entrepreneur can credibly pledgea larger due repayment to outside parties. The fact that inflation eventuallyundershoots its steady state level after an initial expansion is a feature of op-timal policy under commitment that is often reported in the literature, seeFigure 1 in Steinsson (2003, p. 1443) and Woodford (2003) for a discussionof the history dependence of optimal policy. Such a policy exploits the for-ward looking nature of price setting which improves the inflation output gaptrade-off.

    We therefore conclude that the credit market imperfections introduced in thismodel due not warrant a significant departure from the objective of pricestability. Only a small amount of inflation is tolerated under the optimal policy.

    25

  • 1 20−0.6

    −0.4

    −0.2

    0output

    optimalprice stability

    1 20−0.2

    −0.1

    0

    labor

    1 20

    −1

    −0.5

    0Intermediate goods

    1 20

    −0.2

    −0.1

    0

    household consumption

    1 20−1.5

    −1

    −0.5

    0

    entrepreneurs net worth

    1 20

    −15

    −10

    −5

    banks net worth

    1 20−1.5

    −1

    −0.5

    0entrepreneur capital

    1 20

    −0.2

    −0.1

    0

    asset price

    1 200

    0.05

    0.1

    due repayment

    1 20−0.12

    −0.1−0.08−0.06−0.04−0.02

    return to banker

    1 20−3

    −2

    −1

    0loans

    1 20−15

    −10

    −5

    capital−asset−ratio

    1 20−1.5

    −1

    −0.5

    0

    leverage

    1 20−0.3−0.2−0.1

    0

    nominal interest rate

    1 20

    0

    0.02

    0.04

    inflation

    Fig. 5. Response to bank net worth shock under the optimized rule

    9 Conclusion

    This paper has evaluated a monetary general equilibrium model featuringcredit frictions that arise from a dual moral hazard problem in financial con-tracts. A dual moral hazard problem as outlined in Chen (2001) is embedded ina New Keynesian model with sticky prices. Incentive compatibility constraintsin financial contracts imply a role for net worth of entrepreneurs and banks inthe extension of credit. The model is shown to significantly alter business cy-cles dynamics relative to the standard sticky price model. In particular, creditconstraints work to amplify and propagate exogenous shocks via their effecton net worth of both banks and entrepreneurs. The role of banks in affectingbusiness cycle dynamics is shown to be small. The reasons lies in the factthat only the sum of entrepreneurs’ and banks’ net worth matters for capitalholding of entrepreneurs in this model. Banks net worth however is roughlyan order of magnitude smaller that of entrepreneurs. Therefore, it takes largevariations in banks’ net worth to significantly affect macroeconomic variables.

    The model is then used for policy analysis. It is first shown that standardinterest rate rules should not respond to asset price growth or loan in growthon top of responding to inflation. Reacting strongly to these financial variables

    26

  • may decrease households expected utility by up to one per cent of periodconsumption.

    Furthermore, it is shown that optimal monetary that maximizes expected util-ity of households does not fully stabilize inflation in response to technologyshocks or bank net worth shocks. However, the amount of inflation variabilitytolerated in response to either technology shocks or bank net worth shocks isextremely small. This result can been seen as supporting the case for pricestability in a model with multiple credit frictions. One may wonder to whatextent this result is due to the particular parameterization of this model. Wenote that the near optimality of price stability arises in this model despite acalibration that probably overstates the adverse effect of credit constraints inthis model. For instance, we have calibrated the model such that in the steadystate half of the aggregate capital stock is held by households. That allocationis far from surplus maximizing. It implies that household’s marginal productis roughly 20 times smaller that of entrepreneurs. It is this relatively large dif-ference in relative productivity which gives the model a strong amplificationand propagation mechanism. It appears that despite strong inefficient fluctua-tions arising from credit constraints, smoothing of business cycle fluctuationsis not an important objective for policy in monetary models with staggeredprice setting.

    We conclude with some caveats to our policy conclusion. First we have usedCalvo (1983) contracts to introduced staggered price setting. As shown inPaustian (2004), that device may overstate the welfare losses from inflation.Second, we have not allowed for nominal contracts. Inflation can therefore noterode the real debt burden of agents in our model and we have therefore shutoff a channel through which central banks can influence real activity in thismodel. Preliminary extension of the present analysis in this direction showthat these caveats do not significantly affect our results.

    Acknowledgments

    We would like to thank in advance our discussant Reint Gropp. Special thanksto Jan Vlieghe for valuable work in earlier stages of this paper. Thanks toJürgen von Hagen and Haiping Zhang for helpful comments. We thank con-ference and seminar participants at the European Winter Meeting of theEconometric Society in Stockholm, the Bank of England, the Bundesbank,the University of Munich, the University of Würzburg and the Center for Eu-ropean Integration Studies at the University of Bonn. The views expressedhere are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the Bankof England.

    27

  • Technical Appendix - not for publication

    The no moral hazard reference model

    Here, we document the modifications to the model that are required whenthere is no moral hazard at the level of the bank and the firm. Specifically,the modification we conduct makes each banks decision to monitor perfectlyobservable at zero cost to all other agents in the economy. The surplus max-imizing allocation of capital is the one that equates the marginal productof capital of household production with the marginal product of the en-trepreneurs. Making monitoring public information permits us to drop thebanks incentive compatibility constraint from the list of equilibrium condi-tions. Banks in this case will no longer be able to command a share of thesurplus from projects they monitor. Like households, therefore, banks will re-ceive an expected return just sufficient to satisfy their participation constraint.The incentive to continually postpone consumption and accumulate net worthis therefore eliminated and, given linear utility, the exact time path of con-sumption and savings will be indeterminate. An interesting extreme case toanalyze involves the bank accumulating zero net worth and simply consum-ing its endowment period by period. Similarly, we assume that the choice ofthe project is fully observable at no cost and therefore the entrepreneurs nolonger command a share of the project. As was the case for bankers, there con-sumption path is indeterminate and we analyze the case where they consumetheir endowment in any period. The economy then collapses a version of thestandard dynamic new Keynesian model. The equations characterizing equi-librium in this case are summarized below. Equilibrium in this model are se-quences

    {Cht , Nt, K

    et , K

    ht , K̃t, Kt, Z

    kt , It, Xt,Mt, qt, p

    ∗t , P̃t, πt, vt, r

    nt , r

    dt

    }that sat-

    isfy the following equilibrium conditions, as well as the Fisher equation and a

    28

  • transversality condition for households capital holdings:

    qt(cht

    )− 1σ = βEt

    (cht+1

    )− 1σ

    [(1− δ̃)(qt+1 + Zkt+1) + vt+1G

    ′ (kht

    )]

    λ(Kht

    )²−1= phR

    (Cht

    )− 1σ = βEtr

    dt

    (Cht+1

    )− 1σ

    χ(1−Nt)ψ = XtTt(1− γ)(

    MtNt

    )γ (Cht

    )− 1σ

    vt = TtXtγ(

    NtMt

    )1−γ

    1 = θπ²−1t + (1− θ) (p∗t )1−²P̃t = (1− θ) (p∗t )−² + θπ²t P̃t−1

    TtMγt N

    1−γt = C

    ht + It

    Mt =λ

    ²

    (Kht−1

    )²+ pHrK

    et−1

    Kt = Kht + K

    et

    rnt =

    (1

    β

    )1−ρr (rnt−1

    )ρπ

    (1−ρr)(1+κ)t e

    ut

    1 = φqtµ

    (It

    K̃t−1

    )φ−1,

    K̃t = (1− δ)pHKet + (1− δ̃)KhtZkt = (1− φ)qtµt

    (It

    K̃t−1

    Kt = µIφt K̃

    1−φt−1 + K̃t−1

    p∗t =²

    ²− 1Et

    ∑∞i=0(θβ)

    i(Cht+i

    )− 1σ Xt+iπ

    ²t,t+iTt+iM

    γt+iN

    1−γt+i

    Et∑∞

    i=0(θβ)i(Cht+i

    )− 1σ π²−1t,t+iTt+iM

    γt+iN

    1−γt+i

    Here, p∗t is defined asP ∗tPt

    and πt,t+j ≡ Πji=1πt+i, i.e the cumulative inflationrates between period t and t + j.

    9.1 Solution method and computation of welfare measure

    We solve the model using the second-order solution method outlined in Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe (2004b). The accuracy of the obtained solution is assessed byuse of Euler equation residuals in the appendix. To fix notation, consider thegeneric representation for rational expectations models used by Schmitt-Grohé

    29

  • and Uribe (2004b)

    Et f(yt+1, yt,xt+1,xt) = 0. (46)

    f is a known function describing the equilibrium conditions of the modeleconomy, yt is a vector of co-state variables and xt a vector of state variablespartitioned as xt = [x1,t; x2,t]. x1,t is a vector of endogenous state variablesand x2,t a vector of state variables following an exogenous stochastic process

    x2,t+1 = Lx2,t + Ñσ²t. (47)

    L and Ñ are known coefficient matrices, ²t is a vector of innovations withbounded support, independently and identically distributed with mean zeroand identity covariance matrix I. σ is a parameter scaling the standard devi-ation of the innovations. The solution to the model described by (??) is of theform

    yt = g(xt, σ), (48)

    xt+1 = h(xt, σ) + σN²t+1, with: N =

    0

    . (49)

    Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe (2004b) derive the second-order Taylor approxima-tion to the policy functions g(·) and h(·) and provide MATLAB codes for thenumerical implementation. The approximate model dynamics obtained fromtheir second-order approximation can be compactly expressed as

    yt = Gxt +1

    2G∗(xt ⊗ xt) + 1

    2gσ2, (50)

    xt+1 = Hxt +1

    2H∗(xt ⊗ xt) + 1

    2hσ2 + σN²t+1. (51)

    yt and xt are expressed as deviations from the deterministic steady state.G and H are coefficient matrices representing the linear part of the Taylorapproximation. The matrices G∗ and H∗ form the second-order part jointlywith the vectors g and h.

    Unconditional means of the model’s variables can be constructed as follows.Let µy,Σy denote unconditional mean and covariance matrix of y, respec-tively. To construct first and second moments of the co-state variables assumecovariance stationarity and take expectation of (50) and (51)

    µy = Gµx +1

    2G∗vec(Σx + µxµ

    ′x) +

    1

    2gσ2, (52)

    µx = Hµx +1

    2H∗vec(Σx + µxµ

    ′x) +

    1

    2hσ2. (53)

    30

  • Since variances can be computed accurately up to second-order from the linearpart of the policy function, it is sufficient to approximate vec(Σx + µxµ

    ′x) ≈

    vec(Σx) and vec(Σy + µyµ′y) ≈ vec(Σy). It is then possible to construct the

    variances using the formulas for second moments of stationary vector autore-gressive processes given in Hamilton (1994, p.265)

    vec(Σx) = σ2(I −H ⊗H)−1(N ⊗N)vec(I), (54)

    vec(Σy) = (G⊗G)vec(Σx) (55)

    Given these approximations for the variances, the means can be computedfrom (52) and (53) as

    µx =1

    2(I −H)−1

    (H∗vec(Σx) + hσ2

    )(56)

    µy = Gµx +1

    2G∗vec(Σy) +

    1

    2gσ2 (57)

    Given an expression for the unconditional mean of the models variables wecan easily compute welfare.

    Euler equation residuals

    Judd (1998) advocates the inspection of Euler equations residuals to assess theaccuracy of the obtained solution. One plots the residual in the Euler equationas a function of the state variables of the system. Let xt+1 = h

    s(xt) denotetransition function for the state variables obtained under solution method sWe denote the dependence of a generic co-state variable y on the state vectorxt by y(xt). The residual arising from the Euler equation for capital holdingsis:

    Rs(xt) = 1−

    {βEtC (hs(xt))

    − 1σ

    [q (hs(xt)) +

    v(hs(xt))β

    (λKe(xt)

    ) 1²

    ]}−σ

    C(xt)(58)

    The residual gives the error from following the approximated policy rule asa fraction of current period consumption. 20 Under certain conditions the ap-proximation error of the policy function is of the same order of magnitudeas the Euler equation residual as pointed out by Santos (2000). Figures (6)and (7) plot the absolute value of the consumption Euler equation residualobtained from the second-order accurate solution method over a range of de-viations of the 2 state variables from −10% to +10% from their steady statelevels 21 The residual is expressed in base 10 logarithms for the ease of visu-alization.

    20 The monetary policy rule that is used to obtain the solution is the baseline rule

    31

  • −0.1

    −0.05

    0

    0.05

    −0.1

    −0.05

    0

    0.05

    −4.8

    −4.6

    −4.4

    −4.2

    −4

    −3.8

    −3.6

    deviation state 2

    Euler residual using approximation of order 1

    deviation state 1

    log1

    0 E

    uler

    res

    idua

    l

    Fig. 6. Euler residuals: First-order approximiation

    −0.1

    −0.05

    0

    0.05

    −0.1

    −0.05

    0

    0.05

    −8.5

    −8

    −7.5

    −7

    −6.5

    −6

    −5.5

    −5

    deviation state 2

    Euler residual using approximation of order 2

    deviation state 1

    log1

    0 E

    uler

    res

    idua

    l

    Fig. 7. Euler residuals: Second-order approximiation

    One can see that the second-order approximation yields smaller Euler equa-tion residual over the entire state space. The average 22 Euler equation resid-ual from the second-order approximation is more than order of magnitudesmaller than the one from the first-order approximation. When we plot theEuler equation residuals for other selected state variables, similar plots emerge.Nevertheless, it would be good to compute an average Euler equation error

    with an inflation inertia coefficient of 0.9 and a long-run response to inflation of 1.521 The two state variables are the capital stock and the return to the banker, theother states are fixed at their deterministic steady state values. The expectation iscomputed using Gaussian quadrature with 10 nodes.22 We do not weight the points in the state space with their probabilities, as thesein turn can only accurately be computed using the unknown exact solution.

    32

  • over all points in the state space.

    References

    Aikman, D., Vlieghe, G., Spring 2004 2004. How much does bank capitalmatter? Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, 48–58.

    Basu, S., Fernald, J. G., 1993. Constant returns and small markups in u.s.manufacturing. Center for Research on Economic and Social Theory andDepartment of Ecomics, University of Michigan, 1993-19.

    Bernanke, B., Gertler, M., Gilchrist, S., 2000. The financial accelerator in aquantitative business cycle framework. In: Taylor, J., Woodford, M. (Eds.),Handbook of Macroeconomics. Vol. 1C. Elsevier, pp. 1341–1393.

    Bernanke, B. S., Gertler, M., 2001. Should central banks respond to move-ments in asset prices? American Economic Review 91 (2), 253–257.

    Bills, M., Klenow, P. J., 2004. Some evidence on the importance of stickyprices. Journal of Political Economy 112 (5), 947–985.

    Bolton, P., Freixas, X., 2001. Corporate finance and the monetary transmissonmechanism. CEPR DP 2892.

    Calvo, G. A., 1983. Staggered price setting in a utility-maximizing framework.Journal of Monetary Economics 12, 383–398.

    Carlstrom, C., Fuerst, T. S., 2001. Monetary shocks, agency costs, and businesscycles. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 54.

    Carlstrom, C. T., Fuerst, T. S., 1997. Agency costs, net worth and businessfluctuations: A computable general equilibrium analysis. American Eco-nomic Review 87 (5), 893–910.

    Chen, N. K., 2001. Bank net worth, asset prices and economic activity. Journalof Monetary Economics 48 (2), 415–436.

    Collard, F., Dellas, H., 2005. Tax distortions and the case for price stability.Journal of Monetary Economics 52, 249–273.

    Collard, F., Juillard, M., 2001. A higher-order taylor expansion approach tosimulation of stochastic forward-looking models with an application to anon-linear phillips curve. Computational Economics 17, 125–139.

    Diamond, D. W., 1984. Financial intermediation and delegated monitoring.Review of Economic Studies 51 (3), 393–414.

    Dupor, B., 2003. Optimal random monetary policy with nominal rigidity. Jour-nal of Ecomic Theory 112, 66–78.

    Eberly, J. J., 1997. International evidence on investment and fundamentals.European Economic 41, 1055–1078.

    Ennis, H. M., 2001. Loanable funds, monitoring and banking. European Fi-nance Review 5, 79–114.

    Friedman, B., 1991. Comment on ’the credit crunch,’ by ben s. bernanke andcara s. lown. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2, 240–247.

    33

  • Gambacorta, L., Mistrulli, P. E., 2004. Does bank capital affect lending be-havior? Journal of Financial Intermediation 13, 436–457.

    Gilchrist, S., Leahy, J. V., 2002. Monetary policy and asset prices. Journal ofMonetary Economics 49, 75–97.

    Goodfriend, M., King, R. G., 2001. The case for price stability, nBER WorkingPaper 8423.

    Hamilton, J. D., 1994. Time Series Analysis. Princeton University Press.Harrison, P., Sussmann, O., Zeira, J., 1999. Finance and growth: Theory and

    new evidence. Finance and Economics Discussion Series 1999 - 35. Wash-ington: Board of Governers of the Federal Reserve System.

    Holmstrom, B., Tirole, J., 1997. Financial intermediation, loanable funds, andthe real sector. Quarterly Journal of Economics 112 (3), 663–691.

    Judd, K. L., 1998. Numerical Methods in Economics. MIT Press.Khan, A., King, R. G., Wolman, A. L., 2003. Optimal monetary policy. Review

    of Economic Studies 70, 825–860.Kiyotaki, N., Moore, J., Apr. 1997. Credit cycles. The Journal of Political

    Economy 105 (2), 211–248.Meh, C., Moran, K., 2004. Bank capital, agency costs, and monetary policy.

    Bank of Canda Working Paper 2004-6.Paustian, M., October 2004. Can wage and price stickines account for sizeable

    welfare costs of business cycle variations?, bonn Econ Discussion Paper18/2004, October 2004.

    Peek, J., Rosengren, E. S., 1997. The international transmission of financialshocks: The case of japan. American Economic Review 87 (4), 495–505.

    Peek, J., Rosengren, E. S., 2000. Collateral damage: Effects of japanese bank-ing crisis on real activity in the united states. American Economic Review90 (1), 30–45.

    Samolyk, K. A., 1994. Banking conditions and regional economic performance:evidence of a regional credit channel. Journal of Monetary Economics 34 (4),259–278.

    Santos, M., 2000. Accuracy of numerical solutions using the euler equationresiduals. Econometrica 68, 1377–1402.

    Schmitt-Grohé, S., Uribe, M., 2004a. Optimal simple and implementable fiscaland monetary rules. NBER Working Paper 10253.

    Schmitt-Grohé, S., Uribe, M., 2004b. Solving dynamic general equilibriummodels using a second-order approximation to the policy function. Journalof Economic Dynamics and Control 28, 755–775.

    Steinsson, J., 2003. Optimal monetary policy in an economy with inflationpersistence. Journal of Monetary Economics 50, 1425–1456.

    Van den Heuvel, S. J., 2002. Does bank capital matter for monetary transmis-sion? FRBNY Economic Policy Review 8, 259–265.

    Woodford, M., 2003. Optimal interest-rate smoothing. Review of EconomicStudies 70, 861–886.

    Yun, T., 1996. Nominal price rigidity, money supply endogeneity, and businesscycles. Journal of Monetary Economics 37, 345–370.

    34