61
Arbitrage An Undergraduate Introduction to Financial Mathematics J. Robert Buchanan 2010 J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    2

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

ArbitrageAn Undergraduate Introduction to Financial Mathematics

J. Robert Buchanan

2010

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 2: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Efficient Market Hypothesis

The Efficient Market Hypothesis has many forms butessentially can be taken to mean

prices on all securities and products reflect all knowninformation,

current prices are the best unbiased estimate of the valueof the security or product,prices will adjust to any new information nearlyinstantaneously,an investor cannot outperform the market using knowninformation except through luck.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 3: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Efficient Market Hypothesis

The Efficient Market Hypothesis has many forms butessentially can be taken to mean

prices on all securities and products reflect all knowninformation,current prices are the best unbiased estimate of the valueof the security or product,

prices will adjust to any new information nearlyinstantaneously,an investor cannot outperform the market using knowninformation except through luck.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 4: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Efficient Market Hypothesis

The Efficient Market Hypothesis has many forms butessentially can be taken to mean

prices on all securities and products reflect all knowninformation,current prices are the best unbiased estimate of the valueof the security or product,prices will adjust to any new information nearlyinstantaneously,

an investor cannot outperform the market using knowninformation except through luck.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 5: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Efficient Market Hypothesis

The Efficient Market Hypothesis has many forms butessentially can be taken to mean

prices on all securities and products reflect all knowninformation,current prices are the best unbiased estimate of the valueof the security or product,prices will adjust to any new information nearlyinstantaneously,an investor cannot outperform the market using knowninformation except through luck.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 6: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Simple Arbitrage Situation

Arbitrage arises from mis-priced financial instruments.

Example

CostCo sells 100 stamps for $43.75.USPS sell 100 stamps for $44.00.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 7: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Intuitive Idea

Imagine we will bet on the outcome of an experiment.The Arbitrage Theorem states that either the probabilities ofthe outcomes are such that

all bets are fair, orthere is a betting scheme which produces a positive gainindependent of the outcome of the experiment.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 8: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Odds

The odds against an outcome X are related to probabilities ofthe outcome according to the formula:

n : m against =⇒ P(X ) =m

m + n.

The odds for an outcome X are related to probabilities of theoutcome according to the formula:

n : m in favor =⇒ P(X ) =n

m + n.

For a wager of m dollars on a event X with odds against ofn : m, if X occurs, we win n dollars, otherwise we lose ourinvestment.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 9: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Example (1 of 2)

ExampleSuppose the odds against player A defeating player B in atennis match are 3 : 1 and the odds against player B defeatingplayer A are 1 : 1.

P(A wins) = 0.25 and P(B wins) = 0.5

Determine a betting strategy which guarantees a positive netprofit regardless of the outcome of the tennis match.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 10: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Example (2 of 2)

Betting strategy: wager $1 on player A and $2 on player B.A wins: gain $3 on the first bet and lose $2 on the second,net gain of $1.B wins: lose $1 on the first bet and gain $2 on the second,net gain of $1.

There is a positive payoff no matter which player wins.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 11: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Introduction to Linear Programming

Linear programming is a branch of mathematics concernedwith optimizing a linear function of several variables subject tosome set of constraints (linear equalities or inequalities) on thevariables.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 12: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Example (1 of 3)

ExampleA bank may invest its deposits in loans which earn 6% interestper year and in the purchase of stocks which increase in valueby 13% per year. Any un-invested amount is simply held by thebank. Suppose that government regulations require that thebank invest no more than 60% of its deposits in stocks. As agood business practice the bank wishes to devote at least 25%of its deposits to loans. Determine how the bank shouldallocate its capital so as to maximize the total return on itsinvestments.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 13: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Example (2 of 3)

Assume the bank can invest a fraction x in loans andfraction y in stocks.

The total return is therefore 0.06x + 0.13y .The constraints are:

0.25 ≤ x0 ≤ y ≤ 0.60x + y ≤ 1

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 14: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Example (2 of 3)

Assume the bank can invest a fraction x in loans andfraction y in stocks.The total return is therefore 0.06x + 0.13y .

The constraints are:0.25 ≤ x0 ≤ y ≤ 0.60x + y ≤ 1

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 15: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Example (2 of 3)

Assume the bank can invest a fraction x in loans andfraction y in stocks.The total return is therefore 0.06x + 0.13y .The constraints are:

0.25 ≤ x0 ≤ y ≤ 0.60x + y ≤ 1

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 16: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Example (3 of 3)

Feasible Region

0.06 x + 0.13 y = k

0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0

0.0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1.0

x

y

Optimal return occurs when x = 0.4 and y = 0.6.J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 17: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Linear Programming Notation (1 of 3)

If c and x are vectors with n components each, the notation

cT x = c1x1 + c2x2 + · · ·+ cnxn

represents a weighted sum of the components of x with theweights being the components of c.

Constraints will be expressed in the form aT x ≤ z.

aT x ≥ z ⇐⇒ (−a)T x ≤ −zaT x = z ⇐⇒ aT x ≤ z and (−a)T x ≤ −z

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 18: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Linear Programming Notation (1 of 3)

If c and x are vectors with n components each, the notation

cT x = c1x1 + c2x2 + · · ·+ cnxn

represents a weighted sum of the components of x with theweights being the components of c.

Constraints will be expressed in the form aT x ≤ z.

aT x ≥ z ⇐⇒ (−a)T x ≤ −zaT x = z ⇐⇒ aT x ≤ z and (−a)T x ≤ −z

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 19: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Linear Programming Notation (2 of 3)

We write u < v if ui < vi for i = 1,2, . . . ,n. Similarly foru > v,u ≤ v, andu ≥ v.

If 0 denotes the zero vector then x ≥ 0 is an example of a signconstraint.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 20: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Linear Programming Notation (2 of 3)

We write u < v if ui < vi for i = 1,2, . . . ,n. Similarly foru > v,u ≤ v, andu ≥ v.

If 0 denotes the zero vector then x ≥ 0 is an example of a signconstraint.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 21: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Linear Programming Notation (3 of 3)

The processes of maximizing and minimizing cT x areequivalent in the sense that cT x is a maximum if and only if(−c)T x is a minimum.

Suppose there are m inequality constraints:

aT1 x ≤ b1

aT2 x ≤ b2

...aT

mx ≤ bm

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 22: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Linear Programming Notation (3 of 3)

The processes of maximizing and minimizing cT x areequivalent in the sense that cT x is a maximum if and only if(−c)T x is a minimum.

Suppose there are m inequality constraints:

aT1 x ≤ b1

aT2 x ≤ b2

...aT

mx ≤ bm

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 23: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

General Linear Program

Ax =

a11 a12 · · · a1na21 a22 · · · a2n

......

...am1 am2 · · · amn

x1x2...

xn

b1b2...

bm

= b.

The general form of a linear program will be

“Maximize cT x subject to the constraints Ax ≤ b andx ≥ 0.”

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 24: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Feasible Vectors and Cost Functions

DefinitionVector x is feasible if x ≥ 0 and Ax ≤ b.

DefinitionIf c is a vector of n components, then we define

cT x = c1x1 + c2x2 + · · ·+ cnxn

to be the cost function.

DefinitionVector x is an optimal solution if x is feasible and maximizesthe cost function.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 25: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Feasible Vectors and Cost Functions

DefinitionVector x is feasible if x ≥ 0 and Ax ≤ b.

DefinitionIf c is a vector of n components, then we define

cT x = c1x1 + c2x2 + · · ·+ cnxn

to be the cost function.

DefinitionVector x is an optimal solution if x is feasible and maximizesthe cost function.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 26: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Feasible Vectors and Cost Functions

DefinitionVector x is feasible if x ≥ 0 and Ax ≤ b.

DefinitionIf c is a vector of n components, then we define

cT x = c1x1 + c2x2 + · · ·+ cnxn

to be the cost function.

DefinitionVector x is an optimal solution if x is feasible and maximizesthe cost function.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 27: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Example (1 of 2)

Example

Use the notion of the intersection of planes in R3 to minimize5x1 + 4x2 + 8x3 subject to x1 + x2 + x3 = 1 and x is feasible.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 28: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Example (2 of 2)

0.0

0.5

1.0

x1

0.0

0.5

1.0

x2

0.0

0.5

1.0

x3

Constraint Set

0.0

0.5

1.0

x1

0.0

0.5

1.0

x2

0.0

0.5

1.0

x3

Constraint Set

5x1+4x2+8x3=k

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 29: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Slack Variables

Many optimization problems may include inequalityconstraints.

Inequality constraints can be converted to equality constraintsby introducing slack variables. Thus

x1 + x2 + x3 ≤ 1 becomes x1 + x2 + x3 + x4 = 1,

where x4 ≥ 0 and “takes up the slack” to produce equality.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 30: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Example (1 of 2)

Example

Use the notion of the intersection of planes in R3 to minimize5x1 + 4x2 + 8x3 subject to x1 + x2 + x3 ≤ 1 and x is feasible.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 31: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Example (2 of 2)

If the constraints are x1 + x2 + x3 ≤ 1 and x feasible, then theset of points where the solution must be found would resemblea tetrahedron with vertices at (0,0,0), (1,0,0), (0,1,0), and(0,0,1).

Feasible Region

5x1+4x2+8x3=k-0.5

0.0

0.5

1.0

x1

-0.5

0.0

0.5

1.0

x2

-0.5

0.0

0.5

1.0

x3

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 32: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Matrix Notation for Slack Variables

Suppose A is an m × n matrix, x is a vector of n components,and b is a vector of m components, then by augmenting x withm slack variables and A with the m ×m identity matrix theinequality constraint Ax ≤ b is equivalent to

a11 a12 · · · a1n 1 0 · · · 0a21 a22 · · · a2n 0 1 · · · 0

......

......

......

am1 am2 · · · amn 0 0 · · · 1

x1x2...

xnx̂n+1x̂n+2

...x̂n+m

=

b1b2...

bm

[A Im

] [ xx̂

]= b.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 33: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Canonical Linear Form

The general linear problem can now be stated in equivalentform

“maximize cT x subject to Ax = b and x ≥ 0”,

whereA is an m × (n + m) matrix consisting of the originalconstraint matrix augmented with the identity matrix, andx is the previous solution vector augmented with the slackvariables.

This new form of the linear problem will be called the canonicalform.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 34: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Dual Problems

For every linear programming problem of the type discussedabove, there is an associated problem known as its dual.Henceforth the original problem will be known as the primal.These paired optimization problems are related in the followingways.

Primal: Maximize cT x subject to Ax ≤ b and x ≥ 0.Dual: Minimize bT y subject to AT y ≥ c and y ≥ 0.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 35: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Observations

Primal: Maximize cT x subject to Ax ≤ b and x ≥ 0.Dual: Minimize bT y subject to AT y ≥ c and y ≥ 0.

Note:1 the process of maximization in the primal is replaced with

the process of minimization in the dual,2 the unknown of the dual is a vector y with m components,3 the vector b moves from the constraint of the primal to the

cost function of the dual,4 the vector c moves from the cost of the primal to the

constraint of the dual,5 the constraints of the dual are inequalities and there are n

of them.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 36: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Dual of the Dual

TheoremThe dual of the dual is the primal.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 37: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Proof

Starting with the dual problem,

Minimize bT y subject to AT y ≥ c and y ≥ 0.

We can re-write the dual in general form,

Maximize (−b)T y subject to (−A)T y ≤ −c and y ≥ 0.

Now the dual of this problem (i.e., the dual of the dual) is

Minimize (−c)T x subject to ((−A)T )T x ≥ −b and x ≥ 0.

This problem is logically equivalent to the problem

Maximize cT x subject to Ax ≤ b and x ≥ 0,

which is the primal problem.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 38: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Weak Duality Theorem

Theorem (Weak Duality Theorem)If x and y are the feasible solutions of the primal and dualproblems respectively, then cT x ≤ bT y. If cT x = bT y thenthese solutions are optimal for their respective problems.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 39: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Proof of Weak Duality Theorem

Feasible solutions to the primal and the dual problems mustsatisfy the constraints Ax ≤ b with x ≥ 0 (for the primalproblem) and AT y ≥ c with y ≥ 0 (for the dual). Multiply theconstraint in the dual by xT

xT AT y ≥ xT c ⇐⇒ cT x ≤ yT Ax.

Multiply the constraint in the primal by yT

yT Ax ≤ yT b = bT y.

Directions of the inequalities are preserved because x ≥ 0 andy ≥ 0. Combining these last two inequalities produces

cT x ≤ yT Ax ≤ bT y.

Therefore we have cT x ≤ bT y. If cT x = bT y then x and y mustbe optimal since no x can make cT x larger than bT y and no ycan make bT y smaller than cT x.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 40: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Example (1 of 2)

ExamplePrimal: Maximize 4x1 + 3x2 subject to x1 + x2 ≤ 2 andx1, x2 ≥ 0.Dual: Minimize 2y1 subject to y1 ≥ 3, y1 ≥ 4, and y1 ≥ 0.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 41: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Example (2 of 2)

The minimum value of y1 subject to the constraints must bey1 = 4. According to the Weak Duality Theorem then theminimum of the cost function of the primal must be at least 8.Applying the level set argument as before, the largest value of kfor which the level set 4x1 + 3x2 = k intersects the set offeasible points for the primal is k = 8.

Feasible Region

4x1+3x2=8

0.0 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0

0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

x1

x 2

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 42: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

More on Duality

TheoremOptimality in the primal and dual problems requires eitherxj = 0 or (AT y)j = cj for each j = 1, . . . ,n.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 43: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Proof

When x and y are optimal for their respective problems then

bT y = yT Ax = cT x(yT A− cT )x = 0(AT y− c)T x = 0.

Since x ≥ 0 and AT y− c ≥ 0 then vector x must be zero inevery component for which vector AT y− c is positive and viceversa.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 44: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Example (1 of 4)

Example

Primal: Maximize cT x = −3x1 + 2x2 − x3 + 3x4 subject tox ≥ 0 and

[1 1 −1 0−2 0 1 1

]x1x2x3x4

≤ [ 53

]

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 45: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Example (2 of 4)

Dual: Minimize bT y = 5y1 + 3y2 subject to1 −21 0−1 10 1

[ y1y2

]≥

−32−13

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 46: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Example (3 of 4)

1 2 3 4 5 6

2.0

2.5

3.0

3.5

4.0

4.5

5.0

y1

y 2

Optimal solution is at (y1, y2) = (3,3) and has value 24.J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 47: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Example (4 of 4)

Strict inequality is present in the second and third constraintssince

y1 = 3 > 2−y1 + y2 = 0 > −1.

Thus the second and third components of x in the primalproblem must be zero. Therefore the primal can be recast asPrimal: Maximize −3x1 + 3x4 subject to x1 ≥ 0, x4 ≥ 0 and

[1 1 −1 0−2 0 1 1

]x100x4

=

[x1

−2x1 + x4

]≤[

53

]

Thus x1 = 5 and x4 = 13, the maximum of the cost function forthe primal is 24 and it occurs at (x1, x2, x3, x4) = (5,0,0,13).

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 48: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Duality Theorem

Theorem (Duality Theorem)If there is an optimal x in the primal, then there is an optimal yin the dual and the minimum of cT x equals the maximum ofyT b.

Remark: before proving the Duality Theorem we must state alemma which will be used in the proof.

Lemma (Farkas Alternative)Exactly one of the following two statements is true. Either

1 Ax ≤ b has a solution x ≥ 0, or2 AT y ≥ 0 with bT y < 0 has a solution y ≥ 0.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 49: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Duality Theorem

Theorem (Duality Theorem)If there is an optimal x in the primal, then there is an optimal yin the dual and the minimum of cT x equals the maximum ofyT b.

Remark: before proving the Duality Theorem we must state alemma which will be used in the proof.

Lemma (Farkas Alternative)Exactly one of the following two statements is true. Either

1 Ax ≤ b has a solution x ≥ 0, or2 AT y ≥ 0 with bT y < 0 has a solution y ≥ 0.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 50: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Proof (1 of 6)

Primal: Maximize cT x subject to Ax ≤ b and x ≥ 0.Dual: Minimize bT y subject to AT y ≥ c and y ≥ 0.

Assuming there are feasible solutions to each problem then wecan re-write the constraint of the dual as (−A)T y ≤ −c withy ≥ 0. Thus according to the constraint on the primal, there-written constraint on the dual, and the conclusion of theWeak Duality Theorem the following inequalities hold forx,y ≥ 0.

Ax ≤ b(−A)T y ≤ −c

cT x− bT y ≤ 0

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 51: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Proof (2 of 6)

These inequalities can be written in the block matrix form A 00 −AT

cT −bT

[ xy

]≤

b−c

0

.According to the Farkas Alternative Lemma either thisinequality has a solution 〈x,y〉 ≥ 0 or the alternative

[AT 0 c

0 −A −b

] uvλ

≥ 0 and[

bT −cT 0] u

< 0

has a solution 〈u,v, λ〉 ≥ 0.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 52: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Proof (3 of 6)

We may decompose this block matrix to derive the followingsystem of inequalities:

AT u + λc ≥ 0, −Av− λb ≥ 0, bT u− cT v < 0

with u ≥ 0, v ≥ 0, and λ ≥ 0. If λ > 0 then this system ofinequalities is equivalent to the following system.

A(

v)≤ −b

AT(

u)≥ −c

−bT(

u)

> −cT(

v)

Since u ≥ 0 and v ≥ 0 the vectors 1λu ≥ 0 and 1

λv ≥ 0 as well.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 53: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Proof (4 of 6)

The first two inequalities form a primal problem and its dual.

Primal: A(

v)≤ −b

Dual: AT(

u)≥ −c

If we apply the Weak Duality Theorem, then it must be the casethat −bT ( 1

λu)≤ −cT ( 1

λv), contradicting the inequality:

−bT(

u)> −cT

(1λ

v)

Therefore we know that λ = 0.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 54: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Proof (5 of 6)

Thus the Farkas Alternative simplifies to the following system:

Av ≤ 0, AT u ≥ 0, and bT u < cT v

where u ≥ 0 and v ≥ 0. The last inequality implies thatbT u < 0 or cT v > 0. If bT u < 0 then the primal problem Ax ≤ bhas no feasible solution x ≥ 0. To see this note that togetherthe inequalities x ≥ 0, Ax ≤ b, and bT u < 0 imply that

(Ax)T ≤ bT

xT AT ≤ bT

xT(

AT u)≤ bT u < 0.

However, x ≥ 0 and AT u ≥ 0 and thus xT (AT u)≥ 0, a

contradiction.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 55: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Proof (6 of 6)

If cT v > 0 then the dual problem AT y ≥ c has no feasiblesolution y ≥ 0. To see this note that together the inequalitiesy ≥ 0, AT y ≥ c, and cT v > 0 imply that(

AT y)T

≥ cT

yT A ≥ cT

yT (Av) ≥ cT v > 0yT (−Av) < 0

However, y ≥ 0 and −Av ≥ 0 and thus yT (−Av) ≥ 0, acontradiction.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 56: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Fundamental Theorem of Finance (1 of 2)

Assumptions and background:Experiment has m possible outcomes numbered 1 throughm.We can place n wagers (numbered 1 through n) on theoutcomes.rij is the return for a unit bet on wager i ∈ {1,2, . . . ,n}when the outcome of the experiment is j ∈ {1,2, . . . ,m}.Vector x = (x1, x2, . . . , xn) is called a betting strategy.Component xi is the amount placed on wager i .Return from a betting strategy is

∑ni=1 xi rij .

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 57: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Fundamental Theorem of Finance (2 of 2)

Theorem (Arbitrage Theorem)

Exactly one of the following is true: either1 there is a vector of probabilities y = 〈y1, y2, . . . , ym〉 for

which

m∑j=1

yj rij = 0, for each i = 1,2, . . . ,n, or

2 there is a betting strategy x = 〈x1, x2, . . . , xn〉 for which

n∑i=1

xi rij > 0, for each j = 1,2, . . . ,m.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 58: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Proof (1 of 4)

Let the n-tuple (x1, x2, . . . , xn) be the betting strategy.Vector x = 〈x1, x2, . . . , xn, xn+1〉 where the (n + 1)stelement is the payoff for the betting strategy.

We would like to maximize xn+1 under the constraint that∑ni=1 xi rji ≥ xn+1 for j = 1,2, . . . ,m. This is equivalent to∑ni=1 xi(−rji) + xn+1 ≤ 0 for j = 1,2, . . . ,m.

c = 〈 0, . . . ,0︸ ︷︷ ︸n components

,1〉 and b = 〈 0, . . . ,0︸ ︷︷ ︸m components

The maximization problem above can be stated as “MaximizecT x = xn+1 subject to Ax ≤ b and x ≥ 0”.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 59: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Proof (2 of 4)

Ax =

−r11 −r12 · · · −r1n 1−r21 −r22 · · · −r2n 1

......

......

−rm1 −rm2 · · · −rmn 1

x1x2...

xnxn+1

00...0

.

The dual of this primal problem can be stated as “MinimizebT y = 0 subject to AT y ≥ c and y ≥ 0.” The unknown y is avector of m components. Since b = 0 the cost function isminimized at 0.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 60: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Proof (3 of 4)

The dual problem is that of minimizing 0 subject to y ≥ 0 and−r11 −r21 · · · −rm1−r12 −r22 · · · −rm2

......

...−r1n −r2n · · · −rmn

1 1 · · · 1

y1y2...

ym−1ym

=

00...01

.

This is equivalent to the system of equations,∑m

j=1 yj rji = 0 fori = 1,2, . . . ,n;

∑mj=1 yj = 1, and yj ≥ 0 for j = 1,2, . . . ,m. The

dual problem is feasible with a minimum value of zero if andonly if y is a probability vector for which all bets have anexpected return of zero.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage

Page 61: Arbitrage - Millersville University - Welcome to Millersville

Proof (4 of 4)

Suppose the dual problem is feasible, the primal problem isalso feasible since xi = 0 for i = 1,2, . . . ,n + 1 satisfies theinequality constraints of the dual. According to the DualityTheorem then the maximum of the primal problem is zerowhich means no guaranteed profit is possible. In other words if(1) is true then (2) is false.

Now suppose the dual problem is not feasible. According to theDuality Theorem the primal problem has no optimal solution.Therefore zero is not the maximum payoff, thus there is abetting strategy which produces a positive payoff. Thus we seethat if (1) is false then (2) is true.

J. Robert Buchanan Arbitrage