87
Democracy and Income (Distribution) Jess Benhabib NYU August 2011 Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 1 / 43

Democracy and Income Distribution

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

Jess Benhabib (New York University) delivered this lecture on September 26, 2011 at Banc Sabadell Auditorium in Barcelona.About Barcelona GSE Lectures: http://www.barcelonagse.eu/gselectures.html

Citation preview

Page 1: Democracy and Income Distribution

Democracy and Income (Distribution)

Jess Benhabib

NYU

August 2011

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 1 / 43

Page 2: Democracy and Income Distribution

Democracy and Income Distribition

My preferred title would be Democracy and Income, for reasons thatwill be clear in a moment.

The questions will be:

1 Why is democracy more sustainable at high levels of income but notat low levels?

2 Are growth, and democracy, driven by good institutions (propertyrights, rule of law, constraints on executive) or are they endogenous,primarily a function of wealth or income?

I will attempt a sketch of some theory, give an overview of the recentwork, and then turn to the debate on the empirics of Democracy andIncome.Finally I will discuss our recent empirical paper (Benhabib, Corvalanand Spiegel (2011)) that adresses the questions raised above. (Let’spostpone the definition of Democracy to later.)

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 2 / 43

Page 3: Democracy and Income Distribution

Democracy and Income Distribition

My preferred title would be Democracy and Income, for reasons thatwill be clear in a moment.The questions will be:

1 Why is democracy more sustainable at high levels of income but notat low levels?

2 Are growth, and democracy, driven by good institutions (propertyrights, rule of law, constraints on executive) or are they endogenous,primarily a function of wealth or income?

I will attempt a sketch of some theory, give an overview of the recentwork, and then turn to the debate on the empirics of Democracy andIncome.Finally I will discuss our recent empirical paper (Benhabib, Corvalanand Spiegel (2011)) that adresses the questions raised above. (Let’spostpone the definition of Democracy to later.)

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 2 / 43

Page 4: Democracy and Income Distribution

Democracy and Income Distribition

My preferred title would be Democracy and Income, for reasons thatwill be clear in a moment.The questions will be:

1 Why is democracy more sustainable at high levels of income but notat low levels?

2 Are growth, and democracy, driven by good institutions (propertyrights, rule of law, constraints on executive) or are they endogenous,primarily a function of wealth or income?

I will attempt a sketch of some theory, give an overview of the recentwork, and then turn to the debate on the empirics of Democracy andIncome.Finally I will discuss our recent empirical paper (Benhabib, Corvalanand Spiegel (2011)) that adresses the questions raised above. (Let’spostpone the definition of Democracy to later.)

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 2 / 43

Page 5: Democracy and Income Distribution

Democracy and Income Distribition

My preferred title would be Democracy and Income, for reasons thatwill be clear in a moment.The questions will be:

1 Why is democracy more sustainable at high levels of income but notat low levels?

2 Are growth, and democracy, driven by good institutions (propertyrights, rule of law, constraints on executive) or are they endogenous,primarily a function of wealth or income?

I will attempt a sketch of some theory, give an overview of the recentwork, and then turn to the debate on the empirics of Democracy andIncome.Finally I will discuss our recent empirical paper (Benhabib, Corvalanand Spiegel (2011)) that adresses the questions raised above. (Let’spostpone the definition of Democracy to later.)

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 2 / 43

Page 6: Democracy and Income Distribution

Democracy and Income Distribition

My preferred title would be Democracy and Income, for reasons thatwill be clear in a moment.The questions will be:

1 Why is democracy more sustainable at high levels of income but notat low levels?

2 Are growth, and democracy, driven by good institutions (propertyrights, rule of law, constraints on executive) or are they endogenous,primarily a function of wealth or income?

I will attempt a sketch of some theory, give an overview of the recentwork, and then turn to the debate on the empirics of Democracy andIncome.

Finally I will discuss our recent empirical paper (Benhabib, Corvalanand Spiegel (2011)) that adresses the questions raised above. (Let’spostpone the definition of Democracy to later.)

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 2 / 43

Page 7: Democracy and Income Distribution

Democracy and Income Distribition

My preferred title would be Democracy and Income, for reasons thatwill be clear in a moment.The questions will be:

1 Why is democracy more sustainable at high levels of income but notat low levels?

2 Are growth, and democracy, driven by good institutions (propertyrights, rule of law, constraints on executive) or are they endogenous,primarily a function of wealth or income?

I will attempt a sketch of some theory, give an overview of the recentwork, and then turn to the debate on the empirics of Democracy andIncome.Finally I will discuss our recent empirical paper (Benhabib, Corvalanand Spiegel (2011)) that adresses the questions raised above. (Let’spostpone the definition of Democracy to later.)

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 2 / 43

Page 8: Democracy and Income Distribution

Inequality, Growth and Democracy

Let me start however, with Democracy and Inequality.

The most obvious hypothesis is that excessive and persistentinequality leads to social conflict and coups, and is incompatible withdemocracy. In the absence of redistribution that mediates andameliorates inequality, democracy cannot survive.

But this may be too simplistic: the goverment may redistribute onlyto the point which avoids revolt by the poor (left), or stop short of thelevel of redistribution that would trigger a coup by the rich (right).

Here specifics of the distribution of power, the costs of collectiveaction , the degree of repression and the potential use of force allmatter. (For example recently new social media may have reducedcollective action costs.)

So political economy is diffi cult. Empirically, what do we know fromsome classic papers?

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 3 / 43

Page 9: Democracy and Income Distribution

Inequality, Growth and Democracy

Let me start however, with Democracy and Inequality.

The most obvious hypothesis is that excessive and persistentinequality leads to social conflict and coups, and is incompatible withdemocracy. In the absence of redistribution that mediates andameliorates inequality, democracy cannot survive.

But this may be too simplistic: the goverment may redistribute onlyto the point which avoids revolt by the poor (left), or stop short of thelevel of redistribution that would trigger a coup by the rich (right).

Here specifics of the distribution of power, the costs of collectiveaction , the degree of repression and the potential use of force allmatter. (For example recently new social media may have reducedcollective action costs.)

So political economy is diffi cult. Empirically, what do we know fromsome classic papers?

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 3 / 43

Page 10: Democracy and Income Distribution

Inequality, Growth and Democracy

Let me start however, with Democracy and Inequality.

The most obvious hypothesis is that excessive and persistentinequality leads to social conflict and coups, and is incompatible withdemocracy. In the absence of redistribution that mediates andameliorates inequality, democracy cannot survive.

But this may be too simplistic: the goverment may redistribute onlyto the point which avoids revolt by the poor (left), or stop short of thelevel of redistribution that would trigger a coup by the rich (right).

Here specifics of the distribution of power, the costs of collectiveaction , the degree of repression and the potential use of force allmatter. (For example recently new social media may have reducedcollective action costs.)

So political economy is diffi cult. Empirically, what do we know fromsome classic papers?

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 3 / 43

Page 11: Democracy and Income Distribution

Inequality, Growth and Democracy

Let me start however, with Democracy and Inequality.

The most obvious hypothesis is that excessive and persistentinequality leads to social conflict and coups, and is incompatible withdemocracy. In the absence of redistribution that mediates andameliorates inequality, democracy cannot survive.

But this may be too simplistic: the goverment may redistribute onlyto the point which avoids revolt by the poor (left), or stop short of thelevel of redistribution that would trigger a coup by the rich (right).

Here specifics of the distribution of power, the costs of collectiveaction , the degree of repression and the potential use of force allmatter. (For example recently new social media may have reducedcollective action costs.)

So political economy is diffi cult. Empirically, what do we know fromsome classic papers?

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 3 / 43

Page 12: Democracy and Income Distribution

Inequality, Growth and Democracy

Let me start however, with Democracy and Inequality.

The most obvious hypothesis is that excessive and persistentinequality leads to social conflict and coups, and is incompatible withdemocracy. In the absence of redistribution that mediates andameliorates inequality, democracy cannot survive.

But this may be too simplistic: the goverment may redistribute onlyto the point which avoids revolt by the poor (left), or stop short of thelevel of redistribution that would trigger a coup by the rich (right).

Here specifics of the distribution of power, the costs of collectiveaction , the degree of repression and the potential use of force allmatter. (For example recently new social media may have reducedcollective action costs.)

So political economy is diffi cult. Empirically, what do we know fromsome classic papers?

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 3 / 43

Page 13: Democracy and Income Distribution

"We are specifically interested in two questions:

I. Does income inequality increase political instability?2. Does political instability reduce investment?

According to our findings, the answer to both questions is ’yes’. First,more unequal societies are more politically unstable: in particular, ourresults suggest that political stability is enhanced by the presence of awealthy middle class. Second, political instability has an adverse effect oninvestment and, therefore, on growth. Furthermore, these two effects(from inequality to instability, and from instability to investment) are notonly statistically significant, but also economically significant."

A. Alesina and R. Perotti "Income distribution, political instability, andinvestment" EER, 1996.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 4 / 43

Page 14: Democracy and Income Distribution

"More equal societies have lower fertility rates and higher rates ofinvestment in education. Both are reflected in higher rates of growth.Also, very unequal societies tend to be politically and sociallyunstable, which is reflected in lower rates of investment and thereforegrowth. Finally, the data do not support the idea that moreequal societies, particularly those with democratic institutions,grow faster because they generate fewer demands forredistribution and therefore fewer distortions."

R. Perotti, "Growth, Income Distribution, and Democracy: What the DataSay," Journal of Economic Growth, (1996)

Here we also have hints of inequality retarding growth through creditmarket imperfections and social instability.

The point in bold: In more equal countries with democraticinstitutions, typically richer countries, there may be moreredistribution, rather than less. Redistribution is mediated by thegovernment and a welfare state. Maybe because the stakes arehigher?

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 5 / 43

Page 15: Democracy and Income Distribution

"More equal societies have lower fertility rates and higher rates ofinvestment in education. Both are reflected in higher rates of growth.Also, very unequal societies tend to be politically and sociallyunstable, which is reflected in lower rates of investment and thereforegrowth. Finally, the data do not support the idea that moreequal societies, particularly those with democratic institutions,grow faster because they generate fewer demands forredistribution and therefore fewer distortions."

R. Perotti, "Growth, Income Distribution, and Democracy: What the DataSay," Journal of Economic Growth, (1996)

Here we also have hints of inequality retarding growth through creditmarket imperfections and social instability.

The point in bold: In more equal countries with democraticinstitutions, typically richer countries, there may be moreredistribution, rather than less. Redistribution is mediated by thegovernment and a welfare state. Maybe because the stakes arehigher?

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 5 / 43

Page 16: Democracy and Income Distribution

"More equal societies have lower fertility rates and higher rates ofinvestment in education. Both are reflected in higher rates of growth.Also, very unequal societies tend to be politically and sociallyunstable, which is reflected in lower rates of investment and thereforegrowth. Finally, the data do not support the idea that moreequal societies, particularly those with democratic institutions,grow faster because they generate fewer demands forredistribution and therefore fewer distortions."

R. Perotti, "Growth, Income Distribution, and Democracy: What the DataSay," Journal of Economic Growth, (1996)

Here we also have hints of inequality retarding growth through creditmarket imperfections and social instability.

The point in bold: In more equal countries with democraticinstitutions, typically richer countries, there may be moreredistribution, rather than less. Redistribution is mediated by thegovernment and a welfare state. Maybe because the stakes arehigher?

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 5 / 43

Page 17: Democracy and Income Distribution

"Evidence from a broad panel of countries shows little overall relationbetween income inequality and rates of growth and investment. Forgrowth, higher inequality tends to retard growth in poor countries andencourage growth in richer places."

R. Barro, "Inequality and Growth in a Panel of Countries," JOEG, (2000).

Note the differential impact of inequality between rich and poor. Canricher countries tolerate more inequality with less social disruptionand adverse effects on growth?

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 6 / 43

Page 18: Democracy and Income Distribution

"Evidence from a broad panel of countries shows little overall relationbetween income inequality and rates of growth and investment. Forgrowth, higher inequality tends to retard growth in poor countries andencourage growth in richer places."

R. Barro, "Inequality and Growth in a Panel of Countries," JOEG, (2000).

Note the differential impact of inequality between rich and poor. Canricher countries tolerate more inequality with less social disruptionand adverse effects on growth?

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 6 / 43

Page 19: Democracy and Income Distribution

Income, Growth and DemocracyProperty Rights?

So let’s move to explore the relationship of income, rather than incomedistribution, on growth and democracy.

A key concept, often measured and included in econometricspecifications, is the "security of property rights." The followingsketch of model, though problematic and too abstract, can set sometentative initial ideas.

What if "property rights / institutions" are endogenous, a function ofmore basic fundamentals, like wealth or income?

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 7 / 43

Page 20: Democracy and Income Distribution

Income, Growth and DemocracyProperty Rights?

So let’s move to explore the relationship of income, rather than incomedistribution, on growth and democracy.

A key concept, often measured and included in econometricspecifications, is the "security of property rights." The followingsketch of model, though problematic and too abstract, can set sometentative initial ideas.

What if "property rights / institutions" are endogenous, a function ofmore basic fundamentals, like wealth or income?

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 7 / 43

Page 21: Democracy and Income Distribution

Expropriation, Appropriation, Tragedy of the Commons

Expropriative redistributive activities can result from nationalizations,confiscations, required bribes to offi cials, arbitrary taxes, coups...

Appropriative redistributive activities can have legitimate, clientelistforms: subsidies, regulations, wage and price controls, taxes targetedto specific groups, an overvalued currency to favor urban vs ruralareas producing exportables (agricultural and mineral goods),restrictions on mineral and agricultural exports to be channeledthrough govenment marketing boards, govenment fertilizermonopolies, allocation of civil service jobs... (whether the governmentis elected or not.)To simplify, the absence of well-defined property rights over thelong-horizon may give rise to a dynamic "Tragedy of the Commons".(Benhabib and Radner, 1992, Benhabib and Rustichini, 1996).With various interest groups engaging of appropriation/expropriation(even with pre or post fisc equality) expected returns on productiveactivities are reduced, and growth can slow down, or get trapped.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 8 / 43

Page 22: Democracy and Income Distribution

Expropriation, Appropriation, Tragedy of the Commons

Expropriative redistributive activities can result from nationalizations,confiscations, required bribes to offi cials, arbitrary taxes, coups...Appropriative redistributive activities can have legitimate, clientelistforms: subsidies, regulations, wage and price controls, taxes targetedto specific groups, an overvalued currency to favor urban vs ruralareas producing exportables (agricultural and mineral goods),restrictions on mineral and agricultural exports to be channeledthrough govenment marketing boards, govenment fertilizermonopolies, allocation of civil service jobs... (whether the governmentis elected or not.)

To simplify, the absence of well-defined property rights over thelong-horizon may give rise to a dynamic "Tragedy of the Commons".(Benhabib and Radner, 1992, Benhabib and Rustichini, 1996).With various interest groups engaging of appropriation/expropriation(even with pre or post fisc equality) expected returns on productiveactivities are reduced, and growth can slow down, or get trapped.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 8 / 43

Page 23: Democracy and Income Distribution

Expropriation, Appropriation, Tragedy of the Commons

Expropriative redistributive activities can result from nationalizations,confiscations, required bribes to offi cials, arbitrary taxes, coups...Appropriative redistributive activities can have legitimate, clientelistforms: subsidies, regulations, wage and price controls, taxes targetedto specific groups, an overvalued currency to favor urban vs ruralareas producing exportables (agricultural and mineral goods),restrictions on mineral and agricultural exports to be channeledthrough govenment marketing boards, govenment fertilizermonopolies, allocation of civil service jobs... (whether the governmentis elected or not.)To simplify, the absence of well-defined property rights over thelong-horizon may give rise to a dynamic "Tragedy of the Commons".(Benhabib and Radner, 1992, Benhabib and Rustichini, 1996).

With various interest groups engaging of appropriation/expropriation(even with pre or post fisc equality) expected returns on productiveactivities are reduced, and growth can slow down, or get trapped.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 8 / 43

Page 24: Democracy and Income Distribution

Expropriation, Appropriation, Tragedy of the Commons

Expropriative redistributive activities can result from nationalizations,confiscations, required bribes to offi cials, arbitrary taxes, coups...Appropriative redistributive activities can have legitimate, clientelistforms: subsidies, regulations, wage and price controls, taxes targetedto specific groups, an overvalued currency to favor urban vs ruralareas producing exportables (agricultural and mineral goods),restrictions on mineral and agricultural exports to be channeledthrough govenment marketing boards, govenment fertilizermonopolies, allocation of civil service jobs... (whether the governmentis elected or not.)To simplify, the absence of well-defined property rights over thelong-horizon may give rise to a dynamic "Tragedy of the Commons".(Benhabib and Radner, 1992, Benhabib and Rustichini, 1996).With various interest groups engaging of appropriation/expropriation(even with pre or post fisc equality) expected returns on productiveactivities are reduced, and growth can slow down, or get trapped.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 8 / 43

Page 25: Democracy and Income Distribution

Questions

With actors or interest groups having long term, forward-lookingobjectives, this problem can get complicated.

Does it pay for the various interest groups to adhere to institutionalconstrains and refrain from short-term expropriation in order tosustain higher growth and future well-being?

Can you sustain cooperation because the high short-term payoff ofrevolt and too high expropriation is just not worth it in the long run?

The twist we are looking for is whether cooperative actions aresustainable from income/wealth levels above a treshold, but notbelow it (for a given discount rate).

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 9 / 43

Page 26: Democracy and Income Distribution

Questions

With actors or interest groups having long term, forward-lookingobjectives, this problem can get complicated.

Does it pay for the various interest groups to adhere to institutionalconstrains and refrain from short-term expropriation in order tosustain higher growth and future well-being?

Can you sustain cooperation because the high short-term payoff ofrevolt and too high expropriation is just not worth it in the long run?

The twist we are looking for is whether cooperative actions aresustainable from income/wealth levels above a treshold, but notbelow it (for a given discount rate).

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 9 / 43

Page 27: Democracy and Income Distribution

Questions

With actors or interest groups having long term, forward-lookingobjectives, this problem can get complicated.

Does it pay for the various interest groups to adhere to institutionalconstrains and refrain from short-term expropriation in order tosustain higher growth and future well-being?

Can you sustain cooperation because the high short-term payoff ofrevolt and too high expropriation is just not worth it in the long run?

The twist we are looking for is whether cooperative actions aresustainable from income/wealth levels above a treshold, but notbelow it (for a given discount rate).

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 9 / 43

Page 28: Democracy and Income Distribution

Sustainable Growth: A Model Too Abstract

Suppose groups voluntarily agree not to expropriate, or revolt becausethe one time gain is not worth trigerring a bad (high appropriation)equilibrium with low and uncertain effective returns for the longer run.

Suppose a first-best cooperative outcome with growth isself-sustaining as an equilibrium from high income levels.

But it may not be at lower income levels: The marginal utility of onetime expropriation is smaller at high levels of income, and the lossassociated with reversion to a bad equilibrium too big...

The same is not true at low wealth and income levels: marginalutilities are high and the benefits of slow accumulation are distant...

Rocking the boat is not worth it if you are rich, only if you are poor..

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 10 / 43

Page 29: Democracy and Income Distribution

Sustainable Growth: A Model Too Abstract

Suppose groups voluntarily agree not to expropriate, or revolt becausethe one time gain is not worth trigerring a bad (high appropriation)equilibrium with low and uncertain effective returns for the longer run.

Suppose a first-best cooperative outcome with growth isself-sustaining as an equilibrium from high income levels.

But it may not be at lower income levels: The marginal utility of onetime expropriation is smaller at high levels of income, and the lossassociated with reversion to a bad equilibrium too big...

The same is not true at low wealth and income levels: marginalutilities are high and the benefits of slow accumulation are distant...

Rocking the boat is not worth it if you are rich, only if you are poor..

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 10 / 43

Page 30: Democracy and Income Distribution

Sustainable Growth: A Model Too Abstract

Suppose groups voluntarily agree not to expropriate, or revolt becausethe one time gain is not worth trigerring a bad (high appropriation)equilibrium with low and uncertain effective returns for the longer run.

Suppose a first-best cooperative outcome with growth isself-sustaining as an equilibrium from high income levels.

But it may not be at lower income levels: The marginal utility of onetime expropriation is smaller at high levels of income, and the lossassociated with reversion to a bad equilibrium too big...

The same is not true at low wealth and income levels: marginalutilities are high and the benefits of slow accumulation are distant...

Rocking the boat is not worth it if you are rich, only if you are poor..

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 10 / 43

Page 31: Democracy and Income Distribution

Sustainable Growth: A Model Too Abstract

Suppose groups voluntarily agree not to expropriate, or revolt becausethe one time gain is not worth trigerring a bad (high appropriation)equilibrium with low and uncertain effective returns for the longer run.

Suppose a first-best cooperative outcome with growth isself-sustaining as an equilibrium from high income levels.

But it may not be at lower income levels: The marginal utility of onetime expropriation is smaller at high levels of income, and the lossassociated with reversion to a bad equilibrium too big...

The same is not true at low wealth and income levels: marginalutilities are high and the benefits of slow accumulation are distant...

Rocking the boat is not worth it if you are rich, only if you are poor..

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 10 / 43

Page 32: Democracy and Income Distribution

Sustainable Growth: A Model Too Abstract

Suppose groups voluntarily agree not to expropriate, or revolt becausethe one time gain is not worth trigerring a bad (high appropriation)equilibrium with low and uncertain effective returns for the longer run.

Suppose a first-best cooperative outcome with growth isself-sustaining as an equilibrium from high income levels.

But it may not be at lower income levels: The marginal utility of onetime expropriation is smaller at high levels of income, and the lossassociated with reversion to a bad equilibrium too big...

The same is not true at low wealth and income levels: marginalutilities are high and the benefits of slow accumulation are distant...

Rocking the boat is not worth it if you are rich, only if you are poor..

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 10 / 43

Page 33: Democracy and Income Distribution

Second Best?

The second-best sustainable equilibrium may entail slower growth andaccumulation until a treshold wealth level is crossed, or in theextreme, we could get a poverty trap. (all for a given discount rate).

Redistributive pressures arising from inequality, or conflicts over thedistribution of income and wealth may be mediated through politicaland democratic processes, but may in certain cases lead to socialinstability, coups or repression in poorer countries.

So we may observe expropriative activities and coups more frequentlyat lower income/wealth levels.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 11 / 43

Page 34: Democracy and Income Distribution

Second Best?

The second-best sustainable equilibrium may entail slower growth andaccumulation until a treshold wealth level is crossed, or in theextreme, we could get a poverty trap. (all for a given discount rate).

Redistributive pressures arising from inequality, or conflicts over thedistribution of income and wealth may be mediated through politicaland democratic processes, but may in certain cases lead to socialinstability, coups or repression in poorer countries.

So we may observe expropriative activities and coups more frequentlyat lower income/wealth levels.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 11 / 43

Page 35: Democracy and Income Distribution

Second Best?

The second-best sustainable equilibrium may entail slower growth andaccumulation until a treshold wealth level is crossed, or in theextreme, we could get a poverty trap. (all for a given discount rate).

Redistributive pressures arising from inequality, or conflicts over thedistribution of income and wealth may be mediated through politicaland democratic processes, but may in certain cases lead to socialinstability, coups or repression in poorer countries.

So we may observe expropriative activities and coups more frequentlyat lower income/wealth levels.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 11 / 43

Page 36: Democracy and Income Distribution

In a Picture

Think of "a" as repression"

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 12 / 43

Page 37: Democracy and Income Distribution

Digression: Homotheticity

A technical digression about homogeneity: Why should enforcability ofcooperation depend on wealth if production and preferences arehomothetic? Even if if production and preferences are homothetic, butthere is a fixed factor, you can get this result: (there may be a maximumtime endowment to be allocated between labor and leisure for example. )

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 13 / 43

Page 38: Democracy and Income Distribution

Role of Institutions?

We can already signal a basic question to be addressed later:

Can good institutions (property rights, rule of law, constraints on theexecutive, etc) secure cooperation and good behavior, or areinstitutions endogenous, so that they evolve to reflect (or theirimplementation reflects) self interested computations by variousgroups?

We’ll get to this.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 14 / 43

Page 39: Democracy and Income Distribution

Role of Institutions?

We can already signal a basic question to be addressed later:

Can good institutions (property rights, rule of law, constraints on theexecutive, etc) secure cooperation and good behavior, or areinstitutions endogenous, so that they evolve to reflect (or theirimplementation reflects) self interested computations by variousgroups?

We’ll get to this.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 14 / 43

Page 40: Democracy and Income Distribution

Role of Institutions?

We can already signal a basic question to be addressed later:

Can good institutions (property rights, rule of law, constraints on theexecutive, etc) secure cooperation and good behavior, or areinstitutions endogenous, so that they evolve to reflect (or theirimplementation reflects) self interested computations by variousgroups?

We’ll get to this.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 14 / 43

Page 41: Democracy and Income Distribution

Some problems with the model

:

First, a significant source of growth is TFP, not investment.

Second, TFP growth diffuses from technology leaders and can(irresistibly) drive growth, despite the political regimes andexpropriations. Distance to the leader and educational levels maydrive technology adoption and the diffusion rate.

Parente and Prescott (1993, 2002) reintroduce politics to explainTFP diffusion across countries. They make the point that technologyadoption can be blocked or retarded by vested interests throughvarious political barriers.

Nevertheless so far the analysis, while it is dynamic and allowsforward looking agents, is too abstract and too much of a black box.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 15 / 43

Page 42: Democracy and Income Distribution

Some problems with the model

:

First, a significant source of growth is TFP, not investment.

Second, TFP growth diffuses from technology leaders and can(irresistibly) drive growth, despite the political regimes andexpropriations. Distance to the leader and educational levels maydrive technology adoption and the diffusion rate.

Parente and Prescott (1993, 2002) reintroduce politics to explainTFP diffusion across countries. They make the point that technologyadoption can be blocked or retarded by vested interests throughvarious political barriers.

Nevertheless so far the analysis, while it is dynamic and allowsforward looking agents, is too abstract and too much of a black box.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 15 / 43

Page 43: Democracy and Income Distribution

Some problems with the model

:

First, a significant source of growth is TFP, not investment.

Second, TFP growth diffuses from technology leaders and can(irresistibly) drive growth, despite the political regimes andexpropriations. Distance to the leader and educational levels maydrive technology adoption and the diffusion rate.

Parente and Prescott (1993, 2002) reintroduce politics to explainTFP diffusion across countries. They make the point that technologyadoption can be blocked or retarded by vested interests throughvarious political barriers.

Nevertheless so far the analysis, while it is dynamic and allowsforward looking agents, is too abstract and too much of a black box.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 15 / 43

Page 44: Democracy and Income Distribution

Some problems with the model

:

First, a significant source of growth is TFP, not investment.

Second, TFP growth diffuses from technology leaders and can(irresistibly) drive growth, despite the political regimes andexpropriations. Distance to the leader and educational levels maydrive technology adoption and the diffusion rate.

Parente and Prescott (1993, 2002) reintroduce politics to explainTFP diffusion across countries. They make the point that technologyadoption can be blocked or retarded by vested interests throughvarious political barriers.

Nevertheless so far the analysis, while it is dynamic and allowsforward looking agents, is too abstract and too much of a black box.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 15 / 43

Page 45: Democracy and Income Distribution

A model of sustainable democracy (Benhabib-Przeworski,ET (2006))

Now we switch from sustainability of high growth rates tosustainability of democracy.

Democracy here is the median voter setting taxes and redistributions(Note: we show the median voter thm holds in our context even withthe infinite sequence of taxes)

Agents are long-lived, and heterogeneous in initial wealth.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 16 / 43

Page 46: Democracy and Income Distribution

A model of sustainable democracy (Benhabib-Przeworski,ET (2006))

Now we switch from sustainability of high growth rates tosustainability of democracy.

Democracy here is the median voter setting taxes and redistributions(Note: we show the median voter thm holds in our context even withthe infinite sequence of taxes)

Agents are long-lived, and heterogeneous in initial wealth.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 16 / 43

Page 47: Democracy and Income Distribution

A model of sustainable democracy (Benhabib-Przeworski,ET (2006))

Now we switch from sustainability of high growth rates tosustainability of democracy.

Democracy here is the median voter setting taxes and redistributions(Note: we show the median voter thm holds in our context even withthe infinite sequence of taxes)

Agents are long-lived, and heterogeneous in initial wealth.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 16 / 43

Page 48: Democracy and Income Distribution

The upper x% and the lower y% of the wealth tail may attempt acoup if they find the redistribution excessive or insuffi cient, that istheir long-term expected utility is higher under the coup for everyonein that tail.

If the left or the right revolts there is a probabilistic outcome of a leftor right dictatorship.

Under a right dictatorship taxes and redistrubutions are zero, under aleft dictatorship rediredistribution equalizes wealth immediately (withzero taxes afterwards. An interesting tangential issue here: willinequality nevertheless re-emerge in some form? Remember Pareto.)

All else equal, everyone prefers democracy. There is a fixed cost underdictatorship (which can differ for the right and left, depending who isin power.).

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 17 / 43

Page 49: Democracy and Income Distribution

The upper x% and the lower y% of the wealth tail may attempt acoup if they find the redistribution excessive or insuffi cient, that istheir long-term expected utility is higher under the coup for everyonein that tail.

If the left or the right revolts there is a probabilistic outcome of a leftor right dictatorship.

Under a right dictatorship taxes and redistrubutions are zero, under aleft dictatorship rediredistribution equalizes wealth immediately (withzero taxes afterwards. An interesting tangential issue here: willinequality nevertheless re-emerge in some form? Remember Pareto.)

All else equal, everyone prefers democracy. There is a fixed cost underdictatorship (which can differ for the right and left, depending who isin power.).

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 17 / 43

Page 50: Democracy and Income Distribution

The upper x% and the lower y% of the wealth tail may attempt acoup if they find the redistribution excessive or insuffi cient, that istheir long-term expected utility is higher under the coup for everyonein that tail.

If the left or the right revolts there is a probabilistic outcome of a leftor right dictatorship.

Under a right dictatorship taxes and redistrubutions are zero, under aleft dictatorship rediredistribution equalizes wealth immediately (withzero taxes afterwards. An interesting tangential issue here: willinequality nevertheless re-emerge in some form? Remember Pareto.)

All else equal, everyone prefers democracy. There is a fixed cost underdictatorship (which can differ for the right and left, depending who isin power.).

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 17 / 43

Page 51: Democracy and Income Distribution

The upper x% and the lower y% of the wealth tail may attempt acoup if they find the redistribution excessive or insuffi cient, that istheir long-term expected utility is higher under the coup for everyonein that tail.

If the left or the right revolts there is a probabilistic outcome of a leftor right dictatorship.

Under a right dictatorship taxes and redistrubutions are zero, under aleft dictatorship rediredistribution equalizes wealth immediately (withzero taxes afterwards. An interesting tangential issue here: willinequality nevertheless re-emerge in some form? Remember Pareto.)

All else equal, everyone prefers democracy. There is a fixed cost underdictatorship (which can differ for the right and left, depending who isin power.).

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 17 / 43

Page 52: Democracy and Income Distribution

RESULTS

We ask what redistributions of income and assets are feasible in ademocracy, given the initial assets and their distribution.

The question is motivated by the possibility that if redistribution isinsuffi cient for the poor or excessive for the rich, they may turnagainst democracy.

In turn, if no redistribution simultaneously satisfies the poor and thewealthy, democracy cannot be sustained.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 18 / 43

Page 53: Democracy and Income Distribution

RESULTS

We ask what redistributions of income and assets are feasible in ademocracy, given the initial assets and their distribution.

The question is motivated by the possibility that if redistribution isinsuffi cient for the poor or excessive for the rich, they may turnagainst democracy.

In turn, if no redistribution simultaneously satisfies the poor and thewealthy, democracy cannot be sustained.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 18 / 43

Page 54: Democracy and Income Distribution

RESULTS

We ask what redistributions of income and assets are feasible in ademocracy, given the initial assets and their distribution.

The question is motivated by the possibility that if redistribution isinsuffi cient for the poor or excessive for the rich, they may turnagainst democracy.

In turn, if no redistribution simultaneously satisfies the poor and thewealthy, democracy cannot be sustained.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 18 / 43

Page 55: Democracy and Income Distribution

RESULTS CONT’D

Hence, the corollary question concerns the conditions under whichdemocracy is sustainable. We find that democracies survive inwealthy societies.

Conditional on the initial income distribution, each country has athreshold of capital stock above which democracy survives.

This threshold is lower when the distribution of initial endowments ismore equal and when the revolutionary prowess of right or left groupsin the tails are lower.

Yet in poor unequal countries there exist no redistribution schemewhich would be accepted both by the poor and the wealthy.Hence,democracy cannot survive.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 19 / 43

Page 56: Democracy and Income Distribution

RESULTS CONT’D

Hence, the corollary question concerns the conditions under whichdemocracy is sustainable. We find that democracies survive inwealthy societies.

Conditional on the initial income distribution, each country has athreshold of capital stock above which democracy survives.

This threshold is lower when the distribution of initial endowments ismore equal and when the revolutionary prowess of right or left groupsin the tails are lower.

Yet in poor unequal countries there exist no redistribution schemewhich would be accepted both by the poor and the wealthy.Hence,democracy cannot survive.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 19 / 43

Page 57: Democracy and Income Distribution

RESULTS CONT’D

Hence, the corollary question concerns the conditions under whichdemocracy is sustainable. We find that democracies survive inwealthy societies.

Conditional on the initial income distribution, each country has athreshold of capital stock above which democracy survives.

This threshold is lower when the distribution of initial endowments ismore equal and when the revolutionary prowess of right or left groupsin the tails are lower.

Yet in poor unequal countries there exist no redistribution schemewhich would be accepted both by the poor and the wealthy.Hence,democracy cannot survive.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 19 / 43

Page 58: Democracy and Income Distribution

RESULTS CONT’D

Hence, the corollary question concerns the conditions under whichdemocracy is sustainable. We find that democracies survive inwealthy societies.

Conditional on the initial income distribution, each country has athreshold of capital stock above which democracy survives.

This threshold is lower when the distribution of initial endowments ismore equal and when the revolutionary prowess of right or left groupsin the tails are lower.

Yet in poor unequal countries there exist no redistribution schemewhich would be accepted both by the poor and the wealthy.Hence,democracy cannot survive.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 19 / 43

Page 59: Democracy and Income Distribution

RESULTS CONT’D

As endowments increase, redistribution schemes that satisfy both thepoor and the wealthy emerge.

Moreover, as capital stock grows the wealthy tolerate more and thepoor less redistribution, so that the set of feasible redistributionsbecomes larger.

Since the median voter prefers one such scheme to the dictatorship ofeither group, democracy survives.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 20 / 43

Page 60: Democracy and Income Distribution

RESULTS CONT’D

As endowments increase, redistribution schemes that satisfy both thepoor and the wealthy emerge.

Moreover, as capital stock grows the wealthy tolerate more and thepoor less redistribution, so that the set of feasible redistributionsbecomes larger.

Since the median voter prefers one such scheme to the dictatorship ofeither group, democracy survives.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 20 / 43

Page 61: Democracy and Income Distribution

RESULTS CONT’D

As endowments increase, redistribution schemes that satisfy both thepoor and the wealthy emerge.

Moreover, as capital stock grows the wealthy tolerate more and thepoor less redistribution, so that the set of feasible redistributionsbecomes larger.

Since the median voter prefers one such scheme to the dictatorship ofeither group, democracy survives.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 20 / 43

Page 62: Democracy and Income Distribution

EMPIRICS (based on Przeworski et al, 2000)

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 21 / 43

Page 63: Democracy and Income Distribution

Modernization Theory

"The general income level of a nation also affects its receptivity todemocratic norms. If there is enough wealth in the country so that it doesmake too much difference whether some redistribution takes place, it iseasier to accept the idea that it does not matter greatly which side is inpower. But if loss of offi ce means serious losses for major groups, they willseek to retain offi ce by any means available."

Lipset, S.M.: Political man: the social bases of politics. Garden City:Doubleday 1960.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 22 / 43

Page 64: Democracy and Income Distribution

What is democracy?

Robert A Dahl (1971): Electoral Competition and Participation

Przeworski et al (2000):

Countries are democratic if the following all hold:1 The chief executive is elected2 The legislature is elected3 There is more than one party competing in the elections4 An alternation in power under identical electoral rules has taken place

Otherwise, countries are coded as dictatorships. This is a binary measure.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 23 / 43

Page 65: Democracy and Income Distribution

Polity IV

The Polity measure of democracy is the difference of two scores.

1 Democracy score2 Autocracy score

The Polity IV measure is based on attributes:

1 competitiveness of executive recruitment2 openness of executive recruitment3 constraints that exist on the executive4 regulation of political participation5 competitiveness of political participation

This is a continuous measure from aggegating the above, ranging from -10to 10.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 24 / 43

Page 66: Democracy and Income Distribution

Freedom House

Freedom House’s annual measure has two dimensions that produce acontinuous measure:

1 Political rights dimension2 Civil rights dimension

Raters score 10 questions, from 0 to 4, summed to produce a score from 0to 40. The 0-40 score is converted into a 1 to 7 scale.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 25 / 43

Page 67: Democracy and Income Distribution

Freedom House Cont’d

Example questions used to develop the political rights dimension:

1 Is the head of state elected in free and fair elections?2 Is there pervasive corruption?3 Is the government open, accountable, and transparent between elections?4 Is there a competitive opposition?

Example questions used to develop the civil rights dimension:

1 Are the media free and independent?2 Is there an independent judiciary?3 Is there equal treatment under the law?4 Is there equality of opportunity?5 Do citizens have the right to own property?

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 26 / 43

Page 68: Democracy and Income Distribution

Vanhannen

Scores are generated from multiplying two attributes and dividing by 100:

Competition: 1−% of votes to the largest partyParticipation: % of total population voting

Note: The democracy indices are highly correlated.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 27 / 43

Page 69: Democracy and Income Distribution

Institutions and Critical Junctures in History

"We favor another explanation for this pattern. Even in the absence of asimple causal link from income to democracy, political and economicdevelopment paths are interlinked and are jointly affected by variousfactors. Societies may embark on divergent political-economicdevelopment paths, some leading to relative prosperity and democracy,others to relative poverty and dictatorship. Our hypothesis is that thepositive cross-sectional relationship and the 500-year correlationbetween changes in income and democracy are caused by the factthat countries have embarked on divergent development paths atsome critical junctures during the past 500 years."

Acemoglu, Johnson, Robinson, Yared, "Income and Democracy" (AER,2008)

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 28 / 43

Page 70: Democracy and Income Distribution

Using Settler Mortality as Instrument for Institutions

"We provide support for this hypothesis by documenting that the positiveassociation between changes in income and democracy over the past 500years is largely accounted for by a range of historical variables. For thewhole world sample, the positive association is considerably weakenedwhen we control for date of independence, early constraints on theexecutive, and religion. We then turn to the sample of former Europeancolonies, where we have better proxies for factors that have influenced thedevelopment paths of nations. AJR(2001, 2002) and Engerman andSokoloff (1997) argue that differences in European colonizationstrategies have been a major determinant of the divergentdevelopment paths of colonial societies. This suggests that thecritical juncture for most societies corresponds to their experienceunder European colonization."

Acemoglu, Johnson, Robinson, Yared, "Income and Democracy" (AER,2008)

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 29 / 43

Page 71: Democracy and Income Distribution

"Furthermore, AJR(2002) show that the density of indigenous populationsat the time of colonization has been a particularly important variable inshaping colonization strategies, and provide estimates of populationdensities in the year 1500 (before colonization). When we useinformation on population density, as well as on independence yearand early constraints on the executive, the 500-year relationshipbetween changes in income and democracy in the former coloniessample disappears. This is consistent with the hypothesis that thepositive cross-sectional relationship between income and democracy todayis the result of societies embarking on divergent development paths atcertain critical junctures during the past 500 years"

AJRY (2008)

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 30 / 43

Page 72: Democracy and Income Distribution

Using Fixed Effects for Divergent Paths at Colonization

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 31 / 43

Page 73: Democracy and Income Distribution

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 32 / 43

Page 74: Democracy and Income Distribution

Do Institutions Persist?

"Following AJR, statistical studies of the impact of institutions adopt thefollowing procedure:1) Regress current incomes for a recent date (or an average of recentdates) on recent institutions and some control variables;2) Instrument recent institutions by instrumenting institutions at sometime immemorial.Yet this assumption is patently false. Here is a crosstab of institutionalquality as measured by the variable used by AJR (“constraints on the chiefexecutive”), of exit-year institutions (when countries ceased to exist orinformation is last available) by entry-year institutions (the year ofindependence or soon after) for all countries that appear in the PolityIVdata set (including those that were never colonies)."

A. Przeworski, "The Last Instance: Are Institutions the Primary CauseofEconomic Development?", Arch.europ.sociol.,(2004).

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 33 / 43

Page 75: Democracy and Income Distribution

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 34 / 43

Page 76: Democracy and Income Distribution

Another Hypothesis on Settlers

"The correlation between AJR’s proposed instruments and their preferredmeasures of institutions is very high indeed. For example, the logarithm ofsettler mortality is correlated at -.54 with average executive constraints,and -.51 with average expropriation risk, while the logarithm of populationdensity in 1500s is correlated at -.35 and -.40 with the same measures ofinstitutions.

Edward L. Glaeser, Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, andAndrei Shleifer, "Do Institutions Cause Growth?" Journal of EconomicGrowth, 2004"

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 35 / 43

Page 77: Democracy and Income Distribution

Settlers and Human Capital, Income and Growth

"...Still, both settler mortality and 1500 population density are stronglycorrelated with today’s per capita income. Why might this be so?... Wehave seen that human capital is an important determinant of economicgrowth. The importance of malaria in determining current income pointsin the same direction. Could the influence of AJR’s proposed instrumentson today’s development work through human capital? Put differently,perhaps when colonizers settled, they brought with them their know-howrather than constraints on the executive."

Glaeser et al, JOEG, 2004.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 36 / 43

Page 78: Democracy and Income Distribution

Settlers, Human Capital, Growth, Income and Democracy

"Our evidence suggests in contrast that the Lipset-Przeworski-Barro viewof the world is more accurate: countries that emerge from povertyaccumulate human and physical capital under dictatorships, and then,once they become richer, are increasingly likely to improve theirinstitutions." Glaeser et al, JOEG, 2004.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 37 / 43

Page 79: Democracy and Income Distribution

Benhabib, Corvalan, Spiegel, 2011 on Fixed EffectRegressions

Our analysis confronts two primary issues:

First, more and better-measured data on both income and democracyhas become available since the publication of AJRY (2008). Thisdevelopment is crucial because the inclusion of country fixed effectsreduces inference to that based on within-country variation in thedata. However, as we show below, the initial Penn World Tables 6.1(PWT 6.1) sample has data for shorter time spans than thoseavailable in either the newer Penn World Tables 6.3 data set [Heston,et al, (2009)] (PWT 6.3), or the alternative Maddison (2003) dataset.There is reason to believe that these new panels will be moreinformative, as the (within country) coeffi cients of variation in all ofthe democracy measures considered increases when one goes from theoriginal PWT 6.1 data set to either the PWT 6.3 or Maddisonalternatives.Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 38 / 43

Page 80: Democracy and Income Distribution

Second, the measures of democracy used in AJRY are discrete(Przeworski et al), or censored (Freedom House, Polity (two-sided),Vanhanen (one-sided)) violating the maintained assumptions underOLS. We respond to this issue by using either a two-sided Tobitspecification or the double-censoring specification of Alan, Honoré,and Leth-Petersen (2008) and we use conditional and unconditionalLogit specifications to obtain estimates for the binary Przeworskimeasure. Additionally, for the four measures of democracy —FreedomHouse, Polity, Index of Democratization and DD —we also use theWooldridge (2005) estimator (WE). This estimator generalizes theChamberlain (1980) estimator used by AJRY (2009) andparameterizes the fixed effects as well as the initial conditions in adynamic panel.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 39 / 43

Page 81: Democracy and Income Distribution

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 40 / 43

Page 82: Democracy and Income Distribution

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 41 / 43

Page 83: Democracy and Income Distribution

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 42 / 43

Page 84: Democracy and Income Distribution

Conclusion

Why is Democracy more sustainable at high levels of income but notat low levels?

1 Current wealth and current democracy are both the result of earlyand persistent institutions that secure property and constrain theexecutive.

2 Democracies survive in wealthy societies. The general income level ofa nation affects its receptivity to democratic norms: "Higher incomesreduce the intensity of conflict over the distribution of income, andthereby give way to democratic institutions that discourageexpropriation and support redistributive fiscal policies under the ruleof law." (Benhabib, Corvalan, Spiegel, 2011).

We think the second explanation is more likely.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 43 / 43

Page 85: Democracy and Income Distribution

Conclusion

Why is Democracy more sustainable at high levels of income but notat low levels?

1 Current wealth and current democracy are both the result of earlyand persistent institutions that secure property and constrain theexecutive.

2 Democracies survive in wealthy societies. The general income level ofa nation affects its receptivity to democratic norms: "Higher incomesreduce the intensity of conflict over the distribution of income, andthereby give way to democratic institutions that discourageexpropriation and support redistributive fiscal policies under the ruleof law." (Benhabib, Corvalan, Spiegel, 2011).

We think the second explanation is more likely.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 43 / 43

Page 86: Democracy and Income Distribution

Conclusion

Why is Democracy more sustainable at high levels of income but notat low levels?

1 Current wealth and current democracy are both the result of earlyand persistent institutions that secure property and constrain theexecutive.

2 Democracies survive in wealthy societies. The general income level ofa nation affects its receptivity to democratic norms: "Higher incomesreduce the intensity of conflict over the distribution of income, andthereby give way to democratic institutions that discourageexpropriation and support redistributive fiscal policies under the ruleof law." (Benhabib, Corvalan, Spiegel, 2011).

We think the second explanation is more likely.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 43 / 43

Page 87: Democracy and Income Distribution

Conclusion

Why is Democracy more sustainable at high levels of income but notat low levels?

1 Current wealth and current democracy are both the result of earlyand persistent institutions that secure property and constrain theexecutive.

2 Democracies survive in wealthy societies. The general income level ofa nation affects its receptivity to democratic norms: "Higher incomesreduce the intensity of conflict over the distribution of income, andthereby give way to democratic institutions that discourageexpropriation and support redistributive fiscal policies under the ruleof law." (Benhabib, Corvalan, Spiegel, 2011).

We think the second explanation is more likely.

Jess Benhabib (NYU) Democracy and Income (Distribution) August 2011 43 / 43