36
Working Paper Series 2016/59/STR/IIPI (Revised version of 2015/66/EPS/IIPI) A Working Paper is the author’s intellectual property. It is intended as a means to promote research to interested readers. Its content should not be copied or hosted on any server without written permission from [email protected] Find more INSEAD papers at http://www.insead.edu/facultyresearch/research/search_papers.cfm Mapping the Business Systems of 61 Major Economies: A Taxonomy and Implications for Varieties of Capitalism and Business Systems Research Michael A. Witt INSEAD, [email protected] (Corresponding author) Luiz Ricardo Kabbach de Castro EESC - Universidade de São Paulo, [email protected] Kenneth Amaeshi University of Edinburgh Business School, [email protected] Sami Mahroum INSEAD, [email protected] Dorothee Bohle Central European University, [email protected] Lawrence Saez School of Oriental and African Studies (SOAS), [email protected] Efforts to build a universal theory of the world’s business systems require empirical grounding in an understanding of the variety that need explaining. To support such theorizing, we analyzed the institutional structures of 61 major economies, accounting for 93.5 percent of 2013 world GDP (PPP). We found nine main types of business systems: Collaborative, Coordinated Market, Liberal Market, European Peripheral, Advanced Emerging, Advanced City, Arab Oil-Based, Emerging, and Socialist Economies. Our findings suggest empirical support for the CME vs. LME dichotomy for part of the OECD; identify some of the business systems proposed recently as sub-types of larger clusters; indicate that institutional diversity seems to increase with development level; and cast doubt on the notions of state-led and family-led capitalism as types of business systems. Keywords: Varieties of Capitalism; Africa; Asia; Central and Eastern Europe; Middle East; South America JEL Classification: P1, P2, P50 Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2660126

Working Paper Series · Working Paper Series 2016/59/STR/IIPI (Revised version of 2015/66/EPS/IIPI) A Working Paper is the author’s intellectual property. It is intended as a means

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    0

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Working Paper Series · Working Paper Series 2016/59/STR/IIPI (Revised version of 2015/66/EPS/IIPI) A Working Paper is the author’s intellectual property. It is intended as a means

Working Paper Series 2016/59/STR/IIPI

(Revised version of 2015/66/EPS/IIPI)

A Working Paper is the author’s intellectual property. It is intended as a means to promote research to interested readers. Its content should not be copied or hosted on any server without written permission from [email protected] Find more INSEAD papers at http://www.insead.edu/facultyresearch/research/search_papers.cfm

Mapping the Business Systems of 61 Major Economies:

A Taxonomy and Implications for Varieties of Capitalism and Business Systems Research

Michael A. Witt

INSEAD, [email protected] (Corresponding author)

Luiz Ricardo Kabbach de Castro

EESC - Universidade de São Paulo, [email protected]

Kenneth Amaeshi University of Edinburgh Business School, [email protected]

Sami Mahroum

INSEAD, [email protected]

Dorothee Bohle Central European University, [email protected]

Lawrence Saez

School of Oriental and African Studies (SOAS), [email protected] Efforts to build a universal theory of the world’s business systems require empirical grounding in an understanding of the variety that need explaining. To support such theorizing, we analyzed the institutional structures of 61 major economies, accounting for 93.5 percent of 2013 world GDP (PPP). We found nine main types of business systems: Collaborative, Coordinated Market, Liberal Market, European Peripheral, Advanced Emerging, Advanced City, Arab Oil-Based, Emerging, and Socialist Economies. Our findings suggest empirical support for the CME vs. LME dichotomy for part of the OECD; identify some of the business systems proposed recently as sub-types of larger clusters; indicate that institutional diversity seems to increase with development level; and cast doubt on the notions of state-led and family-led capitalism as types of business systems. Keywords: Varieties of Capitalism; Africa; Asia; Central and Eastern Europe; Middle East; South America JEL Classification: P1, P2, P50

Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2660126

Page 2: Working Paper Series · Working Paper Series 2016/59/STR/IIPI (Revised version of 2015/66/EPS/IIPI) A Working Paper is the author’s intellectual property. It is intended as a means

1. Introduction

What are the world’s main types of business systems,1 and what are their characteristics? The

answer to this question is of great relevance not only to multinational enterprises grappling with

varying rules of the game in different countries. It is also a prerequisite for the building of a

general theory of varieties of business systems in the world, which in turn would enable

theorizing about the implications of these varieties for economic and political outcomes such as

wealth generation and distribution or comparative advantages. Such theory can only emerge

when it is clear what it needs to explain (Starbuck, 1993; Weick, 1995; Swedberg, 2014) – that is,

when the gamut of business systems in the world economy is known.

Recent years have seen the literature move towards a more encompassing understanding

of business systems. Whitley’s (1999) seminal work on business systems focused essentially on

the OECD and Northeast Asia, while Hall and Soskice’s Varieties of Capitalism (2001) as well

as Amable’s work (2003) limited their scope to the OECD. Subsequent works have since added

insights on business systems in different regions of the world, including Africa (e.g., Wood and

Frynas, 2006; Amaeshi and Amao, 2009), Asia (e.g., Kim, 2010; Boyer et al., 2012; Kalinowski,

2013; Witt and Redding, 2013; Zhang and Whitley, 2013), Eastern Europe (e.g., Nölke and

Vliegenthart, 2009; Bohle and Greskovits, 2012), and South America (e.g., Schneider, 2009;

Schneider, 2013; Musacchio and Lazzarini, 2014). A growing number of pieces have also

explored categories that span regions, such as those of state capitalism (e.g., Bremmer, 2009;

Nölke, 2010) or of emerging markets (e.g., Fainshmidt et al., forthcoming). The overall result of

these efforts has been a much-improved empirical understanding of the institutional structures of

previously understudied geographies. However, a consolidated overview of the overall

landscape of the business systems in the world economy, and thus a firmer foundation for

theorizing about them, is still absent from the literature.

The objective of this paper is to take a step towards evolving such a firmer foundation.

We propose a first step towards a geographically encompassing taxonomy of the world’s major

business systems and their characteristics. Based on a synthesis of prior research and the in-

depth knowledge of regional experts, we undertake an analysis of the business systems of 61

major economies in the world. Our sample spans all continents save Antarctica, and it accounts

1 We use the terms “business systems” and “varieties of capitalism” interchangeably (for a justification, see Witt &

Redding, 2013).

Page 3: Working Paper Series · Working Paper Series 2016/59/STR/IIPI (Revised version of 2015/66/EPS/IIPI) A Working Paper is the author’s intellectual property. It is intended as a means

2

for 93.5 percent of 2013 world GDP, measured at purchasing power parity (PPP) (World Bank,

2015). While our coverage does not reach 100 percent – an unlikely feat for any paper in the

foreseeable future – it seems to us that just as a jigsaw puzzle that is 93.5 percent complete, our

results should provide a reasonable approximation of the overall picture.

Our analysis identified nine main types of business systems. Three of these include

economies from at least two continents, which suggests the presence of underlying drivers other

than geography. Our findings have a number of potentially important implications for the field.

Among others, they underline the validity of the CME vs. LME dichotomy for parts of the

OECD, but not the rest of the world; identify some of the labels proposed in recent years as valid

but sub-types of larger clusters; find high institutional similarity among most emerging markets

as well as advanced emerging markets on the one hand and institutional diversity of advanced

industrialized countries on the other; and call into doubt the notions of state-led and family-led

capitalism as business systems.

In the sections that follow, we first lay the groundwork by identifying our general

epistemological approach in the context of the existing literature. We then explain the

dimensions of comparison we employed in this paper, our data, and our methods before

presenting our results and discussing the characteristics of the clusters we identified. We then

spell our possible implications of our findings for taxonomizing the world’s business systems

before closing with a discussion of limitations and attendant potential for future research.

2. Motivation and Epistemology

We assume that it is desirable to develop a general theory of the world’s business systems, where

“theory” is defined as a “systematic [set] of interrelated statements intended to explain some

aspect of social life” (Babble, 2012: 44). Fully developed, such a theory would probably spell

out mechanisms to account for the origins of the business systems we observe; their likely

trajectories over time, also in response to external shocks; and their impact on economic,

political, and social factors such as economic growth, quality of life, inequality, and sectoral

strengths and weaknesses. To the extent multiple mechanisms are at work, such theory would

ideally also lay out the contingencies under which individual mechanisms are (de)activated.

The field has already evolved important theoretical insights about all aspects of our ideal-

typical theory. For instance, a number of works have put the evolution of varieties of capitalism

Page 4: Working Paper Series · Working Paper Series 2016/59/STR/IIPI (Revised version of 2015/66/EPS/IIPI) A Working Paper is the author’s intellectual property. It is intended as a means

3

in historical perspective and identified drivers leading to the present diversity among advanced

industrialized economies (Streeck and Yamamura, 2001; Thelen, 2004; Hancké et al., 2007;

Cusack et al., 2010). In terms of evolution over time, research has explored the question of

convergence (Djelic, 1998; Whitley, 1999; Deakin et al., forthcoming), but also an apparent

trend towards liberalization (Thelen, 2014; Van der Zwan, 2014) and institutional adaptability

more generally (Streeck and Thelen, 2005; Vogel, 2006; Witt, 2006; Hall and Thelen, 2009;

Jackson and Deeg, 2012). And with regard to outcomes, the literature has examined the linkages

between varieties of capitalism and results such as comparative advantages (Hall and Soskice,

2001; Whitley, 2008; Schneider and Paunescu, 2012; Witt and Jackson, forthcoming), innovative

capabilities (Boyer, 2004; Akkermans et al., 2009; Allen, 2013; Keller and Block, 2013;

Boschma and Capone, 2015), CSR (Matten and Moon, 2008; Gjølberg, 2009; Jackson and

Apostolakou, 2010; Brammer et al., 2012; Kang and Moon, 2012) and inequality (Rueda and

Pontusson, 2000; Schneider and Makszin, 2014; Thelen, 2014).

This list is far from exhaustive, and a comprehensive review of these efforts is beyond the

possibilities even of dedicated review papers (Wood et al., 2014), leave alone research papers

such as this one. At the same time, the list does serve to illustrate two larger points. One is that

the field has not succeeded in building a general, unified theory accounting for different aspects

of business systems, such as origins, future trajectories, and effects. At the same time, much

older disciplines, such as physics and economics, have likewise not succeeded in building

unified theories. The second is that most of the leading theoretical works in our field have been

built around the specific context of the West plus Japan. There is no doubt that these economies

and a better understanding of how they work are important. However, this partial approach it is

a problem from the perspective of building the overall theory we outlined earlier in that, in all

probability, much of these theories is geographically contingent.

A key challenge in this context has been that we know much too little about the

institutional characteristics of the rest of the world. A comprehensive theory of the kind we

introduced earlier cannot emerge unless it is clear what empirical realities it needs to explain

(Starbuck, 1993; Weick, 1995; Swedberg, 2014). As Swedberg (2014: 10) summarized, “you

cannot theorize without having something to theorize about; and this something you have to

acquire through observation.” Starbuck (1993) and Weick (1995) make the same point,

underscoring the importance of understanding the phenomenon at hand, as expressed in data, as a

Page 5: Working Paper Series · Working Paper Series 2016/59/STR/IIPI (Revised version of 2015/66/EPS/IIPI) A Working Paper is the author’s intellectual property. It is intended as a means

4

step towards devising theory. It is then the immersion in these data that allow theories to emerge

(Swedberg, 2014), through processes such as abduction (Peirce, 1957). Building out the theory

itself is likely to be a protracted process (Sutton and Staw, 1995; Weick, 1995; Swedberg, 2014)

that is beyond the scope of this paper.

The first precondition for theorizing about the world’s business systems is thus the

availability of an empirical understanding of what needs explaining. As mentioned in the

introduction, a growing number of works has begun to evolve the requisite information, albeit

usually in a piecemeal fashion. Efforts have also been underway to categorize the empirical

insights thus gained into typologies. While a necessary step in making sense of the data, this has

created challenges in its own. In particular, different labels are in use for different categories of

various overlap. This problem has been with us since the early days, with LMEs (Dore, 2000;

Hall and Soskice, 2001), fragmented business systems (Whitley, 1999) and market based

capitalism (Amable, 2003) arguably referring to the same set of economies. In addition, since

most of the empirical work continues to be geographically organized, it is not necessarily clear

whether a given type is regionally confined or part of a larger, globally present pattern. For

instance, are there economies in both Europe and Asia that belong to the same, “state-led”

variety of capitalism? Proponents of state capitalism would say yes, others (e.g., Witt and

Redding, 2013) suggest the answer is no.

As a result, the overall lay of the land of the world’s business systems – which economies

have similar structures, and how many types actually exist? – remains unclear. The objective of

this paper is to help remedy this situation by taking the next step in understanding the data:

presenting a typology of the world’s major business systems.

3. The world’s business systems: a comparison

We generalize the approach taken by Witt and Redding (2013) in their exploration of Asian

business systems to gain a comprehensive overview of the types of business systems present in

the world’s major economies.

Data

Page 6: Working Paper Series · Working Paper Series 2016/59/STR/IIPI (Revised version of 2015/66/EPS/IIPI) A Working Paper is the author’s intellectual property. It is intended as a means

5

Ideally, this study would have included all of the 184 economies presently covered by the World

Bank. In reality, very little is known about the institutional structures of most them, which

limited the range of economies for which we could hope to obtain the requisite in-depth expert

judgment (see below). In selecting our sample, we thus strove to strike a balance between

feasibility in terms of data availability and relevance in terms of coverage of global economic

activity.

We initially selected the 60 largest economies of the world, as measured by GDP at

purchasing power parity (PPP) in 2013, the latest year available at the point of selection (World

Bank, 2015). Each of these economies had a total 2013 PPP GDP of at least US$200 billion, and

collectively, they accounted for 94.7 percent of world GDP. We added to this sample three

smaller economies with a GDP somewhat below US$200 billion, on the grounds that prior

treatment in the literature made their inclusion feasible and relevant: Ireland, New Zealand, and

Slovakia. During data collection, it further became clear that there was insufficient knowledge

about Iran and Iraq, which we had to drop as a result. Our final sample thus encompassed 61

economies, accounting for 93.5 percent of world GDP (Table 1).

*** Table 1 about here ***

For each of these economies, we collected a wide range of institutional data (Table 2).

Our measures and the eight institutional dimensions they represent essentially replicated those

used by Witt and Redding (2013), which combined the key institutional categories identified in

Hall and Soskice (2001), Whitley (1999), Amable (2003), Redding (2005), Hancké, Rhodes, and

Thatcher (2007), and Morgan, Campbell, Crouch, Pedersen, and Whitley (2010). We did,

however, make some minor modifications. Some of these were the result of fine-tuning. For

instance, consultations with experts on business groups, a form of interfirm relations, revealed

that these structures are essentially ubiquitous, with the United States as the key exception. We

thus eliminated this measure and instead followed Schneider et al. (2012) by adding statistics for

mergers and acquisitions as an indicator of interfirm relations.

*** Table 2 about here ***

In other cases, data availability led to changes. For example, union density information

for our full sample was not available. At the same time, the International Trade Union Congress

(2014) has since published a new, comprehensive comparison of trade union rights, which

arguably provides a more meaningful picture of the institutional structure of employment

Page 7: Working Paper Series · Working Paper Series 2016/59/STR/IIPI (Revised version of 2015/66/EPS/IIPI) A Working Paper is the author’s intellectual property. It is intended as a means

6

relations than the size of unions alone. Similarly, the United Nations has stopped publishing the

Education Attainment Index, replacing it with the average years of schooling received by adults

and the average years of schooling children can expect to receive. We consequently constructed

a new index by factor-analyzing the two variables.

We further found that some of the economies explored in this paper rely heavily on

foreign capital (e.g., Bohle and Greskovits, 2012). We thus added the stock of inward foreign

direct investment (IFDI) normalized by GDP as a measure in the financial sphere.

As Witt and Redding (2013) discussed, obtaining comparative statistics for institutional

analysis is essentially impossible for many variables of interest. We thus followed their

approach and used statistics where possible and expert qualitative judgment where necessary.

Qualitative judgment for this paper was partially derived from the literature, partially provided

by the authors.2 Specifically, judgments for Anglo-Saxon and Western European economies as

well as for those Asian economies covered by Witt and Redding (2013) were based on the extant

business systems literature. For all other economies, the authors drew on their personal expertise

researching and working in these economies. This process was equivalent to that used by Witt

and Redding (2013), with the key difference that we coded our judgments directly while Witt

and Redding (2013) extracted theirs from country chapters, written by third authors, in the

Oxford Handbook of Asian Business Systems (Witt and Redding, 2014). To reduce the risk of

false assessments, we further consulted with other scholars with relevant regional expertise.

Cluster analysis

To identify the different types of Asian business systems present in our sample, we performed

hierarchical cluster analysis, which has been proposed as an appropriate method to investigate

complex and interrelated dimensions of nations not only as a methodology device, but also as a

foundational tool for sense-making and conceptualization of the object under investigation

(Georgas and Berry, 1995; Ronen and Shenkar, 2013).

We recoded qualitative data in form of dummy variables. For instance, we expressed

differences in employment tenure in three dummy variables, one for short-term, one for medium-

2 The authors of this paper are experts on business systems in different parts of the world. To preserve anonymity in

peer review, we cannot reveal our names to establish our credibility. However, we are known to the editor, who is

in a position to take this information into account in his decision.

Page 8: Working Paper Series · Working Paper Series 2016/59/STR/IIPI (Revised version of 2015/66/EPS/IIPI) A Working Paper is the author’s intellectual property. It is intended as a means

7

term, and one for long-term employment. We normalized all measures to eliminate distortions

from differences in numerical magnitude across variables.

We employed hierarchical cluster analysis as implemented in Stata 13.1 (StataCorp,

2013b) using the Gower dissimilarity measure, which is suitable for mixed continuous and

categorical variables as present in our data (StataCorp, 2013a). We chose average linkage (more

specifically, unweighted pair-group method using averages (UPGMA) linkage), which avoids the

tendencies of single linkage and complete linkage to produce extreme results (Greenacre and

Primicerio, 2013).

Given growing interest in viewing varieties of business systems as different sets of

institutional configurations (Jackson, 2005; Kogut and Ragin, 2006; Schneider and Paunescu,

2012), we considered the use of fuzzy-set qualitative comparative analysis (fsQCA) as an

alternative approach. We found the method to be unsuitable because the number of institutional

measures in our dataset is too large for fsQCA to handle. At 48 variables, fsQCA would produce

a truth table of 248

= 281,474,976,710,656 possible configurations. Factor analysis of our

variables identified 11 factors with eigenvalue larger than 1, which would yield 2,048 possible

configurations – still too many. Reducing the number of factors to a manageable number of

about 5, resulting in 32 combinations, would imply the elimination of 6 meaningful factors and

thus a large loss of possibly differentiating information. We consequently decided against the

use of fsQCA.

Figure 1 shows the dendrogram produced by the cluster analysis, and Table 3 presents the

attendant pairwise dissimilarity measures, or “institutional distances” (cf. Jackson and Deeg,

2008).

*** Figure 1 about here ***

*** Table 3 about here ***

To establish how many clusters are actually present in these results, we drew on the

methodological literature on stopping rules, that is, algorithms designed to identify the optimum

number of clusters without the influence of subjective author judgment. Among the many

stopping rules in existence, the methodological literature has identified two as most reliable: the

Calinski-Harabasz pseudo-F index and the Duda-Hart Je(2)/Je(1) index (Milligan and Cooper,

1985; Everitt et al., 2011; StataCorp, 2013a). The literature further suggests that the Calinski-

Page 9: Working Paper Series · Working Paper Series 2016/59/STR/IIPI (Revised version of 2015/66/EPS/IIPI) A Working Paper is the author’s intellectual property. It is intended as a means

8

Harabasz stopping rule works better for smaller numbers of clusters in the data, while the Duda-

Hart rule performs better if 4 or more clusters are present (Milligan and Cooper, 1985).

Application of the Calinski-Harabasz stopping rule (StataCorp, 2013a) to our results

suggested the presence of only 4 clusters in the data: (1) 27 emerging markets, shown in the

dendrogram as the branch ranking from ID to CU (read from left to right); (2) a branch mixing

18 advanced emerging markets, Eastern European economies, and Southern European economies,

shown in the dendrogram as ranging from HK to GE; (3) a branch with 6 Anglo-Saxon

economies (GB to IE); and (4) a branch with 10 Northern European economies plus Japan (NO

to JP).

Prior research suggests that this result – 61 economies sorting into only 4 clusters – is

likely to be an underestimate. For instance, Whitley (1999) already identified 6 different types

of business systems present in the advanced industrialized countries plus Northeast Asia. Witt

and Redding (2013) found 7 types of business systems using the advanced industrialized

countries as well as the major Asian economies ranging from India eastwards to Japan. And

exploring a range of emerging economies, Fainshmidt et al. (forthcoming) identified seven types

of clusters. The Calinski-Harabasz rule has a tendency to underestimate the actual number of

clusters in the data once the number clusters becomes large (Milligan and Cooper, 1985), and in

light of the prior evidence, we suspect such underestimation was the case here.

By contrast, the Duda-Hart stopping rule (StataCorp, 2013a) suggested an optimum

number of 9 or 10 clusters. While 9 clusters minimized the Je(2)/Je(1) ratio, the pseudo T-

squared value was minimized for 10 clusters. Either choice was thus methodologically

defensible, and given prior evidence and advantages of the Duda-Hart stopping rule for 4 or

more clusters, likely to be more credible than that produced by the Calinski-Harabasz rule.

To aid us in choosing between 9 or 10 clusters, we conducted a robustness test using

weighted average linkage, which may have advantages for clusters with uneven numbers of

members (Everitt et al., 2011). The resultant dendrogram positions of the 61 economies were

consistent with those produced by average linkage. The Duda-Hart stopping rule suggested the

presence of 9 clusters for those results, suggesting that 9 may indeed be the optimum number.

However, in doing so, it eliminated Japan as a single-member cluster and instead established

Nigeria as a cluster in itself.

Page 10: Working Paper Series · Working Paper Series 2016/59/STR/IIPI (Revised version of 2015/66/EPS/IIPI) A Working Paper is the author’s intellectual property. It is intended as a means

9

On balance, we judged the clustering produced by average linkage to be more credible.

Both types of linkages produced an awkward single-member cluster. However, there is evidence

to support this positioning for Japan, which differs from its closets kin, Northern European

economies, in its reliance on micro-corporatist arrangements (Aoki, 1988; Estevez-Abe et al.,

2001; Inagami and Whittaker, 2005). To our knowledge, there is no prior evidence that would

support classifying Nigeria as a unique type of capitalism.

In sum, our analysis suggests the presence of 9 clusters among the 61 economies

explored, as shown in Table 4.

*** Table 4 about here ***

Discussion by cluster

Coordinated and Liberal Market Economies. The economies included in these two clusters are

identical with the groupings proposed by Hall and Soskice (2001), with the exception of Japan.

The replication of these two clusters in our analysis suggests that the original Varieties of

Capitalism (VoC) formulation did succeed in capturing a big divide among the advanced

industrialized economies.

At the same time, it is also clear from Figure 1 that critics of the VoC approach were

correct to point out the existence of important distinctions within these groupings (e.g., Amable,

2003; Campbell and Pedersen, 2007; Hancké et al., 2007). Within the CMEs, for instance, we

see two subgroupings: what one could term “classical CMEs” including Austria, Belgium,

Finland, Germany, the Netherlands, and Sweden; and CMEs with a twist, including Denmark

and Switzerland, which combine features of CMEs with those of LMEs (e.g., Danish “flexicurity”

in employment relations), as well as Norway. We likewise see some variance inside the LME

camp. Ireland stands out as relatively dissimilar, which is consistent with its relatively recent

heritage of corporatism (Ó'Riain, 2014).

The characteristics of these economies have been discussed at length in the literature, so

we will not reiterate them here.

Collaborative Economies. The Duda-Hart stopping rule singled out Japan as a cluster of

its own, though it is closely related to the CMEs. We named this cluster in accordance with

Whitley (1999), who had previously identified Japan as a business system separate from the

Page 11: Working Paper Series · Working Paper Series 2016/59/STR/IIPI (Revised version of 2015/66/EPS/IIPI) A Working Paper is the author’s intellectual property. It is intended as a means

10

CMEs. While one can question whether a cluster of one is meaningful as it seems to represent

an exception (albeit an important one) rather than a general pattern, we retained it because doing

otherwise would introduce the precise arbitrariness that stopping rules are intended to prevent.

There is likewise ample literature on the Japanese business system, so we will not enter a

discussion of it here.

European Peripheral Economies. This group comprises the Southern European

economies as well as the Central European economies west of the Ukraine. Inside this cluster,

we find two sub-clusters (Figure 1): the Southern European economies of France, Greece, Italy,

Portugal, and Spain; and the Central European economies of the Czech Republic, Hungary,

Poland, Romania, and Slovakia. This subdivision within this cluster is consistent with their

separate treatment in the literature (e.g., Schmidt, 2002; Amable, 2003; Nölke and Vliegenthart,

2009; Bohle and Greskovits, 2012).

At the same time, important institutional parallels seem to have evolved. These business

systems tend to have3 high levels of general education, long-term average employment tenures in

excess of 10 years, industrial unions with some admixtures of craft unions, bank-led financial

systems mixing market and relationship criteria for credit allocation, and top-down decision-

making inside firms with medium levels of delegation. They also tend to have an important role

for family and some state ownership of firms, about average levels of investor protection,

medium to high rule of the law, welfare state structures with developmental admixtures in the

Central European economies, top-down political governance, and above average levels of voice

and accountability as well as government effectiveness.

Advanced Emerging Economies. This is a geographically heterogeneous group of

emerging economies with relatively high levels of per capita GDP. Inside the cluster, Figure 1

suggests three subgroups: Chile and Turkey, Israel and South Africa, and Korea and Taiwan.

The pairing of Korea and Taiwan is consistent with prior findings of similarities (Witt and

Redding, 2013) on the back of similar paths of economic development drawing on

developmental state policies (e.g., Amsden, 1989; Wade, 1990). Israel and South Africa may

have evolved similarities in the context of international isolation and an active state role in

3 Please note that the list that follows, and similar lists below, indicate general tendencies. Individual economies

may deviate on some dimensions.

Page 12: Working Paper Series · Working Paper Series 2016/59/STR/IIPI (Revised version of 2015/66/EPS/IIPI) A Working Paper is the author’s intellectual property. It is intended as a means

11

response to security concerns. Chile and Turkey share long periods of military dominance and

attendant military involvement in the commercial sector.

Common themes in this cluster are decent levels of general education, medium-length

employment tenures, on-the-job and private vocational training, bank-led financial systems

mixing relationships and market criteria in allocating funds, and top-down decision-making

inside the firm. Other common themes include a strong role for family ownership and control

paired with investor protection that is somewhat above average, developmental state policies,

top-down state governance, and, except Turkey, above average institutionalized trust, voice and

accountability, and state effectiveness.

Advanced City Economies. This cluster comprises Hong Kong and Singapore, which are

the only two city-based economies of sufficient size to be included in our sample. Though the

details vary somewhat, both are trade-dependent hub economies with high levels of economic

freedom so as to attract foreign investors. On the back of these strategies, both have attained

very high levels of per capita GDP.

Institutionally, both feature good general education, short-term tenure, private skills

acquisition, predominantly industrial unions with limited rights, bank-led financial systems with

very high levels of inward foreign direct investment and allocation based on market criteria and

relationships. In addition, they show top-down decision-making inside firms with limited

delegation, promotions based on relationships with a performance element, a strong role of

family ownership (and, in Singapore, state ownership), high levels of investor protection,

regulatory states (with developmental elements in Singapore), top-down state decision-making,

and high levels of government effectiveness.

Arab Oil-Based Economies. This group brings together Kuwait, Qatar, Saudi Arabia, and

the United Arab Emirates. Common feature of these economies is the continued importance of

oil production and exports, attempts at diversification into other industries notwithstanding.

Institutional patterns are historically weak but improving education, usually short-term

tenures, the virtual absence of unions and very weak union rights, bank-led financial systems

with low stocks of foreign direct investment and market-based allocation of funds, top-down

decision-making in firms with limited delegation to employees and promotions based on

relationships and performance. Further, there are important roles for family and state ownership

in the economy, poor to average investor protection, above average rule of law, states combining

Page 13: Working Paper Series · Working Paper Series 2016/59/STR/IIPI (Revised version of 2015/66/EPS/IIPI) A Working Paper is the author’s intellectual property. It is intended as a means

12

predatory, developmental, and welfare elements, top-down state decision-making, poor voice and

accountability, and average (Kuwait, Saudi Arabia) to good government effectiveness.

Emerging Economies. This cluster is by far the largest cluster with a geographically very

heterogeneous range of economies. Common tendency is the presence of relatively low levels of

per capita GDP, with Russia as an outlier as a result of its revenues derived from resources such

as oil and gas. Inside this cluster, we see a number of sub-clusters, many of them based on

geographic proximity and documented in the literature. For instance, China and Vietnam cluster

together and are in turn relatively similar to India, as established in prior work (Witt and Redding,

2013, 2014). Bangladesh and Pakistan cluster together, which is plausible given that Bangladesh

used to be part of Pakistan, and are themselves similar to India, with which they formed British

India until 1947. Indonesia, the Philippines, and Thailand cluster together, which is again

consistent with prior work (Witt and Redding, 2013). Unsurprising close clustering is further

visible among Colombia, Mexico, and Peru.

But there are also a few surprises. Malaysia forms a sub-cluster with Egypt and Morocco,

Russia with Algeria, Brazil with Kazakhstan, and Argentina with Ukraine. In this context, it is

worth remembering that according to the Duda-Hart stopping rule, these branches do not

constitute valid individual clusters, which implies that the similarities within these sub-clusters

are not much greater than those across them. Given that our knowledge of the institutional

structures of emerging markets is much weaker than that for OECD countries, it is entirely

possible that some of these sub-clusters formed on the basis of measurement error.

The overall clustering, however, shows high levels of consistency across the economies

included in it. General themes include weak past and current education, short-term job tenures,

private skills acquisition, suppressed unions, bank-led finance allocated on the basis of

relationships and state guidance, top-down decision-making inside firms with low delegation and

promotion based on relationships, family and state ownership of firms with often poor investor

protection, low rule of law (except Malaysia), predatory state policies with developmental

admixtures in some cases, top-down state decision-making with generally low levels of voice

and accountability, and poor state effectiveness (again except Malaysia).

Socialist Economies. This last cluster consists of Cuba and Venezuela. Both represent

old-style socialist economies, with Venezuela arguably having regressed to this state under the

rule of Hugo Chavez and his successor. Structurally, these economies feature weak current but

Page 14: Working Paper Series · Working Paper Series 2016/59/STR/IIPI (Revised version of 2015/66/EPS/IIPI) A Working Paper is the author’s intellectual property. It is intended as a means

13

decent expected education, weak union rights, bank-led financial systems with very low inward

foreign direct investment and state allocation of funds, top-down decision-making with low

delegation inside firms and promotion based on seniority, state ownership and control of firms

(with a family element in Venezuela), very weak investor protection, very weak rule of law,

predatory state structures, top-down state decision-making, and very poor voice and

accountability as well as state effectiveness.

4. Implications

Our findings have a number of possible implications for our understanding of the world’s

business systems, in particular with respect to existing taxonomies. First, as already briefly

mentioned, the results suggest that Hall and Soskice (2001) did capture an important pattern by

distinguishing CMEs and LMEs, even given the variance within these groups. However, our

findings do not support efforts to apply these categories to economies other than those originally

included in them. They do not travel. Different categories are needed for the field to make sense

of the rest of the world. By extension, this also suggests that the underlying mechanism in the

Varieties of Capitalism approach of institutional complementarities through coherence (cf. Witt

and Jackson, forthcoming) – liberal through for the ideal-typical LME, coordinated for the ideal-

typical CME – is unlikely to extend to the rest of the world.

Second, the results suggest that at least some of the labels used in the field are

empirically valid but, globally speaking, probably part of the same clusters. This effect is most

striking for the Emerging Economies. Prior research has suggested various labels for economies

included in this cluster, such as hierarchical capitalism (Schneider, 2013) and post-socialist

economies and emerging Southeast Asian economies (Witt and Redding, 2013). Each of these

groupings of countries and the labels these prior works have attached to them have some

empirical justification. However, again putting these economies in global perspective and using

statistical methods to identify the most defensible clustering suggests that these and similar

economies all form one large type business system.

One interpretation is that while there are many ways to be a rich economy – CMEs,

LMEs, European Peripheral Economies, and Collaborative Economies – there may be limited

institutional variance among poorer emerging markets. This would be generally consistent with

Gerschenkron’s (1962) observation that late-developing economies leveraged institutional

Page 15: Working Paper Series · Working Paper Series 2016/59/STR/IIPI (Revised version of 2015/66/EPS/IIPI) A Working Paper is the author’s intellectual property. It is intended as a means

14

innovations, both relative to other poor economies but also their more advanced counterparts, to

catch up. Path dependency and the absence of a clear trend towards institutional convergence

among the advanced industrialized economies may then explain the persistence of resultant

institutional diversity over time.

While this can account for diversity at the developed end of the spectrum, it leaves open

the question why poorer countries are structurally similar. One interpretation might be that there

is a default mode of organizing societies that have not experienced profound modernization and

attendant institutional and economic development (Giddens and Pierson, 1998; Eisenstadt, 2000;

Beinhocker, 2005). One consistent feature of emerging markets in our sample, for instance, is

the relatively low levels of institutionalized trust, as expressed in the rule of law. In other words,

abstract rules and regulations have not yet superseded the patrimonial structures typical of

traditional societies (Li and Redding, 2014).

At the same time, all emerging markets are clearly not the same. China, for instance, has

done much better economically than, say, Pakistan or Indonesia. More generally, the Emerging

Economies includes both, economies that have seen little development and those that have made

great strides. To the extent the latter draw on institutional innovations as envisioned by

Gerschenkron (1962), this is not (yet?) visible in the data.

One possible interpretation is that the current dimensions for comparing business systems,

as outlined in Table 2, fail to capture these institutional innovations. In other words, this may be

a case of omitted variables, and it seems to us that this question would be a fruitful discussion

topic for the field. It may, however, also be possible that institutional innovation may matter

relatively less for producing growth in economies with lower income levels (Beinhocker, 2005;

Fatás and Mihov, 2009). For instance, the quality of institutions, and thus the role of institutional

innovation, may become relevant only once an economy approaches middle income levels, and

lack of institutional innovation may then lead to stagnation known as the “middle-income trap”

(Redding and Witt, 2007; Lewin et al., 2016; Doner and Schneider, forthcoming). The

development of institutionalized trust (Redding and Witt, 2007) and attendant changes in

governance (Witt, 2016) may be needed to overcome it.

Alternatively, or perhaps in addition, future research may well find that performance

differences within this group may be a function less of the presence or absence of individual

institutional characteristics, but rather of configurations of institutions and their

Page 16: Working Paper Series · Working Paper Series 2016/59/STR/IIPI (Revised version of 2015/66/EPS/IIPI) A Working Paper is the author’s intellectual property. It is intended as a means

15

complementarities. Complementarities have occupied a prominent place in the Varieties of

Capitalism literature, where they tend to be equated with coherence across institutional realms,

as already mentioned. However, such coherence is difficult to maintain across multiple realms,

as evident even among the advanced industrialized economies (Witt and Jackson, forthcoming).

Possibly more relevant may thus be Streeck’s (1997) concept of “beneficial constraints,” in

which opposing institutional logics across different institutional realms may produce

complementarities and thus contribute to economic performance. It may thus be acceptable, for

instance, for corruption to be high as long as government effectiveness is such that this private

rent seeking can be channeled to contribute to building up industrial capacity – as was arguably

the case in China for many years. Where such constraint is missing, the proceeds of corruption

may be more likely to materialize on bank accounts in third countries.

We should also acknowledge the influence of other, non-institutional drivers of

performance differences. For instance, the presence of external military threats, ethnic

homogeneity, and the absence of natural resources have all been linked to a higher propensity for

economic development. These non-institutional factors are, strictly speaking, beyond the scope

of business systems analysis. To the extent business systems theory seeks to evolve an

understanding of variety in outcomes, however, these and other factors are likely to need taking

into account.

Similarly, the literature has suggested a distinction between Southern European and

Central European economies. This divide is visible as a sub-cluster in our results, which

provides support for the validity of the respective labels. At the same time, putting these

economies in global perspective and applying statistical procedures for deciding the number of

clusters present in the data, we find that relative to the rest of the world, similarities are such that

both Southern and Central European economies seem to form a single cluster. Much of the

above discussion about Emerging Economies applies here as well, mutatis mutandis. For

instance, it is possible that the common clustering is a result of institutional dimensions that go

beyond those commonly accepted as relevant (Table 2).

Third, the Advanced Emerging Economies combine low geographic proximity with

relatively high institutional similarity. The economies in this group have reached relatively high

levels of per capita GDP and are generally considered exemplars of successful economic

development (stagnant South Africa with its very special economic history being the obvious

Page 17: Working Paper Series · Working Paper Series 2016/59/STR/IIPI (Revised version of 2015/66/EPS/IIPI) A Working Paper is the author’s intellectual property. It is intended as a means

16

exception, though recent developments suggest it may be joined by Turkey). This raises the

question whether there may, at least currently, be one particular institutional trajectory towards

high economic development – per capita GDP levels past the middle income trap – for countries

that have neither oil (like the Arab nations) nor are cities (like Hong Kong and Singapore).

While the economies in this cluster had very different institutional starting points, they

apparently converged on similar institutional structures as they got richer. It further suggests that

notions of a geographically based pattern towards development – such as the “Asian

development model” (Kojima, 2000) – may be missing part of the larger picture.

Fourth, our clusters raise questions about the validity of state-led capitalism as a type of

business system. We find economies usually associated with the state-led model distributed

across several clusters: Emerging Economies, Oil-based Arab Economies, Advanced City

Economies, Advanced Emerging Economies, Southern European Economies, and the Socialist

Economies. This is a very large spread of institutional differences that the “state-led” category

would need to accommodate – too large, in our view, to be analytically meaningful.

Recent works on state-led capitalism have recognized this issue and have started to

provide for subcategories (Musacchio et al., 2015). Given the emphasis on ownership patterns,

this may provide for a useful classification with respect to corporate governance outcomes.

However, the underlying logic of state-led capitalism qua business system will remain flawed

because it commits the fallacy of composition: there is a similar role of the state across

economies, thus these economies represent a variety of capitalism. This argument will work

only if one assumes that all the other dimensions of business systems research has identified

(Table 2) are inconsequential, or at least secondary.

The same challenge applies to the newer notion of family-led business systems (Aguilera

et al., 2013; Fainshmidt et al., forthcoming). Economies with important roles for family

business are present in the Emerging Economies, the Advanced City Economies, the Advanced

Emerging Economies of both types, parts of European Peripheral Economies, and the CMEs.

Again, this suggests that the “family-led” category includes too much institutional heterogeneity

to be useful for defining a type of business system, and the same concerns about the underlying

logic as for state capitalism applies.

5. Conclusion and Limitations

Page 18: Working Paper Series · Working Paper Series 2016/59/STR/IIPI (Revised version of 2015/66/EPS/IIPI) A Working Paper is the author’s intellectual property. It is intended as a means

17

In this paper, we have undertaken an analysis of the business systems of 61 of the largest

economies in the world, accounting for 93.5 percent of 2013 world GDP at purchasing power

parity. We have found nine main types of business systems in our sample and discussed the

characteristics of each of these clusters as well as the possible implications for the field. Among

others, they underline the validity of the CME vs. LME dichotomy for parts of the OECD, but

not the rest of the world; identify some of the labels proposed in recent years as valid but sub-

types of larger clusters; find high institutional similarity among most emerging markets as well

as advanced emerging markets on the one hand and institutional diversity of advanced

industrialized countries on the other; and call into doubt the notions of state-led and family-led

capitalism as business systems.

Our work, as all others, has limitations. In particular, about half of the data used in the

cluster analysis depended on expert judgment. While we have made great efforts to ensure

accuracy of these judgments, including through triangulation with other experts and, where

possible, the literature, measurement error is bound to have occurred in a number of cases. The

same can be said about the statistics used, with data from less developed economies often having

a greater probability of measurement error even if they are reported by reputable organizations

such as the World Bank.

As a result, it is likely that at least some of the positions identified by our cluster analysis

will be affected by measurement error. This error is likely to be smallest for the OECD countries,

where good data and plentiful prior research have established a fairly clear picture. As a general

rule, the less developed and the less researched a given economy, the higher the risk of

measurement error. Presumably, the risk is greatest for the African and Arab economies in the

sample.

This points to what we believe to be the most important implication for future research

growing out of this discussion. We need better data especially for non-OECD countries to

support expert judgment and, ultimately, to provide usable globally comparative institutional

data. Especially for the less explored geographies covered by our sample – Africa and the

Middle East – the cost/benefit ratio for empirical research seems highly favorable given the very

limited state of our current knowledge. Crucial would also be to obtain some sense of how Iran

and Iraq function. These economies, which are both troubled but fairly large, may well cluster

Page 19: Working Paper Series · Working Paper Series 2016/59/STR/IIPI (Revised version of 2015/66/EPS/IIPI) A Working Paper is the author’s intellectual property. It is intended as a means

18

with the Oil-rich Arab Economies. On the other hand, they may not; Iran, for instance, could

present as a separate kind of business system not observed elsewhere.

At the same time, the field needs to be on the lookout for better measures of constructs it

has identified as important. The issue of construct validity in comparative institutional analysis

was already discussed in Witt and Redding (2013), and we would like to second it here. We

overcame some of these issues through expert judgment, but in the end, it would be better to

have hard measures. For instance, given the centrality of corporate funding in our understanding

of business systems, we need to gain a comparative understanding of where firms (not the private

sector, which includes households) get what proportions of their outside funding. Occasionally,

such data become available for select countries (e.g., Witt, 2006). Making this kind of

information available on a broadly comparable basis, and ideally in a time series, would be a

great boon to future research.

Lastly, future research may of course extend the scope to include further countries. In

our view, this would probably be academically interesting but not very substantively meaningful.

Once Iran and Iraq have been brought into the picture, the remaining economies account, at

present, for less than 5 percent of the world economy. All else equal, it would be more fruitful to

put efforts into improving the quality of our measures than to work on including the remaining

small economies.

We began this paper with two questions: What are the world’s main types of business

systems, and what are their characteristics? We hope that with this paper, we have helped shed

some light on these questions and helped motivate further research that will help overcome the

limitations of this study. Comparative institutional analysis has made great strides in the past

two decades, but much work remains yet to be done. The agenda of understanding the world’s

business systems, and attendant efforts at theorizing them, has a long future ahead.

Page 20: Working Paper Series · Working Paper Series 2016/59/STR/IIPI (Revised version of 2015/66/EPS/IIPI) A Working Paper is the author’s intellectual property. It is intended as a means

19

References

Aguilera, R. V., Judge, W. Q. and Musacchio, A. (2013) Note on International Corporate

Governance, Boston, Harvard Business School Press.

Akkermans, D., Castaldi, C. and Los, B. (2009) 'Do 'Liberal Market Economies' Really Innovate

More Radically Than 'Coordinated Market Economies'?: Hall and Soskice Reconsidered',

Research Policy, 38, 181-191.

Allen, M. M. (2013) 'Comparative Capitalisms and the Institutional Embeddedness of Innovative

Capabilities', Socio-Economic Review, 11, 771-794.

Amable, B. (2003) The Diversity of Modern Capitalism, Oxford, UK, Oxford University Press.

Amaeshi, K. and Amao, O. O. (2009) 'Corporate Social Responsibility in Transnational Spaces:

Exploring Influences of Varieties of Capitalism on Expressions of Corporate Codes of Conduct

in Nigeria', Journal of Business Ethics, 86, 225-239.

Amsden, A. H. (1989) Asia's Next Giant: South Korea and Late Industrialization, Oxford, UK,

Oxford University Press.

Aoki, M. (1988) Information, Incentices, and Bargaining in the Japanese Economy, Cambridge,

UK, Cambridge University Press.

Babble, E. R. (2012) The Practice of Social Research, Belmont, CA, Wadsworth Publishing.

Beinhocker, E. D. (2005) The Origin of Wealth: Evolution, Complexity, and the Radical

Remaking of Economics, London, Random House.

Bohle, D. and Greskovits, B. (2012) Capitalist Diversity on Europe's Periphery, Ithaca, NY,

Cornell University Press.

Boschma, R. and Capone, G. (2015) 'Institutions and Diversification: Related Versus Unrelated

Diversification in a Varieties of Capitalism Framework', Research Policy, 44, 1902-1914.

Boyer, R. (2004) 'New Growth Regimes, but Still Institutional Diversity', Socio-Economic

Review, 2, 1-32.

Boyer, R., Uemura, H. and Isogai, A. (eds) (2012) Diversity and Transformations of Asian

Capitalisms, Abingdon, UK, Routledge.

Brammer, S., Jackson, G. and Matten, D. (2012) 'Corporate Social Responsibility and

Institutional Theory: New Perspectives on Private Governance', Socio-Economic Review, 10, 3-

28.

Bremmer, I. (2009) 'State Capitalism Comes of Age', Foreign Affairs, 88, 40-55.

Page 21: Working Paper Series · Working Paper Series 2016/59/STR/IIPI (Revised version of 2015/66/EPS/IIPI) A Working Paper is the author’s intellectual property. It is intended as a means

20

Campbell, J. L. and Pedersen, O. K. (2007) 'The Varieties of Capitalism and Hybrid Success

Denmark in the Global Economy', Comparative Political Studies, 40, 307-332.

Cusack, T., Iversen, T. and Soskice, D. (2010) 'Coevolution of Capitalism and Political

Representation: The Choice of Electoral Systems', American Political Science Review, 104, 393-

403.

Deakin, S., Mollica, V. and Sarkar, P. (forthcoming) 'Varieties of Creditor Protection: Insolvency

Law Reform and Credit Expansion in Developed Market Economies', Socio-Economic Review,

1-26.

Djelic, M.-L. (1998) Exporting the American Model: The Postwar Transformation of European

Business, Oxford, UK, Oxford University Press.

Doner, R. and Schneider, B. R. (forthcoming) 'The Middle-Income Trap: More Politics Than

Economics', World Politics.

Dore, R. P. (2000) Stock Market Capitalism: Welfare Capitalism: Japan and Germany Versus

the Anglo-Saxons, Oxford, UK, Oxford University Press.

Eisenstadt, S. N. (2000) 'Multiple Modernities', Daedalus, 129, 1-29.

Estevez-Abe, M., Iversen, T. and Soskice, D. (2001) 'Social Protection and the Formation of

Skills: A Reinterpretation of the Welfare State'. In Hall, P. A. and Soskice, D. (eds) Varieties of

Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage, Oxford, UK, Oxford

University Press, pp. 145-183.

Everitt, B. S., Landau, S., Leese, M. and Stahl, D. (2011) Cluster Analysis, 5th, Southern Gate,

UK, Wiley.

Fainshmidt, S., Judge, W. Q., Aguilera, R. V. and Smith, A. (forthcoming) 'Varieties of

Institutional Systems: A Contextual Taxonomy of Understudied Countries', Journal of World

Business.

Fatás, A. and Mihov, I. (2009) 'Another Challenge to China's Growth', Harvard Business Review,

87, 23.

Georgas, J. and Berry, J. W. (1995) 'An Ecocultural Taxonomy for Cross-Cultural Psychology',

Cross-Cultural Research, 29, 121-157.

Gerschenkron., A. (1962) Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective: A Book of Essays,

Cambridge, MA, Belknap Press.

Giddens, A. and Pierson, C. (1998) Conversations with Anthony Giddens: Making Sense of

Modernity, Stanford, CA, Stanford University Press.

Page 22: Working Paper Series · Working Paper Series 2016/59/STR/IIPI (Revised version of 2015/66/EPS/IIPI) A Working Paper is the author’s intellectual property. It is intended as a means

21

Gjølberg, M. (2009) 'Measuring the Immeasurable?: Constructing an Index of CSR Practices and

CSR Performance in 20 Countries', Scandinavian Journal of Management, 25, 10-22.

Greenacre, M. and Primicerio, R. (2013) Multivariate Analysis of Ecological Data, Bilbao, Spain,

BBVA Foundation.

Hall, P. A. and Soskice, D. (2001) 'An Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism'. In Hall, P. A. and

Soskice, D. (eds) Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative

Advantage, Oxford, UK, Oxford University Press, pp. 1-68.

Hall, P. A. and Thelen, K. (2009) 'Institutional Change in Varieties of Capitalism', Socio-

Economic Review, 7, 7-34.

Hancké, B., Rhodes, M. and Thatcher, M. (2007) 'Introduction: Beyond Varieties of Capitalism'.

In Hancké, B., Rhodes, M. and Thatcher, M. (eds) Beyond Varieties of Capitalism: Conflict,

Contradictions, and Complementarities in the European Economy, Oxford, UK, Oxford

University Press, pp. 3-38.

Inagami, T. and Whittaker, D. H. (2005) The New Community Firm: Employment, Governance

and Management Reform in Japan, Cambridge, UK, Cambridge University Press.

International Trade Union Confederation (2014) ITUC Global Rights Index, Brussels, ITUC.

Jackson, G. (2005) 'Toward a Comparative Perspective on Corporate and Labour Management:

Enterprise Coalitions and National Trajectories'. In Gospel, H. and Pendleton, A. (eds)

Corporate Governance and Labour Management: An International Comparison, Oxford, UK,

Oxford University Press, pp. 284-309.

Jackson, G. and Apostolakou, A. (2010) 'Corporate Social Responsibility in Western Europe: An

Institutional Mirror or Substitute?', Journal of Business Ethics, 94, 371-394.

Jackson, G. and Deeg, R. (2008) 'Comparing Capitalisms: Understanding Institutional Diversity

and Its Implications for International Business', Journal of International Business Studies, 39,

540-561.

Jackson, G. and Deeg, R. (2012) 'The Long-Term Trajectories of Institutional Change in

European Capitalism', Journal of European Public Policy, 19, 1109-1125.

Kalinowski, T. (2013) 'Regulating International Finance and the Diversity of Capitalism', Socio-

Economic Review, 11, 471-496.

Kang, N. and Moon, J. (2012) 'Institutional Complementarity between Corporate Governance

and Corporate Social Responsibility: A Comparative Institutional Analysis of Three Capitalisms',

Socio-Economic Review, 10, 85-108.

Page 23: Working Paper Series · Working Paper Series 2016/59/STR/IIPI (Revised version of 2015/66/EPS/IIPI) A Working Paper is the author’s intellectual property. It is intended as a means

22

Keller, M. R. and Block, F. (2013) 'Explaining the Transformation in the US Innovation System:

The Impact of a Small Government Program', Socio-Economic Review, 11, 629-656.

Kim, P. H. (2010) 'The East Asian Welfare State Debate and Surrogate Social Policy: An

Exploratory Study on Japan and South Korea', Socio-Economic Review, 8, 411-435.

Kogut, B. and Ragin, C. (2006) 'Exploring Complexity When Diversity Is Limited: Institutional

Complementarity in Theories of Rule of Law and National Systems Revisited', European

Management Review, 3, 44-59.

Kojima, K. (2000) 'The “Flying Geese” Model of Asian Economic Development: Origin,

Theoretical Extensions, and Regional Policy Implications', Journal of Asian Economics, 11, 375-

401.

Lewin, A. Y., Kenney, M. and Murmann, J. P. (eds) (2016) China's Innovation Challenge:

Overcoming the Middle-Income Trap, Cambridge, UK, Cambridge University Press.

Li, P. P. and Redding, G. (2014) 'Social Capital in Asia: Its Dual Nature and Function'. In Witt,

M. A. and Redding, G. (eds) The Oxford Handbook of Asian Business Systems, Oxford, UK,

Oxford University Press, pp. 513-537.

Matten, D. and Moon, J. (2008) '"Implicit" and "Explicit" CSR: A Conceptual Framework for a

Comparative Understanding of Corporate Social Responsibility', Academy of Management

Review, 33, 404-424.

Milligan, G. W. and Cooper, M. C. (1985) 'An Examination of Procedures for Determining the

Number of Clusters in a Data Set', Psychometrika, 50, 159-179.

Morgan, G., Campbell, J. H., Crouch, C., Pedersen, O. K. and Whitley, R. (eds) (2010) The

Oxford Handbook of Comparative Institutional Analysis, Oxford, UK, Oxford University Press.

Musacchio, A. and Lazzarini, S. G. (2014) Reinventing State Capitalism, Harvard University

Press.

Musacchio, A., Lazzarini, S. G. and Aguilera, R. V. (2015) 'New Varieties of State Capitalism:

Strategic and Governance Implications', The Academy of Management Perspectives, 29, 115-131.

Nölke, A. (2010) 'A “Bric”-Variety of Capitalism and Social Inequality: The Case of Brazil',

Revista de Estudos e Pesquisas sobre as Américas, 4, 1.

Nölke, A. and Vliegenthart, A. (2009) 'Enlarging the Varieties of Capitalism: The Emergence of

Dependent Market Economies in East Central Europe', World Politics, 61, 670-702.

Ó'Riain, S. (2014) The Rise and Fall of Ireland's Celtic Tiger: Liberalism, Boom and Bust,

Cambridge University Press.

Page 24: Working Paper Series · Working Paper Series 2016/59/STR/IIPI (Revised version of 2015/66/EPS/IIPI) A Working Paper is the author’s intellectual property. It is intended as a means

23

Peirce, C. S. (1957) Essays in the Philosophy of Science, New York, Bobbs-Merrill.

Redding, G. (2005) 'The Thick Description and Comparison of Societal Systems of Capitalism',

Journal of International Business Studies, 36, 123-155.

Redding, G. and Witt, M. A. (2007) The Future of Chinese Capitalism: Choices and Chances,

Oxford, UK, Oxford University Press.

Ronen, S. and Shenkar, O. (2013) 'Mapping World Cultures: Cluster Formation, Sources and

Implications', Journal of International Business Studies, 44, 867-897.

Rueda, D. and Pontusson, J. (2000) 'Wage Inequality and Varieties of Capitalism', World Politics,

52, 350-383.

Schmidt, V. A. (2002) The Futures of European Capitalism, Oxford, UK, Oxford University

Press.

Schneider, B. R. (2009) 'Hierarchical Market Economies and Varieties of Capitalism in Latin

America', Journal of Latin American Studies, 41, 553-575.

Schneider, B. R. (2013) Hierarchical Capitalism in Latin America, Cambridge University Press.

Schneider, C. Q. and Makszin, K. (2014) 'Forms of Welfare Capitalism and Education-Based

Participatory Inequality', Socio-Economic Review, 12, 437-462.

Schneider, M. R. and Paunescu, M. (2012) 'Changing Varieties of Capitalism and Revealed

Comparative Advantage: A Test of the Hall and Soskice Hypothesis', Socio-Economic Review,

10, 731-753.

Starbuck, W. H. (1993) 'Watch Where You Step! Or Indiana Starbuck Amid the Perils of

Academe'. In Bedeian, A. G. (ed) Managerial Laureates, Greenwich, CT, JAI Press, pp. 63-110.

StataCorp (2013a) Stata 13 Base Reference Manual, College Station, TX, Stata Press.

StataCorp (2013b) Stata Statistical Software: Release 13.1, College Station, TX, StataCorp LP.

Streeck, W. (1997) 'Beneficial Constraints: On the Economic Limits of Rational Voluntarism'. In

Hollingsworth, J. R. and Boyer, R. (eds) Contemporary Capitalism: The Embeddedness of

Institutions, Cambridge, UK, Cambridge University Press, pp. 197-219.

Streeck, W. and Thelen, K. (2005) 'Introduction: Institutional Change in Advanced Political

Economies'. In Streeck, W. and Thelen, K. (eds) Beyond Continuity: Institutional Change in

Advanced Political Economies, Oxford, UK, Oxford University Press, pp. 1-39.

Streeck, W. and Yamamura, K. (eds) (2001) The Origins of Nonliberal Capitalism: Germany

and Japan in Comparison, Ithaca, NY, Cornell University Press.

Page 25: Working Paper Series · Working Paper Series 2016/59/STR/IIPI (Revised version of 2015/66/EPS/IIPI) A Working Paper is the author’s intellectual property. It is intended as a means

24

Sutton, R. I. and Staw, B. M. (1995) 'What Theory Is Not', Administrative Science Quarterly, 40,

371-384.

Swedberg, R. (2014) 'Theorizing in Sociology and Social Science: Turning to the Context of

Discovery', Theory and Society, 41, 1-40.

Thelen, K. (2004) How Institutions Evolve: The Political Economy of Skills in Germany, Britain,

the United States, and Japan, Cambridge University Press.

Thelen, K. (2014) Varieties of Liberalization and the New Politics of Social Solidarity,

Cambridge University Press.

Van der Zwan, N. (2014) 'Making Sense of Financialization', Socio-Economic Review, 12, 99-

129.

Vogel, S. K. (2006) Japan Remodeled: How Government and Industry Are Reforming Japanese

Capitalism, Ithaca, NY, Cornell University Press.

Wade, R. (1990) Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East

Asian Industrialization, Princeton, NJ, Princeton University Press.

Weick, K. E. (1995) 'What Theory Is Not, Theorizing Is', Administrative Science Quarterly, 40,

385-390.

Whitley, R. (1999) Divergent Capitalisms: The Social Structuring and Change of Business

Systems, Oxford, UK, Oxford University Press.

Whitley, R. (2008) Business Systems and Organizational Capabilities: The Institutoinal

Structuring of Competitive Competences, Oxford, UK, Oxford University Press.

Witt, M. A. (2006) Changing Japanese Capitalism: Societal Coordination and Institutional

Adjustment, Cambridge, UK, Cambridge University Press.

Witt, M. A. (2016) 'The Road Ahead for China: Implications from South Korea's Experience'. In

Lewin, A. Y., Kenney, M. and Murmann, J. P. (eds) China's Innovation Challenge: Overcoming

the Middle Income Trap, Cambridge, UK, Cambridge University Press, pp. 87-107.

Witt, M. A. and Jackson, G. (forthcoming) 'Varieties of Capitalism and Institutional Comparative

Advantage: A Test and Reinterpretation', Journal of International Business Studies.

Witt, M. A. and Redding, G. (2013) 'Asian Business Systems: Institutional Comparison, Clusters

and Implications for Varieties of Capitalism and Business Systems Theory', Socio-Economic

Review, 11, 265-300.

Page 26: Working Paper Series · Working Paper Series 2016/59/STR/IIPI (Revised version of 2015/66/EPS/IIPI) A Working Paper is the author’s intellectual property. It is intended as a means

25

Witt, M. A. and Redding, G. (eds) (2014) The Oxford Handbook of Asian Business Systems,

Oxford, UK, Oxford University Press.

Wood, G., Dibben, P. and Ogden, S. (2014) 'Comparative Capitalism without Capitalism, and

Production without Workers: The Limits and Possibilities of Contemporary Institutional

Analysis', International Journal of Management Reviews, 16, 384-396.

Wood, G. and Frynas, J. G. (2006) 'The Institutional Basis of Economic Failure: Anatomy of the

Segmented Business System', Socio-Economic Review, 4, 239-277.

World Bank (2015) World Development Indicators, Washington, DC, World Bank.

Zhang, X. and Whitley, R. (2013) 'Changing Macro-Structural Varieties of East Asian

Capitalism', Socio-Economic Review, 11, 301-336.

Page 27: Working Paper Series · Working Paper Series 2016/59/STR/IIPI (Revised version of 2015/66/EPS/IIPI) A Working Paper is the author’s intellectual property. It is intended as a means

26

Figure 1 Dendrogram of clusters of business systems among the world’s major economies

Page 28: Working Paper Series · Working Paper Series 2016/59/STR/IIPI (Revised version of 2015/66/EPS/IIPI) A Working Paper is the author’s intellectual property. It is intended as a means

27

Table 1 Economies included in this study, by GDP size at purchasing power parity (PPP), 2013. Source: World Bank, 2015

Rank Economy PPP GDP Rank Economy PPP GDP Rank Economy PPP GDP

1 United States 16,768

23 Argentina 928

45 Austria 385

2 China 16,162

24 Poland 911

46 Hong Kong 382

3 India 6,776

25 Egypt 910

47 Romania 379

4 Japan 4,641

26 Pakistan 838

48 Peru 358

5 Germany 3,585

27 Netherlands 778

49 Norway 333

6 Russia 3,460

28 Malaysia 694

50 Czech Republic 303

7 Brazil 3,413

29 South Africa 663

51 Qatar 297

8 France 2,501

30 Philippines 643

52 Kuwait 287

9 UK 2,465

31 Colombia 600

53 Greece 284

10 Indonesia 2,389

32 Venezuela 553

54 Portugal 280

11 Italy 2,130

33 United Arab Emirates 551

55 Israel 264

12 Mexico 2,014

34 Algeria 522

56 Denmark 244

13 South Korea 1,664

35 Iraq* 500

57 Morocco 242

14 Saudi Arabia 1,547

36 Vietnam 475

58 Hungary 220

15 Spain 1,536

37 Belgium 466

59 Cuba 212

16 Canada 1,520

38 Bangladesh 462

60 Finland 208

17 Turkey 1,425

39 Switzerland 457

62 Ireland 199

18 Iran* 1,207

40 Sweden 433

69 New Zealand 153

19 Australia 1,007

41 Singapore 425

70 Slovakia 137

20 Nigeria 973

42 Ukraine 400

21 Taiwan 971

43 Kazakhstan 395

Total GDP** 95,569

22 Thailand 965

44 Chile 386

World GDP 102,255

* dropped from the analysis because of lack of data

** sum of the GDP of all economies in this study, excluding Iran and Iraq

Page 29: Working Paper Series · Working Paper Series 2016/59/STR/IIPI (Revised version of 2015/66/EPS/IIPI) A Working Paper is the author’s intellectual property. It is intended as a means

28

Table 2 Measures and data sources

Dimension Measure Options for variables based on

qualitative assessment

Source

Education Literacy rates CIA World Factbook

Mean years of schooling Human Development

Report

Expected years of schooling Human Development

Report

Mean employment tenure short, medium, long

Main method of skills acquisition OJT, public vocational training,

private

Employment

relations

Union type company, party, industrial, craft

Union rights ITUC

Finance Main source of funding banks, markets

IFDI stock over GDP UNCTAD

Main criteria for allocation of

funds

state, relationships, market

Interfirm

relations

Number of M&A deals over

GDP, 2011-2013

Thomson One

Internal

dynamics

Internal decision-making

structure

top-down, participatory

Extent of delegation low, medium, high

Main criteria for pay raises and

promotions

seniority, performance,

relationships

Ownership

and

governance

Main ownership of large firms family, state, market (widely

held)

Main controlling owner family, state, market (widely

Page 30: Working Paper Series · Working Paper Series 2016/59/STR/IIPI (Revised version of 2015/66/EPS/IIPI) A Working Paper is the author’s intellectual property. It is intended as a means

29

held)

Investor protection World Bank Doing

Business

Social capital Rule of law Worldwide

Governance Indicators

State Type developmental, predatory,

regulatory, welfare

Decision-making bottom-up, participatory

(corporatist), top-down

Voice and accountability Worldwide

Governance Indicators

Government effectiveness Worldwide

Governance Indicators

Regulatory quality Worldwide

Governance Indicators

Note: Taiwan data missing from international statistics completed using data from Taiwan National Statistics

Page 31: Working Paper Series · Working Paper Series 2016/59/STR/IIPI (Revised version of 2015/66/EPS/IIPI) A Working Paper is the author’s intellectual property. It is intended as a means

30

Table 3 Pairwise institutional distances (Gower dissimilarity matrix), higher = less similar

DZ AR AU AT BD BE BR CA CL CN CO CU CZ DK EG FI FR DE GE HK HU IN ID

DZ Algeria

AR Argentina 0.18

AU Australia 0.45 0.41

AT Austria 0.54 0.46 0.54

BD Bangladesh 0.26 0.24 0.60 0.46

BE Belgium 0.56 0.43 0.52 0.04 0.48

BR Brazil 0.26 0.19 0.47 0.42 0.22 0.40

CA Canada 0.50 0.46 0.06 0.53 0.60 0.52 0.52

CL Chile 0.43 0.31 0.38 0.38 0.36 0.36 0.18 0.34

CN China 0.26 0.22 0.53 0.53 0.18 0.55 0.25 0.58 0.42

CO Colombia 0.20 0.10 0.39 0.44 0.26 0.41 0.12 0.44 0.24 0.23

CU Cuba 0.31 0.37 0.59 0.50 0.24 0.52 0.37 0.60 0.49 0.26 0.40

CZ Czech Republic 0.37 0.43 0.45 0.27 0.30 0.28 0.30 0.46 0.32 0.41 0.37 0.29

DK Denmark 0.58 0.45 0.46 0.13 0.60 0.13 0.46 0.41 0.38 0.66 0.43 0.59 0.39

EG Egypt 0.12 0.16 0.56 0.52 0.14 0.54 0.19 0.61 0.37 0.14 0.18 0.30 0.39 0.61

FI Finland 0.55 0.52 0.53 0.06 0.48 0.10 0.44 0.52 0.44 0.54 0.50 0.47 0.28 0.12 0.53

FR France 0.44 0.31 0.40 0.16 0.36 0.13 0.27 0.40 0.24 0.43 0.29 0.44 0.21 0.24 0.41 0.22

DE Germany 0.58 0.46 0.49 0.05 0.51 0.04 0.42 0.49 0.38 0.57 0.44 0.50 0.31 0.09 0.56 0.07 0.16

GE Greece 0.22 0.20 0.51 0.33 0.18 0.35 0.22 0.51 0.32 0.20 0.22 0.31 0.25 0.46 0.20 0.34 0.22 0.37

HK Hong Kong 0.33 0.21 0.27 0.43 0.44 0.39 0.27 0.31 0.24 0.37 0.18 0.57 0.42 0.40 0.35 0.47 0.27 0.43 0.31

HU Hungary 0.38 0.35 0.54 0.25 0.31 0.27 0.22 0.50 0.22 0.37 0.29 0.34 0.13 0.30 0.31 0.27 0.20 0.30 0.22 0.36

IN India 0.20 0.16 0.55 0.46 0.14 0.48 0.18 0.60 0.36 0.15 0.22 0.32 0.39 0.59 0.13 0.48 0.35 0.51 0.14 0.34 0.36

ID Indonesia 0.16 0.09 0.40 0.49 0.29 0.46 0.21 0.45 0.34 0.23 0.11 0.44 0.46 0.49 0.18 0.55 0.34 0.49 0.22 0.23 0.38 0.21

IE Ireland 0.50 0.46 0.16 0.44 0.51 0.41 0.47 0.17 0.38 0.53 0.39 0.51 0.31 0.42 0.57 0.45 0.30 0.39 0.42 0.40 0.44 0.55 0.45

DZ AR AU AT BD BE BR CA CL CN CO CU CZ DK EG FI FR DE GE HK HU IN ID

IL Israel 0.52 0.34 0.36 0.40 0.48 0.38 0.35 0.30 0.24 0.50 0.32 0.43 0.39 0.30 0.45 0.41 0.31 0.35 0.44 0.33 0.29 0.43 0.42

IT Italy 0.34 0.25 0.50 0.21 0.26 0.23 0.26 0.50 0.26 0.33 0.28 0.34 0.19 0.34 0.32 0.27 0.10 0.25 0.13 0.31 0.16 0.26 0.29

Page 32: Working Paper Series · Working Paper Series 2016/59/STR/IIPI (Revised version of 2015/66/EPS/IIPI) A Working Paper is the author’s intellectual property. It is intended as a means

31

JP Japan 0.52 0.53 0.44 0.25 0.53 0.22 0.45 0.45 0.37 0.56 0.47 0.48 0.29 0.29 0.55 0.27 0.29 0.20 0.45 0.51 0.37 0.58 0.47

KZ Kazakhstan 0.22 0.17 0.52 0.43 0.18 0.40 0.16 0.57 0.33 0.16 0.15 0.26 0.31 0.52 0.15 0.45 0.32 0.43 0.15 0.31 0.28 0.16 0.19

KR Korea 0.36 0.33 0.38 0.43 0.36 0.41 0.26 0.34 0.20 0.38 0.25 0.40 0.31 0.37 0.34 0.45 0.28 0.38 0.32 0.32 0.26 0.40 0.26

KW Kuwait 0.29 0.28 0.43 0.39 0.31 0.40 0.20 0.48 0.37 0.28 0.21 0.35 0.31 0.43 0.27 0.40 0.28 0.43 0.26 0.36 0.23 0.32 0.25

MY Malaysia 0.20 0.15 0.45 0.54 0.25 0.52 0.21 0.49 0.35 0.18 0.15 0.39 0.43 0.53 0.14 0.55 0.38 0.55 0.23 0.28 0.36 0.21 0.11

MX Mexico 0.20 0.09 0.38 0.43 0.26 0.40 0.11 0.43 0.23 0.24 0.02 0.40 0.35 0.43 0.18 0.49 0.28 0.43 0.22 0.17 0.27 0.23 0.11

MA Morocco 0.19 0.21 0.50 0.55 0.15 0.57 0.22 0.56 0.40 0.20 0.22 0.37 0.38 0.59 0.12 0.57 0.45 0.60 0.29 0.39 0.35 0.22 0.17

NL Netherlands 0.60 0.56 0.39 0.15 0.61 0.14 0.53 0.39 0.44 0.68 0.55 0.51 0.32 0.17 0.66 0.15 0.26 0.11 0.48 0.51 0.40 0.61 0.60

NZ New Zealand 0.46 0.42 0.02 0.53 0.61 0.51 0.48 0.07 0.39 0.54 0.40 0.60 0.45 0.46 0.57 0.53 0.40 0.49 0.52 0.27 0.54 0.56 0.41

NG Nigeria 0.21 0.19 0.46 0.42 0.29 0.39 0.23 0.52 0.36 0.38 0.17 0.44 0.44 0.42 0.23 0.48 0.27 0.42 0.33 0.30 0.36 0.30 0.17

NO Norway 0.56 0.52 0.49 0.16 0.58 0.20 0.49 0.43 0.45 0.60 0.50 0.57 0.37 0.12 0.54 0.11 0.31 0.16 0.40 0.46 0.28 0.52 0.56

PK Pakistan 0.22 0.19 0.56 0.46 0.06 0.48 0.22 0.60 0.40 0.19 0.27 0.30 0.35 0.59 0.15 0.48 0.36 0.51 0.19 0.39 0.36 0.11 0.25

PE Peru 0.23 0.11 0.36 0.45 0.28 0.42 0.13 0.41 0.21 0.27 0.04 0.43 0.38 0.45 0.20 0.51 0.30 0.45 0.24 0.20 0.30 0.25 0.13

PH Philippines 0.15 0.10 0.40 0.49 0.30 0.47 0.22 0.45 0.34 0.22 0.11 0.43 0.46 0.49 0.17 0.55 0.35 0.49 0.21 0.24 0.38 0.21 0.02

PL Poland 0.25 0.22 0.39 0.45 0.32 0.44 0.27 0.44 0.38 0.33 0.21 0.47 0.43 0.45 0.26 0.47 0.36 0.45 0.30 0.31 0.39 0.29 0.21

PT Portugal 0.24 0.21 0.39 0.45 0.32 0.45 0.27 0.44 0.39 0.32 0.21 0.47 0.44 0.46 0.26 0.48 0.36 0.46 0.30 0.30 0.40 0.29 0.20

QA Qatar 0.24 0.21 0.39 0.46 0.31 0.45 0.27 0.45 0.40 0.32 0.20 0.48 0.45 0.46 0.25 0.48 0.37 0.47 0.30 0.30 0.41 0.28 0.19

RO Romania 0.23 0.20 0.39 0.46 0.31 0.46 0.26 0.45 0.40 0.31 0.20 0.48 0.46 0.47 0.25 0.49 0.38 0.48 0.30 0.30 0.42 0.27 0.18

RU Russia 0.22 0.19 0.38 0.47 0.31 0.47 0.26 0.45 0.41 0.31 0.19 0.49 0.47 0.47 0.24 0.50 0.38 0.48 0.30 0.29 0.42 0.27 0.17

SA Saudi Arabia 0.21 0.18 0.38 0.48 0.30 0.47 0.26 0.45 0.41 0.31 0.19 0.49 0.48 0.48 0.23 0.50 0.39 0.49 0.30 0.29 0.43 0.26 0.16

SG Singapore 0.20 0.18 0.38 0.48 0.30 0.48 0.26 0.45 0.42 0.30 0.18 0.50 0.48 0.48 0.23 0.51 0.39 0.50 0.30 0.29 0.44 0.26 0.16

SK Slovakia 0.19 0.17 0.37 0.49 0.30 0.49 0.26 0.45 0.43 0.30 0.18 0.50 0.49 0.49 0.22 0.52 0.40 0.51 0.30 0.28 0.45 0.25 0.15

ZA South Africa 0.18 0.16 0.37 0.49 0.29 0.49 0.26 0.45 0.43 0.30 0.17 0.51 0.50 0.50 0.22 0.52 0.41 0.51 0.30 0.28 0.46 0.25 0.14

DZ AR AU AT BD BE BR CA CL CN CO CU CZ DK EG FI FR DE GE HK HU IN ID

ES Spain 0.32 0.19 0.41 0.27 0.29 0.24 0.25 0.42 0.22 0.31 0.22 0.42 0.24 0.35 0.30 0.33 0.12 0.27 0.11 0.22 0.23 0.24 0.23

SE Sweden 0.61 0.48 0.45 0.12 0.58 0.11 0.49 0.44 0.45 0.60 0.46 0.57 0.38 0.13 0.59 0.11 0.22 0.08 0.40 0.42 0.37 0.53 0.52

CH Switzerland 0.64 0.51 0.43 0.16 0.61 0.15 0.48 0.38 0.34 0.63 0.50 0.60 0.41 0.09 0.62 0.15 0.27 0.12 0.47 0.37 0.30 0.61 0.55

TW Taiwan 0.32 0.24 0.42 0.42 0.32 0.39 0.25 0.37 0.18 0.34 0.22 0.45 0.35 0.37 0.30 0.48 0.27 0.42 0.28 0.27 0.24 0.36 0.17

TH Thailand 0.17 0.10 0.44 0.48 0.26 0.45 0.16 0.48 0.28 0.23 0.07 0.40 0.41 0.47 0.14 0.54 0.33 0.48 0.21 0.23 0.33 0.22 0.06

TR Turkey 0.39 0.29 0.39 0.43 0.26 0.41 0.21 0.34 0.14 0.37 0.19 0.40 0.31 0.43 0.32 0.49 0.28 0.43 0.30 0.31 0.23 0.36 0.30

Page 33: Working Paper Series · Working Paper Series 2016/59/STR/IIPI (Revised version of 2015/66/EPS/IIPI) A Working Paper is the author’s intellectual property. It is intended as a means

32

UA Ukraine 0.11 0.10 0.45 0.45 0.20 0.47 0.19 0.50 0.35 0.19 0.13 0.33 0.37 0.49 0.13 0.46 0.34 0.49 0.13 0.25 0.29 0.14 0.12

AE UAE 0.30 0.30 0.42 0.38 0.32 0.40 0.22 0.47 0.36 0.29 0.21 0.37 0.31 0.42 0.28 0.40 0.27 0.42 0.26 0.35 0.24 0.33 0.27

GB UK 0.47 0.43 0.08 0.51 0.57 0.49 0.49 0.04 0.31 0.55 0.41 0.61 0.43 0.44 0.58 0.56 0.37 0.51 0.48 0.28 0.47 0.57 0.42

US United States 0.47 0.43 0.07 0.58 0.62 0.56 0.45 0.12 0.37 0.55 0.41 0.62 0.49 0.52 0.59 0.59 0.44 0.53 0.53 0.31 0.57 0.53 0.42

VE Venezuela 0.22 0.23 0.53 0.44 0.25 0.46 0.25 0.59 0.43 0.28 0.31 0.18 0.32 0.53 0.21 0.46 0.39 0.49 0.29 0.43 0.28 0.24 0.30

VN Vietnam 0.26 0.18 0.48 0.53 0.23 0.50 0.26 0.54 0.42 0.06 0.24 0.31 0.45 0.62 0.19 0.54 0.38 0.53 0.21 0.32 0.42 0.15 0.19

IE IL IT JP KZ KR KW MY MX MA NL NZ NG NO PK PE PH PL PT QA RO RU SA

IL Israel 0.36

IT Italy 0.40 0.39

JP Japan 0.30 0.48 0.33

KZ Kazakhstan 0.48 0.41 0.27 0.50

KR Korea 0.33 0.32 0.30 0.28 0.33

KW Kuwait 0.39 0.36 0.27 0.46 0.29 0.35

MY Malaysia 0.44 0.38 0.35 0.48 0.18 0.25 0.24

MX Mexico 0.39 0.31 0.27 0.46 0.16 0.26 0.20 0.16

MA Morocco 0.51 0.48 0.35 0.53 0.26 0.34 0.21 0.13 0.22

NL Netherlands 0.30 0.46 0.36 0.17 0.54 0.44 0.54 0.64 0.53 0.70

NZ New Zealand 0.15 0.36 0.50 0.44 0.53 0.39 0.44 0.45 0.39 0.51 0.39

NG Nigeria 0.51 0.40 0.31 0.49 0.28 0.33 0.22 0.27 0.17 0.24 0.52 0.47

NO Norway 0.44 0.37 0.36 0.36 0.50 0.44 0.45 0.55 0.50 0.62 0.20 0.48 0.53

PK Pakistan 0.56 0.53 0.26 0.58 0.19 0.41 0.31 0.26 0.27 0.15 0.62 0.56 0.25 0.57

PE Peru 0.36 0.34 0.29 0.43 0.17 0.28 0.22 0.18 0.03 0.24 0.51 0.37 0.20 0.52 0.29

PH Philippines 0.45 0.42 0.29 0.48 0.19 0.25 0.26 0.11 0.12 0.18 0.60 0.41 0.17 0.56 0.26 0.14

PL Poland 0.37 0.30 0.14 0.26 0.25 0.22 0.30 0.33 0.25 0.37 0.33 0.51 0.29 0.38 0.38 0.27 0.32

PT Portugal 0.30 0.38 0.12 0.38 0.23 0.29 0.36 0.29 0.22 0.34 0.41 0.40 0.35 0.41 0.26 0.24 0.24 0.18

QA Qatar 0.38 0.35 0.28 0.45 0.30 0.33 0.03 0.24 0.22 0.23 0.53 0.43 0.23 0.45 0.33 0.24 0.26 0.30 0.35

RO Romania 0.30 0.45 0.24 0.32 0.32 0.37 0.33 0.46 0.37 0.39 0.31 0.44 0.45 0.41 0.35 0.34 0.48 0.20 0.28 0.34

RU Russia 0.45 0.49 0.35 0.53 0.26 0.39 0.30 0.20 0.26 0.22 0.60 0.41 0.35 0.56 0.25 0.27 0.21 0.48 0.36 0.31 0.42

SA Saudi Arabia 0.43 0.31 0.36 0.54 0.25 0.28 0.19 0.17 0.20 0.21 0.67 0.48 0.34 0.49 0.29 0.22 0.23 0.38 0.35 0.19 0.41 0.23

SG Singapore 0.35 0.31 0.39 0.50 0.31 0.32 0.31 0.22 0.21 0.29 0.55 0.30 0.30 0.45 0.38 0.24 0.28 0.31 0.28 0.30 0.41 0.39 0.35

Page 34: Working Paper Series · Working Paper Series 2016/59/STR/IIPI (Revised version of 2015/66/EPS/IIPI) A Working Paper is the author’s intellectual property. It is intended as a means

33

IE IL IT JP KZ KR KW MY MX MA NL NZ NG NO PK PE PH PL PT QA RO RU SA

SK Slovakia 0.28 0.27 0.18 0.35 0.26 0.33 0.31 0.39 0.26 0.42 0.32 0.42 0.34 0.34 0.39 0.28 0.37 0.11 0.15 0.31 0.21 0.47 0.39

ZA South Africa 0.29 0.18 0.28 0.45 0.30 0.25 0.26 0.29 0.16 0.37 0.47 0.34 0.29 0.38 0.42 0.18 0.27 0.27 0.25 0.27 0.40 0.38 0.20

ES Spain 0.31 0.35 0.09 0.34 0.21 0.26 0.35 0.28 0.21 0.38 0.37 0.41 0.34 0.38 0.29 0.23 0.23 0.16 0.04 0.34 0.31 0.33 0.34

SE Sweden 0.36 0.37 0.32 0.27 0.45 0.45 0.50 0.56 0.45 0.67 0.11 0.45 0.49 0.11 0.58 0.48 0.52 0.30 0.33 0.50 0.41 0.61 0.59

CH Switzerland 0.48 0.31 0.37 0.30 0.53 0.39 0.49 0.59 0.48 0.65 0.20 0.44 0.47 0.16 0.61 0.51 0.55 0.33 0.40 0.48 0.49 0.64 0.57

TW Taiwan 0.37 0.30 0.24 0.35 0.29 0.11 0.30 0.18 0.21 0.24 0.52 0.42 0.29 0.48 0.37 0.23 0.17 0.20 0.22 0.29 0.40 0.34 0.24

TH Thailand 0.44 0.36 0.28 0.46 0.15 0.25 0.25 0.10 0.07 0.17 0.59 0.44 0.18 0.55 0.26 0.09 0.07 0.26 0.23 0.27 0.42 0.25 0.23

TR Turkey 0.34 0.31 0.27 0.41 0.29 0.20 0.29 0.32 0.20 0.32 0.49 0.39 0.31 0.49 0.32 0.18 0.30 0.25 0.22 0.30 0.28 0.45 0.23

UA Ukraine 0.50 0.43 0.25 0.57 0.13 0.35 0.22 0.16 0.13 0.19 0.60 0.46 0.22 0.47 0.17 0.15 0.12 0.36 0.25 0.23 0.39 0.15 0.20

AE UAE 0.38 0.35 0.28 0.45 0.30 0.33 0.03 0.23 0.22 0.23 0.53 0.43 0.23 0.45 0.33 0.24 0.27 0.30 0.35 0.01 0.34 0.32 0.19

GB UK 0.18 0.33 0.47 0.46 0.54 0.35 0.45 0.46 0.40 0.52 0.42 0.09 0.48 0.47 0.57 0.38 0.42 0.47 0.37 0.44 0.40 0.44 0.40

US United States 0.21 0.34 0.53 0.48 0.54 0.40 0.45 0.47 0.40 0.53 0.45 0.08 0.49 0.55 0.57 0.38 0.43 0.53 0.43 0.45 0.46 0.45 0.49

VE Venezuela 0.58 0.42 0.29 0.56 0.24 0.42 0.25 0.32 0.30 0.27 0.55 0.54 0.29 0.51 0.20 0.33 0.31 0.36 0.37 0.27 0.33 0.23 0.29

VN Vietnam 0.53 0.51 0.33 0.56 0.16 0.38 0.34 0.18 0.25 0.25 0.63 0.49 0.32 0.60 0.19 0.27 0.18 0.40 0.28 0.34 0.47 0.18 0.26

SG SK ZA ES SE CH TW TH TR UA AE GB US VE

SK Slovakia 0.28

ZA South Africa 0.25 0.21

ES Spain 0.30 0.16 0.23

SE Sweden 0.45 0.25 0.39 0.29

CH Switzerland 0.44 0.33 0.39 0.37 0.16

TW Taiwan 0.26 0.31 0.19 0.20 0.49 0.43

TH Thailand 0.22 0.31 0.21 0.22 0.51 0.54 0.16

TR Turkey 0.30 0.26 0.16 0.26 0.50 0.44 0.21 0.25

UA Ukraine 0.28 0.37 0.28 0.23 0.52 0.55 0.27 0.13 0.31

AE UAE 0.30 0.31 0.27 0.34 0.50 0.48 0.30 0.27 0.30 0.24

GB UK 0.31 0.40 0.27 0.39 0.47 0.41 0.34 0.45 0.31 0.47 0.44

US United States 0.36 0.46 0.37 0.45 0.51 0.50 0.45 0.46 0.41 0.47 0.45 0.14

Page 35: Working Paper Series · Working Paper Series 2016/59/STR/IIPI (Revised version of 2015/66/EPS/IIPI) A Working Paper is the author’s intellectual property. It is intended as a means

34

VE Venezuela 0.46 0.40 0.40 0.36 0.56 0.54 0.40 0.31 0.36 0.21 0.28 0.55 0.57

VN Vietnam 0.41 0.41 0.40 0.27 0.56 0.58 0.35 0.24 0.38 0.18 0.34 0.50 0.51 0.28

Page 36: Working Paper Series · Working Paper Series 2016/59/STR/IIPI (Revised version of 2015/66/EPS/IIPI) A Working Paper is the author’s intellectual property. It is intended as a means

35

Table 4 Clusters of business systems among the world’s major economies

Socialist

Economies

Emerging

Economies

Arab Oil-

Based

Economies

Advanced

City

Economies

Advanced

Emerging

Economies

European

Peripheral

Economies

Liberal

Market

Economies

Coordinated

Market

Economies

Collaborative

Economies

Cuba Algeria Kuwait Hong Kong Chile Czech Rep. Australia Austria Japan

Venezuela Argentina Qatar Singapore Israel France Canada Belgium

Bangladesh S. Arabia Korea Greece Ireland Denmark

Brazil UAE S. Africa Hungary N. Zealand Finland

China Taiwan Italy UK Germany

Colombia Turkey Poland US Netherlands

Egypt Portugal Norway

India Romania Sweden

Indonesia Slovakia Switzerland

Kazakhstan Spain

Malaysia

Mexico

Morocco

Nigeria

Pakistan

Peru

Philippines

Russia

Thailand

Ukraine

Vietnam