Wernerfelt-1984-A Resource-Basead View of the firm.pdf

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/10/2019 Wernerfelt-1984-A Resource-Basead View of the firm.pdf

    1/10

    Strategic Management Journal Vol. 5 , 171-180 1984)

    /

    Resource-based View o f the Firm

    BIRGER WERNERFELT

    Graduate School

    of

    Business Administration The University

    of

    c

    ichigan Ann Arbor Michigan U.S.A.

    Summary

    The paper explores the usefulness of analysing fi rms fr om the

    resource side rather than from the product side. I n anplogy to entry

    barriers and growth-share matrices

    the concepts of rtsource

    posi tion barrier and resource-product matt ices are suggested These

    tools

    are then used to highlight the new strategic option@s?hich

    naturally emerge r om the resource perspective.

    I N T R O D U C T I O N

    For

    the f i rm, resources an d prod ucts a r e two sides of the sam e coin . Most produ cts requi re

    the services

    of

    several resources and most resources can be used in several products. By

    specifying the size of the f irms activity in different pro duc t m arke ts, i t is possible to infer

    the min imu m necessary resource com mitm ents . Conversely, by specifying a resource profile

    for a f irm , i t is possible to f ind the op tima l prod uct-m arke t activit ies.

    Bo th perspectives o n the firm a re reflected in the l i terature on strategic mana gem ent. T he

    t radi t ional concept of strategy An drew s, 1971) is phrased in terms of the resource posi t ion

    strengths and weaknesses) of th e firm, whereas most of ou r forma l economic tools opera te

    on the product-market side. While these two perspectives should ul t imately yield the

    sam e insights, o ne might expect these insights to com e with differing ease, dep end ing o n the

    perspec t ive taken .

    T h e p u r p o se of this pap er is to develop so me simple economic to ols for analysing a firms

    resource posit ion an d to look at som e strategic op tion s suggested by this analysis. This wil l

    ap ply , in part ic ular, t o the relat ionship between profi tabil ity an d resources, as well as ways

    to m anag e the f i rms resource posi tion over t ime.

    Look ing a t econo mic unit s in te rms of the ir resource endowm ents has

    a

    long tradit ion in

    economics. The analysis is typical ly confined, however, to categories such as labour,

    cap i t a l, and p e rhaps l and . T he idea of looking at f i rms as a broader set of resources goes

    back to the seminal work of Penrose (1959), bu t , apar t f rom Ru bin 1973) , has rece ived

    re la tively li tt le for ma l a t tent ion . The reason, no d oub t . i s the unpleasan t proper ties for

    model l ing purposes) of some key examples of resources, such as technological ski l ls. The

    ma them atics used by eco nom ists typical ly require tha t resources exhibit decl ining return s

    t o sca le , as in the t radi t ional theory of

    fac tor dem and . By vi r tue

    of

    analysing this type of

    resource , th e economic theory of factor demand becomes a special case of t he t heory pu t

    forward in this paper. By dealing with the financial resources of the f i rm, the product

    por t fol io theor ies in

    a

    sense become another special case of the theory discussed below.

    0143-2095/84/020171-10 01.00

    Received 14June 1982

    984

    by J o h n

    Wiley

    &

    Sons,

    L t d .

    Revised 7 April 1983

  • 8/10/2019 Wernerfelt-1984-A Resource-Basead View of the firm.pdf

    2/10

    172

    Birger Wernerfelt

    Also, th e idea tha t m ul t iproduct f irms benefi t f r om non-f inancia l l inkages such as jo int

    costs, is a n old bu t largely neglected par t of econo mics. Recently i t has , however, received

    renewed a t tent io n, mainly throug h the formal iza t ion of the economies of scope concep t see

    e.g. P an za r an d Will ig, 1981).

    I t turns out that the resource perspective provides a basis for addressing some key issues

    in the for m ula t ion of strategy fo r diversified firms, such as:

    a ) O n which of th e f irms curr ent resources s hou ld diversif icat ion

    be

    based?

    b) W hich resources shou ld be developed thro ugh diversif ica tion?

    c) In what sequence an d in to what m arkets should diversi fica tion take place?

    d) W ha t types of f irms will i t be desirable for this part icula r f irm to acq uire?

    Specifically, the fol lowing p rop osit io ns will be argued:

    4

    1.

    Look ing a t f i rms in te rms of their resources leads to different imm edia te insighrs tha n

    the trad it iona l pro du ct perspective. In pa rt icula r, diversified firms are seen in a new

    On e can iden t ify t ypes

    of

    resources which can lead to h igh profi ts . In ana logy to en t ry

    barr iers, these a re associated with w hat w e wil l cal l resource posi t ion barriers.

    S t ra t egy fo r a bigger firm involves striking a balance be tween the exploi ta t ion of

    exist ing resources and the development of new ones. In ana logy to t he g rowth-sha re

    ma trix, this c an be visualized in w hat we w ill cal l a r e source -p roduc t m a t r ix .

    An acquisi t ion can be seen as a purchase of a bundle of resources in a highly

    imperfec t m arke t . By basing the purcase o n a ra re resource , on e can ceterisparibus

    maximize th is imperfec t ion and ones chances of buying cheap and ge t t ing good

    re turns.

    light.

    4 T

    2.

    3 .

    4

    In th e next sec tion the s imple economics

    of

    different types

    of

    resources will be examined

    an d the result s will be appl ied to the charac ter i st ics of attract iv e, high profit yielding,

    resources. T hen th e analysis is confined to a part icular typ e

    of

    resource and som e st rategies

    for ma nag ing a f irms resource posi t ion over t ime will be looked at .

    RESOURCES

    AND

    P R O F I T A B I L I T Y

    By a resource is meant anything which could be thought of as a st rength o r weakness of a

    given firm. More formally, a f i rms resources at a given t ime could be defined as those

    tangible an d intangible) assets which are tied semipermanently t o the firm see Caves,

    1980). Examples of resources are: brand names, in-house knowledge

    of

    technology,

    employment of skil led personnel , t rade contacts, machinery, efficient procedures, capital ,

    etc . In this sec t ion, we wil l ask th e ques t ion: U nde r what circumstances will a resource lead

    to high return s over longer periods of t ime?

    For purposes of analysis, Porte rs f ive competi t ive forces Po rter , 1980) will be used,

    al tho ugh these were original ly intended as tools for analysis of produc t s on ly .

    General

    effects

    This heading wil l cover the bargaining power of suppl ie rs and buyers as well as the thre a t

    posed by sub st i tute resources.

  • 8/10/2019 Wernerfelt-1984-A Resource-Basead View of the firm.pdf

    3/10

    A Resource-based View of the Firm 173

    If the

    production of a resource itself or of one of its critical inputs

    is controlled by

    a

    monopolistic group, it will,

    ceterisparibus

    diminish the returns available to the users of the

    resource. A patent holder, for example, appropriates part

    of

    the profits of his licence

    holders. On a smaller scale,

    a

    good advertising agency will be able to take a share of the

    image builders (customers) profit.

    An equally bad situation can occur on the output side

    if

    the

    products resulting fr om use

    of

    the resource can be sold only

    n

    monopsonistic markets.

    If

    a

    subcontractor develops a

    machine which is fully idiosyncratic to one customer, he will stand to gain less than

    if

    the

    machine has more buyers.

    Finally, the availability of substitute resources will tend to depress returns t o the holders

    of

    a

    given resource. A recent example is provided by the way electronic and hydraulic skills

    have eroded the payoffs to electrical and mechanical skills.

    First mo ver advantages-resource positio n barriers

    In some cases,

    a

    holder of

    a

    resource is

    able to maintain a relative position

    visca-vis>

    ther

    holders and third persons as long as these act rationally.

    That is, the fact that soheone

    already has the resource affects the costs and/or revenues of later acquirers adversely. In

    these situations the holder can be said to enjoy the protection of a resource position barrier.

    Defined in this way, resource position barriers are thus only partially analogous to entry

    barriers, since they also contain the mechanisms which make an advantage over another

    resource holder defensible. (Entry barriers in the traditional market context deal only with

    the situation between incumbents and potential entrants, not with the situation among the

    incumbents.) Just like entry barriers, resource position barriers do, however, indicate a

    potential

    for

    high returns, since one competitor will have an advantage.

    Note that this (resource-based) concept in some sense supersedes the traditional (product-

    based) entry barrier concept, but in another sense does not:

    (a) If

    a

    firm,has entry barriers towards newcomers in market A, which shares the use of

    a resource with market B, then another firm which

    is

    strong in B might have

    a

    cost

    advantage there and enter A in that way.

    (b) If the firm has

    a

    resource position barrier in resource

    a

    which is used in market

    A,

    it

    might still survive the collapse of

    A if

    it could use

    a

    somewhere else.

    On the other hand,

    for

    a resource position barrier to be valuable, it should translate into an

    entry barrier in at least one market.

    So, an entry barrier without

    a

    resource position barrier leaves the firm vulnerable to

    diversifying entrants whereas a resource position barrier without an entry barrier leaves the

    firm unable to exploit the barrier.

    There is thus a nice duality between the two concepts,

    corresponding to the duality between products and resources.

    Attractive resources

    It is possible to identify classes of resources for which resource position barriers can be built

    up. By their nature, these barriers are often self-reproducing; that

    is a firm which at a given

    time, finds itself in some sense ahead of others may use these barriers to cement that lead. It

    is the properties of the resources and their mode of acquisition which allow this to be done.

    What

    a

    firm wants is to create a situation where its own resource position directly or

    indirectly makes it more digicult for others to catch up.

    To analyse a resource for a general

  • 8/10/2019 Wernerfelt-1984-A Resource-Basead View of the firm.pdf

    4/10

    174

    Birger Wernerfelt

    potential for high returns, one has to look at the ways in which

    a

    firm with

    a

    strong position

    can influence the acquisition costs or the user revenues of

    a

    firm with a weaker position.

    Let us apply this to a few examples.

    Machine capacity

    It is well known that production processes with decreasing returns to scale cannot yield high

    returns

    if

    they can be bought in open markets. On the other hand, economies of scale in the

    use of resources are the prime example of product entry barriers (Spence, 1979). From the

    resource perspective, the product entry barrier translates into a resource position barrier,

    since it will be irrational for entrants to buy the resource necessary to compete in a market

    where excess capacity would lead to cut-throat competition and low returns.

    So,

    in this case,

    the resource position barrier operates through lower expected revenues for prospective

    acquirers.

    c

    Customer loyalty

    I >

    In this case the nature of the market for the resource generates the resource position barrief.

    It is much easier to pioneer a position than to replace someone else who already has it

    see

    Ries and Trout, 1981). Here, later buyers will have to pay higher prices than earlier buyers.

    Related examples are the first mover advantages in government contacts, access to raw

    materials, etc.

    Production experience

    As

    is well known, if the leader executes the experience curve strategy correctly, then later

    resource producers have to get their experience in an uphill battle with earlier producers who

    have lower costs. Ideally, later acquirers should pay more for the experience and expect

    lower returns from it (Boston Consulting Group, 1972). On the other hand,

    if

    experience

    leaks from the early movers to later movers, the effect is to reduce the costs of the latter, so

    that we might apprqach. he case of an unpatented idea for which no sustainable first mover

    advantage exists. This is the case, for example, with many production systems and

    procedures.

    Technological leads

    Here again, two counteracting effects are at work. On the one hand,

    a

    technological lead

    will allow the firm higher returns, and thus enable it to keep better people in

    a

    more

    stimulating setting so that the organization can develop and calibrate more advanced ideas

    than followers. The followers, on the other hand, will often find the reinvention of your

    ideas easier than you found the original invention.

    So

    you need to keep growing your

    technological capability in order to protect your position. This should, however, be feasible

    if

    you use your high current returns to feed

    R & D.

    A good analogy is a high tree in

    a

    low

    forest; since it will get more sun, it

    will

    grow faster and stay taller.

    In general, one should keep in mind that most resources can be used in several products.

    As a result, a given resource position barrier

    will

    often have consequences for several

    products, each yielding part of the resulting return. A resource such as managerial skills,

    which could be analysed much like technological leads above, is a good example of this.

    The general attractiveness of a resource, understood as its capacity to support

    a

    resource

    position barrier, is only

    a

    necessary, not

    a

    sufficient, condition for

    a

    given firm to be

    interested in it. If everyone goes for the potentially attractive resources and only a few can

  • 8/10/2019 Wernerfelt-1984-A Resource-Basead View of the firm.pdf

    5/10

    A Resource-based View of the Firm

    175

    win in each, firms will lose unless they pick their fights well. So f irms need to f ind those

    resources which can s usta in a resource posi t ion barr ie r , b ut in which no o ne current ly has

    one , an d where they have a good chance

    of

    being a mo ng th e few w ho succeed in bui ld ing

    one . They have t o loo k a t resources which co mbin e well wi th w hat they a l ready have and in

    which they a re l ikely t o face only a few com peti t ive acq uirers.

    Mergers

    and

    acquisitions

    Merge rs and acqu i s i t i ons p rov ide an oppor tun i ty to t rade otherwise non-marketable

    resources an d t o bu y o r se ll resources in bundles . Th roug h th is vehic le o ne can , for example ,

    sell an im age o r buy a com bina t ion of technological capabil i t ies a nd con tacts in a-given set

    of ma rkets . A s i s well kno wn , th is is a very imperfec t m arket wi th few buyers an d ta rge ts ,

    an d ye t wi th a low degree of t ransparency owing to th e he terogenei ty of bo th buye rs and

    targets.

    A

    key impl ica t ion of the lat ter is that a given target wil l have differmt values for

    di fferent buyers , wi th par t icularly big var iance a mo ng those w ho can obta in som e sor t of fit

    synergy) between their resources an d those of the ta rge t .

    Because o f th e e xtrem e difficult ies of investigating oft en discreetly):

    a) wh at resources a given target has

    b) which of tho se the firm can effectively ta ke ad van tage of

    c) wha t the cost of doing so will be

    d) wha t t he f irm cou ld pay fo r them

    prospective buyers oft en l imit their search to targets which sat isfy certain simple cri teria . A

    resource-based set of acquisi t ion strategies Salter an d W einh old, 1980) is:

    i ) re la ted supplem entary ge t mo re of thos e resources you alre ady have)

    i i) related c om plem entar y get resources which com bine effect ively with those you

    al ready have) .

    Other acquisi t ion s t ra tegies a re more product -or iented and tend to focus on the f i rms

    ab il it y t o en t e r and do mina te ) a tt r ac tive marke t s .

    Le t us he re focus on the purchase of resource bundles, takin g as given th e profi tabil i ty of

    using different combinations. In this perspective,

    ones chan ce of maximizing m arke t

    imper fec t ion a nd pe rhaps ge tt ing

    a

    cheap buy would be grea test if one t r i ed to bu i ld on

    ones m ost unu sual resource or resource posi tion. Doing so should make i t possible

    to

    get

    in to buying si tuat io ns with relat ively l it t le com peti t io n, bu t also with relat ively few targets.

    Al though, in theory, i t would be best to be the sole sui table buyer of a lot of identical

    ta rge ts , even a b i late ra l mo nopo ly s i tua t ion would be be t te r th an a gam e with severa l

    identical buyers an d sel lers. Especial ly since the lat ter s i tuat io n wil l most l ikely lead o ne in to

    heavier com pet i t ion in the race to build resource posi t ion barriers af ter the acquisi tions have

    taken place.

    D Y N A M I C R E S O U RC E M A N A G E M E N T : A N E X A M P L E

    In th e previous sect ion, several si tua t ions in which firms could get high returns fro m

    individual resources were examined . In genera l, a f i rs t mover adv antage in a n a t t rac t ive

    resource should yield high returns in the markets where the resource in quest ion is

  • 8/10/2019 Wernerfelt-1984-A Resource-Basead View of the firm.pdf

    6/10

    176

    Birger Wernerfelt

    Figure

    1.

    Resource-product

    matrix

    dominating. This theory will now be applied to a particular type of resource, the experience

    type, produced jointly with products. Finally, some ways in which

    a

    firm can grow its pool

    of such resources, will be investigated.

    The resource-pro duct matrix

    The analysis will be conducted through what could be called

    a

    resource-product matrix, in

    which the checked entries indicate the importance of a resource in a product and vice versa

    (see Figure

    1).

    This matrix, which is a close cousin of the growth-share matrix, could be made more

    informative by replacing the checks with one (or two) numbers, indicating the relative

    importance of resources in products or (and) vice versa. As will be seen, even the simple

    form above is, however, a very powerful tool. Below it will be used to illustrate several

    different patterns of resource development.

    Sequential entry

    The use of

    a

    single resource in several businesses is the diversification pattern most often

    considered in business policy (Andrews, 1971). A typical example is provided by BICs

    (BIC, 1974) use

    of

    their mass marketing skills, which proved critical in pens, lighters and

    razors, but insufficient in pantihose. Attempts to base firms on a single strong technology

    also fall into this category. Several consulting firms market concepts which exploit this

    growth pattern (e.g. the shared experience of the Boston Consulting Group and the

    activity analysis of Braxton Associates).

    Although the general idea is to expand your position in a single resource, it is not always

    optimal to go full force in several markets simultaneously even with experience curve

    effects. Quite often, it is better to develop the resource in one market and then to enter other

    markets from a position of strength. An example is BIC, which entered the markets for

    pens, lighters and razors sequentially. This

    sequential entry

    strategy (an idea going back to

    John Stuart Mill, and his writings on infant industry protection), is also often followed by

    firms when they go international, as illustrated in Figure

    2,

    where the firm develops

    production skills before going international.

    To demonstrate the feasibility

    of

    this, we can look at

    a

    simple mathematical model. (A

  • 8/10/2019 Wernerfelt-1984-A Resource-Basead View of the firm.pdf

    7/10

    A Resource-based Viewof the Firm

    177

    D I I

    I

    Figure 2 . Sequential entry

    more elaborate formalization can be found in Bardhan,

    1971.) A

    firm can operate

    in

    two

    markets,

    A

    and

    B,

    which are such that it takes

    a

    hours to process

    I

    to produce

    a

    unit of

    product A, whereas it takes

    b

    and

    b

    hours of processes

    I

    and

    11

    respectively, to produce a

    unit of.product B. Assume process

    I1

    skills to be available in a perfect market, whereas

    process

    I

    skills can be developed via experience curve effects.

    So,

    skills in process

    I

    are the

    attractive resource. Finally, look at the firm as having a two-period time horizon and

    consider the wisdom

    of

    developing process

    I

    skills in market A before market B is entered.

    I n

    the following, all parameters are assumed positive and subscripts A, B,

    I 1 1 1, 2 ,

    refer

    to the markets, processes, and periods so named.

    The demand curves are assumed t o be constant over the two periods and linear

    so

    that the

    quantity sold is

    a

    linear function of the price charged. This can be written

    as:

    A i s A - P A A ,

    i

    1,2

    Bi

    O B - P B B ,

    1 , 2

    where

    0,

    and 8, are the volumes sold at zero price and q, and q he decline in volume per

    unit price increase.

    Variable costs are assumed to be zero and fixed costs,

    C,

    of selling above zero outputs are

    in period 1 composed

    of a

    constant cost of operating each process.

    I n

    period

    2 ,

    process

    I

    costs are, however, lowered by

    q

    A and q or each hour the process was used in period 1 .

    So

    we get:

    C A I

    Y A I ,

    i f A ,

    O

    c A 2 Y A I - r A l ( a IA 1 + b l B l ) , i f A 2 > 0

    CBI

    Y B I + Y B I I , ifB, O

    C B , = ~ B i - q B d a r A i + b i B i ) + ~ B 1 1 , if B2 > 0

    The simple linear version of the experience curve is chosen for analytical convenience and is

    in

    no

    way crucial to the qualitative results below.

    If

    the firm tries to maximize the total profit over the two periods, the objective

    is

    to

    maximize:

    (pA1

    Al)+(A2 A2)+(pB1 B l B l ) +(B2 B2 B 2 )

  • 8/10/2019 Wernerfelt-1984-A Resource-Basead View of the firm.pdf

    8/10

    178

    Birger Wernerfelt

    By inserting the above equations, differentiating with respect to

    PA, ,

    PAz

    PSI, e2

    and

    using the first order conditions, we find that, i f all outputs are positive, the optimal levels

    are

    AT Pjkl) 3c8.4 AU1(VA1 VB I ) ] ,

    where

    V B ~= 0

    if

    B2 0

    A T P z , ) = 46,

    T ,*l) 3 L e B + 4 B b I ( V A I V BI)]

    BT(P,*2) 0,.

    By inserting

    A; , A:, B ; , B*,),

    A: ,

    A:, 0 B:)

    and

    A:, A*,, 0,. 0)

    in the maximant, one can find the conditions under which it is optimal to enter market B

    only in the second period. These conditions are:

    B bI (V A 1 + V BI )+ [ B & 1 - b I ( V A I + V B 1 ) 1 2 4 B