69
Valuation of Structured Products Pricing of Commodity Linked Notes Shahid Jamil, Stud nr: SJ80094 Academic Advisor: Jochen Dorn Department of Business Studies Aarhus School of Business, University of Aarhus February 2011

Valuation of Structured Products

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Valuation of Structured Products

Valuation of Structured Products

Pricing of Commodity Linked Notes

Shahid Jamil, Stud nr: SJ80094

Academic Advisor: Jochen Dorn

Department of Business Studies

Aarhus School of Business, University of Aarhus

February 2011

Page 2: Valuation of Structured Products

1

Abstract

Structured products including commodity linked structured products have complex

composition. These are suitable for those investors who want a complete or partial

protection of their investment. A typical structured product is a combination of a risk

free bond and an option. The bond part guarantees capital protection while the option

part provides the possibility of payoff. The option pricing is the tricky part of these

products and a wide range of theories are available to price them. In this thesis the well

known Black & Scholes option pricing frame work is applied and the theoretical

estimated price of the selected commodity linked structured notes are compared with

their issue price to evaluate if these products are offered to the investors at fair price.

Page 3: Valuation of Structured Products

2

Table of Contents

1. Introduction .......................................................................................................................... 5

2. Structured Products .................................................................................................................. 8

2.1 Structured products are suitable for investors who .......................................................... 9

2.2 Disadvantage of structured Products ................................................................................ 10

2.3 Difference between a Conventional Bond and a Commodity Linked Bond ...................... 10

2.4 Commodity –Linked Bonds, a brief history ....................................................................... 11

2.5 Classification ...................................................................................................................... 12

2.5.1 Classic Products .......................................................................................................... 12

2.5.2 Corridor Products ....................................................................................................... 13

2.5.3 Guarantee Products ................................................................................................... 13

2.5.4 Turbo Products ........................................................................................................... 13

2.6 Products with exotic option components ......................................................................... 13

2.6.1 Barrier Products ......................................................................................................... 13

2.6.2 Rainbow Products ...................................................................................................... 14

2.7 Structure of structured products ...................................................................................... 14

2.7.1 The Bond Component ................................................................................................ 15

2.7.2 The Option Component .............................................................................................. 17

2.7.3 Swaps.......................................................................................................................... 17

2.7.4 Participation Rate ....................................................................................................... 18

3 Understanding Options ............................................................................................................ 19

3.1 Exotic Options ................................................................................................................... 19

3.2 Path dependent options .................................................................................................... 19

3.2.1 Asian options .............................................................................................................. 19

3.2.2 Lookback options ....................................................................................................... 21

3.2.3 Ladder options............................................................................................................ 21

3.2.4 Barrier options............................................................................................................ 21

3.3 Time dependent options ................................................................................................... 22

3.4 Multifactor options ........................................................................................................... 23

3.5 Payoff modified options .................................................................................................... 23

4 Option Pricing Theory ............................................................................................................... 25

4.1 Assumptions ...................................................................................................................... 25

4.2 Stochastic Process ............................................................................................................. 26

Page 4: Valuation of Structured Products

3

4.2.1 Properties of a stochastic process.................................................................................. 26

4.2.2 The Markov Property ................................................................................................. 26

4.2.3 Wiener Process ........................................................................................................... 26

4.2.4 Generalized Wiener Process ...................................................................................... 27

4.2.4 Geometric Brownian motion ...................................................................................... 28

4.2.6 Ito’s Lemma ................................................................................................................ 29

4.2.7 Risk Neutral Valuation ................................................................................................ 30

5 The Black- Scholes Equation (BS) ............................................................................................. 31

5.1 Options on dividend paying stock ..................................................................................... 35

5.2 Commodity Options .......................................................................................................... 35

5.3 Options on many underlying ............................................................................................. 36

5.4 Black- Scholes Pricing Formulas ........................................................................................ 37

5.5 Upper and Lower bounds for the call option .................................................................... 38

5.6 Forward Contract .............................................................................................................. 39

5.7 Futures contracts .............................................................................................................. 40

5.8 Futures Options ................................................................................................................. 42

5.9 Pricing of European futures options ................................................................................. 43

6 An overview of the selected products ..................................................................................... 45

6.1 DB Råvarer 2013 Basel (the “Notes”) ................................................................................ 46

6.1.1 Payoff Structure ......................................................................................................... 46

6.1.2 Risk Factors ................................................................................................................. 47

6.1.3 Issuance costs ............................................................................................................. 47

6.1.4 Embedded option ....................................................................................................... 47

6.1.5 The underlying asset ........................................................................................... 48

6.2 Analysis of Råvarer Basis 2010 .......................................................................................... 48

6.2.1. Payoff Structure ........................................................................................................ 48

6.2.2 Risk factors ................................................................................................................. 49

6.2.3 Issuance costs ............................................................................................................. 50

6.2.4 Embedded option ....................................................................................................... 50

6.2.5 Underlying Asset ........................................................................................................ 50

7 Pricing of the selected products ............................................................................................... 51

7.1 Pricing of DB Råvarer 2013 Basel ...................................................................................... 52

7.1.1 Deriving the Zero Coupons ......................................................................................... 52

7.2 Term Structure for Råvare.r Basis 2010 ............................................................................ 53

Page 5: Valuation of Structured Products

4

7.3 Option Pricing .................................................................................................................... 55

7.4 Estimating Volatility .......................................................................................................... 55

7.5 Monte Carlo Simulation .................................................................................................... 56

7.6 Variance Reduction Technique ......................................................................................... 57

7.7 Generating Random numbers ........................................................................................... 57

7.8 DB Råvarer Basel 2013 ...................................................................................................... 58

7.9 Pricing of Råvarer Basel 2010 ............................................................................................ 59

8 Evaluation of the Model ........................................................................................................... 61

8.1 Possible extensions to the thesis ...................................................................................... 62

9 Conclusion ................................................................................................................................ 65

References ................................................................................................................................... 67

Page 6: Valuation of Structured Products

5

1. Introduction

Structured products are drawing more and more investors now a day. Retail and

institutional investors alike are piling into these products. Structured products are

suitable for defensive or conservative investors because investments in structured

products assure a complete or partial protection of their invested capital but at the same

time, they can take advantage of the economic exposure to the growth potential of the

selected underlying. The underlying asset can be a single or a basket of the underlying

assets.

The popular structured products offer exposure to the equities, foreign exchange,

indices, volatility indices, commodities and commodity indexes such as S&P

commodity index, the Dow Jones-AIG commodity index or the Rogers International

commodities index. Commodity indices differ from the equity indices. The underlying

investments are not shares, bonds or the commodities themselves but “futures” contracts

on a single or a basket of commodities (a contract to buy or sell an asset at a given

future date for a set price). Futures contracts generally expire after three months;

therefore the so called rolling principal is applied for futures index where the index

sponsor replaces near to expiry contracts with the longer maturity contracts.

Structured products have become very advanced too in their structure. The complex

mechanisms within their structures are sometimes difficult to understand by the

investors and even sometimes by the financial managers too.

So, the theme of this thesis is to present an in depth analysis of the selected structured

products. The following will describe exactly what this thesis will be answering

• What are structured products and their composition?

• How the individual components of a structured product are valued. That is, how

are bonds priced (coupon and zero coupon bonds), and how the underlying

embedded options are priced (plain vanilla and exotic options)?

• What is the theoretical fair value of the selected structured products and whether

these products are offered to the investors at fair value, overvalued or

undervalued?

Page 7: Valuation of Structured Products

6

Structured products can be found in a wide variety of underlying assets. The underlying

assets can be from equities to equity indices, foreign exchange, interest rates,

commodities or commodity indices. This thesis will mainly focus on valuing

commodity linked structured products.

The contents of the thesis are split into two parts. The first section mainly focuses on the

theory behind the structured products. This section consist of chapters 2, 3, 4 and 5.

Section two consists of the valuation of the selected products and comparison of the

theoretical price with the issuing price of the selected products. Chapters 6, 7, 8 and 9

will be part of the second part of this thesis.

Chapter 2 begins with the introduction and definition of structured products and then

defining the commodity linked structured products. It will also describe in general how

structured products are engineered. This chapter will also discuss the advantages and

disadvantages of commodity linked products, their brief history, the difference between

a conventional bond and a structured bond and explanation of different concepts within

structured products.

Structured products normally consist of two components i.e. the bond and an embedded

option. The option component is generally the most tricky and complex part of these

products. Chapter three, four and five consist of the option theory including their

classification and the underlying concepts involved in option pricing in particular

stochastic process, geometric Brownian motion and generalized Wienner process. Black

and Scholes option pricing framework along with underlying assumptions and the

concept of risk neutral world will be discussed in chapter five.

Chapter six and seven deal with the pricing issues of the selected products. Chapter six

begins with the analysis of prospectus of the selected products. While chapter seven

starts with pricing of the bond and option part of these structured products. Valuation of

the option components start with an overview of the Monte Carlo simulation. The

qualitative and quantitative comparison of theoretical and issue price of the products is

performed. Chapter eight starts with a critical evaluation of the underlying assumptions

and their effect on valuation model. This thesis will give an understanding of how the

structured products are priced and therefore will trigger readers interest to find

improvements in the pricing model and possibly to use other pricing models too. So, a

Page 8: Valuation of Structured Products

7

brief description of the alternative option pricing models is also discussed in chapter 8.

Finally, the thesis ends up with a brief conclusion in chapter 9.

Although, structured products are available with a wide variety of underlying assets, but

this thesis will focus on commodity linked products. The products are selected from the

Danish market, therefore, interest rates will also be considered from the Danish market.

The valuation will be performed by applying the well known Black & Scholes option

pricing theory because the main theme of this thesis is the valuation of the selected

products and not to evaluate the performance of different option pricing models.

Therefore, other advanced option pricing models are not considered in this thesis. In

order to price the option component in Black & Scholes frame work, Monte Carlo

simulations are applied which follows the principal of risk neutral random walk. Tax

issues will not be considered in the valuation process. Default risk of the issuing firm

will be also disregarded because the selected products in this thesis are from the issuers

with very good credit ratings.

The data for this thesis has been downloaded directly from the Dow Jones UBS

commodity index web site, while the data for deriving zero coupon term structure was

down loaded from data stream.

Finally, I would like to thank my advisor Jochen Dorn for his use full guidance and

patience during the thesis.

Page 9: Valuation of Structured Products

8

2. Structured Products

Structured products have emerged as an important instrument in financial markets. A

structured product can be defined as a security that combines the features of a fixed

income security with the characteristics of a derivative transaction. Generally, a

structured product contains two components i.e. a fixed income security (a zero coupon

bond that guarantees full or part of the invested capital) and an option or forward – like

instrument which has a specific class of the asset as an underlying. The underlying

assets can be equity, interest rate, an index, inflation, foreign exchange, commodities or

credit. The underlying can be a single asset or a basket of multiple assets. The additional

payoff of a structured product depends on the performance of the underlying asset.

Structured products are also said to be a ‘marriage of a fixed income security and an

option like instrument1

When the underlying in a structured product is a commodity or a basket of commodities

or a commodity index then they are called commodity- linked structured products. The

underlying commodities can be for example crude oil, gas oil, metal (gold, silver,

copper, and precious metals), energy etc.

’.

Commodity indices are different from the other indices. The underlying investments are

not bonds or shares or the commodities themselves but it is ‘futures’ contracts on the

commodities. A futures contract is defined as the contract which gives its holder the

right but not the obligation to buy or sell an asset (commodities, equity, foreign

exchange etc) at a given future date at an agreed price. Futures have normally three

months expiry date. These expiry dates are normally standardized. The index sponsor is

therefore required to replace the expiring futures contracts with the new ones traded on

the futures market (every three months). This is called the ‘rolling’ principle. When a

futures contract expires, the index will treat it as sold and the proceeds are reinvested in

the new futures contract that will again expire after the next three months.

1 BNP Paribas equities & Derivatives handbook

Page 10: Valuation of Structured Products

9

The index level takes care, the price movements in the underlying commodities and

takes into account the price difference between the old and the new futures contract that

are rolled.2

Commodity linked structured products are available in a wide variety of range. One of

them is Commodity- Linked bonds/ Notes, which is also the topic of this thesis.

Commodity linked notes or bonds are classified into two classes, i.e. The Forward type

and the option type. In a forward type bond, the coupon and or principle payment to the

bearer are linearly related to the price of the stated reference commodity i.e. it allows

the holder to receive either the nominal face value or the designated commodity amount

at maturity . While, an option type bond, the coupon payments are similar to that of a

conventional bond but at maturity, the bearer receives the face value plus an option to

buy or sell a predetermined quantity of the commodity at specified price

3

2.1 Structured products are suitable for investors who

. In literature

both the terms (bonds and note) are used interchangeably.

4

1. Want protection of their invested capital by hedging the risk of existing

investments.

2. Want to enhance the return from their investment while controlling risks,

whereby the structure is designed to enhance equity return with leverage.

3. Want to diversify with the adjustable risk/ return profiles and market cycle

optimization capabilities of structured products.

4. Want to exploit their market view with more freedom and flexibility.

5. Want a growth by capitalizing on the market upside while protecting the

downside.

6. Want to benefit from periodic returns with limited risks. This income type of

structure is built to deliver coupons while protecting capital

2 Barclays Wealth, Light Energy Commodity Plan 2,3 Joseph Atta- Mensah. Commodity- Linked Bonds 4 BNP Paribas equities & Derivatives handbook

Page 11: Valuation of Structured Products

10

2.2 Disadvantage of structured Products

Despite the fact, that structured products including commodity linked products provide

capital protection and a possible payoff from the option component, the investor still

loses the payoff associated with a traditional risk free bond. In a structured product, the

investor receives only the invested capital if the option expires out of the money, but in

a traditional bond, the investor receives a risk free interest of his invested capital along

with the invested capital. This lost risk free interest or profit is called the Opportunity

cost and can be defined as the “forgone risk-free rate of return that could have been

achieved if the principal would have been invested in the safe fixed- income securities

such as Treasury bills”5

For example, if an investor invests 100 DKK in treasury bonds for one year with a 5%

interest rate. He will receive DKK105 at maturity while if he invests in a structured

product, he will only get DKK 100 at maturity plus a possible payoff from the option

embedded in it, because he will actually invest 100*1,05^-1 = DKK 95 in the risk free

investment and DKK 5 will go to buy a call option plus administration fee . This DKK 5

from investment in risk free bond will be the opportunity cost that he will miss if he

would invest in a structured product. The payoff of a traditional bond will exceed as

long as the option component of a structured product is out of the money, at the money

or if it is in the money but still below DKK105.

.

2.3 Difference between a Conventional Bond and a Commodity Linked Bond6

Commodity linked bonds are different from conventional bonds in many aspects. Some

of the key differences between are

1. In conventional bonds, the investor receives fixed coupon payments i.e. interest

payments during the life cycle of the bond (annually or semiannually etc) and

the face value at the maturity of the bond. While the holder of a commodity

linked bond receives the physical units of the underlying commodity or

equivalent of its monetary value. Similarly the coupon payments may or not be

5 Lehman Brothers, A guide to Equity_Linked Notes

Page 12: Valuation of Structured Products

11

in units of the underlying commodity (it depends upon the performance of the

underlying).

2. The nominal return of a conventional bond held to maturity is known while the

real return is not known because of inflation. On the other hand both the real and

the nominal return of a commodity linked bond are unknown.

3. The results of Atta- Mensah study also show that the coupon rate for a

conventional bonds are greater than that of the commodity linked bonds whose

terminal payoff is greater of the face value and monetary value of a pre-specified

unit of a commodity.

4. The coupon rate of a conventional bond is less than that of a commodity linked

bond that pays its holders on maturity the minimum of the face value and the

monetary value of a pre-specified unit of a commodity.

2.4 Commodity –Linked Bonds, a brief history

The concept of structured note is considered to be relatively new in the financial

markets. In reality these products have been in existence for a considerable time. For

example callable notes and equity linked securities i.e. convertibles and debt with equity

warrants are the precursors to the structured note products that are common place today.

Commodity linked bonds were introduced during 1970’s when the oil backed bonds

were issued by the Mexican Government in the financial market. These bonds were

called Petrobonds. Each 1000 Peso bond was linked to 1.95353 barrels of oil with a

coupon payment of 12. 658% annually and had three years to maturity. Later on the

French Government issued gold backed bonds during 1973. They were known as

‘Giscard’ in the financial markets. These bonds have 7% coupon rate and redemption

value was indexed to the one kilogram bar of gold. In 1981 Eco Bay Mines Company of

Canada also issued gold warrants. Commodity linked bond with sliver as an underlying

was issued during 1983 and again in 1985 by the Sunshine Mining Company in USA.

The objective was to hedge against the fluctuations in the price of silver.

Later on, bonds indexed to other commodities like nickel, copper, silver, cobalt and

platinum were issued during 1984 by Inco. (a leading producer of metals). Now a days,

commodity linked bond are issued by many investment banks around the world. These

bonds are linked to the performance of a basket of specific commodities or commodity

Page 13: Valuation of Structured Products

12

index for example Goldman Sachs Commodity Index (GSCI), London Metal Exchange

(LME), S & P commodity index or Dow Jones UBS commodity index.

2.5 Classification

Structured products including commodity linked structured products are available with

a wide variety of product characteristics and heterogeneous characteristics in the

market. However, Pavel A Stoimenov and Sascha Wilkens, in their article about the

equity linked structured products in the German market, “Are Structured Products

Fairly Priced”? have classified them according to the underlying option components

embedded in the product. As is shown in the figure 1, structured products can be

divided into two categories i.e. Plain vanilla Option- Component and exotic Option-

component. Plain vanilla products are further classified into Classic, Corridor,

Guarantee and Turbo while Exotic components products are further classified into

Barrier and rainbow. Barrier structured products are further divided into Knock- in,

Partial Knock- in and knock – out products. The brief definitions of these products are

discussed below.

Figure 1

2.5.1 Classic Products

A classic structured product has the basic characteristics of a bond except that the issuer

has the right to redeem it at maturity by repayment of its nominal value or delivery of

previously fixed number of specified shares. In general, structured products can be

Page 14: Valuation of Structured Products

13

categorized into with and without coupon payments. Products with coupon payments

are called as ‘reverse convertibles’, while those without coupon payments are named as

‘discount certificates’.

2.5.2 Corridor Products

The payout of a corridor structured product depends on whether the underlying at

maturity is quoted within a certain range.

2.5.3 Guarantee Products

A guarantee product is similar to that of a corridor product. The only difference is that

in a guarantee product, fixed minimum repayments are guaranteed to the investor. So, if

price of the underlying falls below the reference value, then the investor will always get

the guaranteed amount.

2.5.4 Turbo Products

The payout of a turbo product is doubled if the underlying is quoted within a certain

price range at maturity. This is called turbo effect. But there are three possibilities at

maturity. If, for example, L and K are lower and upper reference prices, then at

maturity, if

1. St fixing ≤ L, the product is redeemed in shares;

2. L < St fixing < K, a cash settlement with s(2 St fixing - L) occurs;

3. K ≤ St fixing, the maximum amount s (2K - L) will be paid.

2.6 Products with exotic option components

2.6.1 Barrier Products

Barrier products are the most common type of structured products, where the embedded

option is a barrier one. The redemption of a barrier product depends upon whether the

underlying reaches a certain fixed price barrier during its lifetime. In a knock in product,

if the underlying reaches or crosses a fixed pre specified lower price barrier, then the

stocks are delivered at maturity. In such a case the product behaves like a classic

product. A knock in pays the maximum amount if the underlying is always above this

barrier regardless of the St Fixing . In the case of a knock out product, if the underlying

Page 15: Valuation of Structured Products

14

reaches or crosses the pre specified upper price barrier, then the issuer loses his choice

of redemption and the products behaves like a regular bond in this case. In a partial time

knock in product, the barrier criterion is tested only within a certain time interval,

generally a few months immediately before maturity.

2.6.2 Rainbow Products

The rainbow products have more than one underlying. In a rainbow product, the issuer

has the right to choose between the specified underlying on redemption.

2.7 Structure of structured products

Commodity linked notes like other types of structured products provide partial or 100%

capital protection depending upon the investor’s specific needs. A typical commodity

linked bond provides 100% capital protection at maturity independent of the

performance of the underlying commodity or commodity index. The structure of a

simple commodity linked note can be sketched as

This figure shows that when an investor buys a structured product (equity, commodity

or any other asset as an underlying), he/ she actually has bought a package which

consists of a bond and an option or a swap (forward or future) and the fee on top of it.

The payoff of a structured product (note) is equal to the par amount of the note plus a

commodity / equity etc linked coupon. The payoff is either

1. Zero, if the underlying has depreciated from the initial agreed upon strike level

Bond Commodity linked Note Principal

Payoff Option/ Swap

Page 16: Valuation of Structured Products

15

2. Or the participation rate times the percentage change in the underlying

commodity/ equity times the par amount of the note7

In order to understand how a structured note works, we consider a simple example,

where an investor wants to invest 100 DKK over five years with full capital protection

and exposure to the S & P Commodity index. This means that the investor will get at

least his/ her 100 DKK at the end of five years no matter if the index depreciates or

appreciates. The investment bank will apply the appropriate interest rate (treasury

bonds, LIBOR or REPO rate) and find out the present value of 100 DKK (future value).

For example, if the five years interest rate was 5 %. Then the present value of this five

years zero coupon bond will be 78.35 DKK (100 * 1.05-5) today. It means that the

structure provider (investment bank) will have 100-78.35 = 21.65 DKK to purchase an

option or a futures/ forwards contract. Now let’s consider that a five – years S & P call

option costs 23.65 and 2 is the administration and margin costs, then the investor will

benefit from 83. 87 % ((21.65 – 2) / 23.65) participation in the S & P index’s upside.

.

2.7.1 The Bond Component

The bond component of a structured product is the most important part of it. It is also

the major part of any structured product. The bond component ensures that the investor

will receive the agreed amount of his/ her investment at maturity. The agreed amount

can be a 100 % of the invested capital or it can also be partial protection depending

upon the product. Structured products in general have the characteristics of a zero

coupon bond but it can also have coupon payments (annual or a semi- annual). The

main advantage of a zero coupon bond is that the investor gets all his investment back at

the same time instead of coupon payments at the end each period (annual or semi-

annual). The risk free interest rate applied to a zero coupon bond ensures that the

present value of the investment will grow continuously until maturity. The risk free

interest rate is normally taken from the government bonds (the rate at which the state

borrows money).

If an amount A is invested for n years at an interest rate R per annum and if R is

compounded once per annum i.e. m=1, then the terminal value of the investment will be

7 Lehman Brothers ( equity – Linked Notes)

Page 17: Valuation of Structured Products

16

𝐴(1 + 𝑅𝑚

)𝑛𝑚

If 𝑚 → +∞, we compound more and more frequently, then we obtain the well known

compounding frequency interest rates and the future value or the terminal value will be given as

𝐴𝑒𝑅𝑛

In the same way the present value of a future amount can be written as

𝐴𝑒−𝑅𝑛

The pricing of a zero coupon bond or any other fixed income security can be derived if

we know the zero coupon (ZC) yield curve. The term structure of ZC rates (also known

as ZC yield curve) is the curve relating maturities t (time horizons) with the

corresponding ZC interest rate R(t).

𝑃𝑟𝑖𝑐𝑒 = ∑ 𝐹𝑡(1+𝑅(𝑡))𝑡

𝑇𝑡=1 = ∑ 𝐹𝑡𝑇

𝑡=1 𝐵(𝑡) (1)

Here

• B(t) means the discount factor at time t ( the prices of zero coupon rates with face

value of 1)

• R(t) is the zero coupon rate derived from B(t) and

• F (t) is the known cash flow or also called the principal amount.

When a structure note/ bond have the features of a coupon bond, then it can be

considered as the portfolio of zero coupon bonds. The price of such a bond can be

written as the present value of the sum of all cash flows (coupon payments) for each

period plus the principal amount and can by the following expression

𝑃𝑟𝑖𝑐𝑒 = ∑ 𝐶𝐹𝑡𝑛 .𝐵𝑡 + 𝐹𝑡𝐵𝑛 = ∑ 𝐶𝐹𝑡𝑛 . (1 + 𝑅𝑡)−𝑡 + 𝐹𝑡 (1 + 𝑅𝑡)−𝑛 (2)

Where,

• CFt is the cash flow in time t

Page 18: Valuation of Structured Products

17

2.7.2 The Option Component

The option component is the 2nd part of a structured product. Option component

provides the chances of payoff. Options are of two types i.e. a call and a put. A call

option provides its holder the right to buy an asset at a certain date on a pre specified

price while the put option gives its holder the right to sell an asset at a pre specified

price on a certain date. Call options are normally embedded in structured products

because it is easy to earn on something whose price is increasing rather than decreasing

as in case of a put option. Option component is also the risky part of any structured,

because the payoff depends on the performance of the underlying. If the option

embedded in a structured product expires out of the money (i.e. the strike price of the

call option is higher than the corresponding price of the underlying) than it will not be

exercised and the holder will get no profit but instead loose the money to buy that

option but he will still receive his invested capital. If on the other hand, an option

expires in the money, then it will be exercised and the holder will earn profit along with

the guaranteed capital. The expression at the money means that when the strike price of

the call option is equal to the price of the underlying.

There are two possibilities to exercise an option. In a European style option, the holder

can exercise his right to buy or sell an asset only at the maturity of the option. In an

American style, the holder can exercise his right to buy or sell the underlying before the

maturity of the option too.

2.7.3 Swaps

Commodity linked structured products can also be found with swaps in their structures.

Forwards are an example of swap and commodity swaps are in fact a series of forward

contracts on a commodity with different maturity dates and the same delivery prices.8

The commodity linked products as mentioned by Schwartz9

8 John C Hull: P-173 Option, Futures and Other derivatives

issued for example by

Sunshine company during 80’s or by the Mexican Government during 1979 backed by

silver and oil respectively are examples of the products with forward type component in

the structured product, where the company promised to pay either the face value or

market value of the underlying commodity.

9 Eduardo S. Schawartz: The Pricing of Commodity Linked bonds

Page 19: Valuation of Structured Products

18

2.7.4 Participation Rate

Participation rate determines that how much the product will participate in the

performance of the underlying. It can be defined as the exposure of a product to

movements in the price of its underlying. A participation rate of 100 % means that the

investor would receive the return that will be exactly equal to the rise in the price of the

underlying. For example if the underlying has increased by 25% at maturity, then the

investor will also receive 25% return. But if it is low as mentioned in the example on

page 9 i.e. 87.83 % then the investor will get DKK 21(87.83% * 25).

Participation rate depends on the value of the option embedded in the structured

product, the administration and other issuing costs and the present value of the bond

component of the product. The participation rate depends on many factors. For example

if the issuing costs of the product are low then the participation rate can be higher.

Similarly, if the value of embedded option is high/ low then the participation rate can

lower/ high. Participation rate is generally not set prior to the expiry of the issuance

period and it appears as estimate in the prospectus. The participation rate can be

calculated by the following relation

𝑃𝑎𝑟𝑡𝑖𝑐𝑖𝑝𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛 𝑟𝑎𝑡𝑒 =𝑖𝑠𝑠𝑢𝑒 𝑝𝑟𝑖𝑐𝑒 − 𝑐𝑜𝑠𝑡𝑠 − 𝑃𝑉 𝑜𝑓 𝑏𝑜𝑛𝑑

𝑃𝑟𝑖𝑐𝑒 𝑜𝑓 𝑜𝑝𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛 𝑐𝑜𝑚𝑝𝑜𝑛𝑒𝑛𝑡∗ 100 (3)

Participation rate is also named as Gearing. The above equation also shows that there

other factor which determines the participation rate. For example, the interest rate used

to calculate the present value of the bond component, the life time of the product and

volatility of the underlying asset. For example a low interest rate will result in high

present value of the bond component and can reduce the participation rate and vice

versa. Similarly volatility of the underlying asset can also affect participation rate. If the

volatility of the underlying asset is lower, consequently the option will have lower value

and ultimately a higher participation rate. Cheaper options embedded in the structured

products also result in high participation rate. For example, exotic options are generally

cheaper than plain vanilla options. Therefore, now a day exotic options are generally

embedded in the structured product which increase the participation rate and can result

in higher payoffs at the end.

Page 20: Valuation of Structured Products

19

3 Understanding Options

Options are classified into plain vanilla and exotic options. Plain vanilla options are

standard options while the exotic options are complex in nature. The complex options

have low prices as compared to the standard options. Therefore, exotic options are

generally embedded in structured products, which also make the products interesting for

investor’s point of view. Some examples of exotic options are barrier, chooser, look

back, Asian, Himalayan and basket options. Their detail will be discussed later on. If

the price of an embedded option/ options is lower, then the participation rate will be

higher and more payoff for the investor.

3.1 Exotic Options

An option whose characteristics, including strike price calculations/ determinations,

payoff characteristics, premium payment terms or activation/expiration mechanisms

vary from standard call and put options or where the underlying asset involves

combined or multiple underlying assets are called exotic options (Das2001, p718).

Exotic options are also called thirds generation risk management products. Although it

is hard to classify all the options, but they can be roughly divided into five to six

categories.10

3.2 Path dependent options

In path dependent options the final payoff depends on particular path that asset prices

follow over their life rather than asset’s value at expiration. The path of the underlying

determines payoff and structure of the options. Path dependent options are further

divided into weak and strong path dependent options. In strong path dependency, the

payoff depends on some property of the asset price path along with the value of the

underlying at present moment of time and some other extra variable (Wilmot 2007,

p252). Examples of strong path dependent options are

3.2.1 Asian options

Asian options are examples of strong path dependent options. In Asian options the

payoff is determined by comparing the strike/ spot price of the underlying with the

10 Das divided exotic options into five classes while Wilmott into six categories.

Page 21: Valuation of Structured Products

20

average value of strike/ spot price during a specific period of time. They are strongly

path dependent because their value prior to expiry depends on the path taken and not

just where they have reached. Asian options were originated from Tokyo office of the

bankers trust in 1987. Asian options are normally cheaper than the plain vanilla options

because averages are less volatile and therefore less risky. Average can be calculated by

means of arithmetic, or geometric average of the prices. In Asian options

• There is a specific period over which the prices are taken. End of the averaging

interval can be shorter than or equal to the options expiration date, the starting

value can be any time before. In particular, after an average option is traded, the

beginning of the averaging period typically lies in the past, so that parts of the

values contributing to the average are already known.

• The market generally uses discrete sampling, like daily fixing.

• Weighting different weights may be assigned to the prices to account for a non-

linear, i.e. skewed, price distribution

• The wide range of variations covers also the possible right for early execution.

Asian options are popular in risk management for currencies and commodities because

they provide protection against rapid price movements or manipulation in thinly traded

underlying at maturity, i.e. reduction of significance of the closing price through

averaging. These options reduce hedging costs because they are cheaper than standard

options. Average Price Options can be used to hedge a stream of (received) payments

(e.g. a USD average call can be bought to hedge the ongoing EUR revenues of a US

based company). Different amounts of the payments can be reflected in flexible

weights, i.e. the prices related to higher payments are assigned a higher weight than

those related to smaller cash flows when calculating the average. With Average Strike

Options the strike price can be set at the average of the underlying price which is a

helpful structure in volatile or hardly predictable markets.

An average price call pays (AT – K) +, where AT denotes the geometric or arithmetic

average price of the underlying𝑆𝑡𝑖. The geometric average of the underlying can be

calculated as

𝐺𝑒𝑜𝑚𝑒𝑡𝑟𝑖𝑐 𝑀𝑒𝑎𝑛 = �∏ 𝑆𝑡𝑖𝑛𝑖=0

𝑛 (4)

Page 22: Valuation of Structured Products

21

And the arithmetic or the simple average can be calculated as

𝐴𝑇 = 1𝑛

∑ 𝑆𝑡𝑖𝑛𝑖=0 (5)

Week path dependency means that the option depends only on the underlying price and

the time. Barrier options are examples of week path dependent options. The payoff in

these options depends on if the underlying hits a pre specified value at some time before

expiry.

3.2.2 Lookback options

In these options the purchaser has the right at expiration to set the strike price of the

options at the most favorable price for the asset that has occurred during a specified

time. In a lookback call option, the buyer can choose to buy the underlying asset at the

lowest price that has occurred over a specified period, typically the life of the option.

Details about lookback options can be found in Fx options and structured products by

Uwe Wystrup.

3.2.3 Ladder options

The strike price in these options is periodically reset based on the underlying evolution

of the asset price. A ladder option can be identical to lookback when the amount of reset

is set to infinity.

3.2.4 Barrier options

Barrier options are weekly path dependent options. Das also classified them as limit

dependent options because their payoff depends on the realized asset path via its level.

Certain aspects of the contract are triggered if the asset price becomes too high or too

low. For example, an up- and – out call option pays off the usual max (S-K, 0) at expiry

unless at any time previously the underlying asset has traded at a value Su or higher. It

means if the asset reaches this level then it is said to ‘knock out’ and become worthless.

The option can also be “knocked in” instead of “Knock out”, where the payoff is

received only if the level is reached (Wilmott 2007, P288). Barrier options can be

divided into two types (out option and in option) i.e. up- and – out, down- and- out, up-

and- in and down- and- in.

Page 23: Valuation of Structured Products

22

• The ‘out option’ pays off only if a specified level is not reached. Otherwise the

option is said to have knocked out and becomes worthless.

• The ‘in option’ pays off as long as the level is reached before expiry. If the

barrier is reached then it is said to have knocked in. In options contracts starts

worthless and only become active when the predetermined barrier is reached.

If the barrier is set above the initial asset value then it is said to have an ‘up option’ and

if the barrier is set below the initial asset value then it is said to have ‘down option’

Barrier options generally are of American style. It means that the barrier level is active

during the entire duration of the option: any time between today and maturity the spot

hits the barrier, the option becomes worthless. If the barrier level is only active at

maturity the barrier option is of European style and can in fact be replicated by a

vertical spread and a digital option.

Apart from a lower or an upper barrier, double barrier options are also available. Double

barrier options have both upper and lower barrier. In double ‘out’ option the contract

becomes worthless if either of the barriers is reached. In a double ‘in’ option one of the

barriers must be reached before expiry, otherwise the option expires worthless.

In some cases a so called rebate is paid if for example in an ‘out’ option the barrier level

is reached. The rebate may be paid as soon as the barrier is triggered or not until expiry.

The above mentioned barrier options are standard in nature. The barrier options can also

have exotic type features for example resetting of barrier, outside barrier options, soft

barriers and Parisian options. Detail discussion can be found in Wilmott 2007, p300.

3.3 Time dependent options

In time dependent options the buyer has the right to nominate a specific characteristic of

the option as a function of time for example the expiration of the option. Preference or

chooser option is an example of time dependent option. In a chooser option, at a

predetermined date (normally after commencement and before expiry) the buyer can

choose if the contract should be a call or a put option. Bermudan options are also

example of time dependent options, where early exercise of the option is possible on

certain dates or periods.

Page 24: Valuation of Structured Products

23

3.4 Multifactor options

In multi factor options, the payoff depends on the relationship between multiple assets.

It means there is second source of randomness such as a second underlying asset.

Compound, basket, exchange, quanto, rainbow are the examples of multifactor options.

In Compound options (options on options), the holder has the right but not an obligation

to buy or sell another predetermined options at a pre agreed time. The compound

options can be a call on a call, a put on a put, a call on a put and put on a call.

Compound options have two strike prices and two exercise dates. For examples in a call

on a call option, on the first exercise date T1, the holder of the compound option is

entitled to pay the first strike price K1, and receive a call option. This call option gives

him the right to buy the underlying asset for the second strike price K2 on the second

exercise date. The compound option will be exercised on the first exercise date only if

the value of the option on the date is greater than the first strike price.

In basket options the payoff is based on the cumulative performance of the underlying

assets and in exchange options the holder has the right to exchange one asset for

another. The underlying assets can be individual stocks or stock indices, currencies or

commodities etc. If the payoff is determined on performance of maximum or minimum

of two more underlying assets, then these option are named as Rainbow option. A

quanto option can be any cash-settled option, whose payoff is converted into another

currency at maturity than that of the underlying asset at a pre-specified rate, called the

quanto factor. There can be quanto plain vanilla, quanto barriers, quanto forward starts,

quanto corridors, etc.

3.5 Payoff modified options

These options entail adjustment to the linear and smooth payoffs that are associated

with conventional options (Das 2001, p723). Examples include

• Digital options: Digital options have discontinuous payouts irrespective of the

normal options whose payoffs are smooth. In a normal option, if it is further in

the money the higher the payout to the purchaser. While in digital option the

payout is normally fixed provided if certain conditioned are met. For examples,

in the typical structure of digital option, if the strike price is reached the payouts

Page 25: Valuation of Structured Products

24

are fixed predetermined amounts no matter how much the option is in the

money.

• Contingent premium: A contingent premium option is basically a European

option. The premium will be paid to the writer if the contingent premium option

finishes "in the money". Otherwise, if the option expires "at the money" then, no

premium will be paid. It means no premium is paid in the beginning of the

contract and is due at expiration of the options only if it expires in the money. In

other words, the contingent premium structure is a combination of a

conventional option and a digital option.

• Power options: A power option is a derivative with payoff depending on the asset

price at expiry raised to some power α, where α is higher than 1.

Page 26: Valuation of Structured Products

25

4 Option Pricing Theory

This section will discuss the underlying concepts in Black & Scholes option pricing

theory. For example, the assumption of model, stochastic process, Markove property,

generalized Wienner process, geometric Brownian motion, Ito’s lemma, risk neutral

evaluation and finally the Black & Scholes option pricing formulae are discussed.

4.1 Assumptions

The famous Black and Scholes (B&S) model has several underlying assumptions like

other option pricing models. The understanding of these assumptions will help to

analyze the advantages and the drawbacks of the model. The underlying assumptions

are discussed below

1. The markets are efficient i.e. the markets are assumed to be liquid. There is price

continuity. The markets are fair and provide all information to all the players. It

means no transaction costs in buying or selling stock or options.

2. The underlying is perfectly divisible and short selling is allowed. A seller who

does not own a security will simply accept the price of the security from a buyer

and will agree to settle with buyer on the same future date by paying him an

amount equal to the price of the security on that date

3. There are no costs of carrying to the commodity (evaporation, obsolescence,

insurance etc) and that the commodity is held for speculative purposes like a

stock.

4. The commodity price, firm value and the interest rate follow continuous time

diffusion processes. It means that the interest rate is known and it is constant

(risk free) through time (Schwartz 1982). In other words there exists a risk free

security that returns $1 at time T when 1e-r(T-t) is invested at time T.

5. The stock/commodity price follows a random walk in continuous time

(geometric Brownian motion) with a variance rate proportional to the square of

the price. Thus the distribution of the possible stock/ commodity price at the end

of any infinite interval is log normal and the variance rate of the return on the

stock/ commodity is constant

6. The model deals with European style options only that can be exercised at

maturity only.

Page 27: Valuation of Structured Products

26

4.2 Stochastic Process

We know that the prices of commodities, stocks and interest rates etc change over time

in the financial markets. If the change in value is uncertain over time i.e. if the change in

price of a commodity, equity or currency exchange is unpredictable over time then this

kind of price behavior is called a stochastic process. In other words any variable whose

value changes over time in an uncertain way is said to follow a stochastic process (Hull

2008, p 259) and it can be discrete time and continuous time stochastic process. In a

discrete time process the value of a variable is assumed to change at fixed time intervals

of time, while changes can take place at any time in a continuous time stochastic

process.

4.2.1 Properties of a stochastic process

4.2.2 The Markov Property

A stochastic process is said to have the Markov property, when only the present value

of a variable is relevant to predict its future value (Hull 2008, p 259) i.e. the process has

no memory beyond where it is now. It means that the past history of that variable and

pattern of changes in value would be irrelevant to predict future prices. So it means that

to predict the future price of a commodity bundle, the only relevant price will be the

today’s price and it will be independent of its price during the last week or year.

4.2.3 Wiener Process

Wiener process is a particular type of Markov process which has a mean change of zero

and a variance rate of 1.0 per year. Wiener process is also called Brownian motion

(named after a Scottish botanist Robert Brown). Brownian motion has been used in physics

to describe the motion of the particle that is subject to a large number of small molecular

shocks. It is among the simplest type of continuous stochastic process. In mathematical finance,

this concept was first used by Louis Bachelier during the 1900 in his PHD thesis, where he

presented the stochastic analysis of stock and option markets

A variable Z follows a Wiener process if it has the following two properties (Hull 2008,

p261)

1. The change ∆Z during a small period of time ∆t will be

Page 28: Valuation of Structured Products

27

∆𝑍 = 𝜀 √∆𝑡 (6)

Here, ε has a standardized normal distribution with mean zero and standard deviation of

1, that is; N (0, 1).

2. The values of ∆ Z for any two different short interval of time ∆t are independent.

It means that Z has independent increments and ∆Z 1 is independent of ∆Z2 if ∆t1

does not overlap with ∆t2.

The first property shows that ∆ Z has a normal distribution with i.e.

Mean of ∆ Z = Z (t) – Z (0) = 0

Standard deviation of ∆ Z = √∆𝑡

And variance of ∆ Z = ∆ t

The Wiener process is both the Markov and Martingale process (zero drift stochastic

process). By martingale process, it means that the expected value at any future time is

equal to its value today. Martingale property is an important part of the risk neutral

evaluation.

4.2.4 Generalized Wiener Process

It is clear from the Wiener process that if we choose it as a model then the stock/

commodity price can take negative values at any point in time with a probability of 0.5

and it will have a constant zero mean and it is not an ideal model to price stock prices.

So we have to consider a better model called Generalized Wiener Process. The basic

Wiener Process also states that ∆Z has a zero drift rate and a variance rate of 1.0. Zero

drift means that the expected value of Z at any future time is equal to its current value

and the variance rate of 1.0 means that the change in a time interval of length T equals

T. Here we consider a discrete time random walk

X0 = x, Xi = Xi-1 + a ∆t + b √∆t εi where ε i ~ N (0, 1)

And the increments are given by ∆ Xi = a ∆t + b √∆t εi

Page 29: Valuation of Structured Products

28

Here ‘a’ is the constant drift rate and ‘b’ is the volatility rate. When we take smaller and

smaller time steps ∆t, then the above equation can be written as

𝑋 (𝑡) = 𝑥 + 𝑎 𝑡 + 𝑏 𝑍 (𝑡) (7)

The above equation is called the Generalized Wiener Process. The above equation can

be written in the differential form as follows

𝑑𝑋 = 𝑎 𝑑𝑡 + 𝑏 𝑑𝑍 (8)

So for a stock price we can conclude that

• Its expected percentage change in a short period of time remains constant, not

it’s expected absolute change in a short period of time.

• The size of the future stock price movements is proportional to the level of the

stock price

4.2.4 Geometric Brownian motion

Generalized wiener process fails to capture a key aspect of the stock / commodity prices

i.e. the percentage return required by the investors is independent of the stock price. It

means that the investor will demand the same return, does not matter if the stock price is

DKK 10 or DKK 100. So, the assumption of constant expected drift rate needs to be

replaced by the assumption that expected return (i.e. expected drift divided by the stock

price) is constant. So, if P is the price of a commodity bundle at time t, then the

expected drift rate in P should be assumed to be µP for some constant parameter µ. It

means that the expected increase in P (in a short period of time ∆t) is µP ∆t. The

parameter µ is the expected rate of return on the price, expressed in decimal form.

If the volatility of the commodity price is zero, then the model implies that

∆P = µ P∆t And as ∆t approaches to zero then

dP = µP dt or 𝑑𝑃𝑃

= 𝜇 𝑑𝑡 (9)

Integrating the equation (7) between 0 and time T, we get

Page 30: Valuation of Structured Products

29

𝑃𝑇 = 𝑃0 𝑒𝜇𝑇 (10)

PT and P0 are the commodity prices at time T and time 0 respectively. This equation

shows that when variance rate is zero, the commodity price grows at a continuously

compounded rate of µ per unit of time. But in practice, commodity prices or stock prices

exhibit volatility. Here it can be assumed that the variation in the percentage return in

short period of time ∆t is the same regardless of the commodity price. It means that the

investor is just as uncertain of the percentage return when the price is DKK 100 as when

it is DKK 10. It means that the standard deviation of the change in a short period of time

∆t should be proportional to the commodity price and it can be written as follows

𝑑𝑃 = 𝜇 𝑃𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎𝑃 𝑑𝑧

Or 𝑑𝑃𝑃

= 𝜇 𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎 𝑑𝑧 P > 0 (11)

This equation is called the Geometric Brownian motion. The important feature of this

equation is that the commodity or stock price will never become negative.

4.2.6 Ito’s Lemma

Ito’s lemma is the most important rule of stochastic calculus. It was discovered by the

mathematician K. Ito in 1951. According to Ito’s lemma the ordinary rules of calculus

do not apply to the stochastic processes For example, consider a function F(Z) = Z2

where Z is a Brownian motion. Then according to ordinary calculus, dF (Z) = 2ZdZ.

But this is not true for stochastic processes. In order to drive rules for stochastic

calculus, we have to apply Taylor expansion i.e.

𝑑𝐹 = 𝑑𝐹𝑑𝑍𝑑𝑍 + 1

2𝑑2𝐹𝑑𝑍2

𝑑𝑡…….. (12)

So from the F (Z) = Z2 we have 𝑑𝐹𝑑𝑍

= 2Z and 𝑑2𝐹𝑑𝑍2

= 2 substituting these values in the

above Taylor expression we get 𝑑𝐹 = 2𝑍𝑑𝑍 + 𝑑𝑡

Now we consider the Geometric Brownian motion equation i.e.

𝑑𝑃 = 𝜇 𝑃𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎𝑃 𝑑𝑧 (13)

Page 31: Valuation of Structured Products

30

Here 𝑎 (𝑃, 𝑡) = 𝜇𝑃 𝑎𝑛𝑑 𝑏(𝑃, 𝑡) = 𝜎𝑃

Now consider the function 𝐹(𝑃) = log𝑃

Then 𝑑(𝑙𝑜𝑔𝑃)𝑑𝑃

= 1𝑃

𝑎𝑛𝑑 𝑑2(logP)𝑑𝑃2 = − 1

𝑃2

And by Ito’s lemma 𝑑𝐹 = 𝑑𝐹𝑑𝑃𝑑𝑃 + 1

2𝑏2(𝑡,𝑃) 𝑑2𝑃

𝑑𝑝2𝑑𝑡 and substituting the values we

obtain 𝑑𝐹 = 1𝑃𝑑𝑃 − 1

2𝜎2𝑃2 ∗ 1

𝑃2 𝑑𝑡 (14)

And substituting equation (13) in equation (14), we get

𝑑𝐹 = 𝜇 𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎 𝑑𝑧 − 12𝜎2 𝑑𝑡

Or 𝑑𝐹 = �𝜇 − 12𝜎2� 𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎 𝑑𝑧 (15)

Since 𝜎 and 𝜇 constant, this equation shows that F= log P follows a generalized Wiener

process. It has a constant drift rate of �𝜇 − 12𝜎2� and constant variance rate of 𝜎2. The

change in ln P between time 0 and some future time T is therefore normally distributed

with mean �𝜇 − 12𝜎2� and variance 𝜎2𝑇. It means that

ln𝑃𝑡 ~∅ �𝑙𝑛𝑃0 + �𝜇 − 𝜎2

2� 𝑇,𝜎2𝑇� (16)

Equation (16) shows that 𝑃𝑡 is normally distributed. A variable has a lognormal

distribution if the natural logarithm of variable is normally distributed. This model

implies that that the price of a commodity bundle/ stock price at time T, given the price

today, are log normally distributed. The standard deviation of the stock price is𝜎√𝑇. It

is proportional to the square root of how far ahead we are looking (Hull 2007, p 271).

4.2.7 Risk Neutral Valuation

Risk- neutral valuation is an important concept in option pricing and particularly while

deriving the famous Black- Scholes option pricing equation. According to this principal

we can assume that the world is risk neutral when pricing options. It means that present

value of any cash flow can be obtained by discounting its expected future value at risk

Page 32: Valuation of Structured Products

31

free interest rate. So, in order to calculate the payoff of a derivative at particular time by

risk neutral valuation we assume that expected future return from the underlying asset is

the risk free interest rate “r”, that is, 𝜇 = 𝑟. Then we have to calculate the expected

payoff from the derivative and finally discount this expected payoff at the risk free

interest rate. In a risk- neutral world all individual investors are indifferent to risk and

they require no compensation (premium) for risk and the expected return on all

securities is the risk free interest rate. The solutions obtained in the risk- neutral world

also hold in the real world (risk- averse world) because in the risk-averse assumption

the expected growth rate in the stock price changes and discount rate that must be used

for any payoffs from the derivative changes. It happens that these two changes always

offset each other exactly (Hull 2007, p290).

5 The Black- Scholes Equation (BS)

The Black- Scholes model was derived by Fischer Black and Myron Scholes in the

early 1970s for the pricing of stock options. Robert Merton also participated in the

creation of this novel model. Therefore, sometimes, this model is also named as the

Black- Scholes- Merton model. This model was perhaps the biggest breakthrough in the

field of option pricing and rapidly got its acceptance among the financial engineers. The

success of financial engineering in the last 30 years is highly because of this model. In

1997, Myron Scholes and Robert Merton because of creating this model were also

awarded the Nobel Prize for economics.

The BS model shows that the value of an option depends on two factors i.e. the stock

price and the time to expiry/ maturity provided that the ideal market conditions

discussed earlier hold. Therefore, it is possible to create a hedge position by having a

long position in one option and a short position by some amount ∆ in the underlying ,

whose value will not depend on the stock price. If this portfolio is hedged continuously

then the portfolio of these two will be risk free and the expected return will be the risk

free interest rate. The riskless portfolio can be created because stock price and the

derivative price are both affected by the same underlying source of uncertainty i.e.

stock/ commodity price movements. In any short period of time, the price of the

derivative is perfectly correlated with the price of the underlying (Hull 2007, p285).

Page 33: Valuation of Structured Products

32

In order to find the value “f” of a derivative written on an asset by BS model, the stock/

commodity price P follows geometric Brownian motion given in equation (11). In

general, the value f will be a function of many parameters in the contract i.e.

f (P, t, σ, μ,K,T, r )

Here

• P and T are variables

• σ and μ are associated with the underlying asset’s price

• Strike price K and time to maturity T depends on the specific details of the

contract.

• And interest rate r depends on the currency in which the asset is quoted.

We assume here that value of an option is a function of time t and current price P of the

underlying and drop the other parameters. Therefore we can write as follows

f (P, t )

To begin with we assume that we know the value f of the option and

• Form a portfolio, which we hold for a period of length dt, by taking a long position

in the option and a short position of a quantity Δ in the underlying.

• Determine the quantity Δ so that our portfolio is risk-free over a time period of

length dt.

• By a no arbitrage argument, the rate of return of this risk-free portfolio must be

equal to the risk-free interest rate r. What comes out of this restriction is an equation

whose solution is the option price f.

Suppose we know the value of the option f (P, t) at time t and Π denote the value of a

portfolio consisting of a long position in the option and a short position in a quantity Δ,

delta, of the underlying

Π(𝑡) = 𝑓 (𝑃, 𝑡) − Δ · 𝑃 (17)

In equation (12), the term f (P, t) is the option part of the portfolio and Δ · P is the short

asset position (negative sign).

Page 34: Valuation of Structured Products

33

During the next time period of length dt the change in the portfolio value is given by

𝑑Π = 𝑑𝑓 (𝑃, 𝑡) − Δ · 𝑑𝑃 (18)

(Δ is fixed during the period t, t + dt). The portfolio Π is self financing, replicating, and

hedging strategy. It replicates a risk free investment. There is no stochastic term,

therefore it is hedged.

From Ito’s lemma we can compute df and we get

𝑑𝑓(𝑃, 𝑡) = 𝜕𝑓𝜕𝑡𝑑𝑡 + 𝜕𝑓

𝜕𝑃𝑑𝑃 + 1

2𝜎2𝑃2 𝜕

2𝑓𝜕𝑃2

𝑑𝑡 (19)

Substituting equation (19) into equation (18), we get

d Π = 𝜕𝑓𝜕𝑡𝑑𝑡 + 𝜕𝑓

𝜕𝑃𝑑𝑃 + 1

2𝜎2𝑃2 𝜕

2𝑓𝜕𝑃2

𝑑𝑡 - Δ · dP

Re-arranging the above equation,

𝑑 Π = �𝜕𝑓𝜕𝑡

+ 12𝜎2𝑃2 𝜕

2𝑓𝜕𝑃2

�𝑑𝑡 + �𝜕𝑓𝜕𝑃− ∆�𝑑𝑃 (20)

In the right hand side of equation (20), the expression containing the term dt is the

deterministic term while the with dP is random. The random term is the risk factor in

the portfolio. The risk in the portfolio can be removed if

�𝜕𝑓𝜕𝑃− ∆� = 0 (21)

I.e. if, for the small period of time from t to t + dt, we choose the quantity Δ as

𝜕𝑓𝜕𝑃

= ∆ (22)

Therefore, equation (17) becomes

Π(𝑡) = 𝑓 (𝑃, 𝑡) − 𝜕𝑓𝜕𝑃

𝑃 (23)

Then the randomness reduces to zero. The reduction in randomness is called hedging.

The perfect elimination of risk by exploiting correlation between two instruments

Page 35: Valuation of Structured Products

34

(option and the underlying in our portfolio) is called Delta hedging (Wilmott, p142).

Delta hedging is an example of perfect hedging. It means if we are allowed at any point

in time t to continuously re-balance our portfolio by choosing the quantity Δ in the

underlying (i.e. if we are entitled to continuous trading), then we have constructed a

portfolio which is risk-less and with dynamics given by

𝑑 Π = �𝜕𝑓𝜕𝑡

+ 12𝜎2𝑃2 𝜕

2𝑓𝜕𝑃2

�𝑑𝑡 (24)

If there are no arbitrage opportunities in our market, then it must hold that our risk-less

portfolio should yield the risk-free interest rate r, i.e.

𝑑 Π = 𝑟 Π 𝑑𝑡 (25)

Substituting the values of d Π and Π from equation 24, and 23 in equation 25 we get

�𝜕𝑓𝜕𝑡

+ 12𝜎2𝑃2 𝜕

2𝑓𝜕𝑃2

�𝑑𝑡 = 𝑟 �𝑓 − 𝜕𝑓𝜕𝑃𝑃� 𝑑𝑡

After re-arranging the above equation we get

𝜕𝑓𝜕𝑡

+ 12𝜎2𝑃2 𝜕

2𝑓𝜕𝑃2

+ 𝑟 𝜕𝑓𝜕𝑃𝑃 − 𝑟𝑓 = 0 (26)

Equation (26) is the famous BS equation. The price of any option which depends on P

and t must satisfy the BS equation otherwise it cannot be price of the derivative without

creating arbitrage opportunities for the traders. BS equation is a linear parabolic partial

differential equation. By the term linear means, if we have two solutions of the equation

then the sum of the two solutions is itself a solution. Parabolic means it has a second

order derivative with respect to one variable P and a first order derivative with respect

to the variable t. Therefore equations of this type are called heat or diffusion equations

of mechanics (Wilmott 2007, p158).

The BS equation shows that value of a stock option when expressed in terms of the

value of the underlying, does not depend on drift rate or expected return µ. This is

dropped out when the dP term is eliminated from the portfolio. It is also clear from this

Page 36: Valuation of Structured Products

35

equation that the variables appear in this equation (stock price, time, volatility and risk-

free interest rate) are all independent of risk preferences.

Another point to be noted from equation (26) is that we can not see whether this

equation is valuing a call or a put option. It means we will have to specify the final

conditions and specify the option value f as a function of the underlying at expiry date

T. For example, if we have a call option, then we know that f(P,T) = max( P- K, 0) and

for a put option the final condition will be f(P,T) = max(K- S, 0)

5.1 Options on dividend paying stock

Let q be the amount of continuous and constant dividend yield. Then equation (26) can

be re-written as

𝜕𝑓𝜕𝑡

+ 12𝜎2𝑃2 𝜕

2𝑓𝜕𝑃2

+ (𝑟 − 𝑞) 𝜕𝑓𝜕𝑃𝑃 − 𝑟𝑓 = 0 (27)

5.2 Commodity Options

Options are called commodity options when the underlying is a commodity or

commodities. Commodity options differ from the security options in the way that it

cannot be exercised before the future fixed (expiry) date. Therefore, in a European

option rather than an American style option11

𝜕𝑓𝜕𝑡

+ 12𝜎2𝑃2 𝜕

2𝑓𝜕𝑃2

+ (𝑟 + 𝑞) 𝜕𝑓𝜕𝑃𝑃 − 𝑟𝑓 = 0 (28)

, the holder of the commodity option can

choose whether or not he wants to buy the commodity at the specified price. Then we

have to adjust the general BS equation (26). Commodities have the cost of carry. That

is, the commodities cannot be held without storage cost. So, if we assume that q is the

storage cost associated with the commodity, which means that if we simply hold the

commodity, it will lose value even if the price remains fixed. It means that for each unit

of commodity held an amount qP dt will be required during the short period of time dt

to finance the holding (like a negative dividend). Therefore, equation (26) can be

modified as follows (Wilmott, p148)

11 F. Black, The Pricing of Commodity Contracts, Journal of financial Economics, 3 (March 1976)

Page 37: Valuation of Structured Products

36

The BS model can also be derived in many other ways instead of the classical risk-

neutral valuation. For example the Martingale approach, the binomial model and capital

asset pricing model (CAPM)

5.3 Options on many underlying

Options with many underlying assets are called basket options, options on baskets or

rainbow options. The basket can be any weighted sum of the underlying assets as long

as the weights are all positive. The value of these options depends on price, time to

maturity and additional variable i.e. the correlation between assets in the basket. The

payoff from the basket depend on the degree of correlation among the underlying assets

i.e. if the underlying assets are highly correlated with each other, then the option’s

payoff will be high and vice versa. The basic option pricing with one underlying can be

extended to more than one underlying too. First of all the idea of lognormal random

walk needed to be extended for multiple assets. I.e. The geometric Brownian motion of

an asset price (equation 11) can be easily extended to multiple assets. Therefore,

equation 11 can be written as

𝑑𝑃𝑖 = 𝜇𝑖𝑃 𝑖𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎𝑖𝑃𝑖𝑑𝑍𝑖 (29)

Here 𝑃𝑖 is the price of ith asset, i= 1, 2, 3…..,d and 𝜇𝑖 and 𝜎𝑖 are the drift and volatility

of the assets and dZ is the Wiener process for the respective asset. dZi can be still

considered to be as a random number drawn from normal distribution with a mean of

zero and a standard deviation of dt0,05 i.e .

𝐸[𝑑𝑍𝑖] = 0 𝑎𝑛𝑑 𝐸 �𝑑𝑍𝑖2 � = 𝑑𝑡

In baskets options, the assets are also correlated with each other, therefore the log

normal random walks are also considered to be correlated with each other. That is

𝐸[𝑑𝑍𝑖𝑑𝑍𝑗] = 𝜌𝑖𝑗𝑑𝑡

Here 𝜌𝑖𝑗 is the correlation coefficient between ith and jth random walks. The symmetric

matrix with ρij as the entry in the ith row and jth column is called the correlation matrix.

For example, if we have a basket option with three underlying assets i.e. n = 3 and the

correlation matrix can be written as

Page 38: Valuation of Structured Products

37

1 𝜌12 𝜌13𝜌21 1 𝜌23𝜌31 𝜌32 1

Here, 𝜌𝑖𝑖 = 1 𝑎𝑛𝑑 𝜌𝑖𝑗 = 𝜌𝑗𝑖. The correlation matrix is positive definite.

We can apply multi dimensional ito’s lemma to manipulate functions of many random

variables. So, if we a have a function of variables Pn where n= 1, 2, 3 ….. And time t,

then 𝑑𝑓 = � 𝛿𝑓𝛿𝑡

+ 12∑𝑑𝑖=1 ∑ 𝜎𝑖𝑑

𝑗=1 𝜎𝑗𝜌𝑖𝑗𝑃𝑖𝑃𝑗𝜕2𝑓𝜕𝑃𝑖𝑃𝑗

� 𝑑𝑡 + ∑ 𝜕𝑉𝜕𝑃𝑖

𝑑𝑖=1 𝑑𝑃𝑖 (30)

The pricing model for basket options following BS model can be derived in the same

way as for the single asset, i.e. by setting up a portfolio consisting of one basket option

and short a number ∆ o f each o f th e asset p rice P in th e basket. Employ the

multidimensional Ito’s Lemma, take Δi = ∂V/∂Pi to eliminate the risk, and set the

return of the portfolio equal to the risk-free rate. We are able to arrive at the multi

dimensional version of the Black and Scholes equation (Wilmott 2007, p277)

�𝛿𝑓𝛿𝑡

+ 12∑𝑑𝑖=1 ∑ 𝜎𝑖𝑑

𝑗=1 𝜎𝑗𝜌𝑖𝑗𝑃𝑖𝑃𝑗𝜕2𝑓𝜕𝑃𝑖𝑃𝑗

� + 𝑟 ∑ 𝜕𝑉𝜕𝑃𝑖

𝑑𝑖=1 𝑃𝑖 − 𝑟𝑓 = 0 (31)

5.4 Black- Scholes Pricing Formulas

Consider now the case of a call option with maturity T and strike price K written on a

stock / commodity paying no dividends. Assume that we stand at time t, that the current

price of the underlying is P0, that the interest rate is r and that the volatility of the stock

is σ. Here P follows geometric Brownian motion described by equation (11).

Then we know that

𝐶 = 𝑒−𝑟(𝑇−𝑡)𝐸[max(𝑃 − 𝐾) , 0] (32)

Recalling, we know that P follows a lognormal distribution with mean

�𝜇 − 12𝜎2� 𝑎𝑛𝑑 𝑣𝑎𝑟𝑖𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 𝑜𝑓 𝜎2𝑇 and

𝐸 [𝑃] = 𝑃𝑒𝑟(𝑇−𝑡) (33)

Page 39: Valuation of Structured Products

38

Then value of the European call option can written as

𝐶 = 𝑃0 𝑁(𝑑1) − 𝐾𝑒−𝑟(𝑇−𝑡)𝑁(𝑑2) (34)

Equation (34) can also be written as

𝐶 = 𝑒−𝑟(𝑇−𝑡)[𝑃0 𝑁(𝑑1)𝑒𝑟(𝑇−𝑡) − 𝐾𝑁(𝑑2)] (35)

Where N(.) is the cumulative probability distribution function for standardized normal

distribution and

𝑑1 =ln�P0K �+�r+

σ2

2 �(T−t)

σ√T−t

And 𝑑2 = 𝑑1 − 𝜎√𝑇 − 𝑡

N(d2) is the probability that the option will be exercised (P > K) in a risk- neutral world

so that KN(d2) i.e. strike price times the probability that the strike price will be paid.

The expression 𝑃0 𝑁(𝑑1)𝑒𝑟(𝑇−𝑡) is the expected value in risk- neutral of a variable

which is equal to PT if PT > K and to zero otherwise. We can also say that the expected

value of the call option at maturity will be 𝑃0 𝑁(𝑑1)𝑒𝑟(𝑇−𝑡) − 𝐾𝑁(𝑑2).

The value of a European put option P on a non dividend paying underlying can be

written as

𝑃𝑢𝑡 𝑜𝑝𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛 𝑣𝑎𝑙𝑢𝑒 = −𝑃0 𝑁(−𝑑1) + 𝐾𝑒−𝑟(𝑇−𝑡)𝑁(−𝑑2) (36)

The value of European call and put option on dividend paying stocks can be written as

𝐶 = 𝑃0 𝑒−𝑞(𝑇−𝑡)𝑁(𝑑1) − 𝐾𝑒−𝑟(𝑇−𝑡)𝑁(𝑑2) (37)

𝑃𝑢𝑡 𝑜𝑝𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛 𝑣𝑎𝑙𝑢𝑒 = −𝑃0 𝑒−𝑞(𝑇−𝑡)𝑁(−𝑑1) + 𝐾𝑒−𝑟(𝑇−𝑡)𝑁(−𝑑2) (38)

5.5 Upper and Lower bounds for the call option

Structured products have in general embedded call options and therefore it is important

to evaluate whether the prices of call option follows the no-arbitrage argument. We

know that call price has boundary conditions (upper and lower bounds). Boundary

Page 40: Valuation of Structured Products

39

conditions tell us how the solution must behave for all time at certain values of the asset

(Wilmott 2007, P159). If an option is above the upper bound or below the lower bound,

then there exist arbitrage opportunities for investors. So from equation (37), the lower

bound for a call option can be written as

𝐶 + 𝐾𝑒−𝑟(𝑇−𝑡)𝑁(𝑑2) ≥ 𝑃0 𝑒−𝑞(𝑇−𝑡)𝑁(𝑑1) Or

𝐶 ≥ 𝑃0 𝑒−𝑞(𝑇−𝑡)𝑁(𝑑1) − 𝐾𝑒−𝑟(𝑇−𝑡)𝑁(𝑑2)

And the upper bound for call option is given by

𝐶 ≤ 𝑃0

It means that the option value is always less than the corresponding underlying asset or

the underlying asset is always worth more than the corresponding call option.

Therefore, stock price is an upper bound to the option price. Similarly, for a put option,

the option can never be worth more than the strike price i.e. it can not be worth more

than the present value of K today (Hull 2008, p206). If it is not true, then the arbitrageur

could make riskless profit by writing the option and investing the proceeds of the sale at

the risk free interest rate.

𝑝 ≤ 𝐾 𝑜𝑟 𝑝 ≤ 𝐾 exp (−𝑟𝑇)

5.6 Forward Contract

A forward contract is an agreement to buy or sell the asset P at a future date T (delivery

date) for a fixed price K (delivery price). The payoff from a long position of forward

contract is therefore

𝑉(𝑃,𝑇) = 𝑃 − 𝐾 (39)

The delivery price K is typically delivered so that at initiation the contract has value

zero. By no arbitrage argument we have

𝐾 = 𝑒𝑟𝑇𝑃0 (40)

Page 41: Valuation of Structured Products

40

A forward contact sometimes also called a cash forward sale. There are some

disadvantages associated with the forward contracts i.e.

• Default risk, particularly if the prices are either high or low by the delivery date,

which negate the main value of a forward contract- price certainty

• The only way to legally terminate a contract was by mutual agreement, which would

be unlikely when the market price was significantly different from the delivery

price;

• There was no easy way to resell the contract, because it had customized terms that

specifically suited the seller and buyer—hence, forward contracts were highly

illiquid.

Eventually, organized exchanges developed that solved these basic problems. To lower

the risk of default, the exchanges required that money to be deposited with a 3rd party to

ensure the performance of the contract. The exchanges also standardized the contracts

by stipulating the types of contracts that they would sell, including its terms.

Standardized contracts were easier to sell or to offset with another contract that

eliminated the liability of the original contract. Standard specifications include the

amount of the commodity, the grade, and delivery dates. These standard forward

contracts were called futures, and the exchanges developed listings for these contracts

that greatly increased their liquidity.

5.7 Futures contracts

A futures contract is an agreement between two parties to buy or sell an asset at a

certain time in the future for a certain price, the current futures price of the asset.

Futures contracts are similar to forward contracts, but the principal difference lies in the

way payments are being made. In a forward contract, the whole gain or loss is realized

at the end of the life of the contract. But in case of the futures contract, the gain or loss

is realized day by day through a mechanism known as marking to market.

In mark to market mechanism, the contract is settled every day and simultaneously a

new contract, with the same maturity, is written according to the current futures price of

the underlying. Any profit or loss during the day is recorded in the account of the

contract holder. At any point in time, the value of the futures contract itself is therefore

Page 42: Valuation of Structured Products

41

zero (i.e. it is a zero sum game, which means that short side’s loss or gain is the long

side’s gain or loss) , but we have also a capital gain which comes from the previous

days cash settlements. The futures price of an asset, for a given maturity, varies from

day to day, but at maturity it must be the same as the price of the underlying.

In general, at any point in time t the value of the futures contract is zero, but we have a

capital gain given by

Capital gain = change in futures prices = Ft − F0

At the expiry of the contract, the total cash flows will amount to

(ST − FT−1) + · · · + (F2 − F1) + (F1 − F0) = ST − F0

In order to find out the futures price F(P,T) for a futures contract with expiry T on an

asset P, we assume that the price follows Geometric Brownian motion given in equation

(8). We create a portfolio Π consisting of one long futures contract and short Δ of the

underlying. The portfolio value is given by

Π = −ΔP (41)

We know that the value of the futures contract is zero. But, when computing the

portfolio change during the next time period we need to take into account the cash

settlement which is given by the change in the futures price, i.e.

𝑑Π = 𝑑𝐹 – Δ𝑑𝑃 (42)

Applying Ito’s Lemma, we finally get

d Π = 𝜕𝐹𝜕𝑡𝑑𝑡 + 𝜕𝐹

𝜕𝑃𝑑𝑃 + 1

2𝜎2𝑃2 𝜕

2𝐹𝜕𝑃2

𝑑𝑡 - Δ · dP (43)

Assuming that Δ = 𝜕𝐹𝜕𝑃 and to eliminate the risk, the following condition must hold

𝑑Π = 𝑟Π𝑑𝑡 (44)

Substituting equations 41and 43 into 44, we get

Page 43: Valuation of Structured Products

42

𝜕𝐹𝜕𝑡

𝑑𝑡 + 𝜕𝐹𝜕𝑃

𝑑𝑃 + 12𝜎2𝑃2

𝜕2𝐹𝜕𝑃2

𝑑𝑡 − Δ · 𝑑𝑃 = r(−∆P)dt

�𝜕𝐹𝜕𝑡

+ 12𝜎2𝑃2 𝜕

2𝐹𝜕𝑃2

+ r∆P�dt − Δ 𝑑𝑃 + 𝜕𝐹𝜕𝑃𝑑𝑃 = 0

𝜕𝐹𝜕𝑡

+ 12𝜎2𝑃2 𝜕

2𝐹𝜕𝑃2

+ 𝑟𝑃 𝜕𝐹𝜕𝑃

= 0 (45)

The important point to note in equation (45) is that there are only three terms instead of four as

in BS equation. The final condition is

𝐹(𝑃,𝑇) = 𝑃

i.e. The futures price and the underlying must have the same value at maturity.

It can also be shown that 𝐹(𝑡,𝑃) = P𝑒𝑟(𝑇−𝑡)

Since 𝜕𝐹𝜕𝑡

= −𝑟 𝑃𝑒𝑟(𝑇−𝑡) , 𝜕𝐹𝜕𝑃

= 𝑒𝑟(𝑇−𝑡) 𝑎𝑛𝑑 𝜕2𝐹

𝜕𝑃2= 0 and substituting these values in

equation (45) we get zero. It should also be noted here that futures price is equal to the

forward contract if interest rate is considered to be constant.

When we also assume that P follows Geometric Brownian motion (11) and again substituting in

equation 34, we get

𝑑𝐹 = −𝑟𝑃𝑒𝑟(𝑇−𝑡) + 𝑒𝑟(𝑇−𝑡) (𝜇𝑃𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎𝑃𝑑𝑍) Or

𝑑𝐹 = −𝑟𝐹𝑑𝑡 + µ𝐹𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎𝐹𝑑𝑍

𝑑𝐹 = ( 𝜇 − 𝑟)𝐹𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎𝐹𝑑𝑍 (46)

It means that futures price follow Geometric Brownian motion with drift (µ-r). In a risk neutral

world i.e. µ= r, so the above equation becomes

𝑑𝐹 = 𝜎𝐹𝑑𝑍 (47)

5.8 Futures Options

When the underlying of an option is a futures contract, then it is called a futures options

or options on futures. A futures option is the right, but not the obligation, to enter into a

futures contract at a certain futures price by a certain date. If a call option is exercised,

Page 44: Valuation of Structured Products

43

the holder acquires a long position in the underlying futures contract plus a cash amount

equal to the current futures price minus the strike price. If a put option is exercised, the

holder acquires a short position in the underlying futures contract plus a cash amount

equal to the strike price minus the current futures price.

Permanent trading of futures options was approved in 1987, and since then the

popularity of these contracts has grown very fast (Hull 2007, p341). Futures options are

getting popularity because

• The futures contracts are more liquid and easy to trade than the underlying asset.

• A futures price is known immediately from trading on the futures exchange,

while the spot price of the underlying asset may not be so readily available.

• Futures on commodities are easier to trade than the commodities themselves.

• There is lower transaction costs associated with futures options than spot

options.

• Futures options facilitate hedging, arbitrage and speculation, because future

options are usually traded side by side in the same exchange

Futures options are usually settled in cash, because exercising a futures contract does

not lead to delivery of the underlying asset, as in most circumstances the underlying

futures contract is closed out prior to delivery. This is good for investor with limited

capital who may find it difficult to come up with the funds to buy the underlying asset

when an option is exercised Hull 2007, p344).

5.9 Pricing of European futures options

For a European call option with maturity date To, strike price K and written on a futures

contract with expiry Tf > To, the payoff function is given by

𝑚𝑎𝑥[(𝐹(𝑇0,𝑃) − 𝐾), 0]

It can also be written as 𝑚𝑎𝑥 �𝑃((𝑇0)𝑒𝑟�𝑇𝑓−𝑇0� − 𝐾),0� (48)

And for European put option the payoff function is given by

max [�𝐾 − 𝐹(𝑇0,𝑃)�, 0]

Page 45: Valuation of Structured Products

44

Or max �(𝐾 − 𝑃(𝑇0)𝑒𝑟�𝑇𝑓−𝑇0�� , 0]

Here F(T0) is the futures price at maturity. If the futures contract mature at the same

time as the options contract, then F(T0)= P(T0) and the two options are equivalent.

In a risk neutral world, the European futures options can be evaluated by considering

future prices as assets paying dividends at a continuous yield q = r. The price of a

European Call option C and put option P is then given by

𝑐 = 𝐹𝑒−𝑟𝑇𝑁(𝑑1) − 𝐾𝑒−𝑟𝑇𝑁(𝑑2) (49)

𝑝 = 𝑒−𝑟𝑇[𝐾𝑁(−𝑑2) − 𝐹𝑁(−𝑑1)] (50)

Where 𝑁(𝑑1) and 𝑁(𝑑2) are cumulative normal distribution function given by

𝑑1 = ln�𝐹𝑒

−𝑟𝑇

𝐾 �+�𝑟+ 𝜎2

2 �𝑇

𝜎√𝑇=

ln�𝐹𝐾� + 𝜎2𝑇/2

𝜎√𝑇 (51)

𝑑2 = 𝑑1 − 𝜎√𝑇 (52)

The interest rate factor has been dropped out of the formula because the investment in a

futures contract is zero. The formula derived above is the same as the value of a security

option that pays continuous dividend at a rate equal to the stock price times the interest

rate, when the option can only be exercised at maturity. Equations (49) and (50) are also

named as Black’s Model for valuing futures options. This model does not require the

options contract and the futures contract to mature at the same time.

Page 46: Valuation of Structured Products

45

6 An overview of the selected products

Structured products to be analyzed in this thesis are chosen from the Danish market.

The chosen structured products are DB Råvarer 2013 Basel issued by Danske Bank and

Råvarer Basis 2010 issued by Nordea Bank. Both banks are the leading financial

institutions in Denmark. The prospects for structured products from different issuers

contain more or less identical information about the products. The typical information

included in the prospectus is

• Name of the product

• Name of the issuer and the guarantor

• ISIN code for the issuing product

• Offer date (period) of the product

• Initial date

• Expiry date

• Issue price

• Risk factors associated with the product

• Minimum and or maximum redemption amount

• The underlying asset/assets, index/ indices and their category

• Number of underlying assets and their contributing weights

• Brief description of the underlying assets/ indices

• Initial price of the underlying

• Credit rating of the issuer

• Specified currency of the notes

• Formula for the final payoff

• Coupon type

• Coupon payment dates if applicable

• Initial or final valuation period or date.

• Annual costs related to the notes e.g. commission, listing costs etc

• Participation rate

Page 47: Valuation of Structured Products

46

6.1 DB Råvarer 2013 Basel (the “Notes”)

DB Råvarer 2013 Basel is issued and guaranteed by Danske bank. The offer period of

the product was from 12 April 2010 to and including 29 April 2010. The product has an

ISIN code of DK0030240247 and it will be listed on Copenhagen stock exchange

(OMX.com). The investor has to keep this product for three years (i.e. A zero coupon

commodity index linked note maturing in three years), because investment period of the

product is three years i.e. from 10 May 2010 to 13 May 2013. DB Råvarer 2013 Basel is

commodity linked note. The note consists of a bond with maturity of three years and a

call option on Dow Jones UBS commodity index. The note was issued at a price of

105% of the aggregate nominal amount. The minimum amount of the issuing notes

would be DKK 25,000,000. The issuer has the right to cancel the issue if the

subscription of the notes will be less the DKK25, 000,000.

6.1.1 Payoff Structure

The product will pay no coupon payments until expiry. The final redemption amount

will depend on the performance of the underlying index but it will not be less than 95%

and it will not be more that 35%. It means if the index performance is between 95% to

100%, then the redemption amount will be calculated accordingly but it will not be less

than 95%, and if the index performance is 100% or more, then the investor will get

100% or a maximum of 135% of nominal amount at maturity depending upon index

performance. The percentage of maximum payoff (Cap) will be set no later than 6 May

2010. The final commodity linked redemption amount will be according to following

formula

𝐶𝑎𝑙𝑐𝑢𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛 𝑎𝑚𝑜𝑢𝑛𝑡 ∗ (100% + 𝑀𝑎𝑥 �−5%;𝑀𝑖𝑛 �𝐶𝑎𝑝; 𝐼𝑛𝑑𝑒𝑥 𝐹𝑖𝑛𝑎𝑙𝐼𝑛𝑖𝑡𝑖𝑎𝑙 𝐼𝑛𝑑𝑒𝑥

− 100%��) (53)

Here

• Initial index means the initial price of the underlying at the initial date which is

10 May 2010. This initial date is also the strike date and therefore the index

price on this date will be the strike price too. The initial index value set by the

bank was 130.2348.

• Final index means the value of the index at maturity which is 13 May 2013. The

valuation date of the option will be 26 April 2010, which will be considered as

Page 48: Valuation of Structured Products

47

the initial spot price of the index. So it means that the major amount of the

redemption amount will come from the zero coupon bond and the rest from the

option part.

6.1.2 Risk Factors

The issuance price of the bond is 105% of the nominal amount. It means that the

investor pays 5% premium or issuing costs which will be gone no matter if the option

component expires worthless or in the money. If the underlying commodity index

performs below 100 %, then the investor can lose only 5% of the nominal amount. But

from 100% and onward performance of the underlying, the investor will get at least

100% of the nominal amount. So the only loss to the investor in this case will be the 5%

of its initial invested plus an opportunity cost that he would have earned if he would

have invested in the risk free investment i.e. bonds.

The other risk associated with the bond can be the default risk of the issuer. In this case,

Danske bank (issuer) has a good credit rating. Credit rating of Danske at the time of

issuance of the bond was ‘Aa3 ‘according to Moody’s and ‘A’ according to Standard &

Poors and Fitch. It means that, the bank has the strong capacity to meet its financial

commitments and obligations, are judged to be of very high quality and are subject to

very low credit risk. So, we can say that the risk associated with commodity linked note

is very low.

6.1.3 Issuance costs

The issuer also charges costs associated with the issuance of the bond. The issuance

costs included are arranger fee of 0,967% annually, estimated listing fee of NASDAQ

OMX Copenhagen A/S of 0.017% annually and a fee to VP securities which is about

0.17% annually. So the total annual issuance cost will be about 1% of aggregate

nominal amount of DKK 50,000,000.00

6.1.4 Embedded option

The embedded option is the most important part of the structured product. The option

embedded in this product is a capped call option with three years of expiry. The payoff

is set to the level of 35% maximum and if the index performance is between 95% -

Page 49: Valuation of Structured Products

48

100% than the final redemption amount will be calculated accordingly. The final payoff

can be calculated from the equation 53.

6.1.5 The underlying asset

The underlying asset is the Dow Jones UBS Commodity index composed of futures

contracts on physical commodities. Unlike equities, which typically entitles the holder

to a continuing stake in a corporation, commodity contracts normally specify a certain

date for the delivery of the underlying physical commodity. In order to avoid the

delivery process and maintain a longer futures position, nearby contracts must be sold

and contracts that have not yet reached the delivery period must be purchased. This is

called “rolling” a futures position.

The Dow Jones UBS Commodity index is composed of commodities traded on US

exchanges except aluminum, nickel and zinc which trade on the London Metal

exchange.

6.2 Analysis of Råvarer Basis 2010

Råvarer Basis 2010 was issued by KommunalBanken A/S on 16 June 2006. The ISIN

code for the product is DK0030030861. The note will mature in four years and the

maturity date was 16June 2010. The subscription period of the product was from 22

May 2006 to and including 9 June 2006. The product was available at a minimum

amount of DKK 10,000 for the investors while the total subscription will be a minimum

of DKK 25,000,000.00. The product is a combination of a zero coupon bond and a call

option. The underlying asset is the DJAIJ commodity index. According to Reuters

(May7, 2009), DJAIG commodity index was acquired by Dow Jones UBS and therefore

renamed as Dow Jones UBS commodity index12

6.2.1. Payoff Structure

. The product was issued at 104% of

the aggregate principal amount (Nominal amount). The product offered no coupon

payments until expiry. This product was also listed on the Copenhagen Stock exchange.

Final payoff of the product depends on the performance of the underlying index but the

minimum redemption amount will be at par. It means this product guarantees the

12 http://uk.reuters.com/article/idUKN0731630220090507

Page 50: Valuation of Structured Products

49

investor 100% of the invested amount no matter what the index performance will be

negative. This product does not have any limit for the up side payoff unlike DB Råvarer

Basel. The final redemption amount will be calculated according to the following

formula

𝑃𝑟𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑖𝑝𝑎𝑙 ∗ [1 + 𝑃𝑎𝑟𝑡𝑖𝑐𝑖𝑝𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛 𝑟𝑎𝑡𝑒 𝐷𝐽𝐴𝐼𝐺2010 ∗ {max �0; 𝐷𝐽𝐴𝐼𝐺𝑒𝑛𝑑−𝐷𝐽𝐴𝐼𝐺 𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑟𝑡 𝐷𝐽𝐴𝐼𝐺𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑟𝑡

�}]

Here

• 𝐷𝐽𝐴𝐼𝐺𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑟𝑡 , is the official closing price of the DJAIG on 16 June 2006 as

determined by the calculation agent.

• 𝐷𝐽𝐴𝐼𝐺𝑒𝑛𝑑 , is the arithmetic means of the official closing price of DJAIG on

each of the determination dates. The determinatioon dates are

• 01 December 2009, 04 January 2010, 01 February 2010, 01 March 2010, 06

April 2010, 04 May 2010 and 01 June 2010.

• Participation rate will be fixed by the calculation agent on 13 June 2006 and it

will not be less than 70%. The expected participation rate is about 87%

6.2.2 Risk factors

The prospectus does not mention any credit rating information of the issuing bank

(Kommunal Bank) and also the distributor of the notes which is Nordea Bank. It

includes in the prospectus that the status of instruments is senior. It means that in case

of default, the note holders will have the priority for getting their money back. Apart

from the default risk

• The investor will lose 4% of the invested amount because the notes are issued at

104% of the nominal amount.

• The investor will miss the opportunity of earning the profit from investing in a

risk free bond.

• The good news for the investor here is that he will get at least 100% of the

invested amount if the underlying index performs negative or zero plus an

opportunity to earn unlimited profit if the underlying performs more than zero.

Page 51: Valuation of Structured Products

50

6.2.3 Issuance costs

The issuing costs include commission and concession which is about 3% of the

aggregate principal amount. The total estimated expenses based on an issue of DKK

200,000,000 are DKK 200,000 which include a fee of DKK 40,000 for listing on stock

exchange, VP: DKK 10,000, service charges to Nordea bank about DKK 5,000 and a

license fee of DKK 100,000

6.2.4 Embedded option

The embedded option is call option and the strike price is the arithmetic average of the

seven determination dates mentioned above. Therefore, it is considered to be an Asian

style option, because the payoff depends on the average performance of the underlying

commodity index.

6.2.5 Underlying Asset

DJAIG was the underlying index in this option but after acquisition by Dow Jones

commodity index, the underlying index is Dow Jones UBS commodity index. The

description of the index is already mentioned above during analyzing DB Råvarer basel

2013.

Page 52: Valuation of Structured Products

51

7 Pricing of the selected products

This section will deal with the valuation of the structured products. All structured

products face the risk of trading at prices that differ substantially from their fair values.

Given that there would otherwise be no liquidity in the secondary market, issuers

generally act as market makers for their own products during the exchange trade.

Alternatively, structured products can be bought and sold over-the-counter with the

issuing firm. As a consequence, almost any transaction involves the product's issuer as

one counter-party, and there is a possibility that unfavourable prices will be quoted. As

a rule of thumb, the more complex the product, the higher the margins entailed in

quotes13

The price of a commodity linked bond can be calculated as

𝐵(𝑃, 𝑡) = 𝐶𝑟

(1 − 𝑒−𝑟𝑇) + 𝐹𝑒−𝑟𝑇 + 𝑊(𝑃,𝑇)14 (54)

Where 𝑊(𝑃,𝑇) is the Black and Scholes solution (as derived earlier in last section) to

the value of a call option with exercise price K. The above equation shows that the

value of a commodity linked bond is equal to the discounted value of future coupon

payments (if any) and face value of the bond plus a call option to buy the reference

commodity bundle at agreed exercise price. The above relation holds if we assume that

• The firm issuing the bond has no default risk

• Interest rate is constant

• There is no cost of carrying to the commodity (evaporation, obsolescence,

insurance etc) and that the commodity is held for speculative purpose like a

stock15

.

13 The pricing of structured products in Germany; By Wilkens; Journal of Derivatives Vol.11 14 Option pricing theory and its application; by Eduardo S. Schwartz, The Journal of Finance. May 1982 15 Details can be found in the above mentioned reference 14.

Page 53: Valuation of Structured Products

52

7.1 Pricing of DB Råvarer 2013 Basel

This section will consist of pricing the bond and the option components of the DB

Råvarer 2013.

7.1.1 Deriving the Zero Coupons

In order to calculate the present value of the bond component of DB Råvarer Basel we

need to find out the discount rates or the interest rate. Since the note will mature in three

years therefore we need to find the set of zero coupon bonds whose maturity is from one

to three years. The table below shows a set of zero coupon bonds issued by Real Kredit

Denmark with maturity from one to years. These bonds were issued around the same

period when DB Råvarer was issued. Therefore at that time these bonds were also not

listed on the stock exchange and consequently no market prices were available in the

beginning. Therefore, we assume that the price of the bond would be equal to the

market price (i.e. the par value is the same as the principal value). The term structure is

as follows

Table 1

Bond maturity Coupon rate Price Principal

1 Year 2% 100 100

2 Years 2% 100 100

3 Years 2% 100 100

So, discount factors and the interest rates calculated on the basis of continuous

compounding (equation 2) are given in the following table. The discount factor and the

interest rate are actually nearly the same because of the fact that we have assumed that

the par value and principal value of the bonds are equal. The detailed calculations can

be found in the excel spread sheet on CD Rom

Table 2

Time to Maturity Disc. Factor r(0,T) 1 0,980198673 0,020201 2 0,960789439 0,020201 3 0,941764534 0,020201

Page 54: Valuation of Structured Products

53

The graph below shows a decreasing trend in discount factor with the passage of time

while the interest rate is constant, because all bonds have the same coupon rates and

market price of the bonds is assumed to be equal to the principal amount.

So, from table 2 we can find out the present value of the bond component as given

below

PV = 100* 0, 94176 = 94,176 (55)

7.2 Term Structure for Råvare.r Basis 2010

In order to derive the zero coupon term structure we need to find the set of bonds which

were issued during the same period as the issuance of the Råvarere Basis 2010. The

maturity of the structured note is four years therefore we need a set of bonds with

maturity from one to four years. BRF kredit issued bonds with maturity from one to

four years. These bonds were issued during June 2006 and were listed on Copenhagen

the stock exchange. The term structure is given in the following table

Table 3

Time to Maturity Coupon Price Principal 1 3% 100 100 2 3% 100 100 3 3% 100 100 4 3% 100 100

0

0,2

0,4

0,6

0,8

1

1,2

1 2 3

Discount factor

r(0,T)

Page 55: Valuation of Structured Products

54

The market prices of the bonds were not available during the June 2006 because they

started to trade during July 2006. Therefore, here we make the same assumption again

that the market price of the bonds is equal the principal amount. The term structure can

be derived by assuming the continuous compounding again and is given in table 4

below.

Table 4

Time Discount factor R(0,t) 1 0,970445534 0,030454534 2 0,941764534 0,030454534 3 0,913931185 0,030454534 4 0,886920437 0,030454534

The graph below shows that the discount factor is decreasing as the time to maturity is

increasing. On the other hands the interest rate is unchanged during the four years

because we assumed principal and market price of the bonds to be equal.

After calculating the discount factor and interest rates we can calculate the present value

of the Råvaere 2010. Therefore,

PV= 100* 0.88692

= 88. 692 (56)

0

0,2

0,4

0,6

0,8

1

1,2

0 1 2 3 4 5

Discount factor

R(0,T)

Page 56: Valuation of Structured Products

55

7.3 Option Pricing

This section will deal with the pricing of the embedded options within the selected

structured products. The theoretical price of the option will be calculated by the Black

& Scholes formula and also by the Monte Carlo simulations. The Black–Scholes option-

pricing framework is applied because of its wide acceptance, its simplicity and

elegance, and its mathematical tractability. All conclusions derived in the thesis can be

used as benchmarks for other more sophisticated option-pricing models.

Before we can calculate option price, we need to calculate one of the most important

parameter named as volatility.

7.4 Estimating Volatility

Volatility “σ” is an important parameter in option pricing. It is the degree of uncertainty

about the stock returns and is also known as standard deviation. To estimate volatility,

the stock, commodity etc prices are usually observed at fixed interval of time (e.g. daily

closing price, weekly or monthly etc). Volatility can be estimated by the following

formula

𝜎 = � 1(𝑀−1)

∑ (log𝑃𝑡 −𝑀𝑖=1 log𝑃𝑡−1)2 (57)

Here

• log𝑃𝑡 𝑎𝑛𝑑 log𝑃𝑡−1,are log of stock/commodity prices at time t and t-1

respectively, M is the number of observations in the series

The selection of appropriate number of observation M is also tricky. More data

generally lead to accuracy but choosing too old data can also be irrelevant to predict the

future volatility. Choosing data over the most recent 90 to 180 days can estimate

reasonably well estimate of volatility. In option pricing however, it is good idea to set M

equal to the number of days to which the volatility is to be applied. Therefore, if an

option matures in two years, then it is good idea to take the daily data for the recent two

years.

Page 57: Valuation of Structured Products

56

Equation (57) calculates the so called historical volatility on daily basis. In option

pricing, we normally use annual volatility. So the annualized volatility σ (yearly) can be

estimated by multiplying the equation (57) with the square root of number of trading

days in a year (assume 252 trading days/ year). That is,

𝜎𝑦𝑒𝑎𝑟𝑙𝑦 = 𝜎𝑑𝑎𝑖𝑙𝑦 ∗ √252 (58)

There are other ways to estimate volatility which are not considered in this thesis.

7.5 Monte Carlo Simulation

Monte Carlo simulation is being named after the city of Monte Carlo which is famous

for its casinos. In Monte Carlo simulations random numbers are generated according to

the probabilities assumed to be connected with the source of uncertainty for example

stock, commodities, interest rates or option prices etc. Monte Carlo simulations has

been using since 1977 for option pricing. The method is proved to be accurate for

option pricing. The method is particularly good for the pricing of Asian options and

other path dependent options. Monte Carlo simulation is based on the principal of risk

neutral random walks of the stock, commodities etc.

Monte Carlo simulation for option pricing has many advantages. For example, simple

mathematics is involved to perform the simulation, correlations can be easily modeled

and simulation can be performed on excel spreadsheet too. We can generate more

simulations to get accurate results (Wilmott 2007, p586). As we know in a risk neutral

world the present value of any cash flow can be obtained by discounting its expected

future value at risk free interest rate i.e.

𝑂𝑝𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛 𝑣𝑎𝑙𝑢𝑒 = 𝑒−𝑟(𝑇−𝑡)𝐸[𝑝𝑎𝑦𝑜𝑓𝑓(𝑃)]

The above relation holds if the expectation is with respect risk neutral random walk i.e.

the geometric Brownian motion in equation (11) mentioned in the previous section.

Precisely the method of pricing the option with Monte Carlo simulation has the

following steps

• First of all produce random numbers from standardized normal distribution or

some other approximation.

Page 58: Valuation of Structured Products

57

• Start with the today’s value of the asset 𝑃0 over the required period of time

(from today up to maturity). The asset price up to maturity can be found by the

so called Euler method which is a discrete way of simulating the time series for

𝑃0 and is given by

𝛿𝑃 = 𝑟 𝑃 𝛿𝑡 + 𝜎𝑃√𝛿𝑡 𝜑

Here 𝜑 is drawn from the standardized normal distribution. Applying Ito’s

lemma to the above equation we can simulate the asset price as follows

𝑃(𝑡 + 𝛿𝑡) = 𝑃𝑡𝑒�𝑟−𝜎

2

2 �𝛿𝑡+ 𝜎√𝛿𝑡 𝜑

• Perform many such realizations over the time horizon and then calculate the

arithmetic average of corresponding payoffs

• Finally take the present value of this average payoff according to risk free

interest rate. This will be the option value (Wilmott 2007, p582).

7.6 Variance Reduction Technique

One of the drawbacks of Monte Carlo simulation is that it generates high variances

which lead to computational inefficiency and therefore can produce biased estimates of

the option price16

7.7 Generating Random numbers

. But according to Wilmott, we can apply variance reduction

techniques to overcome this drawback. One of the variance reduction techniques is

called Antithetic variable. In this technique first of all we calculate the option price by

generating random variables in a usual way. Secondly, we find the option price by

producing negative random variables. The option value will be the average of these

values. This technique works well because of the symmetry in the Normal distribution

and it also easy to implement.

There are many ways to generate random numbers. The most common methods are

NormSinv(RND()) in excel, Box- Muller method and Marsaglia- Bray. For the pricing

of DB Råvarer basel 2013, random numbers are generated by Marsaglia – Bray method.

Marsagalia- Bray method is used because it is the most efficient way to generate 16 Option pricing and Monte Carlo simulations. George M. Jabbour. Journal of economics and business research Sept.2005

Page 59: Valuation of Structured Products

58

random numbers and we can get better convergence rate than other random number

generating methods17

7.8 DB Råvarer Basel 2013

.

The embedded in DB Råvarer Basel 2013 is considered to be plain vanilla option. The

only thing to consider is the minimum and maximum payoff from the investment. The

option is valued considering the fact that we are standing on the valuation date which is

26- April-2010. So we consider that that the official closing price on 26-April-2006 is

the initial value i.e. P0 and the strike price, as mentioned in the prospectus, will be the

official closing price on the index on 10- May-2010. Since the maturity of the option

component is considered to be the same as that of the structured bond which is three

years. Therefore, historical volatility is estimated from the last three years data on Dow

Jones UBS commodity index. Since the time period between the initial date and the

strike date is about 11 trading days, therefore, it is assumed that the time for the option

is equal to 0.04 (11/252). The raw data and calculations can be found in excel file on the

CD Rom. The E-view output of log return and the volatility is calculated and the daily

historical volatility estimate is 0.014991. The annual volatility estimate according to

equation (45) is

𝜎𝐴𝑛𝑛𝑢𝑎𝑙 = 0.014991 ∗ √252 = 23.797% (59)

Table5

Initial index P0 Final index KT Interest rate r Maturity T Volatility

135.75 130.23 2% 0,04 23.79

The value of the option is estimated from the standard Black and Scholes formula for

pricing the European call option and the Monte Carlo simulations. The simulations are

performed following the risk neutral random walk up to maturity of the contract. The

results are given as

Black and Scholes price of the Call option: 6.37

From Monte Carlo simulations

17 Lecture slides

Page 60: Valuation of Structured Products

59

Table6

Simulations 5000 20000 40000 90000

Call Price 6.28 6.39 6.37 6.37

The idea to compare Call value from Black and Scholes formula and Monte Carlo

simulations is that as long we increase the number of simulations, the Monte Carlo

estimate of the call price converges to the Black and Scholes call price. It means that the

increase in number of simulations can lead to increase in accuracy by Monte Carlo

simulations.

So adding the PV of the bond and the option components according to equation (54),

the theoretical value of the DB Råvarer Basel 2013 is

𝑃𝑉 𝑜𝑓 𝑡ℎ𝑒 𝑠𝑡𝑟𝑢𝑐𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑒𝑑 𝑛𝑜𝑡𝑒 = 94.17 + 6.37 = 100.54 (60)

The product was issued at 105 of the nominal amount. So, it means that the theoretical

price estimated in Black & Scoles world is less than the issue price. Therefore, we can

say that the product was offered at higher price than its theoretical fair price.

7.9 Pricing of Råvarer Basel 2010

The embedded option in Nordea Bank’s structured product is assumed to be Asian type

because the payoff depends on the arithmetic average of the strike price at some fixed

interval of time (fixing dates) during the life time of the product. The product had four

years maturity time which is from 16-June-2006 to 16-June -2010. So we assume that

we are standing in past time which is 16-June 2006, which will be the initial price on

the Dow Jones UBS commodity index. The historical volatility is estimated taking the

last four years index prices from the date of option valuation (16-June-2002 to 16- June-

2006). The daily volatility estimate is 0.0100. So the annualized volatility estimate will

be

𝜎𝐴𝑛𝑛𝑢𝑎𝑙 = 0.01 ∗ √252 = 15.8% (61)

The final value of the index is estimated by Monte Carlo simulation following risk

neutral assumption. Each valuation date is estimated by performing 5000 simulations

and by assuming that there are 21 trading days (one month) among all the fixing dates.

Page 61: Valuation of Structured Products

60

The simulated index values are then continuously compounded to maturity date. Table

below shows each fixing date.

Table 7

Fixing Date Simulated Index value

01-Dec-2009 200.40

04- Jan-2010 200.52

01-Feb-2010 200.75

01-Mar-2010 200.82

06-Apr-2010 200.91

04-May-2010 201.16

01-Jun-2010 201.24

The final price of the index is equal to the arithmetic average of the fixing dates, which

is equal to 200.83. So the parameters required to estimate option are

Table 8

Initial index value P0 170.51

Final Index KT 200.83

Interest rate r 3%

Time to Maturity T 4 years

Volatility 15.8%

So, the estimate of the Call option with the above mentioned parameters performed with

5000 simulations is

Price of the Call Option = 21.68

The theoretical price of the Råvarer Basel 2010 can now be calculated by adding the PV

of the bond and the option components according to equation (54). Therefore,

𝑃𝑉 𝑜𝑓 𝑡ℎ𝑒 𝑠𝑡𝑟𝑢𝑐𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑒𝑑 𝑛𝑜𝑡𝑒 = 88.69 + 21.68 = 110.37 (62)

Equation (62) shows the calculated theoretical price for Råvarer Basel 2010 in Black &

Scholes world, with the assumptions of a perfect world discussed earlier. The issuing

price was 104% of the nominal amount. It means that the theoretical price is higher than

the issue price of the note. These results show that Black & Scholes option pricing

Page 62: Valuation of Structured Products

61

method under price the option when it is in the money and over price the option when it

is out of money. We can not make a concrete conclusion on the basis of only two

products evaluation that these observations are true but James D. Macbeth and Larry

also in their analysis showed that Balck & Scholes model tends to under price the option

that are in the money and overprice them is they are out of money18

8 Evaluation of the Model

.

The model misprices the options because of the set of assumption we took into

considerations.

• We assumed that the volatility of the returns remains constant throughout the

maturity of the product, which is not true in the real world. As a matter of fact

volatility of returns is not constant instead it changes over time. It can also be

observed in our data. It is also found from studies that higher value of volatility

may lead to higher theoretical value of the option and vice versa. Although in

both products the underlying is the same index but the time period is different.

Even then the annual volatility for the data from April 2010 to April 2013 is

different than the data from June 2006 to June 2010. The volatility estimates for

both the time periods were 23.79% and 15.8% respectively. We also assumed

historical volatility to calculate the options but according to Markove property,

only the present value of a variable is relevant to predict its future behavior. It

means historical volatility may not be good predictor of the future volatility.

• We assumed that the log of returns follow a normal distribution. This

assumption is not true always. The descriptive statistics for both the time series

data are given below. The data from these two tables show, that the returns in

both the time series are not normally distributed because Jarque-Bera test for

normality for both the data series is well above the probability values.

• Kurtosis for both the time series data is also nearly four in the first table while it

is more than four in the second table, which is also a violation for normality to

18 An Empirical Examination of the Black-Scholes Call Option Pricing Model, James Macbeth and Larry

Journal of finance Dec 1979

Page 63: Valuation of Structured Products

62

hold. High values of kurtosis means, that the returns have heavy tails which is

not a characteristic of the normal distribution. Returns from both the time series

data also have skewness (also called volatility smile). It means that the returns

are not distributed symmetrically around the mean. Positive and negative

skewness in table 9 and 10 show that data in both time series is right and left

skewed respectively.

Table9: Råvarer Basel 2010

Mean 0,000554 Median 0,000682 Maximum 0,048236 Minimum -0,31199 Std. Dev. 0,010067 Skewness 0,084407 Kurtosis 3,685963 Jarque-Bera 20,79348 Probability 0,000031

Table 10: Råvarer Basel 2013

Mean -0,00031 Median -0,000028 Maximum 0,056475 Minimum -0,064023 Std. Dev. 0,014991 Skewness -0,264433 Kurtosis 4,517711 Jarque-Bera 81,26153 Probability 0,000

• In BS model for option pricing, we assumed that the interest rate is known and

constant. In reality interest rate is not constant all the time but it also changes

over time. Therefore, the assumption of constant interest rate can also lead to

misprice both the bond and option components with the structured products.

8.1 Possible extensions to the thesis

The objective of this thesis was to see how the structured products are designed and the

theory involved for their estimation. The option component embedded was estimated by

using well known Black and Scholes option pricing formula. The model is applied

because of its wide acceptance, its simplicity and elegance, and its mathematical

tractability. The results obtained in this thesis can be used as a bench mark for further

Page 64: Valuation of Structured Products

63

readings. There are a number of possible extensions to this thesis. Some of them could

be

• The pricing of the structured products could also be performed by considering

the default risk of the firm issuing these products and by relaxing the assumption

of constant risk free interest rate.

• Option pricing can be performed in many ways. For example BS model assumes

that the asset’s price change continuously over time producing a log normal

distribution (geometric Brownian motion). Another possibility is that the prices

do not follow geometric Brownian motion but instead it can be assumed that

process of price changes follows jumps. There are further three possibilities in

jump assumption i.e. price changes continuously (diffusion model), or the

continuous changes are overlaid with jumps (jump – diffusion model) or the

price changes are only jumps (pure jumps). These processes are collectively

called Levy process.

The Constant Elasticity of Variance Model is an example of the diffusion model where

the risk neutral process for a stock price is given by

𝑑𝑆 = (𝑟 − 𝑞)𝑆𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎 𝑆𝛼 𝑑𝑍 (63)

Here α is a positive constant. If it is equal to one, then the equation becomes Geometric

Brownian motion.

Another useful option pricing model was suggested by Merton and is called Merton’s

mixed jump-diffusion model. In this model the continuous price changes are associated

with jumps. The risk neutral process of asset’s price behavior can be written as

𝑑𝑆𝑆

= (𝑟 − 𝑞 − 𝛾𝑘)𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎𝑑𝑍 + 𝑑𝑝 (64)

Here 𝛾 is average number of jumps per year and 𝑘 is the average size of the jump and is

measured as a percentage of the asset price. The percentage jump size is assumed to be

drawn from a probability distribution in the model. dZ is Wienner process and dp is the

poisson process generating the jumps.

Page 65: Valuation of Structured Products

64

Variance- Gamma model is an example of pure jump model. A gamma process is pure

jump process where small jumps occur very frequently and large jumps occur only

occasionally. Details about the model can found in Hull, p594.

Another possibility to price the option components embedded in structured products is

to relax the assumption of constant volatility. Hull and White, and the well known

Heston model to price the options in stochastic volatility frame are examples of the

models that consider stochastic volatility.

Page 66: Valuation of Structured Products

65

9 Conclusion

Structured products are getting popularity among the investors now a day. Therefore,

the main objective of this thesis was to see how these products in general and

commodity linked products in particular are valued and how they are engineered. These

products can be divided into different categories according to their payoff structure.

Structured products generally consist of two components. The major component is a

zero coupon bond which ensures complete or partial protection of the invested capital

and an option component, which provides the opportunity of payoff. The issuing firms

discount the future payment into present value according to risk free interest rate and

then subtract it form the future amount. The difference is used to buy the option. While

deriving the zero coupon term structure, it was noted the discount factor decreases as

the time to maturity increases. The options are classified into plain vanilla and exotic

options. Exotic options are further subdivided into five to six groups according to their

payoff profile. The valuation of the embedded options is the tricky part of the valuation

process because the options embedded in these products are generally complex and

some time difficult to understand.

Option pricing theories involve set of assumptions and concepts that needed to be

understood before we can estimate them. Plain vanilla options are comparatively easy to

estimate while exotic option calculation is challenging. In this thesis the famous Black

& Scholes option pricing frame work is applied which is based on ideal market

assumptions like no transaction costs, constant volatility and interest rate, log returns

are normally distributed and the assumption that the underlying follows Geometric

Brownian motion. First, Brownian motion was introduced, but it can allow price to

become negative was therefore, replaced by Geometric Brownian motion because here

the prices never become negative. The Black Scholes frame work is based on delta

hedging principal and therefore was also explained. The ability to completely hedge the

option means that the expected returns must be equal the risk free rate of return.

Exotic options are difficult to price in particular when payoff structure become advance.

Therefore, Monte Carlo simulations were introduced in the pricing section of the option

component and discussed how it can be used to estimate the complex options.

Page 67: Valuation of Structured Products

66

Two commodity index linked notes were analyzed in the thesis. The embedded option

in DB Råvarer Basel 20013 is assumed to be standard European style call option with

the exception that the maximum payoff was limited up to a level of 35%. The embedded

option in Nordea Bank’s commodity linked note Råvarer Basel 2010 was Asian type,

because the final payoff was calculated on the basis of arithmetic average of each fixing

date (from December 2009 to June 2010). In this thesis we estimated the annualized

historical volatility and disregard other techniques to estimate volatility.

The theoretical fair price of DB Råvarer Basel 2013 was 100.54 while its issuance price

was 105. It means that the theoretical price is lower than the issuance price. In case of

Nordea Bank’s Råvarer Basel 2010, the estimated fair price was 110.37 while the issue

price was 104. It means the model underpriced Råvarer Basel 2013 and over priced

Råvarer 2010. Another important point to note here was that Black & Scholes frame

work underpriced the option which was in the money and overpriced the option which

was out of money. The model mispriced the embedded options because the underlying

assumptions in the model are not realistic. It is shown in several studies that volatility is

not constant but it changes over time. Similarly, interest rate also changes over time.

The assumption of log normal returns is also not true always. The data set for the two

selected products also showed that returns are not normally distributed but they are

skewed and have heavy tails.

In the end, suggestions are discussed to improve the option pricing model, for example

levy models and stochastic volatility models. The assumptions in these models are more

realistic than Black & Scholes model.

Studies also show that traders and market makers still resist using the so called cutting

edge option pricing formulas and the most widely used option pricing model is still

Black & Scholes with some so called ad hoc changes and frequent updating of

parameters. So we can say that the results obtained from this model can be used as a

bench mark for further studies.

Page 68: Valuation of Structured Products

67

References

Barclays Wealth, Light Energy Commodity Plan

Black, F, & Scholes, M. (1973). The pricing of options and corporate liabilities. Journal

of Political Economy, 81(3), 637

BNP Paribas equities & Derivatives handbook

Bruce Tuckman, Fixed income securities. Wiley & sons

Das 2001, structured products and hybrid securities. John Wiley & sons

Douglas R. Emery A closer look at Black–Scholes option thetas. J Econ Finan (2008)

Eduardo S Schawartz 1982, “Option pricing theory and its application. The pricing of

commodity- linked bonds” The Journal of Finance Vol. XXXV11 NO. 2.

John Crosby, January 2007, A multi- factor jump- diffusion model for commodities.

Quantitative Finance, Vol. 8. No. 2. March 2008. PP. 181-200

John Crosby, June 2007. Pricing a class of exotic commodity options in a multi- factor

jump- diffusion model. Quantitative Finance, Vol. 8, No. 5, PP. 471-483

John C Hull 2008. Options, Futures and other derivatives. Pearson Prentice Hall

JAMES D. MACBETH, An Empirical Examination of the Black-Scholes Call Option

Pricing Model, Journal of finance Dec 1979

Joseph Atta- Mensah (1992). The Valuation of Commodity- Linked Bonds. University

of New Brunswick.

Page 69: Valuation of Structured Products

68

Lehman Brothers, A guide to Equity_Linked Notes

Peter Car 1987, A note on the pricing of commodity linked bonds. The Journal of

Finance VOL. XLII, NO. 4. September 1987. PP. 1071-1076

Sergei Mikhailov .Heston’s Stochastic Volatility Model Implementation, Calibration

and Some Extensions

Uwe Wystup 2006, FX options and structured products. www.mathfinance.com

Wilmott P 2007, Paul Wilmott introduces quantitative finance

Wilmott , Exotic Options Pricing and Advanced Levy Models, John Wiley & sons

Web addresses for the selected products

http://www.danskebank.dk/da-dk/Privat/Opsparing-og-

investering/Investering/Produkter/strukturerede-

produkter/Documents/2010/DBRÅVARER2013/Preliminary_Final_Terms_Final_Basal

.pdf

http://www.nordea.dk/sitemod/upload/Root/main_dk/Privat/Raadgivning/Opsparing/Str

ukturerede_produkter/Oevrige_obligationer/prospekt_raavarerBasis2010.pdf