14
Utility portfolio optimization with liability and multiple risky assets under the extended CIR model HAO CHANG Tianjin Polytechnic University Department of Mathematics Bin-shui West Road 399, 300387 Tianjin CHINA [email protected] JI-MEI LU Tianjin Polytechnic University School of Electrical Engineering and Automation Bin-shui West Road 399, 300387 Tianjin CHINA [email protected] Abstract: This paper studies an asset and liability management problem with extended Cox-Ingersoll-Ross (CIR) interest rate, where the financial market is composed of one risk-free asset and multiple risky assets and one zero-coupon bond. We assume that risk-free interest rate is driven by extended CIR interest rate model, while liability is modeled by Brownian motion with drift and is generally correlated with stock price. Firstly, we use stochastic optimal control theory to obtain Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) equation for the value function and choose power utility and exponential utility for our analysis. Secondly, we obtain the closed-form solutions to the optimal investment strategies by applying variable change technique. Finally, a numerical example is presented to analyze the dynamic behavior of the optimal investment strategy and provide some economic implications for our results. Key–Words: CIR interest rate model; liability process; dynamic portfolio selection; stochastic optimal control; optimal investment strategy; 1 Introduction Dynamic portfolio selection problems with stochastic interest rates have been paid much more attentions to in recent years. The Vasicek model (1977) and Cox- Ingersoll-Ross(CIR) model (1985) were the most im- portant models which described the term structure of interest rate dynamics. Stanton (1997) presented a nonparametric technique to estimate the drift and dif- fusion of the short rate, and the market price and the interest rate risk. Korn and Kraft (2001) used stochas- tic optimal control approach to study portfolio prob- lems with stochastic interest rates and obtained the closed-form solutions of the optimal portfolios, and further presented verification theorem of the optimal solutions in the stochastic interest rate environments. Deelstra et al.(2000, 2003) investigated an investment and consumption problem in a CIR framework and the optimal policy for an insurer in the presence of a min- imum guarantee respectively. Later, Grasselli (2003) studied an investment problem where the interest rate followed the CIR dynamics and obtained the optimal investment strategy in explicit form for HARA util- ity. Bielecki et al.(2005) focused on risk sensitive portfolio management problem with CIR interest rate dynamics. Liu (2007) assumed that risk-free interest rate and the appreciate rate and volatility term were functions of state variable, which followed Markovian diffusion process, and applied stochastic optimal con- trol approach to study an investment and consump- tion problem in the finite horizon. Gao (2008) in- vestigated a defined contribution pension funds prob- lem with affine interest rate dynamics, which included the Vasicek model and the CIR model, and obtained the explicit solution of the optimal investment strat- egy. Li and Wu (2009) was concerned with a dynamic portfolio selection problem with CIR interest rate and Heson’s stochastic volatility and obtained the explicit expression of the optimal investment policy. Ferland and Watier (2010) applied backward stochastic dif- ferential equation theory to study the mean-variance model with extended CIR interest rate dynamics and presented the explicit expressions of the optimal in- vestment strategy and the efficient frontier. Nowadays, the asset and liability management (ALM) problem is of both theoretical interest and practical importance, and has attracted more and more attentions in the last decade in the actuarial science and financial modelling. In recent years, many scholars have studied ALM problems in differ- ent situations. Leippold et al.(2004), Yi et al.(2008), Chen and Yang (2011) and Yao et al.(2013) studied mean-variance ALM problems in a multi-period en- vironment under different market assumptions. Chiu and Li (2006), Xie et al.(2008) and Zeng and Li WSEAS TRANSACTIONS on SYSTEMS and CONTROL Hao Chang, Ji-Mei Lu E-ISSN: 2224-2856 255 Volume 9, 2014

Utility portfolio optimization with liability and multiple ... › multimedia › journals › control › 2014 › a... · Utility portfolio optimization with liability and multiple

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    3

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Utility portfolio optimization with liability and multiple ... › multimedia › journals › control › 2014 › a... · Utility portfolio optimization with liability and multiple

Utility portfolio optimization with liability and multiple risky assetsunder the extended CIR model

HAO CHANGTianjin Polytechnic University

Department of MathematicsBin-shui West Road 399, 300387 Tianjin

[email protected]

JI-MEI LUTianjin Polytechnic University

School of Electrical Engineering and AutomationBin-shui West Road 399, 300387 Tianjin

[email protected]

Abstract: This paper studies an asset and liability management problem with extended Cox-Ingersoll-Ross (CIR)interest rate, where the financial market is composed of one risk-free asset and multiple risky assets and onezero-coupon bond. We assume that risk-free interest rate is driven by extended CIR interest rate model, whileliability is modeled by Brownian motion with drift and is generally correlated with stock price. Firstly, we usestochastic optimal control theory to obtain Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) equation for the value function andchoose power utility and exponential utility for our analysis. Secondly, we obtain the closed-form solutions to theoptimal investment strategies by applying variable change technique. Finally, a numerical example is presented toanalyze the dynamic behavior of the optimal investment strategy and provide some economic implications for ourresults.

Key–Words: CIR interest rate model; liability process; dynamic portfolio selection; stochastic optimal control;optimal investment strategy;

1 Introduction

Dynamic portfolio selection problems with stochasticinterest rates have been paid much more attentions toin recent years. The Vasicek model (1977) and Cox-Ingersoll-Ross(CIR) model (1985) were the most im-portant models which described the term structure ofinterest rate dynamics. Stanton (1997) presented anonparametric technique to estimate the drift and dif-fusion of the short rate, and the market price and theinterest rate risk. Korn and Kraft (2001) used stochas-tic optimal control approach to study portfolio prob-lems with stochastic interest rates and obtained theclosed-form solutions of the optimal portfolios, andfurther presented verification theorem of the optimalsolutions in the stochastic interest rate environments.Deelstra et al.(2000, 2003) investigated an investmentand consumption problem in a CIR framework and theoptimal policy for an insurer in the presence of a min-imum guarantee respectively. Later, Grasselli (2003)studied an investment problem where the interest ratefollowed the CIR dynamics and obtained the optimalinvestment strategy in explicit form for HARA util-ity. Bielecki et al.(2005) focused on risk sensitiveportfolio management problem with CIR interest ratedynamics. Liu (2007) assumed that risk-free interestrate and the appreciate rate and volatility term werefunctions of state variable, which followed Markovian

diffusion process, and applied stochastic optimal con-trol approach to study an investment and consump-tion problem in the finite horizon. Gao (2008) in-vestigated a defined contribution pension funds prob-lem with affine interest rate dynamics, which includedthe Vasicek model and the CIR model, and obtainedthe explicit solution of the optimal investment strat-egy. Li and Wu (2009) was concerned with a dynamicportfolio selection problem with CIR interest rate andHeson’s stochastic volatility and obtained the explicitexpression of the optimal investment policy. Ferlandand Watier (2010) applied backward stochastic dif-ferential equation theory to study the mean-variancemodel with extended CIR interest rate dynamics andpresented the explicit expressions of the optimal in-vestment strategy and the efficient frontier.

Nowadays, the asset and liability management(ALM) problem is of both theoretical interest andpractical importance, and has attracted more andmore attentions in the last decade in the actuarialscience and financial modelling. In recent years,many scholars have studied ALM problems in differ-ent situations. Leippold et al.(2004), Yi et al.(2008),Chen and Yang (2011) and Yao et al.(2013) studiedmean-variance ALM problems in a multi-period en-vironment under different market assumptions. Chiuand Li (2006), Xie et al.(2008) and Zeng and Li

WSEAS TRANSACTIONS on SYSTEMS and CONTROL Hao Chang, Ji-Mei Lu

E-ISSN: 2224-2856 255 Volume 9, 2014

Page 2: Utility portfolio optimization with liability and multiple ... › multimedia › journals › control › 2014 › a... · Utility portfolio optimization with liability and multiple

(2011) investigated mean-variance ALM problem ina continuous-time framework under different liabil-ity processes. Chen et al.(2008), Xie (2009) andLi and Shu (2011) considered continuous-time mean-variance ALM problems in the regime switching set-ting; Chiu and Wong (2011, 2013) focused on dy-namic portfolio selection problems with cointegratedassets both in a mean-variance framework and ex-pected utility framework respectively. Later, Chiu andWong (2012, 2013) investigated mean-variance ALMproblems, where the prices of the assets are cointe-grated. Leippold et al.(2011) and Yao et al.(2013)concerned mean-variance ALM problems with en-dogenous liability both in a multi-period setting andcontinuous-time setting respectively. In the above lit-erature mentioned, risk-free interest rate was all keptfixed. Such an assumption is too restrictive for manyfinancial institutions. In fact, the interest rate isn’t al-ways fixed in the real-world environments. Hence,considering ALM problems in the stochastic interestrate environments for many financial institutions orinvestor is more practice.

To the best of our knowledge, the ALM prob-lem with CIR interest rate dynamics has not been re-ported in the existing literatures. In this paper, weassumed that risk-free interest rate is driven by theCIR model, and there are multiple risky assets andone zero-coupon bond in the financial market. The li-ability process is governed by Brownian motion withdrift and is generally correlated with stock price dy-namics. We firstly use dynamic programming prin-ciple to get the HJB equation for the value functionand investigate the optimal investment strategies inthe power utility and exponential utility cases. Due tothe stochastic interest rate model and liability process,those factors make the HJB equation more sophisti-cated. Fortunately, we introduce a differential opera-tor to transform the equation (16) into (23), which iseasily solved directly. Secondly, we obtain the closed-form solutions to the optimal investment strategies byapplying variable change technique. Finally, a numer-ical example is presented to analyze the dynamic be-havior of the optimal investment strategy and providesome economic implications for our results. There arethree main contribution in this paper: (i) the ALMproblem with CIR interest rate dynamics is studied;(ii) the explicit expressions of the optimal investmentstrategies are obtained in the power utility and expo-nential utility cases; (iii) a verification theorem for theportfolio optimization problem with CIR interest ratedynamics is provided.

The rest of this paper is organized as follows. Theproblem formulation is presented in Section 2. In Sec-tion 3, we use dynamic programming principle to ob-tain the HJB equation and obtain the explicit expres-

sion and geometric structure of the optimal investmentstrategies in the power utility and exponential utilitycases by applying variable change technique. Section4 presents a numerical example to illustrate the effectof market parameters on the optimal investment strate-gies and gives some economic implications. Section 5concludes the paper.

2 Problem formulation

In this section we provide a dynamic portfolio selec-tion problem with liability process and extended CIRinterest rate.

Throughout this paper, we assume that (·)′ rep-resents the transpose of a vector or a matrix, [0, T ]represents the fixed and finite investment horizon,(Ω,F , Ft06t6T , P ) represents a given filtered com-plete probability space, where Ft06t6T is a filtra-tion and each Ft can be interpreted as the informationavailable at time t, and any decision made at time t isbased on those information.

2.1 Financial market

Assume that the financial market is composed of onerisk-free asset and multiple risky assets and one zero-coupon bond.

One risk-free asset is interpreted as cash or bankaccount, whose price at time t is denoted by S0(t).Then S0(t) evolves according to

dS0(t)

S0(t)= r(t)dt, S0(0) = 1, (1)

where r(t) is risk-free interest rate.In this paper, we suppose that the dynamics of

short rate r(t) is driven by CIR interest rate model:

dr(t) = (a− br(t))dt− σr√r(t)dWr(t),

r(0) = r0 > 0, (2)

where Wr(t) is a one-dimension standard Brownianmotion defined on (Ω,F , Ft06t6T , P ), a, b and σrare all positive real constants and satisfy the condition:2a > σ2r . It leads to that r(t) > 0 for all t ∈ [0, T ].

Multiple risky assets is the stocks, whose priceof the ith stock at time t is denoted by Si(t), i =1, 2, · · · , n. Then the dynamics of Si(t) can bedescribed by (referring to Deelstra and Grasselli etal.(2003), Ferland and Watier (2010)):

dSi(t)

Si(t)= r(t)dt+

n∑j=1

σij(dWj(t) + λjdt)+

WSEAS TRANSACTIONS on SYSTEMS and CONTROL Hao Chang, Ji-Mei Lu

E-ISSN: 2224-2856 256 Volume 9, 2014

Page 3: Utility portfolio optimization with liability and multiple ... › multimedia › journals › control › 2014 › a... · Utility portfolio optimization with liability and multiple

σir√r(t)(dWr(t) + λr

√r(t)dt), Si(0) = si > 0,

(3)where WS(t) = (W1(t),W2(t), · · · ,Wn(t))

′ is an−dimension independent and standard Brownianmotion defined on (Ω,F , Ft06t6T , P ) and is in-dependent of Wr(t). In addition, ΣS = (σij)n×n

represents the volatility matrix of the stock. LettingΣr = (σ1r, σ2r, · · · , σnr)′, Λ = (λ1, λ2, · · · , λn)′,then Σr

√r(t) represents the volatility of stock price

generated by the volatility of interest rate, λr√r(t)

and Λ can be taken as risk compensation coefficientvector generated by the volatility risk of the stock andthe risk of interest rate respectively. It implies that thestock prices are influenced by the short rate and cor-responding market price of risk.

The zero-coupon bond with maturity T , and theprice of zero-coupon bond at time t is denoted byB(t, T ), then the dynamics of B(t, T ) can be repre-sented by

dB(t, T )

B(t, T )= r(t)dt+ σB(t)(dWr(t) + λr

√r(t)dt),

B(T, T ) = 1, (4)

where σB(t) = σr(t)h(t)√r(t), and we have

h(t) =2(1− em(T−t))

m− (b− λrσr) + em(T−t)(m+ b− λrσr),

m =√

(b− λrσr)2 + 2σ2r . (5)

2.2 Liability process

Assume that an investor is equipped with an initial en-dowment w0 > 0 and an initial liability l0 > 0 at timet = 0, then the net initial wealth of an investor is givenby x0 = w0 − l0. Suppose that the accumulative lia-bility of the investor at time t is denoted by L(t), thenL(t) can be described by the following Brownian mo-tion with drift:

dL(t) = udt+ vdWL(t), L(0) = l0 > 0, (6)

where u and v are the positive constants, and WL(t)is a one-dimension standard Brownian motion on(Ω,F , Ft06t6T , P ). In this paper, we assume thatWL(t) is correlated with stock prices and the correla-tion coefficient between WL(t) and Wi(t) is denotedby ρi, i = 1, 2, · · · , n. Letting ρ = (ρ1, ρ2, · · · , ρn)′,thenWL(t) can be expressed as: WL(t) = ρ′WS(t)+√

1− ∥ρ∥2WL(t), where WL(t) is a one-dimensionstandard Brownian motion on (Ω,F , Ft06t6T , P )

and is independent of WS(t). Therefore, liability pro-cess L(t) can be rewritten as

dL(t) = udt+ vρ′dWS(t) + v

√1− ∥ρ∥2dWL(t),

L(0) = l0 > 0. (7)

2.3 Wealth process

Assume that the amount invested in the ith stock attime t is denoted by πi(t), i = 1, 2, · · · , n, and theamount invested in the zero-coupon bond is denotedby πB(t), then the amount invested in the risk-free as-

set is given by π0(t) = X(t) −n∑

i=1πi(t) − πB(t),

where X(t) represents the net wealth of an investorat time t. Suppose that the financial market is fric-tionless and is allowed to short-selling the stock. Let-ting πS(t) = (π1(t), π2(t), · · · , πn(t))′, then the netwealth process under trading strategy πS(t) and πB(t)can be written as:

dX(t) = (X(t)−n∑

i=1

πi(t)− πB(t))dS0(t)

S0(t)

+

n∑i=1

πi(t)dSi(t)

Si(t)+ πB(t)

dB(t, T )

B(t, T )− dL(t).

Taking (1), (3), (4) and (7) into consideration, we canget

dX(t) = [r(t)X(t) + πS(t)(ΣSΛ + Σrλrr(t))

+πB(t)σB(t)λr√r(t)− u]dt

+(π′S(t)ΣS − vρ′)dWS(t)− v

√1− ∥ρ∥2dWL(t)

+(π′S(t)Σr

√r(t) + πB(t)σB(t))dWr(t), (8)

with the initial value X(0) = x0.

2.4 Optimization criterion

Definition 1(Admissible strategy). Trading strategyπS(t) and πB(t) are admissible if the following con-ditions are satisfied:

(i) πS(t) and πB(t) are progressively measurable;

(ii) E∫ T0 [(π′S(t)ΣS − vρ′)2 + (v

√1− ∥ρ∥2)2

+(π′S(t)Σr

√r(t) + πB(t)σB(t))

2]dt <∞;

(iii) For all initial conditions (t0, r0, x0), thewealth process X(t) with X(0) = x0 has a pathwiseunique solution.

WSEAS TRANSACTIONS on SYSTEMS and CONTROL Hao Chang, Ji-Mei Lu

E-ISSN: 2224-2856 257 Volume 9, 2014

Page 4: Utility portfolio optimization with liability and multiple ... › multimedia › journals › control › 2014 › a... · Utility portfolio optimization with liability and multiple

We denote the set of all admissible strategies byΓ, and the optimization problem of the investor in theutility framework can be expressed as:

MaximizeπS∈Γ,πB∈Γ

EU(X(T )). (9)

where U(·) represents utility function and satisfies thecondition: the first-order derivative U(x) > 0 and thesecond-order derivative U(x) < 0.

3 The optimal portfolios

In this section, we apply dynamic programming prin-ciple and variable change technique to solve the prob-lem (9) and choose power utility and exponential util-ity for our analysis.

We define the value function J(t, r, x) of theproblem (9) as

J(t, r, x) = supπS∈Γ,πB∈Γ

E[U(X(T )) |X(t) = x, r(t) = r ]

with boundary condition: J(T, r, x) = U(x).Theorem 1.. Assume that J(t, r, x) is continu-

ously differentiable with respect to t ∈ [0, T ], andtwice continuously differentiable with respective to(r, x) ∈ R × R, then J(t, r, x) satisfies the follow-ing HJB equation:

supπS∈Γ,πB∈Γ

Jt + [rx+ πS(t)(ΣSΛ + Σrλrr)

+πB(t)σB(t)λr√r − u]Jx

+1

2[(π′S(t)ΣS − vρ′)2 + (v

√1− ∥ρ∥2)2

+(π′S(t)Σr

√r + πB(t)σB(t))

2]Jxx

+(a− br)Jr +1

2σ2rrJrr

− σr√r[π′S(t)Σr

√r + πB(t)σB(t)]Jxr

= 0. (10)

where Jt, Jr, Jrr, Jx, Jxx, Jxr represent the first-orderand second-order partial derivatives of the value func-tion with respect to the variables t, r, x.

Proof. According to Theorem 3.1 of Lin and Li(2011), we assume that

J(t, r, x) = supπS∈Γ,πB∈Γ

E[J(θ, r(θ), XπS ,πB (θ))].

For any stopping time θ ∈ ℜt,T , where ℜt,T repre-sents the set of all stopping time valued in [t, T ].

Considering the time θ = t+h, for arbitrary πS ∈Γ, πB ∈ Γ, we have

J(t, r, x) > E[J(t+ h, r(t+ h), XπS ,πB (t+ h))].

Applying Ito′s formula between t and t+ h, we have

J(t+ h, r(t+ h), XπS ,πB (t+ h)) = J(t, r, x)

+∫ t+ht (∂J∂t + ℓπS ,πBJ)(u, r(u), XπS ,πB (u))du+ lo-

cal martingale.where ℓπS ,πBJ is defined by

ℓπS ,πBJ = [rXt + πS(t)(ΣSΛ + Σrλrr)

+πB(t)σB(t)λr√r − u]Jx

+1

2[(π′S(t)ΣS − vρ′)2 + (v

√1− ∥ρ∥2)2

+(π′S(t)Σr

√r + πB(t)σB(t))

2]Jxx

+(a− br)Jr +1

2σ2rrJrr

−σr√r[π′S(t)Σr

√r + πB(t)σB(t)]Jxr.

Then we obtain∫ t+h

t(∂J

∂t+ ℓπS ,πBJ)(u, r(u), XπS ,πB (u))du 6 0.

Dividing by h and letting h→ 0, this leads to

∂J

∂t+ ℓπS ,πBJ 6 0.

On the other hand, suppose that π∗S ∈ Γ and π∗B ∈Γ are the optimal investment strategies, then we have

J(t, r, x) = E[J(t+ h, r(t+ h), Xπ∗S ,π

∗B (t+ h))].

By similar arguments as above, we obtain

∂J

∂t+ ℓπ

∗S ,π

∗BJ = 0.

Summarizing the above arguments, we obtain thatJ(t, r, x) should satisfy

∂J

∂t+ sup

πS∈Γ,πB∈ΓℓπS ,πBJ = 0.

This completes the proof of Theorem 1.The first-order maximizing conditions for the op-

timal strategy yield:

πS(t) = −(Σ′S)

−1ΛJxJxx

+ (Σ′S)

−1ρv, (11)

πB(t) = −λr

√r − Λ′Σ−1

S Σr√r

σB(t)· JxJxx

+σr√r

σB(t)· JrxJxx

−ρ′vΣ−1

S Σr√r

σB(t). (12)

WSEAS TRANSACTIONS on SYSTEMS and CONTROL Hao Chang, Ji-Mei Lu

E-ISSN: 2224-2856 258 Volume 9, 2014

Page 5: Utility portfolio optimization with liability and multiple ... › multimedia › journals › control › 2014 › a... · Utility portfolio optimization with liability and multiple

Plugging (11) and (12) into (10), we get

Jt + rxJx + (Λ′ρv − u)Jx

+1

2v2(1− ∥ρ∥2)Jxx + (a− br)Jr

+1

2σ2rrJrr −

1

2(∥Λ∥2 + λ2rr)

J2x

Jxx

+λrσrrJxJrxJxx

− 1

2σ2rr

J2rx

Jxx= 0. (13)

The following subsection, we try our best to solvethe second-order nonlinear partial differential equa-tion (13) by conjecturing the structure of the valuefunction.

3.1 Power utility

Assume that power utility is expressed as

U(x) =xη

η, η < 1, η = 0.

Conjecturing a solution to (13) with the followingform:

J(t, r, x) =(x− g(t, r))η

ηf(t, r),

g(T, r) = 0, f(T, r) = 1. (14)

The partial derivatives of (14) are given by

Jt = −(x− g)η−1gtf +(x− g)η

ηft,

Jr = −(x− g)η−1grf +(x− g)η

ηfr,

Jx = (x− g)η−1f,

Jxx = (η − 1)(x− g)η−2f,

Jrx = −(η − 1)(x− g)η−2grf + (x− g)η−1fr,

Jrr = (η − 1)(x− g)η−2g2rf +(x− g)η

ηfrr

−2(x− g)η−1frgr − (x− g)η−1grrf.

Putting the above partial derivatives in (13), we get

(x− g)η

η

[ft + (ηr − η

2(η − 1)(∥Λ∥2 + λ2rr))f

+(a− br +η

η − 1λrσrr)fr

+1

2σ2rrfrr −

η

2(η − 1)σ2rr

f2rf

]

+1

2(η − 1)(x− g)η−2v2(1− ∥ρ∥2)f

+(x− g)η−1 [gt + (a− br + λrσrr)gr

+1

2σ2rrgrr −rg − (Λ′ρv − u)

]= 0.

Eliminating the dependence on the variable x, weget the following two partial differential equations un-der the condition: 1− ∥ρ∥2 = 0.

ft + (ηr − η

2(η − 1)(∥Λ∥2 + λ2rr))f

+(a− br +η

η − 1λrσrr)fr +

1

2σ2rrfrr

− η

2(η − 1)σ2rr

f2rf

= 0, f(T, r) = 1; (15)

gt − rg + (a− br + λrσrr)gr

+1

2σ2rrgrr + u− Λ′ρv = 0, g(T, r) = 0. (16)

Lemma 1. Assume that the solution of (15) is ofthe structure f(t, r) = eD1(t)+D2(t)r with boundaryconditions: D1(T ) = 0 and D2(T ) = 0, then underthe condition: η < b2

(λrσr−b)2+2σ2r

, D1(t) and D2(t)

are given by (22) and (21), respectively.Proof. Substituting f(t, r) = eD1(t)+D2(t)r into

(15), we get

eD1(t)+D2(t)r

D1(t)−

η

2(η − 1)∥Λ∥2 + aD2(t)

+r[D2(t) + (η − η

2(η − 1)λ2r)

+(η

η − 1λrσr − b)D2(t)−

1

2(η − 1)σ2rD

22(t)]

= 0.

Further, we can get the following two equations:

D2(t) + (η − η

2(η − 1)λ2r) + (

η

η − 1λrσr − b)D2(t)

− 1

2(η − 1)σ2rD

22(t) = 0, D2(T ) = 0; (17)

D1(t)−η

2(η − 1)∥Λ∥2+aD2(t) = 0, D1(T ) = 0.

(18)The equation (17) can be rewritten as

1

m1 −m2

∫ T

t(

1

D2(t)−m1− 1

D2(t)−m2)dD2(t)

=σ2r

2(η − 1)(T − t). (19)

WSEAS TRANSACTIONS on SYSTEMS and CONTROL Hao Chang, Ji-Mei Lu

E-ISSN: 2224-2856 259 Volume 9, 2014

Page 6: Utility portfolio optimization with liability and multiple ... › multimedia › journals › control › 2014 › a... · Utility portfolio optimization with liability and multiple

where m1 and m2 are two different roots of the fol-lowing quadratic equation:

1

2(η − 1)σ2rD

22(t)− (

η

η − 1λrσr − b)D2(t)

−(η − η

2(η − 1)λ2r) = 0.

i.e. under the condition η < b2

(λrσr−b)2+2σ2r

, we get

m1,2 =ηλrσr − (η − 1)b

σ2r

±√η(η − 1)(λrσr − b)2 + (η − 1)(2ησ2r − b2)

σ2r.

(20)Solving the equation (19), we obtain

D2(t) =m1m2(1− exp σ2

r2(η−1)(m1 −m2)(T − t))

m1 −m2 · exp σ2r

2(η−1)(m1 −m2)(T − t).

(21)Integrating the both sides of (18), we get

D1(t) = a

∫ T

tD2(t)dt−

η

2(η − 1)∥Λ∥2 (T − t).

(22)Therefore, the proof of Lemma 1 is completed. Lemma 2. Suppose that the solution to (15) is of

the structure g(t, r) = (u− Λ′ρv)∫ Tt g(u, r)du, then

g(t, r) satisfies the following equation:

gt − rg + (a− br + λrσrr)gr

+1

2σ2rrgrr = 0, g(T, r) = 1. (23)

Proof. We introduce a differential operator as follows.

∇g = −rg + (a− br + λrσrr)gr +1

2σ2rrgrr.

Then (16) is rewritten as

gt +∇g + u− Λ′ρv = 0, g(T, r) = 0. (24)

Considering g(t, r) = (u − Λ′ρv)∫ Tt g(u, r)du,

we yieldgt = −(u− Λ′ρv)g(t, r)

= (u− Λ′ρv)(

∫ T

t

∂g(u, r)

∂udu− g(T, r)),

gr = (u− Λ′ρv)

∫ T

t

∂g(u, r)

∂rdu,

grr = (u− Λ′ρv)

∫ T

t

∂2g(u, r)

∂r2du.

Further, we have

∇g = (u− Λ′ρv)

∫ T

t∇g(u, r)du.

Inserting gt and ∇g into

(u− Λ′ρv)

∫ T

t[∂g(u, r)

∂u+∇g(u, r)]du

−(u− Λ′ρv)(g(T, r)− 1) = 0.

In fact, we have

∂g(u, r)

∂u+∇g(u, r) = 0, g(T, r) = 1.

The proof of Lemma 2 is completed. Lemma 3. Letting g(t, r) = eD3(t)+D4(t)r is the

solution to the equation (23), where boundary condi-tions are given by D3(T ) = 0 and D4(T ) = 0, thenD3(t) and D4(t) are determined by (28) and (27), re-spectively.

Proof. Putting g(t, r) = eD3(t)+D4(t)r in theequation (23) yields:

eD3(t)+D4(t)rD3(t) + aD4(t)

+[D4(t)− 1+(λrσr − b)D4(t)+1

2σ2rD

24(t)]r = 0.

We can decompose the above equation into thefollowing two equations in order to eliminate the de-pendence on r:

D4(t)− 1 + (λrσr − b)D4(t)

+1

2σ2rD

24(t) = 0, D4(t) = 0. (25)

D3(t) + aD4(t) = 0, D3(t) = 0. (26)

Using the same analysis as the equations (17) and(18), we derive

D4(t) =m3m4(1− exp−1

2σ2r (m3 −m4)(T − t))

m3 −m4 · exp−12σ

2r (m3 −m4)(T − t)

.

(27)

D3(t) = a

∫ T

tD4(t)dt. (28)

where m3 and m4 are given by

m3,4 =b− λrσrσ2r

±√

(b− λrσr)2 + 2σ2rσ2r

.

Therefore, we complete the proof of Lemma 3. Further, we have

JxJxx

=1

η − 1(x− g),

WSEAS TRANSACTIONS on SYSTEMS and CONTROL Hao Chang, Ji-Mei Lu

E-ISSN: 2224-2856 260 Volume 9, 2014

Page 7: Utility portfolio optimization with liability and multiple ... › multimedia › journals › control › 2014 › a... · Utility portfolio optimization with liability and multiple

JrxJxx

= −gr +1

η − 1(x− g)

frf

= −gr +1

η − 1(x− g)D2(t).

Finally, we obtain the optimal investment strate-gies in the power utility case.

Proposition 1. Assume that utility function isgiven by U(x) = xη

η , with η < 1 and η = 0, then

under the conditions: η < Min b2

(λrσr−b)2+2σ2r, 1,

η = 0 and ∥ρ∥2 = 1, the optimal investment strategiesof the problem (9) are given by

π∗S(t) =1

1− η(Σ′

S)−1Λ(X(t)− g) + (Σ′

S)−1ρv,

(29)

π∗B(t) =1

1− η·λr

√r(t)− Λ′Σ−1

S Σr

√r(t)

σB(t)(X(t)−g)+

σr√r(t)

σB(t)·( 1

η − 1(X(t)−g)D2(t)−gr)−

ρ′vΣ−1S Σr

√r(t)

σB(t).

(30)where g = g(t, r) = (u − Λ′ρv)

∫ Tt g(u, r)du,

g(t, r) = eD3(t)+D4(t)r, D2(t), D3(t) and D4(t) aregiven by (21), (28) and (27), respectively.

Remark1. If the liability is not considered, i.e.u = v = 0, then g = g(t, r) = 0. Therefore, theoptimal policy of the problem (9) for power utility isreduced to

π∗S(t) =1

1− η(Σ′

S)−1ΛX(t),

π∗B(t) =1

1− η·λr

√r(t)− Λ′Σ−1

S Σr

√r(t)

σB(t)X(t)+

1

η − 1·σr√r(t)

σB(t)X(t)D2(t).

where D2(t) is given by(21).Remark2. If η → 0, then we have D2(t) = 0.

It is all well-known that power utility is degeneratedto logarithm utility when η → 0. Hence, the optimalpolicy of the problem (9) is given by

π∗S(t) = (Σ′S)

−1Λ(X(t)− g) + (Σ′S)

−1ρv.

π∗B(t) =λr

√r(t)− Λ′Σ−1

S Σr

√r(t)

σB(t)(X(t)− g)+

σr√r(t)

σB(t)· (−gr)−

ρ′vΣ−1S Σr

√r(t)

σB(t).

where g = g(t, r) = (u − Λ′ρv)∫ Tt g(u, r)du,

g(t, r) = eD3(t)+D4(t)r, D3(t) and D4(t) are givenby (28) and (27), respectively.

3.2 Exponential utility

Assume that exponential utility is expressed as

U(x) = − 1

βe−βx, β > 0.

Further, we suppose that the solution to (13) is ofthe following structure

J(t, r, x) = − 1

βexp−βK(t, r)(x−L(t, r))+M(t, r).

(31)with boundary conditions: K(T, r) = 1, L(T, r) = 0,M(T, r) = 0.

Then we have

Jt = J(−βxKt + βKtL+ βKLt +Mt),

Jx = J(−βK), Jxx = J(−βK)2,

Jr = J(−βxKr + βKrL+ βKLr +Mr),

Jrx = J(−βK)(−βxKr+βKrL+βKLr+Mr+Kr

K),

Jrr = J(−βxKr + βKrL+ βKLr +Mr)2

+J(−βxKrr+βKrrL+2βKrLr+βKLrr+Mrr).(32)

Putting (32) into (13), after some calculations, we ob-tain

J −βx[Kt + rK + (a− br + λrσrr)Kr

+1

2σ2rrKrr − σ2rr

K2r

K]

+βK

[L

K(Kt + (a− br + λrσrr)Kr +

1

2σ2rrKrr

−σ2rrK2

r

K) + Lt + (a− br + λrσrr)Lr

+1

2σ2rrLrr + u− Λ′ρv +

1

2v2(1− ∥ρ∥2)βK

]+Mt + (a− br + λrσrr − σ2rr

Kr

K)Mr +

1

2σ2rrMrr

−1

2(∥Λ∥2 + λ2rr + σ2rr(

Kr

K)2 − 2λrσrr

Kr

K)

= 0.

(33)Eliminating the dependence on the variable x, we

can decompose (33) into the following three partialdifferential equations:

Kt + rK + (a− br + λrσrr)Kr

+1

2σ2rrKrr − σ2rr

K2r

K= 0, K(T, r) = 1; (34)

WSEAS TRANSACTIONS on SYSTEMS and CONTROL Hao Chang, Ji-Mei Lu

E-ISSN: 2224-2856 261 Volume 9, 2014

Page 8: Utility portfolio optimization with liability and multiple ... › multimedia › journals › control › 2014 › a... · Utility portfolio optimization with liability and multiple

βK

[L

K(Kt + (a− br + λrσrr)Kr

+1

2σ2rrKrr − σ2rr

K2r

K) + Lt + u− Λ′ρv

+1

2σ2rrLrr + (a− br + λrσrr)Lr

+1

2v2(1− ∥ρ∥2)βK

]= 0, L(T, r) = 0; (35)

Mt + (a− br + λrσrr − σ2rrKr

K)Mr +

1

2σ2rrMrr

−1

2(∥Λ∥2 + λ2rr + σ2rr(

Kr

K)2 − 2λrσrr

Kr

K) = 0.

(36)Lemma 4. Assume that the solution to (34) is

of the form: K(t, r) = eD5(t)+D6(t)r, with boundaryconditions given by D5(T ) = 0 and D6(T ) = 0, thenD6(t) and D5(t) are determined by (39) and (40), re-spectively.

Proof. Plugging K(t, r) = eD5(t)+D6(t)r into(34) yields

eD5(t)+D6(t)rD5(t) + aD6(t)

+[D6(t)+1+(λrσr − b)D6(t)−1

2σ2rD

26(t)]r = 0.

Then we have

D6(t)+1+(λrσr−b)D6(t)−1

2σ2rD

26(t) = 0, (37)

D5(t) + aD6(t) = 0. (38)

Solving (37) and (38), we get

D6(t) =m5m6(1− exp1

2σ2r (m5 −m6)(T − t))

m5 −m6 · exp12σ

2r (m5 −m6)(T − t)

,

(39)

D5(t) = a

∫ T

tD6(t)dt. (40)

where m5 and m6 are given by

m5,6 =λrσr − b

σ2r±

√(b− λrσr)2 + 2σ2r

σ2r.

The proof is completed. Lemma 5. Suppose that the solution to (35) is

L(t, r) = (u − Λ′ρv)∫ Tt L(u, r)du and L(t, r) =

eD7(t)+D8(t)r, with boundary conditions: D7(T ) = 0

and D8(T ) = 0, then under the condition ∥ρ∥2 = 1,we obtain D8(t) = D4(t) and D7(t) = D3(t).

Proof. Taking (34) and the condition ∥ρ∥2 = 1into considerations, we get

Lt − rL+ (a− br + λrσrr)Lr

+1

2σ2rrLrr + u− Λ′ρv = 0, L(T, r) = 0. (41)

Applying the same approach as (16) and referringto the proof of Lemma 2 and Lemma 3, we can easilyget the results of Lemma 5.

Lemma 6. Assume that the solution to (36) is ex-pressed asM(t, r) = D9(t)+D10(t)r, with boundaryconditions given by D9(T ) = 0 and D10(T ) = 0,then D10(t) and D9(t) are determined by (45) and(46), respectively.

Proof. Introducing M(t, r) = D9(t) + D10(t)rin the equation (36), we derive

D9(t) + aD10(t)−1

2∥Λ∥2

+r[D10(t) + (λrσr − b− σ2rD6(t))D10(t)

−1

2(λr − σrD6(t))

2] = 0. (42)

Comparing the coefficients on the both sides of (42),we get

D10(t) + (λrσr − b− σ2rD6(t))D10(t)

−1

2(λr − σrD6(t))

2 = 0, D10(T ) = 0; (43)

D9(t)+aD10(t)−1

2∥Λ∥2 = 0, D9(T ) = 0. (44)

Solving (43) and (44) yields:

D10(t) = −1

2e−

∫ t0 (λrσr−b−σ2

rD6(t))dt

·∫ T

t(λr − σrD6(t))

2e∫ t0 (λrσr−b−σ2

rD6(t))dtdt,

(45)

D9(t) = a

∫ T

tD10(t)dt−

1

2∥Λ∥2 (T − t). (46)

The proof of Lemma 6 is completed. Further, applying (32) and the results of Lemma

4, Lemma 5 and Lemma 6, we have

JxJxx

= − 1

βK,

JrxJxx

=Kr

Kx− Kr

KL− Lr −

Mr

βK− Kr

βK2

= D6(t)(x− L)− Lr −1

βK(D10(t) +D6(t)).

Finally, we can summarize the optimal investmentstrategies of the problem (9) for exponential utilitymaximization in the following Proposition 2.

WSEAS TRANSACTIONS on SYSTEMS and CONTROL Hao Chang, Ji-Mei Lu

E-ISSN: 2224-2856 262 Volume 9, 2014

Page 9: Utility portfolio optimization with liability and multiple ... › multimedia › journals › control › 2014 › a... · Utility portfolio optimization with liability and multiple

Proposition 2. If utility function is given byU(x) = − 1

β e−βx, β > 0, then under the condition

∥ρ∥2 = 1, the optimal policies of the problem (9) are

π∗S(t) =1

βK(Σ′

S)−1Λ + (Σ′

S)−1ρv, (47)

π∗B(t) =1

βK·λr

√r(t)− Λ′Σ−1

S Σr

√r(t)

σB(t)

+σr√r(t)

σB(t)· [D6(t)(X(t)− L)− Lr

− 1

βK(D10(t) +D6(t))]−

ρ′vΣ−1S Σr

√r(t)

σB(t). (48)

where K = K(t, r) = eD5(t)+D6(t)r, L = L(t, r) =

(u − Λ′ρv)∫ Tt L(u, r)du, L(t, r) = eD7(t)+D8(t)r,

D5(t), D6(t), D7(t), D8(t) and D10(t) are given byLemma 4-Lemma 6.

Remark3. If there is no liability, i.e. u = v =0, and it leads to L = L(t, r) = 0. Therefore, theoptimal policies with CIR interest rate dynamics forexponential utility ate given by

π∗S(t) =1

βK(Σ′

S)−1Λ,

π∗B(t) =1

βK·λr

√r(t)− Λ′Σ−1

S Σr

√r(t)

σB(t)+

σr√r(t)

σB(t)· [D6(t)X(t)− 1

βK(D10(t) +D6(t))].

where K = K(t, r) = eD5(t)+D6(t)r, in addition,D5(t), D6(t) andD10(t) are given by (40), (39), (45),respectively.

4 Numerical analysis

This section provides a numerical example to illus-trate the impact of market parameters on the optimalinvestment strategy. Assume that the financial marketis composed of one risk-free asset and two risky as-sets and one zero-coupon bond. Throughout this sec-tion, unless otherwise stated, the basic parameters aregiven by a = 0.35, b = 0.4, σr = 0.1, r(0) = 0.05,Λ = (0.4, 0.6)′, Σr = (0.16, 0.32)′, λr = 0.16,u = 200, v = 300, ρ = (0.6, 0.8)′, t = 0, T = 2,

X(0) = 1000, ΣS =

(1.68 0.680.68 1.46

). Notice that in

the following figures, the amount invested in the bankaccount is denoted by the thick line, i.e. π∗0(t), and thesum of the amount invested in the stocks is given bythe dashed line, i.e.

∑2i=1 π

∗i (t), and the amount in-

vested in the zero-coupon bond is represented by theorange line, i.e. π∗B(t).

4.1 Sensitivity analysis in the power utilitycase

Under power utility, assume that the risky aversionfactor is given by η = −0.2. It can be seen from ev-ery gragh of Fig.1-Fig.6 that how market parametersaffect the optimal investment strategy. Some resultsare summarized as follows.

(a1)∑2

i=1 π∗i (t) is not sensitive to the parameter

b, and π∗B(t) increases with respect to (w.r.t) the valueof b, and π∗0(t) decreases w.r.t the parameter b. It isshown from the equation (1) that the expected value ofinterest rate will decrease with the increasing value ofb. It means that the the bigger the value of b becomes,the smaller amount an investor invests the risk-free as-set and the bigger amount in the zero-coupon bond.

(a2)∑2

i=1 π∗i (t) is not sensitive to the parameter

σr as well, and π∗B(t) decreases in the value of σr,and π∗0(t) is increasing with the parameter σr. Noticethat when the value of σr is increasing, the volatilityof interest rate is increasing as well. So, it tells usthat an investor should invest the less amount in thezero-coupon bond and invest the more amount in therisk-free asset.

(a3)∑2

i=1 π∗i (t) and π∗B(t) are all decreasing

with the increasing value of the parameter u, andπ∗0(t) increases w.r.t the parameter u. Noting that thebigger the value of u is, the bigger the expected valueof liability is. It displays that an investor should investthe less amount of wealth in the risky assets and investthe more amount in the risk-free asset.

(a4)∑2

i=1 π∗i (t) and π∗B(t) increases w.r.t the pa-

rameter v, and π∗0(t) decreases w.r.t the paremeter v.In fact, the parameter v represents the volatility of li-ability. Hence, the larger the value of v is, the morerisk the liability results into. It illustates that an in-vestor should invest the more amount of wealth in therisky assets and invests the less amount in the risk-freeasset in order to hedge the risk of liability.

(a5)∑2

i=1 π∗i (t) keeps fixed almost with the in-

vestment horizon T , while π∗B(t) decreases w.r.t theparameter T and π∗0(t) increases w.r.t the value of T .It shows that π∗B(t) is decreasing and π∗0(t) is increas-ing when the value of T is increasing. In fact, thebigger the value of T is, the bigger the value of T − tis. Hence, it indicates that as time t elapses, an in-vestor should invest the more amount of wealth in thezero-coupon bond and keeps the less amount in therisk-free asset.

(a6)∑2

i=1 π∗i (t) and π∗B(t) increases w.r.t risk

aversion factor η and π∗0(t) decreases w.r.t the valueof η. Under power utility, the risk aversion coefficientof an investor is denoted by 1−η. Therefore, when thevalue of η is increasing, the risk aversion agree of in-vestor is decreasing. It leads to that an investor would

WSEAS TRANSACTIONS on SYSTEMS and CONTROL Hao Chang, Ji-Mei Lu

E-ISSN: 2224-2856 263 Volume 9, 2014

Page 10: Utility portfolio optimization with liability and multiple ... › multimedia › journals › control › 2014 › a... · Utility portfolio optimization with liability and multiple

invest the more amount of wealth in the risky assetsand invest the less amount in the risk-free asset.

4.2 Sensitivity analysis in the exponentialutility case

Under exponential utility, suppose that β = 0.001 andλr = 0.01, the other market parameters keep fixed.Fig.7-Fig.12 illustrate that how market parameters im-pact on the optimal investment strategy. In addition,the following conclusions are drawn.

(b1)∑2

i=1 π∗i (t) is not sensitive to the parameter

b, while π∗B(t) increases with respect to b and π∗0(t)decreases with respect to b. This is to say, the big-ger the value of b is, the more amount of wealth aninvestor invests in the zero-coupon bond and the lessamount in the risk-free asset.

(b2)∑2

i=1 π∗i (t) keeps fixed almost w.r.t the pa-

rameter σr, in the meantime, π∗B(t) decreases w.r.t theparameter b and π∗0(t) increases w.r.t the value of b. Itimplies that as the value of b becomes larger, an in-vestor should invest the less amount of wealth in thezero-coupon bond and invest the more amount in therisk-free asset.

(b3)∑2

i=1 π∗i (t) is fixed in the value of λr, while

π∗B(t) is decreasing with the value of λr and π∗0(t) isincreasing. It indicates that when the value of λr be-come larger, an investor should invest the less amountof wealth in the zero-coupon bond and invest the moreamount in the risk-free asset.

(b4)∑2

i=1 π∗i (t) and π∗B(t) increases with respect

to the parameter v, while π∗0(t) decreases w.r.t thevalue of v. It tells us that when the volatility of liabil-ity is increasing, the investor should invest the moreamount of wealth in the risky assets in order to hedgethe risk resulted from the liability.

(b5)∑2

i=1 π∗i (t) and π∗B(t) is decreasing in the

value of T , while π∗0(t) increases w.r.t the parameterT . It implies that as time elapses, an investor wouldtake more risk and invest more money in the risky as-sets.

(b6)∑2

i=1 π∗i (t) and π∗B(t) decreases with the

value of β, while π∗0(t) increases w.r.t the parameterβ. It is well-known that the risk aversion coefficient inthe exponential utility case is given by β. Therefore,the bigger the value of β is, the more risk aversion aninvestor is faced with. This is the reason why an in-vestor would invest less money in the risky assets andinvest more money in the risk-free asset.

5 Conclusions

In this paper, we have studied an asset and liabilitymanagement problem with CIR interest rate dynam-

0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0

0

100

200

300

400

500

b

opti

mal

inve

stm

ents

trat

egy

bank account

zero-couponstock

Figure 1: The impact of b on the optimal policies withpower preference

0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5

-400

-200

0

200

400

600

800

Σr

optim

alin

vest

men

tstr

ateg

y

bank account

zero-couponstock

Figure 2: The impact of σr on the optimal policieswith power preference

100 200 300 400 500-100

0

100

200

300

400

500

600

u

optim

alin

vest

men

tstr

ateg

y

bank account

zero-couponstock

Figure 3: The impact of u on the optimal policies withpower preference

WSEAS TRANSACTIONS on SYSTEMS and CONTROL Hao Chang, Ji-Mei Lu

E-ISSN: 2224-2856 264 Volume 9, 2014

Page 11: Utility portfolio optimization with liability and multiple ... › multimedia › journals › control › 2014 › a... · Utility portfolio optimization with liability and multiple

100 200 300 400 500

-200

0

200

400

600

800

1000

v

opti

mal

inve

stm

ents

trat

egy

bank account

zero-couponstock

Figure 4: The impact of v on the optimal policies withpower preference

1 2 3 4 5

0

100

200

300

400

500

600

T

optim

alin

vest

men

tstr

ateg

y

bank account

zero-couponstock

Figure 5: The impact of T on the optimal policies withpower preference

-2.0 -1.5 -1.0 -0.5 0.0 0.5

-1000

-500

0

500

1000

Η

optim

alin

vest

men

tstr

ateg

y

bank account

zero-couponstock

Figure 6: The impact of η on the optimal policies withpower preference

0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8

-200

0

200

400

600

800

1000

b

optim

alin

vest

men

tstr

ateg

y bank account

zero-couponstock

Figure 7: The impact of b on the optimal policies withexponential preference

0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6

-500

0

500

1000

1500

Σr

optim

alin

vest

men

tstr

ateg

y

bank account

zero-couponstock

Figure 8: The impact of σr on the optimal policieswith exponential preference

0.05 0.10 0.15 0.20 0.25 0.30

-500

0

500

1000

Λr

optim

alin

vest

men

tstr

ateg

y

bank account

zero-couponstock

Figure 9: The impact of λr on the optimal policieswith exponential preference

WSEAS TRANSACTIONS on SYSTEMS and CONTROL Hao Chang, Ji-Mei Lu

E-ISSN: 2224-2856 265 Volume 9, 2014

Page 12: Utility portfolio optimization with liability and multiple ... › multimedia › journals › control › 2014 › a... · Utility portfolio optimization with liability and multiple

100 200 300 400 500

-200

0

200

400

600

800

1000

v

opti

mal

inve

stm

ents

trat

egy

bank account

zero-couponstock

Figure 10: The impact of v on the optimal policieswith exponential preference

1 2 3 4 5-1000

-500

0

500

1000

1500

T

optim

alin

vest

men

tstr

ateg

y

bank account

zero-couponstock

Figure 11: The impact of T on the optimal policieswith exponential preference

0.0006 0.0008 0.0010 0.0012 0.0014 0.0016 0.0018 0.0020

-200

0

200

400

600

800

1000

Β

opti

mal

inve

stm

ents

trat

egy bank account

zero-couponstock

Figure 12: The impact of β on the optimal policieswith exponential preference

ics. The financial market is composed of one risk-freeasset and multiple risky assets and one zero-couponbond. The liability process is assumed to be driven byBrownian motion with drift and be generally corre-lated with stock price dynamics, while the price pro-cesses of stocks and zero-coupon are affected by in-terest rate dynamics. The closed-form solutions tothe optimal investment strategies for power utility andexponential utility are obtained. We also present anumerical example to analyze the influence of mar-ket parameters on the optimal investment strategiesand provide some economic implications. Some im-portant results are found: (i) the optimal investmentstrategy with liability and stochastic interest rate ismore sophisticated than that with stochastic interestrate only; (ii) the optimal policies for power and expo-nential utility have opposite trend with respect to riskaversion factor; (iii) the optimal policies for powerand exponential utility almost have the same trend inthe value of the parameter b, σr, v, T .

In future research on the asset and liability man-agement problem, it would be interesting to extendour model to the following two aspects. On theone hand, we can consider the ALM problem withstochastic interest rate dynamics in the mean-varianceframework and aim to obtain the closed-form solutionto the optimal policy and efficient frontier. On theother hand, we can also consider the ALM problemwith other stochastic dynamics in the HARA frame-work and expect to achieve the explicit expression ofthe optimal policy, for example, Heston’s stochasticvolatility and CEV model and so on. In those situa-tions, it may be difficult to guess the form of the valuefunction, and it needs us to explore new methodology.

Acknowledgements: The research was sup-ported by the Humanities and Social Science Re-search Youth Foundation of Ministry of Education(No:11YJC790006), the Higher School Science andTechnology Development Foundation of Tianjin (No:20100821).

References:

[1] O.A. Vasicek, An equilibrium characterizationof the term structure, Journal of Financial Eco-nomics. 5, 1977, pp. 177–188.

[2] J.C. Cox, J.E. Ingersoll, S.A.Ross, A theory ofthe term structure of interest rates, Economet-rica. 53, 1985, pp. 385–408.

[3] R. Stanton, A nonparametric model of termstructure dynamics and the market price of inter-est rate risk, The Journal of Finance. 52, 1997,pp. 1973–2002.

WSEAS TRANSACTIONS on SYSTEMS and CONTROL Hao Chang, Ji-Mei Lu

E-ISSN: 2224-2856 266 Volume 9, 2014

Page 13: Utility portfolio optimization with liability and multiple ... › multimedia › journals › control › 2014 › a... · Utility portfolio optimization with liability and multiple

[4] R. Korn, H. Kraft, A stochastic control approachto portfolio problems with stochastic interestrates, SIAM Journal of Control and optimization.40, 2001, pp. 1250–1269.

[5] G. Deelstra, M. Grasselli, P.F. Koehl, Optimalinvestment strategies in a CIR framework, Jour-nal of Applied Probability. 37, 2000, pp. 936–946.

[6] G. Deelstra, M. Grasselli, P.F. Koehl, Optimalinvestment strategies in the presence of a min-imum guarantee, Insurance: Mathematics andEconomics. 33, 2003, pp. 189–207.

[7] M. Grasselli, A stability result for the HARAclass with stochastic interest rates, Insurance:Mathematics and Economics. 33, 2003, pp. 611–627.

[8] T.R. Bielecki, S. Pliska, S.J. Sheu, Risk Sensi-tive Portfolio Management with Cox-Ingersoll-Ross Interest Rates:The HJB Equation, SIAMJournal on Control and Optimization. 44, 2005,pp. 1811–1843.

[9] J. Liu, Portfolio selection in stochastic envi-ronments, The Review of Financial Studies. 20,2007, pp. 1–39.

[10] J.W. Gao, Stochastic optimal control of DC pen-sion funds, Insurance: Mathematics and Eco-nomics. 42, 2008, pp. 1159–1164.

[11] J.Z. Li, R. Wu, Optimal investment problem withstochastic interest rate and stochastic volatility:maximizing a power utility, Applied StochasticModels in Business and Industry. 25, 2009, pp.407–420.

[12] R. Ferland, F. Watier, Mean–variance effi-ciency with extended CIR interest rates, AppliedStochastic Models in Business and Industry. 26,2010, pp. 71–84.

[13] M. Leippold, F. Trojani, P.A. Vanini, geomet-ric approach to multi-period mean-variance op-timization of assets and liabilities, Journal ofEconomics Dynamics and Control. 28, 2004, pp.1079–1113.

[14] L. Yi, Z.F. Li, D. Li, Multi-period portfolio se-lection for asset–liability management with un-certain investment horizon, Journal of Indus-trial and Management Optimization. 4, 2008,pp. 535–552.

[15] P. Chen, H.L. Yang, Markowitz’s mean–varianceasset–liability management with regime switch-ing: a multi-period model, Applied Mathemati-cal Finance. 18, 2011, pp. 29–50.

[16] H.X. Yao, Y. Zeng, S.M. Chen, Multi-periodmean–variance asset–liability management withuncontrolled cash flow and uncertain time-horizon,Economic Modelling. 30, 2013, pp.492–500.

[17] M.C. Chiu, D. Li, Asset and liability manage-ment under a continuous-time mean-varianceoptimization framework, Insurance: Mathemat-ics and Economics. 39, 2006, pp. 330–355.

[18] S.X. Xie, Z.F. Li, S.Y. Wang, Continuous-timeportfolio selection with liability: mean-variancemodel and stochastic LQ approach, Insurance:Mathematics and Economics. 42, 2008, pp. 943–953.

[19] Y. Zeng, Z.F. Li, Asset–liability managementunder benchmark and mean–variance criteria ina jump diffusion market, Journal of Systems Sci-ence and Complexity. 24, 2011, pp. 317–327.

[20] P, Chen, H.L. Yang, G. Yin, Markowitz’smean–variance asset–liability management withregime switching: a continuous-time model,Insurance: Mathematics and Economics. 43,2008, pp. 456–465.

[21] S.X. Xie, Continuous-time mean–variance port-folio selection with liability and regime switch-ing, Insurance: Mathematics and Economics.45, 2009, pp. 148–155.

[22] Z.C. Li, H.S. Shu, Optimal portfolio selectionwith liability management and Markov switch-ing under constrained variance, Computers andMathematics with Applications. 61, 2011, pp.2271–2277.

[23] M.C. Chiu , H.Y. Wong, Mean–variance portfo-lio selection of cointegrated assets, Journal ofEconomic Dynamics and Control. 35, 2011, pp.1369–1385.

[24] M.C. Chiu, H.Y. Wong, Optimal investment forinsurer with cointegrated assets: CRRA util-ity, Insurance: Mathematics and Economics. 52,2013, pp. 52–64.

[25] M.C. Chiu, H.Y. Wong, Mean-variance asset-liability management: cointegrated assets andinsurance liabilities, European Journal of Oper-ational Research. 223, 2012, pp. 785–793.

[26] M.C. Chiu, H.Y. Wong, Mean-variance principleof managing cointegrated risky assets and ran-dom liabilities, Operations Research Letters. 41,2013, pp. 98–106.

[27] M. Leippold, F. Trojani, P. Vanini, Multi-periodmean–variance efficient portfolios with endoge-nous liabilities, Quantitative Finance. 11, 2011,pp. 1535–1546.

[28] H.X. Yao, Y.Z. Lai, Y. Li, Continuous-timemean–variance asset–liability management withendogenous liabilities, Insurance: Mathematicsand Economics. 52, 2013, pp. 6–17.

WSEAS TRANSACTIONS on SYSTEMS and CONTROL Hao Chang, Ji-Mei Lu

E-ISSN: 2224-2856 267 Volume 9, 2014

Page 14: Utility portfolio optimization with liability and multiple ... › multimedia › journals › control › 2014 › a... · Utility portfolio optimization with liability and multiple

[29] X. Lin, Y.F. Li, Optimal reinsurance and invest-ment for a jump diffusion risk process under theCEV Model, North American Actuarial Journal.15, 2011, pp. 417–431.

WSEAS TRANSACTIONS on SYSTEMS and CONTROL Hao Chang, Ji-Mei Lu

E-ISSN: 2224-2856 268 Volume 9, 2014