33
1 The intergenerational elasticity of income in the United States is rising in tandem with income inequality and returns to schooling Moshe Justman, a Anna Krush, b Hadas Millo c Abstract We examine the hypothesis that intergenerational mobility in the United States has decreased while inequality and returns to schooling have risen among white males born between 1952 and 1979, using linked parent-child data from the United States Panel Study of Income Dynamics. In a two-stage process, we first estimate lifetime family income for fathers and lifetime earnings for sons within a succession of overlapping ten-year cohort groups. We then estimate the intergenerational elasticity of income (an inverse measure of intergenerational mobility), the 90-10 gap in the logarithm of lifetime earnings, and the average return to a year of schooling within each ten-year cohort group. We find that all three time-series are increasing—the intergenerational elasticity of income increased annually by 0.01, on average—and exhibit correlations of 0.85 and higher between each pair of measures. Intergenerational correlations of the logarithm of income or of income rank have not been rising. JEL codes: D31, I32 a Department of Economics, Ben Gurion University, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research, The University of Melbourne, and School of Economics and Management, Ruppin Academic Center; corresponding author, [email protected]. b Department of Economics, Ben Gurion University; [email protected] c Department of Economics, Ben Gurion University; [email protected]

The intergenerational elasticity of income in the United ... · JEL codes: D31, I32 . a. Department of Economics, Ben Gurion University, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    2

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

1

The intergenerational elasticity of income in the United States is rising in tandem with income

inequality and returns to schooling

Moshe Justman,a Anna Krush,b Hadas Millo c

Abstract

We examine the hypothesis that intergenerational mobility in the United States has

decreased while inequality and returns to schooling have risen among white males

born between 1952 and 1979, using linked parent-child data from the United States

Panel Study of Income Dynamics. In a two-stage process, we first estimate lifetime

family income for fathers and lifetime earnings for sons within a succession of

overlapping ten-year cohort groups. We then estimate the intergenerational elasticity

of income (an inverse measure of intergenerational mobility), the 90-10 gap in the

logarithm of lifetime earnings, and the average return to a year of schooling within

each ten-year cohort group. We find that all three time-series are increasing—the

intergenerational elasticity of income increased annually by 0.01, on average—and

exhibit correlations of 0.85 and higher between each pair of measures.

Intergenerational correlations of the logarithm of income or of income rank have not

been rising.

JEL codes: D31, I32

a Department of Economics, Ben Gurion University, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research, The University of Melbourne, and School of Economics and Management, Ruppin Academic Center; corresponding author, [email protected]. b Department of Economics, Ben Gurion University; [email protected] c Department of Economics, Ben Gurion University; [email protected]

2

1. Introduction

Increased income inequality has heightened interest in estimating recent trends in

intergenerational income mobility, in order to determine whether this observed rise in

inequality has been offset by increased economic opportunity or aggravated by

reduced mobility. Solon (2004), following Becker and Tomes (1979), has argued on

theoretical grounds that intergenerational mobility should fall when inequality and

returns to human capital rise. Parents with higher income have more resources to

invest in their children's human capital, and the higher the return to human capital the

stronger their incentive to do so.1 Thus, greater variance in parents' income reduces

mobility, and a high return on human capital further increases inequality in outcomes

between children of the rich and the poor.

We test this hypothesis by comparing trends in intergenerational mobility,

inequality and returns to schooling among white males in the United States born

between 1952 and 1979 using individually linked parent-child data from the United

States Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID). Following Justman and Krush

(2013), our analysis proceeds in two stages. In the first stage, we estimate fathers’

lifetime family income and son’s lifetime earnings for our sample of father-son pairs.

In the second stage, we estimate intergenerational mobility in each year as the

intergenerational elasticity of lifetime labor income of white males in a rolling ten-

year cohort group with respect to their fathers’ lifetime family income.2 We estimate

income inequality, in that year, as the 90-10 gap in the logarithm of lifetime earnings

among this same group of sons; and returns to schooling in that year by regressing the

1 They also invest more nonfinancial resources in their children (Jerrim and Macmillan, 2015). 2 Women's participation in the work force changed markedly in this period, and combining men and women in the same analysis would introduce an added layer of complexity. We also exclude non-white men because of the small number of usable observations in the PSID (we expand on this below).

3

logarithm of lifetime labor income on years of schooling, again for the same ten-year

cohort group. We find a rising trend in the intergenerational elasticity of income, with

an average annual increase of 0.010, implying a decline in intergenerational mobility,

and strong positive correlations, ranging from 0.85 to 0.92, between each pair of

outcome variables. Thus, we find that the recent rise in earnings inequality in the

United States has been accompanied by reduced intergenerational mobility and rising

returns to human capital, supporting Solon's hypothesis. Sensitivity tests indicate that

these findings are not sensitive to the composition of the sample, or how inequality or

returns to schooling are measured, but they are sensitive to the measure of

intergenerational mobility. There has not been a decline in the correlation of log-

income or in the rank correlation of income across generations.

This is broadly consistent with existing empirical evidence, which provides

some indirect support for Solon’s thesis. Cross-country regressions over a subset of

OECD countries find a negative correlation between intergenerational mobility and

income inequality (sometimes referred to as the "Great Gatsby Curve") and a negative

association between intergenerational mobility and returns to human capital (Blanden,

2013; Corak, 2013).3 However, this is at most indicative as Solon’s theory referred to

trends in a single country; and cross-country analyses combine data from varying

sources, often with differently defined outcome measures, and their conclusions may

reflect other dimensions along which countries differ.4

3 Corak and Blanden both measure mobility as the intergenerational elasticity of income. Corak measures inequality as the Gini coefficient of annual income; Blanden also looks at the 90-10 and 80-20 earnings ratios and the share of child poverty. Corak measures returns to human capital as the college premium; Blanden also considers the average return to a year of schooling. 4For example, Scandinavian countries have comprehensive registry data, which reduces measurement error, compared to studies of the United States studies that use much sparser panel data (Marks, 2014, p.231). Countries also differ in how the IGE varies with income (Bratsberg, et al. 2007).

4

Results from within-country studies are mixed. Blanden, Gregg and

Macmillan (2007) use longitudinal survey data to compare two birth cohorts in the

United Kingdom, and find that returns to higher education and the intergenerational

elasticity of income are both significantly higher for the younger cohort, also

supporting Solon's hypothesis. However, subsequent findings of strong year-to-year

fluctuations in intergenerational elasticity (see below) imply that comparing just two

cohorts may not be sufficient to establish a trend. Aaronson and Mazumder’s (2008)

time-series analysis of United States decennial census data from 1950 to 2000 finds a

negative trend in intergenerational mobility; juxtaposed with Katz and Autor’s (1999)

finding of rising inequality and Goldin and Katz’s (1999) finding of increased returns

to education, this, too, is consistent with Solon’s hypothesis. However, as Aaronson

and Mazumder’s data is not linked across generations, they use child's state-of-birth to

instrument for parental income. This assumes a stable relation between parental

income and state of residence, which may be undermined by changes in geographic

patterns of earnings in the half-century covered by the study.5

Closer to our approach, analyses of annual variation over time in

intergenerational mobility in the United States using linked parent-child data from the

PSID covering the older cohorts in our sample—including Mayer and Lopoo (2005),

Lee and Solon (2006, 2009), Hertz (2007)—generally do not find significant trends

among males. This may be attributed to the strong year-to-year fluctuations of their

annual estimates, and the short periods they are able to examine, due to data

limitations, which make it difficult to uncover any underlying trends.6 A more recent

5 In addition, Katz and Autor (1999) and Goldin and Katz (1999) use different subsets of census data. 6 See, e.g., figure 1 in Lee and Solon (2009) and figure 4 in Hertz (2007). Mayer and Lopoo (2005) consider sons born between 1949 and 1965; and Lee and Solon (2009) and Hertz (2007) consider sons born between 1952 and 1979, using data to 2000. None of these find a precisely measured zero trend.

5

study by Chetty, Hendren, Kline and Saez (2014) using tax records on very large

samples measures intergenerational mobility as within-cohort rank correlations, a very

different measure to intergenerational elasticity, and also find no trend. As their data

is available only for recent cohorts they focus their analysis on children born between

1971 and 1993, a much later span than the cohorts we study. Moreover, for their

longest time series they consider income in a single year for both parents and

children; and for cohorts born after 1986, consider college enrolment at age 19 instead

of income rank.

Two key elements of our research design set it apart from previous efforts.

The first is our focus on a moving ten-year cohort group. Our point of departure is the

notion that the intergenerational elasticity of income in an economy in a given year

refers to its working-age population in that year, estimated by regressing the logarithm

of their lifetime incomes on the logarithm of their parents' lifetime incomes.7

However, this is impossible to estimate from a full set of data even for a single year,

as it would require more than a century of longitudinal data to measure the lifetime

income of the current workforce and their parents, and could only be determined with

a very long lag.8 The PSID, the longest available series of longitudinal data, runs from

1968, with 2012 the latest year available for this study.

There are inherent tradeoffs between the accuracy with which we are able to

estimate lifetime income, the span of cohorts representing the population in a given

year, and the period of time over which we can estimate a trend. The need to identify

father-son pairs requires that we observe sons initially living with their fathers, and so

7 Conceptually, this is closest to the approach taken by Lee and Solon (2006, 2009) and Hertz (2007). 8 The lifetime income of currently active workers who have recently entered the workforce will not be known for decades, and even a reasonable approximation can only be obtained after some years.

6

to minimize self-selection, we choose as our oldest cohort sons born in 1952, who

turned 18 in 1968, the first year of the PSID. At the other end of the spectrum, to

allow us to obtain reliable estimates of lifetime income, we limit our sample to sons

born no later than 1979, for whom we have observations on income at age 33 or older.

Altogether, we have 28 successive cohorts. Following single cohorts implicitly

assumes that the only relevant comparisons are to people of one’s own exact age. We

set the size of our cohort group at ten years, which allows us to follow our outcome

variables over 19 years. Identifying a cohort-year with a calendar year is arbitrary. It

seems intuitive to identify calendar years with sons’ prime working ages, when they

are in their thirties or forties. To fix ideas, we describe our study as following the

intergenerational elasticity of income, income inequality and returns to schooling of

36-45 year-old white males between 1998 and 2015; we could equivalently say, for

example, that we are following 33-42 year olds from 1995 to 2012.

A second key element is our use of lifetime income to estimate all three

outcomes, using a two-stage procedure. This is a marked departure with regard to

income inequality, which conventionally refers to the dispersion of annual income in

the population. However, inequality measures based on annual income introduce

spurious demographic effects when compared to measures of mobility in lifetime

income, as they are strongly affected by the age distribution of the population in that

year, confounding the comparison to intergenerational mobility.9 By measuring it

with respect to lifetime income we avoid this problem.

Specifically, in the first stage, we estimate Mincer equations within each ten-

year cohort group to predict separately fathers' family income and sons' earnings at

9 Thus, in the extreme case in which everyone had the same lifetime income, the age distribution of the population introduce considerable variation in annual income.

7

age forty, which we take as proxies for lifetime income and earnings, repeating the

estimation within each cohort-group to allow the age structure of income to vary over

time.10 To minimize classical measurement error we utilize all available observations

on fathers' family income and sons' earnings; and exclude fathers with less than five

positive observations until the age of 64 and sons with less than three non-missing

observations from the age of 29. In the second stage, we use these estimates to

estimate annual intergenerational elasticities, the 90-10 log income gap, and returns to

schooling, and compare their movement over time and find that they are strongly

correlated.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows: Section 2 describes the data we

use; Section 3 sets out our empirical methodology; Section 4 presents our main

results; Section 5 presents sensitivity analyses; and Section 6 concludes.

2. The Data

We use the Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID), from its inception in 1968 until

2012, with data collected annually until 1996 and bi-annually thereafter. The PSID

comprises both a representative national sample drawn from the Survey Research

Center (SRC), and a sample of low-income families, the Survey of Economic

Opportunities (SEO). As we wanted to avoid an over-representation of families with

low-income, we follow Lee and Solon (2006, 2009), Hertz (2007) and other studies in

using only the SRC sample.

10 Using predicted income at age 40 as our proxy for lifetime income follows Haider and Solon's (2006) analysis of the relation between annual and lifetime income. It generally differs from observed income at age 40, incorporating all available income data. We also used other methods, such as taking a simple average or a discounted sum of observed income and obtained values closely correlated with our measure.

8

2.1 Constructing the Sample

Estimating the IGE requires data on parents' earnings or income and their children's

earnings. Due to significant changes in women labor market participation in the

United States in the second half of the twentieth century, we focus on sons’ labor

income (or earnings), and estimate its elasticity with respect to parental family

income, and restrict our attention to families in which the father is the head of the

household.11 There are 8,275 father-son pairs in the SRC, from 5,749 families. For

reasons discussed above, we limit our attention to pairs in which the son was born

between 1952 and 1979. There are 2,834 such pairs in the SRC. We extract 1,324

father-son pairs in which the son is reported as a household head and has at least three

non-missing observations on labor income from the age of 29; and his father has at

least five years of non-zero observations on family income until the age of 64, and at

least three until the age of 60. Because of the under-representation of non-white

families in this sample, and to maintain comparability over time, we restrict our

attention to white males.12 This leaves us with a sample of 1,217 father-son pairs,

arranged by son's birth year (see Appendix A for descriptive statistics.)

2.2 Representativeness of the sample

The PSID sample was broadly representative in 1968, but has since suffered from

nonrandom sample attrition. The sample used in this study is a sub-sample of the

SRC, and suffers from further attrition.13 The question then arises, how representative

11 This follows Chadwick and Solon (2002), Mazumder (2005), Mayer and Lopoo (2005) and Aaronson and Mazumder (2008). It assumes that all the family's financial resources affect the child's future. 12 Large segments of the current non-white population are immigrants, for whom parental income is unavailable. In any event, interpreting economic time trends for populations with large migration flows raises conceptual challenges that are rarely addressed. 13 The PSID release sampling weights to ensure that the sample is representative. These weights can be used to compensate for the attrition, but only when using both SRC and SEO (Hertz, 2007). Our sample is a sub-sample of the SRC, which has suffered from attrition. Therefore the estimates obtained in this

9

is our sample of the general white population in the United States. To address this, we

compare historical time-series of the Gini coefficient and the share of white males

with 12-15 years of schooling in the United States, to our sample statistic. As these

government statistics are arranged by year (and not by year of birth), we arrange our

data similarly for these comparisons. Our sample includes 2,064 individuals—

between 573 and 1586 in each year—of whom 1,217 are sons and 847 are fathers.

We calculate the sample Gini coefficient for each year from all annual income

observations in that year, from 1969 to 2012, and compared this to the historical time

series of Gini coefficients of the annual income of white households in those years

(United States Census Bureau, 2016a). It yields a very close fit, with a correlation of

0.98 (Figure 1, and Table A2 in the Appendix). In constructing a time series of

schooling from our sample, we note that individual schooling cannot decline over

time, and so where schooling is reported in a given year and unreported in subsequent

years, we assume that it is unchanged in those years and fill it in. We then compare

the shares of 25-80 year-olds white men with 12-15 years of schooling in our sample

each year, from 1977 (the year our oldest cohort of sons turns 25) to 2012, to the

historical series (United States Census Bureau, 2016b), and obtain a correlation of

0.78 (Figure 2 and Table A3 in the Appendix).

study may be biased due to nonrandom attrition, and we cannot use the PSID weights for correction. Hertz discussed and implemented a method to generate weights for sub-samples of the PSID with respect to the sample selection criteria in order to overcome the attrition bias.

10

Figure 1. Gini coefficient of annual family income of white males, 1969 to 2012, sample statistics compared to historical United States data

Note: Sample data from PSID, authors’ calculations; United States data from United States Census Bureau (2016a). Each data point represents a year.

Figure 2. Share of white males aged 25-80 with 12-15 years of schooling, sample statistics compared to historical United States data

Note: Sample data from PSID, authors’ calculations; United States data from United States Census Bureau (2016b). Each data point represents a year.

0.20

0.25

0.30

0.35

0.40

0.45

0.50

0.33 0.35 0.37 0.39 0.41 0.43

Sam

ple

stat

istic

s

United States data

0.53

0.54

0.55

0.56

0.57

0.58

0.59

0.60

0.46 0.48 0.50 0.52 0.54 0.56 0.58

Sam

ple

stat

istic

s

United States data

11

2.3 Successive cohort groups

We measure trends in outcomes by following moving windows of ten-year cohort

groups, which are long enough to provide a characteristic picture of income mobility

at a given time, but short enough to allow us to observe variation in IGE across time.

This allows us to aggregate the father-son pairs in our sample into nineteen successive

ten-year cohort-groups from the oldest, born in 1952-61, to the youngest, born in

1970-79. There is no single way of identifying these groups with specific years. For

ease of exposition, we set this arbitrarily as the year in which the group is aged 36-45.

Table 1. Sample statistics, ten-year cohort-groups

Sons Fathers

Sons' year of birth

N Mean

number of observations

Mean age of

observed income

N Mean

number of observations

Mean age of

observed income

1952-61 453 23 35 323 28 56 1953-62 447 22 35 321 28 55 1954-63 440 21 35 314 28 54 1955-64 429 20 34 309 29 54 1956-65 414 19 34 305 29 53 1957-66 393 19 34 294 30 52 1958-67 418 17 34 322 31 51 1959-68 413 17 33 321 31 50 1960-69 415 16 33 323 31 49 1961-70 393 15 33 310 31 48 1962-71 393 14 33 312 31 47 1963-72 397 13 33 317 31 46 1964-73 402 12 32 321 31 45 1965-74 405 11 32 326 30 43 1966-75 411 10 32 327 30 42 1967-76 427 10 32 343 30 42 1968-77 412 9 31 344 29 41 1969-78 433 8 31 358 29 40 1970-79 439 7 31 371 28 40

12

The size of these cohort-groups ranges between 393 and 453 father-son pairs,

with an average of 416 (descriptive statistics in Table 1). Cohort-groups are similar in

the average number of income observations per father, between 28 and 31, while the

average age at which father’s income is observed drops from 56 for the youngest

cohort-group to 40 for the oldest cohort-group. Given the large number of years of

father’s income data for all groups and our focus on father’s estimated income at age,

these age disparities should not affect our results. The average age at which son’s

labor-income is observed varies in a much narrower range, dropping from 35 to 31,

while the average number of observations per son drops more sharply, from 23 for the

oldest cohort-group to 7 for the youngest cohort-group. Sons’ average years of

education range from 14.04 to 14.38 and are negatively correlated with the share of

sons with 12-15 years of education, with a correlation of -0.92.

3. Empirical method

To characterize the relationship between intergenerational mobility, inequality and

returns to human capital, as they vary over time for our nineteen successive cohort-

groups, we use the two-stage method introduced in Justman and Krush (2013). In the

first stage, we predict individual income at age forty, within each cohort-group, which

serves as our proxy for lifetime income. Then, in the second stage, we use these

proxies for lifetime income to estimate the intergenerational elasticity of lifetime

income, the 90-10 log earnings gap (as our measure of income inequality), and returns

to years of schooling, within each cohort group, producing three time series, and

calculate pairwise correlations. Strong positive correlations support Solon's (2004)

theory with regard to the covariation of these measures over time.

13

3.1 Estimating lifetime income

The first stage of estimating the IGE and other measures relevant to our analysis is to

estimate sons' lifetime earnings and fathers' lifetime income, in the sample extracted

from the PSID. Haider and Solon (2006) show that using income at age forty as a

proxy for lifetime income minimizes attenuation bias, yielding a bias that is not

statistically different from zero. Therefore, we use the predicted labor-income of sons

at the age of forty as a proxy for their lifetime-labor income, and fathers' predicted

family income at the age of forty as a proxy for lifetime family income.

To this purpose we use an expanded version of the Mincer wage equation:

(1) 𝑦𝑦𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 = 𝛼𝛼1𝑖𝑖𝐷𝐷𝑖𝑖 + 𝛼𝛼2𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝑒𝑒𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 + 𝛼𝛼3𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝑒𝑒𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖2 + 𝛼𝛼4𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝑐𝑐𝑖𝑖 ∙ 𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝑒𝑒𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 + 𝛼𝛼5𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝑐𝑐𝑖𝑖 ∙ 𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝑒𝑒𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖2

+ 𝛼𝛼6𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 ∙ 𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝑒𝑒𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 + 𝛼𝛼7𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 ∙ 𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝑒𝑒𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖2 + 𝜀𝜀𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖

where 𝑦𝑦𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 is individual's i's labor income or family income in year j. Family income

includes the taxable income of the head of the family and his wife, and transfer

payments. All income data is corrected to 2010 dollars using the Consumer Price

Index; and labor and family income are both bottom- and top-coded at annual levels

of, respectively, $150 and $150,000 in 1967 dollars.14 𝐷𝐷𝑖𝑖 is an individual indicator

variable; 𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝑒𝑒 𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 is an individual's age in year j minus 40; 𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝐸𝑐𝑐𝑖𝑖 represents a set of

indicator variables for 8 years of schooling or less, 8-10 years, 11-12, 13-15, 16 and

17 years or more. Individual education is equal to the highest reported value of years

of schooling in the survey; 𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 is a set of indicator variables for individual i's

14 Annual earnings below $150 are set equal to $150 and above $150,000 are set equal to $150,000. The reasoning behind this is that our sample sizes are small, and OLS regressions, which we use, are generally sensitive to extreme income values, and all the more so for a log-log specification of income, which is sensitive to the treatment of small values. Chetty et al. (2014), Lee and Solon (2009) and Hertz (2007) trimmed values over $150,000 and below $150 (in 1967 dollars), and Mayer and Lopoo (2005) trimmed the upper and lower 1% observations.

14

marital status at year j: married, never married, widowed, divorced and separated; 𝜀𝜀𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖

is an i.i.d. error term; 𝛼𝛼1𝑖𝑖,𝛼𝛼2 …𝛼𝛼7 are the regression coefficients. When individual i's

age is forty the variable 𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝑒𝑒 𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 takes the value of 0, and the individual's predicted

income is equal to 𝛼𝛼1𝑖𝑖, the coefficient of the individual indicator variable Di.

We predict individual income by cohort-group separately for sons and fathers,

which allows the regression coefficients to change between cohort-groups.15 There are

at most 10 predictions for each individual, a single prediction for sons born in 1952 or

1979 who participate in one cohort-group, and for their fathers. Sons born in 1953 or

1978, and their fathers, participate in 2 cohort groups and have 2 income predictions,

and so on. The mean and standard deviation of predicted lifetime income for fathers

and sons, by cohort-group, are presented in Table 2. Fathers' mean family income and

its standard deviation are stable over time, while sons' mean labor income follows an

inverted U-shaped pattern, and its standard deviation increases. It is not possible to

assess recent trends in mobility in lifetime income without some extrapolation, and

while we limit our attention to sons’ with what we believe is a reasonable basis for

estimating lifetime income, there is an innate difference between these estimates for

younger cohorts of sons still in their thirties, and those obtained for fathers or for

older cohorts in their late forties or fifties. Where the income estimates for older

individuals describe realized lifetime income, those for younger cohorts are an

extrapolation based on past trends that may change over time. This is especially true

for the youngest cohorts, for whom we observe the short-term effects of the 2008

recession, but not its longer term effects.

15 This follows Hertz (2007), Aaronson and Mazumder (2008) and Justman and Krush (2013), all of whom allow the age-earnings profile to change over time.

15

3.2 Estimating intergenerational mobility, inequality and returns to schooling

In the second stage, we estimate measures of intergenerational mobility, inequality

and the return to human capital for each cohort-group.

We measure intergenerational immobility—the extent to which economic

differences between families persist—as the intergenerational elasticity of income,

regressing the logarithm of our estimate of son's lifetime earnings on the logarithm of

our estimate of their parents’ family lifetime income:

(2) 𝑙𝑙𝑙𝑙 𝑦𝑦𝑖𝑖 = 𝛼𝛼 + 𝛽𝛽 𝑙𝑙𝑙𝑙 𝑥𝑥𝑖𝑖 + 𝜀𝜀𝑖𝑖

where 𝑦𝑦𝑖𝑖 is son i's predicted labor-income at age forty; 𝑥𝑥𝑖𝑖 is his father's predicted

family income at age forty; and 𝛽𝛽 is our estimate of the intergenerational elasticity of

income. It is an inverse measure of mobility, measuring persistence of income across

generations—larger values imply slower regression to the mean. Our sensitivity

analysis considers three alternative measures of mobility: the intergenerational

correlation of predicted income at age forty, of its logarithm, and of its rank.

Our measure of income inequality, the 90-10 log wage gap, follows Katz and

Author (1999), with the significant exception that we apply it to our estimate of

lifetime earnings.16 It is the gap between the logarithm of predicted income at age

forty at the 90th and the 10th percentiles of the distribution of sons’ lifetime earnings,

within each ten-year cohort-group. Larger values indicate greater inequality. Our

sensitivity analysis considers two alternative measures of inequality: the coefficient of

variation of the logarithm of sons’ predicted earnings at age forty; and the Gini

coefficient of their predicted earnings at age forty.

16 Katz and Autor consider variation in annual income at a point in time.

16

17

We use average lifetime returns to a year of schooling as our measure of

returns to human capital, which we estimate by regressing the logarithm of sons’

predicted earnings at age forty on years of schooling within each ten-year cohort

group of sons. Our sensitivity analysis considers an alternative measure, the college

premium, following Goldin and Katz (1999).

4. Results

We estimated these three times-series—the intergenerational elasticity of lifetime

income; the 90-10 gap in the logarithm of lifetime income; and the average return to a

year of schooling—within each of our nineteen successive cohort-groups (born

between 1952 and 1979). All three, presented graphically as standardized values, in

Figure 3, and numerically in Table 3, show a clear upward trend.

Figure 3. Standardized intergenerational elasticity of family income between fathers and sons, 90-10 log annual lifetime labor-income gap by year and return to schooling by year, for sons aged 36-45 in each year

18

Table 3: Estimates of the intergenerational elasticity between fathers' family income and sons' labor income, sons' 90-10 log labor income gap and sons' return to schooling, by cohort group

Sons' year of birth N Estimated

elasticity Standard

error 90-10 log wage gap

Return to schooling

1952-61 453 0.504 0.053 1.415 0.161 1953-62 447 0.489 0.052 1.419 0.151 1954-63 440 0.551 0.052 1.437 0.159 1955-64 429 0.526 0.053 1.498 0.170 1956-65 414 0.460 0.049 1.480 0.180 1957-66 393 0.492 0.052 1.448 0.173 1958-67 418 0.548 0.057 1.490 0.179 1959-68 413 0.540 0.058 1.513 0.184 1960-69 415 0.563 0.059 1.600 0.197 1961-70 393 0.567 0.062 1.567 0.192 1962-71 393 0.633 0.067 1.619 0.212 1963-72 397 0.621 0.067 1.663 0.217 1964-73 402 0.600 0.068 1.627 0.217 1965-74 405 0.681 0.069 1.613 0.223 1966-75 411 0.603 0.069 1.563 0.214 1967-76 427 0.616 0.072 1.649 0.232 1968-77 412 0.619 0.075 1.554 0.225 1969-78 433 0.664 0.080 1.646 0.240 1970-79 439 0.656 0.068 1.645 0.222

Intergenerational elasticity values for the oldest ten cohort-groups are all

below 0.6 while those for the youngest nine cohort-groups are never below 0.6.

Regressing the nineteen cohort-group elasticities on a linear time trend yields an

average annual increase of 0.010, indicating that mobility has decreased over time. At

the same time, standard errors of the estimated intergenerational elasticity also

increased at a roughly similar rate.17 The 90-10 log wage gap time series exhibits a

similar pattern, with values for the older cohorts clearly lower than values for the

younger cohorts. Regressing this gap on a linear time trend yields an average annual

17 The ratio of coefficient to standard error, the t-statistic, varies in a narrow range, from 8.25 to 10.60.

19

increase of 0.013, very close to the average annual increase in the intergenerational

elasticity. Finally, the average return to a year of schooling has also increased in this

period, from 0.151 to 0.240, with average annual growth of 0.0047.

Solon (2004) theory leads us to expect positive correlations between the three

time-series in Table 3, and this is indeed the case. This is evident from a graphic

comparison in Figure 4, after standardizing each of the time-series, and from their

correlation. The correlation between our estimated elasticities and the 90-10 log wage

gap is 0.85; between these elasticities and returns to schooling it is 0.88; and between

the 90-10 log wage gap and returns to schooling, 0.92. Thus we find that rising

inequality in the United States in recent years has gone hand in hand with a decline in

intergenerational income mobility and rising returns to schooling.

5. Sensitivity analysis

In this section, we present two sets of sensitivity analyses. The first relates to the

construction of the data; the second to our choice of statistical measures. With regard

to construction of the data, we test if the results hold if we exclude from each cohort-

group all sons who have an older brother in the same cohort-group; if we include non-

white males (adding a control for race to the Mincer equation used to estimate lifetime

income); and if we forgo top and bottom coding. The correlations, in Table 4, show

that our qualitative findings remain intact. (Tables B1-B3 in the Appendix present the

underlying values of the outcome variables by cohort-group.)

20

Table 4. Correlations between the main outcome variables

IGE- Inequality

IGE- Returns to schooling

Inequality- Returns to schooling

Basic specification 0.85 0.88 0.92

Selection on siblings 0.77 0.77 0.92

No selection on race 0.88 0.83 0.91

No top and bottom coding 0.78 0.81 0.93

Table 5. Alternative measures of mobility, inequality and returns to schooling

a. Correlations between measures of mobility and inequality

90-10 log wage gap

Coefficient of variation of log

income

Gini coefficient of lifetime income

Intergenerational elasticity of income 0.85 0.83 0.60

Correlation of income 0.40 0.79 0.06

Correlation of log income -0.28 -0.67 -0.02

Rank correlation 0.25 -0.07 0.45

b. Correlations between measures of mobility and returns to schooling

Average return to a year of schooling College premium

Intergenerational elasticity of income 0.88 0.88

Correlation of income 0.63 0.79

Correlation of log income -0.49 -0.52

Rank correlation 0.11 0.08

c. Correlations between measures of inequality and returns to schooling

90-10 log wage gap

Coefficient of variation of log

income

Gini coefficient of income

Average return to a year of schooling 0.92 0.93 0.73

College premium 0.83 0.94 0.51

21

The second set of tests considers alternative measures of intergenerational mobility,

inequality and returns to education, all referring to our basic data specification. We

consider three alternative measures of intergenerational mobility—the Pearson

correlation of lifetime income, the Pearson correlation of the logarithm of lifetime

income, and the Spearman rank correlation of lifetime income (within each cohort-

group); two alternative measures of inequality—the coefficient of variation of the

logarithm of lifetime income and the Gini coefficient of lifetime income; and one

alternative measure of returns to education, the college premium. Their pairwise

correlations are compared in Table 5. (Tables B4-B5 in the Appendix present the

underlying values of the outcome variables by cohort-group.) Panel a presents

correlations between alternative measures of intergenerational mobility and

inequality; panel b presents correlations between alternative measures of

intergenerational mobility and returns to schooling; and panel c presents correlations

between alternative measures of inequality and returns to schooling. Our results are

generally robust to how we measure returns to schooling or inequality but highly

sensitive to how we measure intergenerational mobility.

Figure 4. Three alternative measures of intergenerational mobility

0.25

0.30

0.35

0.40

0.45

0.50Correlationof logincome

Correlationof income

Rankcorrelation

22

The three alternative measures of mobility are presented in Figure 4. Each

captures a different dimension of intergenerational mobility (Fields and Ok, 1996).

The correlation of income remains constant for most of the period and then rises

sharply in later years; the correlation of the logarithm of income exhibits a weakly

declining trend; and the rank correlation shows no trend.18 This indicates that the

decline in income mobility reflected in the intergenerational elasticity of income is

closely tied with the rise in inequality, as Solon’s (204) analysis suggests, i.e., with

widening gaps between fixed positions in the rank distribution of earnings rather than

with reduced positional (i.e., rank) mobility. This is also evident in that the estimated

intergenerational elasticity equals the correlation of the logarithm of income

multiplied by the ratio of the standard deviations of sons’ log earnings to fathers’ log

income: in this sense, too, the increase in the dispersion of sons’ income is driving the

rise in the intergenerational elasticity.

6. Conclusions

In this study, we examined the relationships between intergenerational mobility,

inequality and return to human capital over time in the United States, using the PSID

data to 2012. We focus on white father-son pairs for sons born between 1952 and

1979, and limited our attention to father-son pairs in which the son has at least three

non-missing observations on labor income from the age of 29 and the father has at

least five years of non-zero observations of family income until the age of 64. We

exclude non-white pairs because of their under-representation in our PSID sample.

18 Chetty et al. (2014), examining a later period, with some overlap, also find no trend in the intergenerational rank correlation of income.

23

These father-son pairs were aggregated into nineteen successive rolling ten-

year cohort-groups by sons’ year of birth, and we estimated sons' earnings and fathers'

family income at age forty within each of our nineteen cohort-groups, as a proxy for

their lifetime earnings or income. We then used these estimates of lifetime income to

produce three time-series: the intergenerational elasticity of earnings with respect to

family income, as an inverse measure of intergenerational mobility; sons’ 90-10 log

lifetime earnings gap, as a measure of inequality; and sons' average return to a year of

schooling, as a measure of return to human capital.

This approach has several conceptual advantages. It estimates its three time

series from the same set of data; it focuses on lifetime income for all three measures;

and it identifies each year with a ten-year cohort group that is more representative of

that year than a single cohort. Its main weakness is its small, non-random sample size.

Comparing the behavior of our sample 1969 to 2012 with time series for the general

white male population of the United States, we find a correlation of 0.98 for the Gini

coefficient of annual income, and 0.78 for the share of white males aged 36-45 with

12-15 years of schooling.

We then calculated pairwise correlations between these time series, and found

strong, positive co-movement. We found a correlation of 0.85 between the

intergenerational elasticity of income and the 90-10 log earnings gap; 0.88 between

the intergenerational elasticity and returns to human capital; and 0.92 between the 90-

10 log earnings gap and returns to human capital. The results indicate that declining

intergenerational mobility moved in tandem with rising inequality and returns to

human capital in the United States over time, as posited by Solon (2004) and indicated

by some previous suggestive evidence.

24

Our results are generally robust to alternative sampling criteria and to

alternative measures of inequality and returns to human capital but depend strongly on

the choice of measure of intergenerational mobility. They hold weakly if it is

measured as the intergenerational correlation of income but not at all if it is measured

as the intergenerational correlation of the logarithm of income or of income rank. This

highlights the link between rising inequality and reduced mobility.

References

Aaronson, D and B Mazumder, 2008. Intergenerational economic mobility in the United States, 1940 to 2000. Journal of Human Resorces 41(1):139-172.

Becker, G and N Tomes, 1979. An equilibrium theory of the distribution of income and intergenerational mobility. Journal of Political Economy 87(6):1153-1189.

Blanden, J, 2013. Cross‐country rankings in intergenerational mobility: A comparison of approaches from economics and sociology. Journal of Economic Surveys 27(1):38-73.

Blanden, J, P Gregg and L Macmillan, 2007. Accounting for intergenerational income persistence: Noncognitive skills, ability and education. Economic Journal 117(519):C43-C60.

Bratsberg, B, K Røed, O Raaum, R Naylor, M Jäntti, T Eriksson, R Österbacka, 2007. Nonlinearities in intergenerational earnings mobility: Consequences for cross-country comparisons. Economic Journal 117(519): C72-92.

Chadwick, L and G Solon, 2002. Intergenerational income mobility among daughters. American Economic Review 92(1):335-344.

Chetty, R, N Hendren, P Kline, E Saez and N Turner, 2014. Is the United States still a land of opportunity? Recent trends in intergenerational mobility. American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings 104(5):141–147.

Corak, M, 2013. Income inequality, equality of opportunity, and intergenerational mobility. Journal of Economic Perspectives 27(3):79-102.

Fields, G and E Ok, 1996. The meaning and measurement of income mobility. Journal of Economic Theory 71(2):349-377.

Goldin, C and L Katz, 1999. The returns to skill in the United States across the twentieth century. WP 7126. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

25

Haider, S and G Solon, 2006. Life-cycle variation in the association between current and lifetime earnings. American Economic Review 96:1308-1320.

Hertz, T, 2007. Trends in the intergenerational elasticity of family income in the United States. Industrial Relations 46:22-50.

Jerrim, J and L Macmillan, 2015. Income inequality, intergenerational mobility, and the Great Gatsby curve: Is education the key? Social Forces 94:505-533.

Justman, M and A Krush, 2013. Less equal and less mobile: Evidence of a decline in intergenerational income mobility in the United States. WP 43/13, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research, University of Melbourne.

Katz, L and D Autor, 1999. Changes in the wage structure and earnings inequality. In O Ashenfelter and D Card, eds., Handbook of labor economics Vol. 3A, pp. 1463–1555. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science, North-Holland.

Lee, C-I and G Solon, 2006. Trends in intergenerational income mobility. WP 12007. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

Lee, C-I and G Solon, 2009. Trends in intergenerational income mobility. Review of Economics and Statistics 91:766-772.

Marks, G N, 2014. Educaton, Social Background and Cognitive Ability: The decline of the social. New York: Routledge.

Mayer, S E and L M Lopoo, 2005. Has the intergenerational transmission of economic status changed? Journal of Human Resources 40:169-185.

Mazumder, B, 2005. Fortunate sons: new estimates of intergenerational mobility in the U.S. using social security earnings data. Review of Economics and Statistics 87(2):235–55.

Solon, G, 2004. A model of intergenerational mobility variation over time and place. In M. Corak, ed., Generational Income Mobility in North America and Europe, pp. 38-47. Cambridge University Press.

United States Census Bureau, 2016a. Historical Income tables: Income Inequality, Table H-4. Retrieved October 2016 from: http://www.census.gov/data/tables/ time-series/demo/income-poverty/historical-income-households.html

United States Census Bureau, 2016b. Historical education tables: Educational attainment, Table A-2. Retrieved October 2016, from: https://www.census. gov/hhes/socdemo/education/data/cps/historical/

26

Appendix A. Descriptive statistics and comparison to US data

A1. Number of father-sons pairs by son's birth year

Sons' year of birth

Number of sons

Number of sons reported as household's

heads

Number of sons reported as

household's heads with enough observations

Number of white sons reported as

household's heads with enough observations

1952 61 53 43 42 1953 67 63 50 46 1954 79 67 54 52 1955 74 64 55 55 1956 79 64 56 51 1957 62 53 41 40 1958 68 55 36 34 1959 65 54 46 43 1960 83 64 53 50 1961 82 54 45 40 1962 68 51 38 36 1963 82 59 43 39 1964 77 57 45 41 1965 84 52 42 40 1966 75 47 34 30 1967 132 94 69 65 1968 87 46 31 29 1969 107 74 51 45 1970 82 50 32 28 1971 113 65 41 40 1972 111 62 48 40 1973 142 63 50 44 1974 136 64 46 44 1975 152 56 49 46 1976 149 68 52 46 1977 140 69 59 50 1978 194 69 55 50 1979 183 82 60 51 Total 2,834 1,719 1,324 1,217

Note: The “number of sons” is the number of individuals who have fathers in the SRC. “Enough observations” are defined for sons as at least three non-missing observations on labor income from the age of 29; and for fathers as at least five years of non-zero observations on family income until the age of 64, and at least three until the age of 60.

27

A2. Gini coefficient of annual family income, comparison by year

Year US Data PSID Our sample Gini N Gini N Gini

1969 0.341 2,801 0.380 573 0.282 1970 0.345 2,982 0.377 619 0.276 1971 0.347 3,130 0.376 653 0.277 1972 0.350 3,283 0.379 704 0.272 1973 0.346 3,425 0.377 762 0.290 1974 0.346 3,581 0.381 817 0.310 1975 0.349 3,707 0.377 866 0.302 1976 0.348 3,814 0.381 921 0.304 1977 0.352 3,938 0.377 969 0.291 1978 0.353 4,035 0.386 998 0.311 1979 0.354 4,156 0.380 1,043 0.306 1980 0.353 4,270 0.399 1,071 0.330 1981 0.358 4,378 0.395 1,097 0.325 1982 0.368 4,472 0.398 1,136 0.339 1983 0.370 4,540 0.400 1,158 0.344 1984 0.371 4,609 0.401 1,175 0.351 1985 0.378 4,669 0.402 1,212 0.359 1986 0.380 4,714 0.403 1,233 0.363 1987 0.380 4,784 0.408 1,258 0.374 1988 0.382 4,852 0.410 1,274 0.387 1989 0.389 6,419 0.437 1,298 0.376 1990 0.384 6,376 0.437 1,309 0.370 1991 0.384 6,639 0.442 1,331 0.388 1992 0.390 6,610 0.452 1,344 0.378 1993 0.416 5,707 0.485 1,429 0.430 1994 0.416 5,909 0.481 1,451 0.441 1995 0.409 5,864 0.473 1,454 0.427 1996 0.414 4,674 0.463 1,466 0.424 1998 0.422 4,683 0.467 1,484 0.436 2000 0.425 4,915 0.485 1,537 0.452 2002 0.414 5,139 0.479 1,580 0.443 2004 0.420 5,232 0.494 1,586 0.470 2006 0.425 5,332 0.480 1,568 0.451 2008 0.417 5,575 0.496 1,542 0.460 2010 0.418 5,598 0.498 1,460 0.471 2012 0.429 5,630 0.504 1,382 0.483

Note: US data is the time-series of the Gini coefficient for white households, from United States Census Bureaus, 2016a. “PSID” refers to all households in the SRC and the SEO whose heads self-identify as white. "Sample" refers to all households in the study sample as described in the text. Household family income in the PSID and sample data equals husband and wife's taxable income plus transfer income from all sources.

28

A3. Years of schooling, by year, as percentage of non-missing observations

U.S Census Bureau Sample

year 12-15 years of schooling

At least 16 years of

schooling N 12-15 years

of schooling

At least 16 years of

schooling 1977 0.473 0.202 855 0.538 0.249 1978 0.479 0.207 911 0.548 0.245 1979 0.489 0.214 957 0.558 0.242 1980 0.489 0.221 1013 0.563 0.242 1981 0.499 0.222 1065 0.565 0.246 1982 0.504 0.230 1101 0.569 0.243 1983 0.504 0.240 1127 0.571 0.246 1984 0.515 0.239 1170 0.566 0.283 1985 0.520 0.240 1225 0.565 0.286 1986 0.524 0.241 1268 0.567 0.289 1987 0.528 0.245 1307 0.573 0.290 1988 0.527 0.250 1343 0.577 0.288 1989 0.532 0.254 1383 0.578 0.291 1990 0.538 0.253 1424 0.575 0.291 1991 0.544 0.254 1454 0.576 0.292 1992 0.559 0.252 1513 0.580 0.291 1993 0.561 0.257 1569 0.578 0.295 1994 0.560 0.261 1611 0.579 0.295 1995 0.558 0.272 1637 0.576 0.300 1996 0.558 0.269 1673 0.577 0.300 1998 0.563 0.273 1731 0.581 0.300 2000 0.563 0.285 1781 0.590 0.296 2002 0.552 0.291 1850 0.594 0.295 2004 0.553 0.300 1920 0.595 0.300 2006 0.558 0.297 1901 0.596 0.302 2008 0.558 0.305 1886 0.569 0.353 2010 0.561 0.308 1828 0.572 0.357 2012 0.557 0.319 1782 0.567 0.363

Note: US data from US Census Bureau, Historical education tables: Educational attainment, table A-2. "Sample" refers to all individuals in the sample obtained in this study as described in subsection 4.1. Columns C and E are the shares of individuals with 12-15 years of schooling, in a year, out of all non-missing observations in that year. Columns D and F are the shares of individuals reporting at least 16 years of schooling in a year, out of all non-missing observations in that year.

29

Appendix B. Sensitivity analyses

Table B1. Estimates of the intergenerational elasticity between fathers' family income and sons' labor income, sons' 90-10 log labor income gap and sons' return to schooling, by cohort group, selection on siblings

Sons' year of birth N Intergenerational

elasticity 90-10 log

earnings gap Returns to a year

of schooling

1952-61 323 0.499 1.372 0.161 1953-62 321 0.491 1.354 0.153 1954-63 314 0.598 1.409 0.167 1955-64 309 0.573 1.434 0.172 1956-65 305 0.540 1.496 0.197 1957-66 294 0.580 1.471 0.195 1958-67 322 0.576 1.539 0.197 1959-68 321 0.547 1.480 0.198 1960-69 323 0.544 1.507 0.199 1961-70 310 0.538 1.556 0.190 1962-71 312 0.602 1.562 0.211 1963-72 317 0.597 1.644 0.220 1964-73 321 0.576 1.589 0.219 1965-74 326 0.640 1.548 0.215 1966-75 327 0.555 1.461 0.201 1967-76 343 0.599 1.572 0.231 1968-77 344 0.628 1.616 0.235 1969-78 358 0.672 1.671 0.247 1970-79 371 0.653 1.667 0.221

Note: We include only the oldest son of each father (the oldest brother) in each cohort group, reducing sample sizes by 15-30%. Regression of the IGE on a linear time trend yields an annual average growth rate of 0.0064.

30

Table B2. Estimates of the intergenerational elasticity between fathers' family income and sons' labor income, sons' 90-10 log labor income gap and sons' return to schooling, by cohort group, no selection on race

Sons' year of birth N Intergenerational

elasticity 90-10 log

earnings gap Return to a year of

schooling

1952-61 477 0.424 1.424 0.167 1953-62 472 0.392 1.417 0.159 1954-63 464 0.550 1.467 0.166 1955-64 455 0.525 1.504 0.176 1956-65 441 0.499 1.504 0.188 1957-66 420 0.507 1.518 0.195 1958-67 447 0.544 1.543 0.195 1959-68 442 0.565 1.521 0.194 1960-69 446 0.577 1.601 0.205 1961-70 423 0.584 1.620 0.203 1962-71 420 0.625 1.653 0.218 1963-72 428 0.628 1.700 0.224 1964-73 436 0.606 1.630 0.221 1965-74 437 0.675 1.628 0.224 1966-75 445 0.576 1.557 0.217 1967-76 462 0.551 1.622 0.229 1968-77 451 0.569 1.590 0.218 1969-78 475 0.640 1.656 0.241 1970-79 484 0.625 1.684 0.221

Note: We include African American and Hispanic pairs in the sample and add dummy variables for race in the specification used for estimating income at age 40, our proxy for lifetime income. The share of African American and Hispanic pairs in each cohort group increases from 5% for the oldest cohort-group to 9.3% for the youngest. Regression of the IGE on a linear time trend yields annual average growth of 0.0096.

31

Table B3. Estimates of the intergenerational elasticity between fathers' family income and sons' labor income, sons' 90-10 log earnings gap and sons' return to a year of schooling, by cohort group, no top and bottom income coding

Sons' year of birth N Intergenerational

elasticity 90-10 log

earnings gap Return to a year of

schooling

1952-61 453 0.468 1.417 0.162 1953-62 447 0.457 1.425 0.152 1954-63 440 0.523 1.447 0.161 1955-64 429 0.486 1.515 0.174 1956-65 414 0.342 1.479 0.183 1957-66 393 0.376 1.475 0.176 1958-67 418 0.532 1.484 0.182 1959-68 413 0.526 1.542 0.187 1960-69 415 0.554 1.604 0.201 1961-70 393 0.563 1.591 0.197 1962-71 393 0.636 1.636 0.219 1963-72 397 0.624 1.725 0.226 1964-73 402 0.605 1.698 0.226 1965-74 405 0.704 1.625 0.228 1966-75 411 0.594 1.567 0.212 1967-76 427 0.600 1.657 0.232 1968-77 412 0.609 1.584 0.223 1969-78 433 0.685 1.657 0.237 1970-79 439 0.658 1.659 0.221

Note: Selection on race and no selection on siblings, as in the baseline specification.

32

Table B4. Estimates of the 90-10 log wage gap, the coefficient of variation of sons' log labor income, the Gini coefficient, sons' return to a year of schooling, and the college premium, by cohort group, baseline sample

Sons' year of birth

N 90-10 log earnings gap

CV of log

earnings

Gini of lifetime earnings

Return to a year of

schooling

College premium

1952-61 453 1.415 0.055 0.304 0.161 0.602 1953-62 447 1.419 0.053 0.298 0.151 0.582 1954-63 440 1.437 0.054 0.307 0.159 0.623 1955-64 429 1.498 0.055 0.320 0.170 0.598 1956-65 414 1.480 0.055 0.329 0.180 0.622 1957-66 393 1.448 0.055 0.329 0.173 0.605 1958-67 418 1.490 0.055 0.335 0.179 0.698 1959-68 413 1.513 0.055 0.337 0.184 0.704 1960-69 415 1.600 0.058 0.345 0.197 0.767 1961-70 393 1.567 0.058 0.341 0.192 0.709 1962-71 393 1.619 0.061 0.349 0.212 0.822 1963-72 397 1.663 0.061 0.349 0.217 0.842 1964-73 402 1.627 0.062 0.342 0.217 0.860 1965-74 405 1.613 0.064 0.349 0.223 0.952 1966-75 411 1.563 0.066 0.333 0.214 0.953 1967-76 427 1.649 0.069 0.338 0.232 1.073 1968-77 412 1.554 0.068 0.327 0.225 0.992 1969-78 433 1.646 0.073 0.341 0.240 1.048 1970-79 439 1.645 0.064 0.328 0.222 1.099

Note: The CV for a cohort-group is the ratio of the standard deviation of sons' annual lifetime log earnings to its mean. The college premium for a cohort-group is the difference between the mean of sons' logarithm of annual lifetime earnings for sons with exactly 16 years of schooling and that of sons with exactly 12 years of schooling.

33

Table B5. Estimates of the intergenerational elasticity of income, the correlation between sons' labor income and fathers' family income, the correlation between the logarithm of sons' labor income and the logarithm of fathers' family income, and Spearman's rank correlation coefficient between sons' labor income and fathers' family income, by cohort group, baseline sample

Sons' year of birth N Intergenerational

elasticity Correlation of income

Correlation of log income

Rank correlation

1952-61 453 0.468 0.291 0.408 0.430 1953-62 447 0.457 0.309 0.405 0.417 1954-63 440 0.523 0.344 0.453 0.453 1955-64 429 0.486 0.334 0.434 0.432 1956-65 414 0.342 0.306 0.421 0.437 1957-66 393 0.376 0.307 0.431 0.441 1958-67 418 0.532 0.303 0.428 0.451 1959-68 413 0.526 0.297 0.417 0.444 1960-69 415 0.554 0.314 0.427 0.444 1961-70 393 0.563 0.302 0.421 0.442 1962-71 393 0.636 0.312 0.433 0.458 1963-72 397 0.624 0.298 0.421 0.447 1964-73 402 0.605 0.295 0.404 0.423 1965-74 405 0.704 0.380 0.441 0.453 1966-75 411 0.594 0.418 0.396 0.438 1967-76 427 0.600 0.402 0.384 0.436 1968-77 412 0.609 0.447 0.379 0.418 1969-78 433 0.685 0.408 0.374 0.437 1970-79 439 0.658 0.418 0.424 0.450

Note: All income is lifetime income, proxied by estimated income at age 40 (estimated separately for fathers and sons within each cohort-group.)