28
The East Asian crisis and the globalization discourse Aseem Prakash The George Washington University, Washington, D.C. ABSTRACT This paper examines the implications of the 1997 East Asian crisis for the globalization discourse in the context of three issues: the reversibility of globalization, the role of the state in economic activity, and institutional de cits, domestic and supranational, to manage the burgeoning volumes of cross-border economic exchanges. It focuses on Thailand, Malaysia, Indonesia, and South Korea – the countries most severely affected by the 1997 crisis. It concludes that: (1) globalization is potentially reversible in some issue areas, provided there is the political will to do so; (2) states continue to matter in economic activity; (3) the new system of global commerce and nance must ensure accountability at various levels without undermining the democratic bases of the polity. KEYWORDS Globalization, East Asian crisis, capital controls, rating agencies ISSUES Economic globalization can be de ned as the set of processes leading to increasing levels of cross-border integration of factor, intermediate goods, and nal products markets along with the increasing salience of multi- national enterprises’ cross-border value chains. 2 Though economic integration is not a new phenomena, the impact of the current integra- tion processes – globalization – is not ephemeral in that they are causing longterm structural changes in the global economy. Non-economic dimensions of globalization are important as well (Appadurai, 1996) and may overlap with the economic ones. Focusing on economic globaliza- tion (henceforth globalization) only, this paper examines the implications Review of International Political Economy 8:1 Spring 2001: 119–146 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 3411 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 Folio Review of International Political Economy ISSN 0969-2290 print/ISSN 1466-4526 online © 2001 Taylor & Francis Ltd http://www.tandf.co.uk DOI: 10.1080/09692290010010290

The East Asian crisis and the globalization discoursefaculty.washington.edu/aseem/east-asia.pdfthe crisis – is evident in domestic restructuring. Prior to 1997, not many scholars

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    0

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: The East Asian crisis and the globalization discoursefaculty.washington.edu/aseem/east-asia.pdfthe crisis – is evident in domestic restructuring. Prior to 1997, not many scholars

The East Asian crisis and theglobalization discourse

Aseem PrakashThe George Washington University, Washington, D.C.

ABSTRACT

This paper examines the implications of the 1997 East Asian crisis for theglobalization discourse in the context of three issues: the reversibility ofglobalization, the role of the state in economic activity, and institutionalde�cits, domestic and supranational, to manage the burgeoning volumesof cross-border economic exchanges. It focuses on Thailand, Malaysia,Indonesia, and South Korea – the countries most severely affected by the1997 crisis. It concludes that: (1) globalization is potentially reversible insome issue areas, provided there is the political will to do so; (2) statescontinue to matter in economic activity; (3) the new system of globalcommerce and �nance must ensure accountability at various levels withoutundermining the democratic bases of the polity.

KEYWORDS

Globalization, East Asian crisis, capital controls, rating agencies

ISSUES

Economic globalization can be de�ned as the set of processes leading toincreasing levels of cross-border integration of factor, intermediate goods,and �nal products markets along with the increasing salience of multi-national enterprises’ cross-border value chains.2 Though economicintegration is not a new phenomena, the impact of the current integra-tion processes – globalization – is not ephemeral in that they are causinglongterm structural changes in the global economy. Non-economicdimensions of globalization are important as well (Appadurai, 1996) andmay overlap with the economic ones. Focusing on economic globaliza-tion (henceforth globalization) only, this paper examines the implications

Review of International Political Economy 8:1 Spring 2001: 119–146

123456789

101112131415161718192021222324252627282930313233

341135363738394041424344

Folio Review of International Political EconomyISSN 0969-2290 print/ISSN 1466-4526 online © 2001 Taylor & Francis Ltd

http://www.tandf.co.ukDOI: 10.1080/0969229001001029 0

Page 2: The East Asian crisis and the globalization discoursefaculty.washington.edu/aseem/east-asia.pdfthe crisis – is evident in domestic restructuring. Prior to 1997, not many scholars

of the 1997 East Asian crisis for the globalization discourse. It analyzesthis subject in the context of three issues: the reversibility of globaliza-tion, the role of the state in economic activity, and institutional2 de�cits,domestic and supranational, to manage the burgeoning volumes of cross-border economic exchanges. My focus is on Thailand, Malaysia,Indonesia, and South Korea – the countries most severely affected bythe 1997 crisis.

BACKGROUND

Twenty-three economies comprise East Asia. Much of the IPE literature(and the famous 1992 World Bank study) focuses on eight of them: Japan, the ‘tigers’ (Hong Kong, South Korea, Singapore, and Taiwan), and the newly industrializing countries (NICs) – Indonesia, Malaysia,and Thailand. Between 1965 and 1990, these economies grew three times as fast as Latin America (5.4 percent versus 1.8 percent per annum)and 25 times faster than Sub-Saharan Africa (5.4 percent versus 0.2percent per annum). This growth was accompanied by (or perhapsbolstered by) signi�cant reductions in poverty and in-come inequa-lity, as well as signi�cant increases in life expectancy (from 56 to 71 years versus from 36 and 49 to 62 in low- and middle-incomecountries).While recognizing that the term ‘East Asian model’ is rather broad

given the variations within these countries in terms of initial economicand political conditions, domestic institutions, and economic strategies(Haggard, 1990; McIntyre, 1994), I employ it to contrast the East Asiansystems with those found in the Anglo-American economies. The keydifferences, inter alia, pertain to the nature of business–government rela-tionships (adversarial versus non-adversarial), the direct role of govern-ment in economic activity (interventionist versus non-interventionist),and the structure of corporate governance (varying focus on shareholderwealth maximization). The degree of the East Asian economic meltdown, the subsequent

recovery, and the policies put in place by domestic governments tocombat this crisis have varied across countries. Taiwan and Singapore,the celebrated examples of the ‘developmental state’, (Johnson, 1982)more or less escaped this crisis while South Korea, another develop-mental state, did not. The South Korean economy has recovered fasterthan the Indonesian and the Thai economies. Malaysia did not adoptthe IMF’s programme and even imposed capital controls, while Thailand,Korea, Philippines, and Indonesia adopted the IMF recommended tightmonetary and �scal policies. Instead of retreating, the state is vigorouslyinvolved in industrial restructuring in Korea and Malaysia. However,the economic power of the Korean chaebols has not appreciably declined.

REVIEW OF INTERNATIONAL POLITICAL ECONOMY

111123456789

11110111213141516171819

11120212223242526272829

11130313233343536373839

11140414243

11144

Folio 120

Page 3: The East Asian crisis and the globalization discoursefaculty.washington.edu/aseem/east-asia.pdfthe crisis – is evident in domestic restructuring. Prior to 1997, not many scholars

In the Philippines and Malaysia, crony-capitalism – an alleged cause ofthe crisis – is evident in domestic restructuring.Prior to 1997, not many scholars questioned the viability of the East

Asian model, Young (1994, 1995) and Krugman (1995) being the notableexceptions. Young (and Krugman who drew upon his work) argued that the East Asian economies could not sustain their aggregate growthrates due to decelerating total factor productivity (TFP) growth. Between1966 and 1991, the annual TFP growth rates in Hong Kong (2.3 percent)Singapore (0.2 percent) South Korea (1.7 percent) and Taiwan (2.1percent) were low compared to their per capita GDP growth rates (6 to7 percent). Quite contrary to the World Bank study, Young concludedthat the claim about export-led growth creating dynamic gains was notvalid; one shot static neoclassical gains alone explained the miracle.However, neither the World Bank nor Young foresaw an imminenteconomic collapse or fundamental structural weaknesses that would makethe East Asian economies vulnerable to �nancial crises.The World Bank study identi�ed two perspectives to explain the

‘miracle’: neoclassical and revisionist.3 Neoclassical economics or the‘market friendly’ perspective attributed the miracle to stable macro-economic policies and a reliable legal system that created a conduciveinstitutional environment for market-based competition. To employWade’s (1990) terminology, this perspective includes both the ‘freemarket’ school (growth due to the absence of government) as well as the ‘simulated market’ school (state intervention corrected marketdistortions due to institutional failures). In contrast to other developingcountries that relied on import-substitution and subsidized speci�cindustries, East Asia’s export-orientation and the absence of price controlscreated conditions for ef�cient resource allocation (Aikman, 1986;Krueger, 1990; Ranis, 1993). Notwithstanding selective interventions, thecountries’ industrial structures were consistent with factor advantagesas well as their changing factor endowments.4 Government investmentsin education and public health provided public goods that raised labourforce productivity.The ‘revisionists’, in contrast, emphasized the role of governmental

interventions in the manufacturing sector (industrial policies) and �nan-cial markets (Amsden, 1989; Wade, 1990; Rodrik, 1995; Singh, 1995). Theysuggested that governments deliberately distorted prices (such as providingcheaper credit) to channelize investments in ‘key industries’, and selec-tively favoured some export industries over others.5Instead of taking sides in this ideologically charged debate, this paper

focuses on identifying key lessons for the globalization discourse. Section I brie�y examines the etiologies of the East Asian crisis. SectionII focuses on three issues that resonate both in the globalization and theEast Asian crisis debates: the reversibility of globalization, the role of

PRAKASH: THE EAST ASIAN CRISIS

111123456789

11110111213141516171819

11120212223242526272829

11130313233343536373839

11140414243

11144

Folio 121

Page 4: The East Asian crisis and the globalization discoursefaculty.washington.edu/aseem/east-asia.pdfthe crisis – is evident in domestic restructuring. Prior to 1997, not many scholars

governments in economic activity, and institutional requirements forsuccessfully coping with globalization. Finally, Section III provides theconclusions and identi�es areas for further research.

I THE ETIOLOGIES OF THE CRISIS

The causes of the East Asian crisis, its severity, and timing lie in both the domestic and international political economies. They includestructural factors as well as speci�c policies of domestic governments,international institutions, and private actors. This section focuses on keycauses that are symptomatic of institutional de�cits in the domestic andinternational spheres, and how these institutional inadequacies madethese countries vulnerable to economic globalization.

Accumulation of short-term debt

Capital account liberalization and �nancial deregulation that began inthe 1980s created opportunities for East Asian �rms to tap into interna-tional capital markets. Both debt-GDP and short-term debt-total debtratios increased. Between 1990 and 1996, foreign debt as a proportionof GDP increased from 14 percent to 28 percent in Korea, from 33 percentto 50 percent in Thailand, and from 36 percent to 40 percent in Malaysia.During the same period, short-term debt as a proportion of total debtincreased from 31 percent to 50 percent in Korea, from 16 percent to 25percent in Indonesia, from 12 percent to 28 percent in Malaysia, from30 percent to 41 percent in Thailand. Contrast this with Taiwan andSingapore that did not suffer signi�cantly from the crisis: short-termdebt as a proportion of total debt declined from 88 percent to 68 percentin Taiwan, and increased marginally from 18 percent to 20 percent inSingapore (Corsetti et al. 1998). The demand for short-term debt was high because �rms had ambitious

expansion plans and interest rates were lower abroad. Under-supervised�nancial systems with poor disclosure practices – a major institutionalde�ciency – allowed �rms to accumulate huge debts and to make impru-dent investments (more of it below). The problem was compounded asEast Asian businesses are typically more leveraged than the Anglo-American ones: debt-equity ratios of 3:1 are common versus 1:1.5 inAnglo-American �rms.6 High debt-equity ratios can create liquidity prob-lems – as they did for East Asian �rms. Plus, since they require highbreak-even points, �rms become susceptible to drops in capacity utiliza-tion. Highly leveraged businesses are also vulnerable to interest rateincreases – which were put in effect under IMF guidelines. Recall thatmany highly-leveraged American businesses failed in the 1980s due tohigh interest rates. The travails of many East Asian businesses are similar.

REVIEW OF INTERNATIONAL POLITICAL ECONOMY

111123456789

11110111213141516171819

11120212223242526272829

11130313233343536373839

11140414243

11144

Folio 122

Page 5: The East Asian crisis and the globalization discoursefaculty.washington.edu/aseem/east-asia.pdfthe crisis – is evident in domestic restructuring. Prior to 1997, not many scholars

The supply of funds was high because foreign banks were �ushed withfunds. Emerging markets offered higher returns than most developedeconomies (Kahler, 1998). With a recession in Japan limiting domesticdemand, Japanese banks aggressively loaned to East Asia. The cheap-money policy to offset the impact of the 1985 Plaza Accord on the yen,also created excess liquidity in the system (Bevacqua, 1988). By 1996,loans to Asian-crisis countries accounted for 43 percent of their capitalversus 27 percent for G7 banks (World Bank, 1998). From the other sideof the picture, by June 1997, as a proportion of total loans outstanding,Japanese banks accounted for about 23 percent in Korea, 36 percent inMalaysia, 54 percent in Thailand, and 39 percent in Indonesia (BIS, 1998).

Regulatory oversight

Did lax regulatory oversight over banks contribute to the crisis? Someclaim that evidence about high levels of bad loans was available priorto the crisis. As proportions of total lending, non-performing loans were8 percent in Korea, 13 percent in Indonesia, 10 percent in Malaysia, 14percent in Philippines, and 13 percent in Thailand (Corsetti, Pesenti, andRoubini, 1998). However, Radelet and Sachs (1999) suggest that thebanking sector’s health had improved in the pre-crisis years: in Indonesia,the proportion of non-performing loans actually fell from 12 percent in1994 to 9 percent in 1996 and in Malaysia, from 8 percent in 1994 to 4percent in 1996.

Balance of payments (BOP) woes

Arguably, Thailand’s economic downturn started in 1996 with economicgrowth slowing down, land boom petering out, and the stock marketsoftening. In contrast to 20 percent per annum export growth during1990-1995, Thailand’s exports stagnated in 1996. With booming imports,its current account de�cit reached 8 percent of GDP in 1996. Why did most East Asian governments not devalue their currencies? For one, there was resistance given the signi�cant external debt burdens. In Korea, additional devaluation would have allowed per capita incometo fall below the cherished $10,000 mark, an ignominy that PresidentKim Young Sam did not want to be associated with (Moon, 2000).Another factor contributing to the BOP woes was the increased compe-tition for labour-intensive exports from China and Vietnam. For example,between 1990–95, wage rates in the apparel sector rose annually by atleast 12 percent in Malaysia, Indonesia, and Thailand (Radelet and Sachs,1999).7

PRAKASH: THE EAST ASIAN CRISIS

111123456789

11110111213141516171819

11120212223242526272829

11130313233343536373839

11140414243

11144

Folio 123

Page 6: The East Asian crisis and the globalization discoursefaculty.washington.edu/aseem/east-asia.pdfthe crisis – is evident in domestic restructuring. Prior to 1997, not many scholars

Contagion effect

An important structural factor responsible for the fast spread of the crisis– the regional contagion – is the high degree of economic linkages. This,in part, is due to the ‘Flying Geese’ (Kaname, 1961) pattern of regionalindustrialization. For 1995–97, the share of the region (including Japanand China) in the countries’ total exports was sizeable: 54 percent forIndonesia, 44 percent for Korea, 51 percent for Malaysia, 48 percent forSingapore, and 45 percent for Thailand (United Nations, 1999a).Consequently, uncoordinated national policies in the pre-IMF interven-tion phase were not effective. Due to continuing recession at home, theregional powerhouse – Japan – could not provide the demand stimulus,enabling the East Asian countries to export their way out of the crisis.This contrasts with the US support to Mexico during the 1994–95 pesocrisis (for a comparison of Mexican and East Asian crises, see Hale, 1998).

Imprudent investments

Many investments made by East Asian conglomerates were in sectorswith substantial global, regional, and domestic overcapacities (Bevacqua,1998). These included real estate (Thailand, Malaysia, and Indonesia),automobiles (Korea and Indonesia), steel (Korea), and semi-conductors(Korea and Malaysia). East Asia represented a classic case of �nancialmismanagement: short-term �nancing (unhedged) for projects havinglong gestation lags and in sectors with overcapacities. In Korea, 64 percent of the merchant banks’ borrowing were short-term while 95 percent of their lending was long-term (Chang, 1998). Thus, East Asiancountries faced a liquidity crisis, not a solvency crisis, due to a mismatchin the term structures of their assets and foreign liabilities (more of itbelow).In addition to overcapacities, Freeman (1998) points out that East Asian

economies were competitive in hardware manufacturing, not in soft-ware development. As the ICT sector shifted to the latter and manymanufacturing industries also increasingly began relying on softwaresuperiority as a basis for product performance, the East Asian economiesfaced worsening international competitiveness of their exporting sectors.Some investments were also in the non-traded sectors: the revenues

accrued in domestic currencies while the debts incurred to �nance these projects were denominated in foreign currencies. Such currencymismatches are �ne as long as exchange rates remain stable (or in theEast Asian case, exchange rates remain �xed and in consonance withthe economic and political fundamentals). If the local currency depreci-ates unexpectedly – exchange rate risk – debt holders incur additionalcosts for debt servicing. If the levels of depreciation are signi�cant – as

REVIEW OF INTERNATIONAL POLITICAL ECONOMY

111123456789

11110111213141516171819

11120212223242526272829

11130313233343536373839

11140414243

11144

Folio 124

Page 7: The East Asian crisis and the globalization discoursefaculty.washington.edu/aseem/east-asia.pdfthe crisis – is evident in domestic restructuring. Prior to 1997, not many scholars

they were – projects could become unviable. Debts can be hedged (at acost) to guard against exchange rate risks. However, a signi�cant propor-tion of the East Asian short-term debts were unhedged.

Reversal of capital �ows

An important cause in precipitating the crisis was the sharp reversal incapital �ows. Private capital in�ows to the �ve most affected Asianeconomies (Indonesia, South Korea, Thailand, Philippines, and Malaysia)amounted to $97 billion in 1996. In the �rst half of 1997, the out�owsreached $12 billion: a reversal of $109 billion in six months, amountingto about 10 percent of their combined 1996 GDPs (Radelet and Sachs,1999). It is doubtful if any country can withstand an exogenous shockof this magnitude. The capital out�ows can be attributed to the suddendown-grading of debt ratings by credit rating agencies, and the ‘herdbehavior’ of �nancial market actors that caused a veritable bank run,and the absence of the international lender of last resort (Sachs, 1997).As I discuss subsequently, the IMF and the credit rating agencies bearsigni�cant responsibility for the sharp (unjusti�ed) drop in market con�-dence. IMF, in particular, is accused of failing to predict the crisis,responding slowly and inadequately to request for funds, imposing de�a-tionary monetary and �scal policies that accentuated the drop in marketcon�dence.

Recovery

The East Asian economies contracted in 1998: Malaysia by 7.5 percent,Korea by 6.7 percent, Thailand by 10.4 percent, and Indonesia by13.2percent. They have grown in real terms in 1999: Malaysia by 5.4 percent,Korea by 10.7 percent, Thailand by 4.1 percent and Indonesia by 0.2percent (ADB, 2000). Apropos BOP, in 1998 and 1999, Malaysia as wellas IMF’s patients posted current account surpluses, primarily due toimport contraction. In 1998 and 1999, the ratios of the current accountto GDP were as follows – Malaysia: 12.9 percent and 14.0 percent, Korea:12.8 percent and 6.1 percent, Thailand: 12.7 percent and 9.1 percent, andIndonesia: 4.1 percent and 3.5 percent (ADB, 2000), Clearly, based onGDP and BOP indicators (as well as other indicators such as in�ationand unemployment rates), the extent of recovery has been uneven acrosscountries.To summarize, factors emanating both in the domestic and interna-

tional political economies contributed to the crisis, its severity, andtiming. Many of these factors can be traced to institutional de�cits that created conditions for economic vulnerability and accentuated theimpact of speculative attacks. As discussed in the next section, these

PRAKASH: THE EAST ASIAN CRISIS

111123456789

11110111213141516171819

11120212223242526272829

11130313233343536373839

11140414243

11144

Folio 125

Page 8: The East Asian crisis and the globalization discoursefaculty.washington.edu/aseem/east-asia.pdfthe crisis – is evident in domestic restructuring. Prior to 1997, not many scholars

lessons help us to understand how to respond to the challenges of glob-alization, the abilities of governments to do so, and the institutionalchanges required for these tasks.

II IMPLICATIONS FOR THE GLOBALIZATIONDISCOURSE

What policy lessons can be distilled from the East Asian experience,especially in the context of the implications of globalization for economicgovernance? This section examines implications in three contexts: rever-sibility of globalization, the role of governments in reversing somefeatures of globalization, and bridging the institutional de�cits.

Globalization: Reversible or Irreversible?

A claim, implicit as well as explicit, frequently encountered in the glob-alization debates is that globalization processes are irreversible andinexorable (Ohmae, 1991). The argument is that globalization is anoutcome of technological advances that have fostered cross-border inte-gration and undermined the Westphalian territoriality. Advances intransportation and communication have enabled �rms to manage far-�ung operations at low costs while increasing R&D costs are forcingthem to tap multiple markets (Kobrin, 1999).8 Associated with the‘inevitability’ position is the claim that globalization is irreversible orreversible at such high costs that policymakers cannot afford to imposeon their citizens (for an excellent critique see, Cohen, 1996). What does the East Asian experience tell us about these claims? Let

me focus on Malaysia’s attempt to stand up to �nancial markets, theepitome of globalization. Malaysia neither took IMF loans nor imple-mented IMF policies. The ringgit came under speculative attack in August1997. In September 1998, Malaysia imposed capital controls by banningoffshore trade in its companies’ shares. It, however, exempted MNEssuch as Dell and Intel from such controls, making it clear that foreigndirect investment is welcome but short-term capital is not. In February1999, Malaysia relaxed capital controls by replacing the moratorium onremoving foreign currency with an exit tax on investments of durationof less than one year. In September 1999, capital controls were relaxedfurther with the exit tax only on gains, not the full value of investments(New York Times, 1999). 9An important policy issue is whether Malaysia chose the right course

by not following IMF’s prescriptions. Without doubt, capital controlsenabled the Malaysian government to lower interest rates and to relaxthe credit squeeze, thereby stimulating the economy. Malaysia’s actions,however, were vehemently criticized. There were proclamations that

REVIEW OF INTERNATIONAL POLITICAL ECONOMY

111123456789

11110111213141516171819

11120212223242526272829

11130313233343536373839

11140414243

11144

Folio 126

Page 9: The East Asian crisis and the globalization discoursefaculty.washington.edu/aseem/east-asia.pdfthe crisis – is evident in domestic restructuring. Prior to 1997, not many scholars

�nancial markets will extract retribution when Malaysia wants to tap into the world capital markets. Notwithstanding these warnings, the Kuala Lumpur Stock Exchange’s composite index increased by 39percent in 1999 (ADB, 2000). With the relaxation in capital controls inFebruary 1999 (when a graduated exit levy replaced the moratorium on capital repatriation) and then in September 1999 (a uniform levy of10 percent on capital gains replaced graduated levy that varied from 10to 30 percent), capital out�ows during the third and fourth quarters of1999 remained moderate (RM 5.2 billion and RM 3.2 billion) and therewas net in�ow in the �rst quarter of 2000 (RM 6.9 billion). From $31.4billion in the third quarter of 1999, foreign exchange reserves margin-ally declined to $30.9 billion in the fourth quarter and have increased to$32.8 billion by end February 2000 (Bank Negara Malaysia, 2000).10Malaysia’s success does not imply that the IMF’s programs have not

worked. Lim (1999) points out that IMF patients’ balance of paymentsde�cits turned surpluses within three months of adopting IMF policies,currencies appreciated within six months, in�ation was controlled within12 months, and the interest rates reached the pre-crisis levels within 15 months.11 Take the case of South Korea. The won has bounced back – from a high of 843 wons to the dollar in 1997, it collapsed to 1,960 wons to the dollar in December 1997, and hovered around 1100in April 2000. Lim predicts that because the IMF has forced Korea toundertake structural transformation (more of it below), its economicrecovery will be more sustainable than Malaysia’s which is trying to rebuild on its extant structures of industrial organization and corpo-rate governance.There are two perspective on whether the Malaysian experience

suggests that capital controls can succeed. The �rst is that short-termcapital will be wary of entering Malaysia. As suggested in the PublicChoice literature, for market-based systems to succeed, the rulers needto establish institutions that provide ‘credible assurance’ to market actorsthat they will not (and cannot) expropriate wealth (North and Weingast,1989; for a discussion on the tradeoff between government’s credibilityand decisiveness, see Haggard and McIntyre, 1998). This is a classicdilemma in political economy – rulers strong enough to enforce prop-erty rights can also con�scate wealth. Institutions such as division ofpower, an independent judiciary that can review the executive’s actions,and even reputations for fair play provide such assurances. Such insti-tutions provide bene�ts to governments such as lower risk premiumsfor political risk on debts. It could be argued that by ‘opportunistically’imposing capital controls, Malaysia violated its implicit commitment ofallowing unfettered capital �ows, and will therefore be penalized bymarket actors. The trial of Anwar Ibrahim (who opposed capital controls)has also sown doubts about the judiciary’s independence.

PRAKASH: THE EAST ASIAN CRISIS

111123456789

11110111213141516171819

11120212223242526272829

11130313233343536373839

11140414243

11144

Folio 127

Page 10: The East Asian crisis and the globalization discoursefaculty.washington.edu/aseem/east-asia.pdfthe crisis – is evident in domestic restructuring. Prior to 1997, not many scholars

Critics also point out that when Malaysia imposed capital controls andpegged its currency to the dollar (3.8 ringgit to a dollar), the baht andthe rupiah were appreciating due to the IMF prescribed tight monetarypolicies. With exports that account for 70 percent of its GDP becomingmore competitive, a competitive exchange rate helped Malaysia topartially export its way out of recession. Further, Malaysia was lessaffected by the crisis since it had stronger fundamentals than IMF’spatients (Lim, 1999). For example, in June 1997, the ratio of Malaysia’sshort-term debt owed to commercial banks to foreign exchange reservesstood at 0.612 as compared to 1.704 for Indonesia, 2.073 for Korea, and1.453 for Thailand (Radelet and Sachs, 1999). Malaysia’s recovery, there-fore, should not be attributed to capital controls.Malaysia’s defenders point out that investors have short memories;

they will return if Malaysian markets offer attractive investment oppor-tunities. After all, Morgan Stanley Capital International, which haddropped Malaysia from its Asian emerging market stock index, rein-stated it in August 1999 (New York Times, 1999). In addition, Malaysiais not the only country to have intervened in the market. The HongKong Monetary Authority also intervened in the currency market,thereby violating its reputation as the bastion of free market. Wouldinvestors then boycott Hong Kong (and by implication China) as well? The Malaysian government is also not anxious to restore itscredibility with �nancial traders. This is attested by a new tax imposedon pro�ts from short-term investments (the ones that are for less thanone year).The Malaysian experience is also a testimony to how controversial

policies inform policy debates and force reassessment of established para-digms. Subsequent to President Mahathir Mohamad’s actions, someeconomists reputed for forcefully arguing against governmental inter-ventions, acknowledged that there is a case for capital controls. Krugman(1998) noted that capital controls are justi�ed in crises. Bhagwati (1998)pointed out that the logic for free trade in goods and services cannot beextended to free movement of capital. Contrary to Milton Friedman’sclaim that speculative �ows respond to economic fundamentals,Bhagwati suggested that speculative capital �ows can destabilize andchange the economic fundamentals (see also, Eichengreen et al., 1995),and hence the need to reign them in. As previously discussed, Malaysia’s economic recovery is comparable

to that of the IMF patients. Even if Malaysia has not outperformed them, it did not face domestic unrest.12 In sum, Malaysia’s impositionof capital controls and its success in stabilizing its economy withoutmuch retribution from �nancial markets, suggests that in some cases globalization is potentially reversible and governments retain (at leastsome) powers to in�uence cross-border economic �ows. Importantly,

REVIEW OF INTERNATIONAL POLITICAL ECONOMY

111123456789

11110111213141516171819

11120212223242526272829

11130313233343536373839

11140414243

11144

Folio 128

Page 11: The East Asian crisis and the globalization discoursefaculty.washington.edu/aseem/east-asia.pdfthe crisis – is evident in domestic restructuring. Prior to 1997, not many scholars

established paradigms can be challenged if political leaders have the willto do so.

Is state a passe’?

Debates over the obsolescence of the nation state in the economic sphere– ‘obsolete or obstinate’ as Hoffman (1966) had put it – have a longhistory. Even Adam Smith was worried about the constraining in�uenceof capital �ows on governments (Garrett, 1998). Three decades ago,Kindleberger (1969: 207) asserted that ‘the state is about through as aneconomic unit’. Vernon (1971) made a similar argument in his treatise,Sovereignty at Bay. This debate has prominently resonated in the global-ization literature (Ohmae, 1990; Kobrin, 1999; for a critique, Boyer andDrache, 1996; Evans, 1997; Weiss, 1998). It seems that the East Asiangovernments that were active in the ‘miracle’ phase, are playing impor-tant roles in the recovery phase as well.13 Some believe that there was too much of state intervention – a

structural de�ciency – that weakened the system and contributed to thecrisis. Ironically, this group had previously asserted that the East Asianmiracle was due to the absence of market-distorting state interventions.For them, the crisis represents the limits to statist policies. If East Asiahas to move to the next phase of economic development, it needs toadopt the Anglo-American model. Contemporary Bill Gates type ofcapitalism �ourishes only within the Anglo-American model, not withother kinds of ‘state-societal relationships’ (Hart, 1992).Others argue that the crisis was caused by the early withdrawal

of the state (beginning mid-1980s) from the economic sphere, not anexcessive presence. Henderson (1999) traces the crisis to property market speculation in Thailand, Malaysia, and Indonesia. The 1997vacancy rates in the central business districts of Jakarta and Bangkokwere 10 percent and 15 percent ( J. P. Morgan, 1998).14 By the end of 1997, the banking system’s exposure to the real estate market was estimated at about 25–30 percent in Indonesia, 30–40 percent inMalaysia and Thailand while 15–20 percent in Korea (BIS, 1997).Henderson attributes property market speculation to the Chinesecommunity’s alliance with domestic political elites that wanted quickpro�ts. The Chinese community constitutes around 14 percent ofThailand’s population, 30 percent of Malaysia’s, and 3 percent ofIndonesia’s. Due to historical and cultural reasons, it has dominated thelocal economies. With the regulators captured, there was little regula-tory oversight over bank lending for real estate. The bursting of propertybubbles precipitated the crisis. With real estate also being used ascollaterals by many banks, falling property values reduced the collat-erals’ value. This forced banks to call the loans or drastically reduce

PRAKASH: THE EAST ASIAN CRISIS

111123456789

11110111213141516171819

11120212223242526272829

11130313233343536373839

11140414243

11144

Folio 129

Page 12: The East Asian crisis and the globalization discoursefaculty.washington.edu/aseem/east-asia.pdfthe crisis – is evident in domestic restructuring. Prior to 1997, not many scholars

working capital loans. This pushed many borrowing �rms into liquiditycrises.Why did property speculation not take place in Taiwan, Singapore

(both predominantly Chinese), and South Korea? Henderson attributesthis to the preferences of the domestic political elite for establishingworld-class manufacturing industries. In Singapore, since most manu-facturing was owned by MNEs, there was little need to rely on short-termspeculative capital. Taiwan’s ruling Koumintang party controlled mostbanks and large industries and favoured investment in the manufac-turing sector.15 In South Korea, at least until the ascendancy of KimYoung Sam to the presidency in 1992, short-term foreign borrowing andthe venues for their investment were controlled. In South Korea andTaiwan, rent control rendered property markets less attractive for spec-ulative investment. Thus, the governing elites had the will and the powerto ensure that real estate markets did not become havens for specula-tive capital.16 In other words, in statist economies, elite preferencessigni�cantly in�uence how capital is accumulated and invested.What about non-statist economies? Here the abilities of elites to

in�uence how capital is accumulated and deployed are constrained. Well-functioning, adequately resourced institutions that foster transparencyin rule making and enforcement can play an important role inconstraining elite behaviour. Institutional design could thus reduce thechance of the capture.Lim (1999) believes that the crisis resulted from excessive and prema-

ture liberalization. Beginning in the mid-1980s, responding to the rise ofthe ‘pro-market ideology’ and the pressures from the US to open up thedomestic economy, the Korean state began retreating from an activistindustrial policy that involved, inter alia, investment co-ordination. Thisretreat enabled chaebols to over-invest in sectors with excess capacities.With chaebols able to raise funds directly from foreign capital markets,the government’s ability to channelize investments was weakened.Chang (1998) notes that abolishing �ve year plans, replacing them withthe ‘100 Day Plan for a New Economy’, and jettisoning publicly knowncriteria for investment coordination, created opportunities for the rise of crony-capitalism. Government interventions could now be ad hoc, not be subjected to peer scrutiny. The classic cases are the Hanbobankruptcy scandal involving President Kim Young Sam’s son, and the entry of Samsung in the automobile sector that was plagued byglobal, regional, and domestic excess capacities.17 In contrast to Korea,both Taiwan and Singapore continued with activist industrial policiesand prevented over-capacities from emerging in most industries.Governmental policies aimed at decreasing the economy’s reliance onthe East Asian market for exports enabled these countries to bettercombat the regional contagion.

REVIEW OF INTERNATIONAL POLITICAL ECONOMY

111123456789

11110111213141516171819

11120212223242526272829

11130313233343536373839

11140414243

11144

Folio 130

Page 13: The East Asian crisis and the globalization discoursefaculty.washington.edu/aseem/east-asia.pdfthe crisis – is evident in domestic restructuring. Prior to 1997, not many scholars

Are these countries then dismantling crony-capitalist structures? InKorea, the chaebols are �ghting hard to preserve the existing structure;the recent spectacle about restructuring Daewoo being case in point. InMalaysia, Halim Saad of Renong Group and a friend of PresidentMohamad, has avoided liquidation. The recent measures to consolidateMalaysia’s 21 banks, 25 �nance companies, and 12 merchant banks into 6 mega banking groups have favoured friends of Finance MinisterDaim Zainuddin and penalized bankers close to the ousted Deputy Prime Minister Anwar Ibrahim. In Indonesia, Anthony Salim and HashimDjojohadikusumo continue to preside over their industrial empiresalthough their alleged benefactor, President Suharto, is out of power.While in the Philippines, Eduardo Cojuangco, a friend of formerPresident Marcos as well as the current President, is back in business(Frank, 1999).The lessons from the above discussion are the following. First,

government remains a key player in economic restructuring. Domesticpolitics, not the IMF prescriptions alone, signi�cantly in�uences howgovernments choose to structure. This is understandable since the IMF focuses predominantly on macro-economic variables. Second,government interventions per se were not responsible for the crisis. Afterall, activist industrial policies in Taiwan and Singapore helped them to limit over-capacities in key sectors, the emergence of property bubbles,and the piling up of short-term debt. This conclusion is also supportedby the literature on the emergence of the ‘competition state’ that promotesthe economic interests of domestic �rms in global markets (Palan and Abbot, 1996; Cerny, 1997). Third, coping with globalization does not always require dismantling the state through liberalization, deregu-lation, or privatization. The retreat of the state co-occurs withreregulation. The universal prescription for scaling back the state canhave grave consequences especially when other domestic institu-tions cannot take up its regulatory and allocative functions. Because East Asian economies faced institutional de�cits in their domestic environment, the early withdrawal of the state only accentuatedeconomic dislocation.

International institutions: need for a change?

A recurring theme in the globalization and the East Asian crisis debates is that cross-border economic integration co-occurs with a relative lack of accountability of actors such as the IMF, credit ratingagencies, and other �nancial actors. In this context, I brie�y examinethree issues pertaining to international institutional environment: ratingagencies, hedge funds, and recent proposals for a new architecture of�nance.

PRAKASH: THE EAST ASIAN CRISIS

111123456789

11110111213141516171819

11120212223242526272829

11130313233343536373839

11140414243

11144

Folio 131

Page 14: The East Asian crisis and the globalization discoursefaculty.washington.edu/aseem/east-asia.pdfthe crisis – is evident in domestic restructuring. Prior to 1997, not many scholars

Ratings AgenciesThe role of credit rating institutions in precipitating the crisis has comeunder scrutiny. Speci�cally, why did they not predict the crisis, thenreact slowly to it, and �nally, drastically down-grade credit ratings? For reference, even in October 1997, three months after the bhat’scollapse, both Moody’s and Standard and Poor’s ranked Thai govern-ment bonds as grade A. On the other hand, on December 11, 1997,Standard and Poor’s suddenly downgraded South Korea’s sovereignratings by three notches to BBB minus – almost a junk bond rating –leading to investor panic (Financial Times, 1997). Two reasons wereprovided. First, South Korea’s foreign liabilities (public and private) weremuch higher than the government’s previous declarations. Second, theBank of Korea’s futile currency market interventions to support the won had signi�cantly depleted its reserves in that they covered barelya month of imports. Before I critique the raters, a brief discussion about their functioning

(for an extended discussion see, Sinclair, 1994, 1999). Rating agenciesmeasure relative, not absolute, default risks for a given security. Twoissues arise. First, whether their ratings lag or lead the market. If thelatter, then they may encourage herd behavior on the part of investors.Second, since they charge the debt issuers for their services, they do notserve as creditors’ agents. Will debtors then shop around for the leaststringent ratings, abetting a race-to-the-bottom (Spar and Yof�e, 2000)among raters? A 1994 Federal Reserve of New York study reported thatreputational considerations provide suf�cient disincentives for races-to-the-bottom (cited in Financial Times, 1998).Why did the raters falter, if they did? Both Standard and Poor’s as

well as Moody’s plead not guilty. Only Fitch IBCA, Europe’s leadingrating agency, issued a formal report analyzing credit agencies’ records.Admitting its mistakes, Fitch (1998) noted that it incorrectly assumedthat: (a) a high proportion of short-term debt is problematic for highlyindebted countries only; and (b) only public sector debt impacts creditworthiness, and sovereign crisis cannot emerge from dif�culties in theprivate sector. Rating agencies assess solvency, not liquidity. East Asia suffered

primarily from a liquidity crisis due to mismatch of the term structuresof �rms’ assets and liabilities. Not surprisingly, rating agencies were offthe mark (Financial Times, 1998). However, ratings are as good as theinformation governments and �rms provide to them. Recall that for many months after the onset, the Korean government could not give acorrect estimate of the level and the composition of its foreign debt. But can a surgeon remove a healthy organ on the justi�cation that thepatient had incorrectly described the symptoms? Does the doctor haveany responsibility to triangulate the information provided by the

REVIEW OF INTERNATIONAL POLITICAL ECONOMY

111123456789

11110111213141516171819

11120212223242526272829

11130313233343536373839

11140414243

11144

Folio 132

Page 15: The East Asian crisis and the globalization discoursefaculty.washington.edu/aseem/east-asia.pdfthe crisis – is evident in domestic restructuring. Prior to 1997, not many scholars

patient, especially if the patient fears the surgery and has incentives tomisrepresent information?The East Asian experience suggests that credit raters exercise in�u-

ence without the ‘desired’ level of accountability. Their accountabilityextends beyond their �duciary accountability to debt issuers. Any actorwhose actions create sizable externalities (a market failure) becomes apotential target for public policy interventions.18 Credit rating agenciesare clearly such actors.How should accountability be enforced? Literature suggests two

routes: regulation (ex ante) and a liability system (ex post) (Baron, 1999).Regulations can be imposed by governments or by actors themselves.Self-regulation seems improbable given that credit rating agencies (FitchIBCA being the exception) have yet to acknowledge the problems intheir risk assessment procedures and put in systems to prevent a repeatof their East Asian performance in the future. The logic for a recourseto the liability system is that if �rms can be sued for defective products,credit raters that are in the information business, should be liable fortheir ‘incorrect’ ratings – either their pre-crisis assessments of the EastAsian economies or their in-crisis ratings were wrong. An importantsubject for future research is to examine under what conditions shouldcredit rating agencies be accountable to the liability system as opposedto ex ante regulation.

Hedge FundsHedge funds grabbed the limelight after President Mahathir Mohamad(incorrectly) accused them (speci�cally, George Soros’s Quantum fund)of conspiring against Malaysia at the behest of western countries. They again received scrutiny after the collapse of Long Term CapitalManagement (LTCM) and its bailout negotiated under the auspices ofthe Federal Reserve of New York.Why have hedge funds become important actors in the international

political economy? Hedge funds are investment vehicles for high networth individuals. Their leverage levels shame that of the Koreanchaebols. For reference, the LTCM reportedly leveraged about $5 billionof its capital into about $120 billion of investment – a leverage of 24. They simultaneously bet (hence the term hedge) that prices of some securities will rise while of others will fall. As along as the gains from one bet can offset the losses from others, hedge funds makepro�ts.Harmes (1998) correctly point out that hedge funds, especially macro

hedge funds that control about 25 percent of industry’s assets, serve asmarket leaders and opinion makers. Institutional investors such aspension funds and mutual funds often take cues from them regardingtheir investment strategies. By 1995, institutional investors controlled

PRAKASH: THE EAST ASIAN CRISIS

111123456789

11110111213141516171819

11120212223242526272829

11130313233343536373839

11140414243

11144

Folio 133

Page 16: The East Asian crisis and the globalization discoursefaculty.washington.edu/aseem/east-asia.pdfthe crisis – is evident in domestic restructuring. Prior to 1997, not many scholars

40 percent of US household assets. Thus, hedge funds commandenormous in�uence on how capital is allocated.Hedge fund’s functioning poses interesting questions. First, who

regulates them? Shockingly, hedge funds operate with negligible regu-latory oversight. They are not expected to publicly disclose how muchand where they have invested. Second, how do they impact �nancialmarkets? Because they tend to make small pro�ts on every transaction,hedge funds are high-volume betters. Their impact is magni�ed sincetheir high volume investments are quickly moved across securities (boththe magnitude and the velocity are important). Their failure createsmassive negative externalities; hence the need for bailing them out(Eichengreen and Mathieson, 1998; Greenspan, 1998; Brown et al., 1999).This leads, however, to the issue of moral hazards. Hedge funds reapthe bene�ts of smart investments but do not suffer the consequences ofbad investments.Without doubt, hedge funds need to be regulated and moral hazards

curbed. They should be required to periodically declare their positionsand their �nancial leverage needs to be limited as well. Otherwise, everytime a hedge fund collapses, the government will need to bail it outwith public funds. This discussion leads to a broader issue of reigning-in short-term

capital �ows. Imposing ‘Tobin Tax’ (Tobin, 1978) has been suggested asa possible remedy (Felix, 1995; Kuttner, 1998). I do not �nd this proposalappropriate and politically feasible (for a review of this debate, see Haq, Kaul, and Grunberg, 1996). In particular, it is not clear how theTobin tax will curb moral hazards, who will be its bene�ciaries, andwho will decide its appropriation. In an era when it is fashionable togroan about excruciating tax burdens, imposing yet another tax, and that at the supra-national level, will not muster many supporters. Insteadof new taxes, there is a need for a new �nancial architecture that iden-ti�es the actors, the rules, and the procedures for managing �nancialglobalization.

New Architecture 19The East Asian crisis calls for reassessing the roles, the responsibility,and the accountability of actors, domestic and international, private aswell as inter-governmental. A new or reformed global architecture couldcontribute towards this objective. The issue is complicated because ofcompeting visions regarding this architecture. Not surprisingly, mostgovernments are proposing frameworks that suit the economic needs oftheir domestic �rms, again underscoring that �rms can be associatedwith speci�c countries and that governments view themselves asdefenders of domestic commercial interests (Pauly and Reich, 1997).Eichengreen (1999: 9) notes:

REVIEW OF INTERNATIONAL POLITICAL ECONOMY

111123456789

11110111213141516171819

11120212223242526272829

11130313233343536373839

11140414243

11144

Folio 134

Page 17: The East Asian crisis and the globalization discoursefaculty.washington.edu/aseem/east-asia.pdfthe crisis – is evident in domestic restructuring. Prior to 1997, not many scholars

The UK government proposes merging the IMF, The World Bank,and the Bank for International Settlements (BIS) to create a single superregulator of �nancial markets. The French proposevesting additional decision making power in the interim committeeof �nance ministers . . . not incidentally giving Europe a counter-weight to the disproportionate in�uence enjoyed by the USTreasury. The German government has mooted the idea of targetzones for exchange rates to prevent currencies from misbehaving.

In this context, the US proposal is interesting (Sanger,1999). It calls for:(a) curbing moral hazards by forcing lenders to bear a greater share ofthe bailouts; (b) encouraging countries to move towards �exible exchangerates; (c) discouraging the use of short-term debt for long-term invest-ments; and (d) requiring full disclosures about outstanding debt bothby governments and market actors such as hedge funds.The US proposal rejects the use of capital controls to reign in short-

term �ows. It also does not suggest turning the IMF into the lender of last resort because this could encourage reckless private lending.Further, there is no mention of creating a new international bankruptcyorganization or empowering an existing one to perform this function.Akin to the chapter 11 provision in the US, this organization could help in orderly restructuring of troubled �rms/countries (Cohen, 1989).With increased volumes of cross-border �nancial �ows and theirvolatility, as well as shorter product cycles and fast pace of technolog-ical exchange, a supra-national organization is required to oversee‘creative destruction’, for ‘capitalism without bankruptcy is likeCatholicism without sin’ (Eichengreen, 1999: 15). It seems that mostsuggested changes are already in the process of being put in place.Instead of outlining a bold blueprint for a new architecture, the USproposal suggests cautious and incremental changes in the existingsystem. Perhaps, the US position was also in�uenced by the forthcoming

House, Senate, and Presidential elections that entail sizeable ‘soft money’contributions from Wall Street – a point that Wade and Veneroso (1998)allude to.20 Capital controls will certainly not persuade Wall Street togenerously support campaigns. Also, reforming international �nancialinstitutions is not a theme that excites the electorate. In fact, interna-tional issues seem to be taking a back seat in US political debates. Withthe recent rejection of the Comprehensive Test Ban Treaty, some fearthat ‘new isolationism’ is on the rise. I believe that major reforms willhave to wait until the year 2000 presidential and congressional electionsor if the stock market ‘corrects’ itself sooner than anticipated. The lattermight force the US government to actively push for a genuinely newarchitecture.

PRAKASH: THE EAST ASIAN CRISIS

111123456789

11110111213141516171819

11120212223242526272829

11130313233343536373839

11140414243

11144

Folio 135

Page 18: The East Asian crisis and the globalization discoursefaculty.washington.edu/aseem/east-asia.pdfthe crisis – is evident in domestic restructuring. Prior to 1997, not many scholars

In the mid-1980s, the East Asian economies began liberalizing their�nancial markets partly due to OECD and IMF pressure. The OECDmade �nancial market liberalization a pre-condition for Korea to jointhe hallowed club. However, hasty liberalization coupled with lowerinterest rates abroad resulted in a massive accumulation of short-termdebt. Implicit and explicit government loan guarantees created moralhazard problems, whereby lenders did not adequately scrutinize projects. Institutional changes may require dismantling the close relationships

that large �rms in the East Asian economies have enjoyed with banks.Given the signi�cant social externalities, positive as well as negative,created by the �nancial system for the economy (the ‘architecture of allarchitectures’ as Cerny (1994) puts it), governments cannot turn a blind-eye or take refuge in arguments that arms-length relationships betweenbankers and borrowers is not in consonance with the Asian style ofmanagement. Similarly, the US should not try to manipulate the newarchitecture to serve its Wall Street supporters.In sum, the East Asian crisis has drawn attention to institutional de�cits

at multiple levels, and the need to exercise greater oversight over creditrating agencies and hedge funds. As discussed in the previous section,the IMF also needs to become more accountable to the stakeholders whoare expected to jettison their political mandates for its prescriptions. The�nancial architecture needs to have domestic foundations – it is certainlybeing shaped by domestic interests.

II I CONCLUSIONS

This paper examined the implications of the East Asian crisis for theglobalization discourse in the context of three issues: reversibility ofglobalization, roles of governments in economic activity, and institu-tional changes to cope with globalization. The conclusions are: (1)globalization is potentially reversible is some issue areas, provided thereis the political will to do so; (2) states continue to matter in economicactivity; (3) the new system of global commerce and �nance must ensureaccountability at various levels without undermining the democraticbases of the polity. The rest of this section elaborates on these themesand raises issues for further research.Both the euphoria of the 1980s about the East Asian model and the

condemnation post 1997 crisis inadequately capture the strengths andthe weaknesses of the East Asian experience. Though the East Asianeconomic achievements are impressive, their systems of industrialorganization suffered from multiple weaknesses (for an elaboration seeMathews, 1998). The interventionist state retreated in the 1990s withoutestablishing other institutions to enforce economic accountability.Institutions do not change or arise overnight, a learning also supported

REVIEW OF INTERNATIONAL POLITICAL ECONOMY

111123456789

11110111213141516171819

11120212223242526272829

11130313233343536373839

11140414243

11144

Folio 136

Page 19: The East Asian crisis and the globalization discoursefaculty.washington.edu/aseem/east-asia.pdfthe crisis – is evident in domestic restructuring. Prior to 1997, not many scholars

by the experience of the transitional economics of Central and EasternEurope (Boycko et al., 1995). The implication then is that deregulationand liberalization – the key vehicles for the spread of market-basedsystems – needs to be graduated and tailored to domestic needs. Ofcourse, there should be cross-fertilization and diffusion of the best prac-tices across models. However, it is problematic to insist that there is onlyone correct model to cope with globalization, to impose it, and to assumethat the institutional infrastructure to support the model would arise ifthere is a ‘demand’ for it. Thus, the East Asian experience does not vali-date the ‘convergence hypothesis’ (Berger and Dore, 1996) It is not clearwhether East Asian countries will (and should) gravitate suf�cientlytowards the Anglo-American model. Rather, this experience suggeststhat imposing Anglo-American policies (such as free capital �ows)without establishing domestic Anglo-American institutions (such asaccountability to stock markets, accounting standards) is an invitationto economic problems.Many globalization enthusiasts belief that surging levels of economic

�ows will mitigate country con�icts (Ohmae, 1991), a utopia shared byAngell (1910) as well. Since trade is a win-win for the trading entities,‘power’ – the ability to shape preferences and outcomes – will matterless in international relations. However, the IMF’s handling of the EastAsian crisis seems to vindicate the neorealist paradigm: power matters,international institutions represent interests of the hegemons, and coun-tries seek relative gains (Waltz, 1979; Grieco, 1988). A good example isthe debate on the Asian monetary system. In the �rst few months of thecrisis, the IMF and the US Treasury believed that the crisis would endsoon and not have signi�cant economic impact. This was rooted in theassumption that the Mexican formula of tight budgetary and monetarypolicy would work in Thailand, the �rst victim of the crisis. As the crisisaccentuated and spread to other countries, there were demands forbailing out Thailand. Though the US treasury pressurized the IMF forundertaking this, it did not offer any �nancial support. This is perhapsdue to Congress’ anger over the Treasury’s tapping of the Exchange RateStabilization Fund during the Mexican crisis. The lack of US supportbecame an emotional issue in Thailand where it was viewed as betrayal.At this point, Japan stepped in and offered to underwrite a $100 billionAsia Monetary Fund to cope with the crisis. Not wanting the Japaneseto undermine the IMF’s in�uence, and hence their own in�uence in the region, the US Treasury lobbied against it (Bello, 1998). Korea andChina were subtly reminded of their historical legacy with Japan andencouraged to shoot down this proposal. Although Thailand bled forwant of additional funds, power politics prevented the creation of aregional institution that would provide funds to the crisis countries but also undermine the IMF’s in�uence (New York Times, 1998).

PRAKASH: THE EAST ASIAN CRISIS

111123456789

11110111213141516171819

11120212223242526272829

11130313233343536373839

11140414243

11144

Folio 137

Page 20: The East Asian crisis and the globalization discoursefaculty.washington.edu/aseem/east-asia.pdfthe crisis – is evident in domestic restructuring. Prior to 1997, not many scholars

This paper identi�ed many institutional de�ciencies in the East Asianeconomies that led, for example, to piling up of short-term debt to �nancelong-term investment. Some institutional problems are exaggerated,however. For example, I believe that the role of crony-capitalism as astructural cause in fostering the crisis is exaggerated. There are de�ni-tional issues with the term crony-capitalism as well.21 Evidence thatrampant corruption – that results from crony-capitalism – precipitatedthe East Asian crisis is not persuasive. First, as many surveys (such asTransparency International’s) indicated, corruption levels varied acrossEast Asia – Indonesia and Thailand were ranked more corrupt thanKorea and yet all the three countries faced the crisis. Clearly, corrup-tion is not a discriminating variable. Second, as Wedder (1990) argues,corruption was in decline in years prior to the crisis. Third, the 1993World Bank study (especially, pages 1, 5, 6, 14, and 20) actually praisedEast Asian countries for their transparent systems of economic decision-making.22 Why has corruption now become a major issue? The previousdescriptions of the East Asian industrial organization such as ‘alliancecapitalism’ (Gerlach, 1992) were quite complimentary. The learning isthat media and policy networks tend to be swayed by fads. If a countryis doing well, its strengths are highlighted, and the weaknesses arediscounted. Once in crisis, weaknesses – real and imaginary – are in thenews. In almost an Orwellian fashion, a given attribute that was previ-ously a strength is now portrayed as a weakness. Thus, in addition toexercising ‘structural power’ (Strange, 1999), media and key policynetwork exercise ‘relational power’ (Strange, 1999) as well – the suddenloss of con�dence in 1997 leading to veritable bank runs being tellingexamples. This leads to the issue of elite preferences. The paper highlighted how

real estate speculation was rampant only in some East Asian countries.In contrast to Thailand, Taiwan and Singapore invested their savings in creating manufacturing capacities. Similarly, despite mounting BOPwoes, some East Asian governments (notably Korea) did not devaluetheir currencies. Devaluation imposes asymmetric costs on domesticactors: exporters and creditors win while importers and debtors lose. Inour context, most private debt denominated in US dollars was incurredby actors that also had export interests. Then, why did the dominantcoalitions prefer export uncompetiveness to increased debt burdens?Thus, a key issue of future research is how and why elite preferencesdiffer across countries, and how only sometimes they translate into insti-tutional capacities that enable countries to cope with globalization.23An associated subject is the role of leaders in in�uencing elite

preferences and policy discourses. Though realists (Morganthau, 1978)did emphasis the role of leaders in in�uencing policy outcomes, neore-alists and neoliberal institutionalists had tended to downplay it and

REVIEW OF INTERNATIONAL POLITICAL ECONOMY

111123456789

11110111213141516171819

11120212223242526272829

11130313233343536373839

11140414243

11144

Folio 138

Page 21: The East Asian crisis and the globalization discoursefaculty.washington.edu/aseem/east-asia.pdfthe crisis – is evident in domestic restructuring. Prior to 1997, not many scholars

focused instead on structural factors. More recently, constructivists haveemphasized the role of ideas in shaping preferences and strategies(Wendt, 1999). Based on the Malaysian experience, this papers suggeststhat IPE scholars could perhaps pay more attention to how speci�c indi-viduals (such as President Mohamad of Malaysia) are able to signi�cantlyimpact policy discourses. As discussed elsewhere (Prakash and Hart,2000a) IPE scholars could perhaps draw insights from organizationaltheory that has an extensive and sophisticated literature on leadership(for recent surveys see, Luthans, 1995 and Northouse, 1997).24To conclude, this paper is a modest attempt to draw some key impli-

cations for the globalization discourse from the East Asian crisis. Theprocesses of globalization and opposition to them continue to unfold inmany ways. The East Asian economies have also bounced back from thecrisis though there are variations in their levels of recovery and the levelsof domestic restructuring. As some of the issues raised in the concludingsection suggest, understanding the implications of globalization for theEast Asian crisis and vice-versa should remain an active area of intel-lectual enquiry.

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

Previous versions of this paper were presented at the annual conferences ofthe Academy of International Business, Charleston, SC, November 20–23,1999, and the International Studies Association, Los Angles, CA, March 14–19,2000. Financial support from the Of�ce of the Dean, The Elliott School ofInternational Affairs, The George Washington University, is gratefullyacknowledged. I thank Jennifer Baka, James Dean, Lorraine Eden, JeffreyHart, Robert Grosse, Daniel Kane, Stefanie Lenway, Alan Rugman, JamesThurman, RIPE editors, and the three anonymous reviewers for theircomments, and Fakhri Hilmi for his research assistance.

NOTES

1 For one set of surveys of the huge literature on globalization, see Prakashand Hart (1999, 2000a, 2000b, 2000c).

2 While acknowledging that the notion of an institution is highly contested inIPE literature, this paper views institutions as rules that permit, prohibit, orprescribe actions (Ostrom, 1986). Organizations, in contrast, are physical enti-ties (North, 1990).

3 There are other perspectives as well. For example, Freeman (1998) highlightsthe contributions of technical change and R&D to East Asian economicgrowth. I treat, however, technical changes as dependent variables, outcomesof initiatives by both governments and �rms articulated within given histor-ical and institutional contexts. For recent comprehensive reviews on thecauses of the miracle see, Barnard and Ravenhill (1995) and Kang (1995).

4 Interestingly, the 1994 Mexican currency crisis led to the speculation thatEast Asia might be the next in the line for it had similar fundamentals: itsuffered from balance of payment de�cits and it �nanced long-term invest-

PRAKASH: THE EAST ASIAN CRISIS

111123456789

11110111213141516171819

11120212223242526272829

11130313233343536373839

11140414243

11144

Folio 139

Page 22: The East Asian crisis and the globalization discoursefaculty.washington.edu/aseem/east-asia.pdfthe crisis – is evident in domestic restructuring. Prior to 1997, not many scholars

ment with unhedged short-term debt. Since East Asia was still a miracle and not an IMF patient, its propensity for a similar crisis was discounted.The defenders pointed out its high saving rates, low in�ation, and soundbudgetary policies (Kawai, 1998).

5 It seems that both the neoclassicalists and the revisionists versions are prob-lematic. If the Asian miracle was due to the absence of market-distortinggovernmental interventions, neoclassicalists cannot attribute the crisis toexcessive governmental interventions and crony-capitalism as these attrib-utes did not exist in their previous explanations. The revisionists need toexplain how the astute and enlightened East Asian governments allowedsigni�cant macro-economic imbalances (more of which later) to develop.Laying blame on exogenous factors alone and exonerating the governmentis not persuasive because domestic factors, institutional as well as policy-related, contributed to the crisis.

6 In 1997, the debt-equity ratio of Korea’s top 30 chaebols was 3.87 comparedto 2.0 for Japan and 1.6 for the US (Mathews, 1998)

7 However, Fernald et al’s (1998) empirical analysis (cited in Goldstein, 1998)suggests that competition from Chinese exports did not signi�cantlycontribute to the crisis.

8 For a discussion on globalization as an independent and dependent vari-able, see Prakash and Hart (1999).

9 The political fallout between President Mahathir Mohamad and his formerdeputy, Anwar Ibrahim, who opposed capital controls, and the historicalanimosity between Malaysia and Singapore complicated the issue.

10 As the anonymous reviewer rightly points out, the long-term effects ofimposing capital controls remain to be seen.

11 The IMF points out that restrictive monetary policies succeeded in stabi-lizing currencies during the 1994–95 Latin American Tequila crisis as wellas more recently in Brazil, Hong Kong, and the Czech Republic (Fischer,1998).However, Furman and Stiglitz (1998) argue that because the bene�ts andcosts of interest rates increases varied across the crisis countries, the IMF’sone-size-�ts-all approach has doubtful validity.

12 There was unrest over the jailing of Anwar Ibrahim. However, I have notfound evidence of protests against capital controls.

13 Globalization processes may require new roles for governments in promotingstrategic industries (Hart and Prakash, 1999) and in establishing social safety-nets (McGinnis, 1999).

14 Since the vacancy rate in Kuala Lumpur was only 3 percent, J. P. Morgan’sdata does not support Henderson’s assertion about Malaysia.

15 The Koumintang party consisting of mainland Chinese controls key indus-tries while the local Taiwanese focus on small scale industries (this, of course,may change with the defeat of Koumintang in the recent elections). For polit-ical reasons, the government did not allow chaebol like vertically integratedindustrial structures to emerge in the private sector (Hamilton, 1996).

16 I am deliberately not using the phrases ‘strong’ and ‘weak’ states. States’strengths and weaknesses may differ across issue areas, negotiating actors,and international environments. For a review see, Katzenstein (1978),Wallerstein (1974) and Mastanduno et al. (1989). Also, for lack of space, this paper does not examine learnings about theimpact of political system or regime type on economic growth (for a review,see Przeworski and Limongi (1993).

17 Hyundai, one of the largest chaebols, was denied permission to enter thesteel industry while Hanbo, a small chaebol, received permission. Further,

REVIEW OF INTERNATIONAL POLITICAL ECONOMY

111123456789

11110111213141516171819

11120212223242526272829

11130313233343536373839

11140414243

11144

Folio 140

Page 23: The East Asian crisis and the globalization discoursefaculty.washington.edu/aseem/east-asia.pdfthe crisis – is evident in domestic restructuring. Prior to 1997, not many scholars

due to political in�uence, Hanbo managed to receive extensions on its loanobligations (Mathews, 1998).

18 Governments also fail; market failures do not per se justify governmentalinterventions (Wolf, 1979).

19 The literature on the new architecture of global �nance is rather vast. See,for example, Soros (1997), Camdessus (1998), Goldstein (1999), Eichengreen(1999) as well as policy reports put out by G 7(1998), G 22(1998), and morerecently the Meltzer Committee report (2000).

20 As the anonymous reviewer rightly points out, the issue of how domesticand international politics impact each other is complex. Some key worksinclude, Putnam (1988), Evans et al. (1994), and Keohane and Milner (1996).

21 Do the Savings and Loan scandal of 1980s,and, more recently, the campaign�nance debate in the US suggest that crony-capitalism operates in Anglo-American systems as well? Clearly, crony-capitalism cannot be exclusivelylinked to any given system of industrial organization.

22 For example, it notes:

In contrast to lobbying, where rules are murky and groups seeksecret advantage over one another, the (business-government)deliberations councils are intended to make allocation rules clearto all participants . . . technocrats used deliberation councils toestablish contest among �rms . . . one of the by-products of thesecontests was to reduce private resources devoted to wasteful rent-seeking activities (1993: 14; italics mine).

23 I owe this point to the anonymous reviewer.24 An examination of leadership does not suggest that one neglects structural

issues. I am making an argument against deterministic notions (such as glob-alization is inevitable) that discount the role of human agency. In this context,see Prakash (2000)

REFERENCES

Aikman, D. (1986) The Paci�c Rim: Area of Change, Area of Opportunity, Boston:Little Brown.

Amsden, Alice (1989) Asia’s Next Giant: South Korea and Late Industrialization,New York: Oxford University Press.

Angell, Norman [1910] (1933) The Great Illusion, New York: G.P. Putnam.Appadurai, Arjun (1996) Modernity at Large: Cultural Dimensions of Globalization.

Minneapolis, MN: University of Minnesota Press. Asian Development Bank/ADB (2000) Asian Development Outlook 2000.New York:

Oxford University Press.Bank for International Settlements/BIS (1997) 67th Annual Report, Basle: BIS.—— (1998) The Maturity, Sectoral, and Nationality Distribution of International

Lending, First Half of 1997, January (Basle: BIS).Bank Negara Malaysia (Central Bank of Malaysia) (2000) Economic and Financial

Developments in the Malaysia Economy in the Fourth Quarter of 1999,<http://www.bnm.gov.my/pub/qb/1999_Q4.pdf> retrieved on April 28, 2000

Baron, David (1999) Business and Public Policy, 2nd edn, Upper Saddle River, NJ:Prentice Hall Inc.

Bello, Walden (1998) ‘East Asia: on the eve of the great transformation?’ Reviewof International Political Economy 5: 424–44.

PRAKASH: THE EAST ASIAN CRISIS

111123456789

11110111213141516171819

11120212223242526272829

11130313233343536373839

11140414243

11144

Folio 141

Page 24: The East Asian crisis and the globalization discoursefaculty.washington.edu/aseem/east-asia.pdfthe crisis – is evident in domestic restructuring. Prior to 1997, not many scholars

Bevacqua, Ron (1998) ‘Whither Japanese model? The Asian economic crisis andthe continuation of Cold War politics in the Paci�c Rim’, Review of InternationalPolitical Economy 5: 410–23.

Berger, Suzanne and Dore, Ronald (eds) (1996) National Diversity and GlobalCapitalism, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.

Bernard, Mitchell and Ravenhill, John (1995) ‘Beyond product cycles and �yinggeese’, World Politics 47: 171–209.

Bhagwati, Jagdish (1998) ‘Yes to free trade and maybe to capital control’, TheWall Street Journal, November 16: A38.

Boycko, Maxim, Shleifer, Andrei and Vishny, Robert (1995) Privatizing Russia,Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

Boyer, R. and Drache, D. (eds) (1996) States Against Markets. London and NewYork: Routledge.

Brown, Stephen J., Goetzmann, William and Park, James (1998) Hedge Funds andthe Asian Currency Crisis of 1997. NBER Working Paper No. 6427 (February),Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

Camdessus, Michel ( 1998) Towards an Agenda for International Monetary and Finan-cial Reform, <http://www.imf.org/external/np/speeches/1998/110698.htm>

Chang, Ha-Joong (1998) ‘Korea: The Misunderstood Crisis,’ World Development26; 1555–61.

Cerny, Philip G. (1994) ‘The Infrastructure of the infrastructure? toward‘embedded �nancial orthodoxy’ in the international political economy’, inRonen P. Palan and Barry Gills (eds), Transcending the State Global Divide: ANeostructuralist Agenda in International Relations, pp. 223–149, Boulder, CO:Lynne Reinner.

—— (1997) ‘Paradoxes of the competition state: The dynamics of political glob-alization’, Government and Opposition 32: 251–74.

Cohen, Benjamin J. (1989) ‘A global chapter 11’, Foreign Policy 75: 109–27. —— (1996) ‘Phoenix risen: the resurrection of global �nance’, World Politics 48:

268–96.Corsetti, Giancarol, Pesenti, Paolo and Roubini, Nouriel (1998) ‘What caused the

Asian currency and �nancial crisis? Part I: A macroeconomic overview’,Revised Draft, September 1998 <http://www.stern.nyu/~nroubinin>(accessed 4th November 1999).

Eichengreen, Barry, Tobin, James and Wyplosz, Charles (1995) ‘Two cases forsand in the wheels of international �nance,’ Economic Journal 105: 162–72.

Eichengreen, Barry and Mathieson, Donald with Chadha, Bankim, Jansen, AnneKodres, Laura and Sharma, Sunil (1998) Hedge Funds and Financial MarketDynamics. Occasional Paper No. 155 (May). Washington, DC: InternationalMonetary Fund.

Eichengreen, Barry (1999) Towards a New International Financial Architecture,Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics.

Evans, P. B. (1997) ‘The eclipse of the state?’, World Politics 50: 62–87.Evans, Peter B., Harold K. Jacobson, and Robert D. Putnam (editors) (1994)

Double–edged Diplomacy, Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.Felix, David (1995) Financial globalization vs. Free Trade: The Case for the Tobin Tax,

UNCTAD Discussion Paper no. 108, New York: UNCTAD.Financial Times (1997) ‘South Korea: credit rating agencies under �re’, 12

December, <http://www.stern.nyu.edu/~nroubinbi/asia/creditangenciesudenr�reFt1297.htm> (accessed 7 September 1999).

—— (1998) ‘Rating agencies: different kind of risk’, 8 May <http://www.ft.com/specails98/q2872.htm> (accessed 7 September 1999).

REVIEW OF INTERNATIONAL POLITICAL ECONOMY

111123456789

11110111213141516171819

11120212223242526272829

11130313233343536373839

11140414243

11144

Folio 142

Page 25: The East Asian crisis and the globalization discoursefaculty.washington.edu/aseem/east-asia.pdfthe crisis – is evident in domestic restructuring. Prior to 1997, not many scholars

Fischer, Stanley (1998) The Asian Crisis: A View from the IMF.<http://www/imf.org/external/np/speeches/1998/012298.htm> (accessed7 September 1999).

Fitch IBCA (1998) Asia: Agencies’ Harsh Lessons in a Crisis, 13 January<http://www.bradynet.com/e312.html> (accessed 7 September 1999).

Frank, R. (1999) The crony capitalists: ‘people here never thought I’d survive’,Wall Street Journal (1999f) ‘ August 30: A1.

Freeman, Chris (1998) ‘The East Asian crisis, technical change, and the worldeconomy’, Review of International Political Economy 5: 393–409.

Furman, Jason and Stiglitz, Joseph (1998) ‘Economic crises: evidence and insightsfrom East Asia’, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2. Washington, DC:Brookings Institute.

Garrett, Geoffrey (1998) ‘Global markets and national politics: collision courseor virtuous circle?’ International Organization 52: 787–824.

Gerlach, Michael L. (1992) Alliance Capitalism: The Social Organization of JapaneseBusiness. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.

Goldstein, Morris (1998) The Asian Financial Crisis: Causes, Cures, and SystemicImplications, Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics.

Grieco, Joseph M. (1988) ‘Anarchy and the limits of cooperation’, InternationalOrganization 42: 485–507.

Greenspan, Alan (1998) Testimony of Chairman Alan Greenspan, January 30, 1998<http://www.bog.frb.fed.us/boarddocs/testimont/19980130.htm>(accessed 8 December 1998).

Group of Seven (G–7) (1998) Declaration of G7 �nance minsters and Central BankGovernors. <http:///www.imf.org/external/np/g7/103098dc.htm>.

Group of 22 (G–22) (1998) Report of the Working Group on Transparency andAccountability. Washington, DC: G22.

Haggard, Stephan (1990) Pathways from the Periphery, Ithaca, NY: CornellUniversity Press.

Haggard, Stephan and McIntyre, Andrew (1998) ‘The political economy of theAsian economic crisis’, Review of International Political Economy 5: 381–392.

Hale, David D. (1998) ‘Will Mexico’s recovery from crisis be a model for EastAsia?’, in Ross H. McLeod and Ross Garnaut (eds) East Asia in Crisis, Londonand New York: Routledge, pp. 266–86.

Hamilton, Gary G. (1996) ‘The organization of capitalism in South Korea andTaiwan’, in A. E. Safarian and Wendy Dobson (eds) East Asian Capitalism:Diversity and Dynamism, Toronto: University of Toronto Press, pp. 19–44.

Harmes, Adam (1998) ‘Institutional investors and the reproduction of neoliber-alism’, Review of International Political Economy 5: 92–121.

Hart, Jeffrey A. (1992) Rival Capitalists. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Hart, Jeffrey A. and Prakash, Aseem (1997) ‘Strategic trade and investment

policies: implications for the study of international political economy’, WorldEconomy 20: 457–76.

Haq, Mahbub ul, Kaul, Inge and Grunberg, Isabelle (eds) (1996) The Tobin Tax:Coping with �nancial Volatility, New York: Oxford University Press.

Henderson, Jeffrey (1999) ‘Uneven crisis: on the institutional foundations of EastAsian economic turmoil’, Economy and Society 28.

Hoffmann, Stanley (1966) ‘Obstinate or obsolete? The fate of nation–state andthe case of western Europe’, Daedalus 95: 862–915.

Johnson, Chalmers (1982) MITI and the Japanese Miracle, Stanford, CA: StanfordUniversity Press.

J. P. Morgan (1998) Asian Financial Markets, January.

PRAKASH: THE EAST ASIAN CRISIS

111123456789

11110111213141516171819

11120212223242526272829

11130313233343536373839

11140414243

11144

Folio 143

Page 26: The East Asian crisis and the globalization discoursefaculty.washington.edu/aseem/east-asia.pdfthe crisis – is evident in domestic restructuring. Prior to 1997, not many scholars

Kahler, Miles (1998) ‘Introduction: capital �ows and �nancial crises in the 1990s’,in Miles Kahler (editor) Capital Flows and Financial Crises, Ithaca, NY: CornellUniversity Press, pp. 1–22.

Kaname, Akamatsu (1961) ‘A theory of unbalanced growth in the worldeconomy’, Weltwirtzschaftliches Archiv 86(1).

Kang, David C. (1995) ‘South Korean and Taiwanese development and the newinstitutional economic’, International Organization 49: 555–73.

Katzenstein, Peter J. (ed) (1978), Between Power and Plenty, Madison, WI:University of Wisconsin Press.

Kawai, Masahiro (1998) ‘The East Asian Crisis: Causes and Lessons’, ContemporaryEconomic Policy 16: 157–73.

Keohane, Robert O. and Milner, Helen V. (eds) (1996) Internationalization andDomestic Politics, Cambridge University Press.

Kindleberger, Charles (1969) American Business Abroad: Six Lectures on DirectInvestment, New Haven, Connecticut: Yale University Press.

Kobrin, Stephen J. (1999) ‘Back to the future: neomedievalism and the post-modern digital world economy’, in Aseem Prakash and Jeffrey A. Hart (eds)Globalization and Governance, London and New York: Routledge, pp. 165–1878.

Krueger, Anne O. (1990) ‘Asian trade and growth lessons’, American EconomicReview 80: 108–12.

Krugman, Paul R. (1994) ‘The myth of the East Asian miracle’, Foreign Affairs73: 63–78.

—— (1998) ‘Saving Asia: it’s time to get radical’, <http://www.path�nder.com/fortune/investor/1998/980907/sol5.html> (accessed 19 November 1998).

Kuttner, Robert (1998) ‘When the free market is too free’, Business Week, October12: 24.

Lim, Linda Y. C. (1999) ‘Economic policy lessons from the Asian crisis’, A paperprepared for the Expert Group meeting on ‘Economic Governance withinthe Context of Globalization,’ Department of Economic and Social Affairs,United Nations, September 27–29, 1999.

Luthans, F. (1995) Organizational Behavior, Singapore: McGraw Hill.Mastanduno, Michael, Lake, David A. and Ikenberry, G. John (1989) ‘Towards

a realist theory of state action’, International Studies Quarterly 33: 457–74.Mathews, John A. (1998) ‘Fashioning a new Korean model out of the crisis’,

Cambridge Journal of Economics 22: 747–59.McGinnis, Michael D. (1999) ‘Rent-seeking, redistribution, and reform in the

governance of global markets’, in Aseem Prakash and Jeffrey A. Hart (eds)Globalization and Governance, London: Routledge, pp. 54–76.

McIntyre, Andrew (ed) (1994) Business and Government in Industrializing Asia,Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.

Meltzer Committee (The International Financial Institution Advisory commission) (2000) <http://phantomx.gsia.cmu.edu/IFIAC/USMain.html>(accessed 24 April 2000).

Moon, Chung-in (2000) ‘In the shadow of broken cheers’, in Aseem Prakash andJeffrey A. Hart (eds) Responding to Globalization, London and New York:Routledge, pp. 65–94.

Morgenthau, Hans (1978) Politics Among Nations. New York: Knopf.New York Times (1998) ‘Financial crisis is a match for crack U.S. economists’,

September 24: A10.—— (1999) ‘Regaining con�dence, Malaysia ends most curbs on foreign

investment’, September 2: C6.

REVIEW OF INTERNATIONAL POLITICAL ECONOMY

111123456789

11110111213141516171819

11120212223242526272829

11130313233343536373839

11140414243

11144

Folio 144

Page 27: The East Asian crisis and the globalization discoursefaculty.washington.edu/aseem/east-asia.pdfthe crisis – is evident in domestic restructuring. Prior to 1997, not many scholars

North, Douglass C. (1990) Institutions, Institutional Change, and EconomicPerformance, New York: Cambridge University Press.

North, Douglass C. and Weingast, Barry R. (1989) ‘Constitutions and commitments: the evolution of institutions governing public choice in Seventeenth–Century England’, The Journal of Economic History 49: 803–832.

Northouse, P. G. (1997) Leadership: Theory and Practice. Thousand Oaks: SagePublications.

Ohmae, Keinchi (1991) The Borderless World, New York: Harper.Ostrom, Elinor (1986) ‘An agenda in the study of institutions’, Public Choice 48:

3–25.Palan, Ronen and Abbot, Jason with Dean, Phil (1996) State Strategies in the Global

Political Economy, London: PinterPauly, Louis W. and Reich, Simon (1997) ‘National structure and multinational

corporate behavior’, International Organization 51: 1–30.Prakash, Aseem (2000) Greening the Firm: The Politics of Corporate Environmentalism.

Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Prakash, Aseem and Hart, Jeffrey A. (1999) ‘Globalization and governance: an

introduction’, in Aseem Prakash and Jeffrey A. Hart (eds) Globalization andGovernance, London: Routledge, pp. 1–32.

—— (2000a) ‘Responding to globalization: an introduction,’ in Aseem Prakashand Jeffrey A. Hart (eds) Responding to Globalization, London: Routledge, pp. 1–27.

—— (2000b) ‘Coping with globalization: an introduction,’ in Aseem Prakash andJeffrey A. Hart (eds) Coping with Globalization, London: Routledge, pp. 1–26.

—— (2000c) ‘Indicators of economic integration’, Global Governance, 6: 95–114.Przeworski, Adam and Limongi, Fernando (1993) ‘Political regimes and economic

growth’, Journal of Economic Perspectives 7: 51–69.Putnam, Robert D. (1988) ‘Diplomacy and domestic politics: The logic of two-

level games’, International Organization 42: 427–60.Radelet, Steven, and Sachs, Jeffrey A. (1999) ’What have we learned, so far, from

the East Asian �nancial crisis?’, January 4, 1999. manuscript.Ranis, G. (1993) ‘Another look at the East Asian miracle’, World Bank Economic

Review 9: 509–34.Rodrik, Dani (1995) ‘Getting interventions right: how South Korea and Taiwan

grew rich’, Economic Policy 20: 55–107.Sachs, Jeffrey D. (1997) ‘The wrong medicine for Asia’, New York Times, November

3: Op-Ed.Sanger, D. E. (1999) ‘Rubin propose modest limits on lending risk’, New York

Times April 22: C4.Sinclair, Timothy J. (1994) ‘Passing judgements: credit rating processes as regu-

latory mechanism of governance in the emerging world order’, Review ofInternational Political Economy, 1: 133–59.

—— (1999) ‘Bond-rating agencies and coordination in the global politicaleconomy’, in A. Claire Cutler, Virginia Hau�er, and Tony Porter (eds) PrivateAuthority and International Affairs, State University of New York Press, pp. 153–68.

Singh, Ajit (1995) ‘The causes of fast economic growth in East Asia’, UNCTADReview: 91–127.

Soros, George (1997) ‘Avoiding a breakdown: Asia’s crisis demands a rethink ofinternational regulation’, Financial Times, December 31: 12

PRAKASH: THE EAST ASIAN CRISIS

111123456789

11110111213141516171819

11120212223242526272829

11130313233343536373839

11140414243

11144

Folio 145

Page 28: The East Asian crisis and the globalization discoursefaculty.washington.edu/aseem/east-asia.pdfthe crisis – is evident in domestic restructuring. Prior to 1997, not many scholars

Spar, Debora L. and Yof�e, David B. (2000) ‘A race to the bottom or governancefrom the top?’, in Aseem Prakash and Jeffrey A. Hart (eds) Coping withGlobalization, London and New York: Routledge, pp. 31–51.

Strange, S. (1999) ‘An international political economy perspective’, in J. H.Dunning (ed.) Governments, Globalization, and International Business, OxfordUniversity Press, pp. 132–45.

Tobin, James (1978) ‘A proposal for international monetary reform’, EasternEconomic Journal 4: 153–59.

United Nations (1999a) World Economic and Social Survey, Department of Economicand Social Affairs, New York: The United Nations.

Vernon, Raymond (1971) Sovereignty at Bay, New York: Basic Books.Wade, Robert (1990) Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of

Government in East Asian Industrialization, Princeton, NJ: Princeton UniversityPress.

Wade, Robert and Veneroso, Frank (1998) ‘The Asian crisis: the high debt modelversus the Wall Street-Treasury-IMF complex’, New Left Review 228: 3–23.

Wallerstein, Immanuel (1974) The Modern World-System: Capitalist Agriculture andthe Origins of the European World-Economy in the Sixteenth Century, New York:Academic Press.

Waltz, Kenneth (1999) Theory of International Politics, Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.

Weder, Beatrice (1999)Model, Myth, or Miracle? Reassessing the Role of Governmentsin the East Asian Experience, Tokyo: United Nations University Press.

Weiss, L. (1998) The Myth of the Powerless State, Ithaca, NY: Cornell UniversityPress.

Wendt, Alexander (1999) Social Theory of International Politics, CambridgeUniversity Press.

Wolf, Charles, Jr. (1979) ‘A theory of nonmarket failures’, Journal of Law andEconomics 22:

World Bank (1992) The East Asian Miracle: Economic Growth and Public Policy,New York: Oxford University Press.

—— (1998) Global Development Finance, vol. 1. Washington, DC: The World Bank. Young, Alwyn (1994) ‘Lessons from the East Asian NICs: a contrarian view’,

European Economic Review 38: 964–73.—— (1995) ‘The tyranny of numbers: confronting the statistical realities of the

East Asian growth numbers’, The Quarterly Journal of Economics 110: 641–80.

REVIEW OF INTERNATIONAL POLITICAL ECONOMY

111123456789

11110111213141516171819

11120212223242526272829

11130313233343536373839

11140414243

11144

Folio 146