166
The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization: An Empirical Analysis Investigation No. 332-375 Publication 3069 October 1997

The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    0

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis

Investigation No. 332-375

Publication 3069 October 1997

Page 2: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

Acting Director, Office of Economics

U.S. International Trade Commission

Robert A. RogowskyDirector of Operations

COMMISSIONERS

Don E. Newquist

Marcia E. Miller, Chairman

Lynn M. Bragg, Vice Chairman

Carol T. Crawford

Address all communications toSecretary to the Commission

United States International Trade CommissionWashington, DC 20436

This report was prepared by

Project LeaderMichael Ferrantino

Deputy Project LeaderArona Butcher

Primary ReviewersRonald BabulaDavid Ingersoll

Major Contributors

Office of EconomicsNancy Benjamin, Arona Butcher, William Donnelly,

Michael Ferrantino, Kyle Johnson, Peter Pogany, Walker Pollard,Robert Rogowsky, Christopher Taylor

Office of IndustriesStephen Wanser

Supporting assistance was provided by:Patricia Thomas and Paula Wells, Secretarial Services

David Colin, Gregory Neichin, and Seta Pillsbury, Interns

Under the Direction of:William A. Donnelly, Division Chief

Research Division

Page 3: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

U.S. International Trade Commission

Washington, DC 20436

Publication 3069 October 1997

The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis

Page 4: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted
Page 5: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

iii

PREFACE

On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) institutedinvestigation No. 332-375, The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization: An Empirical Analysis. Theinvestigation, conducted under section 332(g) of the Tariff Act of 1930, is in response to a request fromthe United States Trade Representative (USTR) (see appendix A). A report was delivered to the USTRin October 1997. This study updates a previous investigation on the same topic (USITC publication2608, February 1993).

The purpose of this investigation is to review and summarize the existing literature on the dynamiceconomic effects resulting from trade opening agreements, including theoretical work and empiricalapplications. In particular, the USTR requested a background discussion of the relationship betweentrade and the underlying causes of economic growth, such as capital accumulation, technologicalchange, and labor force growth. The USTR also requested that USITC explore empirically thepotential improvements suggested by its critical assessment of the results of the body of literaturereviewed.

The USITC solicited public comment for this investigation by publishing a notice in the FederalRegister of December 11, 1996 (61FR234). Appendix B contains a copy of the notice. Nosubmissions were received in response to the notice of investigation.

Page 6: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

iv

Page 7: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

v

ABSTRACT

This report reviews theoretical and empirical literature on the dynamic economic effects of tradeliberalization. The primary focus of the report is the relationship between economic growth and tradeliberalization. A critical assessment of the literature is provided, as well as are several empiricalexplorations of the relationship between international trade and economic growth arising from thatassessment.

Economic theory generally supports the conclusion that trade liberalization has a positive effect oneconomic growth. Theorists disagree as to whether increases in the growth rate of a country’seconomy after a single episode of liberalization last indefinitely or are time-limited, and some haveconstructed scenarios in which liberalization might slow economic growth. Some empirical studieshave identified a positive linkage between a country’s rate of economic growth and its openness tointernational trade, while others have failed to demonstrate this linkage. One of the unresolved issuesin such research is the appropriate quantitative measurement of the concept of “openness”.

There is stronger evidence that economic growth itself causes increases in the share of theeconomy accounted for by international trade, as well as shifts in the composition of trade away fromprimary products and towards more advanced manufactures; this body of evidence is extended in thecurrent report. In recent years, new techniques of simulation modeling have emerged for theassessment of dynamic effects of trade liberalization; these techniques are particularly well suited forexploring some of the positive linkages between trade liberalization and economic growth.

Empirical research indicates that the most rapidly growing countries tend to have high rates ofcapital investment, high rates of schooling and other types of human capital formation, andgovernment policies conducive to the accumulation of physical and human capital. There is empiricalevidence of a positive linkage between trade liberalization and the rate of investment, generating anindirect linkage between trade and growth. Other studies, as well as the Commission’s own research,indicate that the linkages among trade, investment, and growth are particularly strong for foreigndirect investment, but less strong for investment financed by domestic savings. The Commission’sempirical exploration found mixed evidence in support of a positive effect of liberalization ontechnological change, in line with the existing literature. The Commission also found a statisticalassociation between a country’s degree of trade liberalization and increased female labor forceparticipation, a potential source of economic growth, but no association across countries was foundbetween liberalization and secondary school enrollment.

Page 8: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

vi

Page 9: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

vii

TABLE OF CONTENTS

����

Preface iii. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Abstract v. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Executive Summary xiii. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Chapter 1. IntroductionScope 1-1. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Approach 1-1. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Organization 1-3. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

PART IThe Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization: An Overview of the Literature

Chapter 2. International Differences in Economic GrowthThe importance of economic growth 2-1. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Theories of economic growth 2-1. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Neoclassical growth theory 2-2. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Characteristics of the neoclassical model 2-2. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Predictions of the neoclassical model with respect to growth 2-3. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . The relationship between trade and growth in the neoclassical model 2-4. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Alternatives to the neoclassical model 2-5. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Criticisms of the neoclassical model 2-5. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Growth effects through suspension of diminishing returns 2-7. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Learning-by-doing 2-8. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Human capital accumulation 2-8. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Product differentiation and quality improvement 2-9. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . International transmission of technology and intellectual property rights 2-9. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Do differences between growth theories matter for policy? 2-11. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Cross-country evidence on growth and convergence 2-12. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Evidence for conditional convergence 2-12. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Does the evidence distinguish between theories of growth? 2-13. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Interpretations of the “East Asian miracle” 2-15. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Chapter 3. Evidence on the Linkages Among Trade, Openness, and GrowthAggregate evidence 3-1. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

The “export-led growth” literature 3-1. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Openness in the statistical analysis of cross-country growth 3-2. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Trade and factor accumulation 3-5. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Dynamic effects of trade liberalization on aggregate savings 3-5. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Theory 3-6. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Empirical evidence 3-8. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

The dependency ratio 3-9. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Per capita income and growth of per capita income 3-9. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Real rate of interest and rate of inflation 3-10. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Foreign savings 3-10. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Political factors 3-10. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Exports and savings behavior 3-11. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Page 10: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

viii

TABLE OF CONTENTS- Continued

����

Chapter 3. Evidence on the Linkages Among Trade, Openness, and Growth-Cont.Dynamic effect of trade liberalization on foreign direct investment 3-11. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Review of empirical literature on FDI and growth 3-13. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Technology transfer 3-14. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Spillover effects 3-14. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Review of empirical literature on the determinants of FDI 3-14. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . The relationship between openness to trade and FDI 3-15. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . The relationship between FDI openness and FDI 3-15. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Other determinants of FDI 3-16. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Conclusions on the dynamic effects of FDI 3-16. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Trade, technology, and productivity 3-17. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Aggregate and industry-level evidence 3-17. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Micro-level evidence 3-18. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Evidence for the United States 3-19. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Evidence for developed countries 3-19. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Evidence for developing countries 3-20. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Openness, development, and human capital 3-21. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Trade, income growth, and patterns of demand 3-22. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Introduction 3-22. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Income in trade theories and models 3-23. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Theoretical work related to the income sensitivity of trade 3-25. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

The Prebisch-Singer hypothesis 3-25. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Linder’s representative demand theory 3-25. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Markusen’s model 3-26. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Empirical studies related to the income sensitivity of trade 3-26. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Estimates of aggregate import demand and export supply elasticities 3-26. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Estimates of sectoral import demand and export supply elasticities 3-27. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Variability in estimates of income elasticities 3-28. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Chapter 4. Dynamic Modeling of Trade LiberalizationDynamic general equilibrium models 4-1. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Specific reasons for using dynamic models 4-1. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Classification of dynamic general equilibrium models 4-2. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Calibration of dynamic CGE models 4-2. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Dynamic models in the study of trade liberalization 4-4. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Related applications 4-5. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

PART IICritical Assessment of Literature and Empirical Explorations

Chapter 5. Critical Assessment of Literature and Summary of Empirical ExplorationsIntroduction 5-1. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Lessons of the general literature on economic growth 5-1. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Conditions under which growth takes place 5-1. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Endogenous growth 5-2. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Critique of the empirical literature on trade and growth 5-2. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Direct tests of the trade-growth relationship 5-2. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Indirect linkages between trade and growth 5-2. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Page 11: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

ix

TABLE OF CONTENTS- Continued

����

Chapter 5. Critical Assessment of Literature and Summary of Empirical Explorations-Cont.Summary of the results of empirical explorations 5-4. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Savings and trade liberalization 5-4. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . U.S. direct investment abroad, trade liberalization, and FDI liberalization 5-4. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Technological progress in OECD manufacturing and trade liberalization 5-5. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Trade, human capital accumulation, and labor force growth 5-5. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Trade and income growth 5-5. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Chapter 6. Openness and SavingHypothesis tested 6-1. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Background 6-1. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Data and methodology 6-2. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Data 6-2. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Methodology 6-3. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Results 6-5. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Chapter 7. Trade and Investment Openness and Foreign Direct InvestmentHypothesis tested 7-1. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Background 7-1. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Methodology and data 7-1. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Results 7-4. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Concluding observations 7-7. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Chapter 8. Trade, Trade Policy, and Productivity Growth in ManufacturingHypothesis tested 8-1. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Background 8-1. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Data and methodology 8-2. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Growth accounting 8-2. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Data sources 8-4. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Summary features of data 8-5. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Principal results 8-7. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Concluding observations 8-13. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Chapter 9. The Effect of Openness on Labor Markets and Human CapitalHypothesis tested 9-1. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Background 9-1. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Data and methodology 9-1. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Results 9-2. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Chapter 10. Income-Trade Interactions in the Analysis of Trade LiberalizationEstimates of national and global income elasticities of import demand 10-2. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Calculation of national income elasticities to import 10-2. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . The model 10-2. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . The data 10-3. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Estimation strategy and results by country 10-3. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Generalization to global level 10-4. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Page 12: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

x

TABLE OF CONTENTS- Continued

����

Chapter 10. Income-Trade Interactions in the Analysis of Trade Liberalization-Cont.Gross income elasticities of trade in particular sectors 10-6. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Income elasticities for U.S. machinery and transport equipment exports 10-8. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Methodology 10-9. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . The data 10-9. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Application to U.S. machinery and transport equipment 10-9. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Results 10-9. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Development, consumption, and trade: Chenery curves 10-10. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Data and methodology 10-10. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Results 10-11. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Assessing future levels of income sensitivity 10-14. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

AppendixesA. Request Letter A-1. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . B. Federal Register Notice B-1. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . C. Bibliography C-1. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Figures2.1 GDP Growth Per Head, 1962-93: High-Income Countries 2-4. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2.2 GDP Growth Per Head, 1962-93: 100 Countries 2-6. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3.1 Investment vs. savings 3-7. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6.1 Savings rate vs. openness, as measured by Sachs-Warner index 6-4. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6.2 Savings rate vs. openness, as measured by trade/GDP ratio 6-4. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7.1 Trade openness vs. U.S. FDI/ foreign GDP 7-1. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7.2 FDI openness vs. U.S. FDI/ foreign GDP 7-2. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8.1 Tariffs and TFP growth, by sector 8-8. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8.2 Tariffs and labor productivity growth, by sector 8-8. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9.1 Urban population vs. openness, as measured by Sachs-Warner index 9-3. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9.2 Secondary school enrollment vs. openness, as measured by Sachs-Warner index 9-3. . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9.3 Female labor force vs. openness, as measured by Sachs-Warner index 9-4. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9.4 Urban population vs. openness, as measured by trade/GDP ratio 9-4. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9.5 Secondary school enrollment vs. openness, as measured by trade/GDP ratio 9-5. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9.6 Female labor force vs. openness, as measured by trade/GDP ratio 9-5. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10.1 Chenery curves: relating per capita income levels to shares of commodity (service)

sectors in total consumption 10-13. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Tables2.1 Simulation of neoclassical vs. endogenous Growth 2-12. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3.1 Measures of openness, ranked for 27 Countries 3-3. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3.2 Inflows and Outflows of FDI 1990-1995 3-12. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3.3 U.S. direct investments abroad at historical cost 3-13. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3.4 Selected import and export elasticities of demand in U.S. industries by SIC categories,

1980-1991 3-29. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6.1 Description of data 6-3. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6.2 Effects of openness on saving 6-6. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6.3 Interpretation of results 6-7. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7.1 Data sources used in FDI analysis 7-1. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7.2 Foreign direct investment: coefficients of regression and related t-statistics - 1993 7-5. . . . . . . . . . . .

Page 13: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

xi

TABLE OF CONTENTS- Continued

����

Tables - Continued7.3 Foreign direct investment by industry: coefficients of seemingly unrelated regression

and related t-statistics - 1993 7-6. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8.1 Sectors and countries used in the analysis 8-5. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8.2 Growth rates of productivity, 1980-88, aggregate manufacturing 8-6. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8.3 Absolute levels of productivity, 1988, aggregate manufacturing 8-6. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8.4 Growth rates of productivity, 1980-88, particular manufacturing sectors 8-7. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8.5 Key to names of dependent variables in Tables 8.7 through 8.9 8-9. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8.6 Descriptive statistics for regression data 8-9. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8.7 Effects of tariffs on OECD manufacturing productivity 8-10. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8.8 Effects of exports on OECD manufacturing productivity 8-11. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8.9 Effects of imports on OECD manufacturing productivity 8-12. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9.1 Means, standard deviations, minima, and maxima of principal variables 9-2. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9.2 Effects of trade openness on human capitasl, with dependency ratio

(oppenness measured by Sachs-Warner) 9-6. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9.3 Effects of trade openness on human capital, with dependency ratio

(oppenness measured by trade/GDP ratio) 9-6. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10.1 Seemingly unrelated regression estimates 10-5. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10.2 Selected estimates of gross elasticities of world trade with respect to world income, 1980-95,

by 4-digit SITC categories 10-7. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10.3 Regression of consumption shares on per capita income 10-12. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10.4 Cross-country, sectoral income elasticities of consumption, estimated from Chenery curves 10-14. . . . . . .

Page 14: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

xii

Page 15: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

xiii

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

BackgroundThe U.S. Trade Representative requested that the U.S. International Trade Commission review

and summarize the existing literature on the dynamic economic effects resulting from trade openingagreements. The summary was to include theoretical work and empirical applications; a backgrounddiscussion of the relationship between trade and underlying causes of economic growth; and adiscussion of attempts to simulate the dynamic effects of actual or potential trade agreements. USTRalso requested that the USITC explore empirically potential improvements in the understanding of therelationship between trade liberalization and economic growth, in light of a critical assessment of theresults of the body of literature reviewed.

In order to carry out this task, the Commission has reviewed an extensive body of literature,covering both traditional and newer theories of economic growth and its relationship to internationaltrade and foreign direct investment (FDI); empirical studies of the determinants of economic growth;and empirical studies of the relationship among trade, trade liberalization, and economic growth.Particular emphasis was given to literature relating trade and its liberalization to such underlyingcauses of economic growth as the accumulation of physical and human capital, and technologicalchange. The relationship between economic growth and the recent rapid growth in global trade, on thedemand side of the economy, was also examined, along with current attempts to simulate the effects oftrade agreements in a dynamic modeling environment. This review of literature constitutes Part I ofthe present study.

As a result of the Commission’s critical analysis of the existing literature, opportunities wereidentified for empirical explorations of existing data which might shed further light on the relationshipbetween trade liberalization and economic growth. The results of the critical analysis of the literature,and of five empirical explorations into the linkages among trade, trade liberalization, and economicgrowth, appear in part II of the present study.

Summary of Findings1,2

Review of Literature

Theories of Economic Growth

� It is generally accepted that the ultimate sources of economic growth are the accumulation ofproductive resources and technological change, which enhances the efficiency with which thoseresources are used. The key resources are labor, which expands with population growth andincreases in the labor force participation rate; physical capital, which expands through

1 For Vice Chairman Bragg’s views on economic modeling, see U.S. International Trade Commission,The Economic Effects of Antidumping and Countervailing Duty Orders and Suspension Agreements, USITCpublication 2900 (June 1995), p. xii, and The Impact of the North American Free Trade Agreement on theU.S. Economy and Industries: A Three Year Review, USITC publication 3045 (June 1997), p. F–1.

2 Commissioner Newquist notes his approval of this report is primarily for the limited adminstrativepurpose of transmitting a Commission staff response to the request of the U.S. Trade Representative.

Page 16: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

xiv

investment; and human capital, which expands through education, training, and experience.Technological change may take place through learning-by-doing or by directed investments intechnological progress (e.g., R&D spending).

� A great deal of modern theoretical and empirical work on economic growth is based on theneoclassical growth model. This model features assumptions such as diminishing returns tocapital investment and a common international technology, which give rise to the prediction ofconvergence (poor countries grow faster than rich ones, converging ultimately to the samestandard of living). This prediction is broadly consistent with the experience of industrialcountries in recent decades.

� In the long run, economic growth in the neoclassical model depends on the rate of technologicalprogress, which the model assumes rather than explains. Trade liberalization, by improvingeconomic efficiency, can give rise to more rapid growth in the medium run (several decades) butnot in the very long run.

� Criticisms of the neoclassical model include the fact that the prediction of convergence fails forpoorer countries (some have grown extremely rapidly, while others have experienced absolutedeclines in living standards), and that the rate of technological change is influenced byrecognizable economic factors. Thus, in the last decade or so endogenous growth theories haveemerged. There are many varieties of endogenous growth theory, emphasizing variously R&Dspending, human capital, learning-by-doing, technological spillovers, and the underlyingtechnology of production.

� Many varieties of endogenous growth theory predict that improvements in efficiency, such asthose induced by trade liberalization, could have permanent rather than temporary effects oneconomic growth. However, the theories in general yield ambiguous results about the impact oftrade liberalization on economic growth. Under some scenarios liberalization promotes growth,while under others it could retard growth (depending, for example, on how it influences firms’incentives to engage in R&D, or individuals’ incentives to acquire more schooling).

Empirical Evidence on Trade and Growth� While endogenous growth theories have led to a richer appreciation of the nature and role of

technological change, the limited empirical evidence to date does not clearly favor these theoriesover neoclassical growth theory. There is widespread agreement that international comparativedata fit a pattern of conditional convergence (among countries with similar rates of investmentand levels of schooling, poor countries grow faster than rich ones, ultimately converging to thesame standard of living). Conditional convergence can be reconciled with both an extendedversion of the neoclassical model and some versions of endogenous growth models.

� A wide variety of techniques has been used in an attempt to demonstrate that increases in exports,increases in trade, or liberalized trade policies lead to faster rates of economic growth. In-depthcomparative country studies, popularized in the 1970s, suggested that developing countries withpolicies which were relatively open toward international trade enjoyed better economicperformance than countries with relatively closed policies. Attempts to establish statisticalcausation between exports and growth have had mixed success, as have attempts to includemeasures of trade or trade liberalization in cross-country studies of economic growth.

2—ContinuedCommissioner Newquist does not necessarily concur with the theoretical work or empirical applicationsreviewed and summarized in this report. For further discussion of Commissioner Newquist’s view regardingthe theory and application of economic modelling, particularly its limitations, see The Impact of the NorthAmerican Free Trade Agreement on the U.S. Economy and Industries: A Three Year Review, Inv. No.332–381, USITC Pub. 3045 at Appendix F (June 1997); The Economic Effects of Antidumping andCountervailing Duty Orders and Suspension Agreements, Inv. No. 332–344, USITC Pub. 2900 at xi (“Viewsof Commissioner Don Newquist”) (June 1995) ; see also, Potential Impact on the U.S. Economy andIndustries of the GATT Uruguay Round Agreements, Volume I, Inv. No. 332–353, USITC Pub. 2790 at I–7,n. 17 (June 1994); Potential Impact on the U.S. Economy and Selected Industries of the North AmericanFree–Trade Agreement, Inv. No. 332–337, USITC Pub. 2597 at 1–6, n. 9 (January 1993).

Page 17: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

xv

� One difficulty with much empirical literature on trade and growth is that there are a variety ofmeasures of openness. These are based variously on ratios of trade to GDP, measures of tariffs andNTBs, measures of exchange rate distortion, subjective assessments of policies, survey data, andeconometric measures of the difference between actual trade and statistically expected trade.These measures do not consistently agree with each other, with countries scored as “open” by onecriterion appearing to be “closed” by another criteria. This suggests that there may be severaltypes of openness and/or fragility in the available data.

� One possibility is that more open trade may induce more rapid economic growth indirectly, eitherby accelerating the accumulation of productive resources or by accelerating the rate oftechnological change. The evidence is particularly strong that open economies experience higherrates of investment, which in turn influence rates of per capita income growth.

Trade and the Causes of Growth - Empirical Evidence

� Savings and Investment - There is substantial evidence that expansion of trade is associated with ahigher share of investment in national income. Capital investment is usually financed primarilythrough national savings, and partly through net foreign investment. There has been very littleempirical work directly linking trade with savings.

� Foreign Direct Investment - Trade and FDI are linked in a number of ways. FDI may eithersubstitute for trade (in the case of tariff-hopping investment) or be complementary to trade (in thecase of intrafirm trade). Because of this, different researchers have obtained different results onthe relationship between trade barriers and FDI, although lower barriers to FDI itself areassociated with higher FDI. There is evidence that the growth effects of FDI may be stronger thanthose for domestically financed investment, which is consistent with the observation that foreignmultinationals often possess technological advantages over host-country firms.

� Technology - Increased exposure to imports may enhance productivity by forcing less efficientfirms to adopt new efficiencies, reduce their scale of operations, or exit the market. Suchproductivity effects have been found in some studies but not others. There is evidence that theproductivity-enhancing effects of technological knowledge spill partially across internationalborders but are partly retained in the inventing country. The strength of recognition of foreignintellectual property rights influences international technology payments and may (depending onthe study) affect trade and FDI flows.

� Labor and Human Capital - There has been little empirical research on effects of trade on eitherthe incentives to accumulate human capital (e.g., through schooling or on-the-job experience) oron the labor force participation rate. The experience of the East Asian Tigers (Hong Kong, Korea,Singapore, and Taiwan), which experienced rapid increases in labor force participation andschooling, unusually high rates of economic growth, and were relatively open compared to otherdeveloping countries, is suggestive of possible linkages among openness, human capitalformation, and labor force participation.

Trade and the Growth of Demand; Dynamic Modeling of TradeLiberalization

� International trade has grown more rapidly than world output in the postwar period. This may bein part due to the composition of traded goods, if these goods consist disproportionately of goodswhose relative importance in consumer budgets grows as real incomes rise. This effect ofeconomic growth on international trade, operating on the demand side of the economy,complements the potential ”supply-side” effects of trade liberalization on growth discussedelsewhere in the report. Improved and more focused estimates of the historical effects of growingincomes on patterns of trade, production, and consumption may aid in calibrating attempts tomodel the dynamic effects of trade liberalization.

Page 18: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

xvi

� In recent years, computable general equilibrium (CGE) models have been used increasingly toanalyze the effects of trade policies. CGE models can be static or dynamic, with dynamic modelstaking into consideration changes that ensue with the passage of time. While static CGE modelscontinue to be the predominant tool of trade policy analysis, the use of dynamic CGE models isspreading. Such models can be particularly useful in identifying transitional changes (e.g.,phased implementation of a policy reform) or effects of trade liberalization on economic growthand development. Recent attempts to use dynamic CGE models to replicate patterns in historicaldata show that realistic modeling of long-run changes in trade, particularly for rapidly growingeconomies, is a challenging task for modelers.

Critical Assessments� Current empirical literature indicates that the primary determinants of economic growth are

investment in physical and human capital, technological progress, and a pattern of institutions andincentives under which investment and technological innovation are encouraged. The degree towhich any given country possesses the above conditions for economic growth is in large partindependent of trade policy. This helps to explain the mixed results of empirical attempts toidentify direct linkages between trade and economic growth.

� At present, it is easier to find evidence for an indirect relationship between trade and economicgrowth, operating through one of the proximate causes of growth, than for a direct relationship.Fairly strong evidence links trade liberalization to higher rates of aggregate investment, whilemore suggestive evidence links liberalization to higher rates of foreign direct investment andaccelerated productivity growth. Accordingly, the focus of the empirical explorations in part II ison the search for additional evidence linking trade to the accumulation of productive resources,and to technological change.

� An additional focus of empirical exploration in part II is on the sensitivity of trade flows in generalto growth in incomes. This sensitivity is greater than is often recognized, and its existence raisesimportant issues for the dynamic modeling of trade liberalization. This analysis of demand-sideconnections between trade and growth complements the analysis of supply-side factors elsewherein the report.

Summary of the Results of Empirical Explorations� Savings and Trade Liberalization - Higher-income countries save more, as do more

rapidly-growing countries. In rapidly-growing countries, the savings rate tends to be lower if ahigh proportion of the population consists of children. A high share of trade in the nationaleconomy is associated with a higher savings rate, particularly for more rapidly-growingeconomies. For major episodes of liberalization captured by the Sachs-Warner index (anindicator of an economy’s openness), there appears to be no particular relationship betweenliberalization and savings.

� U.S. Direct Investment Abroad, Trade Liberalization, and FDI Liberalization - U.S. FDI abroad isconcentrated in countries with large economies and in countries geographically closer to theUnited States. U.S. FDI is more strongly attracted to countries with both open FDI policies andopen trade policies. The strength of the measured FDI effect is large. The effect of open tradepolicies in stimulating FDI suggests that trade and FDI tend on balance to be complementary.Open trade policies appear to be attractive for U.S. direct investments in manufacturing andservices, but have no discernible impact for U.S. FDI in the petroleum industry. However, U.S.investors are strongly attracted to open FDI policies in all industries examined.

� Technological Progress in OECD Manufacturing and Trade Liberalization - There is evidence ofcross-country convergence in industrial productivity in the OECD; within a given sector,low-productivity countries experience more rapid productivity growth than countries leading inproductivity. A stronger research effort is also associated with greater productivity gains.

Page 19: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

xvii

High-tariff sectors tend to have low productivity growth, while low-tariff sectors tend to havehigh productivity growth. After accounting for other determinants of productivity growth, thenegative association between tariffs and productivity is broadly confirmed, but is statisticallysignificant only for some measures of productivity. A positive association between exportperformance and productivity growth appears to be somewhat stronger. There is no observablerelationship in the data analyzed between import penetration and productivity growth.

� Trade, Human Capital Accumulation, and Labor Force Growth — Some measures of opennessare associated statistically with measures of labor force participation or human capital. Moreopen economies have a higher female proportion of the labor force, implying a higher labor forceparticipation rate overall. Economies with a higher ratio of trade to GDP have a larger percentageof the labor force in urban areas, where wages are higher; however, the Sachs-Warner index ofopenness is uncorrelated with urbanization. No statistically significant association was foundbetween the secondary school enrollment ratio and openness to international trade.

� Trade and Income Growth - Most countries were found to have imports which grow more thanproportionately with respect to income, while in some countries imports have grown roughlyproportionately with income. As a ”best estimate,” controlling for relative prices, every onepercent increase in real global incomes has induced approximately a 1.8 percent increase in globaltrade. A calculation was performed of the gross income elasticity (uncorrected for relative pricechanges) of various categories of global trade during recent years. Also, a methodology forformal estimation of the sensitivity of export demand for a specific commodity (U.S. machineryand equipment) with respect to rest-of-world income was demonstrated. Taken together, theseestimates show that transportation equipment, machinery and equipment in general (particularlyelectronic equipment), and apparel have accounted for a sizable share of the mostrapidly-growing international trade. An analysis of global consumption patterns across countrieswith different levels of income identifies a group of commodities (including transport equipment,machinery, and apparel) as having a larger share of consumption in high-income than low-incomecountries.

Page 20: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

1-1

CHAPTER 1Introduction

ScopeThis study analyzes the dynamic economic effects

resulting from trade liberalization, extending andupdating an earlier report by the U.S. InternationalTrade Commission (USITC) that was transmitted tothe United States Trade Representative (USTR) inFebruary 1993.1 The original study covered primarilytheoretical literature. Since the release of that report,the empirical literature on trade, growth, and thedynamic relationship between the two has expandedrapidly, including attempts to simulate the dynamiceffects of actual or potential trade agreements. TheUSTR has requested the USITC : (1) to review andcritically assess these advances in the literature, and(2) to explore empirically the potential improvementssuggested by this assessment.2

ApproachThe primary focus of this investigation is to assess

the potential impact of trade liberalization oneconomic growth. Do countries which adopt policiesencouraging freer trade enjoy more rapid rates ofgrowth in per capita income than otherwise similarcountries which do not engage in trade liberalization?The importance of this question becomes apparentwhen it is realized that the enormous differences inthe standards of living between one country andanother have emerged as the result of relatively smalldifferences in the rate of economic growth,maintained over decades. Thus, the potential impactof trade liberalization on economic growth, howevermodest, might have important consequences forstandards of living. The analysis of this impactrequires an understanding of the general reasons whyeconomic growth is rapid in some countries and slowin others, and whether trade liberalization has beeninfluential in enhancing economic growth. Inaddition, analysis requires examination of whether acountry’s “openness” to international trade can bereasonably captured by one or more quantitativeindicators.

1 See USITC, The Dynamic Effects of TradeLiberalization: A Survey, USITC publication 2608,Washington, DC, February 1993.

2 A copy of the USTR’s request letter appears asAppendix A of this report.

The term dynamic effects in the title of thisinvestigation refers to effects on the rate of economicgrowth that are manifested over an extended periodof time. The dynamic effects of trade liberalizationare in contrast to the concept of static efficiency gains.In the context of trade liberalization, “static efficiencygains” refers to one-time benefits of liberalizationwhich arise as national prices become more closelyaligned with the global price structure, and theresulting reallocation of resources that takes placewithin the economy in response to these pricechanges. The method of measuring static efficiencygains by comparing the performance of the economyin two scenarios for a single base year (in this casewith and without liberalization), is referred to ascomparative statics.

Traditional methods of analyzing tradeagreements, relying on comparative statics,3 generallysimulate the effects of the trade agreement at a singlepoint in time, using available data for a single,historical base year, and consider only static efficiencygains from liberalization. However, if tradeliberalization influences the rate of economic growth,even by a few tenths of a percentage point annually,its potential consequences would turn out to besubstantially greater than those captured by staticefficiency gains, since the effects would be bothextended and compounded over time. It is, therefore,presumed that measures of dynamic gains from trademight be larger than comparative-statics measures ofgains from trade. There has been increasing interestin this possibility as indicated in USTR’s request letterwhich states that “An understanding and appreciationof the potential dynamic gains from trade are neededto contribute to more fully informed assessments ofthe trade policy options that confront the Presidentand Congress.”

3 Examples of USITC studies utilizing the method ofcomparative statics include USITC, Economy-WideModeling of the Economic Implications of a FTA WithMexico and a NAFTA With Canada and Mexico, USITCpublication 2508, May 1992; USITC, The EconomicEffects of Antidumping and Countervailing Duty Ordersand Suspension Agreements, USITC publication 2900,June 1995; and USITC, The Economic Effects of U.S.Import Restraints: First Biannual Update, USITCpublication 2935, December 1995.

Page 21: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

1-2

For the purposes of this investigation, the termtrade liberalization is defined broadly to includeliberalization of trade in goods and services, capital,and technology. Liberalization of trade in capital (i.e.foreign investment, particularly foreign directinvestment (FDI)) is increasingly undertaken ordiscussed simultaneously with trade liberalization, asin the North American Free Trade Agreement(NAFTA), in the Uruguay Round Agreement onTrade-Related Investment Measures (TRIMS), and inthe Asia-Pacific Economic Cooperation forum(APEC). As will be discussed in this report,expansion of foreign investment has directconsequences for both economic growth andmerchandise trade. In addition, certain types ofinvestment liberalization and trade liberalizationcoincide in a formal, legal sense (i.e., TRIMS). Tradein technology, such as cross-border licensing ofintellectual property, has characteristics in commonwith foreign investment; technology trade is a subjectof recent liberalization initiatives, and it is linked bothsubstantively and formally with merchandise trade.Improvement of foreigners’ intellectual propertyprotection is being undertaken simultaneously withtrade liberalization, and technology trade has potentialconsequences both for economic growth and formerchandise trade.

This study reviews theoretical literature oneconomic growth, with the primary aim of identifyingpotential mechanisms by which trade liberalizationmight influence the rate of economic growth. Muchof economic growth theory is focused on sources ofgrowth other than international trade, such asinvestment and savings, human capital formation (e.g.,education and training), and the state of technology.Since the efficiency gains associated with tradeliberalization in standard international economics areeffectively similar to an improvement in technology,these theories can be used to draw inferences aboutthe growth effects of trade liberalization. In othertheories of economic growth, an explicit role forinternational trade is posited, and the consequences ofliberalization can be discussed directly.

The review of empirical literature on economicgrowth examines a variety of methods for assessingthe quantitative impact of increased trade, or of tradeliberalization, on economic growth. While some ofthese attempts have produced evidence of a positiverelationship, particularly for countries which undergosudden and radical trade liberalization, the evidencefor a positive relationship between more modest tradeliberalizations and economic growth is tentative andof mixed quality. One issue arising in such work isthe difficulty of quantifying the degree of “openness”associated with a given economy. As can beanticipated, such a task is quite complex and hence,there is no single universally accepted technique for

measuring the “openness” of an economy tointernational trade. This report considers alternativeswhich have been proposed thus far, and their strengthsand weaknesses.

The review of empirical literature indicates thattrade liberalization may principally influenceeconomic growth through indirect channels, byinfluencing more immediate determinants of growth.These determinants include investment (includingparticularly foreign investment), technologicalchange, the accumulation of human capital (e.g,through education and training), and labor forceparticipation. The analysis of investment in this studycontains two components; an analysis of the impact oftrade liberalization on domestic savings (sincedomestic savings is the primary means of financinginvestment in most countries) and an analysis offoreign investment. The analysis of foreigninvestment examines the responsiveness of the stockof U.S. foreign direct investment (FDI) in variouscountries to the openness of those countries’ policiestowards trade and FDI. Similarly, analyses of theimpact of trade, and its liberalization, are undertakenwith respect to the rate of technological change, andto human capital accumulation. The effect ofopenness on technological change, as measured bygrowth in output in excess of growth in inputs, isanalyzed for various manufacturing sectors in asample of developed countries. The concept ofhuman capital formation is captured by threemeasures; the secondary school enrollment rate, thepercent of population living in urban areas, and theproportion of the labor force that is female.

The impact of trade liberalization on domesticsavings, FDI, total factor productivity, and humancapital is investigated using econometric techniques,in a manner which takes into account the impact ofother key variables on the performance of each ofthese determinants of economic growth. For example,the impact of age distribution and per capita incomefor a given economy is considered in the analyses ofsavings behavior and human capital; the effects oflocation are considered in the analysis of FDI; and theimpact of research and development is examined inthe analysis of technological change.

The request letter identifies “attempts to simulatethe dynamic effects of actual or potential tradeagreements” as a component of the empiricalliterature to be reviewed. Thus, the study reviews theprimary technique by which such simulations havebeen carried out, namely, dynamic computable generalequilibrium (DCGE) modeling. DCGE modeling is atechnique which is being increasingly used to estimatethe effects of trade liberalization for a given country,for regions, or for the global economy. The reviewindicates that DCGE modeling is a valuable supple-ment to comparative statics in simulating the general

Page 22: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

1-3

equilibrium impact of potential changes in tradepolicy. However, experience using DCGE models toreplicate the historical levels of trade suggests thatattempts to simulate future trends in trade patterns ona forward-looking basis, over long periods of time,presents particular challenges.

These challenges arise from rapidly moving trendsthat are difficult to model. The Commission’s analysisidentifies two such trends: the persistent tendency forworld trade to grow more rapidly than world income,and the tendency of both consumption and trade toshift into different categories of goods and services asincome rises. The effects of economic growth ontrade operate through the demand side of theeconomy, in contrast to the “supply-side” effects oftrade liberalization on labor, physical and humancapital, and technological change emphasizedelsewhere in the report. This report examines thesechanging patterns of trade and consumption, both inthe literature review and in the subsequent empiricalanalysis. A better understanding of these patterns,and their underlying economic causes, is likely to leadto future improvements in estimating of the dynamicconsequences of trade liberalization.

OrganizationThis report is divided into two parts. Part I,

consisting of Chapters 1 through 4, presents thereview of literature as requested by USTR. Thisreview includes a current overview of the principaltheoretical frameworks for the study of economicgrowth, emphasizing the differences betweentraditional and more recent models of economicgrowth and their consequences for trade liberalization,and presents empirical evidence on the primarysources of differences between countries in the rate ofeconomic growth (Chapter 2). This is followed by anexamination of the empirical linkages among trade,openness, and growth (Chapter 3). Measures used in

the literature to capture the concept of “openness tointernational trade” are discussed. Also discussed isthe relationship between trade and the underlyingcauses of economic growth, such as capitalaccumulation, technological change, and labor forcegrowth. Chapter 3 also examines evidencedemonstrating that international trade is highlysensitive to changes in demand (in technical terms,there is a high income elasticity of demand for tradedgoods). An increasing number of attempts have beenmade to simulate the dynamic effects of actual orpotential trade agreements in recent years; thisliterature is reviewed in chapter 4.

Part II, consisting of chapters 5 through 10,comprises the Commission’s critical assessment of theliterature reviewed in Part I, as well as severalempirical explorations suggested by that criticalassessment, pursuant to the request letter. Chapter 5contains the critical assessment of the literature. Itsynthesizes the discussion in chapters 2 though 4,identifies the strengths and weaknesses of the existingliterature, and relates these to the Commission’schoice of topics for empirical exploration insubsequent chapters. It also briefly summarizes thenature and results of the empirical explorations whichconstitute chapters 6 through 10.

Chapters 6 through 9 provide econometricinvestigations of the impact of trade liberalization onsavings behavior, foreign direct investment, totalfactor productivity, and human capital, respectively.Chapter 10 explores the persistent tendency for worldtrade to grow more rapidly than world income inrecent decades, and relates this tendency totransformation in global consumption patterns. Theevidence from the literature on this topic, presented inchapter 3, is extended and focused in theCommission’s own statistical analysis. This analysispresents new estimates of income elasticities for theworld, and for particular countries, sectors, andcommodities.

Page 23: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted
Page 24: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

PART I The Dynamic Effects of Trade

Liberalization: An Overview of theLiterature

Page 25: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted
Page 26: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

2-1

CHAPTER 2International Differences in

Economic Growth

This chapter reviews modern theories of economicgrowth, with the dual purpose of identifying theprimary determinants of economic growth in thesetheories and examining their predictions about theeffects of trade liberalization on economic growth.Particular attention is given to the differences betweenthe neoclassical growth model and recent alternativesto that model, which are often grouped together as“endogenous growth theory”; the divergingpredictions of these theories as to whether growtheffects of trade liberalization are temporary orpermanent; and the question of whether thesedifferences among theories are relevant for publicpolicy. Empirical evidence on the primary issuesraised by economic growth theory is examined,including the principal reasons why the economies ofsome countries grow faster than those of others andthe question of whether current evidence distinguishesbetween neoclassical and endogenous growth theories.This discussion provides background for theexamination of empirical evidence regarding theparticular impact of “openness,” or tradeliberalization, on economic growth in chapter 3.

The Importance ofEconomic Growth

The focus of this investigation is an empiricalquestion: Does trade liberalization cause economieswhich liberalize to grow more rapidly than thosewhich do not? Small differences in economic growth,maintained for extended periods of time, can lead todramatic differences in standards of living. Thesedifferences help account for the interest of policy-makers and analysts in learning whether dynamicgains from trade liberalization exist, however small.In order to emphasize this point, and motivate furtherthe discussion in the balance of the report, someexamples are presented here.

The effects of sustained differences in the rate ofeconomic growth can be illustrated by the so-called

“rule of 72.”1 If two economies begin with the sameincome per person, but growth in income per personin the first economy exceeds that in the second by2 percent per year, in 36 years the faster-growingeconomy will enjoy approximately double thestandard of living in the second economy. If thedifference in per capita income growth is 3 percentper year, this doubling of the relative living standardwill take place in 24 years, or within a generation.Examples of such sustained differences in growthbetween countries are numerous. A dramaticexample of the consequences of sustained differencesin economic growth rates is provided by acomparison of El Salvador and Japan. In themid-1950s, the per capita income of El Salvador wasroughly equal to, or even slightly higher than, that inJapan (Bhagwati (1966)).2 In 1993, according toWorld Bank data, the income of one Japanese personwas approximately equal to that of 24 Salvadorans.This difference can be accounted for by a sustaineddifference of less than 9 percent per year ineconomic growth per person, maintained over 38years.3 Most differences in economic growthbetween countries can be attributed to causes otherthan differences in trade policies. Nonetheless, iftrade liberalization can be shown to make even amodest contribution to more rapid economic growth,such a contribution would have importantconsequences for the progress of human well-being,for both the United States and its trading partners.

Theories of EconomicGrowth

Many of the most fundamental principles relatingto economic growth, international trade, and therelationship between them were anticipated by the

1 Technical note.—Under the “rule of 72,” the numberof years it takes for a quantity to double can beapproximated by dividing its annual growth rate into thenumber 72.

2 Full citations to literature referenced in this reportappear in Appendix C.

3 USITC staff calculation.

Page 27: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

2-2

classical economists, such as David Hume (1711-76),Adam Smith (1723-90), David Ricardo (1772-1823),and John Stuart Mill (1806-73). These principlesinclude, among others:

� The realization that sustained increases in realwages can be maintained by steady increases incapital per worker;

� The role of saving, or abstaining fromconsumption, in financing capital accumu-lation;

� The role of improvements in the “useful arts,”advances in machinery, and extensions of thedivision of labor (in modern parlance,technological change) in raising livingstandards ; and

� The twin possibilities that capital accumulationand technological progress could lead toexpansion in international trade, and thatinternational trade could improve theconditions for economic growth. The feedbackeffects of trade on economic growth wererecognized to operate through a number ofchannels, including the importation of inputs todomestic manufactures; international diffusionof new production techniques and newconsumption possibilities; and wider extensionof the division of labor, promoting increasedeconomies of scale.

After languishing for nearly a century, interest inthe theory of economic growth revived in themid-20th century. Plans for the reconstruction ofEurope and Japan after World War II, the problem ofvery low living standards in the newly independentformer colonies, and the Soviet Union’s experience ofrapid increases in mechanization and industrial outputin the Stalin/Khrushchev years converged to dramatizeissues surrounding economic growth. Westernattempts at constructing new mathematical theories ofeconomic growth, most notably those of Roy Harrod(1939) and Evsey Domar (1946), relied onassumptions of technologically fixed proportionsbetween labor and capital and fixed rates of savingindependent of any human decisions about theappropriate rate of savings. The logical implicationsof such restrictive assumptions were that stable,long-run economic growth was unlikely in marketeconomies, and that chronic growth of eitherunemployment or idle machinery was very likely.4

4 Similar assumptions were utilized in themathematical models of central planning employed in theSoviet Union and adapted for use in some developingeconomies (e.g., the Mahalanobis (1955) model adopted

Neoclassical Growth TheoryThe neoclassical growth theory of Robert Solow

(1956) and Trevor Swan (1956) is generallyrecognized as the modern beginning of fruitfultheorizing about economic growth in marketeconomies. The neoclassical theory overcame theparadoxes of the Harrod/Domar model by recognizingthat substitution between labor and capital takes placein response to changes in their relative prices.Profit-seeking firms will employ more machinery perworker if the wage rate rises relative to the user costof capital,5 and will employ more workers permachine if the user cost of capital rises relative to thewage rate. This process insures that sustainedincreases in real income per worker can be maintainedconsistently with long-run full employment of bothlabor and capital.6

Characteristics of the NeoclassicalModel

The basic neoclassical model employs thefollowing additional assumptions:

� The economy operates under constant returnsto scale, i.e., simultaneously increasing inputsof labor and capital by an identical proportionwill increase output by the same proportion;

4—Continuedfor India’s Second Five-Year Plan.) It was believed thatthe supposed difficulties of instability and chronicunemployment in market economies could be overcomeby government fiat with regard to savings, accumulation,and technology. Among other things, these modelsoverlooked the possibility that continuing accumulation ofcapital equipment, unaccompanied by market-drivenimprovements in productivity, could lead to an eventualstagnation of living standards - a possibility that becamereality in the Soviet and East European economies duringthe 1970s and 1980s (Easterly and Fischer (1995)).

5 The user cost of capital (or rental rate of capital) isa function of equipment prices, the rate of interest, andthe rate of depreciation on previously installed capital.Increases in any of the above raise the user cost ofcapital, and vice versa. The user cost of capital can beinfluenced by the tax treatment of interest anddepreciation (Jorgenson (1963)). Standard theoryrecognizes that capital gains, and its taxation, may alsoinfluence the user cost of capital, but the empiricalsignificance of this effect is a matter of considerablecontroversy (Gravelle (1994), Feldstein (1995), Moriger(1995)).

6 It bears emphasizing that the goal of growth theoryis to describe long-run economic processes, for which theidea of full employment of labor and capital is reasonable.The theory of business cycles, which recognizes thatrecessions are associated with surges in unemploymentand analyzes policies directed at macroeconomicstabilization, is generally kept distinct from growth theoryfor reasons of analytical tractability.

Page 28: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

2-3

� There are diminishing returns to both labor andcapital. If the stock of capital were somehow tobe fixed, employing additional workers wouldlead to steadily falling additions to output foreach additional worker, and thus to fallingwages. Similarly, if the labor force were fixed,installing additional capital would lead tosteadily falling additions to output for eachadditional unit of capital, and thus to fallingmarket returns to capital.

� In fact, however, the labor force is constantlygrowing with population growth, and the stockof capital also grows. Annual investment,which increases the capital stock, is financedout of savings, and a portion of that investmentis used to replace the depreciation of old capital.The labor force growth rate, the rate of savingsout of national income, and the depreciation rateare “exogenous” in the basic neoclassicalmodel; that is, they are assumed to be fixed bysome mechanism operating outside the model,with the model itself making no further attemptto explain the values which they take.7

� Technological improvements also take place ata constant rate. Any given combination of laborand capital produces more and more output astime goes on, because of improvements in thetechniques of production. The rate oftechnological progress is also fixedexogenously, with the model itself making noparticular attempt to explain why technologicalprogress might be either fast or slow.

Predictions of the NeoclassicalModel With Respect to Growth

In the Solow/Swan model, per capita incomesmay grow both because of increases in capital perworker and because of technological change. Becauseof diminishing returns to capital, however, the impactof additional savings and investment eventuallydeclines, to the point at which the available savings isonly sufficient to cover depreciation and growth in thelabor force. At this point, although savings and

7 In more sophisticated versions of the neoclassicalgrowth model, the savings rate is determined byhousehold decisionmaking, and may thus fluctuate overtime (Ramsey (1928), Cass (1965), Koopmans (1965)). Inthe longer run, the growth of the labor force is influencedby household decisions about childbearing (Becker andBarro (1988), Barro and Becker (1989)), as well as bydecisions about labor-force participation. There isoverwhelming evidence that the birth rate tends to declinewith increases in living standards, thus providing anadditional boost to per capita income (Birdsall (1989)).

investment continue to take place, capital per workerstops increasing. This implies that if there were notechnological change, growth in per capita incomewould also stop. Viewed another way, in the longrun the growth in per capita income is just equal tothe rate of technological change, and is entirelygenerated by technological change. This situationrepresents the long-run dynamic equilibrium of aneoclassical economy.

One of the most important predictions of theneoclassical model is that of convergence in percapita incomes — i.e., low-income countries shouldgrow more rapidly than high-income countries, otherthings being equal. This prediction arises whenconsidering the behavior of the model in cases wherethe economy has not yet reached its long-runequilibrium (in technical terms, this is calledanalyzing the model’s transitional dynamics).Initially, per capita incomes may be low, becausecapital per worker is low. The economy may not yethave saved and invested enough to take advantage ofthe technological opportunities which currently exist.This gives a stimulus to new savings and investment,which will increase capital per worker; per capitaincomes will then rise. Since low-income countriesstart out with less capital per worker than high-incomecountries, their rate of return on capital is higher, theincentive for capital accumulation is thus greater, andincome growth is faster. As capital accumulates, andthe rate of return on capital falls, growth of per capitaincome gradually decelerates until it equals the rate ofpure technological change. Figure 2-1 graphs the rateof per capita GDP growth relative to 1962 per capitaGDP over the period 1962-93 for 20 countries inwhich per capita GDP exceeded $5000 in 1962.8 Thecountries include Australia, Canada, Japan, NewZealand, the United States, and fifteen Europeancountries. The relationship plotted shows fairlyclearly that within this group of relativelyhigh-income countries, there has been convergence ofper capita income, with initially poorer countries onaverage outgrowing initially more affluent countries.

The neoclassical model, as presented above,predicts an ultimate cessation of growth in livingstandards under circumstances in which technologicalprogress is minimal, driven by diminishing returns toinvestment. The historical experience of the SovietUnion and Eastern Europe in the postwar era isgenerally viewed as exemplifying such a situation.

8 Technical note: The data for this graph come fromWorld Bank, STARS (Socioeconomic Time-Series Accessand Retrieval System), on CD-ROM, op. cit. The plottedline was fit to the points on the graph according to thefollowing regression (t-statistics in parentheses):(Growth of per capita = 4.812 - .0002877* (Per capita income 1962-93) (5.44) (2.65) income in 1962) R2 = .29

Page 29: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

2-4

1

2

3

4

5

4000 6000 8000 10000 12000 14000 16000 18000

Figure 2-1GDP growth per head 1962-93: High income countries

Ann

ual p

er c

apita

GD

P g

row

th

1962 per capita income (1987 $)

Source: USITC staff calculations, see text.

These economies experienced very high rates ofaccumulation of physical capital undergovernment-directed policies of forced savings,deliberately allocating low quantities of labor andother resources to consumer goods in order topromote equipment manufacture, construction, andother heavy industries.9 While these policies led torapid rates of economic growth in the 1950s, theabsence of economic incentives for innovators andminimization of economic contacts with the Westerneconomies led to a virtual halt in technical progressfor civilian applications, with an ultimate stagnationof economic growth by the 1970s and 1980s.

9 Considerable attention has been given to “goldenrules” for choosing the savings rate, which wouldmaximize the value of consumption (Phelps (1966)).Because of diminishing returns, it is in principle possiblefor an economy to “oversave,” forever putting off today’sconsumption in order to accumulate for some distantfuture consumption, and in the process achieving a lowerrate of consumption in each year than households wouldotherwise prefer. The rate of forced savings andinvestment in the postwar Communist economies plainlyfar exceeded the “golden rule” rate. When householdsmake the savings decisions, inefficient savings in excessof the “golden rule” cannot take place because of thetypical desire of households to enjoy consumption soonerrather than later (Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1995), p. 74).

The Relationship Between Tradeand Growth in the NeoclassicalModel

In the basic neoclassical model, tradeliberalization affects the economy by increasing theoverall level of technological efficiency. Thisefficiency gain is of the “comparative-static” typedescribed in chapter 1. The national price structuremoves closer to the international price structure, andthe marketplace reallocates workers and capital tothose sectors whose product yields the highestincomes at international prices. In this respect, tradeliberalization operates in a manner similar to aone-time improvement in technology, or a removal ofgovernment-induced domestic distortions to theeconomy, or any other event which increases the levelof production obtainable from a given supply of laborand capital. Since economies with higher levels oftechnological efficiency enjoy higher per capitaincome, trade liberalization leads to a long-run higherlevel of per capita income. This implies a period ofhigher growth of per capita income, at first rapid andthen slower, after which the economy settles down tothe new, higher level of per capita income implied bythe trade liberalization. (If technological progress is

Page 30: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

2-5

taking place for other reasons, the liberalizationinduces a period of growth of per capita income inexcess of the rate of technological progress, afterwhich the growth rate gradually declines to the rate oftechnological progress.)

This property of the neoclassical model is oftendescribed as a level effect of trade liberalization.Liberalization increases the long-run level of percapita income but not its long-run rate of growth.Any increase in the rate of growth of per capitaincome takes place only in the transition to the new,higher level, and lasts only until sufficient savings andinvestment has taken place to achieve that higherlevel. The search for alternatives to the neoclassicalgrowth model has been motivated in part by a desireto demonstrate that trade liberalization could inducegrowth effects as well, i.e., permanent long-runincreases in the rate of growth of per capita income.

Increases in the national savings rate, orreductions in the rate of population growth, alsoincrease the long-run level of per capita income in theneoclassical growth model. As is the case withimprovements in technological efficiency, thesechanges have no long-run impact on the rate ofgrowth of per capita income, but induce increases inthe growth rate during the dynamic transition to thenew, higher level of per capita income. Typically,those newer economic theories which predictpermanent growth effects for trade liberalization alsopredict permanent growth effects for increases in thenational savings rate or reductions in the rate ofpopulation growth.

Alternatives to the NeoclassicalModel

Criticisms of the NeoclassicalModel

There have been a variety of criticisms of theneoclassical model. An example of such criticism,implied by the above discussion, is that in the realworld one might expect that “good” governmentpolicies, such as trade liberalization, policies topromote domestic savings, and the removal ofdistortions in the domestic marketplace, ought topermanently increase the rate of economic growth,while in the neoclassical model such policies onlytemporarily increase the growth rate. East Asianeconomies such as Korea, Taiwan, Hong Kong, andSingapore have maintained for some decades growthrates of per capita income in excess of those generallythought to be feasible in the 1950s, when theneoclassical model was developed. This dramatic

experience has been referred to as the “East AsianMiracle,” and the countries involved as the “EastAsian Tigers” or “Four Tigers.” Attempts to identifypolicy choices which may have induced such highgrowth rates in those countries have also brought theneoclassical model itself under scrutiny.

Also, the neoclassical prediction of convergencein per capita incomes, which characterizes theexperience of the developed countries fairly well,turns out not to hold either for the developingcountries or for the world as a whole. On average,incomes in the world’s poor countries do not growrapidly enough to catch up to those in the richcountries. While some countries, like the “East AsianTigers,” have experienced high growth rates and rapidconvergence, others have maintained a fairly steadygap in living standards relative to the OECD level,while still others have diverged, or fallen behind, insome cases experiencing persistent declines in percapita income.

Figure 2-2 graphs the rate of per capita GDPgrowth relative to 1962 per capita GDP over theperiod 1962-93 for a broader group of 100 countriesfor which relevant data are available.10 While figure2-1 showed that among the more affluent economiesthere was a tendency for lower-income countries togrow faster than higher-income countries, figure 2-2shows that for the world as a whole there is noparticular tendency for poorer countries to “catch up”to richer ones. Indeed, the evidence indicates thatover time, the poorer countries have on average fallenfurther behind the richer ones in terms of livingstandards (Pritchett (1997)).

The neoclassical model presents a partialexplanation for this state of affairs. Countries differin overall technological efficiency, in savings rates,and in the growth rate of the labor force, and thelong-run level of per capita income depends on allthese factors. Thus, different countries should beexpected to converge to different levels of per capitaincome. In the language of the model, differentcountries have different “long-run steady states,”depending on technological efficiency, savings rates,population growth, and so forth. Thus, the fact thatsome rich countries grow faster than some poorcountries should not automatically lead to rejection ofthe neoclassical model. However, even afteraccounting for these differences in countries, some

10 Technical note: The data for this graph come fromWorld Bank, STARS (Socioeconomic Time-Series Accessand Retrieval System), on CD-ROM, op. cit. The plottedline was fit to the points on the graph according to thefollowing regression (t-statistics in parentheses):(Growth of per capita = 1.833 +.00006723* (Per capita income 1962-93) (8.08) (1.21) income in 1962) R2 = .01

Page 31: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

2-6

��

��

� ���� ����� ����� �����

Figure 2-2GDP growth per head 1962-93: 100 countries

Ann

ual p

er c

apita

GD

P g

row

th

1962 per capita income (1987 $)

Source: USITC staff calculations, see text.

analysts argue that current disparities in growth ratesare much larger than can plausibly be explained bythe neoclassical model (Romer, P. (1986, 1994);Lucas (1988)).

A wide variety of alternatives to the neoclassicalgrowth model have been proposed, which are oftengrouped together under the term “endogenous growththeory.”11 In many of these alternative models,positive shifts in the rate of national savings, or in thestatic level of technological efficiency, can cause thegrowth rate of the economy to be permanently higher.If these models are correct, even a trade liberalizationwhich induces only static gains in economic efficiencymay in fact lead to a permanent increase in the rate ofeconomic growth, since all static efficiency effectslead to dynamic growth effects in these models.

11 This use of the term “endogenous” is somewhatmisleading with respect to its normal use in economictheory. It is meant to suggest that while in neoclassicaltheory, the long-run growth rate of per capita income isset exogenously equal to the assumed rate of technologicalprogress, in endogenous growth models the growth rate isgenerally solved for “within the model,” or endogenously,as a function of the exogenously given parameters. But

Some of the new models of economic growthexpand the list of basic sources of growth beyondlabor, capital, and technological efficiency to includesuch factors as human capital, knowledge capital (or“R&D capital”), increasing the variety of availablegoods, or improved quality of goods. A good deal ofeffort has been invested in modeling the incentives foraccumulating technological knowledge (throughprofit-oriented expenditures on research anddevelopment (R&D) or through “learning-by-doing”)or for accumulating human capital (through theopportunity cost of foregone wages during schoolingor through an “education industry”). In thesemodels, there is no clear theoretical prediction thattrade liberalization either increases or decreases therate of economic growth. The proposed mechanismslinking trade liberalization to knowledge generation orhuman capital accumulation are complex and varyfrom model to model. This ultimately leaves the issueof the impact of trade liberalization on economicgrowth as a matter for empirical testing.

11—Continuedin the neoclassical model, the growth rate duringtransitional dynamics is in fact an endogenous function ofunderlying parameters, and actual economies spend mostor all of the time in a transitional state.

Page 32: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

2-7

Growth Effects ThroughSuspension of Diminishing Returns

As discussed above, in the neoclassical model theultimate cessation of economic growth withouttechnological change is driven by diminishing returnsto capital. The particular rate of diminishing returnsis dictated by the mathematical relationship betweennational output or GDP, on the one hand, and inputsof labor and capital, on the other. The standardchoice for this relationship, the Cobb-Douglasproduction function with constant returns to scale,12

specifies a particular rate of diminishing returns aswell as a particular rate at which capital can besubstituted for labor in the production of goods. Therelative simplicity of the Cobb-Douglas form is ofgreat convenience for both theoretical and empiricalwork, and frequently provides usable approximationsto empirical data.

In practice it is possible that it is easier tosubstitute between capital and labor than is implied bythe Cobb-Douglas production function. Suchsubstitution tends to alleviate diminishing returns tocapital, and leads with sufficient capital accumulationto constant returns to capital. If this is the case, thenit can be shown that growth in per capita income canbe maintained indefinitely, even without technologicalprogress, as long as the savings rate is high enough.Further increases in the savings rate lead to permanentincreases in the growth rate of per capita income, asdo improvements in the level of technical efficiency.This, in turn, implies that trade liberalization maypermanently increase the growth of per capita incomeeven if the only channel through which suchliberalization operates is an increase in the staticefficiency of the economy.13

12 Technical note.- The Cobb-Douglas productionfunction with constant returns to scale is written as

Q = ALβK1-β , in which Q represents national output, Lrepresents labor input, K represents the capital stock, Arepresents the level of technology, and β and 1-βrepresent the shares of national income paid to labor andcapital respectively. In this formulation the marginalproductivity of capital can be shown to be equal to

A(K/L) 1-β , which decreases as capital per workerincreases since β < 1, and the elasticity of substitutionbetween capital and labor can be shown to equal 1.

13 Pitchford (1960) was apparently the first todemonstrate this point using aconstant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) productionfunction, of which the Cobb-Douglas function is a specialcase. Long and Wong (1996) show that as thecapital-labor ratio increases over time, the growth modelbased on the CES production function reduces in the limitto the pedagogically popular model based on the functionQ = AK (output depends on the level of capital only).For further elaboration of this class of models see Jensenand Larsen (1987) and Jensen (1994). Jones andManuelli (1990) and Rebelo (1991) show that in

In practice, it is an empirical question whethercapital and labor are sufficiently substitutable in realeconomies as to permit static efficiency gains totranslate into dynamic growth effects. There has beenas yet relatively little work on this question, althoughit is attracting increasing attention. The measurementof substitutability between capital and labor isintimately bound up with the measurement of the rateof technological change, raising some complex issuesof quantification (Rodrik (1997)).

One empirical difficulty with the models ofendogenous growth described above is that they donot retain the prediction of convergence in rates ofeconomic growth arising from the neoclassical model.As discussed above, data for the group of relativelyaffluent countries display this convergence property.Later in this chapter, it will be shown that growthrates in developing countries display a weakerproperty of conditional convergence; that is,lower-income countries grow more rapidly thanhigher-income ones after accounting for othervariables. Recall that in the neoclassical framework,poor countries grow faster than rich ones because theyhave a higher rate of return on capital and thusaccumulate capital more rapidly. The difference inthe rates of return on capital between poor and richcountries comes from diminishing returns.Endogenous growth models, on the other hand, tendto include assumptions which suspend diminishingreturns to capital. These assumptions lead to theresult that one-time improvements in efficiency (suchas trade liberalizations) can permanently increase therate of economic growth. But, they simultaneouslytake away the prediction that sufficiently similareconomies will converge in per capita income. Sincethere is empricial support for conditional convergence,a credible theory of growth ought to account for thisphenomenon.

One simple strategy for modeling endogenousgrowth while retaining the prediction of convergencein per capita income is to adopt more elaborateproduction functions.14 Many models of endogenousgrowth contain detailed mathematical descriptions of

13—Continuedtwo-sector models with both a consumption and aninvestment good, endogenous growth can be maintainedeven if consumption goods are produced underdiminishing returns to capital, so long as there areconstant returns to capital in the investment-goods sector.

14 In Jones and Manuelli (1990), this is achieved bysimple additive combination of the production functionsused in the neoclassical and AK-type endogenous growth

models, so that Q = AK + BLβK1-β. With capitalaccumulation, this model approaches the Q = AK modelin the limit with long-run constant returns to capital, andthus can exhibit endogenous growth under the appropriateconditions. But in the transition to the long run, there arediminishing returns to capital, so that the model predictsconvergence of per capita incomes.

Page 33: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

2-8

the process by which profit-seeking firms engage inR&D, causing technological progress. In order tomake this mathematical detail feasible, the theoristoften relies on cruder specifications of theunderlying production process. In practice, this hasmade it difficult to build theoretical models ofendogenous growth with both realistic descriptions ofthe process of technological change and convergencein per capita income.

Recently, this difficulty has been overcome byemphasizing the fact that innovation in thetechnologically “leading” economies is relativelyexpensive, while technological imitation in the“following” economies is relatively cheap (Barro andSala-i-Martin (1997)). The relative ease of imitationimplies that followers grow faster than leaders. Also,economic growth rates can be permanently altered byany policy changes which influence the incentive toinvent or imitate, most notably policies affectingintellectual property. Policies discouraging theunlicensed imitation of intellectual property, forexample, make it easier for technological leaders tocapture the returns from R&D expenditures whilemaking it more expensive for technological followersto engage in imitation.

Learning-By-DoingIncreasing experience in production enhances the

productivity of workers, and is also a way ofaccumulating technological knowledge (Arrow(1962)). Thus, the efficiency of production mayincrease over time with the accumulation ofproduction experience. In a seminal formulation ofmodern endogenous growth theory (Romer, P. (1986)),learning-by-doing is assumed to take place inproportion with capital accumulation. Each firm’scapital accumulation contributes to a social pool ofknowledge on which all other firms in the sameeconomy can draw. These knowledge spillovereffects between firms overcome the diminishingreturns to capital. Any change leading to increasesin the average product of capital (including efficiencygains from trade liberalization) can thus increase thegrowth rate of per capita income.

The learning-by-doing model displays severalimportant properties of later and more elaborateendogenous growth models. One property is that theoptimal rate of economic growth is higher than therate obtained under decentralized markets, sinceprivate firms do not value the gains to society arisingfrom spillovers of their own learning-by-doing toother firms. Theoretically, policy instruments such asan investment tax credit or a production subsidyfinanced by non-distortionary taxation could inducefirms to increase their learning-by-doing to thesocially optimal rate. It is unclear what practical

relevance this result has for economic policymaking.There are at present no empirical tools sufficient tomeasure the deviation of private learning-by-doingfrom the socially optimal rate. Furthermore, mostreal-world tax credits and subsidies single out specificsectors or activities, and are financed by non-neutraltaxation, thus introducing distortions andinefficiencies into private decisionmaking that offsetor outweigh any social gains from learning-by-doingspillovers.

One seemingly counterintuitive property of thismodel (and of some other endogenous growth models)is that the rate of economic growth depends on theoverall size of the labor force, since a larger laborforce increases the productivity of capital. Thisimplies that large countries should grow more rapidlythan small countries (since more learning takes placewith more people) and that as population growthaccelerates, the rate of per capita income growthshould accelerate also. Barro and Sala-i-Martin(1995) provide weak evidence for more rapideconomic growth in more populous countries.Kremer (1993) argues that, in the very long run, theacceleration of population growth from Neolithictimes to approximately 1970 has been associated withproductivity growth in the manner predicted byendogenous growth theory.

Human Capital AccumulationIn one class of models, production requires human

capital as well as physical capital. (e.g., Uzawa(1965), Lucas (1988)). Workers with more humancapital (“skilled workers”) are more productive thanworkers with less, and the level of human capital canbe increased through education. Education is a costlyactivity, requiring either time withdrawn from marketlabor or allocations of capital and labor to an“education industry.” The accumulation of humancapital becomes easier the more human capital thatworkers already have, since skilled workers learnmore readily. Furthermore, increases in human capitalcontribute to a pool of “general knowledge” that is ofbenefit to all workers. These effects tend tocounteract the diminishing returns to capital, so that inthe long run the rate of economic growth isdetermined by human capital accumulation.

The rate at which individuals decide toaccumulate human capital is governed by its rate ofreturn relative to physical capital. If human capital isapplied to more efficient production processes, or ifthe demand for goods produced using human capitalincreases, the rate of return of human capital willincrease. Thus, trade liberalization may increase thereturn to human capital, by increasing the efficiencyof production in general or by making possible thesale of goods in a wider market. The human capitalchannel is thus one potential way in which trade

Page 34: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

2-9

liberalization can increase the rate of economicgrowth.

The growth effects of human capital on tradeliberalization may vary depending on whether aparticular country specializes in skilled-labor-intensivegoods or unskilled-labor-intensive goods under freetrade. For countries relatively well-endowed withskilled labor (i.e. the United States and otherdeveloped countries), trade liberalization induces ashift toward the production of skilled-labor-intensivegoods, providing incentives for more rapid increasesin human capital, and greater economic growth. Forcountries relatively well-endowed with unskilled labor(i.e. some developing countries), trade liberalizationleads to increased importation of skilled-labor-intensive goods and increased domestic production ofunskilled-labor-intensive goods, reducing the incentiveto accumulate human capital, and thus the rate ofeconomic growth (Stokey (1991), Young (1991)).

The possibility that trade liberalization may causea disincentive for human capital accumulation in thepoorer countries does not automatically imply that itis detrimental to such countries, since theconventional static efficiency gains to tradeliberalization may outweigh the reduced incentive toaccumulate human capitol. Moreover, developingcountries may benefit directly from human capitalaccumulation in developed countries if there areinternational spillovers in knowledge. There is as yetno definitive empirical evidence on the relativeimportance of these various effects.

Product Differentiation and QualityImprovement

In the simple concept of technological changeunderlying the neoclassical growth model,technological improvement is modeled as an increasein unit output per unit of an index of inputs.Alternate ways of conceptualizing technical changeinclude expansion in the variety of products andimprovement in the quality of products. Models ofeconomic growth have been developed incorporatingboth variety expansion (Grossman and Helpman(1991), ch.3; and Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1995),ch.6), and quality improvement (Grossman andHelpman (1991), ch.4; and Barro and Sala-i-Martin(1995), ch.7). Variety expansion and qualityimprovement may be of direct benefit to consumers,or they may enhance the efficiency of production tothe extent that the variety and/or quality ofintermediate goods matters for productivity.

In these newer models of growth and technology,directed R&D activity by firms leads to technologicaladvance. The rate of technological change, and inturn economic growth, are “endogenous” in the sense

that alterations in the structure of the economy mayalter the incentives to do research. The models allowfor a rich specification of the process of technologicalchange, taking into account the productivity ofresearch laboratories, the intensity of consumers’desire for new and improved products, the rate ofreturn on R&D relative to physical capital, and theextent of intranational or international technologicalspillovers.

As it turns out, there are deep structuralsimilarities between models of economic growthbased on variety expansion and those based on qualityimprovement. In both cases, the public spillovers or“externalities” generated by technologicalimprovements serve to stave off diminishing returns inphysical capital, providing for long-run sustainabilityof economic growth. Some properties of the varietyexpansion or quality improvement models are similarto properties of the learning-by-doing and humancapital models. These include the possibility thatenhancing the level of efficiency (through tradeliberalization or other beneficial policy reform)enhances the long-run growth rate; the prediction thatlarger economies grow faster; and the result that therate of technological change in decentralized privatemarkets may fall short of the social optimum.15

International Transmission ofTechnology and IntellectualProperty Rights

International trade may enhance the internationaltransmission of technology in several ways. First,commercial contacts between countries can serve as asource of information about new products andproduction processes. Second, international trade intechnological information itself can take place throughlicensing contracts and joint ventures; such trade isfacilitated by strong recognition of foreign intellectualproperty rights (IPRs). Third, an importantcomponent of technology is embodied in new capitalequipment, which is internationally traded. Fourth,international trade in capital through FDI carries withit a component of technology transfer. Barro andSala-i-Martin (1995, ch. 8) point out thattechnological diffusion and imitation provide a

15 In decentralized private markets, it may be the casethat additional R&D activity would generate socialbenefits in excess of the cost of R&D. Simultaneosly,additional private benefits to the firms engaging in R&Dmay fall short of the cost of R&D because of thepossibility of imitation. Thus, the activity does not takeplace, and the rate of technological change is slower thanit otherwise would have been. It is in this sense thatdecentralized private markets can lead, in theory, to ratesof technological change falling short of the socialoptimum.

Page 35: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

2-10

powerful reason to expect international convergenceof productivity and per capita income, independentlyof the arguments arising from the neoclassicalmodel.

A number of models of international trade andtechnology transfer are developed in Grossman andHelpman (1991, chs 9-12). In these modelstechnological innovation takes place in developedcountries (the “North”) while developing countries(the “South”) acquire new technology largely throughimitation. Both innovation and imitation require R&Dexpenditures, though some variants of the modelconsider technology transfer as a pure byproduct ofincreasing trade flows. Goods are produced underimperfect competition, giving innovators temporarymonopoly rents which last until the products areimitated. Strong IPRs in the North, and recognitionof Northern IPRs in the South, can increase themonopoly rents to innovators and lengthen the timeof the “product cycle” (Vernon (1966)) by which newinnovations are transferred from North to South. Models of this type are said to exhibit “creativedestruction,” as new inventions are induced by theprospect of market power, which is eroded byimitation and competition, and are called“Schumpeterian,” after the Austrian economist JosephSchumpeter (1883-1950). Further examples ofSchumpeterian models of trade and growth includeSegerstrom, Anant, and Dinopoulos (1990),Segerstrom (1991) and Aghion and Howitt (1992).

In general, these models yield ambiguouspredictions about the welfare effects of tradeliberalization, strengthening of intellectual propertyprotection, R&D subsidies, or indeed any other policyunder consideration. At the heart of this ambiguity isthe tradeoff between competition in pricing (whichincreases social welfare by cheapening old goods, butreduces the incentive to invent new ones) andtemporary monopoly in new innovations (whichpromotes invention by insuring the rewards ofinvention to the monopolist, but also prevents usefuldissemination of the innovation). This leadsimmediately to the question of optimal patent life(Nordhaus (1969)), which should be long enough toprovide some incentive to innovators but not so longas to indefinitely prolong the distortions of monopolypricing.16 An analogous principle applies to thegeographical extension of IPRs (Chin and Grossman(1990), Deardorff (1992)). Extending the geographicscope of patents or trademarks through recognition offoreign IPRs by an increased number of foreigncountries increases the profitability of the patent toinnovators, which may increase the incentives

16 A real-world example is the case ofpharmaceuticals, for which stronger IPR protection mayspeed the pace of innovation but also reduce the supply ofcheap generic drugs.

for innovation. Simultaneously, it expands thegeographic scope of the patent monopoly, with theassociated costs of monopoly pricing orunderproduction of the good in some markets. Thus,in models of the geographical extension of IPRs,spread of mandatory IPRs from the North to theSouth is seen as likely to reduce Southern welfare(because of the deceleration of the rate ofimitation)17 and may in theory reduce Northernwelfare as well (if the return from higher rates ofNorthern innovation is insufficient to fullycompensate Northern consumers fully for lostopportunities to buy cheap imitation imports).

Trade liberalization in markets experiencinginnovation subject to imperfect competition also facesthis tradeoff between the gains from innovation andthe gains from competition. Liberalization expandsthe geographical range over which new innovationscan be marketed, thus increasing the incentive forinnovation — an effect which was well known toAdam Smith. Simultaneously, however, internationaltrade exposes oligopolists to intensified competitionand declining profit rates. This, in turn, reduces theincentive to innovate, and may reduce the pool offinancing for innovation if firms’ retained earnings area preferred source of funding for R&D. Dependingon whether the positive effect of market expansion oninnovation outweighs the negative countereffect ofincreased competition, the net consequences of tradeliberalization on technological progress may bepositive are negative, and so are theoreticallyambiguous.

Furthermore, trade liberalization causes expansionof some sectors and contraction of others inaccordance with comparative advantage. A countryspecializing in high-technology goods would expect tosee production of those goods expand underliberalization, which could enhance the rate ofinnovation through, for example, stronger learning-by-doing effects. A country whose underlyingcomparative advantage was in low-technology goodswould experience contraction of the high-technologysector under trade liberalization, and possibly a lowerrate of innovation. However, a country whoseproduction shifts to less technologically dynamicgoods is not necessarily harmed on balance by tradeliberalization, as the static efficiency gains fromimproved resource allocation may offset any negativeeffects on innovation.

17 Direct foreign investment from North to South mayalso be encouraged by stronger IPRs. In this case, thegrowth benefits from induced investment might offset thecosts of slower imitation, giving rise to net gains for theSouth in strengthening IPRs.

Page 36: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

2-11

Do Differences Between GrowthTheories Matter For Policy?

If the principal interest of policymakers is inachieving sustained increases in economic growth,does it matter particularly whether the story told bythe neoclassical growth model or the one told by theendogenous growth model is more nearly “true”?Within realistic time frames of policymaking,probably not.

Both models provide complementary insights as tothe potential linkages between trade liberalization andgrowth, with the neoclassical model emphasizingincreases in economic efficiency arising fromliberalization while endogenous growth models admitthe possibility that trade liberalization might increasethe rate of technical innovation. These insights are ofgreat usefulness to policymakers, and the varioustrade-growth linkages which different models positlikely operate simultaneously in the real world.Moreover, on many important issues, there is no deepclash between the two modeling traditions; whilesome causes of economic growth (e.g., R&Dspending) are explicitly modeled in the endogenousgrowth framework, these causes are not denied by theneoclassical model but simply assumed to beoperating in the background. Neoclassical andendogenous growth models are in broad agreementthat the accumulation of physical and human capital,and technological progress, are the principal causes ofeconomic growth.

The principal difference between the twoframeworks is that trade liberalization increases thegrowth rate in the neoclassical model onlytemporarily, during a transitional period, while inendogenous growth models the growth effect may bepermanent. This may seem to be a dramaticdifference, but in practice the distinction is probablynot that significant. The period of transitional growthenvisioned by the neoclassical model can last ageneration or more; by the time transitional effectsfrom a single liberalization have damped out, somenew shift in economic efficiency (induced possibly byanother round of liberalization, or through someextraneous cause) will have emerged. This makes itdifficult to distinguish in practice between the effectsof a large shift in efficiency in the neoclassical modeland a small shift in the permanent economic growthrate in the endogenous growth model. At present,then, empirical evidence is unlikely to provide adefinitive resolution to the debate among schools ofgrowth theory.18 A belief that trade liberalizationcontributes importantly, marginally, or not at all tofaster growth does not commit the analyst to any

18 See the section, “Does the Evidence DistinguishBetween Theories of Growth?” later in this chapter.

particular preference regarding competing theories ofeconomic growth.

The following simulation exercise illustrates thepoint that a given path of economic growth in the realworld can usually be “explained” by either aneoclassical or an endogeonous growth model, andthus the difficulty of distinguishing between the twousing empirical data. While the particular numericalvalues in the example are contrived for illustrativepurposes, the point made by the illustration holdsmore generally. Recall that in the neoclassical model,trade liberalization operates by increasing theefficiency of the economy on a one-shot basis. Theneoclassical economy grows more rapidly during theprocess of convergence to the new level of efficiency,after which the growth rate gradually decelerates tothe growth rate of long-run technological change. Inendogenous growth models, trade liberalization canoperate by permanently increasing the rate ofeconomic growth. But this means that a large,one-shot efficiency increase in a “neoclassical world,”absorbed bit by bit during the convergence process,looks a lot like a small increase in the permanent rateof economic growth in the “endogenous growth”world. In the long run, of course, the growth rateincrease is always better, but the difference may notmake much practical impact until the distant future.

Table 2-1 presents a simulation comparing theprogress of per capita income over 80 years in ahypothetical middle-income country under both aneoclassical growth and an endogenous growthscenario.

In each scenario, per capita income is assumed tohave been increasing at a rate of 2 percent per yearprior to year 0. In the endogenous growth scenario,the rate of income growth has accelerated by 10percent, to 2.2 percent per year, beginning in year 1.In the “neoclassical growth” scenario, the countryexperiences a one-shot productivity improvement inyear 1 which will amount to 12 percent of per capitaincome in the long run.19 The economy continues tohave a long-run growth rate of 2 percent a year, butconverges to its new level of productivity at 2.5percent per year, a rate of convergence consistent withthe empirical literature reviewed in chapter 3.

The growth experienced by the economy in thetwo scenarios looks practically identical. Areal-world pattern of economic growth resemblingclosely either the first or second column would

19 Technical note.—The formula for per capitaincome, Yt , in years 1 and afterward in the endogenousgrowth scenario is

Yt = (1.022)*Yt-1

while in the neoclassical growth scenario, it is

Yt = (1.02)*Yt-1 +(.025)(1-.025)t*(.12*Yt-1)

Page 37: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

2-12

Table 2-1Simulation of Neoclassical vs. Endogenous Growth

Scenario I: Scenario II:Year Neoclassical Growth Endogenous Growth

Per Capita Income Per Capita Income

0 $10,000 $10,000. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5 11,192 11,149. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10 12,506 12,431. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15 13,955 13,860. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20 15,552 15,453. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25 17,312 17,229. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30 19,252 19,210. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35 21,392 21,418. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 40 23,752 23,880. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 80 53,854 57,026. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Source: USITC staff calculations.

probably not tend to resemble one more than theother on average. While some difference is apparentafter 80 years, it is highly unlikely that the growthperformance of a real economy would be determinedby one shift to productivity 80 years earlier, with noother shifts in the intervening period; thus, thecontrolled experiment illustrated in the situation doesnot arise. The simulation illustrates a more generalprinciple: any given real-world acceleration ofeconomic growth, whether caused by tradeliberalization or by some other mechanism, canprobably be reconciled with either a neoclassical oran endogenous model of economic growth. Thus,the use made by policymakers of the insights fromneoclassical and/or endogenous growth modelsshould rest principally on the persuasiveness andrealism of the insights derived from each modelingtradition rather than from a belief that real-worlddata verify one modeling tradition and falsify theother.

Cross-CountryEvidence on Growth and

Convergence

Evidence for ConditionalConvergence

A substantial body of literature has emergedattempting to provide statistical explanations for thefact that the economies of some countries grow fasterthan those of others. A principal finding of thisliterature is the phenomenon of conditionalconvergence - i.e., poor countries grow faster thanrich ones after accounting for other variables that mayinfluence the long-run level of per capita GDP (Barro

(1991); Mankiw, D. Romer and Weil (1992); Barroand Sala-i-Martin(1995)). The strategy used is toselect a sample of countries and test the hypothesisthat countries which are poorer at the beginning of theperiod grow more rapidly than countries which startout richer, after accounting statistically for otherimportant determinants of economic growth. Thehypothesis of conditional convergence is generallyconfirmed in tests which control for the share ofinvestment in GDP (positively associated withgrowth), a measure of human capital such as thesecondary school enrollment rate (also positivelyassociated with growth), and the population growthrate (in theory, negatively associated with growth, butoften not statistically significant). Many othervariables have been tried as well. Based on theavailable results, economists infer that per capitaincome converges to its long run steady state at about2 to 3 percent per year. Thus, for two countries withthe same long-run prospects, but with one countryinitially experiencing a lower per capita income, thelower-income country should “catch up” halfway tothe higher-income country in about 23 to 35 years,and three-quarters of the way in about 45 to 70 years.

Among the more notable contributions on thistopic, Fagerberg (1994) surveys a wide range ofeconometric studies on the determinants of economicgrowth, while Levine and Renelt (1992) examine over50 candidate variables as determinants of the growthrate of GDP, and Sala-i-Martin (1997), in an extensionof Levine and Renelt’s work, uses over 60 potentialvariables.

In Levine and Renelt’s work, variables are“robust” determinants of growth if they lead tostatistically significant growth effects in a consistentdirection (positive or negative) regardless of whatother variables are added to the analysis, and “fragile”if the addition or deletion of additional variables

Page 38: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

2-13

brings the growth effect into question statistically.20

Among the statistically robust determinants ofgrowth, there is widespread agreement that a highershare of investment (i.e., gross fixed capitalformation) in GDP implies a higher growth rate ofGDP, as does a higher rate of education.21 Thepopulation growth rate is frequently used as acontrol variable in the cross-country analysis ofgrowth, since economic theory predicts thatpopulation growth is negatively correlated withaccumulation of capital per worker; however, thiseffect is statistically insignificant in 7 of the 16studies reviewed by Fagerberg and found to bestatistically fragile by Levine and Renelt.

A number of researchers have found that eitherthe size of government or its behavior influences therate of economic growth. Fagerberg cites six studiesfor which a higher share of government consumptionin GDP is associated with lower growth. Levine andRenelt find that this effect becomes statisticallyinsignificant in some tests, with a measure ofgovernment consumption minus defense andeducational expenditures giving better results. Anumber of studies have used subjective indices of thedegree to which government promotes a set ofinstitutions conducive to physical and human capitalaccumulation and providing rewards to innovativeeffort. These institutions include the rule of law ingeneral (as opposed to bureaucratic whim), security ofprivate property, business contract law, a functionalmechanism for domestic payments (i.e., a workablebanking system), intellectual property rights, and aminimization of government corruption. Barro (1996)reports a positive impact of a “rule-of-law” oneconomic growth; Asian Development Bank (1997)and World Bank (1997) find that growth isencouraged by an index of “institutional quality”; andHolmes, Johnson and Kirkpatrick, eds., (1997)construct an index of “economic freedom,” which iscorrelated with per capita income. While constructedusing somewhat different methodologies, the variousindices of “rule-of-law,” “institutional quality,” and“economic freedom” appear to be measuring similarattributes of government performance and behavior,which are robustly associated with economic growth.

20 In Sala-i-Martin (1997), a somewhat broadercriterion of statistical robustness is used, and a larger listof variables is found to potentially influence economicgrowth.

21 The results of De Long and Summers (1991) andJones (1994) indicate that this effect is due almost entirelyto investment in machinery and equipment, accounting forabout one-third of gross investment. Blomströ m, Lipseyand Zejan (1996) argue that causation runs from GDPgrowth to investment (or equipment investment), ratherthan from investment (or equipment investment) to GDPgrowth.

Measures of innovation, such as patentapplications in foreign countries or employment ofscientists and engineers in R&D, are positivelycorrelated with growth in four of five studiesexamined by Fagerberg, but are not examined byLevine and Renelt. Measures of inflation, moneygrowth, and political instability have been found to benegatively correlated with growth in some studies, butare statistically fragile; Levine and Renelt have somesuccess in showing that the volatility of domesticcredit growth is negatively correlated with per capitaGDP growth.

Does the Evidence DistinguishBetween Theories of Growth?

There have been relatively few attempts to testneoclassical growth theory against any particularalternative version of endogenous growth theory, andthe available results have so far been mixed. In partthis is due to the fact that economies are substantiallymore complex than the models devised to explainthem; as Solow (1994) remarks, “. . . the experiencesof very different national economies are not to beexplained as if they represented different ‘points’ onsome well-defined surface.” The cross-section testsof the convergence hypothesis described above are notwell suited to the analysis of the shifting determinantsof growth in any particular country. Pack (1994)makes a forceful case for examining endogenousgrowth theories using time-series data on individualcountries.

Current studies attempting to test neoclassicalgrowth theory directly against endogenous growththeory generally seek to test the prediction ofendogenous growth theory that changes in the level ofsome variable that influences economic growth inducepermanent, long-run changes in the rate of economicgrowth. Jones (1995) points out that the rate of GDPgrowth in the United States from 1880 to 1929 was1.81 percent, from 1929 to 1987 was 1.75 percent,and from 1950 to 1987 was 1.91 percent. Suchcalculations, which cover sufficiently long periods thatthe Great Depression and World War II may beviewed as short-run anomalies, reveal no significantshifts in the long-run growth rate. If any of theunderlying determinants of growth have shifted, thiswould appear to refute endogenous growth theoriesunless the movements of those underlyingdeterminants happen to be offsetting. Jones arguesthat the rapid increase in scientists and engineersengaged in R&D in developed countries in 1950should have induced a large increase in the postwargrowth rate if endogenous growth theories were true.His estimates indicate that increases in the rate ofinvestment produce growth effects lasting for five to

Page 39: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

2-14

eight years only, consistent with the neoclassicalmodel. Results for other OECD countries are broadlysimilar.

Yi and Kocherlakota (1996) examine the growthrate of per capita GDP in the United States from 1881to 1991 and in the United Kingdom from 1831 to1991. Their estimates indicate that increases in thelevel of public capital investment positively influencethe growth rate of per capita GDP, while increases inthe level of taxation have a negative influence onGDP growth. Interpreting these findings as evidencein favor of the endogenous growth model, they pointout that since public expenditures require taxation, thepositive and negative effects on growth tend to beroughly offsetting in the long run, consistent with thesteady trend in growth rates noted by Jones.

Results on the effect of R&D or other measures oftechnological activity on growth rates are of particularinterest for several reasons. If national technologicaleffort affects the rate of economic growth positively,such a finding lends weight to those growth modelsemphasizing directed technological activity. Also, afinding that national R&D affects national growthwould imply that technological spillovers acrossborders are relatively limited, and that each countrycan capture some of the fruits of national R&D withinnational borders. If spillovers were very large, as theywould be if technologies could be imitated costlessly,all countries would have the same rate oftechnological progress, and there would be noparticular national-level incentives for engaging inR&D. Findings that national R&D spending ispositively correlated with economic growth thus implyas well that a country which effectively preserves itsintellectual property against foreign imitation wouldthereby enhance its own growth rate.

Lichtenberg (1992) is typical of many studiesfinding a very high social rate of return to R&D. InLichtenberg’s study, the dollar-for-dollar effects ofR&D on the rate of productivity growth are estimatedto be seven or eight times larger than the productivityeffects of the rate of fixed investment. Fagerberg(1987, 1988) finds that growth in patent applicationsin foreign countries is positively correlated with GDPgrowth, and Romer, P. (1989) finds that large orgrowing numbers of scientists and engineersemployed in R&D boost growth in countries withhigh investment rates.

One difficulty with the basic Solow/Swanneoclassical model is that while it does predictconvergence among countries’ standard of living, theparticular rate of convergence predicted is higher thanthe rate obtained by empirical estimates. Accordingto the neoclassical model, the rate of convergence can

be calculated from the rate of diminishing returns tocapital, which is greater when the share of capital innational income is small. Estimated rates ofconvergence of around 2 to 3 percent per year implyin a neoclassical framework that capital should bepaid around 75 percent of the national income. Theactual share of capital, about one-third of the nationalincome in most developed countries, implies a muchfaster rate of income convergence of about 5.6 percent(Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1995), p. 38).

This seeming paradox has been resolved in severalstudies which estimate an extended version of theneoclassical model, in which human capital and/orR&D capital are included along with labor andphysical capital in the list of productive inputs(Mankiw, D. Romer, and Weil (1992), Mankiw(1995), Nonneman and Van Houdt (1996)). Using alarge sample including both developed and developingcountries, the average share of national incomeattributable to “broad capital” (including physicalcapital, R&D capital, and that part of wagescorresponding to human capital as opposed to rawlabor) appears to be sufficiently high to account forthe relatively slow rates of per capita incomeconvergence actually observed.

Mankiw, D. Romer, and Weil (1992) estimate thatabout one-third of national income should beattributed to human capital, while Mankiw (1995)argues less formally that about two-thirds of laborincome, or about half of national income, couldrepresent a return to human capital.22 Nonneman andVan Houdt (1996) find that when the stock of R&Dcapital is accounted for, the share of human capitaldrops to about 15 percent. Their estimates imply anOECD-wide average social rate of return of about 20percent on R&D capital, about 7.4 percent on humancapital, and about 4.5 percent on physical capital.Regardless of the relative shares of the various typesof capital in output, proponents of extended versionsof the neoclassical model maintain that they accountfor the principal features of economic growth withoutneed for recourse to some of the more problematicfeatures of endogenous growth models, such as thesuspension of diminishing returns.

22 One line of argument in Mankiw (1995) is that theminimum wage in the United States is about one-third ofthe average wage, leaving two-thirds for human capital.Another is that labor economists estimate that anadditional year of schooling increases real wages by atleast 8 percent, and the average American has 13 years ofschooling. Compounding the 8 percent return implies thatwages are 270 percent of the level they would be in theabsence of schooling. Again, this gives an effect ofschooling (human capital) amounting to about two-thirdsof the average wage.

Page 40: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

2-15

Interpretations of the “EastAsian Miracle”

The recent debate about the sources of rapideconomic growth in East Asia has some interestingimplications for the choice among theories of growth.In a widely cited study, Young (1995) found that mostof the economic growth in Hong Kong, Singapore,South Korea, and Taiwan could be attributed toaccumulation of productive inputs, including risinglabor force participation rates, improving education,and (except for Hong Kong) rising rates ofinvestment. After controlling for these factors, theremaining contribution of total factor productivity(TFP) growth23 is relatively modest, implying ratesof technological progress no greater than those in theOECD and Latin America. Krugman (1994), basinghis argument on Young’s estimates, speculated thatbecause of diminishing returns to capital, the EastAsian economies could experience rapid decelerationin economic growth in the absence of greater attentionto technological performance, drawing analogies tothe collapse of growth in the Soviet Union even asrapid accumulation of capital equipment proceeded.Krugman’s reading of Young’s results, more so thanthe results themselves, was widely criticized by someAsian observers (e.g., Tay (1966)).

23 Total factor productivity (TFP) growth is defined asthat part of the growth rate in output in excess of growthattributed to increases in input, and is a widely usedmeasure of the rate of technological change.

Recently, Rodrik (1997) has pointed out thatYoung’s estimates may be reconciled with high ratesof TFP growth for East Asia if substitution betweenlabor and capital is relatively difficult. Whilepotentially rehabilitating the role of technologicalimprovements for East Asian growth (a useful findingfor endogenous growth models focusing on R&D), theimplied lower rates of substitutability between capitaland labor undermine endogenous growth models thatdepend on high rates of substitutability.

Ventura (1997) offers an alternative interpretationof the “East Asian Miracle.” Beginning from theobservation that the extremely high growth rates inper capita income in East Asia, fueled by high rates ofinvestment, appear to be inconsistent with the notionof diminishing returns to capital, Ventura argues thatsuch diminishing returns operate at the global level,but can be suspended at the national level forcountries engaging aggressively in international trade.If capital can be easily substituted for labor, and theeconomy is open to trade, then capital per worker canbe increased and diminishing returns to capital can beavoided by exporting the additional product of newcapital overseas. The high rate of substitutabilitybetween labor and capital required to bring this aboutis consistent with some arguments for endogenousgrowth, as presented above. However, to the extentthat diminishing returns to capital still exist at theglobal level, Ventura’s analysis implies that it isprobably infeasible for most countries tosimultaneously emulate the East Asian example.

Page 41: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted
Page 42: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

3-1

CHAPTER 3Evidence on the Linkages Among Trade,

Openness, and GrowthThis chapter reviews a variety of attempts in the

literature to examine empirically the proposition thateconomies that are more open to trade experiencemore rapid economic growth. It considers thestrengths and weaknesses of various measures of“openness” which have been used in the empiricalliterature. Much of the chapter is devoted toreviewing empirical evidence linking trade to otherfactors that have been shown in chapter 2 to influenceeconomic growth. These factors include investment,which is considered both in general and in the contextof separate components of investment (the portionfinanced through domestic savings and the portionfinanced through foreign direct investment (FDI));productivity growth and technological change; andhuman capital accumulation. These factors operate onthe supply side of the economy, by increasing theoutput of goods. The final section of the chapterreviews literature pertaining to a demand-sidephenomenon — namely, the tendency of global tradeto grow faster than global income in the postwarperiod — and discusses the potential implications ofthis tendency for the dynamic effects of tradeliberalization and for appropriate simulation of thoseeffects by the types of methods discussed in chapter 4.

Aggregate Evidence

The Literature on “Export-LedGrowth”1

The 1970s saw several pioneering attempts atsystematic multicountry investigation of trade policyand economic performance in the developingcountries. Studies by Little, Scitovsky, and Scott(1970) (for the OECD), and by Balassa (1971),calculated effective rates of protection for severaldeveloping countries.2 These studies concluded

1 For a more detailed discussion, see Edwards (1993).2 The effective rate of protection (ERP) for a specific

industry is defined as the percentage increase in valueadded induced by a country’s tariff structure. ERPs arerelatively high when high tariffs are imposed on an

that post-World War II protectionist policies hadartificially encouraged industrialization, suppressedagriculture, and reduced exports by movingcountries’ production away from cost-basedcomparative advantages. While these studies did notdirectly calculate impacts on the rate of economicgrowth, they did argue that developing-countryprotectionism had suppressed savings and inducedlarge-scale unemployment of labor andunderutilization of capacity, all factors which wouldbe expected to have direct consequences foreconomic growth. The promotion of relativelyhigh-wage manufacturing at the expense ofagriculture, in which most of the poorest individualswere employed, was also believed to have worsenedincome distribution.

In a subsequent multivolume study for theNational Bureau of Economic Research, Bhagwati(1978) and Krueger (1978) examined trade regimes ofa number of developing economies3 using the conceptof an effective exchange rate. The effective exchangerate was an attempt to summarize in a single measurethe net effect of policies such as import tariffs andsurcharges, export subsidies and incentives, importlicensing, and exchange rate policies. National policyregimes were classed as “import substituting,”“neutral,” or “export promoting” depending onwhether the effective exchange rate for hard currencypaid by importers was less than, equal to, or greaterthan the corresponding rate paid by exporters.

The costs of an import substituting policy, asmeasured by effective exchange rates in theBhagwati/Krueger study, were found to be similar to

2—Continuedindustry’s output and low tariffs are imposed on anindustry’s productive inputs, and relatively low in thereverse situation. For extreme cases in which tariffprotection makes inputs sufficiently expensive relative tooutput, the effective rate of protection can be negative.Little, Scitovsky and Scott examined Argentina, Brazil,Mexico, India, Pakistan, the Philippines, and Taiwan.Balassa analyzed Chile, Brazil, Mexico, Malaysia,Pakistan, the Philippines, and Norway.

3 These were Turkey, Ghana, Israel, Egypt, thePhilippines, India, Korea, Chile, and Colombia. Additionalwork on Brazil and Pakistan was not published in separatecountry volumes.

Page 43: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

3-2

the costs of high and sectorally uneven, effectiverates of protection in the Little-Scitovsky-Scott/Balassa methodology. These studies revealed a greatdegree of institutional detail about developing-country trade and exchange regimes. They wereunquestionably influential in formulating theintellectual case that countries undergoing structuraladjustment subsequent to the debt crisis of the early1980s ought to undertake trade and exchangeliberalization, and in spurring further research on thelinkages between trade regimes and economicperformance.

The statistical relationship between exports andgrowth has been examined numerous times. Earlyresearch (e.g., Emery (1967), Kravis (1970), Krueger(1978), and Balassa (1978, 1982)) providedindications that various measures of liberalizationwere associated with export expansion, and thatexport expansion was associated with economicgrowth. More recent work on the export-led growthhypothesis (e.g., Jung and Marshall (1985);Bahmani-Oskooee, Hamid, and Ghiath (1991);Esfahani (1991); and Serletis (1992)) employs modernstatistical techniques, focusing on Granger-Simscausality testing.4 These studies find that for many,but not all, developing countries, increases in exportsare associated with increases in economic growth aftera few quarters, or one or two years. Often, the samestudies find causation in the reverse direction, fromeconomic growth to exports.

One interpretation of the above-discussedstatistical methods for identifying “export-led growth”in single-country time-series data is that theyprimarily pick up the short-term benefits of exports ineasing foreign exchange shortages and enablingpurchase of imported inputs into production, such asspare parts and petroleum (Esfahani (1991)).Longer-term, and possibly more important, benefits oftrade liberalization for growth are not well capturedby these techniques. For example, trade liberalizationis widely recognized to be a key component in therecent economic success of Chile, yet causality testsdo not find evidence of “export-led growth” (AminGutiérrez de Piñeres and Ferrantino (1997)).

4 In Granger-Sims causality testing, variable X is saidto “cause” variable Y if, in a regression of current valuesof Y on past values of X, there is a statistically significantrelationship. The regression may include other variables aswell. Bivariate Granger-Sims causality is said to occurwhen X “Granger-Sims causes” Y and Y “Granger-Simscauses” X simultaneously. A statistical finding ofGranger-Sims causality does not necessarily imply that X“causes” Y in a material or mechanical sense. SeeGranger (1989), chapter 5, for more details.

Openness in the StatisticalAnalysis of Cross-CountryGrowth

Another recent approach to empirical testing is toadd measures of trade, or trade liberalization, to thestatistical analysis of cross-country growth describedin chapter 2. This effort has led to mixed results, withsome studies finding strong positive effects of trade,or trade liberalization, on growth while others findlittle or no effect. An important difficulty is that thereare a variety of available empirical measures of acountry’s trade stance, which often disagreesubstantially on whether a particular country is “open”or “closed.” For example, many researchers usesimple ratios, such as the ratios of exports to GDP,imports to GDP, or exports plus imports to GDP. Butit is well known that such trade ratios tend to be largefor small countries and small for large countriesregardless of trade policy, and thus do not provideparticularly reliable indicators of the stance of policy.5

Pritchett (1996) examines six presumably moresophisticated measures of openness: average tariffs,the percentage of imports covered by non-tariffbarriers (NTBs),6 an index of structure-adjusted tradeintensity,7 Edward Leamer’s measures of opennessand trade distortion,8 and Dollar’s measure of pricedistortion.9 For the 15 possible pairwise comparisons

5 For example, in 1994 total trade in goods andnonfactor services amounted to 21 percent of GDP for theUnited States, 16 percent for Japan, and 44 percent forGermany and France. By contrast, the same figureamounted to 101 percent for Mozambique, 106 percent forBulgaria, 118 percent for Mongolia, and 128 percent forAzerbaijan (derived from World Bank (1996)). The traderatio employed in many empirical studies thus classifiesthe first set of economies as “closed” and the second setas “open”.

6 Both tariffs and NTB coverage ratios were derivedfrom UNCTAD (1988).

7 This is the ratio of exports plus imports to GDP,controlling for population, land area, per capita GDP, theCIF/FOB ratio, and whether countries are oil exporters orindustrial market economies.

8 Leamer (1988) constructs an econometric model oftrade based on the Heckscher-Ohlin factor abundancetheory. The Leamer openness measure represents thedeviation of total trade volume from its theoreticallypredicted value, while the trade-distortion index representsthe deviation of the sectoral pattern of trade from itstheoretically predicted pattern.

9 Dollar (1992) analyzes price data from theInternational Comparisons Project (Summers and Heston(1988)), which compare price levels in different countriesin a common currency, adjusting for purchasing-powerparity. After controlling for per capita GDP (sinceabsolute prices tend to be higher in rich countries than inpoor countries) and other variables, Dollar interprets arelatively low national price level as evidence of outwardorientation and a relatively high price level as evidence ofinward orientation.

Page 44: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

3-3

among these variables, Pritchett finds only two casesin which there is a statistically significant correlationat the 5 percent level among openness measures inthe expected direction. In five cases, the correlationis actually perverse, with countries scored as openby one measure being, on average, scored as closedby another. These results suggest both that opennessis difficult to quantify, and that statisticalinvestigations of the effect of openness on eitherexport growth or GDP growth are unlikely to bedirectly comparable with each other.

There is some evidence that the average tariffmay be a more useful indicator of a country’s overalltrade policy stance than is often supposed.Interestingly, Pritchett finds that average tariffs aresignificantly negatively correlated with Leamer’sopenness index, and significantly positively correlatedwith the NTB coverage ratio. This suggests thathigh-tariff countries are likely to have high NTBs aswell, and that low-tariff countries indeed import morethan do high-income countries once appropriatecountry characteristics are controlled for. Lee and

Swagel (1997) also report that average tariffs arepositively associated with the NTB coverage ratio,across countries and industries, after accounting forother factors which may influence the politicaldemand for protection.10

Table 3-1 gives an example of the types ofconflicting results that can be obtained by

10 Another advantage of average tariffs is that theyare relatively easy to measure compared with NTBs.While analysts differ over whether to average tariffs on atrade-weighted basis (in order to reflect more importantcommodities) or on a simple-average basis (because ifhigh tariffs reduce imports, they receive small weightsunder trade weighting), in practice trade-weighted andsimple averages are often similar, and are derived fromthe same raw data. The NTB coverage ratio as reportedby UNCTAD has several conceptual problems. Forexample, it does not include restrictions applied withinnational borders which may affect trade, and it does notreflect the relative severity of distortions (i.e. NTBs with ahigh or low “tariff equivalent” are treated identically inthe coverage ratio). See Laird and Yeats (1990) and Leeand Swagel (1997) for more details.

Table 3-1Measures of Openness, ranked for 27 Countries

(A ranking of 1 indicates ‘most open’ by the measure indicated.)

Share of Import duties Leamer’s Dollar’s trade in as percent of trade intensity exchange rate

GDP imports ratio distortionCountry (1994) (1994) (1988) (1976-85)

Thailand 1 15 4 4. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Philippines 2 21 (1) 211. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Kenya 3 16 (1) 26. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Canada 4 5 15 8. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Korea 5 11 (1) 21. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Morocco 6 (1) 10 24. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Egypt 7 20 9 27. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . United Kingdom 8 3 5 218. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Indonesia 9 92 8 215. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Italy 10 (1) 1 211. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . South Africa 11 8 (1) 3. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Germany 12 12 2 19. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Spain 13 4 6 9. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . France 14 12 11 215. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Turkey 15 92 3 218. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Australia 16 12 18 25. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Ethiopia 17 19 12 215. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Pakistan 18 22 9 5. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Colombia 19 14 19 6. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Mexico 20 13 (1) 2. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Bangladesh 21 (1) 14 1. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . India 22 23 (1) 13. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Peru 23 18 21 7. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . United States 24 6 13 10. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Japan 25 7 7 23. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Argentina 26 17 20 22. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Brazil 27 (1) 17 14. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

1 Not available.2 Tied with another country for this measure, for which the same rank is shown.

Sources: Trade as percent of GDP and Import Duties as percent of Imports from World Development Indicators 1997(CD-ROM); Edward E. Leamer, “Measures of Openness,” in Robert Baldwin, ed., (1988) Trade Policy Issues andEmpirical Analysis (University of Chicago Press); David Dollar, “Outward-oriented Developing Economies Really DoGrow More Rapidly; Evidence from 95 LDCs, 1976-85,” Economic Development and Cultural Change, 1992; ITC stafftabulation.

Page 45: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

3-4

comparing various widely used and cited measuresof openness to international trade. While some ofthese measures were compiled for different years, itis likely that a comparison using identical yearswould display similar discrepancies, owing to thedifferences in the underlying concepts of opennessemployed. There remains a core methodologicaldifficulty in agreeing either on an appropriateempirical counterpart for the intuitive concept of“openness to trade” invoked by policymakers andanalysts, or on an effective empirical methodologyfor implementing any given quantitative measure, asdefined in the abstract, using actual data. Forexample, the Philippines has a high share of trade innational income and appears open according to thatcriterion; it also has comparatively high tariffs andhas had (according to one measure) a fairly distortedexchange rate making tradable goods unusuallyexpensive in the local market. Kenya has a hightrade share in national income and relatively littlemeasured exchange rate distortion, but high tariffs.The United States is one of the lowest-tariffeconomies in the world (and by that measure one ofthe most open), but appears to be one of the mostclosed when trade as a share of GDP is considered.Correcting the trade share by Leamer’s econometricprocedure makes the United States appear to be onlyaverage rather than closed. It is apparent that almostany country can be scored as unusually “open,”“closed,” or “average” depending on the measurechosen.

Sachs and Warner (1995) obtain quite a strongpositive effect of openness on economic growth.Their approach is to construct a dummy variable11

classifying a large number of economies year by yearas “open” or “closed” using such indicators as tariffsand quotas on intermediate and capital goods, theblack market foreign exchange premium, the existenceof export marketing boards, and the classification ofsome countries as “socialist.” In a variant of thestandard regression used to study cross-countrygrowth, Sachs and Warner estimate that annual percapita GDP growth in open economies exceeded thatin closed economies by 2.2 percent to 2.5 percent.Sala-i-Martin (1997) finds that the number of years inwhich an economy has been open according to Sachsand Warner is strongly associated with economicgrowth.

While the Sachs and Warner result is useful, theirmeasure of openness essentially captures a country’sfirst major step away from an extremelyinward-oriented regime. For example, South Korea isconsidered to be have been “open” since 1968,

11 A dummy variable is an on-off indicator whichtakes the value 1 when some condition (in this case,openness) is true and 0 when it is false.

Brazil is “open” since in 1991, and India since 1994.The Sachs-Warner data thus cannot be used to inferthe effects of substantial, but less dramatic,liberalization moves that are the more typical subjectof trade negotiations.

Harrison (1996) reviews over 20 previous studiesattempting to relate trade shares, measures of pricedistortion, and other measures of trade liberalizationto GDP growth or micro-level productivity. Harrisonconcludes that although methods and research designsdiffer, the bulk of the evidence leans toward a positiveeffect of liberalization on growth and productivity,and that causality tests of export-led growth are notparticularly revealing. In her own statistical analyses,Harrison finds that the black market foreign exchangepremium (International Currency Analysis, variousyears), an index based on country sources on tariffsand NTBs (Thomas, Halevi, and Stanton (1991)), andan index of movements toward international prices(Bhalla and Lau (1991)) are good predictors of GDPgrowth, while other indicators (including Dollar’sindex of exchange rate distortion) do not perform aswell. Using a different set of openness measures,Harrison notes that some measures are uncorrelatedwith others, although the problem is not quite assevere as with the set of openness measures examinedby Pritchett.

In an innovative contribution, Frankel and D.Romer (1996) point out another problem plaguingempirical work that attempts to link trade and growth.Countries adopting liberal trade policies are likely toadopt other policy reforms simultaneously, such asfree-market domestic policies and stable fiscal andmonetary policies. This mixture of policyliberalizations is likely to influence trade and growthat the same time, thus confounding statistical attemptsto demonstrate that countries which trade more alsogrow faster. Frankel and Romer get around thisproblem by exploiting the gravity model of trade,which relates bilateral trade flows statistically to thesize of countries’ economies and the distance betweenthem. They argue that the part of trade explained bydistance is unlikely to be correlated with countries’policy decisions, since physical distances betweencountries are immutable with respect to policy. Usingthe distance-correlated portion of trade as a proxy fortotal trade,12 they find strong evidence that countrieswhich trade more enjoy higher per capita incomes.Frankel and Romer do not directly examine GDPgrowth.

12 In statistical parlance, an instrumental variable.

Page 46: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

3-5

Trade and FactorAccumulation

There are increasing indications that the primaryeffect of trade liberalization on growth operatesthrough factor accumulation. More liberal economiesenjoy higher rates of capital investment, which in turnlead to economic growth. If the effects ofliberalization on growth operate through this indirectchannel, it would explain much of the difficulty thatmany studies have in finding a direct impact of tradeon growth when controlling for the investment shareof GDP, human capital, and population or labor forcegrowth. Attempts to add measures of trade or tradeliberalization to the standard growth/convergenceempirical setup thus implicitly assume that the way inwhich liberalization affects growth is through the rateof technological change. The possibility thatliberalization does influence technology andproductivity will be taken up later in this chapter. Inthis section, some evidence linking trade to factoraccumulation is reviewed.

Levine and Renelt (1992), as reported above, findall of their candidate measures of trade and opennessto be statistically fragile in terms of explaining therate of GDP growth. However, three of theirmeasures (the share of exports in GDP, Leamer’sopenness index, and Leamer’s distortion index) turnout to be statistically robust in explaining investment,which in turn is positively correlated with economicgrowth. According to one of their estimates, anincrease in exports amounting to 1 percent of GDPleads to an increase of 0.14 percent in the investmentshare of GDP.

Harrison (1996) finds that the simple share oftrade in GDP is positively and significantly related tothe share of investment in GDP in a variety of tests.Other measures of openness considered by Harrisonare either weakly correlated or uncorrelated with theinvestment share. Sachs and Warner (1995) find thattheir “open” economies have shares of investment inGDP which are 5.4 percent higher after controlling forper capita income (richer countries have higherinvestment shares), but find no such relationshipbetween openness and increases in either the primaryschool enrollment rate or the secondary schoolenrollment rate, suggesting weak links betweenopenness and human capital. Frankel and Romer(1996), by contrast, find that trade shares and theirpreferred statistical proxy for trade shares arepositively correlated with the investment rate, andmarginally positively correlated with both highersecondary school enrollment rates and lowerpopulation growth rates.

Wacziarg (1996) represents an ambitious attemptto account for direct and indirect effects of trade

liberalization. Wacziarg’s trade policy indexincorporates information on tariff revenues as apercentage of imports, NTB coverage ratios, andSachs and Warner’s openness indicator. This index isimbedded in a framework in which economic growthdepends directly on the share of manufacturedexports, on human capital, the investment ratio, theratio of foreign direct investment to GDP, thegovernment share of GDP, and other variables. Tradepolicy, in turn, operates directly and indirectly on thevarious determinants of growth. Wacziarg attributesslightly over half of the growth-inducing effects oftrade liberalization to increases in the rate of grossdomestic investment, about 15 percent to boostingmanufactured exports, and the rest to improvedmacroeconomic policy discipline, smaller government,boosting foreign direct investment, and lowering theblack-market premium on foreign exchange.13

Alwyn Young (1995) notes that over the periodfrom 1966-199014 both labor force participation ratesand years of schooling rose rapidly in Hong Kong,Singapore, South Korea, and Taiwan. As notedabove, Young attributes much of the rapid economicgrowth in these countries to these increases in rawlabor input (partially due to increasing femaleparticipation rates) and human capital. It is an openquestion whether the outward orientation of theseeconomies played a role in boosting the rewards toeither labor force participation or schooling.

Dynamic Effects of TradeLiberalization on AggregateSavings

The review of literature discussed above andearlier in chapter 2 indicates that trade liberalizationmay not influence economic growth directly, butindirectly through determinants of growth, one ofwhich is investment. Investment has been shown tobe the engine of economic growth, both in theory byBarro and Sala-i-Martin (1992), and in empirical workby Mason (1988), Levine and Renelt (1992), andWacziarg (1996). Investment, by definition, mustinvolve saving, that is, use of current production (andimports) for something other than currentconsumption (and exports). Among the 57developing countries analyzed in chapter 6, grossdomestic savings averaged 67.4 percent of domesticinvestment between 1970 and 1995. The

13 Unlike the other studies reviewed here, which treatthe black-market premium as a measure of openness,Wacziarg considers it to be a proxy for the general levelof government-induced distortions in the economy, andthus to have a direct effect on the rate of economicgrowth.

14 For Hong Kong, 1960-1991.

Page 47: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

3-6

corresponding figure for the 17 developed countriesanalyzed in chapter 6 was 99.7 percent.

The linkage between savings rates and investmentrates may appear to be relatively straighforward. Forexample, it may be readily assumed that savings thatoriginate in a given country are also invested in thatcountry. However, this may not necessarily be so,because this linkage will depend on howinternationally mobile capital is. If capital is perfectlymobile between countries, there is no necessaryrelation between domestic savings and domesticinvestment since savings in each country would beexpected to respond to worldwide opportunities forinvestment. Thus, if the relationship betweendomestic savings and investment is severed, increasesin the former will not be translated into a higherdomestic capital stock and therefore will not result inaccelerated domestic growth. If, however,international mobility of capital is limited, then higherdomestic savings will generate higher domesticinvestment and growth.

The extent to which domestic savings andinvestment are related is an empirical question.Feldstein and Horioka (1980) tested for a relationshipbetween domestic savings and domestic investment inOECD countries and found a positive and significantrelationship between these variables—a higher rate ofsavings led to higher rate of investment. More recentstudies by Frankel (1985), Mason (1988), Feldsteinand Bacchetta (1991), Montiel (1994), and Gordonand Bovenberg (1996) have also presented resultsindicating that domestic savings are correlated withinvestment. The most plausible explanation forobserved capital immobility, according to Gordon andBovenberg, is asymmetric information acrosscountries. That is, foreign investors may be at adisadvantage compared with domestic investors owingto their poorer knowledge of domestic markets. Thus,foreign investors are vulnerable to being overchargedwhen they acquire shares in a firm or purchase inputsand services, leading in general to less efficientinvestment of resources.

The relatively close association between domesticsavings and investment for all the countries is evidentin figure 3-1. This relationship holds when thedeveloped and developing countries are examinedtogether as well as when the data are examinedseparately for these countries.15 The simplecorrelation between savings and investment when all

15 There are 74 countries in the sample that includesthe developed as well as developing countries; 17developed and 55 developing. The econometric analysisthat examines the relationship between trade liberalizationand savings rate in part II utilizes data for thesedeveloped and developing countries.

countries are considered together is 0.72; it is 0.75and 0.69, respectively, for developed and developingcountries. Also, as shown in figure 3 (b), developedcountries appear to be exporters of capital as theshare of domestic savings in GDP is greater than theshare of investment in GDP. In contrast, thedeveloping countries are importers of capital as theirshare of domestic savings in GDP is lower than theshare of investment in GDP.

Since the rate of domestic savings is a keydeterminant of the rate of domestic investment, oneneeds to examine how trade liberalization influencesdomestic savings in the context of other determinantsof domestic savings. This section reviews thetheoretical and empirical literature that discusses thedeterminants of savings behavior in an economy aswell as whether openness influences this determinantof investment. Chapter 6 of this report provides aneconometric investigation of the relationship of tradeliberalization and aggregate savings given the effect ofthe other determinants of savings. It should benoted that there is limited theoretical and empiricalliterature focusing on the relationship of tradeliberalization and savings behavior. There is asubstantial amount of research, however, on thedeterminants of savings, a particular focus being onthe examination of savings behavior in the developingcountries compared with developed countries.

TheoryModern theories of consumption and its relation to

income, and concomitantly the relation betweensavings and income, are based on models ofintertemporal optimization by households. (SeeGersovitz (1988). The permanent income hypothesisoriginally expounded by Friedman (1957) andsubsequent life-cycle hypotheses (LCH) as stated byModigliani (1965) are the foundations of this line oftheory. The empirical literature on the determinantsof savings has tended to be based on the LCHapproach.

Life-cycle theories of savings predict that the agecomposition of a country’s population shouldinfluence a country’s observed savings behavior.According to the LCH, the higher the proportion of acountry’s population that is not in the active laborforce, the lower its savings rate should be, and viceversa. Individuals will dissave when they are youngand have very low income, save during theirproductive years, and once again dissave when theyretire. However, if individuals have positive bequestmotives, they will tend to save some wealth for theirheirs. Therefore, according to this hypothesis,aggregate savings are influenced by the demographicsof the population.

Page 48: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

3-7

0

10

20

30

40

50

0 10 20 30 40 50

10

20

30

40

0 10 20 30 40 50

10

20

30

40

50

0 10 20 30 40 50

Figure 3-1Investment vs. savings

Inve

stm

ent/G

DP

Trade/GDP

Figure 3-1b: Developed countries

Inve

stm

ent/G

DP

Savings/GDP

Figure 3-1c: Developing countries

Inve

stm

ent/G

DP

Savings/GDP

45 deg

45 deg

45 deg

Figure 3-1a: All countries

Page 49: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

3-8

The groundwork for analyzing the dependence ofaggregate savings on population growth was laid inthe late 1960s by Tobin (1967), and Leff (1969). Leff(1969) tested this hypothesis by examining the role ofdemographic factors in determining the aggregatesavings rate using international cross-section data.Leff”s major conclusion was “that dependency ratiosare a statistically distinct and quantitatively importantinfluence on aggregate savings ratios, both for the 74countries considered as a whole and within thesubsets of developed and underdevelopedcountries.”16 Typically, life-cycle theory underlies theframework for analyzing savings behavior for both thedeveloping and developed economies.

Fry and Mason (1982), Mason (1988), Collins(1991), and Kang (1994) propose and test hypothesesrelated to the life-cycle theory emphasizing level andtiming effects—which are not mutuallyexclusive—associated with savings behavior. Forexample, the level of savings is found to decline whenthe dependency ratio increases since more childrenmay induce a rise in current consumption, as well asreduced bequests. However, the latter result inbequests may not occur, since an increase in thenumber of family members may induce intertemporalsubstitution, i.e., current consumption increases areoffset by reduced consumption in the future. Also,the dampening impact of high fertility (level effects)will vary with the rate of growth of income. Thiseffect of the real growth on savings (timing effects) isa function of the mean age at which households earnan income compared with the mean age at which theyconsume. Therefore, in two economies with identicalpositive growth rates, it is expected that savings willbe lower where the mean age of consumption is lower(i.e., households where there are more children thanworking adults) than the mean age of earnings. Theseanalyses done by Fry and Mason (1982), Collins(1991), and Kang (1994) are referred to asvariable-rate growth models. The econometricinvestigation conducted in chapter 6 in this study isbased on these types of models.

Not all studies reviewed below focus on theselevel and timing effects. Other studies haveaugmented the life-cycle framework by examining theimpact of economic factors (macroeconomic policies,personal income, inflation rate, interest rate, liquidityconstraints, exchange rates, and fiscal policy), andpolitical variables (coup attempts and rate of politicalassassinations) on the savings rate in an economy.The empirical results regarding the impact of thesevariables together with life-cycle variables arereviewed below.

16 Leff (1969), pp. 893-94.

Empirical Evidence

Research on estimating savings behavior tends toanalyze national savings primarily for developingcountries.17 Studies done by Gyimah-Brempong andTraynor (1996), Higgins and Williamson (1996),Doshi (1994), Kang (1994), Collins (1991), Fry(1986), Gupta (1987), Lee (1971), Gioviannini (1983,1985), Laumans (1982), Ram (1982), and Fry andMason (1982) use cross-section, time series data toanalyze national saving rates. These studies vary inthe way they apply the life-cycle theory as theexplanatory variables that are included in the modelspecification differ as do the time period and countrycoverage of the data.

Since life-cycle theories apply directly tohouseholds, it would be more appropriate to useprivate savings rates to examine savings behavior.However, comparable data are not available onhousehold savings across countries; data on nationalsavings rates are more readily available for a largernumber of countries and for a greater number ofyears. In addition, private savings are expected toform a large and typically a predominant part of totalsavings.18 Some studies—for example, by Ogaki,Ostry, and Reinhart (1996), Edwards (1995),Schmidt-Hebbel, Webb, and Corsetti (1991) andSnyder (1971)—were able to obtain comparablehousehold data to analyze savings behavior for thecountries in their respective samples. Lahiri (1988)used time series data for 8 Asian countries over 20years, and Rossi (1988) used cross-section time seriesdata for 49 countries over 10 years to implicitlyanalyze the impact on savings behavior. These studiesexamine the impact of life-cycle variables and otherfactors such as inflation on private consumption ratherthan private or national savings.

17 For general surveys, see Mikesell, Raymond F., andJames E. Zinser, 1973, “Nature of the Savings Function inDeveloping Countries: A Survey of the Theoretical andEmpirical Literature,” Journal of Economic Literature 11(1): 1-26; Gersovitz, Mark, 1988, “Saving andDevelopment,” in Hollis Chenery and Srinivasan, eds.,Handbook of Development Economics, vol. 1 New York:North-Holland; Deaton Angus, 1989, “Saving inDeveloping Countries: Theory and Review.” Proceedingsof the World Bank Annual Conference on DevelopmentEconomics, 1989. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.

18 It may be preferable to model savings behavior byits components—private, government, and business—asdifferent models may be needed to explain the savingsbehavior of different entities. However, it is not clearwhether one should isolate private savings to examine theimpact of demographic variables in a life-cycle modelsince corporate and government savings are substitutes forhousehold savings. Mason (1988) suggests that thesesavings should be considered jointly in assessing life-cycletheories as applied in the examination of savings behaviorof an economy.

Page 50: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

3-9

The main savings (or consumption) determinantsconsidered by the literature are life-cycle variablesincluding the age dependency ratio, per capita GDP,and rate of growth of GDP; the real rate of interestcapturing the characteristics of the financial sector;the rate of inflation reflects macroeconomic stability;foreign savings reflect capital inflows or currentaccount deficit; and variables capturing thecharacteristics of the political system. The empiricalfindings with respect to the impact of each of thesevariables on savings behavior are presented below.

The Dependency RatioThe life-cycle models of savings imply that age

distribution of the population influences the rate ofsavings in an economy. That is, households that havemore children are expected to save less, and retiredpeople are expected to work less and, therefore,partially live off their savings. These two factors, inturn, are expected to reduce the rate of savings in aneconomy. The dependency ratio most commonly usedin the literature includes people under the age of 15 orover 65 as a share of the population. Savings ratesare expected to depend negatively on the dependencyratio because if there are a large number of inactivepeople compared with those in their productive years,aggregate savings are expected to be relatively low.

Leff (1969) found a strong negative effect of thedependency ratio on savings. The robustness of theseresults was challenged by subsequent studies done byRam (1982) and Gupta (1987) as they did not find asignificant negative relationship between saving ratesand the dependency ratio. Doshi’s (1994) findingswere consistent with Leff’s results for the total sampleand high-income countries but did not showsignificant negative effects of the dependency ratio onthe savings ratio for low-income countries. Also,Schmidt-Hebbel, Webb, and Corsetti (1992) gotvarying results depending on the specification andestimation techniques they used.19 Other research inthis area, however, does get significant negativeresults between these variables (Fry (1982), Lahiri(1988), Collins (1991), Edwards (1995), Higgins andWilliamson (1994), and Kang ( 1994)). The mixedresults found in this area of research tend to besensitive to the sample selection and estimationtechniques used, as well as to how savings behavioris specified.

19 Ordinary least squares (OLS) and fixed effectsamong other techniques were used. The OLS resultsrelated to the dependency ratio were significant andnegative while results with respect to this variableobtained from other techniques were insignificant.Fixed-effects models attempt to control for the existenceof time and/or individual specific characteristicsdetermining the independent variable which areunobservable to the investigator and are either fixed orconstant. In other words, for each identified group in the

Per Capita Income and Growth ofPer Capita Income

All the research reviewed in this study includesper capita income as an explanatory variable in thespecification investigating savings behavior. Percapita income is expected to be positively related tothe savings rate as rich people tend to save morebecause they are in the position to plan for futureconsumption while poor people have less of a cushionand tend to consume a much larger portion of theircurrent income. That is, it is expected that moreadvanced countries will tend to save a higherpercentage of GDP than will developing countries.

The studies do get a positive relationship betweensavings rate and per capita income. The rate ofgrowth of per capita income is also included as anexplanatory variable besides per capita income insome studies to test for timing effects. This variableis hypothesized to be positively related to savings.The studies which include this variable (Fry andMason (1988), Collins (1991), Bosworth (1993),Carroll and Weil (1993), and Kang (1994)) do get thisresult. This finding reflects a “virtuous circle”, wherereal growth in income leads to higher savings whichin turn lead to higher growth. Also, referring to thelevel and timing effects emphasized by Fry andMason (1982) and Mason (1988), higher growth willraise the lifetime income of younger households thatare expected to save (level effects) for their retirementversus the older households, which tend to dissave.

Real growth can also work interactively with othervariables that may affect the savings rate such asinterest rate and the dependency ratio, therebyaffecting the timing of savings. Significant resultsare obtained by Fry and Mason (1988), Collins(1991), and Kang (1994) when these interaction termsare included in their analysis. For example, the highincome growth variable interacting with thedependency ratio variable in the study done by Kang(1994) for Korea suggests that “in an economygrowing at a real rate of 9.1%, a reduction in thedependency ratio by 40 percentage points, forexample from .90 to .50 would raise saving ratios by24% of GNP.”20 Collins (1991) found that for middleincome countries the dependency ratio variable is notsignificant if the interaction between this variable andthe growth of income is excluded. Her study foundthat for those countries where the growth rateexceeded 6.8 percent, the net effect of the rise in thedependency rate will lead to reduced savings.

19—Continuedsample (country, industry, household, etc.) there arecharacteristics that are unobserved by the investigator, butare important in explaining the dependent variable.Ignoring the potential presence of these group effects maylead to biased estimates.

20 Kang (1994), pp. 106

Page 51: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

3-10

Real Rate of Interest and Rate ofInflation

Most of the studies reviewed find the effect of theinterest rate on savings to be insignificant. However,in his estimates of a savings function for seven Asiandeveloping countries, Fry (1978, 1980) shows that thereal rate of interest has a significant positive effect onsaving. The sample included Burma (1962-72), India(1962-72), Korea (1962-72), Malaysia (1963-72),Phillippines (1962-72), Singapore (1965-72), andTaiwan (1962-72). Giovannini (1983, 1985) revisitedFry’s study and found that two observations (Korea in1967 and 1968) were responsible for the results.These two observations reflected financial reformsthat took place in Korea in 1965. When the data setwas expanded to include more years for all these 8Asian countries, Giovannini found the real interestelasticity of savings to be insiginifcant in all his tests. Edwards (1995) finds the real rate of interestinsignificant in influencing saving rates for a 36-country data set. This finding is mainly due to theincome effect offsetting the substitution effect. Thatis, the lack of response suggests that the substitutioneffect (the rise in the real interest rate createsincentives to save more and it makes presentconsumption more expensive in relation to futureconsumption, so savings increase) and the incomeeffect (higher interest rates make it possible to earnmore with the same capital, so that consumptionincreases) tend to cancel one another out.

Only a few studies reviewed here include inflation(defined as the rate of change in the CPI) in theanalysis of savings behavior. These studies (Gupta(1987), Lahiri (1988), and Edwards (1995)) get mixedresults depending on the region studied. In Gupta’sstudy, both expected and unexpected inflationvariables have positive and significant results for theAsian sample while neither inflation variable wassignificant for the Latin American countries. In hisall-Asian sample, Lahiri got mixed results for hiseight separate country regressions. Edwards’ analysisof savings behavior for the 36 countries showed thatinflation did not have significant effect.

Foreign SavingsIf access to foreign funds at international interest

rates is unlimited, foreign savings can readily fill thegap between domestic investment and domesticsavings, and foreign savings do not determine thedomestic savings rate of an economy. However, ifaccess to foreign borrowing is limited, then domesticsavers (and investors) are constrained in theirintertemporal choices by the size of available foreignfunds, and foreign savings become a determinant ofdomestic savings. During most of the post-WWII

period, developing countries have not facedunrestricted access to foreign funds because manycountries have maintained controls over foreignborrowing. Hence, foreign savings have beenexogenous with respect to household (investor)savings behavior and can be considered as a substitutefor household savings. Therefore, the impact offoreign savings on domestic savings measures thedegree of substitutability between foreign savings (orcurrent account deficit) and national private savings.

A number of studies include foreign savings as adeterminant of savings rates for an economy. Fry(1978, 1980), Giovannini (1985), and Edwards (1995)found a significant and negative impact of foreignsavings on domestic savings. The estimatedcoefficients indicated less than a one-to-onerelationship between foreign and private savings,suggesting that these two types of savings are notperfect substitutes. Gupta (1987) found a positiverelationship for his sample of Latin Americancountries, but not for Asian countries. These mixedresults seem to depend on the sample and the modelspecification.

Political FactorsThe political factor, which attempts to capture the

degree of structural political instability in a country, isanother variable included by some studies to examinesavings behavior. It is expected that savings behaviorwill be adversely affected by political instability,which increases the uncertainty of the environment inwhich savings and investment take place and henceadversely affects rates of investment and economicgrowth.

Some of the proxies used to reflect politicalinstability for a country are frequency of governmenttransfers, frequency of politically motivatedassassinations, and attacks. All three variables wereused by Edwards (1995) in his assessment of savingsbehavior for a 36-country data set. He found nosignificant effect of political instability on savingsbehavior in his sample of countries.Gyimah-Brempong and Traynor (1996) computed ameasure of political instability which reflected aweighted index of politically unstable events in a year.These events included successful and attempted coupsd’etat, guerrilla warfare, secession movements,political assassinations, revolutions, riots andconstitutional changes. They used cross-sectionaltime series data and simultaneous equation model toinvestigate the effects of political instability on thesavings rate in Sub-Sahara Africa. Their resultsindicate that political instability had a significantnegative effect on the savings rate, decreasing savingsboth directly and indirectly through a reduction in thegrowth of rate of real GDP.

Page 52: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

3-11

Exports and Savings BehaviorThere is minimal research analyzing the impact of

trade liberalization on savings behavior in the contextof examining the influence of openness on the savingsrate in an economy. However, several studies haveinvestigated the relationship between savings andexports.

According to Maizels (1968), variation in exportsmight result in associated variations in domesticsavings because (a) the propensity to save is higher inthe export sector than elsewhere, (b) governmentsavings rely heavily on taxes on foreign trade, and (c)a sustained growth in exports could result in a rise inthe marginal savings propensities in other sectors.Maizels tested the hypothesis using annual data for 11countries (Australia, South Africa, Ireland, Iceland,Rhodesia, Burma, India, Malawi, Zambia, Jamaica,and Trinidad and Tobago) during the 1950-60.Maizels’ hypothesis tested whether export income hasa higher explanatory power than nonexport income(GDP minus exports) in the determination of grossdomestic savings. Maizels’ results confirmed hishypothesis as he got significant results regarding thepositive relationship between savings rate and exports.

Lee (1970) employed Maizels’ approach but useda much larger sample of countries ( 28 countries; 20developing and 8 developed), and his data covered alonger period of time (15 years). Lee’s results areconsistent with Maizels where exports seem to bemore significant than non-export GDP. Lee’s resultsalso indicate that savings response was not limitedonly to developing “primary-exporting” countries butalso to “nonprimary exporting” countries.

Laumas (1982) revisited Maizels’ and Lee’sresearch, using estimation techniques that tested forthe stability of the savings function. Laumas gotresults that confirmed Maizels’ finding that marginalpropensity to save out of exports is greater thannonexport income for primary exporting countries.However, Laumas did not replicate Lee’s results fornonprimary exporting countries. Lahiri (1988), usinga different specification for the savings behavior thanthat employed by both Maizels and Lee, did not get aconsistently significant relationship between savingsand exports for all the countries in his sample.Lahiri’s specification tested for the effect on thesavings behavior of variables that included thedependency ratio, rate of growth of per capita income,inflation, change in terms of trade, and exports as apercent of GDP. His sample included 8 Asiancountries—India, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, thePhillippines, Singapore, Sri Lanka, and Thailand.Lahiri’s results indicate that exports did not have asignificant impact in five countries, although he gotsome support for his hypothesis in the cases ofIndonesia and Thailand. In the case of Malaysia, the

direction of the impact is reversed: an increasedexport orientation would reduce the private savingsrate.

The most likely reasons for getting mixed resultsby these studies are the specification of the savingsfunction, the sample of countries used, and the periodof time being investigated. The focus of the researchreviewed above was to assess whether variations inexports resulted in variations in savings behavior fora given set of countries and not to test for theinfluence of openness or trade liberalization on thesavings rates of these countries. Openness, asdiscussed earlier, encompasses a broader definition oftrade where imports are also included in the traderatio or where other liberalization actions beyond thatrelated to trade liberalization are also included; as inthe Sachs-Warner openness index.

Chapter 6 provides an econometric investigationof the effect of trade liberalization on savingsbehavior for a sample 74 countries includingdeveloped and developing countries. The savingsfunction is specified to include life-cycle variables,income variables, and an openness index.

Dynamic Effects of TradeLiberalization on Foreign DirectInvestment

The principal question to be addressed in thisstudy is whether trade liberalization influences therate of economic growth. Trade liberalization maynot directly affect growth but it may affect investmentwhich in turn affects growth. As discussed in chapter2 and in the savings section above, investment is animportant determinant of growth.

Foreign direct investment, (FDI), defined as theinvestment that a firm headquartered in one countrymakes in operations in another country, is acomponent of the total investment in a country. Someresearchers, e.g. Borensztein, de-Gregorio, and Lee(1995) and Blomström, Lipsey, and Zejan (1992), findthat FDI is more important to a country’s growth thandomestic investment because investment by foreignfirms, (multinationals),21 includes improvedtechnology.

There are any number of ways for judging theimportance of FDI with respect to the worldeconomy. Rugman (1988) estimates that one-half ofall trade and one-fifth of world GDP are attributableto multinationals. The sales of U.S. affiliatesabroad—firms affiliated with U.S.-based multi-

21 Multinationals are firms which have investments inmultiple countries. Firms that engage in FDI are bydefinition multinationals.

Page 53: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

3-12

nationals—are over twice the size of U.S. exports.Exports from U.S. based firms to affiliates of U.S.firms abroad accounted for 30 percent of exports in1992 (U.S. Department of Commerce, (1994)).

Table 3-2 shows the inflows and outflows of FDIfrom 1990 to 1995 grouped by developed anddeveloping countries. While FDI is still mainly adeveloped-world phenomenon, developing countriesare playing an increasing role both as recipients andas suppliers of FDI. The bottom two rows of thetable show the developing countries inflows andoutflows of FDI as a share of the total inflows from1990-1995 increased from approximately 17 to 33percent of the total; outflows from developingcountries doubled as well in this same period.

Table 3-3 shows U.S. investments abroad valuedat historical cost.22 While the use of historical costwill undervalue older assets, this comparison showsthe countries which have received and are receivingU.S. FDI. In 1995, the stock of U.S. FDI abroad wasapproaching three-quarters of a billion dollars. Theaverage annual growth rate in the last column of thetable shows that overall U.S. FDI abroad increased by

22 Historical cost is the price paid for assets.Therefore, if the current value of an asset is above thepurchase price, the historical cost of an asset will be lessthan the current value.

over 8 percent a year during 1980-95. With theexception of Africa, most regions of the world saw asizable increase in investment by U.S. multinationals;Japan and Asia showed the largest increase. Interms of share of total, U.S. investments showed apattern similar to that of FDI in table 3-2. Theshare of total U.S. investments in Latin America,Africa, the Middle East and Other Asia, increasedfrom 26 percent in 1980 to 28 percent in 1995.Most of the countries in those regions could beconsidered developing.

The existence of a dynamic effect of liberalizationthrough FDI is dependent on there being linksbetween trade liberalization, FDI, and growth. Toexamine these links two distinct issues must bediscussed. The first concerns the role of FDI indetermining a country’s growth. If FDI does notaffect a country’s growth rate, there can be nodynamic effect, only a static effect. The second issueconcerns the linkage between policy liberalization andFDI flows. Since trade liberalization is usuallyaccompanied by a decrease in restrictions on FDI aswell, it is useful to consider these two issues jointly.For policy liberalization to have a dynamic effect,with respect to FDI, both of these linkages must exist.For there to be a dynamic effect, policy liberalizationmust lead to more FDI, which in turn must lead togrowth.

Table 3-2Inflows and outflows of FDI 1990-95ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

CountryÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1990ÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1991ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1992ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1993ÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1994ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1995ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1990-1995ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ����������

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ Billions of current dollars

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎPercentage ChangeÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

InflowsÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

169.8ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

114.0ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

114.0ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

129.3ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

132.8ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

203.2ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

20

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Outflows ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

222.5 ÎÎÎÎÎÎ

201.9ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

181.4 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

192.4 ÎÎÎÎÎÎ

190.9ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

270.5 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

22

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Developing: ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎInflows ÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎ 33.7 ÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎ 41.3ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

50.4 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

73.1 ÎÎÎÎÎÎ

87.0ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

99.7 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

196

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Outflows ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

17.8 ÎÎÎÎÎÎ

8.9ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

21.0 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

33.0 ÎÎÎÎÎÎ

38.6ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

47.0 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

164ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Developing:(as percent of total):

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎInflows ÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎ 16.6 ÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎ 26.6ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

30.7 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

36.1 ÎÎÎÎÎÎ

39.6ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

32.9 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎOutflows ÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎ 7.4 ÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎ 4.2ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

10.4 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

14.6 ÎÎÎÎÎÎ

16.8ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

14.8 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Source: UNCTAD, 1997.

Page 54: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

3-13

Table 3-3U.S. investments abroad at historical costÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Country ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1980 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1985 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1990 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1995 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1980-1995ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Millions ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Avg. annual growthPercent

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

All Countries ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

215,375 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

230,250 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

424,086ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

708,145 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

8.26

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Canada ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

45,119 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

46,909 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

67,033ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

81,387 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

4.01

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Europe ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

96,287 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

105,171 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

211,194ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

363,527 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

9.26ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Japan ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

6,225 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

9,235 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

20,997ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

39,198 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

13.05ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

AustraliaÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

7,654ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

8,772ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

14,846ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

24,713ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

8.13ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Latin America and W. Hem.ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

38,761ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

28,261ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

81,592ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

122,765ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

7.99

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Africa ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

6,128 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

5,891 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

4,861ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

6,516 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.41

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Middle East ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

2,163 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

4,606 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

3,806ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

7,982 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

9.09

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Other Asia ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

8,505 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

15,400 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

22,890ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

62,057 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

14.17

Source: U.S. Department of Commerce, 1994.

The following sections are a review of theprevious research on these two linkages. There seemsto be a broad consensus that liberalization leads tomore FDI and FDI leads to growth. Therefore, theevidence thus far indicates a dynamic effect ofliberalization through FDI.

Review of Empirical Literature onFDI and Growth

There are two main strands to the empiricalliterature on FDI and growth. One strand examinescross-country regressions relating GDP growth tovarious attributes, including FDI. Another strandexamines how FDI may lead to growth. The latterliterature presents a number of postulated transmissionpaths whereby FDI may lead to more growth. Mostof the attention in this research is on identifyingtransmission paths. For example, a study may showthat FDI leads to improved technology in a sectorwith the link to increased growth assumed. It isuseful to examine some of the articles that look athow FDI affects growth explicitly and then examinehow FDI might cause growth.

Balasubramanyam, Salisu, and Sapsford (1996)examine the role of FDI in the growth process indeveloping countries characterized by different policyregimes. They use cross-country regressions on asample of developing countries divided into twogroups. One group of countries is judged to be“export promoting” and the other “importsubstituting,” the two groups are divided on the basis

of the countries’ import policies. The study finds thatFDI affects growth for the whole sample of countries,but the impact of FDI on growth is strongest for thosecountries with export-promoting policies. Theexplanation provided is that these countries are able tobetter use FDI and the technology it brings.

Blomström, Lipsey, and Zejan (1992) find thatFDI is an important contributor to growth for higherincome developing countries, but not for the lowestincome countries. This finding is a similar to that ofBalasubramanyam et al. to the extent that the impactof FDI on growth is determined by the internalsituation of the country.

Borensenztein, de-Gregorio, and Lee (1995) use asample of 69 developing countries in a cross-sectionanalysis to examine the contribution of FDI to growthin these countries. Their results show that FDI isimportant in technology transfer. In addition, theyfind that FDI contributes more to growth than doesdomestic investment and FDI spurs domesticinvestment as firms in the host country try to catch upor supply the multinationals. Like the two studiesabove, they find that the ability of the host country tofully exploit the benefits of FDI depends on the hostcountry’s policies and attributes.

The transmission paths postulated on how FDIleads to growth can be divided into two main groups:the direct effect of technology transfer, and spillovereffects. The link between the transfer of technologyand growth is that multinationals possess technologyembodied in the plant, equipment or management andimproved technology leads to growth. The degree to

Page 55: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

3-14

which this technology affects the host country is notclear. A spillover effect of FDI is any indirecteffect. For example, increased efficiency due to theincrease in competition is a spillover effect.

Technology transferThe subject of multinationals and technology

transfer has received a great deal of attention for twoimportant reasons. First, multinationals perform thebulk of the research and development in the world.Second, some type of superior knowledge, such asskilled management or a unique product, has typicallymade the multinational successful (Blomström,(1991)).

Davidson and McFetridge (1985) examine themode of technology transfer by multinationals on thebasis of a number of country and industry specificvariables. They have panel data of transactions byU.S. multinationals with their affiliates and otherfirms. They found that technology is less likely to betransferred (1) if the technology is newer, (2) the moreresearch and development intensive the industry is, (3)if it is technology that has previously been transferredleast, and (4) if the multinational had affiliates in thecountry. McFetridge (1987) examines technologytransfer using data for Canadian companies and findssimilar results.

Mansfield and Romeo (1984) find that technologytransferred to affiliates was newer than that transferredto other firms. They examine affiliates in bothdeveloped and developing countries regardinglicensing of technology and joint ventures. Affiliatesin developed countries obtained new technology fromthe parent company when it was an average of 5.8years old; affiliates in developing countries obtainednew technology an average of 4 years later, or onaverage 9.8 years after the parent had the sametechnology. Non-affiliated firms received the oldesttechnology. On average, non-affiliated firms receivedtechnology when it was 13.1 years old.

Not only do affiliates receive technology of amore recent vintage, but they receive the newtechnology and support for it on a flow basis.Behrman and Wallender (1976) discuss qualitativedifferences in the transfer of technology betweenaffiliated firms. Affiliates have continuous access tothe parent firm that developed the new method ofproduction, the products, management techniques,and so forth.

Spillover effectsSpillover effects, or indirect effects of FDI on

growth, can take many forms. Investment bymultinationals can mean more competition in an

industry, more human capital in a country because ofthe training of employees, or it may have other effectson customers and suppliers, such as suppliers’increasing the quality of their product to meetstandards set by the multinational. The empiricalresearch on this subject examines the existence andsize of these effects. Many of the studies do notexamine how productivity gains affect growth, butsimply measure productivity increases as the marketshare of the multinationals increases.

Gorecki (1976) found that multinationals wereable to enter new product markets in a country wheredomestic firms could not because of entry barriers.Multinationals have attributes that a domestic entrantmight not have, such as a larger stock of R&D andgreater access to capital. Blomström (1986) examinesproductivity in Mexico and finds that the largestspillover effect is the procompetitive effect ofadditional firms in an industry by the entry of foreignmultinationals. A number of other studies also findthe entry of multinationals is negatively related inconcentration in an industry (Rosenbluth (1970) andDunning (1974)). Thus there appears to be a positivespillover effect from increased competition.

The evidence on the positive effects of FDI onhuman capital is less clear. Studies of developingcountries indicate that a sizable number of themanagers of locally owned firms were trained byforeign multinationals (Katz (1987), Yoshihara (1988),and Gershenberg (1986)). There is also evidence thatmultinationals directly transfer management expertiseto their suppliers (Behrman and Wallender (1976), andLipsey (1994)). Dunning (1958) found evidence thatforeign firms engaged in the training of localsuppliers. Brash (1966) found similar results byexamining the relationship between General Motorsand its suppliers in Australia. Case studies or surveyson upstream spillovers of FDI, such as Lim and Pang(1982) surveyed multinationals in Singapore andfound a willingness to help local suppliers establishthemselves.

Review of Empirical Literature onthe Determinants of FDI

The second linkage necessary for there to be adynamic effect of liberalization through FDI is thatliberalization must lead to more FDI. There are anynumber of determinants of FDI other than policymeasures, the main concern of this review is thosedeterminants related to government policy. The effectof government policies and policy changes on FDIflows is determined by the motivation of firms. Thetwo main motivations for firms to invest abroad are toserve a market and to source products or servicesfrom that country, either for sale in another country oras inputs to production in another country. An

Page 56: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

3-15

example of investing to serve a market is U.S. firms’investing in Europe to serve the European CommonMarket as it was being formed (Scaperlanda andBalough (1983)). An example of the sourcingmotivation is U.S. firms’ investing in Asia, LatinAmerica, and so forth to perform some portion of themanufacturing process (Frobel, Heinricks, and Krege(1980)). Of course these two motivations are notmutually exclusive, but trade policy will have verydifferent effects depending on the motives of theinvesting firms.

The relationship between openness to tradeand FDI

Early research typically suggested that the higherthe tariff level in a country and industry, the higherwill be the FDI in that country and industry; i.e., therewill be tariff-jumping investment. This result impliesthat trade, exports, and affiliate sales generated byFDI are substitutes. Horst (1972) examined across-section of industries in Canada; the resultsshowed a negative relationship between exports andtariffs. The higher the tariff the more likely a U.S.firm was to supply the Canadian market fromCanadian affiliates rather than exports. Orr (1975)found that these results were not robust to slightvariations in the data set. When less aggregatedindustry groupings were used the negative relationshipbetween tariffs and exports disappeared. Studies byNicholas (1986) and Hollander (1984) also show anegative relationship between tariffs and FDI. Thereare a number of other studies that found norelationship between tariffs and exports (Buckley andDunning (1976) and Ferrantino (1993)).

Research of a more recent vintage has typicallyfound complementarity between FDI and exports orcomplementarity and substitution on different levels.For example, both Lipsey and Weiss (1981) andClausing (1996) find that FDI and exports arecomplements using aggregate FDI and export flows.This complementarity may show up in this type ofexamination owing to country specific heterogeneity.In other words, what makes a country a good place toexport to also makes it a good place to invest. Forexample a country that has a productive labor forcewill attract FDI, but this country will likely have wellpaid workers which will attract exports as well.

Two studies that look at more dissagregated FDIdata are Head and Ries (1997) and Blonigen (1997).Using firm level time series data on 935manufacturing firms Head and Ries (1997) investigatethe apparent complementarity between FDI andexports. In total they find complementarity, butevidence suggests this may be due to intermediategoods’ being imported by the affiliates and theincrease in aggregate demand caused by investment.

Blonigen (1997) finds substitution andcomplementarity between FDI and exports byexamining Japanese auto parts exports to the UnitedStates. Japanese investment in auto plants in theUnited States is complementary to Japanese auto partsexports. Japanese investment in auto parts firms inthe United States is a substitute for Japanese autoparts exports.

A study which looks at the substitution betweenexports and foreign affiliate sales in a jointlydetermined framework with explicit incorporation oftariff and nontariff barriers is Brainard (1993). Bymeans of a cross-section of industries she looks at thesales of U.S. affiliates abroad and exports. There is astrong negative relationship between tariffs andexports. An elasticity of 0.38 to 0.45 is shown as therelationship between tariffs and affiliate sales. Forexample, a 1-percent increase in the tariff brings anincrease of approximately one-third to one-halfpercent in affiliate sales. She also looks at theinfluence of nontariff barriers to trade on affiliatesales. In her results nontariff barriers are positivelyrelated to affiliate sales with an elasticity of 0.17.

The relationship between FDI opennessand FDI

Government policy on FDI can take many forms.Some governments place restrictions on FDI such astechnology transfer requirements, local-contentrequirements, or sectoral prohibitions. Governmentsalso give incentives for foreign investments such aslower operating taxes or tariff breaks on importedinputs. A country’s FDI policy also includes the legalprotection afforded to foreign investors against suchthreats as expropriation. With an increased interest inbilateral and multilateral investment negotiations, theeffect of FDI liberalization on FDI flows is important.The investment agreement in the Uruguay Round ontrade-related investment measures (e.g., minimumexport and local content requirements) and domesticregulations that may impede FDI (e.g., licensingrequirements) is a current move toward liberalizingthe investment environment. This negotiating processis only beginning, and other more wide ranginginvestment agreements are under discussion.

The complexities of FDI regimes and theirvarying effects make empirical estimation challenging.In order to measure the effect of FDI policy, ameasure of the restrictiveness or openness of acountry’s FDI policy must be constructed. Most ofthe empirical work has relied on a tally of thenumber of restrictions on or incentives for FDI thatexist in a country. Therefore, a lot of the evidence onthe effect of FDI policy on FDI is still anecdotal orcovered in case studies. The case study research alsohas an emphasis on the effect of inducements morethan restrictions.

Page 57: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

3-16

Reuber (1973) shows that a variety ofinducements are offered to investors including tariffprotection; import quota protection; tariff reductionson imported equipment, and imported components,and tariff reductions on imported raw materials; taxholidays; accelerated depreciation of plant andequipment for tax purposes; and government builtinfrastructure. In the case studies the author does notfind a significant effect of these inducements onincreasing FDI. The survey of companies suggest thatfirms believe governments that give inducements toattract investment will raise firm costs in other waysto recover lost revenue. This paper also summarizesprevious empirical studies on the impact of FDIrestrictions and incentives, which show mixed results.Guisinger and Associates (1985) wrote case studies of74 major investments in 30 countries. They foundthat over 50 percent of these investments benefitedfrom some type of inducement. Also the number ofinducements was actually greater for investments toserve the local market than it was for exports.

Murtha (1991) concludes that companies pay agreat deal of attention to the consistency ofgovernment policy of countries in which they investor from which they purchase supplies. The moredisruptive or inconsistent a government’s policies are,the less likely a firm is to be involved with thecountry or its suppliers.

Export processing zones (EPZs) are an importantpolicy measure used primarily by developingcountries to attract investment. These zones are away of providing relief from the normal taxes, tariffs,and so forth, without repealing them for the entirecountry. Frobel, Heinricks, and Krege (1980) look atEPZs throughout the world and found thatthree-quarters of the activity was in textiles, wearingapparel, and electronic goods. Woodward and Rolfe(1993) show that the amount of land set aside forEPZs is a significant determinant of the amount ofFDI in Caribbean countries. Ranis and Shive (1985)found a significant positive effect of EPZs inattracting FDI to Taiwan.

There has been some empirical work oncumulative FDI openness measures looking at theeffects on FDI. Brainard (1993) finds a largenegative elasticity of FDI barriers and affiliate sales.FDI barriers are measured by using a survey measurefrom the World Competitiveness Report. For a1-percent increase in FDI barriers there is a3.2-percent decrease in affiliate sales, while exportsincrease by 1.6 percent. Ferrantino (1993) finds thatrestrictive policies on FDI lessen the amount ofinvestment in a country as well. His measure of FDIopenness is derived from the Commerce DepartmentU.S. FDI surveys. Weisman (1997) finds that FDI inthe former Soviet Bloc reacts to investor perceived

risk. His measure of risk contains government policyvariables, many of which affect FDI.

Other determinants of FDIIn terms of country-specific variables, there are a

few categories of variables typically used. Onecategory attempts to measure the attractiveness of themarket for sales. In other words, variables such asGDP (for the size of the market), GDP per capita (forthe wealth of the market), and growth in GDP (for thegrowth in the market) should all be positively relatedto FDI. The other category of variables measures theattractiveness of the market for production. Variablessuch as labor costs, productivity, and skill level of thework force have all been used as determinants of FDI.Other variables which judge the overall attractivenessof the market including inflation and exchange ratevariation or uncertainty have been used to measuremacro-economic policies or risk. Each of thesevariables has been used in empirical research on FDIdepending data availability and the specific researchquestion being examined.

In terms of industry-specific issues, the variablesused either relate the industry in the home country ofthe multinational to the industry in the prospectivehost country, or are specific to the industry itself. Anexample of the former is the wage rate in the hostcountry compared with the wage rate in the homecountry. An example of an industry-specific variableis a measure of economies of scale or the necessityfor some specific natural resource, such as oil for thepetroleum industry. Other industry-specific variablesinclude the level of corporate profits in the industry,concentration in the industry, the research anddevelopment intensity of the industry, or the degree oflabor intensity. Each of these variables could beimportant in determining the size and location of FDIflows depending on the specific question and industryto be examined.

Conclusions on the Dynamic Effectsof FDI

There seems to be a relatively broad consensusthat FDI will in most cases lead to growth. What isnot as clear is exactly how FDI translates into growth.There remains a great deal of empirical work to bedone on the effects of FDI on the host country, but thework to this point clearly suggests that there arebenefits to the host country from FDI. More work onthe transmission mechanisms of how FDI contributesto growth is important as well.

The research on effects of tariffs and nontariffbarriers on FDI or the relationship of trade and FDIhas gone through an evolution. As the theories aboutfirms’ motivations have been changing and as data

Page 58: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

3-17

and data analysis techniques have improved, theconclusions drawn about these relationships havechanged. The ability to conclusively answer thisresearch question on the relationship of trade and FDIis constrained by a lack of data, in some cases theappropriate data, and the actual relationship verylikely contains elements of substitution andcomplementarity. Markusen (1995) summarizes someof the recent research on the relationship betweentrade barriers and FDI by stating that trade barrierscause a substitution toward FDI, but they alsodepress both trade and investment. Thus high barriersto trade will tend to cause a substitution away fromexports towards FDI (affiliate sales), butsimultaneously depress both trade and investment.

Although the research on the effects of FDI policyon FDI is more conclusive, the number of articles onthe subject is limited. The research finds that an openFDI policy leads to more FDI. Measures of FDIopenness are limited and have been mostly surveymeasures.

Chapter 7 investigates the relationship betweenFDI and the openness of policies on trade and FDI.The relationship between policy openness and FDI isthe subject of the empirical exploration in chapter 7because FDI and trade policy openness affect theamount of FDI a country receives and may also affectthe growth effects of FDI.

There are linkages between policy liberalizationand FDI, and between FDI and growth. Tariffliberalization increases FDI in the aggregate and FDIopenness increases FDI. Existing research alsosuggests that FDI has a positive growth effect. FDIliberalization leads to more FDI, which has a positiveeffect on growth.

Trade, Technology, andProductivity

This section discusses potential links betweeninternational trade and technological change,particularly as such change is manifested inproductivity growth. First, there is international tradein technologies themselves, as well as goods. Theextent and effect of international technology trade canbe influenced by policies with respect to intellectualproperty, foreign investment, and merchandise trade.Second, numerous investigators have proposed thateither exporting, or importing, may be a cause ofgreater productivity growth. It has been argued thatgreater import competition enhances productivitygrowth by forcing less efficient firms to operate moreefficiently and by rewarding more efficient domesticfirms with an increase in market share. Since hightariffs and NTBs reduce import competition, a similarnegative effect of trade barriers on productivity can be

posited. Increased exports might enhance productivityby exposing the exporting firm to new technologicalinformation from the customer (see Aw and Hwang(1995), for Taiwan.)

Evidence on these topics using aggregate nationalor industry-level data is reviewed first, followed byevidence using micro-level data on individual firms.

Aggregate and Industry-LevelEvidence

There have been several recent attempts tomeasure the degree of international technologicalspillovers, and the extent to which they are correlatedwith trade. The question of spillovers is important forseveral reasons. First, trade-induced technologicalspillovers may represent a channel through whichgreater trade can enhance growth and productivitydirectly. Second, the degree of spillovers hasconsequences for the impact of internationalagreements for the recognition of intellectual property.Third, the question of whether spillovers are large orsmall is relevant for distinguishing among variousmodels of economic growth. At one extreme, theSolow-Swan neoclassical model implicitly treatstechnology as an international public good, whileendogenous growth models that model R&Dincentives often assume that countries are able toappropriate part or all of national technologicalprogress within national boundaries.

Coe, Helpman, and Hoffmeister (1995) attempt tomeasure the benefits of developed-country R&D fordeveloping countries which do little or no R&D.They find substantial technology spillovers; forexample, an addition to the R&D capital stock23 of$100 in either the United States or Japan increasesGDP in the developing world as a whole by about$25. Most significantly, the benefits to developingcountries of developed-country R&D are stronglycorrelated with the developing countries’ openness tointernational trade as measured by the import share ofGDP. According to the study’s estimates, developingcountries which are relatively open to imports enjoyfurther productivity gains by shifting trade toR&D-intensive developed countries (i.e., to the UnitedStates and Japan, rather than to Europe or Canada.)

23 This is measured as the sum of current and pastR&D expenditures, with an allowance for depreciatingvalue of older expenditures.

Page 59: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

3-18

But Keller (1997), revisiting the estimates of Coe etal., demonstrates that artificial, randomly generatedtrade patterns can give rise to positive estimates ofinternational R&D spillovers even larger than thoseestimated on the actual data, casting doubt on theclaim that patterns of international trade areimportant in driving R&D spillovers.

Eaton and Kortum (1994) use data oninternational patenting, productivity, and research tomeasure technology flows among the five leadingresearch economies (France, Germany, Japan, theUnited States, and the United Kingdom). They findthat each of the five countries derives a substantialshare of its productivity gains from research in othercountries, ranging from 35 to 78 percent of totalproductivity gains. By contrast, inventors earnbetween 80 and (for the United States) 98 percent ofthe value of their inventions from domestic sources.In an extension covering 19 OECD countries, Eatonand Kortum (1995) estimate that about 18 percent ofU.S. productivity growth comes from non-U.S.-basedR&D; about 73 percent of Japanese productivitygrowth comes from non-Japanese R&D and from 89to nearly 100 percent of other OECD countries’productivity growth derives from R&D performedoutside the countries’ borders.

Chua (1993) finds evidence that internationalgrowth spillovers may pertain to physical and humancapital also, but that these spillovers are regionallylocalized. From 14 to 18 percent of a country’sgrowth rate depends on the levels of physical andhuman capital of neighboring countries. Within aparticular geographic region (such as Latin Americaor Africa), the tendency for poorer countries to “catchup” to richer countries is stronger than for the worldas a whole; in fact, the estimated rate of convergencewithin regions is about 0.5 to 0.8 percent per annumhigher than the convergence rate between regions.Chua’s results explain, for example, why countries inNorth Africa (close to Europe), East Africa (close toAsia) and southern Africa (close to South Africa)show consistently stronger growth performance thancountries in west-central Africa (which do not haveany immediate high-income neighbors).

There has also been research done into thelinkages between trade and intellectual propertyprotection. Ferrantino (1993) showed that intrafirmtechnology payments of U.S. multinational firmsincreased when the foreign subsidiary was located in acountry with strong recognition of foreign IPRs. U.S.exports to foreign subsidiaries of U.S. multinationalfirms (i.e., intrafirm exports) were higher for countrieswith weak IPRs, perhaps reflecting a desire to shieldsteps of vertically integrated production processesfrom observation. By contrast, there was littleevidence of an impact of foreign IPR policy on arm’slength U.S. exports (i.e., exports other than intrafirm

exports). Maskus and Penubarti (1995), analyzingbilateral trade by sector for a larger group ofcountries, and using a different measure of thestrength of IPRs, found that increasing patentprotection was associated with increases in bilateralmanufacturing imports into developing economies.

In a series of papers using a new and carefullyconstructed set of measurements of intellectualproperty protection across countries and time, Ginarteand Park (1995, 1996a, 1996b) establish thathigher-income countries, as well as countries with astrong base of R&D and human capital, and thosewith liberal political and economic institutions, aremore likely to adopt strong IPRs; that strong IPRsstimulate growth indirectly by promotingaccumulation of physical capital and R&D capital;and that strong IPRs encourage internationalcross-licensing of patents when first introduced, butmay discourage such cross-licensing at the highestlevels of protection owing to increases in the marketpower effect of patent protection.

The degree to which the technology transferred toa firm’s foreign subsidiary diffuses any furtherthrough the host country’s economy is a matter ofsome dispute. Westphal, Rhee, and Pursell (1984) andYoung (1992) argue that in South Korea, Hong Kong,and Singapore, local employees of foreign enterprisesacquired sufficient technological and managerialknowledge to subsequently set up shop independently.By contrast, Helleiner (1989) and Caves (1996, chs. 7and 9) review the literature on technological spilloverfrom foreign subsidiaries of developed-countrymultinational firms located in developing countries,and find the evidence to be mixed. The overall lessonmay be that the extent of technology spillover inducedby FDI depends on the level of local human capital,which was relatively high in East Asia in comparisonwith other developing regions.

Micro-Level EvidenceThis section describes salient examples of

empirical work testing specifically for a relationshipbetween trade regimes and productivity, focusing onsector-level and firm-level data. The hypothesis beingtested in these studies is whether increased exposureto international trade causes a response in firms thatwill ultimately be measurable in terms of improvedefficiency. Firms losing the shelter of protectionfrom imports may need to improve efficiency, adoptnew technologies, or be forced to exit or lose marketshare. In this way, more efficient firms will come tohold a larger market share and measured sector-levelproductivity will rise. This response may take avariety of forms; thus researchers have examined therelation between trade regimes and variousmechanisms for improving productivity.

Page 60: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

3-19

Evidence for the United States

Caves and Barton (1990) use U.S. firm-level datato estimate the gap between a firm’s degree oftechnological efficiency and the best-practice level ofefficiency in the relevant industry. They then checkfor the statistical relation between this measure ofrelative efficiency and several factors that mightexplain it, including openness to trade. Thefundamental factors explaining variation in efficiencyinclude diversity in the capital/labor ratio acrossplants, R&D expenditures, plant size, age of capitalstock, and measures of industry concentration. Whenimport penetration is added as an explanatory factor, itis shown to have a positive but not highly statisticallysignificant influence on efficiency. But when theimpact on efficiency of import penetration ismeasured jointly with a term measuring the degree ofexcess concentration over minimum efficient scale,the coefficient is positive and highly significant.Caves and Barton conclude, “Increasing importcompetition by one standard deviation (an increase of10 percentage points in imports/new supply) raises anindustry’s efficiency by 0.05 standard deviation. Inshort, import competition has become a strong factorenforcing technical efficiency on U.S. manufacturingindustries with high concentration levels that are notdue to production-scale economies.”(Caves andBarton, 1990, p. 94)

These researchers find less favorable results forexport shares, which actually show a negativerelationship with efficiency. Their evidence indicatesthat exporting activity is so unevenly distributedacross firms and plants within an industry that thegains of those that export cause the remainder of theindustry to appear inefficient by comparison.

MacDonald (1994) finds results on the role ofimport competition similar to those of Caves andBarton. Using data on labor productivity in 94 U.S.industries, he finds that in highly concentratedindustries, a five percentage point increase in importshare over a 3-year period is associated with a 3.7percentage point increase in annual labor productivitygrowth over the next 3-year period.

Harrison and Revenga (1995) also test therelationship between openness to trade andproductivity growth in the United States at theindustry level. They measure efficiency by theresidual growth in output over the amount explainedby inputs of labor, capital, and intermediate goods, aswell as spending on R&D. They consider bothimports and exports expressed as shares of sales in thesame regression framework. Using annual data from1958 to 1984 they find a negative relationshipbetween trade and productivity growth. They pointout, as does Harrison (1994), that increased import

competition can cause a decline in output in the shortrun which will lead to a decline in productivity asthey have measured it. However, the efforts by firmsto improve efficiency, or the gains in market share bythe more efficient firms, will take effect only over aperiod of time.

To allow for longer term efficiency improvementsto take effect, they repeat their estimation acrosssectors for only two representative years, 1958 and1984. They find that both import competition andexport activity are positively associated withproductivity increases over the long term, though onlythe import share is significant at the 5 percent level.They note that this positive relationship disappearswhen they adjust for capacity utilization (and improvethe price measure on material inputs), although manywould argue that changes in capacity utilizationshould count as part of productivity growth andshould not be factored out separately.

Evidence for developed countriesNishimizu and Page (1991) also find a short-term

negative correlation between import penetration andtotal factor productivity (TFP) growth for the UnitedStates, Japan, Sweden, and Finland in a studycovering twelve industries in these and thirteendeveloping countries between the late 1950s and theearly 1980s. Their results indicate, however, that TFPgrowth ultimately recovers after an increase in importcompetition, especially among more market-orientedeconomies. They conclude, “Taken together, theseresults demonstrate that dynamic gains canaccompany superior productivity performance in moreopen and market-oriented policy environments. This,in turn, suggests a case for the medium- to long-termbenefits of such policy environments.” (Nishimizuand Page, 1991, p. 260)

A study by the Economic Planning AdvisoryCommission of Australia (1996) provides furtherevidence using sectoral data on 14 OECD countries.For each country, aggregate TFP growth is averagedover four five-year periods from 1970 to 1989. Thenthe relationship is tested between TFP and annualaverage tariff rates, which are introduced with aparticular lag structure. The results show a significantimpact of tariff changes on TFP growth. Specifically,the study finds that a one percentage point cut intariffs raises TFP by 3.4 percent over 19 years.Notably, the results show a similar effect when therelationship is tested for year-to year measures of TFP,although data on TFP are statistically smoothed ratherthan averaged over five years. The lag structure onthe tariff protection variable indicates that tariffchanges do not significantly affect TFP for the firstfour years, but their influence persists 19 years later.

Page 61: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

3-20

Evidence for developing countriesPack (1988) conducted an extensive survey of

sectoral and firm-level studies of productivity indeveloping countries. He examines literaturecomparing the performance of outward- versus inwardand oriented or import substituting economies,concludes: “Thus, to date there is no clearconfirmation of the hypothesis that countries with anexternal orientation benefit from greater growth intechnical efficiency in the component sectors ofmanufacturing.” (Park (1988), p. 353) He does,however, cite a study by Handoussa, Nishimizu, andPage (1986) of public sector firms in Egypt over aperiod of trade liberalization there (1973-79). Theyfind that the liberalization program was successful infostering rapid TFP growth. They conclude thatincreased capacity utilization, made possible by arelaxation of the foreign exchange constraint, was animportant factor behind the impressive rates of TFPgrowth in public sector firms.

Recently, a new body of research has examinedthe relation between trade reforms and productivitygrowth in developing countries using firm-level data.Tybout and Westbrook (1995) studied Mexico, whichstarted a major trade liberalization program in 1985.Using Mexican plant-level data from 1984 to 1990,they measured productivity from both the productionside and the cost side. That is, they measured growthin output beyond that explained by increases in inputsas well as reductions in the costs of producing a givenlevel of output. They measured openness to tradeusing import license coverage, official tariff rates,import penetration, and export shares. Using rankcorrelations, their results show that sectors starting thesample period as relatively open to trade registeredcomparatively large cost reductions. However, theyfind less association between changes in tradeopenness and cost reduction. They posit thatincreased import competition caused a decline inoutput, and thus in measured productivity, in the shortrun.

Using the same Mexican data over the sameperiod, Venables and Wijnbergen (1993) find asignificant acceleration of TFP growth after the 1985trade reform for 38 of 47 industries. This associationbetween changes in trade regime and changes in TFPgrowth was found by comparing TFP growth for theperiod before the trade reforms (1984-87) to that inthe post-reform period (1987-90).

A similar study was undertaken by Tybout et al.using firm level data from Chile. This studyexamined the results of Chile’s industrial census takenbefore (1967) and after (1979) the institution of amajor trade reform in Chile (1974-79). Again theyuse rank correlations to indicate patterns ofassociation between changes in the level of import

protection and changes in sectoral efficiency acrossthe period of trade reform. The results show thatsectors posting relatively large declines in protectionalso have larger decreases in employment as well asincreases in value added and output, especially amongsmaller firms. Larger reductions in protection are alsoassociated with higher output per unit of capital andvalue added per unit of capital. They conclude thatsince lower import protection is associated withincreased output per worker and output per unit ofcapital, that a measure of TFP growth would also becorrelated with changes in protection. Further testsincluding measures of returns to scale and averageefficiency confirm their conclusions that the industriesexperiencing the greatest tariff reductions achieved themost productivity improvement.

Harrison (1994) also estimates the relationbetween trade regime and productivity using firmlevel data covering 1979-87 from Côte d’Ivoire. Côted’Ivoire implemented a major trade reform in1985-87. She points out that traditional productionfunction-based estimates of TFP growth can be biasedif production is actually characterized by imperfectcompetition and increasing or decreasing returns toscale. She estimates a revised production-sidemeasure of productivity which allows for marketpower and scale economies and thereby generatesvalues for the price markups associated with marketpower and for parameters representing returns toscale. She then generates revised TFP measures andcompares them, first across time — before and afterthe trade reform, and then across categories of importprotection — high and low. She finds thatproductivity growth accelerated after the trade reform,that low-protection sectors showed higherproductivity growth than high-protection sectors, andthat these relationships were enhanced by includingthe parameters allowing for imperfect competition andother than constant returns to scale. The study alsopoints out that the previously noted negative short-runimpact of import competition on productivitydisappears in the final analysis where productivitymeasures are averaged over several years to produce aperiod average.

Thus both theory and data indicate the potentialfor greater import competition to lead to a short termdecline in productivity, and studies testing for year-to-year correlations find little support for a positiverelationship. But studies that measure productivity asperiod averages or compare productivity across longerperiods of time, especially across periods of notabletrade liberalization, find positive correlations betweentrade openness and productivity. This indicates thatthe effects of a change in the trade regime onproductivity manifest themselves only gradually.Therefore, investigators have applied firm-level datato examine some of the mechanisms by which higher

Page 62: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

3-21

industry efficiency may be achieved. Specifically,they have tested whether increased trade competitionreduces the monopolistic profits arising from marketpower, allows the most efficient firms to expand andexploit efficiencies of operating at a larger scale,and/or forces the less efficient to exit the industry.

Harrison (1994) tests whether trade reform isassociated with a decline in price markups, and thuswith a decline in market power, using data from Côted’Ivoire. She finds that firms in the most protectedsectors have the highest price-cost margins, and shefinds weak evidence that these margins fell duringCôte d’Ivoire’s trade reform. Levinsohn (1993) foundsimilar results with firm-level data for Turkey for1983-86. Tybout examines the impact of tradeliberalization on increased exploitation of scaleeconomies for Chile and Mexico, thus on increasedproduction levels or greater returns to scale, but findslittle or no relationship. Using firm-level data forseveral developing countries in the World Bankresearch project “Industrial Competition, Productivity,and Their Relation to Trade Regimes, (the ICPTproject), Tybout (1989) and Roberts (1989) test for acorrelation between import protection and the rate ofentry and exit of firms in particular industries.However, they found no significant correlationbetween fluctuation in import penetration and entryand exit patterns.

Thus the exact mechanisms by which changes inimport protection may affect productivity have notbeen firmly established with firm-level data andapparently vary greatly across countries and industries(Tybout (1992)). Given the large number ofstructural changes taking place in developingcountries over the years for which data were collectedfor these studies, it is not surprising that the processesgenerating productivity increases proved to becomplex. Nevertheless, researchers have found directlinks between changes in trade regime andproductivity growth in developing countries when therelationship is measured over the medium term, longenough for efficiency measures to be put in place.

Openness, Development, andHuman Capital

The relationship between human capital andeconomic growth is well researched and documented.Human capital has several components. Theseinclude, on a national level, the size of the labor force(and the labor force participation rate), the ratio of theprime-age labor force to the “dependent” segments ofthe population in both the young and the old agegroups, and (at both aggregate and individual levels)the education, training, and experience of workers.Growth is generally discussed in terms of GDP per

capita; as more of the population moves into the laborforce the labor force per capita increases; as workersbecome more productive, output per worker (and percapita of the population) increases.

The linkages between growth and openness totrade have also been established in an extensiveliterature on development strategies and trade policies;much of the analysis in this report treats variousaspects of the trade-growth connection. However,there has been little work done on the connectionbetween trade policy and human capital formation.This section will review some of the literature ongrowth and human capital, with a particular emphasison any insights it may offer for potential research onpossible effects of trade policy.

A good starting point for this discussion is arecent paper by Jacob Mincer (1995). Mincerprovides a useful catalog of components of humancapital and its measurement, with some descriptiveand econometric measures of its connection toeconomic growth both historically, in the UnitedStates, and globally, across countries. Measures ofhuman capital formation utilizing historical data, aslisted by Mincer, include (1) growth of education, (2)an increase in per capita real income (which isvirtually synonymous with economic growth), (3)urbanization, (4) the demographic transition, and (5)increased female participation in the labor market.

Education is a key component of human capital,and has a clear relation to economic growth, both as acause and an effect. Education is both an investmentgood and a consumption good; as a consumptiongood, it is acquired out of increased earnings, and asan investment good, it yields a return, part of which atleast is reflected in increased earnings. In the UnitedStates the percentage of the population that hadcompleted high school by age 18 went from 3.5percent in 1890 to 87.0 percent in 1990. In 1890, 54percent of the population age 5 to 19 was enrolled inschool; by 1990 the figure was 92 percent. In 1990,according to U.N. data, 11.4 percent of the populationaged 25 and above in high income countries had somepostsecondary education. Among middle-incomecountries, the figure was 3.0 percent, and for lowincome countries, only 0.6 percent of the populationhad postsecondary education. Within countries therelationship between schooling and earnings hasalways been apparent. For a selection of developingcountries reported on in 1995, the lowest quintile ofthe population in terms of income received fromabout 1 to 5 years of schooling, while the highestincome quintiles received 3 to 7 years of schooling(World Bank, 1995).

Urbanization has long been considered anindicator of human capital. Historically, economicgrowth has coincided with a movement of population(and labor force) off the land and out of the

Page 63: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

3-22

agricultural sector into the urban, industrial andservice labor force. This has been due to increases inboth farm and non-farm productivity, since a smallerwork force has been able to meet the food needs ofthe population, freeing more labor to produce goodsand services that have higher income elasticities ofdemand, and higher wage levels. Mincer’s data forthe United States shows a decrease in the agriculturallabor force from 44 percent of the total labor force in1890 to 4 percent in 1990. Across countries, 78percent of the population in high income countrieslived in cities in 1990, while 26 percent of thepopulation in low income countries was urbanized.The World Bank report cited above notes a strongtendency for the size of the agricultural labor force toshrink as per capita GDP grows, but notes that growthis associated with higher wages in both agriculturaland manufacturing sectors (World Bank, 1995, pp. 19and 31).

The demographic transition describes therelationship between linked changes in fertility andmortality rates experienced by countries during thegrowth process. Briefly, as incomes rise (or ascountries gain access to medical and public healthtechnologies and practices), mortality rates falldramatically and population rises. After a lag, fertilityalso falls, due in part to higher infant survival rates,but more importantly to the desire of parents to spendmore resources on each child, particularly on humancapital investment (often referred to as higher“quality” of children). The result is a change from apopulation with high birth and death rates, to a muchlarger population with lower birth and death rates. Asthe number of children falls and income per capita(and per child) rises, there are further incentives forinvestment in human capital.

One of the factors that contributes to (and resultsfrom) the higher “cost” of children is the increasinglabor force participation of women that is observed aseconomies grow. This requires, initially, “...a sharpdivision of labor between the sexes in market andhousehold activities, which is clearly much greater atthe outset of economic growth (or in less advancedeconomies) when wages are low and fertility is high.,taking up much of the adult life of mothers” (Mincer,p. 35). If income elasticities of market goods,including expenditures on the “quality” of children,are higher than the income elasticities of goodsproduced at home (including the number of children,or fertility), one would expect a decrease in fertilityand an increase in the labor force participation ofwomen. In the United States, labor force participationof all women increased from 19 percent in 1890 to 60percent in 1990; for married women, the change wasfrom 4.6 percent to 63 percent. Across countries,according to Mincer’s UN data, the labor forceparticipation of women in high income countries was

42 percent, while in middle and low income countriesthe figure was 28 to 32 percent.

There has been some work to link human capitalgrowth to trade openness. Gould and Ruffin (1995)based their work on a standard Solow growth model,augmented to include the contribution of humancapital. They find that human capital has an effect asan “engine of growth” (i.e., that investment in humancapital accelerates growth) as well as an independenteffect as an input to production, along with ordinaryphysical capital and labor (the level of human capitalincreases output). Empirically, they estimate aclassical Solow growth model, augmented to includehuman capital as a factor to production. Holdingconstant its contribution to growth in that context,they examine the effect of the stock of human capitalon residual variation in growth. More interesting istheir finding that these effects vary with the opennessof the trade regime; human capital has an enhancedeffect on growth in more open economies.Barthelemy, Dessus, and Varoudakis (1997) also finda connection between the contribution of humancapital to growth and the openness of the economy toworld trade, in which human capital enhances theability of a country to benefit from the exposure tonew technologies that comes with openness to trade.This is not saying that openness enhances humancapital, but that it, in a sense, increases the returns tohuman capital by augmenting its effect on growth.

Trade, Income Growth, andPatterns of Demand

IntroductionStatistics show that since World War II, the

growth of global trade has consistently exceeded thegrowth of global income. From 1960 to 1995, theaverage annual rate of real growth in global tradewas 6.1 percent, considerably higher than the 3.8percent average real growth rate of output24. (Councilof Economic Advisors (1997)). Thus, postwar tradeproved to be income-elastic.25 In addition, economistshave noted a compositional change in internationaltrade. Since the mid-1970s, there has been a

24 In national income accounting terms, output isidentical to income.

25 When spending on a given commodity groupgrows faster than income, demand for that commoditygroup is termed income-elastic. When spending on a givencommodity group grows more slowly than income,demand for that commodity group is termedincome-inelastic. As income rises, the share of outlays onincome-elastic goods increases and the share of outlays onincome-inelastic goods falls. The demand for goods forwhich spending increases at the same rate as income, sothat their share in the total income remains constant, is

Page 64: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

3-23

been a progressive shift in trade away from rawmaterials and semi-manufactured goods towarddiverse manufactured goods within the same cate-gories, and toward goods produced by“knowledge-intensive” or “high-technology” indus-tries (Ethier (1982)). These changes in thecomposition of trade are linked to underlyingchanges in the composition of global consumption.

Most theoretical and empirical trade models donot track these changes accurately. To simplifyanalysis, traditional models of international trade havecharacterized demand for imports with the assumptionof unitary income elasticity.26 This assumption,called homotheticity, means that increases in the levelof income result in proportional increases in imports.In other words, trade is unit-elastic with regard toincome. Consequently, trade and income always growat the same rate, and when domestic income changes,the ratio of trade to total income remains constant. Inaddition, under the assumption of a homotheticdemand system, changes in income do not affect thecommodity composition of imports because everygood within that demand system has a unitary incomeelasticity of demand. In trade models characterizedby homothetic demand, only changes in relative pricesaffect the share of imports. Therefore, a homotheticdemand system may also be characterized asincome-neutral.27 The alternative system, in whichthe shares of expenditures on imports change asincome rises, and in which growth in the income levelaffects the commodity composition, is referred to asnonhomothetic. Under the nonhomothetic system,income elasticities are different from 1. A

25—Continuedcalled unit-elastic. Consumer studies show that thenecessities of life are generally income-inelastic, whereasgoods and services consumed above subsistence levels(called luxuries in consumer economics) areincome-elastic. As incomes rise, consumers increase theproportion spent on higher-quality goods and services(Deaton and Muellbauer (1986)). Such shifts in nationalspending patterns affect both imports and exports(Krugman and Obstfeld (1996)). A country withincreasing per capita incomes becomes a larger potentialmarket for more expensive, higher-quality foreign goodsand services. Increases in national productivity, whichinduce increases in per capita real income, expandnational export capacity (Linder (1961)).

26 The income elasticity of imports is the measurethat is most frequently used to express, compare, andanalyze the effects of rising income levels on trade. Itindicates either the percentage of change in total importsor in a particular group of commodities or services, as aresult of a one percent increase in incomes in a country,region, or in the world. See Theil (1975).

27 For background information on income-neutrality indemand analysis, see Pogany (1997).

nonhomothetic demand system may also be calledincome-sensitive.28

The assumption of income-neutrality in trademodels has significant consequences. Appliedsimulation models of trade, such as computablegeneral equilibrium (CGE) models, featuringincome-neutral demand, have usually generated onlysmall departures from this strict proportionality oftrade to income. As a result, when these models areused in backcasting exercises (that is, simulations ofpast history), they produce results that understate thehistorical growth of trade, particularly in rapidlyexpanding economies. Thus, in comparative static ordynamic simulation analyses of alternative tradeliberalization scenarios, the imposition of incomeneutrality tends to understate the potential economiceffects of trade liberalization. Such results maypotentially include understatements of the benefits oftrade liberalization in dynamic simulations of growingeconomies.

The relatively fast growth of trade and the shiftsin its composition mentioned above, have promptedseveral studies on the relationship between income,levels and trade. These studies provide furtherevidence that changes in real per capita income play asignificant role in shaping trade patterns. Theimplications of this research for future attempts tomodel the dynamic relationships between incomes andtrade are far-reaching. Improved modeling of theserelationships would enhance the ability to assess theeffects of global and/or regional trade liberalizationmeasures in a more precise and detailed manner.

Income in Trade Theories andModels

Until the 1970s, international trade theory wasprincipally concerned with analyzing and explaininginterindustry trade, also labeled “North-South” trade.Such trade is typified by the export of raw materialsor simple manufactures by a developing country(South) to enable itself to import advanced capitalgoods and consumer durables from the industrialized,developed countries (North).29 However, asmentioned earlier, the 1970s brought a significant shifttoward intraindustry trade, also labeled “North-North”trade. Such trade is typified by trade in automobiles,computers, and household electronics between thehigh per capita income, developed countries. Much ofthe North-North trade was (and remains) concentratedin the so-called knowledge-intensive or high-techindustries.

28 The income neutrality and sensitivity of exports areconcepts that are analogous to the income neutrality andsensitivity of imports. Since at the world level, importsequal exports, the income neutrality to import or exportmay be called the income neutrality to trade. Similarly, atthe world level, the income sensitivity to import or exportmay be called the income sensitivity to trade.

29 See Krugman and Obstfeld (1996).

Page 65: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

3-24

Several explanations emerged to account for theincome-elastic nature of postwar trade and the shifttoward intraindustry trade. They included politicalfactors, such as global and regional tradeliberalization; breakthroughs in the technology oftransportation and communications; imbalances ininternational wage rates; and advantages of producingvarious parts of a product in different countries.30

In the late 1970s, the “new international tradetheories,” which emphasized economies of scale andproduct differentiation, emerged to explain the risingprominence of North-North trade.31 In these theories,the ability of consumers to choose from an increasingvariety of products is limited by high unit costs ofproducing small batches of products for relativelysmall, compartmentalized domestic markets.International trade can exploit economies of scale byopening up sales of every product to a world market,thereby enabling production of more varieties of agood and lowering prices for each variety produced.Therefore, the “new international trade theories”provide a mathematical formalism for Adam Smith’sassertion that “the division of labor is limited by theextent of the market.”32

The rapid rise of intraindustry (North-North), andwithin that knowledge-intensive industry trade, isdirectly linked to the growth of per capita income,because the demand for variety in sophisticatedproducts and services emerges only at relatively highper capita income levels. Hence, the growth of percapita income significantly affects not only thevolume but also the composition of internationaltrade.

These observations notwithstanding, most modelsbased on either the classical or the new internationaltrade theories still assume unitary income elasticities,

30 For more on this subject, see Krugman (1995) andJun Ishii and Kei-Mu Yi (1997).

31 The term “economies of scale” signifies thepercentage of reduction in average costs achieved by agiven percentage increase in all of the inputs used in theproduction process. External economies of scale in anindustry are reductions in the average costs of a givenfirm as a result of the expansion of other firms in thesame industry, or as a result of the agglomeration ofsimilar firms in the same geographic region. Readyaccess to a highly skilled labor force is a typical source ofexternal economies. Infrastructure spillovers, such as goodtransportation and communication networks, good bankingand venture capital networks, and a stable economicenvironment, are also sources of external economies ofscale. Internal economies of scale for a given firm arereductions in its average costs achieved by expanding itsown scale of output. For descriptions and comparisons ofthese theories, see Helpman and Krugman (1994, 1986)and Ethier (1982).

32 For descriptions and comparisons of these theories,see Helpman and Krugman (1986) and Ethier (1982). Fora numerical demonstration of the increased weight of theNorth-North type of exchanges in the trade of severalindustrialized countries, see Gagnon and Rose (1990).

that is, income-neutral demand systems.33 Asexplained above, by definition, this assumptionprecludes any effect of increases in per capitaincome on the composition of international trade.Necessarily, these models conclude that economicdevelopment does not affect the composition oftrade. Studies such as Winters (1984) and Alston,et al. (1990), have shown that income neutrality doesnot correspond to actually observed consumerbehavior. In these works the authors show thatincome elasticities of domestic or foreign purchasesare either higher than unity, that is, imports growfaster than incomes, or are lower than unity, that is,imports fall behind the growth of incomes.

The application of income-neutral demandsystems appears to be inevitable in dynamic modelsdesigned for making very long-term forecasts. Theassumption of unitary income elasticity is the onlyreasonable choice if a single income elasticity must bechosen to describe import reactions to the growth ofincome over a long period of time. If the long-termmeasure consistently exceeds unity for a nation,imports would eventually consume the entire nationalincome.34 The assumption of an income-neutral modelis also a useful simplification for modelers. However,as stated above, income neutrality precludes thecomplete understanding of the consequences of tradeissues, because trade models featuring income neutraldemand will not replicate the recent historicalexperience of the interaction between trade andincome.

At present, the contradiction between the recentempirical evidence and the need to make trade modelsproduce long-term equilibrium solutions forcesmodelers to make difficult choices. Regarding theanalysis of trade liberalization agreements, the use ofincome-neutrality-based models facilitates theexploration of the effects of relative price changescaused by tariff cuts. It also allows the considerationof such effects over an undefined time horizon;however, this outcome is achieved only at the cost ofpotentially understating and distorting the effects ofrising incomes over more concrete forecast periods,such as 10 or 20 years.35

33 The assumption of income-neutrality is oftenimplicit rather than explicit in trade models. Thesimplifying assumptions of constant returns to scale inproduction and perfect competition in all goods and factormarkets can impose income-neutrality algebraically on themodel’s demand and supply systems. For further thoughtson this subject, see Lundback and Torstensson (1996).

34 In a dynamic general equilibrium framework,“long-term” reflects the period of time required for themodeled economy to regain its equilibrium following amajor simulated shock. That is, the long-term is notnecessarily 10 or 15 years.

35 For more on this subject, see Chapter 4 ondynamic general equilibrium models.

Page 66: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

3-25

Some progress is being made in combining theadvantages of income-neutral and income-sensitiveequation systems in trade models.36 Continuingresearch that underscores the significance of incomein shaping trade patterns serves as a constant reminderfor modelers to exploit further opportunities in thisarea.

Theoretical Work Related to theIncome Sensitivity of Trade

The significance of income levels in economicanalysis has long been established. Therefore, thebranch of literature in international trade thatemphasizes the role of income does not represent atheoretical breakthrough, but rather a completion ofmore general trade theories.37

The Prebisch-Singer hypothesisH. Singer (Singer (1950)) and R. Prebisch

(Prebisch (1959)) are credited with the first wellknown application of income-sensitivity in inter-national trade theory (Hunter and Markusen (1988)).Prebisch and Singer argued that the income elasticityfor primary products is expected to remainconsistently lower than the income elasticity formanufactured products. Consequently, the terms oftrade of developing countries that derive their export

36 The USITC uses multi-country computable generalequilibrium (CGE) models to analyze trade issues. Tovarying degrees, all of these models featureincome-sensitive systems. One group of models, whichincludes the Commission’s Latin American Regional(LAR) model, relies on a widely used flexible functionalform, called the “almost ideal demand system” (AIDS), tocalculate income elasticities. AIDS allows for a practicallyunlimited variation in income elasticities by country andcommodity group. (For an application of AIDS toestimating the world income elasticity of demand for U.S.machinery and equipment, see chapter 10.) The GlobalTrade Analysis Project (GTAP) model relies on theconcept of constant difference of elasticities (CDE) toapply income sensitivity. The CDE is a quasi-flexibleform that allows individual income elasticities to differfrom unity to a limited extent. Both the AIDS-based CGEmodels and the GTAP model can also be run withincome-neutral systems, thereby allowing for comparativeanalysis of the results. For a description of the LARmodel, see Benjamin and Pogany (1997) and for theGTAP model, see Hertel (1997). A promising newapproach to applying income-sensitivity to dynamic tradeanalysis was presented by Ho and Jorgenson at theUSITC’s 1997. APEC symposium (Ho and Jorgenson,1997)). The Ho and Jorgenson procedure combines theincome-sensitive approach with the logistic function toestablish upper bounds on market shares. For more ondynamic CGE models, see chapter 4.

37 For example, J. Torstensson expanded theHecksher-Ohlin theory, originally featuring income-neutralequations, with income-sensitive equations. SeeTorstensson (1993).

revenues mainly from the production of primaryproducts would deteriorate vis-à-vis the terms oftrade of the developed countries. In other words,the developing countries would have to give awayincreasingly larger amounts of their primary productsto obtain the same amount of manufactured productsfrom the developed countries. During the 1950s and1960s, the Prebisch-Singer hypothesis provided theintellectual justification for development policies thatemphasize import-substituting industrialization. Thistheory also claimed that the increased ability of thedeveloping countries to participate in the globalgrowth of demand for manufactured products wouldcompensate for the high costs of newindustrialization. The theory failed to correspond tothe realities of economic development (Spraos(1980)) and the policy of import substitution hasbeen largely discredited (Edwards (1993)).Nonetheless, the interaction between income andtrade emphasized by Singer and Prebischpermanently underscored the significance of incomelevels in shaping the pattern of international trade.

Linder’s representative demand theory

S. Linder’s representative demand theory (Linder(1961)) attributes a critical role to the per capitaincome in determining trade flows. According to thistheory, a country tends to export those products forwhich it has relatively large domestic markets or forwhich it expends relatively significant amounts ofresources on a per capita basis to satisfy domesticdemand.38 These products make up the country’s“representative demand;” reflecting its per capitaincome, its special needs and its resources, whichinclude the overall level of scientific andtechnological development.

The early development of the U.S. automobileindustry is an example of the mechanism behind therepresentative demand theory. Americans developed ataste for the personal automobile during the earlyyears of the twentieth century.39 The country’s percapita income level was high enough to permit theswitch from horses to the automobile on a large scale,and scientific-technological advances (industrialdevelopment, in general, and internal-combustionengineering, in particular) allowed for the massproduction of automobiles. Following Henry Ford’sintroduction of the assembly line in 1913, theproduction and ownership of automobiles soared inthe United States. From 123,990 automobiles

38 For a critical evaluation of the theory, see Weder(1996), and Lundback and Torstensson (1996).

39 For details about the early history of the U.S. auto-mobile industry, see Bloomfield (1978) and Encyclopediaof American Business History and Biography (1989).

Page 67: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

3-26

produced in 1909, production rose to 6.7 millionunits in 1919, making every sixteenth American anautomobile owner. The large domestic automobilemarket prepared U.S. firms to compete in worldmarkets, and the U.S. automobile industry soonestablished its global position.

Another example of the representative demandmechanism at work is the Swiss freight forwardingindustry. Given Switzerland’s varied topography andthe multilingual ethnic composition of its population,the country had to devote more resources per capita tothe development of its freight forwarding industrythan most other countries at the same level ofdevelopment. The efforts to satisfy domestic needsgave Swiss freight forwarders a comparativeadvantage in the international arena. Switzerland’sneighbors, Germany, France, and Italy, were the firstto recognize the advantages of using Swiss freightforwarders to conduct trade among themselves (Weder(1996)).

In essence, the representative demand theorycompletes theories based on differing nationalresource endowments by adding the idea of anendogenous technological development process. Thegrowth of per capita income is the critical conditionfor the emergence and satisfaction of specificdomestic needs and the development of comparativeadvantage in international trade.40

This theory inspired further theoreticaldevelopments such as Vernon’s “product cycle” theory(Vernon (1966)) and Porter’s concept of “competitiveadvantage of nations” (Porter (1990)). Thus, Linder’sideas presaged the contemporary “new internationaltrade theories” that identify endogenous relationsbetween trade and technological progress to explainintraindustry trade.

Markusen’s ModelIn 1986, J.R. Markusen showed that, in addition to

factor endowments and imperfect competition, theassumption of income sensitivity of demand in worldtrade is required to explain observed trade flows

40 Nonetheless, Linder emphasizes the necessity of thejoint occurrence of the factors cited in the development ofrepresentative demand. Regarding special domestic needas an underlying requirement, he mentions that it isunlikely that Eskimos will develop a comparativeadvantage in refrigeration technology, or that tropicalcountries will develop comparative advantage in theproduction of ice-breaker ships. He also points out that ahigh per capita income level does not necessarily imply ahigh level of scientific-technological development. Amodern example of this may be a developingoil-producing and oil-exporting country. Its high level ofper capita income is not matched with a high enoughlevel of scientific-technological development to turndemand for household electronics, for instance, intorepresentative demand.

(Markusen (1986)). In his theoretical model,Markusen divided the world into a relativelycapital-abundant North and a relativelylabor-abundant South. He further divided the Northinto East and West with identical endowments. Thefunctions in the model describing demand could beeither income-neutral or income-sensitive; and thefunctions describing supply allowed for variations inresource endowments and for multiple varieties ofeach product. Assuming income-neutral demand,Markusen derived the conditions for two benchmarkequilibria. In one equilibrium, the North and theSouth had identical resource endowments, and theoutcome was pure intraindustry trade. In the secondequilibrium, there is no product differentiation, andthe outcome was pure interindustry trade. “Mixed”trade in the model was generated by transferringcapital to the North and by allowing for productdifferentiation in the North, that is, between East andWest.

Markusen’s experiments demonstrated that underthe assumption of income-neutral preferences, thehistorical displacement of interindustry trade byintraindustry trade cannot be replicated. However, inthe experiment in which demand is characterized byincome-sensitive preferences, the Markusen resultsapproximate historical experience. Intraindustry tradegrows faster than interindustry trade and, thereby, theformer displaces the latter. Thus, income-sensitivedemand, which reflects differences in the level andcomposition of demand at various stages of economicdevelopment, is shown to play a crucial role inexplaining trade. Markusen’s conclusion is that boththe “classical” and the ”new international tradetheories,” which reflect mainly income-neutralpreferences, help determine the direction of trade, butthat income-sensitive demand functions are requiredto determine the volume of trade (Markusen (1986)).

Empirical Studies Related to theIncome Sensitivity of Trade

Since the late 1960s, considerable effort has beenexpended to estimate income elasticities ininternational trade. Most of the studies have dealtwith the industrialized countries because they havegenerally more extensive and accurate economic data,and are subject to fewer and smaller shocks affectingthe normal functioning of the market mechanism.41

Estimates of aggregate import demand andexport supply elasticities

Houthakker and Magee used ordinary leastsquares (OLS) on annual observations for the period

41 See more on this subject in chapter 10.

Page 68: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

3-27

1951-66, to regress the export and import marketshares of 27 countries on relative prices and GNP(Houthakker and Magee (1969)). They foundincome elasticities of import demand significantlydifferent from 1. For example, the income elasticityof imports for the period considered was 1.51 for theUnited States and 1.23 for Japan. The studyinspired both a lively professional debate and furthereconometric studies regarding the role of income indetermining trade flows.

The fundamental conclusion of the studiesconducted during the 1970s and 1980s was that fromthe late 1940s to the mid 1980s, the income elasticityof import demand and export supply for theindustrialized countries fell between 1 and 2. That is,imports were income elastic and income sensitivityprevailed in the trade among industrialized countries.The rise of imports (and exports) in the real GDP ofthe industrialized countries is a summary statistic thatsupports this general conclusion, but models usingincome-neutral equations would have predicted aconstant share of imports and exports. For a completesurvey of these studies, see Goldstein and Khan(1985).

The joint consideration of income elasticities toimport and to export served to analyze the forces thatdetermine differences in national trade performance.For example, the following tabulation shows theaverage income elasticities to import and to export forthe United States and Japan calculated by several ofthese studies for the first three decades of the postwarperiod:42

Average Averageincome incomeelasticity elasticityto import to export

United States 1.93 1.40. . . . . . . Japan 1.04 2.57. . . . . . . . . . . . . .

These elasticities reflect the tendencies underlyingthe buildup of U.S. trade deficits and Japanese tradesurpluses in later years.

A frequently used empirical relationship derivedfrom the joint analysis of income elasticities to importand to export is that, even if countries had equalpropensities to import and equal abilities to export,short and medium-run trade imbalances would stillpersist because countries grow at different rates.Therefore, since there is no mechanism to synchronizegrowth rates among the countries, trade imbalanceswill always persist; some countries will have surplusesand some will have deficits (Goldstein and Khan(1985)).

42 The averages presented are the arithmetic means ofthe appropriate estimates found in the literature surveyarticle of Goldstein and Khan (1985).

In 1996, J. Lundback and J. Tortsensson providedeconometric evidence that income sensitivity is animportant phenomenon under the conditions ofmonopolistic competition. Using annual data for themembers of the Organization for EconomicCooperation and Development (OECD), they showedthat increases in per capita income lead first to anincreased domestic supply of advanced industrialcommodities, and then to a net export in thesecommodities (Lundback and Tortsensson (1996)).43

This study econometrically confirmed Linder’s repre-sentative trade theory and Markusen’s proof.

Estimates of sectoral import demand andexport supply elasticities

Several studies dealt with income elasticities ofdemand for disaggregate import categories. Thesestudies generally showed the growing tendency ofindustrialized countries to shift their trade towardmanufactured goods. Taplin’s 1973 study, whichcovered the largest number of countries among studiesof this genre, showed the following income elasticitiesto import by commodity category: Food andbeverages (SITCs 0 and 1), 0.84; raw materials(SITCs 2 and 4), 0.75; fuels (SITC 3), 0.96; andmanufactures (SITCs 5, 6, 7, 8 and 9), 1.44 (Taplin(1973)). Hence, manufactures are income elastic,whereas basic foods and raw materials are incomeinelastic. For a survey of studies on sectoral elasticitycalculations until the mid-1980s, see Goldstein andKhan (1985).

In 1986, C. R. Shiells, R. M. Stern, and A. V.Deardorff used two-stage least squares on 1962-78data to estimate income elasticities of U.S. importdemand for 41 SIC 3-digit industries (Shiells, Stern,Deardorff (1986)). In 1988, L. C. Hunter and J. R.Markusen published an econometric study using thelinear expenditure system (LES) approach to estimateincome elasticities for 11 commodities in 34 countries,including several developing countries (Hunter andMarkusen (1988)). In 1993, using the “almost idealdemand system,” K. A. Reinert, D. W. Roland-Holst,and C. R. Shiells estimated income elasticities inNAFTA trade (Reinert, Roland-Holst, and Shiells(1993)).

Comparatively few estimates have been made onsectoral export elasticities, and many of theseestimates assumed away the influence of prices.44

43 The study actually used a sample of 12 OECDmembers, made up of the United States, Canada, Japan,Australia, and 8 EU countries.

44 “Despite over thirty years of econometric work ontrade equations,” wrote Goldstein and Khan in 1985, “itdoes not take a very large table to present a reasonablycomprehensive list of existing estimates of the price

Page 69: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

3-28

One study is that of W. Alterman at the U.S.Bureau of Labor Statistics. Table 3-4 shows selectedU.S. import and export elasticities of demand from theAlterman study. The elasticities of demand for U.S.exports with respect to global income are of particularinterest. Very high income elasticities, in the order of2 to 6, are observed for auto parts, several categoriesof industrial machinery and electronic goods, andceramics. As chapter 10 shows, these high elasticitiesare consistent with recent shifts in global trade andwith evidence of the transformation of consumptionpatterns in developing countries.45

Variability in estimates of incomeelasticities

Econometric work has produced a wide dispersionof income elasticity estimates, making thisphenomenon itself a subject of further investigation.For example, on the basis of 39 different studiespublished between 1946 and 1994, J. Marquez hasinvestigated the dispersion of income elasticityestimates for the United States, Canada, and Japan(Marquez (1995)). Income elasticities in these studiesranged from 0.7 to 2.6 for the United States, from 0.5to 2.0 for Canada, and from 0.4 to 1.7 for Japan.

Marquez identified two possible causes of thedispersion: methodological differences and differences

in the time periods considered. Furthermore, hedetermined that the differences in the periodsconsidered contributed more significantly to thedispersion of results than did the differences in themethodology employed. Since the income elasticitiesto import characterize the expenditure structure of agiven country for a given time period, this structure isbound to change as economies evolve and consumertastes and manufacturing technologies change. Inaddition to these secular factors, cyclical factors alsoinfluence spending patterns and income elasticities.These fundamentals preclude the possibility ofcalculating a single national income elasticity toimport, which then might be used to predict futuretrade flows based on forecasts of economic growth(Marquez (1993)).

44—Continuedelasticity of supply for export.” (Goldstein and Khan(1985)). This table also presents income elasticities ofsupply for the same categories, indicating an equalsparsity of income elasticities to export, since the twomeasures are computed by the same equations.

45 Preliminary estimates by J. Marquez of the Boardof Governors of the Federal Reserve System indicated thatduring 1975-93, the foreign income elasticity of U.S.exports may have been 3.0 for computers, and 1.0 forsemiconductors ( J. Marquez, Board of Governors of theFederal Reserve System, interview with USITC staff, Aug.4, 1997). The final results of the study on sectoral incomeelasticities conducted by Mr. Marquez will be publishedafter the completion of the present study.

Page 70: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

3-29

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Table 3-4Selected import and export elasticities of demand in U.S. industries, by SIC categories, 1980-91ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎSIC category

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎDescription

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Import elasticityof demand (1)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Exportelasticity ofdemandÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎ301ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎTires and inner tubes

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ0.719

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

21.620ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ307

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎMiscellaneous plastic products

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ1.258

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ 1.759ÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎ314ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎFootwear, except rubber

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ1.235

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

21.204ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

326ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Ceramic and china wareÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.800ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

5.518ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

331ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Rolling and finishing mill productsÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.770ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

2-0.111ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

333ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Smelter and refined nonferrous metalsÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.535ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

20.376ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

335ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Rolled, extruded nonferrous. metalsÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.107ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

4.123ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

342ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Cutlery, hand and edge tools, hardware, n.e.s.ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.853ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

20.991ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

349 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Fabricated metal products, n.e.s. ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.529 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

21.536ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

351 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Engines and turbines, and parts, n.e.s. ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.951 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

22.354ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

352 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Farm and garden machinery and equipment ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.241 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

6.435ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

353 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Construction, mining, oil-field equipment ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.326 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

5.233ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

354 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Metalworking machinery, equipment, parts ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.134 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

5.984ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

355 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Special industry machinery ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.165 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

4.715ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

356 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

General industrial machinery ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.111 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

2.275

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

357 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Office and computing machinery ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.971 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

3.920

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

358 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Refrigeration and service industry ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.492 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

3.076

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

361 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Electric distribution equipment ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.039 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

20.829

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

362 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Electrical industrial apparatus ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.199 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

2.190

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

363 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Household appliances and parts ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.542 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.822

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

364 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Electric lighting and wiring equipment ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.735 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

4.274

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

365 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Radio and TV receiving equipment ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.211 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

3.901

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

366 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Communication equipment ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.978 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

2.820

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

367 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Electronic components and accessories ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.230 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

2.824

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

369 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Electrical machinery, equipment, and supplies ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.868 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

21.422

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

3711 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Motor vehicles ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.386 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

22.006

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

3714 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Motor-vehicle parts and accessories ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.124 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

5.615

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

372 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Aircraft and parts, n.e.s. ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.972 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

20.875

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

382 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Measuring and controlling instruments ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.994 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

2.404

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

384 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Medical and dental instruments and supplies ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.467 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.607

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

386 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Photographic equipment and supplies ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.012 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

21.386

ÎÎÎÎÎ387 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎWatches, clocks ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ1.561 ÎÎÎÎÎÎ 5.049ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ391

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎJewelry, silverware, and plated ware

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ1.482

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

24.471ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ394

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎToys and sporting goods

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ1.683

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ -5.886

1 All estimates were significant at least at the 15-percent level.2 The estimate was not significant at the 15 percent level.

Source: Alterman, 1995.

Page 71: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted
Page 72: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

4-1

CHAPTER 4Dynamic Modeling of Trade Liberalization

Dynamic GeneralEquilibrium Models

As noted in the request letter from USTR, the useof computable general equilibrium (CGE) models tosimulate the effects of trade policies has increasedrapidly and forms part of the body of literature on thepotential dynamic gains from trade. Since CGEmodels can simultaneously take into accountinteractions among economic agents (consumers andproducers), sectors, and macroeconomic variables,assessments made with them are more detailed andcomprehensive than those made through othermethods.1 Multi-country CGE models are especiallysuitable for analyzing trade issues in a regional orglobal context.

CGE models can be static or dynamic. Thedifference is that dynamic CGE (DCGE) models takeinto consideration changes that ensue with the passageof time. Some of these models can calculate thelength of time required for an economy to go from theequilibrium that preceded the implementation of anew trade policy to the one that would follow it(free-terminal-time approach). Or they may be usedto explore economic developments during a fixed,hypothetically specified transition period followingthe implementation of the new policy(fixed-terminal-time approach).2

Although the advantages of DCGE models arewidely recognized, and their application is spreading,at this writing they have not replaced static CGEmodels as the dominant tools of trade policy analysis.In fact, comparisons with post-simulation data havedemonstrated that static models are quite effective inassessing the impact of policy changes over relativelyshort time horizons.3

1 For an introduction to CGE models for the generalreader, see Pogany (1996).

2 Since both the free- and fixed-terminal-timeexperiments explore alternative time paths of economicvariables, they both may be regarded as exercises incomparative dynamics, or sensitivity analysis with respectto time.

3 For example, Kehoe, Polo, and Sancho showed thata static CGE model predicted most of the price changesthat occurred in Spain as a result of the country’s 1986tax reform. The analysis was particularly difficult because

Specific Reasons for UsingDynamic Models

DCGE models have considerable advantages overstatic models when the time horizon is relatively longor when the economy examined is expected toundergo quantitatively important changes before itabsorbs the effects of a new policy. The followingspecific reasons recommend the use of DCGE modelsin studying the dynamic effects of trade:

(1) They can more fully represent behaviorthat is fundamentally dependent on time such asthe decisions to save or invest in the interest offuture returns . Not taking into account transitional-period savings induced by trade liberalization tends tounderstate capital accumulation, cross-country capitalmovement, technological progress, and economicgrowth incidental to trade liberalization.4

(2) They reveal more of the distortionaryinfluences that are inherent in effective tariffstructures before the implementation of a tradeliberalization agreement. Consequently, the mea-sured welfare effects of the removal of the distortionswill also be more complete (Young and Romero,1994).

(3) Empirical research provides robustevidence that trade liberalization can have a majorimpact on economic development, thereby vali-dating the quantitatively important results thatDCGE models, along with other dynamic modelsequipped with endogenous-growth-generatingcapabilities, tend to produce.5 Although economists

3—Continuedthe tax reform was incidental to Spain’s entry into theEU, an event that brought many significant changes in thecountry’s economy (Kehoe, Polo, and Sancho, 1991).From a theoretical point of view, the good predictiveperformance of static models is not surprising, sinceresults obtained from static models are expected to reflectthe longer-run tendencies of dynamic processes in aneconomy (Hanson, 1970).

4 For an appraisal of transitional effects in tradepolicy analysis, see Francois and Shiells (1994).

5 For examples, see Bayoumi, Coe, and Helpman(1996) and Kehoe (1994).

Page 73: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

4-2

have been aware of the advantages of the DCGE forsome time, models to realize its potential advantagesin the analysis of trade liberalization have emergedonly recently.

Classification of DynamicGeneral Equilibrium

ModelsDCGE models can be classified in several ways.

One main criterion of classification is whether theoptimization involves one or several periods at a time.Models that compute equilibrium solutions one periodat a time are characterized as “sequential solution” or“recursive” models. Those that optimize over severalperiods at once are characterized as “fully dynamic”or “multi-period” models. Sequential models arestatic CGE models adapted to generate steady statesolutions for consecutive periods. Fully dynamicmodels incorporate time as a variable.6

Each approach has its advantages. Data,behavioral parameters, and even computationalmethods used by sequential solution DCGE modelscan be updated before running them for the nextperiod. This permits the incorporation of informationobtained from alternative sources of research, therebyimparting flexibility in making these models “forwardlooking”. Using such a sequential solution approach,the model designed by Hinojosa, Lewis, andRobinson captures some of the potential dynamicgains from trade liberalization (Hinojosa, Lewis, andRobinson, 1995). In their simulations of WesternHemisphere trade liberalization, the incorporation ofthe dynamic increases in productivity leads todramatic improvements in welfare gains, though theauthors emphasize the need for empirical estimationof the importance of such externalities. Empiricaltests by Devarajan and Zou (1996); Lee (1995);Baldwin and Seghazza (1996); and Esfahani (1991)revealed the critical role of foreign capital goodsimports in the growth of developing countries.Benjamin and Pogany (1997) used a trade externalityof this type in a sequential solution simulation ofproposed Western Hemisphere trade agreements.Over four time periods, welfare gains from tradeliberalization increased from 0.2 to 1.0 percent ofGDP over the case where no externality was used.

In contrast to sequential solution models, fullydynamic models are “deterministic”. One of the

6 For an introduction to fully dynamic models, see(Devarajan and Go, 1995). The study explains thestructure and working mechanism, and demonstrates theuse of the simplest, fully dynamic model designed toanalyze international trade issues.

conditions for yielding steady state results is that theeconomy remain on its long-term equilibrium pathacross the time horizon of optimization. As aconsequence, fully dynamic models algebraicallyimpose the rigidities of optimizing behavior andpredetermined rates of time preferences on producersand consumers in each period and across theeconomies composing the models.7 The validity ofsuch theoretical simplifications is strongly disputedin the empirical literature.8 However, fully dynamicmodels account for transitional changes with agreater regularity and completeness than dosequential models. They produce more consistentresults in policy simulations involving the long run(that is, at least 10 years). Sequential DCGE modelshave the advantage that they can be built on existingstatic CGE platforms.9 Building fully dynamicmodels requires a fresh start, because these modelsmust incorporate techniques of dynamicoptimization.10

Calibration of DynamicCGE Models

The usefulness of CGE models in conductingsimulations of the impact of policy changes isenhanced if the models can be shown to replicateknown outcomes from the recent past. In particular,models that portray developments over time need toaccommodate features identified in chapter 10 such as

7 For details, see (Dervis, de Melo, and Robinson,1982) and (Ethier, Helpman, and Neary, 1995).

8 For an analysis of intertemporal choices in thetheory of consumer behavior, see (Deaton and Muellbauer,1986).

9 Examples of building dynamics into static modelsare the USITC’s Latin American Regional Model(Benjamin and Pogany, 1997); and the one used at theFederal Reserve Bank of Chicago, which built a dynamic,one-sector (macro) international real business cycle modelon a static CGE platform (Kouparitsas, 1997).

10 Three such techniques have evolved, providing abasis for classification of fully dynamic models. Theoldest one, called calculus of variation, dates back to the18th century discoveries of mathematician L. Euler (1707-1783). Dynamic programming, based on the principle ofoptimality, the so-called Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation, was developed during the 1950s.Dynamic optimization based on the so-called maximumprinciple emerged in the early 1960s and is associatedwith L.S. Pontryagin. The maximum principle isgenerally used in conjunction with the Hamiltonian systemof functions, which is a method of solving nonlineardifferential equations. For details, see (Leonard and Long,1992) and (Takayama, 1994). The calculus of variationand the maximum principle are compatible, since bothare calculus-based. The two are often combined inmodels. Some newer models also incorporate gametheoretic methods, such as the Markov decision processes,in dynamic optimization techniques. For a survey ofapplications of the theory of games in general equilibriummodeling, see (Mertens and Sorin, 1994).

Page 74: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

4-3

the rising share of trade in total income and therising share of certain commodities in householdconsumption. Various approaches have been used totrack recent history in recursive CGE models,beginning with single-country models. Chenery,Lewis, de Melo, and Robinson (1986) use asingle-country model to replicate the developmentpatterns of several medium-income countries from1963 to 1983. Using empirical evaluations ofexpenditure shares known as Chenery curves (alsodiscussed in detail in chapter 10), they imposeobserved dynamic trends in these shares so thatincome elasticities by commodity remain one duringeach solution but differ from one over time. Theyalso construct exogenous series for other parameters,including changes in input-output coefficients, and arange of assumptions on the inflow of foreigncapital, and the growth of total factor productivityby sector. They further build in responses for themigration of labor across regional and skillcategories and the allocation of capital acrosssectors, and allow for the growing substitutability ofdomestic and foreign goods by making tradeelasticities greater in the long run than in the shortrun. By specifying these trends they are able totrack fairly well the structure of the sources ofgrowth by forms of domestic and foreign demandand by sector.

Mitra (1994) reports on the results of severalexercises using recursive CGE models to track thehistory of various developing countries. In thesecases, the historical values of several aggregatetracking variables, such as GDP, private consumption,exports, imports, and foreign savings are included inthe exercise while certain model parameters, such assectoral factor productivity and household savingsrates, are allowed to vary. The tracking performanceis then “optimized” by finding the parameter valuesthat minimize the sum of the squared deviationsbetween the model-generated values and the actualones. The results indicate a rather close trackingrecord across the different countries.

An important step in tracking history with CGEmodels was taken by Gehlhar (1996) who conducted atracking exercise with a global multi-country model.He alters the Global Trade Analysis Project (GTAP)model by distinguishing a productive factorrepresenting human capital. By making exogenousreductions in the values of all primary factors, he“backcasts” the model from 1992 to 1982 and thenmeasures the model outcomes for export shares bycountry against the actual 1982 values. To close thegap between model and actual outcomes he finds thespecification of the human capital factor a necessaryadjustment, along with doubling trade elasticities from

levels already well above empirical estimates. Thetracking exercise is encouraging, but even with thenoted adjustments he finds that the modelsystematically underpredicts changes in export sharesfor the countries in the study. This is not surprisinggiven the rapidly growing share of trade in incomeover the period, and given the large number ofparameters used to improve tracking in thesingle-country examples. Further, the GTAP exerciseprojects back to a single distant year, whereas theexamples noted above use data for a number ofintervening years to aid in tracking the pattern ofdevelopments over time.

In the category of fully dynamic optimizingmodels, the work by Ho and Jorgenson (1997)illustrates a major modeling effort to track actualoutcomes. Theirs is an open-economy model of theU.S. that is completely econometrically specified.This means they use econometric tests based on datafrom 1947 to 1985 to develop behavioral equationsfor the model that fit the actual behavior over theperiod. In discussing the difficulties of modelingtrade over time, Ho and Jorgenson note the sharpacceleration of trade as a share of U.S. income, aswell as the lack of any convergence to a particularlevel yet apparent in the data. This lack of stability inthe relationship leads them to model trade shares as afunction of time, using a logistic trend. They alsonote empirical evidence on the disproportional relationbetween growth in income and growth in theconsumption of particular goods, as is shown in thework on Chenery curves in chapter 10. They observethat, given this empirical evidence, assuming anincome elasticity of one for the components ofconsumption renders a model unsuitable forbackcasting and would bias sectoral projections of theeconomy. Hence, their econometric approach.

Thus a number of techniques have been developedto improve the fit between model results and actualoutcomes. Given the variety of objectives inmodeling exercises, historical tracking is seldomundertaken in structural CGE models and notechnique has become standard. A close fit indicatesthat conditions present in the model reflect actualconditions across many dimensions, and this allows amore refined interpretation of trade policysimulations. Such detailed interpretations becomeimportant in attempts to model growth and to capturethe essential features governing the relation betweentrade and growth. Empirical evidence on some ofthese important interactions have been identified inthis study. Nevertheless, there are notable challengesin calibrating dynamic models for the analysis of tradeand growth. These difficulties need to be taken into

Page 75: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

4-4

account when analyzing model results and theinfluence that model assumptions have upon them.

Dynamic Models in theStudy of TradeLiberalization

The literature on DCGE-based assessments oftrade liberalization began in the early 1990s.Goulder, Eichenberg, Jorgenson, and Ho pioneered thefield by developing intertemporal models withforward-looking savings and investment behavior toanalyze trade policy alternatives. For details, seeGoulder and Eichenberg (1992), and Jorgensen andHo (1993). Moreover, Baldwin performedmulti-sectoral, dynamic analysis to address issues ofcapital movements and accumulation in the context ofEuropean integration (1990-1993).11 Keuschnigg andKohler made a significant contribution by includingimperfect competition in DCGE models. For details,see, Keuschnigg and Kohler (1994).

Despite these achievements, attempts to useDCGE models to assess the consequences of tradeliberalization remained limited. Harrison,Rutherford, and Tarr complained with reason in 1995:“While the dynamic effects of trade liberalization andthe Uruguay Round are often described, they arerarely estimated”.12 However, the recentdevelopments in trade policy modeling are signs ofnoteworthy progress in this domain. The followingdiscussion summarizes these developments and pointsout the advantages of using the dynamic instead of thestatic approach.

Dynamic modeling of trade liberalization oftenemphasizes the role of capital markets and investment,since this is the most essentially time-sensitivebehavior and is lacking from static models. Forexample, in their dynamic U.S. model Ho andJorgenson (1997 and 1994) estimate that global tariffremoval would lead to a real U.S. consumption gainof 0.16 percent in the first year, but a 0.82 percentgain in the long run. The important feature leading tohigher long run gains is that trade liberalization bringsdown the price of capital goods, leading to highergrowth of investment, output and consumption.

The Economic Research Service (ERS) of theU.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA) developed amodel to analyze the consequences of a possible tradeagreement between the United States and the

11 For Baldwin’s contributions in this domain, seereferences in Keuschnigg and Kohler (1994).

12 Harrison, Rutherford, and Tarr in Martin andWinters (1995) p. 233.

MERCOSUR.13 Using the data base of the GlobalTrade Analysis Project (GTAP), the ERS model hasfour commodity sectors: products of agriculture andfood processing, minerals and materials,manufactured goods, and services. By creating aresidual geographic aggregate (“the rest of theworld”), the model allows for an analysis ofU.S.-MERCOSUR trade and other economicinteractions in a global numerical framework. Inaddition to showing that the elimination of tariffsbetween the United States and the MERCOSURwould significantly benefit U.S.-MERCOSUR trade,ERS compared the results generated by the staticand dynamic modeling approaches. By takingeconomic developments over time into account, theeffects of tariff reductions on sectoral output underthe dynamic approach consistently exceeded thestatic effects in all four model sectors, both in theUnited States and the MERCOSUR.14 The dynamicversion also allowed for calculations that could notbe performed under the static version. For example,the study indicated that a complete elimination oftariffs between the United States and theMERCOSUR would lead to an increase in the shareof manufactured products among U.S. exports to theMERCOSUR from 49.33 percent in the base year to55.89 percent after an adjustment period. For detailson this ERS project, see Diao and Somwaru (1996).

Kouparitsas (Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago)investigated the distribution of welfare gains arisingfrom NAFTA. The study showed that adjustment tothe trade agreement in the economies of the membercountries will be virtually complete by 2004, the dateof complete implementation. The study compared itsown estimates of post-implementation steady stategrowth rates with estimates derived by various staticCGE models. These comparisons indicate that staticmodels understate the economic growth enhancingeffects of the agreement for all three countries,especially for Mexico (Kouparitsas, 1997).

McKibbin (Australian National University and theBrookings Institution) quantified the impact of trade

13 The Southern Common Market (MERCOSUR)includes Argentina, Brazil, Paraguay, and Uruguay. It isthe second largest trading bloc after NAFTA in theWestern Hemisphere. For a description of MERCOSUR,see Rivera, A.S., “After NAFTA: Western HemisphereTrade Liberalization and Alternative Paths to Integration,”The Social Science Journal, vol. 32, no. 4, pp. 389-407,October 1995.

14 For example, based on the assumption that alltariffs were eliminated in both the United States andMERCOSUR, the annual rates of sectoral growth in theUnited States under the dynamic system, with ratesgenerated under the static system shown in parentheses,were as follows: products of agriculture and foodprocessing, 2.19 (0.54); minerals and materials, 1.23(0.40); manufactured goods, 2.25 (0.99), and services,0.97 (-0.22).

Page 76: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

4-5

liberalization under the Asia-Pacific EconomicCooperation (APEC)15 regional grouping (McKibbin,1996 and 1997). The analysis revealed that benefitsfrom trade liberalization may accrue even before it isimplemented, by generating an increase in the globalcapital stock (McKibbin, 1997). It alsodemonstrated that the package and timing ofmacroeconomic policies that coincide with theintroduction of trade liberalization play vital roles inthe overall growth and welfare enhancing impact ofan agreement.

Related ApplicationsDCGE models have been used to analyze many

different aspects of international trade and its dynamicinteraction with economic growth. At U.S.Government organizations, Benjamin (USITC)

15 For a description of the Asia-Pacific EconomicCooperation (APEC), see The Year in Trade: OTAP 1993,USITC, no. 2769.

analyzed the effects of real devaluation oninvestment in selected developing countries, takinginto consideration the unequal intensity of capital inthe various producing sectors (Benjamin, 1996A).Tseng (U.S. Department of Energy) studied therelationship between economic growth andenvironmental issues (Tseng, 1996). At multilateralorganizations, Devarajan and Zou (The World Bank)researched the role of increased exports in economicdevelopment (Devarajan and Zou, 1996), and Petri(OECD) researched the relationship between tradepolicies and direct foreign investment (Petri, 1997).At academic organizations, Mercenier (University ofMontreal) explored the role of trade and investmentin the structural changes of heavily-indebteddeveloping economies (Mercenier, 1997); andBagnoli (The Brookings Institution), McKibbin(Australian National University and The BrookingsInstitution), and Wilcoxen (University of Texas)explored global economic prospects and structuralchanges (Bagnoli, McKibbin, and Wilcoxen, 1996).

Page 77: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted
Page 78: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

PART II Critical Assessment of Literature and

Empirical Explorations

Page 79: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted
Page 80: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

5-1

CHAPTER 5Critical Assessment and Summary of

Empirical ExtensionsIntroduction

This chapter provides a critical assessment of theliterature surveyed in Part I, summarizing theprincipal conclusions of practical value topolicymakers and discussing the limitations ofexisting work. It is not within the scope of thecurrent investigation, nor is it practically feasible, toundertake new empirical research that woulddefinitively settle the outstanding issues surroundingthe dynamic effects of trade liberalization.Nonetheless, the USITC has identified certain areas inwhich an examination of the evidence may yieldinsights beyond those currently available in theexisting literature. The results of those empiricalexplorations are briefly summarized in this chapter,and presented in full detail in chapters 6 through 10.

While many theoretical arguments have beenadvanced for a linkage between trade liberalizationand economic growth, the available empiricalevidence on this relationship is relativelyinconclusive. This is due both to the likelihood thatthe growth effects of trade liberalization are relativelysmall compared with other determinants of economicgrowth, and to the fact that the concept of “openness”is difficult to quantify objectively. The USITC’scritical analysis of the available literature indicatesthat attempts to identify trade liberalization’s indirectimpact on economic growth, through its influence onthe primary determinants of economic growth, offerrelatively good prospects of uncovering new evidenceof the relationship between trade and growth. Suchattempts are a primary focus of the empiricalexplorations in part II.

Lessons of the GeneralLiterature on Economic

Growth

Conditions Under WhichGrowth Takes Place

It is well established, both theoretically andempirically, that the presence or absence of certain

conditions strongly influence the long-run rate ofeconomic growth in a given country. Theseconditions include the following:

� A high rate of investment in physical capital,including investment in machinery, equipment,and structures. While some portion of thisinvestment may be financed by foreigners,through either direct or portfolio investment, inpractice the bulk of domestic capital investmentmust be financed by domestic savings, whichimplies that a high rate of savings is an essentialfeature of economic growth.

� A high rate of investment in human capital, i.e.,in the productive abilities of individualworkers. The formation of human capitalincludes formal education, on-the-jobexperience, training, and, particularly indeveloping countries, some aspects of bodilyhealth.

� A relatively rapid rate of technologicalprogress, including the invention of newproducts and processes, the application ofrecently invented products and processes to awider range of economic activity, and theconservation of resources in the productionprocess. The level of formal R&D activities isan important determinant of the rate of nationaltechnological change, though such activities areby no means the exclusive vehicle by whichtechnological progress takes place.

� A pattern of institutions and incentives whichencourages the accumulation of physical andhuman capital, and rewards technologicalprogress. At its most basic level, this includesthe establishment of the rule of law (includingthe enforceability of business contracts) inplace of autocratic or bureaucratic whim, andthe protection within law of well-definedprivate property rights, including rights tointellectual property as well as physicalproperty. In a country in which the rule of lawand private property rights are already wellestablished, fiscal decisions are the mainchannel through which government policy canaffect the rates of physical and human capitalaccumulation and the rate of technologicalprogress.

Page 81: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

5-2

This (not necessarily exhaustive) list of theprincipal determinants of economic growth isconsidered uncontroversial. For the present purpose,it is important to recognize that the strength of manykey determinants of economic growth is influencedprimarily by factors other than trade liberalization.The rate of savings, for example, is strongly affectedby the age structure of the population and the localavailability of a variety of financial assets. Decisionsabout the schooling of children, especially girls, areheavily influenced by social and cultural factors.Countries may attract foreign investment simplybecause they are well endowed with natural resources.Civil wars and insurrections may cripple a country’sability to establish the rule of law or effective privateproperty rights. Such circumstances, often having adramatic effect on national living standards andgrowth in living standards, are largely unaffected bytrade policy.

Endogenous GrowthThe debate between theoretical models of the

economy exhibiting either “neoclassical” or“endogenous” growth appears to say much about thepotential usefulness of trade policy in enhancinggrowth. But on closer inspection, the practicalcontent of this debate for policymakers is lessdramatic. In endogenous growth models, anyimprovement in economic efficiency translates into apermanent increase in the rate of economic growth. Ifthese models are superior reflections of reality, theyimply that those advocating efficiency-enhancingpolicies (such as trade liberalization) are justified inattributing to these policies the compound-interesteffects of higher growth rates, and thus a bigger “bangfor the buck.” But as the review in part I makes clear,the empirical evidence on the relative merits ofendogenous versus neoclassical growth models is atbest inconclusive. In addition, neoclassical modelsadmit the possibility that a sufficiently large tradeliberalization may induce enough economic growth,for a long enough period of time, to be of interest topolicymakers.

Critique of the EmpiricalLiterature on Trade and

Growth

Direct Tests of theTrade-Growth Relationship

Part I reviewed some of the numerous efforts toinclude measures of trade, or trade liberalization, in

statistical attempts to explain why some countriesgrow faster than others. Most such efforts haveyielded weak or inconclusive results. Many of theoutstanding exceptions have employed a measure ofopenness devised by Sachs and Warner (1995), whichis highly correlated with growth.

The relatively weak performance of moststatistical attempts to demonstrate that greatereconomic growth is induced by larger trade flows, ormore liberal trade policies, has several sources. First,many of the most significant determinants ofeconomic growth may be unrelated to trade policy, asdiscussed above. In addition, the degree of“openness” or trade liberalization in a nationaleconomy has proved difficult to measure objectively.As discussed in chapter 3, countries which arerelatively “open” according to some statisticalmeasures appear relatively “closed” according toothers, and no single statistical measure captures in avery sensitive way all of the practical differencesbetween trade policies.

Although the Sachs-Warner measure of opennessdiscussed above is strongly correlated with economicgrowth, it is fairly imprecise as a measure ofliberalization. It categorizes a country at a point intime as absolutely “open” or “closed,” usingindicators that capture many policy decisionscountries make beyond trade policy. It makes nodistinction, for example, between the degree of“openness” of the United States, the Republic ofKorea, and India in the mid-1990s. While theSachs-Warner measure captures the effect of suchradical reforms in economic policy as the fall ofCommunism or the Latin American response to the1980s debt crisis, it is relatively unhelpful inassessing the impact of the smaller practical stepstoward liberalization which are the everyday topic oftrade policy discussions.

Indirect Linkages BetweenTrade and Growth

The literature review in chapter 3 uncovered somerelatively strong evidence for higher rates of capitalinvestment in more open economies. Since the rate ofinvestment is perhaps the leading determinant of therate of economic growth, the linkage of openness togrowth through the channel of higher investmentoffers a likely prospect for generating new evidenceof the effects of trade liberalization on the rate ofeconomic growth. National investment may befinanced either through national savings, or fromabroad through the importation of capital (foreigninvestment). National savings is by far the largestcomponent of national investment, but the relationship

Page 82: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

5-3

between openness and national savings has beenrelatively unstudied empirically. In extension of thisdiscussion, chapter 6 is devoted to an empiricalexploration of the relationship between openness andnational savings.

Chapter 3 also discussed some relatively recentstudies of the effect of foreign-funded investment(particularly direct investment) on economic growth.Evidence is accumulating that the growth effects offoreign direct investment exceed the growth effects ofan equivalent value of domestic investment. Thisresult is generally attributed to the superiortechnological capabilities of multinational firms.Flows of direct investment respond both to tradeliberalization and to direct liberalization of foreigndirect investment. The response of direct investmentto trade liberalization is particularly complex, sincedirect investment is often functionally linked to flowsof merchandise trade but can also act as a substitutefor trade flows. In a related discussion, chapter 7explores the response of direct investment to bothinvestment liberalization and trade liberalization,using recent data on U.S. direct investment abroad.

Chapter 3 also reviews the empirical literature onthe relationship between trade and technologicalchange. It has been argued that increased importspromote technical efficiency, by increasingcompetitive pressure on less efficient firms. It hasalso been argued that the acts of exporting andimporting themselves serve as a conduit forcross-border flows of technological information, byexposing firms to information about world marketsand to the technological knowledge of their customersand/or suppliers. Finally, technologies are purchasedand sold directly across borders, and the extent ofthese purchases is influenced by the degree ofintellectual property protection granted to foreigners.While some researchers have generated evidence forpositive linkages between trade and technologicaladvance, others have failed to find such linkages.Chapter 8 analyzes data on trade flows, tariffs, andmanufacturing productivity in OECD countries insearch of new evidence on this topic.

Human capital formation is also an importantdeterminant of economic growth, as discussed above.Many of the circumstances giving rise to incentivesfor physical capital formation can also promotehuman capital formation. Trade liberalization tends toincrease the rewards to human capital, both byincreasing the purchasing power of householdincomes and by enhancing the global marketability ofgoods and services produced using human capital.The available empirical research on linkages betweentrade and human capital is limited. In an attempt toaddress this gap, chapter 9 examines evidence on

openness, human capital accumulation, and growth fora cross-section of countries.

Finally, chapter 3 examined some of the evidencethat growth in global trade has outpaced growth inglobal incomes in recent decades, and that trade hasshifted significantly among categories of goods. Whilethis disproportionate growth is frequently attributed topostwar trade liberalization, a significant part ofrecent trade growth appears linked to the special roleof traded goods in the demand of consumers withgrowing incomes. The understatement, in manyanalyses, of the demand-side linkage from growth totrade leads to a potential understatement of the gainsfrom trade liberalization, though the precisemechanism through which such gains operate is notyet clearly understood. In a further assessment of themagnitude and distribution of this effect, chapter 10examines evidence on the sensitivity of internationaltrade to economic growth at the global level, thenational level, and for particular industries.

Chapter 4 looked at the performance of recentattempts to simulate global economic growth and thegrowth consequences of trade liberalization, by meansof dynamic computable-general-equilibrium (DCGE)models. DCGE modeling of trade liberalization is stillin its relative infancy, but shows promise as a tool forexamining the potential interactions between trade andeconomic growth. Some results from economists’current investigation of the process of economicgrowth, and of the relationships between trade andgrowth, have been incorporated in CGE models.Recursive models in particular have included elementsof productivity growth and the growth of labor skills.Some have focused on the international aspects ofthese factors, but have pointed out the gap betweenempirical evidence and the formulations used insimulation models. The principal focus of fullydynamic simulation models has been to incorporatethe dynamic behavior governing physical capitalaccumulation. Some initial attempts have been madeto capture the peculiarities of foreign directinvestment (Petri (1997)), but the question of howbest to model FDI remains open. Similarly, others(Chenery et al., (1986) and Ho and Jorgenson (1997))have attempted to include the historical tendencies oftrade to grow faster than income, and for trade andconsumption to shift among sectors as income rises(as discussed in chapters 3 and 10). Nevertheless, anumber of difficulties remain in reconciling empiricalevidence on trade and growth with dynamic modelformulations that track recent history to a satisfactorydegree and capture the relevant interactions in a fullydynamic solution. This poses important unresolvedproblems for attempts of DCGE modelers to provideplausible forward-looking projections of trade growthand income growth simultaneously.

Page 83: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

5-4

Summary of the Results ofEmpirical Explorations

Empirical analysis was conducted to determine theimpact of trade, and its liberalization, on variousprincipal causes of economic growth, includinginvestment, technological change, and human capitalformation. The linkage between trade and investmentwas studied in separate examinations of trade anddomestic savings (since domestic savings is theprimary means of financing investment in mostcountries) and trade and foreign direct investment(since FDI is particularly linked to trade and mayhave additional benefits for economic growth).Empirical analysis was also conducted on thetendencies or international trade to grow faster thanincome and of the composition of consumption andtrade to evolve over time.

These empirical analyses took into accountvariables other than trade, and its liberalization, whichare relevant for each stage of the analysis, such as therole of R&D spending in the relationship betweentrade and technological change, and the role ofrelative prices in the relationship between incomegrowth and trade growth.

The results of each of these econometricinvestigations may be relevant to dynamic simulationsof the impact of trade liberalization in growingeconomies. These include, in particular, the findingsthat more open trade and FDI policies are linked togreater FDI flows; the possibility of an associationbetween trade liberalization and more rapidproductivity growth in manufacturing; a potentialpositive effect of liberalization on labor force growth,operating through the female labor force participationrate; and the feedback relationships between economicgrowth and the volume and structure of internationaltrade and global consumption. Each of theserelationships can be potentially exploited in dynamicmodels and would tend to give higher estimates of thegains from trade liberalization.

The results of the Commission’s empiricalexplorations are contained in chapters 6 through 10and are summarized below.

Savings and TradeLiberalization

Chapter 6 examines the determinants of the rate ofdomestic savings for a large sample of countries overthe period 1970-95. The determinants of savingsinclude the level of per capita GDP, the rate of realeconomic growth, and the dependency ratio (definedas the ratio of persons under age 15 to theworking-age population). Openness is measured both

by the ratio of trade to GDP and by the number ofyears during which the country was open according tothe Sachs-Warner index, accumulated over five-yearperiods. The analysis confirms that higher-incomecountries save a higher percentage of their income, asdo more rapidly-growing countries. The effect ofhigh dependency ratios in depressing the savings rateis most clearly observed for rapidly-growingcountries.

The analysis leans weakly in the direction of apositive correlation between openness and the savingsrate. This correlation is not completely robust.Whether openness is measured by the share of trade inGDP or by the Sachs-Warner index, the ability to finda positive correlation between openness and savingsdepends on the group of countries being analyzed andthe manner in which the other determinants of savingsare introduced. The effect of openness appears tovary with the rate of economic growth. For morerapidly-growing countries, a high openness ratingaccording to the Sachs-Warner index appears topromote a higher savings rate, while openness andeconomic growth may have a weak negativecorrelation for slow-growing countries.

U.S. Direct Investment Abroad,Trade Liberalization, and FDILiberalization

Chapter 7 analyzes the stock of U.S. directinvestment abroad in 1993, both in the aggregate andby broad industrial groupings. Differences amongvarious potential locations for U.S. FDI in terms ofthe host country’s openness to trade and, separately,openness to direct investment, are quantified using asurvey of executives reported in the WorldCompetitiveness Report. Potential determinants ofFDI examined include host country GDP, the rate ofinflation, wages paid by U.S. multinationals indifferent countries, historical profitability levels ofaffiliates, and distance between the United States andthe host country. The analysis confirms that U.S. FDIis concentrated in countries with large economies andin countries geographically closer to the United States.

U.S. direct investment abroad is more stronglyattracted to countries with both open FDI policies andopen trade policies. The strength of the measuredFDI effect is surprisingly large. The effect of opentrade policies in stimulating FDI suggests that tradeand FDI tend on balance to be complementary. Opentrade policies appear to be attractive for U.S. directinvestments in manufacturing and services, but haveno discernible impact for U.S. FDI in the petroleumindustry. However, U.S. investors are stronglyattracted to open FDI policies in all industriesexamined.

Page 84: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

5-5

Technological Progress inOECD Manufacturing andTrade Liberalization

Chapter 8 examines the determinants of growth inmanufacturing productivity for a sample of thirteenOECD countries and eighteen manufacturing sectorsduring 1980-91. A number of alternate productivitygrowth measures are analyzed. The average tariff ineach manufacturing sector during the late 1980s isused as a measure of trade policy. The ratio ofexports to output and the ratio of imports to apparentconsumption are used as measures of trade flows.The analysis considers the impact on productivitygrowth of research effort in each country and industry,as well as the tendency within sectors oflow-productivity countries to converge in productivityto the countries with high levels of productivity.Analysis confirms that low-productivity industries inthe OECD, relative to similar industries in othercountries, experience more rapid productivity gainsand that a stronger research effort is associated withgreater productivity gains.

High-tariff sectors tend to have low productivitygrowth, while low-tariff sectors tend to have highproductivity growth. The negative correlation betweentariffs and productivity observed in the raw data isbroadly confirmed in the econometric analysis, but isstatistically significant only for some measures ofproductivity. A positive association between exportperformance and productivity growth appears to besomewhat stronger. There is no observable relation-ship in the data analyzed between import penetrationand productivity growth. Chapter 8 includes adiscussion of the extent to which causation fromproductivity to trade, or from trade to productivity,may account for the observed relationships.

Trade, Human CapitalAccumulation, and Labor ForceGrowth

Chapter 9 examines, the linkage between humancapital as measured by secondary school enrollmentrates, the rate of urbanization, and the proportion ofthe labor force which is female and openness asmeasured by the Sachs-Warner index and the ratio oftotal trade to GDP. The analysis takes into accountthe level of per capita income and the dependencyratio. High-income countries tend to have higher ratesof urbanization and secondary school enrollment,while countries with a high ratio of children toworking-age adults tend to have lower rates of both

secondary school enrollment and female labor forceparticipation.

The female labor force proportion is positivelyassociated with openness after taking account ofincome and the dependency ratio, regardless of whichmeasure of openness is used. This suggests that aseconomies become more open to international trade,the ratio of workers to total population increases, withpositive effects on per capita income. TheSachs-Warner measure of openness is uncorrelatedwith either schooling or urbanization, while the ratioof trade to GDP is positively associated withurbanization and weakly but negatively associatedwith schooling.

Trade and Income GrowthChapter 10 examines evidence on the tendency for

trade to grow more rapidly than income, using severaltypes of data. Estimates of the elasticity of demandfor imports with respect to income were generated fora number of countries. Controlling for relative pricemovements, in many countries imports grow morethan proportionately with respect to income, while insome countries, imports have grown roughlyproportionately with income. As a “best estimate,”controlling for relative prices, every one percentincrease in real global incomes has inducedapproximately a 1.8 percent increase in global trade.

Estimates at the global level of the gross incomeelasticity of trade in particular sectors (uncorrected forprice movements) during 1983-89 reveal that for 16 ofthe 20 largest 4-digit SITC categories in internationaltrade, trade grew faster than income, and in manycases several times faster than income. Thesecategories account for about 31 percent of globaltrade, and are concentrated in transport equipment,machinery (particulary electronics), and apparel.Examining the differences in consumption patternsbetween high- and low-income regions in 1992, itturns out that the categories of trade which havegrown particularly rapidly also weigh more heavily inthe consumption budgets of higher-income countries.This suggests that an important part of the recentrapid growth in world trade is due to shiftingconsumption patterns. Along similar lines, anestimate of the demand for U.S. exports of machineryand transport equipment (SITC 7) indicates that forevery $1 increase in rest-of-world income, U.S.exports in these categories increased by $1.65. Thisestimate utilized an econometric procedure due toDeaton and Muellbauer (1986), which is particularlywell suited to representing relationships betweendemand and changes in income and price in a mannerconsistent with economic theory.

Page 85: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted
Page 86: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

6-1

CHAPTER 6Openness and Saving

Hypothesis TestedDomestic savings, as shown in part I, is the

primary source of funding for domestic investment inmost countries. The studies reviewed in chapter 3examined the key variables that determine savingsbehavior in developing and developed countries.However, the focus of these studies was not on howtrade liberalization influences savings behavior inthese countries, although a few examined therelationship between savings and exports. Thischapter provides an econometric investigation of theimpact of trade liberalization on savings behavior,given the influence of variables such as agedistribution, per capita income, and the growth rate ofGDP, for a sample containing 74 developed anddeveloping countries.

The basic hypothesis is whether domestic savingis associated with trade openness. This hypothesis istested by estimating domestic savings rates in thecontext of a variable rate-of-growth model oflife-cycle saving. The impact of trade liberalizationon savings behavior is measured by two indicators ofopenness: the Sachs-Warner index and the trade ratio.As defined earlier in part I, the Sachs-Warner index isan indicator of whether a country is “open” in a givenyear, while the trade ratio is the ratio of total trade(exports plus imports) relative to GDP. It is expectedthat the trade ratio will capture gradations of tradeliberalization that are not possible to capture with theSachs-Warner index. Both openness measures areexpected to have a net positive association withsavings rates.

BackgroundThe model used in this section is based on the

variable rate-of-growth model of life-cycle saving ofFry and Mason (1982) and extensions of that model inCollins (1991) as reviewed in chapter 3. The currentinvestigation is intended to augment this model toassess the impact of openness on savings behavior indeveloped and developing countries.

This type of model distinguishes between leveland growth effects on saving. Level effects involvefactors that affect the share of income that is saved

over the life-cycle, that is, the average propensity tosave out of lifetime income. Growth effects influencethe timing of household saving. If a householdincreases consumption (reduces saving) in one periodonly to reduce consumption (increase saving) by acorresponding amount in a later period, only thetiming and not the level of saving is affected. Factorsthat affect the timing of saving influence theaggregate saving function by changing the mean ageof consumption (µc) relative to the mean age ofearning (µy). The mean age of consumption can bedefined as the weighted average age of the typicalhousehold, the weights determined by annual sharesof lifetime consumption for such a household. Themean age of earning is similarly defined. Factors thataffect the timing of household saving workinteractively with the real GDP growth rate. If twocountries have the same difference between the meanage of consumption and the mean age of earning, thecountry with the higher growth rate can be expectedto have a higher savings rate.

Savings behavior is specified as follows:

6.1 ln [1/(1-Saving)] = L + Growth(µc -µy)

where L is the level effect and (µc-µy) is thedifference between the mean ages of consumptionand earning.

It is assumed that L and (µc-µy) are simplefunctions of social and economic characteristics, W.1

6.2 L = Wβ

6.3 µc -µy = Wδ

The variables included in W are a constant term;the dependency ratio, D14; real per capita income,PCY; real growth in GDP, g; and openness indices,OI, alternatively the Sachs-Warner index, SW, or thetrade ratio, TR.

Combining (6.1), (6.2), and (6.3) yields thefollowing equation for estimation:

1 Fry and Mason and Collins derive an aggregateconsumption function in logarithmic terms.Ln[1/(1-Saving)] = -lnc by definition, where c is aggregateconsumption. As noted by Fry and Mason (1982), Collins(1991), and Kang (1994), ln [1/(1-Saving)] ≈ Saving atmoderate levels of saving. For example, if Saving = 0.2,ln [1/(1-Saving)] = 0.223.

Page 87: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

6-2

6.4 ln[1/(1-saving)] = β0 + β1D14 + β2PCY + β3OI+ g(δ0 + δ1D14 + δ2PCY + δ3OI),

where the variables are as defined above, and the βsand δs are coefficients to be estimated. Theright-hand term in parentheses captures theinteraction of growth with dependency and per capitaincome. A partial guide to interpretation of resultsfollows.

As can be seen from equation 6.4, the value of thecoefficient of g is influenced by the coefficients δ0through δ3, along with associated variable values. Forexample, if δ1 through δ3 are all zero, the effect ofgrowth on the savings rate is constant and equal to δ0.If δ1 is negative, then the effect of growth on savingis smaller at higher dependency ratios. If δ3 ispositive, then the effect of growth on saving is largerat higher levels of openness. In addition, the neteffects of openness, dependency, and per capitaincome are influenced by the growth rate. Forexample, the net effect of openness (OI) on saving isβ3 + δ3g, indicating that the net effect of openness onsaving depends on the real growth rate—if δ3 ispositive, the effect of openness on saving will belarger at higher growth rates.

As shown in chapter 3, studies of the effects ofage distribution (such as the D14) on saving reachedmixed conclusions as to its sign and significance.Therefore, the expected sign of β1 is not clear, sincean increase in the share of the population under 15could lead to both positive and negative effects onsaving. It may raise the lifetime consumption ofhouseholds, thereby reducing saving, or it may raisethe share of lifetime earnings left as bequests. On theother hand, the expected sign of δ1 is negative, sincean increase in the dependency ratio is likely to reducethe mean age of consumption, with little effect on themean age of earnings in an economy, implying alower savings rate, provided there is positive realgrowth. The expected sign of β2 is positive, sincecountries with higher real incomes tend to have fewerliquidity restraints and problems with subsistence,which make saving more difficult. The expected signof δ2 is not clear, although Collins (1991) found asignificantly negative effect. The expected signs of β3and δ3 are positive, since greater openness shouldincrease the return on saving and the reliability of thatreturn.

Data and Methodology

DataAll data are from the World Bank, World

Development Indicators 1997 (WDI) with the

exception of the Sachs-Warner openness index. Thebase sample includes all countries in the WDIdatabase with population greater than 1 million forwhich the savings rate is available for almost all ofthe years 1970-95, oil exporters excluded, for a totalof 74 countries. Limited analysis was also performedon four subsamples of the base sample: (1) 17developed countries; (2) all (57) developing countries;(3) 23 developing countries in sub-Saharan Africa;and (4) 34 developing countries outside of sub-Saharan Africa. All variables are entered as averagesover successive 5-year periods except for thedependency ratio and the Sachs-Warner index, asexplained below. Where annual data points aremissing, an average of non-missing data points in the5-year period was taken.2 The savings rate (Saving)is defined as the ratio of gross domestic saving toGDP.3 In line with theoretical considerationsdiscussed above, Saving is transformed asln [1/(1-Saving)] to serve as the dependent variable,where ln is the natural logarithm.

Independent variables include (1) the dependencyratio (Dependency), which is the ratio of the

2 The last “5-year” period is 1990-95, which actuallyincludes 6 years. Many of the missing data pointsoccurred in this period.

3 Life cycle models of consumption and savingconcentrate on household behavior. Ideally, measures ofincome, consumption, and saving used in testing aspectsof life cycle models should be based on householdincome, consumption, and saving. Consumption andsaving out of disposable personal income are measuresthat might approximate the ideal, but such data areavailable for a limited number of countries and for alimited number of years. The limitations would tend tobias the sample toward developed and more advanceddeveloping countries. The use of gross domestic saving iscommon in the literature even though it includesgovernment saving, business saving, foreign saving, anddepreciation (which is actually dissaving and extremelydifficult to measure). There is some indication thatnonhousehold saving is minimally correlated withexplanatory variables used in the literature, meaning that itis acceptable to use gross aggregate saving in place ofhousehold saving in regressions based on life cyclemodels. See Fry and Mason, pp. 432-3, for furtherdiscussion.

There are conceptual and practical problems inmeasuring saving in developed economies, such as thosementioned above, and these are compounded indeveloping countries where record keeping is less rigorousand much economic activity is “off the books.”Commenting on saving as measured in the U.S. nationalincome and product accounts, David F. Bradford (1991, p.16) says that “the saving measures are neither those thatthe microeconomic theory of consumption explains northose appropriate to assess national economicperformance.” Much of the saving that is important foreconomic growth and development is channeled intoinvestment in human capital. Anne O. Krueger (1991, p.374) has stated that “If savings were defined to includeexpenditures (and forgone income) on human capitalformation, the savings rates used in our growth equationswould look quite different.”

Page 88: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

6-3

population under 15 years of age to the working-agepopulation, (that is, the population aged 15-65);4 (2)per capita income (Income) defined as grossdomestic product per capita in constant 1987 U.S.dollars, entered as the natural logarithm; (3) realgrowth (Growth), which is the growth rate of GDPin constant local currency; (4) the 5-yearSachs-Warner index (SW openness, or SW), which isthe sum of the Sachs-Warner index over the 5-yearperiod (the Sachs-Warner index takes a value of 1 ina year that a country is considered to be “open” and0 otherwise (Sachs and Warner (1995))); and (5) theTrade Ratio (TR) is the ratio of the sum of importsand exports to GDP.

Means and standard deviations of the data areshown in table 6-1. The mean value of thedependency ratio (0.696) indicates that, on average,the under-15 population is less than the working-agepopulation. It should be noted, however, that thedependency ratio can take a value greater than onesince the denominator is the working-age populationrather than the total population. It is not unusual for a“young” country to have an under-15 population thatis larger than its working-age population. TheSachs-Warner openness variable can, in fact, take only6 values—the integers 0 through 5. The actualdistribution is concentrated at 0 (closed in all 5 years)for developing countries, and 5 (open in all 5 years)for developed countries, with a substantial scatteringin between. The trade ratio can take values greaterthan one. This is often the case in small countriesthat engage in a large volume of trade, such as HongKong and Singapore.

Figures 6-1 and 6-2 show the simple relationshipsbetween the savings rate and the openness variables,SW and TR. Figure 6-1 shows mean savings rates ateach value of the Sachs-Warner openness variable

4 Other measures of dependency used in the literatureinclude the ratio of the under 15 population to totalpopulation, the ratio of the under 15 and over 65population to the working-age population, and the ratio ofthe under 15 and over 65 population to the totalpopulation. The measure used in the present study is thesame as the measure used by Fry and Mason (1982).

together with points one standard deviation aboveand below the mean, indicating the distribution ofcountries at each value of SW. As noted above,countries are heavily concentrated at the extremevalues of 0 and 5. There is a generally positiverelationship between the savings rate and SW.Figure 6-2 shows a direct plot of savings ratesversus the trade ratio. Countries are concentrated attrade ratios below 1 with no overtly visiblerelationship between saving and openness in thatrange of trade ratios, but there is a clear relationshipbetween higher trade ratios and higher savings ratesfor countries when trade ratios are above 1.

MethodologyEstimates were made using ordinary least squares

(OLS) and fixed effects techniques.5 Estimates weremade using a White heteroskedasticity correction.6

Estimated coefficients made with and without thiscorrection are identical. Estimated t-statistics madewith and without the correction are of similarmagnitude. F-tests show the fixed effects forindividual countries to be statistically significant.7

5 Fixed-effects models attempt to control for theexistence of time and/or individual specific characteristicsdetermining the independent variable which areunobservable to the investigator and are either fixed orconstant. In other words, for each identified group in thesample (country, industry, household, etc.) there arecharacteristics that are unobserved by the investigator, butare important in explaining the dependent variable.Ignoring the potential presence of these group effects maylead to biased estimates.

6 White (1980). The White procedure corrects forproblems associated with the estimation error variancebeing correlated with one or more of the explanatoryvariables or the variable to be explained. The Whitecorrection procedure uses the sample data to generatestatistically consistent standard-error estimates, even in thepresence of unknown forms of heteroskedasticity.

7 The terms “significant” and “significance” meanstatistically significant and imply there is a relatively highprobability, for example 90 or more in 100, that therelationship between the variables would not haveoccurred by chance.

Table 6-1Description of data

Standard Variable Mean deviation

Saving (ratio to GDP) 0.169 0.100. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Dependency (ratio to working–age population) 0.696 0.229. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Income (per capita, constant 1987 U.S. dollars) 3,790 5,940. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Growth in real GDP (annual percent) 3.74 3.05. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Sachs–Warner openness (see text) 2.15 2.39. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Trade Ratio (ratio to GDP) 0.612 0.453. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Source: See text.

Page 89: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

6-4

0

0.05

0.10

0.15

0.20

0.25

0.30

0.35

Figure 6-1Savings rate vs. openness, as measured by Sachs-Warner index

Sav

ings

rat

e

Sachs-Warner index

Source: World Development Indicators (1997) and Sachs and Warner (1995).

average savings rate plus1 standard deviation

average savings rate minus1 standard deviation

average savings rate

0 1 2 3 54

0

0.05

0.10

0.15

0.20

0.25

0.30

0.35

0.40

0.45

0.50

0

0.05

0.10

0.15

0.20

0.25

0.30

0.35

0.40

0.45

0.50

Figure 6-2Savings rate vs. openness, as measured by trade/GDP ratio

Sav

ings

rat

e

Trade/GDP

Source: World Development Indicators (1997).

0 1 2 3 4

Developed countries Developing countires

Page 90: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

6-5

Since growth and income are indirect functions ofsaving, perhaps with a lag, it is possible that there areproblems with endogeneity. Such problems cangenerally be overcome with regressions usingexogenous instrumental variables. Instrumentalvariables regressions were not performed because thevariables that are appropriate as instruments areavailable only for a subset of the countries in the dataset used. The countries in this subset would tend toconstitute a biased sample of developed andhigher-income developing countries.8

ResultsResults are reported in tables 6-2 and 6-3. Table

6-2 reports twelve equations for the full sample of 74countries with three groupings—one grouping withthe Sachs-Warner index as the openness variable(equations 1-4), one with the trade ratio as theopenness variable (equations 5-8), and one without anopenness variable (equations 9-12).9 Within eachgrouping, the first two equations include interactionterms and the second two do not. The first and thirdequations within each grouping are OLS estimates, thesecond and fourth are fixed effects estimates.10

Results without openness variables (equations9-12 in table 6-2) are similar to those reported byCollins (1991). Most notably, the level effect ofdependency (the coefficient of “Dependency” inequations 9-12) is not significant in any of theregressions, but the growth effect (the coefficient ofD14�g in equations 9 and 10) is significantly negative.This same pattern is also present in the equations withopenness variables (equations 1-8 in table 6-2). Thisindicates, as noted in chapter 3, that in two economieswith identical positive growth rates, savings will belower where the dependency ratio is higher.

Neither of the trade openness variables isconsistently significant over the set of equationsshown in table 6-2 and equations estimated fromsubsamples. For instance, the SW variables are

8 Not much appears to be lost by not using theinstrumental variables technique. Fry and Mason used aninstrumental variables procedure and note that “theordinary least squares estimate [actually, what is beingcalled a fixed effect estimate in the present study] givesvirtually identical results.” Fry and Mason, p. 434.

9 A similar pattern of OLS regressions was estimatedfor four subsamples: (1) 17 developed countries; (2) 57developing countries; (3) 23 developing countries insub-Saharan Africa; and (4) 34 developing countriesoutside of sub-Saharan Africa.

10 The inflation rate and real interest rate were alsotried as explanatory variables, but were found not to berobustly significant.

significant in equation 1, but not in equation 3, andperversely significant in the level term in the fixedeffects regressions (equations 2 and 4); the TRvariables are not significant in equation 5, 6, and 8,but TR is significant in equation 7. There is asimilar mixture of significances of the opennessvariables in regressions done on the previouslymentioned subsamples (not reported). Therefore, thesign and significance of the effect of openness onsaving depends on the model specification and thedata sample.

Interpretation of the net effects of the interactionterms as estimated in equations 1 and 5 are shown intable 6-3. The effect of growth on saving is estimatedto be higher at higher levels of SW and TR, but lowerat higher levels of dependency (D14) and income(PCY). For example, consider the net effect ofgrowth on developed countries and countries insub-Saharan Africa shown in table 6-3. At sampleaverages of D14, PCY, and SW, each percentage pointof growth is estimated to add 3.87 percentage pointsto the savings rate in developed countries versus 1.77percentage points in countries in sub-Saharan Africa.At sample averages of D14, PCY, and TR, eachpercentage point of growth is estimated to add 3.26percentage points to the savings rate in developedcountries versus 1.83 percentage points insub-Saharan Africa. The net effect of growth onsaving was statistically significant in all of the casesreported.

The net effects of SW and TR are also shown intable 6-3. Consider the effects of SW and TR,respectively, on saving at three levels of growth. Atthe average growth rate for the full sample, an extrayear of openness as measured by SW is estimated tosubtract 0.1 percentage points from the savings rate, aresult not statistically distinguishable from zero. At ahigher growth rate (one standard deviation above theaverage growth rate), an extra year of openness addsabout 1.0 percentage point to the savings rate,although, again, this is not significantly different fromzero. At low levels of growth, there is a perverselynegative effect of SW. The net effect of TR isstatistically significant at average and high levels ofgrowth, but not at low levels of growth.

In summary, a high share of trade in an economyis associated with a higher savings rate, particularlyfor more rapidly-growing economies. However, formajor episodes of liberalization as characterized bythe Sachs-Warner index, there appears to be noparticular relationship between liberalization andsavings. The empirical relationship between liberal-ization and savings thus remains an open question.

Page 91: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

Table 6-2Effects of openness on saving

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒEquation

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

Specification

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

Openness

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

Openness �g

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

Dependency

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

Income

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

Growth

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

D14�g

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

Income �g

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

Constant

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

Number ofobservations

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

AdjustedR2

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

F-testfor fixedeffects

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

Sachs-Warner openness

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

(1) ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

OLS ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

-0.014(2.71)

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

0.356(3.15)

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

0.020(0.338)

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

0.055(6.44)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

3.73(1.76)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

-1.98 (1.62)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

-0.203(0.925)

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

-0.248(2.70)

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

367 ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

0.526 ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

(2)

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒFixed effects

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

-0.010 (2.13)

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

0.098(1.06)

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

0.016(0.210)

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

0.125(6.39)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

1.96(1.02)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

-2.02 (1.97)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

0.036(0.193)

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

(1)

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

367

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

0.840

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

10.7

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

(3) ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒOLS ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

0.003(0.837)

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

-0.048(1.07)

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

0.042(6.74)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

1.35(8.01)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

-0.128(1.84)

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

367 ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

0.473 ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

(4)

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

Fixed effects

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ-0.006(2.21)

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

-0.063(1.03)

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

0.132(5.97)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

0.655(5.01)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

(1)

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

367

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

0.827

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

11.1

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

Openness measured by the trade ratio

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

(5) ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

OLS ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

0.016(0.578)

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

0.460(1.00)

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

0.082(1.58)

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

0.051(6.09)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

4.97(2.20)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

-3.28(3.23)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

-0.211(0.878)

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

-0.296(3.27)

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

367 ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

0.525 ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

(6)

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

Fixed effects

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

0.050(1.28)

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

0.377 (0.816)

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

0.142(2.03)

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

0.121(5.50)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

2.13(1.09)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

-2.55(2.82)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

0.052(0.260)

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

(1)

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

367

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

0.837

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

10.4

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

(7) ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

OLS ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

0.055(5.32)

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

-0.050(1.26)

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

0.040(6.56)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

1.20(7.44)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

-0.141(2.03)

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

367 ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

0.509 ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

(8)

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

Fixed effects

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

0.057(1.54)

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

0.019(0.346)

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

0.126(5.31)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

0.617(4.71)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

(1)

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

367

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

0.824

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

9.91

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

No openness variables

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

(9) ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

OLS ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ0.079(1.49)

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

0.046(5.48)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

3.83(1.71)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

-3.41(3.26)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

0.037(0.160)

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

-0.252(2.73)

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

367 ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

0.505 ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

(10)

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

Fixed effects

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

0.098(1.50)

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ0.131(6.07)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

2.18(1.13)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

-2.50(2.77)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

0.071(0.378)

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

(1)

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

367

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

0.835

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

10.9

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

(11) ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

OLS ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

-0.058(1.46)

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ0.043(6.94)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

1.39(8.21)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

-0.126(1.83)

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

367 ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

0.473 ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

(12) ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

Fixed effects ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

-0.013(0.231) ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

0.137(5.92)ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ0.632(4.82) ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

(1) ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

367 ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

0.823 ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

10.8

1 Fixed-effects regressions include constant terms for each country, which are not reported.Note: T-statistics are in parentheses. T-statistics and F-statistics indicating a significance level of .10 are in italics, those significant at .05 are in bold ,those significant at .01 or higher are in bold itlaics .Source: See text.

Page 92: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted
Page 93: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

6-7

Table 6-3Interpretation of results

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Net effect of growth on saving

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

SampleÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

∂S/∂g = 3.73 – 1.98D14 –0.203PCY + 0.356SW1,2

(from eq. 1 in table 6–2)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

∂S/∂g = 4.97 – 3.28D14 –0.211PCY + 0.016TR (fromeq. 5 in table 6–2)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Full sampleDeveloped countriesDeveloping countries Sub–saharan Africa Other developing countries

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

2.39 (3.30) 3.87 (4.24) 2.04 (2.66) 1.77 (2.35)

2.22 (2.84)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

2.21 (3.01) 3.26 (3.54) 2.00 (2.55) 1.83 (2.33)

2.12 (2.67)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Net effect of openness on saving

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Level of growthÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

∂S/∂SW = –0.014 + .356g(from eq. 1 in table 6–2)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ∂S/∂TR = 0.016 + 0.460g(from eq. 5 in table 6–2)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

HighMeanLow

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.010 (0.991)–0.001 (0.149)–0.012 (2.37)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.047 (4.16)0.033 (2.41)0.019 (0.852)

1 S=ln [1/(1–saving)]. S ≈ saving for moderate levels of saving. For example, if s=0.2, S=0.223.2 Estimates of ∂S/∂g are evaluated at sample average values of dependency, income, and openness indices SW

and TR, respectively. T–statistics in parentheses.Note: T–statistics indicating a significance level of .10 are in italics, those significant at .05 are in bold , thosesignificant at .01 are in bold itlaics .

Source: See text.

Page 94: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted
Page 95: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

7-1

CHAPTER 7Trade and Investment Openness and

Foreign Direct Investment

Hypotheses TestedThis analysis investigates the effect of trade and

foreign direct investment (FDI) openness on FDIflows. In other words, does an economy’s opennessas determined by its trade and FDI policy have aneffect on the amount of FDI in that country? One ofthe linkages necessary for a dynamic effect of tradeliberalization, with respect to FDI, is thatliberalization of trade or FDI policy must lead to moreFDI. The other linkage, as discussed in chapter 3, isthat FDI must lead to growth.

In this analysis of trade and FDI policy and FDIflows, two hypotheses are tested. The first is whethergreater openness to FDI, measured by the restrictionsplaced on FDI, leads to a larger stock of FDI in acountry. The second is whether a relationship existsbetween FDI and trade openness. Since the theoreticalliterature and empirical literature come to very mixedconclusions, there can be no maintained hypothesis asto the direction, positive or negative, of therelationship between trade barriers and FDI. The restof the variables in the analysis are other determinantsof FDI drawn from the empirical literature.

Background Markusen (1995) summarizes some of the recent

research on the relationship between trade barriers andFDI by stating that trade barriers cause a substitutiontoward FDI, but they also depress both trade andinvestment. Thus high barriers to trade will tend tocause a substitution away from exports towards FDI(affiliate sales), but simultaneously depress both tradeand FDI. Empirical research on the impact ofgovernment policy on FDI is limited, possibly becausethere are few good quantitative measures of FDIpolicy. Brainard (1993), Ferrantino (1993) andWeisman (1997) find a positive relationship betweenFDI openness and FDI. The more hospitable thepolicy environment to FDI, the more FDI is obtained.

The empirical literature on the determinants ofFDI, as summarized in chapter 3 of this report, coversa wide spectrum of methods and results. Many other

determinants of FDI are investigated in the literature.In terms of country- specific effects, such variables asthe size of the economy, the stability of the economy,exchange rate volatility, wages in the host country, orskill levels have been investigated. Unfortunatelythere is no comprehensive list of determinants, butthere are a large number of potential variables.

Most of the research examining the effect oftariffs and non-tariff barriers on FDI use cross-sectional data. Of the types of regressions estimated inthe FDI literature, studies looking at a cross section ofcountries or industries typically run a reduced formequation using the attributes of the host countries thatmight influence a multinational to locate an affiliatethere.

Methodology and DataThis analysis looks at the determinants of FDI

including trade and FDI policy. The data in thisanalysis are for a cross section of countries andindustries in which there was U.S. FDI in 1993. Thisvariable was chosen because this is the most recentyear for which an FDI openness measure and FDIdata were available. There are 42 countries for whichall the variables listed below were available. These42 countries represent a broad cross section ofdeveloped and developing countries and include mostof the countries in the OECD, Latin America andAsia.

The general specification is a reduced formgravity type equation.1 Due to the number ofobservations available in examining U.S. FDI flows incross section, only a limited number of determinantsof FDI flows could be analyzed. These were thedeterminants most commonly used in the literaturereviewed. FDI is shown as a function of trade andFDI openness, the size of the economy (GDP), the

1 A gravity equation uses distance as a principleexplanatory variable. The distance between countries isexpected to affect their interactions. For examples of thistype of equation and further explanation see Brainard(1993), Ferrantino (1993), Denekamp and Ferrantino(1990), and Lipsey and Weiss (1981).

Page 96: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

7-2

stability of the economy, inflation, cost ofproduction, wages, the distance to the United States,and the profit rate for a previous year. Below is thefinal specification used in this analysis:

FDI = F(Trade Openness, FDI Openness, GDP 1993,Inflation 1993, Wages 1993, Distance, Profit 1983).

Four sets of regressions were estimated using theabove specification:2 (1) a regression for the crosssection of 42 countries; (2) a regression for the crosssection of 28 countries; (3) a regression on a panel of28 countries and 3 industries using binary variables toseparate the individual industry effects.3 For eachindustry, the above specification were estimatedallowing for a correlated error term across the threeregressions, in other words, as a system of seeminglyunrelated regressions.4

2 The first three regressions use ordinary leastsquares.

3 Fixed-effects models attempt to control for theexistence of time and/or individual specific characteristicsdetermining the independent variables which areunobservable to the investigator and are either fixed orconstant. In other words, for each identified group in thesample (country, industry, household, etc.) there arecharacteristics that are unobserved by the investigator, butare important in explaining the dependent variable.Ignoring the potential presence of these group effects maylead to biased estimates.

4 Seemingly unrelated regression consists of a set ofindividual equations as a system of equations which has acontemporaneously correlated error term across equations(Kennedy, (1992)).

The variables in this analysis are shown withmeans and standard deviations in table 7-1. Thedependent variables are the first two items in thetable, total FDI and FDI by industry. Forty-twocountries have data for the total stock of U.S. FDI in1993. A subset of 22 of these 42 countries havecomplete FDI data for 1993 separated into three broadindustry categories: services, manufacturing andpetroleum. Six other countries are missing data onone of the industry categories, but have data forprevious years or for 1994 that allow imputation ofthe missing data from column and row totals. Thereare observations for three industries in the 28countries, giving 84 observations.

Some of the means and standard deviations intable 7-1 are worthy of discussion. The FDI and tradeopenness variables have mean values of 5.77 and 6.70and standard deviations of 1.16 and 1.67 respectively.For these variables, a score of 10 signifies the highestdegree of openness. This shows that most countrieshave an openness rating for FDI between 3 and 8 andfor trade between 3 and 10. The mean values andstandard deviations of GDP, inflation, wages 1993and profit 1983 show the large variation in thesevariables across the sample countries. This largevariation is an artifact of having a broad sample ofdeveloped and developing countries.

The measure of trade openness in this analysiscomes from the World Competitiveness Report for

Table 7–1Data sources used in FDI analysisÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎVariable

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎMean

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎStandard DeviationsÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎTotal FDI (1993 in thousands of U.S. Dollars)ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ40,754

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ87,099ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

FDI by industry (1993 in thousands of U.S.dollars)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ Services ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ34,668 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ73,670

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Manufacturing ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

18,161 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

22,654

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Petroleum ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

5,733 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

11,012

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

FDI openness (survey measure 0–10) ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

5.77 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.16

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Trade openness (survey measure 0–10) ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

6.70 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.67

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Gross Domestic Product (GDP) 1993 (inmillions of 1987 dollars)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ257,997

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ478,253ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎInflation 1993 (in percent)ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ80.98

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ349ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎWages 1993 (in thousands of current dollars)ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ25,364

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ15,979ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Distance (between New York and the largestcity in the country in kilometers)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

8,066

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1,210

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Profit 1983 (net income on sales in percent) ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.32 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

18.5

Source: See text

Page 97: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

7-3

1993. One of the survey questions in this reportconcerns the degree to which government policydiscourages imports. The results of this surveyquestion rank countries between 1 and 10 withrespect to trade openness. A score of 10 representsthe most open. This measure of trade openness isused rather than the Sachs-Warner measure because acompanion measure of FDI openness can becomputed from the same survey. Figure 7-1 showsthe relationship between trade openness and FDI asa percentage of GDP, which controls for the size ofthe economy. There seems to be a positiverelationship between these variables.5 The scatterplotshows significant dispersion, but there is a definiteupward trend. This trend is evident from thecorrelation coefficient of 0.44.

5 Other measures of trade openness examined are the1993 average tariff rate, the range of tariffs in 1993, anda coverage ratio for non-tariff barriers for 1993 from theUnited Nations Conference on Trade and DevelopmentTrade Analysis and Information System.

The measure of FDI openness is calculated from aseries of questions from the World CompetitivenessReport for 1993. FDI openness is calculated by theaverage score on the following survey questions: easeof hiring and firing, price controls, security, thedevelopment of the justice system, antitrustregulations, restrictions on foreign investment,transparency of regulations, the development of anintellectual property regime, and the ease ofcross-border ventures. Figure 7-2 shows therelationship between FDI openness and FDI dividedby GDP. As with the trade openness measure, thereseems to be a positive relationship. There are a fewdata points away from the main cluster, but there isless dispersion than in the trade openness plot. Thislack of dispersion is evident in the correlationcoefficient of 0.59.

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Figure 7-1Trade openness vs. U.S. FDI/foreign GDP

U.S

. FD

I/for

eign

GD

P (

%)

Trade openness

Note.—The higher the openess figure the more a country is considered to be open.

Source: Compiled from official statistics of the U.S. Department of Commerce, the World Bank, and the World Competitiveness Report.

Page 98: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

7-4

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9

Figure 7-2FDI openness vs. U.S. FDI/foreign GDP

U.S

. FD

I/for

eign

GD

P (

%)

FDI openness

Note.—The higher the openess figure the more a country is considered to be open.

Source: Compiled from official statistics of the U.S. Department of Commerce, the World Bank , and the WorldCompetitiveness Report.

The data for the other determinants of FDI comefrom a variety of sources. GDP and the inflationmeasure, the GDP deflator, are from the World BankDevelopment Indicators database for 1993. Themeasure of wages comes from the Bureau ofEconomic Analysis of the U.S. Department ofCommerce. Wages paid to workers of U.S. affiliatesare divided by the number of workers at U.S. affiliatesfor a given country in 1993. The distance measure isthe Fitzpatrick/Modlin direct line distance betweenNew York and the largest city in each country,measured in kilometers. All of the data used in theregressions are in logarithmic form.

The size of the host economy, as measured byGDP, is expected to be positively related to FDI. Thecountry’s macroeconomic stability, as measured by theinflation rate, is expected to be positively related toFDI. Surveys and case studies have shown that firmslike stability since it makes planning and decisionmaking easier. The wage rate paid by U.S. affiliatesin the country is expected to be negatively related toFDI. Investing in a country with high manufacturingcosts is not attractive. The relationship betweendistance from the United States to the host countryand FDI is ambiguous. Since distance could be ameasure of transport costs, cultural distance or similar

latent variables, there is not an expected direction ofthe relationship. Profit in 1983 is expected to bepositively related to the FDI stock in 1993. Higherprofit rates in previous periods will attract moreinvestment.

ResultsTables 7-2 and 7-3 show the results of the series

of regressions on the determinants of FDI. Table 7-2shows the results of regressions for total U.S. FDIabroad for the sample of 42 countries, the subset of28 countries, and the 28 countries with FDI separatedinto the three industries. Table 7-3 shows the resultsfor the system of regressions, one for each industryfor the 28 countries. The adjusted r-squared across theregressions is between 0.58 and 0.80, showing areasonably good fit for cross-sectional analysis.6

6 The r-squared statistic is not defined for the systemof equations estimated in table 7-3. The r-squaredstatistics correspond to the individual OLS equations.Since the seemingly unrelated regression should improvethe efficiency of the estimates, the explained variation forthe system should be greater than that explained by theindividual OLS equations.

Page 99: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

Table 7-2 Foreign direct investment: coefficients 1 of regression and related t-statistics 2 - 1993

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒFDIMeasure

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

TradeOpenness

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

FDIOpenness

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

GDP1993

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

Inflation1993

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

Wages1993

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

Distance

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

Profit1983

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

Petroleum

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

Manufacturing

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

Constant

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

N

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒ

AdjR2ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

F-stat

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒTotal ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

0.25 (2.08) ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

4.11 (5.69) ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

1.23(6.88)ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

0.03(0.32) ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

-0.47(1.23)ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

0.31(1.87) ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

1.70(1.33)ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

(3) ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

(3) ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

-9.86(3.14) ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

42 ÒÒÒÒ

0.73ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

16.8

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

Total ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ0.17(1.56)

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

4.43(6.06)

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

0.93(5.15)

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

-0.04(0.49)

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

-0.18(0.33)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

0.45(2.01)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

1.09(1.32)

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

(3) ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

(3) ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

-5.58(1.85)

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

28 ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒ

0.75ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

12.6

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

By IndustryÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ1.01 (1.96)

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

4.12 (5.89)

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

0.89(6.68)

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

-0.13(1.31)

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

-0.23(0.67)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

-0.39(3.49)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

0.77(1.14)

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

-1.64 (5.66)

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

0.30 (0.13)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

-6.44(2.29)

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

84 ÒÒÒÒ

0.69ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

21.8

1 Variables in natural logs.2 T-Statistics reported are heteroskedastic consistent using the White procedure.3 Not Applicable

Note.—Table 7-1 contains a key to names of the dependent variables. Coefficients printed in italics are statistically significant at .10, coefficients printedin bold are statistically significant at .05, and coefficients printed in bold italics are statistically significant at .01 (one-tailed test).

Source: U.S. International Trade Commission staff calculations.

Page 100: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

Table 7-3Foreign direct investment by industry: coefficients 1 of seemingly unrelated regression and related t-statistics 2 - 1993

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

FDI By Industry

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

TradeOpenness

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

FDIOpenness

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

GDP1993

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

Inflation 1993

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

Wages1993

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

Distance

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

Profit 1983

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

Constant

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

N

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒAdj R 2 3ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

Manufacturing

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

1.35(2.40)

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

3.18(3.58)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

1.02(6.77)

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

0.03(0.32)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

-0.48(1.68)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

-0.39(1.85)

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

1.31(1.98)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

-6.46(1.84)

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

28

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

0.75

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒPetroleum ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

-0.33(0.38)

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

4.54(3.31)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

0.66(2.82)

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

-0.17(1.18)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

0.11(0.25)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

-0.26(0.79)

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

-0.07(-0.07)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

5.74(1.05)

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

28ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

0.58

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒÒ

Services ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

1.96(2.90)

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

5.16(4.85)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

1.03(5.71)

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒÒ

-0.11(1.02)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

-0.31(0.91)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

-0.52(2.05)

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

1.18(1.48)

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒ

-10.44(2.47)

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒ

28ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

ÒÒÒÒÒ

0.80

1 Variables in natural logs.2 T-Statistics reported are calculated using the quadratic form of the analytic first derivative.3 Adj R2 is for estimation of the separate equations

Note.—Table 7-1 contains a key to names of the dependent variables. Coefficients printed in italics are statistically significant at .10, coefficients printedin bold are statistically significant at .05, and coefficients printed in bold italics are statistically significant at .01 (one-tailed test).

Source: U.S. International Trade Commission staff calculations

Page 101: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

7-7

The regressions in table 7-2 show that the tradeopenness measure is positive and significantly7 relatedto FDI flows. The positive relationship leads to theconclusion that trade and FDI are complements,8 inother words that trade and FDI increase or decreasetogether. The coefficients on trade openness rangebetween 0.17 and 1.01,9 showing the more open acountry’s trading regime the more FDI it attracts.

The FDI openness measure shows a similar effecton FDI in all the regressions on table 7-2 and issignificant at the 99 percent confidence level. Thesecoefficients suggest a 1 percent increase in FDIopenness leads to a 4 percent increase in the FDIstock. For example, if Turkey or South Africa wereto increase their openness score from approximately 5to the level of the United Kingdom at approximately7, they could expect an increase in FDI of over 100percent.10 This change is a sizeable increase in FDI,but it is obtained by comparing two of the moreclosed regimes to one of the more open regimes in thesurvey. It is a movement from approximately themean FDI openness to one standard deviation above.The other determinants of FDI shown in table 7-2,GDP (inflation, wages, and profit) show resultssimilar to those found in the literature. GDP has apositive and significant coefficient of approximatelyone throughout the regressions. This estimatesuggests that a one-percent increase in GDPaccompanies a one-percent increase in the FDI stock.

The wages and inflation measures are bothnegatively related to FDI. However, neither of thesemeasures shows a significant relationship to FDI inthe regressions in table 7-2 except for inflation in theindustry regression. The profit measure, return onsales in 1983, is positively and significantly related toFDI in two of the overall regressions. This shows thegreater the profit rate of U.S. affiliates in the countryin 1983, the larger the stock of FDI in 1993.

7 The terms “significant” and “significance”meanstatistically significant and imply there is a relatively highprobability, for example 90 or more in 100, that therelationship between the variables would not haveoccurred by chance.

8 Three other measures of trade openness wereexamined: the average most favored nation (MFN) tariffrate, the range of MFN tariff rates, and the non-tariffbarrier coverage ratio. None of these measures when usedin the regressions showed a significant relationship toFDI.

9 Due to the specification of the variables inlogarithmic form, coefficients for non-binary variables inthe results tables can be interpreted as elasticity estimates.An elasticity is the percentage change in the dependentvariable results for a one percent change in theexplanatory variable.

10 This is calculated by multiplying the percentagechange of FDI openness from 5 to 7 by the coefficient onthe FDI openness variable in the regression.

The distance variable, commonly used in gravitymodels, is negative and statistically significantthroughout the regressions. This variable is difficult tointerpret since it may be a measure for culturaldistance, the expense of shipping, communicationlags, or other market differences related to distance.

The third regression on table 7-2 shows there aresignificant differences across the industries withrespect to the stock of FDI. The petroleum industry issignificantly different from services andmanufacturing. These differences lead to thespecification of separate industry effects regressionswhich are shown on table 7-3.

In table 7-3, trade openness is positive andsignificant in the manufacturing and servicesregressions and has a larger coefficient than in theregressions in table 7-2. FDI openness continues toshow a positive and significant relationship to FDIwith similar coefficients to those in table 7-2. GDP issignificant in all the equations with a coefficient ofapproximately 1. This is consistent with results intable 7-2. Wages have a negative and significantrelationship for manufacturing FDI. The higher thewage rate the less the FDI in manufacturingindustries. This relationship is not evident forservices and petroleum. Distance shows a negativerelationship as in the regressions in table 7-2 exceptfor petroleum. Profit shows a positive and significantrelationship to the current stock of FDI in bothmanufacturing and services. This coefficientthroughout table 7-3 shows an elasticity of profit toFDI of approximately one. For a one-percent increasein profitability in 1983, there is a one-percent increasein the stock of FDI in 1993.

The results on table 7-3 clearly show that theindustry effects are important. The results show thatthe wage rate is significant only for manufacturingFDI. This is not surprising since FDI in services is toserve the market and petroleum FDI is moredetermined by the location of oil reserves. Thisinterpretation for industry differences also explainswhy profit is significant for services andmanufacturing but not for petroleum.

Concluding ObservationsThese results show that trade openness should

bring about an increase in FDI flows. The literaturereview in chapter 3 showed FDI had a positive impacton growth. Taken together, these two linkages showtrade liberalization leads to more FDI which leads togrowth. These results need to be viewed in thecontext of the research reviewed in chapter 3, whichshows a complex relationship between trade and FDI.

FDI openness also has a sizeable effect. WhileBrainard (1993) finds a slightly smaller elasticity of

Page 102: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

7-8

affiliate sales to FDI openness, the results of FDIopenness in this research are of a similar magnitude.FDI openness has the largest effect of thedeterminants examined and, from a policy perspective,may be easier to change than the other determinants.

These relationships between FDI openness andFDI and trade openness and FDI are both positive andsignificant throughout the regressions. This clearlyshows that the countries with more open trade andinvestment regimes have larger stocks of FDI holding

the other determinants of FDI constant. These resultsshow that the link between policy openness and FDI,needed for FDI to have a dynamic effect, does exist.

Other determinants of FDI, such as GDP, wagesand profit, show a significant relationship to the stockof FDI in a country. The elasticity of GDP to FDI isapproximately one. This estimate is an importantparameter in modeling the size of FDI in relation toGDP growth that may be brought about by tradeliberalization.

Page 103: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

8-1

CHAPTER 8Trade, Trade Policy, and Productivity

Growth in Manufacturing

Hypothesis TestedThis chapter seeks to investigate whether

productivity growth in manufacturing is significantlyrelated to either trade flows or trade policy. Theserelationships are estimated after controlling for otherdeterminants of productivity growth, such asconvergence of low-productivity countries to the“state of the art,” and technological effort throughformal R&D. Evidence is examined for a sample ofthirteen OECD countries and eighteen manufacturingsectors during the period 1980-91. Robustness of therelationships examined is explored by examiningseveral alternate measures of total factor productivity(TFP) and labor productivity, as well as by examiningalternate samples of the data.

BackgroundAs discussed in chapter 3, many investigators

have proposed that either exporting or importing maybe a cause of greater productivity growth. Greaterimport competition may enhance productivity growth,by forcing less efficient domestic firms to operatemore efficiently and by rewarding more efficientdomestic firms with an increase in market share.Since high tariffs and NTBs reduce importcompetition, a similar negative effect of trade barrierson productivity can be posited. Increased exportsmight enhance productivity by exposing the exportingfirm to new technological information from thecustomer (see Aw and Hwang (1994) for Taiwan).

Using various econometric techniques on U.S.data, Caves and Barton (1990) and MacDonald(1994) generate a positive association between importpenetration and either technical efficiency orproductivity growth. Several investigators have foundthat measured productivity in developing countriesincreased after an episode of liberalization(Handoussa, Nishimuzu, and Page (1986) for Egypt,Tybout and Westbrook (1995) for Mexico, andTybout, de Melo, and Corbo (1991) for Chile).Evidence for a lagged effect of tariff cuts instimulating productivity growth appears in work by

the Economic Planning Advisory Commission ofAustralia (1996). Other studies have found moreambiguous results (Harrison (1994), Harrison andRevenga (1995)), and the relationship between tradeand productivity growth is not yet a settled empiricalquestion.

An important conceptual issue is the question ofhow one untangles the direction of causation betweenproductivity and trade. In most theories ofinternational trade, if a particular industry in onecountry enjoys superior productivity performancerelative to its counterparts overseas, that industry willbe able to charge lower prices than its competitiors,and its share of the global market will increase.Consequently, that country’s exports in that industrywill expand, and the corresponding imports willcontract. Dollar and Wolff (1993, chapter 7) find thatJapanese comparative advantage (as revealed throughtrading patterns during 1970-82) increased mostrapidly in those industries in which Japanese TFPgrew most rapidly relative to United States TFP, andthat U.S. comparative advantage declined in thoseindustries in which other countries’ TFP converged toor overtook the U.S. productivity level. Anassociation of greater exports with productivitygrowth thus does not necessarily imply that exportingcaused productivity growth. Clerides, Lach, andTybout (1997), using firm-level data from Colombia,Mexico, and Morocco, and taking into accountproductivity changes before and after firms enterexport markets, find that “relatively efficient firmsbecome exporters, but ... firms’ costs are not affectedby previous export market participation.” In the caseof imports, there is a tendency for imports to increasewhen the national industry lags in productivity, eitherbecause foreign products then become relativelycheaper or because they embody higher quality. Thistendency moves in the opposite direction from anypossible positive effect that imports may have onproductivity by putting pressure on less efficientfirms. This makes any efficiency-enhancing effect ofimport competition more difficult to detectempirically.

A similar difficulty exists with estimatedrelationships between tariffs and productivity. If

Page 104: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

8-2

greater import competition directly stimulatesproductivity, then lower tariffs, by stimulating importcompetition, should indirectly stimulate productivity.There is now a substantial literature on the politicaleconomy of trade protection, both theoretical andempirical. This literature is reviewed in Rodrik(1995) and, more briefly, in Lee and Swagel (1997).One hypothesis put forward in this literature is thatnations tend to protect weak industries and industriesin decline; thus, lagging productivity growth in aparticular industry may induce lobbying forprotection. The evidence supporting a political-economy effect of low productivity on protection is atpresent no better than tentative. Still, if such an effectwere indeed present, it would tend on its own toinduce a statistical association between high tariffsand low productivity growth. As in the case of tradeflows and productivity, this would introduce anadditional caveat in interpreting the results. Eitherhigh tariffs, by keeping out import competition,reduce firms’ incentive to improve productivity; orfirms, having difficulty in improving productivity andfinding themselves losing sales and profitability, seekto secure greater protection from import competition;or perhaps both.

The empirical work described below tests forlong-run associations between trade (or trade policy)and productivity for a sample of thirteen OECDcountries and eighteeen manufacturing industries,spanning the universe of manufacturing. A number ofstudies have compared OECD productivity growth forthe entire economy and for aggregate manufacturing(most recently in two papers by Bernard and Jones(February 1996, December 1996)). Both Dollar andWolff (1993) and Pilat (1996) have sought to measureproductivity growth for a number of manufacturingindustries and a number of OECD countries. Dollarand Wolff, as mentioned above, make somesuggestive comparisons concerning trade patterns andTFP growth for Japan and the United States. Pilatanalyzes productivity levels and productivity changein a manner analogous to the present study. Pilatfinds that a high degree of export intensity and lowtariffs are associated with high and rapidly growinglabor productivity, while a high degree of importpenetration is associated with low labor productivity.

One of the limitations of the studies discussed inthe above paragraph is that they measure productivityon a value-added (or “single deflation”) basis. Thiscommonly used method counts productivity gainswhen output increases relative to labor and capitalinputs, but ignores purchased intermediate inputs.

An important advantage of the present study isthat both TFP and labor productivity are measured ona quantity basis, taking into account the possibilitythat technological progress may operate by conservingintermediate inputs of materials, semifinished goods,

and equipment. This method of productivitymeasurement, sometimes referred to as “doubledeflation,” requires the construction of a price indexfor intermediate goods in each country and industry.The analysis in this chapter presents and analyzesTFP and labor productivity figures, both on a quantitybasis and on a value-added basis for comparisonpurposes.

Data and Methodology

Growth AccountingConsider the following relationship between the

value of industry output and its components:8.1 PQ �VA + PMM

In which Q represents the quantity of output; Pthe aggregate price level of output (and PQ thusrepresents the value of output); and PMM representsthe value of purchased materials and otherintermediate goods, which can be decomposed into aprice level PM and an index of quantity M using anappropriate price deflator for intermediate goods. Theterm VA thus represents value-added, or the value ofoutput in excess of purchased inputs, which can bepaid out either to workers or firm owners. Further, let8.2 VA � wL + rK

8.3 � = (wL)/VA

8.4 �L = (wL)/PQ

8.5 �K = (rK)/PQ

Equation 8.2 simply defines value-added as thesum of payments to labor (wL) and payments tocapital (rK). Payments to labor in turn equal the wagerate (w) multiplied by the number of workers (L),while payments to capital equal the rental rate oncapital (r) multiplied by the capital stock (K).Equations 8.3 through 8.5 define various shareparameters, with � representing the share of laborcompensation in value-added, �L the share of laborcompensation in output, and �K the value-added paidto capital, as a share of output. With these definitionsin hand, the various measures of productivity can bedefined as a ratio of value-added (or output) to aweighted sum of the inputs used in production ofvalue-added (or output), with the weightscorresponding to the value shares of the inputs. Thus,total factor productivity on a value-added basis isdefined as:

8.6TFPVA �

VAL�K(1–�)

while equations 8.7 through 8.9 define, respectively,total factor productivity on a quantity basis, labor

Page 105: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

8-3

productivity on a value-added basis, and laborproductivity on a quantity basis:

8.7TFPQ =

Q

L�LK�

KM1-�L

-�K

8.8 LPVA = VA/L

8.9 LPQ = Q/L

Several equations for total factor productivity areestimated of the form

8.10 TFPGt0,t1 = �0 + �1 TFPt0 + �2 RESEARCH + �3 TRADE or TRADEPOLICY

The subscripts i,j for countries and industriesapply to each variable, but are omitted for clarity ofexposition. In the above equation, TFPGt0,t1 is theannualized rate of TFP growth between an initial andterminal year, TFPt0 is the level of TFP in the initialyear, relative to the United States, RESEARCH is ameasure of research intensity, and TRADE (TRADEPOLICY) is a measure of trade flows (tariffs).

8.11 LPGt0,t1 = �0 +�1 G(K/L) + �2 LPt0 + �3 RESEARCH + �4 TRADE or TRADEPOLICY

Analogous equations for labor productivity, of theform in equation 8.11, are also estimated. In thisequation LPGt0,t1 represents the annualized growthrate of labor productivity over the relevant timeperiod; LPt0 is the initial level of labor productivity,measured relative to the United States; and G(K/L) isthe growth rate of the capital-labor ratio. This lastterm is required because increases in capital perworker are important determinants of laborproductivity. Since increased capital use is explicitlytaken account of in measures of TFP, thecorresponding variable is unneccessary in the TFPgrowth equation.

Industries with low initial levels of productivitycompared to similar industries in other countries enjoymore opportunities for technological imitation, andthus are likely to enjoy more rapid productivity

growth. Thus, the expected signs of �1 and �2 arenegative. Since more capital per worker contributesto higher labor productivity, �1 is expected to bepositive. More intense research effort is likely tolead to greater productivity growth, so the expectedsigns of �2 and �3 are positive.

The expected sign of the trade or trade policyvariable (�3 or �4) depends on the particular measureof trade or trade policy. Based on the abovediscussion, the expected association between exportintensity and productivity growth is positive, theexpected association of tariffs and productivity growthis negative, and the expected association betweenimport penetration and productivity growth isambiguous. It should be emphasized that theseexpected associations do not depend on causationrunning from trade (or trade policy) to productivity, orfrom productivity to trade (or trade policy), nor doesthis particular test provide information on thedirection of causality.

Equations 8.10 and 8.11 were estimated for eachproductivity measure, in each sample, using ordinaryleast squares (OLS), fixed country effects, fixedindustry effects, random country effects, and randomindustry effects.1 A preferred specification for each

1 Technical note: It should be understood that thevariables in equations 8.10 and 8.11 vary across countriesand industries only, and do not possess a time dimension,even though the underlying data are short time series.The use of period growth rates and period averagescollapses the information in the time series data, so thatthe analysis is for a single period (either the 1980-88period or the 1980-91 period).

Under ordinary least squares (OLS), the equations tobe estimated are of the form

Yij = � + �Xij ,for which Yij is the dependent variable, Xij represents a(vector of) independent variables, and the intercept � isinvariant for the entire sample. Under the fixed effectsspecification, the estimated equation is of the form

Yij = �i + �Xij ,for which the intercepts are assumed to be different foreach group (in this case, either each country, or eachindustry).

The fixed-effects estimator can be implemented eitherby including dummy variables for each group except one,or by transforming the data into differences from groupmeans. If estimated using dummy variables, theappropriateness of the fixed-effects specification versus thenull hypothesis of OLS can be tested with an F-test onthe vector of dummy variables. The random effectsspecification assumes the same functional form as thefixed effects specification, except that the �i are assumedto be drawn independently from a common distributionwith mean zero, rather than taking specific values for eachgroup, and are uncorrelated with the independentvariables. The null hypothesis of random effects can betested independently against the alternative hypothesis offixed effects using a Hausman test. See Hsiao (1986, ch.3) on the construction of the random effects estimator andthe use of the Hausman test in this case.

Page 106: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

8-4

productivity measure and sample is reported basedon the following testing regime. For each equationestimated, the null hypothesis of OLS was tested inturn against the alternative hypothesis of countryfixed effects, and industry fixed effects, using anF-test on the fixed effects. In the event the nullhypothesis was rejected against either alternative, thenull hypothesis of random effects was tested againstthe alternative of fixed effects using a Hausman test.In the case that both the null hypothesis of OLS andthe null of random effects are rejected, thefixed-effects estimator is reported in the regressiontables (tables 8-7 through 8-9). In the case that thenull hypothesis of OLS is rejected, but the nullhypothesis of random effects is not rejected, therandom effects estimator is reported. If the nullhypothesis of OLS cannot be rejected against eitherthe alternative of country fixed effects or industryfixed effects, OLS is reported. In some cases, thisprocedure leads to two alternative specifications, onewith country effects and another with industryeffects. Since these specifications represent non-nested hypotheses which cannot be tested againsteach other directly, both are reported.

Data SourcesThe data for measuring productivity growth were

largely taken from the OECD STAN Database forIndustrial Analysis. This source provided measures ofoutput, value-added, labor input, and annualinvestment. The value of materials was taken as thedifference between output and value-added. Measuresof value-added are given both in current localcurrency and in constant 1985 local currency; the ratiobetween these two measures provided the price indexfor output. The shares of various intermediate goodsand services in M were obtained from the appropriateinput-output tables in the Global Trade AnalysisProject (GTAP) data base. Country-specific prices ofindividual intermediate goods were obtained from avariety of sources, including the OECD STANDatabase itself for manufactures prices, World Bankdata for services prices, and United Nations MonthlyBulletin of Statistics prices on international marketsfor primary products (converted to local currency).Productivity measurements were made on dataconverted to 1985 constant dollars, using thepurchasing-power parity exchange rate for investmentfrom the International Comparisons Project (describedin Summers and Heston (1991)).2 Capital stocks for

2 The PPP exchange rate for investment is the naturalchoice for deflating the investment time series.Alternatives for the other time series include the PPPexchange rates for GDP, or for consumption. GDPincludes a large share of non-tradable services (andconsumption an even higher share), while investment

countries and industries were generated on aperpetual-inventory basis beginning in 1970. Initialvalues for the capital stocks and depreciation rateswere calibrated based on comparable data from theOECD International Sectoral Database.

The set of productivity measures obtained coversthe thirteen countries and eighteen sectors listed inTable 8-1. For a few countries/industries (for example,instruments in Canada), data are insufficient tocalculate productivity measures. Furthermore,investment data for Australia and Canada are missingin all sectors, preventing the construction of capitalstocks for the years after 1988. Thus, two samples ofproductivity growth rates are used in the analysis: asample for 1980-88, including all 13 countries; and asample for 1980-91, including 11 countries butexcluding Australia and Canada. The samples begin in1980 due to the limited coverage of the variable fornumber of researchers in the OECD Basic Scienceand Technology Data (see above). The choice of twosamples reflects the tradeoff between inclusion of thelargest number of countries/industries feasible (TFPcould not be measured for Australia and Canada after1988 with the data at hand) and the measurement ofproductivity over a longer period of time. Inprinciple, using a larger number of years to measurethe productivity growth rate might be more indicativeof long-run behavior. However, the years 1989-91include recession years for most countries in thesample. In these years, production dropped, and thusmeasured productivity growth temporarily droppedbelow its long-term trend. Thus, the results for thelonger time period may not be that much moreinformative, and the results for the 1980-88 samplemay be marginally preferable. Nonetheless, both setsof results are reported. (Though productivity timeseries for most countries and industries werecalculated beginning in 1970, the sample beginning in1980 was used since data on research effort, describedbelow, begins in 1981).

The variable chosen for research intensity was theratio of research scientists and engineers to the totalnumber of workers. The number of researchers wasobtained from OECD Basic Science and TechnologyStatistics, and is available for 1981-92. An alternativevariable, the ratio of R&D to sales, was also tried inthe regression analysis, yielding similar results. Theresearch variable is averaged over either 1981-88 or1981-91 depending on whether productivity ismeasured over 1980-88 or 1980-91. Basic Scienceand Technology Statistics uses different industry

2—Continuedgoods (like manufactured goods in general) are largelytradable. Thus, it was judged that the PPP exchange ratefor investment was a better proxy for international pricecomparisons of manufactures than either the PPPexchange rate for GDP or that for consumption.

Page 107: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

8-5

Table 8-1Sectors and countries used in the analysis

Sector ISIC numbers Countries

Manufacturing 3000 Australia. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Canada

Food, beverages, tobacco 3100 Germany. . . . . . . . . . . . . . DenmarkTextiles, apparel, leather 3200 Finland. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

FranceWood products, furniture 3300 Great Britain. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . ItalyChemicals 3500 (except 3530,3550,3560) Japan. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

NetherlandsPetroleum refining 3530 Norway. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Rubber, plastics 3550, 3560 Sweden. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Non-metallic minerals 3600 United States. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Iron & steel 3710. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Non-ferrous metals 3720. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Metal products 3810. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Non-electrical machinery 3820. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Electrical machinery 3830. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Shipbuilding 3841. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Motor vehicles 3843. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Other transport 3840 (except 3841, 3843). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Professional goods 3850. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Other manufacturing 3860. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Source: OECD STAN Database.

aggregations for science data in earlier and lateryears, which were spliced together with someinterpolation.

Aggregate exports and imports for each countryand sector were obtained from the Statistics CanadaWorld Trade DataBase. These data are reportedaccording to a modified version of the SITC Rev. 2classification, at the 4-digit level, and were concordedto the ISIC categories described in table 8-1.

The export variable is expressed as the ratio ofexports to output, and the import variable is expressedas the ratio of imports to apparent consumption,where apparent consumption is defined as output plusimports minus exports. Data on the average MFNtariff during the late 1980s were obtained from aCD-ROM produced by the World Trade Organization.During the time period under analysis, countries madefew major revisions to their MFN tariff schedules.The tariff variable is measured for each industry ineach country, and is aggregated from a trade-weightedtariff at the two-digit HS level, using trade weights.A simple average tariff was also tried, yielding similarresults.

Summary Features of DataTable 8-2 presents the estimated annual growth

rates of productivity over the 1980-88 period,according to the various measures. Across the various

measures, manufacturing productivity growth has beenrelatively high in Finland, Great Britain, Italy, andJapan; relatively low in Australia, Canada, Denmark,Germany, and the Netherlands; and about average inFrance, Norway, Sweden, and the United States.These rankings are roughly consistent with thoseobtained by the studies cited above. Productivitygrowth is consistently higher when measured on alabor productivity basis than on a TFP basis, becauselabor productivity growth can be enhanced by addingcapital per worker while TFP growth by definitioncannot. Productivity growth measured on avalue-added basis relatively consistently exceeds thatmeasured on a quantity basis, for both laborproductivity and TFP. This may imply that it isharder to conserve materials and intermediate goodsthrough technical change than to conserve labor andcapital. Or, it may be due to the gradual improvementof the quality of labor inputs due to education andtraining (i.e., increases in human capital), and similarimprovements in the quality of capital goods whichare not captured in the price index used for capitalgoods. For this table and the following two tables,comparisons made for the 1980-91 period, using the11 countries with available data for that period, showsimilar patterns.

Table 8-3 contains a series of comparisons of theabsolute level of productivity in aggregatemanufacturing, using the United States level ofproductivity in 1980 as the benchmark. On average,

Page 108: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

8-6

Table 8-2Growth rates of productivity, 1980-88, aggregate manufacturing

Total factor Total factor Labor Laborproductivity productivity productivity productivity(quantity (value-added (quantity (value-added

Country basis) basis) basis) basis)Annualized percentage change

Australia 0.15 0.97 2.11 1.86. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Canada -0.56 1.82 1.24 2.40. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Denmark -0.39 0.59 -1.09 0.43. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Finland 1.89 4.17 3.35 5.16. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . France -0.27 1.73 1.75 2.70. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Germany -0.40 1.12 0.88 1.54. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Great Britain 1.49 4.65 4.71 1.76. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Italy 0.59 3.71 5.14 4.51. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Japan 1.56 3.77 1.77 4.60. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Netherlands -0.84 1.85 0.19 2.38. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Norway -0.77 1.42 1.60 2.25. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Sweden -0.27 1.73 1.61 2.58. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . United States 1.08 2.90 2.27 3.59. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Source: USITC staff calculations - see text for details.

Table 8-3Absolute levels of productivity, 1988, aggregate manufacturing

Total factor Total factor Labor Laborproductivity productivity productivity productivity(quantity (value-added (quantity (value-added

Country basis) basis) basis) basis)United States in 1980 = 100

Australia 69.8 86.5 94.3 77.2. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Canada 102.3 107.5 96.8 102.7. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Denmark 47.7 54.2 81.7 58.7. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Finland 73.8 81.2 92.7 76.1. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . France 76.3 90.7 91.6 88.7. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Germany 66.7 78.0 90.2 82.9. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Great Britain 64.0 67.6 84.5 62.0. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Italy 76.2 82.3 89.1 76.6. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Japan 66.3 71.8 94.5 84.5. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Netherlands 84.7 85.4 86.2 73.0. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Norway 76.5 71.6 84.0 65.3. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Sweden 59.4 62.4 84.7 66.2. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . United States 119.7 132.7 109.0 125.7. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Source: USITC staff calculations - see text for details.

most countries’ measured productivity levels in 1988still lagged the United States level in 1980, with theexception of Canada. Aside from the United States,absolute levels of manufacturing productivity wererelatively high in Canada, France, and Japan, andrelatively low in Denmark, Great Britain, andSweden.

Table 8-4 provides comparisons of the growthrates of productivity in particular manufacturingsectors, ranked by TFP growth on a quantity basis.Manufacturing sectors differ from each other in thedegree of technological opportunities afforded by thecurrent state of science and engineering; thesedifferences in technological opportunity form asignificant part of the explanation for differentproductivity growth rates (Cohen and Levin (1989))

In general, the rankings of sectors by productivitygrowth correspond fairly well with intuitive notionsabout which sectors enjoy greater or lessertechnological opportunities. Electrical and non-electrical machinery; chemicals; rubber and plastics;instruments; and transportation equipment, n.e.c.(which is dominated by aircraft), score relatively highin productivity growth. Sectors based on naturalresource processing or unskilled labor have hadslower productivity growth. These include food,beverages and tobacco; non-ferrous metals; iron andsteel; pulp, paper, and printing; textiles, apparel, andleather; and petroleum refining.

Table 8-4 also illustrates that for each of the fourmeasures of productivity, productivity growth isnegatively correlated with the average tariff. Sectors

Page 109: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

8-7

Table 8-4Growth rates of productivity, 1980-88, particular manufacturing sectors 1

Total factor Total factor Labor Laborproductivity productivity productivity productivity(quantity (value-added (quantity (value-added Average

Industry basis) basis) basis) basis) tariff

Annualized percentage change PercentFood, beverages, and tobacco2(13) -1.98 0.68 -0.22 0.15 9.13Petroleum refining(13) -0.70 1.44 -1.53 3.77 1.52. . . . . . . . . . Automobiles(11) 0.05 0.27 3.51 3.64 6.19. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Pulp, paper, and printing(13) 0.20 1.41 1.16 1.80 2.35. . . . . Iron and steel(13) 0.42 1.12 0.90 1.98 4.32. . . . . . . . . . . . . . Textiles, apparel, and leather(13) 0.46 1.78 2.49 2.54 13.22. Wood products and furniture(13) 0.60 2.31 1.49 2.43 3.28. . Non-ferrous metals(13) 0.69 1.07 0.39 1.83 2.70. . . . . . . . . . Non-metallic minerals(13) 0.86 2.81 2.94 3.51 6.64. . . . . . . Instruments(10) 0.97 3.07 5.98 4.75 4.06. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Transportation equipment, nec(13) 1.00 4.10 0.73 4.18 0.78Metal products(13) 1.13 2.41 2.67 3.09 5.04. . . . . . . . . . . . . Rubber and plastics(13) 1.31 3.48 3.15 3.63 5.62. . . . . . . . . Chemicals(13) 1.34 4.72 2.60 5.24 4.29. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Non-electrical machinery(13) 2.64 3.71 4.79 4.52 2.98. . . . . Other manufacturing(12) 2.64 4.80 4.14 5.83 3.80. . . . . . . . Electrical machinery(13) 2.66 3.69 4.84 5.14 4.46. . . . . . . . . Shipbuilding(13) 5.98 8.05 7.03 8.31 1.23. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Correlation with average tariff -0.38 -0.38 -0.03 -0.41 (3). . . .

1 The number in parentheses for each sector is the number of countries with available data. Productivity growth rateswere calculated as production-weighted averages of country data. Average tariffs were calculated on a trade-weightedbasis for each country and sector, and then averaged using production weights across countries.

2 Excludes data for Finland, for which the trade-weighted average tariff in this category exceeds 70 percent.

3 Not applicable.

Source: USITC staff calculations - see text for details.

such as food, beverages and tobacco; and textiles,apparel and leather have particularly high averagetariffs and low productivity growth rates, whiletariffs are lower in the sectors which exhibit higherproductivity growth. These relationships areillustrated in figure 8-1 for total factor productivityon a quantity basis, and in figure 8-2 for laborproductivity on a value-added basis. The negativerelationship shown would likely be even moreapparent had data been used reflecting tariff cuts inthe Uruguay Round and the Information TechnologyInitiative, which were concentrated in the sectorswith rapidly growing productivity. In addition, hightariffs are correlated with high NTBs across sectors(Pritchett (1996), Lee and Swagel (1997)). Thisindicates that high productivity growth is alsonegatively correlated with total protection fromtariffs and NTBs.

Principal ResultsTable 8-5 provides a key to the names of the

dependent variables used in tables 8-7 through 8-9.Table 8-6 gives descriptive statistics for the data set

used in the regression. Estimates of equations 8.10and 8.11 are presented in tables 8-7 through 8-9. Inall estimates, the coefficient for initial 1980productivity is strongly and significantly negative,indicating that sectors with lower productivity thantheir counterparts in other OECD countries do indeedenjoy faster productivity growth. This implies thatthere are substantial technological spillovers betweenhigh-productivity countries and low-productivitycountries in the OECD, or put another way, thatinternational technological imitation takes place. Forthe regressions of labor productivity, the growth incapital per worker is uniformly positive and stronglysignificant, in accordance with economic theory. Theeffect of sector-level research intensity, measured byresearch personnel as a share of workers, isuniformly positive for seven of the eight productivitymeasures examined, and is generally statisticallysignificant.

The results on the trade and trade policy measuresare mixed. The simple negative correlation betweentariffs and productivity growth is fairly robust toapplication of the regression framework. A total ofeleven specifications are reported for the eightproductivity measures. The tariff variable is

Page 110: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

8-8

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

–2 0 2 4 6

Figure 8-1Tariffs and total factor productivity growth, by sector

Ave

rage

tarif

f

Total factor productivity growth on quantity basis, 1980-88

Source: USITC staff calculations – see text.

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

0 2 4 6 8 10

Figure 8-2Tariffs and labor productivity growth, by sector

Ave

rage

tarif

f

Labor productivity growth (value-added basis), 1980-88

Source: USITC staff calculations – see text.

Page 111: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

8-9

Table 8-5Key to names of dependent variables in Tables 8-6 through 8-8

Variable name Description

GTQ88 Growth of total factor productivity, quantity basis, 1980-88. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . GTQ91 Growth of total factor productivity, quantity basis, 1980-91. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . GTVA88 Growth of total factor productivity, value-added basis, 1980-88. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . GTVA91 Growth of total factor productivity, value-added basis, 1980-91. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . GLQ88 Growth of labor productivity, quantity basis, 1980-88. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . GLQ91 Growth of labor productivity, quantity basis, 1980-91. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . GLVA88 Growth of labor productivity, value-added basis, 1980-88. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . GLVA91 Growth of labor productivity, value-added basis, 1980-91. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Table 8-6Descriptive statistics for regression data

Mean Standard deviation

Productivity growth rate (APC 1) 1980-1988 1980-1991 1980-1988 1980-1991

Total factor productivity, quantity basis 0.0096 0.0053 0.0039 0.0031. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Total factor productivity, value-added basis 0.0270 0.0222 0.0034 0.0031. . . . . . . . . . . . Labor productivity, quantity basis 0.262 0.0256 0.0453 0.0408. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Labor productivity, value-added basis 0.0336 0.0312 0.0038 0.0033. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Growth of capital per worker1 0.0216 0.0281 0.0259 0.0252. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Researchers (ratio to total workers) 0.0125 0.0151 0.0223 0.0233. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Exports (ratio to output) 0.322 0.326 0.280 0.280. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Imports (ration to apparent consumption) 0.337 0.343 0.27 0.275. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Variables common to both samples

Mean Standard deviation

Productivity level in 1980 (U.S. = 1) Total factor productivity, quantity basis 0.940 0.367. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Total factor productivity, value-added basis 0.729 0.413. . . . . . . . . . . . Labor productivity, quantity basis 0.677 0.353. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Labor productivity, value-added basis 0.698 0.404. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Tariffs (ad valorem, percent) 5.70 6.19. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1 Annual proportionate change.

Note.—Sample for 1980-91 excludes Australia and Canada.Source: USITC staff calculations - see text for details.

Page 112: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

Table 8-7Effects of Tariffs on OECD Manufacturing Productivity (T-statistics in parentheses)

Growth in InitialProductivity Group capital per 1980 Researchers/ Adj. Hausman 2

measure effects Tariffs worker productivity workers Constant N R 2 F-test 1 test

GTQ88 none -.000820 (4) -.0593 .164 .0682 214 .228 0.56, 0.855 (4). . . . . . (2.17) (7.53) (1.50) (8.23)

GTQ91 Ind., -.000403 (4) -.0559 .140 .0348 177 .311 7.47 0.03. . . . . . random (1.29) (8.79) (1.76) (8.22)

GTVA88 Cty., -.000636 (4) -.0246 .123 .0209 215 .086 2.80 0.66. . . . . . random (1.80) (4.39) (1.21) (6.95)

GTVA91 Ind., .000065 (4) -.0270 .205 (4) 179 .356 5.99 (3). . . . . . fixed (0.17) (5.07) (2.11)

GTVA91 Cty., -.000483 (4) -.0137 .135 .0137 179 .034 2.32 0.14. . . . . . random (1.32) (2.49) (1.44) (4.68)

GLQ88 Cty., -.000192 .804 -.0574 -.001 .0207 215 .396 2.29 0.67. . . . . . . random (0.51) (8.66) (7.99) (0.01) (6.12)

GLQ91 Ind., .000100 .658 -.0374 .226 .0088 179 .313 3.01 2.75. . . . . . . random (0.24) (6.79) (5.47) (2.13) (3.12)

GLQ91 Cty., -.000440 .858 -.0329 .138 .0135 179 .358 2.98 0.51. . . . . . . random (1.14) (8.77) (4.66) (1.41) (3.21)

GLVA88 Cty., -.000411 .561 -.0249 .193 .0152 215 .223 2.49 0.57. . . . . . random (1.17) (6.54) (4.29) (1.91) (5.26)

GLVA91 Ind., .000148 .567 -.0258 .231 (4) 179 .473 4.25 12.08. . . . . . fixed (0.41) (6.88) (4.84) (2.44)

GLVA91 Cty., -.000344 .672 -.0125 .211 .0091 179 .276 2.11 0.15. . . . . . random (1.04) (7.90) (2.37) (2.46) (3.04)

1 A significant F-test implies rejection of the null hypothesis of ordinary least squares (OLS) in favor of the alternative hypothesis of fixed effects.2 A significant Hausman test implies rejection of the null hypothesis of random effects in favor of the alternative hypothesis of fixed effects.3 A critical value for the Hausman test could not be computed. The choice between fixed and random effects was made on the basis of adjusted R2.4 Not applicable.5 The first F-test is for the null hypothesis of OLS vs. industry fixed effects; the second is for the null hypothesis of OLS vs. country fixed effects. In

neither case could the null hypothesis be rejected at .10 or less.Note.—Table 8-5 contains a key to names of the dependent variables. Coefficients printed in italics are statistically significant at .10, coefficients printedin bold are statistically significant at .05, and coefficients printed in bold italics are statistically significant at .01 (one-tailed test).Source: USITC staff calculations, see text.

Page 113: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

Table 8-8Effects of Exports on OECD Manufacturing Productivity

Growth in InitialProductivity Group Exports/ capital per 1980 Researchers/ Adj. Hausman 2

measure effects outputs worker productivity workers Constant N R 2 F-test 1 test

GTQ88 none .0071 (4) -.0579 .203 .0594 214 .202 0.57, 0.9755 (4). . . . . . (0.72) (7.26) (1.87) (6.89)

GTQ91 Ind., .0023 (4) -.0670 .097 .0707 177 .547 7.66 (3) . . . . . . fixed (0.31) (10.44) (1.18) (5.80)

GTQ91 Cty., .0315 (4) -.0438 .094 -.0136 177 .268 2.06 2.46. . . . . . random (3.65) (6.82) (1.12) (4.08)

GTVA88 Cty., .0182 (4) -.0231 .104 .0157 215 .086 3.29 1.99. . . . . . random (1.89) (4.11) (1.02) (5.26)

GTVA91 Ind., .0011 (4) -.0269 .205 .0338 179 .355 5.94 11.35. . . . . . fixed (0.12) (4.99) (2.10) (2.67)

GTVA91 Cty., .0311 (4) -.0111 .073 .0075 179 .076 3.38 2.26. . . . . . random (3.12) (2.07) (0.77) (2.63)

GLQ88 Cty., .0273 .801 -.0553 -.054 .0168 215 .416 2.95 2.61. . . . . . . random (2.67) (8.83) (7.79) (0.50) (4.99)

GLQ91 Ind., .0101 .638 -.0387 .247 .0182 179 .460 2.70 3.65. . . . . . . fixed (0.93) (6.18) (5.24) (2.13) (1.22)Cty., .0374 .845 -.0282 .075 .0048 179 .400 4.44 4.47random (3.68) (8.93) (4.11) (0.78) (1.12)

GLVA88 Cty., .0155 .567 -.0241 .173 .0124 215 .228 2.81 1.34. . . . . . random (1.62) (6.67) (4.16) (1.70) (4.30)

GLVA91 Ind., .0076 .578 -.0253 .236 .0249 179 .475 4.22 14.21. . . . . . fixed (0.89) (4.75) (4.75) (2.49) (2.08)Cty., .0219 .660 -.0109 .169 .0050 179 .295 2.69 1.99random (2.42) (7.84) (2.09) (1.95) (1.67)

1 A significant F-test implies rejection of the null hypothesis of ordinary least squares (OLS) in favor of the alternative hypothesis of fixed effects.2 A significant Hausman test implies rejection of the null hypothesis of random effects in favor of the alternative hypothesis of fixed effects.3 A critical value for the Hausman test could not be computed. The choice between fixed and random effects was made on the basis of adjusted R2.4 Not applicable.5 The first F-test is for the null hypothesis of OLS vs. industry fixed effects; the second is for the null hypothesis of OLS vs. country fixed effects. In

neither case could the null hypothesis be rejected at .10 or less.Note.—Table 8-5 contains a key to names of the dependent variables. Coefficients printed in italics are statistically significant at .10, coefficients printed inbold are statistically significant at .05, and coefficients printed in bold italics are statistically significant at .01 (one-tailed test).Source: USITC staff calculations, see text.

Page 114: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

Table 8-9Effects of Imports on OECD Manufacturing Productivity

Imports Growth in InitialProductivity Group apparent capital per 1980 Researchers/ Adj. Hausman 2

measure effects consumption worker productivity workers Constant N R 2 F-test 1 test

GTQ88 none -.0049 (4) -.0586 .208 .0635 214 .201 0.59, 0.755 (4). . . . . . (0.47) (7.37) (1.92) (7.43)

GTQ91 Ind., -.0075 (4) -.0680 .076 .0767 177 .549 8.10 (3). . . . . . fixed (0.97) (10.63) (0.91) (6.15)

GTVA88 Cty., .0036 (4) -.0239 .131 .0147 215 .070 2.78 1.03. . . . . . random (0.33) (4.25) (1.26) (5.30)

GTVA91 Ind., -.0104 (4) -.0281 .186 .0415 179 .360 6.20 133.69. . . . . . fixed (1.12) (5.23) (1.89) (3.16)

GTVA91 Cty., .0120 (4) -.0127 .120 .0089 179 .030 2.44 1.04. . . . . . random (1.06) (2.32) (1.24) (3.17)

GLQ88 Cty., .0054 .810 -.0569 -.008 .0188 215 .397 2.30 2.74. . . . . . . random (0.64) (8.78) (7.85) (0.07) (5.24)

GLQ91 Ind., -.0053 .666 -.0377 .214 .0121 179 .316 3.08 4.55. . . . . . . random (0.49) (6.78) (5.34) (2.03) (3.32)

GLQ91 Cty., .0136 .858 -.0307 .125 .0091 179 .359 3.24 2.74. . . . . . . random (1.19) (8.77) (4.31) (1.26) (2.01)

GLVA88 Cty., .0010 .570 -.0245 .204 .0127 215 .217 2.44 0.85. . . . . . random (0.09) (6.67) (4.22) (1.97) (4.48)

GLVA91 Ind., -.0044 .559 -.0261 .223 .0322 179 .473 4.32 18.70. . . . . . fixed (0.49) (6.70) (4.89) (2.34) (2.57)

GLVA91 Cty., .0054 .671 -.0012 .209 .0071 179 .272 2.14 0.82. . . . . . random (0.54) (7.86) (2.26) (2.37) (2.31)

1 A significant F-test implies rejection of the null hypothesis of ordinary least squares (OLS) in favor of the alternative hypothesis of fixed effects.2 A significant Hausman test implies rejection of the null hypothesis of random effects in favor of the alternative hypothesis of fixed effects.3 A critical value for the Hausman test could not be computed. The choice between fixed and random effects was made on the basis of adjusted R2 .4 Not applicable.5 The first F-test is for the null hypothesis of OLS vs. industry fixed effects; the second is for the null hypothesis of OLS vs. country fixed effects. In

neither case could the null hypothesis be rejected at .10 or less.Note.—Table 8-5 contains a key to names of the dependent variables. Coefficients printed in italics are statistically significant at .10, coefficients printed inbold are statistically significant at .05, and coefficients printed in bold italics are statistically significant at .01 (one-tailed) test. The coefficient on imports isinterpreted using a two-tailed test.

Source: USITC staff calculations, see text.

Page 115: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

8-13

negatively correlated with productivity in eight ofthese, and is statistically significant at the 10 percentlevel or better for three, all measures of TFP. Forthe other five negatively signed specifications, theestimated t-statistic is at least one standard deviationaway from zero, but falls short of the 10 percentlevel of significance. For the three specifications inwhich the tariff variable is positively signed, itscoefficient is negligibly different from zero. Allthree of these specifications employ industry effects.For two of these, F-tests and Hausman tests cannotreject an alternate specification with country effects,and with a stronger negative sign.

The share of exports to output is uniformlypositively associated with productivity growth, aftercontrolling for initial productivity, research effort and(where appropriate) growth in capital per worker.This positive association is statistically significant at.10 or better in seven of the twelve specificationsreported, and significant at .05 or better in sixspecifications. As with the tariff variable, results forthe export variable are stronger when estimated withcountry effects than with industry effects (thisgeneralization also holds for the additionalspecifications estimated but not reported due tounfavorable F-tests or Hausman tests).

The share of imports to apparent consumption isuncorrelated with productivity growth after controllingfor relevant determinants of productivity growth. Thecoefficient on imports is positive in six specificationsand negative in five, in no case achieving significance

at 10 percent or better. Because of the theoreticalambiguity of the relationship between imports andproductivity, a stricter two-tailed test of thesignificance level is used for the coefficient onimports. Using a one-tailed test, however, would notyield any significant coefficients either.

In summary, among manufacturing industries inthe OECD, there is a positive correlation betweenexports and productivity growth, a negativecorrelation between tariffs and productivity growth,and no apparent correlation between imports andproductivity growth. These results are consistent withthe economic considerations discussed above.

Concluding ObservationsIt should be emphasized that while the results

presented here show a positive relationship betweenproductivity and exports, and a negative relationshipbetween productivity and tariffs, it is premature toargue from these results that export experiencedirectly enhances productivity in OECDmanufacturing, or that protection from internationalcompetition has harmed productivity. Alternateexplanations for these phenomena exist in terms of therole of productivity in determining patterns ofcomparative advantage, and in terms of the politicaleconomy of tariffs. Further work on the simultaneityamong trade flows, productivity growth, and tariffformation may yield clearer insights.

Page 116: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted
Page 117: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

9-1

CHAPTER 9The Effect of Openness on Labor Markets

and Human Capital

Hypothesis TestedThis chapter explores and tests the hypothesis that

openness to trade has a direct effect on the size andquality of the labor force, and thus an effect oneconomic growth. It is plausible to suggest that sucheffects might exist, but it is also reasonable to supposethat they would be small. In fact, the exploratoryempirical work that is reported here has been able tofind some evidence of connections between opennessand some measures of human capital. Beforedescribing these results, some definitions andbackground discussion are in order.

BackgroundThe connections between economic growth and

increases in human capital have also been wellestablished. In chapters 2 and 3 a sample of theliterature on this topic was described. Historically ithas been observed that economic growth leads tohuman capital growth. Increased prosperity helps toinduce the demographic transition (a country’stransition, described in chapter 3, from higher tolower mortality rates followed by a transition fromhigher to lower birth rates), leading to increases inboth the size and education of the population.Corresponding shifts of the population from rural tourban residence and from agricultural tomanufacturing employment are further manifestationsof this phenomenon, along with increases in the laborforce participation rate. Conversely, an increasinglyeducated and skilled labor force is an increasinglyproductive one; with higher output per worker, and alarger proportion of the population at work, growth inper capita income almost tautologically follows.

The hypothesis is that there exists a significantdirect link between trade and the growth of humancapital, not mediated by income growth. One mightconjecture a variety of mechanisms by which thislinkage could work. For example, increased tradewould lead to increased exposure to foreignproduction practices; it could lead to increasedtemporary emigration to obtain schooling in foreigncountries; most directly, perhaps, foreign direct

investment would be expected to lead to the trainingof a local labor force in new manufacturing facilities,with the import of new technology.

There has been some recent work estimating theeffects of human capital stocks and growth rates oneconomic development, in the presence of openness totrade. Gould and Ruffin (1995) based their work ona standard Solow growth model, augmented to includethe contribution of human capital, and attempt toseparate the effect of human capital on growth fromits function as an input to production. They findevidence that human capital does contribute togrowth, and that this contribution to growth is higherin an open economy. Barthelemy, Dessus, andVaroudakis (1997) also find a connection between thecontribution of human capital to growth and theopenness of the economy to world trade, in whichhuman capital enhances the ability of a country tobenefit from the exposure to new technologies thatcomes with openness to trade. This is not saying thatopenness enhances human capital, but that it, in asense, increases the returns to human capital andaugments its effect on growth. This chapter willsummarize some of the very simple empirical workperformed by ITC staff to attempt to isolate arelationship between openness to trade and humancapital. In this analysis, all data are taken from theWorld Bank STARS data set.

Data and MethodologyThis chapter seeks to determine whether openness

to trade has a direct effect on human capital measures,independent of the effect of income (as measured hereby per capita GDP). “Human capital” in thisexperiment is measured in three ways: percent of thelabor force that is female, percent of the populationliving in cities, and percent of the eligible populationthat has enrolled in secondary schooling (which maybe greater than 1, where there is significantenrollment of students of ages outside the standard

Page 118: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

9-2

age group).1 All variables are calculated from timeseries data on a set of 75 countries selected from theSTARS data set, on the basis of completeness ofavailable data from 1970 to 1995, pooled into 5-yearintervals. Thus each country is represented by 5observations, and each variable for each observationis in fact the mean of 5 annual observations. Thefollowing table (table 9-1) summarizes the mean,standard deviation, and bounds of the opennessvariables and the human capital measures.

As measures of openness to trade, both the ratioof trade to GDP, ((exports plus imports)/GDP), andthe Sachs-Warner variable summed over the five yearswere considered. Figures 9-1 through 9-3 plot thedistribution of the human capital variables against theSachs-Warner index. For each value of the index, theaverage value of the human capital variable is plotted,as well as its value plus and minus one standarddeviation. In these plots it is possible to see somepositive relationship between urbanization andSachs-Warner openness, and between schooling andopenness. The link between feminization of the laborforce and openness is less striking, but the variation inthis variable seems to narrow with increasingopenness. In particular, among the most openeconomies there are fewer countries with very lowfemale shares of the labor force. Figures 9-4 to 9-6are scatter plots, showing the distributions of each ofthe human capital variables plotted against thetrade/GDP ratio. These plots are somewhat cloudy,indicating that the bivariate relationship may also berather nebulous.

The human capital variables were regressed on thelog of GDP per capita, and on the openness variables,in an attempt to ascertain whether there is a

1 Because some of these variables are expressed aspercentages, a value between zero and one hundred, theyare converted to a logistic form for analysis. First theyare converted to a fraction between zero and one (i.e.,they are divided by 100). Then, each of these proportions“P” is converted to a logit, where logit (P) is the log ofthe “odds ratio”, P/(1-P). For example, if a country’ssecondary schooling completion rate is reported as 65percent, this is converted to log(.65/.35), or 0.62. Thisprocedure transforms a variable that is constrained to liein the interval from 1 to 100 (percent) into one that is inprinciple unbounded.

relationship between openness and human capital,independent of the effect of income. In addition, the14-year dependency ratio is included as anindependent variable. The presence of dependentchildren can be expected to affect human capitalinvestment by reducing the income available forschooling, by adding to the domestic responsibilitiesof mothers (and increasing the cost of female laborforce participation), and by increasing the aggregatecost of educating the dependent population.Estimates were performed with ordinary least squaresregression techniques.

Results Results of the experiments are presented in tables

9-2 and 9-3 above, but can be briefly summarized bynoting that in some cases openness has a consistentsignificant positive link to several human capitalmeasures. To the extent that income is adequatelycontrolled for in these simple single-equation models,the estimation shows some evidence for a direct linkbetween trade openness and at least the moreaggregate “demographic” measures of human capital,urbanization and the feminization of the workforce.In contrast, the secondary schooling enrollment ratiohas a weak positive link to the Sachs-Warner opennessmeasure, and a negative relation to the trade/GDPratio measure. There is a significant link between theSachs-Warner openness measure and the female laborforce share, and between the trade/GDP ratio and theurbanization ratio. This may in part be due to a largeshare of female labor in trade-oriented firms, and tothe expansion of urban trade-oriented manufacturing.

Per-capita income itself has the significantpositive relationship one would expect with schoolingand urbanization. It has an insignificant but negativerelationship with the labor force proportion female.The dependency ratio has a strong negativerelationship with schooling and the female labor forceproportion, as one would expect; a large number ofchildren raises the cost of schooling and makes femalelabor force participation more difficult. In separateexperiments (not shown here) the omission of thedependency ratio variable did not affect the coefficienton trade openness.

Table 9–1Means, Standard Deviations, Minima, and Maxima of Principal Variables

StandardMean Deviation Minimum Maximum

Population urban (fraction of total) 0.45 0.25 0.027 1.000 . . . . . . . . Secondary school enrollment (ratio to total) 0.35 0.28 0.000 1.076Female share of labor force 0.32 0.10 0.060 0.499 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Sachs–Warner 5–year sum (see text) 2.13 2.38 0.000 5.000 . . . . . Trade/GDP ratio 0.61 0.46 0.092 3.782. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Page 119: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

9-3

0

20

40

60

80

100

Figure 9-1Urban population vs. openness, as measured by Sachs-Warner index

Urb

an p

opul

atio

n (%

of t

otal

pop

ulat

ion)

Sachs-Warner index

Source: World Bank (1994) and Sachs and Warner (1995).

1 2 3 4 50

Average plus 1 standard deviation

Average minus 1 standard deviationAverage

0

20

40

60

80

100

Figure 9-2Secondary school enrollment vs. openness, as measured by Sachs-Warner index

Sec

onda

ry s

choo

l enr

ollm

ent r

atio

Sachs-Warner index

Source: World Bank (1994) and Sachs and Warner (1995).

1 2 3 4 50

Average plus 1 standard deviation

Average minus 1 standard deviationAverage

Page 120: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

9-4

15

20

25

30

35

40

45

Figure 9-3Female labor force vs. openness, as measured by Sachs- Warner index

Fem

ale

labo

r fo

rce

(% o

f tot

al la

bor)

Sachs-Warner index

Source: World Bank (1994) and Sachs and Warner (1995).

1 2 3 4 50

Average plus 1 standard deviation

Average minus 1 standard deviationAverage

0

20

40

60

80

100

0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0

Figure 9-4 Urban population vs. openness, as measured by trade/GDP ratio

Urb

an p

opul

atio

n (%

of t

otal

pop

ulat

ion)

Trade/GDP ratioSource: World Bank (1994).

Page 121: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

9-5

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0

Figure 9-5Secondary school enrollment vs. openness, as measured by trade/GDP ratio

Sec

onda

ry s

choo

l enr

ollm

ent r

atio

Trade/GDP ratioSource: World Bank (1994).

0

10

20

30

40

50

0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0

Figure 9-6Female labor force vs. openness, as measured by trade/GDP ratio

Fem

ale

labo

r fo

rce

(% o

f tot

al la

bor)

Trade/GDP ratio

Source: World Bank (1994).

Note.—The higher the openess figure the more a country is considered to be open.

Page 122: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

9-6

Table 9-2Effects of Trade Openness on Human Capital, with Dependency Ratio (Openness measured by Sachs - Warner)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Dependent Variable:ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Secondary SchoolingRatioÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Labor ForceProportion Female

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Urban PopulationRatio

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎIndependent Variable

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ConstantÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-4.35(-6.10)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.28(-0.72)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-5.04(-9.24)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

GDP/CapitaÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.673(10.04)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.032(-0.89)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.689(13.66)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Openness(Sachs-Warner)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.004(0.12)ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.033(2.05)ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.0005(0.02)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Dependency Ratio ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-1.692(-4.04)ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.523(-2.29)ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.223(-0.690)ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Adjusted R-SquaredÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.63ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.06ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.66

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Sample size ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

339ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

367ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

362

Note: T-statistics are in parentheses with significance as follows:italics = Significant at the 90 percent confidence level.bold = Significant at the 95 percent confidence levelitalic bold = Significant at the 99 percent confidence level.

Source: U.S. International Trade Commission staff calculations.

Table 9-3Effects of Trade Openness on Human Capital, with Dependency Ratio (Openness measured byTrade/GDP Ratio)ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Dependent Variable:

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Secondary SchoolingRatio

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Labor ForceProportion Female

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Urban PopulationRatio

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Independent Variable ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Constant ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-4.32(-6.07)ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.27(-0.69)ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-5.11(-9.42)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

GDP/Capita ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.689(10.59)ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.017(-0.50)ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.679(13.88)ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Openness(Trade/GDP Ratio)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.218(-1.74)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.069(1.09)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.254(2.06)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Dependency RatioÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-1.706(-4.23)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.642(-2.91)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.225(-0.726)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Adjusted R-Squared ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.64ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.06ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.66

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Sample size ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

339ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

367ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

362

See notes to table 9-2.

Page 123: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

10-1

CHAPTER 10Income-Trade Interactions in the Analysis

of Trade Liberalization

International trade has grown more rapidly thanworldwide income in recent decades, and globalpatterns of consumption have shown broad shiftsamong different categories of goods and services. Theanalyses presented in this chapter examine differencesin the tendency of trade in differentl goods to growmore rapidly than income for different countries, andrelate those differences to the tendency of differentgoods to grow disproportionately in globalconsumption as global income grows. As discussed inchapters 3, 4, and 5, more accurate estimates of theelasticities of trade and consumption with respect toincome are useful for validation of dynamicsimulation models against historical data, and moreaccurate and detailed estimates of these elasticities canimprove the quality of estimates obtained fromdynamic simulation modeling of the global economy.Models which assume, implicity or explicitly, that allforms of trade and consumption grow proportionatelywith income may understate the benefits of tradeliberalization in a growing economy.

Four types of empirical explorations are presentedin this chapter. First, econometric estimates of theincome elasticity of demand for imports are generatedfor a number of countries. Then, these estimates areaggregated into an estimate of the global incomeelasticity of trade, which adjusts for shifts in therelative prices of tradable goods country by country.The estimate obtained indicates that every $1 increasein global real income during 1974-93 induced anincrease in world trade of approximately $1.82.Second, gross estimates of the global income elasticityof trade in particular sectors, disaggregated to the4-digit SITC level, are presented for the period1980-95. These estimates indicate that a substantialshare of world trade is concentrated in certainparticularly rapidly-growing categories, dominated bytransport equipment, machinery (particularlyelectronics), and apparel. The calculated grossincome elasticities in these sectors substantiallyexceed unity. Third, an estimate is presented of theexport elasticity of world demand for U.S. machineryand transport equipment with respect to real income inthe rest of the world. Machinery and transportequipment account for nearly half of U.S. exports, and

U.S. exports in these categories have grown morerapidly than other exports in recent years. Theestimate is carried out using a technique which isparticularly suitable for representing income and priceelasticities in a flexible manner consistent witheconomic theory.1 The results indicate that during1980-95, an increase of $1 in the rest of the world’sGDP induced an increase in U.S. exports ofmachinery and transport equipment of $1.65. Fourth,an analysis is presented of the possibility that globalshifts in consumption patterns may partly explain thesectoral pattern of rapid trade growth in recent years.In this analysis, the income elasticity of consumptionis examined using cross-section data for a sample ofregions comprising most of the world economy.These data permit comparison of consumptionpatterns in lower-income and higher-income countries.Categories of manufactures that are more important inthe budgets of consumers in higher-income countriescorrespond broadly to the categories of manufactureswith particularly rapid growth in trade. The rapidgrowth of services consumption suggests thepossibility of rapid growth in global services trade.Finally, a brief assessment is offered of the prospectsthat global trade will continue to grow more rapidlythan global income in the immediate future.

This analysis is not intended to identify all thepossible forces that may explain the fact that trade hasgrown more rapidly than income. As pointed out inchapter 3, ongoing trade liberalization and thecheapening of transportation and communications mayalso play a significant role in the story. The availableliterature does not provide a satisfactory integration ofthese various explanations into a unifying econometricframework, owing in part to the difficulty ofquantifying the time-series behavior of trade

1 The income elasticity of demand for a givencommodity is the ratio of the percentage change in thequantity of the commodity demanded to the percentagechange in income. (For more on income elasticities, seesection “Trade, Income Growth, and Patterns of Demand,”in chapter 3.) The price elasticity of demand for a givencommodity is the ration of the percentage change in thequantity of the commodity demanded to the percentage inprice. For background information on elasticities, seeTheil (1975).

Page 124: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

10-2

liberalization and transactions costs. Nonetheless,the evidence presented here suggests that theinfluence of expanding incomes on consumption andtrade provides a significant part of the explanationfor rapid trade growth.

Estimates of National andGlobal Income Elasticities

of Import DemandAs was mentioned in chapter 3, during 1960-95

real world trade grew at 6.1 percent per year whilereal world output grew at 3.8 percent per year. Sinceworld output equals world income, and since thedefinition of income elasticity of trade is thepercentage change in trade divided by the percentagechange in income, these raw data can be used tocompute an estimate of the gross elasticity of worldtrade with respect to world income of 6.1/3.8, orapproximately 1.61. Economists generally prefer towork with the more focused concept of an incomeelasticity of import demand, which recognizes that thedemand for imports depends on the relative prices ofimports with respect to other goods. If import priceshave fallen relative to other prices, this could accountfor some part of the increase in global trade. There areno directly available data on the aggregate importprice for the world, and the construction of such aprice involves significant conceptual difficulties.These difficulties largely explain why direct econo-metric estimates of the global income elasticity ofimport demand are not found in the literature. Thedifficulties are circumvented here by generatingcountry-by-country estimates of the income elasticityof import demand, using country-specific import anddomestic prices, and aggregating these to provide anestimate of the global income elasticity.

The econometric estimates of national incomeelasticities in this section are aggregated to anumerical estimate of a world income elasticity oftrade according to:

������w

i�

i + (1 – wi)�x = �w� �

where wi is the share of country i in worldimports; i is the econometrically estimated incomeelasticity of import demand for country i; x is theassumed income elasticity of import demand for therest of the world, and w is the estimated incomeelasticity of world trade. The value of x is

provided by assumption; a value of 0 generates anabsolute lower bound for plausible estimates of theglobal income elasticity w , while a value of x =1 is used to generate a conservative “best estimate”of w. The hypothesis that the global incomeelasticity does not exceed 1 can be tested byimposing w = 1 in equation 10.1 and using theeconometric estimates of i to solve for x. If thevalue of x obtained by this procedure is negative(which violates the reasonable lower bound of 0),then the global income elasticity exceeds 1.

Calculation of National IncomeElasticities of Import Demand

The ModelImport demand functions were estimated for a

number of countries. In equation 10.2, the subscriptsk and t stand for countries and years, respectively:2

log qk = �0,k + 0,k t = 0,kDk,t t +

k,ylogYk + kDYDk,tlogYk +

k,pdlog PDk + k pm logPMk + �k

������

where qk = real imports

�0,k = constant term

0,k = coefficient of the time trend

D k,t = a dummy variable, set equal to 1 after an episode of structural change in country k and equal to 0 otherwise (see under “Estimation Strategy and Results by Country,” below)

2 By using logarithms for both the dependent andindependent variables, the regression coefficients representelasticities. For a review of the relationship betweenfunctional form and elasticity in regression equations, seeDonnelly (1996). For a general description of this typeof econometric models, see Deaton and Muellbauer (1986,p. 17).

Page 125: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

10-3

�k, y = elasticity of imports with respect to income for country k

�k,Dy = marginal increase in income elasticity of imports after structural break in country k

Yk = real income in country k

�k, pd = elasticity of imports with respect to domestic prices in country k

PDk = domestic price level in country k

�k, pm = elasticity of imports with respect to import prices in country k

PMk = import price level in country k

�k = error term for country k

The expected sign for the regression coefficient ofreal income (that is, the income elasticity of imports ispositive) since increases in income should induceincreases in import demand. In the case of astructural break �k,y represents the income elasticitybefore the structural break and �k,y + �k,Dy representsthe income elasticity after the structural break; thus,both � k, y and � k, y + � k,D y are expected to bepositive. The expected sign of the import priceelasticity is negative, since more expensive importsdiscourage importation. The expected sign of thedomestic price elasticity is positive, since highdomestic prices encourage substitution towardsimports. This specification, expressing import demandas a function of income levels, and domestic andimport prices, is the most widely used one inestimating demand for imports.3

The DataThe econometric analysis included the following

19 countries: Argentina, Canada, Colombia, Côted’Ivoire, France, Germany, India, Indonesia, Italy,Japan, Mexico, Nigeria, Pakistan, South Africa,

3 The most recent major study (Carone (1996)) onU.S. income elasticities of import demand used thisspecification. Carone partially justifies the choice of thisspecification with an econometrics study by Thursby andThursby (1984), which tested the most commonly usedspecifications to model aggregate import demand for theUnited States, Canada, Germany, Japan, and the UnitedKingdom. This study found the functional forms inequation 10.1 to be preferable to several alternatives,based on considerations of the efficiency and unbiasednessof the estimates.

Thailand, Turkey, the United States, the UnitedKingdom, and Zimbabwe. These countries wereselected in order to obtain both representation oflarge economies and broad coverage in terms ofregions, consistent with data availability. Annualdata for 1970-93 were obtained from the WorldBank’s STARS database. The GDP deflator was usedas a proxy for domestic prices and the import priceindex as a proxy for import prices.

Estimation Strategy and Results byCountry

Estimation was carried out on the first-differencedform of equation 10.2. After initial estimation withOLS, the method of seemingly unrelated regression(SUR) was applied to improve the efficiency of theestimates and to account for potentialcontemporaneous correlation of the error terms.4

From the SUR results, a specification for eachindividual country was selected based upon thecorrectness of the sign of the coefficients and their

4 Technical note - Dickey-Fuller unit root testsindicated that each of the time series used in this analysiswas integrated of order 1. Johansen’s full informationmaximum likelihood (FIML) procedure was used to testcointegration among the variables. The test rejected thenull hypothesis of no cointegration among the variablesfor the countries tested, and identified multiplecointegrating vectors. The logarithms of the data werefirst-differenced prior to estimation in order to render thetime series individually stationary. First-differencingvectors of nonstationary but cointegrated variables raiseswell-known issues with respect to appropriate estimationtechnique; see Engle and Granger (1987) and Johansenand Juselius (1990).

Pairwise tests on real income and real imports foreach country reveal that these variables are notcointegrated. This result implies that the multiplecointegrating vectors found by the Johansen testprincipally involve the two price terms, and that purgingthe data of its long-run components through firstdifferencing is unlikely to affect the estimated incomeelasticities significantly.

Using both the CUSUM test and Chow tests onequation 10.1, estimated by ordinary least squares,structural breaks in the estimated relationship wereidentified for certain countries. In order to conservedegrees of freedom, the structural break was accounted forby interacting the dummy variable, D k,t, with the incomeelasticity coefficient and/or the coefficient for the timetrend, β 0,k . Structural breaks occurred for the followingcountries (the year of the break is indicated inparentheses): Canada (1981), Colombia (1984), Côted’Ivoire (1980), France (1978), Germany (1980), India(1982), Italy (1988), Japan (1985), Mexico (1986), Nigeria(1981), Pakistan (1975), South Africa (1985), Turkey(1976), and the United Kingdom (1978). At these dates,the p-value of the Chow test for each country is

Page 126: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

10-4

statistical significance (Table 10-1). The estimatesaccount for structural breaks in the time series andfirst-order autocorrelation. Several alternate specifi-cations were tested with respect to the order ofautocorrelation and the treatment of the structuralbreak. While these do not exhaust the full range ofpotentially applicable econometric techniques, it islikely that the principal result presented in thissection, namely, that the global income elasticity oftrade substantially exceeds 1, is robust to alternativeestimation procedures.

The estimates in table 10-1 are broadly consistentwith economic theory, with the quality of theestimates varying from country to country. This isunsurprising given the wide range of incomes,consumer tastes, and quality of data represented in thesample of countries analyzed. In order to qualify forutilization in the estimate of global income elasticityof trade, the following criteria were employed; theestimate of the income elasticity must be positive bothat the beginning and the end of the period, theestimate of the import price elasticity must benegative, and the estimated residuals must not possessa high degree of serial correlation.

4—Continuedminimized. Indications of structural breaks were identicalunder the Chow test and the CUSUM tests.

The coefficient for the time trend in equation 10.1becomes an intercept term upon first-differencing.Specifications were tested with and without an interceptterm (since a time trend is not always present in the dataon log levels), with and without a structural break in theintercept, and with and without a structural break in theincome elasticity, with the ultimate specification beingchosen on the grounds of goodness-of-fit and consistencyof the estimate parameters of the income and import priceelasticities with economic theory.

The initial SUR specification was based on thetreatment of the structural break and the intercept term inthe OLS specifications. The treatment of the structuralbreak and the intercept were then adjusted according tothe same criteria used to select the original OLSspecification.

Some researchers have investigated the issue ofsimultaneity in import demand equations. In principle,aggregate imports are determined simultaneously byimport demand and export supply. The estimation of asingle equation for import demand, as carried out here,can be motivated by the assumption of an infinitely elasticexport supply curve, the so-called “small country”assumption in international economics (Goldstein andKhan (1985)). Marquez (1992) notes that of 110published econometric studies of trade elasticities during1941-91, 94 treated import demand as if it wereindependent rather than simultaneously determined withexport supply. Moreover, the issue of simultaneityprincipally affects estimates of the price elasticities, sinceprices appear both in the supply and demand functions.The focus of the present analysis is on the incomeelasticity, which generally appears only in the demandfunction.

For all countries except one, the estimated incomeelasticity was positive, consistent with economic

theory; in cases where a structural break was present,income elasticity was positive both before and afterthe break. In the case of Nigeria, an implausiblenegative estimate of the income elasticity appearsbefore the structural break. For 16 countries, thedemand for imports was income-elastic throughout thesample period, while for the other three countries(Côte d’Ivoire, Germany, and India), import demandwas income-elastic for at least part of the sampleperiod. This finding alone is sufficient to indicate ahigh degree of income elasticity for world trade. Theestimates of the import price elasticity were negativefor 14 of the 19 countries, consistent with economictheory, while the estimates for Côte d’Ivoire,Germany, India, Indonesia, and Japan yielded perversepositive signs. For 16 countries, the Durbin-Watsonstatistic either rejects the presence of serial correlationor is in the range of indeterminacy for that statistic.In general, serial correlation does not appear to be aproblem for these estimates. For three countries(India, Indonesia, and Nigeria) the Durbin-Watsonstatistic does indicate the presence of serialcorrelation. Since first-differencing the data used inthe regression eliminated the bulk of the problemassociated with serial correlation, the standards ofcross-sectional regression apply to evaluating thecoefficients of determination (R2). The coefficients ofdetermination in cross-sectional regressions aregenerally lower than those obtained from regressionsperformed on time series data.

Thus, the estimates of six countries (Côte d’Ivoire,Germany, India, Indonesia, Japan, and Nigeria) wereexcluded from the calculation of the global incomeelasticity on grounds of either a perverse sign for theimport price elasticity or serial correlation inresiduals. The estimate of the global income elasticityof trade is based on the econometrically generatedincome elasticities for the remaining thirteencountries. In the case of countries with structuralbreaks in the income elasticity (Colombia, France, andMexico) the estimate for the most recent period (i.e.after the structural break) is used.

Generalization to Global LevelBased on the considerations described above, the

global income elasticity was estimated with equation10.1, using income elasticities for the followingcountries: Argentina, Colombia, Canada, France, Italy,Mexico, Pakistan, South Africa, Thailand, Turkey, theUnited Kingdom, the United States, and Zimbabwe.The average income elasticity for France, Italy, andthe United Kingdom was used to approximate theincome elasticity for the European Union (EU). (The3 countries accounted for close to 40 percent of EUimports during the first half of the 1990s. Thecombined market shares of the countries considered

Page 127: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

10-5

Table 10-1Seemingly unrelated regression estimates 1

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

CountryÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

RealGDP

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

RealGDPshifter

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

GDP priceindex

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Importprice index

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Constant

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Constantshifter

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

R2

(2)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

DWÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ρ (3)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ArgentinaÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

2.41(19.50)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

_ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.05(6.94)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.71(-3.79)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

_ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

_ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.22ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.390ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.37

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Canada ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

2.23(26.95)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

_ ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.22(-1.82)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.36(-4.51)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

_ ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

_ ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.76 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.535ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.76

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Colombia ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

2.08(2.45)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.35(-0.55)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.45(4.31)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.64(-2.38)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.31(-3.61)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

_ ÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.09 ÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.249ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.09

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Côte d’IvoireÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.81(4.32)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.27(-0.94)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.06(0.70)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.45(3.43)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.01(-0.64)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

_ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.26ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.898ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.26

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

France ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

3.00(9.92)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.38(-1.19)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.07(0.66)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.18(-2.51)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

_ ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

_ ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.36 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.252ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.23

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Germany ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.64(13.20)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.90(-6.83)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.12(1.08)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.05(1.42)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

_ ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.02(3.88)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.50 ÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.424ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.50

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

IndiaÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.67(7.39)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.71(6.07)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.10(-1.01)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.14(1.92)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

_ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

_ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.18ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.044ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.11

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Indonesia ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

3.45(12.38)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

_ ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.34(2.49)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.03(0.12)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.18(-6.91)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

_ ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.26 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.209ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.28

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Italy ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

2.50(19.32)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

_ ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.00(0.01)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.22(-3.69)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

_ ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

_ ÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.35 ÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.639ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.33

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

JapanÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

2.98(13.46)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

_ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.89(6.53)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.03(0.40)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.13(-6.85)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.10(5.16)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.51ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

2.160ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.44

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Mexico ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

6.03(29.57)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-2.14(-8.30)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.23(9.70)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.83(-6.00)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.24(-9.10)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.19(11.79)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.74 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.911ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.70

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Nigeria ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-2.64(-6.36)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

3.66(6.41)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.48(5.35)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-1.34(-3.07)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.33(5.21)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.49(-9.18)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.23 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.088ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.11

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Pakistan ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.10(6.62) ÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎ

_ ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.59(17.44) ÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎ

-1.05(-6.60) ÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎ

-0.11(-5.77) ÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎ

_ ÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.30 ÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.529ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.27

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

South AfricaÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

3.52(26.88)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

_ ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.12(-1.64)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.09(-3.07)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.07(-4.80)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.07(4.62)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.68 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

2.109ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.64

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Thailand ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

3.04(14.08)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

_ ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.28(-1.34)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.23(-1.83)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.10(-4.88)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

_ ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.42 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

2.575ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.40

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Turkey ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

2.40(8.74) ÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎ

_ ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.44(3.56) ÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎ

-0.53(-4.37) ÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎ

-0.07(1.76) ÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.14(-3.49) ÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎ

0.34 ÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.470ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.21

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

U.K.ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.18(10.64)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

_ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.26(4.02)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.00(-0.05)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

_ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

_ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.15ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.424ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.07

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

UnitedStates

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

2.22(26.23)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

_ ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.09(-0.95)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.12(-2.65)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

_ ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

_ ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.77 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

2.313ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.75

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Zimbabwe ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.23(17.27)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

_ ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.07(1.38)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.25(-2.58)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-0.01(-0.40)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

_ ÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.13 ÎÎÎÎÎÎ

2.145ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.02

1 Coefficients printed in italics are statistically significant at .10, coefficients printed in bold are statisticallysignificant at .05, and coefficients printed in bold italics are statistically significant at .01 (two- tail test).

2 The R2 reported are results of SUR estimations. They are coefficients of determination, measuring deviationsbetween predicted and observed values. Their interpretation is analogous, but not identical, to that of coefficients ofdetermination obtained from single equation OLS estimations.

3 Denotes the Cochrane-Orcutt serial correlation parameter.

Source: USITC staff calculations; see text for details.

Page 128: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

10-6

accounted for 62 percent of world imports for theperiod under consideration.

Assuming that income neutrality prevailed inglobal trade from 1970 to 1993, equation 10.1becomes 1.44 + 0.38�x = 1, where 1.44 is the sumof the income elasticities of the countries selectedfrom Table 10.1, weighted by their respective marketshares in world imports. This expression shows thatfor income-neutral demand to hold at a global level,the income elasticities in the rest of the world,representing approximately 38 percent of worldimports, would have to sum to a negative number,that is, �x < 0. This is inadmissible, since it impliesthat for these countries, imports decline withincreasing income (i.e. imported goods are inferior inconsumption). Even if the income elasticity ofimports for the countries not included in theestimation was assumed to be zero during the periodunder examination, the global income elasticity oftrade would still be 1.44. This lower-bound estimateis substantially in excess of unity, given that thestandard error of estimates for the countries includedin the calculations, weighted by their market shares,was found to be 0.1457. Thus, even theunrealistically low estimate of 1.44 for the globalincome elasticity of trade exceeds the unit-elasticvalue of 1 by approximately three standard deviations,so that the hypothesis of income-neutrality is rejectedwith better than 99 percent confidence. Using aplausible, but still conservative estimate of 1 for therest-of-world income elasticity of trade, the mostreasonable estimate of the income elasticity of worldtrade comes to 1.82. That is, every $1 increase inworld real incomes generates an increase ofapproximately $1.82 in world trade.

In the course of estimating national incomeelasticities to import, the USITC staff confirmed theconclusion gleaned from the literature that suchestimates are sensitive to the econometricmethodology and time period chosen for thecalculations. (See chapter 3 on the topic ofvariability in published estimates of trade elasticities.)Therefore, estimates of the global income elasticityof trade are also expected to show a wide dispersion.Nonetheless, as the survey of literature on incomeelasticity estimates indicated, and as exploration ofalternate econometric specifications at the USITCconfirmed, income elasticities of imports appear tohave been in excess of unity for the industrializedcountries since the 1960s, as well as for manydeveloping countries, regardless of the methodologyand time period selected for the calculations. Thetrade of the industrialized countries account for thebulk of world trade. Thus, the wide dispersion ofnational and, hence, global estimates notwithstanding,the fact that world trade has been income-elastic in

recent decades is robust to the application of varyingmodes of econometric analysis.

Gross Income Elasticities ofTrade in Particular Sectors

Given that the gross elasticity of world trade withrespect to world income is on the order of 1.5 to 2,the income elasticities of certain specific componentsof trade with respect to world income is likely to besubstantially higher. This is illustrated in part by theestimates of elasticities of U.S. exports with respect toworld income, presented in table 3.4. This section isdesigned to look at income elasticities of moredisaggregated categories of world trade with respectto world income, in particular world trade at the4-digit SITC level over the period 1980-95. In orderto examine such a large set of disaggregatedcategories econometrically, world time series of priceswould be necessary at the 4-digit SITC level. Thissection presents estimates of the gross elasticities ofworld trade in these sectors with respect to worldincome. The gross elasticity used in this section isdefined as the percentage change in per capita realexports divided by the percentage change in per capitareal income, without any attempt to adjust for changesin the relative prices of the goods in question. Thedollar values of both real global exports and realglobal income were calculated using the GDP deflatorfor the United States.

Several estimates of the gross elasticitity of worldtrade with respect to world income have beenpresented already in chapter 3 and in this chapter.5

Summarizing these, the gross elasticity of world tradewith respect to world income was 1.61 during1960-95, 1.51 during 1986-80 and 1.71 during1991-93. Comparing these estimates with each other,and with the econometric estimate computed in theprevious section of 1.82 for the elasticity of globaltrade with respect to global income during 1970-93,suggests that income elasticities are relatively stableover long time periods, and that the gross elasticitiesprovide reasonable first-order approximations toeconometrically estimated elasticities which accountfor price shifts of traded goods. Thus, the grosselasticities presented here for particular sectorsprovide useful information about the responsivenessof narrowly defined categories of trade with respect to

5 Technical note - These estimates use total exportsand total income rather than per capita exports and percapita income. The use of per capita figures is designedto provide gross elasticities based on the expenditurepatterns of a typical household. However, the correctionfor per capita income in the numerator and thedenominator is approximately offsetting, yielding only asmall adjustment to the final figure.

Page 129: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

10-7

Table 10-2Selected estimates of gross elasticities of world trade with respect to world income, 1980-95, by4-digit SITC categories

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

SITC

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Description

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Gross incomeelasticity ofworld trade1980-1995

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Percentage ofworld trade,1995

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

7810 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Passenger motor vehicles ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

4.35 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

4.66

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

776A ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Semiconductors, cathode ray tubes, etc. ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

15.10 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

3.73

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

752A ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Automatic data processing machines and units thereof ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

12.54 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

2.66

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

7849 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Miscellaneous motor vehicle parts ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

4.13 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

2.38

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

7649 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Misc. parts of telecommunications equipment ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

7.18 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

2.19

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

7512 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Calculating machines, cash registers, etc. ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

11.80 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.85

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

583A ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Polymerization and copolymerization products (plastics) ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

5.19 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.85

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

792A ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Aircraft and associated equipment ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.20 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.57

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

7284 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Machines and appliances for particular industries ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

6.58 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.33

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

772A ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Electrical apparatus (switches, relays, fuses, plugs, etc.) ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

6.30 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.32

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

7139 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Parts of internal combustion piston engines ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

4.36 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.01

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

821A ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Furniture and parts thereof ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

5.25 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.94

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

5417 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Medicaments, including veterinary medicaments ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

6.70 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.91

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

7788 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Other electrical machinery and equipment ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

9.00 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.87

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

8748 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Electrical measuring, checking, analyzing instruments ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

3.11 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.84

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

8510 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Footwear ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

3.43 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.82

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

5989 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Miscellaneous chemical products and preparations ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

2.45 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.77

ÎÎÎÎ8939 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎMiscellaneous articles of plastic ÎÎÎÎÎÎ 8.36 ÎÎÎÎÎÎ 0.72ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ8942

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎChildren’s toys and games

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ 6.97

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ 0.59ÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎ714AÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎEngines and motors, non-electric

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ 2.73

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ 0.59

Source: USITC staff calculations; see text for details.

income, as a proxy for econometrically estimatedelasticities. It should be borne in mind that over anextended period of time, relative price shifts can besignificant, and econometrically estimated incomeelasticities using commodity-specific price deflatorswould differ from those presented here.6

Table 10-2 presents calculations of the grosselasticity of world trade with respect to world income,using trade data from the Statistics Canada WorldTrade DataBase on CD-ROM, and data on worldincome and population from the World Bank STARSdatabase. The elasticities were calculated over theperiod 1980-95. The particular 4-digit SITCcategories shown in Table 10-2 constitute the largestcategories of trade for which the estimated crudeincome elasticity exceeds unity. As shown 16 of the20 largest identifiable commodity categories showincome-elastic demand. These categories amounted to31.3 percent of all global trade in 1995. Since the

share of these commodities in global trade isincreasing, there is support for the likelihood ofcontinued high income elasticities of trade in theimmediate short run. Such commodities as autos,semiconductors, computers, aircraft, and plastics havegross global income elasticities of trade ranging from

6 It is not possible to make useful generalizationsabout whether estimated demand functions usingcommodity-specific prices would yield higher or lowerincome elasticities than those presented here. For acommodity such as semiconductors, with rapidly fallingrelative prices, econometric estimation would attributesome part of the rapid growth in trade to falling prices,which would tend to reduce the estimated incomeelasticity. However, using a price index specific tosemiconductors would reveal that the volume increase inglobal semiconductor trade was even more rapid than thatassumed in the present calculation, which would tend toincrease the estimated income elasticity.

Page 130: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

10-8

1.2 to over 10.7 The list of high-elasticity productswith a significant share of international trade is notlimited to “high-technology” products, as it includessuch commodities as furniture, footwear, andchildren’s toys and games. All of the products inTable 10-2, however, possess some significant degreeof product differentiation; there are no agricultural ormineral products on the list, which tend to berelatively homogeneous in their attributes. Textileand apparel products also have high incomeelasticities. While no individual category in textilesand apparel is sufficiently large to appear in Table10-2, the three largest such categories (SITC 8429,“other outer garments of textile fabrics,” SITC 6531,“fabrics, woven of continuous synthetic fabrics, andSITC 8461, “under garments, knitted or crocheted”)account together for approximately 1.5 percent ofglobal trade and have gross income elasticities of6.33, 2.42, and 8.74 respectively.

The transformation of consumption with risingincome provides a partial, but not a complete,explanation for the commodity composition of themost rapidly increasing component of world trade.The list of commodities with rapidly growing trade intable 10.2 includes both commodities in the rapidlygrowing categories of consumption (e.g. motorvehicles and footwear) and commodities which arenot consumption goods at all, but intermediate inputsinto production (e.g. semiconductors, manycomputers, plastics, electrical apparatus.) The rapidgrowth in trade in these commodities may be betterexplained by the transformation of production withrising incomes, which parallels the transformation ofconsumption. As middle-income countries develop,they take on more and more production of “high-tech”commodities, which have become technologicallymature in the most advanced countries, and which arereplaced in the product cycle by new inventions in themost advanced countries (Vernon (1966)). FittingChenery curves to international production data ratherthan consumption data would reveal similar pattern tothose identified in the consumption data. Thus, it isreasonable to argue that a fairly large share of thetransformation of global trade patterns in terms of themost rapidly-growing commodities is associated with

7 Among the 20 largest 4-digit SITC categoriesrepresenting identifiable commodities in world trade in1995, the four for which global trade did not grow morerapidly than global income are petroleum oils and crudeoils obtained from bituminous materials (SITC 3330),universals, plates, and sheets of iron and steel (SITC6749), motor vehicles for transport of goods (SITC 7821),and diamonds, unworked or unmounted (SITC 6672).The categories of “special transactions and commoditiesnot classified as to kind” (SITC 9310) and “non-identifiedproducts” (SITC 9999) accounted jointly for 3.5 percentof global trade in 1995, and had crude income elasticitiesof 2.62 and 6.07, respectively, during the period underconsideration.

rising per capita income, whether on the productionside or on the consumption side. Further research iswarranted to provide additional detail on thesepatterns.

Income Elasticities for U.S.Machinery and Transport

Equipment ExportsThis section demonstrates the estimation of an

income elasticity for the exports of a single industryin a single country, using the example of U.S.machinery and transport equipment exports during1980-95. The measure of income chosen isrest-of-world income, which approximates demand forU. S. products globally. The sector was chosenbecause it accounts for a large share of U.S. exports.During each of the six years from 1990 through 1995,growth in U.S. machinery and equipment exports(SITC 7) outstripped growth in total U.S. exports.The share of machinery and equipment in total U.S.exports increased from 43.3 percent in 1989 to 49.9percent in 1995 (United Nations International TradeStatistics Yearbook, various years, and USITC staffcalculations). The growth rate of U.S. machinery andequipment exports from 1989-95 was a compounded10.1 percent per annum, well exceeding thecompounded 7.6 percent growth in total U.S. exports.By comparison, nominal U.S. GDP rose at a 4.9percent rate during the same period (Council ofEconomic Advisors, 1997, and USITC staffcalculations.)

The section illustrates estimation of the incomeelasticity using the almost ideal demand system(AIDS), which is particularly suited for the flexibleestimation of income and price elasticities in a mannerconsistent with economic theory and which avoids themechanical imposition of homotheticity (constantbudget shares) implicit in some other approaches. AsMarquez (1992) notes, the implied constraintsimposed by economic theory on the econometricestimation of trade elasticities are frequently ignoredin practice, and incorporating these constraints canimprove the quality of the estimates obtained. TheAIDS function is also a useful tool in simulationmodeling.

The estimate of the income elasticity obtained was1.65, indicating that each $1 in rest-of-worldeconomic growth induces $1.65 in U.S. exports ofmachinery and transport equipment. The estimateimplies that in an environment of sustained worldeconomic growth, this large category of U.S. exportsshould continue to enjoy substantial expansion in theimmediate future.

Page 131: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

10-9

MethodologyThe calculation is based on the almost ideal

demand system (AIDS). AIDS facilitates thequantification of consumer demand, based on thewell-established theoretical axioms of optimalconsumer behavior.8 The AIDS model specifiesmarket shares in the following way:

(10.3)wi � �i � � j �ij ln pj � �i ln(X

P)

in which wi is the share of the i-th product in theconsumer’s budget, �i, �ij and �i are parameters tobe estimated, pj is the price of the j-th good,X is total nominal expenditure, and P is a priceindex. The expression (X/P) in the last term,denoting real expenditures, is often treated asexogenous, for example real GDP taken from astatistical source. The interpretation of AIDS issimple: market shares change with relative pricesand real expenditures.9 Given the regressionestimates, the elasticity of substitution between twogoods k and j is calculated according to equation10.4:

(10.4)� k,j = 1 + –

� k,j � k,j

wkwj wk

for which � = 1 for k=j (own-price elasticities) and� = 0 otherwise (cross-price elasticities.) Incomeelasticities are derived from the estimated regressionparameters according to equation 10.5:

(10.5)� k = 1 +

wk

�k

The DataPrice data were used for each of the 1-digit SITC

sectors, omitting SITC 9, “Commodities andtransactions not classified elsewhere.” For the rest ofthe sections, the data base consisted of the following

8 Deaton and Muellbauer developed the AIDS modelto help analyze consumer behavior (Deaton andMuellbauer (1980)). Since its introduction in 1980, AIDShas become a staple of demand theory and has been usedin numerous empirical studies. For a description of itsapplications in a USITC model, see Pogany (1996).

9 Technical note - The imposition of restrictions onthe parameters of equation 10.3 are described in Deatonand Muellbauer (1980); these restrictions ensure that theestimated demand system is consistent with economictheory. Since the present application estimates only asingle equation rather than an entire demand system, onlythe constraint pertaining to the homogeneity of prices isbinding. This requires that the sum of the γij beconstrained to be equal to 0.

time series for 1980-95: U.S. market shares in worldimports, world real export price indices, and realworld GDP less the U.S. GDP.

Application to U.S. Machineryand Transport Equipment

The application of AIDS to estimate world incomeelasticities for machinery and equipment (SITCsection 7) defines the terms of equation 10.3 asfollows: w7 is the share of machinery and equipmentamong worldwide U.S. exports, �7, �7 j and �7 areparameters to be estimated, pj is the world price ofthe j-th product, where j = 0,..,8.

The specification selected included the incometerm (that is, world real GDP less the U.S. real GDP),and the price indices of sections 5-8, that is, industrialproducts. Commodities belonging to sections 5, 6,and 8 were considered gross complements of thecommodities belonging to section 7. The use of worldprices excludes the possibility of investigatingsubstitution among alternative suppliers as a result ofchanges in the relative price of U.S. goods. The riseor fall of price indices reflects global movements inthe given commodity section, not specific to anyparticular supplier, foreign or domestic. Thiscircumstance excludes the effects of short-termcompetition among the suppliers, allowing exami-nation of the longer-term effects of changingworldwide scarcities upon U.S. exports.10

ResultsThe real income coefficient �7 was found to be

0.2950, with a standard error of 0.1017, and a t-ratioof 2.9. Using equation 10.5 with an average w7 =0.4567 for the sample period yields an incomeelasticity of 1.65, implying that a 1-percent rise in therest of the world’s real GDP increased U.S. machineryexports by 1.65 percent. The R2 was 0.9396. Thesum of the price coefficients was near zero, implyingthat the constraint on price homogeneity is fulfilledwithout the normal imposition of constraints and thatthe requirements for a homogeneous cost curve andrelated optimizing behavior in consumption are met.The value of the Durbin-Watson statistic is 1.823,which indicates that the estimates do not suffer fromserial correlation. Applying equation 10.4, and usingthe value of �7 = 0.17547 obtained in the estimation,the own-price elasticity for U.S. exports of machineryand equipment yields - 0.3488.

10 The approach is similar to the first application ofAIDS by Deaton and Muellbauer to postwar domesticconsumption in the United Kingdom (Deaton andMuellbauer (1980)).

Page 132: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

10-10

Development, Consumption,and Trade: Chenery

CurvesThe concentration of global trade in particular

commodities with income-elastic demand constitutesan important part of the explanation as to why tradehas grown more rapidly than income. As countriesdevelop, consumption patterns shift amongcommodities, moving away from food and towardservices, and shifting among categories ofmanufactures. These shifting consumption patternsare an important underlying reason for above-averagegrowth in world trade in general and in certaincategories of world trade in particular. Shifts inconsumption patterns are particularly important forrapidly developing countries as they progressfrom lower-middle-income to upper-middle-incomestatus, corresponding roughly to the World Bank’scurrent (World Development Report (1997), using1995 data) characterization of “middle-incomecountries” as extending approximately from a percapita income of $770 (Lesotho) to $8,210 (Greece).11

These shifts in consumption may be studied byplotting the shares of various items in consumptionfor different countries with different per capitaincomes as a given point in time, and thencharacterizing the relationship between consumptionshares and income by means of fitting smooth curvesto the data. This method is due to Hollis Chenery,and the curves derived are known as “Chenerycurves.”12 Cross-country income elasticities can becalculated based on the fitted Chenery curves; theseelasticities vary according to income level. Under theassumption that consumers with increasing incomewill modify their consumption patterns to resemblethose of consumers in countries with somewhat higherincomes, the estimated Chenery curves can be usedboth to characterize visually the composition ofconsumption at different levels of per capita incomeand to obtain estimates of the income elasticity ofconsumption of different goods and services atdifferent per capita incomes. It should be noted thatthese cross-section estimates of the income elasticityare distinct from, but complementary to, estimates ofthe income elasticity obtained from time-series data.

Data and MethodologyThe Global Trade Analysis Project (GTAP), an

applied general equilibrium model, was the source ofthe consumption share data necessary for generating

11 By comparison, the World Bank reports the percapita income of the United States in 1995 to be $26,980.

12 For details on the application of this methodology,see Chenery (1979).

Chenery curves in this study. Data were used for 22regions, encompassing most of the world economy.13

Consumption is calculated as domestically producedgoods for final consumption, plus imports minusexports. Per capita GNP figures from the WorldBank’s STARS data system were used as proxies forper capita incomes. The GTAP model’s 37commodity groups were aggregated into 10 product(service) sectors, as described in Hertel (1997).14

These sectors are as follows: crops; other agriculturalproducts; mining products; processed food; textiles,leather products, wood products, nonmetallicminerals, and fabricated metal products; chemicals,rubber, plastics, beverages, and tobacco products;transport equipment, machinery, apparel, and primaryferrous metals; petroleum and coal products;services; and (the services of) owner-occupieddwellings. The ratio of payments for labor relativeto payments for other factors of production is similarfor the products (services) within each sector, whilethese ratios are significantly different among thesectors.

For each commodity group, the share of eachsector’s consumption in the region’s total budget wasregressed on per capita GNP and the square of percapita GNP, generating estimates of the parameters c,b1, and b2 of the quadratic function shown in equation10.6:

(10.6) Cij /Yj = c + b1 (Yj /Pj ) +b2(Y/Pj )2

13 The following eight regions in the GTAP databasewere not included in the analysis; “Rest of South Asia”(other than India, e.g. Bangladesh, Pakistan, Sri Lanka);“Central America and Caribbean”; “Rest of SouthAmerica” (countries other than Argentina, Brazil andChile, which are included in the analysis as separateregions); “EU3” (Austria, Finland, and Sweden);“European Free Trade Area” (Iceland, Norway, andSwitzerland); “Middle East and North Africa”; “Rest ofWorld” (consisting of Turkey, Yugoslavia, Vietnam,Afghanistan and miscellaneous smaller countries); andTaiwan.

14 The names used for the manufacturing and servicessectors here are modified from their labels in the GTAPdatabase for ease of interpretation. The original namesand classifications are according to the relative capital-and labor-intensity of production; thus, “processed food,”“chemicals, rubber...”, “textiles, leather...”,, “transportequipment, machinery...”, “services”, and “ownership ofdwellings” in this chapter correspond, respectively, toHertel’s nomenclature of “highly capital-intensivemanufactures,” “moderately capital-intensivemanufactures,” “moderately labor-intensive manufactures,”“highly labor-intensive manufactures,” “labor-intensiveservices,” and “capital-intensive services” in the GTAPdatabase.

Page 133: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

10-11

In the above expression, Cij indicates the level ofdomestic consumption in sector i in region j, Yjequals GDP, and Pj equals population; thus, Y/Prepresents per capita GDP. The coefficients c, b1 andb2 are estimated by OLS regression. The nullhypothesis of unit income elasticity can be testedagainst the alternative of income sensitivity by a jointF-test on the parameters b1 and b2. A finding that theparameters are jointly insignificant amounts to afinding of unit income elasticity, and the graph of theChenery curve will be an approximately horizontalline at the average consumption share. If b1 and b2are jointly significant, consumption in the sector iseither income-elastic or income-inelastic over asignificant range. The graph of the Chenery curvewill be positively sloped if consumption of thesector’s output is income-elastic at all levels of percapita income, negatively sloped if consumption isalways income-inelastic, and either U-shaped orinverted-U-shaped if consumption has elastic andinelastic ranges.

An alternate way of summarizing the informationin the Chenery curves is to calculate the incomeelasticity of consumption for various levels of percapita income. Given estimates of the parameters ofequation 10.6, one can derive the following formulafor the elasticity of per capita consumption withregard to per capita income, eij:

(10.7)

eij = [c +2b1(Yj/Pj)+3b2(Yj/Pj)2 ](Yj/Pj)

(Cij /Pj)

Equation 10.7 permits the derivation of theincome elasticities implied by the regression results.

Results Table 10.3 shows the fitted values for equation

10.6, while figure 10.1 shows the Chenery curvesobtained by graphing the fitted function for a range ofper capita income from $0 to $20,000. Table 10.4shows the estimated elasticities calculated accordingto equation 10.7. These were evaluated at a per capitaincome of $2,000 (approximately equal to that ofThailand), $6,000 (approximately the level ofArgentina), and $12,000 (approximately the level ofNew Zealand).15 The results are generally in a

15 As an example of the relationship between theregression results in table 10.3 and the estimatedelasticities in table 10.4, consider the evaluation of theincome elasticity of food processing at a per capitaincome of $2,000. According to table 10.3, the estimatedvalues of the regression coefficients (which are given inscientific notation when they are small in absolute value)are c = .144, b1 = -7.3*10-6, and b2 = 1.6*10-10. Thus,using equation 10.6 (omitting subscripts for convenience),the estimated share of consumption of food processing

reasonable range, with the categories of crops andagricultural products showing negative incomeelasticities above the middle-income level, implyingthat these are inferior goods in consumption.(Above the middle-income level, primary agriculturalproducts tend increasingly to be channeled into foodprocessing rather than consumed directly in thehousehold). The hypothesis of unit income elasticityis soundly rejected for crops, other agriculturalproducts, food processing, and services, andmarginally rejected for owner-occupied dwellings.Of these sectors, crops, other agriculture, and foodprocessing have income-inelastic demand. Applyingthe data from figure 10.1, the fitted budget share ofthese three food-related sectors together declinesfrom about 27 percent of income for the poorestcountries to about 7 percent of income for a countrywith a per capita income of $15,000. The twoservice sectors (services per se and owner-occupieddwellings) both have income-elastic consumptiondemand, ranging from elasticities of slightly over 1to over 1.4. Again applying figure 10.1, the totalbudget share for services and ownership of dwellingsincreases from about 48 percent of consumption inthe poorest countries to about 66 percent ofconsumption at a per capita income of $15,000.

By conventional statistical standards, the incomeeffects are relatively weak for mining, for petroleumand coal products, and for the three categories ofmanufactures other than food processing.

The earlier analysis in this chapter, as well as theestimates from the literature presented in chapter 3,showed that income elasticities were particularly highfor transport equipment, machinery, and apparel. Inthe GTAP database these categories of manufacturesare aggregated together. Figure 10.1 shows that theestimated budget share of these manufactures in totalconsumption increases from 7 percent for very poorcountries to over 11 percent at a per capita income of$12,000-$13,000, and then declines slightly. Table10.3 reports estimated income elasticities

15—Continuedproducts in total income for an income of Y/P = 2,000 isequal to

C/Y = .144 -(7.3*10-6)(2,000)+1.6*10-10 (2,0002) =.13004

To evaluate the income elasticity according toequation 10.7, first evaluate the final term (Y/P)/(C/P) =Y/C = 1/.13004, or 7.69. Then equation 10.7 can beevaluated directly as

eij = [.144 -2(7.3*10-6)(2,000)+3(1.6*10-10 )(2,0002)]*7.69 = .90

Thus the estimated income elasticity of consumptionof food processing products at a per capita income of$2000 is .90, as found in table 10.4.

Page 134: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

10-12

Table 10-3Regression of consumption shares on per capita income

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Commodity Sector ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Constant ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Per capita income ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Per capita income squared ÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎR2 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

F-TestÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Crops ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.092(5.19)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-1.1E-05(-2.38)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

3.0E-10(1.70)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.36ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

5.37

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Other agricultural productsÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.059(6.41)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-6.4E-06(-2.83)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.8E-10(1.98)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.46ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

7.96ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Mining productsÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.003(1.60)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

2.3E-07(0.45)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-1.2E-11(-0.59)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.03

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.28

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Processed food ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.144(9.86)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-7.3E-0.6(2.00)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.6E-10(1.10)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎ0.42ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ6.85ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Textiles, leather, wood,paper, minerals, fabricatedmetal

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.081(11.00)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-2.0E-07(-0.11)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-3.5E-11(-0.49)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.21

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

2.50

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Chemicals, rubber,plastics, beverages,tobacco products

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.058(5.38)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

2.4E-0.6(0.90)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-1.3E-10(-1.22)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.12ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.2

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Transport equipment,machinery, apparel,primary ferrous metals

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.070(4.44)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

6.4E-06(1.64)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-2.3E-10(-1.49)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.13ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.41

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Petroleum andcoal products

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.016(3.07)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.3E-06(1.05)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-6.0E-11(-1.20)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.08

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.81ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ServicesÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.450(13.62)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

6.2E-06(0.76)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

8.2E-11(0.25)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.43

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

7.17

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Ownership of dwellings ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.028(1.75)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

7.8E-06(1.96)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-2.5E-10(-1.59)

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.21ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

2.60

Note.—Coefficients printed in italics are statistically significant at .10, coefficients printed in bold are statisticallysignificant at .05, and coefficients printed in bold italics are statistically significant at .01.

Source: USITC staff calculations; see text.

Page 135: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

10-13

00.010.020.030.040.050.060.07

–0.01

0.00

0.01

0.02

0.03

–0.02

0.00

0.02

0.04

0.06

0.08

0.10Crops

5,000 10,000 15,000 20,000

–0.002

–0.001

0.000

0.001

0.002

0.003

0.004

0.005Mining products

Textiles, leather products, wood products, paper,

0.040.050.060.070.080.090.100.110.12

Transport equipment, machinery, apparel, and primary

0.45

0.50

0.55

0.60

0.65

0.70

0.75Services

0

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04

0.05

0.06Other agricultural products

0.06

0.08

0.10

0.12

0.14Processed food

0.04

0.05

0.06

0.07

0.08

0.09Chemicals, rubber, beverages and tobacco products

Petroleum and coal

0.03

0.04

0.05

0.06

0.07

0.08

0.09Ownership of dwellings

1 In each of these graphs, the horizontal axis shows annual per capita incomes in dollars, and the vertical axis shows thepercent of the indicated commodity (service) sector in total consumer outlays.

Source: USITC staff calculations; see text.

Figure 10-1Chenery curves: relating per capita income levels to shares of commodity (service) sectors in totalconsumption 1

0

5,000 10,000 15,000 20,0000

5,000 10,000 15,000 20,0000

5,000 10,000 15,000 20,0000

5,000 10,000 15,000 20,0000

5,000 10,000 15,000 20,0000

5,000 10,000 15,000 20,0000

5,000 10,000 15,000 20,0000

5,000 10,000 15,000 20,0000

5,000 10,000 15,000 20,0000

nonmetallic minerals, and fabricated metal products

ferrous metals

Page 136: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

10-14

Table 10-4Cross-country, sectoral income elasticities of consumption, estimated from Chenery curvesÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Per capita income ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

$2,000 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

$6,000 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

$12,000

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Representative country ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Thailand ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Argentina ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

New Zealand

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Income elasticity for consumption of: ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎCrops ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ0.74 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ-0.05 ÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎ-3.79

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Other agricultural products ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.75 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.02 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

-2.68

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Mining products ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.10 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.12 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.84

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Processed food ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.90 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.70 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.48

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Textiles, leather, wood, paper, minerals,fabricated metal products

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.99ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.95ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.83ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Chemicals, rubber, plastics, beverages,tobacco products

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.06

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.08

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

0.88

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

Transport equipment, machinery,apparel, primary ferrous metals

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.13ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.22ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

1.10

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎPetroleum and coal ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ1.12 ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ1.17 ÎÎÎÎÎÎ0.94ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎServices

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ1.03

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ1.09

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ1.44ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎOwnership of dwellingsÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ1.32

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ1.18

ÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎÎ1.26

Source: USITC staff calculations; see text.

corresponding to the Chenery curve of 1.13 at Y =$2,000, 1.22 at Y = $6,000, and 1.10 at Y =$12,000. The finding of income-elastic consumptionfor this category of manufactures is consistent withthe idea that the rapid growth of these products ininternational trade can be attributed to shiftingconsumption patterns in a growing globaleconomy.16

The results in general reject the hypothesis ofhomotheticity in consumption; in other words, thecomposition of consumer budgets in poor and richcountries is decidedly different. If the data wereconsistent with income neutrality, all the Cheney curesshown in figure 10-1 would have been straight lines.The tendency of services to grow disproportionatelywith income is particularly noteworthy. While theavailable data on total world services trade sufferfrom conceptual and reporting problems, it is likelythat services trade has also grown more rapidly thanincome in recent years, in line with the consumptionof services.

16 It is true that the regression estimates do not rejectunit-elasticity in the classical statistical sense: the F-teston the null hypothesis that the two per capita incomecoefficients are zero is .268, which is higher than thecommonly accepted level of .10. It should be borne inmind, though, that this particular regression analysis isdesigned to reveal broad regularities about the data ratherthan to make out-of-sample predictions. The sample ofregions analyzed includes most of the world economyrather than being a small sample from a hypotheticalpopulation of thousands of regions. The results show that

Assessing Future Levels ofIncome Sensitivity

There is no guarantee that greater-than-unitaryincome elasticities of trade will continue in the future.As discussed in chapter 3, it is illogical to expectincome elasticities to exceed 1 forever, otherwisetrade would eventually exceed total income andnon-traded output would become negative.Nonetheless, tendencies in the world economy pointto the continuation of above-unitary income elasticityto trade. As an illustration of this, USITC staffcalculations show that the gross real elasticity ofworld per capita trade, as defined in the section aboveon “Gross Income Elasticities of Trade in ParticularSectors,” increased from 1.51 during 1986-89 to 1.71during 1991-93.

As discussed in chapter 3, the growth of per capitaincome was linked to the increased weight ofintraindustry trade in total world trade since WorldWar II. At present, trade among the developedcountries is dominated by trade in differentiatedmanufactures, for which intraindustry trade isimportant. This pattern of world trade is consistent on

16—Continuedthe budget share of transport equipment, machinery,apparel, etc. in the consumption of upper-middle-incomecountries really is larger on average than in lower-incomecountries, though the consistency of this pattern is weakerthan for services, agriculture, and food processing.

Page 137: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

10-15

theoretical grounds with a high degree of incomeelasticity in world trade (see the section on“Markusen’s Model” in Chapter 3.) However as percapita income increases in the developing countries,it is likely that the relative importance of trade indifferentiated products in these countries will grow.This is due to the transformation of consumption inthese countries towards differentiated products suchas transport equipment, machinery, and apparel, aspresented in the estimates of Chenery curves earlierin this chapter. This transformation of consumptionwill be at least partly reflected in a transformation ofthese countries’ production. The tendency ofproduction and trade in differentiated products toincrease in relative importance for the developingcountries, coupled with the steadily increasing shareof global GDP generated in these countries, implies

that world trade should continue to grow morerapidly than world income in the immediate future.

The likely continuation of income-elastic demandfor traded goods implies particularly strong exportopportunities for those U.S. industries whose exportdemand is particularly sensitive to global increases inincome. As Alterman’s estimates presented in Table3-4 illustrate, these industries include a wide varietyof industrial machinery and electircal and electronicgoods, as well as motor vehicle parts, ceramic andchina ware, and some precision instruments. Thesectoral estimates of gross import elasticitiespresented in this chapter reinforce the identification ofthese sectors as having highly income-sensitive exportdemand, as does the econometric estimate presentedfor U.S. machinery and transport equipment exports.

Page 138: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted
Page 139: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

APPENDIX ARequest Letter

Page 140: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

1

Page 141: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

2

Page 142: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted
Page 143: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

APPENDIX BFederal Register Notice

Page 144: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

1

Page 145: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

2

Page 146: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted
Page 147: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

APPENDIX CBibliography

Page 148: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

C-2

BIBLIOGRAPHYAghion. Philippe, and Peter Howitt, “A Model of Growth through Creative Destruction,” Econometrica 60:2, March

1992, pp. 323-351.

Almon, C., “Household Consumption in the U.S.A., Italy, Spain, and France,” paper presented at the InforumOutlook Conference, University of Maryland, Nov. 20, 1996 (A).

Almon, C., “A Perhaps Adequate Demand System,” Inforum Working Paper, University of Maryland, no. 96-007,July 1996 (B).

Alston, J.M., et al., “Whither Armington Trade Models?,” American Journal of Agricultural Economics, May 1990,pp. 455-467.

Alterman, W., “Using Disaggregated Data to Dissect the U.S. Trade Deficit,” published in the Papers andProceedings, the 10th Annual Meeting of the Korean-America Economic Association, 1995.

Amin Gutiérrez de Piñeres, Sheila, and Michael J. Ferrantino (1997), “Export Diversification and StructuralDynamics in the Growth Process: The Case of Chile,” Journal of Development Economics, forthcoming.

Arrow, Kenneth J., “The Economic Implications of Learning by Doing,” Review of Economic Studies 29, June 1962,pp. 155-173.

Asian Development Bank, “Emerging Asia,” 1997. Cited in Jeffrey Sachs, “Nature, Nurture and Growth,” TheEconomist, June 14, 1997, pp. 19-22.

Aw, B.Y. and A. Hwang, “Productivity and the Export Market: A Firm-Level Analysis,” Journal of Development Economics vol. 47, 1995, pp. 313-332.

Bagnoli, P., W.J. McKibbin, and P.J. Wilcoxen, “Global Economic Prospects: Medium Term Projections andStructural Change,” Brookings Discussion Papers in International Economics, The Brookings Institution,Washington, DC, January 1996.

Bahmani-Oskooee, M., M. Hamid and S.Ghiath, “Exports, Growth and Causality in LDCs: A Re-Examination,”Journal of Development Economics 36:2, 1991, pp. 405-415.

Balassa, Bela, Development Strategies in Semi-Industrial Economies, New York and London: Oxford UniversityPress, 1982.

Balassa, Bela, “Exports and Economic Growth: Further Evidence,” Journal of Development Economics 5:2, June1978, pp. 181-189.

Balassa, Bela, The Structure of Protection in Developing Countries, Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press,1971.

Balasubramanyam, V.N., M. Salisu, and D. Sapsford, “Foreign Direct Investment and Growth in EP and ISCountries,” The Economic Journal, 1996, pp. 92-105.

Baldwin, R., “Determinants of Trade and Foreign Investment,” Review of Economics and Statistics, May 1979, pp.40-48.

Baldwin, R.E. and E. Seghazza, “Testing for Trade-Induced Investment-Led Growth,” Working Paper, no. 5416,National Bureau of Economic Research, 1996.

Barrell R. and N. Pain, “An Econometric Analysis of U.S. Foreign Direct Investment,” Review of Economics andStatistics, May 1996, pp. 200-207.

Barro, Robert J., “Determinants of Economic Growth: A Cross-Country Empirical Study,” National Bureau ofEconomic Research Working Paper no. 5698, Cambridge, MA, August 1996.

Page 149: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

C-3

Barro, Robert J., “Economic Growth in a Cross-Section of Countries,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 106:2 May1991, pp. 407-443.

Barro, Robert J. and Gary S. Becker, “Fertility Choice in a Model of Economic Growth,” Econometrica 57:2 March1989, pp. 481-501.

Barro, R. and Xavier Sala-i-Martin, “Public Finance in Models of Economic Growth,” Review of Economic Studies,1992, p. 4.

Barro, Robert J. and Xavier Sala-i-Martin, Economic Growth, New York: McGraw-Hill, 1995.

Barro, Robert J. and Xavier Sala-i-Martin, “Technological Diffusion, Convergence, and Growth,” Journal ofEconomic Growth 2:1 (March 1997), pp. 1-26.

Barthelemy, J.C., S. Dessus, and A. Varoudakis, “Human Capital and Growth: The Role of the Trade Regime,”Working Paper, OECD Development Center, Paris, May 1997.

Bayoumi, T., D.T. Coe, and E. Helpman, “R&D Spillovers and Global Growth,” Working Paper no. 5628, NationalBureau of Economic Research, June 1996.

Becker, Gary S. and Robert J. Barro, “A Reformulation of the Economic Theory of Fertility,” Quarterly Journal ofEconomics 103:1, February 1988, pp. 1-25.

Behrman J., and Wallender, H., Transfer of Manufacturing Technology within Multinational Enterprises, Cambridge,MA, Ballinger, 1976.

Benjamin, Nancy, “Adjustment and Income Distribution in an Agricultural Economy: A General EquilibriumAnalysis of Cameroon,” World Development, vol. 24, no. 6, pp. 1003-1013, 1996(B).

Benjamin, Nancy, “Dynamic Investment Responses to Real Exchange Rate Changes,” USITC Working Paper,January 1996, no. 96-01-A, (A).

Benjamin, Nancy, “Investment, Expectations, and Dutch Disease: A Comparative Study: Bolivia, Cameroon,Indonesia,” in Applied General Equilibrium and Economic Development, The University Press ofMichigan, eds. J. Mercenier and T.N. Srinivasan, 1997.

Benjamin, Nancy and Peter Pogany, “Free Trade with Chile May Increase U.S. Investment Opportunities in LatinAmerica (Background Information for CGE Policy Simulations),” USITC Working Paper, June 1996, no.96-06-A.

Benjamin, Nancy and Peter Pogany, “Integration and Competitiveness in the Americas: A General EquilibriumModel for Analysis,” paper presented at the 14th Conference of the Business Association of LatinAmerican Studies, Rio de Janeiro, Brazil, April 9-12, 1997.

Bernard, A.B. and C.I. Jones, “Comparing Apples to Oranges: Productivity Convergence and Measurement AcrossIndustries and Countries,” American Economic Review 86:5, December 1996, pp. 1216-38.

Bernard, A.B. and C.I. Jones, “Productivity across Countries and Industries: Time Series Theory and Evidence,”Review of Economics and Statistics 78:1 (February 1996), pp. 135-146.

Berndt, E.R., The Practice of Econometrics, Classic and Contemporary, Addison-Wesley Publishing Company,Reading, Massachusetts, 1991.

Bhagwati, Jagdish, Anatomy and Consequences of Exchange Control Regimes, Cambridge, MA: BallingerPublishing Co. for NBER, 1978.

Bhagwati, Jagdish, The Economics of Underdeveloped Countries, New York: McGraw-Hill, 1966.

Page 150: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

C-4

Bhalla, Surjit, and Laurence J. Lau, “Openness, Technological Progress, and Growth in Developing Countries,”Working Paper, Washington, DC: World Bank, 1991.

Birdsall, Nancy, “Economic Approaches to Population Growth,” Chapter 12 in Hollis Chenery and T.N.Srinivasan, eds., Handbook of Development Economics, vol. 1, Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1989,pp. 478-542.

Blomström, Magnus, “Foreign Investment and Productive Efficiency,” Journal of Industrial Economics, vol. 35,1986, pp. 97-112.

Blomström, Magnus, “Host Country Benefits of Foreign Investment” in Foreign Investment, Technology, andEconomic Growth, ed. D.G. McFetridge, Calgary: University of Calagary Press, 1991.

Blomström, Magnus, Robert E. Lipsey and Manuel Zejan, “Is Fixed Investment the Key to Economic Growth?,”Quarterly Journal of Economics 111:1 February 1996, pp. 269-276.

Blomström, Magnus, Robert Lipsey and Mario Zejan, “What Explains Developing Country Growth,” NBERWorking Paper, no. 4132, August 1992.

Blonigen, B., “In Search of Substitution Between Foreign Production and Exports: The Case of Japanese AutoParts,” Working Paper, 1997.

Bloomfield, G., The World Automobile Industry, London: David and Charles Newton Abbot, 1978.

Borenszentein, E., J. de-Gregorio, and J. Lee, “How Does Foreign Direct Investment Affect Economic Growth?”Working Paper, no. 5057, NBER, 1995.

Bosworth, B., Savings and Investment in the Open Economy, Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution, 1993.

Bradford, David F., “Market Value versus Financial Accounting Measures of National Saving,” in National Savingand Economic Performance, NBER, eds. B. Douglas Bernheim and John B. Shoven, 1991.

Brainard, S.L., “An Empirical Assessment of the Proximity-Concentration Trade off Between Multinational Salesand Trade,” Working Paper 4580, NBER, 1993.

Brash, D.T., American Investment in Australian Industry, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1966.

Brenton, P.A. and L.A. Winters, “Estimating the International Trade Effects of ‘1992’: West Germany,” Journal ofCommon Market Studies, vol. 30, no. 2, pp. 143-153.

Buckley P.J. and J.H. Dunning, “The Industrial Structure of U.S. Direct Investment in the U.K.,” Journal ofInternational Business Studies, vol. 7, Summer 1976, pp. 5-13.

Carone, G., “Modeling the U.S. Demand for Imports Through Cointegration and Error Correction,” IstitutoNazionale per lo Studio della Congiuntura (ISCO), Rome Italy, Working Paper, December 20, 1996.

Carroll, C. and D. Weil, “Savings and Growth: A Reinterpretation,” NBER Working Paper, no. 4470, September1993.

Cass, David, “Optimum Growth in an Aggregative Model of Capital Accumulation,” Review of Economic Studies 32July 1965, pp. 233-240.

Caves, R., Multinational Enterprise and Economic Analysis, 2nd ed., Cambridge University Press, 1996.

Caves, R. and D. Barton, Efficiency in U.S. Marketing Industries, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1990.

Chenery, Hollis, Structural Change and Development Policy, World Bank Research Publication, The World Bank,Washington, DC, 1979.

Page 151: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

C-5

Chenery, Hollis et al., “Alternative Routes to Development,” ch. 11 in Industrialization and Growth: A ComparativeStudy, eds. Hollis Chenery, Sherman Robinson, and Moshe Syrquin, Oxford University Press for The WorldBank, 1986.

Chin, Judith and Gene Grossman, “Intellectual Property Rights and North-South Trade,” in The Political Economyof International Trade, eds. Ronald W. Jones and Anne O. Krueger, Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1990, pp.90-107.

Chua, Hak B., “Regional Spillovers and Economic Growth,” Yale University Economic Growth Center DiscussionPaper, no. 700, September 1993.

Clausing, K., “Does Multinational Activity Displace Trade?,” Reed College Department of Economics WorkingPaper, 1996.

Clerides, S., S. Lach and J. Tybout, “Is ‘Learning-by-Exporting’ Important? Micro-Dynamic Evidence fromColombia, Mexico, and Morocco,” 1997, unpublished.

Coe, David T., Elhanan Helpman and Alexander W. Hoffmaister, “North-South R&D Spillovers,” NBER WorkingPaper No. 5046, 1995, Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

Cohen, Wesley M. and Richard C. Levin, “Empirical Studies of Innovation and Market Structure,” ch. 18 in

Handbook of Industrial Organization, vol. II (1989), eds. R. Schmalensee and R. Willig, pp. 1059- 1108

Collins, Susan M., “Saving Behavior in Ten Developing Countries,” in B. Douglas Bernheim and John B. Shoven,eds., National Saving and Economic Performance, NBER, 1991, pp. 349-72.

Commission of the European Communities, A Journey Through the EC, ISBN 92-825-8124-1, Luxembourg, 1988.

Council of Economic Advisers, Economic Report of the President 1997, U.S. Government Printing Office,Washington, DC, February 1997.

Cushman, D., “Exchange Rate Uncertainty and Foreign Direct Investment in the United States,” Weltwirtchaftiches

Archiv, vol. 124, 1988, pp. 322-336.

Cushman, D., “Real Exchange Rate Risk, Expectations and the Level of Direct Investment,” Review of Economicsand Statistics, May 1985, pp. 297-308.

Davidson, W.H., and D.G. McFetridge, “Key Characteristics in the Choice of International Technology Transfer,”Journal of International Business Studies, vol. 16, 1985, pp.5-21.

Deardorff, Alan V., “Welfare Effects of Global Patent Protection,” Economica, vol. 59, 1992, pp. 33-51.

Deaton, A., “Saving in Developing Countries: Theory and Review,” proceedings of the World Bank AnnualConference on Development Economics 1989, Washington, DC: World Bank, 1989.

Deaton, A. and J. Muellbauer, “An Almost Ideal Demand System,” The American Economic Review 70, June 1980,pp. 312-326.

Deaton, A. and J. Muellbauer, Economics and Consumer Behavior, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1986.

De Long, J. Bradford, and Lawrence Summers, “Equipment Investment and Economic Growth,” Quarterly Journalof Economics, vol. 106 (1991), pp. 445-502.

Denekamp, J. and M. Ferrantino, “Substitution and Complementarity of U.S. Exports and Foreign Based AffiliateSales in a Demand Based Gravity System,” Southern Methodist University Richard B. Johnson Center forEconomic Studies Working Paper, 1990.

Dervis, K., J. de Melo, and S. Robinson, General Equilibrium Models for Development Policy, Cambridge:Cambridge University Press, 1982.

Page 152: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

C-6

Devarajan, S. and D.S. Go, The Simplest Dynamic General Equilibrium Model of Open Economy, World Bank, May1995.

Devarajan, S. and Heng-fu Zou, “Exports, Foreign Technology Imports, and Long-run Growth,” Policy ResearchWorking Paper, World Bank, March 1996.

Diao, X. and A. Somwaru, Dynamic Gains and Losses from Trade Reform: An Intertemporal General EquilibriumModel of the United States and MERCOSUR, United States Department of Agriculture (USDA) EconomicResearch Service, July 1996.

Dissou, Y. and B. Decaluwe, “External Shocks and Adjustment in the Cote d’Ivoire: A Dynamic GeneralEquilibrium Analysis,” paper presented at the Rabat (Morocco) workshop on general equilibrium modeling,September 1995.

Dollar, David, “Outward-Oriented Developing Economies Really Do Grow More Rapidly: Evidence from 95 LDCs,1976-85,” Economic Development and Cultural Change 40, April 1992, pp, 523-544.

Dollar, D. and E. N. Wolff, Competitiveness, Convergence, and International Specialization, Cambridge, MA: MITPress, 1993.

Domar, Evsey D., “Capital Expansion, Rate of Growth, and Employment,” Econometrica 14, April 1946, pp.137-147.

Donnelly, W.A., “Identifying Appropriate Functional Form in Regression Analysis,” USITC, Office of EconomicsResearch Notes, Nov. 15, 1996, pp. 96-11-B.

Doshi, K., “Determinants of Savings Rate: An International Comparison,” Contemporary Economic Policy, vol. 12 ,January 1994.

Dunning, J., American Investment in British Manufacturing Industry., London: Allen & Unwin, 1958.

Dunning, J., Economic Analysis and the Multinational Enterprise, London: Allen & Unwin, 1974.

Dunning, J., Multinational Enterprises and the Global Economy, Addison-Wesley Publishing Co., 1993.

Easterly, William, and Stanley D. Fischer, “The Soviet Economic Decline: Historical and Republican Data,” NBERWorking Paper No. 4735, Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, May 1994.

Eaton, Jonathan, and Samuel Kortum, “International Patenting and Technology Diffusion,” NBER Working PaperNo. 4931, Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, November 1994.

Eaton, Jonathan and Samuel Kortum, “Trade in Ideas: Patenting and Productivity in the OECD,” NBER WorkingPaper, no. 5049, Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, May 1995.

Economic Planning Advisory Commission of Australia, “Tariff Reform and Economic Growth,” Commission Paper,no. 10, February 1996.

Edwards, S., “Why are Savings Rates so Different Across Countries? An International Comparative Analysis,”NBER Working Paper, no. 5097, April 1995.

Edwards, Sebastian, “Openness, Trade Liberalization, and Growth in Developing Countries,” Journal of EconomicLiterature 31 September 1993, pp. 1358-1393.

Emery, Robert, “The Relation of Exports and Economic Growth,” Kyklos 20:4, 1967, pp. 470-484.

Encyclopedia of American Business History and Biography, Bruccoli Clark Layman, Inc./Facts on File, Inc., 1989.

Engle, R.F., and C.W.J. Granger, “Co-integration and Error Correction: Representation, Estimation and Testing,”Econometrica, 1987.

Page 153: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

C-7

Esfahani, Hadi S., “Exports, Imports, and Economic Growth in Semi-Industrialized Countries,” Journal ofDevelopment Economics 35:1, January 1991, pp. 93-116.

Esfahani, H., “Exports, Imports, and Economic Growth in Semi-industrialized Countries,” Development Economics,1991.

Ethier, W.J., “National and International Returns to Scale in the Modern Theory of International Trade,” AmericanEconomic Review, vol. 72, June 1982, pp. 389-405.

Ethier, W.J., E. Helpman, and J.P. Neary, Theory, Policy, and Dynamics in International Trade, (Essays in Honor ofRonald W. Jones), Cambridge University Press, 1995.

Fagerberg, Jan, “A Technology Gap Approach to Why Growth Rates Differ,” Research Policy 16:2-4, August 1987,pp. 87-99.

Fagerberg, Jan, “Technology and International Differences in Growth Rates,” Journal of Economic Literature 102:3,September 1994, pp.1147-1175.

Fagerberg, Jan, “Why Growth Rates Differ,” in Technical Change and Economic Theory, eds. Giovanni Dosi et al.,London: Pinter Publishing, 1988, pp .432-457.

Feldstein, Martin, “Behavioral Response to Tax Rates: Evidence from TRA86,” NBER Working Paper No. 5000,Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, June 1995.

Feldstein, M. and P. Bacchetta, National Saving and Economic Performance, edited by B. Douglas Bernheim andJohn B. Shoven, NBER Project Report, 1991.

Feldstein, M. and C. Horioka, “Domestic Saving and International Capital Flows,” Economic Journal, vol. 90, June1980.

Ferrantino, Michael J., “The Effect of Intellectual Property Rights on International Trade and Investment,”Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv 129:2,1993, pp. 300-331.

Francois, J.F. and C.R. Shiells, “AGE Models of North American Free Trade,” Modeling Trade Policy, AppliedGeneral Equilibrium Assessments of North American Free Trade,” eds. J.F. Francois C.R. and Shiells,Cambridge University Press, 1994.

Frankel, J., “International Capital Mobility and Crowding Out in the U.S. Economy,” NBER Working Paper, no.1773, December 1985.

Frankel, Jeffrey and David Romer, “Trade and Growth: An Empirical Investigation,” NBER Working Paper, no.5476, Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, March 1996.

Friedman, M., A Theory of the Consumption Function, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1957.

Frobel, F., J. Heinricks, and O. Krege, The New International Division of Labour, Cambridge: Cambridge UniversityPress, 1980.

Froot, K. and J. Stein, “Exchange Rates and Foreign Direct Investment: An Imperfect Capital Markets Approach,”The Quarterly Journal of Economics, November 1991, pp. 1191-1217.

Fry, Maxwell J., “Money and Capital or Financial Deepening in Economic Development?,” Journal of Money,Credit and Banking 10, November 1978, pp. 464-475.

Fry, Maxwell J., Money Interest and Banking in Economic Development. Baltimore, Johns Hopkins University press,

1988.

Fry, Maxwell J., “Saving, Investment, Growth and the Cost of Financial Repression,” World Development 8, 1980,pp. 317-327

Page 154: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

C-8

Fry, Maxwell and Andrew Mason, “The Variable Rate-of-Growth Effect in the Life-Cycle Saving Model,” EconomicInquiry 20, no. 3 July 1982, pp. 426-44

Gagnon, J.E. and A.K. Rose, “Why Hasn’t Trade Grown Faster Than Income? Inter-Industry Trade Over the PastCentury,” International Finance Discussion Papers, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,no. 371, January 1990.

Gehlhar, Mark J., “Historical Analysis of Growth and Trade Patterns in the Pacific Rim: An evaluation of the GTAPframework,” ch. in Global Trade Analysis, Modeling and Applications, ed. T.W. Hertel, CambridgeUniversity Press, 1997.

Gershenberg, I., “Labor, Capital, and Management Slack in Multinational and Local Firms in KenyanManufacturing,” Economic Development and Cultural Change, vol. 35, 1986, pp. 163-78.

Gersovitz, M., “Saving and Develpoment,” in Handbook of Development Economics, eds. Hollins, Chenery, andSrinivasan, vol. 1, New York: North-Holland, 1988.

Ginarte, Juan Carlos and Walter G. Park, “Determinants of Intellectual Property Rights: A Cross-Country Study,”typescript, Washington, DC: American University, 1995.

Ginarte, Juan Carlos and Walter G. Park, “Intellectual Property Rights and Economic Growth,” typescript,Washington, DC: American University, 1996.

Ginarte, Juan Carlos and Walter G. Park, “International Technology Diffusion and Patent Protection,” typescript,Washington, DC: American University, 1996.

Giovannini A., “The Interest Elasticity of Savings in Developing Countries: The existing Evidence,” WorldDevelopment, vol. 11, July 1983.

Giovannini, A. “Saving and the Real Interest Rate in LDC’s,” Journal of Development Economics, vol 8, 1985, pp.197-217.

Go, D., “External Shocks, Adjustment Policies, and Investment in a Developing Economy,” Journal of EconomicDevelopment, (44) 1994.

Goldstein, M. and M.S. Khan, “Income and Price Effects in Foreign Trade,” in Handbook of InternationalEconomics, vol. II., eds. R.W. Jones and P.B. Kenen, Elsevier Science Publishers B.V. for InternationalMonetary Fund (IMF), 1985.

Gordon, Roger, H. and A. Lans Bovenberg, “ Why is Capital so Immobile Internationally? Possible Explanationsand Implications for Capital Income Taxation.” American Economic Review, vol. 86 no. 5, December 1996.

Gorecki, P.K., “The Determinants of Entry by Domestic and Foreign Enterprises in Canadian ManufacturingIndustries: Some Comments and Empirical Results,” Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 58, 1976, pp.485-488.

Gould, David M. and Roy J. Ruffin, “Human Capital, Trade, and Economic Growth,” Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv,vol. 131(3), 1995, pp. 425-445.

Goulder, L.H. and B. Eichengreen, “Trade Liberalization in General equilibrium: Intertemporal and InterindustryEffects,” Canadian Journal of Economics, vol. 28, 1992, pp. 253-280.

Goulder, L.H. and L. Bovenberg, “Optimal Environmental Taxation in the Presence of Other Taxes: GeneralEquilibrium Analyses,” The American Economic Review, 86(4), September 1996.

Granger, C.W.J., Forecasting in Business and Economics. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1989.

Gravelle, Jane G., The Economic Effects of Taxing Capital Income. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1994.

Page 155: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

C-9

Grossman, Gene M. and Elhanan Helpman, Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy, Cambridge, MA: MITPress, 1991.

Guisinger S. E. and Associates, Investment Incentives and Performance Requirements, New York: Praeger, 1985.

Gupta, Kanhaya L., “Aggregate Savings, Financial Intermediation, and Interest Rate,” Review of Economics andStatistics, vol. 69, May 1987.

Gyimah-Brempong, K and Thomas L. Traynor, “Political Stability and Savings in Less Developed Countries:Evidence from Sub-Sahara Africa,” The Journal of Development Studies, vol. 32, no. 5, June 1996, pp.695-714.

Hamilton, J.D., Time Series Analysis, Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey, 1994.

Handoussa, Heba, Mieko Nishimizu, and John Page, “Productivity Change in Egyptian Public Sector Industries afterthe “Opening,’” Journal of Development Economics 20: 53-74, 1986.

Hanoch, G., “Production and Demand Models with Direct or Indirect Implicit Additivity,” Econometrica, vol. 43,no. 3, May 1975, pp. 395-419.

Hanson, B., A Survey of General Equilibrium Systems, McGraw-Hill Book Co., New York, 1970.

Harrison, Ann, “Openness and Growth: A Time-Series, Cross-Country Analysis for Developing Countries,” Journalof Development Economics 48, 1996, pp. 419-447.

Harrison, Ann, “Productivity, Imperfect Competition and Trade Reform, Theory and Evidence,” Journal ofInternational Economics, vol. 36, 1994, pp. 53-73.

Harrison, Ann and Ana Revenga, “The Effects of Trade Policy Reform: What Do We Really Know?,” WorkingPaper, no. 5225, National Bureau of Economic Research.

Harrison, G.W., T.F. Rurtherford, and D.G. Tarr, “Quantifying the Uruguay Round,” in The Uruguay Round and theDeveloping Countries, eds. W. Martin and A. Winters, Washington, DC: World Bank, 1995.

Harrod, Roy F., “An Essay in Dynamic Theory,” Economic Journal 49, June 1939, pp. 14-33.

Head, K., and J. Ries, “Overseas Investment and Firm Exports,” Working Paper, 1997.

Helleiner, Gerald, “Transnational Corporations and Direct Foreign Investment,” ch. in Handbook of DevelopmentEconomics Volume 2, eds. Hollis Chenery and T.N. Srinivasan, Amsterdam: North- Holland Publishing,1989, pp. 1441-1480.

Helpman, E., “International Trade in the Presence of Product Differentiation, Economies of Scale and MonopolisticCompetition,” Journal of International Economics 11, North-Holland, 1981, pp. 305-340,.

Helpman, E. and P.R. Krugman, Market Structure and Foreign Trade, Increasing Returns, Imperfect Competition,and the International Economy, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1986.

Helpman, E. and P.R. Krugman,, Trade Policy and Market Structure, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1994.

Hertel, T.W., ed., Global Trade Analysis, Modeling and Applications, Cambridge University Press, 1997.

Higgins, Matthew and Jeffrey G. Williamson, “Asian Demography and Foreign Capital Dependence,” May 1996,NBER Working Paper, no. 5560.

Hinojosa-Ojeda, R.A., J.D. Lewis, and S. Robinson, “Convergence and Divergence Between NAFTA, Chile, andMERCOSUR: Overcoming Dilemmas aof Norht and South American Economic Integration,” report onresearch supported by the Inter-American Development Bank, the United Nations Economic Commissionfor Latin America and the Caribbean (ECLAC), and the North-South Center, January, 1995.

Page 156: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

C-10

Ho, M. and Dale Jorgenson, “Making Trade Policies and U.S. Growth: Some Methodological issues,” paperpresented at the symposium Evaluating APEC Trade Liberalization: Tariff and Nontariff Barriers, USITC,Washington, DC, September 11-12, 1997.

Ho, M. and Dale Jorgenson, Trade Policy and U.S. Economic Growth,” Journal of Policy Modeling, 16(2) 119-46,1994.

Hollander, A., “Foreign Location Decision by U.S. Transnational Firms: An Empirical Study,” Managerial andDecision Economics, vol 5, March 1984, pp. 7-18.

Holmes, Kim R., Bryan T. Johnson, and Melanie Kirkpatrick, eds., 1997 Index of Economic Freedom, Washingtonand New York: The Heritage Foundation and the Wall Street Journal.

Horst, T., “The Industrial Composition of U.S. Exports and Subsidiary Sales to the Canadian Market,” AmericanEconomic Review, March 1972, pp. 37-45.

Houthakker, H.S. and S.P. Magee, “Income and Price Elasticities in World Trade,” Review of Economics andStatistics, 1969, vol. 51, pp. 111-125.

Hsiao, Cheng, Analysis of Panel Data, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1986.

Hummels, D. and J. Levinsohn, “Monopolistic Competition and International Trade: Reconsidering the Evidence,”Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110:3, August 1995, pp. 799-836.

Hunter, L.C. and Markusen, J.R., “Per-Capita Income As a Determinant of Trade,” in R.C. Feenstra, ed. EmpiricalMethods for International Trade, The MIT Press, 1988,

International Currency Analysis, various years

International Monetary Fund, International Financial Statistics, Washington, DC, 1995.

International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook, Washington, DC, May, 1997.

Ishhii, Jun, and Kei-Mu Yi, “The Growth of World Trade,” Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Research Paper,no. 9718, New York, NY, May 1997.

Jensen, Bjarne S., The Dynamic Systems of Basic Economic Growth Models, Dordrecht: Kluwer AcademicPublishers, 1994.

Jensen, Bjarne S. and Mogens E. Larsen, “Growth and Long-Run Stability,” Acta Applicandae Mathematicae 9,1987, pp. 219-237.

Johansen, S. and K. Juselius, “Maximum Likelihood Estimation and Inference on Cointegrationwith Applicationsto the Demand for Money,” Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 1990.

Jones, Charles I., “Economic Growth and the Relative Price of Capital,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 1994, pp.34, 359-382.

Jones, Charles I., “Time Series Tests of Endogenous Growth Models,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 110:2, May1995, pp. 495-525.

Jones, Larry E. and Rodolfo Manuelli, “A Convex Model of Equilibrium Growth: Theory and Policy Implications,”Journal of Political Economy 98:5 June 1990, pp. 1008-37.

Jong-Wha Lee, “Capital Goods Imports and Long-run Growth,” Journal of Development Economics, vol. 48, 1995,pp. 91-110.

Jorgenson, Dale W., “Capital Theory and Investment Behavior,” American Economic Review 53:2 May 1963, pp.

247-259.

Page 157: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

C-11

Jorgenson, D.W. and S. Ho Mun, “Trade Policy and U.S. Economic Growth,” Discussion Paper no. 1634, HarvardInstitute of Economic Research, 1993.

Jorgenson, D.W. and E.A. Hudson, “U.S. Energy Policy and Economic Growth, 1975-2000,” Bell Journal ofEconomics and Management Science, vol. 5, no. 2, Autumn 1974.

Jorgenson, D.W. and D.T. Slesnick, “General Equilibrium Analysis of Natural Gas Price Regulation,” in PublicRegulation, Cambridge, MIT Press, 1987, E.E.Bailey (ed.)

Jorgenson, D.W. and P.J. Wilcoxen, “Environmental Regulation and U.S. Economic Growth,” Rand Journal ofEconomics, 21(2), Summer 1990.

Jorgenson, D.W. and Kun-Young Yun, “Tax Policy and Capital Allocation,” Scandinavian Journal of Economics,vol. 88, no. 2, 1986.

Jung, Woo S. and Peyton J. Marshall, “Exports, Growth, and Causality in Developing Countries,” Journal ofDevelopment Economics 18:2 May/June 1985, pp. 1-12.

Kang, K.H.,”Why Did Korean Save so “Little” and Why Do they Now Save So “Much,” International EconomicJournal, vol. 8, no.4, Winter 1994.

Kanth, R., Paradigms in Economic Development, Classic Perspectives, Critiques, and Reflections, M.E. Sharpe,1994.

Katz, J.M. (ed.), Technology Generation in Latin American Manufacturing Industries, New York, St. Martins Press,1987.

Kehoe, T.J., “Toward a Dynamic General Equilibrium Model of North American Trade,” in Modeling Trade Policy,Applied General Equilibrium Assessments of North American Free Trade,” Cambridge University Press,1994, Francois, J.F. and Shiells, C.R. (eds.)

Kehoe, T.J., Polo, C., and Sancho, F., “An Evaluation of the Performance of an Applied General Equilibrium Modelof the Spanish Economy,” Research Department Working Paper, no. 480, Federal Reserve Bank ofMinneapolis, 1991.

Keller, Wolfgang, “Are International R&D Spillovers Trade Related?” Analyzing Spillovers Among RandomlyMatched Trade Partners, NBER Working Paper, no. 6065, Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of EconomicResearch, June 1997.

Kemp, M.C., The Gains from Trade and the Gains from Aid, Essays in International Trade Theory, Routledge, NewYork, 1995.

Kennedy, P., A Guide to Econometrics: Third Edition, Cambridge: MIT Press, 1992.

Keuschnigg, C. and Kohler, W, “Commercial Policy and Dynamic Adjustment Under Monopolistic Competition,August 1994, paper presented at the University of Vienna, the University of Chimneys, the HumboldtUniversity of Berlin, at the annual meeting of the Austrian Economic Association, and at the annualmeeting of the European Economic Association.

Kharas, H.J. and Shishido, H., “Foreign Borrowing and Macroeconomic Adjustment to External Shocks,” Journal ofDevelopment Economics, 25(1), February 1987.

Klaus Schmidt-Hebbel, Steven B. Webb, and Giancarlo Corsetti, “Household Saving in Developing Countries: First

Cross Country Evidence,” The World Bank Economic Review, vol. 6, no. 3, 1992.

Koopmans, Tjalling C., “On the Concept of Optimal Economic Growth,” in The Econometric Approach toDevelopment Planning, 1965, Amsterdam: North-Holland.

Kouparitsas, M.A., “A Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis of NAFTA,” Economic Perspectives, Federal ReserveBank of Chicago, January/February 1997.

Page 158: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

C-12

Kravis, Irving, “Trade as a Handmaiden of Growth,” Economic Journal 80:320, December 1970, pp. 850- 872.

Kremer, Michael, “Population Growth and Technological Change: One Million B.C. to 1990,” Quarterly Journal ofEconomics 108:3, August 1993, pp.681-716.

Krueger, Anne O., “Comment,” in B. Douglas Bernheim and John B. Shoven, eds., National Saving and EconomicPerformance, NBER, 1991.

Krueger, Anne O., Foreign Trade Regimes and Economic Development: Liberalization Attempts and Consequences,1978, Cambridge, MA: Ballinger Publishing Co. for NBER.

Krugman, P.R., Geography and Trade, Leuven University Press/The MIT Press, 1991.

Krugman, P.R., “Growing World Trade: Causes and Consequences,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, no. 1,The Brookings Institution, Washington, DC, 1995, pp. 327-377.

Krugman, Paul, “The Myth of Asia’s Miracle,” Foreign Affairs, 73, 1994, pp. 6, 62-78.

Krugman, P.R. and Obstfeld, M., International Economics, Theory and Policy, Addison-Wesley, Reading, MA,1996.

Kuznets, S., “Modern Economic Growth: Findings and Reflections,” The American Economic Review,” June 1973,63, pp. 247-258.

Lahiri , A.K., “Dynamics of Asian Savings: The Role of Growth and Age Structure,” IMF Staff Papers, vol. 36,

no.1, 1989.

Laird, Sam and Alexander Yeats, Quantitative Methods for Trade Barrier Analysis (New York: New York UniversityPress), 1990.

Landsburg, M., Pain, N., & Smidkova, K., “Foreign Direct Investment in Central Europe Since 1990: AnEconometric Study,” National Institute Economic Review, May 1996, pp. 104-114.

Laumas, P.S., “Exports and propensity to Save,” Economic Development and Cultural Change, 1982.

Leamer, Edward E. (1988), “Measures of Openness,” in Robert E. Baldwin, ed., Trade Policy Issues and EmpiricalAnalysis (Chicago and London: The University of Chicago Press for NBER), pp. 147-204 (includesdiscussion by Drusilla K. Brown).

Lee, J., “Exports and Propensity to Save in LDCs,” The Economic Journal, vol. 81, 1971.

Lee, J. and Mansfield, E., “Intellectual Property Protection and U.S. Foreign Direct Investment,” Review ofEconomics and Statistics, May 1996, pp. 181-186.

Lee, J. W. and P. Swagel, “Trade Barriers and Trade Flows Across Countries and Industries,” Review of Economicsand Statistics 74, 3, August 1997, pp. 372-382.

Lee, Jong-Wha, “Capital Goods Imports and Long-run Growth,” Journal of Development Economics, vol. 48, 1995,pp. 91-110.

Leff, N.H, “Dependency Rates and Savings Rates,” American Economic Review, December 1969, pp. 59, 886-96.

Leonard, D. and Ngo Van Long, Optimal Control Theory and Static Optimization in Economics, CambridgeUniversity Press, 1992.

Levine, R and D. Renelt, “A Sensitivity Analysis of Cross -Country Growth Regressions.” American EconomicReview, September 1992, Wacziarg, Romain, “Dynamic gains from Trade in Seven Lssons,” Preliminarydraft, September, 1996.

Page 159: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

C-13

Levine, Ross and David Renelt, “A Sensitivity Analysis of Cross-Country Growth Regressions,” AmericanEconomic Review 82:4 September 1992, pp. 942-963.

Levinsohn, James, “Testing the Imports-as-Markets-Discipline Hypothesis,” Journal of International Economics,August 1993, vol. 35.

Lichtenberg, Frank R., “R&D Investment and International Productivity Differences,” NBER Working Paper, no.4161, 1992, Cambridge, MA, National Bureau of Economic Research.

Lim L.Y.C. and Pang E.F., “Vertical Linkages and Multinational Enterprises in Developing Countries, WorldDevelopment, Vol. 10, 1982, pp. 585-595.

Lincoln, E., Japan Facing Economic Maturity, The Brookings Institution, Washington, DC, 1988.

Linder, S., An Essay on Trade and Transformation, Uppsala, Almqvist and Wiksells, 1961.

Lipsey, R., “Outward Direct Investment and the U.S. Economy,” NBER Working Paper, #4691, 1994.

Lipsey, R.G. and P.N. Courant, Economics, Harper-Collins College Publishers, 1995

Lipsey, R. and M. Weiss, “Foreign Production and Exports of Individual Firms,” Review of Economics and Statistics,August 1983, pp. 181-186.

Lipsey, R. and M. Weiss, “Foreign Production and Exports in Manufacturing Industries,” Review of Economics andStatistics, November 1981, pp. 488-494.

Little, Ian, Tibor Scitovsky and Maurice Scott, Industry and Trade in Some Developing Countries, London and NewYork: Oxford University Press for OECD, 1970

Long, Ngo Van and Kar-yiu Wong (1996), “Endogenous Growth and International Trade: A Survey,” typescript,prepared for the conference on “Dynamics, Economic Growth, and International Trade,” Copenhagen,Denmark, August 15-17, 1996.

Lucas, Robert E., “On the Mechanics of Economic Development,” Journal of Monetary Economics 22, 1 July 1988,pp. 3-42.

Lundback, J. and Tortsensson, J., “Demand and International Trade: Theory and Empirical Evidence,” ConferencePaper, presented at the 25th Conference of Economists, Canberra, September 1996.

MacDonald, James M., “Does Import Competition Force Efficient Production?,” Review of Economics andStatistics, November 1994.

Mahalanobis, P.C., “The Approach of Operational Research to Planning in India,” Sankhya: The Indian Journal ofStatistics, 16:1/2, 1955, pp. 3-62.

Maizels, A. Exports and Economic Growth of Developing Countries, Cambridge University Press, 1968.

Mankiw, N. Gregory, “The Growth of Nations,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1995:1, 1995, pp. 275-326(includes discussion by Edmund S. Phelps and Paul M. Romer).

Mankiw, N. Gregory, David Romer and David N. Weil, “A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth,”Quarterly Journal of Economics 107:2 May 1992, pp. 407-437.

Mansfield, E. and Romeo, A., “Reverse Transfer of Technology from Overseas Subsidiaries to American Firms,”IEEE Transactions on Engineering Management, EM-31, August 1984, pp. 610-627.

Mariger, Randall P., “Taxes, Capital Gains Realizations, and Revenues: A Critical Review and Some New Results, Finance and Economics Discussion Series 95/31, June 1995, Washington, DC: Board ofGovernors of the Federal Reserve System.

Page 160: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

C-14

Markusen, J., “The Boundaries of Multinational Enterprises and the Theory of International Trade,” Journal ofEconomic Perspectives, vol. 9, 1995, pp. 169-189.

Markusen, J.R., “Explaining the Volume of Trade: An Eclectic Approach,” The American Economic Review, 76,December 1986, pp. 1002-1011.

Markusen, J.R., Melvin, J.R., Kaempfer, W.H., and Maskus, K.E., International Trade, Theory and Evidence,McGraw-Hill Inc., 1995.

Marquez, J., “The Autonomy of Trade Elasticities: Choice and Consequences,” International Finance DiscussionPapers, no. 442, January 1992, Washington, DC: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

Marquez, J., “The Autonomy of Elasticities for Trade among Canada, Japan, and the United States,” in Japan andthe World Economy 5, 1993, pp. 179-195, North Holland Publishing Company.

Marquez, J., “The Constancy of Illusions or the Illusion of Constancies: Income and Price Elasticities for U.S.Imports, 1890-1992,” International Finance Discussion Papers, no. 475, July 1994, Washington, DC:Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

Marquez, J., “A Century of Trade Elasticities for Canada, Japan, and the United States,” International FinanceDiscussion Papers, no. 531, December 1995, Washington, DC: Board of Governors of the Federal ReserveSystem.

Maskus, Keith E. and Mohan Penubarti, “How Trade-Related are Intellectual Property Rights?,” Journal ofInternational Economics 39, 1995, pp. 227-248.

Mason, Andrew, “Saving, Economic Growth, and Demographic Change,” Population and Development Review 14,No.1, March 1988.

McFetridge, D.G., “The Timing, Mode, and Terms of Technology Transfer: Some Recent Findings” In (A.E.Safarian and G., Bertin eds.) Governments and International Technology Transfer, London: Croom Helm,1987.

McKibbin, W.J., “Regional and Multilateral Trade Liberalization: The Effects on Trade, Investment and Welfare,”paper presented at the symposium: Evaluating APEC Trade Liberalization: Tariff and Nontariff Barriers,USITC, Washington, DC, September 11-12, 1997.

McKibbin, W.J., Quantifying APEC Trade Liberalization: A Dynamic Analysis, Research School of Pacific & AsianStudies, Australian National University, and The Brookings Institution, Washington, DC, March 14, 1996.

McKibbin, W.J. and Salvatore, D., “The Global Economic Consequences of the Uruguay Round,” Open EconomiesReview, 6(2), April 1995.

Mercenier, J. and da Conceicao Sampaio de Souza, M., “Structural Adjustment and Growth in a Highly IndebtedMarket Economy: Brazil, “ in J. Mercenier and T. N. Srinivasan, eds., Applied General Equilibrium andEconomic Development, The University Press of Michigan, 1997.

Mertens, J.F., and Sorin, S., Game-Theoretic Methods in General Equilibrium Analysis, Kluwer AcademicPublishers, Boston, 1994.

Miksell, R.F. and James E. Zinser., “The Nasture of Savings Function in Developing Countries: A Survey of theTheorectical and Empirical Literature,” Journal of Economic Literature, March 1973, pp. 11 1- 26.

Mincer, Jacob, “Economic Development, Growth of Human Capital, and the Dynamics of the Wage Structure,”Journal of Economic Growth, 1(1995), pp.29-48.

Mitra, Pradeep K., Adjustment in Oil-importing Developing Countries: A comparative economic analysis, NewYork: Cambridge University Press, 1994.

Page 161: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

C-15

Modigliani, Franco,”The life Cycle Hypotheses of saving and Intercountry Differences in the Savings Ratio,” inW.A. Eltis et.al.,eds., Induction, Growth and Trade, Oxford, 1970, pp. 197-225.

Montiel, P., “Capital Mobility in Developing Countries,” World Bank Review, vol. 8, September 1994.

Murtha, T.P., “Surviving Industrial Targeting: State Credibility and Public Policy Contingencies in MultinationalSubcontracting”, Journal of Law Economic Organization, Spring 1991, vol. 7, pp. 117-43.

Nicholas, “The Theory of Multinational Enterprices as a Transaction Model,” in Multinationals: Theory and Histroy,eds. Hertner P. and Jones G., Aldershot: Gower, 1986.

Nishimizu, Mieko, and John Page, “Trade Policies, Market Orientation, and Productivity Change in Industry,” inTrade Theory and Economic Reform: North, South and East—Essays in Honor of Bela Belassa, eds. Jaimede Melo and Andre Sapir, Cambridge: Basil Blackwell, 1991.

Nishimizu, Mieko, and John Page, Jr., “Productivity Change and Dynamic Comparative Advantage,” World BankReprint, Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 68, no. 2, May 1986.

Nishimizu, Mieko, and Sherman Robinson, “Trade Policies and Productivity Change in Semi-IndustrializedCountries,” Journal of Development Economics, September/October 1984, pp. 177-206.

Nonneman, Walter and Patrick Van Houdt, “A Further Augmentation of the Solow Model and the Empirics ofGrowth for OECD Countries,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 111:3, August 1996, pp. 943- 953.

Nordhaus, William, Invention, Growth, and Welfare. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1969.

Office of Management and Budget, Budget of the United States Government, Fiscal Year 1998, AnalyticalPerspectives, H. Doc. 105-003, vol. II.

Ogaki, M., J.Ostry and C. Reinhart, “Saving Behavior in Low-and Middle Income Developing Countries: AComparison,” Working paper, International Monetary Fund, Research Department, 1994.

Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), Assessing the Effects of The Uruguay Round,

Trade Policy Issues, no. 2, Paris, France, 1993.

Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development, Basic Science and Technology Statistics, 1994, (4thEdition), on Diskettes, Paris: OECD.

Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development, International Sectoral Data Base 1990-1995, ondiskettes, 1996, Paris: OECD.

Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development, The OECD STAN Database, 1970-93, on Diskettes,1994, Paris: OECD.

Orr, D., “The Industrial Composition of U.S. Exports and Subsidiary Sales to the Canadian Market: Comment,”American Economic Review, March 1975, pp. 230-234.

Pack, Howard, “Endogenous Growth Theory: Intellectual Appeal and Empirical Shortcomings,” Journal ofEconomic Perspectives 8:1, Winter 1994, pp. 55-72.

Pack, Howard, “Industrialization and Trade,” In Hollis Chenery and T.N. Srinivasan, eds., Handbook ofDevelopment Economics, vol. 1, 1988, Amsterdam: North-Holland.

Petri, A.P., “Foreign Direct Investment in a Computable General Equilibrium Framework,” paper prepared for theconference “Making APEC Work: Economic Challenges and Policy Alternatives,” held at the KeioUniversity in Tokyo, Japan, during March 13-14, 1997.

Phelps, Edmund, Golden Rules of Economic Growth: Studies of Efficient and Optimal Investment, 1966, New York:W.W. Norton.

Page 162: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

C-16

Pilat, D., “Competition, Productivity, and Efficiency,” OECD Economic Studies 27:2, 1996, 107-146.

Pitchford, John D., “Growth and the Elasticity of Factor Substitution,” Economic Record 36, 1960, 491-504.

Pogany, P., “The Almost Ideal Demand System and Its Application in General Equilibrium Calculations,” USITCWorking Paper, May 1996, no. 96-05-A.

Pogany, P., “Computable General Equilibrium Models: An Historical Perspective,” USITC Working Paper,

September 1996, no. 96-09-B.

Pogany, P., “Homotheticity in Demand Analysis,” USITC, Office of Economics Research Notes, June 9, 1997,97-06-A.

Porter, M.E., The Competitive Advantage of Nations, The Free Press New York, 1990.

Prebisch, R., “Commercial Policy in the Underdeveloped Countries,” American Economic Review, Papers andProceedings, May 1959, pp. 261-264.

Prema-Chandra Athukorala and Riedel, J., “Modeling NIE Exports: Aggregation, Quantitative Restrictions andChoice of Econometric Methodology,” The Journal of Development Studies, vol. 33, no. 1, October 1996,pp. 81-98.

Pritchett, Lant, “Divergence, Big Time,” Journal of Economic Perspectives vol. 11, no. 3, Summer 1997, pp. 3-17.

Pritchett, Lant, “Measuring Outward Orientation in LDCs: Can it be Done?,” Journal of Development Economics49:2 May 1996, pp. 307-335.

Ram, Rati, “Dependency Rates and Aggregate Savings: A New International Cross-Section Study,” AmericanEconomic Review. June 1982, vol. 72, no. 3.

Ramsey, Frank, “A Mathematical Theory of Saving,” Economic Journal 38, December 1928, pp.543-559.

Ranis, G. and Shive, C., “Direct Foreign Investment in Taiwan’s Development,” in Foreign Trade and Investment:Economic Development in the Newly Industrializing Asian Countries, (Galensons, W. ed.), Madison:University of Wisconsin Press, 1985.

Rebelo, Sergio, “Long-Run Policy Analysis and Long-Run Growth,” Journal of Political Economy, 99:3 June 1991,pp. 500-521.

Reinert, K.A., Roland-Holst, D.W., and Shiells, C.R., “Modeling a North American Free Trade Area: Estimation ofFlexible Functional Forms,” Weltwirschaftliches Archiv, 1993, pp. 55-77.

Reuber, G.L., “Foreign Investment in Canada: A Review,” in Contemporary Economic Problems in Canada,Toronto: Holt Rienhart and Winston, 1973.

Roberts, Mark, “The Structure of Production in Colombian Manufacturing Industries,” 1989, World Bank, CountryEconomics Department, Washington, DC, processed.

Robinson, S., et al., “Structure of the GNAFTA CGE Model,” International Food Policy Institute, Washington, DC,February, 1995.

Robinson, S., Soule, M.J., and Weyerbrock, S., “Import Demand Functions, Trade Volumes, and Terms of Trade

Effects in Multi-Country Trade Models, Working Paper, Department of Agricultural and ResourceEconomics, University of California at Berkeley, January, 1992.

Rodrik, Dani, “Political Economy of Trade Policy,” in G.M. Grossman and K. Rogoff, eds., Handbook ofInternational Economics, vol. III, Chapter 28 (Amsterdam: North-Holland), 1995, pp. 1457-1494.

Rodrik, Dani, “TFPG Controversies, Institutions, and Economic Performance in East Asia,” NBER Working Paper,no. 5914, February 1997, Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

Page 163: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

C-17

Roe, T.L. and Temel, T., “Endogenous Technological Change via Industry Lobbying: Closed Versus Open EconomyModels,” Journal of Economic Development, 21(2), 1996.

Romer, Paul M., “Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth,” Journal of Political Economy 94, 5, October 1986,pp. 1002-1037.

Romer, Paul M., “The Origins of Endogenous Growth,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 8:1, Winter 1994, pp.3-22.

Romer, Paul M., “What Determines the Rate of Growth and Technological Change?,” Working Papers,Macroeconomic Adjustment and Growth, Country Economics Department, WPS 279, Washington, DC,The World Bank, 1989.

Rose, A.K., “Why Has Trade Grown Faster Than Income?,” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,International Finance Discussion Papers, no. 390, November 1990.

Rosenbluth, G., “The Relation between Foreign Control and Concentration in Canadian Industry,” Candian Journalof Economics, vol. 3, 1970, pp. 14-38.

Rossi, Nicola, “Government Spending, The Real Interest Rate, and the Behavior of Liquidity-ConstrainedConsumers in Developing Countries,” IMF Staff Papers 35 (1), 1988, pp. 104-40

Rugman, A. R. “The Multinational Enterprise,” in P. Walter and T. Murray, eds., Handbook of InternationalManagement, (Ingo W. and Murray, T. eds.), New York, Wiley, 1988.

Sachs, Jeffrey D. and Andrew Warner, “Economic Reform and the Process of Global Integration,” Brookings Paperson Economic Activity 1995:1, pp. 1-118 (includes discussion by Anders Å slund and Stanley Fischer).

Sala-i-Martin, Xavier, “I Just Ran Two Million Regressions,” American Economic Review vol. 87 no. 2, May 1997,pp. 178-183.

Salvatore, D., International Economics, Prentice-Hall, Inc., 1995.

Scaperlanda, A.E. and Balough, R.S., “Determinants of U.S. Direct Investment in the EEC Revisted,” EuropeanEconomic Review, May 1983, pp. 381-90.

Schmidt-Hebbel, K., S. Webb and G. Corsetti., “Household Savings in developing Countries,” World BankEconomic Review, vol. 6, September 1992.

Segerstrom, Paul S., “Innovation, Imitation, and Economic Growth,” Journal of Political Economy 99:4 August1991, pp. 807-827.

Segerstrom, Paul S., T.C.A. Anant and Elias Dinopoulos, “A Schumpeterian Model of the Product Life Cycle,”American Economic Review, 80, 1990, pp. 1077-1092.

Serletis, A., “Export Growth and Canadian Economic Development,” Journal of Development Economics, 1992,38:1, pp.133-145.

Shiells, C.R., Stern R.M., and Deardorf, A.V., “Estimates of the Elasticities of Substitution Between Imports andHome Goods for the United States,” Weltwirschaftliches Archiv, 122, 1986, pp. 497-519.

Singer, H.W., “The Distribution of Gains Between Investing and Borrowing Countries,” American EconomicReview, vol. 40, no. 2, May 1950, pp. 473-485.

Snyder, D.W., “Econometrics studies of Household saving Behavior in Developing Countries: A Survey,” Journal ofDevelopment Studies, 1971.

Page 164: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

C-18

Solow, Robert M., “A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 70:1,February 1956, pp. 65-94.

Solow, Robert M., “Perspectives on Growth Theory,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 8:1 Winter 1994, pp. 45-54.

Spraos, J., “The Statistical Debate on the Net Barter Terms of Trade Between Primary Commodities andManufactures,” The Economic Journal, vol. 90, no. 357, March 1980, pp. 107-128.

Stokey, Nancy L., “Human Capital, Product Quality, and Growth,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1991pp. 106,587-616.

Stone, J.R.N., The Measurement of Consumers’ Expenditure and Behavior in the United Kingdom, 1920-1938,Cambridge, Cambridge University Press 1954.

Summers, Robert and Alan Heston, “A New Set of International Comparisons of Real Product and Price Levels:

Estimates for 130 Countries, 1950-85,” Review of Income and Wealth, March, 1-24, 1988.

Summers, Robert, and Alan Heston, “The Penn World Table (Mark 5): An Expanded Set of InternationalComparisons,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 106:2, May 1991), pp. 327-368.

Swan, Trevor W., “Economic Growth and Capital Accumulation,” Economic Record 32, November 1956, pp.334-361.

Takayama, A., Mathematical Economics, Cambridge University Press, 1994.

Taplin, G.B., “A Model of World Trade,” in R. J. Ball, ed., The International Linkage of National Economic Models,Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1973.

Tay, Simon S. C., “The Future of Trade and Environment in Asia,” paper deliverd at The Asia Conference on Tradeand Environment, Singapore, June 27, 1996. Singapore; Asia-Pacific Centre for Environmental Law,typescript.

Theil, H., Theory and Measurement of Consumer Demand, vol. 1, New York: North Holland/American Elsevier,1975.

Thomas, Vinod, Nadav Halevi and Julie Stanton (1991), “Does Policy Reform Improve Performance?,” backgroundpaper for World Development Report 1991. (Washington, DC: World Bank.)

Thursby, J. and Thursby, M., “How Reliable Are Simple, Single Equation Specifications of Import Demand?”Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 66, no. 1, 1984, pp. 120-128.

Tobin, J. 1967, “Life Cycle Saving and Balanced Economic Growth,” William Fellener, ed., Economic studies in theTradition of Irving Fisher, New York: Wiley Press , pp. 231-256.

Torstensson, J., “The Heckscher-Ohlin-Vanek Theorem with Quasi-Homothetic Preferences,” Economics Letters,1993, vol. 76, pp. 102-1011.

Tseng, P., “Full Cost Pricing Analysis of the U.S. Energy/Economic System: A Study Using the U.S.- Markal-MacroModel,” paper presented at the 17th Conference of the International Association for Energy Economics,Boston, MA, October, 1996.

Tybout, James R., “Entry, Exit, Competition, and Productivity in the Chilean Industrial Sector,” World Bank, 1989,Country Economics Department, Washington, DC, processed.

Tybout, James R., “Linking Trade and Productivity: New Research Directions,” World Bank Economic Review, vol.

6, no. 2, 1992, pp. 189-211.

Tybout, James R., Jaime de Melo, and Vittorio Corbo, “The Effects of Trade Reforms on Scale and TechnicalEfficiency: New Evidence from Chile,” Journal of International Economics, 1991 31: pp. 231-50.

Page 165: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

C-19

Tybout, J. and M.D. Westbrook, “Trade Liberalization and the Dimensions of Efficiency Change in MexicanManufacturing Industries,” Journal of International Economics, vol. 39, August 1995, pp. 53-78.

UNCTAD, Handbook of Trade Control Measures of Developing Countries Supplement: A Statistical Analysis ofTrade Control Measures of Developing Countries, 1987. UNCTAD/DDM/Misc. 2 GE.89-55071 (Geneva:United Nations Conference on Trade and Development), 1988.

UNCTAD, Divsion of Transnational Corporations and Investment (UNCTAD-DCTI), World Investment Report1993: Transnational and Corporations and Integrated International Production (New York: UnitedNations), United Nations Publications, 1994.

UNCTAD, Divsion of Transnational Corporations and Investment (UNCTAD-DCTI), World Investment Report1996: Investment Trade and International Policy Arrangements, (New York: United Nations), UnitedNations Publications, 1997.

U.S. Department of Commerce, “U.S. Direct Investment Abroad,” Survey of Current Business, Various Issues, 1994and 1997.

USITC, GTAP Documentation, 1994.

USITC, The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization, USITC publication 2608, Washington, DC, February 1993.

Uzawa, Hirofumi, “Optimal Technical Change in an Aggregative Model of Economic Growth,” InternationalEconomic Review 6 January 1965, 18-31. Aw, B.-Y. and A. Hwang, “Productivity and the Export Market:A Firm-Level Analysis,” Journal of Development Economics 47, 1995, pp. 313-332.

Varian, H.R., Microeconomic Analysis, W.W. Norton and Company, New York, 1992.

Venables, A.J. and S. van Wijnbergen, Trade Liberalization, Productivity, and Competition: The Mexicanexperience, World Bank, 1993, processed.

Ventura, Jaume, “Growth and Interdependence,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 112:1 February 1997, pp. 57-84.

Vernon, Raymond G., “International Investment and International Trade in the Product Cycle,” Quarterly Journal ofEconomics, vol. 80, no. 2, May 1966.

Wacziarg, Romain, “Dynamic Gains from Trade in Seven Lessons,” typescript, September 1996, (Cambridge, MA:Harvard University).

Weder, R., “How Domestic Demand Shapes the Pattern of International Trade,” World Development, 1996, pp.273-286.

Weisman, E., “Transition and Foreign Direct Investment: The Case of the Former Soviet Bloc,” Working Paper,1997.

Westphal, Larry E., Y.W. Rhee and G. Pursell, “Sources of Technological Capability in South Korea,” in M.Fransman and K. King, eds., Technological Capability in Developing Countries, 1984 (London: Pinter).

White, Halbert, “A Heteroskedsticity-Consistent Covariance Matrix and a Direct Test for Heteroskedasticity”Econometrica 48, 1980, pp. 817-838.

Winters, L.A. (ed.), Trade Flows and Trade Policy After “1992”, Cambridge University Press, 1992.

Winters, L.A., “Separability and the Specification of Foreign Trade Functions,” Journal of International Economics17, 1984, pp. 239-263. North Holland.

Woodward D.P., and Rolfe, R.J., “The Location of Export-Oriented Foreign Direct Investment in the CaribbeanBasin,” Journal of International Business Studies, vol. 24, 1993, pp. 121-144.

World Bank, STARS (Socioeconomic Time-Series Access and Retrieval System), CD-ROM, 1994.

Page 166: The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization:An Empirical Analysis · 2014-08-21 · iii PREFACE On December 2, 1996, the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) instituted

C-20

World Bank, World Development Report 1995: Workers in an Integrating World, Oxford University Press for theWorld Bank, 1995.

World Bank, World Development Report 1996: From Plan to Market, Oxford University Press for the World Bank,1996.

World Bank, World Development Report 1997: The State in a Changing World, Oxford University Press for theWorld Bank, 1997.

World Bank, World Development Indicators, CD-ROM, Washington, DC, World Bank, 1997.

Yi, Kei-Mu and Narayana R. Kocherlakota, “Is There Endogenous Long-Run Growth? Evidence from the U.S. andthe U.K.,” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports no. 17, December 1996.

Yoshihara, K. The Rise of Ersatz Capitalism in South East Asia, Oxford, Oxford University Press, 1988.

Young, Alwyn, “Learning by Doing and the Dynamic Effects of International Trade,” Quarterly Journal ofEconomics, 1991, pp. 106, 369-405.

Young, Alwyn (1992), “A Tale of Two Cities: Factor Accumulation and Technical Change in Hong Kong andSingapore,” in Olivier J. Blanchard and Stanley Fisher, eds., NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 1992,(Cambridge MA: MIT Press), pp. 13-54.

Young, Alwyn, “The Tyranny of Numbers: Confronting the Statistical Realities of the East Asian GrowthExperience,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 110:3 August 1995, pp. 641-680.

Young, L. and Romero, J., “A Dynamic Dual Model of the North American Free Trade Agreement,” in J.F. Francois,and C.R. Shiells, eds., Modeling Trade Policy, Applied General Equilibrium Assessments of NorthAmerican Free Trade,” Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994.

Zellner, A., “An Efficient Method of Estimating Seemingly Unrelated Regressions and Tests for Aggregation Bias,”Journal of the American Statistical Association, vol. 57, June 1962, pp. 348-368.

Zellner, A. and D.S. Huang, “Further Properties of Efficient Estimators for Seemingly Unrelated RegressionEquations,” International Economic Review, vol. 3, September 1962, pp. 300-313.