17
CASE FOR FREE TRADE THE DEVELOPMENT

THE DEVELOPMENT CASE FOR FREE TRADEifreetrade.org/pdfs/IFT-Development-preview(low-res).pdf · inhabitants of emerging market economies through a ‘race to the bottom effect’ as

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    2

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: THE DEVELOPMENT CASE FOR FREE TRADEifreetrade.org/pdfs/IFT-Development-preview(low-res).pdf · inhabitants of emerging market economies through a ‘race to the bottom effect’ as

CASE FORFREE TRADE

THE DEVELOPMENT

Page 2: THE DEVELOPMENT CASE FOR FREE TRADEifreetrade.org/pdfs/IFT-Development-preview(low-res).pdf · inhabitants of emerging market economies through a ‘race to the bottom effect’ as

ONE-MINUTE SUMMARY

Much of the public discourse about free trade focuses on the supposed dangers it poses to the environment, to our health

and to vulnerable communities around the world. IFT has teamed up with Brian Sturgess and Oni Oviri to produce this short pamphlet explaining the role of open trade in developing economies.

International trade stimulates economic growth in developing countries:

• Poorer countries that open their economies to international trade tend to grow faster than richer countries.• Economic growth rates in excess of rises in population naturally lead to rising living standards, so trade has a reducing effect on poverty.

Increased openness to trade can improve welfare in developing countries:

• Better health: Studies have found positive links between freer trade and improved health outcomes.• Better governance: Other studies show that increases in import openness cause reductions in corruption.

Increased openness to trade can improve employment conditions in developing countries:

• Women working in emerging manufacturing industries have testified to the benefits of improved working conditions and financial and social independence compared to their alternatives in the informal and agricultural sectors.

• Increased trade means exposure to foreign investment and a shift towards skilled labour, which reduce the incentives for child labour.

One-minute summary

A self-evident truth?

Trade and development

• Economic growth

• Welfare

Trade and labour markets

• Employment

• Wages and productivity

The costs of protectionism

• Tariffs

• Non-tariff barriers

Facilitating trade

Keep trade open

Bibliography

3

4

8

8

10

12

13

15

18

18

20

24

28

29

Increased openness to trade can raise productivity and wages in developing countries:

• Opening an economy with a low-productivity, low-wage agricultural sector will produce gains in value added per worker as urban migration takes place.• In response to rising wages, China is moving towards higher-technology, more capital-intensive manufacturing, and foreign capital is moving elsewhere.

Protectionist policies of developed countries negatively affect their developing trade partners:

• Tariffs: Preferential tariff regimes are often not comprehensive, differentiating between raw and processed goods or differentiating between neighbouring developing countries. This hinders industrialisation, regional integration and entry into global supply chains.• Non-tariff barriers: Developed countries use public health as a pretext to protect domestic producers through sanitary and phytosanitary (SPS) regulations and GMO restrictions. These trade restrictions, as well as large agricultural subsidy schemes, disproportionately affect developing trade partners.

Domestic trade barriers in developing countries can prevent them from enjoying the benefits of freer trade outlined above:

• Poor infrastructure (eg. transport and communications) is one of the most significant trade barriers faced by developing countries.• Plugging the huge infrastructure funding gap is vital in ensuring that open trade policies deliver the promised growth for developing countries.

CASE FORFREE TRADE

THE DEVELOPMENT

Oni OviriOni is Managing Director of Sasare Associates, a consultancy advising on best practice supply chain and logistics management for global private sector and UK public sector organisations.

Brian SturgessBrian is Managing Editor and Chief Economist at World Economics, and worked as a consultant to the Competition Directorate of the European Commission.

AUTHORS:

Page 3: THE DEVELOPMENT CASE FOR FREE TRADEifreetrade.org/pdfs/IFT-Development-preview(low-res).pdf · inhabitants of emerging market economies through a ‘race to the bottom effect’ as

International trade improves human prosperity and is essential for economic

development. This was one of the most important conclusions reached by classical economists Adam Smith[1] and David Ricardo[2] over two centuries ago. It has stood the test of time. When asked what economic principle was non-trivial and true, the eminent American economist and Nobel Laurate Paul Samuelson named Ricardo’s Law of Comparative Advantage published in 1817.

�[1]  Smith (1776)

�[2]  Ricardo (1817)

�[3]  The good can be produced at a lower opportunity cost.

Stated simply, the idea of comparative advantage is that for any two countries producing two different goods, using only one immobile factor of production (originally labour), both countries will always gain from trade even if one country is more efficient in the production of both goods, since the other country still has a relative advantage in the production of one of the goods.[3] Trade allows specialisation which raises output and economic welfare, allowing both countries to consume more of both commodities. This

contrasted sharply with the mercantilist position criticised by both Smith and Ricardo, which suggested that one country’s exporting gains were always at the expense of another’s importing losses. The conclusion of the theory of comparative advantage is powerful and inescapable – restrictions on trade harm economic welfare.

This proposition, based on a simple model of trade between two nations, is robust even in a world comprised of many countries,

many goods and multiple factors of production.[4] The Ricardian theory of the gains from international trade is an essential tool for proponents of freer trade to combat protectionism, but it is not enough. The textbook principle of comparative advantage is essentially static, but since we live in a dynamic world, what is really of interest is the impact of international trade on prosperity over time or on economic growth, and particularly on the prospects for poorer countries. Does freer international trade facilitate or actually cause an expansion in economic activity, and do restrictions on trade hinder development?

Free trade between humans has been responsible for the great expansion in population, rise in living standards and increase in human welfare over the twelve or more millennia since the introduction of agriculture. Recognition of this was the received wisdom throughout most of the nineteenth century. The open international trading system that ended abruptly in 1914 with

�[4]  Dornbusch et al (1977)

�[5]  Williamson et al (1993)

the outbreak of the First World War had created a remarkable period of economic convergence[5] among developed and developing nations, which only resumed after the end of the Second World War in 1945.

Periods of rising integration between economies, the interlinking of markets via international trade and the transfer of technology and human capital, are associated with rising prosperity for our species. Falling trade always occurs in times of dark uncertainty and inevitably results in stagnant or declining living standards and often conflict. The most recent historical experience of a closed global trading system producing a sharp contraction in trade and growth was during the 1930s, a historical anomaly which set back centuries of growing world integration. The impact of this setback is evident in Figure 1, which graphs historical data from various sources of international trade (defined as the sum of the value of world exports and imports) as a ratio of global GDP from 1500 to 2011. Estimates of trade in the late nineteenth

century show a rise in the ratio of trade to GDP of 0.18 in 1870 to 0.33 by 1917. The ratio fell back to 0.1 or 10% of GDP by 1932. The 1930s lesson of the dangers of trade wars was learnt by the economists and politicians who built the institutions that would bolster economic integration after 1945.

A SELF-EVIDENT

TRUTH? What an extraordinary episode in the economic

progress of man that age was that came to an end in August 1914! ... The inhabitant of London could order by telephone, sipping his morning tea in bed, the various products of the whole earth, in such quantity as he may see fit, and reasonably expect their delivery upon his doorstep; he could at the same moment and by the same means adventure his wealth in the natural resources and new enterprises of any quarter of the world, and share, without exertion, or even trouble, in their prospective fruits and advantages…- John Maynard Keynes (1919)

54 ifreetrade.org @IFTtweets

IFT | The Development Case for Free Trade

Page 4: THE DEVELOPMENT CASE FOR FREE TRADEifreetrade.org/pdfs/IFT-Development-preview(low-res).pdf · inhabitants of emerging market economies through a ‘race to the bottom effect’ as

Unfortunately, the painstaking progress in opening up trade since 1945 is now under threat. The mercantilist ideas attacked by Smith and Ricardo remain alive two centuries later, even in the countries that have benefited the most from opening up their economies. We are hearing mercantilist language in the form of “America First”; threats of “tit-for-tat” retaliatory tariffs over commodities like steel; pledges to restrict EU market access for the UK post-Brexit; and a fixation on trade deficits.

The theoretical case for the one-off gains from freer trade is almost self-evident. But the weight of the available evidence concerning trade openness and higher growth in developing countries is more nuanced and needs to be evaluated more closely. There are basically three schools of thought:

• The first, on the liberal side, argues that free trade facilitates the process of growth in emerging economies, acting as a catalyst.

• The second, also on the liberal side, argues that free trade acts as an actual engine of economic growth.

• In contrast, the third school of thought argues that, particularly for countries dependent on commodity exports, free trade can hinder economic development. Restrictions promoting fairer trade or protecting domestic industries are therefore needed to achieve sustainable and balanced economic growth and rising living standards.

Opponents of globalisation also argue that unrestricted trade impoverishes many of the inhabitants of emerging market economies through a ‘race to the bottom effect’ as production is

outsourced at a lower cost. This promotes inequality by driving down wages, leading to the exploitation of women and children.

In the following sections we consider these arguments and weigh the available evidence. We find that the case for free trade enhancing economic welfare by aiding development is overwhelming. The first section considers the relationship between free trade and economic welfare in developing economies, as measured by GDP growth rates, health and institutional quality. The next section demonstrates that free trade raises productivity and wages and does not inevitably lead to a race to the bottom in labour standards and labour market participation. We then explore the very real harmful

effects of protectionism and trade restrictions on developing markets imposed by the developed world. Finally, we show that many of the potential gains from trade are not realised in emerging economies due to deficiencies in their domestic infrastructure, which restrict their ability to participate in global value chains.

THE IDEA OF COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE IS THAT FOR ANY TWO COUNTRIES PRODUCING TWO DIFFERENT GOODS, USING ONLY ONE IMMOBILE FACTOR OF PRODUCTION (ORIGINALLY LABOUR), BOTH COUNTRIES WILL ALWAYS GAIN FROM TRADE EVEN IF ONE COUNTRY IS MORE EFFICIENT IN THE PRODUCTION OF BOTH GOODS, SINCE THE OTHER COUNTRY STILL HAS A RELATIVE ADVANTAGE IN THE PRODUCTION OF ONE OF THE GOODS

THE RICARDIAN THEORY OF THE GAINS FROM INTERNATIONAL TRADE IS AN ESSENTIAL TOOL FOR PROPONENTS OF FREER TRADE TO COMBAT PROTECTIONISM, BUT IT IS NOT ENOUGH.

Figure 1 Trade as a ratio of GDP 1500 to 2011Source: Our World in Data, ourworldindata.org/international-trade

1500

1516

1532

1548

1564

1580

1596

1612

1628

1644

1660

1676

1692

1708

1724

1740

1756

1772

1788

1804

1820

1836

1852

1868

1884

1900

1916

1932

1948

1964

1980

1996

0.6

0.5

0.4

0.3

0.2

0.1

0

Klasing and Milionis (2014)Penn World Tables Version 8.1

Upper bound (Estavadeordal, Frntz and Taylor, 2003)Lower bound (Estavadeordal, Frntz and Taylor, 2003)

76 ifreetrade.org @IFTtweets

IFT | The Development Case for Free Trade

Page 5: THE DEVELOPMENT CASE FOR FREE TRADEifreetrade.org/pdfs/IFT-Development-preview(low-res).pdf · inhabitants of emerging market economies through a ‘race to the bottom effect’ as

Dynamic models of trade and economic development suggest that poorer countries should grow more rapidly than richer countries over time the more they are integrated into the world economy. The experience of countries such as Japan, South Korea, Hong Kong, Singapore and latterly China point to the same conclusion: openness allows the import of capital and modern technologies, resulting in a convergence in living standards as less developed countries catch up.

A seminal, long-run, cross-country study by Jeffrey Sachs and Andrew Warner[9] published in 1995 found that the observed failures of developing economies to converge with richer countries were due to trade policies: open economies converged; restricted economies did not. The authors were writing at a time of growing progress in global economic integration arising from the collapse of communism in the Soviet Union and China’s commitment to join the World Trade Organisation (WTO). The aim of their work, which covered all developing economies with a GDP per capita of less than US$5,000 in 1970, was to document the impact of global integration witnessed since 1970. They used various indicators of cross-country trade openness, such as average tariff rates and the extent of trade covered by non-tariff barriers,[10] as measures of a country’s orientation

�[9]  Sachs and Warner (1995)

�[10]  Specifically, a country was defined to have a closed trade policy if it had a least one of five characteristics: (1) Non-tariff barriers covering 40% or more of trade (2) Average tariff rates of 40% or more (3) A black market exchange rate that is depreciated by 20% or more relative to the official exchange rate (4) A socialist economic system (5) A state monopoly on major exports.

�[11]  Sachs and Warner (1995) p35

�[12]  Wacziarg and Welch (2008)

with the world economy. In particular, the authors examined the timing of trade liberalisation in a large number of countries to assess its impact on subsequent economic growth and on future economic crises.

A robust and detailed statistical analysis of the country data from 1970-89 showed that “open economies outperformed closed economies on three main dimensions of economic performance: economic growth, avoidance of extreme macroeconomic crises and structural change.”[11] A later study extending the Sachs-Warner approach to longer time periods and to more countries found that countries that liberalised their trade policies experienced an increase in average annual growth rates of about 1.5%, and that the average trade to GDP

ratio expanded by approximately 5 percentage points.[12] The study found support for the contention that trade stimulates capital accumulation; post-liberalisation investment rates rose by between 1.5 to 2.0 percentage points.

The evidence that open trade is associated with higher economic growth rates in developing economies is very strong, implying that increased economic integration will aid convergence in living standards between countries - all other things being equal.

Economic growth

�[6]  Kravis (1970)

�[7]  Weinhold and Rauch (1999)

�[8]  Young (1991)

For emerging economies, development depends on internal conditions such

as education levels, natural resources, capital employed, productivity and economic policies. But an openness to external trade also plays a significant role. Trade will provide static gains to a developing country, as predicted by Ricardo, by promoting specialisation so as to achieve the most efficient use of resources and aligning domestic prices with world prices. Openness to trade should therefore allow

higher consumption levels in developing economies through the influence of liberalisation on the level of total value-added or GDP.

There is also a dynamic role for international trade in promoting economic development. Trade has been described by various authors as both a ‘handmaiden’ and as an ‘engine’ of economic growth depending on its role in either: helping to promote a competitive environment conducive to development, pushing up the return on investment at different

levels of capital accumulation; or by accelerating technological progress as a result of importing ideas which increase productivity.[6] One study found that higher productivity growth in the manufacturing sector of less developed economies was greater the higher the level of specialisation.[7] Export-led growth in developing countries produces higher output volumes, raising productivity through the realisation of economies of scale[8] as producers serve larger markets than would have been available domestically.

...poor countries tend to grow faster than richer

countries as long as the poor and rich countries are linked together by trade. Poor, closed countries have often performed significantly less well than the richer countries.- Sachs and Warner (1995)DEVELOPMENT

DYNAMIC MODELS OF TRADE AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT SUGGEST THAT POORER COUNTRIES SHOULD GROW MORE RAPIDLY THAN RICHER COUNTRIES OVER TIME THE MORE THEY ARE INTEGRATED INTO THE WORLD ECONOMY

TRADE AND

98 ifreetrade.org @IFTtweets

IFT | The Development Case for Free Trade

Page 6: THE DEVELOPMENT CASE FOR FREE TRADEifreetrade.org/pdfs/IFT-Development-preview(low-res).pdf · inhabitants of emerging market economies through a ‘race to the bottom effect’ as

�[13]  Owen and Wu (2002)

Welfare

Economic growth rates in excess of rises in population naturally lead to rising

living standards, so a link between trade and development means that trade has a reducing effect on poverty. But there is also evidence of a number of benefits from liberalising trade policy on the economic, political and social welfare of developing countries

through the effects of higher living standards.

A positive link has been found between freer trade and improved health outcomes. A seminal study of 139 developed and emerging countries from 1960 to 1995 discovered that in general, increased openness to trade is associated with lower

rates of infant mortality and higher life expectancies.[13] The relationships were strongest in developing countries and were attributed by the authors to transferred knowledge on the treatment of diseases, better health practices and more efficient health care systems - all facilitated by more open trade arrangements.

Free Trade Agreements (FTAs) are often criticised for raising medicine prices and limiting access to necessary drugs in developing countries, thanks to stringent intellectual property provisions that developed countries – often those with big pharmaceutical industries - insist on including. But one major cross-country study found that bilateral FTAs, particularly those containing Trade Related Aspects of International Property

�[14]  Venkatamaran and Stevens (2015)

�[15]  Novignon and Atakorah (2016)

�[16]  Krueger (1974)

�[17]  Bonaglia et al (2001)

Rights (TRIPS) provisions, are associated with modest positive impacts on health outcomes, measured in terms of infant mortality, life expectancy and deaths from non-communicable diseases.[14]

Openness in general is associated with sound economic policies which themselves are related to better health outcomes. Another study of openness and health in 42 sub-Saharan African countries over the period 1995 to 2013 found a strong positive relationship between openness and increased heath financing, and lower infant and under-five mortality rates.[15] For more information on the relationship between trade and health, do read IFT publication “The Health Case for Free Trade (2018)”.

Not only are the citizens of more open economies wealthier and healthier, but they enjoy better governance. It has long been known that import restrictions result from political pressure and engender cronyism among those who benefit at the expense of society as a whole. Quantitative trade restrictions give a monopolistic power to legal importers, who often participate in illegal, illicit and otherwise corrupt activities in order to appropriate the economic rents generated by their power.

In contrast, it has been argued that globalisation can actually improve governance through three mechanisms:

• Liberal trade policies reduce the number of rent-enhancing restrictions sought by producer lobby groups.

• The force of competitive pressure from foreign producers and the power of international investors reduces the return from corrupt practices.

• Countries that build good institutions capable of combatting corruption face lower production and transaction costs, and are more able to compete successfully in international markets.

The literature on trade corruption and rent-seeking is large and growing,[16] covering many country analyses and case studies. A major OECD study covering a large sample of countries over a 20-year period strongly supports the fact that increases in import openness cause reductions in corruption.[17] The strength of the effect was very strong; the study found that, after controlling for other cross-country differences, openness’ influence on corruption was close to one third of that exercised by the level of development.

...increased trade is associated with improved

health outcomes, in terms of increased life expectancies and lower infant mortality... these benefits are enjoyed primarily by poorer countries…we show that trade may actually decrease international health disparities since the gains are primarily enjoyed by poorer countries.- Owen and Wu (2002)

1110 ifreetrade.org @IFTtweets

IFT | The Development Case for Free Trade

Page 7: THE DEVELOPMENT CASE FOR FREE TRADEifreetrade.org/pdfs/IFT-Development-preview(low-res).pdf · inhabitants of emerging market economies through a ‘race to the bottom effect’ as

Employment

�[18]  Kabeer (2004)

�[19]  ILO (2017)

�[20]  A 1996 article in Life magazine showed a child stitching a football displaying the company’s logo. See Baker (2016).

�[21]  Children under the age of 15 were reported to be living and working on cocoa farms connected to the company in the Ivory Coast. See Sandler Clarke (2015).

Critics of globalisation argue that unrestricted trade causes capital

flows to developing economies in response to relatively lower labour costs, resulting in the employment of children and women in ‘sweatshop’ conditions.

However, studies of female employment in emerging markets have found that engagement with the global economy not only provides income and conditions better than those offered in the informal sector, but also opportunities for empowerment. Paradoxically, attempts to enforce labour standards with ‘social clauses’ can lead to a reduction in the choices available for women to work with dignity. This clash between the perceptions of female work in poor countries as published in much of the western media, and the attitudes of the actual workers, was explored by Naila Kabeer in an in-depth study of the textile industry in Bangladesh.[18]

The exploitation of child labour is repugnant on moral, health and educational grounds, but it also reinforces poverty by driving down the wages of older, unskilled workers in the labour force. New research estimates that globally 152 million children aged between 5 and 17 are enmeshed in systems of child labour.[19] The publicity surrounding high-profile

cases of abuse by international companies such as Nike[20] and Nestlé[21] has led to an unfortunate association between globalisation, multinationals with foreign manufacturing operations, and ‘sweatshop’ labour. But the race

TRADE ANDLABOURMARKETS

These findings do not square easily with the

one-dimensional portraits of export-orientated factories as “showcases of horror for the labor abuses sanctioned by the global free trade economy” promoted by many in the anti-sweat shop campaign.- Kabeer (2004)

STUDIES OF FEMALE EMPLOYMENT IN EMERGING MARKETS HAVE FOUND THAT ENGAGEMENT WITH THE GLOBAL ECONOMY NOT ONLY PROVIDES INCOME AND CONDITIONS BETTER THAN THOSE OFFERED IN THE INFORMAL SECTOR, BUT ALSO OPPORTUNITIES FOR EMPOWERMENT.

1312 ifreetrade.org @IFTtweets

IFT | The Development Case for Free Trade

Page 8: THE DEVELOPMENT CASE FOR FREE TRADEifreetrade.org/pdfs/IFT-Development-preview(low-res).pdf · inhabitants of emerging market economies through a ‘race to the bottom effect’ as

to the bottom hypothesis is naïve. A recent ILO study shows that only 11.9% of child workers are employed in industry, the economic sector most affected by globalisation. The vast majority are employed in agriculture, 70.9%, or services, 17.2%.

There are also a number of economic arguments as to why more open economies have lower incentives than closed ones to maintain the institutional and cultural structures that encourage

�[22]  Aggarwal (1995)

�[23]  Cigno (2002)

�[24]  Neumayer and de Soysa (2005)

child labour; for instance, moving towards skilled labour and capital makes an economy less dependent on the supply of domestic unskilled labour. In countries where child labour is banned but weakly enforced, violations of standards have been found to be more common in the non-tradeable and less export-focused sectors.[22]

The empirical research on trade openness and child labour is sparse,[23] but one detailed cross-

country statistical study into the relationship between trade and child labour in the age-group 10 to 14 found that a greater penetration of Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) was associated with a lower incidence of child labour. This study, covering 125 countries, also found that child labour was lower the more open an economy was to trade, as measured by the sum of imports and exports divided by GDP, rather than other qualitative measures of openness.[24]

Wages and productivity

�[25]  This is the main finding of the Heckscher-Ohlin theory as published in Ohlin (1933).

�[26]  Leamer (1995)

�[27]  See: http://www.icelandnaturally.com/article/businesses-relocating-iceland-abundant-cheap-green-energy

Trade theory predicts that countries with open economies will specialise

in the production of commodities in which they have a comparative advantage. This means that in general,[25] although this has been challenged in some special circumstances,[26] countries will export commodities produced

intensively by inputs in which the country has a relative abundance, and import goods using factors of production that are relatively scarce. Apart from the special cases of primary commodity producers, the factor of production in abundant supply in many developing countries is unskilled labour - male and female.

Manufacturing companies seeking lower labour costs will migrate to countries which are competitive in that factor, which then reduces the prices their products sell at, benefiting consumers. But this process, in an integrated world with free movement of capital, is not restricted to relative labour costs but applies to any factor of

production where efficiency gains are possible through cross-country investment. In fact, labour might not be the most important factor in determining how to maximise production efficiency; as average wages in developing countries rise, labour-motivated migration will decrease. For instance, companies have been relocating to Iceland in recent years, including

those mining crypto-currencies, as a result of the country’s relatively cheap and sustainable electricity.[27]

Opening a typical developing economy to trade inevitably has consequences for employment, productivity and wages. It typically results in increased

FDI by multinational companies seeking more cost-efficient production, as well as increased capital expenditure by domestic enterprises exploiting export opportunities based on a comparative advantage in labour costs. In theory, integration into the world economy is beneficial because it leads to a rise in employment levels in

MANUFACTURING COMPANIES SEEKING LOWER LABOUR COSTS WILL MIGRATE TO COUNTRIES WHICH ARE COMPETITIVE IN THAT FACTOR, WHICH THEN REDUCES THE PRICES THEIR PRODUCTS SELL AT, BENEFITING CONSUMERS.

AGRICULTURE

70.9%INDUSTRY

11.9%SERVICES

17.2%

1514 ifreetrade.org @IFTtweets

IFT | The Development Case for Free Trade

Page 9: THE DEVELOPMENT CASE FOR FREE TRADEifreetrade.org/pdfs/IFT-Development-preview(low-res).pdf · inhabitants of emerging market economies through a ‘race to the bottom effect’ as

experienced by women who moved away from patriarchal agrarian societies to a more independent lifestyle.

Opening an economy with a low-productivity, low-wage agricultural sector will produce gains in value added per worker as urban migration takes place, but this is not the end of the story. As the case of China and other developing economies shows, the move from agriculture to urban-based manufacturing and services sectors results in labour drying up and wages rising. Average minimum wages across China have nearly tripled in less than a decade from Yuan 840 (US$121) per month in 2008 to Yuan 2,420 (US$384) in 2018 (Figure 3). Average wages in manufacturing, including skilled workers, have now risen above the levels in Mexico as productivity has

�[31]  Pan (2016)

�[32]  A group of ten development institutions including the OECD and the WTO.

�[33]  OECD (2012)

�[34]  Lomas (2017)

increased in Chinese factories.[31] This is a general development trend resulting from international trade and is not confined to China. As trade-fuelled growth continues, developing economies reach a tipping point where surplus labour dries up. As rural wages begin to converge with urban labour, shortages

appear and urban employers must offer higher wages to lure workers from the countryside. A report by the International Collaborative Initiative on Trade and Employment (ICTE)[32] surveyed 14 major studies carried out since 2000: all concluded that trade plays an essential role in raising income through its impact on productivity. In Chile, a country which has raised itself to OECD status, workers in the most open sectors earned on average 25% more than those in more closed sectors.[33]

Moreover, the economic history of the last decades shows this process is continual. Already, in response to rising wages, China is moving towards higher-technology, more capital-intensive manufacturing. On the other hand, foreign capital is migrating to a number of countries offering lower labour costs, including Malaysia, India, Indonesia, Thailand and Vietnam.[34]

the industries exposed to trade, whether directly as exporters or indirectly as suppliers. The rise in employment aids the development process because it incentivises an underemployed rural labour force to migrate into the urban manufacturing sector, raising productivity, average wages and the labour participation rate.

The operation of this dual-sector model of economic development is stimulated by exposure to trade.[28] Export-driven development and the movement of labour from agriculture to manufacturing transformed the economies of Japan and Korea in the 1950s and 60s, and is doing so now in countries such as Vietnam, India and China. In China, according to official figures, the rate of urbanisation rose from

�[28]  Lewis (1954)

�[29]  See Lu and Xia (2016)

�[30]  Gaddis and Pieters (2012)

20.9% of the total population in 1982, before the reforms that opened up the economy to international trade, to 56.2% by 2012. Around 236 million people are rural migrants.[29] Chinese data shows that 45% of domestic migrants were relatively young, aged between 16-25 years, and

that two-thirds were male. But development has also increased the rate of female employment in China and in many other countries.

Evidence from Brazil, formerly a heavily protectionist country, shows that the trade liberalisation measures taken between 1987 and 1994, involving tariff cuts and the lifting of non-tariff barriers, had a strong impact on female participation in the labour market. Average nominal tariffs were lowered over that period from 54.9% to 10.2% and the female participation rate in the labour force rose from 46% to 53% (Figure 2).[30]

And it is not just the rate of female employment that increases with the movement of labour from agriculture to manufacturing. Kabeer’s 2004 study of the Bangladesh textile industry highlights the improvement in working conditions in factories compared to agricultural labour, and the increased empowerment

Figure 3 China minimum wages 2008-2018Source: Trading Economics

3000

2500

2000

1500

1000

500

0

2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018

1716 ifreetrade.org @IFTtweets

IFT | The Development Case for Free Trade

Figure 2 Labour market participation in Brazil 1950-2007Source: IBGE, Estatísticas do Século XX

100

90

80

70

60

50

40

30

20

10

0

1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000

female male

Page 10: THE DEVELOPMENT CASE FOR FREE TRADEifreetrade.org/pdfs/IFT-Development-preview(low-res).pdf · inhabitants of emerging market economies through a ‘race to the bottom effect’ as

It is clear that developing countries that open their economies to trade will

benefit from integration with the world while closed economies will forgo growth opportunities. A vast quantity of evidence has shown clearly that emerging

�[35]  WTO (2011)

�[36]  In 1971, the General Agreement on Trade and Tariffs (GATT), the predecessor of the WTO, enacted two waivers to the MFN that permitted tariff preferences to be granted to developing country goods. In 1979, the GATT established a permanent exemption to the MFN obligation by way of the Enabling Clause, which allowed contracting parties to establish systems of trade preferences for other countries, with the caveat that these systems had to be “generalized, non-discriminatory and non-reciprocal” with respect to the countries they benefited.

economies that impose tariffs do not simply protect so-called infant industries, but grow more slowly than economies that liberalise. They also suffer lower living standards, poorer health and higher levels of corruption imposing additional

costs on their citizens. However, domestic trade policies are not the only barriers to developing countries enjoying the benefits of freer trade; the policies of their developed trading partners can also stifle the potential gains from trade.

Tariffs

Many restrictions still exist despite the free trade rhetoric of major trading

blocs such as the United States and the 28 countries comprising the European Union. It has long been

widely recognised that in order to promote development and remedy global economic imbalances, poorer nations require preferential access to developed markets. The WTO permits its members to

set[35] preferential, non-reciprocal trade arrangements with developing economies through the Generalised System of Preferences (GSP), which exempt them from the WTO’s Most Favoured Nation (MFN) rule. In other words, a developed WTO member can lower tariffs vis-à-vis developing nations without having to reduce them for richer nations.[36]

These GSPs now cover the vast majority of countries in the developing world, but they are far from comprehensive in the products they cover. Many products with export potential for countries with abundant labour but without natural resources have been excluded from these preferential arrangements in order to protect domestic producers of

labour-intensive, low-technology manufactured goods such as textiles, leather goods, glass and ceramics.

In addition to the GSP (Figure 4), EU trade with the developing world is also covered by the EU’s European Partnership Agreements (EPAs): a set of (unfinished) reciprocal trade agreements with the Africa Caribbean Pacific (ACP) group of countries, broadly negotiated along regional lines. These offer DFQF access to the EU market for signatory countries in return for around 80% tariff liberalisation on the part of the developing trading partners. Criticisms of this patchwork of reciprocal and non-reciprocal preferences include:

The LDC/non-LDC distinction between EBA and standard GSP

market access is somewhat arbitrary. Graduating from LDC status necessitates a sharp loss of unilateral preferences.Non-LDC developing countries, eg. Kenya, have felt compelled to sign EPAs in order to gain DFQF access to the EU market, which the GSP does not offer, despite not being happy with many of the EPA provisions.

Varying tariff preferences on both the EU and developing partner side across these different arrangements undermine regional integration by hindering customs integration and the development of regional supply chains. There is a certain conditionality in the EU’s offer of EPA and GSP+ preferences, which can be removed if the EU deems certain governance criteria in its trading partners have not been met.

Other tariff anomalies across the world positively transfer wealth away from some developing countries. For example, raw commodities such as coffee and cocoa tend not to face tariffs, but processed commodities such as roasted coffee and chocolate do. Japan applies a bound rate of 0% for un-processed cocoa beans, but charges a 10% tax for cocoa paste wholly or partly defatted, and a 29.8% duty on cocoa powder containing added sugar. India charges a 35% duty on cocoa beans, roasted or not. Differential tariffs on processed goods inhibit the export earnings of developing countries which are reliant on the volatile price of the raw commodities, but it also denies producers the benefits of moving up the supply chain, to extract a higher proportion of total valued added.

PROTECTIONISM THE COSTS OF

Figure 4 The EU’s tiered GSP schemeSource: European Commission Trade Helpdesk

Whoqualifies?

Low and lower-middle income countries

Vulnerable low and lower-middle income countries

Least Developed Countries (LDCs)

Marketaccess

Reduces tariffs on about 66% of EU product lines

Full removal of tariffs on over 66% of EU product lines

Duty-free-quota-free on everything except armaments

How many countries currently covered?

17

9

49

GSP

GSP+

EBA

1918 ifreetrade.org @IFTtweets

IFT | The Development Case for Free Trade

Page 11: THE DEVELOPMENT CASE FOR FREE TRADEifreetrade.org/pdfs/IFT-Development-preview(low-res).pdf · inhabitants of emerging market economies through a ‘race to the bottom effect’ as

Non-tariff barriers

�[37]  UNCTAD (2012)

�[38]  European Parliament (2018)

�[39]  https://www.wto.org/english/res_e/publications_e/wtr12_dataset_e.htm

�[40]  Cato and dos Santos (1998)

Even more damaging to developing economies than tariffs is the large number

of non-tariff barriers they face exporting to the industrialised world.[37] For instance, exports of agricultural products from developing countries have to compete against the highly subsidised agriculture of the developed world. A European Parliament impact study on the effect of the reformed Common Agricultural Policy on developing countries[38] finds that the reintroduction of coupled payments under the Voluntary Coupled Support scheme “is of concern” as it displaces production from third countries. It notes that animal products and sugar still enjoy very high levels of protection, providing direct production incentives in those sectors.

Other significant trade barriers for developing countries include technical measures, such as sanitary or environmental protection measures. The WTO agreement of 1995 on Sanitary and Phytosanitary (SPS) measures reaffirmed that no WTO Member should be prevented from adopting or enforcing measures necessary to protect human, animal or plant life or health. Although the protection of public health is vitally important, the SPS regulations have been used frequently to restrict trade between countries in agricultural and food products, with no scientific public health justification. The number of complaints lodged at the WTO on the protectionist misuse of SPS measures has increased dramatically over the last 20 years,[39] as tariffs have gradually been falling.

SPS regulations affect trade in three ways: By prohibitively raising production and marketing costs for existing producers (or banning their products altogether) By raising entry barriers for potential suppliers By discriminating and therefore diverting trade between countries

Developing economies suffer more acutely from these effects since they have fewer resources to alter production practices speedily; reduced capacity to lodge formal WTO complaints; and their economies tend to rely more heavily on exports of affected products.

An early example of this was the EU’s temporary ban on the import of frozen shrimps from Bangladesh in 1997, following concerns about poor hygiene standards in the processing industry and the efficiency of government inspectors. The measure was estimated to have cost Bangladeshi shrimp producers US$14.6 million in lost revenue.[40] More recently, developed countries have used more convoluted restrictions on things like pesticides as a way to protect domestic producers; EU fruit and vegetable producers tend to rely on pesticides less than producers in more humid climates, and have more advanced agri-tech to combat crop yield issues.

PESTICIDE PROTECTIONISM: Kenyan beans and peas

• Horticulture exports constitute about 30% of Kenya’s agricultural GDP.

• The EU is by far Kenya’s largest export market for horticultural products, taking 45% of exports. Kenya is the second largest exporter of beans and peas to the EU.

• 2009: EU reduces its maximum residue level (MRL) of dimethoate (a chemical in pesticides) to below international recommended

�[41]  From 1.0mg/kg, as recommended in the Codex Alimentarius, to 0.02 mg/kg – an effective ban.

�[42]  KEPHIS (2016)

standards[41] for fresh beans and peas.

• January 2013: Kenyan produce is listed for increased EU safety checks.

• 2013-2015: Kenyan bean and pea exports to the EU fall by US$56 million as produce is consistently rejected after testing in the EU market.[42]

• Kenya loses EU market share in beans and peas to Morocco and Guatemala.

Another problem faced by the developing world’s agriculture sector is the EU’s policy on the

use of genetically modified organisms (GMOs) in foodstuffs. In 1998, the EU imposed a moratorium on the import and cultivation of all new GMO food and animal feed products, pending strict legislation passed in 2003. Thereafter, each was evaluated on a case-by-case basis by the European Food Safety Authority (EFSA) before recommendation to the European Commission. In 2006, the WTO declared the initial moratorium to have been illegal, but the subsequent authorisation process has been slow and individual member states can still invoke ‘safeguard clauses’ to ban individual varieties of GMO

EXPORTS OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS

FROM DEVELOPING COUNTRIES HAVE TO

COMPETE AGAINST THE HIGHLY SUBSIDISED

AGRICULTURE OF THE DEVELOPED WORLD.

2120 ifreetrade.org @IFTtweets

IFT | The Development Case for Free Trade

Page 12: THE DEVELOPMENT CASE FOR FREE TRADEifreetrade.org/pdfs/IFT-Development-preview(low-res).pdf · inhabitants of emerging market economies through a ‘race to the bottom effect’ as

THE ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF RESTRICTING TRADE IN GMOS ARE EXTENSIVE. THE MOST RECENT DATA SHOW THAT IN 2016 MORE THAN 18 MILLION FARMERS IN 26 COUNTRIES – INCLUDING 19 DEVELOPING COUNTRIES – PLANTED OVER 185 MILLION HECTARES OF GMO CROPS.

products.[43] These restrictions have been imposed despite the advice of all but a minority of the scientific community. As well as raising the price of food in the developed world, they reduce the economic incentives to adopt new bio-technology in developing countries, which would raise crop yields, productivity and rural incomes while generating exports.

The economic effects of restricting trade in GMOs are extensive. The most recent data show that in 2016 more than 18 million farmers in 26 countries – including 19 developing countries – planted over 185 million hectares of GMO crops.[44] Trade is affected between major GMO producers such as the US, Brazil and potential consumers in the EU. Among more vulnerable economies, however, the restrictions actually prevent an industry from developing which is sorely needed, especially in sub-Saharan Africa where agricultural productivity lags behind the most. It has been estimated by the Information Technology and Innovation Foundation (ITIF) that the current restrictive climate for agricultural biotech innovations could cost low- and lower-middle-income nations up to US$1.5 trillion in lost economic benefits up to 2050.[45]

We have seen the damage that can be done to developing economies when their developed trading partners use labour standards and health standards as a fig leaf for protectionism. The same is true of environmental standards, as the example of palm oil shows.

�[43]  Through Regulation (EC) 1829/2003

�[44]  See: https://gmo.geneticliteracyproject.org/FAQ/where-are-gmos-grown-and-banned/

�[45]  Giddings et al (2016)

ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION: Malaysian and Indonesian palm oil

Indonesia is the world’s largest palm oil producer, with Malaysia second. Together they account for nearly 90% of global output.

• The palm oil sector employs an estimated 6 million people worldwide and generates more jobs per hectare and more income for smallholders than other farming operations.[46]

• About 80% of current world palm oil production is consumed

�[46]  World Bank (2011)

�[47]  Ibid

�[48]  European Parliament (2017)

�[49]  Baron et al (2017)

�[50]  UN FAO (2015)

in the form of food. The World Bank estimates that an additional 28 million tonnes of vegetable oils will have to be produced annually by 2020.[47]

• A large proportion of EU palm oil imports are used to make biofuels. The EU accounts for 15% of global palm oil use.

• The EU’s Renewable Energy Directive (RED) is currently being revised. The draft includes a ban on the use of palm oil in motor fuels from 2021. Other oilseed crops would not be affected.

• A March 2017 report by the European Parliament[48] led to incorrect figures being cited in the media, including the claim that palm oil is responsible for 40% of global deforestation. The actual figure is more like 2.3%.[49]

• Malaysia has a growing forest area according to official UN data,[50] and is one of the world’s leading preservers of rainforest.

• If the RED is passed with this provision, Indonesia and Malaysia plan to take the case to the WTO.

2322 ifreetrade.org @IFTtweets

IFT | The Development Case for Free Trade

Page 13: THE DEVELOPMENT CASE FOR FREE TRADEifreetrade.org/pdfs/IFT-Development-preview(low-res).pdf · inhabitants of emerging market economies through a ‘race to the bottom effect’ as

Eliminating tariff and non-tariff barriers to trade have been an important

focus for development policies and research for many years; as we have shown above, the effort has been justified. But external barriers to trade are not the only factors hindering poorer countries from integrating more fully into the world economy. In recent decades, bodies such as the World Bank and other development institutions have been increasingly concerned with domestic trade barriers and their role in reducing the ability of developing countries to engage in international trade.

Development is held back by poor infrastructure, but additional investment in improving its quality not only stimulates domestic economic activity, it also has an impact on international trade. Trade can be facilitated by improving both hard infrastructure (telephones, information and communications technology infrastructure, ports, roads and rail links, bridges and airports) and soft infrastructure (border and transport efficiency, and the business and regulatory

�[51]  Harrigan and Venables (2004)

environment). Hard and soft infrastructure quality determines how easy it is to search for international suppliers or customers, to enter into contracts and to ship the goods from the domestic producer to the foreign customer.

Poor infrastructure means higher logistics costs, which reduce the benefits from trade since the delivered costs of imports are higher and exports are less competitive. These costs can be defined in terms of money, time, uncertainty and opportunity cost. Time is particularly important for industries that have adopted just-in-time business practices within an international supply network, since delays in delivery of intermediate inputs have a high impact on the importing firms’ total costs.[51] Similarly,

the more uncertain delivery is, the more costly the exercise to insure inventory as buffer stock to remedy fluctuations in delivery lead time. Finally, lack of access to a good transport or telecommunication service creates varying opportunities between those connected and those not connected. In sub-Saharan Africa, for instance, transport costs for landlocked

countries are 50% higher than those of coastal countries, and their trade volumes 60% lower. This goes a long way to explaining the famously low levels of intra-African trade.[52]

Early research into the relationship between trade and infrastructure found a positive and significant impact of the quality of infrastructure on trade.[53] One study estimated that if a country like Peru or Turkey improved sea port efficiency to a level similar to

�[52]  In 2017, intra-African trade accounted for only around 15% of continental trade.

�[53]  Limão and Venables (2001)

�[54]  Clark et al (2004)

�[55]  Chang et al (2009)

that of Iceland or Australia, it would be able to increase trade by roughly 25%.[54] This finding has been replicated in country after country, and the implication is that liberal trade policies

alone are not enough to ensure economic growth – they must be accompanied by complementary measures such as infrastructure investment in order to have a significant impact.

Trade liberalisation will be far less effective if domestic

conditions do not allow opportunities to be exploited, which may even undermine the public and political support for these open policies. One study demonstrated that the quality of infrastructure (proxied by the number of telephone landlines per capita)[55] has an important impact on the relative success of trade reforms on economic growth. The authors found that in the case of countries with a very poor quality of infrastructure, increases in trade openness could even lead to negative growth, while at the top of the sample trade openness produced positive GDP growth.

The conclusion is inescapable: partners in the developed world need to facilitate trade by helping developing countries improve their infrastructure. This will promote development and trade-fuelled economic growth which will benefit all parties. The African Development Bank has

TRADEFACILITATING

DEVELOPMENT IS HELD BACK BY POOR INFRASTRUCTURE, BUT ADDITIONAL INVESTMENT IN IMPROVING ITS QUALITY NOT ONLY STIMULATES DOMESTIC ECONOMIC ACTIVITY, IT ALSO HAS AN IMPACT ON INTERNATIONAL TRADE.

2524 ifreetrade.org @IFTtweets

IFT | The Development Case for Free Trade

Page 14: THE DEVELOPMENT CASE FOR FREE TRADEifreetrade.org/pdfs/IFT-Development-preview(low-res).pdf · inhabitants of emerging market economies through a ‘race to the bottom effect’ as

estimated that the continent faces an infrastructure funding gap of US$130 to US$170 billion a year,[56] and at the start of 2018 it launched a major initiative to mobilise resources to help meet this gap. Last year the African Export-Import Bank (Afrexim) and China’s Export-Import Bank (Eximbank) began a five-year project to finance the development of industrial parks and special economic zones in order to combat Africa’s infrastructure deficit.

The importance of improving infrastructure, both hard and soft, is recognised by a number

�[56]  Iroegbu-Chikezie (2018)

�[57]  An initiative of the UK Department for International Development, TMEA is currently funded by the governments of Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, the Netherlands, Norway, the UK and the US.

�[58]  The EAC comprises Kenya, Uganda, Rwanda, Tanzania. South Sudan and Burundi.

of more localised institutions across the developing world. Trade Mark East Africa (TMEA), an NGO funded by a range of state development agencies from various developed countries,[57] has the specific aim of growing prosperity within the East African Community (EAC)[58] through trade. TMEA has been involved in a number of hard and soft infrastructure projects of various sizes. The largest recently was a US$20 million dollar project to expand the Port Reitz Road in Mombasa, Kenya, by 6.4 km to support access to the Kipevu West container terminal at the port.

Infrastructure problem: Poor access for Kenyan farmers to quality agricultural information to link to markets. Many access

information through a web of social networks, which is limited and does not have a positive impact on farm productivity.

SolutionTaking advantage of the rapid expansion of mobile phones, TradeMark East Africa (TMEA) facilitated the development of iShamba, a Kenya-based mobile phone subscription for farmers, through an investment of US$347,000.

iShamba (Swahili for “iFarm”) provides quality information on farm inputs, best practices, weather and prices to subscribed farmers. It works through a platform that digitally manages agricultural information and disseminates it

through an SMS distribution and call centre facility. Its advice is tailored to the crops and livestock of each farmer, their location in Kenya, and their region’s crop cycle. The platform delivers real-time information allowing farmers to make informed decisions on farm inputs, crops to plant, pricing and bargaining.

Results• At least 100,000 farmers subscribed,

participation increased 50% since its inception

• Farmers increase farm gate prices of maize and potatoes by 5%

• Potato farmers subscribed to iShamba record 50% greater yield compared to those not subscribed

• Won two awards at the Mobile Innovation Awards.

TradeMark East Africa – Ishamba Project

PARTNERS IN THE DEVELOPED WORLD NEED TO FACILITATE TRADE BY HELPING DEVELOPING COUNTRIES IMPROVE THEIR INFRASTRUCTURE. THIS WILL PROMOTE DEVELOPMENT AND TRADE-FUELLED ECONOMIC GROWTH WHICH WILL BENEFIT ALL PARTIES.

2726 ifreetrade.org @IFTtweets

IFT | The Development Case for Free Trade

Page 15: THE DEVELOPMENT CASE FOR FREE TRADEifreetrade.org/pdfs/IFT-Development-preview(low-res).pdf · inhabitants of emerging market economies through a ‘race to the bottom effect’ as

The evidence that international trade aids the economic

development of poorer countries is strong. We have shown how freer trade boosts economic welfare in developing economies, as measured by GDP growth rates, health and institutional quality. We also demonstrated how open trade raises productivity and wages, rather than leading to a race to the bottom in labour standards and labour market participation. But despite all this, free trade is under threat. The US has imposed tariffs on steel and China has retaliated by raising duties on certain US products;

�[59]  https://ustr.gov/about-us/policy-offices/press-office/fact-sheets/2018/march/title

the signal that export-led growth based on lower labour costs is not considered ‘fair’ by many in the developed world is a bad precedent. In a lesser-reported move, the US has announced

that Rwanda’s preferential access to the US market will be suspended because it has failed to row back on its commitment to eliminate second-hand clothes imports.[59]

Beyond – and even more damaging than - tariffs, the EU uses environmental protection as a pretext for its planned ban on palm oil imports, and public health protection as a pretext for its SPS measures that restrict the import of GMO products. These and other trade-distorting practices like artificially low MRLs and agricultural subsidies disproportionately affect developing countries. The impact of these distortions goes far beyond lost export opportunities, since they suppress technological innovation, investment and industrial development in the developing world. As a result, poorer countries find it more difficult to move beyond the primary commodity export model, add more value to their exports and enter global value chains. The conclusion is clear: protectionism promotes poverty, whatever its short-term rationale.

Aggarwal, M. (1995). “International Trade, Labor Standards, and Labor Market Conditions: An Evaluation of the Linkages”. USITC, Office of Economics Working Paper. 95-06-C, June.

Baker, M. (2016). “Nike and child labour – how it went from laggard to leader”. Mallen Baker’s Respectful Business Blog, 26 February 2016. http://mallenbaker.net/article/clear-reflection/nike-and-child-labour-how-it-went-from-laggard-to-leader

Baron, V., Marchial, R. and Rival, A. (2017). “No, palm oil is not responsible for 40% of global deforestation”. The Conversation. https://theconversation.com/no-palm-oil-is-not-responsible-for-40-of-global-deforestation-78482

Bonaglia, F., de Macedo, J.B. and Bussolo, M. (2001). “How globalization improves governance”. OECD Technical Papers Vol. 181.

Cato, J. and dos Santos, C.A.L. (1998). “European Union 1997 Seafood-Safety Ban: The Economic Impact on Bangladesh Shrimp Processing”. Marine Resources Economics, 13.3, pp.215-227.

Chang, R., Kaltani, L. and Loayza, N. (2009). “Openness can be good for growth: The role of policy complementarities”. Journal of Development Economics, 90, 1, pp. 33-49

Cigno, A., Rosati, F. C., and Guarcello, L. (2002). “Does globalization increase child labor?” World Development, 30, 1579–1589.

Clark, X. Dollar, D. and Micco, A. (2004). “Port Efficiency, Maritime Transport Costs and Bilateral Trade”. NBER Working Paper, No. 10353, March. http://www.nmit.edu.my/wp-content/uploads/2017/10/Port-Efficiency-Maritime-Transport-Costs-and-Bilateral-Trade.pdf

Dornbusch, R., Fischer, S. and Samuelson, P.A. (1977). “Comparative Advantage, Trade, and Payments in a Ricardian Model with a Continuum of Goods”. The American Economic Review, 67, No. 5, pp. 823-839.Estevadeordal, Antoni, Frantz, Brian and Taylor, Alan M. (2003). “The Rise and Fall of World Trade, 1870-1939”. Quarterly Journal of Economics 118(2): 359-407.

European Parliament (2017). “Report on palm oil and deforestation of rainforests”. (2016/2222(INI)). http://www.europarl.europa.eu/sides/getDoc.do?pubRef=-//EP//TEXT+REPORT+A8-2017-0066+0+DOC+XML+V0//EN

European Parliament, DG EXPO (2018). “The impact of the Common Agricultural Policy on Developing Countries”. http://www.europarl.europa.eu/RegData/etudes/STUD/2018/603862/EXPO_STU%282018%29603862_EN.pdf

Gaddis, I. and Pieters, J. (2016). “Trade Liberalization and Female Labor Force Participation: Evidence from Brazil.” Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit, Discussion Paper, 6809 August: http://repec.iza.org/dp6809.pdf

Gausch, L.J. and Kogan, J. (2001). “Inventories in Developing Countries: Levels and Determinants, a Red Flag in Competitiveness and Growth”. World Bank Working Paper, 2552, Washington DC.

Giddings, L.V., Atkinson, R.D. and Wu, J.J. (2016). “Suppressing Growth: How GMO Opposition Hurts Developing Nations”. Information Technology and Innovation Foundation, February. http://www2.itif.org/2016-suppressing-innovation-gmo.pdf

Harrigan, J. and Venables, A. J. (2004). “Timeliness, Trade and Agglomeration”. NBER Working Paper, No. w10404. April. https://ssrn.com/abstract=528985

International Labour Organisation (2017). “Global estimates of child labour: results and trends 2012-2016”. Alliance 8.7. www.alliance87.org/global_estimates_of_child_labour-results_and_trends_2012-2016.pdf

Iroegbu-Chikezie, Okwy (2018). “AfDB to bridge $170b infrastructure gap in Africa”. The Nation. http://thenationonlineng.net/afdb-bridge-170b-infrastructure-gap-africa/Kabeer, N. (2004). “Globalization, Labor Standards, and Women’s Rights: Dilemmas of Collective (In) Action in an Interdependent World”. Feminist Economics, 10, 1, pp.3-35.

Kenya Plant Health Inspectorate Service (KEPHIS) (2016). “Trade impact of default Maximum Residue Limits (MRLs) - the case of Kenya: A presentation at the WTO Maximum Residue Limits (MRL) workshop”. https://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/sps_e/wkshop_oct16_e/s7_1_lucy_namu.pdf

Keynes, J.M. (1919). The Economic Consequences of the Peace. http://www.gutenberg.org/ebooks/15776

Klasing, M.J. and Milionis, P. (2014). “Quantifying the Evolution of World Trade, 1870-1949”. Journal of International Economics, 92, 1, pp. 185-197.

Kravis, I. (1970). “Trade as a handmaiden of growth: similarities between the nineteenth and twentieth centuries”. Economic Journal 80, pp.850-72.

Krueger, A. (1974). “The political economy of the rent-seeking society”. American Economic Review 64, pp. 291–303.

Leamer, E.E. (1995). “The Heckscher-Ohlin Model in Theory and Practice”. Princeton Studies in International Finance, 77, pp.1-60.

BIBLIOGRAPHY

2928 ifreetrade.org @IFTtweets

IFT | The Development Case for Free Trade

Page 16: THE DEVELOPMENT CASE FOR FREE TRADEifreetrade.org/pdfs/IFT-Development-preview(low-res).pdf · inhabitants of emerging market economies through a ‘race to the bottom effect’ as

The IFT launched in September 2017 at the UK Foreign & Commonwealth Office, with speeches by Foreign Secretary

Boris Johnson and Trade Secretary Liam Fox.

IFT is a private, not-for-profit, non-partisan research organisation making the intellectual and moral case for free trade. It is Britain’s

only research organisation dedicated solely to trade policy. It aims to capitalise on the opportunity Brexit has afforded Britain to liberalise its trade policy, by convincing three key audiences that more open trade will benefit the country (and, indeed our trading partners):

policymakers and legislators; businesses; the general public.

Its research covers unilateral trade policy, bilateral, regional and multilateral trade relationships, and sectoral issues.

Lewis, W. A. (1954). “Economic Devel-opment with Unlimited Supplies of Labour”. The Manchester School, 22: pp. 139–91.

Limão, N. and Venables, A.J. (1999). “Infrastructure, Geographical Disad-vantage and Transport Costs”. The World Bank Development Research Group, Policy Research Working Paper 2257, December. http://siteresources.worldbank.org/EXTEXPCOMNET/es-rources/2463593-1213975515123/09_Limao.pdf

Lomas, Matthias (2017). “Which Asian Country Will Replace China as the ‘World’s Factory’?” The Diplomat. https://thediplomat.com/2017/02/which-asian-country-will-replace-china-as-the-worlds-factory/

Lu, M. and Xia, Y. (2016). “Migration in the People’s Republic of China”. ADBI Working Paper Series, No. 593, Septem-ber, Asian Development Bank Institute. https://www.adb.org/sites/default/files/publication/191876/adbi-wp593.pdf

Neumayer, E. and De Soysa, I. (2005). “Trade Openness, Foreign Direct Investment and Child Labor”. World Development, 33, 1, pp. 43–63.

Novignon, J. and Atakorah, Y.B. (2016). “How does the health sector benefit from trade openness? Evidence form panel data across sub-Saharan Africa countries”. Munich Personal RePEc Ar-chive: https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/72258/1/MPRA_paper_72258.pdf

Ohlin, B. (1933). Interregional and In-ternational Trade. Cambridge, Harvard University Press.

Organisation for Economic Co-opera-tion and Development (2012). “Policy Priorities for International Trade and Jobs”. International Collaborative Initia-tive on Trade and Employment (ICTE).

https://www.oecd.org/site/tadicite/policyprioritiesforinternationaltradean-djobs.htm

Owen, A. L., and Wu, S. (2002). “Is Trade Good for your Health?” Review of Inter-national Economics, 15(4), 660-682.

Pan, Kwan Yuk (2016). “Want cheap la-bour? Head to Mexico, not China”. The Financial Times. https://www.ft.com/content/bddc8121-a7a0-3788-a74c-cd-2b49cd3230

Ricardo, D. (1817). The Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo, Vol. 1 Principles of Political Economy and Taxation, ed. Piero Sraffa with the Col-laboration of M.H. Dobb. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

Penn World Tables 8.1, University of Groningen. https://www.rug.nl/ggdc/productivity/pwt/pwt-releases/pwt8.1

Sandler Clarke, J. (2015). “Child labour on Nestlé farms: chocolate giant’s problems continue”. The Guardian, 2 September 2015. https://www.theguardian.com/global-develop-ment-professionals-network/2015/sep/02/child-labour-on-nestle-farms-chocolate-giants-problems-continue

Smith, A. (1776) An Inquiry into the Na-ture and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, A Selected Edition. Adam Smith (Author), Kathryn Sutherland (Editor), 2008, Ox-ford Paperbacks, Oxford, UK; ISBN 978-0-19-953592-7

Sachs, J. D., and Warner, A. (1995). “Economic Reform and the Process of Global Integration”. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1:pp.1–118.

United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (2012). “Internation-al Classification of Non-Tariff Mea-sures”. http://unctad.org/en/Publica-tionsLibrary/ditctab20122_en.pdf

United Nations Food and Agriculture Organisation (2015). “Global Forest Resources Assessment 2015”. http://www.fao.org/3/a-i4808e.pdf

Venkatamaran, S. and Stevens, P. (2015). “Are Free Trade Agreements bad for health? Quantifying the impact of FTAs on health outcomes”. Geneva Net-work, Working Paper, August. https://geneva-network.com/wp-content/up-loads/2015/08/FTAs-and-health.pdf

Wacziarg, R. and Welch, K.H. (2003). “Trade Liberalization and Growth: New Evidence”. The World Bank Economic Review, 22, 2, pp. 187–231.

Weinhold, D. and Rauch, J. (1999). “Openness, specialization and produc-tivity growth in less developed coun-tries”. Canadian Journal of Economics, 32, pp.1009-27.

Williamson, J.G., O’Rourke, K., and Hatton, T.J. (1993). “Mass Migration, Commodity Market Integration and Real Wage Convergence: The Late Nine-teenth Century Atlantic Economy.” NBER Historical Working Paper No. 48, June.

World Bank (2011). “The World Bank Group Framework and IFC Strate-gy for Engagement in the Palm Oil Sector”. https://www.ifc.org/wps/wcm/connect/159dce004ea3bd-0fb359f71dc0e8434d/WBG+Frame-work+and+IFC+Strategy_FINAL_FOR+WEB.pdf?MOD=AJPERES

World Trade Organisation (2011). “The WTO and preferential trade agree-ments: From co-existence to coher-ence.” World Trade Report 2011. https://www.wto.org/english/res_e/publica-tions_e/wtr11_e.htm

Young, A. (1991).”Learning by doing and the dynamic effects of internation-al trade”. Quarterly Journal of Econom-ics, 106, pp.369-405.

30 ifreetrade.org

Page 17: THE DEVELOPMENT CASE FOR FREE TRADEifreetrade.org/pdfs/IFT-Development-preview(low-res).pdf · inhabitants of emerging market economies through a ‘race to the bottom effect’ as

ifreetrade.org | [email protected] | @IFTtweetsIFT Ltd. | 10 Buckingham Street | WC2N 6DF | London | United Kingdom