177
STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION SUBMITTED TO THE DEPARTMENT OF POLITICAL SCIENCE AND THE COMMITTEE ON GRADUATE STUDIES OF STANFORD UNIVERSITY IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Yuen Yuen Ang November 2009

STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    1

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING

IN REFORM CHINA

A DISSERTATION

SUBMITTED TO THE DEPARTMENT OF POLITICAL SCIENCE

AND THE COMMITTEE ON GRADUATE STUDIES

OF STANFORD UNIVERSITY

IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS

FOR THE DEGREE OF

DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY

Yuen Yuen Ang

November 2009

Page 2: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc/3.0/us/

This dissertation is online at: http://purl.stanford.edu/hr313dw9240

© 2010 by Yuen Yuen Ang. All Rights Reserved.

Re-distributed by Stanford University under license with the author.

This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-Noncommercial 3.0 United States License.

ii

Page 3: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

I certify that I have read this dissertation and that, in my opinion, it is fully adequatein scope and quality as a dissertation for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy.

Jean Oi, Primary Adviser

I certify that I have read this dissertation and that, in my opinion, it is fully adequatein scope and quality as a dissertation for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy.

David Laitin

I certify that I have read this dissertation and that, in my opinion, it is fully adequatein scope and quality as a dissertation for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy.

Beatriz Magaloni-Kerpel

I certify that I have read this dissertation and that, in my opinion, it is fully adequatein scope and quality as a dissertation for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy.

Jonathan Rodden

I certify that I have read this dissertation and that, in my opinion, it is fully adequatein scope and quality as a dissertation for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy.

Alberto Diaz-Cayeros

Approved for the Stanford University Committee on Graduate Studies.

Patricia J. Gumport, Vice Provost Graduate Education

This signature page was generated electronically upon submission of this dissertation in electronic format. An original signed hard copy of the signature page is on file inUniversity Archives.

iii

Page 4: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

iv

ABSTRACT

Why and how has China succeeded as a developmental state despite a seemingly rents-ridden

bureaucracy? Following conventional wisdom, “Weberian” bureaucracies are an institutional

precondition for development, especially in interventionist states like China. However, my

research finds that China’s fast-growing economy has not been governed by a purely salaried

civil service. Instead, Chinese bureaucracies still remain partially prebendal; at every level of

government, each office systematically appropriates authority to generate income for itself.

Such a bureaucratic form normally invites predation and hinders capitalism. Yet, in China, state

bureaucracies have been collectively the backbone of economic growth and resilient

authoritarian rule.

My study unravels the paradox of “developmentalism without Weberianness” by illuminating

China’s unique path of bureaucratic adaptation in the reform era – labeled as bureau-

contracting – where contracting takes place within the state bureaucracy. In a bureau-

contracting structure, the state at each level contracts the tasks of governance to its own

bureaucracies, assigning them revenue-making privileges and property rights over income

earned in exchange for services rendered. Contrasting previous emphases on the prevalence of

illicit corruption in China, my study shows how and why bureaucracies in this context are

actually authorized by the state to profit from public office. My research draws on interviews

with 165 cadres across different regions and governmental sectors, as well as new statistical

evidence.

Specifically, I identify two factors that constrain arbitrary and excessively predatory behavior

among Chinese bureaucracies. First, I argue that bureau-contracting represents a remarkably

rigorous system of rents management. Agencies are not free to extract as they please; rather,

they must win and comply with revenue-making policies awarded by the state. Additionally, I

show that with new budgetary instruments in place, financial authorities have increased

information and control over the use of bureaucratic funds. Second, narrow departmental

interests are mediated by local developmental incentives that have remained even after the

Page 5: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

v

1994 fiscal recentralization reform. Using regression analyses of previously unavailable budget

data from Shandong province, my analysis demonstrates that individual local cadres benefit only

in the short-term from extracting rents for their departments, but gain more in the long-term by

promoting businesses and expanding the formal tax base. In short, the combination of an

incentive-compatible fiscal design and increasingly sophisticated instruments of oversight have

sustained an otherwise unorthodox structure of governance in China.

From a comparative institutional perspective, I see bureau-contracting as a species of hybrid

organizations that fuse high-powered contracting with internal authority structures. To use the

language of firms, bureau-contracting is to franchising as Weberian bureaucracies are to directly

owned firms. The success of organizations like these lies in maximizing the benefits of

entrepreneurial incentives and minimizing opportunism simultaneously. In the case of the

Chinese state, bureau-contracting powerfully motivates cadres to self-finance a part (or even all)

of their costs of office, thus reducing the government’s financial burden and allowing the ruling

party to run an expansive state apparatus and patronage network. At the same time, by

constraining rents extraction and preserving local growth incentives, the bureaucratic structure

evolved co-existed with rapid market development under single party rule.

In a phrase, bureau-contracting presents a high-powered but opportunistic alternative to the

Weberian ideal-type. The Chinese experience suggests that “market-compatible” bureaucratic

institutions need not necessarily conform to – and may even diverge significantly – from

standard Western models, at least at early stages of development. Through a micro-level view

into the workings of bureaucracies in China, my observations challenge prevailing assumptions

of bureaucratic organization and notions of corruption in the comparative literature. Relevant to

policy-makers and students of political economy, my findings also inform our understanding of

incentive design in developing and reforming governments.

Page 6: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

vi

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

I remember feeling, during my first field trip to China in the summer of 2006, that I was standing

at the bottom of a mountain, gazing up, and wondering how I could ever get to the top. As a

foreign student, a parent of two children, completing this dissertation has not been easy and

could not have been accomplished alone. It is a great privilege, especially on Thanksgiving, to

acknowledge the kindness, generosity, and guidance of teachers, friends, and family, without

which my journey would have been impossible.

My first debt of gratitude is owed to my advisor, Jean C. Oi. I had taken a leave of absence from

the political science program, unsure if I would return and unsure about what to do with myself

in general. Jean called, emailed, and urged me to return. I still recall her words, “Chiku (eat

bitterness) a little and you’ll have lots of options later on.” It is thanks to her insistence and

devotion as an advisor that I have the privilege today of having an academic career. Although

this career can be “bitter,” sometimes, I cannot imagine another vocation that could be more

rewarding and worthwhile. I thank Jean for prodding me onto this path.

As a mentor, Jean has inspired me with her ferocious tenacity to do research. She imparts by

example a respect for the subjects whom we study, be they officials or farmers, through a

genuine interest to listen to their stories. Methodologically, Jean has taught me the importance

of uncovering complex day-to-day realities through painstaking fieldwork. Analytically, she has

taught me not to judge the behavior we observe, but rather to ask why people act the way they

do. Her influences are every where evident in this dissertation.

Many thanks are owed to the other members of my committee. Alberto Diaz-Cayeros has been

an indispensable source of support ever since my return to graduate school. Alberto injected

sparks into an embarrassingly confused project I presented in my third year, encouraging me to

look into the political economy of public spending. His ideas inspired my data collection efforts

in China and got me hooked on budgetary politics. Jonathan Rodden has listened patiently to my

hours of “rambling.” Although he claims to know little about China, his responses have never

Page 7: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

vii

failed to make me see China in fresh light. I am much indebted to David Laitin’s insights and

teaching. David literally identified for me the forest in the trees. I had been so lost at one point

that David actually wrote me an abstract of what my dissertation should be – that abstract

showed me the light. Last but not least, as a distinguished scholar and mother of three children,

Beatriz Magaloni has been a role model to me. Beyond the dissertation, Beatriz has advised me

throughout a stressful job-hunting process. I am grateful to Beatriz for her academic and

personal advice.

My heartfelt appreciation also goes to the chair of my committee, Andrew Walder. Andy has

been more than a committee chair. He has been very much a member of the committee. Over

the years, he has offered incisive comments on my drafts and presentations that helped shape

my project. Andy has a quiet yet powerful manner of giving encouragement. His support is

cherished deeply.

Although not on my committee, Karen Jusko has been extremely generous in sharing her time

and feedback. She has read my papers, attended presentations, and served on last-minute

notice on my reading committee, each time offering detailed and valuable comments. I also

thank Jonathan Bendor for his sharp insights and his intriguing course on organizational theories

that got me interested in studying bureaucracies.

I wish to say a special word of thanks to my undergraduate advisor, Eve Grace. Learning political

theory from Eve at Colorado College was a liberating experience. Eve’s classes planted in me the

desire to go to graduate school. Although, to her disappointment, I did not in the end study

political theory, I feel truly fortunate to have read some of Tocqueville’s and Rousseau’s

philosophy. Having been raised in a rote-learning environment in Singapore, these classics of the

Western tradition gave me ideas I did not have before. My interest in bureaucratization and

state power, the basis of my dissertation, had stemmed from Tocqueville’s Democracy in

America.

My project is based on substantial field research, which could never have been accomplished

without the assistance of professors and friends in China. I thank Yang Yan, Bian Huimin, Qiao

Page 8: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

viii

Zhijian, Zhu Jinwei, Wu Yuanyi, Feng Shanshu for helping me to arrange interviews. Kuo Tai-

Chun and Xiao Meng connected me to friends in Beijing during my first field trip. Nick Hope

shared useful insights into China’s economic system and was always generous in making

introductions. I have learned a great deal about China from conversations with Bian Huimin, Han

Chaohua, Yuan Weishi. These scholars have survived tumultuous times in the country, and I

deeply admire their courage and ideals.

My appreciation also goes to the officials and rank-to-file cadres who have shared their time and

stories with me. To ensure their anonymity, I cannot name them individually. Some interviewees

were extremely bright and insightful. Some have truly worked hard to serve public interests. I

thank each of them for teaching me about China, institutions, and power through their real-life

experiences.

Besides establishing contacts, the success of my fieldwork depended on having financial

assistance. I have been fortunate to receive grants from the Center for East Asian Studies,

Institute of International Studies, and the Graduate Research Opportunity Fund at Stanford

University, as well as the 1990-Institute and Overseas Young Chinese Foundation. The Andrew

Mellon Foundation/American Council of Learned Societies awarded two fellowships to support

my dissertation write-up and post-doctoral research. At Stanford, the Escondido Family Fund

provided four years of housing subsidy and Bing Nursery offered scholarships to my children.

These had been a critical source of financial aid for my family.

On a personal note, there are many friends whom I must thank. I had returned to graduate

school in the winter of 2004 alone, seven months pregnant with my second child. My husband

was working in Singapore, and my older son, Justin, was cared for by my mother-in-law in Taipei.

After my baby girl was born, I had to tend to my two children while juggling work in graduate

school, until my husband joined us in 2005. Many friends came to my aid during that difficult

time: Xuehua Zhang & Jon Otto, Doug Kerr & Christina Gwin, Vicki Sherman, Brian Goldsmith,

Shawn Gaines, Mee Smuthkalin, Charlotte Lee, and our “Saturday volleyball friends” at Stanford,

Jessica, Zhu-Zhu, Vincent, Xiaobing, Ju Bin, et al. These friends have taken me on grocery

Page 9: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

ix

shopping trips, babysat while I studied for the field exams, sent my son to school, delivered

medicine when I was sick, and so on. I am touched by their unconditional acts of kindness.

At Stanford, I have been lucky to enjoy the comradeship of colleagues, including Woramut

Smuthkalin, Joo-Joun Jung, Chao-Chi Lin, Martin Dimitrov, Kay Shimizu, Charlotte Lee, Alex Kuo,

Chris Chan, Xiaojun Li. My colleagues have provided much-appreciated company, veteran tips on

fieldwork, and feedback on my project at every stage of dissertation research and writing.

Yongshun Cai has played an influential role in encouraging me to publish my field paper and

eventually to return to graduate school. I thank Xuehua Zhang for being a great friend and an

informal mentor. She introduced me to the nuts-and-bolts of doing fieldwork, made contacts for

me, and lent a listening ear to my complaints. At the political science department, I wish to

thank Jeanette Lee Oderman for her compassion and especially her help during my transition

back to Stanford. Eliana Vasquez and Chandelle Arambula also deserve much credit for keeping

scatter-brain students like I on the alert.

Beyond Stanford, family friends and teachers have contributed crucial moral and practical

support. My family and I are deeply grateful to Reverend Daxing for his profound wisdom,

teachings, and medical care. Mr. Westgate, my husband’s high-school teacher, has been a

teacher and a family elder to us. His humor and honesty are always much appreciated. Heartfelt

thanks goes to Hsien L. Chen for his hospitality and generosity. Fiona Ng, who has been like a big

sister, has helped me numerously during my stay in Hong Kong. Yang Yan has been incredibly

kind to me. Shawn Gaines lifted my spirits whenever I was down. Although we had lost touch

twice, he magically showed up again when I needed his support and words of inspiration.

Finally, I give thanks to my family. My parents, both of whom had only attended high school,

worked hard to give me an education. My parents-in-law have provided financial support during

our years in school and showered loving care upon our children. My two children, Qi-Xuan

(Justin) and Qi-Mei (Jamie), fill my life with joy. I thank them for being so gracious and sweet in

bearing with my constant absence, long work hours, and bad moods during dissertation writing.

Page 10: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

x

My husband, Chia-Yu Tang, gave up his career so that I may pursue mine. He left his job in

Singapore and became a full-time dad in Palo Alto, enabling me to work on this dissertation. He

has been an amazing father to our children, especially when I am away from home for weeks,

even months. It is little known to others that he is also an amazing coach with a dual background

in arts and business; he debates hypotheses with me, designs my web site, and edits my

powerpoint slides. Above all, Chia is the beacon of my life. His qualities of kindness, patience,

and quiet courage are priceless.

As this dissertation is built upon my husband’s sacrifices and love for the family, I dedicate my

work to him.

November 26, 2009

Shanghai, China

Page 11: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

xi

TABLE OF CONTENTS

Acknowledgements

List of Tables

List of Figures

CHAPTER 1 –

Introduction

1

CHAPTER 2 –

Bureau-Contracting: The Industrial Organization of Chinese Bureaucracies

27

CHAPTER 3 –

The Structure of Cadre Rewards

65

CHAPTER 4 –

Dual Fiscal Incentives

79

CHAPTER 5 –

The Political Economy of Bureaucratic Adaptation

104

CHAPTER 6 –

Conclusion

125

Appendix A: List of Local Government Offices

Appendix B: The Formal Cadre Wage Scale

Appendix C: List of Interviews

Page 12: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

xii

LIST OF FIGURES

Figure 1.1: Bureau-Contracting and Weberian Bureaucracy Compared 22

Figure 2.1: Bureau-Contracting: Fusing Markets and Hierarchies 31

Figure 2.2: Varieties of State Organization 32

Figure 2.3: Organization Chart of Typical Local Government 35

Figure 2.4: ‘Rules of the Game’ – A Simulation of Budgeting Procedures and Outcomes 63

Figure 4.1: Dual Fiscal Incentives 83

Figure 4.2: Decomposition of Public Spending 88

Figure 4.3: County Spending Structure 88

Figure 4.4: County Revenue Structure 88

Figure 5.1: Local Revenue and Spending Before and After the 1994 Fiscal Reform 113

Figure 5.2: Change in Composition of Extrabudgetary Revenue, 1980-2003 114

Figure 5.3: Change in Public Employment Size, 1955-2003 116

Figure 5.4: ‘Eating budget’ – Cadre Rewards Consume Tax Revenue and Fiscal

Transfers

121

LIST OF TABLES

Table 2.1: Examples of Functions and Fiscal Status of Extrabureaucracies 38

Table 3.1: Composition of Local Cadre Rewards, 2004 66

Table 3.2: Distribution of Cadre Rewards Across Provinces, 2004 71

Table 3.3: Personnel and Administrative Spending Per Cadre in Windy County in 2007 71

Table 4.1: Tax Categories After the 1994 Fiscal Reform (Tax-Sharing System) 89

Table 4.2: Descriptive Statistics of Cadre Rewards, 2001-2005 90

Table 4.3: Descriptive Statistics of Income Streams, 2001-2005 91

Table 4.4: Determinants of Cadre Rewards in Shandong Counties (2001-2005) 94

Table 4.5: Simulation of Short-Term and Long-Term Effects on Benefits Per Cadre 97

Page 13: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

1

CHAPTER 1

INTRODUCTION

“Capitalism and bureaucracy have found one another and belong intimately

together.”

Max Weber, Economy & Society, p. 1465

“Can we identify the kind of transitional administrative system that exist today

in reality? I think we can, but to do so we shall have to employ some new words

and concepts which cannot be found in the standard literature on public

administration.”

Fred Riggs, Administration in Developing Countries, p. 10

Over the past centuries, state institutions have launched on an inexorable process of natural

selection, converging upon a common organizational form – the bureaucracy. As Max Weber

famously observed, the bureaucracy is a new organizational species. Contrasting pre-modern

institutions of governance, modern bureaucracies are legal-rational. They are rules-bound,

hierarchical, meritocratic, politically neutral, and the most basic of all, salaried. Civil servants

receive regular wages from state budget allocations and are barred from exploiting public office

for personal profit. By virtue of its discipline, efficiency, and reliability, the legal–rational

bureaucracy is superior to early patrimonial administrations, featuring fiscal arbitrariness,

personal loyalties, and compensation of officials in kind rather than in money. As is well known,

the Weberian bureaucratic form is a product of and necessary complement to the unique

conditions of modernity: industrial capitalism and centralized authority. Emphatically stated, “its

Page 14: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

2

rise and expansion has everywhere had ‘revolutionary’ results” and lies “at the root of the

modern Western state” (Weber 1968, 1002; 223).

Weber’s thesis has had a profound influence on social science theories and public management

best practices. Present-day notions of state institutional qualities stem from the Weberian ideal-

type. Among policy-makers, there is a near-universal consensus that in order to have state

capacity, it is necessary to first build “effective” administrations along standard Weberian

principles. “Separate public office from private property.” “Introduce entrance examinations.”

“Establish the rule of law.” “Eliminate corruption and nepotism.” “Require reporting.” “Impose

hierarchical oversight.” “Delineate functional jurisdictions.” Efforts to reform public

administrations aim unanimously to bring about higher levels of rationalization and to rid

patrimonial practices that had long ago been abolished in the developed Western hemisphere.

In light of our conventional wisdom, China in the reform era presents a puzzle. Since the

beginning of market reforms in 1979, China has achieved record-breaking development and

modernization under the authoritarian rule of the Chinese Communist Party (CCP). In explaining

the political basis of growth, many experts have characterized China as a developmental state.1

At the local levels, in particular, communist officials had and still continue to perform a crucial

pro-market role. They plan, build, coordinate, attract investments, and manage businesses. And

yet – here lies the puzzle – my study finds that China does not have a standard Weberian

bureaucratic structure, which according to conventional wisdom, is necessary for strong,

developmental states.

Instead, my study finds that Chinese bureaucracies have until this day retained features of pre-

bureaucratic organizations. In particular, I underscore the economic character of their non-

Weberian quality – bureaucracies in China systematically appropriate the powers of office to

generate income for themselves. In the Weberian language, the Chinese administration can be

described as prebendal insofar as public offices can be exploited for departmental or personal

gain. As Weber saw it, prebendalism is dangerous because it invites predation and corrodes

1 We will discuss this literature in more detail in the later sections. Some representative works include

Wade and White 1988; White 1988; Blecher 1991; Gore 1998; Oi 1999; Walder 1995; Duckett 1998;

Howell 1993; Blecher & Shue 2001.

Page 15: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

3

hierarchical control. To students of politics, prebendalism equates “official deviance” (Lu 2000b),

“legalized corruption” (Tarkowski 1988), “[subversion] of the rule of law for personal gain” (Van

de Walle 2007), and “incessant pressures on the state and the consequent fragmentation of

state power” (Joseph 1987). Given the prebendal qualities of the Chinese bureaucracy, it is

perhaps not surprising that many view the administration in China not as developmental, but as

rents-ridden.2

It is not uncommon to find prebendal bureaucracies qualities in present-day developing

countries. Such bureaucracies, for example, have persisted in and ravaged impoverished parts of

sub-Saharan Africa (for example, Joseph 1987 on Nigeria; Evans 1995 on Zaire). What is new,

however, is to find state bureaucracies with prebendal qualities governing a high-growth

economy in a developmental setting, and even more unusually, with a Communist party at the

helm of power. Following Weberian wisdom, if “the development of markets is obstructed, the

use of money primarily consumptive, and the development of capitalism impossible” under

patrimonial and prebendal administrations (Weber 1968, 238), then how could China defy the

norm? What explains the incongruence between reform China’s bureaucratic structure and

economic outcome? How could the same set of bureaucratic agents be developmental and

entrepreneurial on the one hand and predatory on the other? In short, why and how has China

succeeded as a developmental state despite a seemingly rents-ridden bureaucracy?

The aim of this study is not merely to unravel a case of Chinese exceptionalism. Rather, in

explaining the divergence of Chinese state infrastructure from European and more recent East

Asian experiences, I hope to shed new light on some fundamental questions about the

institutional and political bases of development and modernization: What kind of bureaucratic

forms best facilitate state capacity building and market development? Are rents for the ruling

class always incompatible with development and reforms? If not, under what conditions are

they compatible?

2 This literature, which we shall also later discuss, is too long to be exhaustively listed here. Xiaobo Lu

wrote a comprehensive study about organized corruption in China (2000a; 2000b). Minxin Pei (2006)

viewed China as a quintessential “decentralized predatory state.” See Manion (2004), Sun (2004) and

Wedeman (2004) for recent empirical studies of official corruption.

Page 16: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

4

My study suggests that the Chinese experience could offer a structural alternative to the

Weberian ideal-type. I call this alternative bureau-contracting. As a form of state organization,

bureau-contracting is a double-edged sword: it powerfully incentivizes governmental agents to

maximize revenue, which may be taxes or rents, but it also encourages opportunistic behavior.

An understanding of how the Chinese melded and wielded this sword points us to a broader

understanding of the problems of incentive design and rents management, pertinent to

reforming economies and developmental autocracies everywhere. Pairing a neo-institutional

framework with new sources of empirical evidence, both qualitative and quantitative, this study

will illuminate the mechanisms of bureau-contracting, as well as the processes that shaped

them. The following sections will survey the existing literature and consider competing

explanations for the Chinese paradox. Then I will present the analytical tools employed in this

study.

Bureaucratic Structure, Development, and State Capacity

Good governance matters for development and social well-being. A critical element of good

governance is the quality of bureaucracy.3 As Geddes puts it, “All abilities [of states] depend on

the existence of effective bureaucratic organizations. If one wants to understand states as actors,

one needs to look at their bureaucratic innards” (1996, 14). The focus on bureaucratic

competence prompts these questions: What constitutes “effective” bureaucratic organizations?

What connects these organizations to state capacity and desirable economic outcomes?

Weber’s monumental work will be discussed in more detail below.

The Weberian Thesis in Brief

Weber divided institutions of governance into two ideal-types and historical periods:

patrimonial bureaucracies of pre-modern states and legal-rational bureaucracies of modern

states. Patrimonial bureaucracies had two definitive features: personal loyalties and prebendal

financing. Person-to-person clientelism governed patrimonial regimes. Instead of performing

3 In econometric analyses of the relationship between institutions and development, bureaucratic quality

has become a standard measure of state institutional quality (Mauro 1995; Knack and Keefer 1995; La

Porta et al 1999).

Page 17: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

5

official duties in an impersonal capacity, officials and retainers typically pledged personal

allegiance to their political patrons. At the same time, feudal lords rarely paid public servants

regular wages for their services. Instead, they assigned prebends (or benefices) for personal

exploitation.

Essentially, prebends were licenses for officials to extract rents from public office or state assets

as “forms of maintenance.” They included the rights to lease land, collect fees, or conduct

monopoly trade (Weber 1968, 235; 966). This method of administrative financing was known as

prebendalism. Closely associated with prebendalism was the practice of tax farming. In many

early states, such as the Roman Republic, rulers contracted the task of tax collection to

entrepreneurial agents, who offered the highest bid for the right to collect taxes (Levi 1988). Tax

farmers handed over a contracted share of revenue to the ruler or paid a royalty upfront and

then kept the remaining collections as profits.4

Patrimonialism was the most important kind of administration before the emergence of the

modern bureaucracy. Over centuries, as political authority centralized and demands for direct

tax collection grew, rulers abolished prebendal practices and tax farming, replacing them with

salaried civil services (Tilly 1993; Levi 1988). Modern bureaucracies possess five of the following

traits absent in the past: (1) strict adherence to impersonal rules and duties; (2) established

hierarchy of offices; (3) stable career paths with ordered promotion based on merit; (4)

emphasis on technical expertise and fixed jurisdictions; (5) a fixed salary paid in money. These

features lend modern bureaucracies “indubitable technical superiority” and “stringency of

discipline” over their pre-modern predecessors (Weber 1968, 223; 983).

At the heart of the Weberian thesis is that claim that bureaucratic structures have economic

consequences.5 Patrimonialism obstructs market development, while modern bureaucracies

complement capitalism. Different from traditional forms of capitalism (e.g. barter trade), free

market capitalism required large capital investments and routinized organization of inputs and

4 In certain places, tax farmers were private businessmen, but in others, they were local elites and semi-

officials. 5 It should be noted that Weber did not offer a causal argument of bureaucratic competence leading to

growth. As Weber wrote, “The mere fact of bureaucratic organization does not tell us unambiguously

about the concrete direction of its economic effects” (1968, 989).

Page 18: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

6

outputs to serve mass markets. Market capitalism “is altogether too sensitive to all sorts of

irrationalities in the administration of law, administration, and taxation, for these upset the

basis of calculability” (Weber 1968, 240).

As Weber saw it, patrimonial administrations were inimical to industrial capitalism for several

reasons: predation, fiscal arbitrariness, and appropriation. As prebendal officials could generate

private income from public office, they had incentives to maximize extraction. Consequently,

this provoked regular spells of over-taxation and popular rebellion. Further, extraction in

patrimonial regimes was rarely based on laws and rules. Instead, it rested on the whims of lords

and officials, making demands for payment unpredictable to entrepreneurs and subjects. Finally,

as benefice-holders enlarged their coffers and gained independence, the power of the central

ruler risked disintegration. These conditions posed a constant threat to the expansion of

modern markets. In Weber’s view, although legal-rational bureaucracies do not cause growth in

and of themselves, they provide an essential administrative environment for market capitalism

to thrive. Legal-rational bureaucracies allow capitalists to “count on the… rational, predictable

functioning of legal and administrative organs” to make long-term investment decisions (Weber

1968, 1095).

The advantage of legal-rational over patrimonial bureaucracies stems from one primary factor –

the transformation of the official from a benefice-holder to a salaried employee. Patrimonial

officials lived primarily on prebends, not wages; although they performed public duties, they

were entrepreneurial agents whose monetary interests were often at odds with the professed

goals of office. However, when the prebendal bureaucrat or tax farmer becomes a fully salaried

employee, the terms of exchange between state and bureaucrat are altered. In Weber’s words

(1968, 959):

Entrance into an office… is considered an acceptance of a specify duty of fealty

to the purpose of the office in return for the grant of a secure existence.

[Simultaneously then] office holding is not considered ownership of a source of

income, to be exploited for rents or emoluments in exchange for the rendering

of certain services.

Page 19: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

7

It is certainly possible that a salaried official could exploit his office for personal rents even after

being paid – however, doing so is no longer a right, but a crime. As Rose-Ackerman noted in the

contemporary context, “If civil service employment is well paid, corrupt officials suffer real pain

if they are caught and forced out” (1999, 78). Paired with meritocratic recruitment, hierarchical

controls, and processes of professionalization, salaried bureaucracies can perform in an

unprecedentedly disciplined and efficient manner.

In brief, Weber’s central point was that bureaucratic predation is especially disruptive to

modern capitalism. A legal-rational bureaucratic structure supports market development by

removing the threats of arbitrary and excessive extraction. This point is echoed numerously in

recent political economy literature emphasizing the importance of limiting governments and

committing state actors to preserving private property rights (North & Weingast 1989; Weingast

1995).

Empirical Evidence of the Weberian Thesis

The Weberian thesis has inspired volumes of qualitative and quantitative studies. Case studies

by political scientists highlight the role of state bureaucracies in promoting late industrialization

and growth. These authors stressed the “internal characteristics of the state” as a key

determinant of state capacity and effective policy implementation (Stepan 1978; Haggard &

Kaufman 1989; Haggard 1999). Cross-national quantitative analyses by economists found “state

institutional quality” positively associated with investment and growth rates (Mauro 1995;

Knack & Keefer 1995).6 In recent years, a group of sociologists tested the Weberian thesis more

systematically (Evans and Rauch 1999; Rauch and Evans 2000; Henderson et al 2007). They

created a “Weberianness scale” based on survey measures of two Weberian qualities across

countries, meritocratic recruitment and the presence of a predictable career ladder. Confirming

part of the Weberian thesis, their analyses across 35 developing countries from 1970-1990 find

6 Drawing on subjective cross-country risk assessments, measures of state institutional quality have

included quality of bureaucracy, expropriation risk, repudiation of contracts by government, red tape,

corruption, etc.

Page 20: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

8

“Weberianess” significant in predicting growth.7 Collectively, these authors confirmed the

economic impact of state structures and called to improve public institutions along Weberian

principles.

Although Weber did not envision an interventionist role for governments,8 some two decades

ago, the Weberian perspective took an interventionist spin in the developmental state literature.

Inspired by the experiences of newly industrialized economies (NIEs) in East Asia, the literature

attracted a huge following in academic and policy circles. The seminal book of the

developmental school was Chalmers Johnson’s MITI and the Japanese Miracle (1982).

Attributing Japan’s economic take-off in the 1970-80s to pro-active governmental economic

policy, Johnson “constructed a Weberian ideal type of an interventionist state” (Woo-Cumings

1999, 2). Among the features of a developmental state are the establishment of national

priorities for development, the use of economic interventionist tools (e.g. tax breaks and

preferential policies), productive private-public partnerships, and cultivation of strategic

industries.

According to the developmental state literature, a crucial ingredient behind effective state

intervention are elite, meritocratic, politically insulated bureaucracies, as detailed in the cases of

Japan (Johnson 1982), South Korea (Amsden 1989) and Taiwan (Wade 1990). Evans qualified

that for development to occur, state ties with the business class matters too (Evans 1995). As

this condition may fall prey to state capture and possibly corruption, he added that “internal

bureaucratic coherence should be seen as an essential precondition for the state’s effective

participation in external networks” (Evans 1995, 154). Professional bureaucracies structured

along Weberian principles, it is claimed, are inclined to pursue collective goals of national

development, while prebendal bureaucracies are easily torn asunder by self-seeking bureaucrats

(Evans 1995). As such, developmental scholars argued that state intervention could work if

countries build competent bureaucracies and get interventions right (Wade & White 1988;

Campos & Root 1996; Root 1996; Appelbaum and Henderson 1992; Onis 1991; Castells 1992;

7 East Asian countries (Korea, Taiwan, Hong Kong, and Singapore) showed a strong correlation between

high Weberian scores and rapid growth, while sub-Saharan African countries showed a reverse pattern

(Evans and Rauch 2000). 8 As Evans (1995) pointed out, Weber had a neo-utilitarian view of government, that is, the role of

government is only to correct market failures and provide public goods.

Page 21: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

9

Rodrik 1995). By the 1990s, even the World Bank joined the bandwagon, advancing a twin

formula of developmental success that combined “a reputable civil service” with “selective

interventions” (World Bank 1993; World Bank 1997).

The developmental discourse took an abrupt turn in 1997, when the Asian financial crisis struck.

Although the crisis has largely discredited the developmental state model, it did not disprove

the Weberian thesis. To the contrary, many critics blamed the crisis on weakened bureaucratic

quality (Segal and Goodman 2000; Henderson 1998; Pempel 1999). As Kang (2002) countered,

the South Korean bureaucracy was not politically neutral, as earlier claimed (Amsden 1989);

instead, it was susceptible to money politics. Others argued that it grew difficult to sustain

meritocracy and bureaucratic insulation as political conditions changed in the 1990s (Haggard

2000; Heo and Kim 2000; Yusuf 2001, 25). The crisis triggered calls to overhaul the corporate

and state governance structure in East Asia. As Schneider wrote, “interventionist states require

reforms to make them more Weberian” (1999, 297). In short, to many observers, it was not

Weberianness, but rather the lack of Weberianess, that contributed to the 1997 meltdown.

As Pearson (2005) argued, the fallout of state interventionism in East Asia has not eliminated

the role of governments in the economy. Rather, she believes that the developmental state has

merely given way to the regulatory state model. While the developmental state picks winners,

the regulatory state creates a level playing field and enforces rules fairly on market players

(World Bank 2002). Yet, regardless of whichever model prevails, the organizational precondition

for “good governance” remains the same – a law-abiding, rational, salaried administration, as

Weber had described a century ago.

To summarize, the conventional wisdom holds that effective bureaucracies possess certain

characteristics, as outlined by Weber. Weberian bureaucracies do not produce growth in and of

themselves. Nonetheless, a legal-rational bureaucratic structure is almost universally accepted

as a precondition for state capacity and sustained development. Of course, not all bureaucracies

meet the Weberian standards. After all, what Weber provided was an ideal type. Even so, as

Evans asserted, “it only takes a very rough approximation of the Weberian ideal type to confer

Page 22: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

10

advantage” (Evans 1995, 64). Hence, the desirability of the Weberian model of administration

has been taken for granted. The real concern has been how we may realize the model.

The Chinese Anomaly: Developmentalism Without Weberianness

Having established the conventional wisdom, we now turn to consider the Chinese anomaly. As

early as the 1980s, China was seen as a “socialist developmental state” and “socialist guided

market,” grouped alongside capitalist developmental states in East Asia (Wade and White 1988;

White 1988). Underscoring the pro-growth and entrepreneurial traits of Chinese governmental

agents, scholars have employed varied labels, including “local developmental state” (Blecher

1991), “bureaucratic entrepreneurs” (Gore 1998), “local state corporatism” (Oi 1992; 1999),

“market-oriented agents” (Walder 1995), “entrepreneurial state” (Blecher 1991), “state

entrepreneurism” (Duckett 1998), and “market facilitating state” (Howell 1993).

More specifically, developmentalism, broadly defined as state involvement in the economy, in

China has taken several models. First, in the classic developmental state model, governmental

leaders, from central ministries to village heads, are seen to have taken active measures in

building a market-friendly environment. Such measures included macro-economic planning,

infrastructural investments, mobilization of funds, risk and capital pooling, creation of

specialized agencies, provision of incentive packages, coordination across agencies and firms,

and even the supply of advertisement services (for examples, see White 1988; Oi 1992; Oi 1995;

Oi 1999; Walder 1996; Blecher 1991; Blecher & Shue 2001). In doing so, it was said that local

state bureaucracies “consciously aided and abetted the emergence of a greatly expanded

private enterprise sector” (Blecher & Shue 2001, 370). Second, in the corporatist model, local

governments ran publicly owned township and village enterprises (TVEs) like diversified,

dynamic corporations, with governmental executives acting simultaneously as a corporate board

of directors (Oi 1999; Walder 1995; Walder 1998). In a manner reminiscent of administrative

guidance in Japan, leaders selectively targeted enterprises for development. As noted,

“resources and breaks are directed to those enterprises that can generate the most benefit for

the corporate good” (Oi 1999, 119). Third, in the entrepreneurial model, individual state

agencies directly participated in the market by operating risk-taking, profit-making businesses,

Page 23: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

11

ranging from large companies hiring several hundred employees to dance halls and restaurants

(Blecher 1991; Duckett 1998). Collectively, these authors argued that local officials’ abilities to

make long-term decisions, forge alliances with firms, and run productive businesses of their own

contributed to China’s economic dynamism.

And what kind of bureaucratic structure does a local developmental state like China have? It

needs to be acknowledged at the outset that the Chinese bureaucracy does possess some

important Weberian qualities. The CCP enforced a strict hierarchy of offices and an elaborate

system of written files, reporting, and cadre assessment since state establishment. Being a

communist system, China boasts a dense network of party, state, and social organs, reaching

down to previously untouched levels of society. Following the launch of market reforms, central

leaders promoted meritocracy in the bureaucracy. Consequently, Chinese officials have become

increasingly educated (Lee 1991; Walder 2004). On top of that, mandatory cadre retirement was

introduced at Deng’s initiation (Manion 1993; Lee 1991, Chapter 10), creating a relatively stable

career and exit path in the officialdom. Most significantly, the civil service law (gongwuyuanfa)

was promulgated in 2005, providing a legal basis for a formal civil service establishment.9 To

some, China’s bureaucracies are little different from competent bureaucracies in East Asia

(World Bank 1993).10

However, the features and developments discussed above belie a fundamental violation of

Weberian principles – that is, Chinese bureaucracies are not purely salaried. Rather, my research

finds that they remain partly prebendal, or to use a colloquial term, “self-financed.” Indeed,

several studies before mine have noted and criticized the patrimonial, prebendal qualities of the

Chinese bureaucracy. Previous studies described such qualities as “Leninist patrimonialism”

(McCormick 1990), “neo-patrimonialism” (Wei-Arthus 2000), and “patrimonial bureaupreneurs”

(Lu 2000b).11 Going further, Xiaobo Lu asserted that China’s reforms “have not produced ‘party

9 We will discuss the limited scope of the civil service reform in more detail in Chapter 2.

10 For example, an influential report published by the World Bank, The East Asian Miracle: Economic

Growth and Public Policy, praised China and the East Asian NIEs collectively for “producing strong

bureaucracies” that supported pro-growth policies (1993, 178). 11

Another study related to this literature is Andrew Walder’s Communist Neo-traditionalism (1986).

However, Walder did not see neo-traditionalism as necessarily corrupt. His emphasis was on the inter-

meshing of personal loyalties and impersonal duties in manager-worker relationships.

Page 24: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

12

technocrats’ who are procedural-and-rule oriented, but rather neo-traditional quasi-bureaucrats

who approximate prerevolutionary local officials” (Lu 2000a, 233).

Indeed, detracting from the developmental school are those who highlight the corrupt and

predatory side of the Chinese bureaucracy. Empirical studies report that official corruption has

grown more intense and widespread since 1979 (Root 1996; Sun 2004; Manion 2006; Wedeman

2004; Lu 2000a). One author goes so far as to claim that China epitomizes a “decentralized

predatory state” where “the ruling elites are unaccountable and immune from punishment for

wrongdoing [and] consequently unconstrained from adopting predatory policies and practices”

(Pei 2006, 12). Naysayers predicted that corruption will lead China towards “long-term

stagnation” (Pei 2006, 214) and eventually collapse (Chang 2001; Goldstone 1996).

Such critical, pessimistic perspectives certainly capture part of the truth, as do glowing

developmental accounts of the Chinese state. However, the former leaves unanswered the

nagging puzzle of why, if the Chinese bureaucracy were patrimonial and inept, could rapid

development have occurred under the leadership and intervention of CCP officials. The

juxtaposition of developmental behavior alongside bureaucratic predation demands further

explanation. We consider existing approaches to this paradox in the next section.

The Chinese Paradox and Competing Explanations

How can we reconcile contrasting views of the Chinese state bureaucracy, at once

developmental and predatory? To be clear, the purpose of this study is not to explain the

occurrence of growth per se. There are already many theories on China’s growth.12 Rather, our

objective is to explain how markets can flourish even when a crucial prerequisite – a rational,

12

Economists and political scientists have offered many different explanations on China’s spectacular

growth. Political scientists have focused mainly on the role of the state and China’s strategy of economic

reform without political democratization. Ma (2000) provides a useful summary of this literature. One

strand of this literature debates the contribution of decentralization to China’s economic success (Oi 1992;

Oi 1999; Montinola, Qian & Weingast 1995; Cai & Treisman 2006). Modifying the previous literature,

Chapter 5 of this study, “Dual fiscal incentives,” identifies the intersection of inter-governmental

(between levels of government) and intra-government (within each level of government) fiscal

decentralization in reform-era China.

Page 25: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

13

non-predatory bureaucracy – appears lacking. This study also explores why a late industrializing

state with explicit developmental goals, like China, detracted from well-trodden institutional

paths.

One approach to explaining the paradox above is to maintain that China does have an effective

bureaucracy, notwithstanding its imperfections. As I have earlier discussed, the Chinese

bureaucracy is not entirely non-Weberian. Noting the advancement of meritocracy in the reform

age, Lee (1991) claimed that Chinese officials have transformed “from revolutionary cadres to

technocratic bureaucrats.” Supporting Lee’s view, David Li argued that “the massive retirement

program has radically changed the human capital of the Chinese bureaucracy… being better

educated in almost all cases, [the younger officials] were also generally more competent than

their predecessors” (Li 1998, 394). Similarly, Li Cheng points to the “meteoric rise of Chinese

technocrats” (Li 2001, 35), writing that “amidst widespread corruption, there were talented and

highly motivated technocratic bureaucrats and bureaucrat-politicians… who had an increasing

impact in the 1980s and 1990s” (7). The advancement of meritocracy and functional expertise in

the Chinese bureaucracy certainly present significant advantages. Yet, I counter that these

features do not overcome the threats of predation and arbitrariness in a partially prebendal

system. Historically, China was governed by an elite stratum of scholarly officials, but who were

nonetheless susceptible to bureaucratic excesses and corruption. If perverse incentives and

opportunities avail, technocrats will just as likely as unqualified cadres abuse their power for

private gain.

A second approach would argue that development occurred in China despite a corrupt,

patrimonial bureaucracy. As Lu pointed out sharply, “those who perceive the economically

overachieving Chinese state as developmental have overlooked an important factor in the

literature on the capitalist developmental state: a disciplined and capable bureaucracy” (2000a,

288). So why is China both a developmental and predatory state? Lu’s answer was that China

had developed an involutionary bureaucratic regime that failed to rationalize and thus remained

indefinitely patrimonial. In his view, the patrimonial character of the Chinese bureaucracy is the

fundamental cause of widespread corruption in the reform era (2000a; 2000b). Thus, the author

concluded, “We may now better understand the contradictory roles of the Chinese state: the

Page 26: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

14

state’s developmental goals and policies are compromised by its inability to maintain a

disciplined bureaucracy, even though some of its goals have been achieved” (Lu 2000a, 289).

Although Lu has observed a critical paradox, his answer falls short of addressing the puzzle. To

claim that the Chinese state has only achieved “some of its goals” is a serious understatement.

Lu’s formulation furthermore fails to explain why the Chinese state had been unusually

successful at achieving “some of its goals” (some!) and yet unsuccessful at the goal of

bureaucratization. If China’s bureaucracies were backward and undisciplined, as claimed, then

how could China emerge as the fastest-growing economy, in contradiction to Weber’s

predictions? Asked differently, how does patrimonialism in China compare to patrimonialism

elsewhere? Why have patrimonial states like Zaire failed miserably (Evans 1995), while China

saw a different fate?

A third approach can be located in the so-called “East Asian paradox,” where high levels of

corruption accompanied high growth in the 1980s-90s (Wedeman 2002; Rock and Bonnett 2004;

Campos 2001). This literature argued that development can coexist with predatory state actions

if the latter were relatively benign or sufficiently contained. Some claim that corruption in East

Asia was less harmful than corruption in other under-developed states (Wedeman 1997, 2002a,

2002b; Sun 1999, 2005). Wedeman (1997), for example, distinguished between looting, rent-

scrapping and dividend-collecting. He argued that corruption in East Asia took the forms of rent-

scrapping (e.g. self-seeking manipulation of regulatory powers) and dividend-collecting (e.g.

kickbacks to officials in return for favorable treatment) rather than plunder. On a similar note,

others contend that corruption in East Asia is comparatively predictable, with payees usually

getting what they pay for, and was thus less harmful to the economy (Campos et al 2001;

Hutchcroft 1997).

In this literature, it is further argued that structural conditions in East Asia favored restrained

predation. The centralization of power, often in the hands of one dictator, ensured predictability

and limited corruption, as was the case of Indonesia under Suharto (MacIntrye 2000; 2001; see

also Rock and Bonnett 2004; Kang 2002). Furthermore, regulatory power was concentrated in a

small core of elite agencies, approximating centralized corruption, less destructive and more

Page 27: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

15

predictable than decentralized corruption (Bardhan 1997). On the business end, East Asian

economies were dominated by mega-conglomerates, such as the Korean chaebols. Kang (2002)

argued that when the business community is united and strong vis-à-vis a coherent state, like in

the case of South Korea, excessive predation or state capture can be mitigated.

Although the East Asian literature is useful in understanding the differential impact of predatory

state actions, its applicability to China is limited. The East Asian literature centered on grand

money politics between mega-firms and elected politicians, especially in the form of bribe-

taking. While grand corruption also exists in China, the primary issue that affects daily business

conditions is decentralized predation, especially at the local levels. As Kellie Tsai, who has

studied private entrepreneurship in China, related, “In any given week, the typical factory owner

may be approached by dozens of different agencies requesting seemingly random user charges,

surcharges, and contributions for local projects” (Tsai 2004, 15). Notably, such “petty” predation

was absent in the East Asian NIEs, which offered investors market environments free of

harassing bureaus. Furthermore, unlike its East Asian counterparts, China has a mammoth,

multi-tiered administration, with individual offices at each level generating their own pots of

funds, and each having distinct regulatory powers in their jurisdictions. China also has an

extremely diverse business community, a dizzying mosaic of private, state-owned, and

collectives firms without a common voice. Taken together, the fractured structural conditions in

China defy a neat “mutual hostage” situation, which would predict a limited and equitable

distribution of rents (Kang 2002). Thus, the Chinese paradox calls for a different framework of

analysis.

My approach builds on some insights of the existing arguments. I agree that there are different

forms of predatory actions, some more harmful than others. I also agree that extraction is less

harmful if predictable and controlled. However, in reference to Wedeman’s typology, the

existing literature does not explain when authorities would choose rent-scrapping and dividend-

collecting over looting, especially if looting yields more immediate benefits. Furthermore, the

existing literature cannot tell us how patterns of rents-taking become stabilized in a massive

state bureaucracy like in China, where power is not concentrated in the hands of one dictator or

Page 28: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

16

a few pilot agencies, but is highly decentralized.13 In other words, we need to account for how

particular state policies and institutional design condition extractive behavior. We also need to

examine mechanisms of rents management in complex organizational settings.

My interpretation and empirical findings will depart from previous conceptions of neo-

patrimonialism and corruption in significant ways. I submit that the Chinese bureaucracy is not a

standard Weberian bureaucracy seen in developed and developmental states. But I also submit

that it is not a typical patrimonial bureaucracy. In the next section, I develop a neo-institutional

theoretical framework to explain what I think the Chinese bureaucracy represents.

The Bureau-Contracting State

Why has China succeeded as a developmental state despite a seemingly rents-ridden

bureaucracy? My answer to this question comes from an identification of the nature of China’s

bureaucracy and its development in the recent decade. My findings, based on recent fieldwork

and statistical testing, lead me to characterize China’s unique path of bureaucratic adaptation as

bureau-contracting. As the label indicates, bureau-contracting combines the terms

“bureaucracy” and “contracting.” Bureau-contracting denotes a system of contracting within the

state bureaucracy. In terms of physical structure, the term bureau-contracting also describes a

bifurcated bureaucracy that is unique to China, composed of a core elite administration (jiguan

danwei) and a periphery of extrabureaucracies (shiye danwei), bound by a thick familial

relationship.

To students of public administration, the label “bureau-contracting” is paradoxical because

bureaucracy and contracting are ordinarily alternative modes of organization (Moe 1984).

Governments either contract public services to private suppliers or establish their state-funded

public agencies. In developed systems of governance, public and private entities are strictly

13

Some may rightly disagree that power is decentralized in China. Indeed, personal power is still

dominant in the Chinese political system. Here, by “decentralized,” I mean that individual agencies can

exercise administrative power in their respective domains. Often, businesses in China find themselves

having to deal with not just one agency, but multiple ones.

Page 29: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

17

divided. Where mixed entities exist, they are the exception, but not the rule.14 Contrastingly, in

China, bureaucracies are governmental units with party-appointed personnel, but economically,

I found that they behave to varying extent like entrepreneurial contractors in two fundamental

ways. (a) They may generate “self-financed” income through the provision of services to the

party-state.15 (b) They can rightfully retain and use collected funds to finance jobs, benefits, and

administrative costs for their own offices. In short, the state at each level assigns individual

offices revenue-making privileges and de facto property rights over income earned. Framed

differently, it is as if the Chinese government “contracts” the tasks of governance to its public

bureaucracies, exchanging prebends for services, thus creating the paradox of bureau-

contracting.

To be clear, the features of bureau-contracting, as described above, were not implanted

overnight based on some leader’s grandiose design. Neither do I claim that these features are

permanently static. Rather, as I see it, and as we will discuss at length in Chapter 5, the

prevailing structure of bureaucracy is descended from a long historical legacy of prebendal

governance. And as we speak, these features are undergoing what I view as a relentless path of

institutionalization. In other words, I shall claim that while much of the Chinese state has not –

as yet – transformed into a standard Weberian bureaucracy, it is remarkably capable of adapting

and “legal-rationalizing” prebendal elements of governance into its formal bureaucratic

organization. While Weber has described for us one set of bureaucratic rationality, we can

observe in contemporary China, a different set of rationality, so to speak.

An understanding of the Chinese state as a bureau-contracting model removes us from the

binary lens of China as either a classic Weberian bureaucracy or an unfettered corrupt regime,

both of which, I contend, leads us to impartial views of the complex realities. Further, my

framework allows us to identify and test the mechanisms that may allow local state-led

development to occur despite the predatory risks inherent in a neo-prebendal bureaucratic

structure. I underline two of such mechanisms below.

14

I thank Scott Kennedy for pointing me to the existence of mixed public-private entities in the United

States in comparison to China. 15

By self-financed income, I mean revenue earned by and belonging to individual offices at each level.

Self-financed income is part of the non-tax revenue (feishui shouru) in China. Not all non-tax revenue is

extrabudgetary. I will explain further in Chapter 2.

Page 30: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

18

Managed rents

I argue that bureau-contracting constitutes a system of rents management. Before I proceed, let

me define rents in the context of this study. I use rents in the prebendal sense of the word. As

Weber defined, prebends are “life-long assignment to officials of rent payments… in

compensation for the fulfillment of real or fictitious duties of office” (Weber 1968, 967). When

the state awards an office the right to generate private income through the exercise of public

duties, that income functions as rent payments in lieu of budget allocations. In this definition,

self-financed income earned by and belonging to individual state agencies are a form of rent

payments. Often, as seen in China, bureaucracies generate funds for themselves by imposing

excessive regulation or quasi-monopoly rights (see Chapter 2), thus creating socially inefficient

rents in the classical economic sense (Krueger 1974; Buchanan et al 1981; Bhagwati 1983;

Tollison & Tullock 1988). Importantly, bureaucratic rents-extraction in China is qualitatively

different from the kind of lawless plunder described in places like Zaire (see Evans 1995;

Wedeman 1996).

In my account of bureau-contracting, I emphasize two features that function to manage rents

provision for the bureaucracy. First, public agencies and providers require what I call “policy

awards” from the state (awarded at the central and local level) to earn revenue, e.g. policies

sanctioning the exaction of a particular fee. From the late 1990s onwards, a comprehensive

institutional framework and norm of earning self-financed income according to – rather than in

violation of – state policy has evolved. Second, I show how financial authorities developed

enhanced information and control over bureaucratic funds. My research finds that, following

budgetary reforms in the mid-1990s, it has become standard practice for individual

bureaucracies to turn their income into state bank accounts, instead of stashing them away

illegally, but to retain property rights over the use of those funds. The rules of making,

submitting, and spending self-financed income are more rigorously enforced today than during

the “go-go” years of the 1980s and early 1990s. In short, we observe bureaucrats in China still

behaving in entrepreneurial ways but increasingly following standardized rules of procedures. I

discuss both of these features in Chapter 2.

Page 31: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

19

In a utopian state, rents are economically harmful, but in the real world, rents are politically

indispensable. Rents, firstly, are crucial for autocracies to reward and unite political elites

(Magaloni 2006). Secondly, as some argued, creating rents for political interest groups may be a

necessary cost to pay for realizing otherwise painful reforms and producing greater good in the

long run (Shleifer and Treisman 2000; Stiglitz 2000; Zhuravskaya 2007). Thirdly, creating a

privileged governing class is central to any hegemonic party’s power to co-opt society. In the

case of China, as Lee noted, “the sole channel of upward mobility for ambitious individuals has

been through the bureaucracy – a channel that the party-state has easily controlled through its

prerogatives over the personnel management of cadres” (1991, 4; emphasis added). The

combination of a relatively well-rewarded cadre corps and partial meritocracy allows a

hegemonic party not only to satisfy the existing elites, but also to induce citizens to aspire

membership in the bureaucratic strata.16 Finally, from the perspective of individual leaders,

rents sustain patronage machines. As Shirk (1993) pointed out, although China is not an

electoral system, political leaders run extensive patronage networks that feed on the

distribution of jobs, perks, and market access.

Put differently, once politics are taken into account, the problem of development is not to

eliminate rents but to regulate rents provision so as to minimize its costs and to stabilize

patterns of extraction.17 Much of the existing political science literature has identified strategies

for “splitting the spoils” within a small coterie of powerful political elites (Magaloni 2006;

Shleifer and Treisman 2000). However, the systematic distribution of rents, from leading officials

16

The dilemma of citizens under autocratic rule is well illustrated in a blog session upon which I chanced.

A recent graduate had asked whether he/she should join the land bureau or a large private company on a

public blog. The poster received many replies urging him/her to take the position at the land bureau. One

blogger (A) responded, “I noticed a strange phenomenon. Whenever we speak of civil servants or

corruption, we grind our teeth in hate. Yet as soon as someone posts a message like this one, everyone

urges the poster to join the civil service.” Another blogger (B) replied, “There is nothing strange about this.

We don’t hate civil servants, we hate the system. The reason is clear: civil servants have too much

grease.” Blogger A retorted, “Hypocrite! If you hate the system, then why is it that when the opportunity

comes, you want to benefit from the system. You are merely looking for an excuse.” The blog exchanges

were accessed at http://bbs.cz.soufun.com/1820170502~0~304/727074_728265.htm. 17

The problem, as compellingly summed up by Shleifer and Treisman (2000), is a “paradox of rents.” They

wrote, “Transforming stakeholders from opponents to supporters of reform often requires the creation of

rents by the government that these stakeholders can be offered in exchange of their support. An obvious

paradox arises. The goal of reform is to reduce rents and rent seeking” (9).

Page 32: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

20

down to street-level cadres, in massive state organizations is a much less straightforward and

under-examined problem.

In a communist system like China, the cadre corps constitutes a distinct interest group

(Oksenberg 1967). In the revolutionary sense, cadres are the leaders of the masses (Lee 1991).

Today, cadres are composed of a group of over 40 million (46 million by 2007) functionaries

serving in party-state organs, including about 500,000 leading officials, who constitute the heart

of the political system.18 As Walder (2004) asserted,

The political elite of 500,000 cannot rule the country unless it can retain the

obedience of 40 million state cadres… If the elite maintains the discipline of

state bureaucrats and the allegiance of party members, it can withstand

challenges from other groups in society, even in periods of economic hardship

and social upheaval. If, however, challenges from other groups stimulate a

defection of the Party membership and parts of the state bureaucracy, the elite

is in real trouble (197).

But how can the political elite retain the obedience of 40 million cadres? Shirk’s (1993) alludes

to the establishment of rents and patronage machines. However, as she pointed out, “we as yet

have little empirical information about how these local industry-based political machines work

in China” (1993, 189). Building on Shirk’s observations, my research aims to identify mechanisms

for a systematic, arms-length distribution of rents. Yet, different from Shirk’s emphases, my

focus is not on elite politics or person-to-person clientelist exchanges between public and

private actors. Rather, my focus is on the organized allocation of privileges at all levels of the

socialist hierarchy. I bring attention to the contracting relationship between state and

bureaucracy and between sub-components of the bureaucracy.

Dual Fiscal Incentives

I further contend that narrow departmental interests to extract rents are mediated by local

developmental incentives. Several earlier studies have underlined the contribution of fiscal

contracting and local fiscal incentives to China’s economic growth (Oi 1992; Oi 1999; Montinola,

18

The “leading officials” are cadres at the chu rank and above.

Page 33: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

21

Qian & Weingast 1996). From 1979 onwards, each level of government in China contracted with

the next lower level of government, requiring the latter to submit only an agreed share of

revenue. At the same time, local authorities were given unprecedented autonomy over retained

funds and increased responsibilities for expenditure needs, meaning that budget constraints

were hardened. As Oi (1992; 1999) argued, locally retained revenue constituted an economic

surplus that motivated local officials to grow businesses and collect more taxes. Montinola, Qian

and Weingast (1996) concluded that fiscal contracting “induced a strong positive relationship

between local revenue and local economic prosperity for all provinces and cities, thus providing

local officials with an incentive to foster that prosperity” (64).

While the contribution of fiscal contracting to China’s developmental success has received much

attention, I would argue that surprisingly little is known about a simultaneous process of

contracting that has taken place within each level of government. Just as local governments

needed incentives from upper levels to pursue growth, bureaucracies at each level also needed

motivation to self-finance in a new entrepreneurial climate. Following reforms, it was not only

the local governments that enjoyed rights to surpluses in the form of retained taxes.19 I

emphasize that individual bureaucracies too had rights to surpluses in the manner of self-

financed income, which formed each locality’s non-tax revenue. Just as local governments had

autonomy to expend extrabudgetary funds for the locality’s needs, each office had the right to

use the pots of funds generated to pay for cadre wages, benefits, and administrative costs.

A key – but yet unexamined – implication of the fiscal structure described above is that dual

fiscal incentives are at play. On the one hand, local governments collectively had incentives to

grow the economy and increase taxes. On the other hand, individual bureaucracies that

compose local governments had incentives to extract rent payments for the benefit of their own

departments and personnel. Thus understood, a critical question arises as to whether rent-

seeking incentives resulting from bureau-contracting might overshadow developmental

incentives provided by inter-governmental fiscal contracting, particularly in light of the fiscal

recentralization policy of 1994. In my analysis, I hypothesize that local cadres benefit

tremendously in the short-term from increasing self-financed income, but they benefit in the

19

The term “rights to surpluses” come from Oi’s Rural China Takes Off (1999).

Page 34: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

22

long-term only from increased taxes, which in turn depends on the collective capacity of local

governments to attract investments and sustain productive market activities. In Chapter 4, I

report supporting evidence for my hypothesis in a regression analyses of an original budget

dataset.

To sum up, I argue that it is the combination of an incentive-compatible fiscal design and

external instruments of rents management and budgetary oversight that have supplied high-

powered incentives and at the same time checked bureaucratic predation in China. My findings

offer an empirically-tested explanation for the paradoxical coexistence of local

developmentalism and appearances of widespread bureaucratic predation.

The Franchising Logic of Bureau-Contracting

From a comparative institutional perspective, bureau-contracting is a species of hybrid

organizations that fuse high-powered incentives with internal authority structures. What do I

mean? Consider an example from the business world – franchising. Say I am a small business

owner of several restaurants. Each restaurant is operated by a manager whom I hire for a fixed

salary each month. So long as they are happy to keep their jobs, the managers will perform

satisfactorily. But my managers are unlikely to work extremely hard, take initiatives, or bear

risks because they receive the same payoffs regardless of their efforts. To motivate my

managers, I contract with them to take only a share of the restaurant’s revenue and allow them

to keep whatever remains; any losses incurred will also have to be borne by them. In this new

arrangement, my managers are no longer salaried employees; they have become independent

owners.

As they have a residual claim, franchisees are highly motivated to maximize profits. It is this

feature of high-powered incentives that unleashed the entrepreneurial energies of franchisees

and made some franchised firms like McDonald’s extraordinarily successful. However,

franchising has its costs compared to direct ownership. Once my managers become franchisees,

they become independent. If I instruct them to make burgers a standardized way, they may not

follow my orders as they did before, unless I can credibly threaten to terminate the contract. Yet,

Page 35: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

23

even more insidious than open defiance is opportunism. The managers-turned-franchisees may

try to “cheat” our agreement by maximizing their own profits at the expense of my chain’s

reputation. For example, they may use cheaper, low-quality ingredients when making burgers or

add water to milk shakes. Each franchisee will save money for itself by cheating, but the

negative externalities will be spread across the chain. If I fail to control such opportunistic

behavior, customers may soon lose confidence in the brand name and the franchise will go out

of business.

Thus understood, the central problem of franchised organizations is how to unleash agent

entrepreneurism and control opportunism simultaneously. Resolving this problem lies at the

heart of successful franchising, as illustrated in the McDonald’s experience. “[Ray Kroc, the

founder] used franchising to unleash the power of operators who have an ownership stake in

this businesses. Though he demanded adherence to strict operating standards, he also freed

franchisees to market their service as they saw fit, and he motivated them by given them an

opportunity – unheard of in franchising – to become rich before he became rich” (Love 1996, 6).

In a phrase, “The fundamental secret to McDonald’s success is the way it achieves uniformity

and allegiance to an operating regimen without sacrificing the strengths of American

individualism and diversity” (7).

The long preamble aims to illustrate an unusual idea that forms the framework of my analysis,

namely that the problem of bureaucratic organization in China is analogous to the problem of

corporate franchising. In both organizational forms, contracting is conducted within a

hierarchical structure. In organizations like these, incentives are high-powered but the risks of

opportunism (or strategic self-seeking interests) are also high. In the context of the reform-era

Chinese bureaucracy, the central organizational problem is to inject entrepreneurial incentives

into the state bureaucracy but at the same time to constrain opportunistic risks arising from

bureaucratic involvement in the market. The structure of bureau-contracting is a compound of

mechanisms evolved to address this central problem of state organization.

Page 36: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

24

Bureau-Contracting vs. Weberian Ideal Type

As Weber noted, ideal types “after all, are to be considered merely border cases which are of

special and indispensable analytical value, and bracket historical reality which almost always

appears in mixed forms” (1968, 1002; emphasis added). Bureau-contracting is an ideal-type, and

my documentation of the Chinese case illustrates how one significant variety of this ideal-type

may exist in reality. The organizational logic of the ideal-type suggested by the Chinese case may

lend us comparative insights into divergent paths of state institutional development.

Bureau-contracting is a high-powered but opportunistic alternative to the Weberian ideal-type.

Returning to the corporate analogy in this study, bureau-contracting is to franchising as

Weberian bureaucracies are to directly owned firms. Just as franchised corporations may work

as well as non-franchised firms, a bureau-contracting structure may perform a market-

supporting role as Weberian bureaucracies do, depending on the economic and political goals of

the leadership, as well as on the design and enforcement of disciplinary mechanisms and

incentives. Figure 1.1 summarizes the organizational parallels.

Figure 1.1: Bureau-Contracting and Weberian Bureaucracy Compared

My conceptualization of bureau-contracting as an ideal type builds on Weber’s approach in two

respects. First, I do not claim that a bureau-contracting structure causes development, just as

Page 37: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

25

Weber did not argue that legal-rational bureaucracies would lead to growth. Rather, the

argument here is one about “institutional complementarities,” to borrow a phrase from the

authors of Varieties of Capitalism (Hall & Soskice 2001). Second, bureau-contracting as an ideal

type captures a trajectory of development. In describing the ideal type of a legal-rational

bureaucracy based on Germany’s experience, Weber projected the course of European

bureaucratic formation. As he maintained, the modern bureaucratic structure “is everywhere

the product of a long development” (Weber 1968, 957). Similarly, I maintain that the bureau-

contracting model was not consciously imposed by leaders in Beijing at a specific point in history.

Like the Weberian bureaucratic form, it too is the product of an evolutionary process and policy

choices. In Chapter 5, I trace the circumstances and choices that have shaped this process of

institutional change.

Data & Methodology

My research methodology combined “thick interpretation” during an early stage of research

with empirical testing in the later stages. The dissertation involved nine months of fieldwork in

China and 165 interviews with officials and rank-to-file cadres across provinces and

governmental sectors from the period of 2006-2009. I conducted most of my research at the

local levels (particularly county and city governments) in Shandong, Tianjin, Jiangsu, and Sichuan,

with some central-level interviews conducted in Beijing. To my best ability, I heeded the advice

of Fenno to “soak and poke in the data.” In addition to transcribing interviews verbatim, I took

notes of day-to-day observations and casual conversations. In general, I sought to immerse

myself in the habitat of my subjects and develop a realistic set of lens that could help me see

how bureaucrats in China performed their work. In Appendix C, I describe my interviewing

strategy and interview targets.

My primary sources of qualitative data are interview and field notes. Where appropriate, I use

policy documents, Chinese-language secondary literature, and media reports to supplement my

analysis. I believe this purposive choice of data has helped me to draw qualitative conclusions

different from some prevailing views of the Chinese bureaucracy. Many studies relating to

bureaucratic financing, entrepreneurism, and rents have fallen under the scope of corruption.

Page 38: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

26

These studies tend to draw heavily on secondary and media reports because, understandably, it

is difficult to gain access into bureaucracies in China. But, while media reports can be extremely

useful supplements, they tend to be incomplete and sometimes sensational. Relying on

secondary material may lead one fall into urban legends and miss oft-complex realities. In my

field research, I tried simply to uncover the mundane, tedious rules that govern bureaucratic

behavior (thankfully, I have a taste for the mundane!). At the end of the day, I believe it is

mundane, tedious rules that help us to understand what really matters to bureaucrats.

Following the collection of qualitative data, the next challenge was to find quantitative evidence

to test the implications of my institutional narrative, specifically that of dual fiscal incentives. For

this purpose, I created and analyzed a previously unavailable public budget dataset from

Shandong province from the period of 2001-2005. This is a unique “internal” (neibu) data source.

This dataset allows us to measure patterns of administrative financing and revenue streams

among county governments in Shandong with unprecedented though still imperfect precision.

Besides the Shandong dataset, I also employ descriptive statistics on public spending and

employment from other “internal” data sources, compiled by the ministry of finance, primarily

the Local Public Financial Statistics (Difang Caizheng Tongji). To my knowledge, the dissertation

contains one of the first systematic analyses of public spending data in China.

Outline of Dissertation

The rest of the dissertation proceed as follows. Chapter 2 introduces the neo-institutional

concept of bureau-contracting, building on and modifying existing theories of the firm. By

disaggregating the formal organizational structure and budgeting processes, I show how each

bureaucratic unit owns and has autonomous use over all or part of the self-financed income it

generates. I also emphasize the function of state-enacted “policy awards” that authorize

bureaucracies to collect revenue for self-financing. The analysis distinguishes the prebendal logic

of self-financing in China from conventional views of corruption.

Chapter 3 charts the structure of cadre rewards. I decompose cadre rewards and explain why

we observe such large disparities across regions and across offices. I argue that these patterns

reflect an unusually high-powered incentive scheme, but one that is different from incentive

Page 39: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

27

schemes seen in private firms and regular public bureaucracies. The analysis highlights the

coexistence of two sets of fiscal incentives, one motivating bureaucratic actors to maximize tax

revenues for local treasuries, and the other motivating them to maximize departmental

surpluses. The strategies for maximizing fiscal gains in these two respects could potentially be at

odds with each other.

Chapter 4 proceeds to evaluate a theory of dual fiscal incentives systematically. Specifically, I

test the relative strengths of developmental and rents-collecting incentives. Employing an error-

correction model on a county-level budget dataset, the analysis finds confirmation of my

hypothesis that developmental incentives dominate rents-collecting incentives in the long term.

This chapter underlines the combination of an incentive-compatible fiscal design and

institutional mechanisms of rents management.

Chapter 5 examines the political economy of bureaucratic formation in reform-era China, that is,

why the Chinese bureaucracy has come to look the way it is today. I begin by discussing the

historical institutional continuities in China’s administrative structure from imperial times to the

pre-reform period. Then moving to the reform era, the chapter traces the emergence of

entrepreneurism among Chinese bureaucracies, which contributed to initial growth efforts but

created new problems of control. It then looks at how fiscal and administrative reforms

introduced in mid-1990s increased pressures for bureaucracies at all levels to self-finance, but at

the same time, institutionalized processes of self-financing. The end product of the reforms

approximates a bureau-contracting model, rather than a salaried Weberian bureaucracy.

Finally, in concluding, I consider the theoretical implications of my study, particularly with regard

to the design of second-best institutions and the relationship between development and rents. I

emphasize the analytical value of alternative models, as the Chinese case offers, in rethinking

some basic questions about institutional quality and corruption. While not advocating the

Chinese experience, I speculate on the conditions that allow bureau-contracting to germinate

and possibly take root in other contexts. Finally, I discuss remaining questions for future

empirical research.

Page 40: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

28

CHAPTER 2

BUREAU-CONTRACTING:

THE INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION OF CHINESE BUREAUCRACIES

The main government building in the seat of Blossom County was acquired by a proud new

owner: the local land bureau. The landmark property that beamed energy-guzzling laser lights

from the rooftop, cost 230 million yuan to construct, and housed over twenty bureaus (including

the land bureau itself), was sold through the state asset management company. “I don’t

understand why the land bureau would want to buy the entire building,” one cadre mused. “All

its employees can barely fill five floors. What would they do with the rest of the property?” (AI

2007-112). While the use of assets was shrouded in mystery, it was plain that the land bureau

was flushed with funds. Interestingly, its funds had not come from budget allocations. As the

land bureau chief was said to have once boasted, “We don’t need money from the finance

bureau. We have enough money of our own to last ten years” (AI 2007-112).

The wealth of Blossom county’s land bureau may be exceptional, but the rights that public

bureaucracies in China exercise over their “own money” are not. As my brief encounter reveals,

Chinese bureaucracies are distinct from bureaucracies of most governments in their literally

entrepreneurial character – they can own and spend the income they earn. Not unlike firms,

they may suffer deficits or enjoy huge surpluses.

Chapter 1 identifies the industrial logic of bureaucratic organization in China. I develop the

construct of bureau-contracting, situating it in the universe of state organizational forms.

Following the theoretical framework, I illustrate three of the core elements of bureau-

Page 41: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

29

contracting in the Chinese context. A key finding in this analysis is that the state at each level

assigns individual bureaucracies de facto property rights over self-financed income generated.

Bureau-Contracting in Neoinstitutional Perspective

To illustrate how public bureaucracies may behave in part like private contracting firms, I

develop a neo-institutional construct – bureau-contracting. This section first summarizes

standard transaction costs theory, which explains why private and public organizations take the

form they do, and then modifies it to accommodate private-public organizational forms like in

the Chinese case.

Standard Transaction Costs Theory

In the new economics of organization, contracts are the starting point of institutional analyses.

Ronald Coase’s (1937) classic theory of the firm asks why some transactions take place in the

market between firms and others within a firm. Phrased differently, Coase puzzled over the

relative value of market transactions over internal authority structures. The answer proposed by

Williamson (1974) is transaction costs – that is, difficulties posed in completing transactions.

Such difficulties arise from two factors. The first is bounded rationality. Humans cannot possibly

foresee and design contracts ex ante to address all possible contingencies in an exchange; there

is always an element of unpredictability. The second factor is the assumption of opportunism.

Individuals may seek to benefit from an exchange at the expense of the other party through

deception or concealment. Opportunism is, as Williamson had defined, “a lack of candor or

honesty in transactions… [or] self-interest seeking with guile” (1974, 9).

In the neo-institutional paradigm, the mode of transaction chosen depends on one’s calculations

of transaction costs. When it is costly to organize a market transaction, it is preferable to

perform the transaction internally, administered by hierarchical rules. For example, if a firm

lacks information about a service supplier or believes it has difficulty enforcing a contract, it

would choose to organize the service itself through vertical integration, making the suppliers of

the service the firm’s own managers. In Williamson’s words, “considering the risks that simple

Page 42: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

30

(or incomplete) contingent claims contracts pose, the firm may decide to bypass the market and

resort to hierarchical modes of organization” (1974, 9).

There exists an inherent trade-off between market transactions and authority structures. On the

one hand, market transactions supply high powered incentives because efficiency gains flow

directly to the transacting parties, whereas authority structures supply only low powered

incentives as employees benefit indirectly from the firm’s financial gains.20 On the other hand,

market exchanges pose a greater risk of opportunism, whereas authority relations allow more

control and predictability. It is certainly true that even within a hierarchical structure,

opportunistic risks exist. In a classic agency problem, an employee may shirk responsibilities

assigned by the boss. However, in market exchanges, opportunistic risks tend to be even higher

than within an organization either because information is lacking, or more simply, transacting

parties do not have direct control over each other, unlike in an employer-employee relationship.

Adding to our previous point, then, organizational leaders choose between markets and

hierarchies depending on their assessment of the risks and costs of opportunism and the need

for high-powered incentives.

To illustrate, contrast the franchising and direct ownership model in the fast food industry.

Franchising approximates a market-based transaction. A franchising firm contracts to a

franchisee the right to use the company’s brand name and operational software in exchange for

a royalty payment or share of profits. Direct ownership is a hierarchical model. The firm opens

outlets and hires managers to operate them. McDonald’s adopted franchising because the

company’s founding executives aspired to build a massive chain and had do so quickly to

capture market share. In contrast to McDonald’s, In-N-Out, a much smaller Californian burger

chain, runs on a direct ownership model. Its salaried managers may not be as highly motivated

as franchisees to maximize profits; however, managers are easier to monitor and control than

franchisees.

With few exceptions, transactions costs theory has not been applied to analyzing public

bureaucracies. When it has, the issue has been framed as a binary choice that governments face

20

These indirect benefits typically come in the form of promotions or wage raises.

Page 43: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

31

in delivering public services through the private sector (i.e. high powered incentives) or the

public bureaucracy (i.e. low powered incentives) (Moe 1984; Donahue 1989; Acemoglu et al

2007). As an organizational theorist states:

[The government] can create its own bureaucracy, or it can engage in marketlike

transactions by contracting with private actors who promise to provide services

at a stipulated price (there is no prevailing market price) to be paid by the

government (Moe 1984, 759).

In theory, governments choose between contracting or creating a bureaucracy depending on

the transaction costs involved. Certain services, like policing, are delivered through the public

bureaucracy because it poses a high moral hazard risk. Other services, like garbage collection,

are more likely to be contracted to private firms through a competitive bidding process to

increase the efficiency of service delivery.

In standard models of public administration, delivering services through the public bureaucracy

is by definition a low-powered incentive scheme because public servants are not supposed to

capture private gains from public transactions. If they do, it is considered corruption and subject

to punishment. Even when bonuses are introduced, they are awarded based on some objective

measures of individual performance (Frant 1996), but not on a particular agency’s financial

“output.” The anomaly in China, as I will show, is that its public bureaucracies can generate real

surpluses that accrue to their own coffers and not to the state treasury. Furthermore, each

bureau’s financial performance determines actual cadre payoffs.

Bureau-Contracting: Standard Theory Modified

Transaction costs theory has been applied to either private or public organizations.21 It has not,

however, been employed to analyze public-private entities. To push neo-institutional theory

into the realm of mixed organizations, we need to consider multiple dimensions of transactions.

These dimensions can be divided into financial and personnel relations. I illustrate this approach

in Figure 2.1. Financial relations concern whether a government funds public service providers

21

The literature on transaction costs is huge. For a review of its application to theories of political

organization, see Moe (1984).

Page 44: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

32

with high-powered contracting rights (i.e. market-based) or low-powered fixed budget

allocations (i.e. hierarchy based). Personnel relations concern whether the relationship of a

service provider vis-à-vis the government is that of a contracting party (i.e. market-based) or an

employee (i.e. hierarchy based).

Figure 2.1: Bureau-Contracting: Fusing Markets and Hierarchies

The two dimensions of financial and personnel contractual relations create four configurations

of governmental organization. The top left quadrant is private contracting, which involves purely

market-based financial and personnel transactions. Private contractors are entitled to profits

earned from the provision of public services. The bottom right quadrant represents public

bureaucracy, which are staffed by public employees whose salaries are paid through budget

allocations. The top right corner capture certain kinds of state enterprises, in which employees

are not directly appointed by the government but are paid fixed wages regardless of the firm’s

performance. Oil companies in Mexico approximate this organizational form. Managers of these

companies face weak incentives to be entrepreneurial because they receive the same wages

whether or not more profits are earned.22 Finally, the bottom left corner is bureau-contracting,

which fuses market-based administrative financing with hierarchical personnel control. In a

22

I thank Alberto Diaz-Cayeros and Beatriz Magaloni for raising this point.

Market-Based Hierarchy-Based

Ma

rke

t-B

ase

d

Hie

rarc

hy-

Ba

sed

FINANCIAL RELATIONS P

ER

SON

NE

L R

ELA

TIO

NS

Certain forms of

public

enterprises

Private

Contracting

Bureau-

Contracting

Public

Bureaucracy

Page 45: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

33

bureau-contracting model, the service providers are state appointed employees, but

simultaneously, like private contractors, they have rights to profit from the provision of services

to the government.

From a financial perspective, bureau-contracting deviates from conventional models of public

administration insofar as public bureaucracies are assigned property rights over income earned.

As we will see in the Chinese case, each bureaucracy can legitimately retain all or a share of

income generated, in addition to receiving some budget allocation (and in some cases none at

all). Such additional income is generated in the course of conducting governmental functions,

e.g. regulation or public goods provision. In this sense, these bureaucracies behave partly like

contractors, or, in the historical sense, benefice holders.

In terms of personnel management, agents in a bureau-contracting model are public employees,

not private actors. In the Chinese context, the CCP exercises a strict organizational principle of

“party governs cadres” (dangguan ganbu). “Cadres” refer broadly to the functionaries serving in

the party-state organs, numbering over 40 million. China operates a unified system of cadre

management that encompasses all bureaucratic personnel, whether salaried or non-salaried. All

cadres possess bureaucratic rank (jibie), which determines one’s privileges and standing in the

hierarchy and allows the party to transfer cadres from place to place. The party directly appoints

cadres on the nomenklatura list who are at the chu rank and above. A rigorous system of

hierarchical personnel management distinguishes bureau-contracting from pure contracting and

prebendalism in early states.

In terms of physical structure, picture two ideal-types of state organization, as seen in Figure 2.2.

Model 1 represents an extreme example where all services are provided by an oversized state

bureaucracy. Socialist economies like the former Soviet Union come to mind. Under socialism,

the state collects taxes and then redistributes revenue to pay wages to salaried officials. Model

2 represents another extreme of a small state bureaucracy coupled with extensive contracting

of public services, which is typical of liberal market economies like in the United States. Model 3

illustrates the Chinese model, which diverges from the ideal types of Model 1 (big bureaucracy,

Page 46: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

34

no contracting) and Model 2 (small bureaucracy, extensive contracting). The Chinese model is

neither Model 1 nor 2 but a fusion of the two.

Figure 2.2: Varieties of State Organization

Having introduced bureau-contracting in a neo-institutional framework, I now proceed to

explain how it works concretely in the Chinese context. The four core elements are:

I. A bifurcated state structure composed of core bureaus and extrabureaucracies

The state bureaucracy in China is composed of two basic components: bureaus (jiguan danwei)

and extrabureaucracies (shiye danwei). In principle, bureaus (or literally translated as

administrative units) are responsible for administration and regulation, while

extrabureaucracies (or literally translated as service units) deliver public services. In every

governmental sector and at every level of government, a parent bureau manages a group of

extrabureaucracies and has micro-control over the latter’s operation, finances, and personnel

appointment. In reality, extrabureaucracies perform a range of tasks delegated to them by their

respective parent agency. Besides public services provision (e.g. in education and health care),

such tasks may involve enforcing administrative rules, collecting fees, and operating purely

commercial activities. Extrabureaucracies are most appropriately seen as the contracting arm of

the core bureaucracy.

Conventional Models of State Organization

MODEL 1

(Big Bureaucracy, No Contracting)

Bureaucracy

MODEL 2

(Small Bureaucracy, Extensive Contracting)

B

C

C

CC

C

China’s Model of State Organization

B

EB

EB

EBEB

EB

Page 47: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

35

II. Bureaucracies generate self-financed income beyond budget allocations

In addition to receiving varying sums of budget allocations that fund basic wages and

administrative costs, Chinese bureaucracies – by which, I refer collectively to core bureaus and

extrabureaucracies – also generate what I dub self-financed income. Such income comes from

several sources, e.g. fees and fines, user charges, and profits from commercialized operations.

Self-financed income belong to the category of non-tax revenue in China. Some are classified as

extrabudgetary funds.

III. Bureaucracies are empowered by policy awards to generate self-financed income

In order to generate self-financed income, e.g. to collect a particular fee, bureaucracies in China

require “policy awards” from the state that authorizes them to earn revenue. Policy awards may

be granted by the central ministries or by the local (usually provincial) governments. These are

mostly official documents that detail the rights of particular departments in collecting or

generating funds for a stipulated purpose. It is useful to think about policy awards as contracts

awarded by the government to public bureaucracies to provide certain services in exchange for

privileges to profit from office. I also extend the term policy awards to denote the clientelist

relationship between core bureaus and extrabureaucracies. In generating self-financed income,

extrabureaucracies typically need market protection from their parent agencies.

IV. Bureaucracies exercise de facto property rights self-financed income

Finally, I emphasize that individual bureaucracies exercise de facto property rights over revenue

earned. Self-financed income is deposited into the state treasury system. Individual offices then

apply to the finance bureau to spend their accumulated funds. Much of these funds go towards

providing staff wages and benefits.23 Therefore, the more self-financed income is raised, the

more benefits a bureaucracy can provide for its members. In this manner, each bureaucracy

retains the rights to appropriate self-financed income, while the finance authorities have

improved oversight over bureaucratic spending. My documentation here describes practices

23

I report systematic evidence for this claim in Chapter 4.

Page 48: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

36

that have developed since the mid-1990s, when modernizing budgetary reforms were

introduced. In the sections below, I shall discuss each of the elements in further detail, drawing

extensively upon field interviews and observations. Before I proceed, let me briefly introduce

the formal organizational structure in China.

The Formal Organizational Structure

The Chinese state is composed of five formal levels of government and three sets of hierarchies

that are replicated at each level. The five levels are center, province, city, county, and

township.24 The three sets of hierarchies are party, government, and military. The vertical

bureaucracies are known as lines (tiao) and the horizontal bodies as pieces (kuai). The

intersection of vertical and horizontal authorities forms a matrix structure (Lieberthal 2003).

Following the conventional literature, the state bureaucracy in this study refers only to party

and governmental organs, excluding the military and state-owned enterprises.25

China is termed a “party-state” because each level of government has a parallel set of party and

government organizations. At the central level, the leading party organization is the central

party committee, while the government bureaucracy is headed by the state council. At the sub-

national levels, the head of party and head of state corresponds to the local party committee

(dangwei) and government office (zhengfu bangongshi). As Lieberthal stressed, “the party

always exercises ultimate authority over its government counterpart” (2003, 172). The party

exercises ultimate authority through the power of appointment. The organization department, a

party organ with offices at every administrative level, appoints officials. The party secretary,

who leads the party committee, is always the “first-in-command,” while the head of the

governmental apparatus is typically the “second-in-command.”

24

As of 2000, China has 31 provincial-level governments (including Beijing, Shanghai, and Tianjin, which

are municipalities of provincial status), 660 cities, 2,461 counties, and 44,867 townships (Lieberthal 2003,

180-4). 25

Bureaucratic organizations should not be confused with state-owned enterprises, although the latter is

often seen as part of the “state.” In any government, public bureaucracies do not produce goods to sell on

the market; they are engaged in public service functions. Moreover, whereas SOEs are businesses that

pay taxes to the state treasury, public bureaucracies should in theory be fully funded by budget

appropriations.

Page 49: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

37

Figure 2.3: Organization Chart of Typical Local Government

Party Committee

Social Organizations

Pa

rty Co

mm

ittee

Se

creta

riat

Org

an

izatio

n D

ep

artm

en

t

Pro

pa

ga

nd

a D

ep

artm

en

t

Stra

teg

y D

ep

artm

en

t

Po

litical a

nd

Lega

l Affa

irs Co

mm

ittee

Disc

iplin

ary C

om

mitte

e

Co

mm

un

ist You

th L

ea

gu

e

All-W

om

en

’s Fe

de

ratio

n

Wo

rkers’ U

nio

n

Co

mm

erc

e U

nio

n

Fed

era

tion

for th

e H

an

dica

pp

ed

Asso

ciatio

n o

f Scie

nc

e

Government Office

De

velo

pm

en

t an

d R

efo

rm C

om

missio

n

Trad

e C

om

missio

n

Ed

uca

tion

Bu

rea

u

Scie

nce

& Te

ch

no

log

y Bu

rea

u

Eth

nic A

ffairs O

ffice

Pu

blic

Sec

urity B

ure

au

Civ

il Affa

irs Bu

rea

u

Leg

al A

ffairs B

ure

au

Fina

nc

e B

ure

au

So

cial Se

curity

Bu

rea

u

Co

nstru

ctio

n a

nd

Pla

nn

ing

Bu

rea

u

En

viron

me

nta

l Pro

tec

tion

Bu

rea

u

Tran

spo

rtatio

n B

ure

au

Wa

ter A

ffairs B

ure

au

Ag

ricu

lture

Bu

rea

u

Fam

ily P

lan

nin

g B

ure

au

Figure 2.3 illustrates a typical formal organizational chart of a county government. The county is

headed by the party committee, followed by the government office. Generally, party organs

control organizational, personnel, and propaganda functions. Governmental organizations are

responsible for administration, economic regulation, and social services provision. Organs like

the organization department and the disciplinary committee fall under the party committee.

Also included in the party apparatus are state-directed social organizations, such as the

communist youth league and national workers’ union. These organizations, though “social” in

name, are conduct political and ideological work for the CCP and are therefore part of the party

apparatus. Governmental organs include the finance bureau, civil affairs bureau, education

bureau, legal affairs bureau, development and reform commission, and so forth. Appendix A

provides a full list of county offices.

The formal organizational structure is replicated from the central to county levels. Each local

office shares a “professional relationship” (yewu guanxi) with the corresponding line authority

at the next higher level and a “leadership relationship” (lingdao guanxi) with the local

government. The upper line authority provides guidelines on administering a particular sector.

For example, the ministry of education issues guidelines on fee collections that percolate

through the hierarchy to the local education bureaus for implementation. However, it is the

local government, headed by the Party Committee and Government Office, which appoints

Page 50: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

38

officials to the respective offices and manages their finances. In most governmental sectors

(xitong), with the exception of a few vertically-managed offices, horizontal/leadership relations

dominate vertical/professional relations (Lieberthal & Oksenberg 1988).26

At the county levels and above, there exists fairly clear boundaries between offices; each office

administers a particular sector and is headed by a distinct group of executives. Township

governments, the lowest-tiered formal administration, have a simpler administrative structure,

with fewer offices that each take on multiple functions. In addition, townships have a much

smaller staff size than county and city governments. From the 1980s onwards and especially

after the 1994 fiscal reform, township governments, like bureaucracies at the upper levels,

relied heavily on extrabudgetary financing, in particular the exaction of fees and surcharges.

Starting in 2000, the central government introduced rural tax reforms, beginning with the tax-

for-fee reform (feigaishui) (Yep 2004; Kennedy 2007). In 2005, the state council announced

plans to abolish the agriculture tax nationwide. My analysis that follows, describing the behavior

and organization of individual offices, applies primarily to levels of government at the county

and above.

Element (I): Bureaucracies and Extrabureaucracies

Existing analyses of the Chinese bureaucracy have focused either on local governments as a

homogeneous whole or various offices that appear on formal organizational charts. But it is

useful to disaggregate the bureaucracy and look inside it. Each office is composed of two

composite parts: a small core bureaucracy and a sprawling periphery of extrabureaucracies.

Literally translated from Chinese, these organizations are “administrative units” (jiguan danwei)

and “service units” (shiye danwei). About 80 percent of public employment in China is

concentrated in the extrabureaucracies. Thus, shiye units are rightly described as “a big shadow

of the Chinese state” (Lam and Perry 2001, 20).

26

26

This is except in the case of “vertical management” (chuizhi guanli) (Mertha 2005). Since 1998,

several offices ordered by the central government to report to the upper-level administrative authority

(tiao) instead of the local government (kuai). Examples of vertically-managed offices include the customs

office, commerce bureau, weather offices. The majority of offices in China are still locally managed. See

Appendix A for a list of local governmental offices.

Page 51: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

39

Administrative units are those bureaucracies represented on formal state organizational charts,

as seen in Figure 2.3. As their name suggests, these bureaucracies perform the tasks of

administration and regulation. Administrative units include party organs (e.g. organization

department), governmental organs (e.g. finance bureau, legal affairs bureau, education bureau),

policing departments, as well as courts and procuratorates. Functionally, most administrative

units in China are not substantially different from state agencies found elsewhere. In this

analysis, I will refer to the administrative units as “core bureaus” or sometimes “parent

bureaus.”

Compared to the jiguan danwei, the shiye danwei is an ill-defined and oft-misunderstood entity.

The term shiye danwei has been translated variously into “business units” (Barnett 1967),

“institutional work units” (Cheng 2001; Wei-Arthus 2000), “government-funded not-for-profit

organizations” (Yang 2004), “a galaxy of public service providers alongside core government”

(OECD 2006, 81), “nonprofit and nonregulatory” units, and “public service units” (World Bank

2005). I choose to translate shiye danwei analytically as extrabureaucracies.27 This translation

captures the principal feature shared among all shiye danwei – they are attached and

subservient to a core bureau. Each core bureau supervises a group of extrabureaucracies and

exercises micro control over the latter. To illustrate, Table 2.1 lists the bureaus and

extrabureaucracies in a typical local (provincial, city, and county) government. For the remaining

analysis, my use of the term bureaucracy/office/department implies a collective unit of core

bureau and extrabureaucracies.

In theory, extrabureaucracies should not have regulatory powers or profit-making motives

(Cheng 2001). But it is important to separate theory from reality. As Lam and Perry aptly

described, extrabureaucracies “only provide services to their administrative bosses” (2001, 27).

Those services may be public or private in nature. In practice, extrabureaucracies may

administer, organize public services, run businesses, or all of the above (see Table 2.1 for

27

The term “extrabureaucracies” was earlier used by Chinese historians to describe local elites and tax

farmers who performed state services but who were not formal civil servants (Rankin 1993). I review the

historical literature in Chapter 5.

Page 52: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

40

examples).28 Extrabureaucracies include conventional public service providers like public schools

and public hospitals. They also include amorphous entities engaged in administrative

enforcement and semi-or-pure commercial activities, e.g. price assessment center and driving

schools. Table 2 in Appendix A lists the extrabureaucracies under selected agencies in a local

government.

Table 2.1: Examples of Functions and Fiscal Status of Extrabureaucracies (Shiye Danwei)

Administrative Functions

(xingzheng guanli)

Organize Public Services

(youchang/wuchang gongyi)

Runs Businesses

(yingyexing)

Party member center (full)

Cement office (self)

Office for the reform of

construction materials (self)

Office for legal verification of

documents (self)

Labor market center (full)

Agency for the inspection of

construction safety (self)

Environmental inspection team

(full)

Price assessment center (self)

Public schools (full)

Public hospitals and clinics

(partial)

Disease prevention center (full)

Old folk services center (self)

Natural gas company (self)

Street lights management bureau

(partial)

X park management bureau (self)

Sports center (partial)

Sports association (full)

X city conference center (self)

(run by the trade bureau)

Center for driving instruction

(self) (by transportation bureau)

X city resort (self) (by housing

bureau)

Car rental fleet (self) (by

reception bureau)

Translation services center (self)

(by foreign service bureau)

Limited Scope of the Civil Service System

Now that we have drawn the divide between the core bureaucracy and extrabureaucracies, we

may better understand the scope and implications of the Chinese civil service system. The

Chinese government enacted the civil service law in 2005, thereby establishing a formal civil

service. The law defines the functions of civil servants, guarantees them the right to receive

state-budgeted wages, and delineates rules on recruitment, assessment, promotion, dismissal,

as well as other legal rights and obligations.

28

Take for example the legal assistance center, a shiye danwei under the legal affairs bureau. The legal

assistance center provides public services in the form of legal assistance for the poor. At the same time, it

exercises administrative power by requiring law firms to perform pro bono services, an essential condition

for licensing approval. To earn additional income, some legal assistance centers may offer litigation

services for a charge (AI 2007-35).

Page 53: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

41

While the civil service law presents a major breakthrough in China’s bureaucratization efforts,

one would be mistaken to think that China has successfully established a regular salaried

bureaucracy with a piece of legislation. The civil service law remains limited in scope. It applies

only to those cadres with an official administrative position (xingzheng bianzhi), personnel who

usually hold leading positions in the bureaucracy. Only these cadres are titled civil servants

(gongwuyuan). The remaining employees are known as service-unit employees (shiye danwei

renyuan). Nationwide, I was told that there were only about 600,000 civil servants out of 48

million public employees in 2005 (AI 2007-138).29 The central government imposes a strict quota

and entry requirements on the civil service, including competitive entry examinations.

Extrabureaucracies, State-Owned Enterprises, and Bureau-Operated Companies

Extrabureaucracies should be distinguished from state-owned enterprises (SOEs), collective

enterprises, and township and village owned enterprises (TVEs). The latter are state-owned

firms involved in production and are supposed to generate revenue. They do not receive budget

allocations from the government (although they may receive financial bailouts when losses are

incurred); instead, they are required to surrender their profits to the level of government at

which they operate to finance public expenditure. In contrast to the SOEs and TVEs,

extrabureaucracies are public organizations engaged in services provision. In theory, they should,

like public providers elsewhere, receive regular budget allocations from the state and not

pursue profits.

Extrabureaucracies are not the same as bureau-operated companies, although the two are

sometimes confused in the literature.30 Bureau-operated companies proliferated in the 1980s

and early 1990s (Duckett 1998). Shortly after the central leadership signaled the green light to

“get rich,” agencies and extrabureaucracies plunged into a mad rush to set up their own

corporate entities, variously named “jingji shiti (economic subsidiaries), gongsi (companies), or

29

The total number of public employees is reported in the Local Public Financial Statistics (Difang

Caizheng Tongji), published by the Ministry of Finance. 30

For example, Duckett observed that the ‘property companies’ within the real estate management

bureau in Tianjin “have existed for years as ‘administrative companies,’ meaning that they are non-profit

making units that function as part of the state administration” (1998, 107). Given her description, the

company she was referring to was probably a shiye unit, rather than a bureau-operated firm.

Page 54: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

42

sanchan (tertiary sector undertakings)” (Lin & Zhang 1999, 205). Lin and Zhang (1999) gave

these entities the fitting title of “backyard profit centers.” Examples of bureau-operated firms

cited in the literature included restaurants, canteens, dance halls, convention centers, printing

shops, small trading companies, and department stores (Duckett 1998; Blecher 1991; Park et al

1996; Lin and Zhang 1999). The particular phenomenon of bureaucracies going into business is

commonly labeled state entrepreneurism (Blecher 1991; Duckett 1998; Duckett 2001).

Importantly, the kind of entrepreneurism seen in “bureaucrats in business, Chinese-style”

(Duckett 2001) should be distinguished from entrepreneurism under bureau-contracting. First,

bureau-operated businesses were a new product of the reform era. These companies belonged

to the non-state sector, even though they were invested by party-state organs at the township

levels and above. As Duckett pointed out, “they have been neither planned nor anticipated by

central government policy makers” (2001, 23). Extrabureaucracies, in contrast, were an essential

part of the state even under the command economy. They have been existed, alongside core

agencies, since the 1950s (see Chapter 5 on the state structure under Maoist rule). Second, all

extrabureaucracies operate only in the services sectors regulated by their parent bureaus,

whereas corporate entities could be engaged in any business and sector, including in

manufacturing.31 As Duckett noted, “sometimes the businesses [established by state organs]

were related to the administrative work of the parent department, but many conducted

unrelated business” (1998, 26, emphasis added). The distinction drawn here is analytically

important because, as Duckett observed, bureau-operated companies were “profit-making, risk-

taking businesses” that could make losses (1998, 14). Extrabureaucracies, on the other hand, do

not normally incur losses. Most of them enjoy competitive advantages or even monopoly rights

vis-à-vis non-state services providers.

Although bureau-operated businesses prevailed in the earlier stages of reform, most have gone

bust or been divested in the post-1990s period (Yang 2004). One reason for the widespread

closure of these businesses was central state policy. The former premier Zhu Rongji made it a

priority during his tenure to divest party-state organs of their businesses, as they were seen to

31

As emphasized in Chapter 3, extrabureaucracies are the contracting and not just revenue-making arm

of the core bureaucracy.

Page 55: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

43

hamper market development and feed corruption. Another reason for the demise of bureau-

operated businesses was increased market competition. State bureaus have few strengths

compared to private entrepreneurs in running businesses beyond their exclusive regulatory

fields.32 As Hubbard (1995) rightly predicted, bureau-operated businesses will decline over time

“as market development reduces the competitive advantage of government agencies in

business” (350).

Yet, although bureau-operated businesses have largely evaporated from the market, we would

be mistaken to think that entrepreneurism in the Chinese bureaucracy is a thing of the past.

Bureaucrats in China remain highly entrepreneurial. In my interviews with them, Chinese

officials are constantly strategizing for new ways to finance their offices.33 I would argue that

from the mid-1990s, monetary strategies in the bureaucracy have shifted from running backyard

profit centers to bureau-contracting. I would argue that generating revenue through extra-

bureaucracies and by extracting monies in accordance to state policies has become the

dominant and smarter strategy for bureaus to “get along and ahead” financially. In the next

section, we proceed to introduce these monetary strategies. The documentation that follows is

based on the most recent institutional developments.34

Element (II): Budget Allocations vs. Self-Financed Income

Both in theory and in practice, Chinese bureaucracies are not purely salaried. In theory, core

bureaus (jiguan danwei) should be fully state-funded units, while extrabureaucracies (shiye

danwei) are divided into three fiscal categories: fully-funded, partially-funded, and self-funded.

Fully-funded (quane bokuan) units receive full state funding for their basic budgetary needs;

partially-funded (chae bokuan) units receive some financial subsidies; and lastly, self-funded

32

Lacking management expertise, many agencies could not generate sustainable profits from restaurants,

dance halls, and small factories. For example, many factories operated by public schools have closed

down because they were operated by school principals and teachers who were not professional

entrepreneurs (AI 2007-123). 33

To cite another example, in a case study of China’s party schools, organizations that are supposed to

provide ideological training for cadres, Lee (2009) reports that money-making remains a high priority for

the leadership. 34

I conducted fieldwork from 2006 to 2009.

Page 56: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

44

units (zishou zizhi) receive none. Table 2.2 shows examples of extrabureaucracies by funding

type.

Table 2.2: Cross-Tabulation of Public Employees, 2003

(Percentage over total indicated in parenthesis)

Receive state

funding

Entirely Self-

funded

TOTAL

Core bureaucracy

(jiguan danwei)

8,926,450 96,733 9,023,183

(19.4%)

Extrabureaucracies

(shiye danwei)

35,199,835 2,312,272 37,512,107

(80.6%)

TOTAL

44,126,285

(94.8%)

2,409,005

(5.2%)

46,535,290

Source: Local Public Financial Statistics

Budget allocations usually cover only essential budgetary needs, not benefits and frills. As one

finance bureau official expressed colorfully, “budget allocations are used to deliver coals during

snow, not to add blossoms to silk” (AI 2008-154). Hence, being “fully-funded” does not mean

that all of a unit’s expenses are covered by state revenue. Typically, “full state funding” covers

basic operational costs and staff wages.35 Thus, even units that are fully-funded in name, like

public schools and regulatory agencies, are not relieved of financial stress. Furthermore, it is not

unusual for units that are fully-funded or partially-funded in name receive no budget allocations

in fact. For example, I encountered a city-level tourism bureau that was supposed to be a fully-

funded regulatory agency, but was in fact entirely self-financed until 2001 (AI 2007-108).

Similarly, a metallurgy institute was entitled to partial state subsidies, but was forced to find its

own means when the metallurgy bureau, its parent agency, was abolished (AI 2007-111).

For bureaucracies in China to give out staff bonuses, allowances, and benefits not financed by

the local government, or to buy cars and construct new office buildings, they would have to find

their “own money,” as we saw in the example of Blossom county’s land bureau. The “own

35

Basic cadre wages are standardized across the country and hence low in well-off places. Chapter 3

explains the wage structure in further detail.

Page 57: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

45

money” refers to revenue earned by and belonging to individual bureaucracies. For short, I label

them self-financed income.

Sources of self-financed income

There are several different sources of self-financed income. (i) Administrative and regulatory

fees, (ii) fines, (iii) revenue from governmental foundations (jijin) that require contributions from

businesses, (iv) user charges from services provision (shiye shouru), (v) profits from commercial

activities (yingye shouru). Examples of shiye income are school fees, medical charges, and ticket

sales from performances. These are revenue collected from providing governmental services.

Yingye income may include revenue from leasing a piece of state property. In practice, the line

between shiye income and yingye income is blurred.

Self-financed income, non-tax revenue, and extrabudgetary funds

Self-financed income are a part of non-tax revenue category. The two major categories of

revenue in the Chinese fiscal system are tax revenue (shuishou) and non-tax revenue (feishui

shouru). Non-tax revenue is sometimes synonymous with extrabudgetary funds, but a

distinction needs to be made between the two. Non-tax revenue is classified as within-

budgetary funds (yusuan shouru) if they are deposited in the state treasury account (guoku

zhanghu) at each level of government and managed through regular budgetary procedures.

Non-tax revenue is classified as extra-budgetary funds (yusuanwai zijin) if they are deposited in

the extrabudgetary special account (yusuanwai zhuanhu) and are not managed through regular

budgetary procedures, e.g. the budget does not have to be submitted to and approved by the

state legislature.

A common source of confusion in analyzing Chinese fiscal data is that budgetary categories have

changed over time and constantly. It is not surprising to find that budgets are reported

differently across provinces and levels of government. For example, at Blossom county, finance

officials no longer speak of within-budgetary versus extra-budgetary funds. To them, the

appropriate terms are tax revenue and non-tax revenue (AI 2007-115; 2007-116; 2007-117;

Page 58: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

46

2007-118). However, in the finance yearbooks published by the ministry of finance and th7

Shandong financial bureau, the budget is still divided into within-budgetary funds and extra-

budgetary funds (for example, see Caizheng Nianjian in the various years).

For non-experts, it suffices to know that self-financed income collected by individual

bureaucracies at each level of government are a subset of non-tax revenue. They may be

classified as within-budgetary or extra-budgetary funds, depending on the rules periodically

issued by the ministry of finance. It should also be noted that not all non-tax revenue belong to

individual bureaucracies. Some sources of non-tax revenue belong collectively to the local

governments, e.g. township and village self-raised funds and proceeds from leasing state land.

Interestingly, it appears that all bureaucracies make some self-financed income, even in

localities with well-endowed finances. When I asked a local finance official whether there were

any purely state-financed bureaus in the county, he responded (AI 2007-115):

“Pure” ones? Almost none…

Organizations in the judicial system [e.g. courts] should be pure… but wait…

actually, even they are not completely pure.

Well, then are those in the party committee and local governmental office; their

financial needs are guaranteed… But then again, those are not entirely pure too.

So how do bureaucracies generate self-financed income? Importantly, the central and local

governments have an interest in seeing that the bureaucracies can be sufficiently self-funded

without resort to extortion or illegal activities. Hence, the state assigns bureaucracies policy

awards – that is, revenue-making privileges. As one official expressed, “Even if [the state] does

not give them [the bureaucracies] money, it will give them an avenue to make wealth” (AI 2007-

129). In the next section, we will discuss what these avenues are and how they function.

Element (III): Policy Awards

As a popular saying in China goes, “the state may not be able to grant money, but it can grant

policies” (geizhengce bugeiqian). What does this mean? A local official fittingly explained,

Page 59: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

47

“Giving policies and not money happens when the government wants to get something done

but budgetary funds are insufficient… Whether it is to give money or policies, the objective is to

serve the people… But of course we cannot rule out the possibility of individual departments

seeking their own interests” (AI 2008-153). To put it simply, policy awards are privileges

assigned by the government to various departments to generate funds in lieu of budget

allocations. Importantly, such funds are generated in the name of public services provision, as

the quote above emphasized; they should therefore be distinguished from illegal monies (Lu

2000a, 2000b) and profits earned from business operations unrelated to party-state functions

(Duckett 1998).

Policy awards can come from three sources: i) the central governmental authority (usually the

State Council), (ii) central-level Ministries, and (iii) local governmental authorities. Central-level

ministries and provincial governments enact policy awards that will apply at all levels of

government. Sub-provincial governments can then “employ [policy] decisions by upper levels

with flexibility” (AI 2008-155). For example, the Anhui provincial government allowed public

schools to admit students on a tuition-paying basis, but the condition was that fee-paying

students could not compose more than 70 percent of the student population (AI 2008-153).36 A

local official explained, “Privately admitted students pay more fees… This is one kind of policy…

Revenue collected from this policy goes to the public schools, but it needs to be within a zone

approved by the upper levels” (AI 2008-153). In another example, the Jiangsu provincial

government allowed tax bureaus to earn commissions from tax collections. The county

governments may then adjust the commission rate based on local economic conditions (AI

2007-112). It appears then that policies devised by upper level authorities powerfully shape

local bureaucratic behavior. Although many depict local agents as persistently defiant of central

policies, local authorities reflected that they are in fact “constantly waiting for instructions from

above” (AI 2007-52).

I extend the concept of policy awards to capture revenue-making ties between core bureaus and

extrabureaucracies. Core bureaus and extrabureaucracies share a special kind of clientelist

36

Tuition-paying students were initially capped at 70 percent of the student population; the ratio has

recently been reduced to 30 percent (AI 2008-154).

Page 60: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

48

relationship. In the original anthropological sense, clientelism is “an exchange relationship… a

special case of dyadic (two-person) ties… in which an individual of higher socioeconomic status

(patron) uses his own influence and re- sources to provide protection or benefits, or both, for a

person of lower status (client) who, for his part, reciprocates by offering general support and

assistance, including personal services, to the patron” (Scott 1972, 92).

In the Chinese state, the core bureau is like a patron and the extrabureaucracies the clients. The

two entities share a hierarchical relationship. Core bureaus exercise absolute control over their

extrabureaucracies: the former appoints leading positions and mid-level cadres in the latter;

revenue from the state is allocated by the supervising agency to extrabureaucracies; and the

core bureau assigns tasks to its subsidiaries (Lam and Perry 2001, 35). Simultaneously, the two

entities share an exchange relationship. Often, parent bureaus provide their extrabureaucracies

advantageous market access, while extrabureaucracies share their revenue with the parent

agency.

Appropriately, as relations are so tightly enmeshed, leaders of extrabureaucratic units often

refer to their supervising agency in familial terms as “father,” “mother,” or “mother-in-law”

during my interviews with them. Uniquely, however, the clientelist relationship described is not

shared between individuals, but rather between organizations in the same hierarchy. That is to

say, even if a particular bureau chief were replaced, the core bureau and extrabureaucracies

would continue to share the same patronage ties. That implies that the relationship between

core bureaus and extrabureaucracies is not the result of individual manipulation, but rather an

enduring feature of the Chinese state structure.

In the following sections, I will give examples of four major policy awards. Taken together, they

illustrate how bureaucracies in various sectors generate self-financed income in accordance to

state policies, as well as the clientelist relations between core bureaus and extrabureaucracies

in self-financing.

• Policies sanctioning the exaction of fees and fines

• Monopoly privileges

Page 61: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

49

• Permission for public providers to sell their services and make profits

• Permission for public units to form and generate revenue from spin offs

Policies sanctioning the exaction of fees and fines

Bureaucratic predation has been a long-standing problem in China since reforms began. State

agencies were infamous for the “three arbitraries” (sanluan): arbitrary taxation, arbitrary fines,

and arbitrary expropriation (Wedeman 2002, 492). Lu observed that agencies typically exacted

payments “without clear legal mandates” (Lu 2000a, 276). In township and village governments,

sanluan was a major source of peasant burdens and protests (Bernstein & Lu 2003). These

earlier studies rightly described problems that prevailed in the 1980s and 1990s, particularly

after fiscal recentralization in 1994 reduced local governmental revenues.

The good news is, in the last decade, many rationalizing institutional improvements have been

made in the Chinese administration, as documented in Yang’s (2004) study on central reformers’

efforts to “remake the state.” To be clear, fee-and-fine taking has not been abolished in China;

in fact, fees and fines remain an important source of self-financed income for state bureaus. But,

as I observe during recent fieldwork, fee-and-fine taking has become increasingly rules-based,

regulated, and even quite sophisticated, including in the townships. This is especially so

following the enactment of the administrative licensing law (xingzheng xukefa) in 2004, which

provides a national legal framework for the collection of regulatory fees. As these local officials

reveal:

Nowadays fee-taking by various departments is very strictly regulated. The price

bureau and respective departments have to issue a fee taking license (shoufei

xukezheng), indicating the fees that can be taken and the ones that cannot (AI

2008-154).

The [township] governments have undergone tremendous change. Nowadays

arbitrary fee taking and arbitrary fines are gone; fee taking activities have been

regularized… In some instances, public bureaus, for example, the electricity

bureau, even have to enlist the assistance of courts in collecting fees (AI 2008-

146).

Page 62: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

50

As local officials explained, policy awards sanctioning the collection of fees and fines range from

“soft” to “hard” (AI 2007-127; AI 2007-128). According to the administrative licensing law, the

hardest policies are central and local licensing (xuke) provisions. Licensing provisions must have

a clear legal justification for collecting fees and fines. Licensing provisions require a one-year

probation period before they are deliberated at the central or local state legislature (i.e. the

People’s Congress). These provisions become permanent only after they are passed. The next

softer set of provisions are assessment (shenpi) provisions. These are provisions not yet passed

by the legislature but are still legally valid. Last but not least, the softest policies are “red-

headed documents” (hongtou wenjian), named after the bright red department stamp on the

letterhead of official Chinese documents. These are rules issued by regulatory agencies without

higher-level or legislative endorsement. “Some departments issue red-headed documents,

asking for this or that matter to be approved by them. This is fine, but it cannot be brought on

the table because it does not have an explicit legal basis” (AI 2007-128).

The best example of a hard policy award backing the collection of fees and fines is the notorious

case of the steamed bun offices in Zhengzhou city of Henan province. Zhengzhou city

established a steamed bun office at the city level and five in each of the county governments

below. And what do steam bun offices do? City authorities articulated a need to establish

specialized offices to manage steam buns production. The city government issued Provision No.

93, titled “Temporary Provisions on Zhengzhou City’s Steamed Buns Production and Sales

Management.” The provision was passed by the city government’s 14th People’s Congress and

signed by the mayor.

Article 1 proclaimed that “this provision is established in accordance with our country’s laws and

regulations, as well as our city’s practical conditions.” Its lofty goals were “to strengthen the

production and sales management of steamed buns, to promote their mechanized production,

to guarantee the health of our people, and to make the lives of our people more convenient.”

The rest of the provision proceeded to spell out two basic functions of steamed bun offices: to

issue a steamed bun production permit and to fine producers for not possessing the permit. The

legal provision carefully detailed the amount and purpose for which each fee or fine is imposed.

Page 63: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

51

According to the provision, one could be fined from 3,000 to 20,000 yuan for producing steamed

buns without a permit.

The story of Zhengzhou’s steamed bun offices usefully illustrates the network of rules that

authorize fee collections. In order to exact fees and fines, local offices require endorsements

from multiple formal institutions. To legalize fee and fines collection, the local leadership must

enact and pass a state provision through the legislature. To establish a specialized office and

hire employees, the establishment office has to give consent. The price bureau has to issue a fee

taking license. Without these policy awards, the steamed bun office would not be in business.37

Monopoly privileges

When we think about public monopolies, big monopolies like telecommunications and oil come

to mind. However, small-scaled public monopolies have been overlooked. Many

extrabureaucracies in China thrive on having considerable market advantages or monopoly

rights in the supply of public and commercial services.38 Some examples of such services are

utilities supply, greening, tour agencies, media publications, private security, administration of

examinations, and environmental impact assessment. Extrabureaucracies feed on

“administrative protection” (xingzheng baohu) provided by the parent bureaus. Such protection

may come in the form of explicit legal provisions or through the covert exercise of political

influence (for case studies, see Lin and Zhang 1999; Lam & Perry 2001).39 I illustrate my findings

below.

37

The steamed bun office is not an isolated case. There was also the notorious case of the watermelon

offices. See “Steamed bun offices, watermelon offices… are all troublesome offices,” Xinhua, August 4

2006.” 38

Some bureau-operated businesses also enjoyed monopolistic advantages (Lin and Zhang 1999). But, as

Yang (2004) reported, many of these businesses, especially those belonging to the military and law

enforcement organs, have been forcibly closed by the central government. 39

Other studies also reported examples of administrative bureaus extending monopoly privileges to

extrabureaucracies. The personnel ministry and local personnel bureaus grant the talent exchange

centers the exclusive right to process visa applications and the examination centers the lucrative business

of administering professional examinations. The environmental research institute under the

environmental protection bureau is one of the few organizations authorized to conduct environmental

impact assessment, and “due to its special relationship with the bureau, it naturally enjoys an unrivaled

advantage in the competition for business” (Lam & Perry 2001, 34).

Page 64: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

52

Heating supply is one example of a public monopoly service. Heating services for residential and

commercial properties must be centrally supplied. According to the “The Tianjin City Centralized

Heating Management Regulations,” issued by the city government, the local heating offices

plans and organizes the supply of heat. In one particular county, the construction bureau (the

parent bureau) described the heating office as its “the greasiest” extrabureaucracy. The heating

office collects 20 yuan for every square meter of property for which heat is supplied. When

asked about the profits of the office, the bureau official responded nonchalantly, “Yes [they can

make hundreds of thousands]. Even 10 million dollars a year is not a problem” (AI 2008-144).

The interviewee added that the forestry bureau, with its subordinated greening offices, is just as

“greasy” because “[the service of] greening roads and highways belongs entirely to them” (AI

2008-144). Another described the monopoly situation as follows, “The forestry bureau regulates

greening. It can say ‘you cannot touch this tree,’ but then they can touch it themselves” (AI

2007-106).

Even in the tourism business, extrabureaucracies commanded market advantages. In Jiangsu

province, a city-level tourism bureau was an entirely self-funded agency up until 2001. Since its

establishment, the tourism bureau had lived on remissions of revenue from its

extrabureaucracies, which included tour agencies, hotels, car, and boat rental companies. Up

until the late 1990s, public units in the tourism sector were profitable because there were

plenty of new market opportunities and limited competition simultaneously. As the head of the

tour agency explained:

We still continue to share revenue with our parent bureaus… We give it to them

directly, and then they refund it to us… There is some degree of monopoly

involved. For example, the tourism bureau approves tour agent permits

[author’s note: and by implication, it can decide to whom to give these permits].

Sometimes, administrative agencies exercise “soft” influence, rather than hard regulatory power,

in supporting their extrabureaucracies’ business. I give an example from the education sector. In

a county of Jiangsu province, the education bureau had recently established a youth science

center, a science expo for children. The county state budget paid only one-third of the center’s

costs. The remaining income came from fee-charging extracurricular courses offered by Center.

The Center charged 200 yuan for class and paid its instructors 50 yuan an hour, less than the

Page 65: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

53

market rate. Surprised by the low fees and teachers’ pay, I quizzed the director during dinner

about his pricing strategy. The director explained that his plan was to offer high-quality courses

at a low price.

Still, another question remains: why would good teachers choose to work at his center if the pay

was not competitive? The director responded that he had already “made a verbal pact with the

public school principals to send their best teachers” to the Center (AI 2007-121). “[The teachers]

have to give the principals face, right?” In fact, I was told that at another nearby county, public

teachers were mandated to teach at the local Youth Center for only 20 yuan an hour and were

barred from offering classes at home (AI 2007-122). “We are more flexible,” said the director,

“the teachers can teach at our place and build up their reputation, and then they can hold

private lessons.” The vice-director chimed in, “The teachers gain both reputation and money

(mingli shuangshou).” Beaming with pride, the center director unveiled his true business

strategy:

The Culture Center [another extrabureaucracy under the Cultural Bureau] and

the Joyful Tots Education Company hate us to death! Our two thousand

students all came from them! Right now, I can depress the prices, and when

these companies disappear, I can raise the prices.”

The education bureau head, who was also at the banquet, added that “Mr. Li [the director] has a

hard purse” and “the state treasury behind him” (AI 2007-119). That means, should the director

need aid, the education bureau would not abandon him to his own means. Hearing these words,

executives of the youth center immediately toasted the bureau head, thanking him profusely for

his support. The hidden script is that without the bureau’s backing, the school principals would

not have offered the center their best teachers. In fact, without the bureau’s patronage, many

things could not have been done at the center.

Permission for public providers to sell their services and make profits

Public service providers, like public hospitals and schools, are supposed to provide essential

social services free or affordably. Unfortunately, that has not been the case in China’s public

health sector. In the post-Mao period, the public health care system has been financed by the

Page 66: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

54

strategy of “giving policies not money.” Under socialism, health care was heavily subsidized by

the government. The year of 1985 marked a turning point. The State Council approved and

issued a report by the Ministry of Health, entitled “Notice on the Policies of Health Care

Reform.”40 The report emphasized the need to incentivize health care providers and to push

them to become “financially self responsible.” It wrote, “the prices charged for the provision of

health care services have been too low. This is not advantageous for the development of health

care services… [henceforth] public providers may set fees to reflect their costs.” In effect, the

1985 document gave public hospitals and clinics the green light to charge consumers and make

profits.

After granting health care providers the right to charge fees, the state began to cut back on

budgetary allocations for the health care sector. In Jiangsu province, the proportion of public

wages funded by budget allocations fell from 60 percent in 1985 to 31 percent in 1988. At the

national level, state budget allocations as a share of total revenue in the health care sector

dropped from one-third in 1980 to one-quarter in 1990.41 In recent years, the reliance of public

health care providers on user fees has grown even sharper (World Bank 2006). For example, a

city-level hospital in Chongqing I had interviewed was “weaned” of all state funding and became

entirely self-funded by 2007 (AI 2007-32). Ironically then, this was a major public service

provider with no public funding.

Forced to finance themselves, public health care providers turned to their most important

source of revenue: selling drugs and medication. Public hospitals could mark up the price of

drugs by 15 percent. Why not improve medical services and charge higher fees instead? The

answer is that the central government did not authorize charging high fees for medical services.

And why not? As one interviewee explained, the formal wages of white collar workers, including

medical providers, are still suppressed in China. “This has to do with communist ideology. If a

doctor makes thousands of dollars more than an ordinary worker, how is that acceptable?” (AI

2007-46).

40

“Notice on problems related to health care reform policy” (Guowuyuan pizhuan weishengbu guanyu

weisheng gaige ruogan wenti baogaode tongzhi), Report by the Ministry of Health and approved by the

State Council, Issued April 25 1985. 41

“1985: The Year Health Care Reforms Began,” Zhejiang Health Bureau Website,

http://www.zjwst.gov.cn, accessed on July 1, 2008.

Page 67: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

55

The particular combination of incentives and restrictions produced a perverse strategy of

revenue maximization: maximizing the volume and sale price of drugs. This strategy is described

by some health care experts as “provider-induced overconsumption” (Zhang and Gu 2006) or

more popularly known as “using drugs to feed public health” (yiyao yangyi). As a result of this

revenue-maximizing strategy, Chinese patients have found health care prohibitive, not primarily

due to expensive services, but because doctors too often prescribed more medicine than

needed.

Public hospitals not only charge fees and profit from selling drugs, they enjoy an implicit degree

of protection from competition. Private hospitals in China are few compared to public

providers.42 There are two reasons for the lackluster development of private health care

providers. One is difficulties faced in obtaining required licenses, and two, unlike public

providers, private providers are typically not included in the national health insurance system.

Consumers are unwilling to seek medical services in private hospitals if their expenses cannot be

reimbursed. The head of a private hospital in Beijing lamented:43

Private hospitals, like public hospitals, carry the mission of saving patients. We

provide the same quality services and suffer the same burden of owed

payments as public hospitals. But we do not enjoy the state’s beneficial policies.

And we even have to pay taxes. These have sharpened the challenges of survival

and development for private health care providers.

In fact, local health officials may have interests fending off not only private providers, but also

public providers from other well-off Chinese provinces. Fearing competition, health bureau

officials in a Jiangsu city barred leading public hospitals from Shanghai from setting up a branch

in their territory. A local official conceded that it was no wonder that the quality of medical

services has lagged behind the city’s economic prosperity (AI 2007-104).

Permission for public units to form and generate revenue from spin-offs

42

Nationwide, the number of private service suppliers (minban feiqiye) are one-tenth that of public

providers (World Bank 2005). 43

“Hospital executives urge government to create health assistance fund,” Zhongguo Qingnianbao,

January 15 2008

Page 68: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

56

With the enactment of the nine-year compulsory education law in 1986, public elementary and

middle schools in China should be fully state-funded and are therefore not allowed to collect

tuition. But in most localities, there are insufficient funds to finance all public schools. On top of

that, high-ranking “key-point schools” (zhongdian xuexiao) face pressures from the leadership to

build new campuses, and local governments provide limited financial support for these “luxury”

goals. Confronting these circumstances, a set of policy awards emerged in the late 1990s that

authorized public schools to earn additional revenue without having to collect tuition.

The first strategy for revenue-making is to collect “premiums,” i.e. additional payment for

premier education services. Such premiums take two forms. First, the “school leasing fee”

(jiedufei), paid by students who are not formally registered as residents of the locality.44 Second,

the “school selection fee” (zexiaofei), paid by students who seek to gain admission into a

particular school, but who lack a sufficiently high entrance examination score or live outside a

designated geographic range. These premiums run from several thousands to tens of thousands

a year. For example, a key-point elementary school in Chengdu city of Sichuan province charged

a “selection premium” of 45,000 yuan for six years of study, a substantial sum for the average

household. Yet, even at this high price, parents “elbowed to gain admission” into the key-point

schools (AI 2007-44).

While it appears that the policies on premium collections are usually local knowledge, they are

sometimes publicized by the local government. In Hefei city of Anhui province, the city

government issued a public statement that set a ceiling on the collection of premiums and

tuition by public schools.45 Elementary and middle schools may collect 400 and 600 yuan

respectively each term in “school leasing fee.” Public high schools may collect up to 3,500 yuan

for “school leasing” and 3,000 yuan for “school selection” each term. The statement also listed

the titles of the documents issued by the price bureau approving the collection of those fees.

A second strategy of revenue-making is for key-point schools to spin-off private schools. These

have been called “restructured schools” (gaizhi xuexiao), “privately run, publicly assisted

44

It is still not easy for ordinary citizens to transfer their household registration status (hukou) in present-

day China. 45

“Hefei City Education Bureau’s List of Fee Collections,” Hefei Education Network (Hefei Jiaoyu

Xinxiwang), http://www.hfjy.net.cn/, accessed on April 21, 2008.

Page 69: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

57

schools” (minban gongzhi), “a school within a school” (xiaozhongxiao), “private schools run by

famous schools” (mingxiaoban minxiao). And what are they? In short, an interviewee explained,

“[public] schools that charge fees!” She added, “the nine-year compulsory education policy

forbids public schools from charging fees, but these schools are exempted from this policy” (AI

2007-44).

Here is an example (AI 2008-148). Mega High is the best public school in a county of Tianjin. In

1998, Mega established Stellar School, a private school admitting middle and high school

students at a charge of 3,000 yuan each year. With its affiliation to Mega, the spun-off private

school enjoyed a steady recruitment. The familial relationship between the two schools was

evident. The director of Stellar was the principal of Mega. Stellar shared its revenue with Mega.

The two schools shared the same teachers, who receive budgetary allocations from the city

government for their wages. They also shared the same campus, with Stellar fenced up to

separate the two schools symbolically. Lastly, they shared the same boss – the education bureau.

“As you know,” an interviewee summed up, “China’s so-called private schools are different from

those abroad. There are private schools abroad, but all of ours have a state character” (AI 2007-

151).

Political intervention lies behind the hybrid strategy of school financing. The ability of key-point

schools to generate revenue is premised upon an unequal distribution of resources across public

schools in a district. The more unequal the quality of local public schools, the more parents are

induced to pay premiums to enter into good ones. The local education bureau arranges for key-

point schools to pick the best teachers and students before others (AI 2007-44). The advantage

of key-point schools allows them to attract a huge demand for admission, which leads in turn to

over-population and demand for larger campuses, a situation that one principal ironically calls

“a virtuous cycle” (AI 2006-23).

Local governmental leaders also pressured school leaders to conduct lavish remodeling projects,

as they can claim credit for investing in public education. Thus, key-point schools are often

forced to take on sometimes unsustainable loans. An executive in a key-point school revealed,

“We took on a loan of 125 million, with interests of 20 million, which must be repaid by 2010.

Page 70: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

58

This is where it is unreasonable! ‘Build model schools! Create a conducive environment for

education!’ [so we were told] It was the education bureau that made us take the loan, but the

loan is made in the school’s name” (AI 2008-148). It is no wonder then that even a foreign visitor

would have few difficulties distinguishing lavish key-point schools from ordinary ones.

Unintentionally, then, premium school financing feeds into education inequality and vice versa.

The ‘rule-abiding’ quality of self-financing

To summarize, the key take-away of our discussion on policy awards is the surprisingly “rule-

abiding” quality of bureaucratic self-financing, as I have observed based on the most recent

developments. This observation is surprising in light of popular perception and previous

scholarship on the prevalence of arbitrary extraction in China. That said, I am far from asserting

that the existing system developed is perfect. I am sure there are still instances of bureaucracies

collecting revenue in violation of state policies. Illicit acts of corruption by individual officials also

remains a glaring problem. Instead, what I wish to underline is the trajectory of institutional

change in the Chinese administration. From a historical perspective, policy awards are like

prebends that feudal lords assigned to unsalaried officials and tax farming elites as

compensation. While Chinese bureaucrats have yet to transform fully into salaried Weberian

civil servants, they are certainly becoming more attentive and faithful to the rules of

prebendalism, so to speak.

Element (IV): Property Rights Over Self-Financed Income

All public bureaucracies collect fees and service charges; in this respect, the Chinese case is

unexceptional. In standard practice, revenue collected by public bureaucracies is turned into the

state treasury and public employees are paid regular wages through annual budget allocations.

Salaries for public employees are usually fixed based on rank, and public wages are openly

published in developed countries. In formulating budgets, departments report the number of

personnel and the compensation that each is entitled, and then expect to receive at least

enough budget allocations to cover personnel costs. Public employees should not receive more

Page 71: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

59

pay if they collect more revenue. In short, public bureaucracies do not normally own any income

generated.

In China, however, revenue generated by public bureaucracies is turned into the state accounts

and managed by financial authorities, but they retain the right to appropriate those funds to

finance off-budget workers, wages, benefits, and other expenditure needs. In this way, the

revenue earned by a particular department and the payoffs of its employees are pegged. To

explain how this works, I provide a micro-level view into the budgeting rules and processes,

based on extensive interviews with central and local finance officials (AI 2007-111; 112; 113; 114;

115; 116; 117; AI 2008-138; 139; 140; 141; 147; 153).

Units of Negotiation

At the local level, each core bureau and its extrabureaucracies form a collective unit of

negotiation (kou) in the budgeting process. The core bureau represents its extrabureaucracies.

In budgeting terms, the core bureau is known as the first-level fiscal unit (yiji danwei) and the

subsidiaries the second-level fiscal units (erji danwei). The parent bureau vets the budgets of its

subsidiaries and then files a consolidated budget request to the finance bureau. The finance

bureau only negotiates with the bureaus, not the extrabureaucracies. It then allocates a certain

budget to the parent bureau, and it is normally up to the latter to distribute the budget among

its subsidiaries. Evidently, the parent bureaus command significant allocative power over its

subordinates.46

Determining basic budget allocations

Next, the finance bureau has to determine budget allocations for each collective unit. The

finance bureau begins by considering the official fiscal identity of the bargaining party, i.e.

whether its units are fully, partially, or self-funded. The finance bureau also evaluates the

number of bianzhi (official positions). The bianzhi refers to the number of positions that are

46

In one case study, Wang (2004) found huge inequality in the distribution of funds across public schools

in one county. The local education bureau had significant discretion over the distribution of state budget

allocations.

Page 72: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

60

approved by the state and eligible to receive state funding.47 Simply put, the bianzhi is like a

personnel budgeting instrument. The local establishment office (bianban) sets a bianzhi for

every unit. Those employed outside of the bianzhi quota are considered non-official (bianwai).

Normally, the wages of these workers are paid with the hiring units’ own funds and will not be

budgeted.

During negotiations, the finance bureau will then adjust actual budget allocations based on the

availability of self-financed income in a particular unit. “If a new leader arrives in this unit, and

he is good at cracking his brains to find ways to generate revenue, then our budget will have to

be adjusted” (AI 2007-114). As further explained, “Say we [the finance bureau] are supposed to

fill the entire cup. But if this cup has a tiny pipe [of financial resources] attached to it, then we

don’t have to fill the whole cup” (AI 2007-114). That is, if a unit has a flow of external funds (e.g.

from renting an office building), it will discount the finance bureau’s evaluation of its need for

budget allocations.

When the bargaining process concludes, the finance bureau will make budget allocations for

two basic items, (i) salaries according to the “number of heads” (rentoufei) and (ii) operational

expenditure (bangong jingfei). In the final step, budgeting officials will evaluate special

budgetary requests for capital spending, such as the purchase of equipment or construction of

new property.

Budgeting Procedures Following the Budget Reforms

In this section, I discuss how individual offices appropriate self-financed income following

budget reforms in the mid-1990s. The launch of capitalist reforms unleashed unprecedented

opportunities for bureaucracies to accumulate wealth. From the 1980s to early 1990s,

bureaucracies could expend their income with little or no supervision. This resulted in

47

This is except in the case of “entirely self-funded” (zishou zizhi) bureaucracies. These bureaucracies are

also allocated a bianzhi quota to control hiring. However, their positions do not receive budget allocations

from the government. Instead, they are financed by the bureau’s revenue collections.

Page 73: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

61

extravagant spending and cadre bonuses, contributing to public perceptions of widespread

corruption.

Fortunately, unfettered bureaucratic discretion did not last indefinitely. From the mid-1990s

onwards, the ministry of finance launched an ambitious program of budget reforms, introducing

new measures to strengthen control over the collection and disbursement of public revenue.

Such control was progressively extended to the category of non-tax revenue and extra-

budgetary funds.

“Separating revenue from expenditure.” One of the most crucial elements of the reforms was a

new fiscal management policy known as “separating revenue from expenditure” (shouzhi

liangtiaoxian), introduced in 1998. Simply explained, the policy required all public units to turn

revenue collected into the state accounts at the level to which they belong, and the finance

authorities would then disburse the funds according to “plan.” This budgeting procedure creates

one “line” for revenue and another “line” for expenditure.

Centralized treasury management.48 Following the ‘separating revenue from expenditure’ policy

was the treasury management reform (guoku gaige), initiated in 2000. Piloted at the central

level and gradually extended to the sub-national governments, the reform aimed to establish a

treasury single account (TSA). Traditionally, the bank account system in China was fragmented

not only between levels of government but also between departments at each level.

Bureaucracies would set up individual transitory accounts (guoduhu) to deposit funds.49 As these

accounts were not linked or centrally managed, it was extremely difficult for finance authorities

to monitor monetary flows. In implementing the reform, finance authorities took the first

important step of abolishing all transitory accounts.50 Instead, public units were required to

48

I discuss the treasury reform in detail in a separate paper, "Centralizing treasury management in China:

the rationale of the central reformers." Public Administration & Development 29, no. 4 (2009): 263-273. 49

It was standard practice under the traditional treasury system for state units to open transitory

accounts to deposit revenue, as a consolidated treasury account system had not then been created. Such

accounts should be distinguished from so-called “small treasuries” (xiaojinku) or slush funds, private bank

accounts created by officials and departments to deposit illegal monies (Wedeman 2000). 50

As a result of the reform, it has become more difficult than before for offices to set up unauthorized

“small treasuries.”

Page 74: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

62

submit all revenue directly into a consolidated treasury account, which included a separate

account for extra-budgetary monies.

Some observers have been optimistic about the results of the reforms, but perhaps overly so. In

an earlier study, Yang (2004) claimed, “In practice, with the emphasis on the separation of

revenue and expenditure, government agencies or institutions that collect fees and levies no

longer take in the funds themselves… Such a mechanism can generally ensure that those who

collect funds do not simply spend it on themselves. In fact, as the reform was fine-tuned and as

the funds from levies and funds became incorporated into government budgets, the agencies or

offices collected the funds generally lost the right to dispose of the funds collected (240,

emphasis added).” I fully concur with Yang that the budget reforms have considerably enhanced

fiscal management and anti-corruption control. However, contrary to his claims, my research

finds that the measures have not removed bureaucracies of their ownership over earned

proceeds, as I shall explain below.

Refunding Self-Financed Income

Following the budget reforms, the prevailing practice has been for the bureaucracies to turn

collected revenue into the state accounts and then to receive a full or partial refund of the funds

from the finance bureau. The term “refund” is a direct translation of the Chinese word fanhuan,

which local officials use. However, by refund, I do not mean that the finance bureau physically

returns cash to the respective offices (bear in mind that they no longer have individual bank

accounts in places where the treasury single account has been established). Rather, “refund” in

this case refers to an internal accounting practice. Each office submits a formal request to the

finance bureau to appropriate its income for certain purposes (e.g. buying a new car). After the

request is approved, the finance bureau will pay for the item from that particular office’s “pot”

of funds.

Rate of Refund. The “refund” rate varies from place to place and from unit to unit. In Blossom

county, all public units received a uniform 70 percent refund (AI 2007-114; AI 2007-111; AI

2007-119; AI 2007-113). In a poorer county in Tianjin, the rate varied from 50 to 100 percent (AI

Page 75: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

63

2008-139). The public security bureau, a quintessentially powerful agency, enjoyed a full refund.

Generally, unused funds can be rolled over to the next fiscal year (A1 2007-114; 115; 116; 117).

In this manner, self-raised income constitutes, in a real sense, the “surplus” of Chinese

bureaucracies. Retained funds are pooled and then reallocated through regular budgeting

procedures.

Limited spending discretion. With stricter budgeting measures in place, Chinese bureaucracies

have less discretion than before in using the funds they earn. Only following approval of

requests for spending by the finance bureau can departmental funds be appropriated. Further,

as part of the treasury reform, reformers implemented a direct payment mechanism (jizhong

zhifu). The new measure empowers the treasury disbursement center at each level to pay staff

wages and make purchases on behalf of spending units. This mechanism prevents agencies from

spending funds for unauthorized purposes. In addition, many local governments imposed a

ceiling on the disbursement of cadre bonuses. For example, in Blossom county, bonuses were

capped at 30,000 yuan per cadre per year (AI 2007-119).51 Nonetheless, although bureaucracies

have less spending discretion than before, they have not in fact lost ownership of their proceeds.

My findings are paralleled in some recent research and commentaries. In Zhang’s (2008) field

research on agencies’ enlistment of court assistance in collecting fees, she was told by a local

judge in Hubei province,

Although it is said that revenue should be separated from expenditure, in

practice, each unit still takes care of itself... the finance bureau will not give you

additional funds. Each unit’s expenditure is still based on its income.52

Similarly, a commentary in the Southern Daily observed,

“What is ‘separating revenue from expenditure’? Those departments that

collect fees and fines turn their revenue over to finance; the finance bureau

manages them as part of the extra-budgetary funds and then refunds them,

allowing departments to dole out wages, benefits, and operational monies.

51

Restrictions like these, however, resulted inadvertently in the proliferation of in-kind benefits to replace

cash payments, as we will later see in Chapter 3. 52

Interview with County Court, Hubei, 11.2005, by Xuehua Zhang.

Page 76: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

64

Many people see ‘separating revenue from expenditure’ as an anti-corruption

reform. In actuality, it has legalized the collection of fees and fines that are

unjustified in the first place.”53

Critically, in my interviews, budgeting officials emphasized that individual offices retain the

“right of appropriation” (shiyongquan) even after the ‘separating revenue from expenditure’

policy. The obvious implication is that bureaucracies have an incentive to generate revenue for

their offices. Further, the processes of making and spending self-financed income have become

increasingly institutionalized.

A Simulation of Budgeting Rules

To summarize the rules of the game, Figure 2.4 presents a stylized model of the budgeting

processes in a local government with Departments A, B, and C. Each department is composed of

a core agency and its subsidiary extrabureaucracies. The “mobilizable funds” (kezhipei zijin) of

the local government for budgetary distribution come from three main sources:

a) Locally retained within-budgetary revenue (i.e. tax revenue);

b) Fiscal transfers and grants from above;

c) Pooled funds from the extra-budgetary account.

The finance bureau allocates the “plate” (panzi) of mobilizable funds to finance the basic

budgetary needs of the county’s public units. Imagine that the finance bureau allocates 100

million for administrative expenditure, granting 50 million to A, 30 million to B, and 20 million to

C. If the minimum needs of A, B, and C are 100 million, 50 million, and 35 million respectively,

each department would face a shortfall of funds as follows: 50 million for A, 20 million for B, and

15 million for C. The next step for A, B, and C is to submit a request to the finance bureau to

cover their shortfalls with retained self-raised income.

53

“Resolutely abolish the system of self-raised funds,” Southern Daily News, March 29, 2007. The author

of this article is a researcher at the Central Party School.

Page 77: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

65

Department A has just enough funds to break even for the year. Department B has a surplus of 5

million (self-raised income exceed unmet needs), which means it can provide additional benefits

or bonuses for its employees. Department C does not have enough self-raised funds to meet its

minimum administrative expenditure; hence, it must cut back on benefits or even owe wage

payments. This stylized example shows that the amount of self-raised income made by each

bureaucracy is linked to its employees’ payoffs.

The unique-ness of the Chinese administration becomes apparent if we consider textbook

descriptions of public bureaucratic organization, for example, as Terry Moe wrote (1984, 763):

The typical bureau receives a budget from governmental superiors and spends

all of it supplying services to a nonpaying clientele. Regardless of the agency's

performance or how it changes over time, the results are not reflected in an

economic surplus accruing to bureau heads, and this major incentive for the

efficient monitoring of employee behavior fails to operate. Incentive plans that

give employees a share of the "profit" in partial payment for their effort (e.g. in

locating welfare fraud or cost overruns) are also ruled out. The absence of a

residual and its implications for internal efficiency, therefore, would seem to be

factors that immediately set public bureaucracy apart from private

organizations and shape our expectations about their relative performance.

In the Chinese case, each offices “financial” performance (i.e. capacity to generate self-financed

income) is directly linked to the employees’ payoffs. In this case, the bureaucracies have the

potential to accumulate not just a slack, savings from budget allocation, but a real economic

surplus.

Conclusion

Modifying theories of the firm, this chapter develops a hybrid state institutional model labeled

bureau-contracting. We examine the empirical features in the Chinese case. In a bureau-

contracting structure, contracting takes place within the bureaucratic hierarchy at each level of

government. As seen in China, public bureaucracies are not purely salaried; most of them raise a

part or even all of their own funds. Abiding by an intricate set of state rules, individual offices

can earn, retain, and use so-called self-financed income. Critically, the funds examined in this

Page 78: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

66

study are not illicit monies or bribes. The more self-financed income is produced, the more

wealth a bureau amasses. In extreme cases, such as the land bureau in Blossom county featured

in the introduction, offices may grow rich enough to acquire the property of their administrative

bosses.

Page 79: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

67

Figure 2.4: ‘Rules of the Game’ – A Simulation of Budget Procedures and Outcome

Within-Budgetary

Funds

Extra-Budgetary

Funds

Local Taxes

Deficit of 10 mil Y; owed

wages, lower benefits

Surplus of 5 mil Y; more bonuses

or benefits for staff or rollover

funds to next year

Breaks even

Revenue sent to

upper levels

Revenue retained

at local level

Budgeted Funds =

100 million Y

(for administrative

expenditure)

Pooled extra-

budgetary funds

Department B

(allocated 30 mil Y)

Department A

(allocated 50 mil Y)

Department B

(allocated 20 mil Y)

5 mil Y

25 mil Y

50 mil Y

35 mil Y

15 mil Y

20 mil Y

50 mil Y

50 mil Y

Actual

Expenditure Unmet Needs Departmental

Funds

100 mil Y

Department A’s Funds

Department B’s Funds

Department C’s Funds

Fiscal Transfers

Mobilizable

Funds

Page 80: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

68

CHAPTER 3

THE STRUCTURE OF CADRE REWARDS

We cannot study political institutions without studying incentives. And we cannot study

incentives without mapping the structure of financial rewards facing officeholders in a political

system. Incentives for governmental actors have featured prominently in existing analyses of

development. As Oi underscored, “for China the issues were not whether its bureaucracy was

capable of generating economic growth but whether it had the incentive to do so” (1999, 6). But,

despite a widely shared emphasis on incentives, we have not seen to date a comprehensive

documentation of the actual compensation structure of Chinese officials. Unless we know how

much and in what ways bureaucrats are financially rewarded, we cannot appreciate the full

scope of incentives that drive bureaucratic behavior.

Filling this empirical gap, this chapter identifies the structure of cadre rewards in China. The

level of cadre rewards depend on two factors: (1) economic development and tax revenue

collections in a particular locale, and (2) the ability of individual bureaucracies to generate self-

financed income, as I have analyzed in Chapters 2 and 3. Factor (1) results in wide inter-

governmental disparity and factor (2) results in wide inter-bureaucratic disparity in cadre

rewards. In other words, cadres may receive widely variant payoffs depending on which locality

they are in and which office in the locality they serve. Taken together, these patterns suggest

that the Chinese bureaucracy is governed by a uniquely high-powered incentive scheme that

motivates bureaucratic actors to maximize revenue – be it revenue for local state budgets or for

departmental budgets. However, in a public bureaucratic organization, the goal of revenue

maximization can be at odds with the goals of social welfare provision and long-term economic

development. A key implication of the analysis is that conflicting fiscal incentives exist in the

Chinese bureaucracy.

Page 81: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

69

Descriptive statistics in this chapter are based on internal (neibu) budget datasets, compiled by

the Ministry of Finance and local finance bureaus, which break down governmental spending by

types of costs, rather than broad functional sectors. These unique datasets present a valuable

opportunity to measure and examine “cadre rewards” concretely.

Patterns of Cadre Rewards

One strategy for measuring “cadre rewards” is to disaggregate categories of public spending.

There are three categories of current expenditure in China: personnel spending, administrative

spending, and subsidies for individuals and families. From each of these categories, we can

extract spending items that provide compensation or benefits for public employees. For

analytical and descriptive purposes, we measure cadre rewards as the sum of wage payments,

subsidies, and administrative benefits.

In the parlance of political economy (see Magaloni, Diaz-Cayeros & Estevez 2007), wage

payments and subsidies are equivalent to “private goods provision,” i.e. they are direct

monetary benefits for individual cadres. Administrative benefits represent “club goods

provision,” i.e. they are spending on benefits shared among employees in bureaucracies. To be

sure, not all of administrative spending goes towards benefiting cadres individually or as a group;

some spending items serve work purposes, e.g. purchasing specialized equipment and materials.

Hence, in estimating the level of administrative benefits, I take caution to exclude those

spending items not likely to function as in-kind benefits for staff members.

Table 3.1 shows the aggregated structure of cadre rewards at the local (provincial and sub-

provincial) level of two groups in 2004. (a) “PJBC”: public security bureaus, judiciary bureaus,

courts, and procuratorates, (b) “Others”: extrabureaucratic units in the tax, statistics, finance,

auditing, commerce, assets management, tourism, overseas Chinese affairs, labor, customs,

discipline, agricultural development sectors, as well as in the people’s congresses, people’s

consultative committees, social organizations. Although not all party and governmental

organizations are included, this sample covers a wide range of bureaucratic units and thus

provides a fairly representative view of the whole bureaucracy.

Page 82: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

70

Combining the two groups, several features deserve further comment. First, wage payments

composed about one-third of total cadre rewards. In this category, only 38 percent were basic

wages (jiben gongzi). Basic wages are standardized across the country (see later section).

Allowances made up the second largest category at 32 percent, and bonuses followed in the

third place at 15 percent.

Second, in addition to the wage payments discussed above, cadres also received some

additional cash income from subsidies. This category composed 5 percent of total cadre rewards.

Among them, subsidies for retired personnel were the largest share (33 percent), followed by

housing subsidies (32 percent).

Third, administrative benefits took up the lion’s share of cadre rewards, equaling 56 percent of

the total.54 Interestingly, about half of administrative spending fell under an undefined line item

– “others” [what are these?] – that cost 79 billion yuan in 2004, about three-quarters of total

wage payments. We do not know from the data what “others” specifically includes. As a central

finance official explained, “The saying goes: ‘others’ is a basket, everything is stuffed in it (qita

shi yiluokuang, shenme dou wanglizhuang)” (AI 2008-147). I was told that finance officials would

ask departments for details on “other” spending only if the size of expenditure is glaring;

otherwise, this category is a black box.

Based on anecdotal evidence, the “others” spending category could include frequent purchases

of gifts for staff members, a phenomenon observed during my field research and well-

documented in the Chinese media. For example, in one county that I visited, cadres regularly

received gifts from their departments, including seafood, cosmetics, skincare products, visits to

salons, and even shopping certificates. Another major staff benefit is department sponsored or

subsidized vacations. Free wining and dining is a common perk, and state-funded cars are

deployed for private use. As one cadre puts it, “I guess this can be considered a kind of grey

income” (AI 2007-111). The proliferation of in-kind benefits (and bribes) has even spawned an

54

I have excluded from this category spending items that are likely to serve as office expenditure rather

than as collective benefits for cadres, e.g. spending on special materials (e.g. testing equipment, etc.),

spending on books and research materials.

Page 83: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

71

unusual business of “gift recycling” (lipin huishou) across China. One can exchange gift items for

cash at gift recycling shops. Bureaucrats were reportedly frequent patrons of these shops.55

Table 3.1: Composition of Local Cadre Rewards, 2004

PJCP OTHERS TOTAL

WAGE

PAYMENTS

SUB-TOTAL 7012502

(46%)

3638241

(29%)

10650743

(38%)

Basic Wages 2651908 1442553 4094461 (38%)

Allowances 2482715 918154 3400869 (32%)

Bonuses 981856 645980 1627836 (15%)

Social security 183090 179496 362586 (3%)

Others 712933 452058 1164991 (11%)

ADMINISTRATIVE

BENEFITS

SUB-TOTAL 7253048

(48%)

8196625

(66%%)

15449673

(56%)

Office expenditure 506178 552040 1058218

Printing 98981 232221 331202

Utilities 289217 169854 459071

Postage 247669 130962 378631

Heating 137585 101362 238947

Transportation 791389 384535 1175924

Travel 358778 218716 577494

Conference 125891 258913 384804

Training 148431 162313 310744

Entertainment 242032 315562 557594

Benefit fee 153438 111464 264902

Labor fee 72883 167824 240707

Rental 41808 57384 99192

Asset management 38754 61840 100594

Office furnishing 329888 328356 658244

Vehicles 482164 215830 697994

Others 3187962 4727449 7915411 (51%)

SUBSIDIES

SUB-TOTAL 807524

(5%)

520369

(4%)

1327893

(5%)

Subsidies for pre-retirement 42989 18898 61887

Subsidies for retirement 256467 176490 432957

Health subsidies 50542 40368 90910

55

An article from Xinhua reported that the gift recycling business in Harbin city declined because a new

restriction against gift-making in the government (“Harbin officials are disciplined; gift recycling business

declines,” Xinhuanet, Feb. 19 2005). Another article described civil servants as regular clients at gift

recycling shops (“Gift recycling revealed,” Xinkuaibao, Feb. 15 2006). Some of the items brought for

“recycling” may be legitimate gifts from one’s department but they may also be bribes.

Page 84: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

72

Housing subsidies 276024 155614 431638

Scholarships 824 566 1390

Others 180678 128433 309111

TOTAL 15073074 12355235 27428309

Source: Author’s calculation from Local Public Financial Statistics.

The composition of cadre rewards reviewed above reflects a pattern that is already well-known

to bureaucratic insiders – China has a sub-moneterized bureaucratic compensation system.

Many privileges of office come in the form of administrative benefits, rather than wages. This

pattern reflects a common saying that cadres receive “low wages, multiple allowances, and

abundant benefits.”56 Such a compensation structure results from ceilings placed by local

governments on disbursing departmental income as cash payments to public employees.57 To

circumvent the ceilings, wealthier bureaus are compelled to spend surpluses by giving out in-

kind benefits.

Formal vs. Extra-Formal Cadre Wages

To understand what determines the level of cadre rewards, it is helpful to first understand the

monetary wage system for Chinese cadres. There are two cadre wage systems coexisting in

China: a formal (zhidunei) and an extra-formal (zhiduwai) system. In the formal system, the

central government sets a standardized wage scale for civil servants and extrabureaucratic

employees that is uniformly implemented across the country. The formal wage scale presented

several problems, as pointed out by Xu Songtao (2007), the former minister of personnel

management. First, formal cadre wages are generally low in China, especially in comparison to

other occupations requiring equivalent skills (Xu 2007, 214). Second, the wage scale is highly

compressed. Although levels of development ranged widely across regions in China, basic wages

do not reflect local disparities. Hence, while the formal basic wage level may be attractive in

poor and rural areas, they are pitifully insufficient in well-off regions. Further, the wage

differential between officials of different ranks is kept very low. Based on the official pay scale,

56

“What has wage sunning revealed?” Liaowang, Oct. 15 2007. 57

This ceiling appears to vary from place to place. For example, at Blossom County, bonus payments to

cadres were capped at $30,000 a year.

Page 85: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

73

the highest-ranked local official (a Grade 1 mayor) is entitled to 190 yuan in wages per month,

while a Grade 1 administrative support personnel gets yuan (see Appendix B). As Xu pointed out,

wage compression in the formal scheme is much higher in China than in other countries. Third,

wage increments are kept low.58

Appendix B shows the formal wage scale for civil servants. Formal wages consist of four

segments: basic wages (jiben gongzi), function wages (zhiwu gongzi), rank wages (jibei gongzi),

and length-of-service wages. Combining basic, function, and rank wages, the chairman of the

CCP (the paramount head of state) is entitled to a formal salary of 1190 yuan per month – the

maximum in the country. On top of that, one yuan is added to a cadre’s payroll for every year of

accumulated service. In addition to these wages, the central government authorized the

disbursement of local subsidies. According to the pay scale, the maximum sum for local

subsidies was 300 yuan per month. To place these sums in perspective, the average wage of an

urban worker in 1993 per year was 3,371 yuan (or 280 yuan per month), while the average level

of consumption per month was 206 yuan per urban resident and 65 yuan per rural resident.59

Based on the formal compensation scheme, a city mayor would be poorer than the average

urban worker. Clearly, formal cadre wages could not keep up with steeply rising costs of living

in China, especially in fast-growing cities. They were also incompatible with the education level

and social status of the cadre class.

In the reform era, a highly (perhaps even unrealistically) egalitarian formal public pay scheme

was coupled by dramatically expanded opportunities for local governments and departments to

accumulate wealth. The marriage of these two conditions necessitated the emergence of an

extra-formal compensation system. What determines the level of extra-formal compensation?

First, tax revenues collected and retained by local governments, which are highly correlated with

local industrialization and economic development. Second, self-financed income earned by

individual bureaucracies that compose each level of government.

58

In recent years, the central government has tried to increase the formal wages of civil servants using

fiscal transfers. 59

Zhongguo Jingji Nianjian (China Economics Yearbook) 1994, China Economics Press, p. 760.

Page 86: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

74

Tax revenues and intra-governmental disparity

Generally, the level of economic development and tax revenue collections determines the

amount of state budget allocations and the average level of cadre compensation in a particular

locale. As Oi asserted, “increased revenues in local government coffers directly translated into

lucrative (and legal) economic rewards for local officials” (1999, 49). The correlation between

fiscal revenue and cadre payoffs, it is believed, provided a crucial positive incentive for local

officials to pursue local economic growth. In my field research, I have indeed observed a close

association between local developmental outcomes and cadre rewards. Drawing on retained

taxes, rich localities can afford to pay generous subsidies, allowances, and bonuses for meeting

targets, on top of formal wages.

Here, I give an example from Tianjin city (AI 2008-135; 136). Lake county and Hills county were

geographically adjacent counties. However, Lake county was more developed and collected

more taxes than Hills county. Consequently, the average cadre in Lake county enjoyed a much

higher level of compensation than those from Hills county. An official from Hills county

complained bitterly (AI 2008-136):

Our salaries are about half that of Lake county. The basic wages are the same,

but the difference lies in the allowances and subsidies… Since basic wages are

uniform, the local governments cannot change them. But there is another part

of compensation that is based on the finances of local governments. For

example, Lake county gives out a transportation subsidy, but other counties do

not. In addition, they have bonuses for meeting targets. And why is the

difference between localities so large? Because we have no money.

The story of Hills and Lake is unexceptional. Much anecdotal evidence tells us that cadre

rewards vary widely across provinces, cities, counties, and even townships in the same county.

Such anecdotal evidence is supported by descriptive statistics in this study. Table 3.2 compares

the total monetary value of cadre rewards across provincial governments in China in 2004, using

the same set of numbers discussed in Table 3.1. Unfortunately, we cannot estimate the value of

rewards per cadre, as we do not know the number of cadres in these groups. Nonetheless, the

statistics available indicates a very wide variation in the level of cadre rewards across provinces.

As expected, we observe a very strong correlation between cadre rewards per capita and tax

Page 87: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

75

revenue per capita (correlation = 0.96). The description here provides only a rough national view.

In Chapter 4, we will discuss the variation in cadre rewards at the county level and test the

determinants systematically.

Table 3.2: Distribution of Cadre Rewards Across Provinces, 2004

(unit = million yuan)

Mean Std. Dev Min Max

PJBJ 4863.98 4079.04 595.26 21132.19

Others 3989.36 3240.00 116.49 15595.19

Self-Financed Income and Inter-Bureaucratic Disparity

Not only is there a wide gap in cadre rewards across local governments, there is also

tremendous variation in cadre wages and benefits across bureaucracies within the same locality.

I have been fortunate to obtain a rare dataset that records spending by departments in one

county government. Table 3.3 below shows personnel and administrative spending per cadre

across several bureaucracies in Windy county, located in a Northern municipality, in 2007.60 As

we can see, spending per cadre ranged from 28,390 yuan in the civil affairs bureau to 126,035

yuan in the commerce bureau.

What explains the huge variance above? The variance is unlikely the result of unequal levels of

education. Recruitment standards are similar across bureaus and better educated cadres do not

fetch higher formal salaries. Far more likely, then, the variance reflects the varying capacity of

bureaucracies to raise funds and their de facto ownership over revenue collected. The civil

affairs bureau administers poverty relief, provides welfare services for the old and handicapped,

and oversees village elections. The commerce bureau, on the other hand, regulates business and

issues licenses. Based on their functions, it is no wonder that the commerce bureau can afford

to spend much more on cadre wages and benefits than the civil affairs bureau. These descriptive

60

This particular dataset does not break down personnel and administrative spending by sub-categories,

so we do not know how much of personnel spending is composed of basic wages as compared to

allowances and bonuses.

Page 88: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

76

statistics also support my point in Chapter 2 that bureaucracies have not in fact lost their rights

to dispose of self-financed income even after the post-1990s budget reforms.

Table 3.3: Personnel and Administrative Spending Per Cadre in Windy County in 2007

Office Personnel and Administrative

Spending Per Cadre (Yuan)

Commerce Bureau 126,035

Cultural Market Regulation Team 107,323

Party School 104,123

Public Security Bureau 94,406

Disciplinary Committee 91,148

Personnel Bureau 87,439

Finance Bureau 81,162

National Development & Reform Commission 75,585

Cultural Commission 72,930

Environmental Bureau 70,553

Relics Preservation Center 62,089

Civil Affairs Bureau 28,390

Source: Budget report published by Windy County Finance Bureau

Colloquially, wealthy bureaus are known as “greasy offices” (youshui yamen) and the ones less

well-off as “clear offices” (qingshui yamen). Local officials are of course well aware of the

variance in cadre payoffs across bureaus. As one official mused, “Compare the archives office to

the construction bureau – even a fool knows! [their gap in income] What can the archives office

do with those archives?” (AI 2007-128). The media is replete with anecdotes of intra-

bureaucratic income disparity. In one striking example from Guangxi province, it was reported

that a local tax bureau paid a generous spring festival allowance of 18,300 yuan to each

employee, while the other offices, lacking “grease,” could afford no more than a few hundred

dollars.61

Once we understand the egalitarian constraints of the formal wage system, it becomes clear

why few bureaucracies, even fully-funded public units, would not be content with budget

allocations that provide only “basic” needs. Basic wages are insufficient for officials to sustain a

61

“What has sunning wages shown? The benefits of civil servants move towards transparency,” Liaowang,

Oct. 15, 2007.

Page 89: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

77

reasonable level of consumption and social status in a capitalist age. Formal rules of

reimbursement for work-related expenses are similarly obsolete in light of the rising costs of

living. For example, a central-level bureaucrat lamented that the official reimbursement for

lodging during official travel was only 50 yuan a day (AI 2006-11). Seasoned travelers in China

will know that 50 yuan can hardly get one a half-night rest in the cities today. “I am already not

used to that quality of life,” said the bureaucrat (AI 2006-11). As Blecher and Shue pointed out,

“In today’s China, local state actors must compete for authority with other rising social forces in

a newly materialistic culture. When municipal officials take important business prospects out to

dinner these days, they had better not arrive at the restaurant in banged-up jalopies and cheap

shoes” (2001, 389).

High-Powered Incentives: How High? What Kind?

The Chinese bureaucracy is a state organization with uniquely high-powered incentives. These

high-powered incentives take two forms. Firstly, monetary payoffs for local leaders and cadres

increase with economic performance and tax collections. In other words, the local officialdom,

as a collective body, is a claimant to the locality’s prosperity. Secondly, within each level of

government, cadres rewards are further differentiated according to each bureau’s capacity to

earn self-financed income. Each bureau is a claimant to the financial surpluses generated.

Let us place the degree of high-powered incentives in China’s bureaucracy in perspective. Susan

Whiting (2004) studied cadre wage differentials across township governments in a Shanghai

county. Citing a study by Baker et al (1988), she related that in a typical large American

manufacturing firm, workers with the lowest performance ranking received 7.8 percent less

than those who ranked the highest (Baker et al 1988, 595; cited in Whiting 2004, 110). In

comparison, among the townships that Whiting studied, those cadres in the lowest ranked

townships, which were ranked primarily on economic performance, received a whopping 66

percent less than those in the highest ranking townships. A large share of the cadre’s

compensation and income variance across townships, she added, was a consequence of

performance-based bonuses. Such heavy reliance on bonuses was ironically rare in American

firms (Whiting 2004, 111).

Page 90: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

78

My analysis finds high-powered incentives even higher than in Whiting’s study. Across 139

county governments in Shandong province, I find that the average cadre in the poorest county

received 86 percent less in wages and benefits than the wealthiest county in 2005 (see Chapter

4). Returning to our comparison of reward differentials across bureaus in Windy county, listed in

Table 3.3, cadres in the “clearest office” (the civil affairs bureau) had 77 percent less in

monetary rewards than the “greasiest office” (the commerce bureau). That is to say, if we

compared Windy county to the American firm in Baker et al’s study, economic incentives are

about ten times more powerful in a Chinese county government than in a purely capitalist

enterprise. Economic incentives in the Chinese bureaucracy are structured in such way that

bureaucratic agents are motivated to maximize revenue. Local governments want to maximize

revenue for the local coffers. Each bureaucracy wants to maximize revenue for its own

department.

Careful distinctions must be drawn between the drive for revenue maximization in the Chinese

context and other forms of economic motivations. Firstly, the goal of revenue-maximization in

the Chinese bureaucracy is different from the private desires of corrupt officials to extract as

many spoils for themselves as possible in violation of the laws. Here, the organizational principle

is that revenue maximization takes place within boundaries drawn by the state, as explained in

Chapter 3 on policy awards. That said, my point is not that bureaucratic agents in China are

obedient and passive. Far from it, it has been emphasized that opportunism induces high-

powered incentives. Instead, what I mean is that Chinese bureaucracies will strive to maximize

financial gains through clever manipulation of the rules of the game, but without breaking the

rules explicitly.62 Additionally, central-level departments and bureaus take the more active

approach of lobbying for laws that will license their revenue-making activities. This is a

phenomenon known as “departmental law-making” (AI 2007-128).

Secondly, the revenue-maximizing goal in the Chinese bureaucracy should be distinguished from

the profit-maximizing goal of pure private firms. For firms, profits are the bottom-line. Profits

62

Examples are discussed in Chapter 3. Public schools, given the license to collect “premiums”,

concentrated resources on key-point schools to build up their attractiveness and hence capacity to draw

additional payments from willing parents. Regulatory agencies typically support their extrabureaucracies

in generating more income by blocking market competition through the exercise of regulatory power.

Page 91: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

79

are revenue minus costs. Firms will seek to maximize profits by increasing sales or decreasing

costs or a combination of both. However, the corporate concept of costs does not obtain the

same way in a public bureaucratic setting. To elaborate, let us first be reminded that

bureaucracies in China (and any where else) are engaged in the services provision, not

manufacturing. In manufacturing, the physical inputs used to make products constitute the bulk

of costs. In the services business, costs come mainly from labor, especially skilled labor. A profit-

maximizing firm in the services industries will strive to maximize revenue and minimize labor

costs. This may be done by reducing excess staff and/or increasing labor productivity to improve

services provision and consequently sales.

Different from private firms, however, Chinese bureaucracies have economic incentives but they

serve political functions. One of their key functions is to finance public employment. This

prevents political instability that could result from cadre layoffs, absorbs displaced military

personnel and university graduates, and provides patronage capital for political leaders at all

levels of the hierarchy and for the party at large. Thus, bureau chiefs in China do not usually

have the freedom or desire to remove redundant staff. In fact, nepotism appears rife, and

anecdotal evidence suggests that new leaders often bring new personnel, including family

members (Wei-Arthus 2000), to office with them to expand their personal clientelist network.

Finally, I stress that economic incentives in the Chinese bureaucracy are not structured to

reward individuals based on objective measures of good performance as public servants. The

kind of high-powered incentives employed in the Chinese bureaucracy must be distinguished

from high-powered incentives and bonus schemes advocated in conventional theories of new

public management (Frant 1996).

Implications of the Incentive Structure

Following from the preceding discussion, the implications of the incentive structure in China are

apparent. Chinese bureaucracies are motivated by unusually high-powered incentives to

maximize revenue. From the state’s perspective, this is a positive feature insofar as agencies and

extrabureaucracies are driven to self-finance, thereby reducing governmental fiscal burden and

Page 92: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

80

inflating cadre rewards. From the social perspective, however, the consequences can turn out

badly. A research report on shiye units conducted by the development research center (DRC) of

the state council summarizes the resulting problems succinctly, “the goal of maximizing

organizational and personal interests has led to the neglect, if not indeed, abandonment and

damage of the goal of social welfare” (cited in World Bank 2006, 22).

One major consequence of bureau-contracting has been a sharp rise in the costs of essential

social services. As reported recently by the World Bank (2006), service charges have sky-

rocketed in education and health care. Taking 1986 as the base year, tuition and fees in

education financing rose by 15 times in 1994 and increased even more rapidly afterwards to 40

times in 1999 and about 85 times in 2002 (97). In health care, out-of-pocket costs in 1992 were

about ten times that in 1986, and by 2001, they had grown 40 times since the base year.

Scanning the Chinese media and even the Western media, one finds numerous reports about

the adverse effects that such rising costs in education and health care have had on the lives of

citizens.

Another major consequence is limited market competition in the services sectors. Notably, since

China’s entry into the WTO, significant efforts have been made by the central government to

liberalize parts of its services sector, for example, in banking and pharmaceuticals. However, it

appears that there remains a significant chunk of the services sectors that still remain either

explicitly monopolized or dominated by public extrabureaucracies, especially in the litany of

minor sectors, as discussed in Chapter 2. In education and health care, although the number of

private providers is growing (World Bank 2006), my research finds that many of these providers

were either spun off from public providers, invested by former or existing officials, or affiliated

to state entities. It remains difficult for purely private entrepreneurs to enter the services

sectors. In recent years, the central government has begun to make steady efforts to liberalize

the services economy. For example, whereas the tourism bureau used to monopolize the tour

agency business in the 1990s, competition was introduced afterwards. However, compared to

the manufacturing sectors, services still remain state dominated.

Page 93: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

81

A third implication of our analysis of cadre rewards is that the coexistence of two sets of high-

powered incentives are in tension with each other. On the one hand, cadre payoffs are linked to

a particular locale’s economic development and tax collections. Taxes come primarily from

businesses. To collect more taxes, a government has to bring in and retain businesses. On the

other hand, cadre payoffs are also set by the amount of self-financed income that each office is

able to make. Given the system of rents extraction available, will local officials be tempted to

relinquish developmental efforts altogether? That is, if cadres can earn additional income and

benefits through their own department’s self-financing, then does it matter to them if the locale

prospers and brings in taxes to the treasury? If the answer were: it doesn’t matter, then China is

in trouble. Like in a feudal system, local governments will disintegrate into prebendal rackets,

each for its own, and development would not have occurred. For local state-led development to

work, cadres need to have a common personal stake in the locality’s prosperity. This stake,

furthermore, has to exceed, or at least balance, the officialdom’s narrower stake in

departmental finances. In Chapter 4, we will test if such a condition holds.

Conclusion

Monetary incentives matter because they shape bureaucratic behavior, which in turn has

profound effects on economic development and social welfare provision. This chapter presents

one of the first known efforts at mapping the patterns of cadre rewards in China across regions

and governmental branches, using previously unavailable budget data. To summarize, we find

that the Chinese bureaucracy is governed by two coexisting sets of high-powered incentives that

result from the assignment of rights of surpluses to local governments and to individual offices

within each level of government. In consequence, we observe in China an unusually wide

disparity in cadre rewards both across local governments and across bureaucracies. High-

powered economic incentives motivate bureaucratic actors to maximize revenue; however, they

can also produce unintended negative social costs. In the next chapter, we examine the tension

between developmental and rent-seeking incentives more closely.

Page 94: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

82

CHAPTER 5

DUAL FISCAL INCENTIVES

“Politics… takes place on a knife edge… [some] descend into predation while

others turn developmental. On the one side, the winning political strategy is to

extract wealth; on the other, it is to promote its creation.”

Robert Bates, 2008, 718.

To use the words of Robert Bates, politics in China “takes place on a knife edge.” At times, the

Chinese state exudes economic dynamism. Other times, it epitomizes predation. How can we

make sense of this contradiction? My study has tried to new shed light on this question first by

carefully qualifying the nature of “predation” in China. In the preceding chapters, while not

denying that instances of brute power still exist, I have shown that Chinese bureaucracies are

governed by a surprisingly disciplined internal system of self-financing, in which they are

licensed to exact rent payments as a means of compensation and administrative fund-raising.

The institutional patterns described are not wholly a Chinese invention. They should become

familiar if we recall prebendal systems of governance that in pre-modern states.

In this chapter, I take on a further challenge to demonstrate not only that state developmental

efforts and decentralized rent-seeking coexists in China, but also to explain why they have

managed to remain in equilibrium thus far. My analysis centers on a product of intersection

between fiscal contracting (between levels of government) and bureau-contracting (within

levels of government) – I shall call this product dual fiscal incentives. As we have already begun

to explore in Chapter 4, two set of high-powered economic incentives are simultaneously at

work. One set of incentives come from inter-governmental revenue-sharing. All things equal, the

Page 95: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

83

more businesses developed and the more tax revenue a local government collects, the more

local cadres are financially rewarded. A second set of incentives are presented by bureau-

contracting. The more self-financed income each bureau can extract, the more its employees

benefit personally. Self-financed income, while not illegal monies, are essentially quasi-rent

payments.

So why would local cadres not choose to devote their resources to rent-seeking and relinquish

developmental efforts, if both strategies provide legal financial payoffs? My answer pertains to

their time horizon. I propose that while local cadres benefit more in the short-term from

extracting departmental rents than from developing local businesses, they benefit in the long-

term only from expanding the formal tax base. This condition holds insofar as local governments

still benefit from marginal tax increments, even after the 1994 tax reform, and that

developmental opportunities are available sufficiently.

Employing a new county-level budget dataset on an error-correction model, I present evidence

for a theory of dual fiscal incentives. I begin with a brief introduction of China’s fiscal structure

and history. Following which, I develop the theoretical claims and observable implications.

Finally, I present regression analyses to evaluate my hypotheses. In the final section, we

compare endogenous versus external limits on bureaucratic predation.

Background: The Chinese Fiscal System

Since the establishment of the People’s Republic of China to recent times, China has undergone

several phases of fiscal policy. Before 1979, typical of Soviet command economies, revenue

collection and spending decisions in China were highly centralized. Revenue collected by

provincial governments had to be surrendered upwards and then remitted according to central

plans. In such way, each local locality’s spending was not tied to its takings, so incentives to

increase revenue were low. This was the period known as “eating from the same big pot” (chi

daguo fan).

Page 96: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

84

From 1980s onwards, China implemented a revenue-sharing system known as fiscal contracting

(caizheng baogan) or “eating in separate kitchens” (fenzhao chifan). Under fiscal contracting,

each level of government contracted with the next lower level of government; the latter remits

a negotiated share of revenue upwards and then keeps the rest. Revenue-sharing was a bilateral

arrangement between two levels of government. As there are five formal levels of government

in China, there existed four revenue-sharing layers: central-province, province-city, city-county,

and county-townships.63 Fiscal contracting gave local governments more spending autonomy

but also required them to balance their own budgets, thereby hardening budget constraints.

Extrabudgetary revenues were an important element of fiscal contracting. Public funds in China

are composed of within-budgetary and extra-budgetary revenues. Within-budgetary revenues

are formal and nationally imposed taxes, whereas extrabudgetary revenues consisted of a wide

range of non-tax revenue, including local surcharges, retained profits from collective enterprises,

income earned by individual agencies, fees, contributions, etc. Following fiscal contracting in the

post-1979 period, local governments could keep the negotiated share of within-budgetary

revenue and the entire share of extrabudgetary revenue. Simultaneously, local governments

were barred from making loans or establishing their own tax categories.

Fiscal contracting provided powerful incentives for local governments to pursue development

and collect more taxes. It was also during this period that rapid local industrialization and

growth took off. However, the post-1979 fiscal arrangements created new problems. Firstly,

regional disparities widened. Secondly, as fiscal contracting was based on bargaining, the terms

of sharing and tax categories were chaotic. Thirdly and probably most importantly, the central

government rapidly lost fiscal control, as the sum and share of local revenue, especially

extrabudgetary revenue, soared from 1980-1993. Many commentators feared that the central

government had lost political control over provincial leaders because of the latter’s growing

fiscal autonomy (Wang 1995; Wang and Hu 1995).

To address the problems discussed above, the central government replaced fiscal contracting

with a tax-sharing system (fenshuizhi) in 1994. This reform abolished particularistic fiscal

63

“Local governments” thus refer to the provincial and sub-provincial levels of administration.

Page 97: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

85

contracting that defined the 1980-1993 period; instead, it reassigned taxes between the central

and provincial governments by establishing three tax categories: central taxes, local taxes, and

shared taxes (primarily the value-added tax or VAT). The central government also instituted

central tax collection agencies alongside local tax bureaus across the country. In short, the 1994

fiscal reform recentralized revenue and simplified the tax structure.

The 1994 reform was bold but incomplete. Provincial governments were forced to submit more

revenue to the central government than before, but as a compromise, tax rebates were

awarded based on the amount of revenue collected in 1993. Furthermore, while the 1994

reform instituted tax-sharing between the central and provincial governments, it did not specify

the terms of tax sharing at the sub-provincial levels and hence did not entirely eliminate

particularistic fiscal contracting. The central government also recentralized revenue without

sufficiently adjusting expenditure assignments, thus increasing fiscal pressures on local

governments. Fiscal transfers took on greater significance after 1994. With more revenue, the

central government distributed larger amounts of grants to provincial governments, which then

decides how the transfers would be assigned to the localities in its jurisdiction.

Inter-governmental Fiscal Contracting

Many experts saw inter-governmental fiscal contracting as a crucial reform and growth strategy

in China. Susan Shirk (1993) argued that Deng Xiaoping and his reformist team had “played to

the provinces” in a bid to counter resistance against market reforms from central party

bureaucrats. For the Chinese reformers, particularistic fiscal contracting was the dominant

strategy, as it not only benefited provincial public finances, but also provided opportunities for

distributing personal patronage. As Shirk puts it, particularistic contracting “gave party and

government officials at every level opportunities to earn political support from subordinates in

exchange for granting them generous contract terms” (1993, 16).

Other scholars focused on the developmental role of fiscal contracting. Fiscal contracting

provided each level of government the right to retain within-budgetary taxes in excess of an

agreed quota and all the extrabudgetary funds; in exchange for contracts, local governments

Page 98: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

86

took on more spending responsibilities. To generate more revenue, local governments pursued

industrialization and investments actively, in particular, by promoting township and village

enterprises (TVEs), which provided the bulk of local extrabudgetary revenue up until the 1990s

(Oi 1992; 1999). To support development, local governments also offered a whole gamut of

services (Blecher and Shue 2001).

Elaborating on the role of fiscal incentives in China’s growth, Montinola, Qian & Weingast (1995)

contended that China represented a case of market-preserving federalism (MPF). Under MPF,

the central government granted local governments economic autonomy in their jurisdictions

and imposed hard budget constraints (see also Oi 1992). As the authors saw it, this arrangement

was politically stable. Fiscal contracting created a direct link between the economy and fiscal

resources, thus motivating local governments to pursue growth. As argued, fiscal contracting

also induced local governments to compete for investments and taxes, thus constraining

governmental rent-seeking.

Empirical studies find evidence that inter-governmental fiscal incentives do matter for

development. Analysts find a positive relationship between provincial revenue retention rate

and market development in China (Jin et al 2005). Contrasting the Chinese case, it was found

that Russian local governments did not get to keep marginal revenue increases from regional

governments and hence were unmotivated to supply public goods or constrain predation

(Zhuraskarya 2003). To sum up, the authors contend that fiscal incentives propelled local

developmental efforts, and these actions in turn contributed to China’s rapid growth.

The Matrix Structure and Dual Fiscal Incentives

The previous literature discussed has focused on fiscal decentralization between levels of

government. My account of bureau-contracting suggests that fiscal decentralization took place

not only between but also within levels of government. To explain my point, let us first review

the “matrix” state structure in China. I present a stylization in Figure 4.1. There are five formal

levels of government, which I represent as three levels: central, provincial, and sub-provincial

governments. Multiple line bureaucracies exist at the central level, depicted as A, B, and C in

Page 99: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

87

Figure 4.1, which are replicated down the hierarchy. Each level of government is composed of a

parallel set of party and governmental organizations, headed by the Party Committee and

Government Office respectively. The “heads of state” at each level are equivalent to the

headquarters of a multi-tiered corporation. I represent them as red stars in Figure 4.1.

Figure 4.1: Dual Fiscal Incentives

CENTRAL

PROVINCES

SUB-

PROVINCES

Inter-governmental

contracting

Intra-

governmental

contracting

Intra-

governmental

contracting

Intra-

governmental

contracting

3

A B C

A B C

A B C

Superimposed on this matrix structure are dual fiscal incentives. First, inter-governmental fiscal

contracting is a vertical exchange that produces developmental fiscal incentives. Upper level

governments grant the lower level government the right to keep a negotiated portion of

revenue. Here, levels of governments (as collective bodies) are the contracting parties. Second,

bureau-contracting is a horizontal exchange that produces entrepreneurial rents-collecting fiscal

incentives. As detailed in Chapter 2, each level of government (i.e. “the red stars”) contracts

with individual offices, authorizing them to generate self-financed income and then to keep all

or a share of their earnings. These arrangements imply that local governments and individual

offices each have rights to surpluses. Local governments have rights to revenue surpluses,

Page 100: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

88

composed of tax revenue (shared with upper level governments) and extrabudgetary revenue.

Disaggregating the local governments, individual offices have rights to self-financed income.

Having described the matrix structure, we may now see that each bureaucracy at each level of

government is faced with mixed incentives, one to maximize revenue for the local treasury, and

the other to extract departmental surpluses. Facing mixed incentives, local officials in China

often behave in paradoxical ways. On the one hand, local officials are always eager to develop

new market opportunities and draw investments into their localities. But on the other hand,

stories of agencies slapping businesses with fees, fines, and inconveniences seem to abound as

well. I would argue that officials in China are neither purely developmental nor predatory but

both. But how can they be both? More precisely, what keeps the predatory elements from

negating developmental goals and efforts?

Critical to explaining sustained development in China is explaining why bureaucratic predation

has not appeared to “runaway,” as we have seen in other corrupt and rents-ridden states. The

preceding chapters have identified and detailed the institutional mechanisms of bureau-

contracting. In doing so, I distinguished self-financing in the Chinese context from state-

corroding forms of extraction. In this chapter, I add that endogenous limits to bureaucratic

predation exist in complement with mechanisms of rents management. I call these limits

endogenous because they arise naturally, so to speak, and unplanned from the structure of dual

fiscal incentives. They are not consciously imposed by central or reforming authorities.

First, I hypothesize that local cadres benefit more in the short-term from extracting funds for

their own departments than from increased tax revenue. This hypothesis is easy to understand.

Think about self-financed income earned by individual offices as “club funds.” Club funds belong

to the bureaus and can be used to finance jobs, wages, and benefits, subject to some spending

controls. In contrast, tax revenues are like “common pool funds.” Retained taxes serve the

entire locality; they finance both public goods and private goods for the officialdom. So

increases in self-financed income will provide more cadre rewards than equivalent increases in

tax revenue.

Page 101: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

89

Second, I hypothesize that the monetary benefits from self-financing are only short-lived,

whereas the financial rewards from increased tax revenue are cumulative. This hypothesis is less

straightforward and harder to test empirically. As we can gather from the earlier chapters, self-

financed income supplies cadre compensation and some administrative costs, but they are

generally not reinvested, and not used for infrastructural development or social goods provision.

Any increase in self-financed income is therefore like a one-time bonus that expires in a single

period. In contrast, to increase tax revenue collection, local governments have to undertake

long-term developmental efforts (e.g. cultivate strategic industries, urban planning, develop

enterprise incentive packages), attract new businesses, and help promote existing ones. Local

governments may reinvest surplus tax revenue productively, e.g. building new roads and

infrastructure, or spend the funds on social welfare projects, in addition to paying cadres higher

subsidies and allowances. While cadres may not benefit financially from state developmental

efforts immediately, the economic gains should be realized cumulatively over future time

periods.

Phrased succinctly, the implications of the discussion above are as follows:

• H1 (Rent-Seeking Incentives): Increased self-financed income provides only short-term

benefits to individual cadres, but no long-term benefits.

• H2 (Developmental Incentives): Increased tax revenues provide both short-term and

long-term benefits to individual cadres.

Read together, the hypotheses state that Chinese bureaucracies do not face either rent-seeking

or developmental incentives – they face both. The dual fiscal incentive structure distinguishes

Chinese bureaucracies from purely rational bureaucracies that do not make prebendal income.

The structure also distinguishes Chinese bureaucracies from quintessentially predatory

bureaucracies that have rent-seeking incentives but not developmental incentives.

My formulation allows us to evaluate and refine previously untested assumptions in several

strands of literature. Firstly, the fiscal contracting literature proposes that local growth increases

Page 102: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

90

tax revenue, thus motivating local officials to pursue development (Oi 1992; Oi 1999; Montinola

et al 1996). This proposition is premised on the condition that increased tax revenue delivers

personal benefits to the local officialdom. To date, however, we have not seen empirical

evidence for this assumption. H2 aims to test the strength of developmental incentives by

measuring the effects of increased tax revenues on local cadre rewards.

Secondly, the rent-seeking literature on China implies that rent-seeking incentives dominate

developmental incentives (e.g. Pei 2006; Lu 2000a), but fails to provide systematic evidence for

this claim. If they were right, we should observe that only Hypothesis 1 holds. That is, Chinese

cadres benefit only from increased self-financed income but not from increased tax revenue.

Rational bureaucrats, facing this condition, will forgo collective developmental efforts and focus

instead on extracting funds for their respective offices. By comparing Hypothesis 1 against

Hypothesis 2, we can evaluate the relative strengths of rent-seeking and developmental

incentives, and thereby adjudicate between competing claims.

Thirdly, the aforementioned literatures have all neglected the temporal dimension of fiscal

incentives. Existing models specify bureaucratic behavior as if rent-seeking and developmental

incentives are mutually exclusive, when in fact, my theory contends, they coexist but along

different time horizons. Chinese bureaucracies face powerful short-term incentives to extract

revenue for their own benefits. In the short-run, such incentives are likely more powerful than

the financial rewards from increased tax revenues and developmental efforts. However, I

contend that only increased tax revenues yield improvements to cadre compensation and

privileges in the long term. In other words, it is those cadres in regions with vibrant business

conditions and a stable tax base who can enjoy a consistent growth in income and benefits. In

the next section, I proceed to discuss the data used to test the hypotheses proposed.

Data, Measurements & Descriptive Statistics

For the purpose of this analysis, I collected and constructed a county-level budget panel dataset

from Shandong province in the period of 2001-2005. The original data was compiled and

published by the Shandong Provincial Finance Bureau, likely for internal policy-making purposes.

Page 103: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

91

It is therefore a highly reliable source. The data provides an aggregated line-item budget for

each county government in Shandong province, allowing us to identify the amount of personnel

and administrative spending. Unfortunately, it does not break down the county budgets by

departments, but the existing data is sufficient for our purposes.

Budget data is not easy to obtain in China. The data that I use is classified as “internal” (neibu),

i.e., not available for public view. One reason for such secrecy is that this data is far more

informative than data published in the national and local statistical yearbooks. The publicly

available budgets list governmental spending by broad categories (e.g. education, health,

agriculture), not line items (e.g. salaries, transportation, equipment, etc.). They are either

misleading or too thin for meaningful analysis. To my best knowledge, this is the first attempt to

employ line-item budget data from China for empirical testing. My data also provides an

unusually detailed view of how different pots of public funds are actually spent at the sub-

provincial levels in China.

The county is the most important level of local government in China and therefore most

appropriate for our analysis. County governments account for one half of sub-national

expenditure (World Bank 2002, 34) and a major portion of gross domestic production. It is also

at the county level where the delivery of public services is concentrated and overstaffing in the

state bureaucracies most severe (World Bank 2007; World Bank 2002, 158). Therefore, public

spending in the county governments has a significant impact on local economic development

and social welfare.

How representative is Shandong of the rest of China? Shandong is one of the most populous

provinces, situated on the Northern coast. While Shandong is not as wealthy as the Southern

engines like Guangdong or Jiangsu, it is among the fastest growing. Additionally, Shandong still

has a substantial agricultural sector, and its population is composed of a Han majority. In 2005,

there were 142 county governments, ranging widely in population size and economic status.64 It

is reasonable to assume that counties in Shandong are roughly representative of the counties in

coastal and central China, where the vast majority of the population lives. However, we may

64

The dataset has only 139 counties, as three of them did not exist prior to 2004.

Page 104: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

92

expect a very different political and economic dynamic in regions of Western China with a large

minority population (e.g. Tibet and Xinjiang), as well as in impoverished areas dependent on

fiscal transfers.65 Nonetheless, by focusing on the Shandong case as a first step in our analyses,

we can control for the effects of ethnicity and provincial-level idiosyncrasies.

Measuring Cadre Rewards

For our analysis, we need to measure the material benefits that accrue to the local cadre class.

To do so, I divide total public spending in each Shandong county into two major categories:

cadre rewards and social benefits. Cadre rewards include wage payments, subsidies, and

administrative benefits (see Chapter 3). Social benefits include public construction and social

welfare assistance. I exclude a sub-category of “acquisitions and repairs” from both categories,

as it was unclear from the budget description whether this spending goes towards cadre

rewards (e.g. construction of cadre housing) or public goods (e.g. road repairs). Therefore, the

true size of cadre rewards may be larger than estimated here.

County Spending Structure. Figure 4.3 shows the average county spending structure in Shandong

from 2001-2005. Cadre rewards compose at least three-quarters of total spending, ranging from

74 percent to 83 percent.66 On average, each county government spent 447 million yuan on

cadre benefits annually. The situation in Shandong appears consistent with Park et al’s view that

“most local governments put first priority on meeting their wage bills, which constitute the vast

majority of expenditures” (1996, 771).

County Revenue Structure. County government finances in this study are composed of three

parts: retained tax revenues, fiscal transfers, and self-financed income. Unfortunately, we do

not have information on the entire category of extrabudgetary revenue. Nonetheless, in this

65

A rough comparison of public employment size in Shandong counties vs. all of China’s counties finds the

former representative of national patterns, but excluding remote regions (e.g. mountainous areas in the

West) and provincial-level municipalities (e.g. mega districts in Shanghai). 66

We do not have comparable sub-provincial budget data across countries. From a comparative

perspective, this figure may not be unusually high as governments tend to spend the bulk of public funds

on personnel and administrative costs.

Page 105: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

93

analysis, we are primarily comparing the effects of retained tax revenues and self-financed

income on cadre benefits. Hence, the data available is sufficiently useful for our purposes.

Figure 4.2: Decomposition of Public

Spending

Figure 4.3: County Spending Structure

83%

9%

8%

76%

14%

10%

74%

16%

10%

74%

16%

10%

74%

15%

11%

02

0,0

00

40

,00

06

0,0

00

80

,00

0

Pu

blic

Sp

en

din

g (

10

00

0 Y

ua

n)

2001 2002 2003 2004 2005

Cadre benefits Acquisitions & repairs

Social benefits

Figure 4.4: Revenue

Structure

44%

32%

24%

37%

29%

34%

33%

30%

32%

35%

33%

32%

40%

31%

29%

020,0

00

40,0

00

60,0

00

80,0

00

Am

ount of in

com

e (

10000 Y

uan)

2001 2002 2003 2004 2005

tax revenue fiscal transfers

self-financing

Each revenue stream is composed of the following elements. First, retained tax revenues.

Following the 1994 fiscal reform, local governments are entitled to a portion of shared taxes and

local taxes. The bulk of tax revenues come from business activities, for example, the shared

value-added tax, commerce tax, and local enterprise income tax. Hence, to collect more taxes,

local governments have to attract businesses. I list the different tax categories in Table 4.1

above. Second, self-financed income is the sum of fines, fees, and revenue earned by individual

Page 106: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

94

bureaucracies from business activities and service charges not accounted as fines and fees.67

Finally, fiscal transfers include equalization transfers and conditional aid from the upper level

governments.

Table 4.1: Tax Categories After the 1994 Fiscal Reform (Tax-Sharing System)

Central Taxes Local Taxes Shared Taxes

1. Customs tax

2. Consumption tax and

value-added tax

collected by the customs

authority

3. Consumption tax

4. Central enterprise

income tax

5. Income tax of local

banks, foreign banks,

and non-bank financial

institutions

6. Commerce tax, income

tax, profit and urban

management &

construction tax

collected from railway

companies, banks, and

insurance companies.

7. Retained profits of

central state-owned

enterprises

8. Export refund of foreign-

invested enterprises

1. Commerce tax

2. Local enterprise income

tax

3. Retained profits from

local state-owned

enterprises

4. Personal income tax

5. Urban land use tax

6. Fixed assets tax

7. Urban management &

construction tax

8. Real estate tax

9. Vehicle and vessel tax

10. Stamp tax

11. Slaughter tax

12. Agriculture tax

13. Agriculture special

product tax

14. Arable land use tax

15. Deed tax

16. Inheritance tax

17. Land appreciation tax

18. Revenue from leasing

state land

1. Value-added tax

Central 75%

Local 25%

2. Resource tax

Petrol tax belongs to

central; the remaining

to local governments

3. Securities exchange tax

Central 50%

Local 50%

Source: Thirty years of China’s Fiscal Reform (Zhongguo caizheng gaige sanshinian), p. 63.

The three revenue streams each compose about one-third of total revenue. Self-financed

income is a significant part of county public finance. Average self-financed income increased

steadily each year at an annual rate of 0.24 percent in 2002, 12 percent in 2003, 19 percent in

2004, and 7 percent in 2005.68 The highest rate of increase in self-financed income in 2003 and

67

Only this portion of the extrabudgetary revenues is reported by county in the original dataset. A MOF

official I have consulted with agreed that this is a reasonable estimate of revenue belonging to individual

offices (AI 2008-149). 68

The reasons for the drop in percentage in 2005 are unclear.

Page 107: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

95

2004 correlates with the sharpest drop in tax revenues and fiscal transfers, suggesting that

county bureaucracies had to earn more income to compensate for lower state budget

allocations.

Variation of Cadre Rewards and Income Streams

Cadre rewards vary extremely widely across the 139 counties in Shandong Province. Measured

in absolute terms, they vary from 71 million to 1.48 billion yuan, a 20:1 maximum/minimum

ratio. Taking population size into account, cadre rewards span from 178 to 4,010 yuan per capita.

The average county cadre in Shandong received 29,222 yuan in direct and indirect benefits each

year, ranging from as little as 8,970 yuan in Chengwu County to 150,305 yuan in Laoshan

County.

Table 4.2: Descriptive Statistics of Cadre Rewards, 2001-2005

Mean Std. Dev Min Max

Cadre rewards (million yuan) 447 244 71 1479

Cadre rewards per capita (yuan) 755 447 178 4010

Cadre rewards per cadre (yuan) 29,222 16,990 8,970 150,305

Change in cadre rewards 58 93 -357 450

Change in cadre rewards per capita 99 177 -716 954

Change in cadre rewards per cadre 3,789 6,620 -14,843 39,460

The rate of change in cadre rewards varied considerably as well. Mean change in total cadre

rewards was 58 million yuan, but the standard deviation was 93 million yuan. Likewise, the

average change in rewards per cadre was an increment of 3,789 yuan, but the standard

deviation was 6,620 yuan. In the minimum case, each cadre suffered a drop of 14,843 yuan in

rewards, equivalent to one-half of mean per cadre, while in the maximum case, cadres enjoyed

a dramatic raise of 39,460 yuan in a single year. Such large fluctuations in compensation are

unusual in most governments, as public personnel receive regular wages from state budget

allocations and follow a fixed pay structure. These large shifts in annual public personnel

benefits in China provide yet another piece of evidence that actual cadre payoffs are not

determined by a formal compensation scale; they are directly connected to the income of local

governments and individual offices in the localities. They may therefore fluctuate widely.

Page 108: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

96

Table 4.3: Descriptive Statistics of Income Streams, 2001-2005

Mean Std. Dev Min Max

Tax revenue per capita (yuan) 435 402 13 4270

Fiscal transfers per capita (yuan) 352 273 0 2483

Self-financed income per capita (yuan) 316 172 31 1756

Change in tax revenue per capita (yuan) 17 231 -1199 1541

Change in fiscal transfers per capita (yuan) 21 149 -779 767

Change in self-financed income per capita (yuan) 31 91 -475 582

We also observe wide variation in the levels of income streams across counties. Tax revenue per

capita ranges from 13 to 4,270 yuan per capita; fiscal transfers from 0 to 2,483 yuan per capita;

and self-financed income from 31 to 1,756 yuan per capita. We also observe fluctuations in the

three income streams, and with such fluctuations varying widely across the units. Mean change

in tax revenue per capita was an increase of 17 yuan, about 4 percent of the mean, with a

standard deviation of 231 yuan. Mean change in self-financed per capita was larger than that of

tax revenue at 31 yuan, about 10 percent of the mean, with a smaller standard deviation of 91

yuan. In the next section, we proceed to examine the relationships between the shifts in cadre

benefits and the shifts in revenue streams.

Regression Analysis Using the ECM

In this section, we test the implications laid out in Section III, using a single-equation error-

correction model (ECM) on a panel dataset. My theory predicts that rent-seeking strategies

provide only short-term benefits, but developmental efforts deliver both short-term and long-

term benefits to the local officialdom. I operationalize this proposition by proxying rent-seeking

strategies with self-financed income earned by individual bureaucracies and developmental

efforts with retained tax revenues belonging collectively to county governments. Framed in

operationalized terms, I expect increased self-financed income to produce a large but only

transitory boost to cadre benefits, while increased tax revenues will contribute to a gradual but

cumulative growth in compensation and privileges for local cadres, holding other conditions

equal.

Page 109: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

97

The ECM specification is particularly well-suited for our analysis as it enables us to estimate the

parameters of the short-term and long-term effects of the explanatory variables on the

dependent variable simultaneously. The basic idea of the ECM is that there exists a long-run

equilibrium between two or more time series variables, but with short-lived deviations from the

equilibrium.69 Effects of changes in independent variables on the dependent variable may either

be contemporaneous (i.e. limited to a single period) or cumulative (i.e. extended over several

future periods). Using the ECM, we may estimate and compare the temporal effects of changes

in the revenue structure on changes in cadre rewards.

We measure the dependent variable of “cadre rewards” in two ways: rewards per cadre and

cadre rewards per capita. Rewards per cadre measures how changes in the revenue structure

affects the material payoffs of individual cadres, providing a direct indication of the incentives

facing an average cadre, which is critical for assessing our predictions. Cadre rewards per capita

reflects the level of spending on cadre rewards adjusted for population size. Following

conventional analyses of public financial data, we also measure each of the fiscal variables (tax

revenue, self-financed income, and fiscal transfers) in per capita terms.

In the analyses, we control for a number of possible socio-economic determinants of cadre

rewards: GDP per capita, population size, share of urban population, and size of public

employment. We do not need to include controls for minority populations, as these are

negligible in Shandong province, or a dummy for the capital city of Jinan, as city employment

and spending have been excluded from the data.

The ECM specification requires that we include (a) the lagged dependent variable, (b) the lagged

levels of the independent and control variables, and (c) the differenced value of the

independent and control variables. In addition, to control for time-invariant unobserved effects

across the county governments, e.g. historical legacies or cultural attitudes toward cadre

entitlement, we include county dummies in the regression. To control for unit-invariant

69

One common application of the ECM in political science is in voting theories. While there is a normally

stable voting structure reflecting cleavages in society, there are also short-term fluctuations in vote

support in response to transitory “shocks.”

Page 110: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

98

exogenous shocks, e.g. abolition of the agricultural tax in 2002, we include year dummies for

each year of analysis. The error correction version of the model can be expressed as follows:

∆CADREWt = α1 + β1CADREWt-1 + β2∆TAXREVt + β3TAXREVt-1+β4∆SELFINt + β5SELFINt-1 +

β6∆FISTRANt + β7FISTRANt-1 + ∑ controls + ∑ county and time dummies + errors

(1)

where CADREREW = cadre rewards per cadre and per capita, TAXREV = retained tax revenue per

capita, SELFIN = self-financed income per capita, FISTRAN = fiscal transfers per capita. The

parameters β2, β4, and β6 estimate the short-term effects of a one-unit change in tax revenue,

self-financed income, and fiscal transfers respectively on change in cadre rewards, while β3, β5,

and β7 capture the long-term effects. In other words, if the lagged fiscal variables are statistically

significant, then X has a long-term effect on Y; however, the long-term effect does not register

fully immediately but is distributed over future time periods. Substantively, the long-term

multiplier effect equals the coefficient of the lagged independent variable divided by the

negative value of the lagged dependent variable (-β1). The value of the lagged dependent

variable is the error correction term, which indicates the rate at which equilibrium errors are

corrected. That parameter gives us the speed at which the effects of X on Y are realized over

time.

Following the discussion in Section III, the first expectation from theory is that change in self-

financed income will register a larger short-term effect on cadre benefits than an equivalent

change in tax revenue (Hypothesis 1). In the context of the regression, we expect both β2 and β4

to be statistically significant, and β4 to be larger than β2. We also predict that growth in tax

revenue will have a long-term impact on improving cadre benefits, in addition to having a

contemporaneous effect, while an increase in self-financed income will not benefit local cadres

in the long-term (Hypothesis 2). Translated into statistical terms, we expect β5 to be

insignificant.

Page 111: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

99

Results of Analyses

Table 4.4 reports the results of the regressions, which are consistent with expectations. With

two-level fixed effects included in Model 3, the first differences of TAXREV and SELFIN register a

significant and positive effect on CADREW per cadre, with TAXREV having a smaller coefficient

than SELFIN. In the same year, a unit increase in TAXREV will increase the value of benefits for

each cadre by 18 yuan, while a unit increase in SELFIN will raise cadre rewards by 26 yuan. In

other words, in the short-term, the average cadre benefits about 45 percent more from

increased self-financed income than from an equivalent increase in tax revenue.

Similar results hold in Model 6, with CADREW per capita as the dependent variable. The

coefficient of 0.95 on the first differenced of SELFIN indicates that 95 percent of every one-yuan

increase in SELFIN per capita goes towards cadre rewards. This indicates that SELFIN earned and

owned by individual bureaucracies are indeed “club funds.” Almost all of such income finances

private and club goods for local cadres, not public goods provision. In comparison, only 53

percent of increases in TAXREV contributed to cadre benefits, which is consistent with our

earlier characterization of tax revenue as “common pool funds” for the entire locality.

Table 4.4: Determinants of Cadre Rewards in Shandong Counties (2001-2005)

DV= D. Cadre Rewards per Cadre DV= D. Cadre Rewards per Capita

Model (1) Model (2) Model (3) Model (1) Model (2) Model (3)

L. tax revenue

per capita

3.997***

(1.013)

16.742***

(2.516)

13.969***

(2.716)

0.155***

(0.024)

0.542***

(0.060)

0.526***

(0.066)

D. tax revenue

per capita

12.073***

(1.108)

19.475***

(1.942)

18.188***

(1.973)

0.332***

(0.027)

0.540***

(0.046)

0.531***

(0.048)

L. self-financed

income per

capita

-6.188***

(1.603)

4.034

(4.041)

3.864

(4.015)

0.126**

(0.050)

0.479***

(0.103)

0.483***

(0.104)

D. self-financed

income per

capita

25.483***

(2.164)

25.460***

(2.804)

25.605***

(2.867)

0.849***

(0.055)

0.941***

(0.068)

0.949***

(0.071)

L. fiscal

transfers per

capita

-0.357

(1.065)

4.062

(2.683)

-1.808

(3.143)

0.258***

(0.032)

0.445***

(0.067)

0.421***

(0.079)

D. fiscal

transfers per

5.649***

(1.431)

7.863***

(2.066)

4.680**

(2.320)

0.348***

(0.038)

0.430***

(0.051)

0.420***

(0.058)

Page 112: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

100

capita

Controls

L. public

employees (in

1000)

-0.279***

(0.082)

-0.932**

(0.383)

-1.128***

(0.392)

-0.003

(0.002)

0.008

(0.009)

0.007

(0.009)

D. public

employees

-1.631***

(0.262)

-1.167***

(0.328)

-0.954***

(0.333)

-0.001

(0.007)

-0.009

(0.008)

-0.008

(0.008)

L. population (in

10000)

53.202***

(19.168)

434.587***

(88.311)

394.431***

(88.058)

0.268

(0.442)

2.007

(2.095)

1.870

(2.134)

D. population 10.765

(37.788)

-176.650***

(56.463)

-172.595***

(55.810)

-5.459***

(0.995)

-3.847***

(1.382)

-3.789***

(1.388)

L. urban share

of population

-0.803

(10.953)

73.076

(45.863)

45.024

(46.540)

0.013

(0.276)

-1.483

(1.117)

-1.566

(1.152)

D. urban share

of population

26.562

(20.306)

-31.653

(42.575)

-8.102

(43.069)

0.061

(0.518)

1.207

(1.037)

1.250

(1.070)

L. GDP per

capita (in 10000

Y)

1056.001***

(281.238)

2161.292***

(578.929)

1548.202**

(603.871)

-6.122

(6.722)

18.861

(13.777)

16.870

(14.828)

D. GDP per

capita

-214.397

(413.255)

-1181.3**

(491.689)

-801.781

(497.619)

25.643**

(10.454)

-2.074

(11.828)

-0.574

(12.245)

Lagged DV -0.014

(0.034)

-0.445***

(0.051)

-0.482***

(0.518)

-0.237***

(0.039)

-0.636***

(0.048)

-0.637***

(0.049)

County Effects? No Yes Yes No Yes Yes

Time Effects? No No Yes No No Yes

Constant 3369.017

(969.230)

-13326.25

(7912.835)

575.176

(8881.792)

54.00

(22.98)

-293.38

(192.26)

0.637

(0.049)

N 556 556 556 556 556 556

R2 0.50 0.59 0.60 0.60 0.68 0.68

Standard errors in parenthesis. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01

Having examined the short-term effects, we now turn to the long-term effects. Results in Model

3 are consistent with Hypothesis 2. Lagged TAXREV is statistically significant, while lagged SELFIN

is not, meaning only TAXREV has a long-term effect on CADREW per cadre. As earlier discussed,

this long-term impact is likely because growing tax revenue involves taking developmental

actions, such as attracting businesses and constructing infrastructure, which produce a

multiplier effect on the local economy and cadre compensation. In Model 3, the cumulative

effect of a one-yuan increase in tax revenue on CADREW per cadre is 29 yuan. This effect occurs

at a rate dictated by the error correction term, which is 0.482. Equilibrium errors are corrected

at the rate of 48 percent, leaving 52 percent of the disequilibrium shock after one year, 27

percent after two years, 14 percent after three years, and so on. Concretely, that means

Page 113: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

101

increased tax revenue has a long-term effect on improving benefits per cadre that is realized

over a period of about 10 years. The total short-term and long-term effects of increased TAXREV

on CADREW per cadre are 47 yuan, far exceeding the short-term effects of increased SELFIN,

which is 26 yuan.

While only increased taxes affect benefits per cadre in the long-term, both increased taxes and

self-financed income lead to a higher total spending on cadre rewards in the long-term, adjusted

for population size. In Model 6, both lagged TAXREV and SELFIN show statistically significant

effects on CADREW per capita. However, lagged SELFIN has a smaller coefficient of 0.48

compared to 0.53 of lagged TAXREV. In substantive terms, every one thousand yuan increase in

TAXREV and SELFIN per capita would contribute to a cumulative increase in CADREW per capita

of 754 yuan and 832 yuan respectively over several years. Nonetheless, from the perspective of

the individual cadre, total per capita increase in benefits matters less than per cadre increase in

benefits. Thus Model 3 provides strong support for Hypothesis 2.

To place the results in context, we simulate the short-term and long-term effects of fiscal

changes in one particular year on rewards per cadre, as summarized in Table 4.5. From 2004 to

2005, the Shandong counties saw a mean increase of 153 yuan in TAXREV per capita and 28

yuan in SELFIN per capita. We call this Scenario I. All things equal, those increases translate into

a growth in CADREW per cadre of 2,754 yuan and 728 yuan respectively, totaling 3,482 yuan.

Now imagine a Scenario II. The county cadres decided to slack on developmental efforts,

resulting in a stagnation of tax revenue, and instead to compensate for the loss in tax growth by

collecting more self-financed income that year, such as by extracting more fees and fines. In

Scenario II, the counties would experience no increase in TAXREV and 181 yuan increase in

SELFIN per capita. Each cadre would enjoy 4,635 yuan growth in benefits, over a thousand yuan

more than in Scenario I. This suggests that cadres face strong temptations to direct resources

away from developmental efforts toward rent-seeking, as the latter delivers larger immediate

rewards, but only in the short-term.

Calculations change, however, once long-term effects are taken into account. In Scenario I, an

increase in TAXREV of 153 yuan has a cumulative effect on benefits per cadre totaling 4,437

Page 114: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

102

yuan, which will occur over an approximately ten-year period, while increased SELFIN has no

long-term impact. The total effect of the fiscal changes is to increase benefits per cadre by 7,919

yuan. Conversely, in Scenario II, the cadres each received a larger immediate boost in rewards

than they would have had in Scenario I, but over the long term, nothing more. The total effect of

a one-time decision to replace tax growth by collecting more self-financed income is to increase

individual cadre benefits by 4,706 yuan, three thousand yuan less than the increase in Scenario I.

If such a decision were repeated over several years, the cumulative impact of a relative loss of

income to the local cadres is substantial. In other words, with a longer-term horizon in view, it

does not pay for local bureaucracies to behave in purely predatory or rent-seeking ways.

Table 4.5: Simulation of Short-Term and Long-Term Effects on Benefits Per Cadre

Change in Revenue

Per Capita

Short-Term Effects Long-Term Effects Total Effects on

CADREW per cadre

Scenario I TAXREV = $153

SEFLIN = $28

$2,754 + $728 =

$3,482

$4,437 + $0 =

$4,437

$7,919

Scenario II TAXREV = $0

SEFLIN = $181

$0 + $4,706 =

$4,706

$0 + $0 =

$0

$4,706

The effects of fiscal transfers deserve some elaboration. As reported in Models 3 and 6, an

increase in FISTRAN has only a short-term effect but no long-term effect on CADBEN per cadre,

and both a short-term and long-term effect on CADREW per capita. In both specifications of the

dependent variable, the effects of FISTRAN are small compared to those of TAXREV and SELFIN.

In Model 3, every yuan increase in FISTRAN will increase rewards per cadre by merely 5 yuan,

compared to 18 yuan and 26 yuan in the case of TAXREV and SELFIN. In Model 6, the cumulative

effect of a 1,000 yuan growth in FISTRAN compared to an equivalent growth in TAXREV and

SELFIN on total cadre rewards per capita is 660 yuan, compared to 825 and 758 yuan in the two

other categories. Consistent with expectations, the results indicate that fiscal transfers are the

least important of the three revenue streams in affecting cadre compensation and perks.

Finally, turning to the control variables, we find unsurprisingly that the size of public

employment affects CADBEN per cadre negatively in Model 3. On average 183 staff are added to

the county bureaucracies each year, which would reduce rewards per cadre by a modest sum of

174 yuan. Population size shows a negative short-term effect but a positive long-term effect on

Page 115: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

103

CADBEN per cadre. This could be that an increased population produces more demand for

public goods provision in the short-term, diverting funds from cadre rewards. Nevertheless, over

a longer period a larger population may contribute to the local labor force or provide more

targets for rents extraction, thus benefiting the cadres. GDP per capita registers only a long-

term effect on CADREW per cadre, reflecting the delayed rewards that cadres gain from

economic development in their locality. The mean annual increase in GDP per capita is about

3,000 yuan. A one-time mean increase will produce a cumulative growth in benefits per cadre by

963 yuan that will occur over a decade, a 3 percent increment over the average level of benefits.

To summarize, results of my analysis support the claim that local Chinese cadres face short-term

incentives to extract self-financed income for their own departments, but long-term incentives

to grow the local economy and expand the tax base. Developmental efforts and in turn

increased tax revenue generate multiplier effects, both on the local economy and on individual

cadre payoffs. These payoffs do not accrue immediately, but accumulate gradually over time. In

other words, ignoring the future, local cadres harvest more present gains from extracting

departmental rents than from cultivating the tax base. However, if the local officials are far-

sighted enough, they will realize that neglecting market development hurts their pockets in the

long-run. All things equal, those cadres who enjoy the highest compensation growth are those in

localities with thriving businesses that can contribute to the state treasury.

Incentive-Compatibility vs. Instruments of Oversight

My findings add confidence to the hypothesis that endogenous limits on bureaucratic predation

arise when fiscal contracting interacts with bureau-contracting. Yet, one may rightly counter

that a collective action problem remains unsolved. Even if each bureau perceives its long-term

interests in economic development, it still has an incentive to extract and shirk its

developmental role. The costs will be widely distributed across the local government and the

benefits concentrated in the particular bureau that “cheats.” Such a problem will still lead the

bureaus “to ‘overfish’ in the ‘commons’ or the rental havens” (Bardhan 1997, 1325).

Page 116: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

104

My responses to the collective action problem identified above are two-fold. First, it should be

pointed out that the Chinese government has essentially exchanged one kind of collective action

problem for another. Should the government choose to pool the funds collected by each bureau,

without giving them a full or partial residual claim, each bureau will have an incentive to shirk its

revenue-making responsibilities and leave it to others to do the job. This collective action

problem would lead to an under-farming of revenue, which would be an especially serious

problem in light of heightened budgetary pressures in the 1990s, as will be discussed in Chapter

5. Hence, this takes us to the second point. Second, in confronting the potential collective action

problem of “overfishing in the commons,” the state in China, both at the central and local levels,

has devised alternative mechanisms to cope with it.

Mechanisms of bureau-contracting. As argued, the structure of bureau-contracting presents the

foundational set of mechanisms for managing rents provision. By institutionalizing the processes

of exacting self-financed income, the state at each level not only obtains information about the

flow of departmental funds, it also exercises control over what kinds of revenue may or may not

be collected, based on policy awards formulated. By drawing departmental funds into the state

account system, the finance authorities can also implement rules governing the use of those

proceeds. We discuss these mechanisms below.

Mechanisms of promotion. But that is not all. The criteria used for official assessment and

promotion provide another important set of mechanisms. Hierarchical personnel management

is the key to personnel control in China. As several studies have shown, the two most important

criteria for the promotion of local leaders are growth rates and revenue collections (Li and Zhou

2004).70 The local leadership’s almost single-minded focus on growth and taxes guarantee their

attention to business conditions.

Specialized economic agencies. As Wade noted in his study of Taiwan’s developmental

experience, “governing the market requires a small number of powerful policy-making agencies

able to maintain the priorities” (1990, 195). Not unlike the East Asian NICs, many local

70

The adverse effects of this incentive is that local leaders tend to pursue growth at all costs, in particular,

at the costs of environmental protection.

Page 117: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

105

governments in China established specialized economic agencies to lead business development.

For example, one county I visited in Tianjin created a “large projects office” to attract and

manage multi-billion projects. Their officials are constantly on the move, flying across the

country to meet investors and to convince them to invest in their locality (AI 2007-93). Local FDI

(foreign direct investment) offices are also common. Much like the economic development

board (EDB) in Singapore, these offices specialize in planning the macro business environment

and bringing in foreign investments.

Diversified economic targets. At the same time, to keep the other offices in check, I have found

that diversified economic targets are created in some localities. It appears that economic targets

do not fall on the shoulders of local leaders alone. In the same Tianjin county, tax collection and

investment targets were distributed to almost every bureau. I was told even the county people’s

consultative committee (zhengxie), a non-economic organ, is given a target to bring in a certain

amount of investments to the locality each year (AI 2008-144). While this does not seem to

make sense in most governments, it helps local governments in China to keep different offices

involved in business development directly.

Could the institutional mechanisms described above suffice without endogenous limits? That is,

to what extent does it matter that each office and cadre benefit financially from long-term

growth? I would argue that it takes a combination of carrots and sticks to work. Controls, no

matter how tight, may slip. Giving each bureaucrat a personal stake in the local GDP is the

prerequisite to China’s high-powered developmental strategy. Without the “carrots,” it would

not have been possible to stimulate an across-the-board enthusiasm among cadres to pursue

local economic development. It is the promise of the cumulative rewards of collective wealth

that helps the officialdom to look beyond myopic departmental gains.

Conditions for Dual Fiscal Incentives

The structure of dual fiscal incentives balances on a delicate equilibrium that rests on two

conditions. The first condition is that fiscal incentives remain for local governments to pursue

growth and expand the tax base. In this regard, a critical questions arises is whether the 1994

Page 118: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

106

fiscal reform had diminished such positive incentives. Fortunately, the existing evidence

suggests although revenue has been recentralized since 1994, sub-provincial governments

continue to retain a significant share of taxes. My data from Shandong reveals that on average

the county governments retained 65 percent of total taxes collected, with a standard deviation

of 11.94 percent. Further, as Oi observed, “in spite of increased payments to the center, the

1994 system, like its predecessors, leaves the localities a clearly defined residual over which

they have exclusive rights” (Oi 1999, 55). In a similar vein of finding, Jin et al (2005) reported

that the marginal revenue retention rate of the provincial governments is significantly

associated with higher rates of non-state market development and reforms in the state sector

from 1970 to 1999.

A second condition is the availability of opportunities for business development. Some locales,

especially state designated poverty counties, are stuck in landlocked and resource-weak

locations with little hope of breaking out of poverty traps. Even if there were pro-growth fiscal

incentives available, these counties are unable to take advantage of them. Most of these

poverty counties are located in the western and central regions, not the coastal areas. They rely

extensively on fiscal transfers to subsist. My analysis of the Shandong case finds that self-

financed income and retained taxes are much stronger determinants of cadre rewards than

fiscal transfers. But we are likely to find a contrasting pattern of bureaucratic financing and

incentives in locales destined to poverty. It is in these places, I believe, where we expect to find

bureaucracies behaving in purely predatory ways.

Clearly, many questions remain about the longitudinal change in fiscal incentives over three

decades of reform in China. This analysis reflects only patterns in recent years, from 2001-2005.

While the scope of coverage is modest at this stage, it presents the first effort to identify and

test the existence of dual fiscal incentives. It is hoped that such an analysis will provide a useful

foundation for future data collection and analytical efforts.

Page 119: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

107

Conclusion

Collectively, the results of regression analyses using an error-correction model offer solid

evidence for a theory of dual fiscal incentives. We find that while local cadres benefit in the

short-term from extracting income for their departments, they benefit more in the long-term

from growing the local economy and expanding the tax base. In other words, in equilibrium,

bureaucratic rent-seeking in China, though seemingly prevalent, is not “runaway” and has not

thus far over-shadowed incentives for pursuing local development. Such equilibrium can be

maintained so long as upper level governments provide relatively secure and sufficiently

attractive fiscal incentives for lower units to pursue growth and in places where developmental

opportunities are available. Findings from this chapter bridges polarized views of China as a

“local developmental” vs. “decentralized predatory” state. They identify the institutional basis

for the paradoxical coexistence of local state-led development and bureaucratic rent-seeking in

China.

Page 120: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

108

CHAPTER 6

THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF BUREAUCRATIC ADAPTATION

The preceding chapters have established the mechanisms of bureau-contracting in the Chinese

context. This chapter takes a step backward and ponders the origins and development of the

state structure in China, which prompts a complex set of questions. Why did China not follow

the path of other developmental states and develop a fully salaried “Weberian” bureaucracy to

support capitalist development when markets opened in 1979? More broadly, what were the

unique conditions and goals of reform in China that shaped the structure of administration, or,

in other words, what makes the ideal-type of bureau-contracting rare compared to the

Weberian model? Is bureau-contracting merely a transition to the Weberian bureaucracy? Or is

it self-reinforcing?

The chapters that follow do not aim to retell the history of China’s administrative evolution

comprehensively and in detail. Rather, my objective is to extract the forces that shaped

bureaucratic structure in the context of a late-industrializing communist state, thus treating

state structure itself as a variable compound outcome. My approach, following several others

who have studied bureaucracies in democratic systems (Moe 1984; Geddes 1996), maintains

that bureaucratic structures in reforming autocracies are endogenous to politics and the

processes of development. State institutional patterns reflect political interests, changing

economic conditions, and unexpected contingencies of reforms.

Page 121: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

109

Pre-reform institutional legacies of bureau-contracting

This section traces the historical legacies of prebendal administration during early periods of

imperial rule. Interestingly, I find what seems to be the absorption and mutation of pre-modern

institutional features into the Maoist state structure.

Prebendalism in early imperial times

Although China is commonly known as one of the earliest bureaucratized state in history, its

bureaucratization had in fact been persistently incomplete, as some scholars have noted (Kiser

and Cai 2003). Generally, the imperial governments ruled over vast territories through a small

formal administration and a thick patron-client network emanating from the state and

penetrating down to the lowest reaches of society. This strategy of rule was not unique to the

Chinese empire, but common to large early states. The Ottoman Empire exercised a similar

strategy of rule, in which state bureaucrats co-opted bandits and governed alongside an

extensive chain of tax agents and sub-tax agents (Barkey 1994). The structural logic of the past

has persisted in China until the present day.

China has had a long history of prebendalism and patrimonial governance. Historically, the

Chinese administration was composed of a small core of formal state officials and an expansive

sub-layer of semi-officials. Officials were scholars who had passed the imperial examinations

and were formally appointed to office. Although the officials were entitled to a nominal salary

(feng) from the state budget, the salaries were woefully inadequate. Historians have named the

peripheral agents serving alongside the formal officialdom the “extrabureaucracy” (Rankin

1993), “the third realm” (Huang 1993), and “informal extension of the bureaucracy” (Hickey

1991). The extrabureaucracy was composed of two sets of functionaries. First, they included an

army of unsalaried clerks and runners who conducted rudimentary but critical tasks of

administration. They were otherwise known as the “talons and teeth” of the local governments

(Reed 2000). Secondly, they included members of the local gentry who performed public duties

and collected taxes on behalf of the state.

Page 122: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

110

Local offices (yamen) were notoriously underfunded (see for example, Zelin 1984, Chu 1969).

The imperial governments tried to maintain the myth that nominal salaries were enough to

sustain the bureaucracy, so long as the officials possessed high moral integrity. The reality,

however, was that the officialdom was forced to derive an oft-substantial part of its income and

administrative monies by exploiting the privileges of public office as prebends – whatever

earned was kept as private property. Most commonly, magistrates resorted to fee-taking (guifei

and lougui) to hire extrabureaucratic personnel, run offices, provide social services, and not to

forget, enrich themselves. Fees were typically collected by unsalaried clerks or outsourced to

local elites who shared their extractions with the local yamen. Patronage and prebendalism

went hand in hand. As one author wrote, “patronage ties linked together all levels of the

bureaucracy through a network of intra-bureaucratic payments” (Hickey 1991, 398).

Earnest efforts were made in the last decades of the Qing dynasty and the Republican era to

modernize state administration, but with limited success. As part of the “new policies” campaign,

the Qing court tried to eliminate prebendal financing by replacing official’s income from fee-

taking with increased state-budgeted salaries, but the experiment ultimately failed (Hickey

1991). During the Republican period, the Nationalist government extended salaried

bureaucracies down to lower levels of administration (Huang 1993, 229). Previously self-funded

clerks and runners were absorbed into the state bureaucracy. However, these newly formalized

agents ended up competing for control over resources with the local gentry and ended up

undermining administrative capacity (Kuhn 1975). In what Duara calls a process of “state

involution,” the proliferation and extractive practices of “entrepreneurial state brokers”

subverted the rationalization of state institutions, leading up to the fall of the Nationalist regime

(Duara 1988).

The State Structure Under Maoism

What happened to the early state structures and prebendal practices following the Communist

Party’s takeover of power? Given our basic knowledge about the Communist system and

ideology, it is reasonable to expect that the CCP state would have taken over responsibility of all

public functions and abolished entrepreneurial, extra-bureaucratic institutions, which had been

Page 123: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

111

a much reviled source of oppression in traditional local society. Indeed, one official study

reported that upon taking territorial control in 1949, local CCP forces “annihilated the

organizations of the old political power completely” (Wu et al 1998, 38). Yet, it appears that the

CCP had in fact incorporated some institutional features of the past into the Communist

administrative apparatus. While this claim certainly requires more historical investigation, my

preliminary findings suggest a surprising continuity of the basic contours of the traditional

administrative structure well into the Communist period.

Following the Soviet model in terms of organizational structure, the CCP government had since

the founding of the People’s Republic of China established two separate categories of state

bureaucracies: administrative units (xingzheng danwei) and service units (shiye danwei), as

reflected in official documents dating back to the 1950s.71 The third major state organizational

form was state-owned enterprises (SOEs) (qiye danwei). Distinct from administrative and service

units, SOEs were involved in the production of goods, not administration or services provision.

What explains the creation of service units alongside administrative units? Recalling the past, a

veteran official in personnel management related (AI 2007-125).

Shortly following liberation, after our cadres and military men had won the

territories, they began to establish administrative agencies in the state

apparatus. But there were not enough personnel. So everyone involved in

social/public services in society were hauled into the service units. These

individuals helped filled bureaucratic ranks, working with the administrative

units. At that time, the cadre force was not large, yet a lot of work needed to be

done after liberation, unlike the situation now.

The official’s account suggests that shiye units under communism were functionally analogous

to extrabureaucracies under imperial and republican rule – both supplemented a relatively small

formal administration, allowing the state to reach the basic levels of society for governance and

control. Yet, different from the early periods of governance, shiye units and personnel under

communism did not exist in an intermediate realm between state and society; rather, they were

identified as state bureaucracies and agents of the communist regime.

71

The term shiye first appeared officially in the “1954 and 1995 Budget Report,” presented at the first

meeting of the National People’s Congress in 1955 (Zhao 2003, 10)

Page 124: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

112

In terms of finances, state bureaucracies were divided into fully-funded, partially-funded, and

self-funded units following state establishment (AI 2007-56; 2007-62; AI 2007-110). Units that

were not fully state funded relied on fee collections or commercial activities. To give an

illustration, one official study reported that in 1961, a total of 93 units and 2,811 public

personnel in Tianjin city were funded by the collection of fees, including administrative fees

(xingzheng fei) and service-business fees (shiqiye fei) (Wu et al 1998, 177). In addition, even

during the pre-reform era, there existed commercialized (yingyexing) service units that earned

profits (AI 2007-56; AI 2007-125). Some examples included car fleets, hotels, water supply

companies, real estate companies, grocery retail centers, grain processing plants, and so forth.

Such titles as plants (chang) or companies (gongsi) hints at the commercialized nature of some

extrabureaucracies.72 As one cadre explained, “actually these units were a type of state-owned

enterprise, except they were not involved in production” (AI 2007-125). As we will see, many of

the profit-making public bureaucracies studied in the 1980-90s were in fact not new, but had

existed decades before.

Official public financial statistics indicate that state bureaucracies had earned sources of income

beyond budget allocations even during the pre-reform period. From 1952 to 1979, the extra-

budget was composed of five categories, one of which was titled “revenue of administrative

units and institutions” (xingzheng shiyexing shoufei), composing on average 21 percent of extra-

budgetary revenue in the pre-reform period. As discussed in Chapter 2, virtually all governments

collect fees and service charges as part of public financing; what is uncommon, however, is for

bureaucracies that collect the income to own the income. It was unclear from the

aforementioned statistics whether bureaucratic units had owned the revenue they collected or

were only responsible for collecting revenue during the pre-1979 period. It is also unclear

whether and how much discretion local bureaucracies had in using self-financed income in the

pre-reform period as they later did in reform era. An official dataset compiled by the Shandong

provincial finance bureau from 1979-1997 suggests that individual offices did have ownership

over income collected or earned. Extrabudgetary funds were divided by management rights.

72

Earlier official documents often referred to state-owned enterprises and service units collectively as

qishiye danwei.

Page 125: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

113

Administrative and service units (shiye xingzheng danwei) were listed as one of the agents with

management rights, alongside the local finance bureaus.73

Comparing the preceding discussion with the account of bureau-contracting in Chapter 2, we

observe some striking similarities between the administrative structure of the past and of the

present. The extrabureaucracies (shiye danwei) in post-Mao China are likened to the

extrabureaucracies of dynastic China; both conduct the bulk of administrative and social service

functions, but are distinct from and subservient to a small salaried civil service. Even during the

pre-reform period, part of the state bureaucracy, it appeared, was not fully salaried, but had

been “self-financed” through collecting fees and selling services. More importantly, individual

bureaucracies appeared to have rights to dispose the income they collected, although the

existence and extent of such rights require more validation. Prior to reforms, it was likely that

any income made by the bureaucracies served only a subsistence purpose, but not to incentivize

offices for pursue rich rewards. Incentives, however, changed dramatically when Deng and his

reform-minded lieutenants took office and opened markets in 1979.

The Policy Context of the Reform Period

In March 1978, a strategy for prosperity struck a party secretary of Lin village in Fujian province

named Ye. He tried to sell his reform ideas to his supervisors, the commune party cadres. The

first idea was free election at the team level, and the second was a bonus system. “I suggested

that future team leaders be authorized to keep a certain percentage of the surplus from the

team’s production as a bonus. The team head used his discretion to reward hardworking team

members with this bonus. Only by controlling this economic leverage could the team heads

promote production in their teams” (Huang 1998, 137). The Commune Party Secretary

threatened to fire him for his audacious proposal. Fortunately and unexpectedly for Ye, the

political winds shifted in December 1978. The Chinese Communist Party held its Third Plenum of

the Eleventh Party Congress, during which the new paramount leader Deng Xiaoping announced

plans for reform and opening (gaige kaifang). Ye related, “My experiments in Lin village turned

73

It is unclear whether this division of extrabudgetary funds was introduced as part of the post-1979

reforms or had previously been in place.

Page 126: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

114

out to be in line with the new policy. When the announcement of policy change was made, the

Commune Party Secretary congratulated me for having saved my skin this time” (Huang 1998,

139).

The story of party secretary Ye nicely captures the radical shift in policy direction following Deng

Xiaoping’s rise to power after Mao’s death. The reform-era state ideology was, as Deng had

famously pronounced, “To get rich is glorious!” A frenzy of opportunities to get rich like never

before swept up the entire country, from village households to provincial governments and

central departments. It was this historic leap from a socialist system on the brink of collapse to a

capitalist world under communist party dictatorship that set the stage for making bureaucratic

agents who were uniquely entrepreneurial.

In this section, we proceed to examine how the state structure in China, building upon existing

patterns, had since evolved. To understand the path of state development in reform-era China,

it is necessary to divide the reform era into two distinct periods.

• Stage 1: The years from 1979-1993 marked a period of partial reforms, during which

market forces were introduced but only on the edges of a centrally planned economy.

• Stage II: From 1993, full market reforms were launched; the central planning system was

to be supplanted by a modern market system.

Stage 1 of China’s reforms was a period of high-speed growth accompanied by disordered “state

entrepreneurism.” Governmental actors played the simultaneous roles of entrepreneurs and

bureaucrats in the partial reform setting. While they were each highly motivated to pursue

prosperity, they also exploited the free rein afforded to extract income for their own localities

and departments, but to the detriment of central control and sustained market development.

Stage 2 heralded an advanced stage for reforms, where fiscal and administrative reforms were

implemented to recentralize vertical and horizontal state control over local governments and

bureaucracies. It was during this period that state entrepreneurial behavior became more rules-

based and came closer to approximating the ideal-type of bureau-contracting.

Page 127: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

115

Importantly, I stress that post-1993 administrative reforms, while successfully regimenting the

rules and procedures of prebendal financing, did not succeed in creating a regularly salaried

bureaucracy for three reasons: first, increased local budget pressures resulting from the 1994

fiscal recentralization policy; second, expansion of extrabureaucracies as a result of downsizing

policies; and third, the self-reinforcing pattern of self-financing.

Stage 1 Reform: 1979-1993

From 1979 to 1993, China retained the basic framework of a planned economy. Market

institutions were implemented only step-by-step and in an experimental manner, a strategy

famously known as “touching the stones to cross the river.” Through the dual track pricing

system, the state controlled the prices of important commodities, while allowing market

mechanisms to set the remaining prices. And while state-owned enterprises were dominant,

mixed ownership forms, such as township and village enterprises (TVEs), as well as private

enterprises disguised as collectives, mushroomed at the local levels.

Within the framework of a planned economy, extensive decentralization and contracting took

place across their socialist hierarchy. The household responsibility system decentralized

production from communes to individual households, thus encouraging agricultural production.

Inter-governmental fiscal contracting decentralized rights over increased revenue to lower level

governments, motivating local governments to industrialize and develop. State-owned and

collective enterprises contracted with the local governments; the latter provided guidance and

support in exchange for profits that enlarged governmental extrabudgetary wealth. And as

argued, bureaucracies that compose each level of government were similarly accorded residual

rights to income generated. As vividly illustrated in the experiences of village leader Ye, reform-

minded leaders, from the central party committee down to villages, were eager to employ high-

powered incentives to promote the pursuit of wealth in a new entrepreneurial climate.

Although the communist states had all sought to promote “entrepreneurism” and growth in the

1980s, the strategy of reform in China had been differed from that of the former Soviet Union

and Eastern European countries in critical ways. In the latter case, the leadership implemented

Page 128: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

116

political reform and economic reform simultaneously. Furthermore, those countries opted for

the “big bang” approach, uprooting the central planning system and replacing it with a market

system in one fell swoop. In China, market reforms were introduced through communist

political institutions. And reforms were conducted only incrementally. As Susan Shirk (1993)

contrasted,

Gorbachev dismantled the Communist Party’s control over the government and

the society and shifted authority to government institutions, including

democratically elected legislatures (5).

[Deng] opted to retain the traditional communist bureaucratic polity with only

minor modifications. He apparently believed that he could use local officials as

an effective counterweight to the center without changing the political rules of

the game (12).

To overcome resistance to change from party elders, Gorbachev introduced democratization

and mass participation. His strategy, however, backfired. His reforms scrambled a previously

state-centered structure of rewards. Losing faith of the durability of party hegemony and eager

to seize upon newly available capitalist opportunities, party-state cadres “stole the state” en

masse (Solnick 1998). As one observer vividly described, “There was a fin de regime atmosphere

in Moscow in the spring of 1991, and bureaucrats were lining up to jump ship before it was too

late... many members of the elite were now discovering that they could maintain their privileged

positions in society even without the ideology" (Dobbs 1997, 373).

Contrastingly, in China, the path to individual prosperity was tied to one’s privileged position in

the party-state hierarchy. To invert Dobb’s phrase, members of the Chinese political elite could

not have done without the ideology. Indeed, another of Deng’s famous quotes – “Let some get

rich first” – hints at the state-dominated nature of entrepreneurship during the early stages of

reform. Party-state officials were among the “first” to get rich, for although the leadership had

let loose capitalist forces, private entrepreneurship remained ideologically taboo. Consequently,

leaders and cadres took the lead as entrepreneurs in the 1980s and early 1990s, and in the

process, most of them became the prime beneficiaries of partial reforms.

Page 129: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

117

Local leaders mobilized capital to run collective enterprises, which led China’s initial drive for

industrialization and contributed to local finances. State-owned enterprises and supervisory

departments grew rich by exploiting the dual track pricing system, buying inputs cheaply at state

controlled prices and then selling them on the market. Individual bureaucracies, of course, did

not sit idle at the new opportunities for making wealth. Facing a rapidly expanding market,

bureaus and extrabureaucracies could collect more fees, charges, and monopoly rents than

before, and with unprecedented discretion over the use of self-financed income. In addition,

they could even go directly into business.

In the first stage of reform, the state policies and incentive schemes in China produced

remarkable results, especially in contrast to the collapse of the Soviet Union and dismal failures

of reforms in Eastern Europe. From 1979 to 1993, the economy grew at an average rate of 9

percent or 7.5 percent on a per capita basis. Consumer consumption increased threefold.

Household bank deposits increased from 6 percent to 40 percent. The number of people living in

poverty dropped from 250 million to less than 100 million (Qian and Wu 2003, 33). This was a

stage described as “reform without losers” because almost everyone, in particular the political

elites, had something to gain from the changes introduced (Lau et al 2000).

However, the story was not all rosy. Massive opportunities created for officials to profit from

public office back-lashed in 1989. Fed up with the proliferation of corruption and inequality,

students gathered at Tiananmen Square in Beijing to protest for democratic change. The

incident, as we know, ended tragically with the leadership’s decision to crackdown violently on

the protestors. The Tiananmen incident dealt Deng’s reform policies a heavy blow, tainted

investment confidence, and empowered the conservative faction in the party led by Li Peng and

his counterparts. The three years after 1989 saw a period of retrenchment. To rekindle the

flames of reform and remobilize support, Deng embarked on his famous southern tour (nanxun)

in early 1992. Deng’s tour was the precursor to the endorsement of a “socialist market

economy” as the goal of reform during the Fourteenth Party Congress in September 1992.

Page 130: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

118

Stage 2 Reform: 1993 onwards

The year 1993 marked the beginning of full market reforms in China, culminating in the ground-

breaking endorsement of a document entitled “Decisions on Issues Concerning the

Establishment of a Socialist Market Economic Structure.” The new mantra “socialist market

economy” marked a subtle but critical change in the leadership’s ideology and policy program.

“Socialist market economy” had socialist as adjective and market economy as noun, that is to

say, achieving a market economy was the object of China’s reforms, albeit with socialist

characteristics. Interestingly, the new Chinese mantra contrasted the Eastern European slogan

of “market socialism,” which had socialism as the noun and market as the adjective (Qian and

Wu 2003). Before 1993, market mechanisms, though growing rapidly, remained subsidiary to

central planning and public ownership. But after 1993, the leadership decided that markets and

plan would have to switch places.

Following the 1993 decision, the Chinese government aimed to construct an institutional

framework for a modern market system. This involved a number of comprehensive policy

changes (Qian and Wu 2003). First, the central government introduced tax and fiscal reforms to

clarify the tax structure and recentralize control over fiscal resources. Second, the state-owned

enterprises would undergo mass privatization; consequently, the government had to build a

social safety system that had previously been unavailable. In tandem with SOE privatization, the

leadership resolved to promote and protect private entrepreneurship, including through the

clarification of the property rights regime. Third, the bureaucratic apparatus had to be

transformed along with the rest of the economy. State agencies should no longer be

administrators and businesses simultaneously; in the new administrative order, they were

supposed to function as impartial regulators (Yang 2004). This final task, it would appear,

amounted to a major program of bureaucratic rationalization along Weberian principles.

As comprehensively reviewed in Yang’s (2004) recent study, the central government instituted a

host of reforms to discipline the administration. Anti-corruption control was considerably

strengthened through anti-graft laws, anti-money laundering policies, and technical but critical

improvements in the state accounting, auditing, budgeting, and procurement systems. The

Page 131: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

119

budgeting measure of “separating revenue from expenditure,” earlier discussed in Chapter 2,

was introduced in this backdrop of administrative reform. Further, the central government

embarked on two consecutive downsizing campaigns in 1993 and 1998, the latter being the

most ambitious in China’s reform history. Administrative licensing procedures came under

increased standardization through the enactment of a national legal framework. Leaders went

even further to promote the notion and practice of a “service-oriented government.” One-stop

administrative services centers were introduced, along with local experiments that allowed

members of the public to evaluate the performance of government officials. These are just

some examples of the post-1993 institutional reforms. Among them, the central government’s

decision to divest the military and party-state agencies of their business operations was of

particular significance.

Fiscal Reform and Local Budgetary Pressures

For the central leadership, fiscal reforms were a critical component of the post-1993 reform

package. In 1994, the central government decided to replace particularistic fiscal contracting

with a uniform tax-sharing system between the central and provincial governments. Although it

had resolved some old problems, the tax-sharing system created new problems. The tax-sharing

system clarified the terms of tax sharing between the central and provincial governments, but

left the thorny issue of sub-provincial fiscal relations unclear. At the sub-provincial level, it was

bargaining as usual when dividing the local and shared taxes. Worse still, the central

government had recentralized revenue without adjusting local spending responsibilities. As a

result, local governments generally suffered increased budgetary pressures after 1994.

Figure 5.1. below shows the changes in aggregated local governmental revenue and spending

from 1980 to 2005. Before 1994, the sum of local revenue was equivalent to local spending. In

the hey days of the early 1980s, local share of total revenue consistently exceeded its share of

total spending by up to 30 percent. Immediately after 1994, local revenue took a nose dive.

While local revenue has continued to grow in absolute level afterwards, its rate of growth has

clearly fallen behind that of spending, resulting in a widening deficit. In addition, local

Page 132: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

120

governments have had to shoulder a disproportionate share of public spending even as its share

of revenue dropped over the years.

Figure 5.1: Local Revenue and Spending Before and After the 1994 Fiscal Reform

After 1994 Fiscal Reform

-40

-20

020

40

0500

1000

1500

2000

2500

3000

1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005

Local government revenue (billion)

Local government spending (billion)

Local share of total revenue minus share of spending

How could local governments fill the deficit? Local governments (provincial and sub-provincial

governments) are legally barred from borrowing. They are also required to balance their

budgets. Since 1994, the central government distributed increasing amounts of fiscal transfers

to local governments. However, as many experts have pointed out, China’s fiscal transfers

system remains under-developed.74 In many localities, particularly below the provinces and

cities, it would be difficult, if not impossible to subsist only on retained taxes and fiscal transfers.

It appears then that extrabudgetary revenue, which belongs entirely to the localities, became

more important to local finances, particularly at the county levels and below, after fiscal

recentralization.

Yet, even as local governments needed extrabudgetary revenue, local extrabudgets were taking

a hit of a different kind in the 1990s. State-owned and collective enterprises, including the TVEs,

began to incur huge losses. These enterprises were no longer cash cows but a burden to local

74

Citing an earlier World Bank (2002) report, Wong (2005) described the current inter-governmental fiscal

arrangements as “dysfunctional.”

Page 133: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

121

governments. SOEs incurred losses because of persistent inefficiencies and increased market

competition. Market competition had grown steadily over the 1990s. The state pricing system

was largely obsolete by the 1990s, and by 1993, only 10 of product prices were fixed according

to plan (Qian and Wu 2003, 36). The economy had gradually shifted from a “seller’s market” to a

“buyer’s market,” as access to resources freed up beyond the state sector. Losing their

advantages, SOEs soon went deep into the red. TVEs were not spared from huge losses either

(Kung & Lin 2007).

Figure 5.2: Change in Composition of Extrabudgetary Revenue, 1980-2003

0100

200

300

400

500

Extr

a-b

udgeta

ry r

evenue (

bill

ion y

uan)

19

80

19

81

19

82

19

83

19

84

19

85

19

86

19

87

19

88

19

89

19

90

19

91

19

92

19

93

19

94

19

95

19

96

19

97

19

98

19

99

20

00

20

01

20

02

20

03

Bureaucracies State-owned enterprises

Local governments Township self-raised funds

Government Foundations Others

Widespread collapse and privatization of SOEs and TVEs left a huge gap in local extrabudgetary

coffers. Moreover, profits from state-owned and collective enterprises were shifted to the

within-budgetary category after 1994 (Oi 1999). Nationwide, retained profits from state-owned

and collective enterprises used to be the leading source of extrabudgetary revenue in the 1980s

and early 1990s (Oi 1999; Shue, etc.). Figure 5.2 shows the composition of extrabudgetary

revenue before and after the 1994 fiscal reform. Although the data in the two periods are not

strictly comparable because of amendments in the classification of revenue, it nonetheless

suggests that dramatic changes had taken place in the composition of extra-budgets. Before

1993, retained profits from enterprises had composed about 75 percent of total extrabudgetary

revenue, followed by self-financed income belonging to individual bureaucracies, and finally

Page 134: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

122

extrabudgetary revenue belonging collectively to local governments. But from 1993 onwards,

the lion’s share of extrabudgetary revenue came from the bureaucracies.

Based on the patterns described, we may gather that as local share of revenue fell, retained

profits from SOEs and TVEs also tumbled and huge losses were incurred. In a double whammy

situation, it was also during this period that state agencies were forced to severe themselves

from the corporate offsprings that used to supply profits to the bureaucratic sector (Yang 2004).

These developments implied that local offices likely faced more intensive pressures than before

to self-finance.

Expansion of the Extrabureaucracies

From the mid-1990s onwards, budgetary pressures intensified and many departments were

forced to close loss-making commercial operations. Simultaneously, the extrabureaucratic

sector was pushed upon an accelerated track of expansion and marketization. From the 1979

onwards, China’s bureaucracy, measured as the total number of state personnel and on a per

capita basis, has grown steadily and at a steeper rate than prior to reforms, despite a transition

from socialism to capitalism. Notably, growth in absolute personnel size has been concentrated

in the extrabureaucratic sector, while the core administration has held steady at a share 20

percent of total employment throughout the post-1979 period.

A major cause of the physical expansion of the extrabureaucratic sector was, ironically, the

central government’s downsizing campaigns. The Chinese government had conducted regular

downsizing campaigns from the 1950s onwards. In particular, the restructuring program in 1998,

spearheaded by Zhu Rongji, was the most ambitious to date. The 1998 campaign slashed the

number of central ministries from 41 to 29 and central-level personnel under the state council

by half. Downsizing was extended to sub-national governments. It was reported that provincial

governments had successfully reduced their number of organs by 20 percent and personnel size

by 47 percent on average, and sub-provincial governments by 20 percent (Brodsgaard 2002,

375-6; see also Yang 2004, 37-38). Citing media releases, Yang reported similarly that

downsizing had achieved impressive results. Guangdong province was said to have cut its staff

Page 135: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

123

size by 49.3 percent. Hainan province trimmed 50 percent of governmental personnel and 20

percent of party personnel. Yang concluded optimistically, “the Chinese leadership has by the

beginning of the new century achieved remarkable progress in streamlining and downsizing the

government… in the late 1990s, the pace of government reforms, measured in terms of

downsizing… picked up noticeably” (2004, 17 and 25).

Figure 5.3: Change in Public Employment Size, 1955-2003

010

20

30

40

50

Num

ber

of

Public

Em

plo

yees (

mill

ions)

12

34

56

Public

Em

plo

ym

ent

Per

Capita

1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005

PE per 100 population PE per 100 working population

Total public employment Employment in core bureaus (jiguan)

While the results claimed are impressive, it is important not to take official statements at face

value. As John Burns rightly cautioned, “previous research fails to examine the outcomes of

downsizing attempts and sometimes reports changes to bianzhi targets as though they were

actually achieved” (2003, 776; in reference to Brodsgaard 2002). Bianzhi, like the term shiye, is

yet another Chinese term that is confusing to most outsiders and hard to translate. In my view,

the closest translation is from Burns, who defined bianzhi as “all the positions that have been

officially created” (2003, 776). From the central to county levels, the party-state sets and

enforces targets for official public employment through the establishment offices (bianzhi

weiyuanhui bangongshi). Most of the positions that fall within the bianzhi target are budgeted,

i.e. they are eligible for state funding and will be considered during negotiations for budget

Page 136: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

124

appropriations (see Chapter 2). 75 Positions that exceed the hiring quota are known as

“exceeding the bianzhi” (chaobian). Personnel who are hired but not reported as part of the

bianzhi are known as “outside the bianzhi” (bianzhiwai).76 In both of these cases, it is usually the

hiring unit that pays the non-official personnel using its self-financed income, although there are

always exceptions when local finance authorities agree to subsidize personnel costs using state

funds.

To put it simply, then, the bianzhi is an instrument that allows the government to control the

ideal size of bureaucracy. As illustrated in Chapter 2, it is also a tool (although sometimes an

imprecise one) for budgeting personnel costs. In most governments, equivalent bianzhi

institutions do not exist because the size of hiring is controlled through formal budgeting

processes. The final budget passed by the legislature determines the number of personnel that

each office could hire and how much they each would be paid from state revenue. However, in

China, procedures for formulating budgets, and even more importantly, enforcement of

budgetary decisions are still immature. Therefore, the bianzhi system provides a partial

personnel budgeting function. Alternatively, in a socialist framework, we can think about the

bianzhi system as a centrally controlled “plan” for distributing labor in the party-state

bureaucracy. However, bearing in mind that since it is just a plan, the reality may deviate

significantly from the plan.

Having explained the bianzhi system, we may now better understand how it could have been

possible for the central and local governments in China to downsize their personnel by as much

as half in a remarkably short time and without mention of any detailed compensation scheme.

After all, the task of laying off bureaucrats is extremely politically sensitive anywhere, and not to

mention, in a socialist system like China where party-state cadres are guaranteed lifetime

employment. If massive layoffs caused by SOE privatization in the 1990s triggered widespread

workers’ protests across the country, then why had the cadre class kept silent when 20 to 50

percent of them had reportedly lost their jobs? There are two answers: the first is that the

75

Not all of these official positions, however, are budgeted because even wholly self-funded public units

are subject to a bianzhi quota. 76

This happens when units hire more personnel than they are authorized to and when units hire

temporary workers like cleaners and drivers.

Page 137: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

125

central government had cut bianzhi targets, but not the actual number of personnel; the second

is that downsized personnel is systematically shifted from core administrative units to

extrabureaucracies. These answers are clearly reflected in Figure 5.3. Total public personnel size

increased steadily each year, and the expansion is concentrated among the extrabureaucracies.

Flexible Bianzhi. So why were downsized cadres moved from core bureaus to extrabureaucracies?

One reason is that while the core administration was subject to strict hiring limits, while the

extrabureaucracies had a more elastic quota. To elaborate, we return again to the bianzhi

system. As we are familiar by now, there are two organizational components in the Chinese

bureaucracy: core bureaus and extrabureaucracies. In tandem, there are two kinds of positions:

official positions in the administrative bureaus (xingzheng bianzhi), and official positions in the

extrabureaucracies (shiye bianzhi).77 The central government sets a fixed hiring quota on the

former category; this quota is then transmitted from level to level. For example, the central

government may set a fixed quota of 500,000 administrative bianzhi. The province of Shandong

is allotted a bianzhi quota of 50,000, leaving 450,000 for the remaining provinces. Shandong

then distributes this quota among its city governments, and so forth. For the extrabureaucracies,

the bianzhi is not limited by a fixed quota, rather it is determined by a ratio (hebian biaozhun)

that can be readjusted based on local conditions (AI 2006-15). For example, each school may be

allowed to hire additional personnel for every 100 increase in the number of students served. In

another example, a county finance official reflected that the xingzheng bianzhi had been frozen

since 1993. To recruit new personnel, the bureau could request to add an extrabureaucratic

function and hire more shiye bianzhi, whose tasks were in fact identical to colleagues positioned

in the core bureaus (AI 2006-16).

Because of the relative hiring flexibility in the extrabureaucracies, core governmental

departments typically conformed with downsizing mandates by reclassifying their staff from the

category of xingzheng to shiye bianzhi (see Burns case study). In some instances, such

reclassifications involved physical transfers of staff. In most cases, however, no physical change

occurred. The downsized personnel stayed in exactly the same job, except they no longer

77

Following the establishment of the civil service system, functionaries who occupy the xingzheng bianzhi

are officially identified as civil servants (gongwuyuan), who are legally protected from unjustified

dismissal.

Page 138: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

126

occupied a post in the administrative quota, but instead a shiye bianzhi. In a third possible

scenario, which I found common, core bureaus “borrowed” bianzhi from extrabureaucracies;

this practice is known as jiebian. For example, education bureaus “borrowed” teachers from

public schools to work in the bureaus as administrators (AI 2007-42; AI 2007-121). What are the

benefits of doing so? Not only would the education bureau not violate the administrative hiring

quota, “the schools will have to pay for them [the borrowed personnel]” (AI 2007-44). For the

core bureaus, jiebian allows them to expand recruitment without having to incur additional

financial obligations.

Flexible Revenue-Making. Extrabureaucracies have more flexibility in hiring because they have

more flexibility in generating self-financed income. Particularly after the post-1993

administrative reforms, the state has made it clear that core agencies are supposed to be

engaged in administrative and regulatory work, not profit-making. Regulatory agencies (e.g.

environmental protection bureaus, commerce bureaus, etc.) could collect fees and fines as part

of their regulatory functions, but they could not directly be involved in other forms of

commercial activities. Extrabureaucracies, on the other hand, are engaged in services provision,

vaguely defined. Through the provision of state-related services, they could not only collect fees

but also sell their services to consumers for profits often at a monopolistic advantage.

As a World Bank (2005) study reported, extrabureaucracies were increasingly “pushed into the

market” in the reform era. As the study usefully, “The central measure of reform along this

direction is to cut of budget funding to [extrabureaucracies] to force them to generate their own

revenues to survive. ‘Contract responsibility systems’ of various forms were introduced to

implement ‘budget contracting’ (yusuan baogan), thereby the government allocated a pre-

determined amount of fund to the [extrabureaucracies], which were then supposed to retain

any surpluses or make up any funding gaps (World Bank 2005, 91).” Compared to core bureaus,

extrabureaucracies have more autonomy and avenues for generating revenue, depending on

their functional type. As reported by the World Bank, “when a [service unit] is completely

‘pushed into the market,’ it operates almost the same way as a Chinese SOE. This gives rise to a

formal category of [service units] that are ‘managed as enterprises’ (shiye danwei qiyehua

guanli)” (World Bank 2005, 92).

Page 139: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

127

A Bifurcated Bureaucracy. The rationale for maintaining a bifurcated bureaucracy becomes clear

if we recall the historical bureaucratic structure. Following the establishment of the civil service

system in 2005, functionaries who occupy the xingzheng bianzhi are identified as civil servants

(gongwuyuan), who enjoy a set of legal rights and obligations. Only individuals who have passed

the civil service examinations and are formally appointed to office may occupy the

administrative bianzhi. The modern-day civil servants in China are likened to the imperial

officials of the past. They represent the elite strata of the hierarchy and occupy a special

privileges status in society. This stratum must be kept unadulterated at a high quality, for the

state depends on this subset of distinguished individuals to govern the country.

The extrabureaucracies, on the other hand, are like “shock absorbers” in China’s reform

machinery. Shock absorbers are installed in cars to cushion the impact of kinetic energy, thereby

protecting the structure of the automobile. Likewise, extrabureaucracies help to provide

revenue autonomy (when local revenues were cut), flexibility in hiring (when the central

government froze the “administrative” bianzhi), and labor absorption (when bureaucrats from

local governmental agencies were downsized). Extrabureaucracies also allow local authorities,

despite fiscal constraints, to sustain and perpetuate a clientelist network through the

distribution of public jobs, contributing in part to the cohesion of party-state. Contrary to the

view that the CCP has “[failed] to adapt to a changing environment in the post-revolutionary

period” and is threatened by “a process of involutionary development” (Lu 2000, p. 229), we

find that the regime has adapted in quite remarkable ways.

The Self-Reinforcing Logic of Self-Financing

Apart from increased local budgetary pressures and expansion of the extrabureaucratic-state,

there is yet a more basic explanation for why it is so difficult to turn a partially self-financed

bureaucracy into a purely salaried establishment. As highlighted in Chapter 3, official cadre

wages are not only low in China, but also extremely egalitarian. Wages are tightly compressed

and do not reflect varying local economic conditions, meaning the wage gap between the lowest

and highest ranking personnel and those in the richest versus poorest locales is extremely small.

It is self-financed income earned by individual departments and locally retained tax revenues

Page 140: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

128

that determine actual levels of cadre compensation. That means, if the state removes the rights

of bureaucracies to collect revenue for themselves, it would either have to (a) compensate them

for the loss in income through increased budget allocations, or (b) cadres nationwide will be

forced to accept a lower level of compensation and some wholly self-financed bureaucracies

would go unpaid. Option (a) is economically unfeasible, and option (b) is politically unacceptable.

To illustrate my point, consider the following budget statistics from county governments in

Shandong province. In any local government, there are three major sources of revenue: tax

revenue, fiscal transfers, and self-financed income belonging to individual offices. In this

particular dataset, we find that each of these revenue categories compose roughly one third of

total combined fiscal resources. The grey bar shows the average combined sum of retained

taxes and fiscal transfers in the Shandong counties. The red bar shows the average level of cadre

benefits, i.e. wages and in-kind benefits combined. If the county governments barred

bureaucracies from raising their own income or denied their claims over income generated (in

which case the bureaucracies would have no incentive to generate self-financed income), that

would amount to eliminating one third of the county’s fiscal resources. In a situation like this, as

shown clearly in Figure 5.4, nearly all of the remaining revenue in Shandong’s counties would go

towards cadre compensation and administrative monies, leaving little else for infrastructural

development, purchase of equipment, and public goods provision. In fact, in the year of 2002,

the mean county government in Shandong will have to bankrupt itself just to maintain the

original level of cadre benefits.

This example clearly illustrates to us what bureaucrats in China actually mean when they claim

that budget allocations are “insufficient.” The critical question is: When are budget allocations

ever sufficient? How much is objectively sufficient? In most governments, budgetary funds are

allocated based on the number of personnel and the formal salaries that each personnel is

entitled to in a particular office. In this regular context, budgetary funds are considered

insufficient when there is not enough allocated to pay every bureaucrat his or her formal

compensation. In a neo-prebendal context like China, however, the official pay scale lacks

meaning because in many locales and departments, actual compensation far exceeds what is

formally provided. There are certainly cases of poor departments in poor locales that have

trouble paying even minimal formal wages; in this case, we may consider budget allocations

Page 141: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

129

objectively insufficient. But in many other instances across the country, no such “objective”

standard exists: cadres are rewarded based on what they can make, and offices can hire as

many personnel as they can independently finance. If there is in fact no limit to an official’s

actual compensation or an office’s actual size, then budget allocations are always insufficient.

Figure 5.4: ‘Eating budget’ – Cadre rewards consume tax revenue and fiscal transfers

0

10,000

20,000

30,000

40,000

50,000

60,000A

mo

un

t o

f S

pe

nd

ing

/In

co

me

(1

00

00

Yu

an

)

2001 2002 2003 2004 2005

tax revenue and fiscal transfers cadre benefits

My point is best illustrated in the case of Blossom county, already one of the richest in the entire

country. As I was told, all bureaucracies in the county make self-financed income (AI 2007-114).

This is puzzling. If Blossom county is already so wealthy, why does the government not pay its

bureaucracy in full? Why not do away with self-financing, especially given the problems created?

For the local officials, the answer is obvious: there is not enough money for increased budget

allocations. As one official explained (AI 2007-113):

This suggestion [of a fully salaried bureaucracy] is not bad. I raised it to the

former finance bureau chief once. He replied, ‘No way, that will take tens of

millions!’ At that time, our finances were not good enough. Now it’s even worse.

The other day the public security chief told me that that the supporting police

force alone has over 400 personnel. How much do you think that is going to cost?

Interestingly, when the interviewee above remarked that “now it’s even worse,” he did not

mean that Blossom’s public finances were getting worse. Blossom’s tax revenues are impressive

and growing every year. Instead, what he had meant by “now it’s even worse” is that personnel

Page 142: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

130

size had increased again. The growth of formal revenue could not keep up with the growth of

actual administrative costs. And actual administrative costs have kept growing because

individual departments make discretionary sources of income. In other words, a system of

prebendal self-financing, once allowed to take off, becomes a self-reinforcing institution.

The self-reinforcing nature of prebendal financing is not unique to contemporary China. It is an

enduring problem in the governance of early states. Hickey (1991) detailed a fascinating account

of the late Qing government’s efforts to introduce a comprehensive salary reform in 1909-1911.

Formal salaries had been persistently inadequate in the Qing government, thus officials had to

rely heavily on fee-taking to upgrade their compensation and cover the costs of running office.

The objective of the proposed salary reform was to provide large increases in formal salaries in a

payment known as gongfei and thereby abolish fee-taking activities. Reformers undertook

painstaking efforts to induce officials to reveal their true income, promising not to punish them

for hitherto reported funds, in order to determine the increases necessary to offset the

officialdom’s loss in revenue from fees. Nonetheless, in the end, the salary reform still failed to

eliminate fee-taking because despite significant increases in state-authorized income, the

gongfei provided fell short of allowing the officials to maintain their original levels of

consumption. Furthermore (and strangely), the reformers failed to consider providing salaries

for unpaid yamen clerks and runners that constituted the vast sub-bureaucracy in the Qing

dynasty. As Hickey explained, Qing reformers had underestimated the estimation of the gongfei

schedule because “only customary fees deemed ‘legitimate’ were to be converted to the new

forms of remuneration” (411). The author concluded, “By denying the legitimacy of the profit

gained in office, the Qing state was defying the expectations of its officials. To meet such

expectations, salary reform needed to provide not only the actual costs of holding office, but

also financial rewards for the officeholders” (413, emphasis added).

Similarly, in the case of present-day China, leaders and cadres expect to sustain (or increase)

their existing levels of income and benefits, and to keep positions that had been created without

state funding. If the state were to deny bureaucracies of their property rights to income

generated, the bureaucracies would have no motivation to self-finance. And if self-financed

income falls, cadres would have decreased financial rewards and offices would have insufficient

Page 143: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

131

operational monies. The central and local governments may literally have to empty its coffers to

match the bureaucracies’ income from self-financing, and still, that may not be enough.

My identification of the self-reinforcing logic of prebendal financing calls for a reconsideration of

observations in the literature that bureaucracies in China have had to collect fees and charges or

run commercial operations because of “inadequate funding.” There are certainly cases in which

state funding is inadequate, for example, when cadres cannot even make enough money to

make ends meet. But it is important to understand that because Chinese bureaucracies are, by

design, quasi-firm units that profit from public office, no amount of funding is objectively

enough to numb their entrepreneurial instincts.

Thus understood, the challenge of transforming a neo-prebendal bureaucracy into a salaried

bureaucracy goes beyond implementing modern budgetary measures, issuing central directives,

or increasing formal salaries. The challenge is at the core a political one; it involves renegotiating

a contract between the ruling party-state and its bureaucracy. The ruling-party state has to

provide the bureaucracy with its expected level of material rewards, either in cash or through

benefices. A salaried bureaucracy cannot easily be achieved, contrary to some expectations, just

by requiring bureaucracies to hand over their proceeds to the state treasury (Yang 2004; see

Chapter 2).

Conclusion

This chapter has reviewed the evolution of China’s bureaucratic structure from 1979 to the

present period. Evidently, the leadership’s vision of reform has had profound effects on the

trajectory of state institutional development. As we have seen, Deng and his reformist

lieutenants changed the policy landscape dramatically in 1979. The reformers had constructed

their policies upon an existing economic and political structure that had already been more

decentralized than in the former Soviet Union (Shirk 1993), as well as a long and persistent

legacy of prebendal patterns of governance, reviewed in Chapter 6. Deng’s reforms unleashed a

rush of entrepreneurism among the bureaucratic class. From then, high-powered economic

incentives were borne. During the first stage of reforms, they took off in unplanned ways.

Page 144: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

132

From 1993 onwards, as part of the central state’s plan to build a “socialist market economy,”

ambitious fiscal and administrative reforms were launched. These reforms, I have argued, did

not in the produce a regular salaried bureaucracy. In fact, the new tax measures and downsizing

campaigns in the 1990s added pressures on bureaucracies to self-finance, as well as to expand

and marketize the subordinated extrabureaucracies. I have also shown why, independent of the

reforms, self-financing has inflated the actual levels of cadre rewards. As such, it has proven

more difficult than expected to realize an adequate compensation scheme that could allow the

state to institute a purely salaried civil service. Confronting these challenges, I argue that the

state in China has opted for a pragmatic approach. The approach has been to incrementally

regulate opportunities for bureaucracies to profit from public office, rather than to outlaw them

(or to pretend they could be outlawed). This, obviously, is still work in progress, but it appears

the Chinese government is getting better at its tasks. The perfection of this approach is bureau-

contracting.

Page 145: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

133

CHAPTER 6

CONCLUSION

“Where the ‘model bureau’ does not exist, it is obviously futile to ask questions

about what does exist as though it were a ‘model bureau.’ The first task is not to

make this assumption, but to ask: ‘What does in fact exist?’ One may discover,

of course, that what exists is not at all a bad thing.”

Fred Riggs, Public Administration in Developing Countries, p. 9

“The history of the McDonald’s System is the story of an organization that

learned how to harness the power of entrepreneurs – not several but hundreds

of them… In essence, the history of McDonald’s is a case study on managing

entrepreneurs in a corporate setting.”

John F. Love, McDonald’s: Behind the Arches, p. 8

Heeding Fred Rigg’s advice in a classic written nearly 50 years ago, this study began with a

simple empirical task to discover “what does in fact exist” in China in the present day, if not a

“model bureau.” What I found in the end was a state organization not entirely unlike that of

franchised firms like McDonald’s. In a bureau-contracting structure, bureaucrats and contractors

are fused. Bureaucrats are incentivized to maximize revenue though developmental efforts and

state-sanctioned strategies of self-financing. High-powered incentives in any organization,

however, induce individual players to “game the system” by scrapping gains for themselves at

the costs of collective interests and organizational integrity. The practical challenge in a bureau-

contracting state is not simply a problem of control. Rather, the challenge is to harness the

entrepreneurial energies of bureaucratic agents, but at the same time, force conformity of

entrepreneurial behavior to standardized rules in a highly decentralized and massive hierarchy.

Borrowing Love’s phrase, in essence, the history of China’s bureaucratic structure is a case study

on managing entrepreneurs in a bureaucratic setting. Once we understand this central

Page 146: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

134

organizational logic, the particular features of the bureaucratic structure in China, though

unusual and perhaps even unthinkable in view of prevailing doctrines in public administration,

would make sense. And indeed, as Riggs suggested, “what exists is not all at a bad thing.”

Development, Reform, and Second-Best Institutions

The model of bureau-contracting and my findings in the Chinese case challenge our

conventional wisdom about the institutional foundations of state capacity building and market

development. As Weber asserted, “capitalism and bureaucracy have found one another and

belong intimately together” (Weber, 1465). According to Weber, legal-rational bureaucracies

have two defining features: first, expertise and meritocracy; and second, the separation of

public office from the private property of officials. While the Chinese government has advanced

the first feature, it has retained and institutionalized the second.

So why has China been able to achieve state-led development without a Weberian bureaucratic

structure necessary for effective governance? The arguments laid out in this study suggest

several answers. Firstly, consider what we mean by “effective.” The effectiveness of an

instrument rests on the objectives of its use. If we desire an honest, time-sheet-logging, rule-

following administration that shies from infringing upon private property rights, then Weberian

bureaucracies are effective. Alternatively, if we desire a fiercely motivated, interventionist

bureaucracy capable of doubling as entrepreneurs in a start-up, impoverished environment

where pure private entrepreneurship is non-existent or marginal, then Weberian bureaucracies

may not be as effective. A uniquely high-powered bureaucratic structure was suitable for

China’s initial stage of reforms, in light of partial reforms and fiscal constraints. Secondly, as

reforms matured, China has been able to sustain market development without a Weberian

bureaucracy because the refinement of bureau-contracting mechanisms allowed the state to

construct a stable flow of rents for the cadre corps. Thirdly, stable rents need to be matched,

critically, by developmental incentives that prevail so long as local governments are entitled to a

significant portion of marginal tax revenue, even after the 1994 tax reform, as demonstrated in

my analysis of dual fiscal incentives.

Page 147: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

135

My story, in other words, attends to varying institutional demands at different stages of

development, a concern earliest expressed by Gershenkron (1962). In the realm of institutional

design, there has been a long-standing debate between two schools of thoughts. One is the

“first-best institution” school of thought. This school is exemplified by the Washington

Consensus and embraced by multilateral organizations like the IMF. It advocates exporting the

basic institutions of Western developed countries to developing and reforming countries.

Examples of first-best institutions or practices bring to mind legal-rational bureaucracies, a

secure private property rights regime, independent judiciaries, regulatory framework for free

market competition, elimination of trade barriers, and so forth.

However, the “second-best” institutional school rejects the procrustean approach. This school

contests that institutions should be tailored to reflect local knowledge and initial conditions

(Rodrik 2000; Berkowitz et al 2003). As Rodrik, one of the strongest proponents of the second-

best paradigm, expressed, “I shall argue that dealing with the institutional landscape in

developing economies requires a second-best mindset. In such settings, a focus on best-practice

institutions not only creates blind spots, leading us to overlook reforms that might achieve the

desired ends at lower cost, but can also backfire” (2008, 100-101). On the same token, Qian

(2003) argued that China’s reforms have succeeded through the adoption of a range of

transitional institutions from dual track pricing to TVEs. According to Qian, transitional

institutions work “because they achieve two objectives at the same time – they improve

economic efficiency on the one hand, and make the reform compatible for those in power on

the other” (305).

My view of the evolution of the Chinese bureaucracy builds on both the first and second-best

paradigms, but with a twist. Picture China’s political leaders choosing between two institutional

models: bureau-contracting vs. the Weberian ideal-type. At the initial stage of development, I

posit that bureau-contracting was the first-best choice compared to a low-powered Weberian

structure because it could produce more efficiency gains and political capital. However, as

discussed, bureau-contracting was then at its infancy and the mechanisms had yet been

perfected. At the post-1993 stage of development, as reforms deepened, bureau-contracting

became the second-best choice relative to the Weberian model, as the latter is more compatible

Page 148: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

136

with a modern market system. Ironically, it was only from this stage onwards that the

government developed the capacities to realize the bureau-contracting model in its entirety. In

short, what at first had been a first-best model transformed into a second-best reality because

growing out from an initial mode of governance proved more difficult than later administrative

reformers had wished.

Is Bureau-Contracting Transitional?

Qian’s (2003) perspective on transitional institutions points usefully to the political interests and

initial constraints that condition institutional choices. In line with his view, we may consider

bureau-contracting a transitional institution insofar as “they incur high costs and generate lower

benefits than some alternative institutions if other complementary institutions are in place”

(2003, 323, emphasis added). That is, if China had already established a free market system, an

effective taxation apparatus, and had not been ruled by communists, the Weberian model

would have been preferable to a bureau-contracting arrangement. However, I question Qian’s

predictions that “transitional institutions can be superseded by conventional best-practice

institutions when more development and reform take place” (2003, 326). Citing the

disappearance of dual track pricing and TVEs, Qian asserted that transitional institutions “should

not be viewed as permanent” (2003, 323).

Should we expect the Chinese bureaucracy to eventually transform into a salaried Weberian

structure like the ones seen in the East Asian NICs, Western Europe, and the U.S.? As discussed,

China appears in some respects to be inching towards international best practices, most

significantly, through the establishment of a civil service law. But how long might it take before

prebendal practices are completely replaced with regular budget allocations like in most

governments? As I see it now, the Chinese administration appears to be undergoing a

protracted transition.

My point is not that China may never create a salaried bureaucracy. Quite the contrary,

consistent with the views of several others (Qian and Wu 2003; Yang 2004), I see Chinese

policy-makers aiming to take state institutional development in a direction aligned with

Page 149: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

137

“international best practices.” Yet, we must separate aspirations from reality. Discussions in the

preceding sections have underscored the particular challenges and paradoxes confronting

Chinese government in its struggle to Weberianize the bureaucracy from 1993 onwards, a

period of transition from partial to full market reforms. All western developed states were at

some point governed by prebendal bureaucracies; the transformation from prebendalism to

bureaucratization was, as Weber emphasized, a very long process. In China, this long process is

exacerbated by its historical-structural legacies, communist political system, multi-leveled

administration, sheer large size, and an initial decision to unleash entrepreneurial forces among

bureaucratic agents.

Facing the constraints described above, I argue that the leadership has made the pragmatic

choice of regulating, rather than eliminating (or pretending they could eliminate), opportunities

for bureaucratic agents to profit from public office. Long-existing self-financing practices were

gradually regimented through an elaborated internal system of “policy awards.” In this way, the

state compromised by allotting licenses for extracting fees, fines, and monopoly rents on the

one hand, and punishing agencies for arbitrary extraction that goes against state rules on the

other. Furthermore, the bureaucracies’ self-financed income was brought into the state bank

accounts system. As such, the state compromised by allowing bureaucracies to retain a share of

their revenue legally on the one hand, but limited discretion over the use of the income and

subjecting the funds to supervision by financial authorities. Hence, over time, the Chinese state

came closer and closer to approximating a bureau-contracting ideal-type than a Weberian

model.

The Chinese experience reminds us of Rigg’s (1964) prismatic model of administration in

developing countries. Riggs envisioned that structures of administration, like white light passing

through to emerge diffracted upon a screen, can be caught captive in the middle, “imprismed.”

Wisely, he probed, “May not some ‘transitional’ conditions turn out to be relatively permanent?

Can we be certain, for example, that the present stage of administration in Haiti or Bolivia or

Afghanistan is temporary and transitional rather than permanent and final? Or if these societies

are undergoing change, cannot the same be said of England, France, and Canada?” (1964, 4).

Reflecting on Chinese administration, perhaps we should reconsider the assumption that

Page 150: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

138

transitional institutions are stepping stones to some ideal rationalized outcomes found in the

West. Some transitional institutions could, as Riggs suggested, turn out to be relatively

permanent.

Managed Rents, Corruption, and Compromises

Corruption is an oft-bandied about term in the study of governance. What exactly is corruption?

Should we take a strictly legalistic definition (Nye 1967) or broader definitions from the public

interests perspective (Gardiner 2000)? If we use the latter approach, the problem is, as Rose

Ackerman pointed out, “in many societies, no such clear distinction exists [between one’s public

and private roles]” (1999, 91). China is an instance of a society in which public and private

spheres overlap.

My study of China urges that we distinguish state-managed rents provision from rules-violating

acts of corruption, e.g. stealing public funds and taking bribes. Drawing this distinction is

analytically important, because while illicit acts of corruption corrode hierarchical authority or

are signs of corroded authority, certain organized schemes of generating private gains from

public office may actually contribute to authoritarian state strength and even reform agendas.

Bureau-contracting illustrates the latter possibility. The issue here is not one of semantics, but

contextualization and institutional design.

In China, the state organizes and disciplines processes of rents extraction. In the former Soviet

Union under Gorbachev’s reform initiatives, opportunistic bureaucrats “stole” the state en

masse, leading eventually to organizational disintegration (Solnick 1998). By contrast, in China,

the state makes the “rules of the game.” To get along and ahead in the political system, Chinese

officials played by those rules than in defiance of them. To borrow Solnick’s “bank-run” analogy,

the state in China continued to run the bank following reforms, and its agents lined up to collect

their fair share of dividends.

Page 151: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

139

Bureau-Contracting as an Alternative Model

Transactions are the building blocks of all institutions. Transactions, as neo-institutional

economists tell us, take place either through markets or within hierarchies. Markets and

hierarchies are themselves ideal-types. They bracket a whole range of mixed realities with

qualities of the two extremes in varying proportions. There is a third institutional ideal-type that

we have yet to explore: the union of markets and hierarchies. Alternatively, in diagrammatic

terms, think about markets and hierarchies as the ends of a two-dimensional straight line, and

the fusion of markets and hierarchies as projecting a third dimensional space. Some historical

and existing realities have rested on this third dimensional space. Early patrimonial

administrations featured prebendal financing with varying degrees of top-down personnel

control. Modern franchised companies manage entrepreneurial franchisees in complex

corporate organizations. The Chinese state is run by revenue-making bureaucratic agents in a

communist-style authority structure. All three organizational forms, as unrelated to one

another as they may seem, are in fact manifestations of the same organizational abstract:

contracting within hierarchies.

By laying out the conceptual foundation of organizations, this study is not just about the Chinese

bureaucracy. It is more fundamentally about enriching our knowledge of the “third dimensional

space” of organizational forms, specifically in the realm of state governance. Instead of

presuming that bureau-contracting is a “transition” to legal-rational types, it may be more useful

instead to view it as an alternative to the Weberian model. Whereas the Weberian bureaucracy

is a low-powered, low-risk state model, bureau-contracting is high-powered, high-risk model.

Weberian bureaucracies are to directly owned firms as bureau-contracting is to franchising.

Both have virtues and shortfalls. The two models may be equally effective for the purposes of

governance and growth, depending on the stages of development, the goals and constraints

confronting political leaders, and the specific institutional mechanisms designed and enforced.

Ideal-types, as Weber noted, have “indispensable analytical value” (1968, 1002). Following on

Weber’s point, Riggs reminded us that the tendency to accept standard models uncritically

arises “from the lack of alternative models” (1964, 11). “The possibility of describing

Page 152: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

140

administrative reality in terms other than the formal administrative bureau and the criterion for

efficiency arises only when alternative models become available” (12). In light of this objective,

my study has used China as a valuable case for developing an alternative model of public

administration, which, I hope, may help us to better appreciate neo-traditional and developing

contexts where the formal bureau does not exist. In my view, the China case is especially

valuable not only because of its material successes, but also because its leaders have insisted on

attending to the particularities of “Chinese characteristics.” It is this highly tailored model of

reform that has allowed them to forge outcomes that defy norms and straightforward

description.

Pre-Conditions for Bureau-Contracting

The purpose of this study is not to advocate the Chinese experience. Nevertheless, my approach

necessarily raises the question of whether there is any applicability of the bureau-contracting

model outside of China. After all, the conditions in reform-era China are truly unique. Besides

the case of Vietnam, no other communist party-state has launched market reforms successfully

and still survives. If we were to imagine the possibility of permutating bureau-contracting, what

would the underlying conditions be? In what soils can this species grow? I consider some basic

conditions below.

Talented and reform-minded leadership. We cannot discuss China’s reform success without first

giving credit to its talented and reform-minded leadership, most notably Deng Xiaoping. If a

personality like Zaire’s Motubu had taken the helm of power in China in the late 1970s, I would

think the outcome today would have been very different – and disastrous – even if the initial

conditions were exactly the same. The institutional bent in the prevailing social science analyses

makes it oftentimes unappetizing to accept leadership quality as an explanatory variable,

especially since leadership quality is endogenous and disturbingly random.

Yet, as Glaser et al (2004) found and reminded us, poor countries get out of poverty through

policies, often pursued by dictators, and not just by having conventionally desirable institutional

qualities. To deny the role of political leadership in economic and institutional development is to

Page 153: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

141

deny the role of CEOs in producing corporate successes. We need “good” leaders to make

“good” institutions. Good leadership qualities bring to mind a willingness to set priorities for

market development, discipline, determination, foresight, and an eagerness to set an honest

example for one’s subordinates. It is fair to say, I believe, that Deng Xiaoping has exemplified

these qualities.

Instruments of personnel control. The Chinese party-state’s communist system and its

revolutionary beginnings led to the establishment of an impressive organizational apparatus of

personnel control. The degree of penetration of the party-state apparatus into society under

communist rule was unprecedented in China. Party and state organs are enmeshed; officials are

appointed top-down in a unified cadre management system; and dense parallel hierarchies

ensure the transmission of party ideology and state policies from Beijing down to the lowest

work units. As Yasheng Huang (1999) had argued, the power of appointment is the central

government’s weapon of control against local officials. Instruments of personnel control are

critical to a bureau-contracting system; without them, the risk of disintegration can be

prohibitive.

A non-democratic political system. Can bureau-contracting be seen in places where officials are

elected competitively to office? I doubt so. Being a one-party communist regime, the Chinese

government has almost free rein in the structuring of public offices. Not only do citizens have a

weak voice in matters of administrative reform, they have very limited information about how

bureaucracies actually work. The details of administration presented in this study are obtained

through effort. While anecdotes and rumors about the bureaucracy are common, the actual

institutional details are not transparent to the public or even to the scholarly community. As

Terry Moe (1989) noted in the American context, citizens do not care about the arcane details of

public administration, even if the details were open to them. Only organized interest groups

care about bureaucratic structure, because it can be manipulated to fit their interests. In a non-

democratic regime like China, the interest groups who know and can manipulate the inner

workings of bureaucracy are none other than the bureaucrats themselves.

Page 154: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

142

Future Research Directions

It is hoped that this study may invite further empirical research in a number of directions,

particularly in the China case.

Bureau-Contracting and Corruption

First, we might ask what the relationship is between rents management and corruption, and

how we can measure this relationship. My explanation has centered on the creation of a stable

flow of rents to the bureaucracy via bureau-contracting mechanisms. More broadly, where

institutionalized rents are available, are bureaucrats and politicians less likely to resort to illegal

forms of corruption, such as embezzlement and extortion? In other words, when opportunities

to make legal profits from public office are widely available, are officials less likely to steal?

Unfortunately, systematic corruption data is extremely difficult to obtain anywhere and

particularly so in China. As a first step, we may consider coding reports to exposed corruption

cases, but bearing in mind that such data more accurately measures the rate of corruption

control than actual levels of corruption. Another possible step is to conduct extensive business

surveys to obtain perceptive measures of corruption.78

Regional and Temporal Variation

My work here provides one of the first systematic documentation of bureaucratic finances and

cadre rewards in China. Yet, many questions remain with regard to temporal and regional

variation. Will we find a similar pattern of dual fiscal incentives outside of Shandong province,

which is largely representative of the coastal and central regions? I hypothesize that the

patterns of cadre rewards and incentive structures will differ significantly in the Western and

impoverished regions compared to the coastal areas. In the impoverished regions, few

developmental opportunities are available, and local cadres are more likely to behave in a

predatory manner against local residents. In the Western hinterlands like Xinjiang and Tibet, the

78

Reinikka and Svensson (2003) have written a guide on how to survey and measure corruption. They also

provide a useful review of existing corruption surveys.

Page 155: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

143

ethnic factor and succession threats should figure prominently in the distribution of cadre

rewards.

Data on the distribution of public funds remains extremely difficult to obtain in China, and

generally, in non-democratic and especially communist regimes. Scholars of non-democratic

regimes have had to invent creative strategies to trace the distribution of resources and public

funds. My study employs primarily a complete county-level dataset from Shandong province

(Chapter 4) and segments of a national budget and agency-level datasets (Chapter 3). Hopefully,

as more data becomes available in China, we could make progress in empirical measurements.

Fiscal and Career Incentives

Bureaucracies and money have been the subjects of this study. My focus on fiscal incentives is

deliberate. The essence of bureau-contracting is the union of bureaucrat and entrepreneur. We

cannot study this organizational type without a thorough examination of monetary flows and

pursuits. However, for the parsimony of argument and constrained by the lack of data, I have

omitted a systematic analysis of equally important set of incentives – career incentives.79

As a scholar of American politics pointed out, officeholders are motivated by two As: avarice and

ambition (Schlesinger 1966). From a rational choice point of view, individuals who serve in office

seek to maximize their utilities, either by amassing personal wealth or by climbing the career

ladder. Wealth and power normally go together, we would think. But in China, the correlation

between wealth and power is unclear. Anecdotal evidence suggests that officials higher up on

the organizational chart may not necessarily make more money than their subordinates.80 In

future work, more attention needs to be paid to the complicated interaction between fiscal and

career incentives in the Chinese political system.

79

In recent years, some scholars have broken new ground by collecting systematic evidence about the

paths and determinants of official promotion in China (Li and Zhou 2004; Landry 2008). 80

To illustrate, consider some of these examples. Provincial leaders, especially in places like Shanghai and

Guangzhou, could easily be (legally) richer than central party hegemons. As I was told, local officials of the

Beijing municipal government were compensated twice as much as central officials working in Beijing (AI

2006-9). In a city of Sichuan, county officials made less money than street-office (equivalent to townships)

bureaucrats, who were the former’s subordinates, because the latter had well-to-do enterprises under

their direct management (AI 2007-81).

Page 156: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

144

Concluding Note

On a final concluding note, I would like to return to Weber. Weber’s theory of bureaucratization

was based on European, specifically German, experiences, which could be generalized across

modern states. It is seldom noticed that Weber had in fact noted China’s uniqueness compared

to the European model. He wrote (1047-9):

The Chinese empire constituted an essentially different type… Because of the

tremendous expansion of the empire and the small number of officials relative

to the size of population, the Chinese administration was neither intensive nor

was it centralized under the average ruler.

Chinese officialdom did not develop into a modern bureaucracy, for the

functional differentiation of spheres of jurisdiction was carried through only to a

very limited extent in view of the country’s huge size…

This accounts for the specifically anti-bureaucratic and patrimonial tendency of

this administration, which in turn explains its ‘extensive’ character and its

technical backwardness.

Written a century ago, Weber had insightfully pointed to the large size, small officialdom,

decentralized administration, and mixed spheres of jurisdiction – features that continue to

define parts of the present-day Chinese bureaucracy. However, since Weber’s writings, dramatic

and unprecedented changes have unfolded across the Chinese political and economic landscape.

New, entrepreneurial elements emerged and were gradually fused into a pre-existing

patrimonial framework, thus creating novel institutional forms. My study has suggested that it is

not sufficient to appreciate only the Weberian trajectory of bureaucratization. Equally, we

would be mistaken to view the contemporary Chinese bureaucracy as being little different from

early patrimonial or Zairian-style predatory states. The unique-ness of the bureau-contracting

model, I hope, may help us to unravel not only empirical puzzles about the structural bases of

China’s development, but may also point us to alternative paths of modernization and state

institutional building.

Page 157: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

145

APPENDIX A

LIST OF LOCAL GOVERNMENT OFFICES

Table 1 list the offices in a typical local (provincial, city, and county) government based on

information listed on official governmental websites. In China, the structure of bureaucracies

established is generally replicated from the central level to the local levels. Hence, the state

organizational chart is similar across provincial, city, and county governments. Some variation

may exist across locations where certain local governments establish ad-hoc offices for special

purposes. Offices are usually listed on governmental websites in the following clusters: (i) party

organs, (ii) governmental organs, (iii) vertically-managed offices, (iii) court and procuratorate,

and (iv) social organizations. With the exception of social organizations, most of the offices in

Table 1 are “administrative units” (xingzheng danwei). Each functions as the “supervisory

department” (zhuguan bumen) to a subsidiary group of “service units” (shiye danwei).81 In my

analysis, I refer to the administrative and service units as core bureaus and extrabureaucracies

respectively.

Table 2 lists the extrabureaucracies under five different bureaus. Similarly, the structure of

extrabureaucracies vary little between levels of government. Interestingly, in areas I have

conducted fieldwork, local governments remained reluctant to publicize the list of service units

in their locality; some even regard this information as a secret. In my research, I have not come

across any government website that provides a comprehensive list of extrabureaucracies. The

list from Table Y was a partial list provided by the personnel bureau of a city government in

Jiangsu province.

81

The social organizations have a special status because technically they do engage in administrative work

or services provision. Cadres serving in the social organizations are usually given the title of “shiye

personnel approximating civil servants” (canzhao gongwuyuan shiye bianzhi).

Page 158: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

146

Table 1: List of offices listed in a typical local governmental website

Party Organs

Party Committee (党委)

Disciplinary and inspection bureau (纪委监察局)

Organization department (组织部)

Propaganda department (宣传部)

Strategy department (统一战线工作部)

Rural affairs office (农村工作办公室)

Party school (委党校)

Dossier office (档案局)

Retired cadres office (老干部局)

Governmental Organs

Government office (人民政府办公室)

Development and reform committee (发展和改革委员会)

Commerce and trade committee (经济贸易委员会)

Education bureau (教育局)

Public security bureau (公安局)

Civil affairs bureau (民政局)

Foreign affairs office (外事办)

Legal affairs bureau (司法局)

Finance bureau (财政局)

Personnel bureau (人事局)

Labor and social security bureau (吴江市劳动和社保局)

Land bureau (国土资源局)

Construction bureau (建设局)

Urban management (城市管理局)

Transportation bureau (交通局)

Water management bureau (水利局)

Forestry bureau (农林局)

Water production bureau (水产局)

Culture and broadcasting bureau (文化广播电视管理局)

Health bureau (卫生局)

Population and family planning committee (人口和计划生育委员会)

Audit bureau (审计局)

Environmental protection bureau (审计局)

Sports bureau (体育局)

Tourism bureau (旅游局)

Statistics bureau (统计局)

Price bureau (物价局)

Grain bureau (粮食局)

Letters and petition bureau (信访局)

Safety and production inspection bureau (安全生产监督管理局)

Legal enforcement office (法制办公室)

Science and technology bureau (科学技术局)

Minority and religious affairs office (民族宗教事务局)

Administrative services center (行政服务中心)

Page 159: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

147

Vertically-managed offices

Borders inspection and disease control bureau (出入境检验检疫局)

Drugs inspection and management bureau (食品药品监督管理局)

Local tax bureau (地方税务局)

Commerce bureau (工商局)

Customs (海关)

Quality inspection bureau (质量技术监督局)

State tax bureau (国家税务局)

Weather bureau (气象局)

Housing funds management center (住房公积金管理中心吴江分中心)

Court and procuratorate

Local procuratorate (检察院)

Local court (法院)

Social organizations

Labor union (总工会)

Communist youth league (团市委)

All-women’s federation (妇女联合会)

Science and technology association (科学技术协会)

Chinese returned from overseas association (归侨侨眷联合会)

Handicapped association (残联)

Page 160: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

148

Table 2: List of Extrabureaucracies Under Selected Bureaus

Bureau/Administrative Unit

“Supervising Department”

Extrabureaucracies/Service Units

Construction bureau Construction projects quality assessment office

Construction projects inspection team

Construction transaction management center

Construction projects quality inspection office

Construction assembly management office

Construction project design inspection center

Railroad construction office

Urban science research institute

Major construction projects management office

Dossier center for construction projects

Office for managing relocation and moving

Professional school for construction

New technologies in construction company/outreach office

Construction services center

Construction training center

Construction safety inspection center

Construction information center

School for construction techniques

Forestry bureau Party school for the forestry bureau

Forestry and greenery inspection team

ABC city vista point management office

A park management office

B park management office

C park management office

D park management office

Greenery quality inspection and management center

Asset management center

Health bureau Health and sanitation inspection center

Medical personnel and technical services center

Disease prevention and control center

Blood center

Emergency services center

Health association

Medical fees accounting center

Party school of the health bureau

Cheer city hospital

Personnel Bureau Talent services center

Transferred military personnel services center

International talent exchange services center

Talent examination center

Talent market

Commerce and trade

commission

Finance and trade information center

Procurement center for electronics equipment

Page 161: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

149

Cement office

Enterprise training center

Energy and resource training institute

Office for the reform of construction materials

Small and medium enterprise services center

Commerce association

Development and reform

commission

Information center

Planning and economics training center

Investment and management company

Source: Personnel Bureau of Cheer City Government

Page 162: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

150

APPENDIX B

CHINA’S FORMAL CADRE WAGE SCALE

Table 1: Basic and functional wages of civil servants at the provincial and city level

Date of Issue: October 1993

Unit: yuan/month

Function Basic

Wages

Functional wages by grade Basic wages (jiben gongzi) and functional wages

(zhiwu gongzi) combined

1 2 3 4 5 6 1 2 3 4 5 6

Mayor 40 190 165 150 140 130 120 230 205 190 180 170 160

Vice mayor 40 150 140 130 120 110 100 190 180 170 165 150 140

Ju/Chu Chief 40 130 120 110 100 91 82 170 160 150 140 131 122

Vice Ju/Chu Chief 40 110 100 91 82 73 65 150 140 131 122 113 105

Ke Head 40 82 73 65 57 49 42 122 113 105 97 89 82

Vice Ke Head 40 65 57 49 42 36 30 105 97 89 82 76 70

Ke Officer 40 49 42 36 30 24 18 89 82 76 70 64 58

Support Staff 40 42 36 30 24 18 12 82 76 70 64 58 52

Source: Xu 2007, p. 197

Page 163: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

151

Table 2: Wages by Function and Grade

Date of Issue: November 1993

Unit: yuan/month

Function Wages by Function (zhiwu) Wages by Grade

(jibie)

Basic

(jiben)

Wages

Length of

work

(gong

ling)

wages

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 Grade Wage

One yuan

added for

every

year of

service

Chairman

Vice-Chairman

Premier

480 550 630 1 470 90

2 425 90

Vice Premier

Member of the

State Council

400 460 520 580 3 382 90

4 340 90

Minister

Vice Minister

330 380 430 480 530 5 298 90

6 263 90

Si Chief

Ting Chief

270 315 360 405 450 7 228 90

Vice Si Chief

Vice Ting Chief

118 143 168 193 218 243 8 193 90

Chu Chief

County Head

144 174 204 234 264 294 9 164 90

Vice Chu Chief

Vice County Head

118 143 168 193 218 243 10 135 90

11 111 90

Ke Head 96 116 136 156 176 196 216 12 92 90

Vice Ke Head 79 94 109 124 139 154 169 13 77 90

Ke Executive 63 75 87 99 111 123 135 147 14 65 90

Support Staff 50 60 70 80 90 100 110 120 15 55 90

Source: Xu 2007, p. 206

Page 164: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

152

Table 3: Regional subsidies for various “hardship” regions

Date of Issue: February 2001

Unit: yuan/month

Region (1) Region (2) Region (3) Region (4)

Average subsidy 43 86 172 300

Provincial level and above 100 200 -- --

City level 80 160 320 560

County level 60 120 240 420

Ke level 47 95 190 330

Ke and below 40 80 160 280

Source: Xu 2007, p. 203

Page 165: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

153

APPENDIX C

SUMMARY OF INTERVIEW TARGETS

For this study, I conducted 165 interviews in China between 2006 to 2009. The individuals

interviewed are central and local level cadres, ranging from civil servants in leadership positions

to rank-to-file public employees working in administrative agencies and public service providers.

To widen the scope of my research to the furthest extent possible, I conducted interviews in

multiple locations, at all levels of government (from the central government down to the

villages), and across governmental sectors. Some of the interviewees were interviewed more

than once.

Because of the delicate nature of my topic, I have chosen to be doubly careful in protecting the

identity of my interviewees. This study names interviews only by the identification number

assigned to each interviewee, followed by the date on which the first interview was conducted. I

have also chosen not to identify the county and city governments referred to in the study.

Instead, for easy reference, I assign random names to them. The following tables summarize the

distribution of my interviews by location, level of government, and governmental

sector/department.

Page 166: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

154

Table 1: Interviews by Location

Central government 18

Anhui 4

Beijing 2

Chongqing 1

Guangdong 8

Guangxi 1

Hunan 2

Jiangsu 28

Shandong 15

Shanghai 1

Sichuan 41

Tianjin 44

Table 2: Interviews by Level of Government

Central 18

Provincial level 14

City level 27

County level 88

Township and villages 18

Table 3: Interviews by Governmental Sector/Department

Sector/Department No.

Administrative Office 4

Agriculture 2

Arts & Culture 3

Civil Affairs 13

Construction 3

Court 3

Education 23

Environment 12

Finance 22

Health 7

NDRC (National Development & Reform Commission) 7

Party Organs 6

Personnel 21

Research 3

Township and village governments 17

Others 19

Page 167: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

155

REFERENCES

Acemoglu, Daron, Michael Kremer, and Atif Mian. "Incentives in markets, firms, and

governments ." Journal of Law, Economics, and Organizations , 2007: 1-34.

Amsden, Alice. Asia's Next Giant: South Korea and Late Industrialization. New York : Oxford

University Press, 1989.

Appelbaum, R.P., and J. Henderson. States and Development in the Asian Pacific Rim . Newbury

Park, CA: Sage, 1992.

Baker, George P., Michael C. Jensen, and Kevin J. Murphy. "Compensation and Incentives:

Practice vs. Theory." The Journal of Finance, 43, no. 3 (1988): 593-616.

Bardhan, Pranab. "Corruption and development: A review of issues." Journal of Economic

Literature XXXV (1997): 1320-1346.

Barkey, Karen. Bandits and Bureaucrats: The Ottoman Route to State Centralization. Itaca:

Cornell University Press, 1994.

Barnett, Doak. Cadres, Bureaucracy, and Political Power in Communist China. New York :

Columbia University Press, 1967.

Bates, Robert. "The role of the state in development ." In The Oxford handbook of political

economy , by Barry R. Weingast Weingast and Donald Wittman. New York: Oxford

University Press, 2008.

Berkowitz, Daniel, Katharina Pistor, and Jean-Francois Richard. "Economic development, legality,

and the transplant effect." European Economic Review 47, no. 1 (2003): 165-195.

Bernstein, Thomas P., and Xiaobo Lu. Taxation without representation in contemporary rural

China . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2003.

Bhagwati, Jagdish. "Directly unproductive, profit-seeking activities." Journal of Political Economy

90, no. 5 (1983): 988-1002.

Blecher, Mark. "Developmental State, Entreprenuerial State." In The Chinese State in the Era of

Economic Reform, by Gordon White. London: Macmillan, 1991.

Blecher, Mark, and Vivienne Shue. "Into leather: State-led Development and the Private Sector

in Xinji." China Quarterly, 2001: 369-393.

Brodsgaard, Kjeld. "Institutional Reform and the Bianzhi System in China." The China Quarterly,

2002: 361-386.

Page 168: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

156

Buchanan, James M. "Rent seeking and profit seeking." In Toward a theory of the rent-seeking

society , by Buchanan et al. College Station: Texas A&M University Press, 1980.

Buchanan, James M., Robert D. Tollison, and Gordon Tullock. Toward a theory of the rent-

seeking society . Texas: Texas A&M University Press, 1980.

Burns, John P. "Downsizing the Chinese State." The China Quarterly, 2003: 776-802.

Campos, J. Edgardo, Donald Lien, and Sanjay Pradhan. "The impact of corruption on investment:

predictability matters." World Development 27, no. 6 (1999): 1059-1067.

Campos, J. Edgardo, ed. Corruption: The boom and bust of East Asia. Manila, Phillippines: Manila

University Press, 2001.

Campos, Jose Edgardo, and Hilton Root. The Key to the Asian Miracle: Making Shared Growth

Credible . Washington D.C. : Brookings Institution , 1996.

Castells, Manuel. "Four Asian Tigers with a Dragon Head." In States and Development in the

Asian Pacific Rim, by Richard Appelbaum & Jeffrey Henderson (eds.), 33-70. Newbury

Park, CA: Sage, 1992.

Chang, Gordon. The coming collaspe of China. New York : Random House, 2001.

Cheng, Siwei. "Strategic Directions and Policy Implementation for Reforming China's Institutional

Units." In Studies on Economic Reforms and Development in China, by Siwei Cheng.

Oxford University Press, 2001.

Chu, Tung-Tsu. Local government in China under the Ching. Stanford: Stanford University Press,

1969.

Coase, Ronald. "The Nature of the Firm." Economica 4 (1937): 386-405.

Dobbs, Michael. Down with Big Brother: the fall of the Soviet empire. Alfred A. Knopf, 1997.

Donahue, John D. The Privatization Decision: Public Ends, Private Means. New York : Basic Books,

1989.

Duara, Prasenjit. "State involution: A study of local finances in north china, 1911-1935."

Comparative Studies in Society and History 29, no. 1 (1987): 132-161.

Duckett, Jane. "Bureaucrats in Business, Chinese-Style: The lessons of market reform and state

entrepreneurialism in the People's Republic of China." World Development 29, no. 1

(2001): 23-37.

—. The Entreprenuerial State in China: Real Estate and Commerce Departments in the Reform

Era in Tianjin. New York: Routledge, 1998.

Page 169: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

157

Evans, Peter. Embedded Autonomy: States and Industrial Transformation. Princeton, NJ:

Princeton University Press, 1995.

Evans, Peter, and James E. Rauch. "Bureaucracy and Growth: A Cross-national Analysisof the

Effects of “Weberian” State Structures on Economic Growth." American Sociological

Review 64, no. 5 (1999): 748-65.

Frant, Howard. "High-Powered and Low-Powered Incentives in the Public Sector." Journal of

Public Administration Research and Theory, 6 1996: 365-381.

Gardiner, John. "Defining corruption." In Political corruption: concepts and contexts, by A.J.

Heidenheimer & Michael Johnston (eds.). New Brunswick: Transaction Publishers, 2000.

Geddes, Barbara. Politician's Dilemma: Building State Capacity in Latin America. Berkeley.

University of California Press, 1996.

Gerschenkron, Alexander. Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective. Belknap Press ,

1962.

Glaeser, Edward L., Rafael Porta La, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, and Andrei Schleifer. "Do

institutions cause growth?" Journal of economic growth 9 (2004): 271-303.

Goldstone, Jack. "The Coming China Collapse." Foreign Policy 99 (1995): 35-53.

Gore, Lance. Market communism : the institutional foundation of China's post-Mao hyper-

growth . New York: Oxford University Press, 1998.

Haggard, Stepan. The Political Economy of the Asian Financial Crisis. Washington D.C.: Institute

for International Economics, 2000.

—. Pathways from the periphery : the politics of growth in the newly industrializing countries.

Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1990.

Haggard, Stephan, and Robert Kaufman. "The politics of stabilization and structural adjustment."

In Developing country debt and economic performance: the international financial

system, by Jeffrey ed. Sachs. Chicago: University of Chicago Press , 1989.

Hall, Peter A., and David W. Soskice. Varieties of capitalism: the institutional foundations of

comparative advantage. New York: Oxford University Press, 2001.

Henderson, Jeffrey. Industrial transformation in Eastern Europe in light of East Asian experience.

London : Macmillan, 1998.

Henderson, Jeffrey, David Hulme, Jalilian Hossein, and Phillips Richard. "Bureaucratic Effects:

Weberian State Agencies and Poverty Reduction." Sociology 41 (2007): 515-532.

Page 170: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

158

Heo, Uk, and Sunwoong Kim. "Financial Crisis in South Korea: Failure of the Government-Led

Development Paradigm." Asian Survey 11, no. 3 (2000).

Hickey, Paul. "Fee-taking, salary reform, and the structure of state power in late Qing China,

1909-1911." Modern China 17, no. 3 (1991): 389-417.

Howell, Jude. China opens its door: the politics of economic transition. Boulder, CO: Lynne

Rienner, 1993.

Huang, Philip C. "Public sphere/civil society in China? The third realm between state and

society." Modern China 19, no. 2 (1993): 216-40.

Huang, Shu-min. The Spiral Road: Change in a Chinese Village Through the Eyes of a Communist

Party. 2nd Edition. Boulder: Westview Press, 1998.

Huang, Yasheng. Inflation and investment controls in China: The political economy of central-

local relations. Cambridge University Press: 1999.

Hubbard, Michael. "Bureaucrats and Markets in China: The rise and fall of the entrepreneurial

local government." Governance 8, no. 3 (1995): 335-353.

Hutchcroft, Paul D. "The Politics of Privilege: Assessing the impact of rents, corruption, and

clientelism on third world development." Political Studies XLV (1997): 639-658.

Jin, Hehui, Yingyi Qian, and Barry Weingast. "Regional decentralization and fiscal incentives:

federalism, Chinese style." Journal of public economics 89 (2005): 1719-1742.

Johnson, Chalmers. MITI and the Japanese Miracle. Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1982.

Joseph, Richard. Democracy and prebendal politics in Nigeria. Cambridge: Cambridge University

Press, 1987.

Kang, David. Crony Capitalism: Corruption and Development in South Korea and the Phillippines.

Cambridge : Cambridge University Press, 2002.

Khan, Mushtaq H., and Kwame Sundaram Jomo. Rents, Rent-Seeking and Economic

Development:Theory & Evidence in Asia . Boston, MA: Cambridge University Press, 2000.

Kiser, Edgar, and Yong Cai. "War and Bureaucratization in Qin China: Exploring an Anomalous

Case." American Sociological Review 68, no. 4 (2003): 511-539.

Knack, Stephan, and Phillip Keefer. "Institutions and Economic Performance: Cross-Country

Tests Using Alternative Institutional Measures." Economics and Politics 7, no. 3 (1995):

207-27.

Page 171: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

159

Krueger, Anne. "The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society." American Economic Review

64, no. 3 (1974): 291-303.

Kung, J.K., and Lin Y. "The Decline of Township-and-Village Enterprises in China's Economic

Transition." World Development 35, no. 4 (2007): 569-84.

La Porta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert Vishny. "The quality of

government." Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 15, no. 1 (1999): 222-79.

Lam, Tao-Chiu, and James L. Perry. "Service Organizations in China: Reform and Its Limits ." In

Remaking China's Public Management , by Peter Lee and Carlos Lo, 19-41. London:

Quorum Books, 2001.

Landry, Pierre. Decentralized Authoritarianism in China: The Communist Party's Control of Local

Elites in the Post-Mao Era. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2008.

Lau, Lawrence, Yingyi Qian, and Gerard Roland. "Reform without losers: An interpretation of

China's dual-track approach to transition." The Journal of Political Economy 108, no. 1

(2000): 120-143.

Lee, Charlotte. Strategies of Political Control and Party Adaptation in Reform-Era China.

Dissertation, Department of Political Science, Stanford University, 2009.

Lee, Hung-Yung. From Revolutionary Cadres to Party Technocrats in Socialist China. Berkeley:

University of California Press, 1991.

Levi, Margaret. Of Rule and Revenue. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1988.

Li, Cheng. China’s Leaders: The New Generation. Rowman & Littlefield Publishers, 2001.

Li, David. "Changing Incentives of the Chinese Bureaucracy." American Economic Review 88, no.

2 (1998): 393.

Li, Hongbin, and Li-An Zhou. "Political Turnover & Economic Performance: The Incentive Role of

Personnel Control in China." Journal of Public Economics 89, no. 9-10 (2005): 1743-1762.

Lieberthal, Kenneth. Governing China: From Revolution Through Reform. W. W. Norton, 2003.

Lin, Yi-min, and Zhanxin Zhang. "Backyard profit centers: the private assets of public agencies."

In Property Rights and Economic Reform in China, by Jean Oi and Andrew Walder.

Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1999.

Love, John F. McDonald's: Behind the Arches . New York: Bantam Books, 1986.

Lu, Xiaobo. "Booty Socialism, Bureau-Prenuers, and the State in Transition: Organizational

Corruption in China." Comparative Politics 32, no. 3 (2000a): 273-294.

Page 172: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

160

—. Cadres and corruption: the organizational involution of the Chinese Communist Party.

Stanford: Stanford University Press, 2000b.

MacIntyre, Andrew. "Funny Money: Fiscal Policy, Rent-seeking and Economic Performance in

Indonesia." In Rents, rent-seeking, and economic development, by M.H. Khan & Jomo K.S.

Cambridge: Cambride University Press, 2000.

—. "Investment, Property Rights, and Corruption in Indonesia." In Corruption: the boom and

bust of east asia, by J. Edgardo Campos (ed.). Manila, Phillippines: Manila University

Press, 2001.

Magaloni, Beatriz. Voting for autocracy: hegemonic party survival and its demise in mexico.

Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2006.

Magaloni, Beatriz, Alberto Diaz-Cayeros, and Federico Estevez. "Clientelism and Portfolio

Diversification: A Model of Electoral Investment with Applications to Mexico." In Patrons,

Clients, and Policies, by Herbert Kitschelt and Steven Wilkinson. Cambridge: Cambridge

University Press, 2007.

Manion, Melanie. Retirement of revolutionaries in China: public policies, social norms, private

interests. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1993.

—. Corruption By Design: Building Clean Government in Mainland China and Hong Kong.

Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 2004.

Mauro, Paulo. "Corruption and Growth." Quarterly Journal of Economics 110, no. 3 (1995): 681-

712.

McCormick, Barnett. Political reform in post-Mao China. Berkeley: University of California Press,

1990.

Mertha, Andrew. "China's 'Soft' Centralization: Shifting Tiao/Kuai Authority Relations." The

China Quarterly 184 (2005): 791-810.

Moe, Terry. "The New Economics of Organization." American Journal of Political Science 28, no.

4 (1984): 739-777.

Montinola, Yingyi Qian, and Barry Weingast. "Market Preserving Federalism, Chinese-Style: The

political basis for economic success." World Politics 48, no. 1 (1995): 50-81.

Nee, Victor, and Peng Lian. "Sleeping with the Enemy: A Dynamic Model of Declining Political

Commitment in State Socialism." Theory and Society 23 (1994): 253- 296.

Page 173: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

161

North, Douglass, and Barry Weingast. "Constitutions and commitment: The evolution of

institutions governing public choice in 17th century England." The Journal of Economic

History 49, no. 4 (1989): 803-832.

Nye, J.N. "Corruption and Political Development: A Cost-Benefit Analysis." The American Political

Science Review 61, no. 2 (1967): 417-427.

OECD. "Reforming PSU: Challenges." In Governing China. OECD Press, 2006.

Oi, Jean. "Fiscal reforms and the economic foundations of local state corporatism." World

Politics 45, no. 1 (1992): 99-126.

—. Rural China Takes Off: Institutional Foundations of Economic Growth. Berkeley: University of

California Press, 1999.

—. "The role of the local state in China's transitional economy." The China Quarterly 144 (1995):

1132-49.

Onis, Ziya. "The logic of the developmental state." Comparative Politics 24, no. 1 (1991): 109-26.

Park, Albert, Scott Rozelle, Christine Wong, and Ren Changqing. "Distributional consequences of

reforming local public finance in china." The China Quarterly 147 (1996): 751-778.

Pearson, Margaret M. "The Business of Governing Business in China: Institutions & Norms of the

Emerging Regulatory State." World Politics 57, no. 2 (2005): 296-322.

Pei, Minxin. China's Trapped Transition: The Limits of Developmental Autocracy. Cambridge:

Harvard University Press, 2006.

Pempel, T.J. (ed.). The Politics of the Asian Financial Crisis. Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1999.

Przeworski, Adam. "The last instance: Are institutions the primary cause of economic

development?" European Journal of Sociology 45, no. 2 (2004): 165-188.

Qian, Yingyi. "How Reform Worked in China." In In Search of Prosperity: Analytical Narratives on

Economic Growth, by Dani Rodrik. NJ: Princeton University Press, 2003.

Qian, Yingyi, and Jinglian Wu. "China's transition to a market economy: how far across the

river? ." In How far across the river? , by Nicholas C. Hope, Dennis Tao Yang and Mu

Yang Li. Palo Alto: Stanford University Press, 2003.

Rankin, Mary Backus. "Some observations on a Chinese public sphere." Modern China 19, no. 2

(1993): 158-182.

Rauch, James, and Peter Evans. "Bureaucratic Structure and Bureaucratic Performance in Less

Developed Countries." Journal of Public Economics 75 (2000): 49-71.

Page 174: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

162

Reed, Bradly Ward. Talons and Teeth: County Clerks and Runners in the Qing Dynasty. Stanford:

Stanford University Press, 2000.

Reinikka, Ritva and Jakob Svensson. “Survey techniques to measure and explain corruption.”

World Bank Policy Working Paper 3071, 2003.

Riggs, Fred Warren. Administration in developing countries; the theory of prismatic society.

Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1964.

Rock, Michael T., and Heidi Bonnett. "The comparative politics of corruption: Accounting for the

east asian paradox in empirical studies of corruption, growth, and investment." World

Development 32, no. 6 (2004): 999-1017.

Rodrik, Dani. "Getting Interventions Right: How South Korea and Taiwan Grew Rich." Economic

Policy 20 (1995): 55-97.

—. "Second-Best Institutions." American Economic Review 98, no. 2 (2008): 100-104.

Root, Hilton. Small Countries, Big Lessons. Hong Kong: Oxford University Press, 1996.

—. "Has Corruption in China Become Systemic." Asian Survey 8 (1996b).

Rose-Ackerman, Susan. Corruption and Government: Causes, Consequences, and Reform. MA:

Cambridge University Press, 1999.

Schlesinger, Joseph. Ambition and Politics: Political Careers in the United States. Chicago: Rand

McNally, 1966.

Schneider, Ben Ross. "The Desarrollista State in Brazil and Mexico." In The Developmental State,

by Meredith Woo-Cumings (ed.). Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1999.

Segal, Gerald, and Davis (eds.) Goodman. Towards Recovery in the Pacific Asia. London:

Routledge, 2000.

Shirk, Susan. The political logic of economic reform. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1993.

Shleifer, Andrew, and Daniel Treisman. Without a map: political tactics and economic reform in

russia. Cambridge: MIT Press, 2000.

Shue, Vivienne. "Beyond the budget: finance organization and reform in a chinese county."

Modern China 10, no. 2 (1984): 147-186.

Solnick, Steven. Stealing the state: control and collaspe in Soviet institutions . Cambridge, MA:

Harvard University Press, 1998.

Stepan, Alfred. The State and Society: Peru in Comparative Perspective . Princeton, NJ: Princeton

University Press, 1978.

Page 175: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

163

Stiglitz, J. "Wither reform: ten years of transition." In Annual World Bank Conference on

Economic Development , by B. Pleskovic and J. Stiglitz. Washington D.C. : World Bank,

2000.

Sun, Yan. Corruption and Market in Contemporary China. Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 2004.

—. "Corruption, Growth, and Reform: The Chinese Enigma." Current History 104, no. 683 (2005):

257-263.

—. "Reform, State, and Corruption: Is Corruption Less Destructive in China Than in Russia?"

Comparative Politics 32, no. 1 (1999): 1-20.

Tarkowski, Jacek. "A centralized system and corruption: the case of Poland." Asian Journal of

Public Administration 10, no. 1 (1988): 48-70.

Tilly, Charles. Coercion, capital and European states, A.D. 990-1992. Blackwell Publishing, 1993.

Tsai, Kellee. "Off Balance: The Unintended Consequences of Fiscal Federalism in China." Journal

of Chinese Political Science 1, no. 26 (2004): 1-26.

Van de Walle, N. "Meet the new boss, same as the old boss? The evolution of political

clientelism in Africa." In Patrons, Clients, and Policies: Patterns of Democratic

Accountability and Political Competition, by H Kitschelt and Wilkinson S. Cambridge:

Cambridge University Press, 2007.

Wade, Robert. Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East

Asian Industrialization. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1990.

Wade, Robert, and Gordon White. Developmental State in East Asia. IDS Research Reports R16,

1988.

Walder, Andrew. Communist Neo-Traditionalism: Work and Authority in Chinese Industry.

Berkeley: University of California Press, 1986.

—. "Local governments as industrial firms: An organizational analysis of China's transitional

economy." American Journal of Sociology 101, no. 2 (1995): 263-301.

—. "The county government as industrial organization." In Zouping in Transition, by Andrew, ed.

Walder. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1998.

Wang, Rong. "Political determinants of county government budgeting in china: a case study."

Working Paper, Institute of Development Studies (IDS), 2004.

Page 176: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

164

Wang, Shaoguang. "The Rise of the Regions: Fiscal Reform and the Decline of Central State

Capacity in China." In The Waning of the Communist State, by Andrew Walder.

University of California Press, 1995.

Wang, Shaoguang, and Angang Hu. "Guoqing Baogao (Report on National Conditions)." Chinese

Economic Studies 3 (1995).

Weber, Max. Economy and Society. Edited by Guenter Roth and Claus Wittich. New York:

Bedminster, [1904-1911] 1968.

Wedeman, Andrew. "Budgets, extra-budgets, and small treasuries: illegal monies and local

autonomy in China." Journal of Contemporary China 9, no. 25 (2000): 489-511.

—. "Development and corruption: the East Asian Paradox." In Political business in East Asia, by

E.T. Gomez. London: Routledge, 2002a.

—. "Looters, Rent-scrappers, and dividend-collectors: Corruption and growth in Zaire, South

Korea, and the Philippines." The Journal of Developing Areas 31 (1997): 457-478.

—. "State predation and rapid growth: politicization of business in China." In Political business in

East Asia, by E.T. Gomez. London: Routledge, 2002b.

—. "The Intensification of Corruption in China." The China Quarterly 180 (2004): 895-921.

Wei-Arthus, Huiying. A study of authority and relations in chinese governmental agencies and

institutional work units. Lewiston: Edwin Mellon Press, 2000.

Weingast, Barry. "The economic role of political institutions." Journal of Law, Economics, and

Organization 7 (1995): 1-31.

White, Gordon. "The role of the state in China's socialist industrialization." In Developmental

States in East Asia, by Robert Wade & Gordon White (eds.). IDS Research Reports R16,

1988.

Whiting, Susan. "The Cadre Evaluation system at the grass roots: the paradox of party rule." In

Holding China Together, by Barry et al Naughton. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University

Press, 2004.

Williamson, Oliver. Markets and hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications. NY: Free Press,

1974.

Woo-Cumings, Meredith. "Introduction ." In The Developmental State, by Woo-Cumings (ed.)

Meredith. Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1999.

Page 177: STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM …hr313dw9240...STATE, MARKET, AND BUREAU-CONTRACTING IN REFORM CHINA A DISSERTATION ... Eve Grace. Learning political theory from

165

World Bank. Building institutions for markets: World Development 2002. New York: Oxford

University Press, 2000.

—. China: National Development and Sub-National Finance: A Review of Provincial Expenditures.

Report No. 22951-CHA, World Bank, 2002.

—.Deepening public service unit reform to improve service delivery. Beijing: CITIC Press, 2005.

—. The East Asian Miracle: Economic Growth and Public Policy. New York: Oxford University

Press, 1993.

—. World Development Report 1997: The State in a Changing World. New York: Oxford

University Press, 1997.

Wu, Zhongjian, and Sun Jiaming (eds.). Tianjin city bianzhi annals (Tianjinshi jigoubianzhi zhi) .

Tianjin: Tianjin Social Science Academy, 1998.

Xu, Songtao. Looking back at 28 years of personnel reform (Huimou zhongguo renshi zhidu gaige

28 nian). Beijing: Zhongguo Renshi Press, 2007.

Yang, Dali. Remaking the Chinese Leviathan: Market Transition and the Politics of Governance in

China. Stanford: Stanford University Press, 2004.

Yusuf, Shahid. "The east asian miracle at the millennium ." In Rethinking the east asian miracle,

by Joseph E. Stiglitz and Shahid Yusuf. New York : Oxford University Press, 2001.

Zelin, Madeleine. The Magistrate's Tael. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1984.

Zhang, Xuehua. Enforcing environmental regulations in Hubei province, China: Agencies, Courts,

Citizens. Dissertation , Interdisciplinary Graduate Program in Environment and

Resources, Stanford University, 2008.

Zhao, Libo. The reform of shiyedanwei: an analysis of public services development (Shiye danwei

gaige: gonggong shiye fazhan xinjizhi tanxi). Jinan: Shandong People's Press, 2003.

Zhuravskaya, Ekaterina. "Incentives to provide local public goods: fiscal federalism, Russian

style." Journal of public economics 76, no. 3 (2000): 337-386.

—. "Wither Russia? A review of Andrei Shleifer's Normal Country." Journal of Economic

Literature 45, no. 1 (2007): 127-146.