21
Sometimes externality problems can’t be solved by private bargaining (transaction costs are too big). Public policy toward externalities. “Command-and-control” policies. Regulate behavior directly. Examples: Total ban on certain products or procedures. Require certain practices or standards. Set limits on emissions on individual basis.

Sometimes externality problems can’t be solved by private bargaining (transaction costs are too big). Public policy toward externalities. “Command-and-control”

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Sometimes externality problems can’t be solved by private bargaining (transaction costs are too big). Public policy toward externalities. “Command-and-control”

Sometimes externality problems can’t be solved by private bargaining (transaction costs are too big).

Public policy toward externalities.

“Command-and-control” policies.Regulate behavior directly.

Examples:Total ban on certain products or

procedures.Require certain practices or standards.Set limits on emissions on individual basis.

Page 2: Sometimes externality problems can’t be solved by private bargaining (transaction costs are too big). Public policy toward externalities. “Command-and-control”

“Market-based” policies.Provide correct incentives, then let private decision-makers make their own choices.

Examples:Pollution taxes (“Pigovian taxes” --

Arthur Pigou)Designed to “internalize”

pollution’s negative externality, forcing polluters to take account of impact on bystanders.

Tradable pollution permits.

Page 3: Sometimes externality problems can’t be solved by private bargaining (transaction costs are too big). Public policy toward externalities. “Command-and-control”

Sulfur dioxide (SO2) and “acid rain.”(http://www.epa.gov/acidrain/)

“Acid rain”: A general term describing several ways that acids fall out of the atmosphere.

Effects: Damage to forests, soils, fish, wildlife,materials, and human health.

Causes: Mainly SO2 (nitrogen oxides too). About 65% of SO2 emissions come from electric

power plants burning fossil fuels.

Page 4: Sometimes externality problems can’t be solved by private bargaining (transaction costs are too big). Public policy toward externalities. “Command-and-control”

A power utility currently emits 10,000 tons/yr. SO2.

Suppose it is forced to reduce (“abate”) its emissions.

Abatement methods:Install “scrubbers” to remove some SO2.

Switch to coal with lower sulfur content.Modify plant technology to burn natural gas.

Different methods have different costs, so . . .. . . low-cost methods will be used first . . .

. . . leaving high-cost methods as last resort.

Page 5: Sometimes externality problems can’t be solved by private bargaining (transaction costs are too big). Public policy toward externalities. “Command-and-control”

Bottom line: “Marginal abatement cost” (the cost of abating one more ton/yr. of emissions) will increase with the total amount of abatement.

10,000

($/ton)

(tons/yr.)

marginal abatement cost

Note:In this graphpollutionabatement(reduction) increases from left to right.

Page 6: Sometimes externality problems can’t be solved by private bargaining (transaction costs are too big). Public policy toward externalities. “Command-and-control”

($/ton)

(tons/yr.)

Start with the graph again . . .

. . . and rotate it about a vertical axis.

10,000 0 10,000 0

Now abatementis measured fromright to left . . .

. . . and unabated pollution ismeasured fromleft to right.

0 10,000

Page 7: Sometimes externality problems can’t be solved by private bargaining (transaction costs are too big). Public policy toward externalities. “Command-and-control”

When set up in this way, the graph shows WTP for pollution rights.

3,000

For example, the utility’s WTP for the right to emit the 3,000th ton/yr. of pollution . . .. . . would be the cost they would

save by not having to abate it.

. . . and this is the height of the curve at a quantity of 3,000 tons/yr.

($/ton)

(tons/yr.) 0 10,000

WTP for3,000thton/yr.

7,000

This would be the marginalcost of the 7,000 ton/yr. ofabatement . . .

Page 8: Sometimes externality problems can’t be solved by private bargaining (transaction costs are too big). Public policy toward externalities. “Command-and-control”

This gives us the utility’s demand curve for pollution rights.

($/ton)

(tons/yr.)

0 10,000

Suppose the utility had to purchase the right to polluteat any given level.

6,000

The utility would demand 6,000 tons/yr.of pollution rights.

It would abate 4,000 tons/yr. of its previous emissions level . . .

90

Price of pollution “rights” = 90 $/ton.

. . . because these could be abated at marginal cost < 90 $/ton.

It would continue to pollute 6,000 tons/yr because for these, . . .

. . . it’s cheaper to pay for the right to pollute than to abate.

Page 9: Sometimes externality problems can’t be solved by private bargaining (transaction costs are too big). Public policy toward externalities. “Command-and-control”

Now two utilities, each emitting 10K tons/yr. to start, but with different demands for pollution rights.

Suppose the EPA wants to limit total emissions to 10K tons/yr.

One (“command-and-control”) approach:

($/ton)

10,000

“Watts-are-us”

5K limit for each.

($/ton)

10,000 (tons/ yr.)

“Powerama”

5,000 5,000

Page 10: Sometimes externality problems can’t be solved by private bargaining (transaction costs are too big). Public policy toward externalities. “Command-and-control”

The problem: Two utilities would operate at different marginal abatement costs.

($/ton)

10,000 (tons/ yr.)

“Powerama”($/ton)

10,000

“Watts-are-us”

Powerama could pollute 1 more (abate 1 less): savings = $120.

Watts-are-us could pollute 1 less (abate 1 more): extra cost = $100.

Same total emissions but lower cost.

5,000

100

5,000

120

Page 11: Sometimes externality problems can’t be solved by private bargaining (transaction costs are too big). Public policy toward externalities. “Command-and-control”

To get any given level of pollution abatement in the least-cost way, we have to have both (all) utilities operating at the same marginal abatement cost.

One (“market-based”) approach to achieving this:

Put a “price” on pollution rights by imposing a pollution tax.

Let’s say that a tax of 108 $/ton is the “right” level to achieve the target of 10K tons/yr. in total emissions.

(It depends on the demand curves.)

Page 12: Sometimes externality problems can’t be solved by private bargaining (transaction costs are too big). Public policy toward externalities. “Command-and-control”

Let’s bring back the two graphs:

Here’s where they were with individual limits of 5K tons/yr.

Here’s where they’ll be facing a 108 $/ton pollution tax.

($/ton)

10,000 (tons/ yr.)

“Powerama”

4,500 5,500

($/ton)

10,000

“Watts-are-us”

5,000

100 108

5,000

120

Page 13: Sometimes externality problems can’t be solved by private bargaining (transaction costs are too big). Public policy toward externalities. “Command-and-control”

Both utilities pollute up the point at which the pollution tax . . .

. . . (or “price” of pollution rights) . . .. . . is equal to marginal abatement costs.

Result:Equal marginal abatement costs, . . .

. . . which means that the emissions target(10K tons/yr.) is achieved with

lowest total cost.

This is the reason for economists’ preference for “market-based” approaches.

Page 14: Sometimes externality problems can’t be solved by private bargaining (transaction costs are too big). Public policy toward externalities. “Command-and-control”

The utility with “low” marginal abatement costs (Watts-are-us) abates a little more (pollutes a little less) . . .

. . . and the utility with “high” marginal abatement costs (Powerama) abates a little less (pollutes a little more).

What if the EPA doesn’t know pollution rights demands, so it can’t calculate that 108 $/ton is the “right” tax for a 10K ton/yr. target?

Alternative market-based approach:Tradable pollution permits.

Page 15: Sometimes externality problems can’t be solved by private bargaining (transaction costs are too big). Public policy toward externalities. “Command-and-control”

($/ton)

10,000 (tons/ yr.)

“Powerama”

EPA issues permits for 5,000 tons/yr. to each utility.

Powerama (“high” marginal value for permits) can buy extras from . . .

. . . Watts-are-us (“low” marginal value for permits).

($/ton)

10,000

“Watts-are-us”

5,000

100

5,000

120

Page 16: Sometimes externality problems can’t be solved by private bargaining (transaction costs are too big). Public policy toward externalities. “Command-and-control”

Trade will equalize marginal value of permits (marginal abatement costs).

Same result as with 108 $/ton pollution tax.

108

4,500 5,500

($/ton)

10,000 (tons/ yr.)

“Powerama”($/ton)

10,000

“Watts-are-us”

Page 17: Sometimes externality problems can’t be solved by private bargaining (transaction costs are too big). Public policy toward externalities. “Command-and-control”

Tradable permits are used by EPA to control acid rain.

“Cap and Trade” approach.(http://www.epa.gov/airmarkets/. . .)

Clean Air Act Amendments of 1990 (first year in operation: 1995)

(from New York Times, 10/24/97)“Under the Clean Air Act, total sulfur emissions are capped by

giving electric utilities rights to emit sulfur in proportion to their lower, 1980 emissions. Companies that reduce emissions below their allowance by closing plants, switching fuels or attaching chemical scrubbers to their smokestacks are free to sell their surplus pollution rights, while others are free to exceed their limits by buying those rights. Last year (1996), the market price of sulfur allowances averaged just more than $100/ton.”

Page 18: Sometimes externality problems can’t be solved by private bargaining (transaction costs are too big). Public policy toward externalities. “Command-and-control”

Some people have a problem with the pollution permit giveaway.

Utilities get the permits for free, but they have a market value. (A total of about $1 billion per year.)

Utilities like Watts-are-us recapture some of this value through sale of surplus permits. Is this “fair”?

Utilities are subject to “rate-of-return” regulation.(Prices are set by government agency so as to limit

utilities’ profits to a “fair” level.)Value of pollution permit windfall is passed to

consumers in the form of lower electricity prices.

Page 19: Sometimes externality problems can’t be solved by private bargaining (transaction costs are too big). Public policy toward externalities. “Command-and-control”

Back to sale of pollution permits (“sulfur allowances”):

Most sales are privately negotiated . . .. . . but the EPA holds allowance auction each year.

(http://www.epa.gov/airmarkt/trading/auction.html)

Bidders submit sealed bids including bid price and number of allowances. Allowances sold to highest bidder until no allowances remain.

Results from the March 2010 auction:

“Clearing price” (lowest bid that was successful):$36.20. (It was $62 in 2009 and $380 in 2008.)

Page 20: Sometimes externality problems can’t be solved by private bargaining (transaction costs are too big). Public policy toward externalities. “Command-and-control”

Some winning bidders from the 2010 sale:(http://www.epa.gov/airmarkt/trading/2010 . . .)

Ohio Valley Electric Corporation (http://www.ovec . . .)

(8,000 @ $36.88 each)

Green Country Energy LLC (http://www.jpower . . .)

(8 @ $300.00 each)

Acid Rain Retirement Fund (11 @ $81.36 each)(http://www.usm.maine.edu/~pos/arrf.htm)

Bates College Environmental Econ (http://www.bates . . .)

(4 @ $42.67 and $45.50)

Page 21: Sometimes externality problems can’t be solved by private bargaining (transaction costs are too big). Public policy toward externalities. “Command-and-control”

More Cap and Trade programs in the future?

H.R. 2454 American Clean Energy and Security Act of 2009 (“Waxman – Markey Climate Bill”)

(http://www.sourcewatch.org . . .)

(Rep. H. Waxman (D – CA), Rep. E. Markey (D – MA))

Measures to promote clean energy + energy efficiency

. . . including a Cap and Trade program for “greenhouse gases” responsible for global warming.

Passed House in June 2009 (219 – 212). Little chance in Senate