60
Social Security & Insurance Exploring Insurance for Social Security and Its Effect on Political Participation. Mariah Napolitano March 13, 2012 Prof Bryan Engelhardt

Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Social Security & Insurance

Exploring Insurance for Social Security and Its Effect on Political Participation.

Mariah NapolitanoMarch 13, 2012

Prof Bryan Engelhardt

Page 2: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Napolitano 2

Abstract: With the political climate consistently changing, the future of social security and other

government sponsored programs is always at risk. In order to reduce this risk, this paper

proposes introducing a new financial product to the market that would provide insurance for

social security benefits and suggests its affect on campaign contributions. This new market was

modeled and a solution was found where individual purchase full insurance and reduce their

political contributions aimed at continuing social security. To test the model a survey was given

to individuals who were asked about their interest in this new type of insurance and how it would

affect their political participation. The survey provided empirical evidence that a product like this

would be attractive to some individuals and gave important feedback on ways to improve the

product and the model.

Page 3: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Napolitano 3

The ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the

existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies, and tax cuts. Whether it is social

security, Medicare, or the capital gains rate, the futures of these political risk items are constantly

in flux. Brought to the forefront of American society during the 2012 Presidential campaign due

to Republican Vice-President Nominee Paul Ryan’s plan to completely reform the system, the

future of social security is an issue Americans are genuinely and rightly concerned about.

According to the 2012 Social Security Trustees Report, “beneficiaries will face a painful 25

percent benefit cut in 2033 when the Trust Funds are exhausted – three years sooner than

projected just last year” (Paul Ryan website, 2012).

Many Americans who have paid into the social security system since they first started

working are at a risk of receiving a significantly smaller or nonexistent benefit than what they

had planned on for their retirement. Baring any drastic changes to the system this risk of

decreasing or eliminating social security seems like a real possibility, leaving many Americans

without sufficient funds for their retirement. But what if these individuals could guarantee their

social security benefit independent of governmental changes to the system? This paper proposes

creating a market for social security insurance, which would provide individuals the opportunity

to purchase an insurance policy now that would cover any decreases to the social security benefit

they receive when they retire. This type of insurance could also have an effect on the political

participation of the individuals who purchase it so it is important to investigate the changes, if

any, it might have on individuals’ voting or campaign contribution habits.

The paper is composed of two distinct parts; one in which a model is developed to depict

the social security market in a few variations and a second part where 30 individuals were

surveyed about their predictions for social security and their willingness to purchase social

Page 4: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Napolitano 4

security insurance. Through this, I hope to show that insurance for social security (and other

types of political risk) is a feasible financial product that can benefit both American citizens and

insurance companies.

I. Background/Literature Review

Political risk insurance (PRI) is not a new concept, and is commonly used when

companies invest in developing nations. The Overseas Private Investment Corporation (OPIC) an

"independent" U.S. Government agency that sells investment services to assist U.S. companies

investing in developing countries, offers PRI to U.S. investors in over 150 developing nations.

The political risks typically insured are expropriation, political violence, and currency

inconvertibility (Garver, 2009). PRI policies cover “losses to tangible assets, investment value,

and earnings that result from political peril” (OPIC website, 2012). These policies allow U.S.

business to invest in developing nations while hedging the risks associated with unstable

governments.

Much has been written about how the PRI market is changing; books and papers detail

the effects of the September 11th attacks on emerging market investment and PRI (Riordan,

2004) and other discuss the movement away from government insurance policies to private

firms. (Salinger, 2008). But most relevant to the idea of insuring political risk items, like social

security, within the United States, is the discussion of what products are “insurable” and how

that definition changes slightly when considering items of political risk. Kathryn Gordon, of the

Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), talks about these issues in

“Investment Guarantees and Political Risk Insurance: Institutions, Incentives, and

Development”. Insurable risk is defined as an item clients will want to buy which the insurance

Page 5: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Napolitano 5

industry can profitability provided. Gordon lists the conditions necessary, according to the

OECD committee, to make a product insurable; “assessability (probability and severity of losses

should be quantifiable); randomness (the time at which the insured event occurs should be

unpredictable when the policy is underwritten, and the occurrence itself must be independent of

the will of the insured); mutuality (numerous persons exposed to a given hazard should be able to

join together to form a risk community within which the risk is shared and diversified)” (Gordan,

2008).

When discussing political risk items, the definition of insurable can diverge from these

conditions. Political risk items may not have the greatest degree of assessability; calculating the

probabilities of events happening can be challenging and there can be debate over whether an

event has actually occurred. One deviation from the standard conditions, which is not as

applicable to a product like social security insurance, is that many times there are no “risk

communities” because each policy depends on the specifics of the investor, the country of

investment and the product offered (Gordan, 2008). Within the market for social security

insurance the country and the product being offered will be the same for every investment so risk

communities can be formed. In reality social security insurance will create one large risk

community because it is likely that any change in social security policy will affect everyone who

buys the insurance (and more broadly anyone who receives social security). This does create the

issue that given a policy change, the insurance company will have to payout to all of its

customers. In this way, social security insurance is similar on a small scale to flood insurance;

when a flood occurs, it is not typically one building or house that gets flooded but rather an

entire area of buildings, resulting in insurance companies having to payout to large amounts of

customers at a time. One suggestion Erwann O. Michel-Kerjan details in his paper, Catastrophe

Page 6: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Napolitano 6

Economics: The National Flood Insurance Program, for the National Flood Insurance Program

(NFIP) to stay financial sustainable in the event of catastrophe (like Hurricane Katrina) is to

“transfer part of its catastrophe exposure to reinsurers or to investors in the financial markets by

using alternative risk transfer instruments like a catastrophe bond (“cat bond”), a form of

contingent claim” (Michel-Kerjan, 182). A similar plan could be used by insurance companies to

relieve the pressure on the companies should social security get cut in the future. The key for

both the NFIP and any company that provides insurance for social security is to hedge their risk

whether be through reinsurers or finding an investment that is related to the item being insured.

This can be through shorting an investment directly related to the insurance item or investing in

an item inversely related to the item being insured.

One deviation on the definition of insurable that is important for the political risk

associated with social security is that it is not “independent of the will of the insured.”

Individuals have the opportunity to affect the outcome of social security through political

participation, such as voting and campaign contributions. Because of this reason, this paper will

focus on the effect campaign contributions might have on a product like social security

insurance.

Much of the literature on campaign contributes says approximately the same thing,

campaign contributions lead to policies that differ from those preferred by the median voter’s

favored policies (Grossman and Helpman 1996, Prat 2002, Coate 2004, Campante, 2011). In

particular, Grossman and Helpman (1996) showed in their model that a candidate is more likely

to win an election if they cater to special interest groups that are more likely to donate money to

their campaigns. These campaign contributions help candidates get elected because “risk-adverse

voters prefer candidates with a clearer policy position” (Pratt, 2002). Because of this a banning

Page 7: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Napolitano 7

or limiting of campaign contributions moves policies closer to the preferred policies of the

median voters (Pratt, 2002).

Campante (2011) also showed that in combination with voting, contributions lead to a

“wealth bias” in political policies. When wealthy individuals donate money to political

campaigns, the politicians that receive the donations are encouraged to move their policies closer

to those of the wealthy. So the more financial inequality that exists, the more the political system

shifts in favor of the wealthy.

II. Model

Price Discriminating Monopolist with Constant Probabilities

Assumptions

The model assumes five different possible outcomes for social security in the future; it

doesn’t exist at all, it exist with benefits that are 25% of current benefits, with benefits that are

50% of current benefits, with benefits that are 75% of current benefits, and it exists with the

same amount of benefits it provides today.

Each individual also has a utility function u(y) that measures the satisfaction received by

the individual if event y i occurs. This model assumes that individuals are risk-adverse requiring a

concave utility function. Both the firm and the individual believe with probability q i that event i

will happen. Additionally (q0+q25+q50+q75+q100) =1.

The first situation which the model has been dissected for is when the market for social

security insurance is controlled by a price-discriminating monopolist. In this scenario, the

existence of an insurance market allows the individuals to decide on the amount of insurance

they would like to purchase at the price set by an insurance company who has a monopoly on the

Page 8: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Napolitano 8

market. As this market for social security insurance does not currently exist, it is reasonable to

assume that when the market is first created it will be dominated by one firm who will have the

power to price discriminate based on customers’ financials and beliefs about the future.

Model

This scenario calls for two models, one for the individual purchasing (or not purchasing)

the insurance and one for the firm who is providing the insurance. The price of that insurance is

represented by p. While the amounts of insurance in the individual’s model and the amounts in

the insurer’s model are different (one set is quantity demanded and the other set quantity

supplied) when the market is in equilibrium they will be equal so the model only uses one set of

variables to represent both quantities. The ‘quantity’ insurance purchased will be represented by

five different x values; x0 if social security does not exist at all when the individual retires, x25 if

social security exists at 25% of its current level when the individual retires, and so forth all the

way to x100 if social security exists at today’s levels when the individual retires.

Similarly the individual’s retirement portfolio will be represented by 5 variables; y0 if

social security does not exist at all when the individual retires, y25 if social security exists at 25%

of its current level when the individual retires, and so forth all the way to y100 if social security

exists at today’s levels when the individual retires. Additionally, five different probabilities are

necessary, the probability social security will not exist,q0, the probability social security will

exist at 25% of current levels,q25, and so forth until the probability social security will exist at

current levels, q100.

ln ( y ) is used as the utility function (which satisfies the conditions for the utility function

previously mentioned), we must assume that y i∧( y i+xi−p)>0 so the consumer’s decision

function will exist.

Page 9: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Napolitano 9

The firm is in control of the market and will look to maximize its profits, π, by

optimizing all of the insurance amounts x iand the price of that insurance such that the

consumer’s decision function is satisfied.

π=p−(q0∗x0+q25∗x25 +q50∗x50+q75∗x75+q100∗x100) such t h at (1)

q0∗ln ( y0 )+q25∗ln ( y25 )+q50∗ln ( y50 )+q75∗ln ( y75 )+q100∗ln ( y100) ≤ q0∗ln ( y0+x0−p )+q25∗ln ( y25+x25−p )+q50∗ln ( y50+x50−p )+q75∗ln ( y75+x75−p )+q100∗ln ( y100+x100− p ) (2)

The firm’s profit function is equal to the price of the insurance, p, minus the expected cost of the

insurance. The consumer will purchase the insurance if their expected value of not purchasing

the insurance is less than or equal to their expected value of buying insurance. When the

expected values are equal the consumer will be indifferent between purchasing and not

purchasing the insurance.

In the firms profit equation the expected cost of the insurance is equal to

(q0∗x0+q25∗x25+q50∗x50+q75∗x75+q100∗x100 ). The consumer’s expected utility of not having

insurance is the probability of having a certain retirement package multiplied by the value of that

retirement package which can be described as

∑i=0,25,50,75,100

qi∗ln ( y i )

(3)

Similarly the consumer’s expected utility of having insurance is the probability of having a

certain retirement package multiplied by the value of that package plus the insurance payout the

individual would receive minus the price of that insurance. It can be described as

∑i=0,25,50,75,100

qi∗ln ( y i+x i−p)

(4)

Page 10: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Napolitano 10

These conditions lead to a maximization problem with one constraint setting up a Lagrange

multiplier optimization problem,

L=p−(q0∗x0+q25∗x25+q50∗x50+q75∗x75+q100∗x100)−λ∗[q0∗ln ( y0 )+q25∗ln ( y25 )+q50∗ln ( y50 )+q75∗ln ( y75 )+q100∗ln ( y100)−q0∗ln ( y0+x0−p )−q25∗ln ( y25+x25−p )−q50∗ln ( y50+x50−p )−q75∗ln ( y75+x75−p )−q100∗ln ( y100+x100−p )] (5)

This problem has been evaluated and only one solution was found.

The first order conditions of this constrained optimization with respect to x i,

∂ L∂ x i

=−q i−λ ( −qi

y i+x i−p )=0

(6)

can be used to show that the maximizing solution to this problem is full insurance (proof in

Appendix A1.1), which is shown as x i= y100− yi, meaning the insurance payout if event i occurs

is equal to the difference of what the individual would have with today’s level of social security

and what they would have if event i occurred. This result can be used to calculate the price of the

insurance, resulting in

p= y100−( ( y0 )q 0) ( ( y25 )q25 ) ( ( y50 )q50 ) ( ( y75)q75 ) (( y100 )q100 ) (7)

(Proof in Appendix A1.2)

As the probability of the elimination of some or all of social security increases the price of the

insurance also increases which can be understood because it is more likely the firm is going to

have to pay out the insurance plan. The price of the insurance ranges from $0 (if the probability

of social security existing, q, equals 1) to y100− y0 (if the probability of social security not

existing equals,q0, equals 1).

Page 11: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Napolitano 11

Actuarially Fair Market with Constant ‘q’s

Once this product has been on the market for a while it will no longer be sold by one

monopoly firm, instead a group of firms will join the market and drive the price down to its

market equilibrium. Using all the same assumptions as with the price discriminating monopolist

except now the firm is only maximizing profit with respect to x i, the solution is still full

insurance, except now the price is equal to the expected value of the insurance,

p=( q0∗x0+q25∗x25+q50∗x50+q75∗x75+q100∗x100) (8)

Price Discriminating Monopolist with q as a Function of Political Participation

In both of the prior cases, the probability that different levels of social security were

going to exist, q, was assumed to be constant but in reality those probabilities are changing based

on political participation. To incorporate that in the model, let q(c) be the probability that social

security will exists with the same benefit levels, where c is the amount of campaign

contributions, c>0 , q (c ) ϵ [0,1 ] , ∂q∂ c

>0 , ∂2 q∂ c2 <0 ,and q(c) has an inverse. By letting q(c) equal the

probability of social security existing in its current form, 1-q(c) has to cover the four possible

outcomes. Assuming people have a hard time predicting the difference between having social

security survive at 75%, 50%, 25%, and 0% of its current value, we’ll assume the probability of

each of those outcomes is 1−q (c)4

. Let c1be the contribution if the agent does not buy insurance

and c0be the contribution if they do purchase the insurance.

Page 12: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Napolitano 12

Given the same assumptions as the previous price discriminating monopolist with the

except of the probabilities, the firm will look to maximize its profit in terms of x i , p, & c0 with

respect to the consumers decision function,

π=p−( 1−q(c0)4 ( x0+x25+x50+x75 )+q(c0)∗x100)suc h t hat (9)

( 1−q (c1)4 )[ ln ( y0−c1 )+ ln ( y25−c1 )+ ln ( y50−c1 )+ln ( y75−c1 ) ]+q(c1)∗ln ( y100−c1 ) ≤( 1−q ( c0 )

4 ) [ln ( y0+x0−p−c0 )+ln ( y25+x25−p−c0 )+ ln ( y50+x50−p−c0 )+¿ ln ( y75+x75−p−c0 ) ]+q(c0)∗ln ( y100+x100−p−c0 )

(10)

The firm’s profit equation is equal to the price of the insurance minus the expected cost

of the insurance, which is a function of c0, the amount of campaign contributions the individual

will give if they buy the insurance. The individual’s decision function is once again a comparison

of the expected utility of buying the insurance and the expected utility of not buying the

insurance. The expected utility of buying the insurance is equal to the probability of each

outcome occurring, which is a function of c1 the amount of campaign contributions the

individual donates if they don’t buy the insurance, multiplied by the utility of each outcome

occurring which equals the utility of the individual’s retirement package minus the amount of

campaign contributions. Similarly to the expected utility of buying the insurance, the expected

utility of not buying the insurance is equal to the probability of each outcome occurring as a

function of c0, the amount of campaign contributions if the individual buys the insurance,

multiplies by the utility of each outcome occurring which is equal to the retirement package of

the individual plus the insurance payout minus the price of the insurance and the campaign

contribution.

Page 13: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Napolitano 13

This sets up a similar optimization problem except it is now being optimized with respect

to x i , p, & c0. The solution to the optimization is once again full insurance, x i= y100− yi, (proof

in Appendix A2.1). The other variables that maximize the insurance are,

p= y100−c0−(( y 0−c0 ) ( y25−c0 ) ( y50−c0 ) ( y75−c0 ) )1−q(c0)

4 (( y100−c0 )q(c0))

(12)

(Proof in Appendix A2.2)

c0=( ∂ q∂ c )

−1

( 4x0+x25+ x50+x75 )

(13)

(Proof in Appendix A2.3)

The optimal campaign contribution is equal to the inverse derivative of the sum of the insurance

payouts (at the optimal solution,x100=0) divided 4. If we allow q ( c )=1+c2+c , which satisfies the

above conditions, the optimal campaign contributions equal

c0=12∗√ x0+ x25+x50+ x75−2

(14)

(Proof in Appendix A2.4)

To compare this optimal amount of campaign contribution to the pre-insurance amount of

campaign contributions, the optimal campaign contribution before the insurance is offer needs to

be determined. This amount can be determined by maximizing the expected value of social

security without insurance with respect to campaign contributions,c1 . This amount is equal to,

Page 14: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Napolitano 14

c1=( ∂ q∂ c )

−1( 4∗[( 1−q (c1 )4 )∗( −1

y0−c1+ −1

y25−c1+ −1

y50−c1+ −1

y75−c1 )−q (c1 )

y100−c1 ]ln( ( ( y0−c1 ) ( y25−c1 ) ( y50−c1 ) ( y75−c1 ))

( y100−c1 )4 ) ) (15)

(Proof in Appendix A2.5)

In order to compare the optimal campaign contributions before and after insurance it is

sufficient to compare the first derivatives of the probabilities with respect to campaign

contributions, ∂ q∂ c . Since, by assumption, ∂

2 q∂ c2 is always less than 0,

∂ q∂ c is a decreasing function.

This attribute implies an inverse relationship between the how ∂ q∂ c0

and ∂ q∂ c1

are related and how

c0 and c1 are related. From this relationship it can be shown that conditional on ∂ q∂ c

<1, ∂ q∂ c0

> ∂ q∂ c1

therefore c0<c1 (proof in Appendix A2.6). So as long as ∂ q∂ c

<1, optimal campaign contribution

before the insurance is less than the optimal campaign contribution after the insurance.

If we consider the same probability function as earlier, q ( c )=1+c2+c ,

∂ q∂ c

= 1(2+c1)

2 <1

(16)

(Proof in Appendix A2.7)

This satisfies the condition stated above so with this specific probability function, the campaign

contribution before the insurance is more than the campaign contribution after the insurance.

Page 15: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Napolitano 15

III. Survey

Introduction to the Survey

While the models predict that if the market for social security insurance existed there is a

price and amount of insurance that individuals and firms could agree upon, this market currently

does not exist. To attempt to determine if this product is applicable in a real world setting 30

individuals were surveyed about their thoughts on the future of social security, the idea of social

security insurance, and social security’s affect on their political decisions like voting and

contributing to political campaigns. The results could also help determine why this market does

not exist today.

Explaining the Survey

To allow for some variation in what social security might look like when the responders

retired, the model that allowed five possible social security outcomes was used. The responders

were asked a series of questions to establish their thoughts on the future of social security which

was used to determine each q value. They were asked about the likelihood when they retire that

social security would exist in its current form and with at least 75%, 50%, and 25% of its current

benefits. Each question provided a list of answers from which the responder chose; Very High

(80%-100%), High (60%-79%), Low (40%-59%), Very Low (20%-39%), or No Chance (0%-

19%). Once a responder answered (a) Very High (80%-100%) no more probability distribution

questions were asked because the resulting probabilities would have been 0%.

The survey started with basic demographic questions to determine age and gender, both

of which factored into the price of the insurance being offered to the responder. Two additional

questions were necessary to calculate the price of the insurance. One was a question about the

responder’s expected reliance upon social security when they retire was used to estimate the

Page 16: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Napolitano 16

responder’s retirement portfolio and the other was about the responder’s expected age of

retirement.

After all the necessary information was inputted, the price of the insurance in a price-

discriminating monopoly market was calculated and the idea of social security insurance was

introduced to the responder with the following,

“As of today the current average Social Security benefit is about $1,200 per

month which accumulates to more than $250,000 over the course of retirement.

There is some concern that the benefits granted by social security will be cut

sometime in the future. So what I want to do is to offer you the opportunity to

guarantee your roughly $250,000 by purchasing insurance for your social

security. Similar to home or car insurance, this investment will cover your future

benefits should current social security laws change. This policy would payout the

difference between how much social security you would receive under today’s

law and your actual benefit at the time of your retirement. For example if your

monthly benefit was reduced by $600 your insurance payout would total over

$125,000. Keeping all that in mind would you be willing to spend $XXX per

month to ensure your full social security benefit?”

If the responder answered “No” the same deal was offer (full insurance) but this time at the

perfectly- competitive market price (a lower price). If the responder once again answered “No”

they were asked if there was any price at which they would be willing to purchase the insurance,

and if so, what price.

The next set of questions the responders were asked to answer were about reasons they

would not want to buy the insurance. They were asked, “Is there any reason why you wouldn’t

Page 17: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Napolitano 17

want to buy this type of insurance?” Depending on their answer to that question, they were next

asked, if whatever reason they gave in the previous question (ie “I don’t have enough money

now” or “I don’t see social security as an important part of my retirement plan” etc.) did not

exist/happen/matter etc. would they purchase the insurance.

As one of the goals of the survey was to determine if social security insurance would

have an effect on people’s political decisions (both in voting and contributing to political

campaigns), before introducing the idea of social security insurance the responders were asked if

the regularly vote or contributed to political campaign and if they hoped their vote or

contribution would affect social security policy either positively or negatively. After the

insurance was offered, responders were then asked if buying the insurance would affect their

voting and/or contributing decisions because now decreases in social security benefits would not

affect their future benefits.

The full survey is in Appendix B.

Assumptions/Calculating Price

In order to calculate the price of the insurance a few assumptions in our model had to be

made. The first assumption was that males and females would live the national average life

spans, for women, 81 and for men, 76. An interest rate of 5% was assumed. When calculating the

size of the individual’s retirement package not including social security average savings of those

65 and older, average 401(k) balance of those 55 and older, and the average private sector

pension were considered. The size of the individual’s portfolio was dependant on their answer to

whether or not they thought they would be reliant on their social security. Our final assumption

was that everyone was going to receive the current average social security benefit, which is

$1,230 per month.

Page 18: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Napolitano 18

The only slight alteration to the five outcome price-discriminating monopolist problem

set up in the Model section is that instead of have y i as the total size of the individual’s

retirement package in the event i we will have, y i=r+SS i, where r equals the individual’s

retirement portfolio without social security and SSi represents the amount of social security the

individual receives if event i occurs. This results in the price of the insurance being,

p=SS100+r – ( (r+SS0 )q0 ) (( r+SS25 )q25 ) (( r+SS50 )q50 ) (( r+SS75 )q75 ) (( r+SS100)q100)

The survey also asked individuals to consider buying the insurance at the actuarially fair

price.

Because the insurance (both at the monopoly price and the actuarially fair price) is being

paid for and distributed out over an extended period of time, it was necessary to take interest

rates and future/present values of the insurance into consideration. To do so we first solved for

the price of insurance per year in year of retirement dollars which was used to calculate the total

price of the insurance in year of retirement dollars. This amount was then put in today’s dollars

and distributed equally (like an annuity) through the years the individual has left until retirement.

From this price the monthly price of the insurance, which the individual will pay every month

until they retire, is calculated.

Results

The results of this survey proved to be promising for the possibility of the real word

application of social security insurance as 43% of those survey said they would purchase this

insurance if it were offered at the price-discriminating monopoly price. Another 65% of those

who said no to the monopoly price said they would buy the insurance if it were offered at a lower

price which brings the total percentage of those who said yes to some price to 80% of those

surveyed. The average monopoly price of the insurance was $91.91 but more descriptive is the

Page 19: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Napolitano 19

difference in price between those who said that would buy the insurance, $46.29 and those who

said they would not at the monopoly price, $126.80. Of those who said that would not buy the

insurance at the price offer but gave a price at which they would buy the insurance, the average

price given was $51.36 per month. Below are the main descriptive statistics of some of the

important variables discussed in the survey,

Table 1: Descriptive Statistics of Important Variables

Mean Median Standard Deviation

Minimum Maximum

Age 47.1 47. 5. 36 54Retirement Age 67.17 67 2.44 62 70Monopoly Monthly Price $91.91 $61.62 $86.83 $14.93 $430.26Expected Value(Social Security) $10,774 $11,070 $2,516 $4,428 $14,022

In terms of the age statistics the one that appeared to have the most effect on whether or

not the individual chose to purchase the insurance was the difference between ‘years until

retirement’ and ‘years of retirement.’ The average difference was 9.73 years but the average

difference of those who purchased the insurance was 12 years while the average of those who

chose not to purchase at the monopoly price was only 8 years. Of those whose difference was

above the average only 26.67% said they would purchase the insurance while 60% of those

whose difference was below the average would buy the insurance at the monopoly price. This

result is not unexpected because the longer you are retired and the fewer years you have until

retirement the higher your price because you are paying for more years of insurance in less time.

In the survey women and men behaved a bit differently. The percent of women who said

they would purchase the insurance at the monopoly price was 33.33% while the percent of men

willing to purchase the insurance was 50%. However, the average price of a women’s insurance

Page 20: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Napolitano 20

policy, $103.52, was higher than the average price of a man’s policy, $84.71. The obvious driver

of this difference in price is the average life spans used to calculate the years of retirement. Since

women live on average five years later than men, it was not unexpected that the average number

of years retired for women was 12.67 years while the men’s average number was only 8.78.

Another important factor in determining the price of the insurance was the individual’s

probability distribution of the likelihood social security will exist in its varied forms. Most

responders believed that most likely when they retired social security would be at its current

levels however there was a distribution amongst all five possible outcomes,

Table 2: Probability Distribution

Probability you get at least i% of Social Security Very High

80%-100%High

60%-79%Medium40-59%

Low20-39%

Very Low0-19%

100% 0% 20% 43.33% 30% 6.67%75% 16.67% 26.67% 40% 13.33% 3.33%50% 36.67% 33.33% 23.33% 6.67% 0%25% 63.33% 20% 13.33% 3.33% 0%

It can be noted the distribution of the probabilities resembles the probability distribution function

used when campaign contributions were considered where the probability of social security

existing at 100% was one number and the remaining probabilities were equally distributed

amongst the other four outcomes.

Those who believe that the probability social security would exist at its current level was

above the average (55%) had an average monopoly price of $72.45 while those who believed the

probability was below the average had an average price of $125.54. This difference in price can

be explained because as the probability of social security decreasing increases the likely hood

that the firm is going to have to payout the actual insurance benefit increases so they are going to

charge more because their expected cost increases. Additionally as the probability of social

Page 21: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Napolitano 21

security deceasing increases, the expected value of the utility of the insurance for the individual

will increase making the insurance more valuable to them and more likely to purchase the

insurance at a higher price. This is shown by the average cost of the insurance of those whose

q100was less than the average and who said they would purchase the insurance, $67.02, being

greater than the average cost of the insurance of those whose q100was greater than the average

and who said they would purchase the insurance, $37.08. Though for many people who were less

optimistic about the future of social security the increase in price resulting from their beliefs

about the future was too high resulting in only 36% of those whose q100was less than the average

agreeing to purchase the insurance, compared to the 47% of those whose q100was greater than the

average agreeing to purchase the insurance.

When asked about their projected reliance on social security, only 27% of those surveyed

thought that they would be reliant upon social security when they retired. Of those who projected

their reliance upon social security 62.5% agreed to purchase the insurance compared to those

who said they would not be reliant upon social security, where only 36% agreed to purchase the

insurance. While reliance upon social security clearly showed to be a factor in whether or not to

purchase insurance it really did not have much of an impact on the price of the insurance. For

example the monopoly price of insurance for a averaged aged (47) male with an average

probability distribution who plans on retiring at the average retirement age of 67 who does not

believe he will be reliant upon social security is $70.96 and a male with all the same

characteristics except who plans on being reliant upon social security has a price of $74.46, a

difference in price of less than $4 per month, which only accumulates to $600 in today’s dollars

of extra cost.

Page 22: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Napolitano 22

Table 3: Correlation coefficients related to buying the insurance at the monopoly price (where

buying the insurance is denoted with a 1)

Variable Correlation CoefficientGender (Male = 1) 0.1647705Age 0.0232346Probability SS exists at 100% 0.1620708Probability SS exists at 75% 0.1070184Probability SS exists at 50% 0.1647705Probability SS exists at 25% -0.3574661Probability SS exists at 0% -0.1089328Reliant on SS (Reliant = 1) 0.2332413Retirement Age 0.4445927Monopoly Price -0.4673082Expected Value of Insurance -0.4995743Expected Value of Social Security 0.2046543Years Until Retirement 0.1841197Years Retired -0.3291058Difference in yrs retired & years until retirement 0.3039435

Table 4: Average prices of those who agreed to the monopoly price, who said no to the

monopoly price, and the average independent of their monopoly price response,

Avg Price Of Yes – Mon. Avg Price Of No – Mon. Avg Price – Mon.Price $39.48 $130.00 $92.21Men $52.98 $115.36 $84.71Women $31.24 $139.67 $103.52Reliant $38.24 $185.03 $93.28Not Reliant $51.32 $114.32 $91.41

Table 5: Averages of those who agreed to the monopoly price, who said no to the monopoly

price, and the average independent of their monopoly price response,

Yes to Mon. Avg No to Mon. Avg AvgAge 47.23 47.00 47.10Retirement Age 68.38 66.20 67.17Age difference 12.00 8.00 9.25Prob of 100% SS 0.58 0.53 0.55

Page 23: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Napolitano 23

All survey participants were also asked what reasons they had to not purchase the

insurance. Their responses can be divided into four different categories; financial, government,

information/logistical, and moral objections. The most common responses were financial in

nature with four major issues were brought up multiple times. Many people thought the price

was simply too high and the insurance was not worth the price. Another common response was

that this insurance was not in their budget now so they could not afford it. Individual’s also

suggested that there were better investment opportunities with higher returns for the same price

as the insurance, so they felt their money could be used in a better way. Finally, while it was

asked in the survey, responders replied that they were not relying on their social security to be

there so they did not see the need to insure its presence.

Another group of reasons for not purchasing the insurance were attributed to the current

state of government affairs. It was suggested that the risk of social security failing/reducing were

not high enough to warrant purchasing the insurance (even though this was calculated into the

price). One individual stated that “Politicians are so slow moving that more than likely social

security is not going to change before I retire.” The second concern over the current state of

government affairs was that the current economic state of affairs is so precarious that “today my

answer maybe yes, but if we fall off the fiscal cliff tomorrow I might change my mind.”

A small but substantial number of responders rejected the insurance because they felt

they did not have enough information to ease their possible concerns about purchasing the

insurance. Their main concern was making sure the firm that would be providing this insurance

was reliable and sustainable over the long term. They did not want to take on the risk of

purchasing this insurance from a company they were not sure would be around when they

retired. The other main information objection was about the question of contingencies. For

Page 24: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Napolitano 24

example, what would happen if they died young? Would they be able to write the policy over to

a spouse or a dependant?

The last set of objections could be grouped together as moral objections to the insurance.

A few individuals thought that because of the price of the insurance not everyone would be able

to buy it so they felt it was unfair to people who could not afford it. They thought that if many

people bought the insurance the government would not have a large incentive to keep social

security at its current level so those who need social security the most would be severely

negatively impacted. The other moral objection of the insurance was that people believed they

were entitled to their social security and that the government has the responsibility to give them

back at least what they paid into the system.

These moral objections to the insurance can be used to help understand the unexpected

results of the survey with regards to how purchasing social security insurance might affect their

political decisions. Before the insurance was mention, 93% of those surveyed claimed to vote

regularly and 46% of them stated that keeping social security at its current levels was an issue

that considered when deciding who to vote for. No responders answered that they were more

likely to vote for someone who supports reducing social security. 47% of responders said that

they regularly contributed to political campaigns and 50% of that group said that keeping social

security at its current level was an issue they considered when deciding to contribute. Once again

no individuals said they were more likely to donate to a political campaign of someone who

supported reducing social security.

After “offering” the individuals the opportunity to buy social security insurance, they

were asked after buying the insurance about how social security would affect their political

decisions. Because these questions were contingent upon the individual’s response to the

Page 25: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Napolitano 25

previous questions about voting and if they would buy the insurance, when looking for the effect

the insurance has upon these political decisions it is important to only look at individuals who

were able provided answers to all the questions concerned. 77% of those surveyed were able to

answer both the before and after insurance question on how social security effected their voting

habits. Of that group, before the insurance was taken into account, 52% of them claimed to be

more likely to vote for a candidate who supports continuing social security at current levels and

the other 48% said social security did not affect their voting decisions. When the responders

were asked to think about their voting choices after buying the insurance, 48% said they would

be likely to support a candidate who is in favor of keeping social security at its current levels, 4%

said they would support a candidate who wants to reduce social security and the last 48% said it

would have no effect on their voting. Only 17% of responders changed their answer from the

before insurance question. 25% of those who changed went from social security not affecting

voting to supporting someone who wants to reduce social security, and 50% went from

supporting continuing it at current levels to not having it affect their votes. The last 25% of

voters who switched went from social security not affecting their vote before the insurance to

now supporting someone who wants to keep it at current levels.

A difference in proportions test was also used to determine if the difference in responses

before and after the insurance was offered was statistically significant. Before the insurance was

offered 46% of 28 individuals said keeping social security at its current levels is a significant

factor when deciding who to vote for and after the insurance was offered 48% of 23 individuals

said responded the same way. Using a two-tailed hypothesis test, where the null hypothesis is

that the results from both cases are the same and the alternate hypothesis is that they are

different, a z-score of -0.1428 can be calculated based upon this, resulting in a p-value of 0.88.

Page 26: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Napolitano 26

Using a significance level of 0.1, the null hypothesis can be accepted because 0.1 < 0.88,

meaning the results before and after the insurance is offered are statistically the same.

Only 43% of those surveyed were able to answer both the before and after insurance

questions on how social security affected their campaign contributions. Of those individuals,

before the insurance 54% supported keeping social security at current levels and the other half

said it did not affect their contributions. No individuals changed their answers when asked about

their contributing after buying the insurance.

IV. Conclusion

While the survey results did not completely confirm the results of the model, it did

provide some empirical evidence that social security insurance is a financial product some

individuals would be willing to purchase at the price they would be charged under a price-

discriminating monopolist or at some other price. Based on the results of the survey, where price

was the highest indicator of whether or not an individual said they would purchase the insurance,

the product should be targeted at those who would have a lower price per month, which can be

significantly affected by the amount of years they have until retirement and the amount of years

they plan on being retired as well as their thoughts on the future of social security. The insurance

policy would be the most attractive to individuals who fall in the middle ground of the expected

future of social security. Those who strongly believe social security will not exist have

increasing higher prices for the insurance resulting in many individuals responding that the price

was simply too high and those who strongly believe social security will exist in its current form

refuse to buy the insurance even when the price is significantly low because they do not see the

risk of a social security decrease as high enough to warrant an insurance policy.

Page 27: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Napolitano 27

In terms of political participation, the results of the survey indicated that this type of

insurance would not affect their voting and campaign contributing habits in the way the model

predicted, which was that they would donate less after they had purchased the insurance than

they had before. Most responders did not predict the insurance to affect their political

participation at all. Based on the responses to why individuals would not purchase the insurance

it is possible that even if they had the insurance, individuals would still want the social security

program to continue for the sake of those who are unable to or did not purchase the insurance, so

they would not change their voting or contributing habits.

While the results of this analysis of a social security market showed this insurance as a

feasible product, it did bring up some interesting objections and questions as well. Seeing as this

product was offered at an equilibrium price and individuals still rejected the proposal, what

changes can be made in the model to account for individuals’ concerns about the product,

particularly about what effect their buying of the product will have on the future of social

security as well as those who don’t buy it? This concern is legitimate because if more and more

individuals purchase the insurance it is not unreasonable to assume that the government will

become less concerned with the guarantee of social security and make cuts to the system. While

these cuts will not affect those who have the insurance, it will affect both those who did not

purchase the insurance and the insurance companies that have to payout to all their customers.

This issue proposes an extension of the model to include the number of individuals who buy the

insurance. The number (or percentage) of people purchasing the insurance will individually

affect both the probability of social security existing and the profit of the insurance company.

The results of both the analysis of the model and the survey indicate that marketing

insurance for social security would create the opportunity for a multi-million dollar market to

Page 28: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Napolitano 28

develop. It is a desirable financial product individuals would be willing to invest in to protect

against the uncertainty of a government backed subsidy. It would also open the door to

expanding the insurance market for other items associated with political risk which creates an

even bigger opportunity for millions of dollars of transactions.

Page 29: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Napolitano 29

Appendix A

A1: Price Discriminating Monopolist with constant probabilities

L=p−(q0∗x0+q25∗x25+q50∗x50+q75∗x75+q100∗x100)−λ∗[q0∗ln ( y0 )+q25∗ln ( y25 )+q50∗ln ( y50 )+q75∗ln ( y75 )+q100∗ln ( y100)−q0∗ln ( y0+x0−p )−q25∗ln ( y25+x25−p )−q50∗ln ( y50+x50−p )−q75∗ln ( y75+x75−p )−q100∗ln ( y100+x100−p )]∂ L∂ x0

=−q0− λ( −q0

y0+x0−p )∂ L

∂ x25=−q25−λ( −q25

y25+x25−p )∂ L

∂ x50=−q50−λ( −q50

y50+x50−p )∂ L

∂ x75=−q75−λ( −q75

y75+x75−p )∂ L

∂ x100=−q100− λ( −q100

y100+x100−p )∂ L∂ p

=1−λ( q0

y0+x0−p+

q25

y25+x25−p+

q50

y50+x50−p+

q75

y75+x75−p+

q100

y100+x100−p )∂ L∂ λ

=−(q0∗ln ( y 0)+q25∗ln ( y25 )+q50∗ln ( y50 )+q75∗ln ( y75 )+q100∗ln ( y100)−q0∗ln ( y0+x0−p )−q25∗ln ( y25+x25−p )−q50∗ln ( y50+x50−p )−q75∗ln ( y75+x75−p )−q100∗ln ( y100+x100−p ))

A1.1Solving forx i

0=−q0−λ ( −q0

y 0+x0−p )1=( λ

y0+ x0−p )λ= y0+x0−p

By same process,λ= y25+ x25−pλ= y50+ x50−pλ= y75+ x75−p

λ= y100+x100−pSet two of lambdas equal to each other,

y0+x0−p= y100+x100−px100 equals 0 because if Social Security exists in its current form (i = 100) the insurance payout is 0.

y0+x0= y100

Page 30: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Napolitano 30

x0= y100− y0

Repeat same process for all x i,

x25= y100− y25

x50= y100− y50

x75= y100− y75

Solution is full insurance.

A1.2Solving for price∂ L∂ λ

=−(q0∗ln ( y 0)+q25∗ln ( y25 )+q50∗ln ( y50 )+q75∗ln ( y75 )+q100∗ln ( y100)−q0∗ln ( y0+x0−p )−q25∗ln ( y25+x25−p )−q50∗ln ( y50+x50−p )−q75∗ln ( y75+x75−p )−q100∗ln ( y100+x100−p ))=0

Plug in for x i q0∗ln ( y0 )+q25∗ln ( y25 )+q50∗ln ( y50 )+q75∗ln ( y75 )+q100∗ln ( y100)=q0∗ln ( y100−p )+q25∗ln ( y100−p )+q50∗ln ( y100−p )+q75∗ln ( y100−p )+q100∗ln ( y100−p )

ln ( y¿¿100−p)(q0+q25+q50+q75+q100)=ln ( ( y0 )q0 )+ln ( ( y25 )q25 )+ ln ( ( y50 )q50 )+ ln (( y75)q75)+ln ( ( y100 )q100) ¿Since probabilities sum to 1

ln ( y¿¿100−p)(1)=ln (( ( y0 )q0 ) ( ( y25 )q25 ) ( ( y50)q50 ) (( y75 )q 75) ( ( y100 )q100 ))¿( y¿¿100−p)= (( ( y0 )q0 ) (( y25 )q 25) ( ( y50 )q50 ) ( ( y75 )q75 ) (( y100)q100 ))¿

p= y100−( ( y0 )q 0) ( ( y25 )q25 ) ( ( y50 )q50 ) ( ( y75)q75 ) (( y100 )q100 )

A2: Price Discriminating Monopolist with Moving Probabilities

L=p−( 1−q(c0)4 ( x0+x25+x50+x75)+q(c0)∗x100)−λ[( 1−q(c1)

4 ) [ln ( y0−c1 )+ ln ( y25−c1 )+ln ( y50−c1 )+ ln ( y75−c1) ]+q (c1 )∗ln ( y100−c1 )−(1−q ( c0 )4 )[ ln ( y0+x0−p−c0 )+ ln ( y25+ x25−p−c0 )+ ln ( y50+x50−p−c0)+¿ ln ( y75+x75−p−c0 ) ]−q(c0)∗ln ( y100+x100−p−c0 ) ]

∂ L∂ x0

=−1−q(c0)

4−λ( −1−q(c0)

4y0+x0−p−c0

)∂ L

∂ x25=

−1−q (c0)4

− λ( −1−q (c0)4

y25+ x25−p−c0)

∂ L∂ x50

=−1−q (c0)

4− λ( −1−q (c0)

4y50+ x50−p−c0

)∂ L∂ x75

=−1−q (c0)

4− λ( −1−q (c0)

4y75+x75−p−c0

)

Page 31: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Napolitano 31

∂ L∂ x100

=−q (c0)−λ( −q (c0)y100+ x100− p−c0 )

∂ L∂ p

=1−λ( 1−q(c0)4

y0+x0−p−c0+

1−q (c0)4

y25+x25−p−c0+

1−q(c0)4

y50+x50−p−c0+

1−q(c0)4

y75+x75−p−c0+

q (c0)y100+x100−p−c0

)∂ L∂ c0

=q ' (c0)

4 ∗( x0+x25+x50+x75 )−q ' ( c0 )∗x100−λ[ q' (c0)4 ∗( ln ( y0+x0−p−c0 )+ ln ( y25+x25−p−c0 )+ln ( y50+x50−p−c0 )+¿ ln ( y75+x75−p−c0 ))−( 1−q ( c0 )

4 )∗( −1y0+x0−p−c0

+−1

y25+x25−p−c0+

−1y50+x50−p−c0

+−1

y75+ x75−p−c0 )−q' (c0 )∗ln ( y100+x100−p−c0 )−q( c0 )∗−1

y100+x100−p−c0 ]∂ L∂ λ

=−[( 1−q(c1)4 )[ ln ( y0−c1 )+ ln ( y25−c1 )+ ln ( y50−c1 )+ ln ( y75−c1 ) ]+q (c1 )∗ln ( y100−c1 )−(1−q (c0 )

4 )[ ln ( y0+ x0−p−c0 )+ ln ( y25+x25−p−c0 )+ln ( y50+x50−p−c0 )+¿ ln ( y75+x75−p−c0 ) ]−q(c0)∗ln ( y100+x100−p−c0 )]A2.1Solving forx i

0=−1−q (c0)

4−λ ( −1−q (c0)

4y0+x0−p−c0

)1=( λ

y0+ x0−p−c0 )λ= y0+x0−p−c0

By same process,λ= y25+ x25−p−c0

λ= y50+ x50−p−c0

λ= y75+ x75−p−c0

λ= y100+x100−p−c0

Set two of lambdas equal to each other,y0+x0−p−c0= y100+ x100−p−c0

x100 equals 0 because if Social Security exists in its current form (i = 100) the insurance payout is 0.

y0+x0= y100

x0= y100− y0

Repeat same process for all x i,

x25= y100− y25

x50= y100− y50

x75= y100− y75

Solution is full insurance.

A2.2Solving for price

∂ L∂ λ

=−[( 1−q(c1)4 )[ ln ( y0−c1 )+ ln ( y25−c1 )+ ln ( y50−c1 )+ ln ( y75−c1 ) ]+q (c1 )∗ln ( y100−c1 )−(1−q (c0 )

4 )[ ln ( y0+ x0−p−c0 )+ ln ( y25+x25−p−c0 )+ln ( y50+x50−p−c0 )+¿ ln ( y75+x75−p−c0 ) ]−q(c0)∗ln ( y100+x100−p−c0 )]=0

Page 32: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Napolitano 32

Plug in for x i

( 1−q ( c0 )4 ) [ln ( y100− p−c0 )+ ln ( y100− p−c0 )+ ln ( y100−p−c0 )+ ln ( y100−p−c0 ) ]+q (c0 )∗ln ( y100−p−c0 )=( 1−q (c1)

4 )[ ln ( y0−c1 )+ ln ( y25−c1)+ ln ( y50−c1 )+ln ( y75−c1 ) ]+q (c1 )∗ln ( y100−c1)

ln ( y¿¿100−p−c0)(4∗1−q ( c0 )

4−q (c0 ))= ln ( y0

1−q ( c0 )4 )+ ln ( y25

1−q ( c0 )4 )+ ln ( y50

1−q ( c0)4 )+ ln ( y75

1−q ( c0)4 )+ ln ( y100

q ( c0) )¿

ln ( y¿¿100−p−c0)(1)=ln(( y0

1−q (c0 )4 )( y25

1−q ( c0 )4 )( y50

1−q ( c0)4 )( y75

1−q (c0 )4 )( y100

q ( c0) ))¿( y¿¿100−p−c0)=( y0

1−q (c0)4 )( y25

1−q ( c0 )4 )( y50

1−q ( c0)4 )( y75

1−q (c0)4 )( y100

q ( c0 ) )¿

p= y100−c0−( y 0

1−q ( c0)4 )( y25

1−q (c0 )4 )( y50

1−q ( c0 )4 )( y75

1−q ( c0)4 )( y100

q ( c0 ) )

A2.3Solving for optimal campaign contributions, c0

∂ L∂ c0

=q ' (c0)

4 ∗( x0+x25+x50+x75 )−q ' ( c0 )∗x100−λ[ q' (c0)4 ∗( ln ( y0+x0−p−c0 )+ ln ( y25+x25−p−c0 )+ln ( y50+x50−p−c0 )+¿ ln ( y75+x75−p−c0 ))−( 1−q ( c0 )

4 )∗( −1y0+x0−p−c0

+ −1y25+x25−p−c0

+ −1y50+x50−p−c0

+ −1y75+ x75−p−c0 )−q' (c0 )∗ln ( y100+x100−p−c0 )−q

( c0 )∗−1y100+x100−p−c0 ]=0

Set x100 equal to zero and substitute in for optimal x and lambda.

q' (c0)4 ∗( x0+x25+x50+ x75 )−q' (c0 )∗(0 )=( y100−p−c0 )[ q' (c0)

4 ∗( ln ( y100−p−c0 )+ln ( y100−p−c0 )+ln ( y100−p−c0 )+¿ ln ( y100−p−c0 ))−( 1−q (c0 )4 )∗( −1

y100−p−c0+

−1y100−p−c0

+−1

y100−p−c0+

−1y100−p−c0 )−q ' (c0 )∗ln ( y100−p−c0)−q

( c0 )∗−1y100−p−c0 ]

q' (c0)4 ∗( x0+x25+x50+ x75 )=( y100−p−c0 )∗[ q' (c0)

4 ∗4∗ln ( y100−p−c0 )−q' (c0 )∗ln ( y100−p−c0 )−( 1−q (c0 )4 )∗( −4

y100−p−c0 )−q( c0 )∗−1

y100−p−c0 ]q' (c0)

4∗( x0+x25+x50+ x75 )=( y100−p−c0 )∗[ 1−q ( c0 )+q (c0 )

y100−p−c0 ]q ' (c0 )∗( x0+x25+x50+x75 )

4=

( y100−p−c0 )∗1y100−p−c0

q ' (c0 )∗( x0+x25+x50+x75 )4

=1

q ' (c0 )= 4( x0+x25+x50+x75 )

c0=q'−1( 4( x0+ x25+x50+x75 ) )

A2.4Optimal campaign contributions when q=1+c

2+c :

∂∂ c0

( 1+c0

2+c0)= 4

( x0+x25+ x50+x75 )

Page 33: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Napolitano 33

( 1(2+c0 )2 )= 4

( x0+x25+ x50+x75 )

(2+c0 )2=( x0+x25+ x50+x75 )

4

(2+c0 )=√ ( x0+x25+x50+x75)4

c0=12 √( x0+x25+x50+x75)−2

A2.5 Solving for optimal pre-insurance campaign contributions, c1

Maximize the expected value of social security with respect to pre-insurance campaign contributions, c1

EV (c1)=( 1−q(c1)4 )[ ln ( y0−c1 )+ ln ( y25−c1 )+ ln ( y50−c1 )+ ln ( y75−c1 ) ]+q (c1 )∗ln ( y100−c1 )−( 1−q (c0 )

4 )[ ln ( y0+ x0−p−c0 )+ ln ( y25+x25−p−c0 )+ln ( y50+x50−p−c0 )+¿ ln ( y75+x75− p−c0 ) ]−q(c0)∗ln ( y100+x100−p−c0 )

∂ EV∂ c0

=−q '(c1)

4∗( ln ( y0−c1 )+ ln ( y25−c1)+ ln ( y50−c1 )+¿ ln ( y75−c1 ))+( 1−q ( c1)

4 )∗( −1y0−c1

+ −1y25−c1

+ −1y50−c1

+ −1y75−c1 )+q' ( c1 )∗ln ( y100−c1 )+q

(c1 )∗−1y100−c1

=0

q' (c1)4

∗( ln ( ( y0−c1 ) ( y25−c1 ) ( y50−c1 ) ( y75−c1 )))−q' ( c1)∗ln ( y100−c1 )=( 1−q (c1 )4 )∗( −1

y0−c1+ −1

y25−c1+ −1

y50−c1+ −1

y75−c1 )+q( c1)∗−1y100−c1

q ' (c1 )∗(ln ( ( y0−c1 ) ( y25−c1 ) ( y50−c1 ) ( y75−c1 )))−4∗q ' (c1 )∗ln ( y100−c1 )=4∗[( 1−q (c1 )4 )∗( −1

y0−c1+ −1

y25−c1+ −1

y50−c1+ −1

y75−c1 )+q(c1 )∗−1y100−c1 ]

q '(c1)∗( ln( ( ( y0−c1 ) ( y25−c1 ) ( y50−c1 ) ( y75−c1 ))( y100−c1 )4 ))=4∗[( 1−q ( c1)

4 )∗( −1y0−c1

+ −1y25−c1

+ −1y50−c1

+ −1y75−c1 )−

q ( c1 )y100−c1 ]

q '(c1)=

4∗[( 1−q (c1 )4 )∗( −1

y0−c1+

−1y25−c1

+−1

y50−c1+

−1y75−c1 )−

q ( c1)y100−c1 ]

ln( (( y0−c1 ) ( y25−c1 ) ( y50−c1 ) ( y75−c1 ))( y100−c1 )4 )

A2.6 Campaign Contributions Before and After Insurance

Want to show c0<c1.Assumptions about q ( c ),

c>0q ( c ) ϵ [ 0,1 ]

Page 34: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Napolitano 34

∂ q∂ c

>0

∂2 q∂ c2 <0

q(c) has an inverse

Post-Insurance Campaign ContributionsFrom Appendix A2.3

c0=q'−1( 4( x0+ x25+x50+x75 ) )

Pre-Insurance Campaign ContributionsFrom Appendix A2.5

q '(c1)=

4∗[( 1−q (c1 )4 )∗( −1

y0−c1+ −1

y25−c1+ −1

y50−c1+ −1

y75−c1 )−q ( c1)

y100−c1 ]ln( (( y0−c1 ) ( y25−c1 ) ( y50−c1 ) ( y75−c1 ))

( y100−c1 )4 )Proving c0<c1

Because, by assumption, q ' ' (c )<0then it is adequate to show that q ' (c0 )>q' (c1) to prove c0<c1

q ' (c0 )>q' (c1)

4( x0+x25+x50+x75 )

>

4∗[( 1−q (c1 )4 )∗( −1

y0−c1+ −1

y25−c1+ −1

y50−c1+ −1

y75−c1 )−q (c1 )

y100−c1 ]ln( ( ( y0−c1 ) ( y25−c1 ) ( y50−c1 ) ( y75−c1 ))

( y100−c1 )4 )We know ln ( ( ( y0−c1 ) ( y25−c1 ) ( y50−c1 ) ( y75−c1 ))

( y100−c1 )4 )is negative because

( y100−c1 )>( y75−c1 )>( y50−c1 )>( y25−c1 )>( y0−c1 ) coupled with the original assumption that ( y i−c1)>0 then( y100−c1 )4> ( y0−c1 ) ( y25−c1 ) ( y50−c1 ) ( y75−c1 ) indicates that

0<( (( y0−c1 ) ( y25−c1) ( y50−c1) ( y75−c1 ))( y100−c1)4 )<1. The natural log of a number between 0 and 1 is a

negative number.

Page 35: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Napolitano 35

Since q ' (c )>0 and ln ( ( ( y0−c1 ) ( y25−c1 ) ( y50−c1 ) ( y75−c1 ))( y100−c1 )4 )<0 then

4∗[( 1−q (c1 )4 )∗( −1

y0−c1+ −1

y25−c1+ −1

y50−c1+ −1

y75−c1 )−q (c1 )

y100−c1 ]<0.

Since we are multiplying by a negative the sign flips,

ln( (( y0−c1 ) ( y25−c1 ) ( y50−c1 ) ( y75−c1 ))( y100−c1 )4 )

( x0+x25+ x50+x75 )<( 1−q (c1 )

4 )∗( −1y0−c1

+ −1y25−c1

+ −1y50−c1

+ −1y75−c1 )−

q (c1 )y100−c1

If a < c and b > d then ab< c

d so it will be sufficient to show

( x0+x25+x50+x75)>1

And

ln ( ( ( y0−c1 ) ( y25−c1 ) ( y50−c1 ) ( y75−c1 ))( y100−c1 )4 )<( 1−q (c1 )

4 )∗( −1y0−c1

+ −1y25−c1

+ −1y50−c1

+ −1y75−c1 )−

q ( c1)y100−c1

We can show that( x0+x25+x50+x75)>1

( x0+x25+x50+x75)= y100+( y100− y25 )+( y100− y50 )+( y100− y75 )= y100+( y100−.25∗y100)+ ( y100−.50∗y100 )+( y100−.75∗y100)= y100+(.75∗y100 )+ (.50∗ y100)+(.25∗y100)=52∗y100>1→ y100>

25

Since the social security administration will not payout a benefit of less than $1 per month we

know y100>25 so

( x0+x25+x50+x75)>1 .

We can show that

ln ( ( ( y0−c1 ) ( y25−c1 ) ( y50−c1 ) ( y75−c1 ))( y100−c1 )4 )<( 1−q (c1 )

4 )∗( −1y0−c1

+ −1y25−c1

+ −1y50−c1

+ −1y75−c1 )−

q ( c1)y100−c1

We are multiplying by a negative number, so the sign of the inequality switches,

Page 36: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Napolitano 36

1>( 1−q ( c1)

4 )∗( −1y0−c1

+ −1y25−c1

+ −1y50−c1

+ −1y75−c1 )−

q ( c1)y100−c1

ln( (( y0−c1 ) ( y25−c1) ( y50−c1) ( y75−c1 ))( y100−c1)4 )

Which is the same as1>q '(c1)

So if we allow 1>q '(c1) and combine it with( x0+x25+x50+x75)>1

It implies thatq ' (c0 )>q' ( c1)

And since q ' ' (c )<0by assumption,c0<c1

, given1>q '(c1)

A2.7 Campaign Contributions Before and After Insurance when q=1+c

2+c

As shown in A2.5 campaign contributions before the insurance are less than they would be after the insurance (c0<c1 ¿ ,conditional on q '(c1) < 1.

So if we allow q ( c )=1+c2+c (which satisfies the assumptions and is used earlier in the paper), then

q ' (c1 )= 1(2+c1)

2

0<q' (c1)<1

The condition is satisfied, implying c0<c1

Page 37: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Napolitano 37

Appendix B

Social Security Survey

1. What is your sex?2. When were you born?3. Do you regularly vote?

a. Yesb. No

4. If so, is social security policy an issue you consider when deciding who to vote for?a. Yes, likely to vote for candidate who supports continuing social security at

current levelsb. Yes, likely to vote for candidate who supports reducing social securityc. No

5. Do you regularly contribute to political campaigns?a. Yesb. No

6. If so, are you hoping your contribution will affect social security policy either directly or indirectly through which politician is elected?

a. Yes, in support of continuing social security at current levelsb. Yes, in support of reducing social securityc. No

7. In your opinion, what is the likelihood that social security will exist in its current form when you plan on retiring?

a. Very High (80% - 100%)b. High (60% - 79%)c. Medium (40% - 59%)d. Low (20% - 39%)e. Very Low (0%-19%)

8. In your opinion, what is the likelihood that social security will exist with at least 75% of current benefits when you plan on retiring?

a. Very High (80% - 100%)b. High (60% - 79%)c. Medium (40% - 59%)d. Low (20% - 39%)e. Very Low (0%-19%)

9. In your opinion, what is the likelihood that social security will exist with at least 50% of current benefits when you plan on retiring?

a. Very High (80% - 100%)b. High (60% - 79%)

Page 38: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Napolitano 38

c. Medium (40% - 59%)d. Low (20% - 39%)e. Very Low (0%-19%)

10. In your opinion, what is the likelihood that social security will exist with at least 25% of current benefits when you plan on retiring?

a. Very High (80% - 100%)b. High (60% - 79%)c. Medium (40% - 59%)d. Low (20% - 39%)e. Very Low (0%-19%)

11. How reliant do you see yourself being on your Social Security benefits when you retire?a. Reliantb. Not reliant

12. At what age do you plan to start receiving social security benefits?13. As of today the current average Social Security benefit is about $1,200 per month which

accumulates to more than $250,000 over the course of retirement. There is some concern that the benefits granted by social security will be cut sometime in the future. So what I want to do is to offer you the opportunity to guarantee your roughly $250,000 by purchasing insurance for your social security. Similar to home or car insurance, this investment will cover your future benefits should current social security laws change. This policy would payout the difference between how much social security you would receive under today’s law and your actual benefit at the time of your retirement. For example if your monthly benefit was reduced by $600 your insurance payout would total over $125,000. Keeping all that in mind would you be willing to spend $XXX (monopoly price – calculated based on answers to previous questions) per year to ensure your full social security benefit?

a. Yesb. No

14. (If answer to 13 is ‘No’) If you had the opportunity to purchase insurance for your social security benefits for $XXX (actuarially fair price - calculated based upon answers to previous questions) would you?

a. Yesb. No

15. (If answer to 14 is “No”) Is there any price you would be willing to buy the insurance? If so, what is it?

16. Is there any reason why you wouldn’t want to buy this type of insurance?17. (Based on answer to 16) If [whatever reason given in 16] did/didn’t exist/happen/etc.

would you purchase this insurance?18. If you buy this insurance then any changes to decrease social security would not affect

your future benefits. Keeping that in mind, after purchasing this insurance would social security policy be an issue you consider when deciding who to vote for?

Page 39: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Napolitano 39

a. Yes, likely to vote for candidate who supports continuing social security at current levels

b. Yes, likely to vote for candidate who supports reducing social securityc. No

19. If you buy this insurance, will you contribute to political campaigns in the hopes that your contribution will affect social security policy either directly or indirectly through which politician is elected?

a. Yes, in support of continuing social security at current levelsb. Yes, in support of reducing social securityc. No

Page 40: Social Security & Insurance - Web viewThe ever-changing political climate in the United States creates uncertainty in the existence and size of government-sponsored payouts, subsidies,

Napolitano 40

References

Overseas private investment corporation. 2012 [cited Dec 16, 2012 2102]. Available from www.opic.gov.

Campante, Filipe R. (2011), “Redistribution in a Model of Voting and Campaign Contributions”, Journal of Public Economics, 95(7-8), 646-56

Coate, Stephen (2004), “Political Competition with Campaign Contributions and Informative Advertising”, Journal of the European Economic Association 2: 772-804.

Garver, Patrick. 2009. The changing face of political risk. In , eds. Kevin W. Lu, Gero Verheyen and Srilal M. Perera, 81-88Washington, D.C.: World Bank.

Gordon, Kathryn. 2008. Investment guarantees and political risk insurance: Institutions, incentives and development. In , ed. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, 91-122Paris and Washington, D.C.: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development.

Grossman, Gene M. and Elhanan Helpman (1996), “Electoral Competition and SpecialInterest Policies”, Review of Economic Studies 63: 265-286.

Kumru, Cagri S.; Thanopoulos, Athanasios C. (2011), “Social Security Reform with Self-Control Preferences”, Journal of Public Economics 95(7-8), 886-99

Levi, Michelle. “McCain: Campaign Finance Reform is Dead.” Face the Nation, CBS News, Jan 24, 2010, http://www.cbsnews.com/2100-3460_162-6136386.html.

Michel-Kerjan, Erwann O. 2010. Catastrophe economics: The national flood insurance program. Journal of Economic Perspectives 24 (4) (Fall 2010): 165-86.

Prat, Andrea (2002), “Campaign Spending with Office-Seeking Politicians, Rational Voters, and Multiple Lobbies”, Journal of Economic Theory 103: 162-189.

Riordan, Daniel W. 2004. Commentary on political risk insurance in the aftermath of the september 11 attacks and the argentine crisis: An underwriter's view. In , ed. Theodore H. Moran, 116-120Washington, D.C.:; World Bank .

Ryan, Paul. Social security. 2012 [cited Dec 18, 2012 2012]. Available from http://paulryan.house.gov/issues/issue/?IssueID=12227.

Salinger, John J. 2008. Past and future predictions for the political risk insurance industry. In , eds. Theodore H. Moran, Gerald T. West and Keith Martin, 201-208Washington, D.C.: World Bank.