Role of Behavioural Economics in Energy and Climate Policy

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/3/2019 Role of Behavioural Economics in Energy and Climate Policy

    1/31

    The Role of Behavioural Economics in Energy and

    Climate Policy

    Michael G. Pollitt and Irina Shaorshadze

    December 2011

    CWPE 1165 & EPRG 1130

  • 8/3/2019 Role of Behavioural Economics in Energy and Climate Policy

    2/31

    www.eprg.group.cam.ac.uk

    EP

    RG

    WORKING

    PAPER

    Abstract

    The Role of Behavioural Economics in Energyand Climate Policy

    EPRG Working Paper 1130

    Cambridge Working Paper in Economics 1165

    Michael G. Pollitt and Irina Shaorshadze

    This article explores how behavioural economics can be applied to

    energy and climate policy. We present an overview of main concepts of

    behavioural economics and discuss how they differ from the

    assumptions of neoclassical economics. Next, we discuss how

    behavioural economics applies to three areas of energy policy: (1)

    consumption and habits, (2) investment in energy efficiency, and (3)provision of public goods and support for pro-environmental behaviour.

    We conclude that behavioural economics seems unlikely to provide the

    magic bullet to reduce energy consumption by the magnitude required

    by the International Energy Agency's 450 climate policy scenario.

    However it offers new suggestions as to where to start looking for

    potentially sustainable changes in energy consumption. We believe that

    the most useful role within climate policy is in addressing issues of

    public perception of the affordability of climate policy and in facilitating

    the creation of a more responsive energy demand, better capable ofresponding to weather-induced changes in renewable electricity supply.

    Keywords behavioural economics, energy economics, energy demand,

    energy efficiency, private provision of public goods

    JEL Classification D03, D10, Q40, Q58

    Contact [email protected] December 2011Financial Support EPSRC, Flexnet

  • 8/3/2019 Role of Behavioural Economics in Energy and Climate Policy

    3/31

    EPRGWP1130

    1

    TheRoleofBehaviouralEconomicsinEnergyandClimatePolicy

    MichaelG.Pollitt1

    IrinaShaorshadze

    ESRCElectricityPolicyResearchGroup

    UniversityofCambridge

    December2011

    1. Introduction

    While energy efficiency and conservation have been important tenets of energy policy for decades,

    concernsaboutclimatechangehaveputthese issuesatthe forefrontofpolicydialogue. International

    Energy Association (IEA 2010) estimates that by 2020, about 34% of the global decrease in carbon

    emissions in a 450 scenario (limiting the longterm concentration of greenhouse gases in the

    atmosphereto450ppmCO2eq)comparedtothereferencescenarioshouldstemfromdirectenduse

    energyefficiency

    measures.

    This

    goal

    calls

    for

    astep

    change

    in

    how

    individuals

    consume

    energy

    and

    make energyefficiency purchases. Energy consumption, energyefficient investment, and pro

    environmentalactionsinvolveconsumerdecisionmakingandbehaviour.Theseaspectshavegenerated

    increasedinterestindesigningpolicyinterventionsthattargetenergydemand,andinterestinassessing

    theresponsivenessofconsumerbehaviourtothese interventions.Behaviouraleconomicscanprovide

    new perspectives that can inform policy design on how individuals evaluate options, make decisions,

    andchangebehaviour.

    Itisimportanttopointoutthatenergypolicyisnotjustaboutclimatechange,butalsoaboutsecurityof

    energysupplyandabouttheaffordabilityofenergy.Climatepolicysignificantly interactswithbothof

    theseelements

    of

    energy

    policy

    via

    the

    introduction

    of

    expensive

    and

    intermittent

    renewable

    electricity

    andheat.Ifconsumerbehaviourcanbechangedtoreduceenergydemandortomakeenergydemand

    more responsive in time and space to weatherinduced shortages of energy, it could be a significant

    contribution to facilitating the introduction of climate policyinduced renewable energy. By contrast,

    1ThispaperwillbeachapterintheforthcomingHandbookonEnergyandClimateChangeeditedbyRoger

    Fouquet,tobepublishedbyEdwardElgar.TheauthorswishtothanktheEPSRCFlexnetprojectforfinancial

    supportandRogerFouquetforhisencouragementtowritethepaper.Weacknowledgethehelpfulcommentsof

    RogerFouquetandananonymousreferee.Theusualdisclaimerapplies.

  • 8/3/2019 Role of Behavioural Economics in Energy and Climate Policy

    4/31

    EPRGWP1130

    2

    failure toaddresspublicconcernsabout the securityof supplyoraffordability implicationsofclimate

    policymayjeopardizetheachievementofambitiouscarbonemissionsreductiontargets.

    Behaviouraleconomicsusesinsightsfrompsychologyto increasetheexplanatorypowerofeconomics.

    According to neoclassical economics, agents maximize expected utility using exponential discounting,

    and they have access to information that they can assess freely and completely. While this is a

    parsimoniousrepresentationofhoweconomicdecisionsaremade,experimentalsettingsandempirical

    observations indicate that behaviour deviates systematically from what traditional models would

    predict.Someofthepuzzlesthattraditionaleconomicsstrugglestoexplainarethefollowing:whyare

    returnsonequitymuchhigherthanreturnsonbonds(equitypremiumpuzzle);whyarethereuntapped

    opportunitiestoreduce(energy)expenditurethroughincreased(energy)efficiency(efficiencygap);and

    whydoindividualsindulgeinimmediategratification,knowinglycompromisingtheirlongrunwellbeing

    (substance

    abuse)?

    Behavioural

    economics

    challenges

    one

    or

    more

    of

    the

    assumptions

    of

    the

    neoclassical economics, and offers an alternative way to model decision making. These alternative

    modelsoftenbettermatchempiricalobservationsandhavehigherpredictivepowerthanmodelsbased

    purelyonneoclassicalassumptions.

    Whiletraditionaleconomicsassumesindividualsalwaysbehaverationally,behaviouraleconomistsoften

    stress the irrational aspect of decision making, often referred to as behavioural failures. These

    behaviouralfailuresmaymakeindividualsactagainsttheirownlongterminterest.ThalerandSunstein

    (2008)arguethatifindividualsdonotalwayschoosewhatisbestfortheminthelongrun,itiswelfare

    enhancingforpolicymakerstoensurethatthesetofchoicesthat individualsface issuchthata long

    term,welfare

    maximizing

    outcome

    becomes

    more

    likely.

    This

    may

    be

    done

    through

    proper

    framing

    choices, setting appropriate (limited if necessary) choice sets and providing appropriate default

    options. In essence, individuals are nudged towards a welfaremaximizing outcome, even if their

    freedom to choose is still respected. Thaler and Sunstein (2003) called this approach libertarian

    paternalism. Libertarian paternalism would argue for policy interventions in the face of behavioural

    failures,evenifmarketfailuresareabsent.

    Traditionally,economicshasfocusedonhowchangesinpricesaffectbehaviour.Researchinbehavioural

    economicsandpsychologyhasdemonstratedthatnonpecuniary interventionscompare favourablyto

    monetary interventions in changing consumer behaviour. It was also shown thatjudiciously applied

    pecuniaryinterventions

    increase

    the

    impact

    of

    monetary

    interventions

    ifused

    in

    combination.

    This

    has

    increasedinterestinresearchinbehaviouraleconomicsasaguideforpolicymakinginareasasdiverse

    as public health, finance, and law. Thatbehaviouraleconomics can inform decision making inenergy

    policy has increasingly been recognized by policy makers and researchers (Allcott and Mullainathan

    2010;DEFRA2010;OFGEM2011).

    In order to realize energy savings and emissions reductions necessary to address climate change,

    decision makers have to consider tapping into behavioural transformation strategies. Behavioural

    Economics provides insights that can inform this effort. Behaviours that are relevant to household

    energyconsumptionencompassthreebroadareas(1)energyconsumption,curtailment,andhabits;(2)

  • 8/3/2019 Role of Behavioural Economics in Energy and Climate Policy

    5/31

    EPRGWP1130

    3

    energy efficiency investments; and (3) contribution to public goods (i.e. green energy) and pro

    environmental behaviour. These three aspects of energy consumption are interrelated; for example,

    proenvironmentalattitudesmaymakeefficiency investmentsmore likely,andthese investmentsmay

    reduceenergyconsumptioninthelongrun.However,thesetopicsdifferintermsofthedecisionmaking

    andbehavioursinvolved,andwarrantseparatereviews.

    The restof this paper is organized as follows. Section 2presents themajorconcepts that distinguish

    behaviouraleconomics fromneoclassicaleconomics.Sections3,4,and5 form theheartof thepaper

    anddiscusshowbehaviouraleconomics relates toenergyconsumptionandpolicy.Threebroadareas

    related to energy are discussed: energy consumption, curtailment, and habits (section 3); energy

    efficiency investments and purchases (section 4); proenvironmental behaviour and public goods

    (section5).Section6providesconcludingremarks.

    2. BehaviouralEconomicsvs.NeoclassicalEconomicsThemaindeparturesfromneoclassicaleconomicsproposedbybehaviouraleconomicscanbegrouped

    underfourmainareas:(1)timevaryingdiscountrates,(2)prospecttheoryandimportanceofreference

    points,(3)boundedrationality,and(4)prosocialbehaviourandfairness.Belowwebrieflydiscusseach

    oftheseareas.

    2.1. Time-VaryingDiscountRates

    Experimentsshow

    that

    individuals

    use

    ahigher

    discount

    rate

    over

    alonger

    time

    horizon

    than

    over

    a

    shorter timehorizon (Thaler 1981;Benzionetal.1989;HolcombandNelson1992).Todealwith this

    apparent anomaly, behavioural economics proposes hyperbolic discounting. Under hyperbolic

    discounting, individualshavehigherdiscount rates for shorthorizons,but lowdiscount rates for long

    horizons (Laibson 1997). This implies that people will be farsighted when planning if both costs and

    benefits occur in the future. However, they will make shortsighted decisions if costs or benefits are

    immediate (Camerer and Loewenstein 2004). Some of the manifestations of the timeinconsistent

    preferencesareinabilitytoloseweight,stopsmoking,andsaveenoughforretirement(Wilkinson2007).

    If individuals have timevarying discount rates, at somepoint in the future theirpreferences change.

    Preferencesbetween

    two

    future

    rewards

    can

    reverse

    in

    favour

    of

    amore

    proximate

    reward,

    ifthe

    time

    tobothrewardsdiminishes.Anindividualmayprefer$110 in31daysover$100 in30days,butprefer

    $100nowover$110tomorrow.(Fredericketal.2004).Thisisinconsistentwithexponentialdiscounting

    used by neoclassical economics in expected utility models. If agents were to discount future utilities

    exponentially,timepreferenceswouldnotreverse,becausethedelayof30daysissharedbetweenthe

    two options. Timevarying discount rates could explain the tendency to procrastinate. When given a

    choicebetweenperforming5hoursofanunpleasant task todayand5hoursofanunpleasanttask

    tomorrow,mostpeoplechoosethesecondoptionanddelaythetask.Ontheotherhand,whengivena

    choiceof5hoursofunpleasantworkinamonth,versus5hoursofunpleasantworkinamonthanda

  • 8/3/2019 Role of Behavioural Economics in Energy and Climate Policy

    6/31

    EPRGWP1130

    4

    day, most people take the first option. However, ifan individualdecides todo thework inamonth,

    whenthedaycomes,heorshewouldagainprefertodelayituntilthenextday(ODonoghueandRabin

    2000).

    Some individualsmaybeawareof theirtendency toprocrastinate,andmayvalue theopportunity to

    make a commitment. The fact that people value commitment devices has been demonstrated

    empirically. Ashraf et al. (2006) show that when given the choice of depositing money in a savings

    account from which they can draw freely and a bank account that pays the same interest rate but

    restricts when funds can be withdrawn, some individuals choose the latter option. Individuals who

    chosecommitmentsavingaccountsincreasedsavingratesby82%.Traditionaleconomicsfindsithardto

    explainwhysomepeoplewouldchoosean illiquidassetovera liquidasset,even iftheypaythesame

    interestrate.

    2.2. ProspectTheoryandImportanceofReferencePointsInstandardeconomictheory,an individualspreferencesamongdifferentcommoditybundlesdepend

    onwealthandprices,butareindependentfromthecompositionoftheircurrentendowment(assets)or

    theircurrentconsumption.Prospecttheory,developedbyKahnemannandTversky,statesthatwelfare

    changesshouldbeevaluatedaccordingtocertainreferencepoints(KahnemannandTversky1979).The

    followingaresomeofthemanifestationsoftheimportantreferencepointsforwelfareevaluation.

    Lossaversion.Traditionaleconomicsassumes that individualsare riskaverseor riskneutralbutplace

    thesame

    value

    on

    losses

    and

    gains

    of

    equal

    amount.

    Kahnemann

    and

    Tversky

    (1979)

    argue

    that

    valuation of losses is the mirror image of valuation of gains and refer to this phenomenon as the

    reflectioneffect.Decisionmakingwillexhibit the reflectioneffectwhenthe individual isriskaverse in

    the face of potential gains, but riskseeking in the face of potential loss. It has been demonstrated

    empiricallythat individualstendtovalue lossesmorethangains.This isfound incontingentvaluation

    studies that show that willingness to accept (WTA) is typically higher than willingness to pay (WTP)

    (ShogrenandTaylor2008).ShefrinandStatman(1985)demonstratedthatinvestorsholdontoolongto

    thestocksthatlostvalue,butareeagertosellthestocksthatgainedinvalue,andarguethatthisisdue

    toreluctancetosellataloss.Endowment

    effect.

    This

    refers

    to

    the

    extra

    value

    that

    individuals

    attach

    to

    goods

    they

    already

    own

    or

    servicestheyalreadyreceive.Inessence,theendowmentpointisthereferencepoint,andagentshavea

    kink in thevaluationaroundthispoint (Thaler1980).HeberleinandBishop(1986) foundthathunters

    werewillingtopay$31foraparticularhuntingpermitbutwerenotwillingtoletgoofthesamepermit

    forlessthan$143.

    Statusquo bias. Individuals tend to stick to the default option chosen for them. For example, in

    countrieswhereorgandonation isconductedunderpresumedconsent(i.e.consentbydefault,unless

    explicitoppositionwasregisteredbydonor),participationratesare25%30%higherthan incountries

    wheredonation isconductedunder informedconsent(i.e.noconsent ispresumedunless itwasmade

  • 8/3/2019 Role of Behavioural Economics in Energy and Climate Policy

    7/31

    EPRGWP1130

    5

    explicit)(AbadieandGay2006).SamuelsonandZeckhauser(1988)showedthatwhennewhealthcare

    optionswereoffered toHarvardUniversity faculty,new facultymembersweremore likely tochoose

    them,butolderfacultymemberswereunlikelytomodifytheircurrentplans.

    2.3. BoundedRationalityBoundedrationalityreferstothephenomenonthatagentsarerationalbuthavecognitiveconstraintsin

    processing information(Simon1986).Thereforetheydeviatefromrationality incertaincircumstances.

    Someofthemanifestationsofboundedrationalityarethe following: (1)choiceoverload,(2)heuristic

    decisionmaking,and(3)failuretoassessstatisticalprobabilities.

    Choiceoverload refers to the difficulty individuals have in making a choice when presented with too

    manyoptions.

    Studies

    show

    that

    more

    shoppers

    make

    apurchase

    of

    ajam

    when

    they

    are

    presented

    with 6 choices than when they are presented with 24 choices (Iyngar and Lepper 2000). Traditional

    economicsstruggles toexplainthis tendency,andassumesthatmorechoicesarealwayspreferred to

    fewerchoices.

    Heuristicsareshortcutstodecisionmaking,suchasviaaruleofthumb.Traditionaleconomicsassumes

    that individualsuseconceptsofstatisticalsamplingandstatisticalrules(e.g.Bayesrule)forupdating

    probabilitiesoffutureeventsinthefaceofnewevidence(CamererandLoewenstein2004).Experiments

    demonstratethat individualsoftenmakechoices inawaythatdeparts from theBayesianassessment

    thattheyaresupposedtomakeundertraditionaleconomics.Thisdeparturemaybesystematic(biased)

    ratherthan

    idiosyncratic.

    Individuals

    may

    categorize

    purchases

    under

    different

    categories

    and

    have

    different discount rates for these categories. For instance, higher oneoff expenditures may be

    categorizedundera separatementalaccountandhavedifferentdiscount rates thanmultiple smaller

    expenditures. Thaler (1999) showed thatan individuals willingness to spendearned income,windfall

    income,orsavedincome isnotthesame,even ifmoneycanbeused interchangeably.Thiscontradicts

    the assumption of traditional economics that money is fungible. Heath and Soll (1996) suggest thatmentalaccountingcanexplainwhyindividualsmakeapparentlysuboptimalconsumptionchoices.

    There is some indication that consumers do not correctly process statistical information and

    probabilities. They are swayed by vivid and salient information more than by simply convincing,

    statistically

    correct

    information.

    Research

    shows

    that

    individuals

    overstate

    small

    probabilities

    of

    catastrophiclossesorlargegains.JulienandSalanie(2000)findthatonhorseraces,thereisbiastowards

    bettingonlongshots, implying thatgamblers like togamble,buttheyaredisproportionallyafraidof

    small chances of losing when they bet on heavy favourites. Cook and Clotfelter (1993) find that

    Lotteries are popular because players are more sensitive to largejackpots than to the probability of

    winning.

  • 8/3/2019 Role of Behavioural Economics in Energy and Climate Policy

    8/31

    EPRGWP1130

    6

    2.4. Pro-SocialBehaviourandFairnessNeoclassical

    economics

    assumes

    that

    an

    agent

    makes

    choices

    that

    depend

    only

    on

    his

    or

    her

    own

    monetarypayoffandconsumption(Pesendorfer2006).However, inexperimentalgamesandempirical

    studies, it has been demonstrated that individuals seem to value fairness and often act prosocially.

    Kahnemanetal.(1986)showthatconsumershavestrongfeelingsaboutthefairnessofafirmsshort

    run price decisions, and suggest that this prevents firms from exploiting their full monopoly power.

    Individualsoftenactprosocially,contribute tocharities,andengage inproenvironmentalbehaviour,

    even if this imposescostsonthem.Behaviouraleconomicschallenges theview thateconomicagents

    arepurelyselfish.

    If individualsarenotasselfishastraditionaleconomicshasassumed,thisunselfishnesshas important

    implications

    for

    understanding

    the

    private

    provision

    of

    public

    goods.

    According

    to

    neoclassical

    economics, individuals care only about their own consumption of public goods but do not directly

    benefit from theirowncontribution,norare theydirectlyaffectedbyother peoplesconsumptionor

    contribution(BernheimandRangel2007).Traditionaleconomicsclaimsthatpeoplewillhaveatendency

    to free ride, and that public goods will be underprovided unless provisions are mandated through

    taxation. Furthermore, only very wealthy are predicted to make voluntary contributions, and as

    population increases contributions should converge to zero. These assumptions provide testable

    hypotheses thatarecontradictedbyempiricalevidence (Andreoni2006;BernheimandRangel 2007).

    Behavioural economics provides an alternative view to help explain why and when individuals make

    privateprovisionofpublicgoods.

    Two behavioural explanations relate to peoples attitudes towards providing for public goods. First,

    individualsarenotpurelyselfish,butplacevalueonsocialgoods.Inessence,theyvaluenotonlytheir

    ownconsumption,butalsotheconsumptionofothers(theyareotherregarding).Publicgoodsmaystill

    beunderprovided,butthis isbecause individualsthink it isnotfairthattheybeartheburdenfortheir

    provisionat the expenseofothers.Ostrom (1998) finds that inpublic goodsgames (i.e.experiments

    where individuals are given the opportunity to contribute to the provision of a public good) most

    individualsareconditionalcooperators theywillcontribute, iftheyare sure thatotherswilldothe

    same.Second,individualscontributetothesocialgoodbecauseofthewarmgloweffect.Warmglow

    effect refers to the idea that individualsmightparticipate inpublic goods (suchasa greenelectricity

    program)because

    it

    makes

    them

    feel

    good

    (either

    because

    they

    feel

    better

    about

    themselves,

    or

    becausetheycareaboutwhatothersthinkofthem),butnotnecessarilybecausetheycareaboutthe

    publicbenefitperse(Andreoni1990;BernheimandRangel2007).Inessence,besidesvaluingtheirown

    consumptionofpublicgoods,individualsvaluehavingcontributedtopublicgoodprovision.

    Themotivationsforprovidingforpublicgoodsarehardtotestempirically.Asaresult,warmglow is

    often treated as a reduced form of deeper underlying processes (social norms, social signalling,

    reciprocity, altruism, etc.). Disentangling these processes is challenging and their representation may

    vary among different policies and contexts (Bernheim and Rangel 2007). Nevertheless, different

  • 8/3/2019 Role of Behavioural Economics in Energy and Climate Policy

    9/31

    EPRGWP1130

    7

    underlyingmotivationsmayhavedifferentpolicyimplications.Ifanindividualwouldprovideforpublic

    goodsonlywith theassurance thatothersdonot free ride (i.e.showingaconcern for fairness), then

    increasedcontributionbyotherswill increasethe likelihoodofhisorhercontribution. If,ontheother

    hand,anindividualcontributesasastatussymbol(e.g.becauseofadesireforawarmgloworprestige),

    thenprovisionbyothersmaydecreasethelikelihoodofhisorhercontribution.Inthiscase,amonetary

    incentiveforcontributingmaycrowdoutthealtruisticincentivetocontribute.

    Researchers indeedfindthatmonetaryrewardssometimescrowdoutintrinsicmotivation,especiallyif

    themonetaryrewardsaresmall.Forexample,whenasmallmonetarypaymentwasofferedforblood

    donation,blooddonationsactuallydecreased (Titmuss1987[1971]). Itwasalso found thatvolunteers

    performbetterwhentheyarenotcompensatedthanwhentheyreceivesmallmonetarycompensations

    (GneezyandRustichini2000).These findingsarehardtoreconcilewithtraditionaleconomics,butcan

    be

    explained

    by

    behavioural

    economics,

    as

    they

    take

    away

    from

    the

    warm

    glow

    satisfaction

    of

    giving.

    3. EnergyConsumption,Curtailment,andHabits

    In this section we discuss topics that involve repetitive or continuous efforts to reduce energy

    consumption or to change energyuse habits. The policy interventions discussed in this section focus

    primarilyonpromotingenergycurtailmentinthehouseholdenergysector.Inaddition,wediscusshow

    changingthetarifforbillingstructureaffectsenergyconsumptionpatterns.

    3.1. RateStructure:Flatvs.DynamicTariffs

    Themarginalcostofproducingelectricityvariesthroughtheday,andthewholesaleelectricityprice is

    highduringthetimeofpeakelectricityusage.Traditionally,residentialelectricitycustomersfaced flat

    electricity tariffs, and were insulated from fluctuating wholesale electricity prices through the day. If

    electricitydemandbecomesflatter,utilitieswillsaveonenergycostsbyminimizingusageofpeaking

    plants, which are usually less efficient and produce more carbon emissions. Further down the line,

    havingasmootherdemandwillresult inreduced investmentsforbuildingpeakingplants.Costsavings

    caneventuallyberecycledbacktotheconsumers.

    Recently,policymakersandutilitieshavebeenlookingatthepotentialofintroducingtariffsthatvaryby

    thetime

    of

    usage.

    Some

    possible

    variable

    tariffs

    are

    the

    following:

    (1)

    time

    of

    use

    tariffs

    (TOU),

    when

    customers face different tariffs according to the time of day; (2) critical peak pricing (CPP), when

    customers facehighertariffsduringcertaincriticalpeaktimesthroughtheyear;(3)peaktimerebate,

    when customers pay flat electricity tariffs but receive rebates if the electricity usage is reduced

    compared to a certain benchmark at critical times through the year; (4) realtime pricing, when

    customerselectricitytariffsfluctuateinrealtimeaccordingtothewholesaleelectricityprices.

    Timevarying tariffs requireadvanced (smart)meters thatcanmeasureconsumption inreal time.The

    UnitedKingdom, Italy,andthestateofCalifornia intheUSAhave legislated largescaledeploymentof

  • 8/3/2019 Role of Behavioural Economics in Energy and Climate Policy

    10/31

    EPRGWP1130

    8

    smartmeters,withotherjurisdictionsplanningtofollowtheirlead(FaruquiandSergici2009).Extensive

    researchisunderwaybypolicymakers,utilities,andacademicstogaugethepotentialfordemandside

    response(DSR)totimevaryingtariffs.ThevalueofDSRhingesonthepotentialofcustomerbehavioural

    responseandisanareathatcandrawimportantinsightsfrombehaviouraleconomics.Belowaresome

    of the concepts from behavioural economics that are relevant to the decision to implement variable

    rates.

    Endowmenteffect.Billpayerscurrentlyenjoythebenefitofbeinginsulatedfromvariableratesduring the day. Proper design and marketing of the dynamic tariffs will be critical for

    overcoming consumers resistance to changing the costbenefit structure of the way they

    consume electricity. Individuals are attached to their routines and daily habits and may be

    inflexibletomodifythem,ordemandhighcompensationtodoso.

    Statusquobias.Researchshows thatwhenpresentedwithautilitybillwithadefaultchoice,most consumers will not change it (Brennan 2006). Those who object to having the dynamic

    tariffeitherasadefaultormandatoryoption,mentiondistributionalconsiderations.Theyargue

    that most households will remain on the default plan even if it is not optimal for their

    consumptionpatterns.Vulnerablehouseholds,suchastheelderlyanddisabled,willnotbeable

    tovarytheirloadandwillbe losersunderthedynamictariffs, ifthatissetasadefault(Felder

    2010).

    Timevaryingdiscountrates. Introducingdynamictariffsraisesconcernsaboutshorttermcostversus

    the

    lag

    in

    long

    term

    gain

    (Simhauser

    and

    Downer

    2011).

    Dynamic

    pricing

    will

    result

    in

    a

    rate shock, as bills of some consumers will skyrocket in the near term, before behavioural

    adjustments,orbeforehouseholdsacquireenablingtechnologiesorreplaceoldapplianceswith

    ones that better accommodate varying tariffs. Even if the long term costs of smart meter

    infrastructure proves to be beneficial, the long term may be really long (Hanser 2010). Since

    individualstendtohavehigherdiscountratesforthefuture,theymaynotthinkthatthecosts

    areworththebenefits,especiallyifthesavingsareinitiallysmallornil.

    Lossaversion.Ifindividualsvalue(negatively) lossesmorethantheyvaluegains,rate increasesduring peak periods may have tobe compensated with larger ratedecreases during offpeak

    periods.

    Concern for Fairness. Opponents of mandatory dynamic tariffs cite fairness considerationstowardsthevulnerable.Itisarguedthatvulnerablehouseholds(elderly,disabled,andpoor)will

    notbeabletoshiftconsumptiontooffpeak,sincetheyhaveminimalelectricityconsumptionto

    beginwithandareoftenhomebound.On theotherhand,proponents forthedynamic tariffs

    statethatitisnotfairthatpeakyhouseholdsarebeingsubsidizedbylesspeakyhouseholds

    throughflattariffs(Faruqui2010).

  • 8/3/2019 Role of Behavioural Economics in Energy and Climate Policy

    11/31

    EPRGWP1130

    9

    Highelectricitybillsaresalientandraisevociferousopposition that results inamediaoutcry.Moving

    customers en mass to dynamic prices may bring adverse consequences and may result in a strong

    politicalbacklash.Alexander(2010)givesexamplesoflargescaleTOUtariffrolloutsintheUSAthatdid

    notmeetexpectations:

    Central Maine Power Company had implemented a mandatory TOU structure in the 1980s.However, in the1990s, theTOU rate structure was changed to reflecthigherpeakelectricity

    costs,buttheincreasedbillscausedconsumeropposition,andTOUratesweremadevoluntary.

    PugetSoundEnergyofWashington state implementedmandatoryTOUpricing for residentialcustomers in2001.However, theprogramactually resulted inhigherbillsunder thenewrate

    structure.Theprogramwashaltedin2002.

    Alexander(2010)suggeststhathavingapeaktimerebate(PTR)isamoreattractiveoptioncomparedto

    mandatory CPP or TOU. A PTR scheme would leave the underlying rate structure unchanged, but

    provide rebates or credit to those customers who reduce usage during critical peak hours. A rebate

    option should be viewed as carrot only rather than stick only (Maine Public Utilities Commission

    2007;Alexander2010).WithCPP,peakycustomerswillseetheirratesincreaseiftheydonotchange

    behaviour.Ifconsumersfocusmoreonthedownsideriskofhigherbillsthantheupsidepotential,they

    willdislikeCPP.MoreconsumerswouldchoosetotakeadvantageofPTRthanvolunteerforCPP.Letzler

    (2007)arguesthatanincentivecompatiblerebateaddressestheheuristicsofconsumerdecisionmaking

    betterthanCPP.

    In2008,BaltimoreGas&Electric(BGE)conductedadynamicpricingpilotwhichshowedthatconsumers

    respondedtoPTRaswellastoCPP.Asaresult,BGEabandonedCPPandconductedatrialofonlyPTRin

    2009.FaruquiandSergici(2009)review15pilotexperimentswithdynamicpricingofelectricity.Across

    therangeofexperimentsstudied,TOUrates inducedadrop inpeakdemandthatrangedbetween3%

    and6%,andCPP inducedadrop inpeakdemandthatrangedbetween13%to20%.Whencombined,

    thedropinpeakdemandwasinthe27%to44%range.

    3.2. BillingandPaymentMethods

    Howcustomers

    pay

    their

    utility

    bills

    may

    have

    implications

    for

    how

    they

    consume

    energy.

    This

    was

    demonstratedbyastudyofconsumptionandmeter topupbehaviourof thehouseholds inNorthern

    Irelandthatuseprepaymentmeters(Brutscher2011a,b).Brutscher(2011a)showsthatconsumerswith

    prepayment meters tend to consume more electricity. Households tend to purchase relatively small

    amountsoftopups,andadjusttoincreasesintariffsbyincreasingtheirnumberoftopups,ratherthan

    by increasing the amount. However, exogenous increases in minimum topup amount result in

    decreasedenergyuse.This suggeststhatconsumersperceivecostsdifferentlyaccordingtohow large

    they are. They have different mental accounts for larger purchases, and are more aware of the

  • 8/3/2019 Role of Behavioural Economics in Energy and Climate Policy

    12/31

    EPRGWP1130

    10

    consumptionaftertheyhavemadealargetopup.Increasingminimumtopupamountwouldtherefore

    likelyresultindecreasedenergyconsumption.

    Brutscher(2011b)findsthatlowincomehouseholdsuseelectricheatratherthanoilbecausetheyhave

    liquidityconstraintsheatingoil requiresbulkpurchase,whereaselectricitymeterscanbeprepaid in

    smallamounts.Asoilheating ismoreefficientandcheaper inthe longrun,thiscouldbeexplainedby

    timevaryingdiscountrates,whichprevent individualsfromsavingforbulkheatingoilpurchase. Ifthe

    bulkpurchasenecessary forheatingoil involvessavingmoney fora future largepurchase,themoney

    being saved will be subject to temptation to make alternative purchases with more immediate

    gratification.Ifindividualshavehigherdiscountratesforthefarfuturethanforthenearfuture,theywill

    repeatedly succumb to temptation, even if they are aware that saving money will buy them a more

    efficientsourceoffuelinthelongrun.Aheatstampprogram(whereconsumersbuynonfungiblecredits

    towards

    future

    purchases

    of

    oil)

    is

    a

    potential

    solution

    for

    this

    behavioural

    failure.

    Heat

    stamp

    programs,

    currentlyoperatinginvariouscommunitiesinNorthernIreland,letsconsumersgraduallycollectstamps

    thattheycanredeemforthebulkoilpurchase.

    3.3. Non-pecuniaryIncentivestoConserveEnergyNonpecuniary interventionshavebeenattemptedtoelicitreductions inenergyconsumption,often in

    combinationwithmonetary incentivesandinformationprovision.Whereinterventionswerecombined

    withmonetaryincentives,consumptionfeedback,orenergysavinginformation,itishardtodisentangle

    theeffectsoftheseinterventions.

    Competitionhasbeeneffective in incentivizing individuals to reduceenergyconsumption.McClelland

    andCook(1980)studiedtheeffectofcompetitionbetweenmastermeteredresidentialbuildingsatthe

    University of Colorado, USA. The buildings, where occupants were not individually metered, were

    competingonwhichbuildingwouldsavemoreelectricity.Contestantsreceived informationonhowto

    saveelectricityand feedbackonsavingsof theirusage,aswellas theusageof theothergroups.The

    winningbuilding receiveda rewardof$80.Thecontestgroupsused6.6% lesselectricity thancontrol

    groups.However,thesavingsdecreasedwithtime,suggestingthattheeffectoftherewardwasshort

    lived.Fourbuildingsand228familiesparticipatedinthestudy.

    Pallakand

    Cummings

    (1976)

    studied

    whether

    they

    could

    induce

    reduction

    in

    energy

    consumption

    throughsolicitingpubliccommitment.ThestudywascarriedoutinIowaCity,USA.Peoplewhosigneda

    publiccommitmentshowed lowerratesof increase ingasandelectricityusethanthosewhosigneda

    privatecommitmentorthoseinthecontrolgroup.

    Energy savings can also be motivated by assisting consumers with goal setting. Becker (1978) gave

    households a relativelydifficult goal (20%) or a relativelyeasy goal (2%) to reduce electricity use. All

    householdsreceived informationonwhichappliancesusedmoreelectricity,butonlysomehouseholds

    receivedconsumptionfeedback.Onlythehouseholdsthathadthedifficultgoalandreceivedfeedback

  • 8/3/2019 Role of Behavioural Economics in Energy and Climate Policy

    13/31

    EPRGWP1130

    11

    hadasignificantchange inelectricityconsumption(15%savings).Thisstudy involved100familiesthat

    livedinidenticaltownhousesincentralNewJersey,USA.

    Mostoftheresearchconductedonnonpecuniary incentiveshas involvedsmallsamples,and it isnot

    clear if these interventions are scalable. Most of the studies do not monitor interventions for a

    prolongedperiodoftime,anditisnotcertainifhabitswerechangedorbehaviourseventuallyreturned

    to preintervention norms. Where followup studies were conducted, it was typically found that the

    behaviouralchangeswerenotsustained. It isworthnotingthat intheFormerSovietUnioncountries,

    wherepricesignalswere ideologically frownedupon,prizeswereusedextensivelytopromoteenergy

    saving via goal setting, competition, and public appeals. However, anecdotal evidence suggests that

    theseincentives,evenifinitiallyheeded,becameeventuallyineffectivewherepricesignalswereabsent.

    3.4. InfluenceofSocialNormsonHouseholdEnergyConsumptionSocialnormsaffectindividualactionsthroughprovidingguidelinesastowhatisacceptableornormal

    behaviour. Some behavioural interventions aim to influence consumer energy consumption through

    increasing awareness of social norms. A number of studies have attempted to change energy

    consumptionofhouseholdsthroughprovidingthemwiththeconsumptioninformationoftheirpeers,as

    anindicatorofsocialnorms.

    Nolan et al. (2008) left door hangers at 271 homes in San Marcos, California, USA, with different,

    randomly assigned energy conservation messages. Door hangers that compared a given households

    energydemand

    to

    that

    of

    their

    neighbours

    led

    to

    10%

    more

    energy

    demand

    reduction

    than

    door

    hangersthatgaveonlyenergyconservationtips.Schultzetal.(2007)leftdoorhangersin286homesin

    thesamecity.Residentswhohadlowerenergyconsumptionthanaverageincreasedconsumption(the

    boomerangeffect).However,thiseffectwaseliminatedwhenasmileyfacewasdrawnnexttotheir

    energyconsumption.Theauthorpostulatesthatthesmileyfacewas interpretedasanormativesignal

    andresultedinbehaviouralchange.

    While the above studies were based on small sample sizes, their findings were consistent with the

    results of a program run by OPOWER, one of the largest randomized field experiments in history.

    OPOWERmailedhomeenergyreportletterstocustomers,comparingtheirenergyusagetothatoftheir

    neighbors.These

    letters

    also

    gave

    customers

    energy

    conservation

    tips.

    OPOWER

    ran

    aprogram

    for

    23

    utilities,including6ofthelargest10utilitiesintheUSAand600,000households.Thestudyfoundthat

    the interventionreducedaverageenergydemandby1.11%to2.78% fromthebaselineusage (Allcott

    andMullainathan2010).

    Itisnotclearifthebehaviouralchangesresultingfromtheseinterventionscanbesustainedinthelong

    run, or if the novelty of the social comparison would eventually wear off. Costa and Kahn (2010)

    analyzedtheOPOWERdataandfound,infact,thattheprogrameffectswereheterogeneous:whilethe

    electricity conservation nudge of providing feedback to households on their own and peers home

  • 8/3/2019 Role of Behavioural Economics in Energy and Climate Policy

    14/31

    EPRGWP1130

    12

    electricity usage works with political liberals, it backfires with political conservatives. The largescale

    OPOWERexperimentgainedconsiderablemediapublicityandwashailedbyleadingpolicymakersasa

    testament that behavioural economics should motivate viable policy alternatives. However,

    Loewenstein and Ubel (2010) cautioned against being overly reliant on these types of interventions,

    pointing out that the energy savings they generated were very small. They stated that traditional

    mechanisms, such as a carbon tax would be far more effective even if politically more difficult to

    implement,astheywouldincreasethepriceofcarboninlinetoitstruecost.

    3.5. InfluenceofInformationProvisionProviding energysaving information and energyconsumption feedback is successful in eliciting

    behavioural changes. The residential electricity market has traditionally suffered from asymmetric

    information.Traditional

    electricity

    meters

    provide

    cumulative

    consumption

    information

    and

    individuals

    donotalwaysknowwhichappliancesconsumemostelectricityandwhen.Newtechnologies,suchas

    smartappliancesandsmartmetersprovideinnovativewaystoaccessconsumptioninformation.Having

    accesstodisaggregatedconsumption informationthroughavarietyofmedia (i.e.the Internet)makes

    electricity consumption more tractable and easier to manage. Information asymmetry is typically

    assumedtobeamarketfailure,and isstudiedundertheparadigmoftraditionaleconomics.However,

    behaviouraleconomicsfindsthatnotonlyistheinformationimportant,butalsothewayitispresented

    orframed.

    Ifthecommunicationof informationtakes intoaccountthebehavioural failuresandheuristicdecision

    making

    of

    consumers,

    messages

    can

    be

    crafted

    to

    solicit

    a

    sharper

    behavioural

    response.

    Since

    individualsareaffectedmorebysalientinformationratherthansimplyaccurateinformation,thenvisual

    cuesandvividdescriptionsareimportant.Forexample,ThalerandSunstein(2008)foundthatwhenthe

    energycompany inSouthernCaliforniagave itscustomersanAmbientOrbthatglowed inredwhen

    energy consumption was high (salient signal), orb users reduced peak energy demand by 40%. With

    largescale deployment of new technologies that provide innovative ways of communicating

    information, providing appropriate vivid cues will become increasingly important. If consumers are

    affectedby lossesmorethangains,theeffectivemessageshouldstressmoneywastedbymissingthe

    opportunity to save energy rather than emphasizing energysaving behavioural change. The former

    formulationprovidesthesameinformationbutismoreeffective,althoughlesswelcomed,especiallyby

    elderlyand

    vulnerable

    customers.

    Thecredibilityandtrustworthinessofinformationsourcesmakesadifference.CraigandMcCann(1978)

    showed that when consumers received identical letters giving energy conservation advice but on

    different letterheads, the letter from the local energy commission had higher impact than the letter

    from the local utility. In communication, simple, salient, and personally relevant information is more

    effectivethandetailed,technical,andfactualinformation(WilsonandDowlatabadi2007).

  • 8/3/2019 Role of Behavioural Economics in Energy and Climate Policy

    15/31

    EPRGWP1130

    13

    3.6. ChoiceofElectricitySuppliersorTariffsThe

    unregulated

    monopolist

    does

    not

    have

    the

    incentive

    to

    keep

    prices

    down.

    Competition

    between

    suppliersresults in lowerprices if thebuyersareabletoshop forthebestdealandchangesuppliers.

    However,thereare indicationsthatwhenpresentedwithmanysuppliers,consumersdonotswitch. If

    consumersdonotshoparoundforthebestsuppliers,openingmarketsthatwereformerlyregulatedcan

    reduce welfare, if the incumbent supplier increases prices above those that were set by regulators

    (Brennan 2006). Behavioural economics explains this phenomenon by status quo bias, and/or

    informationoverload.

    Traditionaleconomicsoftenassumesthatinformationiscostlessandfreelyavailable.Butwhenallowing

    for cost of searching and obtaining information, traditional economics would explain consumers

    unwillingnessto

    choose

    suppliers

    by

    the

    fact

    that

    search

    is

    costly

    (electricity

    bills

    are

    notoriously

    hard

    to

    read)andthattheproduct(electricity) ishomogenous.WilsonandWaddamsPrice(2005)providethe

    behaviouralexplanation thatconsumersare irrationaland fail to switch.Thishas implications for the

    offeringofmorechoicestoenergyconsumers,whichmightbefacilitatedbythedeploymentofsmart

    meters. Having more choices implies more opportunities for mistakes to be made by customers by

    selecting inappropriatesuppliersfortheirneeds.Itmayalsoreduceswitchingfrom incumbentsdueto

    informationoverload.

    4. Energy-EfficientInvestmentsandPurchasesIncreasing

    energy

    efficiency

    can

    play

    asignificant

    role

    in

    reducing

    overall

    energy

    consumption

    and

    associatedemissions.Efficiency investments involveonetime, large monetarycostsbut result incost

    savings over the long run through lower energy consumption. It has been shown that efficiency

    improvements could result in substantial longrun cost savings. However the energy efficiency gap

    puzzle remains. The gap normally refers to the difference between the observed level of energy

    efficiencyandwhatisconsideredoptimalenergyuse(Jaffeetal.2004).Sometimestheenergyefficiency

    gapis illustratedbycomparingthemarketdiscountrateandtheimplicitdiscountrateimputedfrom

    appliance purchase decisions, taking into account cost of appliances and their energy efficiency

    (Hausman 1979). Studies have shown that the implicit discount rate is between 25 and 100 percent

    (Sanstadetal.2006;Train 1985).Belowwediscussbehaviouralexplanationsof theenergyefficiency

    gapand

    effectiveness

    of

    policy

    interventions

    that

    aim

    to

    tackle

    it.

    4.1. BehaviouralExplanationsfortheEnergyEfficiencyGapItisnotcostlesstoassesshowanewtechnologyfitsintooneshome,ortofindareliablesupplierand

    installer.Furthermore, futureenergypricesand futuresavingsareuncertain.The transactioncostsof

    newtechnologyadoptioncanstillbesignificant,sothatthepurchasepriceisonlythelowerboundof

    adoptioncost (JaffeandStavins1994).Belowwediscusssomeofthebehaviouralexplanationsofthe

    efficiencypuzzle.

  • 8/3/2019 Role of Behavioural Economics in Energy and Climate Policy

    16/31

    EPRGWP1130

    14

    Time inconsistency. Individuals have a high discount rate for future cost savings, but a smalldiscountrateforlargeinitialinvestmentoutlay.Alternatively,individualsmaywanttoinvestin

    energyefficiencybutareprocrastinating,ordonothavethedisciplinetosavemoneytopayfor

    theinitialinvestment.

    Endowmenteffect.Householdsareattachedtotheappliancestheycurrentlyown,andarenotwilling to replace them, even if it is efficient to do so. This can partly be rationalized by the

    certainty that the new equipment works, against the risk of problems in installation or

    operation.

    Salience. Yates and Aronson (1983) suggest that individuals place disproportional weight onvivid

    and

    observable

    factors.

    This

    tendency

    may

    result

    in

    placing

    too

    much

    emphasis

    on

    initial

    investment costs, and underinvestment in energy efficiency. They recommend giving salient

    examples of energy savings and state that energysaving advice should demonstrate the

    experienceofahighlyefficienthouseholdforthemessagetobebetterretained.

    Heuristics.KemptonandMontgomery(1982)useasurveyandfindthatconsumersusesimpleheuristics to assess their energy consumption, which leads to systematic underinvestment in

    energyefficiency.Theyconcludethatthis istheexampleofboundedrationality,whenpeople

    adaptknownmethodstosolvingnewproblems,eveniftheknownmethodsarenotoptimalfor

    thenewsituation.Thismaybetheoptimalstrategy,asitavoidstheeffortofanalyzingthenew

    situation(Simon

    1955).

    For

    example,

    families

    used

    current

    energy

    prices

    to

    calculate

    expected

    savings fromefficiency investment, thusnot taking intoaccount futureprice increases.When

    comparing consumption over the years, households compared their highest utility bills to

    estimatetheirconsumptiontotals.Kemptonetal.(1992)showsthatconsumerssystematically

    miscalculatepaybackperiodsforairconditioners,andthisleadstooverconsumptionofenergy.

    4.2. IncentivesforEnergy-EfficientInvestmentsSinceenergyefficiency investmentsaresubject tomarketandbehavioural failures,policymakersand

    utilities have devised various incentives to overcome them. Behavioural economics can shed light on

    whichefficiency

    promoting

    incentives

    are

    more

    effective.

    Since

    high

    upfront

    costs

    appear

    to

    discourage

    efficiencyinvestments,policymakersoftenattempttoincentivizetheseinvestmentsthroughtaxcredits

    orefficiencyprogramsadministeredbyutilities.

    Income tax credits or deductions have been used in the USA as an instrument to encourage energy

    efficientinvestments.Howeverevidenceoftheireffectivenessismixed.TheU.S.EnergyTaxActof1978

    (ETA78) provided a federal tax credit for residential energyefficiency investments and encouraged

    investment in solar, wind, and geothermal energy technologies. Carpenter and Chester (1988)conductedasurveywithover5,000respondents fromtheUSA.Around89%oftherespondentswere

  • 8/3/2019 Role of Behavioural Economics in Energy and Climate Policy

    17/31

    EPRGWP1130

    15

    awareofETA78sfederaltaxcredit,butonlyaroundonethirdofthemfiledthisclaim.Outofthosewho

    did file the claim, 94% were going to make the investment even without tax incentives (free riding).

    However, Hassett and Metcalf (1995) found that tax credits do encourage efficiency investmentsa

    changeof10percentagepointsinthetaxpriceoftheinvestmentincreasesprobabilityofinvestmentby

    24%. Williams and Poyer (1996) found that tax credits have a significant effect in improving energy

    conservation,evenwithfreeriders.Theysuggestthatthismaybeduetospillovers,assomehouseholds

    maketheinvestmentbecauseofthetaxcredit,butthenfailtofileforthecreditwhenitcomestimeto

    file their taxes. This explanation is consistent with timevarying discount rates and tendency to

    procrastinate.

    In summer 2011, the UK government ran a pilot trial of the Green Deala scheme to encourage

    homeowners to upgrade their buildings by installing energysaving improvements at no upfront cost.

    Repayments

    for

    these

    investments

    would

    be

    made

    via

    a

    charge

    paid

    from

    savings

    made

    on

    a

    customers

    energybills.The trial tookplace in theLondonboroughofSutton,and involved400households that

    respondedtotheadvertisement.Ofthe126householdsthateventuallyreceivedhomeenergyaudits,

    only60signedupforthescheme,evenifthesubsidyrepresented40%.Thehouseholdsthatdidsignup

    fortheschemeindicatedthatfinancialincentiveswerenottheprimarymotivation(BioRegional2011).

    Studiesshowthatevenwhenautilityofferedtosubsidize93%ofthecostofhomeinsulation,consumer

    takeupvariedfrom1%to20%,dependinghowthesubsidywascommunicatedtotheconsumer(Stern

    et al. 1985). Stern (2000) suggests that incentives and interventions interact, and thejoint effect of

    combiningthemisoftenbiggerthanthesumofeachinterventiononitsown.

    4.3. AppliancestandardsandbuildingcodesIf consumers indeed make biased decisions in their efficiency investment, and they do not take

    operating cost into consideration, then appliance standards may be welfare enhancing. Mandatory

    appliancestandardscandefinetheminimumenergyefficiencystandardthatwillberequiredbylawfor

    agivenappliance.Buildingcodeswoulddefinecertainminimumefficiencycharacteristicsthatbuildings

    shouldhave.Inessence,consumerswillnotbeabletochoose inefficientappliancesorhomes,asthey

    will not be on the market. Mandatory standards and codes will encourage manufacturers to provide

    better

    energy

    efficiency

    in

    the

    context

    where

    it

    is

    not

    the

    most

    salient

    feature

    for

    consumers

    (DEFRA

    2010).

    Koomeyetal.(1999)foundthateachdollarofU.S.federalexpenditureonimplementingtheappliance

    energyefficiencystandardscontributed$165ofnetpresentvaluedsavings to theU.S.economyover

    the1990to2010period.Theyestimatedtheaveragebenefit/costratiosfortheseefficiencystandards

    tobeabout3.5 fortheUSAasawhole.Howeverhouseholdsthatare lowapplianceusersmayprefer

    lessefficientappliances,andsufferwelfarelosseswhenstandardsareimposed(Morss1989).

  • 8/3/2019 Role of Behavioural Economics in Energy and Climate Policy

    18/31

    EPRGWP1130

    16

    5. PublicGoodsandPro-EnvironmentalBehaviourSupporting

    green

    energy

    and

    combating

    global

    warming

    is

    apublic

    good.

    Behavioural

    economics

    can

    helpunderstandwhyandunderwhichcircumstancesindividualsarewillingtocontributetothesepublic

    goodsvoluntarily.Thesecontributionsmaybemonetary(i.e.whenindividualspayapremiumforgreen

    energy)ornonmonetary(i.e.whenindividualsactproenvironmentallybutsacrificetheircomfort).

    5.1. ProvisionPointMechanismsandGreenEnergyBehaviouraleconomicsclaimsthatmany individualsareconditionalcooperatorsandvalue fairness.

    Individualswouldbewillingtocontributetopublicgoodsiftheyknowthatothersdonotfreerideand

    also

    contribute

    (this

    is

    what

    a

    tax

    system

    can

    achieve

    formally).

    In

    essence,

    the

    difference

    between

    a

    behaviouralexplanationandatraditionalexplanation is thatunder the former, individualsdonot

    wanttofreeride,theyarejustconcernedthatothersdoandthinkthatthisisnotfair;underthelatter,

    individualshaveaninnatetendencytofreeride,andthatwillbethecaseevenifotherscontribute.

    Moskovitz (1992, 1993a, 1993b) argued that customers would voluntarily sign up and pay higher

    electricityratesiftheadditionalmoneycollectedwereearmarkedtosupportrenewableenergyprojects

    andenvironmentalactivities.Sincethen,utilitiesinmanyjurisdictionshaveofferedgreenenergytariffs.

    These green tariffs represent a contribution to public good. If individuals are indeed willing to make

    voluntary contributions, public policy may harness this tendency through devising mechanisms that

    makethese

    contributions

    more

    likely.

    Public economics has dealt with the problem of underprovision of public goods through such

    mechanismsastaxes,andprovisionpointmechanisms(PPMs).UnderPPMs,individualsmakevoluntary

    contributionstoaproject,withdisclaimerthatifthenecessarybenchmarkamountisnotcollected,the

    contributionswillberefunded.Rondeauetal.(2005)comparedthevoluntarycontributionmechanism

    (VCM)withthePPMinthelaboratoryandinasmallfieldexperiment,andfoundthatthePPMwasable

    to achieve higher contributions. Traverse City Light and Power in Michigan, USA, successfully built a

    windmillusingthismechanism(Holt1996a);thecityofFortCollins inColoradoraisedmoneyforthree

    separatewindturbinesusingit(Holt1996b).

    Roseetal.(2002)usedlaboratoryandfieldexperimentstotesttheuseofaPPMtofinancearenewable

    energyprogramrunbyNiagaraMohawkPowerCorporation intheUSA.Inthe laboratoryexperiment,

    the PPM increased the rate of participation in a green energy program substantially above that of a

    treatmentgroup.WhenthePPMwastestedinthefield,signupratesobservedweremuchhigherthan

    thosefromothergreenpricingprogramsthatsolicitvoluntarycontributions.

    Oneoftheproblemswithsellinggreenenergy insomejurisdictions(suchastheUK) isthatofproving

    additionality.Fixedtargetsforgivenquantitiesofrenewablessetbythegovernmentmeanthatbuying

    greenelectricitysimplyassignsrenewableoutputthatwouldhavebeenforthcominganywaytoagiven

  • 8/3/2019 Role of Behavioural Economics in Energy and Climate Policy

    19/31

    EPRGWP1130

    17

    groupofcustomers.Thisisbecauseallcustomerswillbemadetopayfortherenewableenergyanyway,

    regardlessofwhetheranymakevoluntaryorconditionalcontributions.

    5.2. CrowdingOutIntrinsicMotivationBehaviouraleconomicssuggeststhatifindividualsaremotivatedbythewarmgloweffect,thengiving

    monetary incentives would decrease their motivation for contributing to public goods. On the other

    hand, if individualspayafineforbehaviourthatdiminishespublicgoods,their intrinsicmotivationfor

    avoidingthisbehaviourmaybereduced.Thiscrowdingouthypothesisisintellectuallyappealing,but

    sofarfewstudieshavedemonstratedthiseffectempiricallyinthecontextofenergy.

    Jacobsenetal.(2010)usebillingdataofparticipantsandnonparticipantsinagreenelectricityprogram

    in Memphis, Tennessee. They find that households participating at the minimum threshold level

    increaseelectricityconsumptionby2.5%afterenrolling intheplan.Theyexplainthiswiththebuyin

    mentalityofthesehouseholds.Householdsguiltofgeneratinghighemissionsisreducedbybuyinginto

    green electricity at the minimum threshold, and payment for green electricity crowds out their

    motivation to reduce energy consumption. However, the effect was not large enough to offset the

    environmental benefit of paying for green electricity. Therefore the net effect was a reduction in

    emissions.

    5.3. VoluntaryContributionsandPublicImageIndividuals

    may

    be

    more

    likely

    to

    provide

    public

    goods

    if

    their

    contributions

    are

    publicly

    acknowledged.Thustokengifts(i.e.pins,mugs,andstickers)giveninexchangeforthecontributionare

    onewaytoencourageprovisions.

    Yoeli(2010)conductedalargescaleexperimentincollaborationwithPG&E,aregulatedinvestorowned

    utilityinNorthernCalifornia.Consumersweresent lettersinvitingthemtovolunteertoinstalladevice

    intheirhomesthatwouldallowtheutilitytocontroltheirairconditionerswhenelectricitysupplywas

    tight.Volunteershadtosignupfortheprogramonasheetthatwasdisplayedpubliclynearmailboxes.

    Thetreatmentgroupofhouseholdswasrequestedtowritetheirnamesonthesignupsheet,whilethe

    controlgroupofhouseholdsprovidedaunique,anonymousnumerical identifier.Householdsthathad

    to

    provide

    full

    identity

    information

    had

    a

    higher

    signup

    rate

    (however,

    the

    difference

    was

    not

    statisticallysignificant).

    5.4. PublicAppealstoConserveEnergyWhenincreasingpricesisconsideredsociallyorpoliticallyunacceptable,governmentshaveoccasionally

    resorted topublic appeals through themassmedia to induceenergyconservation. In theabsence of

    price signals, traditional economics would not expect public appeals to change behaviour, because

    individualswouldhavealreadyoptimizedtheirconsumptionchoicesforthegivenprice(andwouldfree

  • 8/3/2019 Role of Behavioural Economics in Energy and Climate Policy

    20/31

    EPRGWP1130

    18

    rideonotherscontributionstothepublicgoodofavoidingblackouts).However,behaviouraleconomics

    suggeststhatpublicappealsmayresultinincreasedawareness,andmayinducealtruisticallymotivated

    individuals to conserve more energy. In addition, some behavioural economists postulate that public

    appealsaffectsocialnorms.

    Reiss and White (2008) used householdlevel data on energy conservation in California during theenergycrisisof20002001.Dataconsistedofa fiveyearpanelofSan Diego Gas & ElectricCompany

    households utility bills. The sample consisted of 70,000 accounts. The prices increased sharply as a

    responsetothecrisiselectricitypricesmorethandoubled inaspanofthreemonths.Asaresult,the

    averagehouseholdelectricityuse fellmore than13% in60days.Following the initialprice increases,

    prices were rolled back and capped, and consumption rebounded to former levels. Subsequently, to

    avoid blackouts, the government used televised public appeals to urge households to reduce energy

    consumption.

    Public

    appeals

    were

    accompanied

    by

    energy

    saving

    advice.

    Public

    appeals

    resulted

    in

    a

    7%

    decline in energy use over six months. It should be noted that the households in California had

    heightenedawarenessoftheconsequencesofenergyshortages.Electricitypriceshaddoubled intheir

    recent memory. Therefore increasing prices was a credible threat for the consumers, and may have

    madethemmorereceptivetosocialappeals.

    IEA (2005)providessome internationalcasestudieswherepublicappealsweresuccessful in reducing

    energyconsumptionquickly.Someofthesuccessfulsolicitationstoreduceenergyoccurred in2001 in

    NewZealand,Australia,andBrazil,asaresultofshortfallscausedbydrought.AtthebeginningofNew

    Zealands 2001 shortfall, the government calculated that blackouts could be avoided if everybody

    reducedtheir

    consumption

    10%

    for

    10

    weeks.

    Thus

    10

    for

    10

    became

    the

    goal.

    The

    government

    distributed advice on how to obtain those savings but gave no incentives towards more efficient

    equipment or reduced bills. New Zealand employed public appeals through many extremely short

    remindersontelevision.Theconservationgoalwasreachedwithin6weeks.

    IEA(2005)statesthatwhileapriceincreaseisthefirstbestscenariotodealwithshortfalls,itmaynotbe

    politicallyfeasibleintheshortrun.Indesigningsuccessfulpublicappealstoreduceelectricityquickly,it

    is importanttoeducateconsumers,raisingtheirawareness,andmakingconservationamatterofcivil

    duty or prestige. This is particularly important inelectricity markets where richer, less pricesensitive

    consumers, by not reducing their consumption in a time of crisis, impose a negative consumption

    externalityon

    the

    poor.

    This

    is

    in

    contrast

    to

    most

    markets

    where

    consumption

    of

    the

    rich

    creates

    a

    positive consumption externality for the poor by allowing economies of scale to be exploited in

    productionandfacilitatingincreasedcompetition.

    5.5. PublicPolicyInstrumentsandEnvironmentalMoralsWhen economic activity has a negative externality, traditional economics suggests that following

    instrumentscanbeusedtocurbtheextentofharmfulbehaviour:taxes,restrictions(i.e.quotasorbans)

    and tradable permits. Taxes will discourage the harmful behavior through increasing its price, while

  • 8/3/2019 Role of Behavioural Economics in Energy and Climate Policy

    21/31

    EPRGWP1130

    19

    quotasdiscouragethebehaviorthroughrestrictingthequantityofthebadallowedoravailable.Taxes

    levied on the activity that generates negative externalities are called Pigovian taxes, and have

    traditionallybeenappliedtogoodssuchascigarettesandalcohol,ortoactivitiessuchaspollution.With

    tradablepermits, theoverallallowable levelofactivity isestablished,andthepermits forthisactivity

    areallocated toentities (usually firms).Theseallowancescanbe traded, sothat theentitieswith the

    lowestmarginalcostsofreducingtheactivitytowardstheallowable levelwillbetheonesthatdoso.

    Tradable allowances have been used to regulate fisheries and air pollution (Frey 2005; Tietenberg,

    2003). Traditional economics assumes that the difference among these three policy instruments is

    purelyintermsofeconomicandadministrativeefficiency.

    Psychologistsarguethatanother importantdistinctionbetweenthese instruments isthattheyvaryto

    the extent that they send the signals that crowd out intrinsic motivation. Frey (1999) calls intrinsic

    motivation forproenvironmentalactivityenvironmentalmoral.Heargues thatboth tradablepermits

    andtaxes

    will

    have

    two

    opposing

    effects

    on

    consumers

    an

    increase

    in

    price

    of

    activity

    will

    discourage

    behavior,butintrinsicenvironmentalmoralwillalsogodownasaresult(crowdingout).Hearguesthat

    environmentalmoralwillbereducedbytradablepermitsmorethanbytaxes:tradablepermitsmaybe

    viewedasbeingsimilarto indulgencessold forsins intheMiddleAges (Goodin,1994).Thesepermits

    mayconveyimpressionthatitisacceptabletosinaslongasonepaysthepriceforit.Freyalsoproposes

    thatbothlowandhighenvironmentaltaxesaremoreeffectivethanmediumleveltaxes.Hearguesthat

    withlowtaxes,consumersmayfeelthatprotectingenvironmentissomethingthathastobedonefrom

    moral obligation. On the other hand, high environmental taxes make harmful behavior prohibitively

    costly and dominate the crowdingout effect. Meanwhile medium environmental taxes result in

    crowdingout intrinsic motivation,butare insufficient to cause reduction inbehavior due toextrinsic

    motivation.

    Withtheclimatepolicythenegativeactivitytobecurtailediscarbonemissions.Taxes,restrictionsand

    tradablepermitsareusedasclimatepolicyinstruments,oftensimultaneously.EuropeanUnionhasthe

    largesttradableemissionsschemeintheworld(EUETS).Sofar,tradablepermitshavebeenassignedto

    the businesses, but not to final consumers. On the other hand, consumers in manyjurisdictions are

    subjecttocarbonpricesdirectly(effectivelyataxonemissions)andquotasindirectly(throughemissions

    standards).Unfortunately,theevidenceofcrowdingoutenvironmentalmoralduetothesignalingeffect

    of taxes and tradable permits has not been evaluated empirically, but studies have established the

    existenceofthephenomenoninthelaboratoryandfieldexperiments(FreyandJegen2001;Decietal.

    1999).However,

    its

    relevance

    to

    the

    actual

    behavior

    of

    consumers,

    as

    well

    as

    the

    magnitude

    of

    the

    effectremainsyettobedetermined.Meanwhile,publicperceptionoftheeffectoftheseinstrumentsis

    relevant for the political economy of public policy. To the extent that the public (particularly pro

    environmental activists) perceive that taxes and tradable permits are morally inferior because they

    seemtosanctionpollutionandemissions,governmentmay findpoliticallyharderto implement these

    mechanisms.

  • 8/3/2019 Role of Behavioural Economics in Energy and Climate Policy

    22/31

    EPRGWP1130

    20

    6. ConcludingRemarksEconomics

    studies

    how

    agents

    interact

    and

    allocate

    limited

    resources.

    In

    essence,

    economics

    is

    about

    behaviourbydefinition.Thetraditionaleconomicsdiscipline isbasedonbehaviouralassumptionsand

    axiomswhichallowmodelstoexplainthekeyphenomenaofinterestparsimoniouslybutwithsufficient

    clarity and accuracy. What is referred to as behavioural economics is the modification of traditional

    assumptions by drawing insights from psychology. Normally, behavioural economists start from

    observationsofhow individualsactuallybehaveandthenshowhowthisbehaviourviolatestraditional

    assumptions.Researchers thenproceedtooffermodelsbasedonalternativeassumptions thatbetter

    match theobservedphenomena.Behaviouraleconomics isagrowingand thriving field,butthereare

    sometheoreticalandempiricalgaps,manyofwhichwerementioned inthissurvey.Belowwediscuss

    someofthefuturedirectionsforbehaviouraleconomicsingeneral,anditsapplicationtoenergypolicy

    inparticular.

    Technological

    innovations,

    such

    as

    smart

    meters

    and

    smart

    appliances

    (and,

    in

    the

    future,

    widespreaduseofelectricvehicles)providenewways tostudyhowconsumerbehaviour responds to

    monetaryandnonmonetaryinterventions.

    Theoreticalandempiricalworkaimedatsortingouttheinteractionsofvariousbehaviouralphenomena.

    Behaviouralstudiesuncoveranomalies inbehaviourthatare inconsistentwithneoclassicaleconomics.

    However,theseanomaliesareoftenstudiedonanadhoc,casebycasebasis.Synthesizingbehavioural

    anomalieswithinaconsistent frameworkwouldbewelcome.Someof thequestions thatneed tobe

    addressed are the following: How do we disentangle behavioural explanations from conventional

    information effects? What are the interactions between the alternative behavioural insights and

    betweenbehavioural

    failures

    and

    market

    failures?

    For

    example,

    how

    do

    loss

    aversion

    and

    hyperbolic

    discount rates interact? Sorting out these interactions will be important in designing the optimal

    packageofbehaviourchangeinducingmeasurestoreduceorshiftenergyconsumption.

    Increased reliance on empirical research and impact evaluation. A lot of behavioural work has been

    basedonexperimentalstudies.However,ultimatelyeconomics isconcernedaboutactualbehaviourin

    markets, and some of the behavioural failures may no longer hold in a real market setting where

    behaviouralanomaliescancelout.Itis importanttoconductempiricalstudiesinordertouncoverhow

    relevantbehaviouralanomaliesaretothewaythemarketsworkinnonidealconditions.Thereseemsto

    be good scope for linking experimental work with empirical trials to see the extent to which strong

    experimentalresults

    can

    be

    reproduced

    in

    fieldwork.

    Studyoflargescaleinterventions.Alotofbehaviouralresearch,bothinexperimentalandfieldsettings,

    hasbeencarriedoutonsmallsamplesizes.Thisraisestwoconcerns:Howscalablearetheinterventions,

    and even if behavioural anomalies do exist, do they represent fundamental departure from the way

    individualsmakechoices,orisitonlyaboutthetailsofthebehaviouraldistribution?Iftheobservation

    is only regarding the tails of the distribution, how thick are the tails (Shogren et. al. 2008)? What is

    needed is much more attention to whole population interventions (i.e. the general rollout of smart

    meters)ornaturalexperiments(suchastheNewZealandscampaignforelectricitydemandreductionin

  • 8/3/2019 Role of Behavioural Economics in Energy and Climate Policy

    23/31

    EPRGWP1130

    21

    2001). Conducting randomized, controlled experiments involving largescale interventions would help

    provide answers to these questions. Widespread useof smart meters will make this sort of research

    mucheasiertoimplementinthefuture.

    Increasedstudyof the relationshipbetweenshortrunand longrunbehaviouralchanges.Whileshort

    runbehaviouralchangesmaybeextremelyusefuland important inenergy,thereare important issues

    todowithwhethercertainbehaviouralchangescanbesustainedoveraprolongedperiod.Withenergy

    consumption this may be important in designing the school curriculum with a view to increasing

    awarenessofenergyconservation,orinkeepingeffectiverepeatedinterventionsaimedatdealingwith

    successiveshortrunenergyshortages.Moststudiesofenergyconsumptionbehaviourdonotresample

    behaviouroveraprolongedperiod,butclearlytheremaybeopportunitiestodesignstudiestomonitor

    theeffectsoflongterminterventionsinthefuture.

    Integratingbehavioural economicswithin theframework of traditional economics. While behavioural

    economics provides insights about the way decisions are made, some of the departures from

    neoclassicaleconomicsarehardtoreconcilewithinthetraditionalframework.Forinstance,howdowe

    evaluate the impacts of policy if we cant make neoclassical assumptions about discounting? If

    individualsarereallyselfconflictedintheirevaluationofcostsandbenefitsovertimethenwhat isthe

    rationaleforthepolicymakerstocatertotheirfarsightedselvesratherthantheirnearsightedselves?

    Whilehyperbolicdiscountingisintellectuallyappealing,itmakesequilibriummodelsintractable.Further

    theoreticalworktoreconcilethesedifferencesisneeded.Institutionaleconomics(followingNorth1990)

    includesthestudyofthe impactoflongrunbehaviouraldifferencesbetweeneconomicagents.Itmay

    bethat

    behavioural

    economics

    is

    away

    of

    understanding

    how

    short

    run

    behaviour

    can

    be

    changed,

    whileinstitutionaleconomicsstudieshowlongbehaviouraldifferencescanbesustainedviathecreation

    ofappropriateinstitutions.Thusunderstandingtheprocessofinstitutionalizingbehaviouralchangemay

    allowareconciliationofmoretraditionaleconomicswithbehaviouraleconomics.Thismaybeimportant

    insuggestingwaysinwhichdifferencesinenergyconsumptionpercapitacurrentlyattributedtovaguely

    definedinstitutionaldifferences(suchasbetweentheUKandDenmark)canbenarrowed.

    Behavioural economics can provide valuable insights on how individuals make their decisions. These

    insightscanbeusedtoincreaseeffectivenessoftraditionalinterventionsinenergypolicy.However,itis

    important that behavioural interventions do not crowd out more effective traditional interventions

    (Loewensteinand

    Ubel

    2010).

    Behavioural

    economics

    should

    complement,

    not

    substitute

    for,

    more

    substantiveeconomicinterventions,suchasthosebasedoninfluencingenergypricing(e.g.viataxation)

    orenergyinvestment(e.g.viasubsidyschemes).

    Tocomebacktowherewebegan,behaviouraleconomicsseemsunlikelytoprovidethemagicbulletto

    reduceenergyconsumptionby the magnitude requiredby the IEA (2010) recommended450 climate

    policy scenario. However it does offer exciting new suggestions as to where to start looking for

    potentiallysustainablechanges inenergyconsumption. Italsomaybethat itsmostusefulrolewithin

    climatepolicy is inaddressing issuesofpublicperceptionof theaffordabilityofclimatepolicyand in

  • 8/3/2019 Role of Behavioural Economics in Energy and Climate Policy

    24/31

    EPRGWP1130

    22

    facilitatingthecreationofamoreresponsiveenergydemand,bettercapableofrespondingtoweather

    inducedchangesinrenewableelectricitysupply.

  • 8/3/2019 Role of Behavioural Economics in Energy and Climate Policy

    25/31

    EPRGWP1130

    23

    References

    AbadieA.

    and

    Gay,

    S.

    (2006).

    The

    impact

    of

    presumed

    consent

    legislation

    on

    cadaveric

    organ

    donation:

    a

    crosscountrystudy.JournalofHealthEconomics25(4):559620.

    Alexander,B.(2010).Dynamicpricing?Notsofast!Aresidentialconsumerperspective.TheElectricity

    Journal23(6):3949.

    Allcott,H.andMullainathan,S.(2010).BehavioralScienceandEnergyPolicy.Cambridge,MA:Ideas42.

    http://ideas42.iq.harvard.edu/publications/behavioral_science_energy_policy.

    Andreoni,J.(1988).Privatelyprovidedpublicgoodsinalargeeconomy:thelimitsofaltruism.Journalof

    PublicEconomics35:773.

    (1990).Impurealtruismanddonationstopublicgoods:atheoryofwarmglowgiving.Economic

    Journal100:464477.

    (2006).Philantropy.InHandbookoftheEconomicsofGiving,Altruism,andReciprocity,vol.2,ed.

    S.C.KolmandJ.Ythier),chapter18.Amsterdam:Elsevier.

    ArielyD.,Bracha,A.andMeier,S.(2007).Doinggoodordoingwell?Imagemotivationandmonetary

    incentivesinbehavingprosocially.AmericanEconomicReview99(1):544555.

    Ashraf,N.,Karlan,D.andYin,W.(2006).TyingOddysseustothemast:Evidencefromacommitment

    savingsproduct

    in

    the

    Phillippines.

    The

    Quarterly

    Journal

    of

    Economics

    121(2):

    635672.

    Becker,L.(1978).Jointeffectoffeedbackandgoalsettingonperformance:afieldstudyofresidential

    energyconservation.JournalofAppliedPsychology63(4):428433.

    BenzionU.,Rapoport,A.andYagil,J.(1989).Discountratesinferredfromdecisions:anexperimental

    study.ManagementScience35(3):270284.

    Bernheim,D.andRangel,A.(2007).Behavioralpubliceconomics:welfarepolicyanalysiswith

    nonstandarddecisionmakers.InBehavioralEconomicsandItsApplications,ed.P.DiamondandH.

    Vartiainen,777.Princeton,NJ:PrincetonUniversityPress.

    BioRegional(2011).HelpingtoinformtheGreenDeal:greenshootsfromPayasYouSave.London:

    BioRegionalSolutionsforResponsibility.

    Brennan, T. (2006).ConsumerPreferenceNot toChoose:MethodologicalandPolicy Implications. RFF

    DiscussionPaper0551.WashingtonDC:ResourcesfortheFuture(RFF).

    Brutscher, P. (2011a). Liquidity Constraints and High Electricity Use. Working Paper EPRG1106.

    Cambridge,UK:ElectricityPolicyWorkingGroup,CambridgeUniversity.

  • 8/3/2019 Role of Behavioural Economics in Energy and Climate Policy

    26/31

    EPRGWP1130

    24

    (2011b).PaymentMatters?AnExploratoryStudyintoPrePaymentElectricityMetering.Working

    PaperEPRG1108.Cambridge,UK:ElectricityPolicyWorkingGroup,CambridgeUniversity.

    Camerer,G.

    and

    Loewenstein,

    G.

    (2004).

    Behavioral

    economics:

    past,

    present,

    future.

    In

    Advances

    in

    BehavioralEconomics, ed. C. Camerer, G. Loewenstein and M. Rabin, 351. New York/Princeton, NJ:

    Sage/PrincetonUniversityPress.

    Campbell, C. and Kamlani, K. (1997). The reasons for wage rigidity: evidence from survey of firms.

    QuarterlyJournalofEconomics112:759789.

    CarpenterE.,andChesterT. (1988).The impactof state taxcreditsandenergypricesonadoptionof

    solarenergysystems.LandEconomics64(4):347355.

    Cook P. and Clotfelter, C. (1993). The peculiar scale economies of lotto.American Economic Review

    83(3):634643.

    Costa,D.andKahn,M.(2010).EnergyConservationNudgesandEnvironmentalist Ideology:Evidence

    fromaRandomizedResidentialElectricityFieldExperiment.NBERWorkingPaperNo.15939.Cambridge,

    MA:NationalBureauofEconomicResearch(NBER).

    Craig,S. andMcCann, J. (1978).Assessingcommunicationseffects onenergyconservation.Journalof

    ConsumerResearch5(2):8288.

    Deci, E., Koestner,R.,and Ryan,R. M. (1999). A metaanalytic review of experiments examining the

    effectsofextrinsicrewardsonintrinsicmotivation.PsychologicalBulletin125:62768.

    DEFRA. (2010). Behavioural Economics and EnergyUsing Products: Scoping Research onDiscounting

    Behaviour and Consumer Reference Points. London: Department for Environment, Food and Rural

    Affairs.

    Faruqui,A.(2010).Theethicsofdynamicpricing.ElectricityJournal23(6):1327.

    and Sergici, S. (2009). Household response to dynamic pricing of electricity a survey of the

    experimentalevidence.JournalofRegulatoryEconomics38(2):193225.

    Felder, A. (2010). The practical equity implications of advanced metering infrastructure. Electricity

    Journal.23(6):

    5664.

    Frederick, S., Loewenstein, G. and ODonoghue, T. (2004). Time discounting and time preference: a

    criticalreview.InAdvancesinBehavioralEconomics,ed.C.Camerer,G.LoewensteinandM.Rabin,162

    222.NewYork/Princeton,NJ:Sage/PrincetonUniversityPress.

    Frey,B.(1999).Moralityandrationalityinenvironmentalpolicy.JournalofConsumerPolicy22(4):395

    417.

    and Jegen, R. (2001). Motivation crowding theory: a survey of empirical evidence.Journal of

    EconomicSurveys15:589611.

  • 8/3/2019 Role of Behavioural Economics in Energy and Climate Policy

    27/31

    EPRGWP1130

    25

    (2005). Excise taxes: Economics, politics, and psychology. In Theory and Practice of Excise

    Taxation: Smoking, Drinking, Gambling, Polluting, and Driving, ed. S. Cnossen. Oxford, UK: Oxford

    UniversityPress.

    Friedman, L. (2002). Bounded rationality versus standard utilitymaximization: a test of energy price

    responsiveness. In Judgments, Decisions, and Public Policy, ed. R. Gowda and J. Fox, 138173.

    Cambridge,UK:CambridgeUniversityPress.

    andHausker,K.(1988).Residentialenergyconsumption:modelsofconsumerbehaviorandtheir

    implicationsforratedesign.JournalofConsumerPolicy11:287313.

    Gardner,G.andStern,P. (2002).EnvironmentalProblemsandHumanBehavior.Boston,MA:Pearson

    CustomPublishing.

    Gillingham,K.,

    Newell,

    G.

    and

    Palmer,

    K.

    (2006).

    Energy

    efficiency

    policies:

    aretrospective

    examination.

    AnnualReviewofEnvironmentandResources31:161192.

    ,Newell,G.andPalmer,K.(2009).EnergyEfficiencyEconomicsandPolicy.DiscussionPaper09

    13.WashingtonDC:ResourcesfortheFuture.

    Gneezy, U. and Rustichini, A. (2000). Pay enough or dont pay at all.QuarterlyJournalofEconomics

    115(3):791810.

    Goodin,R.(1994).Sellingenvironmentalindulgences.Kyklos47:57396.

    Hanser,P.

    (2010).

    On

    dynamic

    prices:

    aclash

    of

    beliefs?

    The

    Electricity

    Journal

    23(6):

    3638.

    Hassett,K.andMetcalf,G.(1995).Energytaxcreditsandresidentialconservationinvestment:evidence

    frompaneldata.JournalofPublicEconomics57(2):201217.

    Hausman,J.(1979).Individualdiscountratesandthepurchaseandutilizationofenergyusingdurables.

    BellJournalofEconomics10(1):3354.

    Heath,C.andSoll,J.(1996).Mentalbudgetingandconsumerdecision.JournalofConsumerResearch:

    AnInterdisciplinaryQuarterly23(1):4052.

    Heberlein,

    T.

    and

    Bishop,

    C.

    (1986).

    Assessing

    the

    validity

    of

    contingent

    valuation:

    Three

    field

    experiments.ScienceoftheTotalEnvironment56:99107.

    Holcomb,J.andNelson,P.(1992).Anotherexperimentallookatindividualtimepreference.Rationality

    andSociety4:199220.

    Holt,E.(1996a).Greenpricingandrestructuring,vol.3.Montpelier,VT:TheRegulatoryAssistance

    Project.Searchfromhttp://www.raponline.org/search.

    Holt, E. (1996b). Green pricing newsletter, vol. 4. Montpelier, VT: The Regulatory Assistance Project.

    Searchfromhttp://www.raponline.org/search.

  • 8/3/2019 Role of Behavioural Economics in Energy and Climate Policy

    28/31

    EPRGWP1130

    26

    IEA(2005).SavingElectricity inaHurry:DealingwithTemporaryShortfalls inElectricitySupplies.Paris:

    InternationalEnergyAgency.

    (2010).

    World

    Energy

    Outlook.

    Paris:

    International

    Energy

    Agency.

    Iyngar,S.andLepper,M.(2000).Whenchoiceisdemotivating:canonedesiretoomuchofagoodthing?

    JournalofPersonalityandSocialPsychology79(6):9951006.

    JacobsenG.,Kotchen,M.andVanderbergh,M.(2010).Thebehaviouralresponsetovoluntaryprovision

    ofanenvironmentalpublicgood:evidencefromresidentialelectricitydemand.NBERWorkingPaperNo.

    16608.Cambridge,MA:NationalBureauofEconomicResearch(NBER).

    Jaffe, A. and Stavins, R. (1994). The energy paradox and the diffusion of conservation technology.

    ResourceandEnergyEconomics16(2):91122.

    ,Newell,R.andStavins,R.(2004).TheEconomicsofenergyefficiency.InEncyclopediaofenergy,

    ed.C.Cleveland,pp7990.Amsterdam:Elsevier.

    Johnson,E.andGoldstein,D.(2003).Dodefaultssavelives?Science302:13381339.

    Julien,B.andSalanie,B.(2000).Estimatingpreferenceunderrisk:thecaseofracetrackbettors.Journal

    ofPoliticalEconomy108(3):503530.

    Kahneman,D.,Knetsch,J.andThaler,R.(1986).Fairnessasaconstraintinprofitseeking:entitlementin

    themarket.AmericanEconomicReview76(4):728741.

    andTversky,A.(1979).Prospecttheory:ananalysisofdecisionunderrisk.Econometrica47(2):

    263291.

    Kempton,W.,Feuermann,D.,McGarity,A.(1992).'Ialwaysturnitonsuper':userdecisionsaboutwhen

    andhowtooperateroomairconditioners.EnergyandBuildings18:177191.

    andMontgomery,L.(1982).Folkquantificationofenergy.Energy7(10):817827.

    Koomey, J., Mahler, S., Webber, C. and McMahon, J. (1999). Projected regional impacts of appliance

    efficiencystandardsfortheUSresidentialsector.Energy24(1):6984.

    Kotchen,M.,

    and

    Moore,

    M.,

    (2004).

    Private

    provision

    of

    environmental

    public

    goods:

    household

    participationingreenelectricityprograms.JournalofEnvironmentalEconomicsandManagement53(1):

    116.

    Laibson,D.(1997).Goldeneggsandhyperbolicdiscounting.QuarterlyJournalofEconomics112(2):443

    477.

    Letzler,R.(2007).ApplyingPsychologytoEconomicPolicyDesign:UsingIncentivePreservingRebatesTo

    IncreaseAcceptance of Critical Peak Electricity Pricing. Working Paper 162. Berkeley: Center for the

    StudyofEnergyMarkets,UniversityofCalifornia.

  • 8/3/2019 Role of Behavioural Economics in Energy and Climate Policy

    29/31

    EPRGWP1130

    27

    Loewenstein,G.andUbel,P.(2010).Economicsbehavingbadly,TheNewYorkTimes,July14.

    Maine Public Utilities Commission, (2007). Rebuttal Testimony of Stephen S. George, Ph. D., Nov. 9,

    2007,Maine

    Public

    Utilities

    Commission,

    Central

    Maine

    Power

    Company,

    Request

    for

    New

    Alternative

    RatePlan,DocketNo.2007 215.

    McClelland, L. and Cook, S. (1980). Promoting energy conservation in mastermetered apartments

    throughgroupfinancialincentives.JournalofAppliedSocialPsychology10(1):2031.

    Morss, F. (1989). The incidence of welfare losses due to appliance efficiency standards. The Energy

    Journal10(1):111118.

    Moskovitz,D. (1992).Renewableenergy:Barriersandopportunities:wallsandbridges.Report forthe

    WorldResourcesInstitute.

    .(1993a).Greenpricing:CustomerchoicemovesbeyondIRP.TheElectricityJournal6(8):4250.

    . (1993b). Green pricing: Experience and lessons learned. The Regulatory Assistance Project,

    Gardiner,ME.

    Nolan,J.,Schultz,P.,Cialdini,R.,Goldstein,N.andGriskevicius,V.(2008).Normativesocialinfluence is

    underdetected.PersonalityandPsychologyBulletin34(7):914923.

    North, D. (1990). Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge, UK:

    CambridgeUniversityPress.

    ODonoghueT.andRabin,M. (2000).Theeconomicsof immediategratification.JournalofBehavioral

    DecisionMaking13(2):233250.

    OFGEM (2011).WhatCanBehaviouralEconomicsSayaboutGBEnergyConsumers?London:Officeof

    GasandElectricityMarkets.

    Ostrom, E. (1998).Abehavioralapproach to the rationalchoice theoryofcollective action.American

    PoliticalScienceReview92(1):122.

    Pallak,MandCummings,N. (1976).Commitmentandvoluntaryenergyconservation.Personalityand

    Psychology

    Bulletin

    2(1):

    2731.

    Pesendorfer,W.(2006).Behavioraleconomicscomesofage:areviewessayonAdvances inBehavioral

    Economics.JournalofEconomicLiterature44(3):712721.

    Reiss,P.andWhite,M.(2008).Whatchangesenergyconsumption?Pricesandpublicpreasures.RAND

    JournalofEconomics39(3):636663.

    Rondeau,D.,Poe,G.andSchulze,W. (2005).VCMorPPM?Acomparisonoftheperformanceof two

    voluntarypublicgoodsmechanisms.JournalofPublicEconomics89(8):15811592.

  • 8/3/2019 Role of Behavioural Economics in Energy and Climate Policy

    30/31

    EPRGWP1130

    28

    Rose,S.,Clark,G.,Poe,D.,Rondeau,D.andSchulze,W.(2002).Fieldandlaboratorytestsofaprovision

    pointmechanism.ResourceandEnergyEconomics24:131155.

    Samuelson,W.

    and

    Zeckhauser,

    R.

    (1988).

    Status

    quo

    bias

    in

    decision

    making.

    Journal

    of

    Risk

    and

    Uncertainty1:759.

    Sanstad,A., Hanemann,M.and Auffhammer,M. (2006).Enduseenergyefficiency inapostcarbon

    Californiaeconomy:Policy issuesand researchfrontiers. The California Climate change Center at UC

    Berkeley,Berkeley,CA,USA.

    Schultz,P.,Nolan,J.,Cialdini,R.,Goldstein,N.andGriskevicius,V.(2007).Theconstructive,destructive,

    andreconstructivepowerofsocialnorms.PsychologicalScience18(5):429434.

    Shefrin,

    H.

    and

    Statman,

    M.

    (1985).

    The

    disposition

    to

    sell

    winners

    too

    early

    and

    ride

    losers

    too

    long:

    theoryandevidence.TheJournalofFinanceXL(3):777790.

    Shogren, F. and Taylor, L. (2008). On behavioralenvironmental economics.ReviewofEnvironmental

    EconomicsandPolicy2(1):2644.

    Simon,H.(1955).Abehaviouralmodelofrationalchoice.TheQuarterlyJournalofEconomics.69(1):99

    118.

    .(1986).Rationalityinpsychologyandeconomics.TheJournalofBusiness59(4):S209S224.

    Simshauser,P.andDowner,D. (2011).LimitedFormDynamicPricing:ApplyingShockTherapytoPeak

    DemandGrowth.WorkingPaperNo.24DynamicPricing.NorthSydney,Australia:AppliedEconomic

    andPolicyResearch,AGLEnergyLtd.

    Stern, P. (2000). Toward a coherent theory of environmentally significant behavior.Journal of Social

    Issues56(3):407424.

    ,Aronson,E.,Darley,J.,Hill,D.,Hirst,E.,Kempton,W.andWilbanks,T.(1985).Theeffectiveness

    ofincentivesforresidentialenergyconservation.EvaluationReview10(2):147176.

    Steven,K.,Rose,A.,Clark,J.,Poe,G.,Rondeau,D.andSchulze,W.(2002).Theprivateprovisionofpublic

    goods: testsofaprovisionpointmechanism for fundinggreenpowerprograms.ResourceandEnergy

    Economics24:131155.

    Thaler, R. (1980). Toward a positive theory of consumer choice.Journal of Economic Behavior and

    Organization1(1):3960.

    .(1981).Someempiricalevidenceofdynamicinconsistency.EconomicsLetters8(3):201207.

    .(1999).Mentalaccountingmatters.JournalofEconomicBehaviorandOrganization12(3):183

    206.

  • 8/3/2019 Ro