19
ORIGINAL PAPER Risk Attitudes and the Incumbency Advantage David L. Eckles Cindy D. Kam Cherie L. Maestas Brian F. Schaffner Ó Springer Science+Business Media New York 2013 Abstract Explanations for the incumbency advantage in American elections have typically pointed to the institutional advantages that incumbents enjoy over chal- lengers but overlook the role of individual traits that reinforce this bias. The institutional advantages enjoyed by incumbents give voters more certainty about who incumbents are and what they might do when (and if) they assume office. We argue that these institutional advantages make incumbents particularly attractive to risk-averse individuals, who shy away from uncertainty and embrace choices that provide more certainty. Using data from 2008 and 2010 Cooperative Congressional Election Study, we show that citizens who are more risk averse are more likely to support incumbent candidates, while citizens who are more risk accepting are more likely to vote for challengers. The foundations of the incumbency advantage, we find, lie not only in the institutional perks of office but also in the individual minds of voters. Keywords Incumbency advantage Á Risk aversion Á Voter choice Á Elections Á Prospect theory D. L. Eckles Department of Risk Management and Insurance, University of Georgia, Athens, GA 30602, USA e-mail: [email protected] C. D. Kam Department of Political Science, Vanderbilt University, Nashville, TN 37203, USA C. L. Maestas Department of Political Science, Florida State University, Tallahassee, FL 32306, USA B. F. Schaffner (&) Department of Political Science, University of Massachusetts, Amherst, Amherst, MA 01002, USA e-mail: [email protected] 123 Polit Behav DOI 10.1007/s11109-013-9258-9

Risk Attitudes and the Incumbency Advantage

  • Upload
    brian-f

  • View
    221

  • Download
    4

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Risk Attitudes and the Incumbency Advantage

ORI GIN AL PA PER

Risk Attitudes and the Incumbency Advantage

David L. Eckles • Cindy D. Kam •

Cherie L. Maestas • Brian F. Schaffner

� Springer Science+Business Media New York 2013

Abstract Explanations for the incumbency advantage in American elections have

typically pointed to the institutional advantages that incumbents enjoy over chal-

lengers but overlook the role of individual traits that reinforce this bias. The

institutional advantages enjoyed by incumbents give voters more certainty about

who incumbents are and what they might do when (and if) they assume office. We

argue that these institutional advantages make incumbents particularly attractive to

risk-averse individuals, who shy away from uncertainty and embrace choices that

provide more certainty. Using data from 2008 and 2010 Cooperative Congressional

Election Study, we show that citizens who are more risk averse are more likely to

support incumbent candidates, while citizens who are more risk accepting are more

likely to vote for challengers. The foundations of the incumbency advantage, we

find, lie not only in the institutional perks of office but also in the individual minds

of voters.

Keywords Incumbency advantage � Risk aversion � Voter choice �Elections � Prospect theory

D. L. Eckles

Department of Risk Management and Insurance, University of Georgia, Athens, GA 30602, USA

e-mail: [email protected]

C. D. Kam

Department of Political Science, Vanderbilt University, Nashville, TN 37203, USA

C. L. Maestas

Department of Political Science, Florida State University, Tallahassee, FL 32306, USA

B. F. Schaffner (&)

Department of Political Science, University of Massachusetts, Amherst, Amherst, MA 01002, USA

e-mail: [email protected]

123

Polit Behav

DOI 10.1007/s11109-013-9258-9

Page 2: Risk Attitudes and the Incumbency Advantage

Incumbency advantage is the established rule in US elections. A substantial body of

research has developed to help explain why this incumbency advantage exists. Most

explanations center on institutions and elite behavior in the US House. Incumbents,

the scholarship suggests, are re-elected because they work hard to satisfy their

constituents while in office (Fenno 1977, 1978; Cain et al. 1987), because they

enjoy franking privileges (Cover and Brumberg 1982), because they can more

effectively raise funds (Jacobson and Kernell 1983; Abramowitz 1991), or because

they can deter high-quality challengers (Stone et al. 2004, 2010). However,

incumbency advantages have grown over the past decades for executive office-

holders as well, which suggests that legislative institutions alone are not a sufficient

explanation for the increased incumbent vote shares and reduced competition for

office (Ansolabehere and Snyder 2002). Further, scholars note that while

incumbents are ‘‘advantaged’’ in terms of vote margin, the margins do not

necessarily translate to a greater probability of winning because they are

accompanied by greater vote volatility (Ansolabehere and Snyder 2002; Jacobson

1987a). The incumbency advantage in US elections may be the norm, but such

advantage is neither inevitable nor guaranteed.

How might we understand the perplexing dual phenomenon of increased vote

margins with punctuations of highly volatile elections? The most plausible elite-side

explanation centers on candidate entry decisions, where strong challengers respond

to national and local conditions, thereby creating volatility in otherwise placid

districts (Jacobson and Kernell 1983; Jacobson 1989). Voters, from this perspective,

respond to the slate of candidates presented to them by elites but little attention is

paid to how mechanisms internal to voters might promote stasis or volatility, or to

how voters may differ amongst themselves in their reactions to these slates. We

suggest that understanding modern era incumbency vote patterns requires unpack-

ing the individual characteristics of voters to understand who contributes to support

for the incumbent and who might be responsive to the entry of a challenger. In

contrast to the elite-centered literature, we highlight the extent to which

heterogeneity in the electorate’s willingness to tolerate risk can help explain some

portion of incumbency advantage. Incumbents receive a greater share of media

attention compared to challengers (Prior 2006) and rely on risk-averting messages

about their past experience, governing ability, and district service (e.g., Druckman

et al. 2009). Challengers offer a risky alternative to an experienced incumbent, but

we argue that for some voters—particularly those who are risk tolerant—a risky

choice may be more appealing than a safe one.

Incumbents, Challengers, and Uncertainty in Political Decision-Making

Since Erikson’s seminal article in 1971, political scientists have amassed a

substantial body of research studying the incumbency advantage (see Carson and

Roberts 2011 for a review). Early explanations of the incumbency advantage

focused on the incumbent’s use of office to maximize the likelihood of re-election

through assisting constituents (i.e., pork barrel politics), generating increased

general visibility, and better fundraising opportunities (Erikson 1971). Further,

Polit Behav

123

Page 3: Risk Attitudes and the Incumbency Advantage

Erikson (1971) points out that the incumbent, by definition, is likely to be a high

quality candidate, and therefore more likely to be re-elected. Since Erikson (1971),

numerous scholars have considered these rationales, and have put forth alternative

explanations for the incumbency advantage. Hood and McKee (2010, p. 346)

provide a useful summary of these explanations:

There are numerous (often complementary) explanations for the incumbency

advantage: credit claiming, position taking, and advertising (Mayhew 1974),

constituency service (Fiorina 1977), declining party attachments (Ferejohn

1977), strategic retirements (Cox and Katz 2002) and strategic challenger

entry (Cox and Katz 1996; Jacobson and Kernell 1983), and the declining

ability of challengers to raise enough money for competitive campaigns

(Abramowitz 1991).

In addition to candidate-specific explanations, several system-level explanations

have been offered for the incumbency advantage. McKelvey and Riezman (1992)

suggest that the incumbency advantage is an artifact of the seniority systems

employed in legislatures. Recently, scholars have also examined general changes in

long-term (Ansolabehere et al. 2000) and short-term (Ansolabehere and Snyder

2002; Desposato and Petrocik 2003) conditions (e.g., economic events) and

redistricting (Cox and Katz 2002; Hood and McKee 2010) as components of

incumbency advantage. Evidence that incumbency has grown similarly in executive

offices and in sub-national legislatures suggests there might be reasons beyond

redistricting or other institutional perquisites enjoyed by legislators (Ansolabehere

and Snyder 2002).

Largely missing from the study of incumbency advantage are voter-level

explanations. By this, we mean specifically that relatively little work has sought to

understand the psychology of the decision to vote for an incumbent rather than a

challenger. Instead, early analyses of congressional voters explored trends in

defections of partisan voters (e.g., Ferejohn 1977; Jacobson 1987b) and tested the

incumbent-level and system-level explanations using data from individual voters

(e.g., Abramowitz 1980; Fiorina 1977, 1981). Scholars found evidence in individual

and aggregate data that the importance of party in vote choice declined over time,

with challenger partisans defecting to vote for incumbents (Ferejohn 1977; Jacobson

1987b). Individual voters preferred incumbents to challengers because they were

more familiar and visible (Abramowitz 1980; Campbell 1983; Jacobson 1981; Mann

and Wolfinger 1980), had positive reputations (Abramowitz 1975; Campbell 1983;

Jacobson 1981), and were attentive to constituents’ needs (Abramowitz 1980; Cover

and Brumberg 1982; Cain et al. 1984; Fiorina 1977, 1981; Yiannakis 1981).1 Overall,

it appeared that voters generally lacked knowledge of congressional candidates and

their positions but whatever limited knowledge they held centered on incumbents.

Later scholarship tied individual-level awareness and assessment of congressio-

nal incumbents to the presence of quality challengers, thus challenger entry patterns

were central to explaining the individual-level findings (Jacobson and Kernell 1983

1 There is some debate as to the size and source of individual level evidence of incumbency advantage in

the early literature (see Born 1986; Eubanks 1985; Fiorina 1981; Johannes and McAdams 1981).

Polit Behav

123

Page 4: Risk Attitudes and the Incumbency Advantage

Jacobson 1981; Mann and Wolfinger 1980; Ragsdale 1981).2 Prior (2006) argued

that the spread of local television stations in the 1960s that offered favorable media

coverage to incumbents increased the incumbency advantage. Television expansion

opened up opportunities for incumbents to credit claim via televised media (Cook

1989) which in turn translated into greater voter support (Prior 2006). In these and

in earlier voter studies, the source of incumbency advantage could be seen through

attitudes and behaviors of voters; the aggregate patters arose as, en masse, voters

responded to the choices presented to them by elites.

With a few notable exceptions, there has been a marked absence of studies that

consider whether attributes internal to the voter shape the importance of incumbency.

Early studies suggested that patterns of aggregate dealignment might be the source of

incumbency advantage (Erikson 1972; Cover 1977) and subsequent tests at the

individual-level found support for this argument as incumbency cues were more

important for weak partisans than strong partisans (Nelson 1978; Cain et al. 1984,

Romero and Sanders 1994). These findings were certainly consistent with Zaller’s (1992)

evidence suggesting that individual-level political awareness influences both receipt and

acceptance of countervailing information from the challenger in congressional elections.

In a similar vein, Prior’s (2006) work suggests a complementary individual-level attribute

that shapes reception and acceptance of campaign information: education. Exposure to

pro-incumbent messaging on local television stations was much more influential for

voters with little education than for voters highly educated. The results suggest the

incumbency advantage might arise not only from biases in the availability of information

but also on individual susceptibility to the information at hand. We argue there has been

little systematic investigation of voter-level explanations beyond these three factors

(partisanship, awareness, and education). The paucity of voter-level psychological

explanations of the incumbency advantage is an important lacuna to address because

incumbency cues may mean different things to different people.

One voter-level explanation mentioned in the existing literature points to a

general level of risk aversion among the mass public.3 As Shepsle (1972) argues,

‘‘the act of voting, like that of gambling or purchasing insurance, is one involving

‘risky’ alternatives’’ (p. 560). In races between incumbents and challengers,

incumbents are generally better known and thus viewed with more certainty

compared with challengers. The voter has experience with how the incumbent

operates when holding that office, but the voter generally must make an uncertain

prospective judgment about how the challenger will behave if elected. And, if voters

uniformly are assumed to be risk averse, then voters will support incumbents over

challengers, all else equal. Shepsle’s (1972) theoretical model suggests that in

conditions under which all voters are risk averse or the majority of voters is risk

2 See Born (1986) for an alternative perspective.3 Notably, risk aversion has been promoted as an explanation for an ‘‘incumbency advantage’’ in non-

political decisions. For example, Muthukrishnan (1995) conducted a series of experiments to determine

the factors that led people to choose a new consumer product over the one they were currently using. The

study found that nearly 40 % of subjects who stayed with their incumbent brand did so despite reporting

that they thought the challenging brand was superior. The author cites risk aversion as the likely reason

that subjects would maintain loyalty to their brand despite recognizing that there appeared to be a better

alternative.

Polit Behav

123

Page 5: Risk Attitudes and the Incumbency Advantage

averse, then incumbency advantage will prevail.4 Following up on Shepsle’s work,

scholars have built in uncertainty into a number of models, with the predominant

assumption being that voters are uniformly risk averse (Davis et al. 1970; Enelow

and Hinich 1981; Bartels 1986; Alvarez 1997).

The risk aversion accounts of voter decision-making portray the public as a

homogeneous mass, cringing from the uncertain and flocking to the certain. But voters

are not uniformly risk averse, as recent empirical research utilizing a variety of

measures has identified clear variation in citizens’ risk attitudes and their consequences

for political behavior and political choices (e.g., Berinsky and Lewis 2007; Eckles and

Schaffner 2011; Ehrlich and Maestas 2010; Kam 2012; Kam and Simas 2010, 2012).

As such, we argue that there is theoretically interesting and important heterogeneity

within the public, particularly with respect to their risk attitudes and the consequences

of those attitudes for electoral decision-making. Our focus on individual-level risk

attitudes fits into a growing literature within political science that examines the effect

of risk attitudes on political choices and behaviors and pushes it further by focusing on

candidate choice within congressional elections in the US.

We expect that risk attitudes will influence an individual’s propensity to vote for an

incumbent, independent of other influences such as partisanship and retrospective

evaluations. Voters generally know more about the incumbent’s positions and

capabilities than they do about the challenger, making them a more certain and, hence,

less risky choice. For example, respondents to the Cooperative Congressional

Election Surveys in 2010 were almost twice as likely to place the incumbent on the

ideological scale as they were to place the challenger, providing support for the notion

that they were generally less certain about where the challenger stood. Though voters

may not share the same ideological beliefs as the incumbent, voters are more likely to

be certain about where the incumbent fits on the ideological spectrum and whether

they can and will carry out campaign promises while in office. Voters can also more

easily assess an incumbent’s ability to bring other sorts of benefits to the district such

as pork projects and constituent services. Projecting a future stream of benefits from a

challenger is much more difficult and much less certain. Although a voter may be

well-informed about which policies a challenger proposes to support once in office,

there is still some risk that the challenger will not carry through on those promises

once elected or will not be effective in pursuing those policies. Moreover, the ability

of a challenger to provide non-policy benefits to the district as effectively as a sitting

incumbent is unknown. Since a voter has already had experience with the incumbent,

they will likely feel more confident about projecting what that candidate will actually

do if she is re-elected. Morgenstern and Zechmeister (2001) refer to this concept as

governing capability, and note that even if voters are unaware of the incumbent

candidate’s issue position, the incumbent may be seen as having a greater capacity to

govern. Thus, even controlling for voter proximity to candidates’ positions, the fact

4 Prospect Theory offers one conditionality to this general argument. According to Prospect Theory,

features of the contextual environment will make decision-makers more or less likely to engage in risky

choice. Within the domain of losses, decision-makers are risk-seeking. Within the domain of gains,

decision-makers are risk-averse. Quattrone and Tversky (2000) argue that voters will stick with the

incumbent (the less risky candidate) in the region of gains (during good economic times) and will take the

‘‘political gamble’’ by backing challengers in the region of losses (during bad economic times).

Polit Behav

123

Page 6: Risk Attitudes and the Incumbency Advantage

that voters will be less certain about the challenger’s positions, traits, and capabilities

than the incumbent’s leads to our expectation that that risk-averse citizens will prefer

incumbents more than risk-tolerant citizens.

Risk Tolerance and Congressional Vote Choice

To assess the relationship between citizens’ risk attitudes and vote choice in

congressional elections, we analyze data from the 2008 Cooperative Congressional

Election Study (CCES).5 The dependent variable, Vote for Incumbent, takes a value

of 1 if an individual voted for the incumbent and 0 if an individual voted for a

challenger. Within the 2008 CCES module that we are analyzing, 49 % of

respondents lived in districts with a Republican incumbent and 51 % lived in districts

with a Democratic incumbent. Among self-reported voters, 61 % voted for an

incumbent and 39 % for a challenger. Our analysis is limited to the 673 voters living

in districts featuring an incumbent and challenger representing the two major parties.

To tap risk attitudes, we utilize a two-question battery pioneered by Barsky et al.

(1997). A version of it appeared on the 1996 Panel Study of Income Dynamics, and

the measure has been validated for political decision-making by Eckles and

Schaffner (2011). The two-question battery first provides respondents with a scenario

in which they currently have a job that offers a stable and certain income every year

for life. Then respondents are asked whether they would take a risky job offer that has

a 50–50 chance of doubling the respondent’s current income and a 50–50 chance of

lowering the respondent’s current income by 30 %. A follow-up question provides

those who were initially risk averse with an alternative job offer that offers a 50–50

chance of doubling the respondent’s current income and a 50–50 chance of lowering

the respondent’s current income by 20 %. A follow-up question provides those who

were initially risk accepting with an alternative job offer that again offers a 50–50

chance of doubling the respondent’s current income and a 50–50 chance of halving

the respondent’s current income. Figure 1 provides the complete question text.

Combining responses to these two items enables us to create a 4-point measure of

Risk Tolerance, ranging from risk intolerant to risk tolerant. Figure 2 displays the

distribution in the 2008 CCES. A little over half of the sample chooses the least risk

tolerant option, always preferring the guaranteed income every year for life over the

two risky options. About 20 % of the sample is maximally risk-tolerant, willing to

accept some possibility of loss in order to maximize possible gain; the remainder of

the sample is distributed in-between.

The measure of risk attitudes consists of a willingness to take a hypothetical

financial gamble relative to keeping a certain financial gain. The advantage to this

5 The CCES is a cooperative survey project that allows teams to purchase individual module surveys.

The survey was conducted via the Internet by YouGov/Polimetrix using a matched random sample

design. A subset of respondents recruited for online surveys were selected by matching them on a set of

demographic characteristics to a randomly selected set of individuals from the population of American

adults. Propensity score weights for the samples were developed so as to ensure that the sample represents

the demographic characteristics of the adult population as reflected in the 2004 and 2008 Current

Population Survey.

Polit Behav

123

Page 7: Risk Attitudes and the Incumbency Advantage

measure is that we have a more or less direct measure of the willingness to take

risks: rather than requiring citizens to engage in an abstract self-reported assessment

of their risk orientation, citizens are given a more or less concrete scenario in which

they make a decision. This measure is limited to one domain of risk-taking: financial

risk. The narrowness of our measure makes it all the more difficult to gain leverage

on political decision-making, if risk attitudes have a certain degree of domain

specificity (e.g., Blais and Weber 2006; Weber et al. 2002). However, the payoff is

that it allows us to say with confidence that the independent variable is quite distinct

from the dependent variable (congressional vote choice): there is no worry that we

are essentially measuring the same thing on both sides of the equation.6

We can address questions of criterion validity by examining whether our measure

has properties that are generally consistent with other measures that have been used

in previous research. We find, consistent with existing literature (e.g., Ehrlich and

Maestas 2010; Kam and Simas 2010; Weber et al. 2002), that women are

significantly less risk tolerant than men (r = 0.11), older people are less risk

tolerant than younger people (r = 0.08), the educated are more risk tolerant,

married people are less risk tolerant, and conservatives are less risk tolerant than

liberals (all pairwise correlations significant at p \ 0.05). Notably, income was

uncorrelated with our risk tolerance scale, indicating that responses to the question

about taking a financial risk were not influenced by the respondent’s current

financial situation. And, Eckles and Schaffner (2011) have demonstrated the

predictive validity of the Risk Tolerance measure for foreign policy opinions.

To make our estimates of the effect of Risk Tolerance more credible, we also

control for a number of factors that are likely to influence an individual’s vote for

the incumbent. Although incumbent status operates as an important determinant of

Fig. 1 Risk tolerance battery

6 The distribution of Risk Tolerance does not appear to be context-dependent. The distribution of Risk

Tolerance in the 1996 PSID (during a relatively strong economy) is strikingly similar to that uncovered in

the 2008 CCES (and in the 2010 CCES as well).

Polit Behav

123

Page 8: Risk Attitudes and the Incumbency Advantage

congressional vote, we also suspect partisanship will be important. We expect that

partisans are much more likely to vote for a candidate from their own party and

substantially less likely to vote for a candidate from the other party. As such, we

include two dummy variables that indicate whether or not the respondent shares the

incumbent candidate’s party affiliation: In-partisan is coded 1 when the respondent

shares the party affiliation of the incumbent; Out-partisan is coded 0 when the

respondent shares the party affiliation of the challenger. The suppressed reference

group thus consists of Independents.7 Because we know that economic conditions

figure heavily into the voter’s decision (Kinder and Kiewiet 1979), we include a

measure of retrospective economic evaluations.8 In addition, we include variables to

capture contextual effects: a dummy variable indicating whether the sitting

incumbent House member is a Republican, to account for general partisan tides of

the year, and a measure of Challenger Quality, on the idea that high-quality

challengers are capable of chipping away at incumbents’ advantage.9

The results in Table 1 demonstrate that Risk Tolerance significantly predicts

willingness to support a challenger: the less risk tolerant an individual is, the more

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

Least risk tolerant Somewhat risk tolerant Moderately risk tolerant Most risk tolerant

Risk Tolerance, CCES 2008

Fig. 2 Distribution of Risk Tolerance, CCES 2008

7 Here, we utilize the three category summary measure (cc307) to ensure that we have enough

respondents in the Independent category.8 The measure is based on cc302 and ranges from 0 (the economy has gotten ‘‘much better’’) to 1 (the

economy has gotten ‘‘much worse’’). In 2008, over a majority of respondents though the economy had

become ‘‘much worse’’ in the past year.9 Challenger quality is a dummy variable that takes on the value of 1 if a challenger held elective office

previously and 0 otherwise. Data on challenger quality and candidate expenditures for 2008 and 2010

were compiled and generously shared by Gary Jacobson.

Polit Behav

123

Page 9: Risk Attitudes and the Incumbency Advantage

likely she is to support the incumbent; the more risk tolerant an individual is, the

more likely she is to support the challenger. Risk Tolerance is not the only

explanation for congressional vote choice. As we can see from the coefficients on

In-Partisan and Out-Partisan, partisanship plays a massive role in explaining vote

choice as well. Voters line up behind members of their own party, and they avoid

members of the opposing party. Risk Tolerance plays an additional, though

supplementary role in decision-making on congressional candidates.

The predicted probabilities in Fig. 3 illustrate the magnitude of the relationship

between Risk Tolerance and Vote for the Incumbent, among out-partisans, indepen-

dents, and in-partisans.10 The predicted probability of voting for the incumbent

declines as Risk Tolerance rises. This effect is most pronounced among Independents

(the middle panel): at the lowest levels of Risk Tolerance, the predicted probability of

voting for the incumbent is about 0.68. At the highest levels of Risk Tolerance, this

predicted probability declines to 0.42. When the incumbent is from the other party, the

predicted probability of supporting the incumbent drops from 0.20 among the least

risk tolerant to 0.06 among the most risk tolerant, as shown in the left panel. When the

incumbent is from the voter’s party, the predicted probability of supporting the

incumbent declines from 0.95 among the least risk tolerant to 0.83 among the most

risk tolerant, as shown in the right panel. Our data suggest that Risk Tolerance matters

for congressional decision-making, but, as demonstrated by the intercept shifts in

Fig. 3, it is not the most important criteria upon which voters rely: partisanship is

massively important. However, finding even some support for a preference for

incumbents not from the voter’s party is consistent with our hypothesis that

incumbents benefit from an individual’s tolerance for risk (or lack thereof).

The basic model that we estimate in Table 1 is just that; it controls for some of

the major explanations typically used in explaining voting in congressional

elections, but it is not comprehensive. More importantly, it does not control for

some potentially important individual-level covariates that could be lurking in the

background. The second column of results in Table 1 come from a model that adds

several individual-level measures to the basic model. These individual-level

measures are important, because they may be correlated with Risk Tolerance and

also may predict willingness to vote for the incumbent. However, we see from the

results in Table 1 that adding in these measures of sex, age, education, income,

marital status, partisanship, and ideology makes almost no difference to the

estimated effect of Risk Tolerance.11 The effect of Risk Tolerance is still strong and

significant and of comparable magnitude.

10 We plot predicted probabilities for respondents in a Democratically held district who hold average

economic assessments.11 Female is a dummy for female respondents (v208). Age is coded 0 (youngest) to 1 (oldest), based on

v207. Education is a six category variable ranging from 0 (no high school degree) to 1 (advanced degree),

based on v213. Income is a 14 category variable ranging from lowest (0) to highest (1), with refusals set to

zero. Income Refused is a dummy for those who refused to report income. Married is a dummy for

married respondents (v214). Partisanship is based on cc307a and consists of the seven-category measure,

ranging from 0 (strong Democrat) to 1 (strong Republican). Ideology is a five-category self-placement

measure based on v243, ranging from 0 (very liberal) to 1 (very conservative).

Polit Behav

123

Page 10: Risk Attitudes and the Incumbency Advantage

Table 1 Risk tolerance and vote for congressional incumbent, 2008

Basic model Covariates Spending Distance

Risk tolerance -0.68***

0.18

-0.60***

0.18

-0.64***

0.19

-0.62***

0.22

In-partisan 1.16***

0.19

1.12***

0.18

1.21***

0.18

0.84***

0.21

Out-partisan -1.32***

0.19

-1.44***

0.20

-1.44***

0.19

-0.89***

0.24

National economic evaluations -0.20

0.46

-0.29

0.48

-0.23

0.48

-0.40

0.62

Republican incumbent -0.06

0.15

-0.12

0.15

-0.02

0.15

-0.11

0.18

Challenger quality 0.03

0.16

-0.09

0.16

0.05

0.16

0.04

0.18

Female respondent 0.24

0.16

0.19

0.16

0.01

0.19

Age of respondent 0.77**

0.30

0.72**

0.29

0.77**

0.35

Education of respondent -0.11

0.23

-0.10

0.24

0.29

0.28

Income of respondent -0.30

0.32

-0.27

0.32

-0.43

0.37

Income refused -0.76**

0.30

-0.72**

0.31

-0.41

0.40

Married respondent 0.16

0.16

0.13

0.16

0.11

0.19

Partisanship of respondent -0.06

0.27

0.04

0.29

0.12

0.32

Ideology of respondent -0.08

0.39

-0.17

0.40

-0.22

0.45

Ln (incumbent spending) 0.19

0.14

0.21

0.17

Ln (challenger spending) -0.09**

0.04

-0.09*

0.04

Ideological distance from incumbent -2.57***

0.37

Intercept 0.64

0.46

0.60

0.54

-1.17

1.92

-0.55

2.23

lnL (pseudo) -271.95 -258.91 -249.08 -172.38

J (districts) 279 279 278 245

N (respondents) 660 660 659 506

Table entry is the weighted probit coefficient with standard error clustered by district below

* p \ 0.10, ** p \ 0.05, *** p \ 0.01, two-tailed

Polit Behav

123

Page 11: Risk Attitudes and the Incumbency Advantage

Our model of voting in congressional elections may be leaving out important

aspects of the candidates and the nature of the election within the district. Our basic

model includes a control for challenger quality, but it is insignificant, perhaps

because it is too coarse a measure.12 As such, our next model includes measures that

should more directly be predictive of voting in congressional elections: spending.

When we include the natural log of incumbent spending and the natural log of

0.2

.4.6

.81

Pre

dict

ed in

cum

bent

vot

e

0 1

Risk Tolerance

Out-Partisans

0.2

.4.6

.81

Pre

dict

ed in

cum

bent

vot

e

0 1

Risk Tolerance

Independents

0.2

.4.6

.81

Pre

dict

ed in

cum

bent

vot

e0 1

Risk Tolerance

In-Partisans

Fig. 3 Predicted vote for the incumbent in 2008, by partisan standing. Predicted probabilities based onbasic model, Table 1

12 We also reanalyzed the models using a variation of the challenger quality measure which

differentiated the prior offices held by challengers (state legislators, other elective office holders, and

former members of the House) with no substantive difference in results. We offer a handful of additional

explanations for the insignificant results on challenger quality. The first has to do with the bluntness of the

dependent measure. Our dependent measure is the dichotomous vote choice at the individual-level.

Challenger quality is a significant predictor of incumbent vote share at the district-level, but its predictive

power is fragile when it comes to the dichotomous measure of district-level incumbent victory. The

second has to do with the merging of individual respondents to districts: we lose about 60 districts in the

merge, given the design of the CCES and the voting patterns of the respondents. Third, the peculiarities of

sampling anywhere between one and seven individual voters per district introduces more imprecision in

estimating district-level effects compared with the aggregate election outcomes. Finally, weighting the

individual-level survey data to be nationally representative allows us to make inferences about

individuals, but results in weighting some districts more than others (in district-level, aggregate analysis,

all districts are equally weighted). For these various reasons, we note that our results speak more

persuasively to individual-level factors than district-level factors. We control for district-level factors to

make our individual-level estimates more credible, but our dataset is not optimally crafted to adjudicate

district-level effects.

Polit Behav

123

Page 12: Risk Attitudes and the Incumbency Advantage

challenger spending, we see that challenger spending significantly predicts voting

for incumbents in the expected direction: the more challengers spend, the less likely

voters are to support the incumbent. More importantly, the introduction of these

campaign-level variables does nothing to the estimated effect of Risk Tolerance.

Still, congressional elections may be determined by more than partisanship and

Risk Tolerance. Ideology—in particular, the ideological distance from the

incumbent—might be an important determinant of how voters decide. The 2008

CCES asked respondents to place themselves and the two house candidates on a

0–100 ideological scale. We generate a measure of ideological distance from the

incumbent that ranges from 0 (respondents place themselves and the incumbent at

the same location) to ?1 (respondents place themselves and the incumbent at

opposite ends of the spectrum).13 When we include this measure of ideological

distance in our model, we see that it does significantly predict voting for the

incumbent: respondents who see a greater distance between themselves and the

incumbent are significantly less likely to support the incumbent. Importantly,

inclusion of this measure makes no difference to the effect of Risk Tolerance.

Thus far, we have shown that citizens who are more risk tolerant are more willing

to entertain a congressional challenger than citizens who are less risk tolerant. We

have established that these basic patterns are robust to the inclusion of a suite of

individual-level characteristics, campaign-level factors, and the intersection of the

two in ideological proximity. We have shown that Risk Tolerance may account for

some willingness to withstand incumbency advantage in 2008. But, are these results

limited to 2008? Was there something unique about the political environment in

2008 in particular that activated risk attitudes in electoral decision-making, or are

these results representative of a more general phenomenon?

The 2008 presidential race pitted the nation’s first serious African-American

presidential hopeful, Barack Obama, against a well-known and well-venerated war

hero, Republican John McCain. The Obama team campaigned on a message of

change, attempting to portray a McCain presidency as simply another four years of

Bush policies and Washington politics, issuing campaign mottos such as ‘‘We are

the change we’ve been waiting for.’’ McCain campaign’s strategy emphasized his

lengthy public service, experience, and established record as a bipartisan statesman,

framing the race as one between a proven veteran and an untested unknown. The

high visibility, high stakes presidential campaign combined with severe economic

turbulence served as a backdrop to the 2008 House races throughout the nation.

Such considerations could have created an environment that was unusually

conducive to the application of risk attitudes to vote choice. Hence, we now

examine whether similar effects manifest themselves two years later, in 2010.

13 We construct our measure using variables cc317a, cc317k, and cc317l. Note that we lose about a

quarter of our respondents, because they are unable or unwilling to place the incumbent on the ideological

scale. Missingness is even more severe when it comes to the challenger: two-thirds of respondents fail to

place the challenger on the ideological scale. The basic result holds when we only include a measure of

challenger proximity: challenger proximity is highly significant and in the expected direction (b = 2.52,

SE = 0.51, p \ 0.01) and more importantly, for Risk Tolerance, b = -0.91, SE = 0.31, p \ 0.01, but N

plummets to 262.

Polit Behav

123

Page 13: Risk Attitudes and the Incumbency Advantage

The 2010 congressional elections provide an important contrast to the 2008

congressional elections. Where 2008 was dominated by the high profile presidential

election, 2010 was a midterm election. The two election years also differ in the

prevailing partisan tides: 2008 was a modestly successful year for the Democrats

where they picked up 21 seats. Election 2010 was most decisively a Republican

victory: the GOP picked up 63 seats in the House and the Democrats suffered their

worst midterm losses in over 70 years.

To analyze the effects of risk attitudes on congressional vote choice in 2010, we

utilize data from the 2010 installment of the CCES. We limit our analysis to the

1,409 voters living in districts featuring an incumbent and challenger representing

the two major parties. Of these respondents, 39 % lived in districts with a

Republican incumbent and 61 % lived in districts with a Democratic incumbent.

Among self-reported voters, 53 % voted for an incumbent and 47 % for a

challenger. The 2010 CCES module contained the identical risk instrumentation,

and the distributions of responses to the risk tolerance battery in 2008 and 2010

were virtually indistinguishable.14 When we re-estimate the relationship in 2010,

using an identical specification, we obtain very similar results, as shown in Table 2.

We see that the effect of Risk Tolerance in 2010 operates as expected: the risk

tolerant are less likely to vote for an incumbent and more likely to vote for a

challenger. We also see that Risk Tolerance is not the primary determinant of

congressional voting: partisanship matters strongly. In-partisans support their

incumbent candidate, and out-partisans are more likely to defect from the

incumbent. As in 2008, Risk Tolerance plays a supplementary, but significant role

in predicting the congressional vote decision. We illustrate these effects in Fig. 4.

As in 2008, we find that the effects are strongest among Independents, among

whom the predicted probability of supporting the incumbent drops from 0.52 among

the least risk tolerant to 0.37 among the most risk tolerant. Among in-partisans, the

predicted probability of voting for the incumbent falls from 0.89 among the least

risk tolerant to 0.80 among the most risk tolerant; among out-partisans, the predicted

probability of voting for the incumbent falls from 0.08 among the least risk tolerant

to 0.04 among the most risk tolerant. And, as in 2008, these results stand up to

inclusion of additional individual-level and campaign-level covariates as shown in

the succeeding columns of Table 2.

For robustness, we also investigated several second-order hypotheses. Of primary

interest, we considered the case that voters make distinctions among challengers –

that challengers who are more experienced seem less ‘‘risky’’ than challengers who

are less experienced. This line of theorizing would suggest an interaction between

risk tolerance and challenger quality, such that the effect of risk tolerance would

emerge more strongly in races featuring less experienced challengers. This is

precisely what we find in 2008, where we uncover a statistically significant

interaction between risk tolerance and challenger quality, such that the effect of risk

tolerance essentially disappears when experienced challengers face incumbents.

However, we uncover statistically insignificant results in 2010, but these results

14 Specifically, 52.3 % of respondents are least risk tolerant, 16.7 % are somewhat risk intolerant, 11.6 %

are more risk tolerant, and 19.3 % are maximally risk tolerant.

Polit Behav

123

Page 14: Risk Attitudes and the Incumbency Advantage

Table 2 Risk tolerance and vote for congressional incumbent, 2010

Basic model Covariates Spending Distance

Risk tolerance -0.38**

0.16

-0.34**

0.15

-0.34***

0.15

-0.49***

0.18

In-partisan 1.17***

0.15

1.24***

0.14

1.22***

0.14

0.74***

0.16

Out-partisan -1.44***

0.21

-1.49***

0.17

-1.49***

0.17

-1.17***

0.20

National economic evaluations -0.23

0.22

-0.02

0.26

-0.01

0.26

0.26

0.30

Republican incumbent 0.19

0.14

0.25*

0.13

0.21

0.17

0.18

0.19

Challenger quality 0.06

0.14

0.06

0.14

0.11

0.15

0.27

0.18

Female respondent 0.02

0.14

0.03

0.14

-0.22

0.16

Age of respondent -0.85**

0.34

-0.83 **

0.33

-0.67*

0.36

Education of respondent 0.19

0.23

0.19

0.23

0.34

0.25

Income of respondent -0.09

0.30

-0.07

0.30

-0.32

0.33

Income refused -0.03

0.24

-0.01

0.24

-0.01

0.27

Married respondent 0.04

0.14

-0.04

0.15

0.01

0.16

Partisanship of respondent -0.31

0.26

-0.30

0.26

-0.08

0.26

Ideology of respondent -0.49

0.30

-0.49

0.30

-0.60*

0.34

Ln (incumbent spending) -0.08

0.15

0.11

0.15

Ln (challenger spending) -0.01

0.06

0.02

0.05

Ideological distance from incumbent -3.76***

0.33

Intercept 0.18

0.21

0.75

0.49

1.99

1.71

3.08

1.96

lnL (pseudo) -450.68 -439.03 -438.38 -268.70

J (districts) 353 353 353 279

N (respondents) 1,367 1,366 1,366 1,184

Table entry is the weighted probit coefficient with standard error clustered by district below

* p \ 0.10, ** p \ 0.05, *** p \ 0.01, two-tailed

Polit Behav

123

Page 15: Risk Attitudes and the Incumbency Advantage

could have been, in part, a function of the peculiarities of the 2010 election. Further

analysis, based upon data from more election years, is warranted.15

Discussion

Explanations for the incumbency advantage have traditionally focused on the

institutional advantages that incumbents hold over challengers: that is, what

contributes to incumbency advantage. We supplement this existing work by

identifying who contributes to incumbency advantage. Our empirical results

demonstrate the important role that risk attitudes play in bolstering incumbent office

holders and in opening the door to challengers. We have shown that tolerance for

risk significantly predicts a willingness to entertain challengers and stray from

incumbents. This effect appears to be strongest among Independents and is

0.2

.4.6

.81

Pre

dict

ed in

cum

bent

vot

e

0 1

Risk Tolerance

Out-Partisans

0.2

.4.6

.81

Pre

dict

ed in

cum

bent

vot

e

0 1

Risk Tolerance

Independents

0.2

.4.6

.81

Pre

dict

ed in

cum

bent

vot

e0 1

Risk Tolerance

In-Partisans

Fig. 4 Predicted vote for the incumbent in 2010, by partisan standing. Predicted probabilities based onbasic model, Table 2

15 It may also be the case that the effect of Risk Tolerance is conditioned by in-party versus out-party

status. Our analyses provide little evidence to support this speculation. Finally, we examined whether the

effect of Risk Tolerance differs across House and Senate elections. We suspect the effect would be

weaker in higher-profile elections, such as senate and presidential races, where citizens might have other

criteria upon which to base their votes. This is essentially what we found in our analysis of the 2008 and

2010 senate vote: a negative but statistically insignificant effect of Risk Tolerance on the likelihood of

voting for the senatorial incumbent. In the interest of conserving space, the tables representing the

analyses described above are omitted. They are available from the authors’ upon request.

Polit Behav

123

Page 16: Risk Attitudes and the Incumbency Advantage

relatively weaker (but still demonstrable) among in-partisans and out-partisans.

These results are not sensitive to model specification, as the results are robust to

inclusion a suite of potentially confounding individual-level characteristics and

contextual-level factors. Finally, we have shown that these results all hold in two

very different electoral contexts, the presidential election year 2008 and the midterm

elections of 2010.

We argue that incumbency advantage might arise, in part, from risk aversion on

the part of voters. A necessary condition for that explanation to work is that risk

aversion affects vote choice in a way that favors incumbents. We explicitly test and

find evidence consistent with that condition. Of course, various factors can interfere

with the link from the individual-level result we have uncovered to aggregate

election outcomes. Indeed, we think it possible that heterogeneity in risk attitudes

might help explain why sometimes the relatively stable, high margins for

incumbents suddenly become volatile. Eligible voters from different ends of the

risk-tolerance scale might, in the aggregate, be differentially mobilized by electoral

context. In ordinary times in ordinary districts, incumbents engage in activities that

capture the interest and attention of local media who, in turn, highlight the positive

and low risk attributes of incumbents—experience, attentiveness, and serving the

interests of the district. Indeed, incumbents themselves work hard to present

themselves as low risk representatives. They steer clear of issues, negativity, and

focus on the uncontroversial work they do for constituents (Druckman et al. 2009).

Challengers to most incumbents are typically too weak and underfunded to reach the

radars of most voters, so in most elections incumbency is one of the only relevant

cues, and a cue that is highly appealing to the risk averse. When national conditions

are ripe, though, challengers, particularly strong challengers, can gain traction in the

media. They often ‘‘go negative’’ and focus on needed changes in government

(Kahn and Kennedy 1999). Change, however, is likely to be more appealing to the

risk tolerant than to the risk averse.

Our results suggest that such challengers may be particularly appealing to the risk

tolerant. And, risk tolerant individuals are more politically active than the risk

averse: they are more likely to engage in costly political activities such as donating

money, working on a campaign, distributing information, or attending political

meetings (Kam 2012). A ready pool of activists willing to participate beyond voting

is necessary for a challenger to mount an effective campaign, and risk tolerant

individuals in the district provide a potential supply this important campaign input.

Since risk tolerant voters are more likely to favor challengers over incumbents,

broader economic or political tides could mobilize risk-tolerant voters in support of

challengers and produce a considerable vote swing.16

In a recent review of the literature on congressional elections, Carson and

Roberts (2011) note that ‘‘the idea that incumbent office-holders have an advantage

16 Our discussion is based on decision-making in single-shot elections, but the shadow of future elections

is worth discussion. If a voter is forward-thinking, she may recognize that today’s challenger (if

successfully elected) will be tomorrow’s incumbent, and her risk attitude should be weighted against

future options and the her discount factor for the future. Such a rationale requires that voters be future-

oriented, an assumption that may rely upon an overly optimistic view of myopic voters (e.g., Healy and

Malhotra 2009).

Polit Behav

123

Page 17: Risk Attitudes and the Incumbency Advantage

over their would-be challengers runs afoul of many tenants of democratic theory

[…]. If incumbent legislators are gaining an electoral advantage due to the rules of

the game being skewed in their favor, then this would be especially problematic and

require some form of change’’ (p. 147). Indeed, by focusing mostly on elite-centered

explanations for the incumbency advantage, the institutional advantages enjoyed by

incumbents become a frequent target for reformers seeking to make elections more

competitive. Specifically, the incumbency advantage has been cited as an impetus

for reforms like term limits, public funding of campaigns, and campaign finance

regulations. Yet, our findings suggest that incumbents, simply because they have

held office, represent what is known versus what is unknown, could still hold an

edge in their reelection campaigns because of widespread risk aversion in the

electorate. While this may give incumbents an advantage, it is one that might

comport with the risk profiles of the mass electorate—suggesting that incumbency

advantage is actually a symptom of citizens voting ‘‘correctly’’—that is, to protect

themselves from uncertainty. Our results also suggest that strategic challengers may

be able to position themselves to chip away at incumbency advantage and mobilize

the risk tolerant into their cause.

Acknowledgments The authors would like to acknowledge the organizations that supported the 2008

and 2010 Cooperative Congressional Election Study data upon which this paper is based. The 2008 data

was funded by the Center for Congressional and Presidential Studies at American University. The 2010

data was funded by the National Science Foundation along with contributions from our departments and

colleges at the Florida State University, the University of Massachusetts, Amherst, and Vanderbilt

University.

References

Abramowitz, A. I. (1975). Name familiarity, reputation, and the incumbency effect in a congressional

election. The Western Political Quarterly, 28(4), 668–684.

Abramowitz, A. I. (1980). A comparison of voting for U.S. senator and representative in 1978. American

Political Science Review, 74, 633–640.

Abramowitz, A. I. (1991). Incumbency, campaign spending, and the decline of competition in U.S. House

elections. Journal of politics, 53(1), 34–56.

Alvarez, R. M. (1997). Information and elections. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.

Ansolabehere, S., & Snyder, J. M., Jr. (2002). The incumbency advantage in U.S. elections: An analysis

of state and federal offices, 1942–2000. Election Law Journal: Rules, Politics, and Policy, 1(3),

315–338.

Ansolabehere, S., Snyder, J. M., Jr, & Charles, S., I. I. I. (2000). Old voters, new voters, and the personal

vote: Using redistricting to measure the incumbency advantage. American Journal of Political

Science, 44(1), 17–34.

Barsky R. B., Juster F. T., Kimball M. S., Shapiro M. D. (1997). Preference parameters and behavioral

heterogeneity: An experimental approach in the Health and Retirement Study. Quarterly Journal of

Economics, 112, 537–579.

Bartels, L. M. (1986). Issue voting under uncertainty: An empirical test. American Journal of Political

Science, 30(4), 709–728.

Berinsky, A. J., & Lewis, J. B. (2007). An estimate of risk aversion in the U.S. electorate. Quarterly

Journal of Political Science, 2, 139–154.

Blais, A.-R., & Weber, E. U. (2006). A domain-specific risk-taking (DOSPERT) scale for adult

populations. Judgment and Decision Making, 1(1), 33–47.

Born, R. (1986). Strategic politicians and unresponsive voters. American Political Science Review, 80(2),

599–612.

Polit Behav

123

Page 18: Risk Attitudes and the Incumbency Advantage

Cain, B., Ferejohn, J. A., & Fiorina, M. P. (1984). The constituency basis of the personal vote for U.S.

representatives and British members of parliament. American Political Science Review, 78(1),

110–125.

Cain, B., Ferejohn, J. A., & Fiorina, M. P. (1987). The personal vote. Cambridge: Harvard University

Press.

Campbell, J. E. (1983). The return of the incumbents: The nature of incumbency advantage. The Western

Political Quarterly, 36(3), 434–444.

Carson, J. M., & Roberts, J. (2011). House and Senate elections. In E. Schickler & F. Lee (Eds.), Oxford

handbook of the American Congress. Oxford: New York.

Cook, T. E. (1989). Making laws and making news: Media strategies in the U.S. House of

Representatives. Brookings Institution Press.

Cover, A. D. (1977). One good term deserves another: The advantage of incumbency in congressional

elections. American Journal of Political Science, 21(3), 523–541.

Cover, A. D., & Brumberg, B. S. (1982). Baby books and ballots: The impact of congressional mail on

constituent opinion. American Political Science Review, 76(2), 347–359.

Cox, G. W., & Katz, J. N. (1996). Why did the incumbency advantage in U.S. House elections grow?

American Journal of Political Science, 40(2), 478–497.

Cox, G. W., & Katz, J. (2002). Elbridge Gerry’s salamander: The electoral consequences of the

reapportionment revolution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Davis, O., Hinich, M., & Ordeshook, P. (1970). An expository development of a mathematical model of

the electoral process. American Political Science Review, 64, 426–448.

Desposato, S. W., & Petrocik, J. R. (2003). The variable incumbency advantage: new voters, redistricting,

and the personal vote. American Journal of Political Science, 47(1), 18–32.

Druckman, J. N., Kifer, M. J., & Parkin, M. (2009). Campaign communications in U.S. congressional

elections. American Political Science Review, 103(3), 343–366.

Eckles, D. L., & Schaffner, B. F. (2011). Risk tolerance and support for potential military interventions.

Public Opinion Quarterly, 75(3), 533–544.

Ehrlich, S., & Maestas, C. (2010). Risk exposure, risk orientation, and policy opinions: The case of free

trade. Political Psychology, 31(5), 657–684.

Enelow, J., & Hinich, M. (1981). A new approach to voter uncertainty in the Downsian spatial model.

American Journal of Political Science, 25, 483–493.

Erikson, R. (1971). The advantage of incumbency in congressional elections. Polity, 3(3), 395–405.

Erikson, R. (1972). Malapportionment, gerrymandering, and party fortunes in congressional elections.

American Political Science Review, 66(4), 1234–1335.

Eubank, R. B. (1985). Incumbent effects on individual-level voting behavior in congressional elections: A

decade of exaggeration. The Journal of Politics, 47(3), 958–967.

Fenno, R. F. (1977). U.S. House members in their constituencies: An exploration. American Political

Science Review, 71(3), 883–917.

Fenno, R. F., Jr. (1978). Home style: House members in their districts. New York: Harper Collins.

Ferejohn, J. (1977). On the decline of competition in congressional elections. American Political Science

Review, 71(1), 166–176.

Fiorina, M. P. (1977). The case of the vanishing marginals: The bureaucracy did it. American Political

Science Review, 71(1), 177–181.

Fiorina, M. P. (1981). Some problems in studying the effects of resource allocation in congressional

elections. American Journal of Political Science, 25(3), 543–567.

Healy, A., & Malhotra, N. (2009). Myopic voters and natural disaster policy. American Political Science

Review, 103(3), 387–406.

Hood, M. V., I. I. I., & McKee, S. C. (2010). Stranger danger: Redistricting, incumbent recognition, and

vote choice. Social Science Quarterly, 91(2), 344–358.

Jacobson, G. C. (1981). Incumbents’ advantages in the 1978 U.S. congressional elections. Legislative

Studies Quarterly, 6(2), 183–200.

Jacobson, G. C. (1987a). The marginals never vanished: incumbency and competition in elections to the

U.S. house of representatives, 1952–82. American Journal of Political Science, 31(1), 126–141.

Jacobson, G. C. (1987b). The politics of congressional elections. Boston, MA: Little Brown.

Jacobson, G. C. (1989). Strategic politicians and the dynamics of U.S. house elections, 1946–86. The

American Political Science Review, 83(3), 773–793.

Jacobson, G. C., & Kernell, S. (1983). Strategy and choice in congressional elections. New Haven: Yale

University Press.

Polit Behav

123

Page 19: Risk Attitudes and the Incumbency Advantage

Johannes, J. R., & McAdams, J. C. (1981). The congressional incumbency effect: Is it casework, policy

compatibility, or something else? An examination of the 1978 election. American Journal of

Political Science, 25(3), 512–542.

Kahn, K. F., & Kennedy, P. J. (1999). The spectacle of U.S. senate campaigns. Princeton, NJ: Princeton

University Press.

Kam, C. D. (2012). Risk attitudes and political participation. American Journal of Political Science,

56(4), 817–836.

Kam, C. D., & Simas, E. N. (2010). Risk orientations and policy frames. Journal of Politics, 72(2), 1–16.

Kam, C. D., & Simas, E. N. (2012). Risk attitudes, candidate characteristics, and vote choice. Public

Opinion Quarterly, 76(4), 747–760.

Kinder, D. R., & Kiewiet, R. D. (1979). Economic discontent and political behavior: The role of personal

grievances and collective economic judgments in congressional voting. American Journal of

Political Science, 23(3), 495–527.

Mann, T., & Wolfinger, R. (1980). Candidates and parties in congressional elections. American Political

Science Review, 71(3), 177–181.

McKelvey, R. D., & Riezman, R. (1992). Seniority in legislatures. American Political Science Review,

86(4), 951–965.

Morgenstern, S., & Zechmeister, E. (2001). Better the devil you know than the saint you don’t? Risk

propensity and vote choice in Mexico. Journal of Politics, 63(1), 93–119.

Muthukrishnan, A. V. (1995). Decision ambiguity and incumbent brand advantage. Journal of Consumer

Research, 22(1), 98–109.

Nelson, C. J. (1978). The effect of incumbency on voting in congressional elections, 1964–1974. Political

Science Quarterly, 3(4), 665–678.

Prior, M. (2006). The incumbent in the living room: The rise of television and the incumbency advantage

in U.S. House elections. Journal of Politics, 68(3), 657–673.

Quattrone, G. A., & Tversky, A. (2000). Contrasting rational and psychological analyses of political

choice. In K. Daniel & T. Amos (Eds.), Choices, values, frames. Cambridge: Cambridge University

Press.

Ragsdale, L. (1981). Incumbent popularity, challenger invisibility, and congressional voters. Legislative

Studies Quarterly, 6(2), 201–218.

Romero, D. W., & Sanders, F. (1994). Loosened partisan attachments and receptivity to incumbent

behaviors: A panel analysis. Political Research Quarterly, 47(1), 177–192.

Shepsle, K. (1972). The strategy of ambiguity: Uncertainty and electoral competition. American Political

Science Review, 66, 555–568.

Stone, W. J., Fulton, S., Maestas, C., & Maisel, L. S. (2010). Incumbency reconsidered: Prospects,

strategic entry, and incumbent quality in U.S. House elections. Journal of Politics, 72(1), 178–190.

Stone, W. J., Maisel, L. S., & Maestas, C. (2004). Quality counts: Extending the strategic polician model

of incumbent deterrence. American Journal of Political Science, 48(3), 479–495.

Weber, E. U., Blais, A.-R., & Betz, N. E. (2002). A domain-specific risk-attitude scale: Measuring risk

perceptions and risk behaviors. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 15, 263–290.

Yiannakis, D. E. (1981). The grateful electorate: Casework and congressional elections. American

Journal of Political Science, 25(3), 569–580.

Zaller, J. (1992). The nature and origins of mass opinion. Cambridge: Cambridge university press.

Polit Behav

123