17
Provided by the author(s) and University College Dublin Library in accordance with publisher policies. Please cite the published version when available. Title Market contagion : evidence from the panics of 1854 and 1857 Authors(s) Ó Gráda, Cormac; Kelly, Morgan Publication date 2000-12 Publication information American Economic Review, 90 (5): 1110-1124 Publisher American Economic Association Link to online version http://www.aeaweb.org/aer/contents/dec2000.html#2; http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=eoh&AN=0556175&site=ehost-live Item record/more information http://hdl.handle.net/10197/459 Publisher's statement All rights reserved Downloaded 2020-08-05T13:07:36Z The UCD community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters! (@ucd_oa) Some rights reserved. For more information, please see the item record link above.

Provided by the author(s) and University College Dublin ... · Economics. University College Dublin, Belfield, Dublin 4, ireland. We thank Patrick Honohan and two anonymous ref-erees

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    0

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Provided by the author(s) and University College Dublin ... · Economics. University College Dublin, Belfield, Dublin 4, ireland. We thank Patrick Honohan and two anonymous ref-erees

Provided by the author(s) and University College Dublin Library in accordance with publisher

policies. Please cite the published version when available.

Title Market contagion : evidence from the panics of 1854 and 1857

Authors(s) Ó Gráda, Cormac; Kelly, Morgan

Publication date 2000-12

Publication information American Economic Review, 90 (5): 1110-1124

Publisher American Economic Association

Link to online version http://www.aeaweb.org/aer/contents/dec2000.html#2;

http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=eoh&AN=0556175&site=ehost-live

Item record/more information http://hdl.handle.net/10197/459

Publisher's statement All rights reserved

Downloaded 2020-08-05T13:07:36Z

The UCD community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access

benefits you. Your story matters! (@ucd_oa)

Some rights reserved. For more information, please see the item record link above.

Page 2: Provided by the author(s) and University College Dublin ... · Economics. University College Dublin, Belfield, Dublin 4, ireland. We thank Patrick Honohan and two anonymous ref-erees

Market Contagion: Evidence from the Panics of 1854 and 1857

By MORGAN KELLY AND CORMAC 6 GRADA*

To test a model of contagion—where individuals hear some bad news and commu-nicate it to their acquaintances, who then pass it on, leading to a market panic—requires a knowledge of the information networks of participants, somethinghitherto unavailable. Eor two panics in the !850's this paper examines the behaviorof Irish depositors in a New York bank. As recent immigrants, their social networkwas determined largely by their place of origin in Ireland, and where they lived inNew York. During both panics this social network turns out to be the primedeterminant of behavior. (JEL G21, N21)

The idea of market panics spreading throughsocial contagion—where individuals hear somebad news and communicate it to their acquaintan-ces, who pass it on in turn. leading to a marketpanic—goes back at least to David Ricardo (1951p. 68), who attributed the panic leading to thesuspension of convertibility in 1797 to "the con-tagion of the unfounded fears of the timid part ofthe community." While suggestive evidence forthe importance of networks of personal contact infinancial markets is provided by the survey data ofRobert J. Shiller {1989 Chs. 1-2), Shiller and JohnPound (1989), and Ellen Hertz's (1998) fascinat-ing ethnographic study of investor groups in theShanghai stock boom of 1992. a forma! test ofmarket contagion requires not only informationon the transactions of individual participants, butalso a knowledge of their information networks,something hitherto unavailable for financialmarkets.'

To test the role of social contagion in marketpanics, this paper looks at the behavior of de-positors in a New York bank, the Emigrant

* Kelly: Departmeni of Economics, University of War-wick, Coventry CV4 7AL. U.K.; 6 Grida: Department ofEconomics. University College Dublin, Belfield, Dublin 4,ireland. We thank Patrick Honohan and two anonymous ref-erees for their detailed and constnictive criticisms of earlierversions of the paper; and Marion Casey and Tyler Anbinderfor guidance on the New York Irish. Any erTors are ours.

' In sociology, the classic study of Bryce Ryan and Neal C.Gross (1943) showed the central role played by influence ofneighbors in the diffusion of hybrid seed com. Josef L^on-ishok et ai. (1992) and Mark Grinblatt et al, (1995) examinewhether instituiional investors herd together in buying or sell-ing the same stock, but find limited evidence for this.

Industrial Savings Bank, during two bank runsin the l850's. We can reconstruct the socialnetworks of these depositors with some confi-dence because of one fact about them: mostwere recent immigrants from Ireland.

The classic pattern of migration is that newlyarrived immigrants move in near people theyknew in their home country." As a recent immi-grant, one's social network in the new world isdetermined in large part by where one came fromin the old. We confirm that social networks reflectplace of origin by using marriage records from achurch located close to the bank. Of Irish couplesmarried there in the 185O's. a majority had comefrom the same county, and very often the sameparish, in Ireland; and frequently inhabited thesame tenement in New York. Consequently, if adepositor had emigrated from County Cork inIreland, we can be quite confident that he knewother depositors from Cork.

After taking account of the individual char-acteristics of depositors and their accounthistories, we test how well social-network vari-ables—county of origin and district of resi-dence—distinguish depositors who closed theiraccounts during each panic from those whostayed with the bank. We use a classification-tree procedure that recursively partitions the setof depositors into increasingly homogeneousgroups of panickers and stayers.

The results obtained are striking. While factorssuch as length of time the account had been open.

^Robert Emst (1994 pp. 40-41); George J. Borjas(1995); Thomas Sowell (1996 pp. 4-9).

IIIO

Page 3: Provided by the author(s) and University College Dublin ... · Economics. University College Dublin, Belfield, Dublin 4, ireland. We thank Patrick Honohan and two anonymous ref-erees

VOL 90 NO. 5 KELLY AND 6 GRADA: MARKET CONTAGION nil

years lived in the United States, and size of ac-count have some role in predicting behavior, themost important characteristic that distinguishespanickers from stayers is county of origin in Ire-land. Depositors from one set of counties tendedto close their accounts in both panics, while oth-erwise identical individuals from other countiestended to stay with the bank. County of origin alsodetermines, in the more important run, the timingof panicking: different groups of depositors closedtheir accounts at different times. The importanceof county of origin in determining behavior doesnot diminish the longer the depositor had lived inAmerica, reflecting the well-known failure ofthese, mostly very poor, immigrants to assimilateinto wider New York society.

Bank panics are the product of observableevents that are perceived by depositors to con-tain adverse information about a bank's sol-vency. They can be the result of a sequence ofstochastic withdrawals (Douglas Diamond andPhilip Dybvig, 1983). or of asymmetric infor-mation between the bank and its depositorsabout the quality of the bank's assets (V. V.Chari and Ravi Jagannathan. 1988).'' What mat-ters is that a few depositors decide for somereason that the bank is in trouble and start topass the news on to their acquaintances.

The rest of the paper is as follows. Section Igives the historical background to the paper,discussing the bank, Irish immigrants in NewYork, and the panics of 1854 and 1857. Ourdata are summarized in Section II, and SectionIII tests the importance of social networks rel-ative to individual characteristics in distinguish-ing depositors who panicked from those whostayed put. Section IV concludes.

1. Historical Background

A. Bank

The Emigrant Industrial Savings Bank(EISB) was one of a score of mutual savings

•' A useful survey of the causes of panics is given byCharles W. Calomiris and Gary Gorton (1991). Our concernhere is with contagion among depositors, rather than thecontagion among lenders considered by Guillermo Calvoand Enrique Mendoza (1995), Jeffrey Sachs et al. (1995),and others. The role of bank solvency in propagating panicsis examined by Calomiri.s and Joseph R. Mason (1997).

banks set up in New York Stale before the CivilWar. These banks, established to offer highinterest and liquidity to the industrious poor,proved extremely popular: in New York City by1860 there wa.s one savings bank account forevery four people (Alan L. Olmstead, 1976 p.4). For good economic histories of the earlysavings banks, see Peter L. Payne and Lance E.Davis (1956) on Baltimore, and Olmstead(1976) on New York City.

The EISB was set up on Chambers Street inthe Sixth Ward by a group of prominent Irishcitizens, acting at the behest of the ubiquitousBishop John Hughes of New York, in Septem-ber 1850. Its first depositors were overwhelm-ingly Irish immigrants and, although it attractedincreasing numbers of German immigrants andIrish-Americans, this group still held almost 90percent of accounts in the late 185O's. By 1860it had over 10,000 accounts and held over $2million on deposit, making it a medium-sizedsavings bank by contemporary standards (Olm-stead, 1976 p. 159).

What makes this bank notable is the largeamount of background information on individ-ual depositors that it collected, which makes itsarchive a primary source of information aboutIrish immigrants to America in the immediatepost-Famine period.* For example, the bank'sfirst depositor, Bridget White, was the wife of atailor living on Henry Street in the SeventhWard. Bom near Mountmellick in QueensCounty, Ireland, she had arrived in New Yorknine years earlier on the Eairfield out of Liver-pool. Her father still lived in Ireland, but hermother was dead. She had four brothers (whosenames are given), three of them living in theUnited States, and three sisters.

The patterns of account holding in the bank arediscussed in 6 Grada and Eugene White (1999)and summarized below in Table 3. While someaccount holders behaved in true Smilesian fash-ion, making small deposits and allowing them toaccumulate, and others made frequent depositsand withdrawals, treating their accounts almost aschecking accounts; in most cases, as George Alteret al. (1994) found for the Philadelphia Saving

" Our data are taken from Reels 4-5 and 15-20 of themicrofilms of the EISB archives in the New York PublicLibrary.

Page 4: Provided by the author(s) and University College Dublin ... · Economics. University College Dublin, Belfield, Dublin 4, ireland. We thank Patrick Honohan and two anonymous ref-erees

un THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW DECEMBER 2000

Fund Society in 1850, accounts were relativelylarge in size, brief in duration, and inactive.

B. People

The EISB was located in the greatest concen-tration of Irish immigrants in North America.New York was the main port of entry into theUnited States for Irish immigrants and, by themid-1850's, contained almost as many Irish-bom people as Dublin. Like immigrants every-where, the Irish tended to cluster inneighborhoods of their own. In New York in1855, Irish immigrants accounted for 28.2 per-cent of the city's population but made up overtwo-fifths of the populations of the First,Foutih, and Sixth Wards. Immigrants from dif-ferent parts of Ireland tended to cluster in dis-tinct enclaves; Monroe Street was known as"Cork Row," in the Fourth Ward the area nextto the East River was "a favorable spot forKerry men and their descendants," and so on(John T. Ridge, 1996 pp. 276-77). The EISBwas located in the Sixth Ward next to streetsteeming with impoverished immigrants fromCounties Kerry and Sligo.

Marriage patterns reflect social networks, andthe importance of regional and local networksfor Irish immigrants is demonstrated by themarriage records of a Roman Catholic Churchlocated a few hundred yards from the EISB, theChurch of the Transfiguration of Our Lord.^ AsTable I shows, in the period 1853 to 1860, mostIrish couples who married there had come fromthe same or neighboring county in Ireland.Among men originating from the well-represented counties of Kerry and Sligo, morethan two-thirds married women from the samecounty and, in most cases, from the same cornerof the same county. Ten of the 15 grooms fromTuosist parish in Kerry married women fromthe same parish, and three more women fromneighboring parishes. Eleven of the 29 groomsfrom the parish of Rahamlish in Sligo marriedwomen from Rahamlish, and another four mar-ried women from a neighboring parish.

Certain Sixth Ward addresses recur in the mar-riage records. For instance, thirteen men, mostly

' These records are discussed in more detail in 0 Grada(1999 pp. 114-21).

TABLE 1- -MARRIAGE PATTERN.S OF IRISH IMMIGRANTS,

1853-1860

Birthplace of spouses of Irish-bompersons married in Church of theTtansfiguration of Our Lord

Percentage

Same countyNeighboring countySame provinceElsewhere in IrelandOutside Ireland

Women

49.418.03.9

21.96.8

Men

51.118.64.0

22.63.6

Notes: Based on all marriages of occupants of Ihe areabounded by Canal, Baxier. Peari. and Chatham/Bowery forthe period October 1853-November 1860. Sample includes722 women and 698 men. Thanks to Heather Griggs whosupplied the database.

with different surnames and mostly from CountyCork, married out of 22 Mulberry Street in the185O's. The residence at 31 Baxter Street suppliedeight grooms, all from Kerry or neighboring westCork, and five of them maixied women giving thesame address. Given that in about one marriage infour both bride and grtxjm gave an address in thesame tenement demonstrates how narrowly cir-cumscribed by place of origin in Ireland and res-idence in New York were the social networks ofIrish immigrants.

C. The Panics of 1854 and J857

Our purpose is to examine how these immi-grants behaved during two bank panics: a smallrun in 1854, and the major Panic of 1857. The1854 run began on December 12 with the newsthat, for the second week running, the Knicker-bocker Bank (parent of the Knickerbocker Sav-ings Bank, the only New York savings bank tofail in the antebellum era) had not produced aweekly statement for the New York bankers'clearinghouse (Olmstead, 1976 pp. 142-43).On December 13 several savings banks wereforced to pay out freely, and on the followingday the Bank of Savings on Chambers Streetsent $200,000 of its government paper to Wash-ington for redemption. The news reduced thedemand for deposits but, although the city'spress was unanimous in denouncing the gull-ibility of those involved in the run and repeat-edly urged that the city's other savings bankswere sound, banks continued to experience highrates of account closure until December 30.

Page 5: Provided by the author(s) and University College Dublin ... · Economics. University College Dublin, Belfield, Dublin 4, ireland. We thank Patrick Honohan and two anonymous ref-erees

VOL 90 NO. 5 KELLY AND 6 GRADA: MARKET CONTAGION 1113

During this period, well over 200 savers in theEISB closed their accounts.

The Panic of 1857 started in New York withnews of the failure of the Ohio Life and TrustCompany (August 24) and of the loss of asteamer en route to New York with $2 millionof uninsured gold bullion (September 17). Thecrisis quickly spread from the United States tothe Utiited Kingdom, where it provoked thesuspension of the Banking Act of 1844, andthence to the Continent (Charles Kindleberger,1978 p. 186). The Panic of 1857 led to a briefbut sharp rise in unemployment in New York(Edwin G. Burrows and Michael Wallace, 1999pp. 845-46) and had a devastating short-termimpact on banking systems and stock exchanges:for a recent interpretation of the panic see Calo-miris and Larry Schweikart (1991).

New York's savings Institutions were farmore seriously affected in 1857 than they hadbeen in 1854. Although the press and the finan-cial establishment were dismissive of the fearsof the crowds who gathered around banks, thedeclines in railway stock and state and munici-pal bonds were such as to threaten the solvencyof at least some of the banks (6 Grada andWhite, 1999). For several days thousands ofaccount holders lined up to withdraw most or allof their savings. On October 13 the savingsbanks invoked a rarely imposed clause in theirarticles of agreement limiting withdrawals ondemand to 10 percent of the outstanding bal-ance, and brought the panic to a close. BetweenSeptember 28 and October 13, 1857 over 500EISB savers closed their accounts, nearly two-fifths of them on October 12 and 13 alone.

II. Data and Estimation

We consider the behavior of depositors dur-ing the panics of 1854 and 1857. Based on ourearlier discussion, we date the 1854 panic as theperiod December 11 to December 30, and the1857 panic as the period September 28 to Oc-tober 13. These two events show clearly asspikes in the monthly series of changes in thenumber of EISB accounts (closures minusopenings) in Figure I. A depositor is defined asa panicker if he closed his account during theseperiods. A possible limitation of this detinitionis that it excludes depositors who removed mostof their money while keeping their account

CHANGE IN NUMBER OF ACCOUNTS

(NET CLOSURES) BY MONTH, 1851-1860

open. However, given the frequency with whichdepositors closed accounts, and the low timecost of reopening an account, this is probablynot important. The relatively short duration ofboth panics reduces the force of a second limi-tation, that our "panickers" include some depos-itors who would have closed their accounts inany case.

For each period, our sample consists of allpanickers and a one in ten sample of otherdepositors who decided not to close their ac-counts. This led to an initial sample of 598accounts for 1854, of which 235 were closedduring the panic; and 1,035 accounts, including505 panickers, for 1857. Note that only a smallproportion of depositors (6 percent in 1854 and8.7 percent in 1857) closed their accounts oneach occasion.^

For each depositor we recorded the date theaccount was opened, the number of deposits andwithdrawals made prior to the panic, and theclosing balance of the account (or its balance atthe end of the panic, if the account stayed open).As well as this account information, we col-lected information about the personal details of

•"The sample size was dictated by ihe need to calculateindividual-iiccounl details from handwrilten bank ledgers.Varying ihe proportion of nonpanicker:! sampled changesthe reported sample probabilities of panicking bui does notaffeci the relative significance of explanatory variables.

Page 6: Provided by the author(s) and University College Dublin ... · Economics. University College Dublin, Belfield, Dublin 4, ireland. We thank Patrick Honohan and two anonymous ref-erees

1H4 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW DECEMBER 2000

FIGURE 2. MAP OF I850 'S NEW YORK, SHOWING PHELPS'S GRID ASSIGNMENTS

Source: Based on City of New York, published by Thomas Cowerthwait & Co. (Philadelphia, 1850).

depositors: their sex, occupation, how long theyhad been living in the United States, atid, mostimportantly, their social networks.

As the marriage data discussed above dem-onstrated, the social networks of Irish immi-grants reflected two interrelated facts about theirlives: where they had come from in Ireland, andwhere they lived in New York. We have data onboth factors: we know the province and countyof origin of most Irish depositors, and the streetaddresses of all depositors.

To convert street addresses into district codeswe use the street grid of Humphrey Phelps's

"New York City Street and Avenue Guide" inPhelps (1857) (see Figure 2). This assigned thecity into grids about 1,000 yards square (approx-imately 11 north-south blocks by 4 east-westblocks).^ Streets in row F below 14th Street aregrouped together as Downtown, the area between14th Street and 32nd Street we label Midtown,and the remainder of Manhattan as Uptown. Our

' Some longer streets span more than one grid square butare assigned by Phelps to one, so some depositors on thesestreets will have been assigned to the wrong square.

Page 7: Provided by the author(s) and University College Dublin ... · Economics. University College Dublin, Belfield, Dublin 4, ireland. We thank Patrick Honohan and two anonymous ref-erees

VOL 90 NO. 5 KELLY AND 6 GRADA: MARKET CONTAGION 1115

TABLE 2—DEFINITIONS OF VARIABLES

PanickedPrevious depositsPrevious withdrawalsClosing balanceLength openYears in United StatesOccupationSexDistrict

County

Account closed during panicNumber of deposits made into account at annualized rate, excluding initial depositNumber of withdrawals from account prior to panicClosing balance if panicked, balance at end of panic otherwiseNumber of months the account had been open prior to panicNumber of years the depositor had lived in the United StatesOccupation: laborer (1), professional (p). or other (o)Female or maleDepositor's address given by grid coordinate of Phelps's 1857 "New York City Street and

Avenue Guide" (3b-6d); otherwise Downtown (dt). Midtown (mt). Uptown (at). LongIsland (ti). Brooklyn (bn), Slalen Island (si). New Jersey (nj). Upstate (us), or oiher (oth)

Depositor's county of origin in Ireland

Note: Panic is defined as the period from December 11 to December 30 for the 1854 data, and from September 28 to October13 for the 1857 data.

TABLE 3—SUMMARY STATISTICS FOR STAYERS AND PANICKERS. 1854 AND 1857

Previou.s depositsPrevious withdrawalsClosing balanceLength openYears in United StatesFemaleLaborerProfessionalUlsterConnachtMunster

Stayers

Z181.33

186.8616.057.98

31.7144.72

4.0733.749.76

29.67

1854

Panickers

2.613.08

124.3611.565.42

31.6159.59

1.5516.0617.6236.79

Stayers

2.011.1

223.3623.8410.6132.9742.78

3.8128.3313.9027.52

1857

Panickers

2.191.45

161.518.348.02

43.3652.38

3.2514.2«15.0440.35

Note: Entries for numerical variables are means; entries for factors are percentages ofaccounts.

Other districts are Brooklyn, Long Island, StatenIsland, New Jersey, Upstate, and other. As well ascapturing potential neighborhood effects, this gridallows us to gauge the impact of shoe-leather costson panicking: depositors living in squares closer tothe bank face a lower cost of going to the bank andclosing their accounts and may therefore be morelikely to panic.^

Restricting ourselves to Irish depositors whosecounty of origin is known, and whose address wecould locate, gave us a sample of 439 accounts,including 193 panickers, for 1854: and 766 ac-counts, including 399 panickers. for 1857. Thevariables that we use to distinguish between pan-ickers and stayers are defined in Table 2, andsummary statistics are presented in Table 3.

There are several notable features about the

We are grateful to a referee for this point.

depositors summarized in Table 3. The first isthe high proportion of unskilled workers—laborers, porters, domestic servants—amongdepositors, composing about half of all ac-counts; with most ofthe remainder belonging toclerks and small capitalists. Secondly, most de-positors were recent immigrants: over 80 per-cent had arrived since the start of the GreatFamine in 1845. Thirdly, at a time when theaverage weekly wage of a male laborer wasaround $5, with a female domestic earningabout half that, the average account balance waslarge: $160 in 1854 and $190 in 1857. withmedians of SI00 and $ 115 respectively. Finally,accounts were short lived—the average accounthad been open for 14 months in 1854 and 21months in 1857—and comparatively inactivewhen open, averaging three or four transactionsa year.

Comparing panickers with stayers, the major

Page 8: Provided by the author(s) and University College Dublin ... · Economics. University College Dublin, Belfield, Dublin 4, ireland. We thank Patrick Honohan and two anonymous ref-erees

1116

Intercept

Previous deposits

Previous withdrawals

Closing balance

Length open

Years in United States

Female

Laborer

Professional

Ulster

Connacht

Munster

DensityNull devianceResidual deviancePercent misclassified

THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW

TABLE 4—CHARACTERISTICS OF PANICKERS:

1854

0.4976(0.2758)0.0139

(0.021)0.0225

(0.0173)-0.0018*(0.0008)

-0.0324**(0.0102)

-0.0456*(0.0201)

-0. I I7I(0.2273)0.452*

(0.2133)-0.4297(0.7098)

0.064860255335

1857

0.5951**(0.2178)0.0059

(0.0261)0.043

(0.0303)-0.001*(0.0005)

-0.0116**(0.0044)

-0.0459**(0.0126)0.3581*

(0.1618)0.2565

(0.1572)0.299

(0.4267)

0.088210611001

39

LOGISTIC REGRESSION

!854

0.5747(0.3314)0.0062

(0.0208)0.0281

(0.0182)-0.001*(0.0008)

-0.034**(0.0105)

-0.04*(0.0202)

-0.1263(0.2319)0.4945*

(0.2182)-0.2398(0.7138)

-0.8247**(0.2951)0.4871

(0.338)-0.0295(0.2617)0.0641

602537

32

DECEMBER 2000

1857

0.6118*(0.2543)

-0.0037(0.0264)0.0389

(0.0306)-0.0008(0.0005)

-0.0117**(0.0045)

-0.0396**(0.0128)0.3627*

(0.1635)0.2124

(0.1591)0.3737

(0.4303)-0.6116**(0.219)0.025

(0.2405)0.2065

(0.1916)0.0882

106198736

Note."!: Logistic regression. Dependent variable: Panicked. Standard errors are in parentheses. 439 observations for 1854. 766for 1857. Density is the mean of the logistic density estimated for each observation, adjusted for the undersampling of stayers:multiplying the coefficient of a numerical variables by this gives the marginal effect of the variahle on the probability ofpanicking. Null deviance and residual deviance are minus twice the log-likelihood (up to a constant) when only the interceptis included, and when all explanatory variables are included respectively. Percent misclassified is the percentage otobservations where the predicied value of the dependent variable differs from the actual value.

* Denotes pseudo-l-statistic significant at 5 percent.** Denotes pseudo-(-statistic significant at I percent.

differences are in size of deposit and length oftime in America: the larger one's account andthe longer one had lived in the United States theless likely one was to panic. Province of originalso mattered, with depositors from Ulster un-derrepresented among panickers relative toother provinces.

This informal division is supported by logis-tic regressions for the probability of panickingreported in Table 4. The regression coefficientsreflect the behavior of the sample where pan-ickers are overrepresented. Up is the fraction ofour sample that panicked, then p/(\0 — 9p) isthe fraction of the bank's depositors that pan-icked. To estimate the marginal effect of a nu-merical variable on the true probability of

panicking for an individual at the mean level ofthe covariates, these coefficients are multipliedby the figure in the row labeled "Density,"which is the logistic multiplier times the deriv-ative ofthe population probability of panicking.The undersampling of stayers implies that thisadjustment factor is substantial, in the range0.06 to 0.08.

In both 1854 and 1857 the probability ofpanicking declines the longer one had lived inthe United States and had been with the bank,the larger one's account balance, and if onecame from Ulster. Holding other covariatesfixed at their mean values, and again adjustingfor the fact that only one in ten stayers weresampled, a depositor from Ulster has a predicted

Page 9: Provided by the author(s) and University College Dublin ... · Economics. University College Dublin, Belfield, Dublin 4, ireland. We thank Patrick Honohan and two anonymous ref-erees

VOL. 90 NO. 5 KELLY AND 6 GRADA: MARKET CONTAGION 1117

TABLE 5—ACCOUNTS AND PANICKER.S BY COUNTY

Counly oforigin

AntrimArmaghCarlowCavanClareCorkDerryDonegalDownDublinFermanaghGalwayKerryKildiireKilkennyLaoisLeitrimLimerickLongfordLouthMayoMeathMonaghanOffal yRascommonSligoTipperaryTyroneWateribrdWestmeathWexfordWicklow

Total

Accounts

10!35

319

496

169

214

24288

1367

341258

11116

127

24128

1675

439

1854

Panickers(percent)

2040

0293345

0126743257150386250435642

1007545t8505029542550445720

44

Accounts

8139

392284n238

36123573a29181351211515242214291932241422163

766

1857

Panickers(percent)

503156265957671750565857749

45785451385367673250553762384355

0

52

probability of panicking of 3 percent in 1854and 5 percent in 1857, only half that of a de-positor from Leinster (the omitted province inthe regression dummies), whose predicted prob-abilities are 8 percent and 10 percent respec-tively. In addition, depositor's occupation issignificant for 1854, while sex is significant for1857.

The importance of networks of personal ac-quaintance in propagating panics can be seen inthe day to day accounts of the bank. During the1854 run, for instance, we find that John Hayesand John Lane {originally from Cork) andThomas Murray and Michael Corcoran (fromRoscommon). all laborers living at 26 CherryStreet, showed up at the bank on September 14and closed their accounts.

Table 5 shows that there is a large variation inthe likelihood of panicking across differentcounties of origin. In 1857, for example, while52 percent of accounts in our sample closedduring the panic, only 17 percent of depositorsoriginally from Donegal and 26 percent fromCavan (both Ulster counties) panicked, com-pared with 67 percent for Meath and 74 percentfor Kerry. The hypothesis that these proportionsare equal across counties is strongly rejected:the chi-squared statistic is 52.4 for 1854 and74.6 for 1857, both significant at I percent. Itcan be seen that the same counties tended toproduce panickers or stayers in both years: therank-order correlation between percentage ofpanickers in both years is 0.55.

Figure 3 maps the likelihood of panicking by

Page 10: Provided by the author(s) and University College Dublin ... · Economics. University College Dublin, Belfield, Dublin 4, ireland. We thank Patrick Honohan and two anonymous ref-erees

1118 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW DECEMBER 2000

PeFcenlsBB ol Banaat 16M

I 1 0 - l BI I 2 0 - M

i B so 73^ 1 SOt

Q NurntHT Dl KCOLfila c

PsicanlBBB ol pBiUckef) 1867

D- IB

I I KI -3B

FIGURE 3. NUMBER OF DEPOSITORS AND PERCE rAGE OF PANICKERS BY COUNTY OF ORIGIN

IN IRELAND. 1854 AND 1857

Note: Dark lines are boundaries of provinces.

county of origin in Ireland. Neglecting countieswith few depositors, it shows not only a strongvariation in the probability of panicking, butalso that the counties least likely to producepanickers are clustered in the north and north-west of the county.

When county-of-origin dummies were addedto the regressions in the first two columns ofTable 4, only Galway and Wexford in 1854were individually significant. However, thecounty dummies are jointly strongly significant:the chi-squared statistic for the hypothesis thattheir coefficients are jointly zero is 54 for 1854and 72 for 1857. Using district-of-residenceinstead of county-of-origin dummies, districts4d and 4e were individually significant in 1854,and district 4b in 1857. Testing joint signifi-cance of all districts gave a borderline signifi-cant chi-squared statistic of 30 for 1854, but ahighly significant 43 for 1857. If county oforigin is already included, the district-of-residence dummies are jointly insignificant for1854, but significant at 2 percent for 1857.While these results suggest that social networkfactors may play an important role in panics, weneed a technique that can handle factors withmany levels, and possible nonlinear interactions

between explanatory variables, more economi-cally than a logistic regression.

III. Social Networks in Panics

To examine the importance of social net-works in propagating panics, an elegant andintuitive approach is provided by the classifica-tion-tree procedure of L. Breiman et al. (1984).^Classification trees use a recursive, binary par-titioning procedure to split the data into groupsof observations that are as homogeneous aspossible in terms of the dependent variable.

The procedure goes through all explanatoryvariables and tries a split at each level for everynumerical variable, and for every combination oflevels for each factor. It chooses the split thatpartitions the data into panickers and stayers withas few misclassifications of individuals as possi-ble. For instance, an account balance of $60 mightprovide the best split, with depositors holding lessthan this tending to panic and those with moretending to stay. The procedure is then repeated for

* A good introduction to classification trees is given byW. N. Venables and B. D. Ripley (1994 Ch. 13).

Page 11: Provided by the author(s) and University College Dublin ... · Economics. University College Dublin, Belfield, Dublin 4, ireland. We thank Patrick Honohan and two anonymous ref-erees

VOL 90 NO. 5 KELLY AND 6 GRADA: MARKET CONTAGION 1119

each of the two new subgroups of data, with thealgorithm again searching through the explanatoryvariables to find the best partition in each case. Forexample, among depositors with a balance of lessthan $60, district of residence niight give the bestsplit, with depositors from districts 4c and 4dtending to panic and those from other districtstending to stay; while for depositors with balancesabove $60, length of time in the United Statesmight give the best partition, with those presentmore than five years being inclined to stay and amajority of those present less than five years pan-icking. This partitioning process continues untilthe process runs out of observations.

Splits higher in the tree are more important interms of distinguishing panickers from stayersthan splits lower down. The result is a decisiontree that gives a rule for classifying each indi-vidual, and states the probability that an indi-vidual is misclassified by this rule. A typicaldecision path might be, for example, that anindividual with less than $60 in the bank, wholived in districts 4c or 4d, and was an unskilledworkers is predicted to he a panicker; and of the12 individuals in the sample that fit this descrip-tion, 4 are incorrectly classified as panickers.

The 32 levels of the county factor lead to overtwo billion possible splits that must be evaluated,making the algorithm impossibly slow. We there-fore omitted depositors from the four countieswith the fewest accounts in each year. This al-lowed the algorithm used to run in a reasonabletime, and reduced the chance of results beingdistorted by a factor level corresponding to ahandful of observations. This gave 420 observa-tions for 1854 and 738 for 1857.

The results of the classification procedure for1854 and 1857, estimated using the S-Plus pack-age, are presented in Figures 4 and 5. The inter-pretation of these figures is straightforward. Thevalue at each node, I or 0, tells whether themajority of depositors at that node were panickers{1) or stayers (0). The number alb below the nodegives the number of misclassified observations aas a fraction of the total number of observations atthe node b. Looking at the left-most path of Figure4, for instance, we can see that of 102 depositorswho came from AnUim, Cavan, Clare, Derry,Donegal, Monaghan, Sligo, and Tyrone, only 23panicked; and of the 7 depositors from these coun-ties who had been with the bank for less than 2.1months, all but one panicked.

The pattern of results in Figures 4 and 5 isimmediate and striking. For both panics, the mostimportant factor that distinguishes panickers fromstayers is county of origin. In both 1854 and 1857,depositors from Cavan, Donegal, Monaghan, Ty-rone, and Sligo tended to stay while depositorsfrom other counties tended to panic. Among de-positors from staying counties, three-quartersstayed with the bank in 1854, and two-thirds in1857- For these depositors, the length of time withthe bank (1854) and the size of their balance{1857) have a secondary effect in reducing the riskof panicking.

Among depositors from other counties,slightly over half those in the sample panickedin 1854 and 60 percent in 1857. In both years,the most important secondary characteristic ofpanickers is length of time in the United States:of 23 depositors in 1854 who had been theremore than 18 years, only 3 panicked; while in1857 more than two-thirds of depositors whohad lived less than 8 years in the United Statespanicked. After this, the most important char-acteristic is district of residence for 1854. withdepositors from the contiguous blocks 4c, 4d,4e, and 5d likely to panic (these blocks lie closeto the bank, which is located in 4c, suggesting apossible role for shoe-leather costs, althoughthis effect is probably mitigated by the smallsize of the city at the time); and in 1857 it isnumber of months with the bank.

These results are highly robust; using anylarge subset of the data in each year gave rise tothe same pattern of partitions.'" The mostimportant assurance of robustness is the simi-larity of the trees generated in each year.

The parsimony of the classification tree isapparent. Using only the first two layers of thetree, 63 percent of depositors are correctly clas-sified in 1854, and 65 percent in 1857, and this

'" A referee raised the possibility that the large numberof levels of the county factor could generate a spuriousimportance for that variable. If depositors are assigned acounty al random, county does appear occasionally as highas the second or third split variable in a tree. In ihis case,however, the generated trees were nonrobust: using differ-ent subsets of each year's data generated different patternsof splits by county, and the county partitions were verydifferent for each year. That a large number of levels neednot generate classiticatory power is shown by ihe district ofresidence variable, with 23 levels, which does not appearhigh in any tree, even when the county variable is omitted.

Page 12: Provided by the author(s) and University College Dublin ... · Economics. University College Dublin, Belfield, Dublin 4, ireland. We thank Patrick Honohan and two anonymous ref-erees

1120 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW DECEMBER 2000

countyiant.cav.da.der.dcHi.mon.sli.tvrcounty:arm,cor,clow,dub.gal,ker.ldd,klk.lao,lei,lirn,lori,may,mea,off,r(}S,tip,wal.wes,wex

length. opan<a. 085/ length, ope n>2.085

1 0

1/7 17/95 ^ ^ 135/295

district: 4c, 4d, 4fl ,5c,cfl, mt, nj .si, u s

3/23

(Jlsinct:3g,3d,3e.4b.4l,5d,bk,H,ul

county:ami,cor,<Jub,ker,kld.lao.lel.mea.ros.wat.wes county :arm .aal. lei, oftcounty:dow.gal,klk,llm.lon,rnay.otf,tip,wex ^ . ^ county: cor ,dow.dub,ker,k Id, kik.lao.lim.lon, may, msa.ros,tip ,wat,wes,wex

1 0

20/BO 0/11

county :cor,dow,dub ,kld,klk.lao.lim,mea.tio,wescounty;k9r,lonpmay.ros,wat,wex

\

5/23

1/11

distr»ct:3c,3d,3e,4t/ disli1cl:4b,5d,bM,ut

\

1

1 0

9/24 1/8

FIGURE 4. CLASSTHCATION TREE, 1854 PANtc

Note: The number in each node denotes whether the majority of depositors there are panickers (1) or stayers (0); the fractionbeneath the node detiotes the proportion of depositors that are misclassified at the node.

rises to 67 and 68 percent respectively if thenext layer of the tree is added. This is similar tothe misclassification rates obtained from thelogits in Table 4.

Classification trees continue to partition datauntil they run out of observations, resultingin overfitting. To prune the fitted tree, two ap-proaches are available. The first is to split the data

Page 13: Provided by the author(s) and University College Dublin ... · Economics. University College Dublin, Belfield, Dublin 4, ireland. We thank Patrick Honohan and two anonymous ref-erees

VOL. 90 NO. 5 KELLY AND 6 GRADA: MARKET CONTAGION 1121

county:arm,cav,don,kld,klk,lon.mon,sli,:yr,wal

ounty :cla,cof,der,club,lor,gal,ker,lao,lei,lim,lou,niay,mea,of(,ros,tip,wes,wex

years.ln.us<7.5

years.in.us>7.5

length, open <21.85*lenglh,open>2i.85

lenglh,opon<8.785

county :cla,cor,dub,lef.gal,lei.otf,tip, wes cl,bal<50.35 \ county:cla,cor,dub,(6f,gal,ker,lim,lou,may,ot(.ro3,wescounlv:ker,lao.lim,lou,may,mea,fOS,weV cl.bal>50,35 county:der.lao,lei,mea.tip.we«

cl.bak162.23 \ county:da,der,dub,(ef,gal,lao,may,mea cl.bal<46V55/ ci.bal>162.23 county:cor.k6r,lei.Hm,oft,ros,lip,wes / cl.bal>461,55

district:3c,3d,3e,4b,4c,5c,5e,dt,ljdistricl:4d,4f,5d,bk.ml,nj,olh,us,ut

county:fer,gal,lou,rnaycounty:cla,cor,dL(b,lim,otf,ros,wes

FIGURE 5. CLAssincATioN TREE, 1857 PANIC

Note: The number in each node denotes whelher the majority of depasitors there are panickers 11) or stayers (0); the fractionbeneath the node denotes the proportion of depositors that are misclassifled at Ihe node.

into a training sample, which generates a treewhose classificatory power is then measured on aseparate testing sample. Adding extra node.s ini-tially reduces misciassification rate in the secondsample until, as overfitted naies are added, the

misciassification rate starts to rise. Alternatively across-validation procedure (Breiman et al., 1984pp. 59-81) can be used where subsets of obser-vations are used in tum to fit the tree, which isthen tested on the remaining observations. Both

Page 14: Provided by the author(s) and University College Dublin ... · Economics. University College Dublin, Belfield, Dublin 4, ireland. We thank Patrick Honohan and two anonymous ref-erees

1122 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW DECEMBER 2000

1 0

0 1 1 0

FIGURE 6. SCHEMATIC VERSION OF CLASSIFICATION TREES IN FIGURES 4 (1854, LEFT)

AND 5 (1857, RIGHT)

Note: The depth of the branches below each node indicates the relative importance of eachsplit in reducing the misclassification rate.

approaches were tried here and, based on misclas-sification rates, suggested the trees with approxi-mately 16 terminal nodes that are reported here.These trees have a misclassification rate of 22percent tor 1854 and 25 percent for 1857.

While the relative importance of each split isindicated by its position in the classificationtree, it is not evident from Figures 4 and 5 howmuch each split contributes to the reduction ofthe misclassification rate. This is shown in Fig-ure 6 where the amount by which each splitimproves the fit of the tree is proportionate tothe length of the branches beneath it. Whilecounty of origin is the most important split forboth trees. Figure 6 shows that county has muchgreater classificatory power for the major panicof 1857 compared with the smaller run in 1854.

Given that county of origin is the most impor-tant determinant of panicking, does it follow thatsocial networks are influencing individual behav-ior, or is county of origin merely proxying forsome omitted individual characteristic such as ed-ucation or previous experience with banks? Whileindividual education is likely to be captured by theoccupation and bank-balance variables, region oforigin may determine the economic sophisticationof recent immigrants. In terms of economic devel-opment, regions of nineteenth-century Ireland can

be ranked Eastern Ulster, Leinster, Munster, andConnacht and Western Ulster. While the impor-tance of the Ulster variable in tbe logistic regres-sions in Table 4 might suggest that economicsophistication of Ulster depositors is what detersthem from panicking, looking at Table 5 and theclassification trees we can see that most Ulsterdepositors came from poorer western countiesrather than the industrialized east. In particular,few depositors from very poor northwestern coun-ties, such as Sligo and Donegal, panicked; whiledepositors who had come from more prosperouseastern counties, such as Dublin, Meath, andWexford, showed a strong tendency to panic.

Few of the EISB"s depositors are likely to havehad previous contact with banks in Ireland, wherejoint-stock commercial banking relied almo.st ex-clusively on a professional and business clientele.While Ireland did have a trustee savings-bankmovement dating from 1815, its scale was tiny:only 90,000 depositors out of a population ofabout 8.5 million on the eve of the Great Famine(1845-1850), compared with nearly 70,000depositors in New York City alone in 1850(Olmstead, 1976 pp. 157-61; 6 Grada, 1994pp. 138-42). Irish savings banks catered to adisproportionately urban clientele, and the over-whelmingly rural background of Irish emigrants

Page 15: Provided by the author(s) and University College Dublin ... · Economics. University College Dublin, Belfield, Dublin 4, ireland. We thank Patrick Honohan and two anonymous ref-erees

VOL 90 NO. 5 KELLY AND O GRADA: MARKf-T CONTAGION 1123

means that few of those who opened accounts inNew York can have previously held accounts inan Irish savings bank. The possibility that someEISB depositors from Dublin and Kerry wereacting on recollections of the well-publicizedfrauds that affected savings banks in Dublin,Tralee, and Killamey in 1848 cannot be ruledout, although arguably such memories wouldhave deterred them from opening an account inthefirstplace(R.D.C. Black, 1960 pp. 152-53;6 Grada, 1999 pp. 54, 155-56).

Do social networks affect the timing of pan-icking? Each of the panics here spanned tbreeweeks. In 1854, 60 percent of panickers left inthe first week, 26 percent in the second, and 14percent in the third week (forgoing a half year'sinterest payment of 3 percent); while in 1857.24 percent left in the first week, 37 percent inthe second, and 39 percent on the first two daysof the third week, before withdrawals were re-stricted. Using a classification tree to determinewbat week tbe account was closed, for 1854.district of residence was tbe most importantdeterminant of timing, but has a high error rate.For 1857 bowever, tbere is a clear difference intiming of closure by county of origin: panickersin the first week tended to be from Clare, Derry,Donegal, Tipperary. and Westmeath: wbereaspanickers in the tbird week tended to be fromFermanagh. Kerry. Longford. Meath. and Sligo.

It might be expected that the effect of countyof origin on bebavior would diminish the longerthe depositor had lived in America and formedotber ties. To test this we split depositors byyears lived in tbe United States (trying splits atfive and eight years) to see if depositors whobad been tbere longer behaved differently fromnew arrivals. However, for both 1854 and 1857.the two groups behaved tbe same, with countyof origin being the prime determinant of pan-icking. This failure to assimilate reflects tbesocial isolation of these immigrants: in general.wealthier Irish immigrants left New York rap-idly for cities with greater economic opportuni-ties; tbose remaining were the poorest and leastskilled (Joseph P. Ferrie, 1999 pp. 47-50).

IV. Conclusion

To test whether social contagion helps topropagate panics in Hnancial markets we needto identify the informational networks of market

participants. In this paper we were able to dotbis by looking at a distinctive group of depos-itors: Irish immigrants living in New York inthe t850's. As immigrants, tbeir social net-works reflected two interrelated facts about theirlives: where tbey bad come from in Ireland andwhere they lived in New York.

When we examined the behavior of thesedepositors in the panics of 1854 and 1857. wefound tbat whether an individual panicked ornot depended strongly on bow long they badlived in America, and how long tbey had beenwith the bank. The most important factor inwhether they panicked, however, was county oforigin. Depositors from one set of countiestended to close their accounts in both panics,while otherwise identical individuals from othercounties tended to stay witb tbe bank. Our re-sults show that individual behavior depends notonly on private information but on access to theinformation and opinions of other group mem-bers, and raises the possibility tbat a handful ofinfluential individuals can have a lot of powerover group opinion.

REFERENCES

Alter. George; Goldin. Claudia and Rotella, Elyse."The Savings of Ordinary Americans: TbePbiladelphia Saving Fund Society in the Mid-Nineteenth Century." Journal of EconomicHistory, December 1994, 54(4). pp. 735-67.

Black, R. D. C. Economic thought and the Irishquestion, IH!7~J870. Cambridge: CambridgeUniversity Press, I960.

Borjas, George J. "Ethnicity. Neighborhoods,and Human-Capital Externalities." AmericanEconomic Review, June 1995. 85(3), pp.365-90.

Breiman, L.; Friedman, J. H.; Olshen, R. A. andStone, C. J. Classification and regression trees.Monterey. CA: Wadswortb and Brtwks-Cole,1984.

Burrows, Edwin G. and Wallace, Michael.Gotham: A history of New York City to 1898.New York: Oxford University Press, 1999.

Calomiris, Charles W. and Gorton, Gary. "TheOrigins of Banking Panics: Models. Facts,and Bank Regulation." in R. Glenn Hubbard,ed.. Financial markets and fmancial crises.Chicago: University of Cbicago Press. 1991.pp. 109-73.

Page 16: Provided by the author(s) and University College Dublin ... · Economics. University College Dublin, Belfield, Dublin 4, ireland. We thank Patrick Honohan and two anonymous ref-erees

J124 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW DECEMBER 2000

Calomiris, Charles W. and Mason, Joseph R."Contagion and Bank Failures Duringthe Great Depression: Tbe June 1932 Chi-cago Banking Panic." American EconomicReview. December 1997, 87(51 pp. 863-83.

Calomiris, Charles W. and Schweikarl, Larry."The Panic of 1857: Origins, Transmission,and Containment." Journal of EconomicHistory, December 1991. 57(4), pp.807-34.

Calvo, Guillermo and Mendoza, Enrique. "Reflee-tiotis on Mexico's Balance of Payments Crisis:A Chronicle of a Death Foretold." Workingpaper. University of Maryland, 1995.

Chari, V. V. and Jagannathan, Ravi. "BankingPanics. Information, and Rational Expecta-tions Equilibrium." Journal of Finance, July1988, 43(3), pp. 749-60.

Diamond, Douglas and Dybvig, Philip. "BankRuns, Liquidity, and Deposit Insurance."Journal of Political Fconomy, June 1983.97(3), pp. 401-19.

Ernst, Rohert. Immigrant life in New York City1825-1863. Syracuse, NY: Syracuse Univer-sity Press. 1994 [originally published in19491.

Ferrie, Joseph P. " Yankeys now ": Immigrants inthe antebellum U.S. New York: Oxford Uni-versity Press. 1999,

Grinblatt, Mark; Titman, Sheridan and Werm-ers, Russ. "Momentum Investment Strategies.Portfolio Performance, and Herding: A Studyof Mutual Fund Behavior." American Eco-nomic Review, December 1995. S5(5), pp.1088-105.

Hertz, Ellen. The trading crowd: An ethnogra-phy of the Shanghai stock market. Cam-bridge: Cambridge University Press. 1998.

Kindleberger, Charles. Manias, panics, andcrashes. New York: Basic Books, 1978.

Lakonishok, Josef; Shieifer, Andrei and Vishny,Robert W. "The Impact of Institutional Trad-ing on Stock Prices." Journal of FinancialEconomics, August 1992. i2( 1), pp. 23-42.

6 Grada, Cormac. Ireland: A new economichistory 1780-1939. Oxford: Oxford Univer-sity Press, 1994.

. Black '47 and beyond: The great Irishfamine in history, economy, and memory.Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press,1999.

6 Grada, Cormac and White, Eugene. "WboPanics During Panics? Evidence from aNineteentb Century Savings Bank." Workingpaper, Rutgers University. 1999.

Olmstead, Alan h. New York Citv mutual savingsbanks. 1819-1861. Chapel Hill, NC: Univer-sity of Noitb Carolina Press, 1976.

Payne. Peter L. and Davis, Lance E. The SavingsBank of Baltimore, 1818-1866: A historicaland analytical study. Baltimore, MD: JohnsHopkins Press, 1956.

Phelps, Humphrey. Strangers and citizen's guideto New York City. New York: GaylordWatson, 1857.

Ricardo, David. The works and correspondenceof David Ricardo, volume 4: Pamphlets andpapers, 1815-1823. Cambridge: CambridgeUniversity Press, 1951.

Ridge, John T. "Irish County Societies in NewYork. 1880-1914." in Ronald H. Bayor andTimothy J. Meagber. eds.. The New YorkIrish. Baltimore. MD: Johns Hopkins Utiiver-sity Press, 1996, pp. 275-300.

Ryan, Bryce and Gross, Neal C. "The Diffusionof Hybrid Seed Corn in Two Iowa Commu-nities." Rural Sociology.. January 1943, 8(1),pp. 15-24.

Sachs, Jeffrey; Tomell, Aaron and Velasco, An-dres. "The Mexican Peso Crisis: SuddenDeath or Death Foretold?" Working paper.Harvard University. 1995.

Shiller, Robert J. Market volatility. Cambridge.MA: MIT Press. 1989.

Shiller, Robert J. and Pound, John. "Survey Ev-idence on Diffusion of Interest and Informa-tion Among Investors." Joumal of EconomicBehavior and Organization, August 1989.72(1), pp. 47-66.

Sowell, Thomas. Migrations and cultures: Aworld view. New York: Basic Books, 1996.

Venables, W. N. and Ripley, B. D. Modern ap-plied statistics with S-plus. New York:Springer-Verlag, 1994.

Page 17: Provided by the author(s) and University College Dublin ... · Economics. University College Dublin, Belfield, Dublin 4, ireland. We thank Patrick Honohan and two anonymous ref-erees