31
Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011 Nick Bloom Productivity and Reallocation

Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011 Nick Bloom Productivity and Reallocation

  • View
    219

  • Download
    4

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011 Nick Bloom Productivity and Reallocation

Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011

Nick Bloom

Productivity and Reallocation

Page 2: Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011 Nick Bloom Productivity and Reallocation

Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011

Big Overview

Economists started looking at establishment data in the 1990s (Haltiwanger, Davis, Bartelsman, Bailey etc.)

There was surprise over:

• High levels of turnover

• Heterogeneity within industries

• The lumpiness of micro-economic activity

• The importance of reallocation in driving productivity

Page 3: Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011 Nick Bloom Productivity and Reallocation

Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011

Why should you be interested in this?

First, this is important to understanding macroeconomic activity – e.g. 3/4 productivity growth is reallocation, unemployment driven by rates of churn

Second, this is a fertile area of research:• It is new – many open questions• It is hard – typically needs mix of empirics, simulation

and modeling, so barriers to entry high

Third, the NBER has a Census node. Census data is painful to access, but this also deters – so still low-hanging fruit (like my Grandma’s attic – some amazing stuff in there)

Page 4: Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011 Nick Bloom Productivity and Reallocation

Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011

High levels of turnover

Heterogeneity within industries

The lumpiness of micro-economic activity

The importance of reallocation in driving productivity

Page 5: Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011 Nick Bloom Productivity and Reallocation

Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011

Turnover

About 15% of jobs are destroyed and 20% created in the private sector every year. About 80% of this turnover occurs within the same SIC-4 digit industry

This is robust across countries (US, Europe, Asia and SA)

But, before I show data a couple of point on definitions:

• This is turnover in “jobs”, defined in terms of establishment employment changes, e.g. CES

• A linked (but distinct concept) is turnover in “employment” – which is two to three times higher – defined in terms of workers changes, e.g. CPS

Page 6: Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011 Nick Bloom Productivity and Reallocation

Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011

Turnover in “Jobs” versus “Employment” – Expanding Firm example

Source: John Haltiwanger Note: Worker flow=14, Job flow=4

Page 7: Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011 Nick Bloom Productivity and Reallocation

Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011Source: John Haltiwanger

Turnover in “Jobs” versus “Employment” – Contracting Firm example

Note: Worker flow=15, Job flow=9

Page 8: Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011 Nick Bloom Productivity and Reallocation

Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011

Quarterly Job Flows in Private Sector, 1990-2005, BED data

Source: John Haltiwanger

(1) Net jobs flows equal change in employment ≈ change in unemployment(2) Gross flows are much bigger than net flows(3) Reduction in job churn that (in manufacturing) part of a longer trend(4) Job destruction does not necessarily mean firing – could be not hiring a replacement for a separation.

Page 9: Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011 Nick Bloom Productivity and Reallocation

Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011

JOLTS monthly worker turnover data

Source: John Haltiwanger

Depth of post 9/11 recession: 1) Figures don’t add up (JOLTS is not good for

employment – CES survey more accurate)2) Still massive churn – including quits – in depths of

the recession (I quit a job in December 2001)

Page 10: Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011 Nick Bloom Productivity and Reallocation

Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011

Job Flows and Employment Flows, total private

Source: John Haltiwanger

Page 11: Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011 Nick Bloom Productivity and Reallocation

Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011

Much of the turnover is creation/destruction in same SIC4 industry

Source: John Haltiwanger, Changes defines as % over average base & end years

Excess reallocation = |job creation| + |job destruction| - |job creation-job destruction|

Page 12: Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011 Nick Bloom Productivity and Reallocation

Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011

This is very much in the spirit of Schumpeter

Page 13: Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011 Nick Bloom Productivity and Reallocation

Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011

This is very much in the spirit of Schumpeter

Although probably his most famous quote was:“Early in life I had three ambitions. I wanted to be the greatest economist in the world, the greatest horseman in Austria, and the best lover in Vienna. Well, I never became the greatest horseman in Austria“

To which the (un-attributed) response was:“Those we knew Schumpeter as an Economist, Lover or a Horseman presumed his skills were in the other two fields”

“The fundamental impulse that keeps the capital engine in motion comes from the new consumers’ goods, the new methods of production and transportation, the new markets... [The process] incessantly revolutionizes from within, incessantly destroying the old one, incessantly creating a new one. This process of Creative Destruction is the essential fact of capitalism.”Schumpeter (p. 83, 1942)

Page 14: Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011 Nick Bloom Productivity and Reallocation

Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011

High levels of turnover

Heterogeneity within industries

The lumpiness of micro-economic activity

The importance of reallocation in driving productivity

Page 15: Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011 Nick Bloom Productivity and Reallocation

Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011

Heterogeneity basic facts

Typical gap between 10th and 90th percentiles of productivity within same industry is 200% (Syverson ,2004)

These spreads are very persistent:• About 70% to 80% annual job-flows are persistent• About 60% to 70% annual productivity growth is

persistent

Page 16: Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011 Nick Bloom Productivity and Reallocation

Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011

What could cause this heterogeneity?

One possibility is pure measurement error, but:

• Productivity is strongly linked with exit and LR growth

• When looking at micro-industries where we measure plant prices (e.g. boxes, bread, block ice, concrete, plywood, etc.) still see this spread (Foster, Haltiwanger and Syverson, 2008 AER)

Page 17: Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011 Nick Bloom Productivity and Reallocation

Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011

Explanations of this heterogeneity?

Several possible economic models of the spread are:

• Mistakes/learning (Jovanovic, 1982 Econometrica)

• Mis-measurement:• “Hard” technology (e.g. R&D)• Skills• Other inputs (computers) or utilization

• Management and managers

Page 18: Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011 Nick Bloom Productivity and Reallocation

Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011

High levels of turnover

Heterogeneity within industries

The lumpiness of micro-economic activity

The importance of reallocation in driving productivity

Page 19: Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011 Nick Bloom Productivity and Reallocation

Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011

Lumpiness of growth

The share of employment growth generated by large adjustments is big (Davis and Haltiwanger, 1992 QJE)

• More than 2/3 manufacturing job creation/destruction accounted for by +25% changes

• For non-manufacturing even greater

Same is true, but more extreme, for investment (Doms and Dunne, 1998 RED).

Suggests substantial adjustment-costs in factor changes

Page 20: Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011 Nick Bloom Productivity and Reallocation

Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011

Lumpiness of employment growth

Source: John Haltiwanger, annual data manufacturing

Page 21: Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011 Nick Bloom Productivity and Reallocation

Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011

High levels of turnover

Heterogeneity within industries

The lumpiness of micro-economic activity

The importance of reallocation in driving productivity

Page 22: Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011 Nick Bloom Productivity and Reallocation

Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011

Measuring productivity (ωi,t)

Labor Productivity:

tititi lvaLP ,,,

Three factor TFP:

timtiktiltiti mklyTFP ,,,,3,

Five factor TFP:

tictietimtiktiltiti cemklyTFP ,,,,,,5,

Note: va=log(value added), l=log(labor force), k=log(tangible capital), m=log(materials, e=log(energy), c=log(IT). If IT included need to remove from tangible capital.

Page 23: Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011 Nick Bloom Productivity and Reallocation

Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011

Defining industry (or aggregate) productivity

Define a simple industry productivity index: Pt

Where:

ωi,t is the productivity of establishment i in period t (i.e. log(labor productivity) or log (TFP))

si,t is the share of establishment i in the industry in period t (i.e. the share of employment or sales in industry employment or sales)

titit sP ,,

Page 24: Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011 Nick Bloom Productivity and Reallocation

Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011

Industry productivity can increase through two channels

• Within Firms (Traditional view)– The same firms become more productive (e.g. new

technology spreads quickly to all firms, like Internet)

• Between Firms (“Schumpeterian”view)– Low TFP firms exit and resources are reallocated to

high TFP firms• High TFP firms expand (e.g. more jobs) & low TFP

firms contract (e.g. less jobs)• Exit/entry

24

Page 25: Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011 Nick Bloom Productivity and Reallocation

Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011

These two effects are well known to cricket fans

Within batsman (each batsman improves)

Between batsman (more time for your best batsman)

25

Page 26: Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011 Nick Bloom Productivity and Reallocation

Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011

Decomposing productivity (1)

Productivity growth for a balance panel of establishments can be broken down into three terms:

termCross ))((

rmBetween te )(

rm Within te)(

1,,1,,

1,1,,

1,,1,

1,1,,,1

titititi

tititi

tititi

tititititt

ss

ss

s

ssPP

Within term is included in representative agent models, while the between and cross terms would not be

Reallocation

Page 27: Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011 Nick Bloom Productivity and Reallocation

Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011

Decomposing productivity (2)

Allowing for entry and exit requires two more terms:

Exit term )(

Entry term )(

termCross ))((

termBetween )(

termWithin )(

,,

,,

,

,

1,,1,,

1,1,,

1,,1,

1,1,,,1

AverageExitExitti

AverageEntryEntryti

titititi

tititi

tititi

tititititt

titi

titi

s

s

ss

ss

s

ssPP

This is the Bailey, Hulten and Campbell (1992) decomposition

Page 28: Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011 Nick Bloom Productivity and Reallocation

Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011

*

Source: John Haltiwanger

Total reallocation (between, entry and exit) accounts for about ½ of manufacturing TFP growth

*Combines -0.08 “between” and 0.34 “cross”

Page 29: Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011 Nick Bloom Productivity and Reallocation

Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011

(A) Treats all reallocation within establishments as “within” growth• Large establishments in balanced panel (500 employees)

(B) Reallocation terms most likely to be downward biased by miss measured prices (Foster, Haltiwanger and Syversson, 2008)

So in manufacturing re-allocation of factors probably accounts for the majority of productivity growth

This is probably even an underestimate

Page 30: Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011 Nick Bloom Productivity and Reallocation

Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011

Source: Foster, Haltiwanger & Krizan (2000 and 2006)

Reallocation (including entry) accounts for almost all Retail TFP growth

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

Retail

ContinuingEstablishments

Net entry

Page 31: Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011 Nick Bloom Productivity and Reallocation

Nick Bloom, Econ 247, 2011

Source: Hsieh and Klenow (2008); mean=1

Differences in reallocation also a factor in explaining cross country TFP gaps