47
Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Why Money is Important Economics 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Kam Yu Winter 2013

Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    2

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Lecture 6 The Monetary EconomyWhy Money is Important

Economics 5118 Macroeconomic Theory

Kam Yu

Winter 2013

Page 2: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Outline

1 Introduction

2 Budget Constraint

3 Models of Money DemandCIAMIUShopping TimeTransaction Costs

4 HyperinflationTheoryReality

5 Optimal Rate of InflationThe Friedman RuleDGE Solution

6 Super-Neutrality of Money

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 2 / 45

Page 3: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Introduction

The Greatest Invention of Civilization?

Functions of Money:

1 Medium of Transactions — barter trade has very high transactioncosts, a modern economy needs a standard unit of measurement forthe prices all goods and services. The medium of exchanges should beconvenient to handle and carry.

2 Store of Wealth — wealth of money is a claim on the whole economyinstead of holding the property rights of some specific physical assets.With money intertemporal substitutions of consumption reduces risksand transaction costs.

3 Credit Market — With money banks can serve as an intermediarybetween borrowers and lenders.

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 3 / 45

Page 4: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Introduction

Key Questions

1 Who control the supply of money?

2 How much money should be circulated in the economy at any time?

3 What is the mechanism of money supply (credit channels)?

4 How do the supply of and demand for money affect the real economy?

5 Can monetary policy be used as a tool to improve the welfare ofhouseholds?

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 4 / 45

Page 5: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Budget Constraint

Nominal Household Budget Constraint

Real household budget constraint:

∆at+1 + ct = xt + rtat .

Let, in period t,

Pt = Consumer price index (CPI),

Bt = Ptbt = Value of bond holding,

Mt = Ptmt = Cash holding,

Rt = Nominal interest rate for Bt .

Nominal household budget constraint:

∆Bt+1 + ∆Mt+1 + Ptct = Ptxt + RtBt . (8.1)

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 5 / 45

Page 6: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Budget Constraint

Real Household Budget Constraint

Define πt+1 = ∆Pt+1/Pt as the inflation rate, dividing (8.1) by Pt gives

(1 + πt+1)bt+1 − bt + (1 + πt+1)mt+1 −mt + ct = xt + Rtbt . (8.2)

Rearranging gives

(1 + πt+1)[∆bt+1 + ∆mt+1] + ct = xt + (Rt − πt+1)bt − πt+1mt . (8.3)

Implications:

1 If Rt+1 = Rt , the real interest rate is rt+1 = Rt − πt+1.

2 In reality rt+1 ' Rt+1 − Et [πt+1].

3 Real return of holding money is −πt+1mt . This is effectively aninflation tax or seigniorage.

4 In the steady state ∆b = ∆m = 0 so that

∆M/M = ∆P/P or µ = π.

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 6 / 45

Page 7: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Budget Constraint

Real Household Budget Constraint

Define πt+1 = ∆Pt+1/Pt as the inflation rate, dividing (8.1) by Pt gives

(1 + πt+1)bt+1 − bt + (1 + πt+1)mt+1 −mt + ct = xt + Rtbt . (8.2)

Rearranging gives

(1 + πt+1)[∆bt+1 + ∆mt+1] + ct = xt + (Rt − πt+1)bt − πt+1mt . (8.3)

Implications:

1 If Rt+1 = Rt , the real interest rate is rt+1 = Rt − πt+1.

2 In reality rt+1 ' Rt+1 − Et [πt+1].

3 Real return of holding money is −πt+1mt . This is effectively aninflation tax or seigniorage.

4 In the steady state ∆b = ∆m = 0 so that

∆M/M = ∆P/P or µ = π.

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 6 / 45

Page 8: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Models of Money Demand CIA

Cash-in-Advance

. . . , the rest pay cash!

Model assumptions:

By the quantity theory of money, MtVt = Ptct .

Assuming Vt = 1 give the money demand function MDt = Ptct , or in

real term, mDt = ct .

Money supply, MSt is exogenous.

In equilibrium MDt = MS

t = Mt .

Households maximize utility by choosing ct , bt+1, and mt+1 subjectto the budget constraint (8.2) and mt = ct .

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 7 / 45

Page 9: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Models of Money Demand CIA

Household Maximization Problem

Lagrangian:

Lt =∞∑s=0

{βsU(ct+s) + λt+s

[xt+s + (1 + Rt+s)bt+s + mt+s

− (1 + πt+s+1)(bt+s+1 + mt+s+1)− ct+s

]+ µt+s(mt+s − ct+s)

}.

First-Order Conditions:

∂Lt∂ct+s

= βsU ′(ct+s)− λt+s − µt+s = 0, s ≥ 0,

∂Lt∂bt+s

= λt+s(1 + Rt+s)− λt+s−1(1 + πt+s) = 0, s ≥ 1,

∂Lt∂mt+s

= λt+s − λt+s−1(1 + πt+s) + µt+s = 0, s ≥ 1.

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 8 / 45

Page 10: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Models of Money Demand CIA

Key Results

Euler equation:βU ′(ct+1)

U ′(ct)(1 + rt+1) = 1. (8.4)

Steady state: ∆ct = ∆mt = 0, implying that rt = θ.

To derive the money demand function, assume for convenience thatr = Rt − πt is constant, in the steady state the budget constraint(8.2) becomes

c = x + rb − πm. (8.5)

Impose the constraint m = c ,

c =xt + rb

1 + π. (8.6)

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 9 / 45

Page 11: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Models of Money Demand CIA

The Cost of Holding Money

Equation (8.5) means that if inflation is positive, using money fortransaction results in paying an inflation tax.

Equation (8.6) implies that the higher the inflation rate in the longrun, the lower the consumption.

Consequently, monetary neutrality does not hold.

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 10 / 45

Page 12: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Models of Money Demand MIU

Money in the Utility Function

This does not mean that households enjoy having money in theirpockets per se.

Money is, like visiting the dentist’s office, not enjoyable but useful.

Utility function is increasing and concave, i.e.,

U(ct ,mt), Uc > 0,Ucc ≤ 0,Um > 0,Umm ≤ 0.

The Lagrangian is

Lt =∞∑s=0

{βsU(ct+s ,mt+s) + λt+s

[xt+s + (1 + Rt+s)bt+s

+ mt+s − (1 + πt+s+1)(bt+s+1 + mt+s+1)− ct+s

]}.

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 11 / 45

Page 13: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Models of Money Demand MIU

First-Order Conditions

∂Lt∂ct+s

= βsUc,t+s − λt+s = 0, s ≥ 0,

∂Lt∂bt+s

= λt+s(1 + Rt+s)− λt+s−1(1 + πt+s) = 0, s ≥ 1,

∂Lt∂mt+s

= βsUm,t+s + λt+s − λt+s−1(1 + πt+s) = 0, s ≥ 1.

The second and the third FOCs implies that

β∂U(ct ,mt)/∂mt = λtRt .

Combining with the first FOC gives

∂U(ct ,mt)/∂mt = Rt∂U(ct ,mt)/∂ct . (8.7)

This means marginal rate of substitution of money to consumption at theoptimum is equal to the the relative cost, which is Rt .

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 12 / 45

Page 14: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Models of Money Demand MIU

Money Demand Function

Take a functional form for utility:

U(ct ,mt) =c1−σt

1− σ+ η

(m1−σ

t

1− σ

).

Equation (8.7) becomesηm−σt = c−σt Rt ,

which gives the real money demand function

mt = ct

Rt

)1/σ

.

Contrast with the CIA model, with mt = ct , an increase in nominalinterest rate reduces money demand.

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 13 / 45

Page 15: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Models of Money Demand Shopping Time

I Shop, Therefore I Am

Households need time to shop:

nt + lt + st = 1.

Higher consumption needs more shopping time, but money can savetime:

st = S(ct ,mt), (8.12)

with S ,Sc ,Scc ≥ 0, Sm ≤ 0,Smm ≥ 0,Scm ≤ 0.

Households still enjoy consumption and leisure:

ut = U(ct , lt), Uc ,Ul ,Ucl ≥ 0,Ucc ,Ull ≤ 0.

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 14 / 45

Page 16: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Models of Money Demand Shopping Time

Household Maximization Problem

Budget constraint same as before, with xt = wtnt :

(1 + πt+1)(bt+1 + mt+1) + ct = wtnt + (1 + Rt)bt + mt .

The Lagrangian is

Lt =∞∑s=0

{βsU(ct+s , lt+s) + λt+s

[wt+snt+s + (1 + Rt+s)bt+s

+ mt+s − (1 + πt+s+1)(bt+s+1 + mt+s+1)− ct+s

]+ µt+s

[nt+s + lt+s + S(ct+s ,mt+s)− 1

]}.

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 15 / 45

Page 17: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Models of Money Demand Shopping Time

First-Order Conditions:

∂Lt∂ct+s

= βsUc,t+s − λt+s + µt+sSc,t+s = 0, s ≥ 0,

∂Lt∂lt+s

= βsUl ,t+s + µt+s = 0, s ≥ 0,

∂Lt∂nt+s

= λt+swt+s + µt+s = 0, s ≥ 0,

∂Lt∂bt+s

= λt+s(1 + Rt+s)− λt+s−1(1 + πt+s) = 0, s ≥ 1,

∂Lt∂mt+s

= λt+s − λt+s−1(1 + πt+s) + µt+sSm,t+s = 0, s ≥ 1.

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 16 / 45

Page 18: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Models of Money Demand Shopping Time

Key Results

The FOCs for bt and mt gives

λt+sRt+s = µt+sSm,t+s .

Combine this with the FOCs for ct and lt , we get

−Ul ,tSm,t = (Uc,t − Ul ,tSc,t)Rt . (8.13)

Left-hand side: Having one more dollar cash save Sm,t time shopping.The extra time gives Ul ,tSm,t more utility.

Right-hand side: The dollar used for shopping could gain interest Rt

and therefore cost Uc,tRt amount of utility. But less consumptionalso mean less shopping time (Sc,tRt) and more leisure. The extraleisure time gives Ul ,tSc,tRt amount of utility.

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 17 / 45

Page 19: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Models of Money Demand Shopping Time

Money Demand

Equation (8.13) can be solved for the money demand mt+1. Take aparametric example, utility is

U(ct , lt) = log ct + η log lt , η > 0,

and shopping time is

st = ψctmt, ψ > 0.

Then

Ul ,t =η

lt, Sm,t = −ψ ct

m2t

,

Uc,t =1

ct, Sc,t =

ψ

mt.

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 18 / 45

Page 20: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Models of Money Demand Shopping Time

Money Demand

Equation (8.13) becomes

ψηctltm2

t

=

(1

ct− ψη

ltmt

)Rt .

Using mt = ψct/st and rearranging give

mt =ctRt

(ηst/lt

1− ηst/lt

). (8.14)

Observations:

Again money demand is sensitive to the interest rate.

An increase of shopping time/leisure ratio, st/lt , increases moneydemand.

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 19 / 45

Page 21: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Models of Money Demand Transaction Costs

Transaction Cost Approach

A more general approach is to include transaction costs of consumption,T (ct ,mt) ≥ 0 with

T (0,m) = 0,Tc ≥ 0,Tcc ≥ 0,Tm ≤ 0,Tmm ≥ 0,Tmc ≤ 0,

and c + T (c ,m) being quasi-concave. The household budget constraint is

(1 + πt+1)(bt+1 + mt+1)− bt −mt + ct + T (ct ,mt) = xt + Rtbt . (8.15)

The Lagrangian is

Lt =∞∑s=0

{βsU(ct+s) + λt+s

[xt+s + (1 + Rt+s)bt+s + mt+s

− (1 + πt+s+1)(bt+s+1 + mt+s+1)− ct+s − T (ct+s ,mt+s)]}.

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 20 / 45

Page 22: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Models of Money Demand Transaction Costs

First-Order Conditions

∂Lt∂ct+s

= βsU ′(ct+s)− λt+s(1 + Tc,t+s) = 0, s ≥ 0,

∂Lt∂bt+s

= λt+s(1 + Rt+s)− λt+s−1(1 + πt+s) = 0, s ≥ 1,

∂Lt∂mt+s

= λt+s(1− Tm,t+s)− λt+s−1(1 + πt+s) = 0, s ≥ 1.

The first two FOCs gives the Euler equation

βU ′(ct+1)

U ′(ct)

1 + Tc,t

1 + Tc,t+1(1 + rt+1) = 1. (8.16)

The last two FOCs gives

Tm,t+1 = −Rt+1. (8.17)

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 21 / 45

Page 23: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Models of Money Demand Transaction Costs

Steady State

In the steady state ∆ct = ∆mt = 0 and the Euler equation becomesrt = θ.Write ct = c ,mt = m,Rt = R, πt = π, and rt = θ. The budgetconstraint and (8.17) become

c + πm + T (c ,m)− x − θb = 0, (8.18)

Tm(c ,m) + R = 0. (8.19)

Equations (8.18) and (8.19) can be written as f (x, y) = 0 wheref : R2 × R3 → R2, x = (c,m)T is the vector of endogenous variables,and y = (x , b,R)T are exogenous.Then

Dxf (x, y) =

[1 + Tc π + Tm

Tmc Tmm

],

Dyf (x, y) =

[−1 −θ 00 0 1

].

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 22 / 45

Page 24: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Models of Money Demand Transaction Costs

Money Demand Function

Note that|Dxf (x, y)| = Tmm(1 + Tc)− Tmc(π + Tm).

If we assume that Tmc = 0, then |Dxf (x, y)| > 0. Now we can apply theimplicit function theorem to f . That is, the solution x = g(y) exists and

Dg(y) = −[Dxf (x, y)]−1Dyf (x, y)

or [∂c/∂x ∂c/∂b ∂c/∂R∂m/∂x ∂m/∂b ∂m/∂R

]=

[1 + Tc π + Tm

Tmc Tmm

]−1 [1 θ 00 0 −1

].

In particular, ∂m/∂R = −1/Tmm ≤ 0 and so money demand is decreasingin R.

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 23 / 45

Page 25: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Hyperinflation Theory

Cagan’s Model of Hyperinflation

Consider a simple demand function for nominal money:

Mt =PtctRαt

=Ptct

(rt + πt+1)α, α > 0.

If ct and rt have steady and low growth rates, we can approximate this by

Mt =φPt

παt+1

. (8.25)

Write mt = logMt , pt = logPt , Cagan’s version of the inflation dynamicsis

mt − pt = −α(Etpt+1 − pt). (8.26)

Rearranging gives a first-order stochastic difference equation in pt :

Etpt+1 =1 + α

αpt −

1

αmt .

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 24 / 45

Page 26: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Hyperinflation Theory

Growth of Money Supply

Since (1 + α)/α > 1, the equation is solved forward to get

pt =1

1 + α

∞∑s=0

1 + α

)s

Etmt+s . (8.27)

Therefore price level depends on current and future money supplies.Suppose mt grows at a constant rate µ,

mt+1 −mt = µ+ εt+1,

where Et [εt+1] = 0. Then

mt+s = mt + µs +s∑

i=1

εt+i .

so thatEtmt+s = mt + µs. (8.27a)

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 25 / 45

Page 27: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Hyperinflation Theory

Money Supply and Inflation

Substitute (8.27a) into (8.27), it can be shown that (exercise)

pt = mt + αµ. (8.27b)

Using (8.27a) and (8.27b), expected inflation is

Etπt+1 = Etpt+1 − pt = Etmt+1 −mt = µ.

Observations

Expected inflation is the exogenous growth rate of money.

There are many hyperinflation episodes in history.

In most cases the government printed money as an inflation tax(seigniorage) to balance the budget due to a failure of the tax system.

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 26 / 45

Page 28: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Hyperinflation Reality

Hyperinflation Episodes

Where When Daily Rate Doubling Time

Hungary 1945–46 207% 15 hoursZimbabwe 2007–08 98% 24.7 hoursGermany 1922–23 20.9% 3.7 daysChina 1947–49 14.1% 5.3 daysTurkmenistan 1992–93 5.71% 12.7 daysUkraine 1992–94 4.6% 15.6 daysRussia 1992 4.22% 17 daysMoldova 1992–93 4.16% 17.2 daysGeorgia 1993–94 3.86% 18.6 days

Source: Steve Hanke and Nicholas Krus, Cato Institute

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 27 / 45

Page 29: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Hyperinflation Reality

The German Experience

Source: Marc Prud’homme, Statistics Canada

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 28 / 45

Page 30: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Hyperinflation Reality

Before 2008

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 29 / 45

Page 31: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Hyperinflation Reality

After 2008

Zimbabwe issued new denominations of its papermoney in 2008 after it dropped 10 zeros from itsinflated currency.

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 30 / 45

Page 32: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Optimal Rate of Inflation The Friedman Rule

The Friedman Rule

Private marginal return for the households to hold cash is −πMarginal cost of printing money is almost zero

Therefore the central bank should set −π = θ

In the long run we know that the real interest rate r = θ

Therefore r = −πNominal interest rate is therefore R = r + π = 0

In this way the opportunity cost of holding nominal balances is zero

As a result, the marginal utility of holding money, Um, will be zero aswell

This argument, however, ignores the fact that government needs revenueand seigniorage is a substitute for other taxes.

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 31 / 45

Page 33: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Optimal Rate of Inflation DGE Solution

The Household’s Problem

Utility (mt is real money balance):

U(ct , lt ,mt), Uc ,Ul ,Um > 0,Ucc ,Ull ,Umm ≤ 0

Budget constraint (note that πt+1mt+1 is seigniorage):

ct + (1 + πt+1)(kt+1 + bt+1 + mt+1)

= (1− τt)wtnt + (1 + Rkt )kt + (1 + Rb

t )bt + mt

Lagrangian:

Lt =∞∑s=0

{βsU(ct+s , lt+s ,mt+s) + λt+s

[(1− τt+s)wt+snt+s

+ (1 + Rkt+s)kt+s + (1 + Rb

t+s)bt+s + mt+s − ct+s

− (1 + πt+s+1)(kt+s+1 + bt+s+1 + mt+s+1)]}

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 32 / 45

Page 34: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Optimal Rate of Inflation DGE Solution

First-Order Conditions

With nt + lt = 1,

∂Lt∂ct+s

= βsUc,t+s − λt+s = 0, s ≥ 0,

∂Lt∂nt+s

= −βsUl ,t+s + λt+s(1− τt+s)wt+s = 0, s ≥ 0,

∂Lt∂kt+s

= λt+s(1 + Rkt+s)− λt+s−1(1 + πt+s) = 0, s ≥ 1,

∂Lt∂bt+s

= λt+s(1 + Rbt+s)− λt+s−1(1 + πt+s) = 0, s ≥ 1,

∂Lt∂mt+s

= βsUm,t+s + λt+s − λt+s−1(1 + πt+s) = 0, s ≥ 1.

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 33 / 45

Page 35: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Optimal Rate of Inflation DGE Solution

Key Results

From the first two FOCs, MRS of leisure to consumption is

∂U(ct , lt ,mt)/∂l

∂U(ct , lt ,mt)/∂c= (1− τt)wt . (8.29)

Therefore income tax τt creates a distortion in labour supply. From theFOCs for capital and bonds,

λt−1

λt=

1 + Rkt

1 + πt= 1 + rkt (8.30)

=1 + Rb

t

1 + πt= 1 + rbt (8.31)

This means that their real rates of returns are equal, that is,

rkt = rbt . (8.32)

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 34 / 45

Page 36: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Optimal Rate of Inflation DGE Solution

Applying the Friedman Rule

The Euler equation is

βUc,t+1

Uc,t(1 + rkt+1) = 1.

In the long run, rk = θ = rb. From the FOCs of c ,m, and b,

∂U(ct , lt ,mt)/∂m

∂U(ct , lt ,mt)/∂c= Rb

t . (8.33)

Applying the Friedman rule, Rbt = 0, which implies that

∂U(ct , lt ,mt)/∂m = 0. This means that households holds real moneybalances until marginal utility of money is zero. Also,

rk = θ = rb = −π.

Since θ > 0, inflation rate will be negative.

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 35 / 45

Page 37: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Optimal Rate of Inflation DGE Solution

Government’s Problem

The government’s objective is to maximize household utility subject to theresource constraint and the implementability condition. Using (8.30) and(8.31), the household budget constraint can be written as

ct + (1 + πt+1)(kt+1 + bt+1 + mt+1)

= (1− τt)wtnt − Rbt mt +

λt−1

λt(1 + πt)(kt + bt + mt).

This is a first-order difference equation in λt−1(1 + πt)(kt + bt + mt).Solving forward gives the intertemporal household budget constraint

λt−1(1 + πt)(kt + bt + mt)

=∞∑s=0

λt+s

[ct+s − (1− τt+s)wt+snt+s + Rb

t+smt+s

].

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 36 / 45

Page 38: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Optimal Rate of Inflation DGE Solution

Implementability Condition Continued

Using the FOCs for ct+s , nt+s , bt+s , and mt+s , the last equation can bewritten as the implementability condition

λt−1(1 + πt)(kt + bt + mt)

=∞∑s=0

βs (Uc,t+sct+s − Ul ,t+snt+s + Um,t+smt+s) . (8.34)

The government budget constraint is

gt + (1 + Rbt )bt + mt = τtwtnt + (1 + πt+1)(bt+1 + mt+1).

The resource constraint can be derive from the household budgetconstraint and the GBC:

F (kt , nt) = ct + kt+1 − (1− δ)kt + gt .

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 37 / 45

Page 39: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Optimal Rate of Inflation DGE Solution

Government’s Problem

Assuming constant returns to scale and competitive markets,

F (kt , nt) = (rkt + δ)kt + wtnt .

The resource constraint becomes

rkt kt + wtnt = ct + kt+1 − kt + gt .

Government maximizes social welfare subject to the resource constraintand the implementability condition,

Lt =∞∑s=0

{βsU(ct+s , lt+s ,mt+s) + φt+s

[rkt+skt+s + wt+snt+s

− ct+s − kt+s+1 + kt+s − gt+s

]}+ µ

[ ∞∑s=0

βs(Uc,t+sct+s − Ul ,t+snt+s + Um,t+smt+s)

− λt−1(kt + bt + mt)

].

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 38 / 45

Page 40: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Optimal Rate of Inflation DGE Solution

Modified Lagrangian

Define

V (ct+s , lt+s ,mt+s , µ) = U(ct+s , lt+s ,mt+s)

+ µ(Uc,t+sct+s − Ul ,t+snt+s + Um,t+smt+s).

The Lagrangian can be rewritten as:

Lt =∞∑s=0

{βsV (ct+s , lt+s ,mt+s , µ) + φt+s

[rkt+skt+s

+ wt+snt+s − ct+s − kt+s+1 + kt+s − gt+s

]}− µλt−1(kt + bt + mt).

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 39 / 45

Page 41: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Optimal Rate of Inflation DGE Solution

First-Order Conditions

∂Lt∂ct+s

= βsVc,t+s − φt+s = 0, s ≥ 0,

∂Lt∂nt+s

= −βsVl ,t+s + φt+swt+s = 0, s ≥ 0,

∂Lt∂kt+s

= φt+s(1 + rkt+s)− φt+s−1 = 0, s ≥ 1,

∂Lt∂mt+s

= βsVm,t+s = 0, s ≥ 1.

The first three FOCs are the same as in Lecture 5 and so the previousresults apply. The last one implies that

Vm,t = (1 + µ)Um,t + µ(Ucm,tct − Ulm,tnt + Umm,tmt) = 0.

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 40 / 45

Page 42: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Optimal Rate of Inflation DGE Solution

Parametric Analysis

Consider the utility function

U(c , l ,m) =c1−σ

1− σ+ η

m1−φ

1− φ+ z(l).

Then the FOC for money becomes

η(1 + µ− µφ)m−φt = 0.

Since η and 1 + µ− µφ are not zero, m−φt = 0.

For φ > 0, we need mt →∞.

Therefore marginal utility of money becomes zero.

By (8.33) this implies that Rbt = 0.

We have shown that the Friedman rule is optimal!

Objection: The result relies on strong assumptions on the functional form.Also, the rule implies a constant rate of deflation, which is somewhatimpractical.

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 41 / 45

Page 43: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Optimal Rate of Inflation DGE Solution

Parametric Analysis

Consider the utility function

U(c , l ,m) =c1−σ

1− σ+ η

m1−φ

1− φ+ z(l).

Then the FOC for money becomes

η(1 + µ− µφ)m−φt = 0.

Since η and 1 + µ− µφ are not zero, m−φt = 0.

For φ > 0, we need mt →∞.

Therefore marginal utility of money becomes zero.

By (8.33) this implies that Rbt = 0.

We have shown that the Friedman rule is optimal!

Objection: The result relies on strong assumptions on the functional form.Also, the rule implies a constant rate of deflation, which is somewhatimpractical.

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 41 / 45

Page 44: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Super-Neutrality of Money

Super-Neutrality of Money

New classical economic models conclude that nominal shocks have nolong-run effect on the real economy.

In the case of monetary shocks it is known as super-neutrality ofmoney.

Changes in money balance do not affect consumption, capital, andoutput.

Our money demand models (CIA, MIU, shopping time) seem toconclude that money is not super-neutral. But the results are basedon partial equilibrium analysis.

A basic general equilibrium model involves a government withseigniorage revenue.

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 42 / 45

Page 45: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Super-Neutrality of Money

Seigniorage and Transfer

Consider a model in which the government return the seigniorage revenueto the households as transfers. The household budget constraint is

(1 + πt+1)(kt+1 + mt+1) + ct + Tt = wtnt + mt + (1 + Rt)kt , (8.35)

where Tt < 0 means a transfer to households. The GBC is

(1 + πt+1)mt+1 −mt + Tt = 0. (8.36)

Eliminating Tt from (8.35) and (8.36) gives the consolidated constraint

(1 + πt+1)kt+1 + ct = wtnt + (1 + Rt)kt .

Notice that money also disappear from the equation.

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 43 / 45

Page 46: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Super-Neutrality of Money

Money Neutrality

The household’s utility maximization problem with utility functionU(ct , lt ,mt) gives the same long-run results of r = R − π = θ andUm/Uc = R (see equation (8.33)).

In the long run the consolidated constraint becomes

c = rk + wn.

Therefore consumption does not depend on money balance.

Capital and output are also independent of m in the long run.

Objection: The model of transferring seigniorage revenue to households isunrealistic.

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 44 / 45

Page 47: Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy - Lakehead Universityflash.lakeheadu.ca/~kyu/E5118/M6.pdfBudget Constraint Nominal Household Budget Constraint Real household budget constraint: a t+1

Super-Neutrality of Money

A Bit More Realistic

Government finances expenditure gt with seigniorage and lump-sumtaxes Tt .

The GBC is(1 + πt+1)mt+1 −mt + Tt = gt . (8.38)

Household behaviour remains the same.

The steady-state consumption is also independent of money:

c = rk + wn − g .

The long-run GBC isg = T + πm.

Kam Yu (LU) Lecture 6 The Monetary Economy Winter 2013 45 / 45