10
Connecting Policy to the FDI Human Capital Threshold: A Theoretical Framework Joshua Jensen * Abstract Many empirical studies over the last 15 years have found that FDI is positively correlated with economic growth conditional on a minimum human capital threshold being met; if this condition is not met effects of FDI on growth are found to be statistically insignificant from zero or even negative. This paper builds off of Borensztein, De Greggario, and Lee’s (1998) theoretical model to incorporate this threshold and evaluate basic policy actions. This paper theoretically demonstrates that when an economy does not meet the FDI human capital threshold it can weakly increase economic growth rates by placing a tax on foreign firms. 1 Introduction A prevalent theme found in policies of governments, whether national or regional, is the attempt to attract foreign direct investment (FDI) via multinational corporations (MNCs). This is especially seen in developing countries. This is based on the basic idea that FDI can bring economic growth, primarily through technology spillovers. Consider, world FDI growth rates over the last three decades have had dramatic increases, peaking around 40 percent average annual growth rate by the late 1990s (Wang and Wong 2011). Further, the literature has shown that human capital is a pivotal factor in determining the impact of FDI. FDI is often sought out at the policy level on the assumption that it will bring economic growth; indeed many countries, especially developing, try to attract MNCs to induce inward FDI (Wang and Wong 2009). For example, Mastromarco (2008) observes that a developing country in early industrialization may find it to be more effective to attract FDI to gain access to technology spillovers, than to just develop the same technology locally. However, FDI may not always have positive effects or be more beneficial than domestic investment. For instance, Figilio and Blonigen (2000) find in US states that while foreign firms tend to pay higher wages, the established incentives to attract the firms usually result in a decrease in public education expenditure. Similarly, Miyamoto (2003) observes that developing countries governments face very limited budgetary resources and tend to underinvest in human capital. Ironically, human capital is found to be a crucial determinant of attracting FDI as well as determining FDI’s effectiveness. Indeed a wave of studies, which will be discussed at length later on, have found that FDI is positively correlated with economic growth conditional on a minimum human capital threshold being met; if this condition is not met effects of FDI on growth are found to be statistically insignificant from zero or even negative (Borensztein, De Greggario, and Lee 1998, Xu 2000, Ford, Rork, and Elmslie 2008, Wang and Wong 2009 & 2011). In a key study, Borensztein, De Greggario, and Lee (1998, henceforth BDL (1998)) establish a strong theoretical framework and demonstrate a positive relationship between FDI and economic growth. Build- ing off of their model, this paper incorporates the human capital threshold into a theoretic framework and evaluates basic policy actions. This paper theoretically demonstrates that when an economy does not meet the FDI human capital threshold it can weakly increase economic growth rates by placing a * Author is from the University of Hawai’i at Manoa. Thank you to Dr. James Roumasset for helpful comments. All errors are my own. 1

Jensen-Theoretical_FDI_Human Capital_Growth_5-12

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Jensen-Theoretical_FDI_Human Capital_Growth_5-12

Connecting Policy to the FDI Human Capital Threshold: A

Theoretical Framework

Joshua Jensen∗

Abstract

Many empirical studies over the last 15 years have found that FDI is positively correlated witheconomic growth conditional on a minimum human capital threshold being met; if this condition isnot met effects of FDI on growth are found to be statistically insignificant from zero or even negative.This paper builds off of Borensztein, De Greggario, and Lee’s (1998) theoretical model to incorporatethis threshold and evaluate basic policy actions. This paper theoretically demonstrates that whenan economy does not meet the FDI human capital threshold it can weakly increase economic growthrates by placing a tax on foreign firms.

1 Introduction

A prevalent theme found in policies of governments, whether national or regional, is the attempt toattract foreign direct investment (FDI) via multinational corporations (MNCs). This is especially seenin developing countries. This is based on the basic idea that FDI can bring economic growth, primarilythrough technology spillovers. Consider, world FDI growth rates over the last three decades have haddramatic increases, peaking around 40 percent average annual growth rate by the late 1990s (Wang andWong 2011). Further, the literature has shown that human capital is a pivotal factor in determining theimpact of FDI.

FDI is often sought out at the policy level on the assumption that it will bring economic growth;indeed many countries, especially developing, try to attract MNCs to induce inward FDI (Wang and Wong2009). For example, Mastromarco (2008) observes that a developing country in early industrializationmay find it to be more effective to attract FDI to gain access to technology spillovers, than to justdevelop the same technology locally. However, FDI may not always have positive effects or be morebeneficial than domestic investment. For instance, Figilio and Blonigen (2000) find in US states thatwhile foreign firms tend to pay higher wages, the established incentives to attract the firms usually resultin a decrease in public education expenditure. Similarly, Miyamoto (2003) observes that developingcountries governments face very limited budgetary resources and tend to underinvest in human capital.Ironically, human capital is found to be a crucial determinant of attracting FDI as well as determiningFDI’s effectiveness. Indeed a wave of studies, which will be discussed at length later on, have found thatFDI is positively correlated with economic growth conditional on a minimum human capital thresholdbeing met; if this condition is not met effects of FDI on growth are found to be statistically insignificantfrom zero or even negative (Borensztein, De Greggario, and Lee 1998, Xu 2000, Ford, Rork, and Elmslie2008, Wang and Wong 2009 & 2011).

In a key study, Borensztein, De Greggario, and Lee (1998, henceforth BDL (1998)) establish a strongtheoretical framework and demonstrate a positive relationship between FDI and economic growth. Build-ing off of their model, this paper incorporates the human capital threshold into a theoretic frameworkand evaluates basic policy actions. This paper theoretically demonstrates that when an economy doesnot meet the FDI human capital threshold it can weakly increase economic growth rates by placing a

∗Author is from the University of Hawai’i at Manoa. Thank you to Dr. James Roumasset for helpful comments. Allerrors are my own.

1

Page 2: Jensen-Theoretical_FDI_Human Capital_Growth_5-12

tax on foreign firms. As well, this paper illustrates a subsidy on human capital formation would strictlyincrease economic growth in all cases, which is what one would predict by BDL (1998).

The paper proceeds as follows: section 2 provides a literature review, section 3 develops the paperstheoretical framework, section 4 analyses two policy actions, and section 5 concludes.

2 Literature Review

FDI has long been a popular topic in Economics, in which there have traditionally been mixed resultson FDI and technology spillovers. In the view of Ford, Rork, and Elmslie (2008, henceforth FRE(2008))although many studies’ results are mixed on FDI and technology spillovers, those that control for thecapacity of local firms to absorb the technology do find correlation between the two. Thus it is clear thatthe host’s absorption capacity plays a crucial role. In that vein, several studies have identified humancapital as an important determinant of FDI. Noorbakhsh, Paloni, and Youssef (2001) find that humancapital has a statistically significant relationship with FDI inflow and is one of the most importantdeterminants of FDI inflow. Additionally they observe that countries that rely on low-cost, low-skilllabor, or natural resources find it difficult to induce FDI for high-value industries. Further, Miyamoto(2003) finds that human capital is a key factor in attracting FDI. Thus, we see that human capital playsa crucial role in determining FDI.

In their seminal study, BDL (1998) establish a robust positive relationship between FDI and economicgrowth provided a minimum threshold of human capital is met; given this condition they further findevidence that FDI contributes to economic growth by being an important vehicle for technology transferand stimulating technological progress in the host country. BDL (1998) use gross FDI inflow panel datafrom the IMF along with Barro and Lee’s (1993) measures of average years of male secondary schoolingas a proxy for human capital stock; the data is across 69 developing countries from 1970 to 1989.Using mainly seemingly unrelated regressions (SUR) techniques, their main regression shows that FDIhas a positive overall effect on economic growth with the magnitude depending on the stock of humancapital. However, when only considering countries with low human capital the direct effect of FDI isobserved to be negative. The authors calculate thresholds of secondary school attainments for variousspecifications, in which each country that satisfies the human capital threshold benefits positively fromFDI in terms of economic growth. Further, the authors infer that the benefits of FDI come through achannel of technological spillover resulting in higher efficiency rather than that of capital accumulation.BDL (1998) also develop a HK model to motivate the study, which this paper builds off of. Theirtheoretical model is important as it establishes a basis for understanding the relationship between FDIand economic growth, which is shown to be strictly positive. However, the model does not account forthe human capital threshold. In all, BDL’s (1998) most robust empirical finding is the positive effect ofFDI on economic growth is dependent on the level of human capital of the host country. Their findingof the FDI and human capital threshold has since been much extended upon.

Moreover, Wang and Wong (2009) provide a meaningful extension of both BDL (1998) and Alfaro,et al. (2004). In short, Alfaro, et al. (2004) find that FDI has a positive correlation with economicgrowth given that a well-developed financial system is in place. Wang and Wong (2009) in bringingthese studies together find evidence that FDI has two main catalysts for economic growth each of whichcreates growth through different channels: 1. once a host country reaches the human capital thresholdFDI is positively correlated with only productivity growth, and 2. that at certain level of developmentin the countrys financial system FDI is positively correlated with only capital growth. The authors showthis using the same data as in BDL (1998) and similar SUR techniques. Wang and Wong’s (2009) maincontribution is studying and providing evidence on the channels of economic growth of FDI under notedcorrelated conditions.

Furthermore, Xu (2000) investigates the impact of FDI on technology transfers and spillovers basedon US MNCs contributions across 40 countries from 1966 to 1994. Xu observes that FDI coming from aUS MNC positively contributes to growth when a minimum human capital threshold is met in the hosteconomy. As well, Wang and Wong (2011) revisit BDL (1998) but take quality of education into accountas well as quantity. They use education quality measures from Lee and Barro (2001), to construct two

2

Page 3: Jensen-Theoretical_FDI_Human Capital_Growth_5-12

separate quality indices. Wang and Wong (2011) find that the BDL (1998) established relationshipbetween FDI and economic growth with a given human capital threshold still holds when controlling foreducation quality, although the human capital threshold is significantly lower. 1

Additionally, FRE (2008) show that US states with high foreign presence grow faster relative to stateswith a low presence given a minimum threshold of human capital. A major improvement in this studyis how it deals with the potential issues of using FDI flow data, an issue which is acknowledged by BDL(1998). 2 As labor conditions are clearly different in the US than developing countries, FRE (2008) usepercent of population with at least a college degree as a more case appropriate proxy for human capitalthan secondary educational attainment. FRE (2008) find that within US states a well educated workforceis important in realizing potential growth effects of FDI and find evidence of a necessary human capitalthreshold to experience a greater impact on per capita output growth than domestic investment.

To conclude, the key finding of positive effects of FDI on economic growth given a met threshold ofhost human capital has been supported in many studies and in both developing and developed countries.This is a strong finding that has many potential economic and policy implications that have yet to beexplored. Hence, this is a rich topic that requires further investigation and has been sparse in theoreticalstudy. This paper attempts to present a theoretical framework that incorporates the human capitalthreshold and investigates two basic policy instruments.

3 Model Framework

This paper’s model is based on and building off of the BDL (1998) theoretical model, which has rootsin the Romer (1990) endogenous technological change model. Based on the history of strong empiricalfindings regarding it, this paper incorporates the FDI human capital threshold and its relationship toFDI and growth into the model.

3.1 Derivation

We begin by defining the key variables:3

Y ≡ final goodA ≡ state of the environmentK ≡ physical capitalH ≡ human capitalH ≡ human capital thresholdx(j) ≡ capital good j in continuum of varietiesm(j) ≡ capital good j rental rateN ≡ total varieties of capital goods in economyN∗ ≡ total world varieties of capital goodsn ≡ capital good varieties produced by domestic firmsn∗ ≡ capital good varieties produced by foreign firmsF (•) ≡ fixed setup cost of technology adaptationr ≡ interest rateC ≡ consumptionσ ≡ risk aversionρ ≡ time discounter

1This emphasizes the importance of quality in education as higher quality reduces the required quantity.2FDI flow data may be suspect as it represents present investment, thus it assumes that related effects take place in

the same period. Hence it is unlikely that flow data reflects effects of spillovers to domestic firms. In this case sign andsignificance both hold, but it is the magnitude that is suspect. To get around this problem FRE (2008) measure FDIthrough the average share of nonbank employment.

3This paper begins by following closely the derivation method of its framework from BDL (1998)

3

Page 4: Jensen-Theoretical_FDI_Human Capital_Growth_5-12

We define an economy with a single consumption good following a constant returns to scale Cobb-Douglas HK production:

Yt = AHαt K

1−αt (1)

H0 & K0 given

The economy has an aggregate of N accumulating varieties of capital goods that comprises physicalcapital. Thus physical capital expands through increasing N . So at each time period:

K =

[∫ N

0

x(j)1−αdj

] 11−α

(2)

Furthermore, in the economy there are two types of firms which produce capital goods: domestic andforeign. All firms directly invest in the economy. Hence,

N = n+ n∗ (3)

As well, equations 1 and 2 imply that the marginal productivity of an individual capital good is:

∂Y

∂x(j)= A(1 − α)Hαx(j)−α

Firms are assumed to rent produced capital goods to final goods producers. Thus, the optimalitycondition would imply the good’s rental rate would equal the good’s marginal productivity,

m(j) = A(1 − α)Hαx(j)−α (4)

Certain technologies must be adapted in order for an increase in the amount of capital varieties.Technology adaptation is assumed to be costly, with fixed setup costs (F ). Foreign firms are assumedto bring advanced ‘knowledge’ on new capital goods that may be available in other countries, therebypotentially making it easier to adopt the technology. Thus technology adaptation costs have a negativerelationship to the ratio of foreign firms to total number of firms (n

N ). Based on the strong empiricalfindings over the last two decades regarding the human capital threshold on FDI as previously discussed,we make the assumption that if the human capital threshold is not met foreign firms are not able toadequately capture gains from an advance in ‘knowledge’. Thus technology adaptation costs incurred inthis case may be no different than domestic firms or perhaps even greater. Also there is assumed to be a‘catch-up’ effect, where it is cheaper to imitate certain products over others,typically products that havebeen around longer. This is achieved by imposing a positive relationship between technology adaptationcosts and the ratio of varieties in an economies to the varieties in the world ( NN∗ ). Thus,

F

(n∗

N,N

N∗, H

)(5)

where:

∂F

∂(n∗

N)

< 0, if H ≥ H

∂F

∂(n∗

N)

≥ 0, otherwise

and∂F

∂(N

N∗)> 0

4

Page 5: Jensen-Theoretical_FDI_Human Capital_Growth_5-12

We then assume capital goods fully depreciate in each time period and steady state where interestrate (r) is constant. So capital firms profits for new variety of capital j are:

Π(j)t =

∫ ∞t

[m(j)x(j) − x(j)]e−r(s−t)ds− F

(n∗

N,N

N∗, H

)(6)

Maximizing equation 6 subject to 4 yields:

x(j) = A1α (1 − α)

2αH (7)

Further, equation 7 back into 4 finds rental rate:

m(j) = (1 − α)−1 (8)

Assuming free entry into market we can conclude equilibrium profits will be zero. Thus with zeroprofits condition we can solve for interest rate:

r = A1αφF

(n∗

N,N

N∗, H

)−1H (9)

where, φ = α(1 − α)2−αα

Consumers maximize a CRRA utility function:

Ut =

∫ ∞t

C1−σs

1 − σe−ρ(s−t)ds (10)

Thus optimal consumption path with rate of return equal to interest rate,

CtCt

=1

σ(r − ρ) (11)

So in steady state equilibrium consumption growth is equal to output growth:

g =1

σ(r − ρ) (12)

Hence by substituting equation 9 into 12 we derive the economy growth rate:

g =1

σ

[A

1αφF

(n∗

N,N

N∗, H

)−1H − ρ

](13)

3.2 Extending Model with Tax and Subsidy

Suppose now there is a tax, τ , imposed on foreign firms. Assume that:

n∗(τ), such that∂n∗

∂τ< 0 (14)

Also suppose a subsidy for human capital formation activities, ξ. Assume that:

H(ξ), such that∂H

∂ξ> 0 (15)

Thus one can restate equation 13 incorporating these definitions:

g(τ) =1

σ

[A

1αφF

(n∗(τ)

N,N

N∗, H(ξ)

)−1H(ξ) − ρ

](16)

Note that the definitions from 14 and 15 imply the following relations:

n∗(τ) < n∗(0)

H(ξ) > H(0)

5

Page 6: Jensen-Theoretical_FDI_Human Capital_Growth_5-12

4 Results

Generally, we find that equation 13 implies:

∂g

∂(n∗

N )= − 1

σ

A 1αφ

F ′(n∗

N ,NN∗ , H

)F(n∗

N ,NN∗ , H

)2H + ρ

(17)

hence,

∂g

∂(n∗

N )=

{> 0, if H ≥ H

≤ 0, otherwise

This is congruent with previous empirical results, that FDI (n∗

N ) affects economic growth positively whenthe human capital threshold is met but has either no effect or a negative effect when not met.

In the following subsections this paper analyses the effect on economic growth from implementingthe two basic policies, a tax on foreign firms and a subsidy to human capital formation. Analysis is doneby comparing an economy with the enacted policy to a baseline economy with no such policies.

4.1 With Tax Alone

Consider a policy of a simple tax specifically on foreign firms as denoted earlier. We compare the growthof an economy that has the policy of a tax on foreign firms, g(τ), and an economy that has no suchpolicy, g(0). We can assume for the analysis that the tax revenue is destroyed.

In analysing a policy of placing a tax on foreign firms, we find two distinct cases of whether or notthe human capital threshold is met.

Case 1: H ≥ HThis case is when the human capital threshold is met. Begin with comparing technology adaptation

fixed costs,

F

(n∗(τ)

N,N

N∗, H

)> F

(n∗(0)

N,N

N∗, H

)due to

∂F

∂ n∗

N

< 0 and n∗(τ) < n∗(0). Hence,

F (τ, •)−1 < F (0, •)−1

F (τ, •)−1H < F (0, •)−1H

So equation 16 implies4 that,g(τ) < g(0) (18)

Under the case where the human capital threshold is met, a policy of a tax on foreign firms yields alower economic growth rate than the baseline. Therefore, as one would expect placing a special tax onforeign firms would reduce the growth of an economy.

4Equation normalized with ξ = 0 in this subsection.

6

Page 7: Jensen-Theoretical_FDI_Human Capital_Growth_5-12

Case 2: H > HIn this case the economy does not satisfy the human capital threshold. So fixed setup costs of

technology adaptation compared are:

F

(n∗(τ)

N,N

N∗, H

)≤ F

(n∗(0)

N,N

N∗, H

)

due to∂F

∂ n∗

N

≥ 0.5 Hence,

F (τ, •)−1H ≥ F (0, •)−1H

Hence, equation 16 implies that,g(τ) ≥ g(0) (19)

So interestingly, placing a tax on foreign firms when the human capital threshold is not met weakly in-creases economic growth rates. Note too that under this same framework if τ2 > τ1, then g(τ2) ≥ g(τ1);which implies that the greater restriction there is on foreign firms the higher growth will be.

Therefore, we find that placing a tax on foreign firms when an economy falls below the human capitalthreshold results in a weakly higher growth rate than the case in which there is no such restrictions onforeign firms. However, if an economy is in a state above the human capital threshold then a tax has theexpected result of constricting the affected firms and lowering economic growth.

4.2 With Subsidy Alone

Consider the policy of a simple subsidy that increases human capital as denoted earlier. Adopting apolicy of subsidizing human capital formation one finds expected results as predicted by the BDL (1998)theoretical model. We find three distinct cases:

Case 1: H > H(ξ) > H(0)In the case where both levels of human capital fall below the threshold, comparing technology adap-

tation costs yields,

F

(n∗

N,N

N∗, H(ξ)

)= F

(n∗

N,N

N∗, H(0)

)as human capital does not directly affect the technology adaptation costs but instead the partial derivativeof FDI. Then of course follows:

F (ξ, •)−1 = F (0, •)−1

F (ξ, •)−1H(ξ) > F (0, •)−1H(0)

Hence a modified equation 16,6

g(ξ) > g(0) (20)

5Also n∗(τ) < n∗(0)6Equation normalized with τ = 0 and denoted as g(ξ) in this subsection.

7

Page 8: Jensen-Theoretical_FDI_Human Capital_Growth_5-12

Case 2: H(ξ) ≥ H > H(0) In this case the economy with the subsidy meets human capitalthreshold, but the baseline does not. It follows,

F

(n∗

N,N

N∗, H(ξ)

)< F

(n∗

N,N

N∗, H(0)

)

due to∂F (ξ, •)

∂n∗

N

< 0 and∂F (0, •)

∂n∗

N

≥ 0. So in extension,

F (ξ, •)−1 > F (0, •)−1

F (ξ, •)−1H(ξ) > F (0, •)−1H(0)

Again equation 16 then implies,g(ξ) > g(0) (21)

Case 3: H(ξ) > H(0) ≥ HLastly when both levels of human capital satisfy the threshold,

F

(n∗

N,N

N∗, H(ξ)

)= F

(n∗

N,N

N∗, H(0)

)again because human capital does not directly affect the technology adaptation costs, as in Case 1.

It follows,F (ξ, •)−1 = F (0, •)−1

F (ξ, •)−1H(ξ) > F (0, •)−1H(0)

So finally equation 16 infers,g(ξ) > g(0) (22)

Therefore, we find that in all three cases the economic growth rate is strictly higher with the subsidythan in the baseline. This is what we would expect, as one of the original results from the BDL (1998)theoretical model is a positive correlation between human capital and economic growth. Note thatuniquely in the case where the economy with the subsidy meets human capital threshold but the baselineeconomy does not, technology adaptation costs F are strictly lower. This policy runs into obvious issuesin terms of funding and may not outweigh opportunity costs for funding other programs.

5 Conclusion

Literature shows strong evidence of the existence of a necessary human capital threshold. Virtually allrelated studies, in both developing and developed countries, have found that FDI is positively correlatedwith economic growth conditional on the condition that a minimum human capital threshold is met; ifthis condition is not met effects are found to be statistically insignificant from zero or even negative.There appears to be no prior existing theoretical model that incorporates this finding. This paper buildsoff of BDL’s (1998) theoretical model to incorporate this human capital threshold and evaluate basicpolicy actions.

This paper theoretically evaluates the policy actions of a tax placed on foreign firms and a subsidy tohuman capital formation. It is demonstrated that when an economy does not meet the FDI human capitalthreshold it can weakly increase economic growth rates by placing a tax on foreign firms. However if the

8

Page 9: Jensen-Theoretical_FDI_Human Capital_Growth_5-12

human capital threshold is met, placing a tax on foreign firms would strictly decrease the economic growthof an economy. Furthermore, this paper illustrates a subsidy on human capital formation would strictlyincrease economic growth in all cases. These are obviously potentially important policy implications andrequire further rigorous investigation.

References

[1] Alfaro, L., et al. “FDI and Economic Growth: The Role of Local Financial Markets.” Journal ofInternational Economics 64.1 (2004): 89-112.

[2] Balasubramanyam, V.N. and Yingqi Wei. Foreign Direct Investment: Six Country Case Studies.Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar Publishing, Inc., 2004.

[3] Barro, Robert and J-W Lee. “International comparisons of educational attainment.” Journal ofMonetary Economics 32 (1993): 361-394.

[4] Barro, Robert and J-W Lee. “International Data on Educational Attainment: Updates and Impli-cations.” Oxford Economic Papers, Oxford University Press, 53.3 (2001): 541-563.

[5] Borensztein, E., J. De Gregorio and J-W. Lee. “How does foreign direct investment affect economicgrowth?” Journal of International Economics 45.1 (1998): 115-135.

[6] Figlio, David and Bruce Blonigen. “The Effects of Direct Foreign Investment on Local Communities.”Journal of Urban Economics 48 (2000): 338-363.

[7] Ford, Timothy C., Bruce T. Elmslie and Jonathan C. Rork. “Foreign Direct Investment, EconomicGrowth, and the Human Capital Threshold: Evidence from US States.” Review of InternationalEconomics 16.1 (2008): 96-113.

[8] Havranek, Tomas and Zuzana Irsova. “Which Foreigners are Worth Wooing? A Meta-Analysisof Vertical Spillovers from FDI.” William Davidson Institute Working Papers Series with numberwp996 (2010).

[9] Kapstein, Ethan B. “Virtuous Circles? Human Capital Formation, Economic Development and theMultinational Enterprise.” OECD Development Centre: Working Paper No. 191. 2002.

[10] Mastromarco, Camilla. “Foreign Capital and Efficiency in Developing Countries.” Bulletin of Eco-nomic Research 60.4 (2008): 351-374.

[11] Miyamoto, Koji. “Human Capital Formation and Foreign Direct Investment in Developing Coun-tries.” Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) Working Paper Series.Paper No. 211. (2003).

[12] Moran, Theodore H., Edward M. Graham and Magnus Blomstrom. Does foreign direct investmentpromote development? Washington DC: Center for Global Development, 2005.

[13] Noorbakhsh, Farhad, Alberto Paloni and Ali Youssef. “Human Capital and FDI Inflows to Devel-oping Countries: New Empirical Evidence.” World Development 29.9 (2001): 1593-1610.

[14] Romer, Paul M. “Endogenous Technological Change.” Journal of Political Economy 98.5 (1990):71-102.

[15] Shatz, Howard J. “Gravity, Education, and Economic Development in a Multinational AffiliateLocation.” The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development 12.2 (2003): 117-150.

[16] Suliman, Adil H. and Andre Varella Mollick. “Human Capital Development, War and Foreign DirectInvestment in Sub-Saharan Africa.” Oxford Development Studies 37.1 (2009): 47-61.

[17] Wang, Miao and M.C. Sunny Wong. “FDI, Education, and Economic Growth: Quality Matters.”Atlantic Economic Journal 39 (2011): 103-115.

[18] Wang, Miao and M.C. Sunny Wong. “Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth: The GrowthAccounting Perspective.” Economic Inquiry 47.4 (2009): 701-710.

9

Page 10: Jensen-Theoretical_FDI_Human Capital_Growth_5-12

[19] Xu, Bin. “Multinational enterprises, technology diffusion, and host country productivity growth.”Journal of Development Economics 62 (2000): 477-493.

[20] Zhang, Kevin Honglin and James R. Markusen. “Vertical multinationals and host-country charac-teristics.” Journal of Development Economics 59.2 (1999): 233-252.

10