164
Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted in fulfilment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy School of Economics and Finance QUT Business School Queensland University of Technology 2020

Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    1

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted

Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries Empirical Evidence from Chile

Javier Beltraacuten

MSc (Economics)

Submitted in fulfilment of the requirements for the degree of

Doctor of Philosophy

School of Economics and Finance

QUT Business School

Queensland University of Technology

2020

i

Keywords

Count data models

Data Envelopment Analysis

Dutch disease

Economic diversity

Incivilities

Income inequality

Local government efficiency

Natural resource dependence

Panel data

Paradox of plenty

Racial diversity

Resource curse hypothesis

Social cohesion

Spatial analysis

ii

Abstract

Persistently high indicators of relative economic disadvantage such as measures of income

inequality can give rise to a feeling of discontent in the population which in turn can trigger

costly social conflicts For instance inequality has been suggested as one of the main causes of

social outburst considering recent events in many countries around the world This has generated

in extant literature an increasing number of criticisms of current political and socio-economic

models This research considers the Chilean economy which is recognised as an example of the

success of standard economic thinking however it is also well-known for its persistently high

levels of inequality an adverse indicator of economic performance This thesis contributes with

three essays to the understanding of the sources and potential consequences of income inequality

in Chile The data consider a panel of 324 Chilean counties and their corresponding municipalities

for the 2006ndash2017 period

The first essay investigates the association between income inequality and the endowment

of natural resources The Gini coefficient of each county is used as a measure of income inequality

The influence of natural resources on income inequality is captured by using the proportion of

employment in the primary sector as a proxy for the degree of dependence on natural resources in

each county Previous literature has identified a significant spatial dimension of income inequality

in Chile but this spatial dimension has been largely neglected in the domain of policy design and

implementation Thus the analysis in this essay applies spatial regression models for cross-

sectional and panel data while controlling for other socioeconomic and demographic

characteristics The main finding is that contrary to what theory predicts our measure of natural

resource dependence in terms of employment shows a robust and significant negative association

with income inequality The main implication of this empirical result is that a transformation

process towards activities less dependent on natural resources reinforces rather than reduces the

persistence of income inequality at least through the channel of employment Hence this

transformation process imposes additional challenges to central and local governments in their

goal of reducing income inequality Empirical analysis also shows a significant degree of positive

spatial autocorrelation of income inequality This means that counties with similar levels of income

iii

inequality tend to cluster in space The regression analysis confirms the importance of capturing

geographical heterogeneity in the explanation of income inequality however gives less support

to a process of spatial dependence like a spillover effect of income inequality among

neighbouring counties

Among the potential consequences of income inequality the literature highlights its

possible impacts on the efficiency in the provision of public services by local authorities however

empirical evidence is very little For this reason the second essay analyses the technical efficiency

of municipal local governments in Chile and examine if income inequality has significant impacts

on the variations in the efficiency levels across municipalities An input-oriented Data

Envelopment Analysis is used to measure municipal efficiency Results reveal that the municipal

production technology is characterized by variable returns to scale but scale inefficiencies only

explain a small proportion of total inefficiency This justify a need for analysing the influence of

variables which are beyond the control of local authorities in explaining differences in municipal

efficiency The main hypothesis tested was whether income inequality has a negative influence on

municipal efficiency whilst a measure of natural resource dependence at the county level was used

as an instrument to control for the effects of possible endogeneity issues Results showed that

changes in income inequality could be associated with changes in the municipal efficiency level

in the same magnitude but in the opposite direction This confirms that local authorities in counties

characterized by high levels of income inequality face greater challenges to achieve more efficient

performance This result suggests that policies aimed at reducing income inequality can also

increase the efficiency of local governments Our results also reveal that policies such as

amalgamation de-amalgamation or cooperation among municipalities should be designed

specifically for each region rather than as a standard national strategy

Finally the third essay analyses how social cohesion is associated with the levels of

economic and racial diversity Social cohesion is proxied using the reported number of antisocial

behaviours catalogued as incivilities Incivilities are those antisocial behaviours which violate

social norms but are not usually considered as criminal Research has documented the implications

of incivilities on human stress health public behaviour and increasing feelings of insecurity and

fear among the population Few studies have explicitly considered incivilities as a dependent

variable to identify their determinants or use them to analyse the weakening of social cohesion and

iv

the growing feeling of social unrest in contemporary societies Economic diversity is proxied using

the Gini coefficient in each county and racial diversity through the number of new visas granted

as proportion of the county population Our findings show that incivilities are strongly associated

with racial diversity and to a lesser extent with economic diversity The rate of incivilities also

shows a negative association with the level of income and a positive relationship with poverty and

unemployment rates These results give empirical support to the idea that both relative and

absolute indicators of economic deprivation play an important role in understanding the growing

problem of incivilities in highly unequal economies like Chile Results also show that the rate of

incivilities is negatively related to the degree of financial autonomy of municipalities These

findings represent promising areas for central and local governments in the implementation of

policies aimed at increasing social cohesion through the reduction of incivilities and other types of

antisocial behaviours

v

Table of Contents

Keywords i

Abstract ii

Table of Contents v

List of Figures viii

List of Tables ix

List of Abbreviations x

Statement of Original Authorship xi

Acknowledgements xii

Chapter 1 Introduction 13

Income inequality and dependence on natural resources 14

Local government efficiency and income inequality 16

Social cohesion and economic diversity 19

Contributions 21

Thesis outline 23

Chapter 2 Natural Resources Curse or Blessing Evidence on Income Inequality at the County Level in Chile 24

21 Introduction 24

22 Inequality and Natural Resources 28 221 Theoretical Framework 28

Cross-country literature 29 Single country evidence 32

222 The relevance of the spatial approach 33

23 Research problem and hypotheses 35

24 Data and Methods 36 241 Operationalization of key variables 36 242 Control variables 40 243 Methods 41 244 Spatial Model Specification 43

25 Results 44 251 Exploratory Spatial Data Analysis (ESDA) 44 252 Cross-sectional analysis 45 253 Panel Data analysis 48

26 Discussion and conclusions 51

Chapter 3 The Impact of Income Inequality on the Efficiency of Municipalities in Chile 55

vi

31 Introduction 55

32 Related Literature 61 321 Measuring efficiency of local governments 61 322 Explaining differences in LGE 63 323 The trade-off between efficiency and equity 64

33 Methodology 66 331 Chilean Municipalities and period of analysis 66 332 Measuring municipal efficiency 68 333 Inputs and outputs used in DEA 70 334 Regression model 71 335 The instrument 75

34 Results and discussion 77 341 DEA results 77

Returns to scale 78 Efficiency measure 80

342 Regression results 82 Exploratory spatial analysis 82 Cross-sectional analysis 83 Panel data analysis 84

35 Conclusions 88

Chapter 4 Social Cohesion Incivilities and Diversity Evidence at the municipal level in Chile 91

41 Introduction 91

42 Related Literature 95 421 The Community Heterogeneity Thesis 95 422 The literature on incivilities 97 423 The ldquoIncivilities Thesisrdquo 99

4 3 Methodology 100 431 Period of analysis and data sample 100 432 Operationalisation of the response variable and exploratory analysis 101 433 Measures of community heterogeneity and control variables 105 434 Methods 108 435 Hypotheses 111

44 Results and Discussion 112

4 5 Conclusions 118

Chapter 5 Conclusions 120

Bibliography 126

Appendices 139

Appendix A Summary statistics income inequality 139

Appendix B Summary statistics for NRD measures by region 140

Appendix C Regional administrative division and defined zones 141

Appendix D Summary statistics numeric controls and correlation matrix 142

vii

Appendix E Static spatial panel models 143

Appendix F Analysis OLS residuals cross-sectional (six-year average) analysis 145

Appendix G Linear panel data models 146

Appendix H Spatial panel models (Generalized Moments (GM) estimation) 147

Appendix I Inputs and outputs used in DEA analysis 148

Appendix J Technical and scale efficiency 149

Appendix K Correlation matrix 150

Appendix L Returns to scale by year and zone 151

Appendix M Returns to scale by year (maps) 152

Appendix N Efficiency status by year (maps) 153

Appendix O Spatial distribution efficiency scores by year (maps) 154

Appendix P Analysis OLS residuals cross-sectional (six-year average) analysis 155

Appendix Q OLS regressions for cross-sectional and panel data 157

Appendix R Quantile maps incivilities rate by group (average total period) 159

Appendix S Correlation matrix numeric covariates 160

Appendix T Negative Binomial regressions 161

Appendix U Coefficients economic and racial diversity by geographical zone 162

viii

List of Figures

Figure 21 Average share in GDP of economic activities (2006ndash17) 37

Figure 22 Evolution of Gini coefficient and measures of NRD (2006ndash17) 38

Figure 23 Spatial distribution of Gini coefficient and NRD (2006ndash17) 39

Figure 23 Moran scatter plots for variables gini and pss_casen 45

Figure 31 Geographical distribution of Chilean regions and macrozones 74

Figure 32 Evolution of efficiency scores and the proportion of firms by sector 77

Figure 33 Evolution technical efficiency (TE) pure technical efficiency (PTE) and scale efficiency (SE) 78

Figure 34 Returns to scale by zone 79

Figure 35 Evolution mean efficiency scores (VRS) by zone 81

Figure 41 Evolution number and rates of incivilities and crime (DMCS) in Chile 2006-2017 102

Figure 42 Evolution total number of incivilities by category 104

Figure 43 Spatial distribution of incivilities rate per 1000 inhabitants (2006 vs 2017) 104

Figure 44 Annual average number of incivilities per county 109

Figure C1 Geographical distribution of Chilean regions and 3 zones 141

Figure D1 Correlation matrix numeric explanatory variables 142

Figure F1 Moran scatter plot OLS residuals 145

Figure I1 Examples of inputs and outputs used to measure LGE (based on Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018) 148

Figure K1 Correlation matrix contextual factors 150

Figure M1 Spatial distribution of returns to scale by county per year 152

Figure N1 Spatial distribution of efficient (E es = 1) and inefficient (I es lt 1) counties per year 153

FigureO1 Custom breaks maps of efficiency scores (VRS) by county per year 154

Figure P1 Moran scatter plot efficiency scores and OLS residuals 155

Figure R1 Spatial distribution of incivilities by group (Average rate per 1000 inhabitants 2006-09-11-13-15-17) 159

Figure S1 Correlation matrix numeric covariates 160

ix

List of Tables

Table 21 Cross-sectional Model Comparison (six-year average data) 47

Table 22 ML Spatial SAR Models 50

Table 23 ML Spatial SEM Models 50

Table 24 ML Spatial SARAR Models 51

Table 31 Descriptive statistics Inputs and Output variables used in DEA analysis 71

Table 32 Summary Statistics Numeric Contextual Factors 74

Table 33 Summary efficiency scores (VRS) by zone and region 80

Table 34 Cross-sectional (censored) regressions 84

Table 35 Panel data regressions 87

Table 41 Summary statistics total count of incivilities and by category (full sample and period) 103

Table 42 Summary statistics numeric explanatory variables 108

Table 43 Poisson regressions 113

Table 44 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson models by region 115

Table 45 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson model by incivility group 116

Table A1 Summary statistics Gini coefficients by year and zone 139

Table B1 Summary statistics NRD measures by region 140

Table D1 Summary Statistics Numeric Explanatory Variables 142

Table F1 Analysis OLS residuals Anselin Method 145

Table G1 Panel regressions (non-spatial) 146

Table H1 GM Spatial Models 147

Table L1 Returns to scale (percentage of municipalities) 151

Table P1 Analysis OLS residuals Anselin Method 155

Table P2 OLS and spatial regression models for the six-year averaged data 156

Table Q1 OLS cross-sectional regression per year 157

Table Q2 OLS panel regressions Pooled random effects and instrumental variable 158

Table T1 Negative Binomial regressions 161

Table U1 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson models by geographic zone 162

x

List of Abbreviations

Constant returns to scale CRS

Data envelopment analysis DEA

Decreasing returns to scale DRS

Efficiency scores ES

Exploratory spatial data analysis ESDA

Generalized methods of moments GMM

Gross Domestic Product GDP

Increasing returns to scale IRS

Local government efficiency LGE

Maximum likelihood ML

Municipal common fund MCF

Natural resource dependence NRD

Natural resource endowment NRE

Ordinary Least Squares OLS

Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development OECD

Own permanent revenues OPR

Resource curse hypothesis RCH

Spatial autoregressive model SAR

Spatial error model SEM

Variable returns to scale VRS

xi

Statement of Original Authorship

The work contained in this thesis has not been previously submitted to meet requirements

for an award at this or any other higher education institution To the best of my knowledge and

belief the thesis contains no material previously published or written by another person except

where due reference is made

Signature QUT Verified Signature

Date _________04092020_________

xii

Acknowledgements

First I would like to thank my wife Lilian who joined me in this challenge and patiently

supported me all these years I would also like to thank our family who always supported us from

Chile I especially thank my sister Silvia who took care of our house and dog

I am also grateful to my supervisory team Dr Radhika Lahiri and Dr Vincent Hoang who

supported and guided me in the process of making this thesis a reality

I also thank the Deans of the Faculty of Economics and Business at my beloved University

of Talca Dr Arcadio Cerda and Dr Rodrigo Herrera who trusted me and supported me in this

process In the same way I would like to thank all the support of the director of the Commercial

Engineering career Mr Milton Inostroza

Finally I would like to thank the government of Chile for the financial support that made

my stay and studies possible here at the Queensland University of Technology

13

Chapter 1 Introduction

Efficiency and equity issues are often considered together in the evaluation of economic

performance While higher efficiency usually measured by growth rates of income per capita

correlates with improvements in measures of well-being the link between inequality and well-

being is less clear This is reflected not only in the type and amount of research related to efficiency

and equity but also in the role that both play in the design of the economic policy For instance

several market-oriented countries have focused primarily on economic growth trusting in a trickle-

down process where financial benefits given to the wealthy are expected to ultimately benefit the

poor However despite the growing interest in the issue of inequality there is a considerable lack

of studies about its consequences

Although some level of inequality is inevitable or even necessary for economic activity this

study is motivated by the argument that relatively high levels of inequality can be associated with

many problems such as persistent unemployment increasing fiscal expenses indebtedness and

political instability (Berg amp Ostry 2011) Inequality can also have other severe social

consequences including increased crime rates teenage pregnancy obesity and fewer

opportunities for low-income households to invest in health and education (Atkinson 2015) In

addition when the role of money and concentration of economic power undermine political

outcomes inequality of opportunities hampers social and economic mobility trust and social

cohesion In summary inequality can increase the fragility of the economic and social situation in

a country reducing economic growth and making it less inclusive and sustainable

14

A country well-known for its market-oriented economy and high level of dependence on

natural resources is Chile Chilean success in terms of economic growth contrasts with its inability

to reduce the persistently high levels of social and economic inequality particularly in the last

three decades Using data for the 2006-2017 period and considering 324 out of 345 Chilean

counties this thesis presents three essays with empirical evidence aiming to explain the

phenomenon of persistent income inequality and some of its potential consequences The first

essay aims to analyse how the evolution and variability of income inequality throughout the

country are associated with the degree of natural resource dependence The second essay studies

the relevance of income inequality in explaining cross-county differences in the performance of

local governments (municipalities) Finally the third essay explores the link between social

cohesion and community heterogeneity highlighting the importance of economic and racial

diversity

Income inequality and dependence on natural resources

The first essay explores how cross-county differences in income inequality are associated

with differences in the degree of dependence on natural resources We use the Gini coefficient in

each county as our dependent variable and the proportion of employment in the primary sector as

our measure of natural resource dependence The main hypothesis is that income inequality should

be positively related to the degree of natural resource dependence To test our hypothesis we use

a spatial econometric approach This approach is motivated by the study of Paredes Iturra and

Lufin (2016) who explore the geographic heterogeneity of income inequality in Chile finding

evidence of a significant spatial dimension

15

The theoretical and empirical literature has mostly proposed a positive link between

inequality and natural resources Although most of the evidence corresponds to cross-country

comparisons there is also increasing body of research at the local level A rationale underpinning

the positive link suggested in the literature is that in natural resource-rich countries ownership is

concentrated in small groups and extraction activities require low-skilled workers (Gylfason amp

Zoega 2003 Leamer Maul Rodriguez amp Schott 1999) Another market-based argument often

labelled as the ldquoDutch Diseaserdquo proposes that natural resource windfalls could be associated with

a crowding-out effect on the manufacturing sector (Corden amp Neary 1982 Easterly 2007) This

process encourages rent-seeking behaviours discourages investment in physical and human

capital and delays the process of technology adoption and industrialization (Auty 2001 Bulte

Damania amp Deacon 2005 Gylfason amp Zoega 2003) The result could be a lower economic

growth which is the central idea under the ldquoResource Curse Hypothesisrdquo (Auty 1993 Sachs amp

Warner 2001)

An ldquoinstitutionalrdquo argument for the positive association between inequality and the

endowment of natural resources is based on the so-called ldquoParadox of Plentyrdquo (Borge Parmer amp

Torvik 2015 Dauvin amp Guerreiro 2017) The idea is that both national and local authorities have

less incentive to operate efficiently when they experience windfalls in their revenues for

instance from natural resources This could end with corrupted authorities exerting patronage

clientelism and designing public policies to favour specific groups of the population (Uslaner amp

Brown 2005) Evidence also suggests that the final effect of natural resource booms on income

inequality will depend on authoritiesrsquo capacity to manage these additional resources the extent of

commuting and migration among regions and the potential increase in the demand for non-tradable

16

goods which are intensive in unskilled workers (Aroca amp Atienza 2011 Cust amp Poelhekke 2015

Fleming amp Measham 2015b Howie amp Atakhanova 2014 Michaels 2011)

Contrary to most theoretical and empirical evidence we find that income inequality shows

a robust and significant negative association with our proxy for natural resource dependence This

result suggests that the process of transformation to an economy less dependent on natural

resources could have exacerbated rather than alleviated the persistence of income inequality The

decrease in the participation of the primary sector in employment in favour mainly of the tertiary

sector highlights the importance of the latter to explain the current high levels of inequality and its

future evolution Another important result is that spatial linear models show practically the same

results as traditional linear models This could be interpreted as the spatial dimension previously

found in income inequality is not the result of spatial dependence in the variable itself for instance

due to a process of spillover among counties Hence the usually found positive spatial

autocorrelation of income inequality (similar levels in neighbouring counties) could be explained

by spatial patterns in other variables or to the spatial heterogeneity that characterizes the Chilean

economy

Local government efficiency and income inequality

Essay 2 delves deep into the potential trade-off between efficiency and equity We measure

the efficiency of Chilean municipalities which correspond to the organizations in charge of

managing each county Municipal efficiency is understood as ldquotechnical efficiencyrdquo that is the

possibility that each municipality has reached the same level of outputs with less use of inputs

Then we analyse how income inequality controlling for other contextual factors such as

socioeconomic demographic geographical and political characteristics may help to explain

17

differences in municipal performance Our main hypothesis is that municipal efficiency is

inversely associated with income inequality Moreover we seek a causal interpretation of this

relationship

Municipal performance could be influenced by income inequality in direct and indirect ways

In a direct sense income inequality is used to capture the degree of heterogeneity and complexity

in the demand for public services that citizens exert over local authorities Hence higher levels of

income inequality should be associated with a more complex set of public services and therefore

with lower levels of municipal efficiency (Jottier Ashworth amp Heyndels 2012) Furthermore

when high levels of inequality exist the richest groups can exert a higher influence over local

authorities resulting in low quality and quantity of services for most of the population Among

indirect effects high and persistent inequality could be the source of corrupted institutions and

local authorities favouring themselves or specific groups This undermines citizensrsquo participation

in civic activities and their willingness to monitor municipal performance (Uslaner amp Brown

2005) Additionally the potential benefits of decentralization on the way local governments

deliver public services will be limited when the context is characterized by corrupted politicians

and a limited administrative and financial capacity (Scott 2009)

We measure municipal efficiency using an input-oriented Data Envelopment Analysis

(DEA) to obtain efficiency scores for our sample of 324 municipalities in each year from 2006 to

2017 Then we study the influence on municipal efficiency of income inequality and our set of

contextual factors using a panel of six years corresponding to those years for which household

income information is available 2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017 Our dependent variable

is the set of efficiency scores which are relative measures of efficiency They are relative to the

18

municipalities included in the sample and they do not imply that higher technical efficiency gains

cannot be achieved Thus we use both cross-sectional and panel censored regression models To

tackle endogeneity issues and suggest a causal interpretation we also propose using the proportion

of firms in the primary sector as an instrument for income inequality

We find an average efficiency score of 83 meaning that Chilean municipalities could

reduce the use of inputs by 17 without reducing their outputs We also measure municipal

efficiency under different assumptions related to returns to scale This allows us to disaggregate

technical efficiency to assess whether inefficiencies are due to management issues (pure technical

efficiency) or scale issues (scale efficiency) Although the results show that most municipalities

operate under increasing or decreasing returns to scale scale inefficiencies only explain a small

proportion of total municipal inefficiencies This highlights the need to look for contextual factors

outside the control of local authorities to explain differences in municipal performance

Geographical representations of our results in terms of returns to scale and efficiency scores

show some spatial clustering process among municipalities Spatial statistics tests confirm that

efficiency scores show a significant positive spatial autocorrelation This means that neighbouring

municipalities tend to show similar levels of efficiency This similar performance could be due to

a process of spatial dependence (eg efficiency spillovers among neighbouring municipalities) or

due to the existence of structural-geographical similarities (spatial heterogeneity) To assess the

spatial dimension in municipal efficiency abstracting from temporal fluctuations we use a cross-

section of data consisting of the six-year average for the variables in our panel After running a

regression of efficiency scores against the set of controls the analysis of OLS residuals shows that

the spatial autocorrelation is almost completely removed This means that the spatial pattern in

19

municipal efficiency can be explained (controlled) by other variables such as regional indicator

variables rather than efficiency itself Given this result we proceed to study the influence of

income inequality on municipal efficiency using traditional (non-spatial) regression analysis

In contrast to literature that emphasizes an equity-efficiency trade-off (Andersen amp Maibom

2020 Berg amp Ostry 2011 Browning amp Johnson 1984 Okun 2015) that is greater equality leads

to lower efficiency we find that municipal efficiency is inversely associated with income

inequality This implies that more equal counties are also those with higher municipal efficiency

Furthermore the coefficient of income inequality is close to one when we use the instrumental

variable approach This means that a reduction in income inequality ceteris paribus should be

associated with an increase in the same magnitude in municipal efficiency This result has strong

policy implications The non-existence of the trade-off suggests that there is more to be gained by

targeting policies towards the reduction of inequality than conventional theories suggest For

instance these policies may help increase the levels of efficiency and well-being at least at the

municipal level

Social cohesion and economic diversity

The third essay studies the relationship between the degree of social cohesion and diversity

in Chile Extant literature has argued that one of the main factors influencing social cohesion is

the degree of economic and ethnic-racial diversity within a society This diversity erodes social

cohesion reducing trust and corrupting institutions (Letki 2008 Rothstein amp Uslaner 2005

Tolsma Van der Meer amp Gesthuizen 2009 Uslaner 2011 2013)

To measure social cohesion scholars have traditionally used measures of social capital trust

or feelings of insecurity (Ariely 2014 Chan To amp Chan 2006 Letki 2008) We suggest the use

20

of the rate of incivilities per 1000 inhabitants as a proxy for social cohesion Incivilities correspond

to those antisocial behaviours (eg groups of rowdy teens and public drunkenness) or visible

neighbourhood conditions (eg graffiti and abandoned buildings) that tend not to be treated as

crime Using the rate of incivilities is arguably a more objective and reliable measure of social

cohesion particularly in countries where institutions of order and security are among the most

trusted An increase in the rate of incivilities rather than changes in crime rates should better

capture the worsening in social cohesion experienced in countries such as Chile where crime rates

are not growing but social conflicts are on the rise Thus the main hypothesis in this essay is that

the rate of incivilities (social cohesion) should be positively (negatively) associated with economic

and racial diversity

Using panel count data models we start analysing how differences in incivilities rates

between and within counties are associated with differences in indicators of relative and absolute

economic disadvantage We use the Gini coefficient of each county as our measure of economic

diversity Although we find a significant and positive association between the rate of incivilities

and the level of income inequality the magnitude of the link seems to be small Among absolute

indicators of economic disadvantage only the level of income shows a strong effect Next we

include our measure of racial diversity We use the number of new visas granted to foreigners as

a proportion of the county population Results show a significant and strong positive association

between the rate of incivilities and racial diversity

To check the robustness of our results we analyse the impact of our measures of economic

and racial diversity running our models separately for each Chilean region and clustering them

geographically We also split the total number of incivilities in four categories to see which type

21

of incivilities show the greatest association with our measures of diversity In general results

support the ldquocommunity heterogeneity hypothesisrdquo that higher community heterogeneity is

associated with higher rates of incivilities (Alesina amp La Ferrara 2002 Letki 2008 Tolsma et al

2009) However results do not support the ldquoincivilities thesisrdquo that the distribution of incivilities

tends to mirror the distribution of income inequality (Skogan 1999 Taylor 1999)

Three results stand out among the set of control variables First the level of education shows

and independent and significant negative association with the rate of incivilities This is in contrast

to previous studies where education acts mainly as a moderator of the effect of economic and racial

diversity on social cohesion (Tolsma et al 2009) The results also show that there is no significant

relationship between the rate of incivilities and the proportion of young population This is relevant

because policies aimed to reduce incivilities usually put the focus on specific groups such as young

people which are linked to physical and social incivilities when social control is weakened

Finally the degree of financial municipal autonomy also shows a significant negative association

with the rate of incivilities This result suggests that municipalities can contribute independently

or together with the central government to reduce incivilities and strengthen social cohesion

Contributions

The three essays in this thesis provide several important insights into the analysis of the

causes and consequences of income inequality particularly in the context of Chile ndash a typical

resource rich economy with persistently high levels of income inequality

Essay 1 advances the understanding of the relationship between income inequality and

natural resources in Chile extending the empirical analysis from the regional level to the county

level In addition the geographic heterogeneity of income inequality is explored with the inclusion

22

of alternative sources of spatial dependence as a potential dimension of the causal relationship

between income inequality and natural resources This essay demonstrates the relevance of natural

resources in explaining the persistence of income inequality even after controlling for other

socioeconomics and institutional factors Findings from this study have potential contribution not

only in the design of policies aimed to reduce income inequality but also in addressing the current

developmental bias between the metropolitan region and the rest of the country

Essay 2 is one of the first studies that undertake a longitudinal analysis of the effects of

income inequality on the efficiency of municipal governments in Chile To capture the role of the

municipal governments in the provision to local people of public services such as education and

health we specify several inputs and outputs in our efficiency model which is different from the

conventional specification in the existing literature For example the number of medical

consultations in public health facilities and the number of enrolled students in public schools are

used as outputs instead of general indicators such as county population Our empirical analysis

also utilises a larger sample of municipalities and covers a much longer period spanning from 2006

to 2017 This essay also investigates the contextual factors beyond the control of local authorities

that can explain variations in the efficiency of municipal governments across the country

Empirical findings from Essay 2 help us increase our understanding of the production

technology of municipalities the sources of inefficiencies and specifically the impact of income

inequality on the performance of local authorities The results deliver two main policy

implications First municipal inefficiencies in the provision of public goods and services differ

across Chilean municipalities In addition efficiency levels show some degree of spatial

autocorrelation This implies that policies such as amalgamation or cooperation among

23

municipalities could have effects beyond the municipalities involved which must be considered

Second the causal effect that income inequality has on municipal efficiency provides another

dimension into the design and implementation of development policies

Essay 3 explores for the first time the effects of economic and racial diversity on social

cohesion in Chile This essay considers incivilities as manifestation of social cohesion and

investigates as extant literature suggests whether indicators of relative economic disadvantage

such as income inequality are among the main factors driving social disorganization and social

unrest Empirical findings suggest that on the one hand economic heterogeneity captured by the

Gini coefficient has a disparate effect both in terms of magnitude and significance on the rate of

incivilities across the country On the other hand the impact of racial heterogeneity appears to be

stronger more significant and of a similar magnitude throughout the country Results also provide

new insights into the design of national policies addressing social disorders particularly those

policies focussed on specific groups of the population and the role of local authorities Overall the

findings provide an opportunity to advance the understanding of the process of weakening in the

social cohesion experienced in Chile and the conflicts that have risen from this process

Thesis outline

The remainder of the thesis is organized as follows Chapter 2 presents essay 1 examining

the association between income inequality and the degree of dependence on natural resources

Chapter 3 presents essay 2 which looks for a causal relationship between municipal efficiency and

income inequality Chapter 4 presents essay 3 analysing the relationship between social cohesion

and economic and racial diversity Finally Chapter 5 presents some concluding remarks

24

Chapter 2 Natural Resources Curse or Blessing Evidence on

Income Inequality at the County Level in Chile

21 Introduction

A phenomenon of increasing inequality of incomes and wealth in recent decades has been

documented by leading scholars and international organizations such as the International Monetary

Fund (Berg amp Ostry 2017 Ostry Berg amp Tsangarides 2014) and the Organization for Economic

Cooperation and Development (Cingano 2014) These efforts have placed the topic of inequality

at the top of the current economic debate recognizing inequality as a determinant not only of

economic growth but also of human development They also have highlighted the necessity for

more research on the drivers of inequality and mechanisms through which it manifests aiming to

design effective policies in reducing economic and social inequalities

Various factors have been analysed as the sources of high and increasing levels of inequality

Among the most significant factors are the levels of income at initial stages of economic

development (Kuznets 1955) Globalization (Milanovic 2016) skill-biased technological change

(Tinbergen 1975) investment in human capital (Murphy amp Topel 2016) institutions

redistributive policy and country-specific characteristics (Acemoglu 1995 2002 Acemoglu

Aghion amp Violante 2001 Acemoglu Johnson amp Robinson 2001) Our focus in this essay is on

the importance that the natural resource endowment (NRE) or lack thereof can play in the

determination of income disparities

25

This essay studies the patterns and evolution of income inequality in the context of a natural

resource-rich country Using the case of the Chilean economy we aim to understand and

disentangle how a phenomenon of high- and persistent-income inequality is related to the

endowment of natural resources that a country owns Chile is an interesting case to study because

despite showing a successful history of economic growth inequality among individuals and among

aggregated spatial units has shown a strong persistence (Paredes et al 2016) Furthermore Chile

has remained among the most unequal countries in the world1

Theory and empirical evidence do not establish a clear link between income inequality and

NRE In addition NRE has received considerably less attention (Auty 2001 ElGindi 2017) and

most of the evidence has been focused on cross-country comparisons For instance NRE can

influence inequality by determining its initial levels (Engerman amp Sokoloff 1994 1997

Engerman Sokoloff Urquiola amp Acemoglu 2002) shaping the evolution of institutions

(Acemoglu 2002) make the educational system less intellectually challenging and moulding the

structure of economic activity (Leamer et al 1999) So studying how cross-county differences in

NRE are associated with the distribution of income within a country has theoretical empirical and

policy implications

In this study we offer empirical evidence on the relationship between income inequality and

the endowment of natural resources using data at the county level in Chile for the period 2006-

2017 Income inequality is measured by the Gini coefficient The importance of NRE is proxied

using a measure of natural resource dependence (NRD) defined as the percentage of the total

1 A 2014 OECD report on income inequality (httpwwwoecdorgsocialincome-distribution-databasehtm) showed Chile as the country with the highest Gini coefficient of disposable income among OECD countries OECD also indicates Chile as the country with the widest gap between the richest 10 percent and the poorest 10 percent of countryrsquos population among its 34 members (OECD 2014)

26

employment in each county corresponding to the primary sector (agriculture forestry fishing and

mining)

The main hypothesis to be tested is whether income inequality is positively associated with

the degree of NRD The transmission mechanisms through which natural resources could influence

socioeconomic outcomes could be based on the market or institutions The market-based approach

argues that natural resource booms could be associated with an appreciation of the real exchange

rate and a crowding out effect over other more productive economic activities such as

manufacturing It could also delay the adoption of new technologies and reduce incentives to invest

in physical and human capital (Gylfason amp Zoega 2003) Based on the ldquoResource Curse

Hypothesisrdquo (RCH) natural resources could be a curse when the political and institutional

framework is weak and natural resources are concentrated in space such as oil and minerals

(Deacon 2011) 2 Among institutional channels a higher NRD or natural resource booms could

be associated with rent seeking misallocation of labour and entrepreneurial talent institutional

and political decline or even violent conflicts For instance the ldquoParadox of Plentyrdquo sustains that

windfalls of revenues as a consequence of resource booms could be related to a lack of incentives

to perform efficiently corruption patronage and local authorities favouring their voters or being

captured by the richest groups (Dauvin amp Guerreiro 2017) Hence a higher NRD or natural

resource booms could be the explanation not only for low levels of growth in regions more

dependent on natural resources but also it could be the root of income disparities

2 There is a wide strand of research on the Resource Curse Hypothesis however the evidence so far is not conclusive Evidence in favour of RCH has been mainly found in developing resource rich countries (Auty 1993 2001 Badeeb Lean amp Clark 2017 Blanco amp Grier 2012 Borge et al 2015 Brunnschweiler amp Bulte 2008 Sachs amp Warner 2001 Van der Ploeg 2011)

27

To test our hypothesis that is whether the levels of income inequality across counties are

positively associated with the degree of NRD we use a spatial econometric approach We use this

approach because attributes such as income inequality in one region may not be independent of

attributes in neighbouring regions (Armstrong amp Taylor 2000) This process of spatial dependence

invalidates the use of traditional (non-spatial) approaches

This study seeks to make two contributions to research First previous empirical evidence

shows a significant spatial dimension of income inequality in Chile (Paredes et al 2016)

However this dimension has been barely explored with most studies limiting the degree of

disaggregation to a regional scale (Aroca amp Bosch 2000) We use a spatial approach which makes

it possible to model and test the significance of the spatial dimension in the analysis of income

inequality and its relationship with other variables Second previous research for the Chilean

economy linking inequality with NRE has been mainly focused on explaining differences between

regions or the importance and effects of the mining-copper sector (Aroca amp Atienza 2011 Ebert

amp La Menza 2015 Lagos amp Blanco 2010 Rehner Baeza amp Barton 2014) We extend this

analysis using data for local economies Identifying and quantifying the impact of NRE on income

inequality at the county level is likely to be more informative for policies aiming to address the

current developmental bias between the metropolitan region and the rest of the country Moreover

the analysis of the role of natural resources in conjunction with other potential sources of inequality

may shed lights in understanding the persistence of the high levels of inequality observed in the

Chilean economy All in all this study could contribute to the design of policies that

simultaneously help reduce inequality increase efficiency and promote sustainable and inclusive

growth

28

Our main finding shows that after controlling for other potential sources of income

inequality such as educational level demographic characteristics and the level of public

government expenditure the degree of dependence on natural resources has a significant effect on

income inequality However contrary to our expectations the effect is negative This result

suggests that the natural or policy-driven process of transformation from primary and extractive

activities to manufacturing and service sectors imposes additional challenges to central and local

authorities aiming to reduce income inequality

In section 22 we review the literature on the relationship between income inequality and

natural resources In section 23 we establish our research problem and main hypothesis Section

24 describes our data and methods and section 25 the empirical results We finish with section

26 discussing our main results concluding and proposing avenues for future research

22 Inequality and Natural Resources

221 Theoretical Framework

Explanations for income inequality can be associated with individual institutional political

and contextual characteristics Individual characteristics include age gender and mainly the level

of education and skills of the population in the labour force For instance globalization and

technological change lead firms to increase the demand for skilled labour deepening income

inequality between skilled and unskilled workers (Atkinson 2015 Milanovic 2016 Tinbergen

1975) Among institutional characteristics labour unions collective bargaining and the minimum

wage have been suggested as explanations of income inequality (Acemoglu Aghion et al 2001

Atkinson 2015) Policy design associated with market regulation progressive taxation and

redistribution can also impact the levels and patterns of inequality

29

A key factor in understanding the levels and differences in income distribution within a

country may be its endowment of natural resources NRE shapes the structure of the economy

(Leamer et al 1999) it is associated with the creation of institutions that define the political

culture and it can also influence the performance of other sectors (Watkins 1963) In addition

NRE determines initial conditions market competition ownership over resources rent seeking

and the geographical concentration of the population and economic activity

Cross‐countryliterature

Bourguignon and Morrison (1990) introduce one of the earliest theoretical frameworks

describing the relationship between inequality and NRE They develop a small open economy

model where income distribution is a function of NRE ownership structure and trade protection

Giving cross-sectional evidence for a group of developing countries they conclude that the impact

of NRE particularly mineral resources and land depends on the number and size of the firms

whether they are public or private and the level of protection A higher concentration of production

in a few private firms a big share of production oriented to foreign instead of domestic markets

and protection increasing the relative price of scarce resources are some of the reasons explaining

why some countries are less egalitarian than others

NRE could also influence the evolution and levels of inequality by determining the initial

distribution of incomes This is known as the ldquoEngerman-Sokoloff Hypothesisrdquo (Engerman amp

Sokoloff 1997 Engerman et al 2002) In addition Leamer (1999) proposes that inequality and

development paths in each economy are a function of its economic structure which in turn depends

on ldquofundamentalsrdquo and ldquosymptomsrdquo On the one hand ldquofundamentalsrdquo refer to resource

endowment production structure closeness to markets and governments interventions On the

30

other hand ldquosymptomsrdquo are related to institutions employment structure and net export structure

Using this conceptual framework Leamer argues that natural Resource-Rich Countries (RRC) can

experience a higher level of inequality because can have a ldquodumbbell educational systemrdquo

ownership is concentrated in small groups and extraction activities require low-skilled workers

This implies fewer incentives to educate citizens until very late in the development process

resulting in human capital not prepared to take advantage of the process of technological progress

and delaying the emergence of more efficient and competitive sectors such as manufacturing and

services

Using 1980 and 1990 data for a group of countries classified according to land abundance

Leamer (1999) provides evidence showing that on the one hand land-scarce countries concentrate

their production and employment in sectors that promote equality such as capital-intensive

manufacturing chemical or machinery On the other hand countries abundant in natural resources

concentrate their production trade or employment in sectors that promote income inequality such

as the production of food beverages extraction activities or forestry

Gylfason and Zoega (2003) using a framework based on standard growth models also

proposed a positive relationship between NRE and inequality They assume that workers can work

in the primary sector or in the manufacturing (including services) sector In addition wage income

is equally distributed in the manufacturing sector but unequally in the primary sector (because of

initial distribution competition rent seeking etc) Therefore inequality will be greater when a

bigger proportion of labour is dedicated to extraction activities in the primary sector This

phenomenon is further amplified because of lower incentives to invest in physical and human

capital to adopt new technologies and to increase the share of the manufacturing sector

31

Diverse mechanisms explaining the link between NRE and inequality have been proposed

arguing that NRE determines simultaneously economic growth and inequality (Gylfason amp Zoega

2003) NRE could impact economic growth through the real exchange rate and the crowding-out

effect on manufacturing (ldquoDutch Diseaserdquo) reducing incentives to invest in physical and human

capital (Easterly 2007) and influencing the processes of technology adoption industrialization

and diversification of the economy in a manner that is less conducive to growth (Bulte et al 2005)

These potential explanations related to the called ldquoResource Curse Hypothesisrdquo do not have strong

empirical support (Auty 2001 Bulte et al 2005)

NRE may also influence economic growth through the quality of institutions (Acemoglu

1995 Acemoglu Aghion et al 2001 Acemoglu amp Robinson 2002 Engerman amp Sokoloff 1997

Engerman et al 2002) the concentration of ownership political power and rent-seeking NRE

acts by shaping institutional context and social infrastructure a phenomenon that is stronger when

resources are spatially concentrated such as minerals and plantations (Bulte et al 2005) NRE

could also have a significant effect on social cohesion and instability spreading its influence like

a disease (Brunori Ferreira amp Peragine 2013 Kanbur amp Venables 2005 Milanovic 2016

Ocampo 2004)

Considering a non-tradable sector intensive in unskilled workers Goderis and Malone

(2011) develop a model where the natural resources sector experiences an exogenous gift of

resource income They analyse the impact over income inequality of resource booms proxied by

changes in a commodity price index They conclude that inequality decreases in the short run but

increases after the initial reduction

32

Fum and Hodler (2010) show that natural resources increase inequality but this is

conditional on the level of ethnical polarization of society Carmignani (2013 2010) confirms this

positive relationship using different measures of dependence and abundance and goes further

arguing that inequality constitutes an indirect channel through which NRE affects human

development

Singlecountryevidence

Most of the studies about the relationship between inequality and NRE derive from cross-

country analyses Evidence for specific countries has been mainly based on case studies Howie

and Atakhanova (2014) based on the model of Goderis and Malone (2011) find for the case of

Kazakhstan that income and consumption inequality decreased significantly after booms in the oil-

and-gas sector because of resource booms increase the demand for non-tradable goods which are

intensive in unskilled workers The results depend on the level of rurality institutional quality

education levels and public spending on health and education Fleming and Measham (2015b

2015a) evaluate the impact of booms in the mining and oil sectors in Australia They find that a

boom in the mining sector increases income inequality due to commuting and migration among

regions This phenomenon can be exacerbated when the demanding access to natural resource

revenues is associated with the creation of more local administrative units (counties provinces and

even regions) but the government capacity is not simultaneously improved (Cust amp Poelhekke

2015 Michaels 2011) Furthermore the benefits that a region can receive in the form of fiscal

transfers can be more than compensated by the loses due to city-to-mine commuting such as the

case of mining regions in Chile (Aroca amp Atienza 2011)

33

Other studies at the local level have analysed the impact of the mining sector in Peru (Aragoacuten

amp Rud 2013 Loayza amp Rigolini 2016 Loayza Teran amp Rigolini 2013) Spain (Domenech

2008) and Canada (Papyrakis amp Raveh 2014) and the effects of oil windfalls in Brazil (Caselli amp

Michaels 2013)

In summary there is a wide range of potential mechanisms through which NRE could

influence income inequality Although most of them seem to suggest a positive relationship others

such as commuting and increased within-county demand for non-tradable goods and services

could lead to a negative association This highlights the need to know the sign of this association

in the Chilean economy where the trend shows a reduction in the degree of NRD After controlling

for other factors a positive link would support the argument that the reduction in the degree of

NRD has been relevant in the reduction experienced by income inequality in the same period

However a negative link would support the position that the reduction in NRD has contributed to

explain the persistence of income inequality and its slow reduction

222 The relevance of the spatial approach

Inequalities within countries are still the most important form of inequality from the political

point of view (Milanovic 2016) People from a geographic area within a country are influenced

and care most about their status relative to the people in other areas in the same country The

influence among regions involves multiple aspects (eg economic political and environmental)

These potential interactions have been traditionally ignored assuming independence among

observations related to different regions Moreover neglecting the process of spatial interaction in

key indicators of the economic and social performance of a country may mislead the design of the

public policy

34

The spatial dimension could play a significant role in understanding the distribution of

income within a country One strand of efforts aiming to capture the geographic heterogeneity of

inequality has been focussed on decomposing general indicators such as the Gini coefficient or the

Theil Index Evidence for different countries including the US (Doran amp Jordan 2016) China

(Akita 2003 Gustafsson amp Shi 2002 Ye Ma Ye Chen amp Xie 2017 Yue Zhang Ye Cheng

amp Leipnik 2014) Japan (Ohtake 2008) South Africa (Leibbrandt Finn amp Woolard 2012) and

Chile (Paredes et al 2016) shows that regional inequality is sensitive to the geographic scale of

analysis These studies also show a significant spatial component in the explanation of inequality

of income expenditure or gross domestic product for each country

Another strand explicitly uses exploratory spatial data analysis (ESDA) and spatial

econometrics ESDA has been used to provide new insights about the nature of regional disparities

of incomes and growth rates (Celebioglu amp Dallrsquoerba 2010 Yue et al 2014) Spatial econometric

models aim to assess and address the nature of the spatial effects These effects could be the result

of ldquospatial heterogeneityrdquo that is different relationships in distinct locations or ldquospatial

dependencerdquo which implies cross-sectional interactions (spillover effects) among units from

distinct but near locations

Spatial spillovers have been analysed to study both positive and negative spatial correlation

among less resource-abundant counties and resource-abundant counties On the one hand less

resource-abundant counties may experience positive spillovers because their industries supply

more goods and services to meet the increasing regional demand They can also be benefited from

positive agglomeration externalities and higher investment in private and public infrastructure

(Allcott amp Keniston 2014 Michaels 2011) On the other hand negative spillovers could be the

35

result of a high degree of interregional migration that limits the rise in wages and higher local

prices due to the increase in the share of the non-tradable sector In addition local governments

could have a limited capacity to translate the revenues from resource booms into effective public

policies promoting a sustained local development (Beine Coulombe amp Vermeulen 2015 Caselli

amp Michaels 2013 Papyrakis amp Raveh 2014)

23 Research problem and hypotheses

We can conclude from our overview of the literature that the theoretical and empirical

evidence about the link between inequality and natural resources is inconclusive This does not

make clear whether the process of reduction in the degree of dependence on natural resources

such as that experienced by the Chilean economy helps to explain the sustained but slow reduction

in income inequality or its high persistence

The research question guiding this study relates to how the natural resource endowment

determines the paths and structure of income inequality in natural resource-rich countries Using

the case of Chile the main hypotheses to be tested is whether a higher degree of dependence on

natural resources is associated with higher levels of income inequality To do that we use data at

the county level and we explicitly include the spatial dimension Our aim is to arrive at a more

comprehensive understanding of the drivers and transmission mechanisms explaining the

evolution and patterns shown by income inequality In addition we test whether the spatial

dimension plays a significant role in explaining differences in income distribution in Chile

36

24 Data and Methods

We use county-level data for the years 2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017 The reason

for not using contiguous years is that income data at the household level are only available every

two-three years from the Chilean National Socioeconomic Characterization Survey (CASEN in its

Spanish acronym)3 For the period 2006-2017 the Chilean administrative division considers 15

regions 54 provinces and 346 counties Data on income are available for 324 counties and six

years resulting in a panel with 1944 observations4

We start evaluating the spatial dimension in our data and analysing the link between

inequality and NRD using a cross-sectional setting To this end we use the ldquosix-year averagerdquo

(2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017) for our variables given the low time variability showed by

our measures of income inequality and NRD Results are then compared with those of a panel data

setting

241 Operationalization of key variables

The dependent variable in the present study income inequality at the county level is

measured calculating the Gini coefficient using three definitions of household income labour

autonomous and monetary income5 Labour income corresponds to the incomes obtained by all

members in the household excluding domestic service consisting of wages and salaries earnings

3 CASEN survey is conducted by the Chilean Ministry of Social Development covering topics such as education employment income and health CASEN is considered nationally representative and it is the main source for measures of inequality and poverty used for the design and evaluation of social policies in Chile 4 The six waves of CASEN for our study considered an average of 75599 households and 252081 individuals 5 The Gini coefficient is chosen because provides an overall estimate of income inequality It summarizes what proportion of the population gains what proportion of the total income The Gini coefficient can range between 0 (everyone in the population has the same income) and 1 (one person earns 100 per cent of the income in the community)

37

from independent work and self-provision of goods Autonomous income is the sum of labour

income and non-labour income (including capital income) consisting of rents interest and dividend

earnings pension healthcare benefits and other private transfers Finally monetary income is

defined as the sum of autonomous income and monetary subsidies which correspond to cash

transfers by the public sector through social programs Appendix A shows summary statistics for

the Gini coefficient of our three measures of income

The main independent variable in our study is the degree of dependence on natural resources

in each county To have an idea of the importance of each economic activity in the Chilean

economy particularly those activities related to natural resources Figure 21 shows their average

share in Chilean Gross Domestic Product (GDP) for the period 2006-17 We can observe that the

leading activities are those related to the primary sector especially mining and to the tertiary

sector where financial personal commerce restaurants and hotels services stand out The shares

of each economic activity in GDP vary significantly between Chilean regions and such

information is not available at the county level

Figure 21 Average share in GDP of economic activities (2006ndash17)

38

Leamer (1999) argues that when the main source of income is labour income (as indeed

happens for the Chilean case) using employment shares allows a better approach to measuring

dependence on natural resources Using employment data from CASEN survey we define our

measure of NRD as the employment in the primary sector (mining fishing forestry and

agriculture) as a percentage of the total employment in each county We name this variable

pss_casen where ldquopssrdquo stands for ldquoprimary sector sharerdquo We built other two proxies of NRD

using data from the ldquoServicio de Impuestos Internosrdquo (SII) which is the agency in charge of

collecting taxes in Chile The variable pss measures the percentage of employment in the primary

sector and the variable pss_firms measures the number of firms in the primary sector as a

percentage of the total number of firms in each county Appendix B shows summary statistics for

our three measures of NRD disaggregated by region

Figure 22 Evolution of Gini coefficient and measures of NRD (2006ndash17)

39

Figure 22 shows the evolution of our measure of inequality (using the Gini coefficient of

autonomous income) and our three potential proxies for NRD for the period 2006-2017 We

observe that both income inequality and the degree of NRD show a downward trend This seems

to support our hypothesis of a positive link between inequality and NRD however we need to

control of other sources of inequality before getting such a conclusion In what follows we use the

variable gini as our measure of income inequality capturing the Gini coefficient of autonomous

income Our measure of NRD is the variable pss_casen defined previously

Figure 23 Spatial distribution of Gini coefficient and NRD (2006ndash17)

Note Gini and NRD averages 2006-09-11-13-15-17 for 324 Chilean counties divided into five equal groups Source Own elaboration based on CASEN survey

40

Figure 23 shows quantile maps for income inequality (on the left) and NRD (on the right)

using the six-years average dataset6 On the one hand we observe that high levels of inequality

seem to be clustered in the Centre-South of the country where agriculture forestry and fishery are

the predominant economic activities Only isolated counties show high inequality in the Centre

(Metropolitan area where the countyrsquos capital is located) and North (Mining) areas On the other

hand our measure of NRD seems to show an opposite spatial pattern than income inequality with

high levels in the Centre and North of the country

242 Control variables

To control for county characteristics we use a set of socio-economic demographic and

institutional variables Economic factors are captured by the natural log of the mean autonomous

household income per capita (in thousands of Chilean pesos of 2017) lnincome the poverty rate

poverty the unemployment rate unemployment the percentage of the population living in rural

areas rural and the average years of education of the population over 15 years old education

Demographic factors include the proportion of the population in the labour force labour_force

and the natural log of population density (population divided by county area) lndensity

We also include the natural log of the total municipal public expenditure per capita

lnmuni_expenditure to control for municipal heterogeneity This heterogeneity is mainly related

to the capacity of municipalities to generate their own revenues In addition the richest

municipalities are in the Metropolitan region which concentrates economic power and around 40

6 After sorting a variable in ascending order quantile maps use the quantiles (quartiles quintiles deciles etc) as class breaks to divide the distribution of the variable where each class includes approximately the same number of observations (counties)

41

of the population This has basically implied a lag in the development of regions other than the

metropolitan region

The spatial distribution of our measures of income inequality and NRD displayed in Figure

23 seems to show different patterns in the North Centre and South of the country Appendix C

shows the administrative division of Chile in 15 regions and how we have grouped them in three

zones North Centre and South We consider as the ldquoCentrerdquo area that formed by the Metropolitan

region (XIII) and its two neighbouring regions V and VI Using the Centre area as our reference

we include in our analysis two dummy variables indicating whether a county is located in the North

area (regions XV I II III and IV) or South area (regions VII VIII IX XIV X XI and XII)

Appendix D shows summary statistics for the set of numeric control variables and the

correlation matrix between our measure of NRD pss_casen and the set of numeric controls

243 Methods

To assess and then consider the spatial nature of the data we need to define the set of relevant

neighbours for each country This is operationalized by building a matrix called ldquoWrdquo with a ldquo1rdquo

for neighbouring counties and a ldquo0rdquo for non-neighbouring counties We could build W using

contiguity-based (whether counties share a border or point) or geography-based (taking the

distances among the centroids of each county polygon) spatial weights Specifically we build a W

matrix considering the 5-nearest counties7 Two reasons explain the choice of k-nearest

neighbours First we cannot use a contiguity criterium because we do not have information about

all the counties and there are some geographically isolated counties Second given the significant

7 We assign a ldquo1rdquo to the five nearest counties to each county based on the distances among the polygon centroids Then W is ldquorow standardizedrdquo This facilitates the interpretation of the spatial lag of a variable as the ldquoweighted average valuerdquo of the same variable in neighbouring counties

42

differences in county areas (ldquobig countiesrdquo in northern and southern regions) using a distance-

band criterium with a not enough large distance band can lead to many ldquoislandsrdquo in extreme regions

and a multi-modal distribution for the number of neighbours

We start testing our inequality and NRD variables for spatial autocorrelation in order to

evaluate statistically the clustering patterns shown in Figure 23 Next we run an OLS regression

of inequality against NRD and our set of controls and we test the spatial autocorrelation of OLS

residuals If we cannot reject the null hypothesis of random spatial distribution we do not need

spatial models to analyse income inequality which would give contrasting evidence to previous

suggestions about the relevance of the spatial dimension of income inequality in Chile (Paredes

2013 Paredes et al 2016) If we find significant spatial autocorrelation in the OLS residuals this

justifies the use of spatial models and highlight the need to find the correct spatial structure8

If inequality in one county spillovers or influences inequality in neighbouring counties the

spatial lag of inequality should be included as an explanatory variable and we should use a spatial

autoregressive model (SAR) If some unobserved variable is the explanation for the clustering of

counties with similar inequality then this will be better captured including a spatial lag of the

errors and we should use a spatial error model (SEM) (Anselin 1988 Anselin amp Bera 1998)

Finally when our main explanatory variable or some of the controls show spatial autocorrelation

a spatial lag of the explanatory variable(s) should be included in our model

8 The existence of spatial autocorrelation violates the standard assumption of independence among observations needed for OLS regression This will result in OLS coefficients biased and inconsistent (Anselin 1988)

43

244 Spatial Model Specification

A model that includes the three forms of spatial dependence described above is called the

Cliff-Ord Model The model in its cross-sectional representation could be expressed as

119910 120582119882119910 119883120573 119882119883120574 119906 (21)

where

119906 120588119882119906 120576 (22)

119882 is our weight matrix that works as an NxN spatial lag operator9 Thus 119882119910 119882119883 and 119882119906

are the spatial lags for the dependent variable explanatory variables and the error term

respectively The parameter 120582 capture the spatial dependence in the dependent variable 120574 the

spatial dependence in the explanatory variables 120588 capture the spatial dependence in the error term

and 120598 is a vector of idiosyncratic errors For instance if ldquoyrdquo is income inequality and ldquoXrdquo a measure

of NRD the level of inequality in one county will be explained by the degree of NRD in the same

county 119883120573 the average degree of NRD in neighbouring counties 119882119883120574 the average level of

inequality in neighbouring counties 120582119882119910 and the average value of residuals in neighbouring

counties 12058811988211990610

From equations (21) and (22) the SAR and SEM models can be seen as special cases of

the Cliff-Ord representation after imposing restrictions over the spatial parameters 120582 120574 and 120588 For

the specification of the spatial panel models we follow the terminology by Croissant and Millo

9 The spatial lag is a weighted sum of the values observed at neighbouring locations 10 On the one hand the impact that income inequality in one county has over income inequality in neighbouring counties is called a ldquoglobal spilloverrdquo and it is associated with the feedback effect among neighbours (one county is its neighboursrsquo neighbourrdquo) on the other hand the influence that the degree of NRD in neighbouring counties has over inequality in one county is called a ldquolocal spilloverrdquo

44

(2018) Spatial panel models including the spatial lag of the dependent variable (SAR) the spatial

lag of the residuals (SEM) or both (SARAR) are described in Appendix E

25 Results

251 Exploratory Spatial Data Analysis (ESDA)

To analyse the significance of the spatial dimension in our data set we use the six-year

average of our variables Spatial autocorrelation is tested using the Moranrsquos I statistic11 Moranrsquos

I measures the correlation of one variable with itself in space12 Figure 24 shows the Moran scatter

plots where the standardized variable (Gini coefficient and NRD for each county) appears in the

horizontal axis against its spatial lag (average value in the 5-nearest neighbouring counties) The

Moranrsquos I (slope of the line in the Moran scatter plot) of income inequality shows a significant

positive spatial autocorrelation that is counties with high (low) inequality tend to be close to each

other

11 There are many statistics to formally test the significance of the spatial dimension in the distribution of our data The null hypothesis assumes spatial randomness which means that there is not spatial structure in the data so any spatial pattern is equally likely to occur and values in one location do not depend on values in other locations The alternative hypotheses can be the existence of positive or negative spatial autocorrelation Positive spatial autocorrelation means similar values in neighbouring locations (less variability than under spatial randomness) Negative spatial autocorrelation means dissimilar values in neighbouring locations (more variability than under spatial randomness) 12 Traditional measures of correlation such as the Pearsonrsquos coefficient measure the degree of linear correlation between two different variables Measures of spatial autocorrelation assess the correlation between the values of one variable in one location related to the values of the same variable in other neighbouring locations

45

Figure 23 Moran scatter plots for variables gini and pss_casen

Moranrsquos I is a measure of global spatial autocorrelation this means it is intended to capture

the clustering property of the entire data set To identify where are the significant hot-spots

(clusters of counties showing high income inequality) or cold-spots (clusters of counties showing

low income inequality) we need local indicators of spatial association (LISA) Using the local

Moranrsquos I (not reported) we find significant hot-spots in the South of the country (mainly

agricultural regions) and significant cold-spots in the Centre (Metropolitan area) of the country

The next step is to check whether the clustering pattern in inequality is the result of a process of

spatial dependence in the variable itself or it can be explained by other variables related to

inequality

252 Cross-sectional analysis

We start analysing differences in income inequality between counties using the six-year

average data and running an OLS regression for the model

119892119894119899119894 120573 120573 119901119904119904_119888119886119904119890119899 120573 119897119899119894119899119888119900119898119890 120573 119901119900119907119890119903119905119910 120573 119906119899119890119898119901119897119900119910119898119890119899119905 120573 119897119886119887119900119906119903_119891119900119903119888119890 120573 119890119889119906119888119886119905119894119900119899 120573 119897119899119889119890119899119904119894119905119910 120573 119903119906119903119886119897 120573 119897119899119898119906119899_119890119909119901119890119899119889119894119905119906119903119890 120573 119899119900119903119905ℎ 120573 119904119900119906119905ℎ

(23)

46

The Moran scatter plot and spatial statistical test of OLS residuals from equation (23) are

in Appendix F OLS residuals show a small but significant positive autocorrelation (Moranrsquos I =

0121) This means that income inequality continues showing a significant degree of spatial

autocorrelation after controlling for the set of covariates In addition robust Lagrange Multiplier

(LM) tests show that a spatial error model is preferred over a spatial lag model (Anselin Bera

Florax amp Yoon 1996)13 This means that income inequality tends to cluster in zones larger than a

county so the analysis should be performed on a larger scale such as provinces regions or macro

zones If the SAR model were preferred it would mean that income inequality in one county is

influenced by the level of income inequality in neighbouring counties To find the spatial structure

that best fits the clustering process of income inequality we run the full set of spatial model

specifications in a cross-sectional setting and results are shown in Table 21

Column 2 in Table 21 shows the results of our ldquoOLSrdquo model The ldquoSLXrdquo model includes

spatial dependence only through the explanatory variables The ldquoSARrdquo model includes the spatial

lag of the dependent variable as a regressor and the ldquoSEMrdquo model includes spatial dependence

through the error term The ldquoSARARrdquo model includes both the spatial lag of the response and the

errors and the ldquoSDMrdquo and ldquoSDEMrdquo are the extensions of the ldquoSARrdquo and ldquoSEMrdquo models

respectively including the spatial lag of the explanatory variables Finally a model including

spatial lags for the response errors and explanatory variables (the ldquoSARARXrdquo model) is shown in

the last column

13 Following the ldquoAnselin methodrdquo when both non robust LM tests are significant we should select between the robust LR tests From Table F1 in Appendix F only the robust LM test for the SEM model (RLMerr) appears as significant

47

Table 21

Cross-sectional Model Comparison (six-year average data)

48

Opposite to our hypothesis we observe a significant and negative coefficient for our measure

of NRD This means that counties more dependent on natural resources show lower levels of

inequality Education years population density and municipal expenditure per capita are also

negatively related to inequality On the other hand the level of income the poverty rate and the

proportion of the population living in rural areas show a positive relationship with income

inequality There is no significant influence of the unemployment rate and the proportion of the

population in the labour force In addition the SAR SEM and SARAR models show a

significantly higher average inequality in the South of the country related to the Centre area

The main finding from our cross-sectional analysis is that there is a significant and negative

relationship between inequality and NRD which is quite robust to the model specification

253 Panel Data analysis

Like the cross-sectional case we start estimating the panel without spatial effects Results

for the pooled fixed effects (FE) and random effects (RE) specifications of equation (3) are in

Appendix G Spatial models were estimated using Maximum Likelihood (ML) and Generalized

Moments (GM) and assuming that the spatial structure (W matrix) is the same for all years14

Tables 22 23 and 24 show results for the ML estimation of the SAR SEM and SARAR models

using the pooled FE and RE specifications Results for the GM estimation are in Appendix H

All our spatial models include time fixed effects In the case of the pooled and RE models they

additionally include indicator variables for those counties located in the North and South of the

country

14 In traditional (non-spatial) panels data are stacked as time series for each observational unit (county) In the case of spatial panels data are stacked as slice of cross-sections for each year in the panel

49

The main result is that the negative and significant effect of NRD on income inequality is

robust to most of the spatial panel specifications In addition the coefficient for the variable

pss_casen changes slightly among panel specifications (pooled FE and RE) but does not change

among spatial models (SAR SEM and SARAR)

Another important finding is related to the significance of the spatial dimension of income

inequality When spatial models cross-sectional or panel are compared to non-spatial models

there are no major differences in the magnitude of the coefficients or their significance This could

mean that the positive spatial autocorrelation shown by income inequality seems to be better

explained by a process of spatial heterogeneity rather than spatial dependence The practical

implication of this result is that including dummy variables for aggregated units (eg regions or

groups of regions) could be enough to control for the spatial dimension in the modelling and

analysis of income inequality

Among control variables years of education seems to be the main variable for the design of

long-term policies aimed at reducing inequality This result is in line with previous evidence for

cross-country studies (Leamer et al 1999) and specific countries (Howie amp Atakhanova 2014)

Municipal expenditure per capita also shows a significant and negative association with income

inequality in the pooled and RE spatial specifications This means that higher municipal

expenditure helps to reduce inequality between counties but its effect is more limited within

counties This result support the importance of local governments (Fleming amp Measham 2015a)

however the negative coefficient appears as evidence against the ldquoParadox of Plentyrdquo (Borge et

al 2015)

50

Table 22

ML Spatial SAR Models

Table 23

ML Spatial SEM Models

51

Table 24

ML Spatial SARAR Models

26 Discussion and conclusions

In this essay we delve deep into the sources of income inequality analysing its association

with the degree of dependence on natural resources using county-level data for the 2006ndash2017

period in Chile Given recent evidence for the Chilean economy suggesting a significant spatial

dimension we assess and incorporate explicitly the spatial structure of income inequality using

spatial methods We use cross-sectional and panel data to evaluate the significance of the spatial

dimension and we test whether NRD has a positive effect on income inequality

Contrary to what theory predicts NRD shows a significant and negative association with

income inequality This result is robust to the type of analysis (cross-sectional vs panel data) the

approach (spatial vs non-spatial) and the inclusion of different controls The negative and

significant coefficient implies that if the degree of NRD would not have experienced a 10 drop

during this period income inequality could have fallen in 2 additional points So the downward

trend in the participation of the primary sector in terms of employment in the Chilean economy

52

could be one of the main reasons explaining the high persistence in the levels of income inequality

This means that those areas that undergo a process of productive transformation mainly towards

the services sector would be facing greater problems to reduce inequality This process of

productive transformation natural or policy-driven highlights the importance of policies focused

on human capital and the role of local governments in reducing inequality

The main implication for policymakers is that a reduction in NRD does not help to reduce

inequality generating additional challenges for local and central governments in its attempt to

transform the structure of their economies to fewer dependent ones on natural resources The

finding of a significant spatial dimension suggests that defining macro zones capturing the spatial

heterogeneity in the data should be done before analysing the relationship among variables and the

design and evaluation of specific policies Particularly relevant in those areas experiencing a

reduction in NRD are migration commuting and the characteristics of the tertiary (services) sector

In addition our findings show that education and municipal expenditure could be effective policy

tools in the fight to reduce inequality in Chile

Although our results seem quite robust they do not allow us to make causal inferences about

the effect of NRD on income inequality However we could think of the following explanation to

explain the negative relationship found and the differences between geographical areas

Areas highly dependent on NR used to demand a high proportion of low-skill labour This

has change in sectors such as the mining sector in the northern area which has simultaneously

experienced an increase in activities related to the service sector such as retail restaurants

transport and housing However those services associated with more skilled labour such as the

finance sector remain concentrated in the capital region The reduction in the degree of NRD

(employment in extractive activities) implies lower labour force but more specialized with most

53

of the low-skilled labour transferred to a service sector characterized by low productivity and low

wages

Non-spatial models show that the North and South particularly the latter present

significantly higher levels of inequality This could be associated with the type of resources with

ldquopointrdquo resources such as minerals in the North and ldquodiffusedrdquo resources such as agriculture in the

South This translates into higher average incomes in the Centre and North areas and lower average

incomes in the South

The reduction in NRD implies not only a movement of the labour force from extractive

activities to manufacturing or services with the latter characterized by low productivity and low

salaries of the labour force We could also speculate that most of the high incomes move to the

central area where the economic power and ownership over firms and resources are concentrated

This would explain low inequality associated with higher average incomes in the central area and

high inequality associated with lower average incomes in the South A more in-depth analysis

capturing the mobility of wealth and labour force between counties or more aggregated areas is

needed to better understand the causal mechanism involved

Our findings open avenues for future research in different strands First studies on the causes

of income inequality should take the role of NRD into consideration which has been overlooked

so far Given that the spatial dimension of income inequality seems to be explained by a

phenomenon of spatial heterogeneity estimation strategies such as spatial regime models or

geographically weighted regression should be used (Chi amp Zhu 2019) Second the effect of NRD

on income inequality could manifest through different channels such as education fiscal transfers

and institutions We could extend our analysis to identify which of these competing channels is

the most relevant Transforming some continuous variables such as educational level to a

54

categorical variable or defining new indicator variables for instance whether a local government

shows or not an efficient performance we could classify counties in different groups and then

check whether there are differences or not in the relationship between income inequality and NRD

A third strand could be to disaggregate our measure of NRD for different industries This

would allow us to test differences among industries and to identify the sectors that promote greater

equality and which greater inequality Forth the analysis of the consequences of income inequality

on other economic and social phenomena such as efficiency economic growth and social cohesion

has a growing interest in researchers and policymakers Our findings suggest that to answer the

question of whether income inequality has a causal impact on other variables we could include a

measure of NRD as an instrument to address endogeneity issues For instance two interesting

topics for future research are the analysis of how differences in income inequality between counties

could help to explain differences in the level of efficiency of local governments and differences in

the degree of social cohesion (unrest) throughout the country Those are the issues to be addressed

in the next two essays

55

Chapter 3 The Impact of Income Inequality on the Efficiency of

Municipalities in Chile

31 Introduction

In Chile municipalities are the smallest administrative unit for which citizens choose their

local authorities playing an important role in the provision of public goods and services at the

local level Municipalities have a similar set of objectives but the level of financial resources

available to finance their activities is highly heterogeneous This could result in significant

differences in the levels of performance between municipalities Despite their importance there is

little empirical evidence about the efficiency of local governments in Chile This essay aims to

measure the technical efficiency of Chilean municipalities and to analyse how local characteristics

particularly those related to income distribution at the county level could help to explain

differences in municipal performance

Cross-country studies situate Chile as an efficient country in international comparisons about

efficiency of government spending (Herrera amp Pang 2005 Loacutepez amp Miller 2008) However

evidence for Chile at the local level is relatively sparse suggesting significant levels of

inefficiency For instance Pacheco Sanchez and Villena (2013) found a mean efficiency level of

around 70 using a sample of 309 municipalities for the period 2008-2010 This suggests that

municipalities could achieve the same level of output by reducing the usage of inputs by an average

of 30 Their study also showed that those municipalities more dependent on the central

56

government or those located in counties with lower income per capita are more efficient than their

counterparts

Most empirical research on Local Government Efficiency (LGE) has been conducted for

member countries of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) of

which Chile has been a member since 2010 In the case of European countries such as Spain and

Italy which share similar characteristics such as the monetary union and levels of GDP per head

efficiency studies have been mainly motivated by budgetary constraints (Balaguer-Coll Brun-

Martos Maacuterquez-Ramos amp Prior 2019 lo Storto 2013) The Chilean context differs in three

main ways from its OECD counterparts First except for the Metropolitan Region that concentrates

most of the population Chilean regions are highly dependent on natural resources Second Chile

is also characterized by one of the highest levels of income inequality among OECD countries

which contrast with the situation of developed natural resource-rich countries such as Australia

and Norway Third although budget constraints are also a relevant issue Chilean municipalities

have experienced a sustained increase in the level of financial resources and expenditure

Another relevant distinction when we benchmark the performance of municipalities across

different countries is the type of public services they provide On the one hand in most of the

countries included Chile the main role of local governments is to provide ldquoservices to peoplerdquo

such as public education and public health On the other hand there are countries such as Australia

where local governments mainly provide ldquoservices to propertyrdquo including waste management

maintenance of local roads and the provision of community facilities such as libraries swimming

pools and parks (Dollery Wallis amp Akimov 2010 Drew Kortt amp Dollery 2015 McQuestin

Drew amp Dollery 2018)

57

Despite contextual differences Chilean municipalities seem not to perform differently from

municipalities in other developed and natural resource-rich countries where income inequality is

significantly less than in Chile (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018a) This result highlights the

need to study the role of income inequality and the degree of dependence on natural resources over

LGE characteristics that have been largely overlooked in the literature

We measure and analyse differences in municipal performance using a two-stage approach

In the first stage we measure municipal efficiency using an input-oriented Data Envelopment

Analysis (DEA) to get a set of ldquoefficiency scoresrdquo In the second stage we regress efficiency scores

against our measure of income inequality controlling for a set of contextual factors describing the

economic socio-demographic and political context of each county

We use a sample of 324 municipalities for the period 2006-2017 During this period Chile

was divided into 346 counties belonging to 15 regions This period was characterized by important

external and internal shocks including the Global Financial Crisis (GFC) one of the biggest

earthquakes in Chilean history in 2010 and three municipal elections The availability of

information allows us to measure efficiency for the full period but the influence of contextual

factors is analysed using a panel of six years (2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017) for which

household income information is available

The main hypothesis tested in the second stage is whether higher levels of income inequality

are associated with lower levels of efficiency Previous evidence shows that when progress is not

evenly shared persistent within-country inequality reduces the effectiveness and efficiency of the

public sector (Ortega Sanjuaacuten amp Casquero 2017 Tandon 2005)

Income inequality has been used to control for a wide range of idiosyncratic factors

associated with historical institutional and cultural factors affecting efficiency (Greene 2016

58

Ortega et al 2017) For instance at the local level income inequality has been considered as an

indicator of economic heterogeneity in the population where higher inequality is associated with

a more heterogeneous set of conflicting demands for public services which adversely affect an

efficient provision (Ashworth Geys Heyndels amp Wille 2014 Geys amp Moesen 2009) Higher

levels of income inequality could also relate to economically privileged groups having a greater

capacity to influence the political system for their own benefit rather than that of the majority

When high inequality is persistent the feeling of frustration and disappointment in the population

could reduce not only trust and cooperation among individuals but also trust in institutions which

would negatively affect government efficiency (Boix amp Posner 1998 Coffeacute amp Geys 2005) For

instance national or local authorities could end exerting patronage and clientelism and showing

rising levels of corruption (Uslaner 2011 Uslaner amp Brown 2005)

One of the main gaps in extant literature is the need to conduct more analysis of LGE using

panel data taking into consideration endogeneity issues and controlling for unobserved

heterogeneity (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018a) To address the above we set-up a panel with

time and county-specific effects and we propose the use of a measure of natural resource

dependence (NRD) as an instrument for income inequality Based on the ldquoParadox of Plentyrdquo

fiscal revenues from natural resources windfalls could be associated with an over expansion of the

public sector fostering rent-seeking and corruption and reducing local government efficiency

(Dauvin amp Guerreiro 2017 Manzano amp Rigobon 2001) In the Chilean case most of the revenues

generated by local governments included those from natural resources end up in a common fund

which benefits all municipalities The aim of this common fund is precisely to reduce inequalities

among municipalities so although we do not expect a direct impact of natural resources on LGE

we could expect an indirect effect through other indicators particularly income inequality

59

As far as we know this is the first study analysing the influence of income inequality as a

determinant of municipal efficiency in Chile Moreover this is the first study in the context of a

natural resource-rich country which specifically suggests a measure of natural resource

dependence as an instrument to correct for endogeneity bias We propose the use of the proportion

of firms in the primary sector as proxy for the degree of NRD in each county We argue that this

variable is a better proxy than using the proportion of employment in the manufacturing sector

which has been proposed in previous studies (Alesina amp La Ferrara 2002) During the period

analysed our proxy remained relatively stable and showed a significant relationship with income

inequality In addition it is less likely that it has directly affected municipal efficiency

This study adds to the literature in two other ways First the extant literature suggests that

efficiency measurement could be highly sensitive to the chosen technique as well as the selection

of inputs and outputs (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018a) Inputs are usually proxied by a single

measure of total public expenditures and outputs by general proxies such as population andor the

number of businesses in each county We offer a novel approach for the selection of inputs and

outputs On the one hand we disaggregate government expenditures into four components

(operation personnel health and education) and we use the number of public schools and health

facilities in each county as a proxy for physical capital On the other hand we use four outputs

aiming to capture the wide variety of goods and services supplied by each municipality Through

this approach we aim to better describe the production function of each municipality capturing

not only the variety of inputs and outputs but also differences in size among municipalities

A third contribution relates to the measurement of LGE in the Chilean context We measure

technical and scale efficiency using a larger sample and a longer period This has empirical and

policy relevance On the one hand it helps us to select the correct DEA model and allows us to

60

determine the importance of scale inefficiencies as explanation for differences in municipal

performance On the other hand efficiency measures increase the information available for both

central and local governments to better understand the production technology that best describes

each municipality and to carry out policies to improve efficiency

We believe that our selection of inputs and outputs the use of a large dataset and the joint

analysis using cross-sectional and panel data provide a more accurate and robust analysis of

municipal efficiency Likewise knowing whether inequality has a significant influence on

municipal efficiency may provide useful insights and guidance for policymakers not only in Chile

but also for countries sharing similar characteristics

DEA results show an average level of technical efficiency (inefficiency) of around 83

(17) This means that municipalities could reduce on average a 17 the use of inputs without

reducing the outputs There are significant differences among geographic areas with the Centre

area (where the countyrsquos capital is located) displaying higher efficiency than the rest of the country

When municipal efficiency is measured under different assumptions about returns to scale results

reveal a production technology with variable returns to scales and around 75 of the

municipalities displaying scale inefficiencies However when technical efficiency is

disaggregated between pure technical efficiency and scale efficiency results show that scale

inefficiency explains a small proportion of the total municipal technical inefficiency This finding

justifies a deeper analysis of the reasons why municipalities could operate inefficiently and why

municipal performance could vary among municipalities

Efficiency scores also show a significant degree of positive spatial autocorrelation This

means that municipal efficiency shows a general clustering process with neighbouring

municipalities showing similar levels of efficiency A further analysis shows that most of the

61

spatial pattern in municipal efficiency is exogenous that is could be associated to other variables

Hence we conduct most of our regression analysis using traditional (non-spatial) methods and

leaving spatial regressions in the appendixes

Findings from cross-sectional and panel regressions support the hypothesis that municipal

performance is significantly and negatively associated with income inequality at the county level

The coefficient of income inequality is close to one which means that reductions in income

inequality ceteris paribus could be associated with increases in municipal efficiency in the same

proportion This result supports the strand of research arguing that there is not a trade-off at least

at the municipal level between equity and efficiency (Andersen amp Maibom 2020 Berg amp Ostry

2011 2017) The main policy implications are that authorities in more unequal counties would

face higher challenges to perform efficiently and policies pertaining to inequality and efficiency

should not be designed independently

The chapter is structured as follows Section 32 provides a brief literature review on related

local government efficiency Section 33 introduces the methodological background and empirical

models Section 34 presents the empirical results and discussions Section 35 concludes the

chapter

32 Related Literature

321 Measuring efficiency of local governments

Studies on measuring LGE can be grouped in those analysing the provision of single services

such as health or education and those assessing overall efficiency (lo Storto 2013) Once inputs

and outputs have been defined efficiency is measured using parametric andor non-parametric

techniques Among the former group Stochastic Frontier Analysis (SFA) seems to be preferred

62

by scholars aiming to measure efficiency and to analyse the link with environmental variables

using a single procedure (Pacheco et al 2013 Tsekeris Sotiris Tsekeris amp Papaioannou 2018)

On the non-parametric group Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA) is by far the most used technique

(Afonso amp Fernandes 2006 Balaguer-Coll amp Prior 2009 lo Storto 2013)

The selection of inputs and outputs depends not only on the aimed of the study (specific

sector vs whole measure of efficiency) but also on the role that municipalities play in different

countries There are countries such as Australia (Drew et al 2015) and Spain (Balaguer-Coll amp

Prior 2009) where local governments mainly supply services to ldquopropertyrdquo such as waste

management and road maintenance In these cases efficiency has been mainly measured using

total indicators of local government expenditure and outputs have been proxied using general

indicators such as population or number of business (Drew et al 2015) On the other hand in

countries such as Italy (lo Storto 2013) and Portugal (Afonso amp Fernandes 2008) in Europe or

Brazil (de Sousa Cribari-Neto amp Stosic 2005) and Chile (Pacheco et al 2013) in South America

municipalities mainly supply services to ldquopeoplerdquo Here in addition to financial expenditures or

revenues inputs have included the number of local government employees the number of schools

or the number of hospitals and health centres School-age population the number of students

enrolled in primary and secondary schools and the number of beds in hospitals have been

considered as outputs Based on the study of Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte (2018a) a wider list of

inputs and outputs used in previous studies can be found in Appendix I

Studies from different countries show important differences in the average efficiency scores

both between and within countries These studies also differ in the samples methodologies and

variables included A summary showing the range and variability of the mean efficiency scores

founds in countries all around the world can be found in Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte (2018a)

63

These authors also show that OECD natural resource-rich countries such as Australia Belgium

and Chile show similar results in terms of mean efficiency scores with LGE studies being less

frequent in Latin American countries

Measuring efficiency of local governments as decision-making units (DMU) presents many

challenges and difficulties (Borger Kerstens Moesen amp Vanneste 1994 Ravallion 2005)

Worthington and Dollery (2000) mention problems with the selection and measurement of inputs

the identification of different stakeholders the hidden characteristic of the ldquolocal government

technologyrdquo and the multidimensionality of the services provided by local governments All these

issues make difficult to identify and distinguish between outputs and outcomes with outputs

commonly proxied by general indicators such as county area or county population Because

efficiency measures are highly sensitive to the chosen technique and the selection of inputs and

outputs Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte (2018a) suggest formulating different specifications and

using less general and unspecified indicators Moreover the complexity in defining outputs and

the use of general indicators make more likely that contextual factors affect municipal efficiency

322 Explaining differences in LGE

To explain differences in local government performance researchers have basically

distinguished between ldquodiscretionaryrdquo and ldquonon-discretionaryrdquo factors Discretionary factors refer

to the degree of discretion of local authorities in the selection and management of inputs and

outputs On the other hand scholars have investigated the influence on LGE of contextual factors

beyond authoritiesrsquo control These factors reflective at the environment where municipalities

operate include economic socio-demographic geographic financial political and institutional

characteristics (da Cruz amp Marques 2014 Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018b)

64

In general the evidence about the influence of contextual factors has delivered mixed and

country-specific results (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018b) Sampaio de Sousa et al (2005)

using data for Brazilian municipalities finds that population density and urbanization rate have

strong positive effects on efficiency scores Benito et al (2010) show that lower levels of

efficiency of Spanish municipalities are associated with a greater economic level a less stable

population and a bigger size of the local government Afonso (2008) finds that per capita income

level and education are not significant factors influencing LGE of Portuguese municipalities He

also finds that municipalities in Northern areas show greater efficiency than their counterparts in

Southern areas More recently Tsekeris (2018) finds that spatial variations in efficiency in Greece

can be attributed to factors related to inter-regional market access specialization and sectoral

concentration resource-factor endowments and political factors among others Characteristics

describing each local government have also been used including municipal indebtedness (Benito

et al 2010) fiscal deficits (Sinha 2017) degree of fiscal autonomy (Boetti Piacenza amp Turati

2009) and individual characteristics of local authorities such as age gender and political ideology

Narboacuten‐Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte (2018b) conclude after analysing 63 articles that studies on the

influence of contextual factors have mostly used cross-sectional data with little attention to

endogeneity issues which makes any causal interpretation doubtful

323 The trade-off between efficiency and equity

The existence of a potential trade-off between efficiency and equity is in the core of

economic discussion (Andersen amp Maibom 2020 Berg amp Ostry 2011 Browning amp Johnson

1984 Okun 2015)15 The argument that economic growth (one of the most common efficiency

15 Redistributive policies distort incentives and lead to suboptimal outcomes and thus efficiency losses

65

measures) could be negatively affected in the search for greater equality has been translated not

only into economic policies that favour economic growth over those that reduce inequality but

also in the emphasis of scholarly research Thus theoretical and empirical research has been

mainly focussed on efficiency and policy implications of a great diversity of shocks and policies

leaving the analysis of inequality as one of measurement and mostly descriptive Additionally

empirical evidence of the trade-off is scant and inconclusive (Andersen amp Maibom 2020

Browning amp Johnson 1984)

Among economic contextual factors that could affect LGE income inequality has been

largely ignored An exception is a cross-country comparison conducted by Ortega (2017) who

analyses the role of inequality on government efficiency in developing countries He finds that

more unequal countries could have higher difficulties to achieve specific health outcomes Income

inequality has even been considered as part of the outputs to measure efficiency particularly for

the case of European and OECD countries (Afonso Schuknecht amp Tanzi 2010 Antonelli amp De

Bonis 2018)

At the local level income inequality has been mainly used as a proxy for the effect of income

heterogeneity Economic inequality could have a direct and an indirect effect on government

efficiency The direct effect poses that higher income inequality could reduce municipal efficiency

because it is associated with a more complex and competing set of public services demanded by

the population (Jottier et al 2012) The indirect effect puts the focus in the link between inequality

social capital and levels of corruption Economic diversity could reduce trust in people and

institutions when related to high and persistent levels of income inequality It could also affect the

willingness to participate in community and political groups the existence of a shared objective

by citizens and the perception of a prosperous future (Uslaner amp Brown 2005)

66

The evidence is ambiguous For instance Geys and Moesen (2009) find that income

inequality has little relation to efficiency of Flemish municipalities and Ashworth et al (2014)

find a negative relationship for the Norwegian case Findings also indicate that inequality is the

strongest determinant of trust and that trust has a greater effect on communal participation than on

political participation (Uslaner amp Brown 2005)

33 Methodology

We follow a two-stage approach widely used in this kind of analysis A DEA analysis is

conducted in the first stage to get efficiency scores for each municipality Then regression analysis

is conducted in the second stage aiming to identify contextual variables other than differences in

the management of inputs that can help to explain the heterogeneity in municipal performance

331 Chilean Municipalities and period of analysis

The territory of Chile is divided into regions and these into provinces which for purposes of

the local administration are divided into counties The local administration of each county resides

in a municipality which is administrated by a Mayor assisted by a Municipal Council16

Municipalities represent the decentralization of the central power in Chile They are autonomous

organizations with legal personality and own patrimony whose purpose is to satisfy the needs of

the local community and ensure their participation in the economic social and cultural progress of

the county Municipalities have a diversity of functions related to public health education and

social assistance among others

16 The Mayor and City Council are elected by suffrage for the citizens of the respective commune every 4 years

67

To achieve their goals two are the main sources of municipal incomes own permanent

revenues (OPR) and the Municipal Common Fund (MCF) OPR are incomes generated by the

county and they are an indicator of the self-financing capacity of each municipality OPR are not

subject to restrictions regarding their investment and they are mainly generated by territorial taxes

commercial patents and circulation permits17 The MCF is a fund that aims to redistribute

community income to ensure compliance with the purpose of the municipalities and their proper

functioning Sources to finance the MCF come from municipal revenues The distribution

mechanism of the fund is regulated by parameters such as whether municipalities generate OPR

per capita lower than the national average and the number of poor people in the commune in

relation to the number of poor people in the country

This study covers the period from 2006 to 2017 During this period Chile was divided into

15 regions 54 provinces and 346 counties18 Although the information on inputs and outputs is

available for the entire period information on contextual factors at the county level such as

household income is only available every two-three years In addition some counties are excluded

from household surveys due to their difficult access Hence we use a sample of 324 municipalities

to measure municipal efficiency for the whole period (3888 observations) However the analysis

of contextual factors is conducted for those years when household income information is available

2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017 (1944 observations)

17 The territorial tax is a tax on agricultural and non-agricultural real estate Specifically of this income only 40 is left to the municipality as its own financing while the remaining 60 is allocated to the MCF (in the case of the four largest communes- Santiago Providencia Las Condes and Vitacura-percentages are 35 and 65 respectively) Unlike the territorial tax commercial patents are regulated mainly by the municipality which chooses the rate to be charged subject to a range established by law and is responsible of their collection Finally regarding the circulation permits 375 is of municipal benefit while 645 is directed to the MCF 18 There are 346 counties managed by 345 municipalities where counties ldquoCabo de Hornosrdquo and ldquoAntaacuterticardquo are managed by the municipality of ldquoCabo de Hornosrdquo

68

332 Measuring municipal efficiency

Municipal efficiency is measured using Data Envelopment Analysis (Coelli Prasada Rao

OrsquoDonnell amp Battese 2005) This is a non-parametric approach that uses linear programming to

measure efficiency for a group of municipalities as decision making units (DMUrsquos) The main

advantage of using DEA and the reason why DEA is used for the case of Chilean municipalities

is its flexibility in handling multiple inputs and outputs without the need to specify a functional

form (Balaguer-Coll amp Prior 2009 Mikušovaacute 2015 Tigga amp Mishra 2015) Following Afonso

and Fernandes (2008) the relationship between inputs and outputs for each municipality could be

represented by the following equation

119884 119891 119883 119894 1 119899 (31)

In equation (31) 119884 is the set of outputs and 119883 the set of inputs for each of the n

municipalities Using linear programming the production frontier is constructed and a vector of

efficiency scores is obtained The frontier represents full technical efficiency mdash the point at which

the highest output occurs given specified inputs or the point at which the lowest amount of inputs

is used to produce a specified quantity of output Efficiency scores under DEA are relative

measures of efficiency They measure a municipalityrsquos efficiency against the other measured

municipalities in the sample and not a hypothetical lsquoperfect municipalityrsquo The further from the

frontier the less technically efficient a municipality is

We use an input-oriented approach because Chilean municipalities have a greater control

over the management of inputs relative to the outputs they have to manage Obtaining efficiency

scores requires an assumption about the returns to scale exhibited by each municipality When

DMUrsquos are homogeneous the CCR model (Charnes Cooper amp Rhodes 1978) which assumes

69

constant return-to-scale (CRS) is the appropriate specification The CCR model assumes full

proportionality between outputs and inputs and that DMUrsquos operate at their optimal When DMUrsquos

are highly heterogeneous as is the case with local governments in most countries it is not realistic

to assume complete proportionality between inputs and outputs nor that all DMUrsquos operate at their

optimum scale In this situation a variable returns-to-scale (VRS) or BCC model (Banker

Charnes amp Cooper 1984) is the preferred formulation

Assuming VRS imposes minimum restrictions on the efficient frontier and allows for

comparisons only among municipalities of similar scale (Coelli et al 2005 Wu Huang amp Pan

2014) This means that when we use the CCR model (assuming CRS) on a heterogeneous sample

of DMUrsquos the resulting measure of technical efficiency that we obtain is related not only to the

management of inputs but also to issues of scale19 To empirically check the validity of the VRS

assumption we measure technical efficiency under CRS VRS and non-increasing returns-to-scale

(NIRS) and we analyse the existence of scale inefficiencies This allows us to check the relevance

of scale effects as a potential explanation of differences in municipal efficiency Appendix J

shows the specification of the DEA model under VRS and how ldquototal technical efficiencyrdquo

(assuming CRS and therefore due to management and scale issues) could be disaggregated in ldquopure

technical efficiencyrdquo (under VRS and related only to management issues) and scale efficiency (due

to scale issues)

19 Assuming VRS can also lead to measurement problems such as overestimation of efficiency scores This is the case when an important proportion of DMUrsquos shows CRS so assuming VRS ignores the information about proportionality between inputs and outputs (Podinovski 2004)

70

333 Inputs and outputs used in DEA

Following the literature on local government expenditure efficiency (Afonso amp Fernandes

2008 de Sousa et al 2005 Dlouhyacute 2018 Tandon 2005 Tigga amp Mishra 2015) and trying to

reflect as well as possible the functioning of municipalities five inputs and four outputs were

selected Input and output data were obtained from the National System of Municipal Information

(SINIM in its Spanish acronym) and they are expressed in thousands of Chilean pesos of 201720

Inputs are Municipal Operational Expenditure X1 (including expenses on goods and

services social assistance investment and transfers to community organizations) Municipal

Personnel Expenditure X2 (including full time and part-time workers) Total Municipal

Expenditure in Education sector X3 Total Municipal Expenditure in Health sector X4 and the

Number of Municipal Buildings X5 (proxied by the number of public facilities in education and

health sectors)

Output variables were selected highlighting the relevance of education and health sectors

and trying to capture the wide range of local services provided by municipalities The variable

ldquoOwn Permanent Revenuesrdquo Y1 is used to capture the scale and diversity of municipal

activities21 The ldquoMonthly Average Enrolmentrdquo in municipal education establishments related to

the school-age population in each county Y2 is used as educational output As health output the

ldquoNumber of Medical Consultationsrdquo in public facilities Y3 is considered Finally the number of

community organizations Y4 is used as output reflecting the promotion of community

development by each municipality Table 31 shows the summary statistics of input and output

20 The data from SINIM database was mostly obtained using the sinimr package (Salas 2019) 21 According to SINIM database this variable aims to measure the management of the municipalityrsquos own resources with respect to the population of the commune

71

variables for the whole sample and period Inputs and outputs excepting the Monthly Average

Enrolment Y2 are measured in per capita terms using county population information from the

National Institute of Statistics (INE in its Spanish acronym)

Table 31

Descriptive statistics Inputs and Output variables used in DEA analysis

334 Regression model

Contextual factors could play an important role not only in explaining why some

municipalities operate inefficiently but also why municipal performance differs among them

These factors may affect municipal performance modifying incentives for local authorities to

operate efficiently and their capability to take advantage of economies of scale They also define

the conditions for cooperation or competition among municipalities and the citizensacute ability and

willingness to monitor local authorities (Afonso amp Fernandes 2008)

Information on income at the household level for each county was obtained from the

ldquoNational Socioeconomic Characterization Surveyrdquo (CASEN in its Spanish acronym) CASEN is

conducted every two-three years being the reason why consecutive years are not considered in

72

our regression analysis The other contextual factors used as controls were obtained from different

sources including SINIM INE and the ldquoServicio de Impuestos Internosrdquo (SII)22

Our main hypothesis is whether higher levels of income inequality are associated with lower

levels of municipal efficiency To test our hypothesis the empirical model is defined as

120579 120573 119892119894119899119894 119885 120573 120575 120572 120598 (32)

Where 120579 is the vector of DEA efficiency scores 119892119894119899119894 is the Gini coefficient of each

county 120575 are year-specific effects 120572 are county-specific constants 120598 is a vector of error terms

and 119885 is a vector of controls Next we discuss the motivation for these controls

The level of purchasing power of countiesrsquo citizens is proxied by the variable log(income)

which is the natural log of the mean household income per capita in thousands of Chilean pesos of

2017 On the one hand poorer counties could display higher efficiency due to their necessity to

take care of their constraint resources (Pacheco et al 2013) On the other hand richer counties

could show higher efficiency because richer citizens exert higher monitoring over local authorities

and demand better quality public services in return for their tax payments (Afonso et al 2010)

The possibility for municipalities to take advantage of economies of scale and urbanization is

captured by three variables First the variable log(density) which correspond to the natural log of

population density Second the dummy variable reg_cap indicating whether a county is a regional

capital or not Third the variable agroland which correspond to the proportion of land for

agricultural use which is informed to the SII We expect a positive effect of log(density) but

negative for regcap and agroland

22 The SII is the institution in charge of collecting taxes in Chile

73

Socio-demographic characteristics are captured including a Dependence Index IDD IDD

corresponds to the number of people under 15 years or over 65 years per 100 people in the active

population (those people between 15 and 65 years old) A higher proportion of young and older

population could be associated with a higher demand for municipal services relating to education

and health making harder to offer public services efficiently The citizensrsquo capacity to monitor

local authorities is proxied including the variable education (average years of education for the

population older than 15 years) and the variable housing (proportion of households which are

owners of the property where they live in each county) In both cases we expect a positive

association with LGE

Among municipal characteristics the variable professional (percentage of municipal

personnel with a professional degree) is used to control for the quality of municipal services and

it is expected a positive impact The variable mcf (proportion of total municipal income coming

from the MCF) is included to capture the influence of financial dependence on the central

government A higher dependence from MCF could be associated with higher efficiency when it

is linked to more control from central government (Worthington amp Dollery 2000) However when

MCF discourages the generation of own resources and proper management of resources from the

fund a lower efficiency should be expected (Bravo 2014) In addition the dummy variable mayor

is included to capture differences among mayors supported by the ldquoLEFTrdquo or the ldquoRIGHTrdquo

political parties related to those ldquoINDEPENDENTrdquo mayors

Table 32 report summary statistics for the set of numeric contextual factors and Appendix

K the corresponding correlation matrix Despite the high correlation between income and

education variables we include both in the regression section as they capture different county

characteristics

74

Table 32

Summary Statistics Numeric Contextual Factors

Figure 31 Geographical distribution of Chilean regions and macrozones

Previous evidence on growth and convergence of Chilean regions have found that regions

tend to cluster spatially (Aroca amp Bosch 2000) Aiming to capture this regional clustering process

75

and considering the high concentration in the number of municipalities and population in the

central area we group municipalities in four ldquozonesrdquo We define as reference the ldquoCentre-Northrdquo

zone consisting of regions XIII (where the countryrsquos capital is located) and its two neighbouring

regions V and VI The ldquoNorthrdquo zone includes regions XV I II III and IV The ldquoCentre-Southrdquo

zone includes regions VII VIII and IX Finally the ldquoSouthrdquo zone embraces regions XIV X XI

and XII Figure 31 displays the regional administrative division and zones considered in this

essay

Efficiency scores (ES) are limited to have values between 0 and 1 However they are relative

measures (relative to the sample of municipalities) This implies that when a municipality is on the

frontier (ES = 1) it does not mean that potentially larger technical efficiency gains cannot be made

Hence equation 32 is estimated using OLS and censored regressions We start running cross-

sectional regressions for each of the six years Then we compare the results with those from panel

regressions Because fixed-effects panel Tobit models could be affected by the incidental

parameters problem (Henningsen 2010 2019) we use random-effects panel Tobit models

including indicator variables for years and zones Finally to deal with the potential endogeneity

problem we also use an instrumental variable approach The instrument is described next

335 The instrument

Government effectiveness and income distribution are both structural components of

economies (Ortega et al 2017 Ravallion 2005) In the search for a causal interpretation for the

influence of income inequality on municipal efficiency we need an instrument which must be

correlated with the variable to be instrumented (in our case income inequality) and uncorrelated

with the error term in the efficiency equation (32) Previous literature has used as instruments for

Gini the number of townships governments in a previous period the percentage of revenues from

76

intergovernmental transfers in a previous period and the current share of the labour force in the

manufacturing sector (Alesina amp La Ferrara 2002) Using the share of the labour force in a specific

sector is unlikely to reduce the problem of endogeneity particularly in countries where local

governments supply mostly ldquoservices to peoplerdquo and the main source of income inequality is

labour income

We propose as an instrument the proportion of firms in the primary sector (mining fishing

forestry and agriculture)

119901119904119904_119891119894119903119898119904Number of firms in the primary sector

Total number of firms (33)

On the one hand this instrument is likely to be correlated with local income inequality in

natural resource-rich countries23 On the other hand we contend that our instrument is less likely

to be correlated with the error term in the efficiency equation First the main services supplied by

Chilean municipalities are services to people (health and education) not to firms Second most of

the revenues collected by municipalities included those associated with natural resources end up

in the municipal common fund whose objective is precisely to reduce inequalities among

municipalities Third services to firms are expected to be more significant with the tertiary sector

We argue that our instrument captures natural and structural conditions which directly

influence income inequality but it does not directly affect LGE Figure 32 shows the evolution

of the annual average efficiency score and the proportion of firms in the primary secondary

(manufacturing) and tertiary (services) sectors We observe that sectors shares have remained

relatively stable with a slight reduction in the participation of the primary sector in favour of the

23 Results confirm a significant association between income inequality and the degree of dependence on natural resources at the county level

77

tertiary sector by the end of the period This is contrary to the evolution of municipal efficiency

which shows a cyclical behaviour as will be shown in the next section

Figure 32 Evolution of efficiency scores and the proportion of firms by sector

34 Results and discussion

341 DEA results

Figure 33 displays the evolution of our three measures of efficiency Overall technical

efficiency pure technical efficiency and scale efficiency are around 78 83 and 95

respectively with fluctuations over the years Therefore around three quarters of the overall

78

inefficiency is attributed to inefficiency in the management of inputs and around one quarter to

scale inefficiencies24

Figure 33 Evolution technical efficiency (TE) pure technical efficiency (PTE) and scale efficiency (SE)

Returnstoscale

Figure 34 reports by zone and for the whole period the proportion of municipalities

showing CRS decreasing returns to scale (DRS) or increasing returns to scale (IRS) Most of the

municipalities operate under variable (increasing or decreasing) returns to scale which could be

explained by the high heterogeneity in size among municipalities A summary of RTS

disaggregated by year and zone is in Appendix L Policies oriented to increase efficiency usually

24 The average scale efficiency score of 95 means that municipalities could get an additional 5 of inputs saving if municipalities were able to change their size to achieve their optimal scale

79

consider amalgamation de-amalgamation or ways of cooperation among municipalities To have

a better idea about where and how feasible is the implementation of such policies Appendix M

shows maps with the administrative division of the country in its 345 municipalities and which

municipalities show CRS IRS or DRS in each of the six years of data

Figure 34 Returns to scale by zone

Based on results for the whole period (Figure 34) the North has the highest proportion of

municipalities exhibiting DRS This suggests the need to reduce the size of municipalities splitting

those ldquotoo bigrdquo creating new administrative areas or giving more autonomy to current

municipalities25 The opposite occurs in the Centre-North area where municipalities mostly

exhibit IRS This indicates the need to merge municipalities An alternative strategy to the

amalgamation process is increasing inter-municipal cooperation (Balaguer-Coll et al 2019)

25 This has been the policy followed in Chile Although two new regions were created (XV in the North and XIV in the South) the number of municipalities has not changed

80

which seems to be a more plausible option in Chile Finally evidence on scale efficiency for the

Centre-South and South areas is not clear in terms of the adequate strategy to improve efficiency

Efficiencymeasure

Although most municipalities show scale inefficiencies (Figure 34) only a small proportion

of total inefficiency is associated to scale issues (Figure 33) Together this results justify not only

the use of the BCC model (efficiency scores under VRS) to capture municipal heterogeneity but

also highlights the need to look for other factors outside the control of local authorities which

could be influencing municipal performance

Table 33

Summary efficiency scores (VRS) by zone and region

Table 33 summarizes ES under VRS using data for the six years of CASEN survey A mean

efficiency score of 83 is found for the full sample and period This means that on average

inefficient municipalities can reduce the use of inputs by 17 to get the same current output By

81

comparing average ES per zone it can be concluded that municipalities in the North Centre-North

Centre-South and South could achieve the same level of output with 17 12 18 and 23 fewer

resources respectively Results also show that one third of the municipalities present an efficiency

score equal to one

Figure 35 shows the evolution of the mean ES for the four zones over the 12 years period

A clear drop in the efficiency level is observed in 2009 (the financial crisis year) excepting for the

North area Likewise although mean efficiency returned to its pre-crisis levels in 2014-2015 a

new drop in efficiency was experienced in 2016 It also seems that the 2010 earthquake did not

generate a significant effect on municipal efficiency Figure 35 also shows that although levels

of efficiency seem to differ among zones they follow a similar trend through time with the only

exception of the North which corresponds to the mining area In addition efficiency seems to be

significantly higher in the Centre-North area This is explained by the high mean level of efficiency

in region XIII which includes the countryrsquos capital city

Figure 35 Evolution mean efficiency scores (VRS) by zone

82

To know which and where are the efficient municipalities and if they are surrounded by

municipalities with a similar level of efficiency Appendix N has maps showing the ldquoefficiency

statusrdquo of each municipality that is whether they are efficient (ES = 1) or inefficient (ES lt 1)

Additionally Appendix O shows ldquoequal intervalsrdquo maps describing the spatial distribution of ES

among municipalities for each of the six years26 Results show that efficient municipalities can be

found all through the country the ldquoefficiency statusrdquo could change from one year to another and

municipalities with similar level-status of efficiency tend to cluster in space

342 Regression results

Exploratoryspatialanalysis

DEA efficiency scores and their geographical representations seem to show that municipal

efficiency presents a spatial clustering pattern This means that municipal performance could be

influenced not only by contextual factors of the county where municipality belongs but also by the

level of efficiency of neighbouring municipalities and their characteristics To test the significance

of the spatial dimension in municipal efficiency we use a cross-section of data considering the six-

year average of efficiency scores the Gini coefficient and the set of controls

We use the Moranrsquos I indicator to test for spatial autocorrelation Moranrsquos I is a measure of

the correlation between the level of efficiency in one municipality and its ldquospatial lagrdquo that is the

average level of efficiency in neighbouring municipalities We define as the relevant neighbours

for each municipality the 5-nearest municipalities This is obtained using the distances among the

26 An equal intervals map uses the same principle as a histogram to organize the observations into categories that divide the range of the variable into equal interval bins For the equal interval classification the value range between the lower and upper bound in each bin is constant across bins but the number of observations in each bin is typically not equal

83

polygonsrsquo centroids (latitude and longitude) of each county Results confirm that municipal

efficiency show a significant level of positive spatial autocorrelation This means that

municipalities tend to have neighbouring municipalities with similar performance

The positive spatial autocorrelation shown by municipal efficiency could be due to the

performance in one municipality is influenced by the performance in neighbouring municipalities

(spatial dependence in the variable itself) or due to structural differences among regions-zones

(spatial heterogeneity) To check the source of the spatial autocorrelation we run an OLS

regression of ES against income inequality and controls and then we test OLS residuals for spatial

autocorrelation Moranrsquos I over OLS residuals although significant is barely higher than zero (see

Appendix P) This means that the spatial effect itself is not a serious issue and can be handle for

instance including zone indicators variables hence we proceed to analyse the influence of income

inequality on LGE using non-spatial regression27

Cross‐sectionalanalysis

We start reporting censored regressions for each year in our panel Efficiency scores have

been rescaled to numbers between 0 and 100 to facilitate the interpretation of the results All

regressions include dummy variables for three of the four zones in which we have grouped Chilean

regions Results are in Table 3428 Income inequality shows a negative sign in all years which is

consistent with our hypothesis that inequality is negatively related to municipal efficiency

However only in three of the six years the effect of income inequality appears as statistically

27 In the case of having incorporated the spatial dimension the two most commonly used forms are including in the model the spatial lag of the dependent variable (spatial autoregressive model SAR) or the spatial lag of the error (spatial error model SEM) Following the method suggested by Anselin et al (1996) Lagrange Multiplier (LM) tests on the OLS residuals showed that the SAR model is preferred over the SEM Moranrsquos I LM tests and spatial regressions can be found in Appendix P 28 Regression results using OLS are in Appendix Q

84

significant Only the income level displays a significant and positive influence on efficiency for

the whole period A higher population density also consistently favours municipal efficiency On

the other hand as we expected a higher IDD makes it more difficult to achieve an efficient

performance29 Consistent with results in Pacheco et al (Pacheco et al 2013) municipal

efficiency show a significant an positive association with the MCF only in the first half of our

period of analysis with the second half showing an insignificant relationship

Table 34

Cross-sectional (censored) regressions

Paneldataanalysis

Estimation results for the six-year panel are reported in Table 35 Columns (1) and (2) show

the results for the pooled and random effects censored models only controlling for zone and year

29 The set of cross-sectional regressions was also run for each zone independently Results confirm that the set of significant contextual factors differs not only among years but also among geographic areas This support previous evidence suggesting that cross-sectional analysis should be treated with caution (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018b)

85

dummies Income inequality appears as non-significant Zone indicator variables confirm that

municipalities located in the Centre-South and South of the country display a lower average level

of efficiency compared to the Centre-North area Time dummies mostly show negative

coefficients This is a signal that shocks such as the GFC and the earthquake in 2010 may have

had a negative impact on efficiency but that impact was not permanent The results for the pooled

and RE models including the full set of controls are reported in columns (3) and (4) These results

show a significant negative influence of income inequality on LGE

When income inequality is instrumented by the variable pss_firms most of the coefficients

remain unchanged except for those associated with the income variables gini and log(income)

This result implies that our original model suffers for instance from the omitted variable bias

This means that LGE and income inequality are determined simultaneously by some variable not

included in our model Columns (5) and (6) show results using our instrument for income

inequality The ldquotrue coefficientrdquo of variable gini remains negative but the magnitude of the

relationship is higher The negative coefficient for gini implies on the one hand that municipalities

located in more unequal counties face more challenges to achieve an efficient management of

public resources On the other hand the coefficient in column (6) is close to one The interpretation

is that for each point of reduction in income inequality ceteris paribus LGE should increase in the

same proportion Next we discuss some of the results associated with the controls variables

Contrary to Pacheco et al (2013) income level has a positive coefficient meaning that richer

counties in terms of income per capita show higher efficiency This could be explained by higher

monitoring and increasing demands from citizen and taxpayers In addition it is expected a higher

efficiency in municipalities located in counties with a higher population density and those with a

lower proportion of land for agricultural use This result is mainly explained by municipalities

86

located in the Centre area The opposite happens with municipalities in the South implying that

they are too ldquosmallrdquo to take advantage of agglomeration economies There is also a limit for

agglomeration and scale economies which is shown by the negative coefficient of the variable

regcap although this coefficient loses its significance in the IV approaches30

Unexpectedly efficiency was found to be negatively associated with the variable education

This result is similar to the case of Czech municipalities (Šťastnaacute amp Gregor 2014) where

explanations include a weakened monitoring effect due to the fact that more educated citizens

present greater mobility and labour cost disadvantages for municipalities with better educated

labour force In Chile an additional explanation could be the relationship between education and

voter turnout Since 2012 voting is no longer mandatory in Chile This fact considerably reduced

voter turnout which in turn may have influenced the monitoring and control effect of more

educated voters For the case of variable IDD results show that local authorities in counties with

higher proportion of aging and young population (related to those in the active population) face a

greater challenge in their quest to offer public services efficiently

The influence of mcf is like that found by Pacheco et al (2013) with municipalities more

dependent on central transfers showing more efficiency31 Political influence captured by the

variable mayor did not show a significant effect This result is like other studies concluding that

the ideological position did not have a significant influence on efficiency (Benito et al 2010

Boetti et al 2009 Cordero Pedraja-Chaparro Pisaflores amp Polo 2017)

30 This negative coefficient suggests that the negative effects of agglomeration economies such as overcrowding pollution high cost of land and traffic congestion could predominate over the positive effects of scale economies in regional capitals 31 When the analysis is conducted for each zone independently MCF displays a negative influence in the North and Centre-North areas but a positive influence in the Centre-South and South areas These results confirm that on the one hand richer municipalities (those in the North and Centre-North) have less incentives for efficient management of their resources On the other hand results support the relevance of MCF helping poorer municipalities (those in the South) to reach their outcomes

87

Table 35

Panel data regressions

88

35 Conclusions

The trade-off between equity and efficiency is in the core of the economic discussion This

ldquoprinciplerdquo has been used by policymakers to prioritize the design of policies focused on economic

growth delaying those policies aimed at reducing economic inequalities This essay offers

empirical evidence of a negative relationship between inequality and efficiency that is a reduction

of income inequality could have positive effects on economic efficiency at least at the level of

local governments

We followed a traditional Two-Stage approach commonly used in the analysis of LGE We

compared cross-sectional and panel data results and we have added an instrumental variable

approach to give a causal interpretation to the link between efficiency and inequality We proposed

the use of a measure of natural resource dependence to instrumentalize the impact of income

inequality on LGE Given that our units of analysis are municipalities and not counties we argue

that our measure of NRD is correlated with income inequality and it does not have a direct

influence on LGE

We found that Chilean municipalities perform better than previous studies suggest

Municipal efficiency depicted significant levels of positive spatial autocorrelation and most of the

municipalities showed to be operating under increasing or decreasing returns to scale This would

imply that the policies generally used to improve efficiency such as amalgamation or cooperation

should be implemented observing the reality of each region and not as strategies at the national

level We also found that scale inefficiency explains a small proportion of the average total

inefficiency reason why the analysis of external factors that could affect the municipal efficiency

takes greater relevance

89

Income inequality plays an important part in explaining municipal efficiency In fact it was

found that reductions in income inequality could result in increases in municipal efficiency in a

similar proportion An unexpected finding was that the levels of education shows a negative

association with municipal performance This could be due to a low average level of education or

the existence of an omitted variable This variable could be the significant reduction in voting

turnout rates for local and national elections due to changes in the voting system during the period

of our analysis All in all our results may help to shed light on the potential consequences of

changes in contextual factors and the design of strategies aimed to increase municipal efficiency

in countries with similar characteristics to the Chilean economy For instance policies oriented to

take advantage of economies of scale can be formulated merging municipalities or establishing

networks in specific sectors such as education or health

Further work needs to be done both in measurement and in the explanation of differences in

municipal performance in Chile One area of future work will be to identify the factors that better

predict why municipalities operates under increasing decreasing or constant returns to scale

Multinomial logistic regression and the application of machine learning algorithms to SINIM data

sets appear as suitable methods for that purpose Intertemporal DEA (Drew amp Dollery 2015)

should be used to measure municipal efficiency capturing changes in total factor productivity In

addition municipalities operate under different levels of geographical authorities such as the

provincial mayor and the regional governor Hence it would be useful to know how each

municipality performs within each region-zone related to how performs to the whole country This

should be done conducting a metafrontier analysis (OrsquoDonnell Rao amp Battese 2008)

We have also identified through a cross sectional spatial exploratory analysis that on

average municipalities with similar levels of efficiency tend to cluster in space Regarding to

90

analyse the importance of contextual factors on municipal efficiency a deeper analysis should use

censored spatial models to check the significance of the spatial dimension in cross-sectional and

panel contexts Another interesting avenue for future research is associated with the negative

association found between LGE and education The significant reduction in votersacute turnout since

the law of automatic registration and voluntary voting in 2011 appears as a natural experiment to

analyse its effects on efficiency indicators such as municipal performance Incorporating variables

such as the voting turnout in each county or classifying municipalities based on individual

institutional political and economic characteristics could help to shed light on which of these

channels is the most relevant when analysing the impact of inequality on municipal efficiency

Finally we argued that an important part of the influence of income inequality over LGE

could be through its indirect effect on trust social capital and social cohesion The final essay will

delve deep in that relationship

91

Chapter 4 Social Cohesion Incivilities and Diversity

Evidence at the municipal level in Chile

41 Introduction

A deterioration in social cohesion could carry significant costs such as a reduction in

generalized trust between individuals and in institutions a society caught in a vicious circle of

inequality and citizens increasingly distanced from civic life (Uslaner 2011) A growing feeling

of frustration and discontentment can eventually translate into a social outbreak with uncertain

results This is precisely what have been happening in many countries around the world included

Chile

ldquoSocial cohesion is a state of affairs concerning both the vertical and the horizontal

interactions among members of society as characterized by a set of attitudes and norms that

includes trust a sense of belonging and the willingness to participate and help as well as their

behavioural manifestationsrdquo (Chan et al 2006) This definition highlights the multidimensionality

in the concept of social cohesion which has been measured using objective andor subjective

indicators of trust social norms solidarity willingness to participate in social and political groups

and feelings of belonging (Ariely 2014 Chan et al 2006) Multidimensionality also implies that

the impact of determinants of social cohesion such as economic and racial diversity could be

different for each of its various dimensions (Ariely 2014)

A common characteristic to all societies is that they are made up of different groups that

differ with respect to race ethnicity income religion language local identity etc The

92

Community Heterogeneity Thesis (Coffeacute amp Geys 2006) argues that individuals prefer to interact

with others that are like themselves Hence high levels of diversity particularly economic and

racial represent a complex scenario to maintain social cohesion One of the most common factors

adduced for social cohesion is income inequality with higher levels linked to lower levels of trust

(Ariely 2014 Rothstein amp Uslaner 2005)

Traditional measures of social cohesion may not be adequately capturing the deterioration

in social connections For instance measures of (lack of) trust include a strong subjective element

On the other hand proxies for social participation such as volunteering jobs or joining to social

organizations have not been supported by empirical evidence as a source of generalized social trust

(Rothstein amp Uslaner 2005) We proposed to use the rate of incivilities which we argue is a more

appropriate measure of the degree of worsening in the social context

Incivilities are those visible disorders in the public space that violate respectful social norms

and tend not to be treated as crimes by the criminal justice system There are two types of

incivilities social and physical Social incivilities include antisocial behaviours such as public

drinking noisy neighbours and fighting in public places Physical incivilities include among

others vandalism graffiti abandoned cars and garbage on the streets Because citizens and

political authorities cannot always distinguish between incivilities and crime they are usually

treated as an additional category of crime This implies that policies aimed to reduce incivilities

are generally based on punitive actions However theory and evidence on incivilities suggest that

factors explaining incivilities and crime could be different (Lewis 2017 Taylor 1999)

In Chile crime rates have shown a sustained downward trend after reaching its highest level

in 2011 On the other hand incivilities rate has shown a sustained upward trend which coincides

with the increasing victimization and feeling of insecurity in the population This has motivated

93

Chilean authorities based on the ldquoBroken Windows Theoryrdquo to propose new punitive actions (or

increase the severity of the current ones) to those who commit this type of antisocial behaviours

The ldquoBroken Windows Theoryrdquo states that higher rates of incivilities are a signal of social

disorganization which result in higher crime rates (J Q Wilson amp Kelling 1982) This is expected

to have consequences on familiesrsquo decisions such as moving away from public spaces or even

leaving their neighbourhoods

As far as we know there is no previous evidence about the potential causes of incivilities in

Chile Efforts to identify the factors explaining incivilities could help not only to reduce the risk

factors favouring violent and property crimes but also to guide interventions aimed to change

social behaviours and strengthen social cohesion in highly unequal societies Thus the main

contribution of the present study is to provide a deeper comprehension of the problem of incivilities

and how they can help to better understand the weakening of social cohesion that many

contemporary societies experience

We aim to offer the first evidence on the factors explaining the evolution and the differences

in incivilities rates in Chile We set up a panel for six years (2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and

2017) and 324 counties (1944 observations) We start exploring the evolution and geographical

distribution of incivilities Then we investigate whether economic and racial diversity after

controlling for other socioeconomic demographic and municipal characteristics can be regarded

as key predictors of incivilities

We use the Gini coefficient to proxy economic heterogeneity and the number of new visas

granted to foreigners as proportion of the county population as proxy for racial diversity The main

hypothesis is whether economic and racial diversity have a positive association with the rate of

incivilities In addition to the arguments regarding the ldquoCommunity Heterogeneity Thesisrdquo Taylor

94

(1999) and Skogan (1986 1999 2015) argue that incivilities are caused by inequality and the lack

of informal mechanisms of social control Based on the ldquoIncivilities Thesisrdquo the patterns of

incivilities should mirror the patterns of inequality (Taylor 1999) Then higher inequality should

be associated with higher physical and social vulnerability of the population This reduces social

control and increases social disorganization which triggers antisocial or negligent behaviours

Our main result reveals a strong positive association between the rate of incivilities and the

number of new visas granted per year The relationship with income inequality although also

positive seems to be less significant These findings give strong support to the ldquoCommunity

Heterogeneity Thesisrdquo and to a lesser extent to the ldquoIncivilities Thesisrdquo When the analysis is

disaggregated geographically racial diversity shows a clear positive effect The impact of income

inequality seems to be conditional depending on the level of income showing no effect in poorer

regions Results also show that the impact of economic and racial diversity differs by type of

incivility For example income inequality shows a strong association with ldquoStreet Tradingrdquo while

racial diversity with ldquoAlcohol Consumptionrdquo Two are the main policy implications On the one

hand a national strategy to address the problems associated with foreign immigration could help

to reduce incivilities For instance a joint effort between national and local authorities to curb

immigration and its distribution throughout the country On the other hand our results show that

the relationship between incivilities and economic diversity differs depending on the region or

geographical area Hence the impact on social cohesion of policies aimed to tackle economic

inequalities should be analysed in each specific context

The rate of incivilities also shows a negative association with the level of municipal financial

autonomy This implies that municipalities can effectively carry out policies to reduce incivilities

beyond the efforts of the central government Another important finding is that our results do not

95

support the hypothesis that a higher proportion of the young population is associated with higher

rates of incivilities Hence policies aimed to reduce incivilities should be focused on the causes of

incivilities rather than the criminalization of behaviours or stigmatization of specific population

groups

The structure of the chapter is as follows Section 42 outlines the relevant literature on social

cohesion and incivilities Section 43 describes the data variables and methodology and

establishes the hypotheses of the study Section 44 contains the results and discussions Section

45 presents the main conclusions

42 Related Literature

421 The Community Heterogeneity Thesis

The idea under ldquoThe Community Heterogeneity Thesisrdquo is that if individuals prefer to

interact with others who are similar to themselves in terms of income race or ethnicity high levels

of income inequality and racial diversity facilitate a context for lower tolerance and antisocial

behaviours lowering the ldquostaterdquo of social cohesion (Alesina 2000 Coffeacute amp Geys 2006 Letki

2008) Alessina and Ferrara (2002) give support to this hypothesis arguing that individuals have a

natural aversion to heterogeneity However the most popular explanation is the principle of

homophily people prefer to interact with others who share the same ethnic heritage have the same

social status and hence share experiences and tastes (Letki 2008 McPherson Smith-Lovin amp

Cook 2001 Tolsma et al 2009) For instance Delhey and Newton (2005) find for a sample of

60 countries that income inequality and ethnicity are strongly and negatively correlated with trust

Tolsma et al (2009) using data for Dutch neighbourhoods and municipalities find that social

cohesion is negatively and consistently affected by economic deprivation but not by ethnic

96

heterogeneity These authors also conclude that the effect of neighbourhood and municipal

characteristics on social cohesion depends on residentsrsquo income and educational level

Rothstein and Uslaner (2005) give two theoretical reasons why economic and racial diversity

should be causally related to social trust a key element of social cohesion First optimism about

the future makes less sense when there is more economic inequality which generally translates into

inequality of opportunities especially in areas such as education and the labour market Second

the distribution of resources and opportunities plays a key role in establishing the belief that people

share a common destiny and have similar fundamental values In highly unequal societies people

are likely to stick with their own kind Perceptions of injustice will reinforce negative stereotypes

of other groups making social trust and accommodation more difficult

Uslaner (2002 2011) and Uslaner and Brown (2005) find that high levels of inequality are

the single major factor driving down trust in people who are different from yourself Evidence for

USA finds that inequality is the strongest determinant of generalized trust over time (Rothstein amp

Uslaner 2005) Reducing inequality and then increasing generalized trust should have positive

consequences at the individual and aggregates levels At the individual level it may lead to greater

tolerance and more acts of altruism for people of different backgrounds At the aggregate level it

may lead to greater economic growth more redistribution from the rich to the poor and less

corruption (Uslaner 2002 2013) Letki (2008) argues that when neighbourhood socio-economic

context (apart from just an individualrsquos socioeconomic status) is considered it turns out to be the

main factor triggering negative attitudes and lack of trust in out-group members

The increasing diversity caused by immigration can also reduce the conditions necessary for

social cohesion (Ariely 2014 Holtug amp Mason 2010) Christel Kesler and Irene Bloemraad

(2010) find for nineteen advanced democracies between 1981 and 2000 that increasing migration

97

generally decreases trust civic engagement and political participation The authors also find that

in more equal countries with clear policies in favour of cultural minorities the negative effects of

migration are mitigated or even reversed Letki (2008) states that deprivation and disorder tend to

be strongly correlated with racial diversity Because we propose the use of the number of disorders

or antisocial behaviours known as ldquoincivilitiesrdquo as our measure of social cohesion we describe the

literature on incivilities in the next section

422 The literature on incivilities

The study of incivilities has been a continuing concern mainly for developed countries since

the 1980s The focus has changed from individual and psychological explanations to ecological

(contextual) and social explanations (Taylor 1999) The individual approach basically considered

perceptions of incivilities as an explanatory variable of fear of crime The ecological explanation

argues that indicators of economic disadvantage (eg income levels income inequality

unemployment rate and poverty rate) are the keys to understand a process of social disorganization

and lack of informal control These economic factors lead to higher rates of inappropriate or

negligent behaviours and ultimately to higher crime rates (Blau amp Blau 1982 Messner Rosenfeld

amp Baumer 2004 Phan Orsquobrien Mendolia amp Paloyo 2017 Sampson 1986)

The negative impact of incivilities is not merely reflected in its association with crime rates

(Skogan 2015) Physical and social incivilities could worsen neighbourhoods by affecting quality

of life perception of the environment and public and private behaviours Previous research has

indicated that a higher level of incivilities is associated with health problems (Branas et al 2011

Cohen et al 2000 Hill amp Angel 2005 Ross 2011 Ross amp Mirowsky 2001) greater

victimization and fear of crime (Brunton-Smith Jackson amp Sutherland 2014 Mijanovich amp

Weitzman 2003) and multiple negative economic effects For instance incivilities could be

98

related to a reduction in commercial activity lower investment in real estate reduction in house

prices (Skogan 2015) and population instability (Hipp 2010)

To describe the state of the art in the study of incivilities and their consequences Skogan

(2015) used the concept of untidiness to characterize the research on incivilities The study of

incivilities has had multiple approaches (economic ecological and psychological) Incivilities

have also been measured using multiple sources of information (police reports surveys trained

observation) which result in different measures (perceptions vs count data) However the question

about what specific factors have the strongest effect on incivilities has been overlooked and

perceptions about incivilities have been used mainly as a predictor of crime fear of crime and

victimization

There are two types of incivilities social and physical Social incivilities are a matter of

behaviour including groups of rowdy teens public drunkenness people fighting and street hassles

Physical incivilities involve visual signs of negligence and decay such as abandoned buildings

broken streetlights trash-filled lots and graffiti (Skogan 1999 2015 Taylor 1999) Three reasons

justify the distinction between physical and social incivilities First like multiple dimensions of

social cohesion different structural and social conditions could be responsible for different types

and categories of incivilities Second punitive sanctions are expected to have a greater impact on

physical than on social incivilities since the latter are more related to behaviours rooted in citizensrsquo

culture Third physical incivilities should be more related to absolute measures of economic

disadvantage (eg poverty or unemployment rates) and social incivilities to relative indicators of

economic disadvantage (eg such as income inequality) This line of research is based on the

ldquoincivilities thesisrdquo which states that to understand the distribution of disorders it is necesary to

analyse the patterns of structured inequalities (Skogan 1986 Taylor 1999)

99

423 The ldquoIncivilities Thesisrdquo

Incivilities theories began with a focus on psychological dynamics (Garofalo 1978) moved

forward to an interest in social psychological processes (J Q Wilson amp Kelling 1982) and finally

evolved into a focus on community dynamics and outcomes (Skogan 1999) Individual and group

behaviours in tandem with ecological features have been proposed as the key factors explaining

incivilities and their posterior influence on social control quality of life and more serious crime

(J Q Wilson amp Kelling 1982)

In terms of ecological factors particularly those related to economic conditions Skogan

(1986) was the first linking the distribution of incivilities to the patterns of structural inequality If

incivilities mirror inequality structure this will have consequences in residentsrsquo health and safety

due to its levels of vulnerability In addition structured inequality associated with the proportion

of the manufacturing sector (eg when fabrics tend to move from cities to farther areas) will be

related to higher social disorganization and differences between urban and rural areas (W J

Wilson 1996) In addition a persistent feeling of relative deprivation (persistently high levels of

income inequality) could lead to fellow inhabitants of the community to commit antisocial

behaviours showing their frustration with the current economic model

The literature on incivilities posits that their causes are different from those of crime (Lewis

2017) Unlike crime analysis especially property crimes information on the location where the

incivility takes place is the same as the location where the perpetrator resides To achieve a

comprehensive understanding of the different types of incivilities it is crucial to consider

incivilities data covering an entire territory and not just specific areas (Hooghe Vanhoutte

Hardyns amp Bircan 2010) If we add to this the availability of panel data it could be possible not

100

only to identify the main determinants of incivilities but also the causal mechanism from income

inequality towards incivilities rate

In Chile citizen security crime and delinquency are among the most significant issues for

citizens based on opinion polls Existing research has found weak evidence of a significant

relationship between crime and indicators of socio-economic disadvantage such as income

inequality and unemployment rate with significant effects only on property crime (Beyer amp

Vergara 2006 Nuntildeez Rivera Villavicencio amp Molina 2003 Rivera Gutieacuterrez amp Nuacutentildeez 2009)

Crime deterrence variables such as the probability of being caught or the number of police

resources have also shown ambiguous results (Beyer amp Vergara 2006 Rivera et al 2009

Vergara 2012) Evidence at the county level shows that crime is higher in urban counties those

with a lower mean income per capita and counties located in the North of the country In addition

at least half of the crimes reported in one county are perpetrated by criminals from other counties

(Rivera et al 2009) No studies could be found about the determinants of incivilities

4 3 Methodology

431 Period of analysis and data sample

Chile is a relatively small country in Latin America with a population of 18346018

inhabitants in 2017 The country is divided into 345 municipalities with on average 53104

inhabitants (median value 18705) Municipalities are the organ of the State Administration

responsible to solve local needs Municipalities are not only the relevant political and

administrative local unit of analysis but also they represent the feeling of lsquocommunityrsquo among

the inhabitants of each municipality (Hooghe et al 2010) Our data includes many sources of

101

heterogeneity among municipalities such as indicators of economic deprivation population

density demographic characteristics and whether the county is a regional or provincial capital

We use a sample of 324 municipalities covering most of the Chilean territory for the period

2006ndash17 Data on incivilities is obtained from the ldquoCentre of Studies and Analysis of Crimerdquo

which is part of the ldquoSubsecretaria de Prevencion del Delitordquo (SPD in its Spanish acronym) of the

Chilean government32 Information on income inequality and control variables is obtained from

the ldquoNational Socioeconomic Characterization Surveyrdquo (CASEN in its Spanish acronym) the

ldquoNational Institute of Statisticsrdquo (INE in its Spanish acronym) the ldquoNational Municipal

Information Systemrdquo (SINIM in its Spanish acronym) and the Immigration Department of the

Government of Chile Our panel only includes the years for which CASEN survey is available

2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017

432 Operationalisation of the response variable and exploratory analysis

Official Chilean records contain information for the total number of cases of incivilities per

year at the county level The number of cases is the sum of complains and detentions reported at

the police Our dependent variable 119894119899119888119894119907119894119897119894119905119894119890119904 correspond to the number of cases per year Due

to population differences comparisons between counties are made using the incivilities rate per

1000 population calculated as

119894119899119888119894119907_119903119886119905119890 lowast 1000 (41)

where 119894119899119888119894119907_119903119886119905119890 is the incivilities rate 119905 is the year 119894 the county and 119899 is the population of the

county per year

32 httpceadspdgovclestadisticas-delictuales

102

Figure 41 illustrates at the top the evolution of the total number (cases reported) of

incivilities and crimes at the country level for the period 2006-1733 At the bottom Figure 41

shows the evolution of the mean county rate per 1000 inhabitants We observe that both the number

of incivilities and the number of crimes has reached similar annual figures however average

county rates per 1000 population show different trends Crime rate displays a sustained fall after

reaching its pick in 2011 Incivilities average county rate which also reached a pick and posterior

drop in 2011 has recovered its upward trend since 2016 considerably exceeding the crime rate

Figure 41 Evolution number and rates of incivilities and crime (DMCS) in Chile 2006-2017

33 Crime refers to ldquocrimes of greater social connotationrdquo (DMCS in its Spanish acronym) which includes violent and property crimes

103

Chilean records classify incivilities in nine categories most of them associated with social

incivilities Summary statistics for the total and for each of the nine categories are presented in

Table 41 In addition Figure 42 shows the evolution of incivilities by category for the whole

period We see that the global trend in incivilities is mainly due to a substantial increase in ldquoStreet

Tradingrdquo and ldquoPublic Alcohol Consumptionrdquo A common element of Figures 41 and 42 is the

significant change in trend experienced by crimes and incivilities in 2011 That year the SPD

became dependent on the Ministry of Interior of the Chilean Government This event put the issue

of crime and delinquency within national priorities for the central government

Table 41

Summary statistics total count of incivilities and by category (full sample and period)

Unlike crime rates we do not expect significant cross-county spillover effects in incivilities

However the questions of where incivilities are concentrated and why they are there can be of

great interest (Skogan 2015) Figure 43 shows quantile maps for the rate of incivilities per 1000

inhabitants for the initial and final years in our panel

104

Figure 42 Evolution total number of incivilities by category

Figure 43 Spatial distribution of incivilities rate per 1000 inhabitants (2006 vs 2017)

105

We observe that the range of values has increased significantly from 2006 to 2017 but the

spatial distribution remains almost unchanged On the one hand high incivilities rates in the North

could be associated with the mining activity On the other hand high rates in the Centre area

(where the countyrsquos capital is located) could be related to the higher population density and the

concentration of the economic activity34

To see how the different types of incivilities are distributed throughout the country we have

grouped those similar categories in four groups ldquoPublic Damagerdquo (ldquoPublic Disturbsrdquo ldquoPublic

Damagerdquo ldquoOtherrdquo) ldquoThreatsrdquo (ldquoPublic Fightrdquo ldquoThreatsrdquo and ldquoAnnoying Noisesrdquo) ldquoAlcohol

Consumptionrdquo (ldquoPublic Alcohol Consumptionrdquo and ldquoDrunkennessrdquo) and ldquoStreet Tradingrdquo This

distinction in groups could be relevant if we expect different patterns and different effects of

community heterogeneity on social cohesion among counties For instance we expect higher

levels of Public Damage in big urban cities Street trading is more likely in urban cities but also in

tourist areas The spatial distribution of these four groups for the six-year-average rate per 1000

inhabitants can be found in Appendix R

433 Measures of community heterogeneity and control variables

Social cohesion income inequality and racial diversity are all ldquocommunityrdquo (not individual)

characteristics Thus to understand their relationship we need aggregated data at least at the

county-municipal level With more disaggregated data like at the suburbs level the required

heterogeneity among groups of citizens is lost (Wilkinson 1999) Like Coffeacute and Geys (2006) we

use the Gini coefficient to capture economic heterogeneity However instead of a measured for

34 We also analysed the spatial distribution of crime rates In general areas with high levels of incivilities not necessarily are associated with high levels of crime This could imply that factors explaining incivilities and crime are different

106

the diversity of nationalities we use the proportion of foreign population to capture racial

heterogeneity Income data is obtained from the CASEN survey The Gini coefficient is calculated

for each county and included through the variable gini Racial heterogeneity is included through

the variable foreign which is the annual number of new VISAS granted to foreigners as a

proportion of the county population Chile has experienced a significant increase in immigration

since 2011 Immigration has been concentrated in the metropolitan region and mining regions in

the North of the country We expect a positive relationship between immigration and incivilities

although as with the relationship between immigration and crime the foundations for this

hypothesis are not strong (Hooghe et al 2010 Sampson 2008)

Economic development is another explanation for social cohesion frequently appealed to

explain trust with wealthier societies considered to exhibit higher levels of trust (Delhey amp

Newton 2005) In this study we include the natural log of the mean household income per capita

log(income) We also include the poverty rate poverty and the unemployment rate

unemployment Unlike the variable log(income) these variables are expected to be positively

associated with the number of incivilities When a relative indicator of economic heterogeneity

such as income inequality is included as determinant of social cohesion we should expect less

effect from absolute indicators of economic disadvantage such as poverty and unemployment rates

(Hooghe et al 2010 Tolsma et al 2009)

Among demographic variables the percentage of inhabitants between 10 and 24 years old is

included through the variable youth The variable women defined as the proportion of the female

population in each county is also included Variable youth is expected to have an ambiguous effect

Although young people have lower victimization and report rates they also represent the group

more likely to commit antisocial behaviours when a community has a low capacity of self-

107

regulation (eg when there is low parental supervision) The female population is associated with

a higher report of incivilities related to the male population

It is argued that crime and incivilities are essentially urban problems (Christiansen 1960

Wirth 1938) We include the variable log(density) defined as the log of population density (the

number of inhabitants divided by the area of each county in square kilometres) and a dummy

variable capital indicating whether a county is an administrative capital (provincial or regional)

Two additional variables are included to capture the level of informal social control exerted

by families living in each municipality First the variable education which is defined as the

average years of education of people over 15 years old Second the variable housing which capture

the proportion of families which are owners of their housing unit Although education and housing

are related to both the possibility of reporting and committing an incivility we expect a negative

association with the rate of incivilities

In Chile crime has been mainly a problem faced by the police and the Central Government

Administration To control for current law enforcement policies we include the variable

deterrence defined as the number of arrests as a proportion of the total number of incivilities cases

In addition municipalities can develop their own initiatives to deal with crime and incivilities

depending on their capacity to generate its own resources The level of financial autonomy from

central transfers is captured by the variable autonomy This variable is obtained from SINIM and

it is defined as the proportion of the budget revenue of each municipality that comes from its own

permanent sources of revenues A categorical variable mayor is also included This variable

indicates whether the municipality mayor is supported by the ldquoLEFTrdquo or the ldquoRIGHTrdquo political

parties (related to those ldquoINDEPENDENTrdquo mayors)

108

Table 42 presents descriptive statistics for our measures of income and racial heterogeneity

and the set of numeric control variables The Pearson correlation among these variables is shown

in Appendix S

Table 42

Summary statistics numeric explanatory variables

434 Methods

The annual count of incivilities as is characteristic for count data is highly concentrated in

a relatively small range of values In addition the distribution is right-skewed due to the presence

of important outliers (counties with a high number of incivilities) Figure 44 shows the

distribution of the six-year average number of incivilities for each of the 15 regions in Chile35 We

observe that regions differ in the number of counties in which they are divided In addition

counties within each region show important differences in the number of incivilities For instance

35 Regions are ordered from left to right and from top to bottom in the way they are geographically distributed from North to South So the northernmost region of the country is the ldquoXVrdquo and the southernmost region is the ldquoXIIrdquo The Metropolitan region (where the countryrsquos capital is located) is region ldquoXIIIrdquo in the centre of the country (see Appendix C)

109

excepting the Metropolitan region ldquoXIIIrdquo most counties in regions located in the centre of the

country (middle row in Figure 44) show a range of incivilities between 0 and 2000 The number

of incivilities is considerably lower in counties located in the northern (top row in Figure 44) and

southern (bottom row in Figure 44) regions of the country compared to regions in the centre of

the country It also seems clear from Figure 44 that the number of incivilities does not follow a

normal distribution

Figure 44 Annual average number of incivilities per county

The number of incivilities can be better described by a Poisson distribution In this case the

number of incivilities is ldquothe countrdquo and the number of incivilities per year is ldquothe rate per unit

timerdquo We are interested in modelling the average number of incivilities per year usually called 120582

as a function of a set of contextual factors to explain differences in incivilities between and within

110

counties The main characteristic of the Poisson distribution is that the mean is equal to the

variance This implies that as the mean rate for a Poisson variable increases the variance also

increases The main implication is we cannot use OLS to model 120582 as a function of the set of

contextual factors because the equal variance assumption in linear regression is violated

The rate of incivilities between counties is not directly comparable due to population

differences We expect counties with more people to have more reports of incivilities since there

are more people who could be affected To capture differences in population which is called the

exposure of our response variable 120582 it is necessary to include a term on the right side of our model

called an offset We will use the log of the county population in thousands as our offset36

Additionally similar to the case of crime data incivilities show a significant degree of

overdispersion (variance higher than the mean) suggesting that there is more variation in the

response than the Poisson model implies37 We also model and regress incivilities assuming a

Negative Binomial distribution to address overdispersion An advantage of this approach is that it

introduces a dispersion parameter in addition to 120582 which gives the model more flexibility38

Considering as the response variable the count of incivilities per year the model can be

expressed as follow

120582 119890119909119901 120573 120573 119892119894119899119894 120573 119891119900119903119890119894119892119899 119883120574 120572 120579 (42)

36 If we think of 120582 as the average number of incivilities per year then represents the number per 1000

inhabitants so that the yearly count is adjusted to be comparable across counties of different sizes Adjusting the yearly count by population is equivalent to adding 119897119900119892 1199011199001199011199061198971198861199051198941199001198991000 to the right-hand side of the regression equation 37 Without adjusting for overdispersion we use incorrect artificially small standard errors leading to artificially small p-values for model coefficients 38 The Negative Binomial model posits selecting a 120582 (average number of incivilities) for each county and then generating a count using a Poisson random variable with the selected 120582 With this approach the counts will be more dispersed than would be expected for observations based on a single Poisson variable with rate 120582

111

where 120582 is the rate of incivilities 119883 is our vector of controls 120572prime119904 are county-specific constants

and 120579prime119904 are time-specific constants Accounting for differences in county population we have

119890119909119901 120573 120573 119892119894119899119894 119883120574 120572 120579 (43)

where 119901119900119901119906119897119886119905119894119900119899 is the county population per year Hence the model to be estimated using

Maximum Likelihood Estimation (MLE) is

119897119900119892 120582 120573 120573 119892119894119899119894 119883120574 120572 120579 119897119900119892 (44)

Finally to account for different effects depending on the type of incivilities we also run

equation (44) for each of the four groups of incivilities defined in section (432)

435 Hypotheses

Based on the community heterogeneity hypothesis the relationship between social cohesion

and diversity should be stronger for lower levels of income and less educated groups of people

(Tolsma et al 2009) Hence contrary to evidence for developed and more equal countries we

expect a significant positive association for the Chilean case where more than 50 of the

population is economically vulnerable (OECD 2017)

The main hypotheses to be tested in this essay is whether the number of incivilities is

positively associated with the level of economic and racial heterogeneity at the county level We

start analysing this association for the full sample and period Next we analyse whether the

relationship between incivilities and our measures of diversity differs by geographic area (region

or zone) Finally we check whether the effect of economic and racial diversity is different

depending on the group of incivilities

112

44 Results and Discussion

Overall our results show that the rate of incivilities displays a stronger and more significant

relationship with racial diversity than with economic heterogeneity This association differs for

different geographic areas and for different types of incivilities Absolute economic indicators

except for income show a significant but small effect Increases in the average levels of income

or education and more financial autonomy for municipalities seem to be effective ways to reduce

the rate of incivilities

We estimate equation (44) assuming that the number of incivilities follows a Poisson

distribution Regional and temporal heterogeneity are captured through the inclusion of dummy

variables for five years (with 2006 as the reference year) and fourteen regional dummies (with

region XIII as the reference region) Results are reported in Table 4339 This table is structured in

two blocks of regressions pooled models in columns (1)-(4) and fixed-effects models in columns

(5)-(8)40 The first column in each block only includes economic indicators relative and absolute

trying to test which ones are more relevant and whether incivilities tend to mirror income

inequality (the ldquoincivilities thesisrdquo) The second column adds the variable foreign to account for

the effect of racial diversity (Letki 2008) The third column includes education to check whether

the association between economic and racial diversity with social cohesion changes (gets less

significant) when we control for educational level (Tolsma et al 2009) The final column in each

block corresponds to the full model specification which includes the rest of controls

39 Pooled estimations were obtained using the R command glm() and compared with results obtained from the command poisson in STATA 15 Fixed effects and random effects models were estimated using the STATA command xtpoisson Negative Binomial models were estimated using the command glmnb() in the MASS package for R and commands nbreg and xtnbreg in STATA 15 Results for Negative Binomial regressions are in Appendix T 40 We have omitted results with random effects due to the literature on panel count data models suggest that the most robust estimator is Poisson regression with Fixed Effects (Santos Silva amp Tenreyro 2010 2011)

113

Table 43

Poisson regressions

114

The positive and significant coefficient for the variable gini besides being small it becomes

insignificant in the fixed effects specification which includes the full set of controls This result

does not seem to be enough evidence to support our hypothesis that more unequal counties display

higher rates of incivilities On the other hand racial diversity through the variable foreign shows

a consistent positive association with the rate of incivilities41 Together coefficients for gini and

foreign seems to support the ldquocommunity heterogeneity thesisrdquo (Letki 2008) but not the

ldquoincivilities thesisrdquo (Skogan 1999) To check this finding we run the pooled full model

specification for each region and results are shown in Table 44 where regions have been ordered

from North to South The sign of the coefficient of the variable gini differs for different regions

Moreover the relationship is insignificant in some of the most unequal regions which are in the

South of the country (VIII IX and XIV) This result rejects the hypothesis that incivilities mirror

structural income inequalities For the variable foreign 12 out of 15 regions confirm the positive

association with the rate of incivilities42

We also run our pooled full model separately for each group of incivilities defined at the end

of section (432) Income inequality keeps its significant but small association with each group of

incivilities (see Table 45) Our measure of racial diversity shows a stronger association with

ldquoAlcohol Consumptionrdquo related to ldquoPublic Damagerdquo and ldquoThreatsrdquo The link with ldquoStreet Tradingrdquo

appears as non-significant These results support our general finding that on the one hand racial

heterogeneity exert a more significant influence on the rate of incivilities than economic

41 To get the effects of the variables gini and foreign over the rate of incivilities per 1000 inhabitants we need to exponentiate their coefficients Thus an increase in one unit in the variable gini increases the rate of incivilities per 1000 inhabitantsrdquo in 1005 times (e^0005) in the pooled full model Similarly an increase in one point in variable foreign is expected to increase the ldquorate of incivilities per 1000 inhabitantsrdquo in 10876 times (e^0084) in the full pooled model and 10471 (e^0046) times in the full Fixed Effects model 42 Given that depending on the geographic location regions share certain characteristics the model was also run clustering regions in 4 zones (see Figure 31 in chapter 3) Results by zone are in Appendix U

115

heterogeneity On the other hand results confirm our hypothesis that the effect of diversity is

different for different types of incivilities

Table 44 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson models by region

Back to our general results in Table 43 the significant and negative coefficient of the

income variable and to a lesser extent the significant and positive coefficients of poverty and

unemployment provide evidence that absolute rather than relative economic indicators may be

more important explanations of the rate of incivilities This is opposite to evidence for the analysis

116

of crime rates such as in Hoodge (2010) and support the idea that determinants of incivilities are

different from those of crime Our results are also opposite to those for Dutch municipalities where

economic indicators turned out to be more important than ethnic heterogeneity (Tolsma et al

2009) The coefficient for the variable log(income) could be interpreted as counties with an income

level under the average face higher problems of antisocial behaviours such as incivilities In

addition as the income level moves far away from its average low level the problem of incivilities

is less relevant43 In terms of policy implications only those policies that achieve a significant

increase in the average level of county income seem to be effective in reducing incivilities and

strengthening social cohesion

Table 45 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson model by incivility group

43 We ran our model splitting the sample of counties in quintiles based on their income level The coefficient for the variable gini only showed a significant (and positive) coefficient for the second third and fourth quintile A non-significant coefficient for the first quintile could imply that other types of inequalities (eg health education) are more relevant in the poorest counties In the case of the fifth quintile (the richest group of counties) they have better facilities in terms of infrastructure police resources self-protection etc which could reduce the potential triggers of incivilities

117

The inclusion of the variable education significantly improved the goodness of fit of the

models and did not generate significant changes in the coefficients of our measures of economic

and racial diversity This result rejects the proposition that the relationship between social

cohesion and diversity becomes less strong when controlled by education (Tolsma et al 2009)

Additionally it highlights the topic of education as a relevant determinant of the rate of incivilities

and social cohesion

Among control variables there are also some important results Opposite to what we

expected the variable youth shows a negative or non-significant coefficient Although this result

could be due to the lack of ldquophysical incivilitiesrdquo in Chilean records it indicates that it is incorrect

to stereotype this group as the main responsible for high incivilities rates The significant and

negative coefficient of the variable autonomy in the fixed effects specification could also have

important policy implications It is a signal that local governments can play an important role in

reducing incivilities or complementing the efforts from the central government Another

interesting result is the significant coefficient of the variable housing The latter finding is

particularly important in the sense that a negative sign supports public policies oriented to increase

homeownership as effective ways to improve social cohesion However the small magnitude of

the coefficient that even showed the opposite sign in some model specifications could be

explained for the high level of segregation that these policies have generated in Chilean society

As mentioned in the Introduction and Literature Review so far only a few studies have

used measures of disorders or incivilities as dependent variable to explain changes in social

cohesion (Skogan 2015) In addition there is no evidence in Chile analysing the determinants of

incivilities separately from those of crimes The importance of our results on identifying the

importance of economic and racial diversity on social cohesion lies mainly in its generality An

118

important number of countries all around the world share a similar context characterized by high

levels of inequality and an explosive increase in immigration These countries are also

experiencing a worsening in social cohesion which increases the risk of a social outburst

4 5 Conclusions

The main goal of this essay was to determine whether differences in incivilities at the county

level mirror differences in income distribution and racial diversity Previous literature suggests a

positive and strong association between social cohesion and indicators of economic disadvantage

relative deprivation and racial diversity (Letki 2008 Tolsma et al 2009 Uslaner amp Brown 2005)

While not all our results were significant they showed helpful insights about how and where

economic and racial diversity are more likely to influence the rate of incivilities and social

cohesion

We used data for the period 2006ndash17 economic heterogeneity was measured through the

Gini coefficient at the county level and racial heterogeneity was proxied by the number of granted

visas to foreigners as proportion of county population We found strong evidence of a significant

and positive association between the rate of incivilities and racial diversity but not with income

inequality Contrary to previous evidence at the municipal level (Coffeacute amp Geys 2006 Tolsma et

al 2009) in general our results give support for the ldquohomophily principlerdquo and the ldquocommunity

heterogeneity hypothesisrdquo However results also showed that the effect of economic and racial

diversity varies throughout the Chilean regions and for the different types of incivilities

We also found that policies aimed at controlling the behaviour of young people did not have

strong empirical support In terms of the role that local governments may have in facing the

119

growing problem of incivilities we found evidence that efforts managed from the municipalities

can be an important complement to those from the central government

Future research should go further on the role of local authorities on incivilities and social

cohesion On the one hand municipalities could have a direct impact on social cohesion through

the implementation of programs complementary to those of central authorities oriented to reduce

incivilities and crime On the other hand social cohesion could be indirectly affected when local

authorities display an inefficient performance supplying public services to citizens or they are

recognized as corrupted institutions We suggest that policy makers from central government

should give local authorities a greater role in fighting antisocial behaviours and crime Evaluating

programs in specific municipalities could help to elucidate the causal effect of for instance higher

fiscal autonomy on the rate of incivilities

Another interesting area for future work will be to analyse how housing policies have

contributed to the phenomenon of segregation of Chilean society and in the process of weakening

social cohesion Finally our main result highlights the need of a deeper analysis of the impact that

foreign immigration is having in Chile For instance disaggregating information by country of

origin and the reasons why immigrants are arriving to the country or specific regions will surely

help to understand the impacts of immigration

120

Chapter 5 Conclusions

This thesis investigated in three essays the issue of income inequality in Chile using county-

level data for the period 2006-2017 The first essay supplied empirical evidence about the

importance of the degree of dependence on natural resources in terms of employment in explaining

cross-county differences in income inequality The second essay analysed the potential causal

effect that income inequality has on the level of technical efficiency of local governments

providing public goods and services Lastly the third essay studied the relationship between social

cohesion measured through the number of antisocial behaviours classified as ldquoincivilitiesrdquo and

the levels of income and racial heterogeneity

Findings from the first essay support the idea that the endowment of natural resources plays

a significant role in explaining income inequality in Chile However contrary to what most

theoretical and empirical evidence postulates our findings showed a robust negative association

between the two variables This means that the reduction experienced in Chile in the degree of

dependence on natural resources in terms of employment has contributed to the persistence of high

levels of income inequality The exploratory analysis indicated that income inequality shows a

general clustering process characterized by a significant and positive spatial autocorrelation

Regarding the previous evidence for Chile (Paredes et al 2016) the regression analysis confirmed

the relevance of the spatial dimension of income inequality through a process of spatial

heterogeneity giving less support to the existence of a process of spatial dependence (spillover

effect) in the variable itself

121

Essay 2 studied the potential trade-off between efficiency and equity analysing the influence

of income inequality on the efficiency of local governments at the municipal level To identify the

causal effect of income inequality on municipal efficiency we proposed the use of the proportion

of firms in the primary sector as an instrument for income inequality Findings confirmed our

hypothesis that efficiency is lower in more unequal counties This result suggests the non-existence

of the trade-off between equity and efficiency Hence policies intended to reduce inequality could

help to increase efficiency at least at the level of municipal local governments

The third essay analysed how social cohesion proxied by the rate of incivilities is associated

with the levels of economic diversity proxied by income inequality and the levels of racial

diversity proxied by the number of new visas grated as proportion of the county population

Findings gave strong support to the hypothesis that the rate of incivilities is positively related to

racial diversity and to a lesser extent to economic diversity In addition the rate of incivilities

appears negatively related to the degree of financial autonomy of municipalities This means that

local governments can effectively contribute to the reduction of incivilities which could help

reduce victimization and crime rates ultimately strengthening social cohesion

Taken together findings from essays 2 and 3 highlight the important role that income

inequality could play in other relevant economic and social dimensions These findings add to the

understanding of the potential consequences of income inequality particularly in natural resource

rich countries with persistently high levels of inequality

The present study has mainly investigated income inequality at the county level In addition

Chilean municipalities play an important role providing ldquoservices to peoplerdquo so our findings could

be applied in other highly unequal countries with a high degree of dependence on natural resources

and local governments with similar responsibilities For instance in Latin America apart from

122

Chile and Brazil there are no studies on the efficiency of local governments Other limitations are

associated with the availability of information For instance important indicators such as GDP per

capita are only available at the regional level and information of incomes is not available annually

In addition given the heterogeneity among municipalities some type of grouping of municipalities

should be performed before looking for causal relationships or conducting program evaluation

Despite these limitations we believe this study could be the basis for different strands of future

research on the topic of inequality local government efficiency and social cohesion

It was stated in chapter 2 based on the resource curse hypothesis literature there are two

elements that determine whether NR are a curse or blessing in terms of socioeconomic outcomes

First the curse is more likely in countries with weak political and governance institutions Second

different types of resources affect institutions differently with resources that are concentrated in

space so-called ldquopointrdquo resources tend to impair institutions while ldquodiffuserdquo resources do not

(Deacon 2011 Isham Woolcock Pritchett amp Busby 2005) Our results showed a negative

relationship between income inequality and our measure of natural resource dependence even after

controlling for zone fixed effects and for the level of government expenditure This result could

be interpreted as a signal that NR has a direct effect on income inequality in addition to the indirect

impact through market or institutional channels Using other potential institutional transmission

channels will shed light about the true effect that the endowment of natural resources has over

income inequality Variables that could capture these institutional channels include the level of

employment in the public sector measures of rule of law and corruption and changes in the

creation of new business in the secondary and tertiary sectors related to the primary sector

Based on results from chapter 3 most of the municipalities show scale inefficiencies One

immediate area for future work will involve using our set of contextual factors to predict the status

123

of municipalities in terms of scale inefficiencies Defining as dependent variable whether a

municipality shows constant decreasing or increasing returns to scale we could run a multinomial

logistic regression to predict municipal status For instance we would expect that a one-unit

increase in the Gini coefficient should increase the probability of scale inefficiencies (increasing

or decreasing returns to scale rather than constant returns to scale) Because the aim in this case

would be predicting a certain result in terms of returns to scale the next step should involve to

split the full sample in training and testing data sets and to use some resampling methods such as

bootstrapping This will allow us to evaluate the performance and accuracy of our model

predictions using different random samples of municipalities Results from Machine Learning

algorithms will help us to assess the generalizability of our results to other data sets

Future work should also benefit greatly by using data on different Latin American countries

to (1) compare the responsibilities of local governments (2) select a common set of inputs and

output to evaluate LGE (3) identify the relevance of scales inefficiencies in explaining differences

in performance and (4) analyse the influence of contextual characteristics over LGE Differences

in the main primary sector activity in each country such as oil in Brazil mining in Chile or Coffee

in Colombia could be responsible for differences in LGE among countries These differences could

be associated with sources of revenue management of expenditure and definitions of outputs or

contextual effects such as corrupted institutions or the delay in the development of other sectors

such as manufacturing or services

To delve deep on reasons explaining the social crisis experienced by Chilean society and

other countries one area of future work will be to analyse the relationship between diversity and

the origins of social revolutions Based on Tiruneh (2014) the three most important factors that

explain the onset of social revolutions are economic development regime type and state

124

ineffectiveness Interesting questions include whether the characteristics of Chilean context at the

end of 2019 are enough to trigger the transformation of the political and socioeconomic system

Social revolutions particularly violent revolutions are less likely in more democratic educated

and wealthy societies So it would be relevant to identify the factors explaining the violence that

has characterized the social crisis in Chile Finally the democratic regime has been maintained in

the last decades with changes between left and right governments This could imply that more

important than the regime has been the efficiency or ineffectiveness of the governments to satisfy

the needs of the population

Future work should also cover the disaggregation of information regarding foreign

population in terms of the reasons for new granted visas and the country of origin Official data

allows us to disaggregate whether the benefit is permanent (students and employees with contract)

or temporary Furthermore most of the new visas were traditionally granted to neighbouring

countries (Peru and Bolivia) a trend that has changed in the recent years to include countries such

as Colombia Venezuela and Haiti An analysis of how economic and social indicators have been

affected by changes in the composition of foreigners their reasons for immigrating to the country

and their geographical distribution have implications for economic policy at both the national and

local levels At the national level such analysis should be a key input when proposing changes to

the national immigration policy At the local level it could help define the role of municipalities

to assess the benefits and challenges of immigration These challenges are mainly related to the

provision of public goods and services such as health and education which in Chile are the

responsibility of the municipalities

The findings of this thesis suggest that policymakers should encourage policies that reduce

income inequality The key role that municipalities could play to strengthen social cohesion and

125

the increasingly important role that foreign population is acquiring in most modern societies are

also interesting avenues for future research However the picture is still incomplete and more

research is needed incorporating other dimensions of inequality This is essential if we want to

understand the reasons that could have triggered the social outbursts experienced by various

economies across the globe

126

Bibliography

Acemoglu D (1995) Reward structures and the allocation of talent European Economic Review 39(1) 17ndash33 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg1010160014-2921(94)00014-Q

Acemoglu D (2002) Technical Change Inequality and the Labor Market Journal of Economic Literature 40(1) 7ndash72 httpsdoiorg1012570022051026976

Acemoglu D Aghion P amp Violante G L (2001) Deunionization Technical Change and Inequality Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 55(1) 229ndash264 httpsdoiorg101016S0167-2231(01)00058-6

Acemoglu D Johnson S amp Robinson J A (2001) The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development An Empirical Investigation The American Economic Review 91(5) 1369ndash1401 httpsdoiorg101257aer9151369

Acemoglu D amp Robinson J A (2002) The Political Economy of the Kuznets Curve Review of Development Economics 6(2) 183ndash203 httpsdoiorg1011111467-936100149

Afonso A amp Fernandes S (2006) Measuring local government spending efficiency Evidence for the Lisbon region Regional Studies 40(1) 39ndash53 httpsdoiorg10108000343400500449937

Afonso A amp Fernandes S (2008) Assessing and explaining the relative efficiency of local government The Journal of Socio-Economics 37(5) 1946ndash1979 httpsdoiorg101016jsocec200703007

Afonso A Schuknecht L amp Tanzi V (2010) Income distribution determinants and public spending efficiency Journal of Economic Inequality 8(3) 367ndash389 httpsdoiorg101007s10888-010-9138-z

Akita T (2003) Decomposing regional income inequality in China and Indonesia using two-stage nested Theil decomposition method The Annals of Regional Science 37(1) 55ndash77 httpsdoiorg101007s001680200107

Alesina A (2000) Participation in heterogeneous communities The Quarterly Journal of Economics 115(3) 847ndash904 httpsdoiorg101162003355300554935

Alesina A amp La Ferrara E (2002) Who trusts others Journal of Public Economics 85(2) 207ndash234 httpsdoiorg101016S0047-2727(01)00084-6

Allcott H amp Keniston D (2014) Dutch Disease or Agglomeration The Local Economic Effects of Natural Resource Booms in Modern America (N W P N 20508 Ed) NBER Working Paper No 20508 (Vol w20508) NBER Working Paper No 20508 NBER Working Paper No 20508 httpsdoiorgNBER Working Paper No 20508

Andersen T M amp Maibom J (2020) The big trade-off between efficiency and equitymdashis it there Oxford Economic Papers 72(2) 391ndash411

127

Anselin L (1988) Spatial econometrics methods and models (Vol 4) DordrechtBoston Kluwer Academic Publishers

Anselin L amp Bera A K (1998) Spatial dependence in linear regression models with an introduction to spatial econometrics Statistics Textbooks and Monographs (Vol 155)

Anselin L Bera A K Florax R amp Yoon M J (1996) Simple diagnostic tests for spatial dependence Regional Science and Urban Economics 26(1) 77ndash104 httpsdoiorg1010160166-0462(95)02111-6

Antonelli M A amp De Bonis V (2018) The efficiency of social public expenditure in European countries a two-stage analysis Applied Economics 1ndash14 httpsdoiorg1010800003684620181489522

Aragoacuten F M amp Rud J P (2013) Natural Resources and Local Communities Evidence from a Peruvian Gold Mine American Economic Journal Economic Policy 5(2) 1ndash25 httpsdoiorg101257pol521

Ariely G (2014) Does Diversity Erode Social Cohesion Conceptual and Methodological Issues Political Studies 62(3) 573ndash595 httpsdoiorg1011111467-924812068

Armstrong H amp Taylor J (2000) Regional economics and policy (3rd ed) Oxford Blackwell

Aroca P amp Atienza M (2011) Economic implications of long distance commuting in the Chilean mining industry Resources Policy 36(3) 196ndash203 httpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201103004

Aroca P amp Bosch M (2000) Crecimiento convergencia y espacio en las regiones chilenas 1960 - 1998 Estudios de Economiacutea 27 199ndash224 Retrieved from httprepositoriouchileclbitstreamhandle2250127853Patricio_Arocapdfsequence=1

Ashworth J Geys B Heyndels B amp Wille F (2014) Competition in the political arena and local government performance Applied Economics 46(19) 2264ndash2276 httpsdoiorg101080000368462014899679

Atkinson A B (2015) Inequality What Can Be Done Harvard University Press

Auty R (1993) Sustaining development in mineral economies the resource curse thesis London [ua] Routledge

Auty R (2001) Resource abundance and economic development (R World Institute for Development Economics Ed) Oxford Oxford University Press

Badeeb R A Lean H H amp Clark J (2017) The evolution of the natural resource curse thesis A critical literature survey Resources Policy 51 123ndash134 httpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201610015

Balaguer-Coll M T Brun-Martos M I Maacuterquez-Ramos L amp Prior D (2019) Local government efficiency determinants and spatial interdependence Applied Economics

128

51(14) 1478ndash1494 httpsdoiorg1010800003684620181527458

Balaguer-Coll M T amp Prior D (2009) Short- and long-term evaluation of efficiency and quality An application to Spanish municipalities Applied Economics 41(23) 2991ndash3002 httpsdoiorg10108000036840701351923

Banker R D Charnes A amp Cooper W W (1984) Some models for estimating technical and scale inefficiencies in data envelopment analysis Management Science 30(9) 1078ndash1092

Beine M Coulombe S amp Vermeulen W N (2015) Dutch Disease and the Mitigation Effect of Migration Evidence from Canadian Provinces The Economic Journal 125(589) 1574ndash1615 httpsdoiorg101111ecoj12171

Benito B Bastida F amp Garciacutea J A (2010) Explaining differences in efficiency an application to Spanish municipalities Applied Economics 42(4) 515ndash528 httpsdoiorg10108000036840701675560

Berg A amp Ostry J (2011) Equality and efficiency Finance amp Development 48(3) 12ndash15

Berg A amp Ostry J (2017) Inequality and Unsustainable Growth Two Sides of the Same Coin IMF ECONOMIC REVIEW 65(4) 792ndash815 httpsdoiorg101057s41308-017-0030-8

Beyer H amp Vergara R (2006) Delincuencia en Chile Determinantes y rol de las poliacuteticas puacuteblicas Instituto de Economiacutea UC

Blanco L amp Grier R (2012) Natural resource dependence and the accumulation of physical and human capital in Latin America Resources Policy 37(3) 281ndash295 httpsdoiorghttpdoiorg101016jresourpol201201005

Blau J R amp Blau P M (1982) The cost of inequality Metropolitan structure and violent crime American Sociological Review 114ndash129

Boetti L Piacenza M amp Turati G (2009) Fiscal decentralization and spending efficiency of local governments An Empirical Investigation on a Sample Of 4

Boix C amp Posner D (1998) Social capital Explaining its origins and effects on government performance British Journal Of Political Science 28 686ndash693

Borge L E Parmer P amp Torvik R (2015) Local natural resource curse JOURNAL OF PUBLIC ECONOMICS 131 101ndash114 httpsdoiorg101016jjpubeco201509002

Borger B Kerstens K Moesen W amp Vanneste J (1994) Explaining differences in productive efficiency An application to Belgian municipalities Public Choice 80(3) 339ndash358 httpsdoiorg101007BF01053225

Bourguignon F amp Morrisson C (1990) Income distribution development and foreign trade A cross-sectional analysislowast European Economic Review 34(6) 1113ndash1132 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg1010160014-2921(90)90071-6

129

Branas C C Cheney R A MacDonald J M Tam V W Jackson T D amp Ten Have T R (2011) A difference-in-differences analysis of health safety and greening vacant urban space American Journal of Epidemiology 174(11) 1296ndash1306

Bravo J (2014) Fondo Comuacuten Municipal y su desincentivo a la recaudacioacuten en Chile Temas de La Agenda Legislativa-Centro de Poliacuteticas Puacuteblicas UC 9(68)

Browning E K amp Johnson W R (1984) The Trade-Off between Equality and Efficiency Journal of Political Economy 92(2) 175ndash203 httpsdoiorg101086261219

Brunnschweiler C N amp Bulte E H (2008) The resource curse revisited and revised A tale of paradoxes and red herrings Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 55(3) 248ndash264 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jjeem200708004

Brunori P Ferreira F H G amp Peragine V (2013) Inequality of opportunity income inequality and economic mobility Some international comparisons In Getting Development Right (pp 85ndash115) Springer

Brunton-Smith I Jackson J amp Sutherland A (2014) Bridging structure and perception On the neighbourhood ecology of beliefs and worries about violent crime British Journal of Criminology 54(4) 503ndash526

Bulte E H Damania R amp Deacon R T (2005) Resource intensity institutions and development World Development 33(7) 1029ndash1044 httpsdoiorg101016jworlddev200504004

Carmignani F (2013) Development outcomes resource abundance and the transmission through inequality Resource and Energy Economics 35(3) 412ndash428 httpsdoiorg101016jreseneeco201304007

Carmignani Fabrizio amp Avom D (2010) The social development effects of primary commodity export dependence Ecological Economics 70(2) 317ndash330 httpsdoiorg101016jecolecon201009003

Caselli F amp Michaels G (2013) Do Oil Windfalls Improve Living Standards Evidence from Brazil American Economic Journal Applied Economics 5(1) 208ndash238 httpsdoiorg101257app51208

Celebioglu F amp Dallrsquoerba S (2010) Spatial disparities across the regions of Turkey An exploratory spatial data analysis Annals of Regional Science 45(2) 379ndash400 httpsdoiorg101007s00168-009-0313-8

Chan J To H-P amp Chan E (2006) Reconsidering social cohesion Developing a definition and analytical framework for empirical research Social Indicators Research 75(2) 273ndash302

Charnes A Cooper W W amp Rhodes E (1978) Measuring the efficiency of decision making units European Journal of Operational Research 2(6) 429ndash444

130

Chi G amp Zhu J (2019) Spatial Regression Models for the Social Sciences SAGE Publications Retrieved from httpsbooksgooglecomaubooksid=zHGkvwEACAAJ

Christiansen K O (1960) Industrialization and urbanization in relation to crime and juvenile delinquency International Review of Criminal Policy 16 3ndash8

Cingano F (2014) Trends in income inequality and its impact on economic growth (Vol 163) Paris OECD Publishing httpsdoiorg1017875jxrjncwxv6j-en

Coelli T J Prasada Rao D S OrsquoDonnell C J amp Battese G E (2005) An introduction to efficiency and productivity analysis An Introduction to Efficiency and Productivity Analysis Springer Science amp Business Media httpsdoiorg101007b136381

Coffeacute H amp Geys B (2005) Institutional Performance and Social Capital An Application to the Local Government Level Journal of Urban Affairs 27(5) 485ndash501 httpsdoiorg101111j0735-2166200500249x

Coffeacute H amp Geys B (2006) Community Heterogeneity A Burden for the Creation of Social Capital Social Science Quarterly 87(5) 1053ndash1072 httpsdoiorg101111j1540-6237200600415x

Cohen D Spear S Scribner R Kissinger P Mason K amp Wildgen J (2000) ldquo Broken windowsrdquo and the risk of gonorrhea American Journal of Public Health 90(2) 230

Corden W M amp Neary J P (1982) Booming sector and de-industrialisation in a small open economy The Economic Journal 92(368) 825ndash848

Cordero J M Pedraja-Chaparro F Pisaflores E C amp Polo C (2017) Efficiency assessment of Portuguese municipalities using a conditional nonparametric approach Journal of Productivity Analysis 48(1) 1ndash24 httpsdoiorg101007s11123-017-0500-z

Croissant Y amp Millo G (2018) Panel Data Econometrics with R John Wiley amp Sons

Cust J amp Poelhekke S (2015) The Local Economic Impacts of Natural Resource Extraction 7 251ndash268 httpsdoiorg101146annurev-resource-100814-125106

da Cruz N F amp Marques R C (2014) Revisiting the determinants of local government performance Omega 44 91ndash103 httpsdoiorg101016JOMEGA201309002

Dauvin M amp Guerreiro D (2017) The Paradox of Plenty A Meta-Analysis World Development 94 httpsdoiorg101016jworlddev201701009

de Sousa M da C S Cribari-Neto F amp Stosic B D (2005) Explaining DEA technical efficiency scores in an outlier corrected environment the case of public services in Brazilian municipalities Brazilian Review of Econometrics 25(2) 287ndash313

Deacon R T (2011) The Political Economy of the Natural Resource Curse A Survey of Theory and Evidence Foundations and Trends in Microeconomics 111-208

Delhey J amp Newton K (2005) Predicting cross-national levels of social trust global pattern or

131

Nordic exceptionalism European Sociological Review 21(4) 311ndash327

Dlouhyacute M (2018) Measuring Geographic Inequalities Dealing with Multiple Health Resources by Data Envelopment Analysis Frontiers in Public Health 6 53 httpsdoiorg103389fpubh201800053

Dollery B Wallis J amp Akimov A (2010) One Size Does Not Fit All The Special Case of Remote Small Local Councils in Outback Queensland Local Government Studies 36(1) 21ndash42 httpsdoiorg10108003003930903435716

Domenech J (2008) Mineral resource abundance and regional growth in Spain 1860ndash2000 Journal of International Development The Journal of the Development Studies Association 20(8) 1122ndash1135

Doran J amp Jordan D (2016) Decomposing US regional income inequality from 1969 to 2009 Applied Economics Letters 23(11) 781ndash784 httpsdoiorg1010801350485120151109030

Drew J amp Dollery B (2015) The State of Things The Dynamic Efficiency of Australian State and Territories Economic Papers A Journal of Applied Economics and Policy 34(3) 165ndash176

Drew J Kortt M amp Dollery B (2015) What Determines Efficiency in Local Government A DEA Analysis of NSW Local Government Economic Papers A Journal of Applied Economics and Policy 34(4) 243ndash256 httpsdoiorg1011111759-344112118

Easterly W (2007) Inequality does cause underdevelopment Insights from a new instrument Journal of Development Economics 84(2) 755ndash776 httpsdoiorghttpdxdoiorg101016jjdeveco200611002

Ebert L amp La Menza T (2015) Chile copper and resource revenue A holistic approach to assessing commodity dependence Resources Policy 43(Supplement C) 101ndash111 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201410007

ElGindi T (2017) Natural resource dependency neoliberal globalization and income inequality Are they related A longitudinal study of developing countries (1980ndash2010) Current Sociology 65(1) 21ndash53 httpsdoiorg1011770011392116632031

Engerman S L amp Sokoloff K L (1994) Factor Endowments Institutions and Differential Paths of Growth Among New World Economies National Bureau of Economic Research

Engerman S L amp Sokoloff K L (1997) Factor endowments institutions and differential paths of growth among new world economies How Latin America Fell Behind 260ndash304

Engerman S L Sokoloff K L Urquiola M amp Acemoglu D (2002) Factor Endowments Inequality and Paths of Development among New World Economies [with Comments] EconomampxedA 3(1) 41ndash109 Retrieved from httpwwwjstororgezp01libraryquteduaustable20065432

132

Faumlre R Grosskopf S amp Lovell C A K (1985) The measurement of efficiency of production (Vol 6) Springer Science amp Business Media

Fleming D A amp Measham T G (2015a) Income Inequality across Australian Regions during the Mining Boom 2001-11 Australian Geographer 46(2) 203ndash216 httpsdoiorg1010800004918220151020596

Fleming D A amp Measham T G (2015b) Local economic impacts of an unconventional energy boom the coal seam gas industry in Australia Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 59(1) 78ndash94 httpsdoiorg1011111467-848912043

Fum R M amp Hodler R (2010) Natural resources and income inequality The role of ethnic divisions Economics Letters 107(3) 360ndash363 httpsdoiorg101016jeconlet201003008

Garofalo J (1978) The fear of crime Broadening our perspective

Geys B amp Moesen W (2009) Exploring Sources of Local Government Technical Inefficiency Evidence from Flemish Municipalities Public Finance and Management 9(1) 1ndash29

Goderis B amp Malone S W (2011) Natural Resource Booms and Inequality Theory and Evidence The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 113(2) 388ndash417 httpsdoiorg101111j1467-9442201101659x

Greene W H (2016) Productivity and Efficiency Analysis (W H Greene L Khalaf R Sickles M Veall amp M-C Voia Eds) (1st ed 20) Cham Springer International Publishing httpsdoiorg101007978-3-319-23228-7

Gustafsson B amp Shi L (2002) Income inequality within and across counties in rural China 1988 and 1995 Journal of Development Economics 69(1) 179ndash204 httpsdoiorg101016S0304-3878(02)00058-5

Gylfason T amp Zoega G (2003) Inequality and Economic Growth Do Natural Resources Matter In T T Eicher S (Ed) Inequality and Growth Theory and Policy Implications (pp 255ndash292) The MIT Press

Henningsen A (2010) Estimating Censored Regression Models in R using the censReg Package R Package Vignettes Collection 5(2) 12

Henningsen A (2019) censReg Censored Regression (Tobit) Models R package version 05-30 httpscranr-projectorgpackage=censReg Retrieved from httpscranr-projectorgpackage=censReg

Herrera S amp Pang G (2005) Efficiency of Public Spending in Developing Countriesthinsp An Efficiency Frontier Approach World Bank Washington DC

Hill T D amp Angel R J (2005) Neighborhood disorder psychological distress and heavy drinking Social Science amp Medicine 61(5) 965ndash975

133

httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jsocscimed200412027

Hipp J R (2010) RESIDENT PERCEPTIONS OF CRIME AND DISORDER HOW MUCH IS ldquoBIASrdquo AND HOW MUCH IS SOCIAL ENVIRONMENT DIFFERENCES Criminology 48(2) 475ndash508 httpsdoiorg101111j1745-9125201000193x

Holtug N amp Mason A (2010) Introduction Immigration diversity and social cohesion SAGE Publications Sage UK London England

Hooghe M Vanhoutte B Hardyns W amp Bircan T (2010) Unemployment Inequality Poverty and Crime Spatial Distribution Patterns of Criminal Acts in Belgium 2001ndash06 The British Journal of Criminology 51(1) 1ndash20 httpsdoiorg101093bjcazq067

Howie P amp Atakhanova Z (2014) Resource boom and inequality Kazakhstan as a case study Resources Policy 39(1) 71ndash79 httpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201311004

Isham J Woolcock M Pritchett L amp Busby G (2005) The Varieties of Resource Experience Natural Resource Export Structures and the Political Economy of Economic Growth The World Bank Economic Review 19(2) 141ndash174 httpsdoiorg101093wberlhi010

Jottier D Ashworth J amp Heyndels B (2012) Understanding Votersrsquo Preferences How the Electoratersquos Complexity Affects Prediction Accuracy and Wishful Thinking among Politicians with Respect to Election Outcomes Kyklos 65(3) 340ndash370 httpsdoiorg101111j1467-6435201200542x

Kanbur S M R amp Venables A (2005) Spatial inequality and development (R World Institute for Development Economics Ed) Oxford Oxford University Press

Kesler C amp Bloemraad I (2010) Does immigration erode social capital The conditional effects of immigration-generated diversity on trust membership and participation across 19 countries 1981ndash2000 Canadian Journal of Political ScienceRevue Canadienne de Science Politique 43(2) 319ndash347

Kuznets S (1955) Economic Growth and Income Inequality The American Economic Review 45(1) 1ndash28 Retrieved from httpwwwjstororgstable1811581

Lagos G amp Blanco E (2010) Mining and development in the region of Antofagasta Resources Policy 35(4) 265ndash275 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201007006

Leamer E E Maul H Rodriguez S amp Schott P K (1999) Does natural resource abundance increase Latin American income inequality Journal of Development Economics 59(1) 3ndash42 httpsdoiorg101016s0304-3878(99)00004-8

Leibbrandt M Finn A amp Woolard I (2012) Describing and decomposing post-apartheid income inequality in South Africa Development Southern Africa 29(1) 19ndash34 httpsdoiorg1010800376835X2012645639

134

Letki N (2008) Does Diversity Erode Social Cohesion Social Capital and Race in British Neighbourhoods Political Studies 56(1) 99ndash126 httpsdoiorg101111j1467-9248200700692x

Lewis D A (2017) Fear of crime Incivility and the production of a social problem Routledge

lo Storto C (2013) Evaluating Technical Efficiency of Italian Major Municipalities A Data Envelopment Analysis model Procedia - Social and Behavioral Sciences 81 346ndash350 httpsdoiorg101016JSBSPRO201306440

Loayza N amp Rigolini J (2016) The Local Impact of Mining on Poverty and Inequality Evidence from the Commodity Boom in Peru World Development 84 219ndash234 httpsdoiorg101016jworlddev201603005

Loayza N Teran A M y amp Rigolini J (2013) Poverty Inequality and the Local Natural Resource Curse World Bank Policy Research Working Paper (6366) httpsdoiorg1015961813-9450-6366

Loacutepez R amp Miller S J (2008) Chile The Unbearable Burden of Inequality World Development 36(12) 2679ndash2695 httpsdoiorg101016jworlddev200801012

Manzano O amp Rigobon R (2001) Resource Curse or Debt Overhang National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper Series No 8390 1 httpsdoiorghttpwwwnberorgpapersw9424bib

McPherson M Smith-Lovin L amp Cook J M (2001) Birds of a Feather Homophily in Social Networks Annual Review of Sociology 27(1) 415ndash444 httpsdoiorg101146annurevsoc271415

McQuestin D Drew J amp Dollery B (2018) Do Municipal Mergers Improve Technical Efficiency An Empirical Analysis of the 2008 Queensland Municipal Merger Program Australian Journal of Public Administration 77(3) 442ndash455 httpsdoiorg1011111467-850012286

Messner S F Rosenfeld R amp Baumer E P (2004) Dimensions of Social Capital and Rates of Criminal Homicide American Sociological Review 69(6) 882ndash903 httpsdoiorg101177000312240406900607

Michaels G (2011) THE LONG TERM CONSEQUENCES OF RESOURCE-BASED SPECIALISATION The Economic Journal 121(551) 31ndash57 httpsdoiorg101111j1468-0297201002402x

Mijanovich T amp Weitzman B C (2003) Which ldquobroken windowsrdquo matter School neighborhood and family characteristics associated with youthsrsquo feelings of unsafety Journal of Urban Health 80(3) 400ndash415

Mikušovaacute P (2015) An Application of DEA Methodology in Efficiency Measurement of the Czech Public Universities Procedia Economics and Finance 25 569ndash578 httpsdoiorg101016S2212-5671(15)00771-6

135

Milanovic B (2016) Global inequality Harvard University Press

Millo G amp Piras G (2012) splm Spatial panel data models in R Journal of Statistical Software 47(1) 1ndash38

Murphy K M amp Topel R H (2016) Human Capital Investment Inequality and Economic Growth JOURNAL OF LABOR ECONOMICS 34(2) S99ndashS127 httpsdoiorg101086683779

Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute I amp De Witte K (2018a) Local governmentsrsquo efficiency a systematic literature reviewmdashpart I International Transactions in Operational Research 25(2) 431ndash468 httpsdoiorg101111itor12364

Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute I amp De Witte K (2018b) Local governmentsrsquo efficiency a systematic literature reviewmdashpart II International Transactions in Operational Research 25(4) 1107ndash1136 httpsdoiorg101111itor12389

Nuntildeez J Rivera J Villavicencio X amp Molina O (2003) Determinantes socioeconoacutemicos y demograacuteficos del crimen en Chile Estudios de Economiacutea 30(1) 55ndash85

OrsquoDonnell C J Rao D S P amp Battese G E (2008) Metafrontier frameworks for the study of firm-level efficiencies and technology ratios Empirical Economics 34(2) 231ndash255 httpsdoiorg101007s00181-007-0119-4

Ocampo J A (2004) Latin Americarsquos Growth and Equity Frustrations During Structural Reforms The Journal of Economic Perspectives 18(2) 67ndash88 httpsdoiorg1012570895330041371349

OECD (2014) Focus on inequality and growth OECD

OECD (2017) Howrsquos Life 2017 Life Satisfaction Oecd httpsdoiorg101787how_life-2017-en

Ohtake F (2008) Inequality in Japan Asian Economic Policy Review 3(1) 87ndash109 httpsdoiorg101111j1748-3131200800093x

Okun A M (2015) Equality and efficiency the big tradeoff Washington DC Brookings Institution Press

Ortega B Sanjuaacuten J amp Casquero A (2017) Determinants of efficiency in reducing child mortality in developing countries The role of inequality and government effectiveness Health Care Management Science 20(4) 500ndash516 httpsdoiorg101007s10729-016-9367-1

Ostry J Berg A amp Tsangarides C (2014) Redistribution inequality and growth International Monetary Fund

Pacheco F Saacutenchez R amp Villena M (2013) Eficiencia de los Gobiernos Locales y sus Determinantes Un anaacutelisis de Fronteras Estocaacutesticas en Datos de Panel para

136

Municipalidades Chilenas Santiago de Chile Chile

Papyrakis E amp Raveh O (2014) An Empirical Analysis of a Regional Dutch Disease The Case of Canada Environmental and Resource Economics 58(2) 179ndash198 httpsdoiorg101007s10640-013-9698-z

Paredes D (2013) The Role of Human Capital Market Potential and Natural Amenities in Understanding Spatial Wage Disparities in Chile Spatial Economic Analysis 8(2) 154ndash175 httpsdoiorg101080174217722013774094

Paredes D Iturra V amp Lufin M (2016) A spatial decomposition of income inequality in Chile Regional Studies 50(5) 771ndash789

Phan P Van Orsquobrien M Mendolia S amp Paloyo A (2017) National pro-poor spending programmes and their effect on income inequality and poverty Evidence from Vietnam Applied Economics 49(55) 5579ndash5590 httpsdoiorg1010800003684620171313957

Podinovski V V (2004) Bridging the Gap between the Constant and Variable Returns-to-Scale Models Selective Proportionality in Data Envelopment Analysis The Journal of the Operational Research Society 55(3) 265ndash276 Retrieved from httpwwwjstororgstable4102006

Ravallion M (2005) On Measuring Aggregate Social Efficiency Economic Development and Cultural Change 53(2) 273ndash292 httpsdoiorg101086425380

Rehner J Baeza S A amp Barton J R (2014) Chilersquos resource-based export boom and its outcomes Regional specialization export stability and economic growth Geoforum 56(Supplement C) 35ndash45 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jgeoforum201406007

Rivera J Gutieacuterrez M amp Nuacutentildeez J (2009) Caracterizacioacuten socioeconoacutemica y espacial de la criminalidad en Chile Revista CEPAL

Ross C E (2011) Collective threat trust and the sense of personal control Journal of Health and Social Behavior 52(3) 287ndash296

Ross C E amp Mirowsky J (2001) Neighborhood disadvantage disorder and health Journal of Health and Social Behavior 258ndash276

Rothstein B amp Uslaner E M (2005) All for all Equality corruption and social trust World Politics 58(1) 41ndash72

Sachs J D amp Warner A M (2001) The curse of natural resources European Economic Review 45(4ndash6) 827ndash838 httpsdoiorg101016S0014-2921(01)00125-8

Salas R (2019) sinimr Chilean Municipalities Information System Wrapper Retrieved from httpsgithubcomrobsalascosinimr

Sampson R J (1986) Crime in Cities The Effects of Formal and Informal Social Control Crime and Justice 8 271ndash311

137

Sampson R J (2008) Rethinking crime and immigration Contexts 7(1) 28ndash33

Santos Silva J M C amp Tenreyro S (2010) On the existence of the maximum likelihood estimates in Poisson regression Economics Letters 107(2) 310ndash312 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jeconlet201002020

Santos Silva J M C amp Tenreyro S (2011) poisson Some convergence issues Stata Journal 11(2) 207ndash212 Retrieved from httpwwwstata-journalcomarticlehtmlarticle=st0225

Scott Z (2009) Decentralisation local development and social cohesion an analytical review GSDRC Research Paper 5

Sinha R P (2017) Fiscal Performance Benchmarking of Indian States-A Robust Frontier Approach The Central European Review of Economics and Management 1(4) 225ndash249

Skogan W (1986) Fear of crime and neighborhood change Crime and Justice 8 203ndash229

Skogan W (1999) Measuring what matters Crime disorder and fear In Measuring what matters Proceedings from the Policing Research Institute meetings (pp 37ndash53) National Institute of Justice Washington DC

Skogan W (2015) Disorder and Decline The State of Research Journal of Research in Crime and Delinquency 52(4) 464ndash485 httpsdoiorg1011770022427815577836

Šťastnaacute L amp Gregor M (2014) Public sector efficiency in transition and beyond evidence from Czech local governments Applied Economics 47(7) 1ndash20 httpsdoiorg101080000368462014978077

Tandon A (2005) Measuring Efficiency of Macro Systems An Application to Millennium Development Goal Attainment Asian Development Review 22(2) 108ndash125

Taylor R B (1999) The incivilities thesis Theory measurement and policy Measuring What Matters 65 88

Tigga N S amp Mishra U S (2015) On Measuring Technical Efficiency of the Health System in India An Application of Data Envelopment Analysis Journal of Health Management 17(3) 285ndash298 httpsdoiorg1011770972063415589229

Tinbergen J (1975) Demographic Development and the Exhaustion of Natural Resources Population and Development Review 1(1) 23ndash32 httpsdoiorg1023071972269

Tiruneh G (2014) Social Revolutions Their Causes Patterns and Phases SAGE Open 4(3) 2158244014548845 httpsdoiorg1011772158244014548845

Tolsma J Van der Meer T amp Gesthuizen M (2009) The impact of neighbourhood and municipality characteristics on social cohesion in the Netherlands Acta Politica 44(3) 286ndash313

Tsekeris Sotiris T Tsekeris T amp Papaioannou S (2018) Regional determinants of technical efficiency evidence from the Greek economy Regional Studies [London]thinsp Carfax

138

httpsdoiorg1010800034340420171390312

Uslaner E (2002) The moral foundations of trust Cambridge University Press

Uslaner E (2011) CORRUPTION AND INEQUALITY DICE Report 9(2) 20ndash24

Uslaner E (2013) Trust and corruption revisited how and why trust and corruption shape each other Quality amp Quantity 47(6) 3603ndash3608 httpsdoiorg101007s11135-012-9742-z

Uslaner E amp Brown M (2005) Inequality trust and civic engagement American Politics Research 33(6) 868ndash894

Van der Ploeg F (2011) Natural Resources Curse or Blessing Journal of Economic Literature 49(2) 366ndash420 httpsdoiorg101257jel492366

Vergara R (2012) Crime Prevention Programs Evidence From CHILE The Developing Economies 50(1) 1ndash24

Watkins M H (1963) A staple theory of economic growth Canadian Journal of Economics and Political ScienceRevue Canadienne de Economiques et Science Politique 29(2) 141ndash158

Wilkinson R G (1999) Income inequality social cohesion and health clarifying the theorymdasha reply to Muntaner and Lynch International Journal of Health Services 29(3) 525ndash543

Wilson J Q amp Kelling G L (1982) Broken windows Atlantic Monthly 249(3) 29ndash38

Wilson W J (1996) When Work Disappears Political Science Quarterly 111(4) 567ndash595 httpsdoiorg1023072152085

Wirth L (1938) Urbanism as a Way of Life American Journal of Sociology 44(1) 1ndash24

Worthington A amp Dollery B (2000) An empirical survey of frontier efficiency measurement techniques in local government Local Government Studies 26(2) 23ndash52 httpsdoiorg10108003003930008433988

Wu P-C Huang T-H amp Pan S-C (2014) Country Performance Evaluation The DEA Model Approach Social Indicators Research 118(2) 835ndash849 httpsdoiorg101007s11205-013-0443-3

Ye X Ma L Ye K Chen J amp Xie Q (2017) Analysis of Regional Inequality from Sectoral Structure Spatial Policy and Economic Development A Case Study of Chongqing China Sustainability 9(4) 633 Retrieved from httpwwwmdpicom2071-105094633

Yue W Z Zhang Y T Ye X Y Cheng Y Q amp Leipnik M R (2014) Dynamics of Multi-Scale Intra-Provincial Regional Inequality in Zhejiang China Sustainability 6(9) 5763ndash5784 httpsdoiorg103390su6095763

139

Appendices

Appendix A Summary statistics income inequality

Table A1

Summary statistics Gini coefficients by year and zone

140

Appendix B Summary statistics for NRD measures by region

Table B1

Summary statistics NRD measures by region

141

Appendix C Regional administrative division and defined zones

Figure C1 Geographical distribution of Chilean regions and 3 zones

142

Appendix D Summary statistics numeric controls and correlation matrix

Table D1

Summary Statistics Numeric Explanatory Variables

Figure D1 Correlation matrix numeric explanatory variables

143

Appendix E Static spatial panel models

Following Millo amp Piras (2012) a model including a spatial lag of the dependent variable and

spatial autoregressive disturbances but not spatial lags for the explanatory variable(s) is called

SARAR model A static spatial SARAR panel could be expressed as

119910 120582 119868 otimes119882 119910 119883120573 119906 (E1)

where y is an 119873 1 vector of observations on the dependent variable X is a 119873 119896 matrix of

observations on the non-stochastic exogenous regressors 119868 an identity matrix of dimension 119879 otimes

is the kronecker operator 119882 is the 119873 119873 spatial weights matrix of known constants whose

diagonal elements are set to zero and 120582 the corresponding spatial parameter44

The disturbance vector is the sum of two terms

119906 120580 otimes 119868 120583 120576 (E2)

where 120580 is a 119879 1 vector of ones 119868 an 119873 119873 identity matrix 120583 is a vector of time-invariant

individual specific effects (not spatially autocorrelated) and 120576 a vector of spatially autocorrelated

innovations that follow a spatial autoregressive process of the form

120576 120588 119868 otimes119882 120576 120584 (E3)

If we assume that spatial correlation applies to both the individual effects 120583 and the remainder

error components 120576 Kapoor et al (2007) propose that the disturbance term 119906 follows a first order

spatial autoregressive process of the form

119906 120588 119868 otimes119882 119906 120576 (E4)

44 Unlike ldquotraditional panelsrdquo which are organized as different time series for each cross-sectional unit ldquospatial panelsrdquo are organized as a series of cross-sections for each year

144

where 119882 is the spatial weights matrix and 119903ℎ119900 the corresponding spatial autoregressive

parameter To further allow for the innovations to be correlated over time the innovations vector

in Equation 7 follows an error component structure

120576 120580 otimes 119868 120583 120584 (E5)

where 120583 is the vector of cross-sectional specific effects 120584 a vector of innovations that vary

both over cross-sectional units and time periods 120580 is a vector of ones and 119868 an 119873 119873 identity

matrix45

Spatial panel models are usually estimated by Maximum Likelihood or GMM46 The SAR

SEM or SARAR models could be estimated with Random or Fixed effects For instance A fixed

effect spatial lag model can be written in stacked form as

119910 120582 119868 otimes119882 119910 120580 otimes 119868 120583 119883120573 120576 (E6)

where 120582 is the spatial autoregressive coefficient 119882 a non-stochastic spatial weights matrix

120580 a column vector of ones of dimension 119879 119868 an 119873 119873 identity matrix and 120576 sim 119873 0120590 On

the other hand a fixed effects spatial error model assuming the disturbance specification by

Kapoor et al (2007) can be written as

119910 120580119879 otimes 119868119873 120583 119883120573 119906119906 120588 119868119879 otimes119882119873 119906 120576

(E7)

where 120588 is the spatial autocorrelation coefficient and 120576 is a well-behaved error term

45 In the regression implementation the specification given by equations (22) and (3) is denoted by ldquobrdquo for ldquoBaltagirdquo On the other hand the specification given by equations (23) and (31) is denoted by ldquokkprdquo for ldquoKapoor Kelejian and Pruchardquo 46 We use the R package splm which allow both types of regression procedure

145

Appendix F Analysis OLS residuals cross-sectional (six-year average) analysis

Table F1

Analysis OLS residuals Anselin Method

Figure F1 Moran scatter plot OLS residuals

146

Appendix G Linear panel data models

Table G1

Panel regressions (non-spatial)

147

Appendix H Spatial panel models (Generalized Moments (GM) estimation)

Table H1

GM Spatial Models

148

Appendix I Inputs and outputs used in DEA analysis

Figure I1 Examples of inputs and outputs used to measure LGE (based on Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018)

149

Appendix J Technical and scale efficiency

Following lo Storto (2013) under an input-oriented specification assuming VRS with n

municipalities using k inputs to produce m outputs the DEA model for a given i-th municipality

is specified with the following mathematical programming problem

119898119894119899 120579119904119906119887119895119890119888119905 119905119900 119910 119884120582 0120579119909 119883120582 01198991prime120582 1  120582 0prime

Where 119910 is the column vector of the outputs and 119909 is the column vector of the inputs

Moreover we can define X as the (k times n) input matrix and Y as the (m times n) output matrix 120579 is a

scalar (that satisfies 120579 1) more specifically it is the efficiency score that measures technical

efficiency It measures the distance between a municipality and the efficiency frontier defined as

a linear combination of the best practice observations With 120579 1 the municipality is inside the

frontier (ie it is inefficient) while 120579 1 implies that the municipality is on the frontier (ie it is

efficient) The vector 120582 is an (n times 1) vector of constants that measures the weights used to compute

the location of an inefficient municipality if it were to become efficient

The total technical efficiency 119879119864 can be decomposed into pure technical efficiency

119879119864 and scale efficiency 119878119864 where 119878119864 119879119864 119879119864 (Coelli et al 2005) To find out

whether a municipality is scale efficient and qualify the type of returns of scale a DEA model

under non-increasing returns to scale 119879119864 is implemented where 119878119864 119879119864 119879119864 Hence

the following rule can be applied (Faumlre Grosskopf amp Lovell 1985)

bull If 119878119864 1 then a municipality is scale efficient both under CRS and VRS

bull If 119878119864 1 it operates under increasing returns to scale

bull If 119878119864 1 it operates under decreasing returns to scale

150

Appendix K Correlation matrix

Figure K1 Correlation matrix contextual factors

151

Appendix L Returns to scale by year and zone

Table L1

Returns to scale (percentage of municipalities)

152

Appendix M Returns to scale by year (maps)

Figure M1 Spatial distribution of returns to scale by county per year

153

Appendix N Efficiency status by year (maps)

Figure N1 Spatial distribution of efficient (E es = 1) and inefficient (I es lt 1) counties per year

154

Appendix O Spatial distribution efficiency scores by year (maps)

FigureO1 Custom breaks maps of efficiency scores (VRS) by county per year

155

Appendix P Analysis OLS residuals cross-sectional (six-year average) analysis

Table P1

Analysis OLS residuals Anselin Method

Figure P1 Moran scatter plot efficiency scores and OLS residuals

156

Table P2

OLS and spatial regression models for the six-year averaged data

157

Appendix Q OLS regressions for cross-sectional and panel data

Table Q1

OLS cross-sectional regression per year

158

Table Q2

OLS panel regressions Pooled random effects and instrumental variable

159

Appendix R Quantile maps incivilities rate by group (average total period)

Figure R1 Spatial distribution of incivilities by group (Average rate per 1000 inhabitants 2006-09-11-13-15-17)

160

Appendix S Correlation matrix numeric covariates

Figure S1 Correlation matrix numeric covariates

161

Appendix T Negative Binomial regressions

Table T1

Negative Binomial regressions

162

Appendix U Coefficients economic and racial diversity by geographical zone

Table U1

Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson models by geographic zone

Page 2: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted

i

Keywords

Count data models

Data Envelopment Analysis

Dutch disease

Economic diversity

Incivilities

Income inequality

Local government efficiency

Natural resource dependence

Panel data

Paradox of plenty

Racial diversity

Resource curse hypothesis

Social cohesion

Spatial analysis

ii

Abstract

Persistently high indicators of relative economic disadvantage such as measures of income

inequality can give rise to a feeling of discontent in the population which in turn can trigger

costly social conflicts For instance inequality has been suggested as one of the main causes of

social outburst considering recent events in many countries around the world This has generated

in extant literature an increasing number of criticisms of current political and socio-economic

models This research considers the Chilean economy which is recognised as an example of the

success of standard economic thinking however it is also well-known for its persistently high

levels of inequality an adverse indicator of economic performance This thesis contributes with

three essays to the understanding of the sources and potential consequences of income inequality

in Chile The data consider a panel of 324 Chilean counties and their corresponding municipalities

for the 2006ndash2017 period

The first essay investigates the association between income inequality and the endowment

of natural resources The Gini coefficient of each county is used as a measure of income inequality

The influence of natural resources on income inequality is captured by using the proportion of

employment in the primary sector as a proxy for the degree of dependence on natural resources in

each county Previous literature has identified a significant spatial dimension of income inequality

in Chile but this spatial dimension has been largely neglected in the domain of policy design and

implementation Thus the analysis in this essay applies spatial regression models for cross-

sectional and panel data while controlling for other socioeconomic and demographic

characteristics The main finding is that contrary to what theory predicts our measure of natural

resource dependence in terms of employment shows a robust and significant negative association

with income inequality The main implication of this empirical result is that a transformation

process towards activities less dependent on natural resources reinforces rather than reduces the

persistence of income inequality at least through the channel of employment Hence this

transformation process imposes additional challenges to central and local governments in their

goal of reducing income inequality Empirical analysis also shows a significant degree of positive

spatial autocorrelation of income inequality This means that counties with similar levels of income

iii

inequality tend to cluster in space The regression analysis confirms the importance of capturing

geographical heterogeneity in the explanation of income inequality however gives less support

to a process of spatial dependence like a spillover effect of income inequality among

neighbouring counties

Among the potential consequences of income inequality the literature highlights its

possible impacts on the efficiency in the provision of public services by local authorities however

empirical evidence is very little For this reason the second essay analyses the technical efficiency

of municipal local governments in Chile and examine if income inequality has significant impacts

on the variations in the efficiency levels across municipalities An input-oriented Data

Envelopment Analysis is used to measure municipal efficiency Results reveal that the municipal

production technology is characterized by variable returns to scale but scale inefficiencies only

explain a small proportion of total inefficiency This justify a need for analysing the influence of

variables which are beyond the control of local authorities in explaining differences in municipal

efficiency The main hypothesis tested was whether income inequality has a negative influence on

municipal efficiency whilst a measure of natural resource dependence at the county level was used

as an instrument to control for the effects of possible endogeneity issues Results showed that

changes in income inequality could be associated with changes in the municipal efficiency level

in the same magnitude but in the opposite direction This confirms that local authorities in counties

characterized by high levels of income inequality face greater challenges to achieve more efficient

performance This result suggests that policies aimed at reducing income inequality can also

increase the efficiency of local governments Our results also reveal that policies such as

amalgamation de-amalgamation or cooperation among municipalities should be designed

specifically for each region rather than as a standard national strategy

Finally the third essay analyses how social cohesion is associated with the levels of

economic and racial diversity Social cohesion is proxied using the reported number of antisocial

behaviours catalogued as incivilities Incivilities are those antisocial behaviours which violate

social norms but are not usually considered as criminal Research has documented the implications

of incivilities on human stress health public behaviour and increasing feelings of insecurity and

fear among the population Few studies have explicitly considered incivilities as a dependent

variable to identify their determinants or use them to analyse the weakening of social cohesion and

iv

the growing feeling of social unrest in contemporary societies Economic diversity is proxied using

the Gini coefficient in each county and racial diversity through the number of new visas granted

as proportion of the county population Our findings show that incivilities are strongly associated

with racial diversity and to a lesser extent with economic diversity The rate of incivilities also

shows a negative association with the level of income and a positive relationship with poverty and

unemployment rates These results give empirical support to the idea that both relative and

absolute indicators of economic deprivation play an important role in understanding the growing

problem of incivilities in highly unequal economies like Chile Results also show that the rate of

incivilities is negatively related to the degree of financial autonomy of municipalities These

findings represent promising areas for central and local governments in the implementation of

policies aimed at increasing social cohesion through the reduction of incivilities and other types of

antisocial behaviours

v

Table of Contents

Keywords i

Abstract ii

Table of Contents v

List of Figures viii

List of Tables ix

List of Abbreviations x

Statement of Original Authorship xi

Acknowledgements xii

Chapter 1 Introduction 13

Income inequality and dependence on natural resources 14

Local government efficiency and income inequality 16

Social cohesion and economic diversity 19

Contributions 21

Thesis outline 23

Chapter 2 Natural Resources Curse or Blessing Evidence on Income Inequality at the County Level in Chile 24

21 Introduction 24

22 Inequality and Natural Resources 28 221 Theoretical Framework 28

Cross-country literature 29 Single country evidence 32

222 The relevance of the spatial approach 33

23 Research problem and hypotheses 35

24 Data and Methods 36 241 Operationalization of key variables 36 242 Control variables 40 243 Methods 41 244 Spatial Model Specification 43

25 Results 44 251 Exploratory Spatial Data Analysis (ESDA) 44 252 Cross-sectional analysis 45 253 Panel Data analysis 48

26 Discussion and conclusions 51

Chapter 3 The Impact of Income Inequality on the Efficiency of Municipalities in Chile 55

vi

31 Introduction 55

32 Related Literature 61 321 Measuring efficiency of local governments 61 322 Explaining differences in LGE 63 323 The trade-off between efficiency and equity 64

33 Methodology 66 331 Chilean Municipalities and period of analysis 66 332 Measuring municipal efficiency 68 333 Inputs and outputs used in DEA 70 334 Regression model 71 335 The instrument 75

34 Results and discussion 77 341 DEA results 77

Returns to scale 78 Efficiency measure 80

342 Regression results 82 Exploratory spatial analysis 82 Cross-sectional analysis 83 Panel data analysis 84

35 Conclusions 88

Chapter 4 Social Cohesion Incivilities and Diversity Evidence at the municipal level in Chile 91

41 Introduction 91

42 Related Literature 95 421 The Community Heterogeneity Thesis 95 422 The literature on incivilities 97 423 The ldquoIncivilities Thesisrdquo 99

4 3 Methodology 100 431 Period of analysis and data sample 100 432 Operationalisation of the response variable and exploratory analysis 101 433 Measures of community heterogeneity and control variables 105 434 Methods 108 435 Hypotheses 111

44 Results and Discussion 112

4 5 Conclusions 118

Chapter 5 Conclusions 120

Bibliography 126

Appendices 139

Appendix A Summary statistics income inequality 139

Appendix B Summary statistics for NRD measures by region 140

Appendix C Regional administrative division and defined zones 141

Appendix D Summary statistics numeric controls and correlation matrix 142

vii

Appendix E Static spatial panel models 143

Appendix F Analysis OLS residuals cross-sectional (six-year average) analysis 145

Appendix G Linear panel data models 146

Appendix H Spatial panel models (Generalized Moments (GM) estimation) 147

Appendix I Inputs and outputs used in DEA analysis 148

Appendix J Technical and scale efficiency 149

Appendix K Correlation matrix 150

Appendix L Returns to scale by year and zone 151

Appendix M Returns to scale by year (maps) 152

Appendix N Efficiency status by year (maps) 153

Appendix O Spatial distribution efficiency scores by year (maps) 154

Appendix P Analysis OLS residuals cross-sectional (six-year average) analysis 155

Appendix Q OLS regressions for cross-sectional and panel data 157

Appendix R Quantile maps incivilities rate by group (average total period) 159

Appendix S Correlation matrix numeric covariates 160

Appendix T Negative Binomial regressions 161

Appendix U Coefficients economic and racial diversity by geographical zone 162

viii

List of Figures

Figure 21 Average share in GDP of economic activities (2006ndash17) 37

Figure 22 Evolution of Gini coefficient and measures of NRD (2006ndash17) 38

Figure 23 Spatial distribution of Gini coefficient and NRD (2006ndash17) 39

Figure 23 Moran scatter plots for variables gini and pss_casen 45

Figure 31 Geographical distribution of Chilean regions and macrozones 74

Figure 32 Evolution of efficiency scores and the proportion of firms by sector 77

Figure 33 Evolution technical efficiency (TE) pure technical efficiency (PTE) and scale efficiency (SE) 78

Figure 34 Returns to scale by zone 79

Figure 35 Evolution mean efficiency scores (VRS) by zone 81

Figure 41 Evolution number and rates of incivilities and crime (DMCS) in Chile 2006-2017 102

Figure 42 Evolution total number of incivilities by category 104

Figure 43 Spatial distribution of incivilities rate per 1000 inhabitants (2006 vs 2017) 104

Figure 44 Annual average number of incivilities per county 109

Figure C1 Geographical distribution of Chilean regions and 3 zones 141

Figure D1 Correlation matrix numeric explanatory variables 142

Figure F1 Moran scatter plot OLS residuals 145

Figure I1 Examples of inputs and outputs used to measure LGE (based on Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018) 148

Figure K1 Correlation matrix contextual factors 150

Figure M1 Spatial distribution of returns to scale by county per year 152

Figure N1 Spatial distribution of efficient (E es = 1) and inefficient (I es lt 1) counties per year 153

FigureO1 Custom breaks maps of efficiency scores (VRS) by county per year 154

Figure P1 Moran scatter plot efficiency scores and OLS residuals 155

Figure R1 Spatial distribution of incivilities by group (Average rate per 1000 inhabitants 2006-09-11-13-15-17) 159

Figure S1 Correlation matrix numeric covariates 160

ix

List of Tables

Table 21 Cross-sectional Model Comparison (six-year average data) 47

Table 22 ML Spatial SAR Models 50

Table 23 ML Spatial SEM Models 50

Table 24 ML Spatial SARAR Models 51

Table 31 Descriptive statistics Inputs and Output variables used in DEA analysis 71

Table 32 Summary Statistics Numeric Contextual Factors 74

Table 33 Summary efficiency scores (VRS) by zone and region 80

Table 34 Cross-sectional (censored) regressions 84

Table 35 Panel data regressions 87

Table 41 Summary statistics total count of incivilities and by category (full sample and period) 103

Table 42 Summary statistics numeric explanatory variables 108

Table 43 Poisson regressions 113

Table 44 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson models by region 115

Table 45 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson model by incivility group 116

Table A1 Summary statistics Gini coefficients by year and zone 139

Table B1 Summary statistics NRD measures by region 140

Table D1 Summary Statistics Numeric Explanatory Variables 142

Table F1 Analysis OLS residuals Anselin Method 145

Table G1 Panel regressions (non-spatial) 146

Table H1 GM Spatial Models 147

Table L1 Returns to scale (percentage of municipalities) 151

Table P1 Analysis OLS residuals Anselin Method 155

Table P2 OLS and spatial regression models for the six-year averaged data 156

Table Q1 OLS cross-sectional regression per year 157

Table Q2 OLS panel regressions Pooled random effects and instrumental variable 158

Table T1 Negative Binomial regressions 161

Table U1 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson models by geographic zone 162

x

List of Abbreviations

Constant returns to scale CRS

Data envelopment analysis DEA

Decreasing returns to scale DRS

Efficiency scores ES

Exploratory spatial data analysis ESDA

Generalized methods of moments GMM

Gross Domestic Product GDP

Increasing returns to scale IRS

Local government efficiency LGE

Maximum likelihood ML

Municipal common fund MCF

Natural resource dependence NRD

Natural resource endowment NRE

Ordinary Least Squares OLS

Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development OECD

Own permanent revenues OPR

Resource curse hypothesis RCH

Spatial autoregressive model SAR

Spatial error model SEM

Variable returns to scale VRS

xi

Statement of Original Authorship

The work contained in this thesis has not been previously submitted to meet requirements

for an award at this or any other higher education institution To the best of my knowledge and

belief the thesis contains no material previously published or written by another person except

where due reference is made

Signature QUT Verified Signature

Date _________04092020_________

xii

Acknowledgements

First I would like to thank my wife Lilian who joined me in this challenge and patiently

supported me all these years I would also like to thank our family who always supported us from

Chile I especially thank my sister Silvia who took care of our house and dog

I am also grateful to my supervisory team Dr Radhika Lahiri and Dr Vincent Hoang who

supported and guided me in the process of making this thesis a reality

I also thank the Deans of the Faculty of Economics and Business at my beloved University

of Talca Dr Arcadio Cerda and Dr Rodrigo Herrera who trusted me and supported me in this

process In the same way I would like to thank all the support of the director of the Commercial

Engineering career Mr Milton Inostroza

Finally I would like to thank the government of Chile for the financial support that made

my stay and studies possible here at the Queensland University of Technology

13

Chapter 1 Introduction

Efficiency and equity issues are often considered together in the evaluation of economic

performance While higher efficiency usually measured by growth rates of income per capita

correlates with improvements in measures of well-being the link between inequality and well-

being is less clear This is reflected not only in the type and amount of research related to efficiency

and equity but also in the role that both play in the design of the economic policy For instance

several market-oriented countries have focused primarily on economic growth trusting in a trickle-

down process where financial benefits given to the wealthy are expected to ultimately benefit the

poor However despite the growing interest in the issue of inequality there is a considerable lack

of studies about its consequences

Although some level of inequality is inevitable or even necessary for economic activity this

study is motivated by the argument that relatively high levels of inequality can be associated with

many problems such as persistent unemployment increasing fiscal expenses indebtedness and

political instability (Berg amp Ostry 2011) Inequality can also have other severe social

consequences including increased crime rates teenage pregnancy obesity and fewer

opportunities for low-income households to invest in health and education (Atkinson 2015) In

addition when the role of money and concentration of economic power undermine political

outcomes inequality of opportunities hampers social and economic mobility trust and social

cohesion In summary inequality can increase the fragility of the economic and social situation in

a country reducing economic growth and making it less inclusive and sustainable

14

A country well-known for its market-oriented economy and high level of dependence on

natural resources is Chile Chilean success in terms of economic growth contrasts with its inability

to reduce the persistently high levels of social and economic inequality particularly in the last

three decades Using data for the 2006-2017 period and considering 324 out of 345 Chilean

counties this thesis presents three essays with empirical evidence aiming to explain the

phenomenon of persistent income inequality and some of its potential consequences The first

essay aims to analyse how the evolution and variability of income inequality throughout the

country are associated with the degree of natural resource dependence The second essay studies

the relevance of income inequality in explaining cross-county differences in the performance of

local governments (municipalities) Finally the third essay explores the link between social

cohesion and community heterogeneity highlighting the importance of economic and racial

diversity

Income inequality and dependence on natural resources

The first essay explores how cross-county differences in income inequality are associated

with differences in the degree of dependence on natural resources We use the Gini coefficient in

each county as our dependent variable and the proportion of employment in the primary sector as

our measure of natural resource dependence The main hypothesis is that income inequality should

be positively related to the degree of natural resource dependence To test our hypothesis we use

a spatial econometric approach This approach is motivated by the study of Paredes Iturra and

Lufin (2016) who explore the geographic heterogeneity of income inequality in Chile finding

evidence of a significant spatial dimension

15

The theoretical and empirical literature has mostly proposed a positive link between

inequality and natural resources Although most of the evidence corresponds to cross-country

comparisons there is also increasing body of research at the local level A rationale underpinning

the positive link suggested in the literature is that in natural resource-rich countries ownership is

concentrated in small groups and extraction activities require low-skilled workers (Gylfason amp

Zoega 2003 Leamer Maul Rodriguez amp Schott 1999) Another market-based argument often

labelled as the ldquoDutch Diseaserdquo proposes that natural resource windfalls could be associated with

a crowding-out effect on the manufacturing sector (Corden amp Neary 1982 Easterly 2007) This

process encourages rent-seeking behaviours discourages investment in physical and human

capital and delays the process of technology adoption and industrialization (Auty 2001 Bulte

Damania amp Deacon 2005 Gylfason amp Zoega 2003) The result could be a lower economic

growth which is the central idea under the ldquoResource Curse Hypothesisrdquo (Auty 1993 Sachs amp

Warner 2001)

An ldquoinstitutionalrdquo argument for the positive association between inequality and the

endowment of natural resources is based on the so-called ldquoParadox of Plentyrdquo (Borge Parmer amp

Torvik 2015 Dauvin amp Guerreiro 2017) The idea is that both national and local authorities have

less incentive to operate efficiently when they experience windfalls in their revenues for

instance from natural resources This could end with corrupted authorities exerting patronage

clientelism and designing public policies to favour specific groups of the population (Uslaner amp

Brown 2005) Evidence also suggests that the final effect of natural resource booms on income

inequality will depend on authoritiesrsquo capacity to manage these additional resources the extent of

commuting and migration among regions and the potential increase in the demand for non-tradable

16

goods which are intensive in unskilled workers (Aroca amp Atienza 2011 Cust amp Poelhekke 2015

Fleming amp Measham 2015b Howie amp Atakhanova 2014 Michaels 2011)

Contrary to most theoretical and empirical evidence we find that income inequality shows

a robust and significant negative association with our proxy for natural resource dependence This

result suggests that the process of transformation to an economy less dependent on natural

resources could have exacerbated rather than alleviated the persistence of income inequality The

decrease in the participation of the primary sector in employment in favour mainly of the tertiary

sector highlights the importance of the latter to explain the current high levels of inequality and its

future evolution Another important result is that spatial linear models show practically the same

results as traditional linear models This could be interpreted as the spatial dimension previously

found in income inequality is not the result of spatial dependence in the variable itself for instance

due to a process of spillover among counties Hence the usually found positive spatial

autocorrelation of income inequality (similar levels in neighbouring counties) could be explained

by spatial patterns in other variables or to the spatial heterogeneity that characterizes the Chilean

economy

Local government efficiency and income inequality

Essay 2 delves deep into the potential trade-off between efficiency and equity We measure

the efficiency of Chilean municipalities which correspond to the organizations in charge of

managing each county Municipal efficiency is understood as ldquotechnical efficiencyrdquo that is the

possibility that each municipality has reached the same level of outputs with less use of inputs

Then we analyse how income inequality controlling for other contextual factors such as

socioeconomic demographic geographical and political characteristics may help to explain

17

differences in municipal performance Our main hypothesis is that municipal efficiency is

inversely associated with income inequality Moreover we seek a causal interpretation of this

relationship

Municipal performance could be influenced by income inequality in direct and indirect ways

In a direct sense income inequality is used to capture the degree of heterogeneity and complexity

in the demand for public services that citizens exert over local authorities Hence higher levels of

income inequality should be associated with a more complex set of public services and therefore

with lower levels of municipal efficiency (Jottier Ashworth amp Heyndels 2012) Furthermore

when high levels of inequality exist the richest groups can exert a higher influence over local

authorities resulting in low quality and quantity of services for most of the population Among

indirect effects high and persistent inequality could be the source of corrupted institutions and

local authorities favouring themselves or specific groups This undermines citizensrsquo participation

in civic activities and their willingness to monitor municipal performance (Uslaner amp Brown

2005) Additionally the potential benefits of decentralization on the way local governments

deliver public services will be limited when the context is characterized by corrupted politicians

and a limited administrative and financial capacity (Scott 2009)

We measure municipal efficiency using an input-oriented Data Envelopment Analysis

(DEA) to obtain efficiency scores for our sample of 324 municipalities in each year from 2006 to

2017 Then we study the influence on municipal efficiency of income inequality and our set of

contextual factors using a panel of six years corresponding to those years for which household

income information is available 2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017 Our dependent variable

is the set of efficiency scores which are relative measures of efficiency They are relative to the

18

municipalities included in the sample and they do not imply that higher technical efficiency gains

cannot be achieved Thus we use both cross-sectional and panel censored regression models To

tackle endogeneity issues and suggest a causal interpretation we also propose using the proportion

of firms in the primary sector as an instrument for income inequality

We find an average efficiency score of 83 meaning that Chilean municipalities could

reduce the use of inputs by 17 without reducing their outputs We also measure municipal

efficiency under different assumptions related to returns to scale This allows us to disaggregate

technical efficiency to assess whether inefficiencies are due to management issues (pure technical

efficiency) or scale issues (scale efficiency) Although the results show that most municipalities

operate under increasing or decreasing returns to scale scale inefficiencies only explain a small

proportion of total municipal inefficiencies This highlights the need to look for contextual factors

outside the control of local authorities to explain differences in municipal performance

Geographical representations of our results in terms of returns to scale and efficiency scores

show some spatial clustering process among municipalities Spatial statistics tests confirm that

efficiency scores show a significant positive spatial autocorrelation This means that neighbouring

municipalities tend to show similar levels of efficiency This similar performance could be due to

a process of spatial dependence (eg efficiency spillovers among neighbouring municipalities) or

due to the existence of structural-geographical similarities (spatial heterogeneity) To assess the

spatial dimension in municipal efficiency abstracting from temporal fluctuations we use a cross-

section of data consisting of the six-year average for the variables in our panel After running a

regression of efficiency scores against the set of controls the analysis of OLS residuals shows that

the spatial autocorrelation is almost completely removed This means that the spatial pattern in

19

municipal efficiency can be explained (controlled) by other variables such as regional indicator

variables rather than efficiency itself Given this result we proceed to study the influence of

income inequality on municipal efficiency using traditional (non-spatial) regression analysis

In contrast to literature that emphasizes an equity-efficiency trade-off (Andersen amp Maibom

2020 Berg amp Ostry 2011 Browning amp Johnson 1984 Okun 2015) that is greater equality leads

to lower efficiency we find that municipal efficiency is inversely associated with income

inequality This implies that more equal counties are also those with higher municipal efficiency

Furthermore the coefficient of income inequality is close to one when we use the instrumental

variable approach This means that a reduction in income inequality ceteris paribus should be

associated with an increase in the same magnitude in municipal efficiency This result has strong

policy implications The non-existence of the trade-off suggests that there is more to be gained by

targeting policies towards the reduction of inequality than conventional theories suggest For

instance these policies may help increase the levels of efficiency and well-being at least at the

municipal level

Social cohesion and economic diversity

The third essay studies the relationship between the degree of social cohesion and diversity

in Chile Extant literature has argued that one of the main factors influencing social cohesion is

the degree of economic and ethnic-racial diversity within a society This diversity erodes social

cohesion reducing trust and corrupting institutions (Letki 2008 Rothstein amp Uslaner 2005

Tolsma Van der Meer amp Gesthuizen 2009 Uslaner 2011 2013)

To measure social cohesion scholars have traditionally used measures of social capital trust

or feelings of insecurity (Ariely 2014 Chan To amp Chan 2006 Letki 2008) We suggest the use

20

of the rate of incivilities per 1000 inhabitants as a proxy for social cohesion Incivilities correspond

to those antisocial behaviours (eg groups of rowdy teens and public drunkenness) or visible

neighbourhood conditions (eg graffiti and abandoned buildings) that tend not to be treated as

crime Using the rate of incivilities is arguably a more objective and reliable measure of social

cohesion particularly in countries where institutions of order and security are among the most

trusted An increase in the rate of incivilities rather than changes in crime rates should better

capture the worsening in social cohesion experienced in countries such as Chile where crime rates

are not growing but social conflicts are on the rise Thus the main hypothesis in this essay is that

the rate of incivilities (social cohesion) should be positively (negatively) associated with economic

and racial diversity

Using panel count data models we start analysing how differences in incivilities rates

between and within counties are associated with differences in indicators of relative and absolute

economic disadvantage We use the Gini coefficient of each county as our measure of economic

diversity Although we find a significant and positive association between the rate of incivilities

and the level of income inequality the magnitude of the link seems to be small Among absolute

indicators of economic disadvantage only the level of income shows a strong effect Next we

include our measure of racial diversity We use the number of new visas granted to foreigners as

a proportion of the county population Results show a significant and strong positive association

between the rate of incivilities and racial diversity

To check the robustness of our results we analyse the impact of our measures of economic

and racial diversity running our models separately for each Chilean region and clustering them

geographically We also split the total number of incivilities in four categories to see which type

21

of incivilities show the greatest association with our measures of diversity In general results

support the ldquocommunity heterogeneity hypothesisrdquo that higher community heterogeneity is

associated with higher rates of incivilities (Alesina amp La Ferrara 2002 Letki 2008 Tolsma et al

2009) However results do not support the ldquoincivilities thesisrdquo that the distribution of incivilities

tends to mirror the distribution of income inequality (Skogan 1999 Taylor 1999)

Three results stand out among the set of control variables First the level of education shows

and independent and significant negative association with the rate of incivilities This is in contrast

to previous studies where education acts mainly as a moderator of the effect of economic and racial

diversity on social cohesion (Tolsma et al 2009) The results also show that there is no significant

relationship between the rate of incivilities and the proportion of young population This is relevant

because policies aimed to reduce incivilities usually put the focus on specific groups such as young

people which are linked to physical and social incivilities when social control is weakened

Finally the degree of financial municipal autonomy also shows a significant negative association

with the rate of incivilities This result suggests that municipalities can contribute independently

or together with the central government to reduce incivilities and strengthen social cohesion

Contributions

The three essays in this thesis provide several important insights into the analysis of the

causes and consequences of income inequality particularly in the context of Chile ndash a typical

resource rich economy with persistently high levels of income inequality

Essay 1 advances the understanding of the relationship between income inequality and

natural resources in Chile extending the empirical analysis from the regional level to the county

level In addition the geographic heterogeneity of income inequality is explored with the inclusion

22

of alternative sources of spatial dependence as a potential dimension of the causal relationship

between income inequality and natural resources This essay demonstrates the relevance of natural

resources in explaining the persistence of income inequality even after controlling for other

socioeconomics and institutional factors Findings from this study have potential contribution not

only in the design of policies aimed to reduce income inequality but also in addressing the current

developmental bias between the metropolitan region and the rest of the country

Essay 2 is one of the first studies that undertake a longitudinal analysis of the effects of

income inequality on the efficiency of municipal governments in Chile To capture the role of the

municipal governments in the provision to local people of public services such as education and

health we specify several inputs and outputs in our efficiency model which is different from the

conventional specification in the existing literature For example the number of medical

consultations in public health facilities and the number of enrolled students in public schools are

used as outputs instead of general indicators such as county population Our empirical analysis

also utilises a larger sample of municipalities and covers a much longer period spanning from 2006

to 2017 This essay also investigates the contextual factors beyond the control of local authorities

that can explain variations in the efficiency of municipal governments across the country

Empirical findings from Essay 2 help us increase our understanding of the production

technology of municipalities the sources of inefficiencies and specifically the impact of income

inequality on the performance of local authorities The results deliver two main policy

implications First municipal inefficiencies in the provision of public goods and services differ

across Chilean municipalities In addition efficiency levels show some degree of spatial

autocorrelation This implies that policies such as amalgamation or cooperation among

23

municipalities could have effects beyond the municipalities involved which must be considered

Second the causal effect that income inequality has on municipal efficiency provides another

dimension into the design and implementation of development policies

Essay 3 explores for the first time the effects of economic and racial diversity on social

cohesion in Chile This essay considers incivilities as manifestation of social cohesion and

investigates as extant literature suggests whether indicators of relative economic disadvantage

such as income inequality are among the main factors driving social disorganization and social

unrest Empirical findings suggest that on the one hand economic heterogeneity captured by the

Gini coefficient has a disparate effect both in terms of magnitude and significance on the rate of

incivilities across the country On the other hand the impact of racial heterogeneity appears to be

stronger more significant and of a similar magnitude throughout the country Results also provide

new insights into the design of national policies addressing social disorders particularly those

policies focussed on specific groups of the population and the role of local authorities Overall the

findings provide an opportunity to advance the understanding of the process of weakening in the

social cohesion experienced in Chile and the conflicts that have risen from this process

Thesis outline

The remainder of the thesis is organized as follows Chapter 2 presents essay 1 examining

the association between income inequality and the degree of dependence on natural resources

Chapter 3 presents essay 2 which looks for a causal relationship between municipal efficiency and

income inequality Chapter 4 presents essay 3 analysing the relationship between social cohesion

and economic and racial diversity Finally Chapter 5 presents some concluding remarks

24

Chapter 2 Natural Resources Curse or Blessing Evidence on

Income Inequality at the County Level in Chile

21 Introduction

A phenomenon of increasing inequality of incomes and wealth in recent decades has been

documented by leading scholars and international organizations such as the International Monetary

Fund (Berg amp Ostry 2017 Ostry Berg amp Tsangarides 2014) and the Organization for Economic

Cooperation and Development (Cingano 2014) These efforts have placed the topic of inequality

at the top of the current economic debate recognizing inequality as a determinant not only of

economic growth but also of human development They also have highlighted the necessity for

more research on the drivers of inequality and mechanisms through which it manifests aiming to

design effective policies in reducing economic and social inequalities

Various factors have been analysed as the sources of high and increasing levels of inequality

Among the most significant factors are the levels of income at initial stages of economic

development (Kuznets 1955) Globalization (Milanovic 2016) skill-biased technological change

(Tinbergen 1975) investment in human capital (Murphy amp Topel 2016) institutions

redistributive policy and country-specific characteristics (Acemoglu 1995 2002 Acemoglu

Aghion amp Violante 2001 Acemoglu Johnson amp Robinson 2001) Our focus in this essay is on

the importance that the natural resource endowment (NRE) or lack thereof can play in the

determination of income disparities

25

This essay studies the patterns and evolution of income inequality in the context of a natural

resource-rich country Using the case of the Chilean economy we aim to understand and

disentangle how a phenomenon of high- and persistent-income inequality is related to the

endowment of natural resources that a country owns Chile is an interesting case to study because

despite showing a successful history of economic growth inequality among individuals and among

aggregated spatial units has shown a strong persistence (Paredes et al 2016) Furthermore Chile

has remained among the most unequal countries in the world1

Theory and empirical evidence do not establish a clear link between income inequality and

NRE In addition NRE has received considerably less attention (Auty 2001 ElGindi 2017) and

most of the evidence has been focused on cross-country comparisons For instance NRE can

influence inequality by determining its initial levels (Engerman amp Sokoloff 1994 1997

Engerman Sokoloff Urquiola amp Acemoglu 2002) shaping the evolution of institutions

(Acemoglu 2002) make the educational system less intellectually challenging and moulding the

structure of economic activity (Leamer et al 1999) So studying how cross-county differences in

NRE are associated with the distribution of income within a country has theoretical empirical and

policy implications

In this study we offer empirical evidence on the relationship between income inequality and

the endowment of natural resources using data at the county level in Chile for the period 2006-

2017 Income inequality is measured by the Gini coefficient The importance of NRE is proxied

using a measure of natural resource dependence (NRD) defined as the percentage of the total

1 A 2014 OECD report on income inequality (httpwwwoecdorgsocialincome-distribution-databasehtm) showed Chile as the country with the highest Gini coefficient of disposable income among OECD countries OECD also indicates Chile as the country with the widest gap between the richest 10 percent and the poorest 10 percent of countryrsquos population among its 34 members (OECD 2014)

26

employment in each county corresponding to the primary sector (agriculture forestry fishing and

mining)

The main hypothesis to be tested is whether income inequality is positively associated with

the degree of NRD The transmission mechanisms through which natural resources could influence

socioeconomic outcomes could be based on the market or institutions The market-based approach

argues that natural resource booms could be associated with an appreciation of the real exchange

rate and a crowding out effect over other more productive economic activities such as

manufacturing It could also delay the adoption of new technologies and reduce incentives to invest

in physical and human capital (Gylfason amp Zoega 2003) Based on the ldquoResource Curse

Hypothesisrdquo (RCH) natural resources could be a curse when the political and institutional

framework is weak and natural resources are concentrated in space such as oil and minerals

(Deacon 2011) 2 Among institutional channels a higher NRD or natural resource booms could

be associated with rent seeking misallocation of labour and entrepreneurial talent institutional

and political decline or even violent conflicts For instance the ldquoParadox of Plentyrdquo sustains that

windfalls of revenues as a consequence of resource booms could be related to a lack of incentives

to perform efficiently corruption patronage and local authorities favouring their voters or being

captured by the richest groups (Dauvin amp Guerreiro 2017) Hence a higher NRD or natural

resource booms could be the explanation not only for low levels of growth in regions more

dependent on natural resources but also it could be the root of income disparities

2 There is a wide strand of research on the Resource Curse Hypothesis however the evidence so far is not conclusive Evidence in favour of RCH has been mainly found in developing resource rich countries (Auty 1993 2001 Badeeb Lean amp Clark 2017 Blanco amp Grier 2012 Borge et al 2015 Brunnschweiler amp Bulte 2008 Sachs amp Warner 2001 Van der Ploeg 2011)

27

To test our hypothesis that is whether the levels of income inequality across counties are

positively associated with the degree of NRD we use a spatial econometric approach We use this

approach because attributes such as income inequality in one region may not be independent of

attributes in neighbouring regions (Armstrong amp Taylor 2000) This process of spatial dependence

invalidates the use of traditional (non-spatial) approaches

This study seeks to make two contributions to research First previous empirical evidence

shows a significant spatial dimension of income inequality in Chile (Paredes et al 2016)

However this dimension has been barely explored with most studies limiting the degree of

disaggregation to a regional scale (Aroca amp Bosch 2000) We use a spatial approach which makes

it possible to model and test the significance of the spatial dimension in the analysis of income

inequality and its relationship with other variables Second previous research for the Chilean

economy linking inequality with NRE has been mainly focused on explaining differences between

regions or the importance and effects of the mining-copper sector (Aroca amp Atienza 2011 Ebert

amp La Menza 2015 Lagos amp Blanco 2010 Rehner Baeza amp Barton 2014) We extend this

analysis using data for local economies Identifying and quantifying the impact of NRE on income

inequality at the county level is likely to be more informative for policies aiming to address the

current developmental bias between the metropolitan region and the rest of the country Moreover

the analysis of the role of natural resources in conjunction with other potential sources of inequality

may shed lights in understanding the persistence of the high levels of inequality observed in the

Chilean economy All in all this study could contribute to the design of policies that

simultaneously help reduce inequality increase efficiency and promote sustainable and inclusive

growth

28

Our main finding shows that after controlling for other potential sources of income

inequality such as educational level demographic characteristics and the level of public

government expenditure the degree of dependence on natural resources has a significant effect on

income inequality However contrary to our expectations the effect is negative This result

suggests that the natural or policy-driven process of transformation from primary and extractive

activities to manufacturing and service sectors imposes additional challenges to central and local

authorities aiming to reduce income inequality

In section 22 we review the literature on the relationship between income inequality and

natural resources In section 23 we establish our research problem and main hypothesis Section

24 describes our data and methods and section 25 the empirical results We finish with section

26 discussing our main results concluding and proposing avenues for future research

22 Inequality and Natural Resources

221 Theoretical Framework

Explanations for income inequality can be associated with individual institutional political

and contextual characteristics Individual characteristics include age gender and mainly the level

of education and skills of the population in the labour force For instance globalization and

technological change lead firms to increase the demand for skilled labour deepening income

inequality between skilled and unskilled workers (Atkinson 2015 Milanovic 2016 Tinbergen

1975) Among institutional characteristics labour unions collective bargaining and the minimum

wage have been suggested as explanations of income inequality (Acemoglu Aghion et al 2001

Atkinson 2015) Policy design associated with market regulation progressive taxation and

redistribution can also impact the levels and patterns of inequality

29

A key factor in understanding the levels and differences in income distribution within a

country may be its endowment of natural resources NRE shapes the structure of the economy

(Leamer et al 1999) it is associated with the creation of institutions that define the political

culture and it can also influence the performance of other sectors (Watkins 1963) In addition

NRE determines initial conditions market competition ownership over resources rent seeking

and the geographical concentration of the population and economic activity

Cross‐countryliterature

Bourguignon and Morrison (1990) introduce one of the earliest theoretical frameworks

describing the relationship between inequality and NRE They develop a small open economy

model where income distribution is a function of NRE ownership structure and trade protection

Giving cross-sectional evidence for a group of developing countries they conclude that the impact

of NRE particularly mineral resources and land depends on the number and size of the firms

whether they are public or private and the level of protection A higher concentration of production

in a few private firms a big share of production oriented to foreign instead of domestic markets

and protection increasing the relative price of scarce resources are some of the reasons explaining

why some countries are less egalitarian than others

NRE could also influence the evolution and levels of inequality by determining the initial

distribution of incomes This is known as the ldquoEngerman-Sokoloff Hypothesisrdquo (Engerman amp

Sokoloff 1997 Engerman et al 2002) In addition Leamer (1999) proposes that inequality and

development paths in each economy are a function of its economic structure which in turn depends

on ldquofundamentalsrdquo and ldquosymptomsrdquo On the one hand ldquofundamentalsrdquo refer to resource

endowment production structure closeness to markets and governments interventions On the

30

other hand ldquosymptomsrdquo are related to institutions employment structure and net export structure

Using this conceptual framework Leamer argues that natural Resource-Rich Countries (RRC) can

experience a higher level of inequality because can have a ldquodumbbell educational systemrdquo

ownership is concentrated in small groups and extraction activities require low-skilled workers

This implies fewer incentives to educate citizens until very late in the development process

resulting in human capital not prepared to take advantage of the process of technological progress

and delaying the emergence of more efficient and competitive sectors such as manufacturing and

services

Using 1980 and 1990 data for a group of countries classified according to land abundance

Leamer (1999) provides evidence showing that on the one hand land-scarce countries concentrate

their production and employment in sectors that promote equality such as capital-intensive

manufacturing chemical or machinery On the other hand countries abundant in natural resources

concentrate their production trade or employment in sectors that promote income inequality such

as the production of food beverages extraction activities or forestry

Gylfason and Zoega (2003) using a framework based on standard growth models also

proposed a positive relationship between NRE and inequality They assume that workers can work

in the primary sector or in the manufacturing (including services) sector In addition wage income

is equally distributed in the manufacturing sector but unequally in the primary sector (because of

initial distribution competition rent seeking etc) Therefore inequality will be greater when a

bigger proportion of labour is dedicated to extraction activities in the primary sector This

phenomenon is further amplified because of lower incentives to invest in physical and human

capital to adopt new technologies and to increase the share of the manufacturing sector

31

Diverse mechanisms explaining the link between NRE and inequality have been proposed

arguing that NRE determines simultaneously economic growth and inequality (Gylfason amp Zoega

2003) NRE could impact economic growth through the real exchange rate and the crowding-out

effect on manufacturing (ldquoDutch Diseaserdquo) reducing incentives to invest in physical and human

capital (Easterly 2007) and influencing the processes of technology adoption industrialization

and diversification of the economy in a manner that is less conducive to growth (Bulte et al 2005)

These potential explanations related to the called ldquoResource Curse Hypothesisrdquo do not have strong

empirical support (Auty 2001 Bulte et al 2005)

NRE may also influence economic growth through the quality of institutions (Acemoglu

1995 Acemoglu Aghion et al 2001 Acemoglu amp Robinson 2002 Engerman amp Sokoloff 1997

Engerman et al 2002) the concentration of ownership political power and rent-seeking NRE

acts by shaping institutional context and social infrastructure a phenomenon that is stronger when

resources are spatially concentrated such as minerals and plantations (Bulte et al 2005) NRE

could also have a significant effect on social cohesion and instability spreading its influence like

a disease (Brunori Ferreira amp Peragine 2013 Kanbur amp Venables 2005 Milanovic 2016

Ocampo 2004)

Considering a non-tradable sector intensive in unskilled workers Goderis and Malone

(2011) develop a model where the natural resources sector experiences an exogenous gift of

resource income They analyse the impact over income inequality of resource booms proxied by

changes in a commodity price index They conclude that inequality decreases in the short run but

increases after the initial reduction

32

Fum and Hodler (2010) show that natural resources increase inequality but this is

conditional on the level of ethnical polarization of society Carmignani (2013 2010) confirms this

positive relationship using different measures of dependence and abundance and goes further

arguing that inequality constitutes an indirect channel through which NRE affects human

development

Singlecountryevidence

Most of the studies about the relationship between inequality and NRE derive from cross-

country analyses Evidence for specific countries has been mainly based on case studies Howie

and Atakhanova (2014) based on the model of Goderis and Malone (2011) find for the case of

Kazakhstan that income and consumption inequality decreased significantly after booms in the oil-

and-gas sector because of resource booms increase the demand for non-tradable goods which are

intensive in unskilled workers The results depend on the level of rurality institutional quality

education levels and public spending on health and education Fleming and Measham (2015b

2015a) evaluate the impact of booms in the mining and oil sectors in Australia They find that a

boom in the mining sector increases income inequality due to commuting and migration among

regions This phenomenon can be exacerbated when the demanding access to natural resource

revenues is associated with the creation of more local administrative units (counties provinces and

even regions) but the government capacity is not simultaneously improved (Cust amp Poelhekke

2015 Michaels 2011) Furthermore the benefits that a region can receive in the form of fiscal

transfers can be more than compensated by the loses due to city-to-mine commuting such as the

case of mining regions in Chile (Aroca amp Atienza 2011)

33

Other studies at the local level have analysed the impact of the mining sector in Peru (Aragoacuten

amp Rud 2013 Loayza amp Rigolini 2016 Loayza Teran amp Rigolini 2013) Spain (Domenech

2008) and Canada (Papyrakis amp Raveh 2014) and the effects of oil windfalls in Brazil (Caselli amp

Michaels 2013)

In summary there is a wide range of potential mechanisms through which NRE could

influence income inequality Although most of them seem to suggest a positive relationship others

such as commuting and increased within-county demand for non-tradable goods and services

could lead to a negative association This highlights the need to know the sign of this association

in the Chilean economy where the trend shows a reduction in the degree of NRD After controlling

for other factors a positive link would support the argument that the reduction in the degree of

NRD has been relevant in the reduction experienced by income inequality in the same period

However a negative link would support the position that the reduction in NRD has contributed to

explain the persistence of income inequality and its slow reduction

222 The relevance of the spatial approach

Inequalities within countries are still the most important form of inequality from the political

point of view (Milanovic 2016) People from a geographic area within a country are influenced

and care most about their status relative to the people in other areas in the same country The

influence among regions involves multiple aspects (eg economic political and environmental)

These potential interactions have been traditionally ignored assuming independence among

observations related to different regions Moreover neglecting the process of spatial interaction in

key indicators of the economic and social performance of a country may mislead the design of the

public policy

34

The spatial dimension could play a significant role in understanding the distribution of

income within a country One strand of efforts aiming to capture the geographic heterogeneity of

inequality has been focussed on decomposing general indicators such as the Gini coefficient or the

Theil Index Evidence for different countries including the US (Doran amp Jordan 2016) China

(Akita 2003 Gustafsson amp Shi 2002 Ye Ma Ye Chen amp Xie 2017 Yue Zhang Ye Cheng

amp Leipnik 2014) Japan (Ohtake 2008) South Africa (Leibbrandt Finn amp Woolard 2012) and

Chile (Paredes et al 2016) shows that regional inequality is sensitive to the geographic scale of

analysis These studies also show a significant spatial component in the explanation of inequality

of income expenditure or gross domestic product for each country

Another strand explicitly uses exploratory spatial data analysis (ESDA) and spatial

econometrics ESDA has been used to provide new insights about the nature of regional disparities

of incomes and growth rates (Celebioglu amp Dallrsquoerba 2010 Yue et al 2014) Spatial econometric

models aim to assess and address the nature of the spatial effects These effects could be the result

of ldquospatial heterogeneityrdquo that is different relationships in distinct locations or ldquospatial

dependencerdquo which implies cross-sectional interactions (spillover effects) among units from

distinct but near locations

Spatial spillovers have been analysed to study both positive and negative spatial correlation

among less resource-abundant counties and resource-abundant counties On the one hand less

resource-abundant counties may experience positive spillovers because their industries supply

more goods and services to meet the increasing regional demand They can also be benefited from

positive agglomeration externalities and higher investment in private and public infrastructure

(Allcott amp Keniston 2014 Michaels 2011) On the other hand negative spillovers could be the

35

result of a high degree of interregional migration that limits the rise in wages and higher local

prices due to the increase in the share of the non-tradable sector In addition local governments

could have a limited capacity to translate the revenues from resource booms into effective public

policies promoting a sustained local development (Beine Coulombe amp Vermeulen 2015 Caselli

amp Michaels 2013 Papyrakis amp Raveh 2014)

23 Research problem and hypotheses

We can conclude from our overview of the literature that the theoretical and empirical

evidence about the link between inequality and natural resources is inconclusive This does not

make clear whether the process of reduction in the degree of dependence on natural resources

such as that experienced by the Chilean economy helps to explain the sustained but slow reduction

in income inequality or its high persistence

The research question guiding this study relates to how the natural resource endowment

determines the paths and structure of income inequality in natural resource-rich countries Using

the case of Chile the main hypotheses to be tested is whether a higher degree of dependence on

natural resources is associated with higher levels of income inequality To do that we use data at

the county level and we explicitly include the spatial dimension Our aim is to arrive at a more

comprehensive understanding of the drivers and transmission mechanisms explaining the

evolution and patterns shown by income inequality In addition we test whether the spatial

dimension plays a significant role in explaining differences in income distribution in Chile

36

24 Data and Methods

We use county-level data for the years 2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017 The reason

for not using contiguous years is that income data at the household level are only available every

two-three years from the Chilean National Socioeconomic Characterization Survey (CASEN in its

Spanish acronym)3 For the period 2006-2017 the Chilean administrative division considers 15

regions 54 provinces and 346 counties Data on income are available for 324 counties and six

years resulting in a panel with 1944 observations4

We start evaluating the spatial dimension in our data and analysing the link between

inequality and NRD using a cross-sectional setting To this end we use the ldquosix-year averagerdquo

(2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017) for our variables given the low time variability showed by

our measures of income inequality and NRD Results are then compared with those of a panel data

setting

241 Operationalization of key variables

The dependent variable in the present study income inequality at the county level is

measured calculating the Gini coefficient using three definitions of household income labour

autonomous and monetary income5 Labour income corresponds to the incomes obtained by all

members in the household excluding domestic service consisting of wages and salaries earnings

3 CASEN survey is conducted by the Chilean Ministry of Social Development covering topics such as education employment income and health CASEN is considered nationally representative and it is the main source for measures of inequality and poverty used for the design and evaluation of social policies in Chile 4 The six waves of CASEN for our study considered an average of 75599 households and 252081 individuals 5 The Gini coefficient is chosen because provides an overall estimate of income inequality It summarizes what proportion of the population gains what proportion of the total income The Gini coefficient can range between 0 (everyone in the population has the same income) and 1 (one person earns 100 per cent of the income in the community)

37

from independent work and self-provision of goods Autonomous income is the sum of labour

income and non-labour income (including capital income) consisting of rents interest and dividend

earnings pension healthcare benefits and other private transfers Finally monetary income is

defined as the sum of autonomous income and monetary subsidies which correspond to cash

transfers by the public sector through social programs Appendix A shows summary statistics for

the Gini coefficient of our three measures of income

The main independent variable in our study is the degree of dependence on natural resources

in each county To have an idea of the importance of each economic activity in the Chilean

economy particularly those activities related to natural resources Figure 21 shows their average

share in Chilean Gross Domestic Product (GDP) for the period 2006-17 We can observe that the

leading activities are those related to the primary sector especially mining and to the tertiary

sector where financial personal commerce restaurants and hotels services stand out The shares

of each economic activity in GDP vary significantly between Chilean regions and such

information is not available at the county level

Figure 21 Average share in GDP of economic activities (2006ndash17)

38

Leamer (1999) argues that when the main source of income is labour income (as indeed

happens for the Chilean case) using employment shares allows a better approach to measuring

dependence on natural resources Using employment data from CASEN survey we define our

measure of NRD as the employment in the primary sector (mining fishing forestry and

agriculture) as a percentage of the total employment in each county We name this variable

pss_casen where ldquopssrdquo stands for ldquoprimary sector sharerdquo We built other two proxies of NRD

using data from the ldquoServicio de Impuestos Internosrdquo (SII) which is the agency in charge of

collecting taxes in Chile The variable pss measures the percentage of employment in the primary

sector and the variable pss_firms measures the number of firms in the primary sector as a

percentage of the total number of firms in each county Appendix B shows summary statistics for

our three measures of NRD disaggregated by region

Figure 22 Evolution of Gini coefficient and measures of NRD (2006ndash17)

39

Figure 22 shows the evolution of our measure of inequality (using the Gini coefficient of

autonomous income) and our three potential proxies for NRD for the period 2006-2017 We

observe that both income inequality and the degree of NRD show a downward trend This seems

to support our hypothesis of a positive link between inequality and NRD however we need to

control of other sources of inequality before getting such a conclusion In what follows we use the

variable gini as our measure of income inequality capturing the Gini coefficient of autonomous

income Our measure of NRD is the variable pss_casen defined previously

Figure 23 Spatial distribution of Gini coefficient and NRD (2006ndash17)

Note Gini and NRD averages 2006-09-11-13-15-17 for 324 Chilean counties divided into five equal groups Source Own elaboration based on CASEN survey

40

Figure 23 shows quantile maps for income inequality (on the left) and NRD (on the right)

using the six-years average dataset6 On the one hand we observe that high levels of inequality

seem to be clustered in the Centre-South of the country where agriculture forestry and fishery are

the predominant economic activities Only isolated counties show high inequality in the Centre

(Metropolitan area where the countyrsquos capital is located) and North (Mining) areas On the other

hand our measure of NRD seems to show an opposite spatial pattern than income inequality with

high levels in the Centre and North of the country

242 Control variables

To control for county characteristics we use a set of socio-economic demographic and

institutional variables Economic factors are captured by the natural log of the mean autonomous

household income per capita (in thousands of Chilean pesos of 2017) lnincome the poverty rate

poverty the unemployment rate unemployment the percentage of the population living in rural

areas rural and the average years of education of the population over 15 years old education

Demographic factors include the proportion of the population in the labour force labour_force

and the natural log of population density (population divided by county area) lndensity

We also include the natural log of the total municipal public expenditure per capita

lnmuni_expenditure to control for municipal heterogeneity This heterogeneity is mainly related

to the capacity of municipalities to generate their own revenues In addition the richest

municipalities are in the Metropolitan region which concentrates economic power and around 40

6 After sorting a variable in ascending order quantile maps use the quantiles (quartiles quintiles deciles etc) as class breaks to divide the distribution of the variable where each class includes approximately the same number of observations (counties)

41

of the population This has basically implied a lag in the development of regions other than the

metropolitan region

The spatial distribution of our measures of income inequality and NRD displayed in Figure

23 seems to show different patterns in the North Centre and South of the country Appendix C

shows the administrative division of Chile in 15 regions and how we have grouped them in three

zones North Centre and South We consider as the ldquoCentrerdquo area that formed by the Metropolitan

region (XIII) and its two neighbouring regions V and VI Using the Centre area as our reference

we include in our analysis two dummy variables indicating whether a county is located in the North

area (regions XV I II III and IV) or South area (regions VII VIII IX XIV X XI and XII)

Appendix D shows summary statistics for the set of numeric control variables and the

correlation matrix between our measure of NRD pss_casen and the set of numeric controls

243 Methods

To assess and then consider the spatial nature of the data we need to define the set of relevant

neighbours for each country This is operationalized by building a matrix called ldquoWrdquo with a ldquo1rdquo

for neighbouring counties and a ldquo0rdquo for non-neighbouring counties We could build W using

contiguity-based (whether counties share a border or point) or geography-based (taking the

distances among the centroids of each county polygon) spatial weights Specifically we build a W

matrix considering the 5-nearest counties7 Two reasons explain the choice of k-nearest

neighbours First we cannot use a contiguity criterium because we do not have information about

all the counties and there are some geographically isolated counties Second given the significant

7 We assign a ldquo1rdquo to the five nearest counties to each county based on the distances among the polygon centroids Then W is ldquorow standardizedrdquo This facilitates the interpretation of the spatial lag of a variable as the ldquoweighted average valuerdquo of the same variable in neighbouring counties

42

differences in county areas (ldquobig countiesrdquo in northern and southern regions) using a distance-

band criterium with a not enough large distance band can lead to many ldquoislandsrdquo in extreme regions

and a multi-modal distribution for the number of neighbours

We start testing our inequality and NRD variables for spatial autocorrelation in order to

evaluate statistically the clustering patterns shown in Figure 23 Next we run an OLS regression

of inequality against NRD and our set of controls and we test the spatial autocorrelation of OLS

residuals If we cannot reject the null hypothesis of random spatial distribution we do not need

spatial models to analyse income inequality which would give contrasting evidence to previous

suggestions about the relevance of the spatial dimension of income inequality in Chile (Paredes

2013 Paredes et al 2016) If we find significant spatial autocorrelation in the OLS residuals this

justifies the use of spatial models and highlight the need to find the correct spatial structure8

If inequality in one county spillovers or influences inequality in neighbouring counties the

spatial lag of inequality should be included as an explanatory variable and we should use a spatial

autoregressive model (SAR) If some unobserved variable is the explanation for the clustering of

counties with similar inequality then this will be better captured including a spatial lag of the

errors and we should use a spatial error model (SEM) (Anselin 1988 Anselin amp Bera 1998)

Finally when our main explanatory variable or some of the controls show spatial autocorrelation

a spatial lag of the explanatory variable(s) should be included in our model

8 The existence of spatial autocorrelation violates the standard assumption of independence among observations needed for OLS regression This will result in OLS coefficients biased and inconsistent (Anselin 1988)

43

244 Spatial Model Specification

A model that includes the three forms of spatial dependence described above is called the

Cliff-Ord Model The model in its cross-sectional representation could be expressed as

119910 120582119882119910 119883120573 119882119883120574 119906 (21)

where

119906 120588119882119906 120576 (22)

119882 is our weight matrix that works as an NxN spatial lag operator9 Thus 119882119910 119882119883 and 119882119906

are the spatial lags for the dependent variable explanatory variables and the error term

respectively The parameter 120582 capture the spatial dependence in the dependent variable 120574 the

spatial dependence in the explanatory variables 120588 capture the spatial dependence in the error term

and 120598 is a vector of idiosyncratic errors For instance if ldquoyrdquo is income inequality and ldquoXrdquo a measure

of NRD the level of inequality in one county will be explained by the degree of NRD in the same

county 119883120573 the average degree of NRD in neighbouring counties 119882119883120574 the average level of

inequality in neighbouring counties 120582119882119910 and the average value of residuals in neighbouring

counties 12058811988211990610

From equations (21) and (22) the SAR and SEM models can be seen as special cases of

the Cliff-Ord representation after imposing restrictions over the spatial parameters 120582 120574 and 120588 For

the specification of the spatial panel models we follow the terminology by Croissant and Millo

9 The spatial lag is a weighted sum of the values observed at neighbouring locations 10 On the one hand the impact that income inequality in one county has over income inequality in neighbouring counties is called a ldquoglobal spilloverrdquo and it is associated with the feedback effect among neighbours (one county is its neighboursrsquo neighbourrdquo) on the other hand the influence that the degree of NRD in neighbouring counties has over inequality in one county is called a ldquolocal spilloverrdquo

44

(2018) Spatial panel models including the spatial lag of the dependent variable (SAR) the spatial

lag of the residuals (SEM) or both (SARAR) are described in Appendix E

25 Results

251 Exploratory Spatial Data Analysis (ESDA)

To analyse the significance of the spatial dimension in our data set we use the six-year

average of our variables Spatial autocorrelation is tested using the Moranrsquos I statistic11 Moranrsquos

I measures the correlation of one variable with itself in space12 Figure 24 shows the Moran scatter

plots where the standardized variable (Gini coefficient and NRD for each county) appears in the

horizontal axis against its spatial lag (average value in the 5-nearest neighbouring counties) The

Moranrsquos I (slope of the line in the Moran scatter plot) of income inequality shows a significant

positive spatial autocorrelation that is counties with high (low) inequality tend to be close to each

other

11 There are many statistics to formally test the significance of the spatial dimension in the distribution of our data The null hypothesis assumes spatial randomness which means that there is not spatial structure in the data so any spatial pattern is equally likely to occur and values in one location do not depend on values in other locations The alternative hypotheses can be the existence of positive or negative spatial autocorrelation Positive spatial autocorrelation means similar values in neighbouring locations (less variability than under spatial randomness) Negative spatial autocorrelation means dissimilar values in neighbouring locations (more variability than under spatial randomness) 12 Traditional measures of correlation such as the Pearsonrsquos coefficient measure the degree of linear correlation between two different variables Measures of spatial autocorrelation assess the correlation between the values of one variable in one location related to the values of the same variable in other neighbouring locations

45

Figure 23 Moran scatter plots for variables gini and pss_casen

Moranrsquos I is a measure of global spatial autocorrelation this means it is intended to capture

the clustering property of the entire data set To identify where are the significant hot-spots

(clusters of counties showing high income inequality) or cold-spots (clusters of counties showing

low income inequality) we need local indicators of spatial association (LISA) Using the local

Moranrsquos I (not reported) we find significant hot-spots in the South of the country (mainly

agricultural regions) and significant cold-spots in the Centre (Metropolitan area) of the country

The next step is to check whether the clustering pattern in inequality is the result of a process of

spatial dependence in the variable itself or it can be explained by other variables related to

inequality

252 Cross-sectional analysis

We start analysing differences in income inequality between counties using the six-year

average data and running an OLS regression for the model

119892119894119899119894 120573 120573 119901119904119904_119888119886119904119890119899 120573 119897119899119894119899119888119900119898119890 120573 119901119900119907119890119903119905119910 120573 119906119899119890119898119901119897119900119910119898119890119899119905 120573 119897119886119887119900119906119903_119891119900119903119888119890 120573 119890119889119906119888119886119905119894119900119899 120573 119897119899119889119890119899119904119894119905119910 120573 119903119906119903119886119897 120573 119897119899119898119906119899_119890119909119901119890119899119889119894119905119906119903119890 120573 119899119900119903119905ℎ 120573 119904119900119906119905ℎ

(23)

46

The Moran scatter plot and spatial statistical test of OLS residuals from equation (23) are

in Appendix F OLS residuals show a small but significant positive autocorrelation (Moranrsquos I =

0121) This means that income inequality continues showing a significant degree of spatial

autocorrelation after controlling for the set of covariates In addition robust Lagrange Multiplier

(LM) tests show that a spatial error model is preferred over a spatial lag model (Anselin Bera

Florax amp Yoon 1996)13 This means that income inequality tends to cluster in zones larger than a

county so the analysis should be performed on a larger scale such as provinces regions or macro

zones If the SAR model were preferred it would mean that income inequality in one county is

influenced by the level of income inequality in neighbouring counties To find the spatial structure

that best fits the clustering process of income inequality we run the full set of spatial model

specifications in a cross-sectional setting and results are shown in Table 21

Column 2 in Table 21 shows the results of our ldquoOLSrdquo model The ldquoSLXrdquo model includes

spatial dependence only through the explanatory variables The ldquoSARrdquo model includes the spatial

lag of the dependent variable as a regressor and the ldquoSEMrdquo model includes spatial dependence

through the error term The ldquoSARARrdquo model includes both the spatial lag of the response and the

errors and the ldquoSDMrdquo and ldquoSDEMrdquo are the extensions of the ldquoSARrdquo and ldquoSEMrdquo models

respectively including the spatial lag of the explanatory variables Finally a model including

spatial lags for the response errors and explanatory variables (the ldquoSARARXrdquo model) is shown in

the last column

13 Following the ldquoAnselin methodrdquo when both non robust LM tests are significant we should select between the robust LR tests From Table F1 in Appendix F only the robust LM test for the SEM model (RLMerr) appears as significant

47

Table 21

Cross-sectional Model Comparison (six-year average data)

48

Opposite to our hypothesis we observe a significant and negative coefficient for our measure

of NRD This means that counties more dependent on natural resources show lower levels of

inequality Education years population density and municipal expenditure per capita are also

negatively related to inequality On the other hand the level of income the poverty rate and the

proportion of the population living in rural areas show a positive relationship with income

inequality There is no significant influence of the unemployment rate and the proportion of the

population in the labour force In addition the SAR SEM and SARAR models show a

significantly higher average inequality in the South of the country related to the Centre area

The main finding from our cross-sectional analysis is that there is a significant and negative

relationship between inequality and NRD which is quite robust to the model specification

253 Panel Data analysis

Like the cross-sectional case we start estimating the panel without spatial effects Results

for the pooled fixed effects (FE) and random effects (RE) specifications of equation (3) are in

Appendix G Spatial models were estimated using Maximum Likelihood (ML) and Generalized

Moments (GM) and assuming that the spatial structure (W matrix) is the same for all years14

Tables 22 23 and 24 show results for the ML estimation of the SAR SEM and SARAR models

using the pooled FE and RE specifications Results for the GM estimation are in Appendix H

All our spatial models include time fixed effects In the case of the pooled and RE models they

additionally include indicator variables for those counties located in the North and South of the

country

14 In traditional (non-spatial) panels data are stacked as time series for each observational unit (county) In the case of spatial panels data are stacked as slice of cross-sections for each year in the panel

49

The main result is that the negative and significant effect of NRD on income inequality is

robust to most of the spatial panel specifications In addition the coefficient for the variable

pss_casen changes slightly among panel specifications (pooled FE and RE) but does not change

among spatial models (SAR SEM and SARAR)

Another important finding is related to the significance of the spatial dimension of income

inequality When spatial models cross-sectional or panel are compared to non-spatial models

there are no major differences in the magnitude of the coefficients or their significance This could

mean that the positive spatial autocorrelation shown by income inequality seems to be better

explained by a process of spatial heterogeneity rather than spatial dependence The practical

implication of this result is that including dummy variables for aggregated units (eg regions or

groups of regions) could be enough to control for the spatial dimension in the modelling and

analysis of income inequality

Among control variables years of education seems to be the main variable for the design of

long-term policies aimed at reducing inequality This result is in line with previous evidence for

cross-country studies (Leamer et al 1999) and specific countries (Howie amp Atakhanova 2014)

Municipal expenditure per capita also shows a significant and negative association with income

inequality in the pooled and RE spatial specifications This means that higher municipal

expenditure helps to reduce inequality between counties but its effect is more limited within

counties This result support the importance of local governments (Fleming amp Measham 2015a)

however the negative coefficient appears as evidence against the ldquoParadox of Plentyrdquo (Borge et

al 2015)

50

Table 22

ML Spatial SAR Models

Table 23

ML Spatial SEM Models

51

Table 24

ML Spatial SARAR Models

26 Discussion and conclusions

In this essay we delve deep into the sources of income inequality analysing its association

with the degree of dependence on natural resources using county-level data for the 2006ndash2017

period in Chile Given recent evidence for the Chilean economy suggesting a significant spatial

dimension we assess and incorporate explicitly the spatial structure of income inequality using

spatial methods We use cross-sectional and panel data to evaluate the significance of the spatial

dimension and we test whether NRD has a positive effect on income inequality

Contrary to what theory predicts NRD shows a significant and negative association with

income inequality This result is robust to the type of analysis (cross-sectional vs panel data) the

approach (spatial vs non-spatial) and the inclusion of different controls The negative and

significant coefficient implies that if the degree of NRD would not have experienced a 10 drop

during this period income inequality could have fallen in 2 additional points So the downward

trend in the participation of the primary sector in terms of employment in the Chilean economy

52

could be one of the main reasons explaining the high persistence in the levels of income inequality

This means that those areas that undergo a process of productive transformation mainly towards

the services sector would be facing greater problems to reduce inequality This process of

productive transformation natural or policy-driven highlights the importance of policies focused

on human capital and the role of local governments in reducing inequality

The main implication for policymakers is that a reduction in NRD does not help to reduce

inequality generating additional challenges for local and central governments in its attempt to

transform the structure of their economies to fewer dependent ones on natural resources The

finding of a significant spatial dimension suggests that defining macro zones capturing the spatial

heterogeneity in the data should be done before analysing the relationship among variables and the

design and evaluation of specific policies Particularly relevant in those areas experiencing a

reduction in NRD are migration commuting and the characteristics of the tertiary (services) sector

In addition our findings show that education and municipal expenditure could be effective policy

tools in the fight to reduce inequality in Chile

Although our results seem quite robust they do not allow us to make causal inferences about

the effect of NRD on income inequality However we could think of the following explanation to

explain the negative relationship found and the differences between geographical areas

Areas highly dependent on NR used to demand a high proportion of low-skill labour This

has change in sectors such as the mining sector in the northern area which has simultaneously

experienced an increase in activities related to the service sector such as retail restaurants

transport and housing However those services associated with more skilled labour such as the

finance sector remain concentrated in the capital region The reduction in the degree of NRD

(employment in extractive activities) implies lower labour force but more specialized with most

53

of the low-skilled labour transferred to a service sector characterized by low productivity and low

wages

Non-spatial models show that the North and South particularly the latter present

significantly higher levels of inequality This could be associated with the type of resources with

ldquopointrdquo resources such as minerals in the North and ldquodiffusedrdquo resources such as agriculture in the

South This translates into higher average incomes in the Centre and North areas and lower average

incomes in the South

The reduction in NRD implies not only a movement of the labour force from extractive

activities to manufacturing or services with the latter characterized by low productivity and low

salaries of the labour force We could also speculate that most of the high incomes move to the

central area where the economic power and ownership over firms and resources are concentrated

This would explain low inequality associated with higher average incomes in the central area and

high inequality associated with lower average incomes in the South A more in-depth analysis

capturing the mobility of wealth and labour force between counties or more aggregated areas is

needed to better understand the causal mechanism involved

Our findings open avenues for future research in different strands First studies on the causes

of income inequality should take the role of NRD into consideration which has been overlooked

so far Given that the spatial dimension of income inequality seems to be explained by a

phenomenon of spatial heterogeneity estimation strategies such as spatial regime models or

geographically weighted regression should be used (Chi amp Zhu 2019) Second the effect of NRD

on income inequality could manifest through different channels such as education fiscal transfers

and institutions We could extend our analysis to identify which of these competing channels is

the most relevant Transforming some continuous variables such as educational level to a

54

categorical variable or defining new indicator variables for instance whether a local government

shows or not an efficient performance we could classify counties in different groups and then

check whether there are differences or not in the relationship between income inequality and NRD

A third strand could be to disaggregate our measure of NRD for different industries This

would allow us to test differences among industries and to identify the sectors that promote greater

equality and which greater inequality Forth the analysis of the consequences of income inequality

on other economic and social phenomena such as efficiency economic growth and social cohesion

has a growing interest in researchers and policymakers Our findings suggest that to answer the

question of whether income inequality has a causal impact on other variables we could include a

measure of NRD as an instrument to address endogeneity issues For instance two interesting

topics for future research are the analysis of how differences in income inequality between counties

could help to explain differences in the level of efficiency of local governments and differences in

the degree of social cohesion (unrest) throughout the country Those are the issues to be addressed

in the next two essays

55

Chapter 3 The Impact of Income Inequality on the Efficiency of

Municipalities in Chile

31 Introduction

In Chile municipalities are the smallest administrative unit for which citizens choose their

local authorities playing an important role in the provision of public goods and services at the

local level Municipalities have a similar set of objectives but the level of financial resources

available to finance their activities is highly heterogeneous This could result in significant

differences in the levels of performance between municipalities Despite their importance there is

little empirical evidence about the efficiency of local governments in Chile This essay aims to

measure the technical efficiency of Chilean municipalities and to analyse how local characteristics

particularly those related to income distribution at the county level could help to explain

differences in municipal performance

Cross-country studies situate Chile as an efficient country in international comparisons about

efficiency of government spending (Herrera amp Pang 2005 Loacutepez amp Miller 2008) However

evidence for Chile at the local level is relatively sparse suggesting significant levels of

inefficiency For instance Pacheco Sanchez and Villena (2013) found a mean efficiency level of

around 70 using a sample of 309 municipalities for the period 2008-2010 This suggests that

municipalities could achieve the same level of output by reducing the usage of inputs by an average

of 30 Their study also showed that those municipalities more dependent on the central

56

government or those located in counties with lower income per capita are more efficient than their

counterparts

Most empirical research on Local Government Efficiency (LGE) has been conducted for

member countries of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) of

which Chile has been a member since 2010 In the case of European countries such as Spain and

Italy which share similar characteristics such as the monetary union and levels of GDP per head

efficiency studies have been mainly motivated by budgetary constraints (Balaguer-Coll Brun-

Martos Maacuterquez-Ramos amp Prior 2019 lo Storto 2013) The Chilean context differs in three

main ways from its OECD counterparts First except for the Metropolitan Region that concentrates

most of the population Chilean regions are highly dependent on natural resources Second Chile

is also characterized by one of the highest levels of income inequality among OECD countries

which contrast with the situation of developed natural resource-rich countries such as Australia

and Norway Third although budget constraints are also a relevant issue Chilean municipalities

have experienced a sustained increase in the level of financial resources and expenditure

Another relevant distinction when we benchmark the performance of municipalities across

different countries is the type of public services they provide On the one hand in most of the

countries included Chile the main role of local governments is to provide ldquoservices to peoplerdquo

such as public education and public health On the other hand there are countries such as Australia

where local governments mainly provide ldquoservices to propertyrdquo including waste management

maintenance of local roads and the provision of community facilities such as libraries swimming

pools and parks (Dollery Wallis amp Akimov 2010 Drew Kortt amp Dollery 2015 McQuestin

Drew amp Dollery 2018)

57

Despite contextual differences Chilean municipalities seem not to perform differently from

municipalities in other developed and natural resource-rich countries where income inequality is

significantly less than in Chile (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018a) This result highlights the

need to study the role of income inequality and the degree of dependence on natural resources over

LGE characteristics that have been largely overlooked in the literature

We measure and analyse differences in municipal performance using a two-stage approach

In the first stage we measure municipal efficiency using an input-oriented Data Envelopment

Analysis (DEA) to get a set of ldquoefficiency scoresrdquo In the second stage we regress efficiency scores

against our measure of income inequality controlling for a set of contextual factors describing the

economic socio-demographic and political context of each county

We use a sample of 324 municipalities for the period 2006-2017 During this period Chile

was divided into 346 counties belonging to 15 regions This period was characterized by important

external and internal shocks including the Global Financial Crisis (GFC) one of the biggest

earthquakes in Chilean history in 2010 and three municipal elections The availability of

information allows us to measure efficiency for the full period but the influence of contextual

factors is analysed using a panel of six years (2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017) for which

household income information is available

The main hypothesis tested in the second stage is whether higher levels of income inequality

are associated with lower levels of efficiency Previous evidence shows that when progress is not

evenly shared persistent within-country inequality reduces the effectiveness and efficiency of the

public sector (Ortega Sanjuaacuten amp Casquero 2017 Tandon 2005)

Income inequality has been used to control for a wide range of idiosyncratic factors

associated with historical institutional and cultural factors affecting efficiency (Greene 2016

58

Ortega et al 2017) For instance at the local level income inequality has been considered as an

indicator of economic heterogeneity in the population where higher inequality is associated with

a more heterogeneous set of conflicting demands for public services which adversely affect an

efficient provision (Ashworth Geys Heyndels amp Wille 2014 Geys amp Moesen 2009) Higher

levels of income inequality could also relate to economically privileged groups having a greater

capacity to influence the political system for their own benefit rather than that of the majority

When high inequality is persistent the feeling of frustration and disappointment in the population

could reduce not only trust and cooperation among individuals but also trust in institutions which

would negatively affect government efficiency (Boix amp Posner 1998 Coffeacute amp Geys 2005) For

instance national or local authorities could end exerting patronage and clientelism and showing

rising levels of corruption (Uslaner 2011 Uslaner amp Brown 2005)

One of the main gaps in extant literature is the need to conduct more analysis of LGE using

panel data taking into consideration endogeneity issues and controlling for unobserved

heterogeneity (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018a) To address the above we set-up a panel with

time and county-specific effects and we propose the use of a measure of natural resource

dependence (NRD) as an instrument for income inequality Based on the ldquoParadox of Plentyrdquo

fiscal revenues from natural resources windfalls could be associated with an over expansion of the

public sector fostering rent-seeking and corruption and reducing local government efficiency

(Dauvin amp Guerreiro 2017 Manzano amp Rigobon 2001) In the Chilean case most of the revenues

generated by local governments included those from natural resources end up in a common fund

which benefits all municipalities The aim of this common fund is precisely to reduce inequalities

among municipalities so although we do not expect a direct impact of natural resources on LGE

we could expect an indirect effect through other indicators particularly income inequality

59

As far as we know this is the first study analysing the influence of income inequality as a

determinant of municipal efficiency in Chile Moreover this is the first study in the context of a

natural resource-rich country which specifically suggests a measure of natural resource

dependence as an instrument to correct for endogeneity bias We propose the use of the proportion

of firms in the primary sector as proxy for the degree of NRD in each county We argue that this

variable is a better proxy than using the proportion of employment in the manufacturing sector

which has been proposed in previous studies (Alesina amp La Ferrara 2002) During the period

analysed our proxy remained relatively stable and showed a significant relationship with income

inequality In addition it is less likely that it has directly affected municipal efficiency

This study adds to the literature in two other ways First the extant literature suggests that

efficiency measurement could be highly sensitive to the chosen technique as well as the selection

of inputs and outputs (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018a) Inputs are usually proxied by a single

measure of total public expenditures and outputs by general proxies such as population andor the

number of businesses in each county We offer a novel approach for the selection of inputs and

outputs On the one hand we disaggregate government expenditures into four components

(operation personnel health and education) and we use the number of public schools and health

facilities in each county as a proxy for physical capital On the other hand we use four outputs

aiming to capture the wide variety of goods and services supplied by each municipality Through

this approach we aim to better describe the production function of each municipality capturing

not only the variety of inputs and outputs but also differences in size among municipalities

A third contribution relates to the measurement of LGE in the Chilean context We measure

technical and scale efficiency using a larger sample and a longer period This has empirical and

policy relevance On the one hand it helps us to select the correct DEA model and allows us to

60

determine the importance of scale inefficiencies as explanation for differences in municipal

performance On the other hand efficiency measures increase the information available for both

central and local governments to better understand the production technology that best describes

each municipality and to carry out policies to improve efficiency

We believe that our selection of inputs and outputs the use of a large dataset and the joint

analysis using cross-sectional and panel data provide a more accurate and robust analysis of

municipal efficiency Likewise knowing whether inequality has a significant influence on

municipal efficiency may provide useful insights and guidance for policymakers not only in Chile

but also for countries sharing similar characteristics

DEA results show an average level of technical efficiency (inefficiency) of around 83

(17) This means that municipalities could reduce on average a 17 the use of inputs without

reducing the outputs There are significant differences among geographic areas with the Centre

area (where the countyrsquos capital is located) displaying higher efficiency than the rest of the country

When municipal efficiency is measured under different assumptions about returns to scale results

reveal a production technology with variable returns to scales and around 75 of the

municipalities displaying scale inefficiencies However when technical efficiency is

disaggregated between pure technical efficiency and scale efficiency results show that scale

inefficiency explains a small proportion of the total municipal technical inefficiency This finding

justifies a deeper analysis of the reasons why municipalities could operate inefficiently and why

municipal performance could vary among municipalities

Efficiency scores also show a significant degree of positive spatial autocorrelation This

means that municipal efficiency shows a general clustering process with neighbouring

municipalities showing similar levels of efficiency A further analysis shows that most of the

61

spatial pattern in municipal efficiency is exogenous that is could be associated to other variables

Hence we conduct most of our regression analysis using traditional (non-spatial) methods and

leaving spatial regressions in the appendixes

Findings from cross-sectional and panel regressions support the hypothesis that municipal

performance is significantly and negatively associated with income inequality at the county level

The coefficient of income inequality is close to one which means that reductions in income

inequality ceteris paribus could be associated with increases in municipal efficiency in the same

proportion This result supports the strand of research arguing that there is not a trade-off at least

at the municipal level between equity and efficiency (Andersen amp Maibom 2020 Berg amp Ostry

2011 2017) The main policy implications are that authorities in more unequal counties would

face higher challenges to perform efficiently and policies pertaining to inequality and efficiency

should not be designed independently

The chapter is structured as follows Section 32 provides a brief literature review on related

local government efficiency Section 33 introduces the methodological background and empirical

models Section 34 presents the empirical results and discussions Section 35 concludes the

chapter

32 Related Literature

321 Measuring efficiency of local governments

Studies on measuring LGE can be grouped in those analysing the provision of single services

such as health or education and those assessing overall efficiency (lo Storto 2013) Once inputs

and outputs have been defined efficiency is measured using parametric andor non-parametric

techniques Among the former group Stochastic Frontier Analysis (SFA) seems to be preferred

62

by scholars aiming to measure efficiency and to analyse the link with environmental variables

using a single procedure (Pacheco et al 2013 Tsekeris Sotiris Tsekeris amp Papaioannou 2018)

On the non-parametric group Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA) is by far the most used technique

(Afonso amp Fernandes 2006 Balaguer-Coll amp Prior 2009 lo Storto 2013)

The selection of inputs and outputs depends not only on the aimed of the study (specific

sector vs whole measure of efficiency) but also on the role that municipalities play in different

countries There are countries such as Australia (Drew et al 2015) and Spain (Balaguer-Coll amp

Prior 2009) where local governments mainly supply services to ldquopropertyrdquo such as waste

management and road maintenance In these cases efficiency has been mainly measured using

total indicators of local government expenditure and outputs have been proxied using general

indicators such as population or number of business (Drew et al 2015) On the other hand in

countries such as Italy (lo Storto 2013) and Portugal (Afonso amp Fernandes 2008) in Europe or

Brazil (de Sousa Cribari-Neto amp Stosic 2005) and Chile (Pacheco et al 2013) in South America

municipalities mainly supply services to ldquopeoplerdquo Here in addition to financial expenditures or

revenues inputs have included the number of local government employees the number of schools

or the number of hospitals and health centres School-age population the number of students

enrolled in primary and secondary schools and the number of beds in hospitals have been

considered as outputs Based on the study of Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte (2018a) a wider list of

inputs and outputs used in previous studies can be found in Appendix I

Studies from different countries show important differences in the average efficiency scores

both between and within countries These studies also differ in the samples methodologies and

variables included A summary showing the range and variability of the mean efficiency scores

founds in countries all around the world can be found in Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte (2018a)

63

These authors also show that OECD natural resource-rich countries such as Australia Belgium

and Chile show similar results in terms of mean efficiency scores with LGE studies being less

frequent in Latin American countries

Measuring efficiency of local governments as decision-making units (DMU) presents many

challenges and difficulties (Borger Kerstens Moesen amp Vanneste 1994 Ravallion 2005)

Worthington and Dollery (2000) mention problems with the selection and measurement of inputs

the identification of different stakeholders the hidden characteristic of the ldquolocal government

technologyrdquo and the multidimensionality of the services provided by local governments All these

issues make difficult to identify and distinguish between outputs and outcomes with outputs

commonly proxied by general indicators such as county area or county population Because

efficiency measures are highly sensitive to the chosen technique and the selection of inputs and

outputs Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte (2018a) suggest formulating different specifications and

using less general and unspecified indicators Moreover the complexity in defining outputs and

the use of general indicators make more likely that contextual factors affect municipal efficiency

322 Explaining differences in LGE

To explain differences in local government performance researchers have basically

distinguished between ldquodiscretionaryrdquo and ldquonon-discretionaryrdquo factors Discretionary factors refer

to the degree of discretion of local authorities in the selection and management of inputs and

outputs On the other hand scholars have investigated the influence on LGE of contextual factors

beyond authoritiesrsquo control These factors reflective at the environment where municipalities

operate include economic socio-demographic geographic financial political and institutional

characteristics (da Cruz amp Marques 2014 Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018b)

64

In general the evidence about the influence of contextual factors has delivered mixed and

country-specific results (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018b) Sampaio de Sousa et al (2005)

using data for Brazilian municipalities finds that population density and urbanization rate have

strong positive effects on efficiency scores Benito et al (2010) show that lower levels of

efficiency of Spanish municipalities are associated with a greater economic level a less stable

population and a bigger size of the local government Afonso (2008) finds that per capita income

level and education are not significant factors influencing LGE of Portuguese municipalities He

also finds that municipalities in Northern areas show greater efficiency than their counterparts in

Southern areas More recently Tsekeris (2018) finds that spatial variations in efficiency in Greece

can be attributed to factors related to inter-regional market access specialization and sectoral

concentration resource-factor endowments and political factors among others Characteristics

describing each local government have also been used including municipal indebtedness (Benito

et al 2010) fiscal deficits (Sinha 2017) degree of fiscal autonomy (Boetti Piacenza amp Turati

2009) and individual characteristics of local authorities such as age gender and political ideology

Narboacuten‐Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte (2018b) conclude after analysing 63 articles that studies on the

influence of contextual factors have mostly used cross-sectional data with little attention to

endogeneity issues which makes any causal interpretation doubtful

323 The trade-off between efficiency and equity

The existence of a potential trade-off between efficiency and equity is in the core of

economic discussion (Andersen amp Maibom 2020 Berg amp Ostry 2011 Browning amp Johnson

1984 Okun 2015)15 The argument that economic growth (one of the most common efficiency

15 Redistributive policies distort incentives and lead to suboptimal outcomes and thus efficiency losses

65

measures) could be negatively affected in the search for greater equality has been translated not

only into economic policies that favour economic growth over those that reduce inequality but

also in the emphasis of scholarly research Thus theoretical and empirical research has been

mainly focussed on efficiency and policy implications of a great diversity of shocks and policies

leaving the analysis of inequality as one of measurement and mostly descriptive Additionally

empirical evidence of the trade-off is scant and inconclusive (Andersen amp Maibom 2020

Browning amp Johnson 1984)

Among economic contextual factors that could affect LGE income inequality has been

largely ignored An exception is a cross-country comparison conducted by Ortega (2017) who

analyses the role of inequality on government efficiency in developing countries He finds that

more unequal countries could have higher difficulties to achieve specific health outcomes Income

inequality has even been considered as part of the outputs to measure efficiency particularly for

the case of European and OECD countries (Afonso Schuknecht amp Tanzi 2010 Antonelli amp De

Bonis 2018)

At the local level income inequality has been mainly used as a proxy for the effect of income

heterogeneity Economic inequality could have a direct and an indirect effect on government

efficiency The direct effect poses that higher income inequality could reduce municipal efficiency

because it is associated with a more complex and competing set of public services demanded by

the population (Jottier et al 2012) The indirect effect puts the focus in the link between inequality

social capital and levels of corruption Economic diversity could reduce trust in people and

institutions when related to high and persistent levels of income inequality It could also affect the

willingness to participate in community and political groups the existence of a shared objective

by citizens and the perception of a prosperous future (Uslaner amp Brown 2005)

66

The evidence is ambiguous For instance Geys and Moesen (2009) find that income

inequality has little relation to efficiency of Flemish municipalities and Ashworth et al (2014)

find a negative relationship for the Norwegian case Findings also indicate that inequality is the

strongest determinant of trust and that trust has a greater effect on communal participation than on

political participation (Uslaner amp Brown 2005)

33 Methodology

We follow a two-stage approach widely used in this kind of analysis A DEA analysis is

conducted in the first stage to get efficiency scores for each municipality Then regression analysis

is conducted in the second stage aiming to identify contextual variables other than differences in

the management of inputs that can help to explain the heterogeneity in municipal performance

331 Chilean Municipalities and period of analysis

The territory of Chile is divided into regions and these into provinces which for purposes of

the local administration are divided into counties The local administration of each county resides

in a municipality which is administrated by a Mayor assisted by a Municipal Council16

Municipalities represent the decentralization of the central power in Chile They are autonomous

organizations with legal personality and own patrimony whose purpose is to satisfy the needs of

the local community and ensure their participation in the economic social and cultural progress of

the county Municipalities have a diversity of functions related to public health education and

social assistance among others

16 The Mayor and City Council are elected by suffrage for the citizens of the respective commune every 4 years

67

To achieve their goals two are the main sources of municipal incomes own permanent

revenues (OPR) and the Municipal Common Fund (MCF) OPR are incomes generated by the

county and they are an indicator of the self-financing capacity of each municipality OPR are not

subject to restrictions regarding their investment and they are mainly generated by territorial taxes

commercial patents and circulation permits17 The MCF is a fund that aims to redistribute

community income to ensure compliance with the purpose of the municipalities and their proper

functioning Sources to finance the MCF come from municipal revenues The distribution

mechanism of the fund is regulated by parameters such as whether municipalities generate OPR

per capita lower than the national average and the number of poor people in the commune in

relation to the number of poor people in the country

This study covers the period from 2006 to 2017 During this period Chile was divided into

15 regions 54 provinces and 346 counties18 Although the information on inputs and outputs is

available for the entire period information on contextual factors at the county level such as

household income is only available every two-three years In addition some counties are excluded

from household surveys due to their difficult access Hence we use a sample of 324 municipalities

to measure municipal efficiency for the whole period (3888 observations) However the analysis

of contextual factors is conducted for those years when household income information is available

2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017 (1944 observations)

17 The territorial tax is a tax on agricultural and non-agricultural real estate Specifically of this income only 40 is left to the municipality as its own financing while the remaining 60 is allocated to the MCF (in the case of the four largest communes- Santiago Providencia Las Condes and Vitacura-percentages are 35 and 65 respectively) Unlike the territorial tax commercial patents are regulated mainly by the municipality which chooses the rate to be charged subject to a range established by law and is responsible of their collection Finally regarding the circulation permits 375 is of municipal benefit while 645 is directed to the MCF 18 There are 346 counties managed by 345 municipalities where counties ldquoCabo de Hornosrdquo and ldquoAntaacuterticardquo are managed by the municipality of ldquoCabo de Hornosrdquo

68

332 Measuring municipal efficiency

Municipal efficiency is measured using Data Envelopment Analysis (Coelli Prasada Rao

OrsquoDonnell amp Battese 2005) This is a non-parametric approach that uses linear programming to

measure efficiency for a group of municipalities as decision making units (DMUrsquos) The main

advantage of using DEA and the reason why DEA is used for the case of Chilean municipalities

is its flexibility in handling multiple inputs and outputs without the need to specify a functional

form (Balaguer-Coll amp Prior 2009 Mikušovaacute 2015 Tigga amp Mishra 2015) Following Afonso

and Fernandes (2008) the relationship between inputs and outputs for each municipality could be

represented by the following equation

119884 119891 119883 119894 1 119899 (31)

In equation (31) 119884 is the set of outputs and 119883 the set of inputs for each of the n

municipalities Using linear programming the production frontier is constructed and a vector of

efficiency scores is obtained The frontier represents full technical efficiency mdash the point at which

the highest output occurs given specified inputs or the point at which the lowest amount of inputs

is used to produce a specified quantity of output Efficiency scores under DEA are relative

measures of efficiency They measure a municipalityrsquos efficiency against the other measured

municipalities in the sample and not a hypothetical lsquoperfect municipalityrsquo The further from the

frontier the less technically efficient a municipality is

We use an input-oriented approach because Chilean municipalities have a greater control

over the management of inputs relative to the outputs they have to manage Obtaining efficiency

scores requires an assumption about the returns to scale exhibited by each municipality When

DMUrsquos are homogeneous the CCR model (Charnes Cooper amp Rhodes 1978) which assumes

69

constant return-to-scale (CRS) is the appropriate specification The CCR model assumes full

proportionality between outputs and inputs and that DMUrsquos operate at their optimal When DMUrsquos

are highly heterogeneous as is the case with local governments in most countries it is not realistic

to assume complete proportionality between inputs and outputs nor that all DMUrsquos operate at their

optimum scale In this situation a variable returns-to-scale (VRS) or BCC model (Banker

Charnes amp Cooper 1984) is the preferred formulation

Assuming VRS imposes minimum restrictions on the efficient frontier and allows for

comparisons only among municipalities of similar scale (Coelli et al 2005 Wu Huang amp Pan

2014) This means that when we use the CCR model (assuming CRS) on a heterogeneous sample

of DMUrsquos the resulting measure of technical efficiency that we obtain is related not only to the

management of inputs but also to issues of scale19 To empirically check the validity of the VRS

assumption we measure technical efficiency under CRS VRS and non-increasing returns-to-scale

(NIRS) and we analyse the existence of scale inefficiencies This allows us to check the relevance

of scale effects as a potential explanation of differences in municipal efficiency Appendix J

shows the specification of the DEA model under VRS and how ldquototal technical efficiencyrdquo

(assuming CRS and therefore due to management and scale issues) could be disaggregated in ldquopure

technical efficiencyrdquo (under VRS and related only to management issues) and scale efficiency (due

to scale issues)

19 Assuming VRS can also lead to measurement problems such as overestimation of efficiency scores This is the case when an important proportion of DMUrsquos shows CRS so assuming VRS ignores the information about proportionality between inputs and outputs (Podinovski 2004)

70

333 Inputs and outputs used in DEA

Following the literature on local government expenditure efficiency (Afonso amp Fernandes

2008 de Sousa et al 2005 Dlouhyacute 2018 Tandon 2005 Tigga amp Mishra 2015) and trying to

reflect as well as possible the functioning of municipalities five inputs and four outputs were

selected Input and output data were obtained from the National System of Municipal Information

(SINIM in its Spanish acronym) and they are expressed in thousands of Chilean pesos of 201720

Inputs are Municipal Operational Expenditure X1 (including expenses on goods and

services social assistance investment and transfers to community organizations) Municipal

Personnel Expenditure X2 (including full time and part-time workers) Total Municipal

Expenditure in Education sector X3 Total Municipal Expenditure in Health sector X4 and the

Number of Municipal Buildings X5 (proxied by the number of public facilities in education and

health sectors)

Output variables were selected highlighting the relevance of education and health sectors

and trying to capture the wide range of local services provided by municipalities The variable

ldquoOwn Permanent Revenuesrdquo Y1 is used to capture the scale and diversity of municipal

activities21 The ldquoMonthly Average Enrolmentrdquo in municipal education establishments related to

the school-age population in each county Y2 is used as educational output As health output the

ldquoNumber of Medical Consultationsrdquo in public facilities Y3 is considered Finally the number of

community organizations Y4 is used as output reflecting the promotion of community

development by each municipality Table 31 shows the summary statistics of input and output

20 The data from SINIM database was mostly obtained using the sinimr package (Salas 2019) 21 According to SINIM database this variable aims to measure the management of the municipalityrsquos own resources with respect to the population of the commune

71

variables for the whole sample and period Inputs and outputs excepting the Monthly Average

Enrolment Y2 are measured in per capita terms using county population information from the

National Institute of Statistics (INE in its Spanish acronym)

Table 31

Descriptive statistics Inputs and Output variables used in DEA analysis

334 Regression model

Contextual factors could play an important role not only in explaining why some

municipalities operate inefficiently but also why municipal performance differs among them

These factors may affect municipal performance modifying incentives for local authorities to

operate efficiently and their capability to take advantage of economies of scale They also define

the conditions for cooperation or competition among municipalities and the citizensacute ability and

willingness to monitor local authorities (Afonso amp Fernandes 2008)

Information on income at the household level for each county was obtained from the

ldquoNational Socioeconomic Characterization Surveyrdquo (CASEN in its Spanish acronym) CASEN is

conducted every two-three years being the reason why consecutive years are not considered in

72

our regression analysis The other contextual factors used as controls were obtained from different

sources including SINIM INE and the ldquoServicio de Impuestos Internosrdquo (SII)22

Our main hypothesis is whether higher levels of income inequality are associated with lower

levels of municipal efficiency To test our hypothesis the empirical model is defined as

120579 120573 119892119894119899119894 119885 120573 120575 120572 120598 (32)

Where 120579 is the vector of DEA efficiency scores 119892119894119899119894 is the Gini coefficient of each

county 120575 are year-specific effects 120572 are county-specific constants 120598 is a vector of error terms

and 119885 is a vector of controls Next we discuss the motivation for these controls

The level of purchasing power of countiesrsquo citizens is proxied by the variable log(income)

which is the natural log of the mean household income per capita in thousands of Chilean pesos of

2017 On the one hand poorer counties could display higher efficiency due to their necessity to

take care of their constraint resources (Pacheco et al 2013) On the other hand richer counties

could show higher efficiency because richer citizens exert higher monitoring over local authorities

and demand better quality public services in return for their tax payments (Afonso et al 2010)

The possibility for municipalities to take advantage of economies of scale and urbanization is

captured by three variables First the variable log(density) which correspond to the natural log of

population density Second the dummy variable reg_cap indicating whether a county is a regional

capital or not Third the variable agroland which correspond to the proportion of land for

agricultural use which is informed to the SII We expect a positive effect of log(density) but

negative for regcap and agroland

22 The SII is the institution in charge of collecting taxes in Chile

73

Socio-demographic characteristics are captured including a Dependence Index IDD IDD

corresponds to the number of people under 15 years or over 65 years per 100 people in the active

population (those people between 15 and 65 years old) A higher proportion of young and older

population could be associated with a higher demand for municipal services relating to education

and health making harder to offer public services efficiently The citizensrsquo capacity to monitor

local authorities is proxied including the variable education (average years of education for the

population older than 15 years) and the variable housing (proportion of households which are

owners of the property where they live in each county) In both cases we expect a positive

association with LGE

Among municipal characteristics the variable professional (percentage of municipal

personnel with a professional degree) is used to control for the quality of municipal services and

it is expected a positive impact The variable mcf (proportion of total municipal income coming

from the MCF) is included to capture the influence of financial dependence on the central

government A higher dependence from MCF could be associated with higher efficiency when it

is linked to more control from central government (Worthington amp Dollery 2000) However when

MCF discourages the generation of own resources and proper management of resources from the

fund a lower efficiency should be expected (Bravo 2014) In addition the dummy variable mayor

is included to capture differences among mayors supported by the ldquoLEFTrdquo or the ldquoRIGHTrdquo

political parties related to those ldquoINDEPENDENTrdquo mayors

Table 32 report summary statistics for the set of numeric contextual factors and Appendix

K the corresponding correlation matrix Despite the high correlation between income and

education variables we include both in the regression section as they capture different county

characteristics

74

Table 32

Summary Statistics Numeric Contextual Factors

Figure 31 Geographical distribution of Chilean regions and macrozones

Previous evidence on growth and convergence of Chilean regions have found that regions

tend to cluster spatially (Aroca amp Bosch 2000) Aiming to capture this regional clustering process

75

and considering the high concentration in the number of municipalities and population in the

central area we group municipalities in four ldquozonesrdquo We define as reference the ldquoCentre-Northrdquo

zone consisting of regions XIII (where the countryrsquos capital is located) and its two neighbouring

regions V and VI The ldquoNorthrdquo zone includes regions XV I II III and IV The ldquoCentre-Southrdquo

zone includes regions VII VIII and IX Finally the ldquoSouthrdquo zone embraces regions XIV X XI

and XII Figure 31 displays the regional administrative division and zones considered in this

essay

Efficiency scores (ES) are limited to have values between 0 and 1 However they are relative

measures (relative to the sample of municipalities) This implies that when a municipality is on the

frontier (ES = 1) it does not mean that potentially larger technical efficiency gains cannot be made

Hence equation 32 is estimated using OLS and censored regressions We start running cross-

sectional regressions for each of the six years Then we compare the results with those from panel

regressions Because fixed-effects panel Tobit models could be affected by the incidental

parameters problem (Henningsen 2010 2019) we use random-effects panel Tobit models

including indicator variables for years and zones Finally to deal with the potential endogeneity

problem we also use an instrumental variable approach The instrument is described next

335 The instrument

Government effectiveness and income distribution are both structural components of

economies (Ortega et al 2017 Ravallion 2005) In the search for a causal interpretation for the

influence of income inequality on municipal efficiency we need an instrument which must be

correlated with the variable to be instrumented (in our case income inequality) and uncorrelated

with the error term in the efficiency equation (32) Previous literature has used as instruments for

Gini the number of townships governments in a previous period the percentage of revenues from

76

intergovernmental transfers in a previous period and the current share of the labour force in the

manufacturing sector (Alesina amp La Ferrara 2002) Using the share of the labour force in a specific

sector is unlikely to reduce the problem of endogeneity particularly in countries where local

governments supply mostly ldquoservices to peoplerdquo and the main source of income inequality is

labour income

We propose as an instrument the proportion of firms in the primary sector (mining fishing

forestry and agriculture)

119901119904119904_119891119894119903119898119904Number of firms in the primary sector

Total number of firms (33)

On the one hand this instrument is likely to be correlated with local income inequality in

natural resource-rich countries23 On the other hand we contend that our instrument is less likely

to be correlated with the error term in the efficiency equation First the main services supplied by

Chilean municipalities are services to people (health and education) not to firms Second most of

the revenues collected by municipalities included those associated with natural resources end up

in the municipal common fund whose objective is precisely to reduce inequalities among

municipalities Third services to firms are expected to be more significant with the tertiary sector

We argue that our instrument captures natural and structural conditions which directly

influence income inequality but it does not directly affect LGE Figure 32 shows the evolution

of the annual average efficiency score and the proportion of firms in the primary secondary

(manufacturing) and tertiary (services) sectors We observe that sectors shares have remained

relatively stable with a slight reduction in the participation of the primary sector in favour of the

23 Results confirm a significant association between income inequality and the degree of dependence on natural resources at the county level

77

tertiary sector by the end of the period This is contrary to the evolution of municipal efficiency

which shows a cyclical behaviour as will be shown in the next section

Figure 32 Evolution of efficiency scores and the proportion of firms by sector

34 Results and discussion

341 DEA results

Figure 33 displays the evolution of our three measures of efficiency Overall technical

efficiency pure technical efficiency and scale efficiency are around 78 83 and 95

respectively with fluctuations over the years Therefore around three quarters of the overall

78

inefficiency is attributed to inefficiency in the management of inputs and around one quarter to

scale inefficiencies24

Figure 33 Evolution technical efficiency (TE) pure technical efficiency (PTE) and scale efficiency (SE)

Returnstoscale

Figure 34 reports by zone and for the whole period the proportion of municipalities

showing CRS decreasing returns to scale (DRS) or increasing returns to scale (IRS) Most of the

municipalities operate under variable (increasing or decreasing) returns to scale which could be

explained by the high heterogeneity in size among municipalities A summary of RTS

disaggregated by year and zone is in Appendix L Policies oriented to increase efficiency usually

24 The average scale efficiency score of 95 means that municipalities could get an additional 5 of inputs saving if municipalities were able to change their size to achieve their optimal scale

79

consider amalgamation de-amalgamation or ways of cooperation among municipalities To have

a better idea about where and how feasible is the implementation of such policies Appendix M

shows maps with the administrative division of the country in its 345 municipalities and which

municipalities show CRS IRS or DRS in each of the six years of data

Figure 34 Returns to scale by zone

Based on results for the whole period (Figure 34) the North has the highest proportion of

municipalities exhibiting DRS This suggests the need to reduce the size of municipalities splitting

those ldquotoo bigrdquo creating new administrative areas or giving more autonomy to current

municipalities25 The opposite occurs in the Centre-North area where municipalities mostly

exhibit IRS This indicates the need to merge municipalities An alternative strategy to the

amalgamation process is increasing inter-municipal cooperation (Balaguer-Coll et al 2019)

25 This has been the policy followed in Chile Although two new regions were created (XV in the North and XIV in the South) the number of municipalities has not changed

80

which seems to be a more plausible option in Chile Finally evidence on scale efficiency for the

Centre-South and South areas is not clear in terms of the adequate strategy to improve efficiency

Efficiencymeasure

Although most municipalities show scale inefficiencies (Figure 34) only a small proportion

of total inefficiency is associated to scale issues (Figure 33) Together this results justify not only

the use of the BCC model (efficiency scores under VRS) to capture municipal heterogeneity but

also highlights the need to look for other factors outside the control of local authorities which

could be influencing municipal performance

Table 33

Summary efficiency scores (VRS) by zone and region

Table 33 summarizes ES under VRS using data for the six years of CASEN survey A mean

efficiency score of 83 is found for the full sample and period This means that on average

inefficient municipalities can reduce the use of inputs by 17 to get the same current output By

81

comparing average ES per zone it can be concluded that municipalities in the North Centre-North

Centre-South and South could achieve the same level of output with 17 12 18 and 23 fewer

resources respectively Results also show that one third of the municipalities present an efficiency

score equal to one

Figure 35 shows the evolution of the mean ES for the four zones over the 12 years period

A clear drop in the efficiency level is observed in 2009 (the financial crisis year) excepting for the

North area Likewise although mean efficiency returned to its pre-crisis levels in 2014-2015 a

new drop in efficiency was experienced in 2016 It also seems that the 2010 earthquake did not

generate a significant effect on municipal efficiency Figure 35 also shows that although levels

of efficiency seem to differ among zones they follow a similar trend through time with the only

exception of the North which corresponds to the mining area In addition efficiency seems to be

significantly higher in the Centre-North area This is explained by the high mean level of efficiency

in region XIII which includes the countryrsquos capital city

Figure 35 Evolution mean efficiency scores (VRS) by zone

82

To know which and where are the efficient municipalities and if they are surrounded by

municipalities with a similar level of efficiency Appendix N has maps showing the ldquoefficiency

statusrdquo of each municipality that is whether they are efficient (ES = 1) or inefficient (ES lt 1)

Additionally Appendix O shows ldquoequal intervalsrdquo maps describing the spatial distribution of ES

among municipalities for each of the six years26 Results show that efficient municipalities can be

found all through the country the ldquoefficiency statusrdquo could change from one year to another and

municipalities with similar level-status of efficiency tend to cluster in space

342 Regression results

Exploratoryspatialanalysis

DEA efficiency scores and their geographical representations seem to show that municipal

efficiency presents a spatial clustering pattern This means that municipal performance could be

influenced not only by contextual factors of the county where municipality belongs but also by the

level of efficiency of neighbouring municipalities and their characteristics To test the significance

of the spatial dimension in municipal efficiency we use a cross-section of data considering the six-

year average of efficiency scores the Gini coefficient and the set of controls

We use the Moranrsquos I indicator to test for spatial autocorrelation Moranrsquos I is a measure of

the correlation between the level of efficiency in one municipality and its ldquospatial lagrdquo that is the

average level of efficiency in neighbouring municipalities We define as the relevant neighbours

for each municipality the 5-nearest municipalities This is obtained using the distances among the

26 An equal intervals map uses the same principle as a histogram to organize the observations into categories that divide the range of the variable into equal interval bins For the equal interval classification the value range between the lower and upper bound in each bin is constant across bins but the number of observations in each bin is typically not equal

83

polygonsrsquo centroids (latitude and longitude) of each county Results confirm that municipal

efficiency show a significant level of positive spatial autocorrelation This means that

municipalities tend to have neighbouring municipalities with similar performance

The positive spatial autocorrelation shown by municipal efficiency could be due to the

performance in one municipality is influenced by the performance in neighbouring municipalities

(spatial dependence in the variable itself) or due to structural differences among regions-zones

(spatial heterogeneity) To check the source of the spatial autocorrelation we run an OLS

regression of ES against income inequality and controls and then we test OLS residuals for spatial

autocorrelation Moranrsquos I over OLS residuals although significant is barely higher than zero (see

Appendix P) This means that the spatial effect itself is not a serious issue and can be handle for

instance including zone indicators variables hence we proceed to analyse the influence of income

inequality on LGE using non-spatial regression27

Cross‐sectionalanalysis

We start reporting censored regressions for each year in our panel Efficiency scores have

been rescaled to numbers between 0 and 100 to facilitate the interpretation of the results All

regressions include dummy variables for three of the four zones in which we have grouped Chilean

regions Results are in Table 3428 Income inequality shows a negative sign in all years which is

consistent with our hypothesis that inequality is negatively related to municipal efficiency

However only in three of the six years the effect of income inequality appears as statistically

27 In the case of having incorporated the spatial dimension the two most commonly used forms are including in the model the spatial lag of the dependent variable (spatial autoregressive model SAR) or the spatial lag of the error (spatial error model SEM) Following the method suggested by Anselin et al (1996) Lagrange Multiplier (LM) tests on the OLS residuals showed that the SAR model is preferred over the SEM Moranrsquos I LM tests and spatial regressions can be found in Appendix P 28 Regression results using OLS are in Appendix Q

84

significant Only the income level displays a significant and positive influence on efficiency for

the whole period A higher population density also consistently favours municipal efficiency On

the other hand as we expected a higher IDD makes it more difficult to achieve an efficient

performance29 Consistent with results in Pacheco et al (Pacheco et al 2013) municipal

efficiency show a significant an positive association with the MCF only in the first half of our

period of analysis with the second half showing an insignificant relationship

Table 34

Cross-sectional (censored) regressions

Paneldataanalysis

Estimation results for the six-year panel are reported in Table 35 Columns (1) and (2) show

the results for the pooled and random effects censored models only controlling for zone and year

29 The set of cross-sectional regressions was also run for each zone independently Results confirm that the set of significant contextual factors differs not only among years but also among geographic areas This support previous evidence suggesting that cross-sectional analysis should be treated with caution (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018b)

85

dummies Income inequality appears as non-significant Zone indicator variables confirm that

municipalities located in the Centre-South and South of the country display a lower average level

of efficiency compared to the Centre-North area Time dummies mostly show negative

coefficients This is a signal that shocks such as the GFC and the earthquake in 2010 may have

had a negative impact on efficiency but that impact was not permanent The results for the pooled

and RE models including the full set of controls are reported in columns (3) and (4) These results

show a significant negative influence of income inequality on LGE

When income inequality is instrumented by the variable pss_firms most of the coefficients

remain unchanged except for those associated with the income variables gini and log(income)

This result implies that our original model suffers for instance from the omitted variable bias

This means that LGE and income inequality are determined simultaneously by some variable not

included in our model Columns (5) and (6) show results using our instrument for income

inequality The ldquotrue coefficientrdquo of variable gini remains negative but the magnitude of the

relationship is higher The negative coefficient for gini implies on the one hand that municipalities

located in more unequal counties face more challenges to achieve an efficient management of

public resources On the other hand the coefficient in column (6) is close to one The interpretation

is that for each point of reduction in income inequality ceteris paribus LGE should increase in the

same proportion Next we discuss some of the results associated with the controls variables

Contrary to Pacheco et al (2013) income level has a positive coefficient meaning that richer

counties in terms of income per capita show higher efficiency This could be explained by higher

monitoring and increasing demands from citizen and taxpayers In addition it is expected a higher

efficiency in municipalities located in counties with a higher population density and those with a

lower proportion of land for agricultural use This result is mainly explained by municipalities

86

located in the Centre area The opposite happens with municipalities in the South implying that

they are too ldquosmallrdquo to take advantage of agglomeration economies There is also a limit for

agglomeration and scale economies which is shown by the negative coefficient of the variable

regcap although this coefficient loses its significance in the IV approaches30

Unexpectedly efficiency was found to be negatively associated with the variable education

This result is similar to the case of Czech municipalities (Šťastnaacute amp Gregor 2014) where

explanations include a weakened monitoring effect due to the fact that more educated citizens

present greater mobility and labour cost disadvantages for municipalities with better educated

labour force In Chile an additional explanation could be the relationship between education and

voter turnout Since 2012 voting is no longer mandatory in Chile This fact considerably reduced

voter turnout which in turn may have influenced the monitoring and control effect of more

educated voters For the case of variable IDD results show that local authorities in counties with

higher proportion of aging and young population (related to those in the active population) face a

greater challenge in their quest to offer public services efficiently

The influence of mcf is like that found by Pacheco et al (2013) with municipalities more

dependent on central transfers showing more efficiency31 Political influence captured by the

variable mayor did not show a significant effect This result is like other studies concluding that

the ideological position did not have a significant influence on efficiency (Benito et al 2010

Boetti et al 2009 Cordero Pedraja-Chaparro Pisaflores amp Polo 2017)

30 This negative coefficient suggests that the negative effects of agglomeration economies such as overcrowding pollution high cost of land and traffic congestion could predominate over the positive effects of scale economies in regional capitals 31 When the analysis is conducted for each zone independently MCF displays a negative influence in the North and Centre-North areas but a positive influence in the Centre-South and South areas These results confirm that on the one hand richer municipalities (those in the North and Centre-North) have less incentives for efficient management of their resources On the other hand results support the relevance of MCF helping poorer municipalities (those in the South) to reach their outcomes

87

Table 35

Panel data regressions

88

35 Conclusions

The trade-off between equity and efficiency is in the core of the economic discussion This

ldquoprinciplerdquo has been used by policymakers to prioritize the design of policies focused on economic

growth delaying those policies aimed at reducing economic inequalities This essay offers

empirical evidence of a negative relationship between inequality and efficiency that is a reduction

of income inequality could have positive effects on economic efficiency at least at the level of

local governments

We followed a traditional Two-Stage approach commonly used in the analysis of LGE We

compared cross-sectional and panel data results and we have added an instrumental variable

approach to give a causal interpretation to the link between efficiency and inequality We proposed

the use of a measure of natural resource dependence to instrumentalize the impact of income

inequality on LGE Given that our units of analysis are municipalities and not counties we argue

that our measure of NRD is correlated with income inequality and it does not have a direct

influence on LGE

We found that Chilean municipalities perform better than previous studies suggest

Municipal efficiency depicted significant levels of positive spatial autocorrelation and most of the

municipalities showed to be operating under increasing or decreasing returns to scale This would

imply that the policies generally used to improve efficiency such as amalgamation or cooperation

should be implemented observing the reality of each region and not as strategies at the national

level We also found that scale inefficiency explains a small proportion of the average total

inefficiency reason why the analysis of external factors that could affect the municipal efficiency

takes greater relevance

89

Income inequality plays an important part in explaining municipal efficiency In fact it was

found that reductions in income inequality could result in increases in municipal efficiency in a

similar proportion An unexpected finding was that the levels of education shows a negative

association with municipal performance This could be due to a low average level of education or

the existence of an omitted variable This variable could be the significant reduction in voting

turnout rates for local and national elections due to changes in the voting system during the period

of our analysis All in all our results may help to shed light on the potential consequences of

changes in contextual factors and the design of strategies aimed to increase municipal efficiency

in countries with similar characteristics to the Chilean economy For instance policies oriented to

take advantage of economies of scale can be formulated merging municipalities or establishing

networks in specific sectors such as education or health

Further work needs to be done both in measurement and in the explanation of differences in

municipal performance in Chile One area of future work will be to identify the factors that better

predict why municipalities operates under increasing decreasing or constant returns to scale

Multinomial logistic regression and the application of machine learning algorithms to SINIM data

sets appear as suitable methods for that purpose Intertemporal DEA (Drew amp Dollery 2015)

should be used to measure municipal efficiency capturing changes in total factor productivity In

addition municipalities operate under different levels of geographical authorities such as the

provincial mayor and the regional governor Hence it would be useful to know how each

municipality performs within each region-zone related to how performs to the whole country This

should be done conducting a metafrontier analysis (OrsquoDonnell Rao amp Battese 2008)

We have also identified through a cross sectional spatial exploratory analysis that on

average municipalities with similar levels of efficiency tend to cluster in space Regarding to

90

analyse the importance of contextual factors on municipal efficiency a deeper analysis should use

censored spatial models to check the significance of the spatial dimension in cross-sectional and

panel contexts Another interesting avenue for future research is associated with the negative

association found between LGE and education The significant reduction in votersacute turnout since

the law of automatic registration and voluntary voting in 2011 appears as a natural experiment to

analyse its effects on efficiency indicators such as municipal performance Incorporating variables

such as the voting turnout in each county or classifying municipalities based on individual

institutional political and economic characteristics could help to shed light on which of these

channels is the most relevant when analysing the impact of inequality on municipal efficiency

Finally we argued that an important part of the influence of income inequality over LGE

could be through its indirect effect on trust social capital and social cohesion The final essay will

delve deep in that relationship

91

Chapter 4 Social Cohesion Incivilities and Diversity

Evidence at the municipal level in Chile

41 Introduction

A deterioration in social cohesion could carry significant costs such as a reduction in

generalized trust between individuals and in institutions a society caught in a vicious circle of

inequality and citizens increasingly distanced from civic life (Uslaner 2011) A growing feeling

of frustration and discontentment can eventually translate into a social outbreak with uncertain

results This is precisely what have been happening in many countries around the world included

Chile

ldquoSocial cohesion is a state of affairs concerning both the vertical and the horizontal

interactions among members of society as characterized by a set of attitudes and norms that

includes trust a sense of belonging and the willingness to participate and help as well as their

behavioural manifestationsrdquo (Chan et al 2006) This definition highlights the multidimensionality

in the concept of social cohesion which has been measured using objective andor subjective

indicators of trust social norms solidarity willingness to participate in social and political groups

and feelings of belonging (Ariely 2014 Chan et al 2006) Multidimensionality also implies that

the impact of determinants of social cohesion such as economic and racial diversity could be

different for each of its various dimensions (Ariely 2014)

A common characteristic to all societies is that they are made up of different groups that

differ with respect to race ethnicity income religion language local identity etc The

92

Community Heterogeneity Thesis (Coffeacute amp Geys 2006) argues that individuals prefer to interact

with others that are like themselves Hence high levels of diversity particularly economic and

racial represent a complex scenario to maintain social cohesion One of the most common factors

adduced for social cohesion is income inequality with higher levels linked to lower levels of trust

(Ariely 2014 Rothstein amp Uslaner 2005)

Traditional measures of social cohesion may not be adequately capturing the deterioration

in social connections For instance measures of (lack of) trust include a strong subjective element

On the other hand proxies for social participation such as volunteering jobs or joining to social

organizations have not been supported by empirical evidence as a source of generalized social trust

(Rothstein amp Uslaner 2005) We proposed to use the rate of incivilities which we argue is a more

appropriate measure of the degree of worsening in the social context

Incivilities are those visible disorders in the public space that violate respectful social norms

and tend not to be treated as crimes by the criminal justice system There are two types of

incivilities social and physical Social incivilities include antisocial behaviours such as public

drinking noisy neighbours and fighting in public places Physical incivilities include among

others vandalism graffiti abandoned cars and garbage on the streets Because citizens and

political authorities cannot always distinguish between incivilities and crime they are usually

treated as an additional category of crime This implies that policies aimed to reduce incivilities

are generally based on punitive actions However theory and evidence on incivilities suggest that

factors explaining incivilities and crime could be different (Lewis 2017 Taylor 1999)

In Chile crime rates have shown a sustained downward trend after reaching its highest level

in 2011 On the other hand incivilities rate has shown a sustained upward trend which coincides

with the increasing victimization and feeling of insecurity in the population This has motivated

93

Chilean authorities based on the ldquoBroken Windows Theoryrdquo to propose new punitive actions (or

increase the severity of the current ones) to those who commit this type of antisocial behaviours

The ldquoBroken Windows Theoryrdquo states that higher rates of incivilities are a signal of social

disorganization which result in higher crime rates (J Q Wilson amp Kelling 1982) This is expected

to have consequences on familiesrsquo decisions such as moving away from public spaces or even

leaving their neighbourhoods

As far as we know there is no previous evidence about the potential causes of incivilities in

Chile Efforts to identify the factors explaining incivilities could help not only to reduce the risk

factors favouring violent and property crimes but also to guide interventions aimed to change

social behaviours and strengthen social cohesion in highly unequal societies Thus the main

contribution of the present study is to provide a deeper comprehension of the problem of incivilities

and how they can help to better understand the weakening of social cohesion that many

contemporary societies experience

We aim to offer the first evidence on the factors explaining the evolution and the differences

in incivilities rates in Chile We set up a panel for six years (2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and

2017) and 324 counties (1944 observations) We start exploring the evolution and geographical

distribution of incivilities Then we investigate whether economic and racial diversity after

controlling for other socioeconomic demographic and municipal characteristics can be regarded

as key predictors of incivilities

We use the Gini coefficient to proxy economic heterogeneity and the number of new visas

granted to foreigners as proportion of the county population as proxy for racial diversity The main

hypothesis is whether economic and racial diversity have a positive association with the rate of

incivilities In addition to the arguments regarding the ldquoCommunity Heterogeneity Thesisrdquo Taylor

94

(1999) and Skogan (1986 1999 2015) argue that incivilities are caused by inequality and the lack

of informal mechanisms of social control Based on the ldquoIncivilities Thesisrdquo the patterns of

incivilities should mirror the patterns of inequality (Taylor 1999) Then higher inequality should

be associated with higher physical and social vulnerability of the population This reduces social

control and increases social disorganization which triggers antisocial or negligent behaviours

Our main result reveals a strong positive association between the rate of incivilities and the

number of new visas granted per year The relationship with income inequality although also

positive seems to be less significant These findings give strong support to the ldquoCommunity

Heterogeneity Thesisrdquo and to a lesser extent to the ldquoIncivilities Thesisrdquo When the analysis is

disaggregated geographically racial diversity shows a clear positive effect The impact of income

inequality seems to be conditional depending on the level of income showing no effect in poorer

regions Results also show that the impact of economic and racial diversity differs by type of

incivility For example income inequality shows a strong association with ldquoStreet Tradingrdquo while

racial diversity with ldquoAlcohol Consumptionrdquo Two are the main policy implications On the one

hand a national strategy to address the problems associated with foreign immigration could help

to reduce incivilities For instance a joint effort between national and local authorities to curb

immigration and its distribution throughout the country On the other hand our results show that

the relationship between incivilities and economic diversity differs depending on the region or

geographical area Hence the impact on social cohesion of policies aimed to tackle economic

inequalities should be analysed in each specific context

The rate of incivilities also shows a negative association with the level of municipal financial

autonomy This implies that municipalities can effectively carry out policies to reduce incivilities

beyond the efforts of the central government Another important finding is that our results do not

95

support the hypothesis that a higher proportion of the young population is associated with higher

rates of incivilities Hence policies aimed to reduce incivilities should be focused on the causes of

incivilities rather than the criminalization of behaviours or stigmatization of specific population

groups

The structure of the chapter is as follows Section 42 outlines the relevant literature on social

cohesion and incivilities Section 43 describes the data variables and methodology and

establishes the hypotheses of the study Section 44 contains the results and discussions Section

45 presents the main conclusions

42 Related Literature

421 The Community Heterogeneity Thesis

The idea under ldquoThe Community Heterogeneity Thesisrdquo is that if individuals prefer to

interact with others who are similar to themselves in terms of income race or ethnicity high levels

of income inequality and racial diversity facilitate a context for lower tolerance and antisocial

behaviours lowering the ldquostaterdquo of social cohesion (Alesina 2000 Coffeacute amp Geys 2006 Letki

2008) Alessina and Ferrara (2002) give support to this hypothesis arguing that individuals have a

natural aversion to heterogeneity However the most popular explanation is the principle of

homophily people prefer to interact with others who share the same ethnic heritage have the same

social status and hence share experiences and tastes (Letki 2008 McPherson Smith-Lovin amp

Cook 2001 Tolsma et al 2009) For instance Delhey and Newton (2005) find for a sample of

60 countries that income inequality and ethnicity are strongly and negatively correlated with trust

Tolsma et al (2009) using data for Dutch neighbourhoods and municipalities find that social

cohesion is negatively and consistently affected by economic deprivation but not by ethnic

96

heterogeneity These authors also conclude that the effect of neighbourhood and municipal

characteristics on social cohesion depends on residentsrsquo income and educational level

Rothstein and Uslaner (2005) give two theoretical reasons why economic and racial diversity

should be causally related to social trust a key element of social cohesion First optimism about

the future makes less sense when there is more economic inequality which generally translates into

inequality of opportunities especially in areas such as education and the labour market Second

the distribution of resources and opportunities plays a key role in establishing the belief that people

share a common destiny and have similar fundamental values In highly unequal societies people

are likely to stick with their own kind Perceptions of injustice will reinforce negative stereotypes

of other groups making social trust and accommodation more difficult

Uslaner (2002 2011) and Uslaner and Brown (2005) find that high levels of inequality are

the single major factor driving down trust in people who are different from yourself Evidence for

USA finds that inequality is the strongest determinant of generalized trust over time (Rothstein amp

Uslaner 2005) Reducing inequality and then increasing generalized trust should have positive

consequences at the individual and aggregates levels At the individual level it may lead to greater

tolerance and more acts of altruism for people of different backgrounds At the aggregate level it

may lead to greater economic growth more redistribution from the rich to the poor and less

corruption (Uslaner 2002 2013) Letki (2008) argues that when neighbourhood socio-economic

context (apart from just an individualrsquos socioeconomic status) is considered it turns out to be the

main factor triggering negative attitudes and lack of trust in out-group members

The increasing diversity caused by immigration can also reduce the conditions necessary for

social cohesion (Ariely 2014 Holtug amp Mason 2010) Christel Kesler and Irene Bloemraad

(2010) find for nineteen advanced democracies between 1981 and 2000 that increasing migration

97

generally decreases trust civic engagement and political participation The authors also find that

in more equal countries with clear policies in favour of cultural minorities the negative effects of

migration are mitigated or even reversed Letki (2008) states that deprivation and disorder tend to

be strongly correlated with racial diversity Because we propose the use of the number of disorders

or antisocial behaviours known as ldquoincivilitiesrdquo as our measure of social cohesion we describe the

literature on incivilities in the next section

422 The literature on incivilities

The study of incivilities has been a continuing concern mainly for developed countries since

the 1980s The focus has changed from individual and psychological explanations to ecological

(contextual) and social explanations (Taylor 1999) The individual approach basically considered

perceptions of incivilities as an explanatory variable of fear of crime The ecological explanation

argues that indicators of economic disadvantage (eg income levels income inequality

unemployment rate and poverty rate) are the keys to understand a process of social disorganization

and lack of informal control These economic factors lead to higher rates of inappropriate or

negligent behaviours and ultimately to higher crime rates (Blau amp Blau 1982 Messner Rosenfeld

amp Baumer 2004 Phan Orsquobrien Mendolia amp Paloyo 2017 Sampson 1986)

The negative impact of incivilities is not merely reflected in its association with crime rates

(Skogan 2015) Physical and social incivilities could worsen neighbourhoods by affecting quality

of life perception of the environment and public and private behaviours Previous research has

indicated that a higher level of incivilities is associated with health problems (Branas et al 2011

Cohen et al 2000 Hill amp Angel 2005 Ross 2011 Ross amp Mirowsky 2001) greater

victimization and fear of crime (Brunton-Smith Jackson amp Sutherland 2014 Mijanovich amp

Weitzman 2003) and multiple negative economic effects For instance incivilities could be

98

related to a reduction in commercial activity lower investment in real estate reduction in house

prices (Skogan 2015) and population instability (Hipp 2010)

To describe the state of the art in the study of incivilities and their consequences Skogan

(2015) used the concept of untidiness to characterize the research on incivilities The study of

incivilities has had multiple approaches (economic ecological and psychological) Incivilities

have also been measured using multiple sources of information (police reports surveys trained

observation) which result in different measures (perceptions vs count data) However the question

about what specific factors have the strongest effect on incivilities has been overlooked and

perceptions about incivilities have been used mainly as a predictor of crime fear of crime and

victimization

There are two types of incivilities social and physical Social incivilities are a matter of

behaviour including groups of rowdy teens public drunkenness people fighting and street hassles

Physical incivilities involve visual signs of negligence and decay such as abandoned buildings

broken streetlights trash-filled lots and graffiti (Skogan 1999 2015 Taylor 1999) Three reasons

justify the distinction between physical and social incivilities First like multiple dimensions of

social cohesion different structural and social conditions could be responsible for different types

and categories of incivilities Second punitive sanctions are expected to have a greater impact on

physical than on social incivilities since the latter are more related to behaviours rooted in citizensrsquo

culture Third physical incivilities should be more related to absolute measures of economic

disadvantage (eg poverty or unemployment rates) and social incivilities to relative indicators of

economic disadvantage (eg such as income inequality) This line of research is based on the

ldquoincivilities thesisrdquo which states that to understand the distribution of disorders it is necesary to

analyse the patterns of structured inequalities (Skogan 1986 Taylor 1999)

99

423 The ldquoIncivilities Thesisrdquo

Incivilities theories began with a focus on psychological dynamics (Garofalo 1978) moved

forward to an interest in social psychological processes (J Q Wilson amp Kelling 1982) and finally

evolved into a focus on community dynamics and outcomes (Skogan 1999) Individual and group

behaviours in tandem with ecological features have been proposed as the key factors explaining

incivilities and their posterior influence on social control quality of life and more serious crime

(J Q Wilson amp Kelling 1982)

In terms of ecological factors particularly those related to economic conditions Skogan

(1986) was the first linking the distribution of incivilities to the patterns of structural inequality If

incivilities mirror inequality structure this will have consequences in residentsrsquo health and safety

due to its levels of vulnerability In addition structured inequality associated with the proportion

of the manufacturing sector (eg when fabrics tend to move from cities to farther areas) will be

related to higher social disorganization and differences between urban and rural areas (W J

Wilson 1996) In addition a persistent feeling of relative deprivation (persistently high levels of

income inequality) could lead to fellow inhabitants of the community to commit antisocial

behaviours showing their frustration with the current economic model

The literature on incivilities posits that their causes are different from those of crime (Lewis

2017) Unlike crime analysis especially property crimes information on the location where the

incivility takes place is the same as the location where the perpetrator resides To achieve a

comprehensive understanding of the different types of incivilities it is crucial to consider

incivilities data covering an entire territory and not just specific areas (Hooghe Vanhoutte

Hardyns amp Bircan 2010) If we add to this the availability of panel data it could be possible not

100

only to identify the main determinants of incivilities but also the causal mechanism from income

inequality towards incivilities rate

In Chile citizen security crime and delinquency are among the most significant issues for

citizens based on opinion polls Existing research has found weak evidence of a significant

relationship between crime and indicators of socio-economic disadvantage such as income

inequality and unemployment rate with significant effects only on property crime (Beyer amp

Vergara 2006 Nuntildeez Rivera Villavicencio amp Molina 2003 Rivera Gutieacuterrez amp Nuacutentildeez 2009)

Crime deterrence variables such as the probability of being caught or the number of police

resources have also shown ambiguous results (Beyer amp Vergara 2006 Rivera et al 2009

Vergara 2012) Evidence at the county level shows that crime is higher in urban counties those

with a lower mean income per capita and counties located in the North of the country In addition

at least half of the crimes reported in one county are perpetrated by criminals from other counties

(Rivera et al 2009) No studies could be found about the determinants of incivilities

4 3 Methodology

431 Period of analysis and data sample

Chile is a relatively small country in Latin America with a population of 18346018

inhabitants in 2017 The country is divided into 345 municipalities with on average 53104

inhabitants (median value 18705) Municipalities are the organ of the State Administration

responsible to solve local needs Municipalities are not only the relevant political and

administrative local unit of analysis but also they represent the feeling of lsquocommunityrsquo among

the inhabitants of each municipality (Hooghe et al 2010) Our data includes many sources of

101

heterogeneity among municipalities such as indicators of economic deprivation population

density demographic characteristics and whether the county is a regional or provincial capital

We use a sample of 324 municipalities covering most of the Chilean territory for the period

2006ndash17 Data on incivilities is obtained from the ldquoCentre of Studies and Analysis of Crimerdquo

which is part of the ldquoSubsecretaria de Prevencion del Delitordquo (SPD in its Spanish acronym) of the

Chilean government32 Information on income inequality and control variables is obtained from

the ldquoNational Socioeconomic Characterization Surveyrdquo (CASEN in its Spanish acronym) the

ldquoNational Institute of Statisticsrdquo (INE in its Spanish acronym) the ldquoNational Municipal

Information Systemrdquo (SINIM in its Spanish acronym) and the Immigration Department of the

Government of Chile Our panel only includes the years for which CASEN survey is available

2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017

432 Operationalisation of the response variable and exploratory analysis

Official Chilean records contain information for the total number of cases of incivilities per

year at the county level The number of cases is the sum of complains and detentions reported at

the police Our dependent variable 119894119899119888119894119907119894119897119894119905119894119890119904 correspond to the number of cases per year Due

to population differences comparisons between counties are made using the incivilities rate per

1000 population calculated as

119894119899119888119894119907_119903119886119905119890 lowast 1000 (41)

where 119894119899119888119894119907_119903119886119905119890 is the incivilities rate 119905 is the year 119894 the county and 119899 is the population of the

county per year

32 httpceadspdgovclestadisticas-delictuales

102

Figure 41 illustrates at the top the evolution of the total number (cases reported) of

incivilities and crimes at the country level for the period 2006-1733 At the bottom Figure 41

shows the evolution of the mean county rate per 1000 inhabitants We observe that both the number

of incivilities and the number of crimes has reached similar annual figures however average

county rates per 1000 population show different trends Crime rate displays a sustained fall after

reaching its pick in 2011 Incivilities average county rate which also reached a pick and posterior

drop in 2011 has recovered its upward trend since 2016 considerably exceeding the crime rate

Figure 41 Evolution number and rates of incivilities and crime (DMCS) in Chile 2006-2017

33 Crime refers to ldquocrimes of greater social connotationrdquo (DMCS in its Spanish acronym) which includes violent and property crimes

103

Chilean records classify incivilities in nine categories most of them associated with social

incivilities Summary statistics for the total and for each of the nine categories are presented in

Table 41 In addition Figure 42 shows the evolution of incivilities by category for the whole

period We see that the global trend in incivilities is mainly due to a substantial increase in ldquoStreet

Tradingrdquo and ldquoPublic Alcohol Consumptionrdquo A common element of Figures 41 and 42 is the

significant change in trend experienced by crimes and incivilities in 2011 That year the SPD

became dependent on the Ministry of Interior of the Chilean Government This event put the issue

of crime and delinquency within national priorities for the central government

Table 41

Summary statistics total count of incivilities and by category (full sample and period)

Unlike crime rates we do not expect significant cross-county spillover effects in incivilities

However the questions of where incivilities are concentrated and why they are there can be of

great interest (Skogan 2015) Figure 43 shows quantile maps for the rate of incivilities per 1000

inhabitants for the initial and final years in our panel

104

Figure 42 Evolution total number of incivilities by category

Figure 43 Spatial distribution of incivilities rate per 1000 inhabitants (2006 vs 2017)

105

We observe that the range of values has increased significantly from 2006 to 2017 but the

spatial distribution remains almost unchanged On the one hand high incivilities rates in the North

could be associated with the mining activity On the other hand high rates in the Centre area

(where the countyrsquos capital is located) could be related to the higher population density and the

concentration of the economic activity34

To see how the different types of incivilities are distributed throughout the country we have

grouped those similar categories in four groups ldquoPublic Damagerdquo (ldquoPublic Disturbsrdquo ldquoPublic

Damagerdquo ldquoOtherrdquo) ldquoThreatsrdquo (ldquoPublic Fightrdquo ldquoThreatsrdquo and ldquoAnnoying Noisesrdquo) ldquoAlcohol

Consumptionrdquo (ldquoPublic Alcohol Consumptionrdquo and ldquoDrunkennessrdquo) and ldquoStreet Tradingrdquo This

distinction in groups could be relevant if we expect different patterns and different effects of

community heterogeneity on social cohesion among counties For instance we expect higher

levels of Public Damage in big urban cities Street trading is more likely in urban cities but also in

tourist areas The spatial distribution of these four groups for the six-year-average rate per 1000

inhabitants can be found in Appendix R

433 Measures of community heterogeneity and control variables

Social cohesion income inequality and racial diversity are all ldquocommunityrdquo (not individual)

characteristics Thus to understand their relationship we need aggregated data at least at the

county-municipal level With more disaggregated data like at the suburbs level the required

heterogeneity among groups of citizens is lost (Wilkinson 1999) Like Coffeacute and Geys (2006) we

use the Gini coefficient to capture economic heterogeneity However instead of a measured for

34 We also analysed the spatial distribution of crime rates In general areas with high levels of incivilities not necessarily are associated with high levels of crime This could imply that factors explaining incivilities and crime are different

106

the diversity of nationalities we use the proportion of foreign population to capture racial

heterogeneity Income data is obtained from the CASEN survey The Gini coefficient is calculated

for each county and included through the variable gini Racial heterogeneity is included through

the variable foreign which is the annual number of new VISAS granted to foreigners as a

proportion of the county population Chile has experienced a significant increase in immigration

since 2011 Immigration has been concentrated in the metropolitan region and mining regions in

the North of the country We expect a positive relationship between immigration and incivilities

although as with the relationship between immigration and crime the foundations for this

hypothesis are not strong (Hooghe et al 2010 Sampson 2008)

Economic development is another explanation for social cohesion frequently appealed to

explain trust with wealthier societies considered to exhibit higher levels of trust (Delhey amp

Newton 2005) In this study we include the natural log of the mean household income per capita

log(income) We also include the poverty rate poverty and the unemployment rate

unemployment Unlike the variable log(income) these variables are expected to be positively

associated with the number of incivilities When a relative indicator of economic heterogeneity

such as income inequality is included as determinant of social cohesion we should expect less

effect from absolute indicators of economic disadvantage such as poverty and unemployment rates

(Hooghe et al 2010 Tolsma et al 2009)

Among demographic variables the percentage of inhabitants between 10 and 24 years old is

included through the variable youth The variable women defined as the proportion of the female

population in each county is also included Variable youth is expected to have an ambiguous effect

Although young people have lower victimization and report rates they also represent the group

more likely to commit antisocial behaviours when a community has a low capacity of self-

107

regulation (eg when there is low parental supervision) The female population is associated with

a higher report of incivilities related to the male population

It is argued that crime and incivilities are essentially urban problems (Christiansen 1960

Wirth 1938) We include the variable log(density) defined as the log of population density (the

number of inhabitants divided by the area of each county in square kilometres) and a dummy

variable capital indicating whether a county is an administrative capital (provincial or regional)

Two additional variables are included to capture the level of informal social control exerted

by families living in each municipality First the variable education which is defined as the

average years of education of people over 15 years old Second the variable housing which capture

the proportion of families which are owners of their housing unit Although education and housing

are related to both the possibility of reporting and committing an incivility we expect a negative

association with the rate of incivilities

In Chile crime has been mainly a problem faced by the police and the Central Government

Administration To control for current law enforcement policies we include the variable

deterrence defined as the number of arrests as a proportion of the total number of incivilities cases

In addition municipalities can develop their own initiatives to deal with crime and incivilities

depending on their capacity to generate its own resources The level of financial autonomy from

central transfers is captured by the variable autonomy This variable is obtained from SINIM and

it is defined as the proportion of the budget revenue of each municipality that comes from its own

permanent sources of revenues A categorical variable mayor is also included This variable

indicates whether the municipality mayor is supported by the ldquoLEFTrdquo or the ldquoRIGHTrdquo political

parties (related to those ldquoINDEPENDENTrdquo mayors)

108

Table 42 presents descriptive statistics for our measures of income and racial heterogeneity

and the set of numeric control variables The Pearson correlation among these variables is shown

in Appendix S

Table 42

Summary statistics numeric explanatory variables

434 Methods

The annual count of incivilities as is characteristic for count data is highly concentrated in

a relatively small range of values In addition the distribution is right-skewed due to the presence

of important outliers (counties with a high number of incivilities) Figure 44 shows the

distribution of the six-year average number of incivilities for each of the 15 regions in Chile35 We

observe that regions differ in the number of counties in which they are divided In addition

counties within each region show important differences in the number of incivilities For instance

35 Regions are ordered from left to right and from top to bottom in the way they are geographically distributed from North to South So the northernmost region of the country is the ldquoXVrdquo and the southernmost region is the ldquoXIIrdquo The Metropolitan region (where the countryrsquos capital is located) is region ldquoXIIIrdquo in the centre of the country (see Appendix C)

109

excepting the Metropolitan region ldquoXIIIrdquo most counties in regions located in the centre of the

country (middle row in Figure 44) show a range of incivilities between 0 and 2000 The number

of incivilities is considerably lower in counties located in the northern (top row in Figure 44) and

southern (bottom row in Figure 44) regions of the country compared to regions in the centre of

the country It also seems clear from Figure 44 that the number of incivilities does not follow a

normal distribution

Figure 44 Annual average number of incivilities per county

The number of incivilities can be better described by a Poisson distribution In this case the

number of incivilities is ldquothe countrdquo and the number of incivilities per year is ldquothe rate per unit

timerdquo We are interested in modelling the average number of incivilities per year usually called 120582

as a function of a set of contextual factors to explain differences in incivilities between and within

110

counties The main characteristic of the Poisson distribution is that the mean is equal to the

variance This implies that as the mean rate for a Poisson variable increases the variance also

increases The main implication is we cannot use OLS to model 120582 as a function of the set of

contextual factors because the equal variance assumption in linear regression is violated

The rate of incivilities between counties is not directly comparable due to population

differences We expect counties with more people to have more reports of incivilities since there

are more people who could be affected To capture differences in population which is called the

exposure of our response variable 120582 it is necessary to include a term on the right side of our model

called an offset We will use the log of the county population in thousands as our offset36

Additionally similar to the case of crime data incivilities show a significant degree of

overdispersion (variance higher than the mean) suggesting that there is more variation in the

response than the Poisson model implies37 We also model and regress incivilities assuming a

Negative Binomial distribution to address overdispersion An advantage of this approach is that it

introduces a dispersion parameter in addition to 120582 which gives the model more flexibility38

Considering as the response variable the count of incivilities per year the model can be

expressed as follow

120582 119890119909119901 120573 120573 119892119894119899119894 120573 119891119900119903119890119894119892119899 119883120574 120572 120579 (42)

36 If we think of 120582 as the average number of incivilities per year then represents the number per 1000

inhabitants so that the yearly count is adjusted to be comparable across counties of different sizes Adjusting the yearly count by population is equivalent to adding 119897119900119892 1199011199001199011199061198971198861199051198941199001198991000 to the right-hand side of the regression equation 37 Without adjusting for overdispersion we use incorrect artificially small standard errors leading to artificially small p-values for model coefficients 38 The Negative Binomial model posits selecting a 120582 (average number of incivilities) for each county and then generating a count using a Poisson random variable with the selected 120582 With this approach the counts will be more dispersed than would be expected for observations based on a single Poisson variable with rate 120582

111

where 120582 is the rate of incivilities 119883 is our vector of controls 120572prime119904 are county-specific constants

and 120579prime119904 are time-specific constants Accounting for differences in county population we have

119890119909119901 120573 120573 119892119894119899119894 119883120574 120572 120579 (43)

where 119901119900119901119906119897119886119905119894119900119899 is the county population per year Hence the model to be estimated using

Maximum Likelihood Estimation (MLE) is

119897119900119892 120582 120573 120573 119892119894119899119894 119883120574 120572 120579 119897119900119892 (44)

Finally to account for different effects depending on the type of incivilities we also run

equation (44) for each of the four groups of incivilities defined in section (432)

435 Hypotheses

Based on the community heterogeneity hypothesis the relationship between social cohesion

and diversity should be stronger for lower levels of income and less educated groups of people

(Tolsma et al 2009) Hence contrary to evidence for developed and more equal countries we

expect a significant positive association for the Chilean case where more than 50 of the

population is economically vulnerable (OECD 2017)

The main hypotheses to be tested in this essay is whether the number of incivilities is

positively associated with the level of economic and racial heterogeneity at the county level We

start analysing this association for the full sample and period Next we analyse whether the

relationship between incivilities and our measures of diversity differs by geographic area (region

or zone) Finally we check whether the effect of economic and racial diversity is different

depending on the group of incivilities

112

44 Results and Discussion

Overall our results show that the rate of incivilities displays a stronger and more significant

relationship with racial diversity than with economic heterogeneity This association differs for

different geographic areas and for different types of incivilities Absolute economic indicators

except for income show a significant but small effect Increases in the average levels of income

or education and more financial autonomy for municipalities seem to be effective ways to reduce

the rate of incivilities

We estimate equation (44) assuming that the number of incivilities follows a Poisson

distribution Regional and temporal heterogeneity are captured through the inclusion of dummy

variables for five years (with 2006 as the reference year) and fourteen regional dummies (with

region XIII as the reference region) Results are reported in Table 4339 This table is structured in

two blocks of regressions pooled models in columns (1)-(4) and fixed-effects models in columns

(5)-(8)40 The first column in each block only includes economic indicators relative and absolute

trying to test which ones are more relevant and whether incivilities tend to mirror income

inequality (the ldquoincivilities thesisrdquo) The second column adds the variable foreign to account for

the effect of racial diversity (Letki 2008) The third column includes education to check whether

the association between economic and racial diversity with social cohesion changes (gets less

significant) when we control for educational level (Tolsma et al 2009) The final column in each

block corresponds to the full model specification which includes the rest of controls

39 Pooled estimations were obtained using the R command glm() and compared with results obtained from the command poisson in STATA 15 Fixed effects and random effects models were estimated using the STATA command xtpoisson Negative Binomial models were estimated using the command glmnb() in the MASS package for R and commands nbreg and xtnbreg in STATA 15 Results for Negative Binomial regressions are in Appendix T 40 We have omitted results with random effects due to the literature on panel count data models suggest that the most robust estimator is Poisson regression with Fixed Effects (Santos Silva amp Tenreyro 2010 2011)

113

Table 43

Poisson regressions

114

The positive and significant coefficient for the variable gini besides being small it becomes

insignificant in the fixed effects specification which includes the full set of controls This result

does not seem to be enough evidence to support our hypothesis that more unequal counties display

higher rates of incivilities On the other hand racial diversity through the variable foreign shows

a consistent positive association with the rate of incivilities41 Together coefficients for gini and

foreign seems to support the ldquocommunity heterogeneity thesisrdquo (Letki 2008) but not the

ldquoincivilities thesisrdquo (Skogan 1999) To check this finding we run the pooled full model

specification for each region and results are shown in Table 44 where regions have been ordered

from North to South The sign of the coefficient of the variable gini differs for different regions

Moreover the relationship is insignificant in some of the most unequal regions which are in the

South of the country (VIII IX and XIV) This result rejects the hypothesis that incivilities mirror

structural income inequalities For the variable foreign 12 out of 15 regions confirm the positive

association with the rate of incivilities42

We also run our pooled full model separately for each group of incivilities defined at the end

of section (432) Income inequality keeps its significant but small association with each group of

incivilities (see Table 45) Our measure of racial diversity shows a stronger association with

ldquoAlcohol Consumptionrdquo related to ldquoPublic Damagerdquo and ldquoThreatsrdquo The link with ldquoStreet Tradingrdquo

appears as non-significant These results support our general finding that on the one hand racial

heterogeneity exert a more significant influence on the rate of incivilities than economic

41 To get the effects of the variables gini and foreign over the rate of incivilities per 1000 inhabitants we need to exponentiate their coefficients Thus an increase in one unit in the variable gini increases the rate of incivilities per 1000 inhabitantsrdquo in 1005 times (e^0005) in the pooled full model Similarly an increase in one point in variable foreign is expected to increase the ldquorate of incivilities per 1000 inhabitantsrdquo in 10876 times (e^0084) in the full pooled model and 10471 (e^0046) times in the full Fixed Effects model 42 Given that depending on the geographic location regions share certain characteristics the model was also run clustering regions in 4 zones (see Figure 31 in chapter 3) Results by zone are in Appendix U

115

heterogeneity On the other hand results confirm our hypothesis that the effect of diversity is

different for different types of incivilities

Table 44 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson models by region

Back to our general results in Table 43 the significant and negative coefficient of the

income variable and to a lesser extent the significant and positive coefficients of poverty and

unemployment provide evidence that absolute rather than relative economic indicators may be

more important explanations of the rate of incivilities This is opposite to evidence for the analysis

116

of crime rates such as in Hoodge (2010) and support the idea that determinants of incivilities are

different from those of crime Our results are also opposite to those for Dutch municipalities where

economic indicators turned out to be more important than ethnic heterogeneity (Tolsma et al

2009) The coefficient for the variable log(income) could be interpreted as counties with an income

level under the average face higher problems of antisocial behaviours such as incivilities In

addition as the income level moves far away from its average low level the problem of incivilities

is less relevant43 In terms of policy implications only those policies that achieve a significant

increase in the average level of county income seem to be effective in reducing incivilities and

strengthening social cohesion

Table 45 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson model by incivility group

43 We ran our model splitting the sample of counties in quintiles based on their income level The coefficient for the variable gini only showed a significant (and positive) coefficient for the second third and fourth quintile A non-significant coefficient for the first quintile could imply that other types of inequalities (eg health education) are more relevant in the poorest counties In the case of the fifth quintile (the richest group of counties) they have better facilities in terms of infrastructure police resources self-protection etc which could reduce the potential triggers of incivilities

117

The inclusion of the variable education significantly improved the goodness of fit of the

models and did not generate significant changes in the coefficients of our measures of economic

and racial diversity This result rejects the proposition that the relationship between social

cohesion and diversity becomes less strong when controlled by education (Tolsma et al 2009)

Additionally it highlights the topic of education as a relevant determinant of the rate of incivilities

and social cohesion

Among control variables there are also some important results Opposite to what we

expected the variable youth shows a negative or non-significant coefficient Although this result

could be due to the lack of ldquophysical incivilitiesrdquo in Chilean records it indicates that it is incorrect

to stereotype this group as the main responsible for high incivilities rates The significant and

negative coefficient of the variable autonomy in the fixed effects specification could also have

important policy implications It is a signal that local governments can play an important role in

reducing incivilities or complementing the efforts from the central government Another

interesting result is the significant coefficient of the variable housing The latter finding is

particularly important in the sense that a negative sign supports public policies oriented to increase

homeownership as effective ways to improve social cohesion However the small magnitude of

the coefficient that even showed the opposite sign in some model specifications could be

explained for the high level of segregation that these policies have generated in Chilean society

As mentioned in the Introduction and Literature Review so far only a few studies have

used measures of disorders or incivilities as dependent variable to explain changes in social

cohesion (Skogan 2015) In addition there is no evidence in Chile analysing the determinants of

incivilities separately from those of crimes The importance of our results on identifying the

importance of economic and racial diversity on social cohesion lies mainly in its generality An

118

important number of countries all around the world share a similar context characterized by high

levels of inequality and an explosive increase in immigration These countries are also

experiencing a worsening in social cohesion which increases the risk of a social outburst

4 5 Conclusions

The main goal of this essay was to determine whether differences in incivilities at the county

level mirror differences in income distribution and racial diversity Previous literature suggests a

positive and strong association between social cohesion and indicators of economic disadvantage

relative deprivation and racial diversity (Letki 2008 Tolsma et al 2009 Uslaner amp Brown 2005)

While not all our results were significant they showed helpful insights about how and where

economic and racial diversity are more likely to influence the rate of incivilities and social

cohesion

We used data for the period 2006ndash17 economic heterogeneity was measured through the

Gini coefficient at the county level and racial heterogeneity was proxied by the number of granted

visas to foreigners as proportion of county population We found strong evidence of a significant

and positive association between the rate of incivilities and racial diversity but not with income

inequality Contrary to previous evidence at the municipal level (Coffeacute amp Geys 2006 Tolsma et

al 2009) in general our results give support for the ldquohomophily principlerdquo and the ldquocommunity

heterogeneity hypothesisrdquo However results also showed that the effect of economic and racial

diversity varies throughout the Chilean regions and for the different types of incivilities

We also found that policies aimed at controlling the behaviour of young people did not have

strong empirical support In terms of the role that local governments may have in facing the

119

growing problem of incivilities we found evidence that efforts managed from the municipalities

can be an important complement to those from the central government

Future research should go further on the role of local authorities on incivilities and social

cohesion On the one hand municipalities could have a direct impact on social cohesion through

the implementation of programs complementary to those of central authorities oriented to reduce

incivilities and crime On the other hand social cohesion could be indirectly affected when local

authorities display an inefficient performance supplying public services to citizens or they are

recognized as corrupted institutions We suggest that policy makers from central government

should give local authorities a greater role in fighting antisocial behaviours and crime Evaluating

programs in specific municipalities could help to elucidate the causal effect of for instance higher

fiscal autonomy on the rate of incivilities

Another interesting area for future work will be to analyse how housing policies have

contributed to the phenomenon of segregation of Chilean society and in the process of weakening

social cohesion Finally our main result highlights the need of a deeper analysis of the impact that

foreign immigration is having in Chile For instance disaggregating information by country of

origin and the reasons why immigrants are arriving to the country or specific regions will surely

help to understand the impacts of immigration

120

Chapter 5 Conclusions

This thesis investigated in three essays the issue of income inequality in Chile using county-

level data for the period 2006-2017 The first essay supplied empirical evidence about the

importance of the degree of dependence on natural resources in terms of employment in explaining

cross-county differences in income inequality The second essay analysed the potential causal

effect that income inequality has on the level of technical efficiency of local governments

providing public goods and services Lastly the third essay studied the relationship between social

cohesion measured through the number of antisocial behaviours classified as ldquoincivilitiesrdquo and

the levels of income and racial heterogeneity

Findings from the first essay support the idea that the endowment of natural resources plays

a significant role in explaining income inequality in Chile However contrary to what most

theoretical and empirical evidence postulates our findings showed a robust negative association

between the two variables This means that the reduction experienced in Chile in the degree of

dependence on natural resources in terms of employment has contributed to the persistence of high

levels of income inequality The exploratory analysis indicated that income inequality shows a

general clustering process characterized by a significant and positive spatial autocorrelation

Regarding the previous evidence for Chile (Paredes et al 2016) the regression analysis confirmed

the relevance of the spatial dimension of income inequality through a process of spatial

heterogeneity giving less support to the existence of a process of spatial dependence (spillover

effect) in the variable itself

121

Essay 2 studied the potential trade-off between efficiency and equity analysing the influence

of income inequality on the efficiency of local governments at the municipal level To identify the

causal effect of income inequality on municipal efficiency we proposed the use of the proportion

of firms in the primary sector as an instrument for income inequality Findings confirmed our

hypothesis that efficiency is lower in more unequal counties This result suggests the non-existence

of the trade-off between equity and efficiency Hence policies intended to reduce inequality could

help to increase efficiency at least at the level of municipal local governments

The third essay analysed how social cohesion proxied by the rate of incivilities is associated

with the levels of economic diversity proxied by income inequality and the levels of racial

diversity proxied by the number of new visas grated as proportion of the county population

Findings gave strong support to the hypothesis that the rate of incivilities is positively related to

racial diversity and to a lesser extent to economic diversity In addition the rate of incivilities

appears negatively related to the degree of financial autonomy of municipalities This means that

local governments can effectively contribute to the reduction of incivilities which could help

reduce victimization and crime rates ultimately strengthening social cohesion

Taken together findings from essays 2 and 3 highlight the important role that income

inequality could play in other relevant economic and social dimensions These findings add to the

understanding of the potential consequences of income inequality particularly in natural resource

rich countries with persistently high levels of inequality

The present study has mainly investigated income inequality at the county level In addition

Chilean municipalities play an important role providing ldquoservices to peoplerdquo so our findings could

be applied in other highly unequal countries with a high degree of dependence on natural resources

and local governments with similar responsibilities For instance in Latin America apart from

122

Chile and Brazil there are no studies on the efficiency of local governments Other limitations are

associated with the availability of information For instance important indicators such as GDP per

capita are only available at the regional level and information of incomes is not available annually

In addition given the heterogeneity among municipalities some type of grouping of municipalities

should be performed before looking for causal relationships or conducting program evaluation

Despite these limitations we believe this study could be the basis for different strands of future

research on the topic of inequality local government efficiency and social cohesion

It was stated in chapter 2 based on the resource curse hypothesis literature there are two

elements that determine whether NR are a curse or blessing in terms of socioeconomic outcomes

First the curse is more likely in countries with weak political and governance institutions Second

different types of resources affect institutions differently with resources that are concentrated in

space so-called ldquopointrdquo resources tend to impair institutions while ldquodiffuserdquo resources do not

(Deacon 2011 Isham Woolcock Pritchett amp Busby 2005) Our results showed a negative

relationship between income inequality and our measure of natural resource dependence even after

controlling for zone fixed effects and for the level of government expenditure This result could

be interpreted as a signal that NR has a direct effect on income inequality in addition to the indirect

impact through market or institutional channels Using other potential institutional transmission

channels will shed light about the true effect that the endowment of natural resources has over

income inequality Variables that could capture these institutional channels include the level of

employment in the public sector measures of rule of law and corruption and changes in the

creation of new business in the secondary and tertiary sectors related to the primary sector

Based on results from chapter 3 most of the municipalities show scale inefficiencies One

immediate area for future work will involve using our set of contextual factors to predict the status

123

of municipalities in terms of scale inefficiencies Defining as dependent variable whether a

municipality shows constant decreasing or increasing returns to scale we could run a multinomial

logistic regression to predict municipal status For instance we would expect that a one-unit

increase in the Gini coefficient should increase the probability of scale inefficiencies (increasing

or decreasing returns to scale rather than constant returns to scale) Because the aim in this case

would be predicting a certain result in terms of returns to scale the next step should involve to

split the full sample in training and testing data sets and to use some resampling methods such as

bootstrapping This will allow us to evaluate the performance and accuracy of our model

predictions using different random samples of municipalities Results from Machine Learning

algorithms will help us to assess the generalizability of our results to other data sets

Future work should also benefit greatly by using data on different Latin American countries

to (1) compare the responsibilities of local governments (2) select a common set of inputs and

output to evaluate LGE (3) identify the relevance of scales inefficiencies in explaining differences

in performance and (4) analyse the influence of contextual characteristics over LGE Differences

in the main primary sector activity in each country such as oil in Brazil mining in Chile or Coffee

in Colombia could be responsible for differences in LGE among countries These differences could

be associated with sources of revenue management of expenditure and definitions of outputs or

contextual effects such as corrupted institutions or the delay in the development of other sectors

such as manufacturing or services

To delve deep on reasons explaining the social crisis experienced by Chilean society and

other countries one area of future work will be to analyse the relationship between diversity and

the origins of social revolutions Based on Tiruneh (2014) the three most important factors that

explain the onset of social revolutions are economic development regime type and state

124

ineffectiveness Interesting questions include whether the characteristics of Chilean context at the

end of 2019 are enough to trigger the transformation of the political and socioeconomic system

Social revolutions particularly violent revolutions are less likely in more democratic educated

and wealthy societies So it would be relevant to identify the factors explaining the violence that

has characterized the social crisis in Chile Finally the democratic regime has been maintained in

the last decades with changes between left and right governments This could imply that more

important than the regime has been the efficiency or ineffectiveness of the governments to satisfy

the needs of the population

Future work should also cover the disaggregation of information regarding foreign

population in terms of the reasons for new granted visas and the country of origin Official data

allows us to disaggregate whether the benefit is permanent (students and employees with contract)

or temporary Furthermore most of the new visas were traditionally granted to neighbouring

countries (Peru and Bolivia) a trend that has changed in the recent years to include countries such

as Colombia Venezuela and Haiti An analysis of how economic and social indicators have been

affected by changes in the composition of foreigners their reasons for immigrating to the country

and their geographical distribution have implications for economic policy at both the national and

local levels At the national level such analysis should be a key input when proposing changes to

the national immigration policy At the local level it could help define the role of municipalities

to assess the benefits and challenges of immigration These challenges are mainly related to the

provision of public goods and services such as health and education which in Chile are the

responsibility of the municipalities

The findings of this thesis suggest that policymakers should encourage policies that reduce

income inequality The key role that municipalities could play to strengthen social cohesion and

125

the increasingly important role that foreign population is acquiring in most modern societies are

also interesting avenues for future research However the picture is still incomplete and more

research is needed incorporating other dimensions of inequality This is essential if we want to

understand the reasons that could have triggered the social outbursts experienced by various

economies across the globe

126

Bibliography

Acemoglu D (1995) Reward structures and the allocation of talent European Economic Review 39(1) 17ndash33 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg1010160014-2921(94)00014-Q

Acemoglu D (2002) Technical Change Inequality and the Labor Market Journal of Economic Literature 40(1) 7ndash72 httpsdoiorg1012570022051026976

Acemoglu D Aghion P amp Violante G L (2001) Deunionization Technical Change and Inequality Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 55(1) 229ndash264 httpsdoiorg101016S0167-2231(01)00058-6

Acemoglu D Johnson S amp Robinson J A (2001) The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development An Empirical Investigation The American Economic Review 91(5) 1369ndash1401 httpsdoiorg101257aer9151369

Acemoglu D amp Robinson J A (2002) The Political Economy of the Kuznets Curve Review of Development Economics 6(2) 183ndash203 httpsdoiorg1011111467-936100149

Afonso A amp Fernandes S (2006) Measuring local government spending efficiency Evidence for the Lisbon region Regional Studies 40(1) 39ndash53 httpsdoiorg10108000343400500449937

Afonso A amp Fernandes S (2008) Assessing and explaining the relative efficiency of local government The Journal of Socio-Economics 37(5) 1946ndash1979 httpsdoiorg101016jsocec200703007

Afonso A Schuknecht L amp Tanzi V (2010) Income distribution determinants and public spending efficiency Journal of Economic Inequality 8(3) 367ndash389 httpsdoiorg101007s10888-010-9138-z

Akita T (2003) Decomposing regional income inequality in China and Indonesia using two-stage nested Theil decomposition method The Annals of Regional Science 37(1) 55ndash77 httpsdoiorg101007s001680200107

Alesina A (2000) Participation in heterogeneous communities The Quarterly Journal of Economics 115(3) 847ndash904 httpsdoiorg101162003355300554935

Alesina A amp La Ferrara E (2002) Who trusts others Journal of Public Economics 85(2) 207ndash234 httpsdoiorg101016S0047-2727(01)00084-6

Allcott H amp Keniston D (2014) Dutch Disease or Agglomeration The Local Economic Effects of Natural Resource Booms in Modern America (N W P N 20508 Ed) NBER Working Paper No 20508 (Vol w20508) NBER Working Paper No 20508 NBER Working Paper No 20508 httpsdoiorgNBER Working Paper No 20508

Andersen T M amp Maibom J (2020) The big trade-off between efficiency and equitymdashis it there Oxford Economic Papers 72(2) 391ndash411

127

Anselin L (1988) Spatial econometrics methods and models (Vol 4) DordrechtBoston Kluwer Academic Publishers

Anselin L amp Bera A K (1998) Spatial dependence in linear regression models with an introduction to spatial econometrics Statistics Textbooks and Monographs (Vol 155)

Anselin L Bera A K Florax R amp Yoon M J (1996) Simple diagnostic tests for spatial dependence Regional Science and Urban Economics 26(1) 77ndash104 httpsdoiorg1010160166-0462(95)02111-6

Antonelli M A amp De Bonis V (2018) The efficiency of social public expenditure in European countries a two-stage analysis Applied Economics 1ndash14 httpsdoiorg1010800003684620181489522

Aragoacuten F M amp Rud J P (2013) Natural Resources and Local Communities Evidence from a Peruvian Gold Mine American Economic Journal Economic Policy 5(2) 1ndash25 httpsdoiorg101257pol521

Ariely G (2014) Does Diversity Erode Social Cohesion Conceptual and Methodological Issues Political Studies 62(3) 573ndash595 httpsdoiorg1011111467-924812068

Armstrong H amp Taylor J (2000) Regional economics and policy (3rd ed) Oxford Blackwell

Aroca P amp Atienza M (2011) Economic implications of long distance commuting in the Chilean mining industry Resources Policy 36(3) 196ndash203 httpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201103004

Aroca P amp Bosch M (2000) Crecimiento convergencia y espacio en las regiones chilenas 1960 - 1998 Estudios de Economiacutea 27 199ndash224 Retrieved from httprepositoriouchileclbitstreamhandle2250127853Patricio_Arocapdfsequence=1

Ashworth J Geys B Heyndels B amp Wille F (2014) Competition in the political arena and local government performance Applied Economics 46(19) 2264ndash2276 httpsdoiorg101080000368462014899679

Atkinson A B (2015) Inequality What Can Be Done Harvard University Press

Auty R (1993) Sustaining development in mineral economies the resource curse thesis London [ua] Routledge

Auty R (2001) Resource abundance and economic development (R World Institute for Development Economics Ed) Oxford Oxford University Press

Badeeb R A Lean H H amp Clark J (2017) The evolution of the natural resource curse thesis A critical literature survey Resources Policy 51 123ndash134 httpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201610015

Balaguer-Coll M T Brun-Martos M I Maacuterquez-Ramos L amp Prior D (2019) Local government efficiency determinants and spatial interdependence Applied Economics

128

51(14) 1478ndash1494 httpsdoiorg1010800003684620181527458

Balaguer-Coll M T amp Prior D (2009) Short- and long-term evaluation of efficiency and quality An application to Spanish municipalities Applied Economics 41(23) 2991ndash3002 httpsdoiorg10108000036840701351923

Banker R D Charnes A amp Cooper W W (1984) Some models for estimating technical and scale inefficiencies in data envelopment analysis Management Science 30(9) 1078ndash1092

Beine M Coulombe S amp Vermeulen W N (2015) Dutch Disease and the Mitigation Effect of Migration Evidence from Canadian Provinces The Economic Journal 125(589) 1574ndash1615 httpsdoiorg101111ecoj12171

Benito B Bastida F amp Garciacutea J A (2010) Explaining differences in efficiency an application to Spanish municipalities Applied Economics 42(4) 515ndash528 httpsdoiorg10108000036840701675560

Berg A amp Ostry J (2011) Equality and efficiency Finance amp Development 48(3) 12ndash15

Berg A amp Ostry J (2017) Inequality and Unsustainable Growth Two Sides of the Same Coin IMF ECONOMIC REVIEW 65(4) 792ndash815 httpsdoiorg101057s41308-017-0030-8

Beyer H amp Vergara R (2006) Delincuencia en Chile Determinantes y rol de las poliacuteticas puacuteblicas Instituto de Economiacutea UC

Blanco L amp Grier R (2012) Natural resource dependence and the accumulation of physical and human capital in Latin America Resources Policy 37(3) 281ndash295 httpsdoiorghttpdoiorg101016jresourpol201201005

Blau J R amp Blau P M (1982) The cost of inequality Metropolitan structure and violent crime American Sociological Review 114ndash129

Boetti L Piacenza M amp Turati G (2009) Fiscal decentralization and spending efficiency of local governments An Empirical Investigation on a Sample Of 4

Boix C amp Posner D (1998) Social capital Explaining its origins and effects on government performance British Journal Of Political Science 28 686ndash693

Borge L E Parmer P amp Torvik R (2015) Local natural resource curse JOURNAL OF PUBLIC ECONOMICS 131 101ndash114 httpsdoiorg101016jjpubeco201509002

Borger B Kerstens K Moesen W amp Vanneste J (1994) Explaining differences in productive efficiency An application to Belgian municipalities Public Choice 80(3) 339ndash358 httpsdoiorg101007BF01053225

Bourguignon F amp Morrisson C (1990) Income distribution development and foreign trade A cross-sectional analysislowast European Economic Review 34(6) 1113ndash1132 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg1010160014-2921(90)90071-6

129

Branas C C Cheney R A MacDonald J M Tam V W Jackson T D amp Ten Have T R (2011) A difference-in-differences analysis of health safety and greening vacant urban space American Journal of Epidemiology 174(11) 1296ndash1306

Bravo J (2014) Fondo Comuacuten Municipal y su desincentivo a la recaudacioacuten en Chile Temas de La Agenda Legislativa-Centro de Poliacuteticas Puacuteblicas UC 9(68)

Browning E K amp Johnson W R (1984) The Trade-Off between Equality and Efficiency Journal of Political Economy 92(2) 175ndash203 httpsdoiorg101086261219

Brunnschweiler C N amp Bulte E H (2008) The resource curse revisited and revised A tale of paradoxes and red herrings Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 55(3) 248ndash264 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jjeem200708004

Brunori P Ferreira F H G amp Peragine V (2013) Inequality of opportunity income inequality and economic mobility Some international comparisons In Getting Development Right (pp 85ndash115) Springer

Brunton-Smith I Jackson J amp Sutherland A (2014) Bridging structure and perception On the neighbourhood ecology of beliefs and worries about violent crime British Journal of Criminology 54(4) 503ndash526

Bulte E H Damania R amp Deacon R T (2005) Resource intensity institutions and development World Development 33(7) 1029ndash1044 httpsdoiorg101016jworlddev200504004

Carmignani F (2013) Development outcomes resource abundance and the transmission through inequality Resource and Energy Economics 35(3) 412ndash428 httpsdoiorg101016jreseneeco201304007

Carmignani Fabrizio amp Avom D (2010) The social development effects of primary commodity export dependence Ecological Economics 70(2) 317ndash330 httpsdoiorg101016jecolecon201009003

Caselli F amp Michaels G (2013) Do Oil Windfalls Improve Living Standards Evidence from Brazil American Economic Journal Applied Economics 5(1) 208ndash238 httpsdoiorg101257app51208

Celebioglu F amp Dallrsquoerba S (2010) Spatial disparities across the regions of Turkey An exploratory spatial data analysis Annals of Regional Science 45(2) 379ndash400 httpsdoiorg101007s00168-009-0313-8

Chan J To H-P amp Chan E (2006) Reconsidering social cohesion Developing a definition and analytical framework for empirical research Social Indicators Research 75(2) 273ndash302

Charnes A Cooper W W amp Rhodes E (1978) Measuring the efficiency of decision making units European Journal of Operational Research 2(6) 429ndash444

130

Chi G amp Zhu J (2019) Spatial Regression Models for the Social Sciences SAGE Publications Retrieved from httpsbooksgooglecomaubooksid=zHGkvwEACAAJ

Christiansen K O (1960) Industrialization and urbanization in relation to crime and juvenile delinquency International Review of Criminal Policy 16 3ndash8

Cingano F (2014) Trends in income inequality and its impact on economic growth (Vol 163) Paris OECD Publishing httpsdoiorg1017875jxrjncwxv6j-en

Coelli T J Prasada Rao D S OrsquoDonnell C J amp Battese G E (2005) An introduction to efficiency and productivity analysis An Introduction to Efficiency and Productivity Analysis Springer Science amp Business Media httpsdoiorg101007b136381

Coffeacute H amp Geys B (2005) Institutional Performance and Social Capital An Application to the Local Government Level Journal of Urban Affairs 27(5) 485ndash501 httpsdoiorg101111j0735-2166200500249x

Coffeacute H amp Geys B (2006) Community Heterogeneity A Burden for the Creation of Social Capital Social Science Quarterly 87(5) 1053ndash1072 httpsdoiorg101111j1540-6237200600415x

Cohen D Spear S Scribner R Kissinger P Mason K amp Wildgen J (2000) ldquo Broken windowsrdquo and the risk of gonorrhea American Journal of Public Health 90(2) 230

Corden W M amp Neary J P (1982) Booming sector and de-industrialisation in a small open economy The Economic Journal 92(368) 825ndash848

Cordero J M Pedraja-Chaparro F Pisaflores E C amp Polo C (2017) Efficiency assessment of Portuguese municipalities using a conditional nonparametric approach Journal of Productivity Analysis 48(1) 1ndash24 httpsdoiorg101007s11123-017-0500-z

Croissant Y amp Millo G (2018) Panel Data Econometrics with R John Wiley amp Sons

Cust J amp Poelhekke S (2015) The Local Economic Impacts of Natural Resource Extraction 7 251ndash268 httpsdoiorg101146annurev-resource-100814-125106

da Cruz N F amp Marques R C (2014) Revisiting the determinants of local government performance Omega 44 91ndash103 httpsdoiorg101016JOMEGA201309002

Dauvin M amp Guerreiro D (2017) The Paradox of Plenty A Meta-Analysis World Development 94 httpsdoiorg101016jworlddev201701009

de Sousa M da C S Cribari-Neto F amp Stosic B D (2005) Explaining DEA technical efficiency scores in an outlier corrected environment the case of public services in Brazilian municipalities Brazilian Review of Econometrics 25(2) 287ndash313

Deacon R T (2011) The Political Economy of the Natural Resource Curse A Survey of Theory and Evidence Foundations and Trends in Microeconomics 111-208

Delhey J amp Newton K (2005) Predicting cross-national levels of social trust global pattern or

131

Nordic exceptionalism European Sociological Review 21(4) 311ndash327

Dlouhyacute M (2018) Measuring Geographic Inequalities Dealing with Multiple Health Resources by Data Envelopment Analysis Frontiers in Public Health 6 53 httpsdoiorg103389fpubh201800053

Dollery B Wallis J amp Akimov A (2010) One Size Does Not Fit All The Special Case of Remote Small Local Councils in Outback Queensland Local Government Studies 36(1) 21ndash42 httpsdoiorg10108003003930903435716

Domenech J (2008) Mineral resource abundance and regional growth in Spain 1860ndash2000 Journal of International Development The Journal of the Development Studies Association 20(8) 1122ndash1135

Doran J amp Jordan D (2016) Decomposing US regional income inequality from 1969 to 2009 Applied Economics Letters 23(11) 781ndash784 httpsdoiorg1010801350485120151109030

Drew J amp Dollery B (2015) The State of Things The Dynamic Efficiency of Australian State and Territories Economic Papers A Journal of Applied Economics and Policy 34(3) 165ndash176

Drew J Kortt M amp Dollery B (2015) What Determines Efficiency in Local Government A DEA Analysis of NSW Local Government Economic Papers A Journal of Applied Economics and Policy 34(4) 243ndash256 httpsdoiorg1011111759-344112118

Easterly W (2007) Inequality does cause underdevelopment Insights from a new instrument Journal of Development Economics 84(2) 755ndash776 httpsdoiorghttpdxdoiorg101016jjdeveco200611002

Ebert L amp La Menza T (2015) Chile copper and resource revenue A holistic approach to assessing commodity dependence Resources Policy 43(Supplement C) 101ndash111 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201410007

ElGindi T (2017) Natural resource dependency neoliberal globalization and income inequality Are they related A longitudinal study of developing countries (1980ndash2010) Current Sociology 65(1) 21ndash53 httpsdoiorg1011770011392116632031

Engerman S L amp Sokoloff K L (1994) Factor Endowments Institutions and Differential Paths of Growth Among New World Economies National Bureau of Economic Research

Engerman S L amp Sokoloff K L (1997) Factor endowments institutions and differential paths of growth among new world economies How Latin America Fell Behind 260ndash304

Engerman S L Sokoloff K L Urquiola M amp Acemoglu D (2002) Factor Endowments Inequality and Paths of Development among New World Economies [with Comments] EconomampxedA 3(1) 41ndash109 Retrieved from httpwwwjstororgezp01libraryquteduaustable20065432

132

Faumlre R Grosskopf S amp Lovell C A K (1985) The measurement of efficiency of production (Vol 6) Springer Science amp Business Media

Fleming D A amp Measham T G (2015a) Income Inequality across Australian Regions during the Mining Boom 2001-11 Australian Geographer 46(2) 203ndash216 httpsdoiorg1010800004918220151020596

Fleming D A amp Measham T G (2015b) Local economic impacts of an unconventional energy boom the coal seam gas industry in Australia Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 59(1) 78ndash94 httpsdoiorg1011111467-848912043

Fum R M amp Hodler R (2010) Natural resources and income inequality The role of ethnic divisions Economics Letters 107(3) 360ndash363 httpsdoiorg101016jeconlet201003008

Garofalo J (1978) The fear of crime Broadening our perspective

Geys B amp Moesen W (2009) Exploring Sources of Local Government Technical Inefficiency Evidence from Flemish Municipalities Public Finance and Management 9(1) 1ndash29

Goderis B amp Malone S W (2011) Natural Resource Booms and Inequality Theory and Evidence The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 113(2) 388ndash417 httpsdoiorg101111j1467-9442201101659x

Greene W H (2016) Productivity and Efficiency Analysis (W H Greene L Khalaf R Sickles M Veall amp M-C Voia Eds) (1st ed 20) Cham Springer International Publishing httpsdoiorg101007978-3-319-23228-7

Gustafsson B amp Shi L (2002) Income inequality within and across counties in rural China 1988 and 1995 Journal of Development Economics 69(1) 179ndash204 httpsdoiorg101016S0304-3878(02)00058-5

Gylfason T amp Zoega G (2003) Inequality and Economic Growth Do Natural Resources Matter In T T Eicher S (Ed) Inequality and Growth Theory and Policy Implications (pp 255ndash292) The MIT Press

Henningsen A (2010) Estimating Censored Regression Models in R using the censReg Package R Package Vignettes Collection 5(2) 12

Henningsen A (2019) censReg Censored Regression (Tobit) Models R package version 05-30 httpscranr-projectorgpackage=censReg Retrieved from httpscranr-projectorgpackage=censReg

Herrera S amp Pang G (2005) Efficiency of Public Spending in Developing Countriesthinsp An Efficiency Frontier Approach World Bank Washington DC

Hill T D amp Angel R J (2005) Neighborhood disorder psychological distress and heavy drinking Social Science amp Medicine 61(5) 965ndash975

133

httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jsocscimed200412027

Hipp J R (2010) RESIDENT PERCEPTIONS OF CRIME AND DISORDER HOW MUCH IS ldquoBIASrdquo AND HOW MUCH IS SOCIAL ENVIRONMENT DIFFERENCES Criminology 48(2) 475ndash508 httpsdoiorg101111j1745-9125201000193x

Holtug N amp Mason A (2010) Introduction Immigration diversity and social cohesion SAGE Publications Sage UK London England

Hooghe M Vanhoutte B Hardyns W amp Bircan T (2010) Unemployment Inequality Poverty and Crime Spatial Distribution Patterns of Criminal Acts in Belgium 2001ndash06 The British Journal of Criminology 51(1) 1ndash20 httpsdoiorg101093bjcazq067

Howie P amp Atakhanova Z (2014) Resource boom and inequality Kazakhstan as a case study Resources Policy 39(1) 71ndash79 httpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201311004

Isham J Woolcock M Pritchett L amp Busby G (2005) The Varieties of Resource Experience Natural Resource Export Structures and the Political Economy of Economic Growth The World Bank Economic Review 19(2) 141ndash174 httpsdoiorg101093wberlhi010

Jottier D Ashworth J amp Heyndels B (2012) Understanding Votersrsquo Preferences How the Electoratersquos Complexity Affects Prediction Accuracy and Wishful Thinking among Politicians with Respect to Election Outcomes Kyklos 65(3) 340ndash370 httpsdoiorg101111j1467-6435201200542x

Kanbur S M R amp Venables A (2005) Spatial inequality and development (R World Institute for Development Economics Ed) Oxford Oxford University Press

Kesler C amp Bloemraad I (2010) Does immigration erode social capital The conditional effects of immigration-generated diversity on trust membership and participation across 19 countries 1981ndash2000 Canadian Journal of Political ScienceRevue Canadienne de Science Politique 43(2) 319ndash347

Kuznets S (1955) Economic Growth and Income Inequality The American Economic Review 45(1) 1ndash28 Retrieved from httpwwwjstororgstable1811581

Lagos G amp Blanco E (2010) Mining and development in the region of Antofagasta Resources Policy 35(4) 265ndash275 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201007006

Leamer E E Maul H Rodriguez S amp Schott P K (1999) Does natural resource abundance increase Latin American income inequality Journal of Development Economics 59(1) 3ndash42 httpsdoiorg101016s0304-3878(99)00004-8

Leibbrandt M Finn A amp Woolard I (2012) Describing and decomposing post-apartheid income inequality in South Africa Development Southern Africa 29(1) 19ndash34 httpsdoiorg1010800376835X2012645639

134

Letki N (2008) Does Diversity Erode Social Cohesion Social Capital and Race in British Neighbourhoods Political Studies 56(1) 99ndash126 httpsdoiorg101111j1467-9248200700692x

Lewis D A (2017) Fear of crime Incivility and the production of a social problem Routledge

lo Storto C (2013) Evaluating Technical Efficiency of Italian Major Municipalities A Data Envelopment Analysis model Procedia - Social and Behavioral Sciences 81 346ndash350 httpsdoiorg101016JSBSPRO201306440

Loayza N amp Rigolini J (2016) The Local Impact of Mining on Poverty and Inequality Evidence from the Commodity Boom in Peru World Development 84 219ndash234 httpsdoiorg101016jworlddev201603005

Loayza N Teran A M y amp Rigolini J (2013) Poverty Inequality and the Local Natural Resource Curse World Bank Policy Research Working Paper (6366) httpsdoiorg1015961813-9450-6366

Loacutepez R amp Miller S J (2008) Chile The Unbearable Burden of Inequality World Development 36(12) 2679ndash2695 httpsdoiorg101016jworlddev200801012

Manzano O amp Rigobon R (2001) Resource Curse or Debt Overhang National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper Series No 8390 1 httpsdoiorghttpwwwnberorgpapersw9424bib

McPherson M Smith-Lovin L amp Cook J M (2001) Birds of a Feather Homophily in Social Networks Annual Review of Sociology 27(1) 415ndash444 httpsdoiorg101146annurevsoc271415

McQuestin D Drew J amp Dollery B (2018) Do Municipal Mergers Improve Technical Efficiency An Empirical Analysis of the 2008 Queensland Municipal Merger Program Australian Journal of Public Administration 77(3) 442ndash455 httpsdoiorg1011111467-850012286

Messner S F Rosenfeld R amp Baumer E P (2004) Dimensions of Social Capital and Rates of Criminal Homicide American Sociological Review 69(6) 882ndash903 httpsdoiorg101177000312240406900607

Michaels G (2011) THE LONG TERM CONSEQUENCES OF RESOURCE-BASED SPECIALISATION The Economic Journal 121(551) 31ndash57 httpsdoiorg101111j1468-0297201002402x

Mijanovich T amp Weitzman B C (2003) Which ldquobroken windowsrdquo matter School neighborhood and family characteristics associated with youthsrsquo feelings of unsafety Journal of Urban Health 80(3) 400ndash415

Mikušovaacute P (2015) An Application of DEA Methodology in Efficiency Measurement of the Czech Public Universities Procedia Economics and Finance 25 569ndash578 httpsdoiorg101016S2212-5671(15)00771-6

135

Milanovic B (2016) Global inequality Harvard University Press

Millo G amp Piras G (2012) splm Spatial panel data models in R Journal of Statistical Software 47(1) 1ndash38

Murphy K M amp Topel R H (2016) Human Capital Investment Inequality and Economic Growth JOURNAL OF LABOR ECONOMICS 34(2) S99ndashS127 httpsdoiorg101086683779

Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute I amp De Witte K (2018a) Local governmentsrsquo efficiency a systematic literature reviewmdashpart I International Transactions in Operational Research 25(2) 431ndash468 httpsdoiorg101111itor12364

Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute I amp De Witte K (2018b) Local governmentsrsquo efficiency a systematic literature reviewmdashpart II International Transactions in Operational Research 25(4) 1107ndash1136 httpsdoiorg101111itor12389

Nuntildeez J Rivera J Villavicencio X amp Molina O (2003) Determinantes socioeconoacutemicos y demograacuteficos del crimen en Chile Estudios de Economiacutea 30(1) 55ndash85

OrsquoDonnell C J Rao D S P amp Battese G E (2008) Metafrontier frameworks for the study of firm-level efficiencies and technology ratios Empirical Economics 34(2) 231ndash255 httpsdoiorg101007s00181-007-0119-4

Ocampo J A (2004) Latin Americarsquos Growth and Equity Frustrations During Structural Reforms The Journal of Economic Perspectives 18(2) 67ndash88 httpsdoiorg1012570895330041371349

OECD (2014) Focus on inequality and growth OECD

OECD (2017) Howrsquos Life 2017 Life Satisfaction Oecd httpsdoiorg101787how_life-2017-en

Ohtake F (2008) Inequality in Japan Asian Economic Policy Review 3(1) 87ndash109 httpsdoiorg101111j1748-3131200800093x

Okun A M (2015) Equality and efficiency the big tradeoff Washington DC Brookings Institution Press

Ortega B Sanjuaacuten J amp Casquero A (2017) Determinants of efficiency in reducing child mortality in developing countries The role of inequality and government effectiveness Health Care Management Science 20(4) 500ndash516 httpsdoiorg101007s10729-016-9367-1

Ostry J Berg A amp Tsangarides C (2014) Redistribution inequality and growth International Monetary Fund

Pacheco F Saacutenchez R amp Villena M (2013) Eficiencia de los Gobiernos Locales y sus Determinantes Un anaacutelisis de Fronteras Estocaacutesticas en Datos de Panel para

136

Municipalidades Chilenas Santiago de Chile Chile

Papyrakis E amp Raveh O (2014) An Empirical Analysis of a Regional Dutch Disease The Case of Canada Environmental and Resource Economics 58(2) 179ndash198 httpsdoiorg101007s10640-013-9698-z

Paredes D (2013) The Role of Human Capital Market Potential and Natural Amenities in Understanding Spatial Wage Disparities in Chile Spatial Economic Analysis 8(2) 154ndash175 httpsdoiorg101080174217722013774094

Paredes D Iturra V amp Lufin M (2016) A spatial decomposition of income inequality in Chile Regional Studies 50(5) 771ndash789

Phan P Van Orsquobrien M Mendolia S amp Paloyo A (2017) National pro-poor spending programmes and their effect on income inequality and poverty Evidence from Vietnam Applied Economics 49(55) 5579ndash5590 httpsdoiorg1010800003684620171313957

Podinovski V V (2004) Bridging the Gap between the Constant and Variable Returns-to-Scale Models Selective Proportionality in Data Envelopment Analysis The Journal of the Operational Research Society 55(3) 265ndash276 Retrieved from httpwwwjstororgstable4102006

Ravallion M (2005) On Measuring Aggregate Social Efficiency Economic Development and Cultural Change 53(2) 273ndash292 httpsdoiorg101086425380

Rehner J Baeza S A amp Barton J R (2014) Chilersquos resource-based export boom and its outcomes Regional specialization export stability and economic growth Geoforum 56(Supplement C) 35ndash45 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jgeoforum201406007

Rivera J Gutieacuterrez M amp Nuacutentildeez J (2009) Caracterizacioacuten socioeconoacutemica y espacial de la criminalidad en Chile Revista CEPAL

Ross C E (2011) Collective threat trust and the sense of personal control Journal of Health and Social Behavior 52(3) 287ndash296

Ross C E amp Mirowsky J (2001) Neighborhood disadvantage disorder and health Journal of Health and Social Behavior 258ndash276

Rothstein B amp Uslaner E M (2005) All for all Equality corruption and social trust World Politics 58(1) 41ndash72

Sachs J D amp Warner A M (2001) The curse of natural resources European Economic Review 45(4ndash6) 827ndash838 httpsdoiorg101016S0014-2921(01)00125-8

Salas R (2019) sinimr Chilean Municipalities Information System Wrapper Retrieved from httpsgithubcomrobsalascosinimr

Sampson R J (1986) Crime in Cities The Effects of Formal and Informal Social Control Crime and Justice 8 271ndash311

137

Sampson R J (2008) Rethinking crime and immigration Contexts 7(1) 28ndash33

Santos Silva J M C amp Tenreyro S (2010) On the existence of the maximum likelihood estimates in Poisson regression Economics Letters 107(2) 310ndash312 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jeconlet201002020

Santos Silva J M C amp Tenreyro S (2011) poisson Some convergence issues Stata Journal 11(2) 207ndash212 Retrieved from httpwwwstata-journalcomarticlehtmlarticle=st0225

Scott Z (2009) Decentralisation local development and social cohesion an analytical review GSDRC Research Paper 5

Sinha R P (2017) Fiscal Performance Benchmarking of Indian States-A Robust Frontier Approach The Central European Review of Economics and Management 1(4) 225ndash249

Skogan W (1986) Fear of crime and neighborhood change Crime and Justice 8 203ndash229

Skogan W (1999) Measuring what matters Crime disorder and fear In Measuring what matters Proceedings from the Policing Research Institute meetings (pp 37ndash53) National Institute of Justice Washington DC

Skogan W (2015) Disorder and Decline The State of Research Journal of Research in Crime and Delinquency 52(4) 464ndash485 httpsdoiorg1011770022427815577836

Šťastnaacute L amp Gregor M (2014) Public sector efficiency in transition and beyond evidence from Czech local governments Applied Economics 47(7) 1ndash20 httpsdoiorg101080000368462014978077

Tandon A (2005) Measuring Efficiency of Macro Systems An Application to Millennium Development Goal Attainment Asian Development Review 22(2) 108ndash125

Taylor R B (1999) The incivilities thesis Theory measurement and policy Measuring What Matters 65 88

Tigga N S amp Mishra U S (2015) On Measuring Technical Efficiency of the Health System in India An Application of Data Envelopment Analysis Journal of Health Management 17(3) 285ndash298 httpsdoiorg1011770972063415589229

Tinbergen J (1975) Demographic Development and the Exhaustion of Natural Resources Population and Development Review 1(1) 23ndash32 httpsdoiorg1023071972269

Tiruneh G (2014) Social Revolutions Their Causes Patterns and Phases SAGE Open 4(3) 2158244014548845 httpsdoiorg1011772158244014548845

Tolsma J Van der Meer T amp Gesthuizen M (2009) The impact of neighbourhood and municipality characteristics on social cohesion in the Netherlands Acta Politica 44(3) 286ndash313

Tsekeris Sotiris T Tsekeris T amp Papaioannou S (2018) Regional determinants of technical efficiency evidence from the Greek economy Regional Studies [London]thinsp Carfax

138

httpsdoiorg1010800034340420171390312

Uslaner E (2002) The moral foundations of trust Cambridge University Press

Uslaner E (2011) CORRUPTION AND INEQUALITY DICE Report 9(2) 20ndash24

Uslaner E (2013) Trust and corruption revisited how and why trust and corruption shape each other Quality amp Quantity 47(6) 3603ndash3608 httpsdoiorg101007s11135-012-9742-z

Uslaner E amp Brown M (2005) Inequality trust and civic engagement American Politics Research 33(6) 868ndash894

Van der Ploeg F (2011) Natural Resources Curse or Blessing Journal of Economic Literature 49(2) 366ndash420 httpsdoiorg101257jel492366

Vergara R (2012) Crime Prevention Programs Evidence From CHILE The Developing Economies 50(1) 1ndash24

Watkins M H (1963) A staple theory of economic growth Canadian Journal of Economics and Political ScienceRevue Canadienne de Economiques et Science Politique 29(2) 141ndash158

Wilkinson R G (1999) Income inequality social cohesion and health clarifying the theorymdasha reply to Muntaner and Lynch International Journal of Health Services 29(3) 525ndash543

Wilson J Q amp Kelling G L (1982) Broken windows Atlantic Monthly 249(3) 29ndash38

Wilson W J (1996) When Work Disappears Political Science Quarterly 111(4) 567ndash595 httpsdoiorg1023072152085

Wirth L (1938) Urbanism as a Way of Life American Journal of Sociology 44(1) 1ndash24

Worthington A amp Dollery B (2000) An empirical survey of frontier efficiency measurement techniques in local government Local Government Studies 26(2) 23ndash52 httpsdoiorg10108003003930008433988

Wu P-C Huang T-H amp Pan S-C (2014) Country Performance Evaluation The DEA Model Approach Social Indicators Research 118(2) 835ndash849 httpsdoiorg101007s11205-013-0443-3

Ye X Ma L Ye K Chen J amp Xie Q (2017) Analysis of Regional Inequality from Sectoral Structure Spatial Policy and Economic Development A Case Study of Chongqing China Sustainability 9(4) 633 Retrieved from httpwwwmdpicom2071-105094633

Yue W Z Zhang Y T Ye X Y Cheng Y Q amp Leipnik M R (2014) Dynamics of Multi-Scale Intra-Provincial Regional Inequality in Zhejiang China Sustainability 6(9) 5763ndash5784 httpsdoiorg103390su6095763

139

Appendices

Appendix A Summary statistics income inequality

Table A1

Summary statistics Gini coefficients by year and zone

140

Appendix B Summary statistics for NRD measures by region

Table B1

Summary statistics NRD measures by region

141

Appendix C Regional administrative division and defined zones

Figure C1 Geographical distribution of Chilean regions and 3 zones

142

Appendix D Summary statistics numeric controls and correlation matrix

Table D1

Summary Statistics Numeric Explanatory Variables

Figure D1 Correlation matrix numeric explanatory variables

143

Appendix E Static spatial panel models

Following Millo amp Piras (2012) a model including a spatial lag of the dependent variable and

spatial autoregressive disturbances but not spatial lags for the explanatory variable(s) is called

SARAR model A static spatial SARAR panel could be expressed as

119910 120582 119868 otimes119882 119910 119883120573 119906 (E1)

where y is an 119873 1 vector of observations on the dependent variable X is a 119873 119896 matrix of

observations on the non-stochastic exogenous regressors 119868 an identity matrix of dimension 119879 otimes

is the kronecker operator 119882 is the 119873 119873 spatial weights matrix of known constants whose

diagonal elements are set to zero and 120582 the corresponding spatial parameter44

The disturbance vector is the sum of two terms

119906 120580 otimes 119868 120583 120576 (E2)

where 120580 is a 119879 1 vector of ones 119868 an 119873 119873 identity matrix 120583 is a vector of time-invariant

individual specific effects (not spatially autocorrelated) and 120576 a vector of spatially autocorrelated

innovations that follow a spatial autoregressive process of the form

120576 120588 119868 otimes119882 120576 120584 (E3)

If we assume that spatial correlation applies to both the individual effects 120583 and the remainder

error components 120576 Kapoor et al (2007) propose that the disturbance term 119906 follows a first order

spatial autoregressive process of the form

119906 120588 119868 otimes119882 119906 120576 (E4)

44 Unlike ldquotraditional panelsrdquo which are organized as different time series for each cross-sectional unit ldquospatial panelsrdquo are organized as a series of cross-sections for each year

144

where 119882 is the spatial weights matrix and 119903ℎ119900 the corresponding spatial autoregressive

parameter To further allow for the innovations to be correlated over time the innovations vector

in Equation 7 follows an error component structure

120576 120580 otimes 119868 120583 120584 (E5)

where 120583 is the vector of cross-sectional specific effects 120584 a vector of innovations that vary

both over cross-sectional units and time periods 120580 is a vector of ones and 119868 an 119873 119873 identity

matrix45

Spatial panel models are usually estimated by Maximum Likelihood or GMM46 The SAR

SEM or SARAR models could be estimated with Random or Fixed effects For instance A fixed

effect spatial lag model can be written in stacked form as

119910 120582 119868 otimes119882 119910 120580 otimes 119868 120583 119883120573 120576 (E6)

where 120582 is the spatial autoregressive coefficient 119882 a non-stochastic spatial weights matrix

120580 a column vector of ones of dimension 119879 119868 an 119873 119873 identity matrix and 120576 sim 119873 0120590 On

the other hand a fixed effects spatial error model assuming the disturbance specification by

Kapoor et al (2007) can be written as

119910 120580119879 otimes 119868119873 120583 119883120573 119906119906 120588 119868119879 otimes119882119873 119906 120576

(E7)

where 120588 is the spatial autocorrelation coefficient and 120576 is a well-behaved error term

45 In the regression implementation the specification given by equations (22) and (3) is denoted by ldquobrdquo for ldquoBaltagirdquo On the other hand the specification given by equations (23) and (31) is denoted by ldquokkprdquo for ldquoKapoor Kelejian and Pruchardquo 46 We use the R package splm which allow both types of regression procedure

145

Appendix F Analysis OLS residuals cross-sectional (six-year average) analysis

Table F1

Analysis OLS residuals Anselin Method

Figure F1 Moran scatter plot OLS residuals

146

Appendix G Linear panel data models

Table G1

Panel regressions (non-spatial)

147

Appendix H Spatial panel models (Generalized Moments (GM) estimation)

Table H1

GM Spatial Models

148

Appendix I Inputs and outputs used in DEA analysis

Figure I1 Examples of inputs and outputs used to measure LGE (based on Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018)

149

Appendix J Technical and scale efficiency

Following lo Storto (2013) under an input-oriented specification assuming VRS with n

municipalities using k inputs to produce m outputs the DEA model for a given i-th municipality

is specified with the following mathematical programming problem

119898119894119899 120579119904119906119887119895119890119888119905 119905119900 119910 119884120582 0120579119909 119883120582 01198991prime120582 1  120582 0prime

Where 119910 is the column vector of the outputs and 119909 is the column vector of the inputs

Moreover we can define X as the (k times n) input matrix and Y as the (m times n) output matrix 120579 is a

scalar (that satisfies 120579 1) more specifically it is the efficiency score that measures technical

efficiency It measures the distance between a municipality and the efficiency frontier defined as

a linear combination of the best practice observations With 120579 1 the municipality is inside the

frontier (ie it is inefficient) while 120579 1 implies that the municipality is on the frontier (ie it is

efficient) The vector 120582 is an (n times 1) vector of constants that measures the weights used to compute

the location of an inefficient municipality if it were to become efficient

The total technical efficiency 119879119864 can be decomposed into pure technical efficiency

119879119864 and scale efficiency 119878119864 where 119878119864 119879119864 119879119864 (Coelli et al 2005) To find out

whether a municipality is scale efficient and qualify the type of returns of scale a DEA model

under non-increasing returns to scale 119879119864 is implemented where 119878119864 119879119864 119879119864 Hence

the following rule can be applied (Faumlre Grosskopf amp Lovell 1985)

bull If 119878119864 1 then a municipality is scale efficient both under CRS and VRS

bull If 119878119864 1 it operates under increasing returns to scale

bull If 119878119864 1 it operates under decreasing returns to scale

150

Appendix K Correlation matrix

Figure K1 Correlation matrix contextual factors

151

Appendix L Returns to scale by year and zone

Table L1

Returns to scale (percentage of municipalities)

152

Appendix M Returns to scale by year (maps)

Figure M1 Spatial distribution of returns to scale by county per year

153

Appendix N Efficiency status by year (maps)

Figure N1 Spatial distribution of efficient (E es = 1) and inefficient (I es lt 1) counties per year

154

Appendix O Spatial distribution efficiency scores by year (maps)

FigureO1 Custom breaks maps of efficiency scores (VRS) by county per year

155

Appendix P Analysis OLS residuals cross-sectional (six-year average) analysis

Table P1

Analysis OLS residuals Anselin Method

Figure P1 Moran scatter plot efficiency scores and OLS residuals

156

Table P2

OLS and spatial regression models for the six-year averaged data

157

Appendix Q OLS regressions for cross-sectional and panel data

Table Q1

OLS cross-sectional regression per year

158

Table Q2

OLS panel regressions Pooled random effects and instrumental variable

159

Appendix R Quantile maps incivilities rate by group (average total period)

Figure R1 Spatial distribution of incivilities by group (Average rate per 1000 inhabitants 2006-09-11-13-15-17)

160

Appendix S Correlation matrix numeric covariates

Figure S1 Correlation matrix numeric covariates

161

Appendix T Negative Binomial regressions

Table T1

Negative Binomial regressions

162

Appendix U Coefficients economic and racial diversity by geographical zone

Table U1

Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson models by geographic zone

Page 3: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted

ii

Abstract

Persistently high indicators of relative economic disadvantage such as measures of income

inequality can give rise to a feeling of discontent in the population which in turn can trigger

costly social conflicts For instance inequality has been suggested as one of the main causes of

social outburst considering recent events in many countries around the world This has generated

in extant literature an increasing number of criticisms of current political and socio-economic

models This research considers the Chilean economy which is recognised as an example of the

success of standard economic thinking however it is also well-known for its persistently high

levels of inequality an adverse indicator of economic performance This thesis contributes with

three essays to the understanding of the sources and potential consequences of income inequality

in Chile The data consider a panel of 324 Chilean counties and their corresponding municipalities

for the 2006ndash2017 period

The first essay investigates the association between income inequality and the endowment

of natural resources The Gini coefficient of each county is used as a measure of income inequality

The influence of natural resources on income inequality is captured by using the proportion of

employment in the primary sector as a proxy for the degree of dependence on natural resources in

each county Previous literature has identified a significant spatial dimension of income inequality

in Chile but this spatial dimension has been largely neglected in the domain of policy design and

implementation Thus the analysis in this essay applies spatial regression models for cross-

sectional and panel data while controlling for other socioeconomic and demographic

characteristics The main finding is that contrary to what theory predicts our measure of natural

resource dependence in terms of employment shows a robust and significant negative association

with income inequality The main implication of this empirical result is that a transformation

process towards activities less dependent on natural resources reinforces rather than reduces the

persistence of income inequality at least through the channel of employment Hence this

transformation process imposes additional challenges to central and local governments in their

goal of reducing income inequality Empirical analysis also shows a significant degree of positive

spatial autocorrelation of income inequality This means that counties with similar levels of income

iii

inequality tend to cluster in space The regression analysis confirms the importance of capturing

geographical heterogeneity in the explanation of income inequality however gives less support

to a process of spatial dependence like a spillover effect of income inequality among

neighbouring counties

Among the potential consequences of income inequality the literature highlights its

possible impacts on the efficiency in the provision of public services by local authorities however

empirical evidence is very little For this reason the second essay analyses the technical efficiency

of municipal local governments in Chile and examine if income inequality has significant impacts

on the variations in the efficiency levels across municipalities An input-oriented Data

Envelopment Analysis is used to measure municipal efficiency Results reveal that the municipal

production technology is characterized by variable returns to scale but scale inefficiencies only

explain a small proportion of total inefficiency This justify a need for analysing the influence of

variables which are beyond the control of local authorities in explaining differences in municipal

efficiency The main hypothesis tested was whether income inequality has a negative influence on

municipal efficiency whilst a measure of natural resource dependence at the county level was used

as an instrument to control for the effects of possible endogeneity issues Results showed that

changes in income inequality could be associated with changes in the municipal efficiency level

in the same magnitude but in the opposite direction This confirms that local authorities in counties

characterized by high levels of income inequality face greater challenges to achieve more efficient

performance This result suggests that policies aimed at reducing income inequality can also

increase the efficiency of local governments Our results also reveal that policies such as

amalgamation de-amalgamation or cooperation among municipalities should be designed

specifically for each region rather than as a standard national strategy

Finally the third essay analyses how social cohesion is associated with the levels of

economic and racial diversity Social cohesion is proxied using the reported number of antisocial

behaviours catalogued as incivilities Incivilities are those antisocial behaviours which violate

social norms but are not usually considered as criminal Research has documented the implications

of incivilities on human stress health public behaviour and increasing feelings of insecurity and

fear among the population Few studies have explicitly considered incivilities as a dependent

variable to identify their determinants or use them to analyse the weakening of social cohesion and

iv

the growing feeling of social unrest in contemporary societies Economic diversity is proxied using

the Gini coefficient in each county and racial diversity through the number of new visas granted

as proportion of the county population Our findings show that incivilities are strongly associated

with racial diversity and to a lesser extent with economic diversity The rate of incivilities also

shows a negative association with the level of income and a positive relationship with poverty and

unemployment rates These results give empirical support to the idea that both relative and

absolute indicators of economic deprivation play an important role in understanding the growing

problem of incivilities in highly unequal economies like Chile Results also show that the rate of

incivilities is negatively related to the degree of financial autonomy of municipalities These

findings represent promising areas for central and local governments in the implementation of

policies aimed at increasing social cohesion through the reduction of incivilities and other types of

antisocial behaviours

v

Table of Contents

Keywords i

Abstract ii

Table of Contents v

List of Figures viii

List of Tables ix

List of Abbreviations x

Statement of Original Authorship xi

Acknowledgements xii

Chapter 1 Introduction 13

Income inequality and dependence on natural resources 14

Local government efficiency and income inequality 16

Social cohesion and economic diversity 19

Contributions 21

Thesis outline 23

Chapter 2 Natural Resources Curse or Blessing Evidence on Income Inequality at the County Level in Chile 24

21 Introduction 24

22 Inequality and Natural Resources 28 221 Theoretical Framework 28

Cross-country literature 29 Single country evidence 32

222 The relevance of the spatial approach 33

23 Research problem and hypotheses 35

24 Data and Methods 36 241 Operationalization of key variables 36 242 Control variables 40 243 Methods 41 244 Spatial Model Specification 43

25 Results 44 251 Exploratory Spatial Data Analysis (ESDA) 44 252 Cross-sectional analysis 45 253 Panel Data analysis 48

26 Discussion and conclusions 51

Chapter 3 The Impact of Income Inequality on the Efficiency of Municipalities in Chile 55

vi

31 Introduction 55

32 Related Literature 61 321 Measuring efficiency of local governments 61 322 Explaining differences in LGE 63 323 The trade-off between efficiency and equity 64

33 Methodology 66 331 Chilean Municipalities and period of analysis 66 332 Measuring municipal efficiency 68 333 Inputs and outputs used in DEA 70 334 Regression model 71 335 The instrument 75

34 Results and discussion 77 341 DEA results 77

Returns to scale 78 Efficiency measure 80

342 Regression results 82 Exploratory spatial analysis 82 Cross-sectional analysis 83 Panel data analysis 84

35 Conclusions 88

Chapter 4 Social Cohesion Incivilities and Diversity Evidence at the municipal level in Chile 91

41 Introduction 91

42 Related Literature 95 421 The Community Heterogeneity Thesis 95 422 The literature on incivilities 97 423 The ldquoIncivilities Thesisrdquo 99

4 3 Methodology 100 431 Period of analysis and data sample 100 432 Operationalisation of the response variable and exploratory analysis 101 433 Measures of community heterogeneity and control variables 105 434 Methods 108 435 Hypotheses 111

44 Results and Discussion 112

4 5 Conclusions 118

Chapter 5 Conclusions 120

Bibliography 126

Appendices 139

Appendix A Summary statistics income inequality 139

Appendix B Summary statistics for NRD measures by region 140

Appendix C Regional administrative division and defined zones 141

Appendix D Summary statistics numeric controls and correlation matrix 142

vii

Appendix E Static spatial panel models 143

Appendix F Analysis OLS residuals cross-sectional (six-year average) analysis 145

Appendix G Linear panel data models 146

Appendix H Spatial panel models (Generalized Moments (GM) estimation) 147

Appendix I Inputs and outputs used in DEA analysis 148

Appendix J Technical and scale efficiency 149

Appendix K Correlation matrix 150

Appendix L Returns to scale by year and zone 151

Appendix M Returns to scale by year (maps) 152

Appendix N Efficiency status by year (maps) 153

Appendix O Spatial distribution efficiency scores by year (maps) 154

Appendix P Analysis OLS residuals cross-sectional (six-year average) analysis 155

Appendix Q OLS regressions for cross-sectional and panel data 157

Appendix R Quantile maps incivilities rate by group (average total period) 159

Appendix S Correlation matrix numeric covariates 160

Appendix T Negative Binomial regressions 161

Appendix U Coefficients economic and racial diversity by geographical zone 162

viii

List of Figures

Figure 21 Average share in GDP of economic activities (2006ndash17) 37

Figure 22 Evolution of Gini coefficient and measures of NRD (2006ndash17) 38

Figure 23 Spatial distribution of Gini coefficient and NRD (2006ndash17) 39

Figure 23 Moran scatter plots for variables gini and pss_casen 45

Figure 31 Geographical distribution of Chilean regions and macrozones 74

Figure 32 Evolution of efficiency scores and the proportion of firms by sector 77

Figure 33 Evolution technical efficiency (TE) pure technical efficiency (PTE) and scale efficiency (SE) 78

Figure 34 Returns to scale by zone 79

Figure 35 Evolution mean efficiency scores (VRS) by zone 81

Figure 41 Evolution number and rates of incivilities and crime (DMCS) in Chile 2006-2017 102

Figure 42 Evolution total number of incivilities by category 104

Figure 43 Spatial distribution of incivilities rate per 1000 inhabitants (2006 vs 2017) 104

Figure 44 Annual average number of incivilities per county 109

Figure C1 Geographical distribution of Chilean regions and 3 zones 141

Figure D1 Correlation matrix numeric explanatory variables 142

Figure F1 Moran scatter plot OLS residuals 145

Figure I1 Examples of inputs and outputs used to measure LGE (based on Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018) 148

Figure K1 Correlation matrix contextual factors 150

Figure M1 Spatial distribution of returns to scale by county per year 152

Figure N1 Spatial distribution of efficient (E es = 1) and inefficient (I es lt 1) counties per year 153

FigureO1 Custom breaks maps of efficiency scores (VRS) by county per year 154

Figure P1 Moran scatter plot efficiency scores and OLS residuals 155

Figure R1 Spatial distribution of incivilities by group (Average rate per 1000 inhabitants 2006-09-11-13-15-17) 159

Figure S1 Correlation matrix numeric covariates 160

ix

List of Tables

Table 21 Cross-sectional Model Comparison (six-year average data) 47

Table 22 ML Spatial SAR Models 50

Table 23 ML Spatial SEM Models 50

Table 24 ML Spatial SARAR Models 51

Table 31 Descriptive statistics Inputs and Output variables used in DEA analysis 71

Table 32 Summary Statistics Numeric Contextual Factors 74

Table 33 Summary efficiency scores (VRS) by zone and region 80

Table 34 Cross-sectional (censored) regressions 84

Table 35 Panel data regressions 87

Table 41 Summary statistics total count of incivilities and by category (full sample and period) 103

Table 42 Summary statistics numeric explanatory variables 108

Table 43 Poisson regressions 113

Table 44 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson models by region 115

Table 45 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson model by incivility group 116

Table A1 Summary statistics Gini coefficients by year and zone 139

Table B1 Summary statistics NRD measures by region 140

Table D1 Summary Statistics Numeric Explanatory Variables 142

Table F1 Analysis OLS residuals Anselin Method 145

Table G1 Panel regressions (non-spatial) 146

Table H1 GM Spatial Models 147

Table L1 Returns to scale (percentage of municipalities) 151

Table P1 Analysis OLS residuals Anselin Method 155

Table P2 OLS and spatial regression models for the six-year averaged data 156

Table Q1 OLS cross-sectional regression per year 157

Table Q2 OLS panel regressions Pooled random effects and instrumental variable 158

Table T1 Negative Binomial regressions 161

Table U1 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson models by geographic zone 162

x

List of Abbreviations

Constant returns to scale CRS

Data envelopment analysis DEA

Decreasing returns to scale DRS

Efficiency scores ES

Exploratory spatial data analysis ESDA

Generalized methods of moments GMM

Gross Domestic Product GDP

Increasing returns to scale IRS

Local government efficiency LGE

Maximum likelihood ML

Municipal common fund MCF

Natural resource dependence NRD

Natural resource endowment NRE

Ordinary Least Squares OLS

Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development OECD

Own permanent revenues OPR

Resource curse hypothesis RCH

Spatial autoregressive model SAR

Spatial error model SEM

Variable returns to scale VRS

xi

Statement of Original Authorship

The work contained in this thesis has not been previously submitted to meet requirements

for an award at this or any other higher education institution To the best of my knowledge and

belief the thesis contains no material previously published or written by another person except

where due reference is made

Signature QUT Verified Signature

Date _________04092020_________

xii

Acknowledgements

First I would like to thank my wife Lilian who joined me in this challenge and patiently

supported me all these years I would also like to thank our family who always supported us from

Chile I especially thank my sister Silvia who took care of our house and dog

I am also grateful to my supervisory team Dr Radhika Lahiri and Dr Vincent Hoang who

supported and guided me in the process of making this thesis a reality

I also thank the Deans of the Faculty of Economics and Business at my beloved University

of Talca Dr Arcadio Cerda and Dr Rodrigo Herrera who trusted me and supported me in this

process In the same way I would like to thank all the support of the director of the Commercial

Engineering career Mr Milton Inostroza

Finally I would like to thank the government of Chile for the financial support that made

my stay and studies possible here at the Queensland University of Technology

13

Chapter 1 Introduction

Efficiency and equity issues are often considered together in the evaluation of economic

performance While higher efficiency usually measured by growth rates of income per capita

correlates with improvements in measures of well-being the link between inequality and well-

being is less clear This is reflected not only in the type and amount of research related to efficiency

and equity but also in the role that both play in the design of the economic policy For instance

several market-oriented countries have focused primarily on economic growth trusting in a trickle-

down process where financial benefits given to the wealthy are expected to ultimately benefit the

poor However despite the growing interest in the issue of inequality there is a considerable lack

of studies about its consequences

Although some level of inequality is inevitable or even necessary for economic activity this

study is motivated by the argument that relatively high levels of inequality can be associated with

many problems such as persistent unemployment increasing fiscal expenses indebtedness and

political instability (Berg amp Ostry 2011) Inequality can also have other severe social

consequences including increased crime rates teenage pregnancy obesity and fewer

opportunities for low-income households to invest in health and education (Atkinson 2015) In

addition when the role of money and concentration of economic power undermine political

outcomes inequality of opportunities hampers social and economic mobility trust and social

cohesion In summary inequality can increase the fragility of the economic and social situation in

a country reducing economic growth and making it less inclusive and sustainable

14

A country well-known for its market-oriented economy and high level of dependence on

natural resources is Chile Chilean success in terms of economic growth contrasts with its inability

to reduce the persistently high levels of social and economic inequality particularly in the last

three decades Using data for the 2006-2017 period and considering 324 out of 345 Chilean

counties this thesis presents three essays with empirical evidence aiming to explain the

phenomenon of persistent income inequality and some of its potential consequences The first

essay aims to analyse how the evolution and variability of income inequality throughout the

country are associated with the degree of natural resource dependence The second essay studies

the relevance of income inequality in explaining cross-county differences in the performance of

local governments (municipalities) Finally the third essay explores the link between social

cohesion and community heterogeneity highlighting the importance of economic and racial

diversity

Income inequality and dependence on natural resources

The first essay explores how cross-county differences in income inequality are associated

with differences in the degree of dependence on natural resources We use the Gini coefficient in

each county as our dependent variable and the proportion of employment in the primary sector as

our measure of natural resource dependence The main hypothesis is that income inequality should

be positively related to the degree of natural resource dependence To test our hypothesis we use

a spatial econometric approach This approach is motivated by the study of Paredes Iturra and

Lufin (2016) who explore the geographic heterogeneity of income inequality in Chile finding

evidence of a significant spatial dimension

15

The theoretical and empirical literature has mostly proposed a positive link between

inequality and natural resources Although most of the evidence corresponds to cross-country

comparisons there is also increasing body of research at the local level A rationale underpinning

the positive link suggested in the literature is that in natural resource-rich countries ownership is

concentrated in small groups and extraction activities require low-skilled workers (Gylfason amp

Zoega 2003 Leamer Maul Rodriguez amp Schott 1999) Another market-based argument often

labelled as the ldquoDutch Diseaserdquo proposes that natural resource windfalls could be associated with

a crowding-out effect on the manufacturing sector (Corden amp Neary 1982 Easterly 2007) This

process encourages rent-seeking behaviours discourages investment in physical and human

capital and delays the process of technology adoption and industrialization (Auty 2001 Bulte

Damania amp Deacon 2005 Gylfason amp Zoega 2003) The result could be a lower economic

growth which is the central idea under the ldquoResource Curse Hypothesisrdquo (Auty 1993 Sachs amp

Warner 2001)

An ldquoinstitutionalrdquo argument for the positive association between inequality and the

endowment of natural resources is based on the so-called ldquoParadox of Plentyrdquo (Borge Parmer amp

Torvik 2015 Dauvin amp Guerreiro 2017) The idea is that both national and local authorities have

less incentive to operate efficiently when they experience windfalls in their revenues for

instance from natural resources This could end with corrupted authorities exerting patronage

clientelism and designing public policies to favour specific groups of the population (Uslaner amp

Brown 2005) Evidence also suggests that the final effect of natural resource booms on income

inequality will depend on authoritiesrsquo capacity to manage these additional resources the extent of

commuting and migration among regions and the potential increase in the demand for non-tradable

16

goods which are intensive in unskilled workers (Aroca amp Atienza 2011 Cust amp Poelhekke 2015

Fleming amp Measham 2015b Howie amp Atakhanova 2014 Michaels 2011)

Contrary to most theoretical and empirical evidence we find that income inequality shows

a robust and significant negative association with our proxy for natural resource dependence This

result suggests that the process of transformation to an economy less dependent on natural

resources could have exacerbated rather than alleviated the persistence of income inequality The

decrease in the participation of the primary sector in employment in favour mainly of the tertiary

sector highlights the importance of the latter to explain the current high levels of inequality and its

future evolution Another important result is that spatial linear models show practically the same

results as traditional linear models This could be interpreted as the spatial dimension previously

found in income inequality is not the result of spatial dependence in the variable itself for instance

due to a process of spillover among counties Hence the usually found positive spatial

autocorrelation of income inequality (similar levels in neighbouring counties) could be explained

by spatial patterns in other variables or to the spatial heterogeneity that characterizes the Chilean

economy

Local government efficiency and income inequality

Essay 2 delves deep into the potential trade-off between efficiency and equity We measure

the efficiency of Chilean municipalities which correspond to the organizations in charge of

managing each county Municipal efficiency is understood as ldquotechnical efficiencyrdquo that is the

possibility that each municipality has reached the same level of outputs with less use of inputs

Then we analyse how income inequality controlling for other contextual factors such as

socioeconomic demographic geographical and political characteristics may help to explain

17

differences in municipal performance Our main hypothesis is that municipal efficiency is

inversely associated with income inequality Moreover we seek a causal interpretation of this

relationship

Municipal performance could be influenced by income inequality in direct and indirect ways

In a direct sense income inequality is used to capture the degree of heterogeneity and complexity

in the demand for public services that citizens exert over local authorities Hence higher levels of

income inequality should be associated with a more complex set of public services and therefore

with lower levels of municipal efficiency (Jottier Ashworth amp Heyndels 2012) Furthermore

when high levels of inequality exist the richest groups can exert a higher influence over local

authorities resulting in low quality and quantity of services for most of the population Among

indirect effects high and persistent inequality could be the source of corrupted institutions and

local authorities favouring themselves or specific groups This undermines citizensrsquo participation

in civic activities and their willingness to monitor municipal performance (Uslaner amp Brown

2005) Additionally the potential benefits of decentralization on the way local governments

deliver public services will be limited when the context is characterized by corrupted politicians

and a limited administrative and financial capacity (Scott 2009)

We measure municipal efficiency using an input-oriented Data Envelopment Analysis

(DEA) to obtain efficiency scores for our sample of 324 municipalities in each year from 2006 to

2017 Then we study the influence on municipal efficiency of income inequality and our set of

contextual factors using a panel of six years corresponding to those years for which household

income information is available 2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017 Our dependent variable

is the set of efficiency scores which are relative measures of efficiency They are relative to the

18

municipalities included in the sample and they do not imply that higher technical efficiency gains

cannot be achieved Thus we use both cross-sectional and panel censored regression models To

tackle endogeneity issues and suggest a causal interpretation we also propose using the proportion

of firms in the primary sector as an instrument for income inequality

We find an average efficiency score of 83 meaning that Chilean municipalities could

reduce the use of inputs by 17 without reducing their outputs We also measure municipal

efficiency under different assumptions related to returns to scale This allows us to disaggregate

technical efficiency to assess whether inefficiencies are due to management issues (pure technical

efficiency) or scale issues (scale efficiency) Although the results show that most municipalities

operate under increasing or decreasing returns to scale scale inefficiencies only explain a small

proportion of total municipal inefficiencies This highlights the need to look for contextual factors

outside the control of local authorities to explain differences in municipal performance

Geographical representations of our results in terms of returns to scale and efficiency scores

show some spatial clustering process among municipalities Spatial statistics tests confirm that

efficiency scores show a significant positive spatial autocorrelation This means that neighbouring

municipalities tend to show similar levels of efficiency This similar performance could be due to

a process of spatial dependence (eg efficiency spillovers among neighbouring municipalities) or

due to the existence of structural-geographical similarities (spatial heterogeneity) To assess the

spatial dimension in municipal efficiency abstracting from temporal fluctuations we use a cross-

section of data consisting of the six-year average for the variables in our panel After running a

regression of efficiency scores against the set of controls the analysis of OLS residuals shows that

the spatial autocorrelation is almost completely removed This means that the spatial pattern in

19

municipal efficiency can be explained (controlled) by other variables such as regional indicator

variables rather than efficiency itself Given this result we proceed to study the influence of

income inequality on municipal efficiency using traditional (non-spatial) regression analysis

In contrast to literature that emphasizes an equity-efficiency trade-off (Andersen amp Maibom

2020 Berg amp Ostry 2011 Browning amp Johnson 1984 Okun 2015) that is greater equality leads

to lower efficiency we find that municipal efficiency is inversely associated with income

inequality This implies that more equal counties are also those with higher municipal efficiency

Furthermore the coefficient of income inequality is close to one when we use the instrumental

variable approach This means that a reduction in income inequality ceteris paribus should be

associated with an increase in the same magnitude in municipal efficiency This result has strong

policy implications The non-existence of the trade-off suggests that there is more to be gained by

targeting policies towards the reduction of inequality than conventional theories suggest For

instance these policies may help increase the levels of efficiency and well-being at least at the

municipal level

Social cohesion and economic diversity

The third essay studies the relationship between the degree of social cohesion and diversity

in Chile Extant literature has argued that one of the main factors influencing social cohesion is

the degree of economic and ethnic-racial diversity within a society This diversity erodes social

cohesion reducing trust and corrupting institutions (Letki 2008 Rothstein amp Uslaner 2005

Tolsma Van der Meer amp Gesthuizen 2009 Uslaner 2011 2013)

To measure social cohesion scholars have traditionally used measures of social capital trust

or feelings of insecurity (Ariely 2014 Chan To amp Chan 2006 Letki 2008) We suggest the use

20

of the rate of incivilities per 1000 inhabitants as a proxy for social cohesion Incivilities correspond

to those antisocial behaviours (eg groups of rowdy teens and public drunkenness) or visible

neighbourhood conditions (eg graffiti and abandoned buildings) that tend not to be treated as

crime Using the rate of incivilities is arguably a more objective and reliable measure of social

cohesion particularly in countries where institutions of order and security are among the most

trusted An increase in the rate of incivilities rather than changes in crime rates should better

capture the worsening in social cohesion experienced in countries such as Chile where crime rates

are not growing but social conflicts are on the rise Thus the main hypothesis in this essay is that

the rate of incivilities (social cohesion) should be positively (negatively) associated with economic

and racial diversity

Using panel count data models we start analysing how differences in incivilities rates

between and within counties are associated with differences in indicators of relative and absolute

economic disadvantage We use the Gini coefficient of each county as our measure of economic

diversity Although we find a significant and positive association between the rate of incivilities

and the level of income inequality the magnitude of the link seems to be small Among absolute

indicators of economic disadvantage only the level of income shows a strong effect Next we

include our measure of racial diversity We use the number of new visas granted to foreigners as

a proportion of the county population Results show a significant and strong positive association

between the rate of incivilities and racial diversity

To check the robustness of our results we analyse the impact of our measures of economic

and racial diversity running our models separately for each Chilean region and clustering them

geographically We also split the total number of incivilities in four categories to see which type

21

of incivilities show the greatest association with our measures of diversity In general results

support the ldquocommunity heterogeneity hypothesisrdquo that higher community heterogeneity is

associated with higher rates of incivilities (Alesina amp La Ferrara 2002 Letki 2008 Tolsma et al

2009) However results do not support the ldquoincivilities thesisrdquo that the distribution of incivilities

tends to mirror the distribution of income inequality (Skogan 1999 Taylor 1999)

Three results stand out among the set of control variables First the level of education shows

and independent and significant negative association with the rate of incivilities This is in contrast

to previous studies where education acts mainly as a moderator of the effect of economic and racial

diversity on social cohesion (Tolsma et al 2009) The results also show that there is no significant

relationship between the rate of incivilities and the proportion of young population This is relevant

because policies aimed to reduce incivilities usually put the focus on specific groups such as young

people which are linked to physical and social incivilities when social control is weakened

Finally the degree of financial municipal autonomy also shows a significant negative association

with the rate of incivilities This result suggests that municipalities can contribute independently

or together with the central government to reduce incivilities and strengthen social cohesion

Contributions

The three essays in this thesis provide several important insights into the analysis of the

causes and consequences of income inequality particularly in the context of Chile ndash a typical

resource rich economy with persistently high levels of income inequality

Essay 1 advances the understanding of the relationship between income inequality and

natural resources in Chile extending the empirical analysis from the regional level to the county

level In addition the geographic heterogeneity of income inequality is explored with the inclusion

22

of alternative sources of spatial dependence as a potential dimension of the causal relationship

between income inequality and natural resources This essay demonstrates the relevance of natural

resources in explaining the persistence of income inequality even after controlling for other

socioeconomics and institutional factors Findings from this study have potential contribution not

only in the design of policies aimed to reduce income inequality but also in addressing the current

developmental bias between the metropolitan region and the rest of the country

Essay 2 is one of the first studies that undertake a longitudinal analysis of the effects of

income inequality on the efficiency of municipal governments in Chile To capture the role of the

municipal governments in the provision to local people of public services such as education and

health we specify several inputs and outputs in our efficiency model which is different from the

conventional specification in the existing literature For example the number of medical

consultations in public health facilities and the number of enrolled students in public schools are

used as outputs instead of general indicators such as county population Our empirical analysis

also utilises a larger sample of municipalities and covers a much longer period spanning from 2006

to 2017 This essay also investigates the contextual factors beyond the control of local authorities

that can explain variations in the efficiency of municipal governments across the country

Empirical findings from Essay 2 help us increase our understanding of the production

technology of municipalities the sources of inefficiencies and specifically the impact of income

inequality on the performance of local authorities The results deliver two main policy

implications First municipal inefficiencies in the provision of public goods and services differ

across Chilean municipalities In addition efficiency levels show some degree of spatial

autocorrelation This implies that policies such as amalgamation or cooperation among

23

municipalities could have effects beyond the municipalities involved which must be considered

Second the causal effect that income inequality has on municipal efficiency provides another

dimension into the design and implementation of development policies

Essay 3 explores for the first time the effects of economic and racial diversity on social

cohesion in Chile This essay considers incivilities as manifestation of social cohesion and

investigates as extant literature suggests whether indicators of relative economic disadvantage

such as income inequality are among the main factors driving social disorganization and social

unrest Empirical findings suggest that on the one hand economic heterogeneity captured by the

Gini coefficient has a disparate effect both in terms of magnitude and significance on the rate of

incivilities across the country On the other hand the impact of racial heterogeneity appears to be

stronger more significant and of a similar magnitude throughout the country Results also provide

new insights into the design of national policies addressing social disorders particularly those

policies focussed on specific groups of the population and the role of local authorities Overall the

findings provide an opportunity to advance the understanding of the process of weakening in the

social cohesion experienced in Chile and the conflicts that have risen from this process

Thesis outline

The remainder of the thesis is organized as follows Chapter 2 presents essay 1 examining

the association between income inequality and the degree of dependence on natural resources

Chapter 3 presents essay 2 which looks for a causal relationship between municipal efficiency and

income inequality Chapter 4 presents essay 3 analysing the relationship between social cohesion

and economic and racial diversity Finally Chapter 5 presents some concluding remarks

24

Chapter 2 Natural Resources Curse or Blessing Evidence on

Income Inequality at the County Level in Chile

21 Introduction

A phenomenon of increasing inequality of incomes and wealth in recent decades has been

documented by leading scholars and international organizations such as the International Monetary

Fund (Berg amp Ostry 2017 Ostry Berg amp Tsangarides 2014) and the Organization for Economic

Cooperation and Development (Cingano 2014) These efforts have placed the topic of inequality

at the top of the current economic debate recognizing inequality as a determinant not only of

economic growth but also of human development They also have highlighted the necessity for

more research on the drivers of inequality and mechanisms through which it manifests aiming to

design effective policies in reducing economic and social inequalities

Various factors have been analysed as the sources of high and increasing levels of inequality

Among the most significant factors are the levels of income at initial stages of economic

development (Kuznets 1955) Globalization (Milanovic 2016) skill-biased technological change

(Tinbergen 1975) investment in human capital (Murphy amp Topel 2016) institutions

redistributive policy and country-specific characteristics (Acemoglu 1995 2002 Acemoglu

Aghion amp Violante 2001 Acemoglu Johnson amp Robinson 2001) Our focus in this essay is on

the importance that the natural resource endowment (NRE) or lack thereof can play in the

determination of income disparities

25

This essay studies the patterns and evolution of income inequality in the context of a natural

resource-rich country Using the case of the Chilean economy we aim to understand and

disentangle how a phenomenon of high- and persistent-income inequality is related to the

endowment of natural resources that a country owns Chile is an interesting case to study because

despite showing a successful history of economic growth inequality among individuals and among

aggregated spatial units has shown a strong persistence (Paredes et al 2016) Furthermore Chile

has remained among the most unequal countries in the world1

Theory and empirical evidence do not establish a clear link between income inequality and

NRE In addition NRE has received considerably less attention (Auty 2001 ElGindi 2017) and

most of the evidence has been focused on cross-country comparisons For instance NRE can

influence inequality by determining its initial levels (Engerman amp Sokoloff 1994 1997

Engerman Sokoloff Urquiola amp Acemoglu 2002) shaping the evolution of institutions

(Acemoglu 2002) make the educational system less intellectually challenging and moulding the

structure of economic activity (Leamer et al 1999) So studying how cross-county differences in

NRE are associated with the distribution of income within a country has theoretical empirical and

policy implications

In this study we offer empirical evidence on the relationship between income inequality and

the endowment of natural resources using data at the county level in Chile for the period 2006-

2017 Income inequality is measured by the Gini coefficient The importance of NRE is proxied

using a measure of natural resource dependence (NRD) defined as the percentage of the total

1 A 2014 OECD report on income inequality (httpwwwoecdorgsocialincome-distribution-databasehtm) showed Chile as the country with the highest Gini coefficient of disposable income among OECD countries OECD also indicates Chile as the country with the widest gap between the richest 10 percent and the poorest 10 percent of countryrsquos population among its 34 members (OECD 2014)

26

employment in each county corresponding to the primary sector (agriculture forestry fishing and

mining)

The main hypothesis to be tested is whether income inequality is positively associated with

the degree of NRD The transmission mechanisms through which natural resources could influence

socioeconomic outcomes could be based on the market or institutions The market-based approach

argues that natural resource booms could be associated with an appreciation of the real exchange

rate and a crowding out effect over other more productive economic activities such as

manufacturing It could also delay the adoption of new technologies and reduce incentives to invest

in physical and human capital (Gylfason amp Zoega 2003) Based on the ldquoResource Curse

Hypothesisrdquo (RCH) natural resources could be a curse when the political and institutional

framework is weak and natural resources are concentrated in space such as oil and minerals

(Deacon 2011) 2 Among institutional channels a higher NRD or natural resource booms could

be associated with rent seeking misallocation of labour and entrepreneurial talent institutional

and political decline or even violent conflicts For instance the ldquoParadox of Plentyrdquo sustains that

windfalls of revenues as a consequence of resource booms could be related to a lack of incentives

to perform efficiently corruption patronage and local authorities favouring their voters or being

captured by the richest groups (Dauvin amp Guerreiro 2017) Hence a higher NRD or natural

resource booms could be the explanation not only for low levels of growth in regions more

dependent on natural resources but also it could be the root of income disparities

2 There is a wide strand of research on the Resource Curse Hypothesis however the evidence so far is not conclusive Evidence in favour of RCH has been mainly found in developing resource rich countries (Auty 1993 2001 Badeeb Lean amp Clark 2017 Blanco amp Grier 2012 Borge et al 2015 Brunnschweiler amp Bulte 2008 Sachs amp Warner 2001 Van der Ploeg 2011)

27

To test our hypothesis that is whether the levels of income inequality across counties are

positively associated with the degree of NRD we use a spatial econometric approach We use this

approach because attributes such as income inequality in one region may not be independent of

attributes in neighbouring regions (Armstrong amp Taylor 2000) This process of spatial dependence

invalidates the use of traditional (non-spatial) approaches

This study seeks to make two contributions to research First previous empirical evidence

shows a significant spatial dimension of income inequality in Chile (Paredes et al 2016)

However this dimension has been barely explored with most studies limiting the degree of

disaggregation to a regional scale (Aroca amp Bosch 2000) We use a spatial approach which makes

it possible to model and test the significance of the spatial dimension in the analysis of income

inequality and its relationship with other variables Second previous research for the Chilean

economy linking inequality with NRE has been mainly focused on explaining differences between

regions or the importance and effects of the mining-copper sector (Aroca amp Atienza 2011 Ebert

amp La Menza 2015 Lagos amp Blanco 2010 Rehner Baeza amp Barton 2014) We extend this

analysis using data for local economies Identifying and quantifying the impact of NRE on income

inequality at the county level is likely to be more informative for policies aiming to address the

current developmental bias between the metropolitan region and the rest of the country Moreover

the analysis of the role of natural resources in conjunction with other potential sources of inequality

may shed lights in understanding the persistence of the high levels of inequality observed in the

Chilean economy All in all this study could contribute to the design of policies that

simultaneously help reduce inequality increase efficiency and promote sustainable and inclusive

growth

28

Our main finding shows that after controlling for other potential sources of income

inequality such as educational level demographic characteristics and the level of public

government expenditure the degree of dependence on natural resources has a significant effect on

income inequality However contrary to our expectations the effect is negative This result

suggests that the natural or policy-driven process of transformation from primary and extractive

activities to manufacturing and service sectors imposes additional challenges to central and local

authorities aiming to reduce income inequality

In section 22 we review the literature on the relationship between income inequality and

natural resources In section 23 we establish our research problem and main hypothesis Section

24 describes our data and methods and section 25 the empirical results We finish with section

26 discussing our main results concluding and proposing avenues for future research

22 Inequality and Natural Resources

221 Theoretical Framework

Explanations for income inequality can be associated with individual institutional political

and contextual characteristics Individual characteristics include age gender and mainly the level

of education and skills of the population in the labour force For instance globalization and

technological change lead firms to increase the demand for skilled labour deepening income

inequality between skilled and unskilled workers (Atkinson 2015 Milanovic 2016 Tinbergen

1975) Among institutional characteristics labour unions collective bargaining and the minimum

wage have been suggested as explanations of income inequality (Acemoglu Aghion et al 2001

Atkinson 2015) Policy design associated with market regulation progressive taxation and

redistribution can also impact the levels and patterns of inequality

29

A key factor in understanding the levels and differences in income distribution within a

country may be its endowment of natural resources NRE shapes the structure of the economy

(Leamer et al 1999) it is associated with the creation of institutions that define the political

culture and it can also influence the performance of other sectors (Watkins 1963) In addition

NRE determines initial conditions market competition ownership over resources rent seeking

and the geographical concentration of the population and economic activity

Cross‐countryliterature

Bourguignon and Morrison (1990) introduce one of the earliest theoretical frameworks

describing the relationship between inequality and NRE They develop a small open economy

model where income distribution is a function of NRE ownership structure and trade protection

Giving cross-sectional evidence for a group of developing countries they conclude that the impact

of NRE particularly mineral resources and land depends on the number and size of the firms

whether they are public or private and the level of protection A higher concentration of production

in a few private firms a big share of production oriented to foreign instead of domestic markets

and protection increasing the relative price of scarce resources are some of the reasons explaining

why some countries are less egalitarian than others

NRE could also influence the evolution and levels of inequality by determining the initial

distribution of incomes This is known as the ldquoEngerman-Sokoloff Hypothesisrdquo (Engerman amp

Sokoloff 1997 Engerman et al 2002) In addition Leamer (1999) proposes that inequality and

development paths in each economy are a function of its economic structure which in turn depends

on ldquofundamentalsrdquo and ldquosymptomsrdquo On the one hand ldquofundamentalsrdquo refer to resource

endowment production structure closeness to markets and governments interventions On the

30

other hand ldquosymptomsrdquo are related to institutions employment structure and net export structure

Using this conceptual framework Leamer argues that natural Resource-Rich Countries (RRC) can

experience a higher level of inequality because can have a ldquodumbbell educational systemrdquo

ownership is concentrated in small groups and extraction activities require low-skilled workers

This implies fewer incentives to educate citizens until very late in the development process

resulting in human capital not prepared to take advantage of the process of technological progress

and delaying the emergence of more efficient and competitive sectors such as manufacturing and

services

Using 1980 and 1990 data for a group of countries classified according to land abundance

Leamer (1999) provides evidence showing that on the one hand land-scarce countries concentrate

their production and employment in sectors that promote equality such as capital-intensive

manufacturing chemical or machinery On the other hand countries abundant in natural resources

concentrate their production trade or employment in sectors that promote income inequality such

as the production of food beverages extraction activities or forestry

Gylfason and Zoega (2003) using a framework based on standard growth models also

proposed a positive relationship between NRE and inequality They assume that workers can work

in the primary sector or in the manufacturing (including services) sector In addition wage income

is equally distributed in the manufacturing sector but unequally in the primary sector (because of

initial distribution competition rent seeking etc) Therefore inequality will be greater when a

bigger proportion of labour is dedicated to extraction activities in the primary sector This

phenomenon is further amplified because of lower incentives to invest in physical and human

capital to adopt new technologies and to increase the share of the manufacturing sector

31

Diverse mechanisms explaining the link between NRE and inequality have been proposed

arguing that NRE determines simultaneously economic growth and inequality (Gylfason amp Zoega

2003) NRE could impact economic growth through the real exchange rate and the crowding-out

effect on manufacturing (ldquoDutch Diseaserdquo) reducing incentives to invest in physical and human

capital (Easterly 2007) and influencing the processes of technology adoption industrialization

and diversification of the economy in a manner that is less conducive to growth (Bulte et al 2005)

These potential explanations related to the called ldquoResource Curse Hypothesisrdquo do not have strong

empirical support (Auty 2001 Bulte et al 2005)

NRE may also influence economic growth through the quality of institutions (Acemoglu

1995 Acemoglu Aghion et al 2001 Acemoglu amp Robinson 2002 Engerman amp Sokoloff 1997

Engerman et al 2002) the concentration of ownership political power and rent-seeking NRE

acts by shaping institutional context and social infrastructure a phenomenon that is stronger when

resources are spatially concentrated such as minerals and plantations (Bulte et al 2005) NRE

could also have a significant effect on social cohesion and instability spreading its influence like

a disease (Brunori Ferreira amp Peragine 2013 Kanbur amp Venables 2005 Milanovic 2016

Ocampo 2004)

Considering a non-tradable sector intensive in unskilled workers Goderis and Malone

(2011) develop a model where the natural resources sector experiences an exogenous gift of

resource income They analyse the impact over income inequality of resource booms proxied by

changes in a commodity price index They conclude that inequality decreases in the short run but

increases after the initial reduction

32

Fum and Hodler (2010) show that natural resources increase inequality but this is

conditional on the level of ethnical polarization of society Carmignani (2013 2010) confirms this

positive relationship using different measures of dependence and abundance and goes further

arguing that inequality constitutes an indirect channel through which NRE affects human

development

Singlecountryevidence

Most of the studies about the relationship between inequality and NRE derive from cross-

country analyses Evidence for specific countries has been mainly based on case studies Howie

and Atakhanova (2014) based on the model of Goderis and Malone (2011) find for the case of

Kazakhstan that income and consumption inequality decreased significantly after booms in the oil-

and-gas sector because of resource booms increase the demand for non-tradable goods which are

intensive in unskilled workers The results depend on the level of rurality institutional quality

education levels and public spending on health and education Fleming and Measham (2015b

2015a) evaluate the impact of booms in the mining and oil sectors in Australia They find that a

boom in the mining sector increases income inequality due to commuting and migration among

regions This phenomenon can be exacerbated when the demanding access to natural resource

revenues is associated with the creation of more local administrative units (counties provinces and

even regions) but the government capacity is not simultaneously improved (Cust amp Poelhekke

2015 Michaels 2011) Furthermore the benefits that a region can receive in the form of fiscal

transfers can be more than compensated by the loses due to city-to-mine commuting such as the

case of mining regions in Chile (Aroca amp Atienza 2011)

33

Other studies at the local level have analysed the impact of the mining sector in Peru (Aragoacuten

amp Rud 2013 Loayza amp Rigolini 2016 Loayza Teran amp Rigolini 2013) Spain (Domenech

2008) and Canada (Papyrakis amp Raveh 2014) and the effects of oil windfalls in Brazil (Caselli amp

Michaels 2013)

In summary there is a wide range of potential mechanisms through which NRE could

influence income inequality Although most of them seem to suggest a positive relationship others

such as commuting and increased within-county demand for non-tradable goods and services

could lead to a negative association This highlights the need to know the sign of this association

in the Chilean economy where the trend shows a reduction in the degree of NRD After controlling

for other factors a positive link would support the argument that the reduction in the degree of

NRD has been relevant in the reduction experienced by income inequality in the same period

However a negative link would support the position that the reduction in NRD has contributed to

explain the persistence of income inequality and its slow reduction

222 The relevance of the spatial approach

Inequalities within countries are still the most important form of inequality from the political

point of view (Milanovic 2016) People from a geographic area within a country are influenced

and care most about their status relative to the people in other areas in the same country The

influence among regions involves multiple aspects (eg economic political and environmental)

These potential interactions have been traditionally ignored assuming independence among

observations related to different regions Moreover neglecting the process of spatial interaction in

key indicators of the economic and social performance of a country may mislead the design of the

public policy

34

The spatial dimension could play a significant role in understanding the distribution of

income within a country One strand of efforts aiming to capture the geographic heterogeneity of

inequality has been focussed on decomposing general indicators such as the Gini coefficient or the

Theil Index Evidence for different countries including the US (Doran amp Jordan 2016) China

(Akita 2003 Gustafsson amp Shi 2002 Ye Ma Ye Chen amp Xie 2017 Yue Zhang Ye Cheng

amp Leipnik 2014) Japan (Ohtake 2008) South Africa (Leibbrandt Finn amp Woolard 2012) and

Chile (Paredes et al 2016) shows that regional inequality is sensitive to the geographic scale of

analysis These studies also show a significant spatial component in the explanation of inequality

of income expenditure or gross domestic product for each country

Another strand explicitly uses exploratory spatial data analysis (ESDA) and spatial

econometrics ESDA has been used to provide new insights about the nature of regional disparities

of incomes and growth rates (Celebioglu amp Dallrsquoerba 2010 Yue et al 2014) Spatial econometric

models aim to assess and address the nature of the spatial effects These effects could be the result

of ldquospatial heterogeneityrdquo that is different relationships in distinct locations or ldquospatial

dependencerdquo which implies cross-sectional interactions (spillover effects) among units from

distinct but near locations

Spatial spillovers have been analysed to study both positive and negative spatial correlation

among less resource-abundant counties and resource-abundant counties On the one hand less

resource-abundant counties may experience positive spillovers because their industries supply

more goods and services to meet the increasing regional demand They can also be benefited from

positive agglomeration externalities and higher investment in private and public infrastructure

(Allcott amp Keniston 2014 Michaels 2011) On the other hand negative spillovers could be the

35

result of a high degree of interregional migration that limits the rise in wages and higher local

prices due to the increase in the share of the non-tradable sector In addition local governments

could have a limited capacity to translate the revenues from resource booms into effective public

policies promoting a sustained local development (Beine Coulombe amp Vermeulen 2015 Caselli

amp Michaels 2013 Papyrakis amp Raveh 2014)

23 Research problem and hypotheses

We can conclude from our overview of the literature that the theoretical and empirical

evidence about the link between inequality and natural resources is inconclusive This does not

make clear whether the process of reduction in the degree of dependence on natural resources

such as that experienced by the Chilean economy helps to explain the sustained but slow reduction

in income inequality or its high persistence

The research question guiding this study relates to how the natural resource endowment

determines the paths and structure of income inequality in natural resource-rich countries Using

the case of Chile the main hypotheses to be tested is whether a higher degree of dependence on

natural resources is associated with higher levels of income inequality To do that we use data at

the county level and we explicitly include the spatial dimension Our aim is to arrive at a more

comprehensive understanding of the drivers and transmission mechanisms explaining the

evolution and patterns shown by income inequality In addition we test whether the spatial

dimension plays a significant role in explaining differences in income distribution in Chile

36

24 Data and Methods

We use county-level data for the years 2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017 The reason

for not using contiguous years is that income data at the household level are only available every

two-three years from the Chilean National Socioeconomic Characterization Survey (CASEN in its

Spanish acronym)3 For the period 2006-2017 the Chilean administrative division considers 15

regions 54 provinces and 346 counties Data on income are available for 324 counties and six

years resulting in a panel with 1944 observations4

We start evaluating the spatial dimension in our data and analysing the link between

inequality and NRD using a cross-sectional setting To this end we use the ldquosix-year averagerdquo

(2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017) for our variables given the low time variability showed by

our measures of income inequality and NRD Results are then compared with those of a panel data

setting

241 Operationalization of key variables

The dependent variable in the present study income inequality at the county level is

measured calculating the Gini coefficient using three definitions of household income labour

autonomous and monetary income5 Labour income corresponds to the incomes obtained by all

members in the household excluding domestic service consisting of wages and salaries earnings

3 CASEN survey is conducted by the Chilean Ministry of Social Development covering topics such as education employment income and health CASEN is considered nationally representative and it is the main source for measures of inequality and poverty used for the design and evaluation of social policies in Chile 4 The six waves of CASEN for our study considered an average of 75599 households and 252081 individuals 5 The Gini coefficient is chosen because provides an overall estimate of income inequality It summarizes what proportion of the population gains what proportion of the total income The Gini coefficient can range between 0 (everyone in the population has the same income) and 1 (one person earns 100 per cent of the income in the community)

37

from independent work and self-provision of goods Autonomous income is the sum of labour

income and non-labour income (including capital income) consisting of rents interest and dividend

earnings pension healthcare benefits and other private transfers Finally monetary income is

defined as the sum of autonomous income and monetary subsidies which correspond to cash

transfers by the public sector through social programs Appendix A shows summary statistics for

the Gini coefficient of our three measures of income

The main independent variable in our study is the degree of dependence on natural resources

in each county To have an idea of the importance of each economic activity in the Chilean

economy particularly those activities related to natural resources Figure 21 shows their average

share in Chilean Gross Domestic Product (GDP) for the period 2006-17 We can observe that the

leading activities are those related to the primary sector especially mining and to the tertiary

sector where financial personal commerce restaurants and hotels services stand out The shares

of each economic activity in GDP vary significantly between Chilean regions and such

information is not available at the county level

Figure 21 Average share in GDP of economic activities (2006ndash17)

38

Leamer (1999) argues that when the main source of income is labour income (as indeed

happens for the Chilean case) using employment shares allows a better approach to measuring

dependence on natural resources Using employment data from CASEN survey we define our

measure of NRD as the employment in the primary sector (mining fishing forestry and

agriculture) as a percentage of the total employment in each county We name this variable

pss_casen where ldquopssrdquo stands for ldquoprimary sector sharerdquo We built other two proxies of NRD

using data from the ldquoServicio de Impuestos Internosrdquo (SII) which is the agency in charge of

collecting taxes in Chile The variable pss measures the percentage of employment in the primary

sector and the variable pss_firms measures the number of firms in the primary sector as a

percentage of the total number of firms in each county Appendix B shows summary statistics for

our three measures of NRD disaggregated by region

Figure 22 Evolution of Gini coefficient and measures of NRD (2006ndash17)

39

Figure 22 shows the evolution of our measure of inequality (using the Gini coefficient of

autonomous income) and our three potential proxies for NRD for the period 2006-2017 We

observe that both income inequality and the degree of NRD show a downward trend This seems

to support our hypothesis of a positive link between inequality and NRD however we need to

control of other sources of inequality before getting such a conclusion In what follows we use the

variable gini as our measure of income inequality capturing the Gini coefficient of autonomous

income Our measure of NRD is the variable pss_casen defined previously

Figure 23 Spatial distribution of Gini coefficient and NRD (2006ndash17)

Note Gini and NRD averages 2006-09-11-13-15-17 for 324 Chilean counties divided into five equal groups Source Own elaboration based on CASEN survey

40

Figure 23 shows quantile maps for income inequality (on the left) and NRD (on the right)

using the six-years average dataset6 On the one hand we observe that high levels of inequality

seem to be clustered in the Centre-South of the country where agriculture forestry and fishery are

the predominant economic activities Only isolated counties show high inequality in the Centre

(Metropolitan area where the countyrsquos capital is located) and North (Mining) areas On the other

hand our measure of NRD seems to show an opposite spatial pattern than income inequality with

high levels in the Centre and North of the country

242 Control variables

To control for county characteristics we use a set of socio-economic demographic and

institutional variables Economic factors are captured by the natural log of the mean autonomous

household income per capita (in thousands of Chilean pesos of 2017) lnincome the poverty rate

poverty the unemployment rate unemployment the percentage of the population living in rural

areas rural and the average years of education of the population over 15 years old education

Demographic factors include the proportion of the population in the labour force labour_force

and the natural log of population density (population divided by county area) lndensity

We also include the natural log of the total municipal public expenditure per capita

lnmuni_expenditure to control for municipal heterogeneity This heterogeneity is mainly related

to the capacity of municipalities to generate their own revenues In addition the richest

municipalities are in the Metropolitan region which concentrates economic power and around 40

6 After sorting a variable in ascending order quantile maps use the quantiles (quartiles quintiles deciles etc) as class breaks to divide the distribution of the variable where each class includes approximately the same number of observations (counties)

41

of the population This has basically implied a lag in the development of regions other than the

metropolitan region

The spatial distribution of our measures of income inequality and NRD displayed in Figure

23 seems to show different patterns in the North Centre and South of the country Appendix C

shows the administrative division of Chile in 15 regions and how we have grouped them in three

zones North Centre and South We consider as the ldquoCentrerdquo area that formed by the Metropolitan

region (XIII) and its two neighbouring regions V and VI Using the Centre area as our reference

we include in our analysis two dummy variables indicating whether a county is located in the North

area (regions XV I II III and IV) or South area (regions VII VIII IX XIV X XI and XII)

Appendix D shows summary statistics for the set of numeric control variables and the

correlation matrix between our measure of NRD pss_casen and the set of numeric controls

243 Methods

To assess and then consider the spatial nature of the data we need to define the set of relevant

neighbours for each country This is operationalized by building a matrix called ldquoWrdquo with a ldquo1rdquo

for neighbouring counties and a ldquo0rdquo for non-neighbouring counties We could build W using

contiguity-based (whether counties share a border or point) or geography-based (taking the

distances among the centroids of each county polygon) spatial weights Specifically we build a W

matrix considering the 5-nearest counties7 Two reasons explain the choice of k-nearest

neighbours First we cannot use a contiguity criterium because we do not have information about

all the counties and there are some geographically isolated counties Second given the significant

7 We assign a ldquo1rdquo to the five nearest counties to each county based on the distances among the polygon centroids Then W is ldquorow standardizedrdquo This facilitates the interpretation of the spatial lag of a variable as the ldquoweighted average valuerdquo of the same variable in neighbouring counties

42

differences in county areas (ldquobig countiesrdquo in northern and southern regions) using a distance-

band criterium with a not enough large distance band can lead to many ldquoislandsrdquo in extreme regions

and a multi-modal distribution for the number of neighbours

We start testing our inequality and NRD variables for spatial autocorrelation in order to

evaluate statistically the clustering patterns shown in Figure 23 Next we run an OLS regression

of inequality against NRD and our set of controls and we test the spatial autocorrelation of OLS

residuals If we cannot reject the null hypothesis of random spatial distribution we do not need

spatial models to analyse income inequality which would give contrasting evidence to previous

suggestions about the relevance of the spatial dimension of income inequality in Chile (Paredes

2013 Paredes et al 2016) If we find significant spatial autocorrelation in the OLS residuals this

justifies the use of spatial models and highlight the need to find the correct spatial structure8

If inequality in one county spillovers or influences inequality in neighbouring counties the

spatial lag of inequality should be included as an explanatory variable and we should use a spatial

autoregressive model (SAR) If some unobserved variable is the explanation for the clustering of

counties with similar inequality then this will be better captured including a spatial lag of the

errors and we should use a spatial error model (SEM) (Anselin 1988 Anselin amp Bera 1998)

Finally when our main explanatory variable or some of the controls show spatial autocorrelation

a spatial lag of the explanatory variable(s) should be included in our model

8 The existence of spatial autocorrelation violates the standard assumption of independence among observations needed for OLS regression This will result in OLS coefficients biased and inconsistent (Anselin 1988)

43

244 Spatial Model Specification

A model that includes the three forms of spatial dependence described above is called the

Cliff-Ord Model The model in its cross-sectional representation could be expressed as

119910 120582119882119910 119883120573 119882119883120574 119906 (21)

where

119906 120588119882119906 120576 (22)

119882 is our weight matrix that works as an NxN spatial lag operator9 Thus 119882119910 119882119883 and 119882119906

are the spatial lags for the dependent variable explanatory variables and the error term

respectively The parameter 120582 capture the spatial dependence in the dependent variable 120574 the

spatial dependence in the explanatory variables 120588 capture the spatial dependence in the error term

and 120598 is a vector of idiosyncratic errors For instance if ldquoyrdquo is income inequality and ldquoXrdquo a measure

of NRD the level of inequality in one county will be explained by the degree of NRD in the same

county 119883120573 the average degree of NRD in neighbouring counties 119882119883120574 the average level of

inequality in neighbouring counties 120582119882119910 and the average value of residuals in neighbouring

counties 12058811988211990610

From equations (21) and (22) the SAR and SEM models can be seen as special cases of

the Cliff-Ord representation after imposing restrictions over the spatial parameters 120582 120574 and 120588 For

the specification of the spatial panel models we follow the terminology by Croissant and Millo

9 The spatial lag is a weighted sum of the values observed at neighbouring locations 10 On the one hand the impact that income inequality in one county has over income inequality in neighbouring counties is called a ldquoglobal spilloverrdquo and it is associated with the feedback effect among neighbours (one county is its neighboursrsquo neighbourrdquo) on the other hand the influence that the degree of NRD in neighbouring counties has over inequality in one county is called a ldquolocal spilloverrdquo

44

(2018) Spatial panel models including the spatial lag of the dependent variable (SAR) the spatial

lag of the residuals (SEM) or both (SARAR) are described in Appendix E

25 Results

251 Exploratory Spatial Data Analysis (ESDA)

To analyse the significance of the spatial dimension in our data set we use the six-year

average of our variables Spatial autocorrelation is tested using the Moranrsquos I statistic11 Moranrsquos

I measures the correlation of one variable with itself in space12 Figure 24 shows the Moran scatter

plots where the standardized variable (Gini coefficient and NRD for each county) appears in the

horizontal axis against its spatial lag (average value in the 5-nearest neighbouring counties) The

Moranrsquos I (slope of the line in the Moran scatter plot) of income inequality shows a significant

positive spatial autocorrelation that is counties with high (low) inequality tend to be close to each

other

11 There are many statistics to formally test the significance of the spatial dimension in the distribution of our data The null hypothesis assumes spatial randomness which means that there is not spatial structure in the data so any spatial pattern is equally likely to occur and values in one location do not depend on values in other locations The alternative hypotheses can be the existence of positive or negative spatial autocorrelation Positive spatial autocorrelation means similar values in neighbouring locations (less variability than under spatial randomness) Negative spatial autocorrelation means dissimilar values in neighbouring locations (more variability than under spatial randomness) 12 Traditional measures of correlation such as the Pearsonrsquos coefficient measure the degree of linear correlation between two different variables Measures of spatial autocorrelation assess the correlation between the values of one variable in one location related to the values of the same variable in other neighbouring locations

45

Figure 23 Moran scatter plots for variables gini and pss_casen

Moranrsquos I is a measure of global spatial autocorrelation this means it is intended to capture

the clustering property of the entire data set To identify where are the significant hot-spots

(clusters of counties showing high income inequality) or cold-spots (clusters of counties showing

low income inequality) we need local indicators of spatial association (LISA) Using the local

Moranrsquos I (not reported) we find significant hot-spots in the South of the country (mainly

agricultural regions) and significant cold-spots in the Centre (Metropolitan area) of the country

The next step is to check whether the clustering pattern in inequality is the result of a process of

spatial dependence in the variable itself or it can be explained by other variables related to

inequality

252 Cross-sectional analysis

We start analysing differences in income inequality between counties using the six-year

average data and running an OLS regression for the model

119892119894119899119894 120573 120573 119901119904119904_119888119886119904119890119899 120573 119897119899119894119899119888119900119898119890 120573 119901119900119907119890119903119905119910 120573 119906119899119890119898119901119897119900119910119898119890119899119905 120573 119897119886119887119900119906119903_119891119900119903119888119890 120573 119890119889119906119888119886119905119894119900119899 120573 119897119899119889119890119899119904119894119905119910 120573 119903119906119903119886119897 120573 119897119899119898119906119899_119890119909119901119890119899119889119894119905119906119903119890 120573 119899119900119903119905ℎ 120573 119904119900119906119905ℎ

(23)

46

The Moran scatter plot and spatial statistical test of OLS residuals from equation (23) are

in Appendix F OLS residuals show a small but significant positive autocorrelation (Moranrsquos I =

0121) This means that income inequality continues showing a significant degree of spatial

autocorrelation after controlling for the set of covariates In addition robust Lagrange Multiplier

(LM) tests show that a spatial error model is preferred over a spatial lag model (Anselin Bera

Florax amp Yoon 1996)13 This means that income inequality tends to cluster in zones larger than a

county so the analysis should be performed on a larger scale such as provinces regions or macro

zones If the SAR model were preferred it would mean that income inequality in one county is

influenced by the level of income inequality in neighbouring counties To find the spatial structure

that best fits the clustering process of income inequality we run the full set of spatial model

specifications in a cross-sectional setting and results are shown in Table 21

Column 2 in Table 21 shows the results of our ldquoOLSrdquo model The ldquoSLXrdquo model includes

spatial dependence only through the explanatory variables The ldquoSARrdquo model includes the spatial

lag of the dependent variable as a regressor and the ldquoSEMrdquo model includes spatial dependence

through the error term The ldquoSARARrdquo model includes both the spatial lag of the response and the

errors and the ldquoSDMrdquo and ldquoSDEMrdquo are the extensions of the ldquoSARrdquo and ldquoSEMrdquo models

respectively including the spatial lag of the explanatory variables Finally a model including

spatial lags for the response errors and explanatory variables (the ldquoSARARXrdquo model) is shown in

the last column

13 Following the ldquoAnselin methodrdquo when both non robust LM tests are significant we should select between the robust LR tests From Table F1 in Appendix F only the robust LM test for the SEM model (RLMerr) appears as significant

47

Table 21

Cross-sectional Model Comparison (six-year average data)

48

Opposite to our hypothesis we observe a significant and negative coefficient for our measure

of NRD This means that counties more dependent on natural resources show lower levels of

inequality Education years population density and municipal expenditure per capita are also

negatively related to inequality On the other hand the level of income the poverty rate and the

proportion of the population living in rural areas show a positive relationship with income

inequality There is no significant influence of the unemployment rate and the proportion of the

population in the labour force In addition the SAR SEM and SARAR models show a

significantly higher average inequality in the South of the country related to the Centre area

The main finding from our cross-sectional analysis is that there is a significant and negative

relationship between inequality and NRD which is quite robust to the model specification

253 Panel Data analysis

Like the cross-sectional case we start estimating the panel without spatial effects Results

for the pooled fixed effects (FE) and random effects (RE) specifications of equation (3) are in

Appendix G Spatial models were estimated using Maximum Likelihood (ML) and Generalized

Moments (GM) and assuming that the spatial structure (W matrix) is the same for all years14

Tables 22 23 and 24 show results for the ML estimation of the SAR SEM and SARAR models

using the pooled FE and RE specifications Results for the GM estimation are in Appendix H

All our spatial models include time fixed effects In the case of the pooled and RE models they

additionally include indicator variables for those counties located in the North and South of the

country

14 In traditional (non-spatial) panels data are stacked as time series for each observational unit (county) In the case of spatial panels data are stacked as slice of cross-sections for each year in the panel

49

The main result is that the negative and significant effect of NRD on income inequality is

robust to most of the spatial panel specifications In addition the coefficient for the variable

pss_casen changes slightly among panel specifications (pooled FE and RE) but does not change

among spatial models (SAR SEM and SARAR)

Another important finding is related to the significance of the spatial dimension of income

inequality When spatial models cross-sectional or panel are compared to non-spatial models

there are no major differences in the magnitude of the coefficients or their significance This could

mean that the positive spatial autocorrelation shown by income inequality seems to be better

explained by a process of spatial heterogeneity rather than spatial dependence The practical

implication of this result is that including dummy variables for aggregated units (eg regions or

groups of regions) could be enough to control for the spatial dimension in the modelling and

analysis of income inequality

Among control variables years of education seems to be the main variable for the design of

long-term policies aimed at reducing inequality This result is in line with previous evidence for

cross-country studies (Leamer et al 1999) and specific countries (Howie amp Atakhanova 2014)

Municipal expenditure per capita also shows a significant and negative association with income

inequality in the pooled and RE spatial specifications This means that higher municipal

expenditure helps to reduce inequality between counties but its effect is more limited within

counties This result support the importance of local governments (Fleming amp Measham 2015a)

however the negative coefficient appears as evidence against the ldquoParadox of Plentyrdquo (Borge et

al 2015)

50

Table 22

ML Spatial SAR Models

Table 23

ML Spatial SEM Models

51

Table 24

ML Spatial SARAR Models

26 Discussion and conclusions

In this essay we delve deep into the sources of income inequality analysing its association

with the degree of dependence on natural resources using county-level data for the 2006ndash2017

period in Chile Given recent evidence for the Chilean economy suggesting a significant spatial

dimension we assess and incorporate explicitly the spatial structure of income inequality using

spatial methods We use cross-sectional and panel data to evaluate the significance of the spatial

dimension and we test whether NRD has a positive effect on income inequality

Contrary to what theory predicts NRD shows a significant and negative association with

income inequality This result is robust to the type of analysis (cross-sectional vs panel data) the

approach (spatial vs non-spatial) and the inclusion of different controls The negative and

significant coefficient implies that if the degree of NRD would not have experienced a 10 drop

during this period income inequality could have fallen in 2 additional points So the downward

trend in the participation of the primary sector in terms of employment in the Chilean economy

52

could be one of the main reasons explaining the high persistence in the levels of income inequality

This means that those areas that undergo a process of productive transformation mainly towards

the services sector would be facing greater problems to reduce inequality This process of

productive transformation natural or policy-driven highlights the importance of policies focused

on human capital and the role of local governments in reducing inequality

The main implication for policymakers is that a reduction in NRD does not help to reduce

inequality generating additional challenges for local and central governments in its attempt to

transform the structure of their economies to fewer dependent ones on natural resources The

finding of a significant spatial dimension suggests that defining macro zones capturing the spatial

heterogeneity in the data should be done before analysing the relationship among variables and the

design and evaluation of specific policies Particularly relevant in those areas experiencing a

reduction in NRD are migration commuting and the characteristics of the tertiary (services) sector

In addition our findings show that education and municipal expenditure could be effective policy

tools in the fight to reduce inequality in Chile

Although our results seem quite robust they do not allow us to make causal inferences about

the effect of NRD on income inequality However we could think of the following explanation to

explain the negative relationship found and the differences between geographical areas

Areas highly dependent on NR used to demand a high proportion of low-skill labour This

has change in sectors such as the mining sector in the northern area which has simultaneously

experienced an increase in activities related to the service sector such as retail restaurants

transport and housing However those services associated with more skilled labour such as the

finance sector remain concentrated in the capital region The reduction in the degree of NRD

(employment in extractive activities) implies lower labour force but more specialized with most

53

of the low-skilled labour transferred to a service sector characterized by low productivity and low

wages

Non-spatial models show that the North and South particularly the latter present

significantly higher levels of inequality This could be associated with the type of resources with

ldquopointrdquo resources such as minerals in the North and ldquodiffusedrdquo resources such as agriculture in the

South This translates into higher average incomes in the Centre and North areas and lower average

incomes in the South

The reduction in NRD implies not only a movement of the labour force from extractive

activities to manufacturing or services with the latter characterized by low productivity and low

salaries of the labour force We could also speculate that most of the high incomes move to the

central area where the economic power and ownership over firms and resources are concentrated

This would explain low inequality associated with higher average incomes in the central area and

high inequality associated with lower average incomes in the South A more in-depth analysis

capturing the mobility of wealth and labour force between counties or more aggregated areas is

needed to better understand the causal mechanism involved

Our findings open avenues for future research in different strands First studies on the causes

of income inequality should take the role of NRD into consideration which has been overlooked

so far Given that the spatial dimension of income inequality seems to be explained by a

phenomenon of spatial heterogeneity estimation strategies such as spatial regime models or

geographically weighted regression should be used (Chi amp Zhu 2019) Second the effect of NRD

on income inequality could manifest through different channels such as education fiscal transfers

and institutions We could extend our analysis to identify which of these competing channels is

the most relevant Transforming some continuous variables such as educational level to a

54

categorical variable or defining new indicator variables for instance whether a local government

shows or not an efficient performance we could classify counties in different groups and then

check whether there are differences or not in the relationship between income inequality and NRD

A third strand could be to disaggregate our measure of NRD for different industries This

would allow us to test differences among industries and to identify the sectors that promote greater

equality and which greater inequality Forth the analysis of the consequences of income inequality

on other economic and social phenomena such as efficiency economic growth and social cohesion

has a growing interest in researchers and policymakers Our findings suggest that to answer the

question of whether income inequality has a causal impact on other variables we could include a

measure of NRD as an instrument to address endogeneity issues For instance two interesting

topics for future research are the analysis of how differences in income inequality between counties

could help to explain differences in the level of efficiency of local governments and differences in

the degree of social cohesion (unrest) throughout the country Those are the issues to be addressed

in the next two essays

55

Chapter 3 The Impact of Income Inequality on the Efficiency of

Municipalities in Chile

31 Introduction

In Chile municipalities are the smallest administrative unit for which citizens choose their

local authorities playing an important role in the provision of public goods and services at the

local level Municipalities have a similar set of objectives but the level of financial resources

available to finance their activities is highly heterogeneous This could result in significant

differences in the levels of performance between municipalities Despite their importance there is

little empirical evidence about the efficiency of local governments in Chile This essay aims to

measure the technical efficiency of Chilean municipalities and to analyse how local characteristics

particularly those related to income distribution at the county level could help to explain

differences in municipal performance

Cross-country studies situate Chile as an efficient country in international comparisons about

efficiency of government spending (Herrera amp Pang 2005 Loacutepez amp Miller 2008) However

evidence for Chile at the local level is relatively sparse suggesting significant levels of

inefficiency For instance Pacheco Sanchez and Villena (2013) found a mean efficiency level of

around 70 using a sample of 309 municipalities for the period 2008-2010 This suggests that

municipalities could achieve the same level of output by reducing the usage of inputs by an average

of 30 Their study also showed that those municipalities more dependent on the central

56

government or those located in counties with lower income per capita are more efficient than their

counterparts

Most empirical research on Local Government Efficiency (LGE) has been conducted for

member countries of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) of

which Chile has been a member since 2010 In the case of European countries such as Spain and

Italy which share similar characteristics such as the monetary union and levels of GDP per head

efficiency studies have been mainly motivated by budgetary constraints (Balaguer-Coll Brun-

Martos Maacuterquez-Ramos amp Prior 2019 lo Storto 2013) The Chilean context differs in three

main ways from its OECD counterparts First except for the Metropolitan Region that concentrates

most of the population Chilean regions are highly dependent on natural resources Second Chile

is also characterized by one of the highest levels of income inequality among OECD countries

which contrast with the situation of developed natural resource-rich countries such as Australia

and Norway Third although budget constraints are also a relevant issue Chilean municipalities

have experienced a sustained increase in the level of financial resources and expenditure

Another relevant distinction when we benchmark the performance of municipalities across

different countries is the type of public services they provide On the one hand in most of the

countries included Chile the main role of local governments is to provide ldquoservices to peoplerdquo

such as public education and public health On the other hand there are countries such as Australia

where local governments mainly provide ldquoservices to propertyrdquo including waste management

maintenance of local roads and the provision of community facilities such as libraries swimming

pools and parks (Dollery Wallis amp Akimov 2010 Drew Kortt amp Dollery 2015 McQuestin

Drew amp Dollery 2018)

57

Despite contextual differences Chilean municipalities seem not to perform differently from

municipalities in other developed and natural resource-rich countries where income inequality is

significantly less than in Chile (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018a) This result highlights the

need to study the role of income inequality and the degree of dependence on natural resources over

LGE characteristics that have been largely overlooked in the literature

We measure and analyse differences in municipal performance using a two-stage approach

In the first stage we measure municipal efficiency using an input-oriented Data Envelopment

Analysis (DEA) to get a set of ldquoefficiency scoresrdquo In the second stage we regress efficiency scores

against our measure of income inequality controlling for a set of contextual factors describing the

economic socio-demographic and political context of each county

We use a sample of 324 municipalities for the period 2006-2017 During this period Chile

was divided into 346 counties belonging to 15 regions This period was characterized by important

external and internal shocks including the Global Financial Crisis (GFC) one of the biggest

earthquakes in Chilean history in 2010 and three municipal elections The availability of

information allows us to measure efficiency for the full period but the influence of contextual

factors is analysed using a panel of six years (2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017) for which

household income information is available

The main hypothesis tested in the second stage is whether higher levels of income inequality

are associated with lower levels of efficiency Previous evidence shows that when progress is not

evenly shared persistent within-country inequality reduces the effectiveness and efficiency of the

public sector (Ortega Sanjuaacuten amp Casquero 2017 Tandon 2005)

Income inequality has been used to control for a wide range of idiosyncratic factors

associated with historical institutional and cultural factors affecting efficiency (Greene 2016

58

Ortega et al 2017) For instance at the local level income inequality has been considered as an

indicator of economic heterogeneity in the population where higher inequality is associated with

a more heterogeneous set of conflicting demands for public services which adversely affect an

efficient provision (Ashworth Geys Heyndels amp Wille 2014 Geys amp Moesen 2009) Higher

levels of income inequality could also relate to economically privileged groups having a greater

capacity to influence the political system for their own benefit rather than that of the majority

When high inequality is persistent the feeling of frustration and disappointment in the population

could reduce not only trust and cooperation among individuals but also trust in institutions which

would negatively affect government efficiency (Boix amp Posner 1998 Coffeacute amp Geys 2005) For

instance national or local authorities could end exerting patronage and clientelism and showing

rising levels of corruption (Uslaner 2011 Uslaner amp Brown 2005)

One of the main gaps in extant literature is the need to conduct more analysis of LGE using

panel data taking into consideration endogeneity issues and controlling for unobserved

heterogeneity (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018a) To address the above we set-up a panel with

time and county-specific effects and we propose the use of a measure of natural resource

dependence (NRD) as an instrument for income inequality Based on the ldquoParadox of Plentyrdquo

fiscal revenues from natural resources windfalls could be associated with an over expansion of the

public sector fostering rent-seeking and corruption and reducing local government efficiency

(Dauvin amp Guerreiro 2017 Manzano amp Rigobon 2001) In the Chilean case most of the revenues

generated by local governments included those from natural resources end up in a common fund

which benefits all municipalities The aim of this common fund is precisely to reduce inequalities

among municipalities so although we do not expect a direct impact of natural resources on LGE

we could expect an indirect effect through other indicators particularly income inequality

59

As far as we know this is the first study analysing the influence of income inequality as a

determinant of municipal efficiency in Chile Moreover this is the first study in the context of a

natural resource-rich country which specifically suggests a measure of natural resource

dependence as an instrument to correct for endogeneity bias We propose the use of the proportion

of firms in the primary sector as proxy for the degree of NRD in each county We argue that this

variable is a better proxy than using the proportion of employment in the manufacturing sector

which has been proposed in previous studies (Alesina amp La Ferrara 2002) During the period

analysed our proxy remained relatively stable and showed a significant relationship with income

inequality In addition it is less likely that it has directly affected municipal efficiency

This study adds to the literature in two other ways First the extant literature suggests that

efficiency measurement could be highly sensitive to the chosen technique as well as the selection

of inputs and outputs (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018a) Inputs are usually proxied by a single

measure of total public expenditures and outputs by general proxies such as population andor the

number of businesses in each county We offer a novel approach for the selection of inputs and

outputs On the one hand we disaggregate government expenditures into four components

(operation personnel health and education) and we use the number of public schools and health

facilities in each county as a proxy for physical capital On the other hand we use four outputs

aiming to capture the wide variety of goods and services supplied by each municipality Through

this approach we aim to better describe the production function of each municipality capturing

not only the variety of inputs and outputs but also differences in size among municipalities

A third contribution relates to the measurement of LGE in the Chilean context We measure

technical and scale efficiency using a larger sample and a longer period This has empirical and

policy relevance On the one hand it helps us to select the correct DEA model and allows us to

60

determine the importance of scale inefficiencies as explanation for differences in municipal

performance On the other hand efficiency measures increase the information available for both

central and local governments to better understand the production technology that best describes

each municipality and to carry out policies to improve efficiency

We believe that our selection of inputs and outputs the use of a large dataset and the joint

analysis using cross-sectional and panel data provide a more accurate and robust analysis of

municipal efficiency Likewise knowing whether inequality has a significant influence on

municipal efficiency may provide useful insights and guidance for policymakers not only in Chile

but also for countries sharing similar characteristics

DEA results show an average level of technical efficiency (inefficiency) of around 83

(17) This means that municipalities could reduce on average a 17 the use of inputs without

reducing the outputs There are significant differences among geographic areas with the Centre

area (where the countyrsquos capital is located) displaying higher efficiency than the rest of the country

When municipal efficiency is measured under different assumptions about returns to scale results

reveal a production technology with variable returns to scales and around 75 of the

municipalities displaying scale inefficiencies However when technical efficiency is

disaggregated between pure technical efficiency and scale efficiency results show that scale

inefficiency explains a small proportion of the total municipal technical inefficiency This finding

justifies a deeper analysis of the reasons why municipalities could operate inefficiently and why

municipal performance could vary among municipalities

Efficiency scores also show a significant degree of positive spatial autocorrelation This

means that municipal efficiency shows a general clustering process with neighbouring

municipalities showing similar levels of efficiency A further analysis shows that most of the

61

spatial pattern in municipal efficiency is exogenous that is could be associated to other variables

Hence we conduct most of our regression analysis using traditional (non-spatial) methods and

leaving spatial regressions in the appendixes

Findings from cross-sectional and panel regressions support the hypothesis that municipal

performance is significantly and negatively associated with income inequality at the county level

The coefficient of income inequality is close to one which means that reductions in income

inequality ceteris paribus could be associated with increases in municipal efficiency in the same

proportion This result supports the strand of research arguing that there is not a trade-off at least

at the municipal level between equity and efficiency (Andersen amp Maibom 2020 Berg amp Ostry

2011 2017) The main policy implications are that authorities in more unequal counties would

face higher challenges to perform efficiently and policies pertaining to inequality and efficiency

should not be designed independently

The chapter is structured as follows Section 32 provides a brief literature review on related

local government efficiency Section 33 introduces the methodological background and empirical

models Section 34 presents the empirical results and discussions Section 35 concludes the

chapter

32 Related Literature

321 Measuring efficiency of local governments

Studies on measuring LGE can be grouped in those analysing the provision of single services

such as health or education and those assessing overall efficiency (lo Storto 2013) Once inputs

and outputs have been defined efficiency is measured using parametric andor non-parametric

techniques Among the former group Stochastic Frontier Analysis (SFA) seems to be preferred

62

by scholars aiming to measure efficiency and to analyse the link with environmental variables

using a single procedure (Pacheco et al 2013 Tsekeris Sotiris Tsekeris amp Papaioannou 2018)

On the non-parametric group Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA) is by far the most used technique

(Afonso amp Fernandes 2006 Balaguer-Coll amp Prior 2009 lo Storto 2013)

The selection of inputs and outputs depends not only on the aimed of the study (specific

sector vs whole measure of efficiency) but also on the role that municipalities play in different

countries There are countries such as Australia (Drew et al 2015) and Spain (Balaguer-Coll amp

Prior 2009) where local governments mainly supply services to ldquopropertyrdquo such as waste

management and road maintenance In these cases efficiency has been mainly measured using

total indicators of local government expenditure and outputs have been proxied using general

indicators such as population or number of business (Drew et al 2015) On the other hand in

countries such as Italy (lo Storto 2013) and Portugal (Afonso amp Fernandes 2008) in Europe or

Brazil (de Sousa Cribari-Neto amp Stosic 2005) and Chile (Pacheco et al 2013) in South America

municipalities mainly supply services to ldquopeoplerdquo Here in addition to financial expenditures or

revenues inputs have included the number of local government employees the number of schools

or the number of hospitals and health centres School-age population the number of students

enrolled in primary and secondary schools and the number of beds in hospitals have been

considered as outputs Based on the study of Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte (2018a) a wider list of

inputs and outputs used in previous studies can be found in Appendix I

Studies from different countries show important differences in the average efficiency scores

both between and within countries These studies also differ in the samples methodologies and

variables included A summary showing the range and variability of the mean efficiency scores

founds in countries all around the world can be found in Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte (2018a)

63

These authors also show that OECD natural resource-rich countries such as Australia Belgium

and Chile show similar results in terms of mean efficiency scores with LGE studies being less

frequent in Latin American countries

Measuring efficiency of local governments as decision-making units (DMU) presents many

challenges and difficulties (Borger Kerstens Moesen amp Vanneste 1994 Ravallion 2005)

Worthington and Dollery (2000) mention problems with the selection and measurement of inputs

the identification of different stakeholders the hidden characteristic of the ldquolocal government

technologyrdquo and the multidimensionality of the services provided by local governments All these

issues make difficult to identify and distinguish between outputs and outcomes with outputs

commonly proxied by general indicators such as county area or county population Because

efficiency measures are highly sensitive to the chosen technique and the selection of inputs and

outputs Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte (2018a) suggest formulating different specifications and

using less general and unspecified indicators Moreover the complexity in defining outputs and

the use of general indicators make more likely that contextual factors affect municipal efficiency

322 Explaining differences in LGE

To explain differences in local government performance researchers have basically

distinguished between ldquodiscretionaryrdquo and ldquonon-discretionaryrdquo factors Discretionary factors refer

to the degree of discretion of local authorities in the selection and management of inputs and

outputs On the other hand scholars have investigated the influence on LGE of contextual factors

beyond authoritiesrsquo control These factors reflective at the environment where municipalities

operate include economic socio-demographic geographic financial political and institutional

characteristics (da Cruz amp Marques 2014 Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018b)

64

In general the evidence about the influence of contextual factors has delivered mixed and

country-specific results (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018b) Sampaio de Sousa et al (2005)

using data for Brazilian municipalities finds that population density and urbanization rate have

strong positive effects on efficiency scores Benito et al (2010) show that lower levels of

efficiency of Spanish municipalities are associated with a greater economic level a less stable

population and a bigger size of the local government Afonso (2008) finds that per capita income

level and education are not significant factors influencing LGE of Portuguese municipalities He

also finds that municipalities in Northern areas show greater efficiency than their counterparts in

Southern areas More recently Tsekeris (2018) finds that spatial variations in efficiency in Greece

can be attributed to factors related to inter-regional market access specialization and sectoral

concentration resource-factor endowments and political factors among others Characteristics

describing each local government have also been used including municipal indebtedness (Benito

et al 2010) fiscal deficits (Sinha 2017) degree of fiscal autonomy (Boetti Piacenza amp Turati

2009) and individual characteristics of local authorities such as age gender and political ideology

Narboacuten‐Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte (2018b) conclude after analysing 63 articles that studies on the

influence of contextual factors have mostly used cross-sectional data with little attention to

endogeneity issues which makes any causal interpretation doubtful

323 The trade-off between efficiency and equity

The existence of a potential trade-off between efficiency and equity is in the core of

economic discussion (Andersen amp Maibom 2020 Berg amp Ostry 2011 Browning amp Johnson

1984 Okun 2015)15 The argument that economic growth (one of the most common efficiency

15 Redistributive policies distort incentives and lead to suboptimal outcomes and thus efficiency losses

65

measures) could be negatively affected in the search for greater equality has been translated not

only into economic policies that favour economic growth over those that reduce inequality but

also in the emphasis of scholarly research Thus theoretical and empirical research has been

mainly focussed on efficiency and policy implications of a great diversity of shocks and policies

leaving the analysis of inequality as one of measurement and mostly descriptive Additionally

empirical evidence of the trade-off is scant and inconclusive (Andersen amp Maibom 2020

Browning amp Johnson 1984)

Among economic contextual factors that could affect LGE income inequality has been

largely ignored An exception is a cross-country comparison conducted by Ortega (2017) who

analyses the role of inequality on government efficiency in developing countries He finds that

more unequal countries could have higher difficulties to achieve specific health outcomes Income

inequality has even been considered as part of the outputs to measure efficiency particularly for

the case of European and OECD countries (Afonso Schuknecht amp Tanzi 2010 Antonelli amp De

Bonis 2018)

At the local level income inequality has been mainly used as a proxy for the effect of income

heterogeneity Economic inequality could have a direct and an indirect effect on government

efficiency The direct effect poses that higher income inequality could reduce municipal efficiency

because it is associated with a more complex and competing set of public services demanded by

the population (Jottier et al 2012) The indirect effect puts the focus in the link between inequality

social capital and levels of corruption Economic diversity could reduce trust in people and

institutions when related to high and persistent levels of income inequality It could also affect the

willingness to participate in community and political groups the existence of a shared objective

by citizens and the perception of a prosperous future (Uslaner amp Brown 2005)

66

The evidence is ambiguous For instance Geys and Moesen (2009) find that income

inequality has little relation to efficiency of Flemish municipalities and Ashworth et al (2014)

find a negative relationship for the Norwegian case Findings also indicate that inequality is the

strongest determinant of trust and that trust has a greater effect on communal participation than on

political participation (Uslaner amp Brown 2005)

33 Methodology

We follow a two-stage approach widely used in this kind of analysis A DEA analysis is

conducted in the first stage to get efficiency scores for each municipality Then regression analysis

is conducted in the second stage aiming to identify contextual variables other than differences in

the management of inputs that can help to explain the heterogeneity in municipal performance

331 Chilean Municipalities and period of analysis

The territory of Chile is divided into regions and these into provinces which for purposes of

the local administration are divided into counties The local administration of each county resides

in a municipality which is administrated by a Mayor assisted by a Municipal Council16

Municipalities represent the decentralization of the central power in Chile They are autonomous

organizations with legal personality and own patrimony whose purpose is to satisfy the needs of

the local community and ensure their participation in the economic social and cultural progress of

the county Municipalities have a diversity of functions related to public health education and

social assistance among others

16 The Mayor and City Council are elected by suffrage for the citizens of the respective commune every 4 years

67

To achieve their goals two are the main sources of municipal incomes own permanent

revenues (OPR) and the Municipal Common Fund (MCF) OPR are incomes generated by the

county and they are an indicator of the self-financing capacity of each municipality OPR are not

subject to restrictions regarding their investment and they are mainly generated by territorial taxes

commercial patents and circulation permits17 The MCF is a fund that aims to redistribute

community income to ensure compliance with the purpose of the municipalities and their proper

functioning Sources to finance the MCF come from municipal revenues The distribution

mechanism of the fund is regulated by parameters such as whether municipalities generate OPR

per capita lower than the national average and the number of poor people in the commune in

relation to the number of poor people in the country

This study covers the period from 2006 to 2017 During this period Chile was divided into

15 regions 54 provinces and 346 counties18 Although the information on inputs and outputs is

available for the entire period information on contextual factors at the county level such as

household income is only available every two-three years In addition some counties are excluded

from household surveys due to their difficult access Hence we use a sample of 324 municipalities

to measure municipal efficiency for the whole period (3888 observations) However the analysis

of contextual factors is conducted for those years when household income information is available

2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017 (1944 observations)

17 The territorial tax is a tax on agricultural and non-agricultural real estate Specifically of this income only 40 is left to the municipality as its own financing while the remaining 60 is allocated to the MCF (in the case of the four largest communes- Santiago Providencia Las Condes and Vitacura-percentages are 35 and 65 respectively) Unlike the territorial tax commercial patents are regulated mainly by the municipality which chooses the rate to be charged subject to a range established by law and is responsible of their collection Finally regarding the circulation permits 375 is of municipal benefit while 645 is directed to the MCF 18 There are 346 counties managed by 345 municipalities where counties ldquoCabo de Hornosrdquo and ldquoAntaacuterticardquo are managed by the municipality of ldquoCabo de Hornosrdquo

68

332 Measuring municipal efficiency

Municipal efficiency is measured using Data Envelopment Analysis (Coelli Prasada Rao

OrsquoDonnell amp Battese 2005) This is a non-parametric approach that uses linear programming to

measure efficiency for a group of municipalities as decision making units (DMUrsquos) The main

advantage of using DEA and the reason why DEA is used for the case of Chilean municipalities

is its flexibility in handling multiple inputs and outputs without the need to specify a functional

form (Balaguer-Coll amp Prior 2009 Mikušovaacute 2015 Tigga amp Mishra 2015) Following Afonso

and Fernandes (2008) the relationship between inputs and outputs for each municipality could be

represented by the following equation

119884 119891 119883 119894 1 119899 (31)

In equation (31) 119884 is the set of outputs and 119883 the set of inputs for each of the n

municipalities Using linear programming the production frontier is constructed and a vector of

efficiency scores is obtained The frontier represents full technical efficiency mdash the point at which

the highest output occurs given specified inputs or the point at which the lowest amount of inputs

is used to produce a specified quantity of output Efficiency scores under DEA are relative

measures of efficiency They measure a municipalityrsquos efficiency against the other measured

municipalities in the sample and not a hypothetical lsquoperfect municipalityrsquo The further from the

frontier the less technically efficient a municipality is

We use an input-oriented approach because Chilean municipalities have a greater control

over the management of inputs relative to the outputs they have to manage Obtaining efficiency

scores requires an assumption about the returns to scale exhibited by each municipality When

DMUrsquos are homogeneous the CCR model (Charnes Cooper amp Rhodes 1978) which assumes

69

constant return-to-scale (CRS) is the appropriate specification The CCR model assumes full

proportionality between outputs and inputs and that DMUrsquos operate at their optimal When DMUrsquos

are highly heterogeneous as is the case with local governments in most countries it is not realistic

to assume complete proportionality between inputs and outputs nor that all DMUrsquos operate at their

optimum scale In this situation a variable returns-to-scale (VRS) or BCC model (Banker

Charnes amp Cooper 1984) is the preferred formulation

Assuming VRS imposes minimum restrictions on the efficient frontier and allows for

comparisons only among municipalities of similar scale (Coelli et al 2005 Wu Huang amp Pan

2014) This means that when we use the CCR model (assuming CRS) on a heterogeneous sample

of DMUrsquos the resulting measure of technical efficiency that we obtain is related not only to the

management of inputs but also to issues of scale19 To empirically check the validity of the VRS

assumption we measure technical efficiency under CRS VRS and non-increasing returns-to-scale

(NIRS) and we analyse the existence of scale inefficiencies This allows us to check the relevance

of scale effects as a potential explanation of differences in municipal efficiency Appendix J

shows the specification of the DEA model under VRS and how ldquototal technical efficiencyrdquo

(assuming CRS and therefore due to management and scale issues) could be disaggregated in ldquopure

technical efficiencyrdquo (under VRS and related only to management issues) and scale efficiency (due

to scale issues)

19 Assuming VRS can also lead to measurement problems such as overestimation of efficiency scores This is the case when an important proportion of DMUrsquos shows CRS so assuming VRS ignores the information about proportionality between inputs and outputs (Podinovski 2004)

70

333 Inputs and outputs used in DEA

Following the literature on local government expenditure efficiency (Afonso amp Fernandes

2008 de Sousa et al 2005 Dlouhyacute 2018 Tandon 2005 Tigga amp Mishra 2015) and trying to

reflect as well as possible the functioning of municipalities five inputs and four outputs were

selected Input and output data were obtained from the National System of Municipal Information

(SINIM in its Spanish acronym) and they are expressed in thousands of Chilean pesos of 201720

Inputs are Municipal Operational Expenditure X1 (including expenses on goods and

services social assistance investment and transfers to community organizations) Municipal

Personnel Expenditure X2 (including full time and part-time workers) Total Municipal

Expenditure in Education sector X3 Total Municipal Expenditure in Health sector X4 and the

Number of Municipal Buildings X5 (proxied by the number of public facilities in education and

health sectors)

Output variables were selected highlighting the relevance of education and health sectors

and trying to capture the wide range of local services provided by municipalities The variable

ldquoOwn Permanent Revenuesrdquo Y1 is used to capture the scale and diversity of municipal

activities21 The ldquoMonthly Average Enrolmentrdquo in municipal education establishments related to

the school-age population in each county Y2 is used as educational output As health output the

ldquoNumber of Medical Consultationsrdquo in public facilities Y3 is considered Finally the number of

community organizations Y4 is used as output reflecting the promotion of community

development by each municipality Table 31 shows the summary statistics of input and output

20 The data from SINIM database was mostly obtained using the sinimr package (Salas 2019) 21 According to SINIM database this variable aims to measure the management of the municipalityrsquos own resources with respect to the population of the commune

71

variables for the whole sample and period Inputs and outputs excepting the Monthly Average

Enrolment Y2 are measured in per capita terms using county population information from the

National Institute of Statistics (INE in its Spanish acronym)

Table 31

Descriptive statistics Inputs and Output variables used in DEA analysis

334 Regression model

Contextual factors could play an important role not only in explaining why some

municipalities operate inefficiently but also why municipal performance differs among them

These factors may affect municipal performance modifying incentives for local authorities to

operate efficiently and their capability to take advantage of economies of scale They also define

the conditions for cooperation or competition among municipalities and the citizensacute ability and

willingness to monitor local authorities (Afonso amp Fernandes 2008)

Information on income at the household level for each county was obtained from the

ldquoNational Socioeconomic Characterization Surveyrdquo (CASEN in its Spanish acronym) CASEN is

conducted every two-three years being the reason why consecutive years are not considered in

72

our regression analysis The other contextual factors used as controls were obtained from different

sources including SINIM INE and the ldquoServicio de Impuestos Internosrdquo (SII)22

Our main hypothesis is whether higher levels of income inequality are associated with lower

levels of municipal efficiency To test our hypothesis the empirical model is defined as

120579 120573 119892119894119899119894 119885 120573 120575 120572 120598 (32)

Where 120579 is the vector of DEA efficiency scores 119892119894119899119894 is the Gini coefficient of each

county 120575 are year-specific effects 120572 are county-specific constants 120598 is a vector of error terms

and 119885 is a vector of controls Next we discuss the motivation for these controls

The level of purchasing power of countiesrsquo citizens is proxied by the variable log(income)

which is the natural log of the mean household income per capita in thousands of Chilean pesos of

2017 On the one hand poorer counties could display higher efficiency due to their necessity to

take care of their constraint resources (Pacheco et al 2013) On the other hand richer counties

could show higher efficiency because richer citizens exert higher monitoring over local authorities

and demand better quality public services in return for their tax payments (Afonso et al 2010)

The possibility for municipalities to take advantage of economies of scale and urbanization is

captured by three variables First the variable log(density) which correspond to the natural log of

population density Second the dummy variable reg_cap indicating whether a county is a regional

capital or not Third the variable agroland which correspond to the proportion of land for

agricultural use which is informed to the SII We expect a positive effect of log(density) but

negative for regcap and agroland

22 The SII is the institution in charge of collecting taxes in Chile

73

Socio-demographic characteristics are captured including a Dependence Index IDD IDD

corresponds to the number of people under 15 years or over 65 years per 100 people in the active

population (those people between 15 and 65 years old) A higher proportion of young and older

population could be associated with a higher demand for municipal services relating to education

and health making harder to offer public services efficiently The citizensrsquo capacity to monitor

local authorities is proxied including the variable education (average years of education for the

population older than 15 years) and the variable housing (proportion of households which are

owners of the property where they live in each county) In both cases we expect a positive

association with LGE

Among municipal characteristics the variable professional (percentage of municipal

personnel with a professional degree) is used to control for the quality of municipal services and

it is expected a positive impact The variable mcf (proportion of total municipal income coming

from the MCF) is included to capture the influence of financial dependence on the central

government A higher dependence from MCF could be associated with higher efficiency when it

is linked to more control from central government (Worthington amp Dollery 2000) However when

MCF discourages the generation of own resources and proper management of resources from the

fund a lower efficiency should be expected (Bravo 2014) In addition the dummy variable mayor

is included to capture differences among mayors supported by the ldquoLEFTrdquo or the ldquoRIGHTrdquo

political parties related to those ldquoINDEPENDENTrdquo mayors

Table 32 report summary statistics for the set of numeric contextual factors and Appendix

K the corresponding correlation matrix Despite the high correlation between income and

education variables we include both in the regression section as they capture different county

characteristics

74

Table 32

Summary Statistics Numeric Contextual Factors

Figure 31 Geographical distribution of Chilean regions and macrozones

Previous evidence on growth and convergence of Chilean regions have found that regions

tend to cluster spatially (Aroca amp Bosch 2000) Aiming to capture this regional clustering process

75

and considering the high concentration in the number of municipalities and population in the

central area we group municipalities in four ldquozonesrdquo We define as reference the ldquoCentre-Northrdquo

zone consisting of regions XIII (where the countryrsquos capital is located) and its two neighbouring

regions V and VI The ldquoNorthrdquo zone includes regions XV I II III and IV The ldquoCentre-Southrdquo

zone includes regions VII VIII and IX Finally the ldquoSouthrdquo zone embraces regions XIV X XI

and XII Figure 31 displays the regional administrative division and zones considered in this

essay

Efficiency scores (ES) are limited to have values between 0 and 1 However they are relative

measures (relative to the sample of municipalities) This implies that when a municipality is on the

frontier (ES = 1) it does not mean that potentially larger technical efficiency gains cannot be made

Hence equation 32 is estimated using OLS and censored regressions We start running cross-

sectional regressions for each of the six years Then we compare the results with those from panel

regressions Because fixed-effects panel Tobit models could be affected by the incidental

parameters problem (Henningsen 2010 2019) we use random-effects panel Tobit models

including indicator variables for years and zones Finally to deal with the potential endogeneity

problem we also use an instrumental variable approach The instrument is described next

335 The instrument

Government effectiveness and income distribution are both structural components of

economies (Ortega et al 2017 Ravallion 2005) In the search for a causal interpretation for the

influence of income inequality on municipal efficiency we need an instrument which must be

correlated with the variable to be instrumented (in our case income inequality) and uncorrelated

with the error term in the efficiency equation (32) Previous literature has used as instruments for

Gini the number of townships governments in a previous period the percentage of revenues from

76

intergovernmental transfers in a previous period and the current share of the labour force in the

manufacturing sector (Alesina amp La Ferrara 2002) Using the share of the labour force in a specific

sector is unlikely to reduce the problem of endogeneity particularly in countries where local

governments supply mostly ldquoservices to peoplerdquo and the main source of income inequality is

labour income

We propose as an instrument the proportion of firms in the primary sector (mining fishing

forestry and agriculture)

119901119904119904_119891119894119903119898119904Number of firms in the primary sector

Total number of firms (33)

On the one hand this instrument is likely to be correlated with local income inequality in

natural resource-rich countries23 On the other hand we contend that our instrument is less likely

to be correlated with the error term in the efficiency equation First the main services supplied by

Chilean municipalities are services to people (health and education) not to firms Second most of

the revenues collected by municipalities included those associated with natural resources end up

in the municipal common fund whose objective is precisely to reduce inequalities among

municipalities Third services to firms are expected to be more significant with the tertiary sector

We argue that our instrument captures natural and structural conditions which directly

influence income inequality but it does not directly affect LGE Figure 32 shows the evolution

of the annual average efficiency score and the proportion of firms in the primary secondary

(manufacturing) and tertiary (services) sectors We observe that sectors shares have remained

relatively stable with a slight reduction in the participation of the primary sector in favour of the

23 Results confirm a significant association between income inequality and the degree of dependence on natural resources at the county level

77

tertiary sector by the end of the period This is contrary to the evolution of municipal efficiency

which shows a cyclical behaviour as will be shown in the next section

Figure 32 Evolution of efficiency scores and the proportion of firms by sector

34 Results and discussion

341 DEA results

Figure 33 displays the evolution of our three measures of efficiency Overall technical

efficiency pure technical efficiency and scale efficiency are around 78 83 and 95

respectively with fluctuations over the years Therefore around three quarters of the overall

78

inefficiency is attributed to inefficiency in the management of inputs and around one quarter to

scale inefficiencies24

Figure 33 Evolution technical efficiency (TE) pure technical efficiency (PTE) and scale efficiency (SE)

Returnstoscale

Figure 34 reports by zone and for the whole period the proportion of municipalities

showing CRS decreasing returns to scale (DRS) or increasing returns to scale (IRS) Most of the

municipalities operate under variable (increasing or decreasing) returns to scale which could be

explained by the high heterogeneity in size among municipalities A summary of RTS

disaggregated by year and zone is in Appendix L Policies oriented to increase efficiency usually

24 The average scale efficiency score of 95 means that municipalities could get an additional 5 of inputs saving if municipalities were able to change their size to achieve their optimal scale

79

consider amalgamation de-amalgamation or ways of cooperation among municipalities To have

a better idea about where and how feasible is the implementation of such policies Appendix M

shows maps with the administrative division of the country in its 345 municipalities and which

municipalities show CRS IRS or DRS in each of the six years of data

Figure 34 Returns to scale by zone

Based on results for the whole period (Figure 34) the North has the highest proportion of

municipalities exhibiting DRS This suggests the need to reduce the size of municipalities splitting

those ldquotoo bigrdquo creating new administrative areas or giving more autonomy to current

municipalities25 The opposite occurs in the Centre-North area where municipalities mostly

exhibit IRS This indicates the need to merge municipalities An alternative strategy to the

amalgamation process is increasing inter-municipal cooperation (Balaguer-Coll et al 2019)

25 This has been the policy followed in Chile Although two new regions were created (XV in the North and XIV in the South) the number of municipalities has not changed

80

which seems to be a more plausible option in Chile Finally evidence on scale efficiency for the

Centre-South and South areas is not clear in terms of the adequate strategy to improve efficiency

Efficiencymeasure

Although most municipalities show scale inefficiencies (Figure 34) only a small proportion

of total inefficiency is associated to scale issues (Figure 33) Together this results justify not only

the use of the BCC model (efficiency scores under VRS) to capture municipal heterogeneity but

also highlights the need to look for other factors outside the control of local authorities which

could be influencing municipal performance

Table 33

Summary efficiency scores (VRS) by zone and region

Table 33 summarizes ES under VRS using data for the six years of CASEN survey A mean

efficiency score of 83 is found for the full sample and period This means that on average

inefficient municipalities can reduce the use of inputs by 17 to get the same current output By

81

comparing average ES per zone it can be concluded that municipalities in the North Centre-North

Centre-South and South could achieve the same level of output with 17 12 18 and 23 fewer

resources respectively Results also show that one third of the municipalities present an efficiency

score equal to one

Figure 35 shows the evolution of the mean ES for the four zones over the 12 years period

A clear drop in the efficiency level is observed in 2009 (the financial crisis year) excepting for the

North area Likewise although mean efficiency returned to its pre-crisis levels in 2014-2015 a

new drop in efficiency was experienced in 2016 It also seems that the 2010 earthquake did not

generate a significant effect on municipal efficiency Figure 35 also shows that although levels

of efficiency seem to differ among zones they follow a similar trend through time with the only

exception of the North which corresponds to the mining area In addition efficiency seems to be

significantly higher in the Centre-North area This is explained by the high mean level of efficiency

in region XIII which includes the countryrsquos capital city

Figure 35 Evolution mean efficiency scores (VRS) by zone

82

To know which and where are the efficient municipalities and if they are surrounded by

municipalities with a similar level of efficiency Appendix N has maps showing the ldquoefficiency

statusrdquo of each municipality that is whether they are efficient (ES = 1) or inefficient (ES lt 1)

Additionally Appendix O shows ldquoequal intervalsrdquo maps describing the spatial distribution of ES

among municipalities for each of the six years26 Results show that efficient municipalities can be

found all through the country the ldquoefficiency statusrdquo could change from one year to another and

municipalities with similar level-status of efficiency tend to cluster in space

342 Regression results

Exploratoryspatialanalysis

DEA efficiency scores and their geographical representations seem to show that municipal

efficiency presents a spatial clustering pattern This means that municipal performance could be

influenced not only by contextual factors of the county where municipality belongs but also by the

level of efficiency of neighbouring municipalities and their characteristics To test the significance

of the spatial dimension in municipal efficiency we use a cross-section of data considering the six-

year average of efficiency scores the Gini coefficient and the set of controls

We use the Moranrsquos I indicator to test for spatial autocorrelation Moranrsquos I is a measure of

the correlation between the level of efficiency in one municipality and its ldquospatial lagrdquo that is the

average level of efficiency in neighbouring municipalities We define as the relevant neighbours

for each municipality the 5-nearest municipalities This is obtained using the distances among the

26 An equal intervals map uses the same principle as a histogram to organize the observations into categories that divide the range of the variable into equal interval bins For the equal interval classification the value range between the lower and upper bound in each bin is constant across bins but the number of observations in each bin is typically not equal

83

polygonsrsquo centroids (latitude and longitude) of each county Results confirm that municipal

efficiency show a significant level of positive spatial autocorrelation This means that

municipalities tend to have neighbouring municipalities with similar performance

The positive spatial autocorrelation shown by municipal efficiency could be due to the

performance in one municipality is influenced by the performance in neighbouring municipalities

(spatial dependence in the variable itself) or due to structural differences among regions-zones

(spatial heterogeneity) To check the source of the spatial autocorrelation we run an OLS

regression of ES against income inequality and controls and then we test OLS residuals for spatial

autocorrelation Moranrsquos I over OLS residuals although significant is barely higher than zero (see

Appendix P) This means that the spatial effect itself is not a serious issue and can be handle for

instance including zone indicators variables hence we proceed to analyse the influence of income

inequality on LGE using non-spatial regression27

Cross‐sectionalanalysis

We start reporting censored regressions for each year in our panel Efficiency scores have

been rescaled to numbers between 0 and 100 to facilitate the interpretation of the results All

regressions include dummy variables for three of the four zones in which we have grouped Chilean

regions Results are in Table 3428 Income inequality shows a negative sign in all years which is

consistent with our hypothesis that inequality is negatively related to municipal efficiency

However only in three of the six years the effect of income inequality appears as statistically

27 In the case of having incorporated the spatial dimension the two most commonly used forms are including in the model the spatial lag of the dependent variable (spatial autoregressive model SAR) or the spatial lag of the error (spatial error model SEM) Following the method suggested by Anselin et al (1996) Lagrange Multiplier (LM) tests on the OLS residuals showed that the SAR model is preferred over the SEM Moranrsquos I LM tests and spatial regressions can be found in Appendix P 28 Regression results using OLS are in Appendix Q

84

significant Only the income level displays a significant and positive influence on efficiency for

the whole period A higher population density also consistently favours municipal efficiency On

the other hand as we expected a higher IDD makes it more difficult to achieve an efficient

performance29 Consistent with results in Pacheco et al (Pacheco et al 2013) municipal

efficiency show a significant an positive association with the MCF only in the first half of our

period of analysis with the second half showing an insignificant relationship

Table 34

Cross-sectional (censored) regressions

Paneldataanalysis

Estimation results for the six-year panel are reported in Table 35 Columns (1) and (2) show

the results for the pooled and random effects censored models only controlling for zone and year

29 The set of cross-sectional regressions was also run for each zone independently Results confirm that the set of significant contextual factors differs not only among years but also among geographic areas This support previous evidence suggesting that cross-sectional analysis should be treated with caution (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018b)

85

dummies Income inequality appears as non-significant Zone indicator variables confirm that

municipalities located in the Centre-South and South of the country display a lower average level

of efficiency compared to the Centre-North area Time dummies mostly show negative

coefficients This is a signal that shocks such as the GFC and the earthquake in 2010 may have

had a negative impact on efficiency but that impact was not permanent The results for the pooled

and RE models including the full set of controls are reported in columns (3) and (4) These results

show a significant negative influence of income inequality on LGE

When income inequality is instrumented by the variable pss_firms most of the coefficients

remain unchanged except for those associated with the income variables gini and log(income)

This result implies that our original model suffers for instance from the omitted variable bias

This means that LGE and income inequality are determined simultaneously by some variable not

included in our model Columns (5) and (6) show results using our instrument for income

inequality The ldquotrue coefficientrdquo of variable gini remains negative but the magnitude of the

relationship is higher The negative coefficient for gini implies on the one hand that municipalities

located in more unequal counties face more challenges to achieve an efficient management of

public resources On the other hand the coefficient in column (6) is close to one The interpretation

is that for each point of reduction in income inequality ceteris paribus LGE should increase in the

same proportion Next we discuss some of the results associated with the controls variables

Contrary to Pacheco et al (2013) income level has a positive coefficient meaning that richer

counties in terms of income per capita show higher efficiency This could be explained by higher

monitoring and increasing demands from citizen and taxpayers In addition it is expected a higher

efficiency in municipalities located in counties with a higher population density and those with a

lower proportion of land for agricultural use This result is mainly explained by municipalities

86

located in the Centre area The opposite happens with municipalities in the South implying that

they are too ldquosmallrdquo to take advantage of agglomeration economies There is also a limit for

agglomeration and scale economies which is shown by the negative coefficient of the variable

regcap although this coefficient loses its significance in the IV approaches30

Unexpectedly efficiency was found to be negatively associated with the variable education

This result is similar to the case of Czech municipalities (Šťastnaacute amp Gregor 2014) where

explanations include a weakened monitoring effect due to the fact that more educated citizens

present greater mobility and labour cost disadvantages for municipalities with better educated

labour force In Chile an additional explanation could be the relationship between education and

voter turnout Since 2012 voting is no longer mandatory in Chile This fact considerably reduced

voter turnout which in turn may have influenced the monitoring and control effect of more

educated voters For the case of variable IDD results show that local authorities in counties with

higher proportion of aging and young population (related to those in the active population) face a

greater challenge in their quest to offer public services efficiently

The influence of mcf is like that found by Pacheco et al (2013) with municipalities more

dependent on central transfers showing more efficiency31 Political influence captured by the

variable mayor did not show a significant effect This result is like other studies concluding that

the ideological position did not have a significant influence on efficiency (Benito et al 2010

Boetti et al 2009 Cordero Pedraja-Chaparro Pisaflores amp Polo 2017)

30 This negative coefficient suggests that the negative effects of agglomeration economies such as overcrowding pollution high cost of land and traffic congestion could predominate over the positive effects of scale economies in regional capitals 31 When the analysis is conducted for each zone independently MCF displays a negative influence in the North and Centre-North areas but a positive influence in the Centre-South and South areas These results confirm that on the one hand richer municipalities (those in the North and Centre-North) have less incentives for efficient management of their resources On the other hand results support the relevance of MCF helping poorer municipalities (those in the South) to reach their outcomes

87

Table 35

Panel data regressions

88

35 Conclusions

The trade-off between equity and efficiency is in the core of the economic discussion This

ldquoprinciplerdquo has been used by policymakers to prioritize the design of policies focused on economic

growth delaying those policies aimed at reducing economic inequalities This essay offers

empirical evidence of a negative relationship between inequality and efficiency that is a reduction

of income inequality could have positive effects on economic efficiency at least at the level of

local governments

We followed a traditional Two-Stage approach commonly used in the analysis of LGE We

compared cross-sectional and panel data results and we have added an instrumental variable

approach to give a causal interpretation to the link between efficiency and inequality We proposed

the use of a measure of natural resource dependence to instrumentalize the impact of income

inequality on LGE Given that our units of analysis are municipalities and not counties we argue

that our measure of NRD is correlated with income inequality and it does not have a direct

influence on LGE

We found that Chilean municipalities perform better than previous studies suggest

Municipal efficiency depicted significant levels of positive spatial autocorrelation and most of the

municipalities showed to be operating under increasing or decreasing returns to scale This would

imply that the policies generally used to improve efficiency such as amalgamation or cooperation

should be implemented observing the reality of each region and not as strategies at the national

level We also found that scale inefficiency explains a small proportion of the average total

inefficiency reason why the analysis of external factors that could affect the municipal efficiency

takes greater relevance

89

Income inequality plays an important part in explaining municipal efficiency In fact it was

found that reductions in income inequality could result in increases in municipal efficiency in a

similar proportion An unexpected finding was that the levels of education shows a negative

association with municipal performance This could be due to a low average level of education or

the existence of an omitted variable This variable could be the significant reduction in voting

turnout rates for local and national elections due to changes in the voting system during the period

of our analysis All in all our results may help to shed light on the potential consequences of

changes in contextual factors and the design of strategies aimed to increase municipal efficiency

in countries with similar characteristics to the Chilean economy For instance policies oriented to

take advantage of economies of scale can be formulated merging municipalities or establishing

networks in specific sectors such as education or health

Further work needs to be done both in measurement and in the explanation of differences in

municipal performance in Chile One area of future work will be to identify the factors that better

predict why municipalities operates under increasing decreasing or constant returns to scale

Multinomial logistic regression and the application of machine learning algorithms to SINIM data

sets appear as suitable methods for that purpose Intertemporal DEA (Drew amp Dollery 2015)

should be used to measure municipal efficiency capturing changes in total factor productivity In

addition municipalities operate under different levels of geographical authorities such as the

provincial mayor and the regional governor Hence it would be useful to know how each

municipality performs within each region-zone related to how performs to the whole country This

should be done conducting a metafrontier analysis (OrsquoDonnell Rao amp Battese 2008)

We have also identified through a cross sectional spatial exploratory analysis that on

average municipalities with similar levels of efficiency tend to cluster in space Regarding to

90

analyse the importance of contextual factors on municipal efficiency a deeper analysis should use

censored spatial models to check the significance of the spatial dimension in cross-sectional and

panel contexts Another interesting avenue for future research is associated with the negative

association found between LGE and education The significant reduction in votersacute turnout since

the law of automatic registration and voluntary voting in 2011 appears as a natural experiment to

analyse its effects on efficiency indicators such as municipal performance Incorporating variables

such as the voting turnout in each county or classifying municipalities based on individual

institutional political and economic characteristics could help to shed light on which of these

channels is the most relevant when analysing the impact of inequality on municipal efficiency

Finally we argued that an important part of the influence of income inequality over LGE

could be through its indirect effect on trust social capital and social cohesion The final essay will

delve deep in that relationship

91

Chapter 4 Social Cohesion Incivilities and Diversity

Evidence at the municipal level in Chile

41 Introduction

A deterioration in social cohesion could carry significant costs such as a reduction in

generalized trust between individuals and in institutions a society caught in a vicious circle of

inequality and citizens increasingly distanced from civic life (Uslaner 2011) A growing feeling

of frustration and discontentment can eventually translate into a social outbreak with uncertain

results This is precisely what have been happening in many countries around the world included

Chile

ldquoSocial cohesion is a state of affairs concerning both the vertical and the horizontal

interactions among members of society as characterized by a set of attitudes and norms that

includes trust a sense of belonging and the willingness to participate and help as well as their

behavioural manifestationsrdquo (Chan et al 2006) This definition highlights the multidimensionality

in the concept of social cohesion which has been measured using objective andor subjective

indicators of trust social norms solidarity willingness to participate in social and political groups

and feelings of belonging (Ariely 2014 Chan et al 2006) Multidimensionality also implies that

the impact of determinants of social cohesion such as economic and racial diversity could be

different for each of its various dimensions (Ariely 2014)

A common characteristic to all societies is that they are made up of different groups that

differ with respect to race ethnicity income religion language local identity etc The

92

Community Heterogeneity Thesis (Coffeacute amp Geys 2006) argues that individuals prefer to interact

with others that are like themselves Hence high levels of diversity particularly economic and

racial represent a complex scenario to maintain social cohesion One of the most common factors

adduced for social cohesion is income inequality with higher levels linked to lower levels of trust

(Ariely 2014 Rothstein amp Uslaner 2005)

Traditional measures of social cohesion may not be adequately capturing the deterioration

in social connections For instance measures of (lack of) trust include a strong subjective element

On the other hand proxies for social participation such as volunteering jobs or joining to social

organizations have not been supported by empirical evidence as a source of generalized social trust

(Rothstein amp Uslaner 2005) We proposed to use the rate of incivilities which we argue is a more

appropriate measure of the degree of worsening in the social context

Incivilities are those visible disorders in the public space that violate respectful social norms

and tend not to be treated as crimes by the criminal justice system There are two types of

incivilities social and physical Social incivilities include antisocial behaviours such as public

drinking noisy neighbours and fighting in public places Physical incivilities include among

others vandalism graffiti abandoned cars and garbage on the streets Because citizens and

political authorities cannot always distinguish between incivilities and crime they are usually

treated as an additional category of crime This implies that policies aimed to reduce incivilities

are generally based on punitive actions However theory and evidence on incivilities suggest that

factors explaining incivilities and crime could be different (Lewis 2017 Taylor 1999)

In Chile crime rates have shown a sustained downward trend after reaching its highest level

in 2011 On the other hand incivilities rate has shown a sustained upward trend which coincides

with the increasing victimization and feeling of insecurity in the population This has motivated

93

Chilean authorities based on the ldquoBroken Windows Theoryrdquo to propose new punitive actions (or

increase the severity of the current ones) to those who commit this type of antisocial behaviours

The ldquoBroken Windows Theoryrdquo states that higher rates of incivilities are a signal of social

disorganization which result in higher crime rates (J Q Wilson amp Kelling 1982) This is expected

to have consequences on familiesrsquo decisions such as moving away from public spaces or even

leaving their neighbourhoods

As far as we know there is no previous evidence about the potential causes of incivilities in

Chile Efforts to identify the factors explaining incivilities could help not only to reduce the risk

factors favouring violent and property crimes but also to guide interventions aimed to change

social behaviours and strengthen social cohesion in highly unequal societies Thus the main

contribution of the present study is to provide a deeper comprehension of the problem of incivilities

and how they can help to better understand the weakening of social cohesion that many

contemporary societies experience

We aim to offer the first evidence on the factors explaining the evolution and the differences

in incivilities rates in Chile We set up a panel for six years (2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and

2017) and 324 counties (1944 observations) We start exploring the evolution and geographical

distribution of incivilities Then we investigate whether economic and racial diversity after

controlling for other socioeconomic demographic and municipal characteristics can be regarded

as key predictors of incivilities

We use the Gini coefficient to proxy economic heterogeneity and the number of new visas

granted to foreigners as proportion of the county population as proxy for racial diversity The main

hypothesis is whether economic and racial diversity have a positive association with the rate of

incivilities In addition to the arguments regarding the ldquoCommunity Heterogeneity Thesisrdquo Taylor

94

(1999) and Skogan (1986 1999 2015) argue that incivilities are caused by inequality and the lack

of informal mechanisms of social control Based on the ldquoIncivilities Thesisrdquo the patterns of

incivilities should mirror the patterns of inequality (Taylor 1999) Then higher inequality should

be associated with higher physical and social vulnerability of the population This reduces social

control and increases social disorganization which triggers antisocial or negligent behaviours

Our main result reveals a strong positive association between the rate of incivilities and the

number of new visas granted per year The relationship with income inequality although also

positive seems to be less significant These findings give strong support to the ldquoCommunity

Heterogeneity Thesisrdquo and to a lesser extent to the ldquoIncivilities Thesisrdquo When the analysis is

disaggregated geographically racial diversity shows a clear positive effect The impact of income

inequality seems to be conditional depending on the level of income showing no effect in poorer

regions Results also show that the impact of economic and racial diversity differs by type of

incivility For example income inequality shows a strong association with ldquoStreet Tradingrdquo while

racial diversity with ldquoAlcohol Consumptionrdquo Two are the main policy implications On the one

hand a national strategy to address the problems associated with foreign immigration could help

to reduce incivilities For instance a joint effort between national and local authorities to curb

immigration and its distribution throughout the country On the other hand our results show that

the relationship between incivilities and economic diversity differs depending on the region or

geographical area Hence the impact on social cohesion of policies aimed to tackle economic

inequalities should be analysed in each specific context

The rate of incivilities also shows a negative association with the level of municipal financial

autonomy This implies that municipalities can effectively carry out policies to reduce incivilities

beyond the efforts of the central government Another important finding is that our results do not

95

support the hypothesis that a higher proportion of the young population is associated with higher

rates of incivilities Hence policies aimed to reduce incivilities should be focused on the causes of

incivilities rather than the criminalization of behaviours or stigmatization of specific population

groups

The structure of the chapter is as follows Section 42 outlines the relevant literature on social

cohesion and incivilities Section 43 describes the data variables and methodology and

establishes the hypotheses of the study Section 44 contains the results and discussions Section

45 presents the main conclusions

42 Related Literature

421 The Community Heterogeneity Thesis

The idea under ldquoThe Community Heterogeneity Thesisrdquo is that if individuals prefer to

interact with others who are similar to themselves in terms of income race or ethnicity high levels

of income inequality and racial diversity facilitate a context for lower tolerance and antisocial

behaviours lowering the ldquostaterdquo of social cohesion (Alesina 2000 Coffeacute amp Geys 2006 Letki

2008) Alessina and Ferrara (2002) give support to this hypothesis arguing that individuals have a

natural aversion to heterogeneity However the most popular explanation is the principle of

homophily people prefer to interact with others who share the same ethnic heritage have the same

social status and hence share experiences and tastes (Letki 2008 McPherson Smith-Lovin amp

Cook 2001 Tolsma et al 2009) For instance Delhey and Newton (2005) find for a sample of

60 countries that income inequality and ethnicity are strongly and negatively correlated with trust

Tolsma et al (2009) using data for Dutch neighbourhoods and municipalities find that social

cohesion is negatively and consistently affected by economic deprivation but not by ethnic

96

heterogeneity These authors also conclude that the effect of neighbourhood and municipal

characteristics on social cohesion depends on residentsrsquo income and educational level

Rothstein and Uslaner (2005) give two theoretical reasons why economic and racial diversity

should be causally related to social trust a key element of social cohesion First optimism about

the future makes less sense when there is more economic inequality which generally translates into

inequality of opportunities especially in areas such as education and the labour market Second

the distribution of resources and opportunities plays a key role in establishing the belief that people

share a common destiny and have similar fundamental values In highly unequal societies people

are likely to stick with their own kind Perceptions of injustice will reinforce negative stereotypes

of other groups making social trust and accommodation more difficult

Uslaner (2002 2011) and Uslaner and Brown (2005) find that high levels of inequality are

the single major factor driving down trust in people who are different from yourself Evidence for

USA finds that inequality is the strongest determinant of generalized trust over time (Rothstein amp

Uslaner 2005) Reducing inequality and then increasing generalized trust should have positive

consequences at the individual and aggregates levels At the individual level it may lead to greater

tolerance and more acts of altruism for people of different backgrounds At the aggregate level it

may lead to greater economic growth more redistribution from the rich to the poor and less

corruption (Uslaner 2002 2013) Letki (2008) argues that when neighbourhood socio-economic

context (apart from just an individualrsquos socioeconomic status) is considered it turns out to be the

main factor triggering negative attitudes and lack of trust in out-group members

The increasing diversity caused by immigration can also reduce the conditions necessary for

social cohesion (Ariely 2014 Holtug amp Mason 2010) Christel Kesler and Irene Bloemraad

(2010) find for nineteen advanced democracies between 1981 and 2000 that increasing migration

97

generally decreases trust civic engagement and political participation The authors also find that

in more equal countries with clear policies in favour of cultural minorities the negative effects of

migration are mitigated or even reversed Letki (2008) states that deprivation and disorder tend to

be strongly correlated with racial diversity Because we propose the use of the number of disorders

or antisocial behaviours known as ldquoincivilitiesrdquo as our measure of social cohesion we describe the

literature on incivilities in the next section

422 The literature on incivilities

The study of incivilities has been a continuing concern mainly for developed countries since

the 1980s The focus has changed from individual and psychological explanations to ecological

(contextual) and social explanations (Taylor 1999) The individual approach basically considered

perceptions of incivilities as an explanatory variable of fear of crime The ecological explanation

argues that indicators of economic disadvantage (eg income levels income inequality

unemployment rate and poverty rate) are the keys to understand a process of social disorganization

and lack of informal control These economic factors lead to higher rates of inappropriate or

negligent behaviours and ultimately to higher crime rates (Blau amp Blau 1982 Messner Rosenfeld

amp Baumer 2004 Phan Orsquobrien Mendolia amp Paloyo 2017 Sampson 1986)

The negative impact of incivilities is not merely reflected in its association with crime rates

(Skogan 2015) Physical and social incivilities could worsen neighbourhoods by affecting quality

of life perception of the environment and public and private behaviours Previous research has

indicated that a higher level of incivilities is associated with health problems (Branas et al 2011

Cohen et al 2000 Hill amp Angel 2005 Ross 2011 Ross amp Mirowsky 2001) greater

victimization and fear of crime (Brunton-Smith Jackson amp Sutherland 2014 Mijanovich amp

Weitzman 2003) and multiple negative economic effects For instance incivilities could be

98

related to a reduction in commercial activity lower investment in real estate reduction in house

prices (Skogan 2015) and population instability (Hipp 2010)

To describe the state of the art in the study of incivilities and their consequences Skogan

(2015) used the concept of untidiness to characterize the research on incivilities The study of

incivilities has had multiple approaches (economic ecological and psychological) Incivilities

have also been measured using multiple sources of information (police reports surveys trained

observation) which result in different measures (perceptions vs count data) However the question

about what specific factors have the strongest effect on incivilities has been overlooked and

perceptions about incivilities have been used mainly as a predictor of crime fear of crime and

victimization

There are two types of incivilities social and physical Social incivilities are a matter of

behaviour including groups of rowdy teens public drunkenness people fighting and street hassles

Physical incivilities involve visual signs of negligence and decay such as abandoned buildings

broken streetlights trash-filled lots and graffiti (Skogan 1999 2015 Taylor 1999) Three reasons

justify the distinction between physical and social incivilities First like multiple dimensions of

social cohesion different structural and social conditions could be responsible for different types

and categories of incivilities Second punitive sanctions are expected to have a greater impact on

physical than on social incivilities since the latter are more related to behaviours rooted in citizensrsquo

culture Third physical incivilities should be more related to absolute measures of economic

disadvantage (eg poverty or unemployment rates) and social incivilities to relative indicators of

economic disadvantage (eg such as income inequality) This line of research is based on the

ldquoincivilities thesisrdquo which states that to understand the distribution of disorders it is necesary to

analyse the patterns of structured inequalities (Skogan 1986 Taylor 1999)

99

423 The ldquoIncivilities Thesisrdquo

Incivilities theories began with a focus on psychological dynamics (Garofalo 1978) moved

forward to an interest in social psychological processes (J Q Wilson amp Kelling 1982) and finally

evolved into a focus on community dynamics and outcomes (Skogan 1999) Individual and group

behaviours in tandem with ecological features have been proposed as the key factors explaining

incivilities and their posterior influence on social control quality of life and more serious crime

(J Q Wilson amp Kelling 1982)

In terms of ecological factors particularly those related to economic conditions Skogan

(1986) was the first linking the distribution of incivilities to the patterns of structural inequality If

incivilities mirror inequality structure this will have consequences in residentsrsquo health and safety

due to its levels of vulnerability In addition structured inequality associated with the proportion

of the manufacturing sector (eg when fabrics tend to move from cities to farther areas) will be

related to higher social disorganization and differences between urban and rural areas (W J

Wilson 1996) In addition a persistent feeling of relative deprivation (persistently high levels of

income inequality) could lead to fellow inhabitants of the community to commit antisocial

behaviours showing their frustration with the current economic model

The literature on incivilities posits that their causes are different from those of crime (Lewis

2017) Unlike crime analysis especially property crimes information on the location where the

incivility takes place is the same as the location where the perpetrator resides To achieve a

comprehensive understanding of the different types of incivilities it is crucial to consider

incivilities data covering an entire territory and not just specific areas (Hooghe Vanhoutte

Hardyns amp Bircan 2010) If we add to this the availability of panel data it could be possible not

100

only to identify the main determinants of incivilities but also the causal mechanism from income

inequality towards incivilities rate

In Chile citizen security crime and delinquency are among the most significant issues for

citizens based on opinion polls Existing research has found weak evidence of a significant

relationship between crime and indicators of socio-economic disadvantage such as income

inequality and unemployment rate with significant effects only on property crime (Beyer amp

Vergara 2006 Nuntildeez Rivera Villavicencio amp Molina 2003 Rivera Gutieacuterrez amp Nuacutentildeez 2009)

Crime deterrence variables such as the probability of being caught or the number of police

resources have also shown ambiguous results (Beyer amp Vergara 2006 Rivera et al 2009

Vergara 2012) Evidence at the county level shows that crime is higher in urban counties those

with a lower mean income per capita and counties located in the North of the country In addition

at least half of the crimes reported in one county are perpetrated by criminals from other counties

(Rivera et al 2009) No studies could be found about the determinants of incivilities

4 3 Methodology

431 Period of analysis and data sample

Chile is a relatively small country in Latin America with a population of 18346018

inhabitants in 2017 The country is divided into 345 municipalities with on average 53104

inhabitants (median value 18705) Municipalities are the organ of the State Administration

responsible to solve local needs Municipalities are not only the relevant political and

administrative local unit of analysis but also they represent the feeling of lsquocommunityrsquo among

the inhabitants of each municipality (Hooghe et al 2010) Our data includes many sources of

101

heterogeneity among municipalities such as indicators of economic deprivation population

density demographic characteristics and whether the county is a regional or provincial capital

We use a sample of 324 municipalities covering most of the Chilean territory for the period

2006ndash17 Data on incivilities is obtained from the ldquoCentre of Studies and Analysis of Crimerdquo

which is part of the ldquoSubsecretaria de Prevencion del Delitordquo (SPD in its Spanish acronym) of the

Chilean government32 Information on income inequality and control variables is obtained from

the ldquoNational Socioeconomic Characterization Surveyrdquo (CASEN in its Spanish acronym) the

ldquoNational Institute of Statisticsrdquo (INE in its Spanish acronym) the ldquoNational Municipal

Information Systemrdquo (SINIM in its Spanish acronym) and the Immigration Department of the

Government of Chile Our panel only includes the years for which CASEN survey is available

2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017

432 Operationalisation of the response variable and exploratory analysis

Official Chilean records contain information for the total number of cases of incivilities per

year at the county level The number of cases is the sum of complains and detentions reported at

the police Our dependent variable 119894119899119888119894119907119894119897119894119905119894119890119904 correspond to the number of cases per year Due

to population differences comparisons between counties are made using the incivilities rate per

1000 population calculated as

119894119899119888119894119907_119903119886119905119890 lowast 1000 (41)

where 119894119899119888119894119907_119903119886119905119890 is the incivilities rate 119905 is the year 119894 the county and 119899 is the population of the

county per year

32 httpceadspdgovclestadisticas-delictuales

102

Figure 41 illustrates at the top the evolution of the total number (cases reported) of

incivilities and crimes at the country level for the period 2006-1733 At the bottom Figure 41

shows the evolution of the mean county rate per 1000 inhabitants We observe that both the number

of incivilities and the number of crimes has reached similar annual figures however average

county rates per 1000 population show different trends Crime rate displays a sustained fall after

reaching its pick in 2011 Incivilities average county rate which also reached a pick and posterior

drop in 2011 has recovered its upward trend since 2016 considerably exceeding the crime rate

Figure 41 Evolution number and rates of incivilities and crime (DMCS) in Chile 2006-2017

33 Crime refers to ldquocrimes of greater social connotationrdquo (DMCS in its Spanish acronym) which includes violent and property crimes

103

Chilean records classify incivilities in nine categories most of them associated with social

incivilities Summary statistics for the total and for each of the nine categories are presented in

Table 41 In addition Figure 42 shows the evolution of incivilities by category for the whole

period We see that the global trend in incivilities is mainly due to a substantial increase in ldquoStreet

Tradingrdquo and ldquoPublic Alcohol Consumptionrdquo A common element of Figures 41 and 42 is the

significant change in trend experienced by crimes and incivilities in 2011 That year the SPD

became dependent on the Ministry of Interior of the Chilean Government This event put the issue

of crime and delinquency within national priorities for the central government

Table 41

Summary statistics total count of incivilities and by category (full sample and period)

Unlike crime rates we do not expect significant cross-county spillover effects in incivilities

However the questions of where incivilities are concentrated and why they are there can be of

great interest (Skogan 2015) Figure 43 shows quantile maps for the rate of incivilities per 1000

inhabitants for the initial and final years in our panel

104

Figure 42 Evolution total number of incivilities by category

Figure 43 Spatial distribution of incivilities rate per 1000 inhabitants (2006 vs 2017)

105

We observe that the range of values has increased significantly from 2006 to 2017 but the

spatial distribution remains almost unchanged On the one hand high incivilities rates in the North

could be associated with the mining activity On the other hand high rates in the Centre area

(where the countyrsquos capital is located) could be related to the higher population density and the

concentration of the economic activity34

To see how the different types of incivilities are distributed throughout the country we have

grouped those similar categories in four groups ldquoPublic Damagerdquo (ldquoPublic Disturbsrdquo ldquoPublic

Damagerdquo ldquoOtherrdquo) ldquoThreatsrdquo (ldquoPublic Fightrdquo ldquoThreatsrdquo and ldquoAnnoying Noisesrdquo) ldquoAlcohol

Consumptionrdquo (ldquoPublic Alcohol Consumptionrdquo and ldquoDrunkennessrdquo) and ldquoStreet Tradingrdquo This

distinction in groups could be relevant if we expect different patterns and different effects of

community heterogeneity on social cohesion among counties For instance we expect higher

levels of Public Damage in big urban cities Street trading is more likely in urban cities but also in

tourist areas The spatial distribution of these four groups for the six-year-average rate per 1000

inhabitants can be found in Appendix R

433 Measures of community heterogeneity and control variables

Social cohesion income inequality and racial diversity are all ldquocommunityrdquo (not individual)

characteristics Thus to understand their relationship we need aggregated data at least at the

county-municipal level With more disaggregated data like at the suburbs level the required

heterogeneity among groups of citizens is lost (Wilkinson 1999) Like Coffeacute and Geys (2006) we

use the Gini coefficient to capture economic heterogeneity However instead of a measured for

34 We also analysed the spatial distribution of crime rates In general areas with high levels of incivilities not necessarily are associated with high levels of crime This could imply that factors explaining incivilities and crime are different

106

the diversity of nationalities we use the proportion of foreign population to capture racial

heterogeneity Income data is obtained from the CASEN survey The Gini coefficient is calculated

for each county and included through the variable gini Racial heterogeneity is included through

the variable foreign which is the annual number of new VISAS granted to foreigners as a

proportion of the county population Chile has experienced a significant increase in immigration

since 2011 Immigration has been concentrated in the metropolitan region and mining regions in

the North of the country We expect a positive relationship between immigration and incivilities

although as with the relationship between immigration and crime the foundations for this

hypothesis are not strong (Hooghe et al 2010 Sampson 2008)

Economic development is another explanation for social cohesion frequently appealed to

explain trust with wealthier societies considered to exhibit higher levels of trust (Delhey amp

Newton 2005) In this study we include the natural log of the mean household income per capita

log(income) We also include the poverty rate poverty and the unemployment rate

unemployment Unlike the variable log(income) these variables are expected to be positively

associated with the number of incivilities When a relative indicator of economic heterogeneity

such as income inequality is included as determinant of social cohesion we should expect less

effect from absolute indicators of economic disadvantage such as poverty and unemployment rates

(Hooghe et al 2010 Tolsma et al 2009)

Among demographic variables the percentage of inhabitants between 10 and 24 years old is

included through the variable youth The variable women defined as the proportion of the female

population in each county is also included Variable youth is expected to have an ambiguous effect

Although young people have lower victimization and report rates they also represent the group

more likely to commit antisocial behaviours when a community has a low capacity of self-

107

regulation (eg when there is low parental supervision) The female population is associated with

a higher report of incivilities related to the male population

It is argued that crime and incivilities are essentially urban problems (Christiansen 1960

Wirth 1938) We include the variable log(density) defined as the log of population density (the

number of inhabitants divided by the area of each county in square kilometres) and a dummy

variable capital indicating whether a county is an administrative capital (provincial or regional)

Two additional variables are included to capture the level of informal social control exerted

by families living in each municipality First the variable education which is defined as the

average years of education of people over 15 years old Second the variable housing which capture

the proportion of families which are owners of their housing unit Although education and housing

are related to both the possibility of reporting and committing an incivility we expect a negative

association with the rate of incivilities

In Chile crime has been mainly a problem faced by the police and the Central Government

Administration To control for current law enforcement policies we include the variable

deterrence defined as the number of arrests as a proportion of the total number of incivilities cases

In addition municipalities can develop their own initiatives to deal with crime and incivilities

depending on their capacity to generate its own resources The level of financial autonomy from

central transfers is captured by the variable autonomy This variable is obtained from SINIM and

it is defined as the proportion of the budget revenue of each municipality that comes from its own

permanent sources of revenues A categorical variable mayor is also included This variable

indicates whether the municipality mayor is supported by the ldquoLEFTrdquo or the ldquoRIGHTrdquo political

parties (related to those ldquoINDEPENDENTrdquo mayors)

108

Table 42 presents descriptive statistics for our measures of income and racial heterogeneity

and the set of numeric control variables The Pearson correlation among these variables is shown

in Appendix S

Table 42

Summary statistics numeric explanatory variables

434 Methods

The annual count of incivilities as is characteristic for count data is highly concentrated in

a relatively small range of values In addition the distribution is right-skewed due to the presence

of important outliers (counties with a high number of incivilities) Figure 44 shows the

distribution of the six-year average number of incivilities for each of the 15 regions in Chile35 We

observe that regions differ in the number of counties in which they are divided In addition

counties within each region show important differences in the number of incivilities For instance

35 Regions are ordered from left to right and from top to bottom in the way they are geographically distributed from North to South So the northernmost region of the country is the ldquoXVrdquo and the southernmost region is the ldquoXIIrdquo The Metropolitan region (where the countryrsquos capital is located) is region ldquoXIIIrdquo in the centre of the country (see Appendix C)

109

excepting the Metropolitan region ldquoXIIIrdquo most counties in regions located in the centre of the

country (middle row in Figure 44) show a range of incivilities between 0 and 2000 The number

of incivilities is considerably lower in counties located in the northern (top row in Figure 44) and

southern (bottom row in Figure 44) regions of the country compared to regions in the centre of

the country It also seems clear from Figure 44 that the number of incivilities does not follow a

normal distribution

Figure 44 Annual average number of incivilities per county

The number of incivilities can be better described by a Poisson distribution In this case the

number of incivilities is ldquothe countrdquo and the number of incivilities per year is ldquothe rate per unit

timerdquo We are interested in modelling the average number of incivilities per year usually called 120582

as a function of a set of contextual factors to explain differences in incivilities between and within

110

counties The main characteristic of the Poisson distribution is that the mean is equal to the

variance This implies that as the mean rate for a Poisson variable increases the variance also

increases The main implication is we cannot use OLS to model 120582 as a function of the set of

contextual factors because the equal variance assumption in linear regression is violated

The rate of incivilities between counties is not directly comparable due to population

differences We expect counties with more people to have more reports of incivilities since there

are more people who could be affected To capture differences in population which is called the

exposure of our response variable 120582 it is necessary to include a term on the right side of our model

called an offset We will use the log of the county population in thousands as our offset36

Additionally similar to the case of crime data incivilities show a significant degree of

overdispersion (variance higher than the mean) suggesting that there is more variation in the

response than the Poisson model implies37 We also model and regress incivilities assuming a

Negative Binomial distribution to address overdispersion An advantage of this approach is that it

introduces a dispersion parameter in addition to 120582 which gives the model more flexibility38

Considering as the response variable the count of incivilities per year the model can be

expressed as follow

120582 119890119909119901 120573 120573 119892119894119899119894 120573 119891119900119903119890119894119892119899 119883120574 120572 120579 (42)

36 If we think of 120582 as the average number of incivilities per year then represents the number per 1000

inhabitants so that the yearly count is adjusted to be comparable across counties of different sizes Adjusting the yearly count by population is equivalent to adding 119897119900119892 1199011199001199011199061198971198861199051198941199001198991000 to the right-hand side of the regression equation 37 Without adjusting for overdispersion we use incorrect artificially small standard errors leading to artificially small p-values for model coefficients 38 The Negative Binomial model posits selecting a 120582 (average number of incivilities) for each county and then generating a count using a Poisson random variable with the selected 120582 With this approach the counts will be more dispersed than would be expected for observations based on a single Poisson variable with rate 120582

111

where 120582 is the rate of incivilities 119883 is our vector of controls 120572prime119904 are county-specific constants

and 120579prime119904 are time-specific constants Accounting for differences in county population we have

119890119909119901 120573 120573 119892119894119899119894 119883120574 120572 120579 (43)

where 119901119900119901119906119897119886119905119894119900119899 is the county population per year Hence the model to be estimated using

Maximum Likelihood Estimation (MLE) is

119897119900119892 120582 120573 120573 119892119894119899119894 119883120574 120572 120579 119897119900119892 (44)

Finally to account for different effects depending on the type of incivilities we also run

equation (44) for each of the four groups of incivilities defined in section (432)

435 Hypotheses

Based on the community heterogeneity hypothesis the relationship between social cohesion

and diversity should be stronger for lower levels of income and less educated groups of people

(Tolsma et al 2009) Hence contrary to evidence for developed and more equal countries we

expect a significant positive association for the Chilean case where more than 50 of the

population is economically vulnerable (OECD 2017)

The main hypotheses to be tested in this essay is whether the number of incivilities is

positively associated with the level of economic and racial heterogeneity at the county level We

start analysing this association for the full sample and period Next we analyse whether the

relationship between incivilities and our measures of diversity differs by geographic area (region

or zone) Finally we check whether the effect of economic and racial diversity is different

depending on the group of incivilities

112

44 Results and Discussion

Overall our results show that the rate of incivilities displays a stronger and more significant

relationship with racial diversity than with economic heterogeneity This association differs for

different geographic areas and for different types of incivilities Absolute economic indicators

except for income show a significant but small effect Increases in the average levels of income

or education and more financial autonomy for municipalities seem to be effective ways to reduce

the rate of incivilities

We estimate equation (44) assuming that the number of incivilities follows a Poisson

distribution Regional and temporal heterogeneity are captured through the inclusion of dummy

variables for five years (with 2006 as the reference year) and fourteen regional dummies (with

region XIII as the reference region) Results are reported in Table 4339 This table is structured in

two blocks of regressions pooled models in columns (1)-(4) and fixed-effects models in columns

(5)-(8)40 The first column in each block only includes economic indicators relative and absolute

trying to test which ones are more relevant and whether incivilities tend to mirror income

inequality (the ldquoincivilities thesisrdquo) The second column adds the variable foreign to account for

the effect of racial diversity (Letki 2008) The third column includes education to check whether

the association between economic and racial diversity with social cohesion changes (gets less

significant) when we control for educational level (Tolsma et al 2009) The final column in each

block corresponds to the full model specification which includes the rest of controls

39 Pooled estimations were obtained using the R command glm() and compared with results obtained from the command poisson in STATA 15 Fixed effects and random effects models were estimated using the STATA command xtpoisson Negative Binomial models were estimated using the command glmnb() in the MASS package for R and commands nbreg and xtnbreg in STATA 15 Results for Negative Binomial regressions are in Appendix T 40 We have omitted results with random effects due to the literature on panel count data models suggest that the most robust estimator is Poisson regression with Fixed Effects (Santos Silva amp Tenreyro 2010 2011)

113

Table 43

Poisson regressions

114

The positive and significant coefficient for the variable gini besides being small it becomes

insignificant in the fixed effects specification which includes the full set of controls This result

does not seem to be enough evidence to support our hypothesis that more unequal counties display

higher rates of incivilities On the other hand racial diversity through the variable foreign shows

a consistent positive association with the rate of incivilities41 Together coefficients for gini and

foreign seems to support the ldquocommunity heterogeneity thesisrdquo (Letki 2008) but not the

ldquoincivilities thesisrdquo (Skogan 1999) To check this finding we run the pooled full model

specification for each region and results are shown in Table 44 where regions have been ordered

from North to South The sign of the coefficient of the variable gini differs for different regions

Moreover the relationship is insignificant in some of the most unequal regions which are in the

South of the country (VIII IX and XIV) This result rejects the hypothesis that incivilities mirror

structural income inequalities For the variable foreign 12 out of 15 regions confirm the positive

association with the rate of incivilities42

We also run our pooled full model separately for each group of incivilities defined at the end

of section (432) Income inequality keeps its significant but small association with each group of

incivilities (see Table 45) Our measure of racial diversity shows a stronger association with

ldquoAlcohol Consumptionrdquo related to ldquoPublic Damagerdquo and ldquoThreatsrdquo The link with ldquoStreet Tradingrdquo

appears as non-significant These results support our general finding that on the one hand racial

heterogeneity exert a more significant influence on the rate of incivilities than economic

41 To get the effects of the variables gini and foreign over the rate of incivilities per 1000 inhabitants we need to exponentiate their coefficients Thus an increase in one unit in the variable gini increases the rate of incivilities per 1000 inhabitantsrdquo in 1005 times (e^0005) in the pooled full model Similarly an increase in one point in variable foreign is expected to increase the ldquorate of incivilities per 1000 inhabitantsrdquo in 10876 times (e^0084) in the full pooled model and 10471 (e^0046) times in the full Fixed Effects model 42 Given that depending on the geographic location regions share certain characteristics the model was also run clustering regions in 4 zones (see Figure 31 in chapter 3) Results by zone are in Appendix U

115

heterogeneity On the other hand results confirm our hypothesis that the effect of diversity is

different for different types of incivilities

Table 44 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson models by region

Back to our general results in Table 43 the significant and negative coefficient of the

income variable and to a lesser extent the significant and positive coefficients of poverty and

unemployment provide evidence that absolute rather than relative economic indicators may be

more important explanations of the rate of incivilities This is opposite to evidence for the analysis

116

of crime rates such as in Hoodge (2010) and support the idea that determinants of incivilities are

different from those of crime Our results are also opposite to those for Dutch municipalities where

economic indicators turned out to be more important than ethnic heterogeneity (Tolsma et al

2009) The coefficient for the variable log(income) could be interpreted as counties with an income

level under the average face higher problems of antisocial behaviours such as incivilities In

addition as the income level moves far away from its average low level the problem of incivilities

is less relevant43 In terms of policy implications only those policies that achieve a significant

increase in the average level of county income seem to be effective in reducing incivilities and

strengthening social cohesion

Table 45 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson model by incivility group

43 We ran our model splitting the sample of counties in quintiles based on their income level The coefficient for the variable gini only showed a significant (and positive) coefficient for the second third and fourth quintile A non-significant coefficient for the first quintile could imply that other types of inequalities (eg health education) are more relevant in the poorest counties In the case of the fifth quintile (the richest group of counties) they have better facilities in terms of infrastructure police resources self-protection etc which could reduce the potential triggers of incivilities

117

The inclusion of the variable education significantly improved the goodness of fit of the

models and did not generate significant changes in the coefficients of our measures of economic

and racial diversity This result rejects the proposition that the relationship between social

cohesion and diversity becomes less strong when controlled by education (Tolsma et al 2009)

Additionally it highlights the topic of education as a relevant determinant of the rate of incivilities

and social cohesion

Among control variables there are also some important results Opposite to what we

expected the variable youth shows a negative or non-significant coefficient Although this result

could be due to the lack of ldquophysical incivilitiesrdquo in Chilean records it indicates that it is incorrect

to stereotype this group as the main responsible for high incivilities rates The significant and

negative coefficient of the variable autonomy in the fixed effects specification could also have

important policy implications It is a signal that local governments can play an important role in

reducing incivilities or complementing the efforts from the central government Another

interesting result is the significant coefficient of the variable housing The latter finding is

particularly important in the sense that a negative sign supports public policies oriented to increase

homeownership as effective ways to improve social cohesion However the small magnitude of

the coefficient that even showed the opposite sign in some model specifications could be

explained for the high level of segregation that these policies have generated in Chilean society

As mentioned in the Introduction and Literature Review so far only a few studies have

used measures of disorders or incivilities as dependent variable to explain changes in social

cohesion (Skogan 2015) In addition there is no evidence in Chile analysing the determinants of

incivilities separately from those of crimes The importance of our results on identifying the

importance of economic and racial diversity on social cohesion lies mainly in its generality An

118

important number of countries all around the world share a similar context characterized by high

levels of inequality and an explosive increase in immigration These countries are also

experiencing a worsening in social cohesion which increases the risk of a social outburst

4 5 Conclusions

The main goal of this essay was to determine whether differences in incivilities at the county

level mirror differences in income distribution and racial diversity Previous literature suggests a

positive and strong association between social cohesion and indicators of economic disadvantage

relative deprivation and racial diversity (Letki 2008 Tolsma et al 2009 Uslaner amp Brown 2005)

While not all our results were significant they showed helpful insights about how and where

economic and racial diversity are more likely to influence the rate of incivilities and social

cohesion

We used data for the period 2006ndash17 economic heterogeneity was measured through the

Gini coefficient at the county level and racial heterogeneity was proxied by the number of granted

visas to foreigners as proportion of county population We found strong evidence of a significant

and positive association between the rate of incivilities and racial diversity but not with income

inequality Contrary to previous evidence at the municipal level (Coffeacute amp Geys 2006 Tolsma et

al 2009) in general our results give support for the ldquohomophily principlerdquo and the ldquocommunity

heterogeneity hypothesisrdquo However results also showed that the effect of economic and racial

diversity varies throughout the Chilean regions and for the different types of incivilities

We also found that policies aimed at controlling the behaviour of young people did not have

strong empirical support In terms of the role that local governments may have in facing the

119

growing problem of incivilities we found evidence that efforts managed from the municipalities

can be an important complement to those from the central government

Future research should go further on the role of local authorities on incivilities and social

cohesion On the one hand municipalities could have a direct impact on social cohesion through

the implementation of programs complementary to those of central authorities oriented to reduce

incivilities and crime On the other hand social cohesion could be indirectly affected when local

authorities display an inefficient performance supplying public services to citizens or they are

recognized as corrupted institutions We suggest that policy makers from central government

should give local authorities a greater role in fighting antisocial behaviours and crime Evaluating

programs in specific municipalities could help to elucidate the causal effect of for instance higher

fiscal autonomy on the rate of incivilities

Another interesting area for future work will be to analyse how housing policies have

contributed to the phenomenon of segregation of Chilean society and in the process of weakening

social cohesion Finally our main result highlights the need of a deeper analysis of the impact that

foreign immigration is having in Chile For instance disaggregating information by country of

origin and the reasons why immigrants are arriving to the country or specific regions will surely

help to understand the impacts of immigration

120

Chapter 5 Conclusions

This thesis investigated in three essays the issue of income inequality in Chile using county-

level data for the period 2006-2017 The first essay supplied empirical evidence about the

importance of the degree of dependence on natural resources in terms of employment in explaining

cross-county differences in income inequality The second essay analysed the potential causal

effect that income inequality has on the level of technical efficiency of local governments

providing public goods and services Lastly the third essay studied the relationship between social

cohesion measured through the number of antisocial behaviours classified as ldquoincivilitiesrdquo and

the levels of income and racial heterogeneity

Findings from the first essay support the idea that the endowment of natural resources plays

a significant role in explaining income inequality in Chile However contrary to what most

theoretical and empirical evidence postulates our findings showed a robust negative association

between the two variables This means that the reduction experienced in Chile in the degree of

dependence on natural resources in terms of employment has contributed to the persistence of high

levels of income inequality The exploratory analysis indicated that income inequality shows a

general clustering process characterized by a significant and positive spatial autocorrelation

Regarding the previous evidence for Chile (Paredes et al 2016) the regression analysis confirmed

the relevance of the spatial dimension of income inequality through a process of spatial

heterogeneity giving less support to the existence of a process of spatial dependence (spillover

effect) in the variable itself

121

Essay 2 studied the potential trade-off between efficiency and equity analysing the influence

of income inequality on the efficiency of local governments at the municipal level To identify the

causal effect of income inequality on municipal efficiency we proposed the use of the proportion

of firms in the primary sector as an instrument for income inequality Findings confirmed our

hypothesis that efficiency is lower in more unequal counties This result suggests the non-existence

of the trade-off between equity and efficiency Hence policies intended to reduce inequality could

help to increase efficiency at least at the level of municipal local governments

The third essay analysed how social cohesion proxied by the rate of incivilities is associated

with the levels of economic diversity proxied by income inequality and the levels of racial

diversity proxied by the number of new visas grated as proportion of the county population

Findings gave strong support to the hypothesis that the rate of incivilities is positively related to

racial diversity and to a lesser extent to economic diversity In addition the rate of incivilities

appears negatively related to the degree of financial autonomy of municipalities This means that

local governments can effectively contribute to the reduction of incivilities which could help

reduce victimization and crime rates ultimately strengthening social cohesion

Taken together findings from essays 2 and 3 highlight the important role that income

inequality could play in other relevant economic and social dimensions These findings add to the

understanding of the potential consequences of income inequality particularly in natural resource

rich countries with persistently high levels of inequality

The present study has mainly investigated income inequality at the county level In addition

Chilean municipalities play an important role providing ldquoservices to peoplerdquo so our findings could

be applied in other highly unequal countries with a high degree of dependence on natural resources

and local governments with similar responsibilities For instance in Latin America apart from

122

Chile and Brazil there are no studies on the efficiency of local governments Other limitations are

associated with the availability of information For instance important indicators such as GDP per

capita are only available at the regional level and information of incomes is not available annually

In addition given the heterogeneity among municipalities some type of grouping of municipalities

should be performed before looking for causal relationships or conducting program evaluation

Despite these limitations we believe this study could be the basis for different strands of future

research on the topic of inequality local government efficiency and social cohesion

It was stated in chapter 2 based on the resource curse hypothesis literature there are two

elements that determine whether NR are a curse or blessing in terms of socioeconomic outcomes

First the curse is more likely in countries with weak political and governance institutions Second

different types of resources affect institutions differently with resources that are concentrated in

space so-called ldquopointrdquo resources tend to impair institutions while ldquodiffuserdquo resources do not

(Deacon 2011 Isham Woolcock Pritchett amp Busby 2005) Our results showed a negative

relationship between income inequality and our measure of natural resource dependence even after

controlling for zone fixed effects and for the level of government expenditure This result could

be interpreted as a signal that NR has a direct effect on income inequality in addition to the indirect

impact through market or institutional channels Using other potential institutional transmission

channels will shed light about the true effect that the endowment of natural resources has over

income inequality Variables that could capture these institutional channels include the level of

employment in the public sector measures of rule of law and corruption and changes in the

creation of new business in the secondary and tertiary sectors related to the primary sector

Based on results from chapter 3 most of the municipalities show scale inefficiencies One

immediate area for future work will involve using our set of contextual factors to predict the status

123

of municipalities in terms of scale inefficiencies Defining as dependent variable whether a

municipality shows constant decreasing or increasing returns to scale we could run a multinomial

logistic regression to predict municipal status For instance we would expect that a one-unit

increase in the Gini coefficient should increase the probability of scale inefficiencies (increasing

or decreasing returns to scale rather than constant returns to scale) Because the aim in this case

would be predicting a certain result in terms of returns to scale the next step should involve to

split the full sample in training and testing data sets and to use some resampling methods such as

bootstrapping This will allow us to evaluate the performance and accuracy of our model

predictions using different random samples of municipalities Results from Machine Learning

algorithms will help us to assess the generalizability of our results to other data sets

Future work should also benefit greatly by using data on different Latin American countries

to (1) compare the responsibilities of local governments (2) select a common set of inputs and

output to evaluate LGE (3) identify the relevance of scales inefficiencies in explaining differences

in performance and (4) analyse the influence of contextual characteristics over LGE Differences

in the main primary sector activity in each country such as oil in Brazil mining in Chile or Coffee

in Colombia could be responsible for differences in LGE among countries These differences could

be associated with sources of revenue management of expenditure and definitions of outputs or

contextual effects such as corrupted institutions or the delay in the development of other sectors

such as manufacturing or services

To delve deep on reasons explaining the social crisis experienced by Chilean society and

other countries one area of future work will be to analyse the relationship between diversity and

the origins of social revolutions Based on Tiruneh (2014) the three most important factors that

explain the onset of social revolutions are economic development regime type and state

124

ineffectiveness Interesting questions include whether the characteristics of Chilean context at the

end of 2019 are enough to trigger the transformation of the political and socioeconomic system

Social revolutions particularly violent revolutions are less likely in more democratic educated

and wealthy societies So it would be relevant to identify the factors explaining the violence that

has characterized the social crisis in Chile Finally the democratic regime has been maintained in

the last decades with changes between left and right governments This could imply that more

important than the regime has been the efficiency or ineffectiveness of the governments to satisfy

the needs of the population

Future work should also cover the disaggregation of information regarding foreign

population in terms of the reasons for new granted visas and the country of origin Official data

allows us to disaggregate whether the benefit is permanent (students and employees with contract)

or temporary Furthermore most of the new visas were traditionally granted to neighbouring

countries (Peru and Bolivia) a trend that has changed in the recent years to include countries such

as Colombia Venezuela and Haiti An analysis of how economic and social indicators have been

affected by changes in the composition of foreigners their reasons for immigrating to the country

and their geographical distribution have implications for economic policy at both the national and

local levels At the national level such analysis should be a key input when proposing changes to

the national immigration policy At the local level it could help define the role of municipalities

to assess the benefits and challenges of immigration These challenges are mainly related to the

provision of public goods and services such as health and education which in Chile are the

responsibility of the municipalities

The findings of this thesis suggest that policymakers should encourage policies that reduce

income inequality The key role that municipalities could play to strengthen social cohesion and

125

the increasingly important role that foreign population is acquiring in most modern societies are

also interesting avenues for future research However the picture is still incomplete and more

research is needed incorporating other dimensions of inequality This is essential if we want to

understand the reasons that could have triggered the social outbursts experienced by various

economies across the globe

126

Bibliography

Acemoglu D (1995) Reward structures and the allocation of talent European Economic Review 39(1) 17ndash33 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg1010160014-2921(94)00014-Q

Acemoglu D (2002) Technical Change Inequality and the Labor Market Journal of Economic Literature 40(1) 7ndash72 httpsdoiorg1012570022051026976

Acemoglu D Aghion P amp Violante G L (2001) Deunionization Technical Change and Inequality Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 55(1) 229ndash264 httpsdoiorg101016S0167-2231(01)00058-6

Acemoglu D Johnson S amp Robinson J A (2001) The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development An Empirical Investigation The American Economic Review 91(5) 1369ndash1401 httpsdoiorg101257aer9151369

Acemoglu D amp Robinson J A (2002) The Political Economy of the Kuznets Curve Review of Development Economics 6(2) 183ndash203 httpsdoiorg1011111467-936100149

Afonso A amp Fernandes S (2006) Measuring local government spending efficiency Evidence for the Lisbon region Regional Studies 40(1) 39ndash53 httpsdoiorg10108000343400500449937

Afonso A amp Fernandes S (2008) Assessing and explaining the relative efficiency of local government The Journal of Socio-Economics 37(5) 1946ndash1979 httpsdoiorg101016jsocec200703007

Afonso A Schuknecht L amp Tanzi V (2010) Income distribution determinants and public spending efficiency Journal of Economic Inequality 8(3) 367ndash389 httpsdoiorg101007s10888-010-9138-z

Akita T (2003) Decomposing regional income inequality in China and Indonesia using two-stage nested Theil decomposition method The Annals of Regional Science 37(1) 55ndash77 httpsdoiorg101007s001680200107

Alesina A (2000) Participation in heterogeneous communities The Quarterly Journal of Economics 115(3) 847ndash904 httpsdoiorg101162003355300554935

Alesina A amp La Ferrara E (2002) Who trusts others Journal of Public Economics 85(2) 207ndash234 httpsdoiorg101016S0047-2727(01)00084-6

Allcott H amp Keniston D (2014) Dutch Disease or Agglomeration The Local Economic Effects of Natural Resource Booms in Modern America (N W P N 20508 Ed) NBER Working Paper No 20508 (Vol w20508) NBER Working Paper No 20508 NBER Working Paper No 20508 httpsdoiorgNBER Working Paper No 20508

Andersen T M amp Maibom J (2020) The big trade-off between efficiency and equitymdashis it there Oxford Economic Papers 72(2) 391ndash411

127

Anselin L (1988) Spatial econometrics methods and models (Vol 4) DordrechtBoston Kluwer Academic Publishers

Anselin L amp Bera A K (1998) Spatial dependence in linear regression models with an introduction to spatial econometrics Statistics Textbooks and Monographs (Vol 155)

Anselin L Bera A K Florax R amp Yoon M J (1996) Simple diagnostic tests for spatial dependence Regional Science and Urban Economics 26(1) 77ndash104 httpsdoiorg1010160166-0462(95)02111-6

Antonelli M A amp De Bonis V (2018) The efficiency of social public expenditure in European countries a two-stage analysis Applied Economics 1ndash14 httpsdoiorg1010800003684620181489522

Aragoacuten F M amp Rud J P (2013) Natural Resources and Local Communities Evidence from a Peruvian Gold Mine American Economic Journal Economic Policy 5(2) 1ndash25 httpsdoiorg101257pol521

Ariely G (2014) Does Diversity Erode Social Cohesion Conceptual and Methodological Issues Political Studies 62(3) 573ndash595 httpsdoiorg1011111467-924812068

Armstrong H amp Taylor J (2000) Regional economics and policy (3rd ed) Oxford Blackwell

Aroca P amp Atienza M (2011) Economic implications of long distance commuting in the Chilean mining industry Resources Policy 36(3) 196ndash203 httpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201103004

Aroca P amp Bosch M (2000) Crecimiento convergencia y espacio en las regiones chilenas 1960 - 1998 Estudios de Economiacutea 27 199ndash224 Retrieved from httprepositoriouchileclbitstreamhandle2250127853Patricio_Arocapdfsequence=1

Ashworth J Geys B Heyndels B amp Wille F (2014) Competition in the political arena and local government performance Applied Economics 46(19) 2264ndash2276 httpsdoiorg101080000368462014899679

Atkinson A B (2015) Inequality What Can Be Done Harvard University Press

Auty R (1993) Sustaining development in mineral economies the resource curse thesis London [ua] Routledge

Auty R (2001) Resource abundance and economic development (R World Institute for Development Economics Ed) Oxford Oxford University Press

Badeeb R A Lean H H amp Clark J (2017) The evolution of the natural resource curse thesis A critical literature survey Resources Policy 51 123ndash134 httpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201610015

Balaguer-Coll M T Brun-Martos M I Maacuterquez-Ramos L amp Prior D (2019) Local government efficiency determinants and spatial interdependence Applied Economics

128

51(14) 1478ndash1494 httpsdoiorg1010800003684620181527458

Balaguer-Coll M T amp Prior D (2009) Short- and long-term evaluation of efficiency and quality An application to Spanish municipalities Applied Economics 41(23) 2991ndash3002 httpsdoiorg10108000036840701351923

Banker R D Charnes A amp Cooper W W (1984) Some models for estimating technical and scale inefficiencies in data envelopment analysis Management Science 30(9) 1078ndash1092

Beine M Coulombe S amp Vermeulen W N (2015) Dutch Disease and the Mitigation Effect of Migration Evidence from Canadian Provinces The Economic Journal 125(589) 1574ndash1615 httpsdoiorg101111ecoj12171

Benito B Bastida F amp Garciacutea J A (2010) Explaining differences in efficiency an application to Spanish municipalities Applied Economics 42(4) 515ndash528 httpsdoiorg10108000036840701675560

Berg A amp Ostry J (2011) Equality and efficiency Finance amp Development 48(3) 12ndash15

Berg A amp Ostry J (2017) Inequality and Unsustainable Growth Two Sides of the Same Coin IMF ECONOMIC REVIEW 65(4) 792ndash815 httpsdoiorg101057s41308-017-0030-8

Beyer H amp Vergara R (2006) Delincuencia en Chile Determinantes y rol de las poliacuteticas puacuteblicas Instituto de Economiacutea UC

Blanco L amp Grier R (2012) Natural resource dependence and the accumulation of physical and human capital in Latin America Resources Policy 37(3) 281ndash295 httpsdoiorghttpdoiorg101016jresourpol201201005

Blau J R amp Blau P M (1982) The cost of inequality Metropolitan structure and violent crime American Sociological Review 114ndash129

Boetti L Piacenza M amp Turati G (2009) Fiscal decentralization and spending efficiency of local governments An Empirical Investigation on a Sample Of 4

Boix C amp Posner D (1998) Social capital Explaining its origins and effects on government performance British Journal Of Political Science 28 686ndash693

Borge L E Parmer P amp Torvik R (2015) Local natural resource curse JOURNAL OF PUBLIC ECONOMICS 131 101ndash114 httpsdoiorg101016jjpubeco201509002

Borger B Kerstens K Moesen W amp Vanneste J (1994) Explaining differences in productive efficiency An application to Belgian municipalities Public Choice 80(3) 339ndash358 httpsdoiorg101007BF01053225

Bourguignon F amp Morrisson C (1990) Income distribution development and foreign trade A cross-sectional analysislowast European Economic Review 34(6) 1113ndash1132 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg1010160014-2921(90)90071-6

129

Branas C C Cheney R A MacDonald J M Tam V W Jackson T D amp Ten Have T R (2011) A difference-in-differences analysis of health safety and greening vacant urban space American Journal of Epidemiology 174(11) 1296ndash1306

Bravo J (2014) Fondo Comuacuten Municipal y su desincentivo a la recaudacioacuten en Chile Temas de La Agenda Legislativa-Centro de Poliacuteticas Puacuteblicas UC 9(68)

Browning E K amp Johnson W R (1984) The Trade-Off between Equality and Efficiency Journal of Political Economy 92(2) 175ndash203 httpsdoiorg101086261219

Brunnschweiler C N amp Bulte E H (2008) The resource curse revisited and revised A tale of paradoxes and red herrings Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 55(3) 248ndash264 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jjeem200708004

Brunori P Ferreira F H G amp Peragine V (2013) Inequality of opportunity income inequality and economic mobility Some international comparisons In Getting Development Right (pp 85ndash115) Springer

Brunton-Smith I Jackson J amp Sutherland A (2014) Bridging structure and perception On the neighbourhood ecology of beliefs and worries about violent crime British Journal of Criminology 54(4) 503ndash526

Bulte E H Damania R amp Deacon R T (2005) Resource intensity institutions and development World Development 33(7) 1029ndash1044 httpsdoiorg101016jworlddev200504004

Carmignani F (2013) Development outcomes resource abundance and the transmission through inequality Resource and Energy Economics 35(3) 412ndash428 httpsdoiorg101016jreseneeco201304007

Carmignani Fabrizio amp Avom D (2010) The social development effects of primary commodity export dependence Ecological Economics 70(2) 317ndash330 httpsdoiorg101016jecolecon201009003

Caselli F amp Michaels G (2013) Do Oil Windfalls Improve Living Standards Evidence from Brazil American Economic Journal Applied Economics 5(1) 208ndash238 httpsdoiorg101257app51208

Celebioglu F amp Dallrsquoerba S (2010) Spatial disparities across the regions of Turkey An exploratory spatial data analysis Annals of Regional Science 45(2) 379ndash400 httpsdoiorg101007s00168-009-0313-8

Chan J To H-P amp Chan E (2006) Reconsidering social cohesion Developing a definition and analytical framework for empirical research Social Indicators Research 75(2) 273ndash302

Charnes A Cooper W W amp Rhodes E (1978) Measuring the efficiency of decision making units European Journal of Operational Research 2(6) 429ndash444

130

Chi G amp Zhu J (2019) Spatial Regression Models for the Social Sciences SAGE Publications Retrieved from httpsbooksgooglecomaubooksid=zHGkvwEACAAJ

Christiansen K O (1960) Industrialization and urbanization in relation to crime and juvenile delinquency International Review of Criminal Policy 16 3ndash8

Cingano F (2014) Trends in income inequality and its impact on economic growth (Vol 163) Paris OECD Publishing httpsdoiorg1017875jxrjncwxv6j-en

Coelli T J Prasada Rao D S OrsquoDonnell C J amp Battese G E (2005) An introduction to efficiency and productivity analysis An Introduction to Efficiency and Productivity Analysis Springer Science amp Business Media httpsdoiorg101007b136381

Coffeacute H amp Geys B (2005) Institutional Performance and Social Capital An Application to the Local Government Level Journal of Urban Affairs 27(5) 485ndash501 httpsdoiorg101111j0735-2166200500249x

Coffeacute H amp Geys B (2006) Community Heterogeneity A Burden for the Creation of Social Capital Social Science Quarterly 87(5) 1053ndash1072 httpsdoiorg101111j1540-6237200600415x

Cohen D Spear S Scribner R Kissinger P Mason K amp Wildgen J (2000) ldquo Broken windowsrdquo and the risk of gonorrhea American Journal of Public Health 90(2) 230

Corden W M amp Neary J P (1982) Booming sector and de-industrialisation in a small open economy The Economic Journal 92(368) 825ndash848

Cordero J M Pedraja-Chaparro F Pisaflores E C amp Polo C (2017) Efficiency assessment of Portuguese municipalities using a conditional nonparametric approach Journal of Productivity Analysis 48(1) 1ndash24 httpsdoiorg101007s11123-017-0500-z

Croissant Y amp Millo G (2018) Panel Data Econometrics with R John Wiley amp Sons

Cust J amp Poelhekke S (2015) The Local Economic Impacts of Natural Resource Extraction 7 251ndash268 httpsdoiorg101146annurev-resource-100814-125106

da Cruz N F amp Marques R C (2014) Revisiting the determinants of local government performance Omega 44 91ndash103 httpsdoiorg101016JOMEGA201309002

Dauvin M amp Guerreiro D (2017) The Paradox of Plenty A Meta-Analysis World Development 94 httpsdoiorg101016jworlddev201701009

de Sousa M da C S Cribari-Neto F amp Stosic B D (2005) Explaining DEA technical efficiency scores in an outlier corrected environment the case of public services in Brazilian municipalities Brazilian Review of Econometrics 25(2) 287ndash313

Deacon R T (2011) The Political Economy of the Natural Resource Curse A Survey of Theory and Evidence Foundations and Trends in Microeconomics 111-208

Delhey J amp Newton K (2005) Predicting cross-national levels of social trust global pattern or

131

Nordic exceptionalism European Sociological Review 21(4) 311ndash327

Dlouhyacute M (2018) Measuring Geographic Inequalities Dealing with Multiple Health Resources by Data Envelopment Analysis Frontiers in Public Health 6 53 httpsdoiorg103389fpubh201800053

Dollery B Wallis J amp Akimov A (2010) One Size Does Not Fit All The Special Case of Remote Small Local Councils in Outback Queensland Local Government Studies 36(1) 21ndash42 httpsdoiorg10108003003930903435716

Domenech J (2008) Mineral resource abundance and regional growth in Spain 1860ndash2000 Journal of International Development The Journal of the Development Studies Association 20(8) 1122ndash1135

Doran J amp Jordan D (2016) Decomposing US regional income inequality from 1969 to 2009 Applied Economics Letters 23(11) 781ndash784 httpsdoiorg1010801350485120151109030

Drew J amp Dollery B (2015) The State of Things The Dynamic Efficiency of Australian State and Territories Economic Papers A Journal of Applied Economics and Policy 34(3) 165ndash176

Drew J Kortt M amp Dollery B (2015) What Determines Efficiency in Local Government A DEA Analysis of NSW Local Government Economic Papers A Journal of Applied Economics and Policy 34(4) 243ndash256 httpsdoiorg1011111759-344112118

Easterly W (2007) Inequality does cause underdevelopment Insights from a new instrument Journal of Development Economics 84(2) 755ndash776 httpsdoiorghttpdxdoiorg101016jjdeveco200611002

Ebert L amp La Menza T (2015) Chile copper and resource revenue A holistic approach to assessing commodity dependence Resources Policy 43(Supplement C) 101ndash111 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201410007

ElGindi T (2017) Natural resource dependency neoliberal globalization and income inequality Are they related A longitudinal study of developing countries (1980ndash2010) Current Sociology 65(1) 21ndash53 httpsdoiorg1011770011392116632031

Engerman S L amp Sokoloff K L (1994) Factor Endowments Institutions and Differential Paths of Growth Among New World Economies National Bureau of Economic Research

Engerman S L amp Sokoloff K L (1997) Factor endowments institutions and differential paths of growth among new world economies How Latin America Fell Behind 260ndash304

Engerman S L Sokoloff K L Urquiola M amp Acemoglu D (2002) Factor Endowments Inequality and Paths of Development among New World Economies [with Comments] EconomampxedA 3(1) 41ndash109 Retrieved from httpwwwjstororgezp01libraryquteduaustable20065432

132

Faumlre R Grosskopf S amp Lovell C A K (1985) The measurement of efficiency of production (Vol 6) Springer Science amp Business Media

Fleming D A amp Measham T G (2015a) Income Inequality across Australian Regions during the Mining Boom 2001-11 Australian Geographer 46(2) 203ndash216 httpsdoiorg1010800004918220151020596

Fleming D A amp Measham T G (2015b) Local economic impacts of an unconventional energy boom the coal seam gas industry in Australia Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 59(1) 78ndash94 httpsdoiorg1011111467-848912043

Fum R M amp Hodler R (2010) Natural resources and income inequality The role of ethnic divisions Economics Letters 107(3) 360ndash363 httpsdoiorg101016jeconlet201003008

Garofalo J (1978) The fear of crime Broadening our perspective

Geys B amp Moesen W (2009) Exploring Sources of Local Government Technical Inefficiency Evidence from Flemish Municipalities Public Finance and Management 9(1) 1ndash29

Goderis B amp Malone S W (2011) Natural Resource Booms and Inequality Theory and Evidence The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 113(2) 388ndash417 httpsdoiorg101111j1467-9442201101659x

Greene W H (2016) Productivity and Efficiency Analysis (W H Greene L Khalaf R Sickles M Veall amp M-C Voia Eds) (1st ed 20) Cham Springer International Publishing httpsdoiorg101007978-3-319-23228-7

Gustafsson B amp Shi L (2002) Income inequality within and across counties in rural China 1988 and 1995 Journal of Development Economics 69(1) 179ndash204 httpsdoiorg101016S0304-3878(02)00058-5

Gylfason T amp Zoega G (2003) Inequality and Economic Growth Do Natural Resources Matter In T T Eicher S (Ed) Inequality and Growth Theory and Policy Implications (pp 255ndash292) The MIT Press

Henningsen A (2010) Estimating Censored Regression Models in R using the censReg Package R Package Vignettes Collection 5(2) 12

Henningsen A (2019) censReg Censored Regression (Tobit) Models R package version 05-30 httpscranr-projectorgpackage=censReg Retrieved from httpscranr-projectorgpackage=censReg

Herrera S amp Pang G (2005) Efficiency of Public Spending in Developing Countriesthinsp An Efficiency Frontier Approach World Bank Washington DC

Hill T D amp Angel R J (2005) Neighborhood disorder psychological distress and heavy drinking Social Science amp Medicine 61(5) 965ndash975

133

httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jsocscimed200412027

Hipp J R (2010) RESIDENT PERCEPTIONS OF CRIME AND DISORDER HOW MUCH IS ldquoBIASrdquo AND HOW MUCH IS SOCIAL ENVIRONMENT DIFFERENCES Criminology 48(2) 475ndash508 httpsdoiorg101111j1745-9125201000193x

Holtug N amp Mason A (2010) Introduction Immigration diversity and social cohesion SAGE Publications Sage UK London England

Hooghe M Vanhoutte B Hardyns W amp Bircan T (2010) Unemployment Inequality Poverty and Crime Spatial Distribution Patterns of Criminal Acts in Belgium 2001ndash06 The British Journal of Criminology 51(1) 1ndash20 httpsdoiorg101093bjcazq067

Howie P amp Atakhanova Z (2014) Resource boom and inequality Kazakhstan as a case study Resources Policy 39(1) 71ndash79 httpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201311004

Isham J Woolcock M Pritchett L amp Busby G (2005) The Varieties of Resource Experience Natural Resource Export Structures and the Political Economy of Economic Growth The World Bank Economic Review 19(2) 141ndash174 httpsdoiorg101093wberlhi010

Jottier D Ashworth J amp Heyndels B (2012) Understanding Votersrsquo Preferences How the Electoratersquos Complexity Affects Prediction Accuracy and Wishful Thinking among Politicians with Respect to Election Outcomes Kyklos 65(3) 340ndash370 httpsdoiorg101111j1467-6435201200542x

Kanbur S M R amp Venables A (2005) Spatial inequality and development (R World Institute for Development Economics Ed) Oxford Oxford University Press

Kesler C amp Bloemraad I (2010) Does immigration erode social capital The conditional effects of immigration-generated diversity on trust membership and participation across 19 countries 1981ndash2000 Canadian Journal of Political ScienceRevue Canadienne de Science Politique 43(2) 319ndash347

Kuznets S (1955) Economic Growth and Income Inequality The American Economic Review 45(1) 1ndash28 Retrieved from httpwwwjstororgstable1811581

Lagos G amp Blanco E (2010) Mining and development in the region of Antofagasta Resources Policy 35(4) 265ndash275 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201007006

Leamer E E Maul H Rodriguez S amp Schott P K (1999) Does natural resource abundance increase Latin American income inequality Journal of Development Economics 59(1) 3ndash42 httpsdoiorg101016s0304-3878(99)00004-8

Leibbrandt M Finn A amp Woolard I (2012) Describing and decomposing post-apartheid income inequality in South Africa Development Southern Africa 29(1) 19ndash34 httpsdoiorg1010800376835X2012645639

134

Letki N (2008) Does Diversity Erode Social Cohesion Social Capital and Race in British Neighbourhoods Political Studies 56(1) 99ndash126 httpsdoiorg101111j1467-9248200700692x

Lewis D A (2017) Fear of crime Incivility and the production of a social problem Routledge

lo Storto C (2013) Evaluating Technical Efficiency of Italian Major Municipalities A Data Envelopment Analysis model Procedia - Social and Behavioral Sciences 81 346ndash350 httpsdoiorg101016JSBSPRO201306440

Loayza N amp Rigolini J (2016) The Local Impact of Mining on Poverty and Inequality Evidence from the Commodity Boom in Peru World Development 84 219ndash234 httpsdoiorg101016jworlddev201603005

Loayza N Teran A M y amp Rigolini J (2013) Poverty Inequality and the Local Natural Resource Curse World Bank Policy Research Working Paper (6366) httpsdoiorg1015961813-9450-6366

Loacutepez R amp Miller S J (2008) Chile The Unbearable Burden of Inequality World Development 36(12) 2679ndash2695 httpsdoiorg101016jworlddev200801012

Manzano O amp Rigobon R (2001) Resource Curse or Debt Overhang National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper Series No 8390 1 httpsdoiorghttpwwwnberorgpapersw9424bib

McPherson M Smith-Lovin L amp Cook J M (2001) Birds of a Feather Homophily in Social Networks Annual Review of Sociology 27(1) 415ndash444 httpsdoiorg101146annurevsoc271415

McQuestin D Drew J amp Dollery B (2018) Do Municipal Mergers Improve Technical Efficiency An Empirical Analysis of the 2008 Queensland Municipal Merger Program Australian Journal of Public Administration 77(3) 442ndash455 httpsdoiorg1011111467-850012286

Messner S F Rosenfeld R amp Baumer E P (2004) Dimensions of Social Capital and Rates of Criminal Homicide American Sociological Review 69(6) 882ndash903 httpsdoiorg101177000312240406900607

Michaels G (2011) THE LONG TERM CONSEQUENCES OF RESOURCE-BASED SPECIALISATION The Economic Journal 121(551) 31ndash57 httpsdoiorg101111j1468-0297201002402x

Mijanovich T amp Weitzman B C (2003) Which ldquobroken windowsrdquo matter School neighborhood and family characteristics associated with youthsrsquo feelings of unsafety Journal of Urban Health 80(3) 400ndash415

Mikušovaacute P (2015) An Application of DEA Methodology in Efficiency Measurement of the Czech Public Universities Procedia Economics and Finance 25 569ndash578 httpsdoiorg101016S2212-5671(15)00771-6

135

Milanovic B (2016) Global inequality Harvard University Press

Millo G amp Piras G (2012) splm Spatial panel data models in R Journal of Statistical Software 47(1) 1ndash38

Murphy K M amp Topel R H (2016) Human Capital Investment Inequality and Economic Growth JOURNAL OF LABOR ECONOMICS 34(2) S99ndashS127 httpsdoiorg101086683779

Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute I amp De Witte K (2018a) Local governmentsrsquo efficiency a systematic literature reviewmdashpart I International Transactions in Operational Research 25(2) 431ndash468 httpsdoiorg101111itor12364

Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute I amp De Witte K (2018b) Local governmentsrsquo efficiency a systematic literature reviewmdashpart II International Transactions in Operational Research 25(4) 1107ndash1136 httpsdoiorg101111itor12389

Nuntildeez J Rivera J Villavicencio X amp Molina O (2003) Determinantes socioeconoacutemicos y demograacuteficos del crimen en Chile Estudios de Economiacutea 30(1) 55ndash85

OrsquoDonnell C J Rao D S P amp Battese G E (2008) Metafrontier frameworks for the study of firm-level efficiencies and technology ratios Empirical Economics 34(2) 231ndash255 httpsdoiorg101007s00181-007-0119-4

Ocampo J A (2004) Latin Americarsquos Growth and Equity Frustrations During Structural Reforms The Journal of Economic Perspectives 18(2) 67ndash88 httpsdoiorg1012570895330041371349

OECD (2014) Focus on inequality and growth OECD

OECD (2017) Howrsquos Life 2017 Life Satisfaction Oecd httpsdoiorg101787how_life-2017-en

Ohtake F (2008) Inequality in Japan Asian Economic Policy Review 3(1) 87ndash109 httpsdoiorg101111j1748-3131200800093x

Okun A M (2015) Equality and efficiency the big tradeoff Washington DC Brookings Institution Press

Ortega B Sanjuaacuten J amp Casquero A (2017) Determinants of efficiency in reducing child mortality in developing countries The role of inequality and government effectiveness Health Care Management Science 20(4) 500ndash516 httpsdoiorg101007s10729-016-9367-1

Ostry J Berg A amp Tsangarides C (2014) Redistribution inequality and growth International Monetary Fund

Pacheco F Saacutenchez R amp Villena M (2013) Eficiencia de los Gobiernos Locales y sus Determinantes Un anaacutelisis de Fronteras Estocaacutesticas en Datos de Panel para

136

Municipalidades Chilenas Santiago de Chile Chile

Papyrakis E amp Raveh O (2014) An Empirical Analysis of a Regional Dutch Disease The Case of Canada Environmental and Resource Economics 58(2) 179ndash198 httpsdoiorg101007s10640-013-9698-z

Paredes D (2013) The Role of Human Capital Market Potential and Natural Amenities in Understanding Spatial Wage Disparities in Chile Spatial Economic Analysis 8(2) 154ndash175 httpsdoiorg101080174217722013774094

Paredes D Iturra V amp Lufin M (2016) A spatial decomposition of income inequality in Chile Regional Studies 50(5) 771ndash789

Phan P Van Orsquobrien M Mendolia S amp Paloyo A (2017) National pro-poor spending programmes and their effect on income inequality and poverty Evidence from Vietnam Applied Economics 49(55) 5579ndash5590 httpsdoiorg1010800003684620171313957

Podinovski V V (2004) Bridging the Gap between the Constant and Variable Returns-to-Scale Models Selective Proportionality in Data Envelopment Analysis The Journal of the Operational Research Society 55(3) 265ndash276 Retrieved from httpwwwjstororgstable4102006

Ravallion M (2005) On Measuring Aggregate Social Efficiency Economic Development and Cultural Change 53(2) 273ndash292 httpsdoiorg101086425380

Rehner J Baeza S A amp Barton J R (2014) Chilersquos resource-based export boom and its outcomes Regional specialization export stability and economic growth Geoforum 56(Supplement C) 35ndash45 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jgeoforum201406007

Rivera J Gutieacuterrez M amp Nuacutentildeez J (2009) Caracterizacioacuten socioeconoacutemica y espacial de la criminalidad en Chile Revista CEPAL

Ross C E (2011) Collective threat trust and the sense of personal control Journal of Health and Social Behavior 52(3) 287ndash296

Ross C E amp Mirowsky J (2001) Neighborhood disadvantage disorder and health Journal of Health and Social Behavior 258ndash276

Rothstein B amp Uslaner E M (2005) All for all Equality corruption and social trust World Politics 58(1) 41ndash72

Sachs J D amp Warner A M (2001) The curse of natural resources European Economic Review 45(4ndash6) 827ndash838 httpsdoiorg101016S0014-2921(01)00125-8

Salas R (2019) sinimr Chilean Municipalities Information System Wrapper Retrieved from httpsgithubcomrobsalascosinimr

Sampson R J (1986) Crime in Cities The Effects of Formal and Informal Social Control Crime and Justice 8 271ndash311

137

Sampson R J (2008) Rethinking crime and immigration Contexts 7(1) 28ndash33

Santos Silva J M C amp Tenreyro S (2010) On the existence of the maximum likelihood estimates in Poisson regression Economics Letters 107(2) 310ndash312 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jeconlet201002020

Santos Silva J M C amp Tenreyro S (2011) poisson Some convergence issues Stata Journal 11(2) 207ndash212 Retrieved from httpwwwstata-journalcomarticlehtmlarticle=st0225

Scott Z (2009) Decentralisation local development and social cohesion an analytical review GSDRC Research Paper 5

Sinha R P (2017) Fiscal Performance Benchmarking of Indian States-A Robust Frontier Approach The Central European Review of Economics and Management 1(4) 225ndash249

Skogan W (1986) Fear of crime and neighborhood change Crime and Justice 8 203ndash229

Skogan W (1999) Measuring what matters Crime disorder and fear In Measuring what matters Proceedings from the Policing Research Institute meetings (pp 37ndash53) National Institute of Justice Washington DC

Skogan W (2015) Disorder and Decline The State of Research Journal of Research in Crime and Delinquency 52(4) 464ndash485 httpsdoiorg1011770022427815577836

Šťastnaacute L amp Gregor M (2014) Public sector efficiency in transition and beyond evidence from Czech local governments Applied Economics 47(7) 1ndash20 httpsdoiorg101080000368462014978077

Tandon A (2005) Measuring Efficiency of Macro Systems An Application to Millennium Development Goal Attainment Asian Development Review 22(2) 108ndash125

Taylor R B (1999) The incivilities thesis Theory measurement and policy Measuring What Matters 65 88

Tigga N S amp Mishra U S (2015) On Measuring Technical Efficiency of the Health System in India An Application of Data Envelopment Analysis Journal of Health Management 17(3) 285ndash298 httpsdoiorg1011770972063415589229

Tinbergen J (1975) Demographic Development and the Exhaustion of Natural Resources Population and Development Review 1(1) 23ndash32 httpsdoiorg1023071972269

Tiruneh G (2014) Social Revolutions Their Causes Patterns and Phases SAGE Open 4(3) 2158244014548845 httpsdoiorg1011772158244014548845

Tolsma J Van der Meer T amp Gesthuizen M (2009) The impact of neighbourhood and municipality characteristics on social cohesion in the Netherlands Acta Politica 44(3) 286ndash313

Tsekeris Sotiris T Tsekeris T amp Papaioannou S (2018) Regional determinants of technical efficiency evidence from the Greek economy Regional Studies [London]thinsp Carfax

138

httpsdoiorg1010800034340420171390312

Uslaner E (2002) The moral foundations of trust Cambridge University Press

Uslaner E (2011) CORRUPTION AND INEQUALITY DICE Report 9(2) 20ndash24

Uslaner E (2013) Trust and corruption revisited how and why trust and corruption shape each other Quality amp Quantity 47(6) 3603ndash3608 httpsdoiorg101007s11135-012-9742-z

Uslaner E amp Brown M (2005) Inequality trust and civic engagement American Politics Research 33(6) 868ndash894

Van der Ploeg F (2011) Natural Resources Curse or Blessing Journal of Economic Literature 49(2) 366ndash420 httpsdoiorg101257jel492366

Vergara R (2012) Crime Prevention Programs Evidence From CHILE The Developing Economies 50(1) 1ndash24

Watkins M H (1963) A staple theory of economic growth Canadian Journal of Economics and Political ScienceRevue Canadienne de Economiques et Science Politique 29(2) 141ndash158

Wilkinson R G (1999) Income inequality social cohesion and health clarifying the theorymdasha reply to Muntaner and Lynch International Journal of Health Services 29(3) 525ndash543

Wilson J Q amp Kelling G L (1982) Broken windows Atlantic Monthly 249(3) 29ndash38

Wilson W J (1996) When Work Disappears Political Science Quarterly 111(4) 567ndash595 httpsdoiorg1023072152085

Wirth L (1938) Urbanism as a Way of Life American Journal of Sociology 44(1) 1ndash24

Worthington A amp Dollery B (2000) An empirical survey of frontier efficiency measurement techniques in local government Local Government Studies 26(2) 23ndash52 httpsdoiorg10108003003930008433988

Wu P-C Huang T-H amp Pan S-C (2014) Country Performance Evaluation The DEA Model Approach Social Indicators Research 118(2) 835ndash849 httpsdoiorg101007s11205-013-0443-3

Ye X Ma L Ye K Chen J amp Xie Q (2017) Analysis of Regional Inequality from Sectoral Structure Spatial Policy and Economic Development A Case Study of Chongqing China Sustainability 9(4) 633 Retrieved from httpwwwmdpicom2071-105094633

Yue W Z Zhang Y T Ye X Y Cheng Y Q amp Leipnik M R (2014) Dynamics of Multi-Scale Intra-Provincial Regional Inequality in Zhejiang China Sustainability 6(9) 5763ndash5784 httpsdoiorg103390su6095763

139

Appendices

Appendix A Summary statistics income inequality

Table A1

Summary statistics Gini coefficients by year and zone

140

Appendix B Summary statistics for NRD measures by region

Table B1

Summary statistics NRD measures by region

141

Appendix C Regional administrative division and defined zones

Figure C1 Geographical distribution of Chilean regions and 3 zones

142

Appendix D Summary statistics numeric controls and correlation matrix

Table D1

Summary Statistics Numeric Explanatory Variables

Figure D1 Correlation matrix numeric explanatory variables

143

Appendix E Static spatial panel models

Following Millo amp Piras (2012) a model including a spatial lag of the dependent variable and

spatial autoregressive disturbances but not spatial lags for the explanatory variable(s) is called

SARAR model A static spatial SARAR panel could be expressed as

119910 120582 119868 otimes119882 119910 119883120573 119906 (E1)

where y is an 119873 1 vector of observations on the dependent variable X is a 119873 119896 matrix of

observations on the non-stochastic exogenous regressors 119868 an identity matrix of dimension 119879 otimes

is the kronecker operator 119882 is the 119873 119873 spatial weights matrix of known constants whose

diagonal elements are set to zero and 120582 the corresponding spatial parameter44

The disturbance vector is the sum of two terms

119906 120580 otimes 119868 120583 120576 (E2)

where 120580 is a 119879 1 vector of ones 119868 an 119873 119873 identity matrix 120583 is a vector of time-invariant

individual specific effects (not spatially autocorrelated) and 120576 a vector of spatially autocorrelated

innovations that follow a spatial autoregressive process of the form

120576 120588 119868 otimes119882 120576 120584 (E3)

If we assume that spatial correlation applies to both the individual effects 120583 and the remainder

error components 120576 Kapoor et al (2007) propose that the disturbance term 119906 follows a first order

spatial autoregressive process of the form

119906 120588 119868 otimes119882 119906 120576 (E4)

44 Unlike ldquotraditional panelsrdquo which are organized as different time series for each cross-sectional unit ldquospatial panelsrdquo are organized as a series of cross-sections for each year

144

where 119882 is the spatial weights matrix and 119903ℎ119900 the corresponding spatial autoregressive

parameter To further allow for the innovations to be correlated over time the innovations vector

in Equation 7 follows an error component structure

120576 120580 otimes 119868 120583 120584 (E5)

where 120583 is the vector of cross-sectional specific effects 120584 a vector of innovations that vary

both over cross-sectional units and time periods 120580 is a vector of ones and 119868 an 119873 119873 identity

matrix45

Spatial panel models are usually estimated by Maximum Likelihood or GMM46 The SAR

SEM or SARAR models could be estimated with Random or Fixed effects For instance A fixed

effect spatial lag model can be written in stacked form as

119910 120582 119868 otimes119882 119910 120580 otimes 119868 120583 119883120573 120576 (E6)

where 120582 is the spatial autoregressive coefficient 119882 a non-stochastic spatial weights matrix

120580 a column vector of ones of dimension 119879 119868 an 119873 119873 identity matrix and 120576 sim 119873 0120590 On

the other hand a fixed effects spatial error model assuming the disturbance specification by

Kapoor et al (2007) can be written as

119910 120580119879 otimes 119868119873 120583 119883120573 119906119906 120588 119868119879 otimes119882119873 119906 120576

(E7)

where 120588 is the spatial autocorrelation coefficient and 120576 is a well-behaved error term

45 In the regression implementation the specification given by equations (22) and (3) is denoted by ldquobrdquo for ldquoBaltagirdquo On the other hand the specification given by equations (23) and (31) is denoted by ldquokkprdquo for ldquoKapoor Kelejian and Pruchardquo 46 We use the R package splm which allow both types of regression procedure

145

Appendix F Analysis OLS residuals cross-sectional (six-year average) analysis

Table F1

Analysis OLS residuals Anselin Method

Figure F1 Moran scatter plot OLS residuals

146

Appendix G Linear panel data models

Table G1

Panel regressions (non-spatial)

147

Appendix H Spatial panel models (Generalized Moments (GM) estimation)

Table H1

GM Spatial Models

148

Appendix I Inputs and outputs used in DEA analysis

Figure I1 Examples of inputs and outputs used to measure LGE (based on Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018)

149

Appendix J Technical and scale efficiency

Following lo Storto (2013) under an input-oriented specification assuming VRS with n

municipalities using k inputs to produce m outputs the DEA model for a given i-th municipality

is specified with the following mathematical programming problem

119898119894119899 120579119904119906119887119895119890119888119905 119905119900 119910 119884120582 0120579119909 119883120582 01198991prime120582 1  120582 0prime

Where 119910 is the column vector of the outputs and 119909 is the column vector of the inputs

Moreover we can define X as the (k times n) input matrix and Y as the (m times n) output matrix 120579 is a

scalar (that satisfies 120579 1) more specifically it is the efficiency score that measures technical

efficiency It measures the distance between a municipality and the efficiency frontier defined as

a linear combination of the best practice observations With 120579 1 the municipality is inside the

frontier (ie it is inefficient) while 120579 1 implies that the municipality is on the frontier (ie it is

efficient) The vector 120582 is an (n times 1) vector of constants that measures the weights used to compute

the location of an inefficient municipality if it were to become efficient

The total technical efficiency 119879119864 can be decomposed into pure technical efficiency

119879119864 and scale efficiency 119878119864 where 119878119864 119879119864 119879119864 (Coelli et al 2005) To find out

whether a municipality is scale efficient and qualify the type of returns of scale a DEA model

under non-increasing returns to scale 119879119864 is implemented where 119878119864 119879119864 119879119864 Hence

the following rule can be applied (Faumlre Grosskopf amp Lovell 1985)

bull If 119878119864 1 then a municipality is scale efficient both under CRS and VRS

bull If 119878119864 1 it operates under increasing returns to scale

bull If 119878119864 1 it operates under decreasing returns to scale

150

Appendix K Correlation matrix

Figure K1 Correlation matrix contextual factors

151

Appendix L Returns to scale by year and zone

Table L1

Returns to scale (percentage of municipalities)

152

Appendix M Returns to scale by year (maps)

Figure M1 Spatial distribution of returns to scale by county per year

153

Appendix N Efficiency status by year (maps)

Figure N1 Spatial distribution of efficient (E es = 1) and inefficient (I es lt 1) counties per year

154

Appendix O Spatial distribution efficiency scores by year (maps)

FigureO1 Custom breaks maps of efficiency scores (VRS) by county per year

155

Appendix P Analysis OLS residuals cross-sectional (six-year average) analysis

Table P1

Analysis OLS residuals Anselin Method

Figure P1 Moran scatter plot efficiency scores and OLS residuals

156

Table P2

OLS and spatial regression models for the six-year averaged data

157

Appendix Q OLS regressions for cross-sectional and panel data

Table Q1

OLS cross-sectional regression per year

158

Table Q2

OLS panel regressions Pooled random effects and instrumental variable

159

Appendix R Quantile maps incivilities rate by group (average total period)

Figure R1 Spatial distribution of incivilities by group (Average rate per 1000 inhabitants 2006-09-11-13-15-17)

160

Appendix S Correlation matrix numeric covariates

Figure S1 Correlation matrix numeric covariates

161

Appendix T Negative Binomial regressions

Table T1

Negative Binomial regressions

162

Appendix U Coefficients economic and racial diversity by geographical zone

Table U1

Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson models by geographic zone

Page 4: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted

iii

inequality tend to cluster in space The regression analysis confirms the importance of capturing

geographical heterogeneity in the explanation of income inequality however gives less support

to a process of spatial dependence like a spillover effect of income inequality among

neighbouring counties

Among the potential consequences of income inequality the literature highlights its

possible impacts on the efficiency in the provision of public services by local authorities however

empirical evidence is very little For this reason the second essay analyses the technical efficiency

of municipal local governments in Chile and examine if income inequality has significant impacts

on the variations in the efficiency levels across municipalities An input-oriented Data

Envelopment Analysis is used to measure municipal efficiency Results reveal that the municipal

production technology is characterized by variable returns to scale but scale inefficiencies only

explain a small proportion of total inefficiency This justify a need for analysing the influence of

variables which are beyond the control of local authorities in explaining differences in municipal

efficiency The main hypothesis tested was whether income inequality has a negative influence on

municipal efficiency whilst a measure of natural resource dependence at the county level was used

as an instrument to control for the effects of possible endogeneity issues Results showed that

changes in income inequality could be associated with changes in the municipal efficiency level

in the same magnitude but in the opposite direction This confirms that local authorities in counties

characterized by high levels of income inequality face greater challenges to achieve more efficient

performance This result suggests that policies aimed at reducing income inequality can also

increase the efficiency of local governments Our results also reveal that policies such as

amalgamation de-amalgamation or cooperation among municipalities should be designed

specifically for each region rather than as a standard national strategy

Finally the third essay analyses how social cohesion is associated with the levels of

economic and racial diversity Social cohesion is proxied using the reported number of antisocial

behaviours catalogued as incivilities Incivilities are those antisocial behaviours which violate

social norms but are not usually considered as criminal Research has documented the implications

of incivilities on human stress health public behaviour and increasing feelings of insecurity and

fear among the population Few studies have explicitly considered incivilities as a dependent

variable to identify their determinants or use them to analyse the weakening of social cohesion and

iv

the growing feeling of social unrest in contemporary societies Economic diversity is proxied using

the Gini coefficient in each county and racial diversity through the number of new visas granted

as proportion of the county population Our findings show that incivilities are strongly associated

with racial diversity and to a lesser extent with economic diversity The rate of incivilities also

shows a negative association with the level of income and a positive relationship with poverty and

unemployment rates These results give empirical support to the idea that both relative and

absolute indicators of economic deprivation play an important role in understanding the growing

problem of incivilities in highly unequal economies like Chile Results also show that the rate of

incivilities is negatively related to the degree of financial autonomy of municipalities These

findings represent promising areas for central and local governments in the implementation of

policies aimed at increasing social cohesion through the reduction of incivilities and other types of

antisocial behaviours

v

Table of Contents

Keywords i

Abstract ii

Table of Contents v

List of Figures viii

List of Tables ix

List of Abbreviations x

Statement of Original Authorship xi

Acknowledgements xii

Chapter 1 Introduction 13

Income inequality and dependence on natural resources 14

Local government efficiency and income inequality 16

Social cohesion and economic diversity 19

Contributions 21

Thesis outline 23

Chapter 2 Natural Resources Curse or Blessing Evidence on Income Inequality at the County Level in Chile 24

21 Introduction 24

22 Inequality and Natural Resources 28 221 Theoretical Framework 28

Cross-country literature 29 Single country evidence 32

222 The relevance of the spatial approach 33

23 Research problem and hypotheses 35

24 Data and Methods 36 241 Operationalization of key variables 36 242 Control variables 40 243 Methods 41 244 Spatial Model Specification 43

25 Results 44 251 Exploratory Spatial Data Analysis (ESDA) 44 252 Cross-sectional analysis 45 253 Panel Data analysis 48

26 Discussion and conclusions 51

Chapter 3 The Impact of Income Inequality on the Efficiency of Municipalities in Chile 55

vi

31 Introduction 55

32 Related Literature 61 321 Measuring efficiency of local governments 61 322 Explaining differences in LGE 63 323 The trade-off between efficiency and equity 64

33 Methodology 66 331 Chilean Municipalities and period of analysis 66 332 Measuring municipal efficiency 68 333 Inputs and outputs used in DEA 70 334 Regression model 71 335 The instrument 75

34 Results and discussion 77 341 DEA results 77

Returns to scale 78 Efficiency measure 80

342 Regression results 82 Exploratory spatial analysis 82 Cross-sectional analysis 83 Panel data analysis 84

35 Conclusions 88

Chapter 4 Social Cohesion Incivilities and Diversity Evidence at the municipal level in Chile 91

41 Introduction 91

42 Related Literature 95 421 The Community Heterogeneity Thesis 95 422 The literature on incivilities 97 423 The ldquoIncivilities Thesisrdquo 99

4 3 Methodology 100 431 Period of analysis and data sample 100 432 Operationalisation of the response variable and exploratory analysis 101 433 Measures of community heterogeneity and control variables 105 434 Methods 108 435 Hypotheses 111

44 Results and Discussion 112

4 5 Conclusions 118

Chapter 5 Conclusions 120

Bibliography 126

Appendices 139

Appendix A Summary statistics income inequality 139

Appendix B Summary statistics for NRD measures by region 140

Appendix C Regional administrative division and defined zones 141

Appendix D Summary statistics numeric controls and correlation matrix 142

vii

Appendix E Static spatial panel models 143

Appendix F Analysis OLS residuals cross-sectional (six-year average) analysis 145

Appendix G Linear panel data models 146

Appendix H Spatial panel models (Generalized Moments (GM) estimation) 147

Appendix I Inputs and outputs used in DEA analysis 148

Appendix J Technical and scale efficiency 149

Appendix K Correlation matrix 150

Appendix L Returns to scale by year and zone 151

Appendix M Returns to scale by year (maps) 152

Appendix N Efficiency status by year (maps) 153

Appendix O Spatial distribution efficiency scores by year (maps) 154

Appendix P Analysis OLS residuals cross-sectional (six-year average) analysis 155

Appendix Q OLS regressions for cross-sectional and panel data 157

Appendix R Quantile maps incivilities rate by group (average total period) 159

Appendix S Correlation matrix numeric covariates 160

Appendix T Negative Binomial regressions 161

Appendix U Coefficients economic and racial diversity by geographical zone 162

viii

List of Figures

Figure 21 Average share in GDP of economic activities (2006ndash17) 37

Figure 22 Evolution of Gini coefficient and measures of NRD (2006ndash17) 38

Figure 23 Spatial distribution of Gini coefficient and NRD (2006ndash17) 39

Figure 23 Moran scatter plots for variables gini and pss_casen 45

Figure 31 Geographical distribution of Chilean regions and macrozones 74

Figure 32 Evolution of efficiency scores and the proportion of firms by sector 77

Figure 33 Evolution technical efficiency (TE) pure technical efficiency (PTE) and scale efficiency (SE) 78

Figure 34 Returns to scale by zone 79

Figure 35 Evolution mean efficiency scores (VRS) by zone 81

Figure 41 Evolution number and rates of incivilities and crime (DMCS) in Chile 2006-2017 102

Figure 42 Evolution total number of incivilities by category 104

Figure 43 Spatial distribution of incivilities rate per 1000 inhabitants (2006 vs 2017) 104

Figure 44 Annual average number of incivilities per county 109

Figure C1 Geographical distribution of Chilean regions and 3 zones 141

Figure D1 Correlation matrix numeric explanatory variables 142

Figure F1 Moran scatter plot OLS residuals 145

Figure I1 Examples of inputs and outputs used to measure LGE (based on Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018) 148

Figure K1 Correlation matrix contextual factors 150

Figure M1 Spatial distribution of returns to scale by county per year 152

Figure N1 Spatial distribution of efficient (E es = 1) and inefficient (I es lt 1) counties per year 153

FigureO1 Custom breaks maps of efficiency scores (VRS) by county per year 154

Figure P1 Moran scatter plot efficiency scores and OLS residuals 155

Figure R1 Spatial distribution of incivilities by group (Average rate per 1000 inhabitants 2006-09-11-13-15-17) 159

Figure S1 Correlation matrix numeric covariates 160

ix

List of Tables

Table 21 Cross-sectional Model Comparison (six-year average data) 47

Table 22 ML Spatial SAR Models 50

Table 23 ML Spatial SEM Models 50

Table 24 ML Spatial SARAR Models 51

Table 31 Descriptive statistics Inputs and Output variables used in DEA analysis 71

Table 32 Summary Statistics Numeric Contextual Factors 74

Table 33 Summary efficiency scores (VRS) by zone and region 80

Table 34 Cross-sectional (censored) regressions 84

Table 35 Panel data regressions 87

Table 41 Summary statistics total count of incivilities and by category (full sample and period) 103

Table 42 Summary statistics numeric explanatory variables 108

Table 43 Poisson regressions 113

Table 44 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson models by region 115

Table 45 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson model by incivility group 116

Table A1 Summary statistics Gini coefficients by year and zone 139

Table B1 Summary statistics NRD measures by region 140

Table D1 Summary Statistics Numeric Explanatory Variables 142

Table F1 Analysis OLS residuals Anselin Method 145

Table G1 Panel regressions (non-spatial) 146

Table H1 GM Spatial Models 147

Table L1 Returns to scale (percentage of municipalities) 151

Table P1 Analysis OLS residuals Anselin Method 155

Table P2 OLS and spatial regression models for the six-year averaged data 156

Table Q1 OLS cross-sectional regression per year 157

Table Q2 OLS panel regressions Pooled random effects and instrumental variable 158

Table T1 Negative Binomial regressions 161

Table U1 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson models by geographic zone 162

x

List of Abbreviations

Constant returns to scale CRS

Data envelopment analysis DEA

Decreasing returns to scale DRS

Efficiency scores ES

Exploratory spatial data analysis ESDA

Generalized methods of moments GMM

Gross Domestic Product GDP

Increasing returns to scale IRS

Local government efficiency LGE

Maximum likelihood ML

Municipal common fund MCF

Natural resource dependence NRD

Natural resource endowment NRE

Ordinary Least Squares OLS

Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development OECD

Own permanent revenues OPR

Resource curse hypothesis RCH

Spatial autoregressive model SAR

Spatial error model SEM

Variable returns to scale VRS

xi

Statement of Original Authorship

The work contained in this thesis has not been previously submitted to meet requirements

for an award at this or any other higher education institution To the best of my knowledge and

belief the thesis contains no material previously published or written by another person except

where due reference is made

Signature QUT Verified Signature

Date _________04092020_________

xii

Acknowledgements

First I would like to thank my wife Lilian who joined me in this challenge and patiently

supported me all these years I would also like to thank our family who always supported us from

Chile I especially thank my sister Silvia who took care of our house and dog

I am also grateful to my supervisory team Dr Radhika Lahiri and Dr Vincent Hoang who

supported and guided me in the process of making this thesis a reality

I also thank the Deans of the Faculty of Economics and Business at my beloved University

of Talca Dr Arcadio Cerda and Dr Rodrigo Herrera who trusted me and supported me in this

process In the same way I would like to thank all the support of the director of the Commercial

Engineering career Mr Milton Inostroza

Finally I would like to thank the government of Chile for the financial support that made

my stay and studies possible here at the Queensland University of Technology

13

Chapter 1 Introduction

Efficiency and equity issues are often considered together in the evaluation of economic

performance While higher efficiency usually measured by growth rates of income per capita

correlates with improvements in measures of well-being the link between inequality and well-

being is less clear This is reflected not only in the type and amount of research related to efficiency

and equity but also in the role that both play in the design of the economic policy For instance

several market-oriented countries have focused primarily on economic growth trusting in a trickle-

down process where financial benefits given to the wealthy are expected to ultimately benefit the

poor However despite the growing interest in the issue of inequality there is a considerable lack

of studies about its consequences

Although some level of inequality is inevitable or even necessary for economic activity this

study is motivated by the argument that relatively high levels of inequality can be associated with

many problems such as persistent unemployment increasing fiscal expenses indebtedness and

political instability (Berg amp Ostry 2011) Inequality can also have other severe social

consequences including increased crime rates teenage pregnancy obesity and fewer

opportunities for low-income households to invest in health and education (Atkinson 2015) In

addition when the role of money and concentration of economic power undermine political

outcomes inequality of opportunities hampers social and economic mobility trust and social

cohesion In summary inequality can increase the fragility of the economic and social situation in

a country reducing economic growth and making it less inclusive and sustainable

14

A country well-known for its market-oriented economy and high level of dependence on

natural resources is Chile Chilean success in terms of economic growth contrasts with its inability

to reduce the persistently high levels of social and economic inequality particularly in the last

three decades Using data for the 2006-2017 period and considering 324 out of 345 Chilean

counties this thesis presents three essays with empirical evidence aiming to explain the

phenomenon of persistent income inequality and some of its potential consequences The first

essay aims to analyse how the evolution and variability of income inequality throughout the

country are associated with the degree of natural resource dependence The second essay studies

the relevance of income inequality in explaining cross-county differences in the performance of

local governments (municipalities) Finally the third essay explores the link between social

cohesion and community heterogeneity highlighting the importance of economic and racial

diversity

Income inequality and dependence on natural resources

The first essay explores how cross-county differences in income inequality are associated

with differences in the degree of dependence on natural resources We use the Gini coefficient in

each county as our dependent variable and the proportion of employment in the primary sector as

our measure of natural resource dependence The main hypothesis is that income inequality should

be positively related to the degree of natural resource dependence To test our hypothesis we use

a spatial econometric approach This approach is motivated by the study of Paredes Iturra and

Lufin (2016) who explore the geographic heterogeneity of income inequality in Chile finding

evidence of a significant spatial dimension

15

The theoretical and empirical literature has mostly proposed a positive link between

inequality and natural resources Although most of the evidence corresponds to cross-country

comparisons there is also increasing body of research at the local level A rationale underpinning

the positive link suggested in the literature is that in natural resource-rich countries ownership is

concentrated in small groups and extraction activities require low-skilled workers (Gylfason amp

Zoega 2003 Leamer Maul Rodriguez amp Schott 1999) Another market-based argument often

labelled as the ldquoDutch Diseaserdquo proposes that natural resource windfalls could be associated with

a crowding-out effect on the manufacturing sector (Corden amp Neary 1982 Easterly 2007) This

process encourages rent-seeking behaviours discourages investment in physical and human

capital and delays the process of technology adoption and industrialization (Auty 2001 Bulte

Damania amp Deacon 2005 Gylfason amp Zoega 2003) The result could be a lower economic

growth which is the central idea under the ldquoResource Curse Hypothesisrdquo (Auty 1993 Sachs amp

Warner 2001)

An ldquoinstitutionalrdquo argument for the positive association between inequality and the

endowment of natural resources is based on the so-called ldquoParadox of Plentyrdquo (Borge Parmer amp

Torvik 2015 Dauvin amp Guerreiro 2017) The idea is that both national and local authorities have

less incentive to operate efficiently when they experience windfalls in their revenues for

instance from natural resources This could end with corrupted authorities exerting patronage

clientelism and designing public policies to favour specific groups of the population (Uslaner amp

Brown 2005) Evidence also suggests that the final effect of natural resource booms on income

inequality will depend on authoritiesrsquo capacity to manage these additional resources the extent of

commuting and migration among regions and the potential increase in the demand for non-tradable

16

goods which are intensive in unskilled workers (Aroca amp Atienza 2011 Cust amp Poelhekke 2015

Fleming amp Measham 2015b Howie amp Atakhanova 2014 Michaels 2011)

Contrary to most theoretical and empirical evidence we find that income inequality shows

a robust and significant negative association with our proxy for natural resource dependence This

result suggests that the process of transformation to an economy less dependent on natural

resources could have exacerbated rather than alleviated the persistence of income inequality The

decrease in the participation of the primary sector in employment in favour mainly of the tertiary

sector highlights the importance of the latter to explain the current high levels of inequality and its

future evolution Another important result is that spatial linear models show practically the same

results as traditional linear models This could be interpreted as the spatial dimension previously

found in income inequality is not the result of spatial dependence in the variable itself for instance

due to a process of spillover among counties Hence the usually found positive spatial

autocorrelation of income inequality (similar levels in neighbouring counties) could be explained

by spatial patterns in other variables or to the spatial heterogeneity that characterizes the Chilean

economy

Local government efficiency and income inequality

Essay 2 delves deep into the potential trade-off between efficiency and equity We measure

the efficiency of Chilean municipalities which correspond to the organizations in charge of

managing each county Municipal efficiency is understood as ldquotechnical efficiencyrdquo that is the

possibility that each municipality has reached the same level of outputs with less use of inputs

Then we analyse how income inequality controlling for other contextual factors such as

socioeconomic demographic geographical and political characteristics may help to explain

17

differences in municipal performance Our main hypothesis is that municipal efficiency is

inversely associated with income inequality Moreover we seek a causal interpretation of this

relationship

Municipal performance could be influenced by income inequality in direct and indirect ways

In a direct sense income inequality is used to capture the degree of heterogeneity and complexity

in the demand for public services that citizens exert over local authorities Hence higher levels of

income inequality should be associated with a more complex set of public services and therefore

with lower levels of municipal efficiency (Jottier Ashworth amp Heyndels 2012) Furthermore

when high levels of inequality exist the richest groups can exert a higher influence over local

authorities resulting in low quality and quantity of services for most of the population Among

indirect effects high and persistent inequality could be the source of corrupted institutions and

local authorities favouring themselves or specific groups This undermines citizensrsquo participation

in civic activities and their willingness to monitor municipal performance (Uslaner amp Brown

2005) Additionally the potential benefits of decentralization on the way local governments

deliver public services will be limited when the context is characterized by corrupted politicians

and a limited administrative and financial capacity (Scott 2009)

We measure municipal efficiency using an input-oriented Data Envelopment Analysis

(DEA) to obtain efficiency scores for our sample of 324 municipalities in each year from 2006 to

2017 Then we study the influence on municipal efficiency of income inequality and our set of

contextual factors using a panel of six years corresponding to those years for which household

income information is available 2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017 Our dependent variable

is the set of efficiency scores which are relative measures of efficiency They are relative to the

18

municipalities included in the sample and they do not imply that higher technical efficiency gains

cannot be achieved Thus we use both cross-sectional and panel censored regression models To

tackle endogeneity issues and suggest a causal interpretation we also propose using the proportion

of firms in the primary sector as an instrument for income inequality

We find an average efficiency score of 83 meaning that Chilean municipalities could

reduce the use of inputs by 17 without reducing their outputs We also measure municipal

efficiency under different assumptions related to returns to scale This allows us to disaggregate

technical efficiency to assess whether inefficiencies are due to management issues (pure technical

efficiency) or scale issues (scale efficiency) Although the results show that most municipalities

operate under increasing or decreasing returns to scale scale inefficiencies only explain a small

proportion of total municipal inefficiencies This highlights the need to look for contextual factors

outside the control of local authorities to explain differences in municipal performance

Geographical representations of our results in terms of returns to scale and efficiency scores

show some spatial clustering process among municipalities Spatial statistics tests confirm that

efficiency scores show a significant positive spatial autocorrelation This means that neighbouring

municipalities tend to show similar levels of efficiency This similar performance could be due to

a process of spatial dependence (eg efficiency spillovers among neighbouring municipalities) or

due to the existence of structural-geographical similarities (spatial heterogeneity) To assess the

spatial dimension in municipal efficiency abstracting from temporal fluctuations we use a cross-

section of data consisting of the six-year average for the variables in our panel After running a

regression of efficiency scores against the set of controls the analysis of OLS residuals shows that

the spatial autocorrelation is almost completely removed This means that the spatial pattern in

19

municipal efficiency can be explained (controlled) by other variables such as regional indicator

variables rather than efficiency itself Given this result we proceed to study the influence of

income inequality on municipal efficiency using traditional (non-spatial) regression analysis

In contrast to literature that emphasizes an equity-efficiency trade-off (Andersen amp Maibom

2020 Berg amp Ostry 2011 Browning amp Johnson 1984 Okun 2015) that is greater equality leads

to lower efficiency we find that municipal efficiency is inversely associated with income

inequality This implies that more equal counties are also those with higher municipal efficiency

Furthermore the coefficient of income inequality is close to one when we use the instrumental

variable approach This means that a reduction in income inequality ceteris paribus should be

associated with an increase in the same magnitude in municipal efficiency This result has strong

policy implications The non-existence of the trade-off suggests that there is more to be gained by

targeting policies towards the reduction of inequality than conventional theories suggest For

instance these policies may help increase the levels of efficiency and well-being at least at the

municipal level

Social cohesion and economic diversity

The third essay studies the relationship between the degree of social cohesion and diversity

in Chile Extant literature has argued that one of the main factors influencing social cohesion is

the degree of economic and ethnic-racial diversity within a society This diversity erodes social

cohesion reducing trust and corrupting institutions (Letki 2008 Rothstein amp Uslaner 2005

Tolsma Van der Meer amp Gesthuizen 2009 Uslaner 2011 2013)

To measure social cohesion scholars have traditionally used measures of social capital trust

or feelings of insecurity (Ariely 2014 Chan To amp Chan 2006 Letki 2008) We suggest the use

20

of the rate of incivilities per 1000 inhabitants as a proxy for social cohesion Incivilities correspond

to those antisocial behaviours (eg groups of rowdy teens and public drunkenness) or visible

neighbourhood conditions (eg graffiti and abandoned buildings) that tend not to be treated as

crime Using the rate of incivilities is arguably a more objective and reliable measure of social

cohesion particularly in countries where institutions of order and security are among the most

trusted An increase in the rate of incivilities rather than changes in crime rates should better

capture the worsening in social cohesion experienced in countries such as Chile where crime rates

are not growing but social conflicts are on the rise Thus the main hypothesis in this essay is that

the rate of incivilities (social cohesion) should be positively (negatively) associated with economic

and racial diversity

Using panel count data models we start analysing how differences in incivilities rates

between and within counties are associated with differences in indicators of relative and absolute

economic disadvantage We use the Gini coefficient of each county as our measure of economic

diversity Although we find a significant and positive association between the rate of incivilities

and the level of income inequality the magnitude of the link seems to be small Among absolute

indicators of economic disadvantage only the level of income shows a strong effect Next we

include our measure of racial diversity We use the number of new visas granted to foreigners as

a proportion of the county population Results show a significant and strong positive association

between the rate of incivilities and racial diversity

To check the robustness of our results we analyse the impact of our measures of economic

and racial diversity running our models separately for each Chilean region and clustering them

geographically We also split the total number of incivilities in four categories to see which type

21

of incivilities show the greatest association with our measures of diversity In general results

support the ldquocommunity heterogeneity hypothesisrdquo that higher community heterogeneity is

associated with higher rates of incivilities (Alesina amp La Ferrara 2002 Letki 2008 Tolsma et al

2009) However results do not support the ldquoincivilities thesisrdquo that the distribution of incivilities

tends to mirror the distribution of income inequality (Skogan 1999 Taylor 1999)

Three results stand out among the set of control variables First the level of education shows

and independent and significant negative association with the rate of incivilities This is in contrast

to previous studies where education acts mainly as a moderator of the effect of economic and racial

diversity on social cohesion (Tolsma et al 2009) The results also show that there is no significant

relationship between the rate of incivilities and the proportion of young population This is relevant

because policies aimed to reduce incivilities usually put the focus on specific groups such as young

people which are linked to physical and social incivilities when social control is weakened

Finally the degree of financial municipal autonomy also shows a significant negative association

with the rate of incivilities This result suggests that municipalities can contribute independently

or together with the central government to reduce incivilities and strengthen social cohesion

Contributions

The three essays in this thesis provide several important insights into the analysis of the

causes and consequences of income inequality particularly in the context of Chile ndash a typical

resource rich economy with persistently high levels of income inequality

Essay 1 advances the understanding of the relationship between income inequality and

natural resources in Chile extending the empirical analysis from the regional level to the county

level In addition the geographic heterogeneity of income inequality is explored with the inclusion

22

of alternative sources of spatial dependence as a potential dimension of the causal relationship

between income inequality and natural resources This essay demonstrates the relevance of natural

resources in explaining the persistence of income inequality even after controlling for other

socioeconomics and institutional factors Findings from this study have potential contribution not

only in the design of policies aimed to reduce income inequality but also in addressing the current

developmental bias between the metropolitan region and the rest of the country

Essay 2 is one of the first studies that undertake a longitudinal analysis of the effects of

income inequality on the efficiency of municipal governments in Chile To capture the role of the

municipal governments in the provision to local people of public services such as education and

health we specify several inputs and outputs in our efficiency model which is different from the

conventional specification in the existing literature For example the number of medical

consultations in public health facilities and the number of enrolled students in public schools are

used as outputs instead of general indicators such as county population Our empirical analysis

also utilises a larger sample of municipalities and covers a much longer period spanning from 2006

to 2017 This essay also investigates the contextual factors beyond the control of local authorities

that can explain variations in the efficiency of municipal governments across the country

Empirical findings from Essay 2 help us increase our understanding of the production

technology of municipalities the sources of inefficiencies and specifically the impact of income

inequality on the performance of local authorities The results deliver two main policy

implications First municipal inefficiencies in the provision of public goods and services differ

across Chilean municipalities In addition efficiency levels show some degree of spatial

autocorrelation This implies that policies such as amalgamation or cooperation among

23

municipalities could have effects beyond the municipalities involved which must be considered

Second the causal effect that income inequality has on municipal efficiency provides another

dimension into the design and implementation of development policies

Essay 3 explores for the first time the effects of economic and racial diversity on social

cohesion in Chile This essay considers incivilities as manifestation of social cohesion and

investigates as extant literature suggests whether indicators of relative economic disadvantage

such as income inequality are among the main factors driving social disorganization and social

unrest Empirical findings suggest that on the one hand economic heterogeneity captured by the

Gini coefficient has a disparate effect both in terms of magnitude and significance on the rate of

incivilities across the country On the other hand the impact of racial heterogeneity appears to be

stronger more significant and of a similar magnitude throughout the country Results also provide

new insights into the design of national policies addressing social disorders particularly those

policies focussed on specific groups of the population and the role of local authorities Overall the

findings provide an opportunity to advance the understanding of the process of weakening in the

social cohesion experienced in Chile and the conflicts that have risen from this process

Thesis outline

The remainder of the thesis is organized as follows Chapter 2 presents essay 1 examining

the association between income inequality and the degree of dependence on natural resources

Chapter 3 presents essay 2 which looks for a causal relationship between municipal efficiency and

income inequality Chapter 4 presents essay 3 analysing the relationship between social cohesion

and economic and racial diversity Finally Chapter 5 presents some concluding remarks

24

Chapter 2 Natural Resources Curse or Blessing Evidence on

Income Inequality at the County Level in Chile

21 Introduction

A phenomenon of increasing inequality of incomes and wealth in recent decades has been

documented by leading scholars and international organizations such as the International Monetary

Fund (Berg amp Ostry 2017 Ostry Berg amp Tsangarides 2014) and the Organization for Economic

Cooperation and Development (Cingano 2014) These efforts have placed the topic of inequality

at the top of the current economic debate recognizing inequality as a determinant not only of

economic growth but also of human development They also have highlighted the necessity for

more research on the drivers of inequality and mechanisms through which it manifests aiming to

design effective policies in reducing economic and social inequalities

Various factors have been analysed as the sources of high and increasing levels of inequality

Among the most significant factors are the levels of income at initial stages of economic

development (Kuznets 1955) Globalization (Milanovic 2016) skill-biased technological change

(Tinbergen 1975) investment in human capital (Murphy amp Topel 2016) institutions

redistributive policy and country-specific characteristics (Acemoglu 1995 2002 Acemoglu

Aghion amp Violante 2001 Acemoglu Johnson amp Robinson 2001) Our focus in this essay is on

the importance that the natural resource endowment (NRE) or lack thereof can play in the

determination of income disparities

25

This essay studies the patterns and evolution of income inequality in the context of a natural

resource-rich country Using the case of the Chilean economy we aim to understand and

disentangle how a phenomenon of high- and persistent-income inequality is related to the

endowment of natural resources that a country owns Chile is an interesting case to study because

despite showing a successful history of economic growth inequality among individuals and among

aggregated spatial units has shown a strong persistence (Paredes et al 2016) Furthermore Chile

has remained among the most unequal countries in the world1

Theory and empirical evidence do not establish a clear link between income inequality and

NRE In addition NRE has received considerably less attention (Auty 2001 ElGindi 2017) and

most of the evidence has been focused on cross-country comparisons For instance NRE can

influence inequality by determining its initial levels (Engerman amp Sokoloff 1994 1997

Engerman Sokoloff Urquiola amp Acemoglu 2002) shaping the evolution of institutions

(Acemoglu 2002) make the educational system less intellectually challenging and moulding the

structure of economic activity (Leamer et al 1999) So studying how cross-county differences in

NRE are associated with the distribution of income within a country has theoretical empirical and

policy implications

In this study we offer empirical evidence on the relationship between income inequality and

the endowment of natural resources using data at the county level in Chile for the period 2006-

2017 Income inequality is measured by the Gini coefficient The importance of NRE is proxied

using a measure of natural resource dependence (NRD) defined as the percentage of the total

1 A 2014 OECD report on income inequality (httpwwwoecdorgsocialincome-distribution-databasehtm) showed Chile as the country with the highest Gini coefficient of disposable income among OECD countries OECD also indicates Chile as the country with the widest gap between the richest 10 percent and the poorest 10 percent of countryrsquos population among its 34 members (OECD 2014)

26

employment in each county corresponding to the primary sector (agriculture forestry fishing and

mining)

The main hypothesis to be tested is whether income inequality is positively associated with

the degree of NRD The transmission mechanisms through which natural resources could influence

socioeconomic outcomes could be based on the market or institutions The market-based approach

argues that natural resource booms could be associated with an appreciation of the real exchange

rate and a crowding out effect over other more productive economic activities such as

manufacturing It could also delay the adoption of new technologies and reduce incentives to invest

in physical and human capital (Gylfason amp Zoega 2003) Based on the ldquoResource Curse

Hypothesisrdquo (RCH) natural resources could be a curse when the political and institutional

framework is weak and natural resources are concentrated in space such as oil and minerals

(Deacon 2011) 2 Among institutional channels a higher NRD or natural resource booms could

be associated with rent seeking misallocation of labour and entrepreneurial talent institutional

and political decline or even violent conflicts For instance the ldquoParadox of Plentyrdquo sustains that

windfalls of revenues as a consequence of resource booms could be related to a lack of incentives

to perform efficiently corruption patronage and local authorities favouring their voters or being

captured by the richest groups (Dauvin amp Guerreiro 2017) Hence a higher NRD or natural

resource booms could be the explanation not only for low levels of growth in regions more

dependent on natural resources but also it could be the root of income disparities

2 There is a wide strand of research on the Resource Curse Hypothesis however the evidence so far is not conclusive Evidence in favour of RCH has been mainly found in developing resource rich countries (Auty 1993 2001 Badeeb Lean amp Clark 2017 Blanco amp Grier 2012 Borge et al 2015 Brunnschweiler amp Bulte 2008 Sachs amp Warner 2001 Van der Ploeg 2011)

27

To test our hypothesis that is whether the levels of income inequality across counties are

positively associated with the degree of NRD we use a spatial econometric approach We use this

approach because attributes such as income inequality in one region may not be independent of

attributes in neighbouring regions (Armstrong amp Taylor 2000) This process of spatial dependence

invalidates the use of traditional (non-spatial) approaches

This study seeks to make two contributions to research First previous empirical evidence

shows a significant spatial dimension of income inequality in Chile (Paredes et al 2016)

However this dimension has been barely explored with most studies limiting the degree of

disaggregation to a regional scale (Aroca amp Bosch 2000) We use a spatial approach which makes

it possible to model and test the significance of the spatial dimension in the analysis of income

inequality and its relationship with other variables Second previous research for the Chilean

economy linking inequality with NRE has been mainly focused on explaining differences between

regions or the importance and effects of the mining-copper sector (Aroca amp Atienza 2011 Ebert

amp La Menza 2015 Lagos amp Blanco 2010 Rehner Baeza amp Barton 2014) We extend this

analysis using data for local economies Identifying and quantifying the impact of NRE on income

inequality at the county level is likely to be more informative for policies aiming to address the

current developmental bias between the metropolitan region and the rest of the country Moreover

the analysis of the role of natural resources in conjunction with other potential sources of inequality

may shed lights in understanding the persistence of the high levels of inequality observed in the

Chilean economy All in all this study could contribute to the design of policies that

simultaneously help reduce inequality increase efficiency and promote sustainable and inclusive

growth

28

Our main finding shows that after controlling for other potential sources of income

inequality such as educational level demographic characteristics and the level of public

government expenditure the degree of dependence on natural resources has a significant effect on

income inequality However contrary to our expectations the effect is negative This result

suggests that the natural or policy-driven process of transformation from primary and extractive

activities to manufacturing and service sectors imposes additional challenges to central and local

authorities aiming to reduce income inequality

In section 22 we review the literature on the relationship between income inequality and

natural resources In section 23 we establish our research problem and main hypothesis Section

24 describes our data and methods and section 25 the empirical results We finish with section

26 discussing our main results concluding and proposing avenues for future research

22 Inequality and Natural Resources

221 Theoretical Framework

Explanations for income inequality can be associated with individual institutional political

and contextual characteristics Individual characteristics include age gender and mainly the level

of education and skills of the population in the labour force For instance globalization and

technological change lead firms to increase the demand for skilled labour deepening income

inequality between skilled and unskilled workers (Atkinson 2015 Milanovic 2016 Tinbergen

1975) Among institutional characteristics labour unions collective bargaining and the minimum

wage have been suggested as explanations of income inequality (Acemoglu Aghion et al 2001

Atkinson 2015) Policy design associated with market regulation progressive taxation and

redistribution can also impact the levels and patterns of inequality

29

A key factor in understanding the levels and differences in income distribution within a

country may be its endowment of natural resources NRE shapes the structure of the economy

(Leamer et al 1999) it is associated with the creation of institutions that define the political

culture and it can also influence the performance of other sectors (Watkins 1963) In addition

NRE determines initial conditions market competition ownership over resources rent seeking

and the geographical concentration of the population and economic activity

Cross‐countryliterature

Bourguignon and Morrison (1990) introduce one of the earliest theoretical frameworks

describing the relationship between inequality and NRE They develop a small open economy

model where income distribution is a function of NRE ownership structure and trade protection

Giving cross-sectional evidence for a group of developing countries they conclude that the impact

of NRE particularly mineral resources and land depends on the number and size of the firms

whether they are public or private and the level of protection A higher concentration of production

in a few private firms a big share of production oriented to foreign instead of domestic markets

and protection increasing the relative price of scarce resources are some of the reasons explaining

why some countries are less egalitarian than others

NRE could also influence the evolution and levels of inequality by determining the initial

distribution of incomes This is known as the ldquoEngerman-Sokoloff Hypothesisrdquo (Engerman amp

Sokoloff 1997 Engerman et al 2002) In addition Leamer (1999) proposes that inequality and

development paths in each economy are a function of its economic structure which in turn depends

on ldquofundamentalsrdquo and ldquosymptomsrdquo On the one hand ldquofundamentalsrdquo refer to resource

endowment production structure closeness to markets and governments interventions On the

30

other hand ldquosymptomsrdquo are related to institutions employment structure and net export structure

Using this conceptual framework Leamer argues that natural Resource-Rich Countries (RRC) can

experience a higher level of inequality because can have a ldquodumbbell educational systemrdquo

ownership is concentrated in small groups and extraction activities require low-skilled workers

This implies fewer incentives to educate citizens until very late in the development process

resulting in human capital not prepared to take advantage of the process of technological progress

and delaying the emergence of more efficient and competitive sectors such as manufacturing and

services

Using 1980 and 1990 data for a group of countries classified according to land abundance

Leamer (1999) provides evidence showing that on the one hand land-scarce countries concentrate

their production and employment in sectors that promote equality such as capital-intensive

manufacturing chemical or machinery On the other hand countries abundant in natural resources

concentrate their production trade or employment in sectors that promote income inequality such

as the production of food beverages extraction activities or forestry

Gylfason and Zoega (2003) using a framework based on standard growth models also

proposed a positive relationship between NRE and inequality They assume that workers can work

in the primary sector or in the manufacturing (including services) sector In addition wage income

is equally distributed in the manufacturing sector but unequally in the primary sector (because of

initial distribution competition rent seeking etc) Therefore inequality will be greater when a

bigger proportion of labour is dedicated to extraction activities in the primary sector This

phenomenon is further amplified because of lower incentives to invest in physical and human

capital to adopt new technologies and to increase the share of the manufacturing sector

31

Diverse mechanisms explaining the link between NRE and inequality have been proposed

arguing that NRE determines simultaneously economic growth and inequality (Gylfason amp Zoega

2003) NRE could impact economic growth through the real exchange rate and the crowding-out

effect on manufacturing (ldquoDutch Diseaserdquo) reducing incentives to invest in physical and human

capital (Easterly 2007) and influencing the processes of technology adoption industrialization

and diversification of the economy in a manner that is less conducive to growth (Bulte et al 2005)

These potential explanations related to the called ldquoResource Curse Hypothesisrdquo do not have strong

empirical support (Auty 2001 Bulte et al 2005)

NRE may also influence economic growth through the quality of institutions (Acemoglu

1995 Acemoglu Aghion et al 2001 Acemoglu amp Robinson 2002 Engerman amp Sokoloff 1997

Engerman et al 2002) the concentration of ownership political power and rent-seeking NRE

acts by shaping institutional context and social infrastructure a phenomenon that is stronger when

resources are spatially concentrated such as minerals and plantations (Bulte et al 2005) NRE

could also have a significant effect on social cohesion and instability spreading its influence like

a disease (Brunori Ferreira amp Peragine 2013 Kanbur amp Venables 2005 Milanovic 2016

Ocampo 2004)

Considering a non-tradable sector intensive in unskilled workers Goderis and Malone

(2011) develop a model where the natural resources sector experiences an exogenous gift of

resource income They analyse the impact over income inequality of resource booms proxied by

changes in a commodity price index They conclude that inequality decreases in the short run but

increases after the initial reduction

32

Fum and Hodler (2010) show that natural resources increase inequality but this is

conditional on the level of ethnical polarization of society Carmignani (2013 2010) confirms this

positive relationship using different measures of dependence and abundance and goes further

arguing that inequality constitutes an indirect channel through which NRE affects human

development

Singlecountryevidence

Most of the studies about the relationship between inequality and NRE derive from cross-

country analyses Evidence for specific countries has been mainly based on case studies Howie

and Atakhanova (2014) based on the model of Goderis and Malone (2011) find for the case of

Kazakhstan that income and consumption inequality decreased significantly after booms in the oil-

and-gas sector because of resource booms increase the demand for non-tradable goods which are

intensive in unskilled workers The results depend on the level of rurality institutional quality

education levels and public spending on health and education Fleming and Measham (2015b

2015a) evaluate the impact of booms in the mining and oil sectors in Australia They find that a

boom in the mining sector increases income inequality due to commuting and migration among

regions This phenomenon can be exacerbated when the demanding access to natural resource

revenues is associated with the creation of more local administrative units (counties provinces and

even regions) but the government capacity is not simultaneously improved (Cust amp Poelhekke

2015 Michaels 2011) Furthermore the benefits that a region can receive in the form of fiscal

transfers can be more than compensated by the loses due to city-to-mine commuting such as the

case of mining regions in Chile (Aroca amp Atienza 2011)

33

Other studies at the local level have analysed the impact of the mining sector in Peru (Aragoacuten

amp Rud 2013 Loayza amp Rigolini 2016 Loayza Teran amp Rigolini 2013) Spain (Domenech

2008) and Canada (Papyrakis amp Raveh 2014) and the effects of oil windfalls in Brazil (Caselli amp

Michaels 2013)

In summary there is a wide range of potential mechanisms through which NRE could

influence income inequality Although most of them seem to suggest a positive relationship others

such as commuting and increased within-county demand for non-tradable goods and services

could lead to a negative association This highlights the need to know the sign of this association

in the Chilean economy where the trend shows a reduction in the degree of NRD After controlling

for other factors a positive link would support the argument that the reduction in the degree of

NRD has been relevant in the reduction experienced by income inequality in the same period

However a negative link would support the position that the reduction in NRD has contributed to

explain the persistence of income inequality and its slow reduction

222 The relevance of the spatial approach

Inequalities within countries are still the most important form of inequality from the political

point of view (Milanovic 2016) People from a geographic area within a country are influenced

and care most about their status relative to the people in other areas in the same country The

influence among regions involves multiple aspects (eg economic political and environmental)

These potential interactions have been traditionally ignored assuming independence among

observations related to different regions Moreover neglecting the process of spatial interaction in

key indicators of the economic and social performance of a country may mislead the design of the

public policy

34

The spatial dimension could play a significant role in understanding the distribution of

income within a country One strand of efforts aiming to capture the geographic heterogeneity of

inequality has been focussed on decomposing general indicators such as the Gini coefficient or the

Theil Index Evidence for different countries including the US (Doran amp Jordan 2016) China

(Akita 2003 Gustafsson amp Shi 2002 Ye Ma Ye Chen amp Xie 2017 Yue Zhang Ye Cheng

amp Leipnik 2014) Japan (Ohtake 2008) South Africa (Leibbrandt Finn amp Woolard 2012) and

Chile (Paredes et al 2016) shows that regional inequality is sensitive to the geographic scale of

analysis These studies also show a significant spatial component in the explanation of inequality

of income expenditure or gross domestic product for each country

Another strand explicitly uses exploratory spatial data analysis (ESDA) and spatial

econometrics ESDA has been used to provide new insights about the nature of regional disparities

of incomes and growth rates (Celebioglu amp Dallrsquoerba 2010 Yue et al 2014) Spatial econometric

models aim to assess and address the nature of the spatial effects These effects could be the result

of ldquospatial heterogeneityrdquo that is different relationships in distinct locations or ldquospatial

dependencerdquo which implies cross-sectional interactions (spillover effects) among units from

distinct but near locations

Spatial spillovers have been analysed to study both positive and negative spatial correlation

among less resource-abundant counties and resource-abundant counties On the one hand less

resource-abundant counties may experience positive spillovers because their industries supply

more goods and services to meet the increasing regional demand They can also be benefited from

positive agglomeration externalities and higher investment in private and public infrastructure

(Allcott amp Keniston 2014 Michaels 2011) On the other hand negative spillovers could be the

35

result of a high degree of interregional migration that limits the rise in wages and higher local

prices due to the increase in the share of the non-tradable sector In addition local governments

could have a limited capacity to translate the revenues from resource booms into effective public

policies promoting a sustained local development (Beine Coulombe amp Vermeulen 2015 Caselli

amp Michaels 2013 Papyrakis amp Raveh 2014)

23 Research problem and hypotheses

We can conclude from our overview of the literature that the theoretical and empirical

evidence about the link between inequality and natural resources is inconclusive This does not

make clear whether the process of reduction in the degree of dependence on natural resources

such as that experienced by the Chilean economy helps to explain the sustained but slow reduction

in income inequality or its high persistence

The research question guiding this study relates to how the natural resource endowment

determines the paths and structure of income inequality in natural resource-rich countries Using

the case of Chile the main hypotheses to be tested is whether a higher degree of dependence on

natural resources is associated with higher levels of income inequality To do that we use data at

the county level and we explicitly include the spatial dimension Our aim is to arrive at a more

comprehensive understanding of the drivers and transmission mechanisms explaining the

evolution and patterns shown by income inequality In addition we test whether the spatial

dimension plays a significant role in explaining differences in income distribution in Chile

36

24 Data and Methods

We use county-level data for the years 2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017 The reason

for not using contiguous years is that income data at the household level are only available every

two-three years from the Chilean National Socioeconomic Characterization Survey (CASEN in its

Spanish acronym)3 For the period 2006-2017 the Chilean administrative division considers 15

regions 54 provinces and 346 counties Data on income are available for 324 counties and six

years resulting in a panel with 1944 observations4

We start evaluating the spatial dimension in our data and analysing the link between

inequality and NRD using a cross-sectional setting To this end we use the ldquosix-year averagerdquo

(2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017) for our variables given the low time variability showed by

our measures of income inequality and NRD Results are then compared with those of a panel data

setting

241 Operationalization of key variables

The dependent variable in the present study income inequality at the county level is

measured calculating the Gini coefficient using three definitions of household income labour

autonomous and monetary income5 Labour income corresponds to the incomes obtained by all

members in the household excluding domestic service consisting of wages and salaries earnings

3 CASEN survey is conducted by the Chilean Ministry of Social Development covering topics such as education employment income and health CASEN is considered nationally representative and it is the main source for measures of inequality and poverty used for the design and evaluation of social policies in Chile 4 The six waves of CASEN for our study considered an average of 75599 households and 252081 individuals 5 The Gini coefficient is chosen because provides an overall estimate of income inequality It summarizes what proportion of the population gains what proportion of the total income The Gini coefficient can range between 0 (everyone in the population has the same income) and 1 (one person earns 100 per cent of the income in the community)

37

from independent work and self-provision of goods Autonomous income is the sum of labour

income and non-labour income (including capital income) consisting of rents interest and dividend

earnings pension healthcare benefits and other private transfers Finally monetary income is

defined as the sum of autonomous income and monetary subsidies which correspond to cash

transfers by the public sector through social programs Appendix A shows summary statistics for

the Gini coefficient of our three measures of income

The main independent variable in our study is the degree of dependence on natural resources

in each county To have an idea of the importance of each economic activity in the Chilean

economy particularly those activities related to natural resources Figure 21 shows their average

share in Chilean Gross Domestic Product (GDP) for the period 2006-17 We can observe that the

leading activities are those related to the primary sector especially mining and to the tertiary

sector where financial personal commerce restaurants and hotels services stand out The shares

of each economic activity in GDP vary significantly between Chilean regions and such

information is not available at the county level

Figure 21 Average share in GDP of economic activities (2006ndash17)

38

Leamer (1999) argues that when the main source of income is labour income (as indeed

happens for the Chilean case) using employment shares allows a better approach to measuring

dependence on natural resources Using employment data from CASEN survey we define our

measure of NRD as the employment in the primary sector (mining fishing forestry and

agriculture) as a percentage of the total employment in each county We name this variable

pss_casen where ldquopssrdquo stands for ldquoprimary sector sharerdquo We built other two proxies of NRD

using data from the ldquoServicio de Impuestos Internosrdquo (SII) which is the agency in charge of

collecting taxes in Chile The variable pss measures the percentage of employment in the primary

sector and the variable pss_firms measures the number of firms in the primary sector as a

percentage of the total number of firms in each county Appendix B shows summary statistics for

our three measures of NRD disaggregated by region

Figure 22 Evolution of Gini coefficient and measures of NRD (2006ndash17)

39

Figure 22 shows the evolution of our measure of inequality (using the Gini coefficient of

autonomous income) and our three potential proxies for NRD for the period 2006-2017 We

observe that both income inequality and the degree of NRD show a downward trend This seems

to support our hypothesis of a positive link between inequality and NRD however we need to

control of other sources of inequality before getting such a conclusion In what follows we use the

variable gini as our measure of income inequality capturing the Gini coefficient of autonomous

income Our measure of NRD is the variable pss_casen defined previously

Figure 23 Spatial distribution of Gini coefficient and NRD (2006ndash17)

Note Gini and NRD averages 2006-09-11-13-15-17 for 324 Chilean counties divided into five equal groups Source Own elaboration based on CASEN survey

40

Figure 23 shows quantile maps for income inequality (on the left) and NRD (on the right)

using the six-years average dataset6 On the one hand we observe that high levels of inequality

seem to be clustered in the Centre-South of the country where agriculture forestry and fishery are

the predominant economic activities Only isolated counties show high inequality in the Centre

(Metropolitan area where the countyrsquos capital is located) and North (Mining) areas On the other

hand our measure of NRD seems to show an opposite spatial pattern than income inequality with

high levels in the Centre and North of the country

242 Control variables

To control for county characteristics we use a set of socio-economic demographic and

institutional variables Economic factors are captured by the natural log of the mean autonomous

household income per capita (in thousands of Chilean pesos of 2017) lnincome the poverty rate

poverty the unemployment rate unemployment the percentage of the population living in rural

areas rural and the average years of education of the population over 15 years old education

Demographic factors include the proportion of the population in the labour force labour_force

and the natural log of population density (population divided by county area) lndensity

We also include the natural log of the total municipal public expenditure per capita

lnmuni_expenditure to control for municipal heterogeneity This heterogeneity is mainly related

to the capacity of municipalities to generate their own revenues In addition the richest

municipalities are in the Metropolitan region which concentrates economic power and around 40

6 After sorting a variable in ascending order quantile maps use the quantiles (quartiles quintiles deciles etc) as class breaks to divide the distribution of the variable where each class includes approximately the same number of observations (counties)

41

of the population This has basically implied a lag in the development of regions other than the

metropolitan region

The spatial distribution of our measures of income inequality and NRD displayed in Figure

23 seems to show different patterns in the North Centre and South of the country Appendix C

shows the administrative division of Chile in 15 regions and how we have grouped them in three

zones North Centre and South We consider as the ldquoCentrerdquo area that formed by the Metropolitan

region (XIII) and its two neighbouring regions V and VI Using the Centre area as our reference

we include in our analysis two dummy variables indicating whether a county is located in the North

area (regions XV I II III and IV) or South area (regions VII VIII IX XIV X XI and XII)

Appendix D shows summary statistics for the set of numeric control variables and the

correlation matrix between our measure of NRD pss_casen and the set of numeric controls

243 Methods

To assess and then consider the spatial nature of the data we need to define the set of relevant

neighbours for each country This is operationalized by building a matrix called ldquoWrdquo with a ldquo1rdquo

for neighbouring counties and a ldquo0rdquo for non-neighbouring counties We could build W using

contiguity-based (whether counties share a border or point) or geography-based (taking the

distances among the centroids of each county polygon) spatial weights Specifically we build a W

matrix considering the 5-nearest counties7 Two reasons explain the choice of k-nearest

neighbours First we cannot use a contiguity criterium because we do not have information about

all the counties and there are some geographically isolated counties Second given the significant

7 We assign a ldquo1rdquo to the five nearest counties to each county based on the distances among the polygon centroids Then W is ldquorow standardizedrdquo This facilitates the interpretation of the spatial lag of a variable as the ldquoweighted average valuerdquo of the same variable in neighbouring counties

42

differences in county areas (ldquobig countiesrdquo in northern and southern regions) using a distance-

band criterium with a not enough large distance band can lead to many ldquoislandsrdquo in extreme regions

and a multi-modal distribution for the number of neighbours

We start testing our inequality and NRD variables for spatial autocorrelation in order to

evaluate statistically the clustering patterns shown in Figure 23 Next we run an OLS regression

of inequality against NRD and our set of controls and we test the spatial autocorrelation of OLS

residuals If we cannot reject the null hypothesis of random spatial distribution we do not need

spatial models to analyse income inequality which would give contrasting evidence to previous

suggestions about the relevance of the spatial dimension of income inequality in Chile (Paredes

2013 Paredes et al 2016) If we find significant spatial autocorrelation in the OLS residuals this

justifies the use of spatial models and highlight the need to find the correct spatial structure8

If inequality in one county spillovers or influences inequality in neighbouring counties the

spatial lag of inequality should be included as an explanatory variable and we should use a spatial

autoregressive model (SAR) If some unobserved variable is the explanation for the clustering of

counties with similar inequality then this will be better captured including a spatial lag of the

errors and we should use a spatial error model (SEM) (Anselin 1988 Anselin amp Bera 1998)

Finally when our main explanatory variable or some of the controls show spatial autocorrelation

a spatial lag of the explanatory variable(s) should be included in our model

8 The existence of spatial autocorrelation violates the standard assumption of independence among observations needed for OLS regression This will result in OLS coefficients biased and inconsistent (Anselin 1988)

43

244 Spatial Model Specification

A model that includes the three forms of spatial dependence described above is called the

Cliff-Ord Model The model in its cross-sectional representation could be expressed as

119910 120582119882119910 119883120573 119882119883120574 119906 (21)

where

119906 120588119882119906 120576 (22)

119882 is our weight matrix that works as an NxN spatial lag operator9 Thus 119882119910 119882119883 and 119882119906

are the spatial lags for the dependent variable explanatory variables and the error term

respectively The parameter 120582 capture the spatial dependence in the dependent variable 120574 the

spatial dependence in the explanatory variables 120588 capture the spatial dependence in the error term

and 120598 is a vector of idiosyncratic errors For instance if ldquoyrdquo is income inequality and ldquoXrdquo a measure

of NRD the level of inequality in one county will be explained by the degree of NRD in the same

county 119883120573 the average degree of NRD in neighbouring counties 119882119883120574 the average level of

inequality in neighbouring counties 120582119882119910 and the average value of residuals in neighbouring

counties 12058811988211990610

From equations (21) and (22) the SAR and SEM models can be seen as special cases of

the Cliff-Ord representation after imposing restrictions over the spatial parameters 120582 120574 and 120588 For

the specification of the spatial panel models we follow the terminology by Croissant and Millo

9 The spatial lag is a weighted sum of the values observed at neighbouring locations 10 On the one hand the impact that income inequality in one county has over income inequality in neighbouring counties is called a ldquoglobal spilloverrdquo and it is associated with the feedback effect among neighbours (one county is its neighboursrsquo neighbourrdquo) on the other hand the influence that the degree of NRD in neighbouring counties has over inequality in one county is called a ldquolocal spilloverrdquo

44

(2018) Spatial panel models including the spatial lag of the dependent variable (SAR) the spatial

lag of the residuals (SEM) or both (SARAR) are described in Appendix E

25 Results

251 Exploratory Spatial Data Analysis (ESDA)

To analyse the significance of the spatial dimension in our data set we use the six-year

average of our variables Spatial autocorrelation is tested using the Moranrsquos I statistic11 Moranrsquos

I measures the correlation of one variable with itself in space12 Figure 24 shows the Moran scatter

plots where the standardized variable (Gini coefficient and NRD for each county) appears in the

horizontal axis against its spatial lag (average value in the 5-nearest neighbouring counties) The

Moranrsquos I (slope of the line in the Moran scatter plot) of income inequality shows a significant

positive spatial autocorrelation that is counties with high (low) inequality tend to be close to each

other

11 There are many statistics to formally test the significance of the spatial dimension in the distribution of our data The null hypothesis assumes spatial randomness which means that there is not spatial structure in the data so any spatial pattern is equally likely to occur and values in one location do not depend on values in other locations The alternative hypotheses can be the existence of positive or negative spatial autocorrelation Positive spatial autocorrelation means similar values in neighbouring locations (less variability than under spatial randomness) Negative spatial autocorrelation means dissimilar values in neighbouring locations (more variability than under spatial randomness) 12 Traditional measures of correlation such as the Pearsonrsquos coefficient measure the degree of linear correlation between two different variables Measures of spatial autocorrelation assess the correlation between the values of one variable in one location related to the values of the same variable in other neighbouring locations

45

Figure 23 Moran scatter plots for variables gini and pss_casen

Moranrsquos I is a measure of global spatial autocorrelation this means it is intended to capture

the clustering property of the entire data set To identify where are the significant hot-spots

(clusters of counties showing high income inequality) or cold-spots (clusters of counties showing

low income inequality) we need local indicators of spatial association (LISA) Using the local

Moranrsquos I (not reported) we find significant hot-spots in the South of the country (mainly

agricultural regions) and significant cold-spots in the Centre (Metropolitan area) of the country

The next step is to check whether the clustering pattern in inequality is the result of a process of

spatial dependence in the variable itself or it can be explained by other variables related to

inequality

252 Cross-sectional analysis

We start analysing differences in income inequality between counties using the six-year

average data and running an OLS regression for the model

119892119894119899119894 120573 120573 119901119904119904_119888119886119904119890119899 120573 119897119899119894119899119888119900119898119890 120573 119901119900119907119890119903119905119910 120573 119906119899119890119898119901119897119900119910119898119890119899119905 120573 119897119886119887119900119906119903_119891119900119903119888119890 120573 119890119889119906119888119886119905119894119900119899 120573 119897119899119889119890119899119904119894119905119910 120573 119903119906119903119886119897 120573 119897119899119898119906119899_119890119909119901119890119899119889119894119905119906119903119890 120573 119899119900119903119905ℎ 120573 119904119900119906119905ℎ

(23)

46

The Moran scatter plot and spatial statistical test of OLS residuals from equation (23) are

in Appendix F OLS residuals show a small but significant positive autocorrelation (Moranrsquos I =

0121) This means that income inequality continues showing a significant degree of spatial

autocorrelation after controlling for the set of covariates In addition robust Lagrange Multiplier

(LM) tests show that a spatial error model is preferred over a spatial lag model (Anselin Bera

Florax amp Yoon 1996)13 This means that income inequality tends to cluster in zones larger than a

county so the analysis should be performed on a larger scale such as provinces regions or macro

zones If the SAR model were preferred it would mean that income inequality in one county is

influenced by the level of income inequality in neighbouring counties To find the spatial structure

that best fits the clustering process of income inequality we run the full set of spatial model

specifications in a cross-sectional setting and results are shown in Table 21

Column 2 in Table 21 shows the results of our ldquoOLSrdquo model The ldquoSLXrdquo model includes

spatial dependence only through the explanatory variables The ldquoSARrdquo model includes the spatial

lag of the dependent variable as a regressor and the ldquoSEMrdquo model includes spatial dependence

through the error term The ldquoSARARrdquo model includes both the spatial lag of the response and the

errors and the ldquoSDMrdquo and ldquoSDEMrdquo are the extensions of the ldquoSARrdquo and ldquoSEMrdquo models

respectively including the spatial lag of the explanatory variables Finally a model including

spatial lags for the response errors and explanatory variables (the ldquoSARARXrdquo model) is shown in

the last column

13 Following the ldquoAnselin methodrdquo when both non robust LM tests are significant we should select between the robust LR tests From Table F1 in Appendix F only the robust LM test for the SEM model (RLMerr) appears as significant

47

Table 21

Cross-sectional Model Comparison (six-year average data)

48

Opposite to our hypothesis we observe a significant and negative coefficient for our measure

of NRD This means that counties more dependent on natural resources show lower levels of

inequality Education years population density and municipal expenditure per capita are also

negatively related to inequality On the other hand the level of income the poverty rate and the

proportion of the population living in rural areas show a positive relationship with income

inequality There is no significant influence of the unemployment rate and the proportion of the

population in the labour force In addition the SAR SEM and SARAR models show a

significantly higher average inequality in the South of the country related to the Centre area

The main finding from our cross-sectional analysis is that there is a significant and negative

relationship between inequality and NRD which is quite robust to the model specification

253 Panel Data analysis

Like the cross-sectional case we start estimating the panel without spatial effects Results

for the pooled fixed effects (FE) and random effects (RE) specifications of equation (3) are in

Appendix G Spatial models were estimated using Maximum Likelihood (ML) and Generalized

Moments (GM) and assuming that the spatial structure (W matrix) is the same for all years14

Tables 22 23 and 24 show results for the ML estimation of the SAR SEM and SARAR models

using the pooled FE and RE specifications Results for the GM estimation are in Appendix H

All our spatial models include time fixed effects In the case of the pooled and RE models they

additionally include indicator variables for those counties located in the North and South of the

country

14 In traditional (non-spatial) panels data are stacked as time series for each observational unit (county) In the case of spatial panels data are stacked as slice of cross-sections for each year in the panel

49

The main result is that the negative and significant effect of NRD on income inequality is

robust to most of the spatial panel specifications In addition the coefficient for the variable

pss_casen changes slightly among panel specifications (pooled FE and RE) but does not change

among spatial models (SAR SEM and SARAR)

Another important finding is related to the significance of the spatial dimension of income

inequality When spatial models cross-sectional or panel are compared to non-spatial models

there are no major differences in the magnitude of the coefficients or their significance This could

mean that the positive spatial autocorrelation shown by income inequality seems to be better

explained by a process of spatial heterogeneity rather than spatial dependence The practical

implication of this result is that including dummy variables for aggregated units (eg regions or

groups of regions) could be enough to control for the spatial dimension in the modelling and

analysis of income inequality

Among control variables years of education seems to be the main variable for the design of

long-term policies aimed at reducing inequality This result is in line with previous evidence for

cross-country studies (Leamer et al 1999) and specific countries (Howie amp Atakhanova 2014)

Municipal expenditure per capita also shows a significant and negative association with income

inequality in the pooled and RE spatial specifications This means that higher municipal

expenditure helps to reduce inequality between counties but its effect is more limited within

counties This result support the importance of local governments (Fleming amp Measham 2015a)

however the negative coefficient appears as evidence against the ldquoParadox of Plentyrdquo (Borge et

al 2015)

50

Table 22

ML Spatial SAR Models

Table 23

ML Spatial SEM Models

51

Table 24

ML Spatial SARAR Models

26 Discussion and conclusions

In this essay we delve deep into the sources of income inequality analysing its association

with the degree of dependence on natural resources using county-level data for the 2006ndash2017

period in Chile Given recent evidence for the Chilean economy suggesting a significant spatial

dimension we assess and incorporate explicitly the spatial structure of income inequality using

spatial methods We use cross-sectional and panel data to evaluate the significance of the spatial

dimension and we test whether NRD has a positive effect on income inequality

Contrary to what theory predicts NRD shows a significant and negative association with

income inequality This result is robust to the type of analysis (cross-sectional vs panel data) the

approach (spatial vs non-spatial) and the inclusion of different controls The negative and

significant coefficient implies that if the degree of NRD would not have experienced a 10 drop

during this period income inequality could have fallen in 2 additional points So the downward

trend in the participation of the primary sector in terms of employment in the Chilean economy

52

could be one of the main reasons explaining the high persistence in the levels of income inequality

This means that those areas that undergo a process of productive transformation mainly towards

the services sector would be facing greater problems to reduce inequality This process of

productive transformation natural or policy-driven highlights the importance of policies focused

on human capital and the role of local governments in reducing inequality

The main implication for policymakers is that a reduction in NRD does not help to reduce

inequality generating additional challenges for local and central governments in its attempt to

transform the structure of their economies to fewer dependent ones on natural resources The

finding of a significant spatial dimension suggests that defining macro zones capturing the spatial

heterogeneity in the data should be done before analysing the relationship among variables and the

design and evaluation of specific policies Particularly relevant in those areas experiencing a

reduction in NRD are migration commuting and the characteristics of the tertiary (services) sector

In addition our findings show that education and municipal expenditure could be effective policy

tools in the fight to reduce inequality in Chile

Although our results seem quite robust they do not allow us to make causal inferences about

the effect of NRD on income inequality However we could think of the following explanation to

explain the negative relationship found and the differences between geographical areas

Areas highly dependent on NR used to demand a high proportion of low-skill labour This

has change in sectors such as the mining sector in the northern area which has simultaneously

experienced an increase in activities related to the service sector such as retail restaurants

transport and housing However those services associated with more skilled labour such as the

finance sector remain concentrated in the capital region The reduction in the degree of NRD

(employment in extractive activities) implies lower labour force but more specialized with most

53

of the low-skilled labour transferred to a service sector characterized by low productivity and low

wages

Non-spatial models show that the North and South particularly the latter present

significantly higher levels of inequality This could be associated with the type of resources with

ldquopointrdquo resources such as minerals in the North and ldquodiffusedrdquo resources such as agriculture in the

South This translates into higher average incomes in the Centre and North areas and lower average

incomes in the South

The reduction in NRD implies not only a movement of the labour force from extractive

activities to manufacturing or services with the latter characterized by low productivity and low

salaries of the labour force We could also speculate that most of the high incomes move to the

central area where the economic power and ownership over firms and resources are concentrated

This would explain low inequality associated with higher average incomes in the central area and

high inequality associated with lower average incomes in the South A more in-depth analysis

capturing the mobility of wealth and labour force between counties or more aggregated areas is

needed to better understand the causal mechanism involved

Our findings open avenues for future research in different strands First studies on the causes

of income inequality should take the role of NRD into consideration which has been overlooked

so far Given that the spatial dimension of income inequality seems to be explained by a

phenomenon of spatial heterogeneity estimation strategies such as spatial regime models or

geographically weighted regression should be used (Chi amp Zhu 2019) Second the effect of NRD

on income inequality could manifest through different channels such as education fiscal transfers

and institutions We could extend our analysis to identify which of these competing channels is

the most relevant Transforming some continuous variables such as educational level to a

54

categorical variable or defining new indicator variables for instance whether a local government

shows or not an efficient performance we could classify counties in different groups and then

check whether there are differences or not in the relationship between income inequality and NRD

A third strand could be to disaggregate our measure of NRD for different industries This

would allow us to test differences among industries and to identify the sectors that promote greater

equality and which greater inequality Forth the analysis of the consequences of income inequality

on other economic and social phenomena such as efficiency economic growth and social cohesion

has a growing interest in researchers and policymakers Our findings suggest that to answer the

question of whether income inequality has a causal impact on other variables we could include a

measure of NRD as an instrument to address endogeneity issues For instance two interesting

topics for future research are the analysis of how differences in income inequality between counties

could help to explain differences in the level of efficiency of local governments and differences in

the degree of social cohesion (unrest) throughout the country Those are the issues to be addressed

in the next two essays

55

Chapter 3 The Impact of Income Inequality on the Efficiency of

Municipalities in Chile

31 Introduction

In Chile municipalities are the smallest administrative unit for which citizens choose their

local authorities playing an important role in the provision of public goods and services at the

local level Municipalities have a similar set of objectives but the level of financial resources

available to finance their activities is highly heterogeneous This could result in significant

differences in the levels of performance between municipalities Despite their importance there is

little empirical evidence about the efficiency of local governments in Chile This essay aims to

measure the technical efficiency of Chilean municipalities and to analyse how local characteristics

particularly those related to income distribution at the county level could help to explain

differences in municipal performance

Cross-country studies situate Chile as an efficient country in international comparisons about

efficiency of government spending (Herrera amp Pang 2005 Loacutepez amp Miller 2008) However

evidence for Chile at the local level is relatively sparse suggesting significant levels of

inefficiency For instance Pacheco Sanchez and Villena (2013) found a mean efficiency level of

around 70 using a sample of 309 municipalities for the period 2008-2010 This suggests that

municipalities could achieve the same level of output by reducing the usage of inputs by an average

of 30 Their study also showed that those municipalities more dependent on the central

56

government or those located in counties with lower income per capita are more efficient than their

counterparts

Most empirical research on Local Government Efficiency (LGE) has been conducted for

member countries of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) of

which Chile has been a member since 2010 In the case of European countries such as Spain and

Italy which share similar characteristics such as the monetary union and levels of GDP per head

efficiency studies have been mainly motivated by budgetary constraints (Balaguer-Coll Brun-

Martos Maacuterquez-Ramos amp Prior 2019 lo Storto 2013) The Chilean context differs in three

main ways from its OECD counterparts First except for the Metropolitan Region that concentrates

most of the population Chilean regions are highly dependent on natural resources Second Chile

is also characterized by one of the highest levels of income inequality among OECD countries

which contrast with the situation of developed natural resource-rich countries such as Australia

and Norway Third although budget constraints are also a relevant issue Chilean municipalities

have experienced a sustained increase in the level of financial resources and expenditure

Another relevant distinction when we benchmark the performance of municipalities across

different countries is the type of public services they provide On the one hand in most of the

countries included Chile the main role of local governments is to provide ldquoservices to peoplerdquo

such as public education and public health On the other hand there are countries such as Australia

where local governments mainly provide ldquoservices to propertyrdquo including waste management

maintenance of local roads and the provision of community facilities such as libraries swimming

pools and parks (Dollery Wallis amp Akimov 2010 Drew Kortt amp Dollery 2015 McQuestin

Drew amp Dollery 2018)

57

Despite contextual differences Chilean municipalities seem not to perform differently from

municipalities in other developed and natural resource-rich countries where income inequality is

significantly less than in Chile (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018a) This result highlights the

need to study the role of income inequality and the degree of dependence on natural resources over

LGE characteristics that have been largely overlooked in the literature

We measure and analyse differences in municipal performance using a two-stage approach

In the first stage we measure municipal efficiency using an input-oriented Data Envelopment

Analysis (DEA) to get a set of ldquoefficiency scoresrdquo In the second stage we regress efficiency scores

against our measure of income inequality controlling for a set of contextual factors describing the

economic socio-demographic and political context of each county

We use a sample of 324 municipalities for the period 2006-2017 During this period Chile

was divided into 346 counties belonging to 15 regions This period was characterized by important

external and internal shocks including the Global Financial Crisis (GFC) one of the biggest

earthquakes in Chilean history in 2010 and three municipal elections The availability of

information allows us to measure efficiency for the full period but the influence of contextual

factors is analysed using a panel of six years (2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017) for which

household income information is available

The main hypothesis tested in the second stage is whether higher levels of income inequality

are associated with lower levels of efficiency Previous evidence shows that when progress is not

evenly shared persistent within-country inequality reduces the effectiveness and efficiency of the

public sector (Ortega Sanjuaacuten amp Casquero 2017 Tandon 2005)

Income inequality has been used to control for a wide range of idiosyncratic factors

associated with historical institutional and cultural factors affecting efficiency (Greene 2016

58

Ortega et al 2017) For instance at the local level income inequality has been considered as an

indicator of economic heterogeneity in the population where higher inequality is associated with

a more heterogeneous set of conflicting demands for public services which adversely affect an

efficient provision (Ashworth Geys Heyndels amp Wille 2014 Geys amp Moesen 2009) Higher

levels of income inequality could also relate to economically privileged groups having a greater

capacity to influence the political system for their own benefit rather than that of the majority

When high inequality is persistent the feeling of frustration and disappointment in the population

could reduce not only trust and cooperation among individuals but also trust in institutions which

would negatively affect government efficiency (Boix amp Posner 1998 Coffeacute amp Geys 2005) For

instance national or local authorities could end exerting patronage and clientelism and showing

rising levels of corruption (Uslaner 2011 Uslaner amp Brown 2005)

One of the main gaps in extant literature is the need to conduct more analysis of LGE using

panel data taking into consideration endogeneity issues and controlling for unobserved

heterogeneity (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018a) To address the above we set-up a panel with

time and county-specific effects and we propose the use of a measure of natural resource

dependence (NRD) as an instrument for income inequality Based on the ldquoParadox of Plentyrdquo

fiscal revenues from natural resources windfalls could be associated with an over expansion of the

public sector fostering rent-seeking and corruption and reducing local government efficiency

(Dauvin amp Guerreiro 2017 Manzano amp Rigobon 2001) In the Chilean case most of the revenues

generated by local governments included those from natural resources end up in a common fund

which benefits all municipalities The aim of this common fund is precisely to reduce inequalities

among municipalities so although we do not expect a direct impact of natural resources on LGE

we could expect an indirect effect through other indicators particularly income inequality

59

As far as we know this is the first study analysing the influence of income inequality as a

determinant of municipal efficiency in Chile Moreover this is the first study in the context of a

natural resource-rich country which specifically suggests a measure of natural resource

dependence as an instrument to correct for endogeneity bias We propose the use of the proportion

of firms in the primary sector as proxy for the degree of NRD in each county We argue that this

variable is a better proxy than using the proportion of employment in the manufacturing sector

which has been proposed in previous studies (Alesina amp La Ferrara 2002) During the period

analysed our proxy remained relatively stable and showed a significant relationship with income

inequality In addition it is less likely that it has directly affected municipal efficiency

This study adds to the literature in two other ways First the extant literature suggests that

efficiency measurement could be highly sensitive to the chosen technique as well as the selection

of inputs and outputs (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018a) Inputs are usually proxied by a single

measure of total public expenditures and outputs by general proxies such as population andor the

number of businesses in each county We offer a novel approach for the selection of inputs and

outputs On the one hand we disaggregate government expenditures into four components

(operation personnel health and education) and we use the number of public schools and health

facilities in each county as a proxy for physical capital On the other hand we use four outputs

aiming to capture the wide variety of goods and services supplied by each municipality Through

this approach we aim to better describe the production function of each municipality capturing

not only the variety of inputs and outputs but also differences in size among municipalities

A third contribution relates to the measurement of LGE in the Chilean context We measure

technical and scale efficiency using a larger sample and a longer period This has empirical and

policy relevance On the one hand it helps us to select the correct DEA model and allows us to

60

determine the importance of scale inefficiencies as explanation for differences in municipal

performance On the other hand efficiency measures increase the information available for both

central and local governments to better understand the production technology that best describes

each municipality and to carry out policies to improve efficiency

We believe that our selection of inputs and outputs the use of a large dataset and the joint

analysis using cross-sectional and panel data provide a more accurate and robust analysis of

municipal efficiency Likewise knowing whether inequality has a significant influence on

municipal efficiency may provide useful insights and guidance for policymakers not only in Chile

but also for countries sharing similar characteristics

DEA results show an average level of technical efficiency (inefficiency) of around 83

(17) This means that municipalities could reduce on average a 17 the use of inputs without

reducing the outputs There are significant differences among geographic areas with the Centre

area (where the countyrsquos capital is located) displaying higher efficiency than the rest of the country

When municipal efficiency is measured under different assumptions about returns to scale results

reveal a production technology with variable returns to scales and around 75 of the

municipalities displaying scale inefficiencies However when technical efficiency is

disaggregated between pure technical efficiency and scale efficiency results show that scale

inefficiency explains a small proportion of the total municipal technical inefficiency This finding

justifies a deeper analysis of the reasons why municipalities could operate inefficiently and why

municipal performance could vary among municipalities

Efficiency scores also show a significant degree of positive spatial autocorrelation This

means that municipal efficiency shows a general clustering process with neighbouring

municipalities showing similar levels of efficiency A further analysis shows that most of the

61

spatial pattern in municipal efficiency is exogenous that is could be associated to other variables

Hence we conduct most of our regression analysis using traditional (non-spatial) methods and

leaving spatial regressions in the appendixes

Findings from cross-sectional and panel regressions support the hypothesis that municipal

performance is significantly and negatively associated with income inequality at the county level

The coefficient of income inequality is close to one which means that reductions in income

inequality ceteris paribus could be associated with increases in municipal efficiency in the same

proportion This result supports the strand of research arguing that there is not a trade-off at least

at the municipal level between equity and efficiency (Andersen amp Maibom 2020 Berg amp Ostry

2011 2017) The main policy implications are that authorities in more unequal counties would

face higher challenges to perform efficiently and policies pertaining to inequality and efficiency

should not be designed independently

The chapter is structured as follows Section 32 provides a brief literature review on related

local government efficiency Section 33 introduces the methodological background and empirical

models Section 34 presents the empirical results and discussions Section 35 concludes the

chapter

32 Related Literature

321 Measuring efficiency of local governments

Studies on measuring LGE can be grouped in those analysing the provision of single services

such as health or education and those assessing overall efficiency (lo Storto 2013) Once inputs

and outputs have been defined efficiency is measured using parametric andor non-parametric

techniques Among the former group Stochastic Frontier Analysis (SFA) seems to be preferred

62

by scholars aiming to measure efficiency and to analyse the link with environmental variables

using a single procedure (Pacheco et al 2013 Tsekeris Sotiris Tsekeris amp Papaioannou 2018)

On the non-parametric group Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA) is by far the most used technique

(Afonso amp Fernandes 2006 Balaguer-Coll amp Prior 2009 lo Storto 2013)

The selection of inputs and outputs depends not only on the aimed of the study (specific

sector vs whole measure of efficiency) but also on the role that municipalities play in different

countries There are countries such as Australia (Drew et al 2015) and Spain (Balaguer-Coll amp

Prior 2009) where local governments mainly supply services to ldquopropertyrdquo such as waste

management and road maintenance In these cases efficiency has been mainly measured using

total indicators of local government expenditure and outputs have been proxied using general

indicators such as population or number of business (Drew et al 2015) On the other hand in

countries such as Italy (lo Storto 2013) and Portugal (Afonso amp Fernandes 2008) in Europe or

Brazil (de Sousa Cribari-Neto amp Stosic 2005) and Chile (Pacheco et al 2013) in South America

municipalities mainly supply services to ldquopeoplerdquo Here in addition to financial expenditures or

revenues inputs have included the number of local government employees the number of schools

or the number of hospitals and health centres School-age population the number of students

enrolled in primary and secondary schools and the number of beds in hospitals have been

considered as outputs Based on the study of Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte (2018a) a wider list of

inputs and outputs used in previous studies can be found in Appendix I

Studies from different countries show important differences in the average efficiency scores

both between and within countries These studies also differ in the samples methodologies and

variables included A summary showing the range and variability of the mean efficiency scores

founds in countries all around the world can be found in Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte (2018a)

63

These authors also show that OECD natural resource-rich countries such as Australia Belgium

and Chile show similar results in terms of mean efficiency scores with LGE studies being less

frequent in Latin American countries

Measuring efficiency of local governments as decision-making units (DMU) presents many

challenges and difficulties (Borger Kerstens Moesen amp Vanneste 1994 Ravallion 2005)

Worthington and Dollery (2000) mention problems with the selection and measurement of inputs

the identification of different stakeholders the hidden characteristic of the ldquolocal government

technologyrdquo and the multidimensionality of the services provided by local governments All these

issues make difficult to identify and distinguish between outputs and outcomes with outputs

commonly proxied by general indicators such as county area or county population Because

efficiency measures are highly sensitive to the chosen technique and the selection of inputs and

outputs Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte (2018a) suggest formulating different specifications and

using less general and unspecified indicators Moreover the complexity in defining outputs and

the use of general indicators make more likely that contextual factors affect municipal efficiency

322 Explaining differences in LGE

To explain differences in local government performance researchers have basically

distinguished between ldquodiscretionaryrdquo and ldquonon-discretionaryrdquo factors Discretionary factors refer

to the degree of discretion of local authorities in the selection and management of inputs and

outputs On the other hand scholars have investigated the influence on LGE of contextual factors

beyond authoritiesrsquo control These factors reflective at the environment where municipalities

operate include economic socio-demographic geographic financial political and institutional

characteristics (da Cruz amp Marques 2014 Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018b)

64

In general the evidence about the influence of contextual factors has delivered mixed and

country-specific results (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018b) Sampaio de Sousa et al (2005)

using data for Brazilian municipalities finds that population density and urbanization rate have

strong positive effects on efficiency scores Benito et al (2010) show that lower levels of

efficiency of Spanish municipalities are associated with a greater economic level a less stable

population and a bigger size of the local government Afonso (2008) finds that per capita income

level and education are not significant factors influencing LGE of Portuguese municipalities He

also finds that municipalities in Northern areas show greater efficiency than their counterparts in

Southern areas More recently Tsekeris (2018) finds that spatial variations in efficiency in Greece

can be attributed to factors related to inter-regional market access specialization and sectoral

concentration resource-factor endowments and political factors among others Characteristics

describing each local government have also been used including municipal indebtedness (Benito

et al 2010) fiscal deficits (Sinha 2017) degree of fiscal autonomy (Boetti Piacenza amp Turati

2009) and individual characteristics of local authorities such as age gender and political ideology

Narboacuten‐Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte (2018b) conclude after analysing 63 articles that studies on the

influence of contextual factors have mostly used cross-sectional data with little attention to

endogeneity issues which makes any causal interpretation doubtful

323 The trade-off between efficiency and equity

The existence of a potential trade-off between efficiency and equity is in the core of

economic discussion (Andersen amp Maibom 2020 Berg amp Ostry 2011 Browning amp Johnson

1984 Okun 2015)15 The argument that economic growth (one of the most common efficiency

15 Redistributive policies distort incentives and lead to suboptimal outcomes and thus efficiency losses

65

measures) could be negatively affected in the search for greater equality has been translated not

only into economic policies that favour economic growth over those that reduce inequality but

also in the emphasis of scholarly research Thus theoretical and empirical research has been

mainly focussed on efficiency and policy implications of a great diversity of shocks and policies

leaving the analysis of inequality as one of measurement and mostly descriptive Additionally

empirical evidence of the trade-off is scant and inconclusive (Andersen amp Maibom 2020

Browning amp Johnson 1984)

Among economic contextual factors that could affect LGE income inequality has been

largely ignored An exception is a cross-country comparison conducted by Ortega (2017) who

analyses the role of inequality on government efficiency in developing countries He finds that

more unequal countries could have higher difficulties to achieve specific health outcomes Income

inequality has even been considered as part of the outputs to measure efficiency particularly for

the case of European and OECD countries (Afonso Schuknecht amp Tanzi 2010 Antonelli amp De

Bonis 2018)

At the local level income inequality has been mainly used as a proxy for the effect of income

heterogeneity Economic inequality could have a direct and an indirect effect on government

efficiency The direct effect poses that higher income inequality could reduce municipal efficiency

because it is associated with a more complex and competing set of public services demanded by

the population (Jottier et al 2012) The indirect effect puts the focus in the link between inequality

social capital and levels of corruption Economic diversity could reduce trust in people and

institutions when related to high and persistent levels of income inequality It could also affect the

willingness to participate in community and political groups the existence of a shared objective

by citizens and the perception of a prosperous future (Uslaner amp Brown 2005)

66

The evidence is ambiguous For instance Geys and Moesen (2009) find that income

inequality has little relation to efficiency of Flemish municipalities and Ashworth et al (2014)

find a negative relationship for the Norwegian case Findings also indicate that inequality is the

strongest determinant of trust and that trust has a greater effect on communal participation than on

political participation (Uslaner amp Brown 2005)

33 Methodology

We follow a two-stage approach widely used in this kind of analysis A DEA analysis is

conducted in the first stage to get efficiency scores for each municipality Then regression analysis

is conducted in the second stage aiming to identify contextual variables other than differences in

the management of inputs that can help to explain the heterogeneity in municipal performance

331 Chilean Municipalities and period of analysis

The territory of Chile is divided into regions and these into provinces which for purposes of

the local administration are divided into counties The local administration of each county resides

in a municipality which is administrated by a Mayor assisted by a Municipal Council16

Municipalities represent the decentralization of the central power in Chile They are autonomous

organizations with legal personality and own patrimony whose purpose is to satisfy the needs of

the local community and ensure their participation in the economic social and cultural progress of

the county Municipalities have a diversity of functions related to public health education and

social assistance among others

16 The Mayor and City Council are elected by suffrage for the citizens of the respective commune every 4 years

67

To achieve their goals two are the main sources of municipal incomes own permanent

revenues (OPR) and the Municipal Common Fund (MCF) OPR are incomes generated by the

county and they are an indicator of the self-financing capacity of each municipality OPR are not

subject to restrictions regarding their investment and they are mainly generated by territorial taxes

commercial patents and circulation permits17 The MCF is a fund that aims to redistribute

community income to ensure compliance with the purpose of the municipalities and their proper

functioning Sources to finance the MCF come from municipal revenues The distribution

mechanism of the fund is regulated by parameters such as whether municipalities generate OPR

per capita lower than the national average and the number of poor people in the commune in

relation to the number of poor people in the country

This study covers the period from 2006 to 2017 During this period Chile was divided into

15 regions 54 provinces and 346 counties18 Although the information on inputs and outputs is

available for the entire period information on contextual factors at the county level such as

household income is only available every two-three years In addition some counties are excluded

from household surveys due to their difficult access Hence we use a sample of 324 municipalities

to measure municipal efficiency for the whole period (3888 observations) However the analysis

of contextual factors is conducted for those years when household income information is available

2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017 (1944 observations)

17 The territorial tax is a tax on agricultural and non-agricultural real estate Specifically of this income only 40 is left to the municipality as its own financing while the remaining 60 is allocated to the MCF (in the case of the four largest communes- Santiago Providencia Las Condes and Vitacura-percentages are 35 and 65 respectively) Unlike the territorial tax commercial patents are regulated mainly by the municipality which chooses the rate to be charged subject to a range established by law and is responsible of their collection Finally regarding the circulation permits 375 is of municipal benefit while 645 is directed to the MCF 18 There are 346 counties managed by 345 municipalities where counties ldquoCabo de Hornosrdquo and ldquoAntaacuterticardquo are managed by the municipality of ldquoCabo de Hornosrdquo

68

332 Measuring municipal efficiency

Municipal efficiency is measured using Data Envelopment Analysis (Coelli Prasada Rao

OrsquoDonnell amp Battese 2005) This is a non-parametric approach that uses linear programming to

measure efficiency for a group of municipalities as decision making units (DMUrsquos) The main

advantage of using DEA and the reason why DEA is used for the case of Chilean municipalities

is its flexibility in handling multiple inputs and outputs without the need to specify a functional

form (Balaguer-Coll amp Prior 2009 Mikušovaacute 2015 Tigga amp Mishra 2015) Following Afonso

and Fernandes (2008) the relationship between inputs and outputs for each municipality could be

represented by the following equation

119884 119891 119883 119894 1 119899 (31)

In equation (31) 119884 is the set of outputs and 119883 the set of inputs for each of the n

municipalities Using linear programming the production frontier is constructed and a vector of

efficiency scores is obtained The frontier represents full technical efficiency mdash the point at which

the highest output occurs given specified inputs or the point at which the lowest amount of inputs

is used to produce a specified quantity of output Efficiency scores under DEA are relative

measures of efficiency They measure a municipalityrsquos efficiency against the other measured

municipalities in the sample and not a hypothetical lsquoperfect municipalityrsquo The further from the

frontier the less technically efficient a municipality is

We use an input-oriented approach because Chilean municipalities have a greater control

over the management of inputs relative to the outputs they have to manage Obtaining efficiency

scores requires an assumption about the returns to scale exhibited by each municipality When

DMUrsquos are homogeneous the CCR model (Charnes Cooper amp Rhodes 1978) which assumes

69

constant return-to-scale (CRS) is the appropriate specification The CCR model assumes full

proportionality between outputs and inputs and that DMUrsquos operate at their optimal When DMUrsquos

are highly heterogeneous as is the case with local governments in most countries it is not realistic

to assume complete proportionality between inputs and outputs nor that all DMUrsquos operate at their

optimum scale In this situation a variable returns-to-scale (VRS) or BCC model (Banker

Charnes amp Cooper 1984) is the preferred formulation

Assuming VRS imposes minimum restrictions on the efficient frontier and allows for

comparisons only among municipalities of similar scale (Coelli et al 2005 Wu Huang amp Pan

2014) This means that when we use the CCR model (assuming CRS) on a heterogeneous sample

of DMUrsquos the resulting measure of technical efficiency that we obtain is related not only to the

management of inputs but also to issues of scale19 To empirically check the validity of the VRS

assumption we measure technical efficiency under CRS VRS and non-increasing returns-to-scale

(NIRS) and we analyse the existence of scale inefficiencies This allows us to check the relevance

of scale effects as a potential explanation of differences in municipal efficiency Appendix J

shows the specification of the DEA model under VRS and how ldquototal technical efficiencyrdquo

(assuming CRS and therefore due to management and scale issues) could be disaggregated in ldquopure

technical efficiencyrdquo (under VRS and related only to management issues) and scale efficiency (due

to scale issues)

19 Assuming VRS can also lead to measurement problems such as overestimation of efficiency scores This is the case when an important proportion of DMUrsquos shows CRS so assuming VRS ignores the information about proportionality between inputs and outputs (Podinovski 2004)

70

333 Inputs and outputs used in DEA

Following the literature on local government expenditure efficiency (Afonso amp Fernandes

2008 de Sousa et al 2005 Dlouhyacute 2018 Tandon 2005 Tigga amp Mishra 2015) and trying to

reflect as well as possible the functioning of municipalities five inputs and four outputs were

selected Input and output data were obtained from the National System of Municipal Information

(SINIM in its Spanish acronym) and they are expressed in thousands of Chilean pesos of 201720

Inputs are Municipal Operational Expenditure X1 (including expenses on goods and

services social assistance investment and transfers to community organizations) Municipal

Personnel Expenditure X2 (including full time and part-time workers) Total Municipal

Expenditure in Education sector X3 Total Municipal Expenditure in Health sector X4 and the

Number of Municipal Buildings X5 (proxied by the number of public facilities in education and

health sectors)

Output variables were selected highlighting the relevance of education and health sectors

and trying to capture the wide range of local services provided by municipalities The variable

ldquoOwn Permanent Revenuesrdquo Y1 is used to capture the scale and diversity of municipal

activities21 The ldquoMonthly Average Enrolmentrdquo in municipal education establishments related to

the school-age population in each county Y2 is used as educational output As health output the

ldquoNumber of Medical Consultationsrdquo in public facilities Y3 is considered Finally the number of

community organizations Y4 is used as output reflecting the promotion of community

development by each municipality Table 31 shows the summary statistics of input and output

20 The data from SINIM database was mostly obtained using the sinimr package (Salas 2019) 21 According to SINIM database this variable aims to measure the management of the municipalityrsquos own resources with respect to the population of the commune

71

variables for the whole sample and period Inputs and outputs excepting the Monthly Average

Enrolment Y2 are measured in per capita terms using county population information from the

National Institute of Statistics (INE in its Spanish acronym)

Table 31

Descriptive statistics Inputs and Output variables used in DEA analysis

334 Regression model

Contextual factors could play an important role not only in explaining why some

municipalities operate inefficiently but also why municipal performance differs among them

These factors may affect municipal performance modifying incentives for local authorities to

operate efficiently and their capability to take advantage of economies of scale They also define

the conditions for cooperation or competition among municipalities and the citizensacute ability and

willingness to monitor local authorities (Afonso amp Fernandes 2008)

Information on income at the household level for each county was obtained from the

ldquoNational Socioeconomic Characterization Surveyrdquo (CASEN in its Spanish acronym) CASEN is

conducted every two-three years being the reason why consecutive years are not considered in

72

our regression analysis The other contextual factors used as controls were obtained from different

sources including SINIM INE and the ldquoServicio de Impuestos Internosrdquo (SII)22

Our main hypothesis is whether higher levels of income inequality are associated with lower

levels of municipal efficiency To test our hypothesis the empirical model is defined as

120579 120573 119892119894119899119894 119885 120573 120575 120572 120598 (32)

Where 120579 is the vector of DEA efficiency scores 119892119894119899119894 is the Gini coefficient of each

county 120575 are year-specific effects 120572 are county-specific constants 120598 is a vector of error terms

and 119885 is a vector of controls Next we discuss the motivation for these controls

The level of purchasing power of countiesrsquo citizens is proxied by the variable log(income)

which is the natural log of the mean household income per capita in thousands of Chilean pesos of

2017 On the one hand poorer counties could display higher efficiency due to their necessity to

take care of their constraint resources (Pacheco et al 2013) On the other hand richer counties

could show higher efficiency because richer citizens exert higher monitoring over local authorities

and demand better quality public services in return for their tax payments (Afonso et al 2010)

The possibility for municipalities to take advantage of economies of scale and urbanization is

captured by three variables First the variable log(density) which correspond to the natural log of

population density Second the dummy variable reg_cap indicating whether a county is a regional

capital or not Third the variable agroland which correspond to the proportion of land for

agricultural use which is informed to the SII We expect a positive effect of log(density) but

negative for regcap and agroland

22 The SII is the institution in charge of collecting taxes in Chile

73

Socio-demographic characteristics are captured including a Dependence Index IDD IDD

corresponds to the number of people under 15 years or over 65 years per 100 people in the active

population (those people between 15 and 65 years old) A higher proportion of young and older

population could be associated with a higher demand for municipal services relating to education

and health making harder to offer public services efficiently The citizensrsquo capacity to monitor

local authorities is proxied including the variable education (average years of education for the

population older than 15 years) and the variable housing (proportion of households which are

owners of the property where they live in each county) In both cases we expect a positive

association with LGE

Among municipal characteristics the variable professional (percentage of municipal

personnel with a professional degree) is used to control for the quality of municipal services and

it is expected a positive impact The variable mcf (proportion of total municipal income coming

from the MCF) is included to capture the influence of financial dependence on the central

government A higher dependence from MCF could be associated with higher efficiency when it

is linked to more control from central government (Worthington amp Dollery 2000) However when

MCF discourages the generation of own resources and proper management of resources from the

fund a lower efficiency should be expected (Bravo 2014) In addition the dummy variable mayor

is included to capture differences among mayors supported by the ldquoLEFTrdquo or the ldquoRIGHTrdquo

political parties related to those ldquoINDEPENDENTrdquo mayors

Table 32 report summary statistics for the set of numeric contextual factors and Appendix

K the corresponding correlation matrix Despite the high correlation between income and

education variables we include both in the regression section as they capture different county

characteristics

74

Table 32

Summary Statistics Numeric Contextual Factors

Figure 31 Geographical distribution of Chilean regions and macrozones

Previous evidence on growth and convergence of Chilean regions have found that regions

tend to cluster spatially (Aroca amp Bosch 2000) Aiming to capture this regional clustering process

75

and considering the high concentration in the number of municipalities and population in the

central area we group municipalities in four ldquozonesrdquo We define as reference the ldquoCentre-Northrdquo

zone consisting of regions XIII (where the countryrsquos capital is located) and its two neighbouring

regions V and VI The ldquoNorthrdquo zone includes regions XV I II III and IV The ldquoCentre-Southrdquo

zone includes regions VII VIII and IX Finally the ldquoSouthrdquo zone embraces regions XIV X XI

and XII Figure 31 displays the regional administrative division and zones considered in this

essay

Efficiency scores (ES) are limited to have values between 0 and 1 However they are relative

measures (relative to the sample of municipalities) This implies that when a municipality is on the

frontier (ES = 1) it does not mean that potentially larger technical efficiency gains cannot be made

Hence equation 32 is estimated using OLS and censored regressions We start running cross-

sectional regressions for each of the six years Then we compare the results with those from panel

regressions Because fixed-effects panel Tobit models could be affected by the incidental

parameters problem (Henningsen 2010 2019) we use random-effects panel Tobit models

including indicator variables for years and zones Finally to deal with the potential endogeneity

problem we also use an instrumental variable approach The instrument is described next

335 The instrument

Government effectiveness and income distribution are both structural components of

economies (Ortega et al 2017 Ravallion 2005) In the search for a causal interpretation for the

influence of income inequality on municipal efficiency we need an instrument which must be

correlated with the variable to be instrumented (in our case income inequality) and uncorrelated

with the error term in the efficiency equation (32) Previous literature has used as instruments for

Gini the number of townships governments in a previous period the percentage of revenues from

76

intergovernmental transfers in a previous period and the current share of the labour force in the

manufacturing sector (Alesina amp La Ferrara 2002) Using the share of the labour force in a specific

sector is unlikely to reduce the problem of endogeneity particularly in countries where local

governments supply mostly ldquoservices to peoplerdquo and the main source of income inequality is

labour income

We propose as an instrument the proportion of firms in the primary sector (mining fishing

forestry and agriculture)

119901119904119904_119891119894119903119898119904Number of firms in the primary sector

Total number of firms (33)

On the one hand this instrument is likely to be correlated with local income inequality in

natural resource-rich countries23 On the other hand we contend that our instrument is less likely

to be correlated with the error term in the efficiency equation First the main services supplied by

Chilean municipalities are services to people (health and education) not to firms Second most of

the revenues collected by municipalities included those associated with natural resources end up

in the municipal common fund whose objective is precisely to reduce inequalities among

municipalities Third services to firms are expected to be more significant with the tertiary sector

We argue that our instrument captures natural and structural conditions which directly

influence income inequality but it does not directly affect LGE Figure 32 shows the evolution

of the annual average efficiency score and the proportion of firms in the primary secondary

(manufacturing) and tertiary (services) sectors We observe that sectors shares have remained

relatively stable with a slight reduction in the participation of the primary sector in favour of the

23 Results confirm a significant association between income inequality and the degree of dependence on natural resources at the county level

77

tertiary sector by the end of the period This is contrary to the evolution of municipal efficiency

which shows a cyclical behaviour as will be shown in the next section

Figure 32 Evolution of efficiency scores and the proportion of firms by sector

34 Results and discussion

341 DEA results

Figure 33 displays the evolution of our three measures of efficiency Overall technical

efficiency pure technical efficiency and scale efficiency are around 78 83 and 95

respectively with fluctuations over the years Therefore around three quarters of the overall

78

inefficiency is attributed to inefficiency in the management of inputs and around one quarter to

scale inefficiencies24

Figure 33 Evolution technical efficiency (TE) pure technical efficiency (PTE) and scale efficiency (SE)

Returnstoscale

Figure 34 reports by zone and for the whole period the proportion of municipalities

showing CRS decreasing returns to scale (DRS) or increasing returns to scale (IRS) Most of the

municipalities operate under variable (increasing or decreasing) returns to scale which could be

explained by the high heterogeneity in size among municipalities A summary of RTS

disaggregated by year and zone is in Appendix L Policies oriented to increase efficiency usually

24 The average scale efficiency score of 95 means that municipalities could get an additional 5 of inputs saving if municipalities were able to change their size to achieve their optimal scale

79

consider amalgamation de-amalgamation or ways of cooperation among municipalities To have

a better idea about where and how feasible is the implementation of such policies Appendix M

shows maps with the administrative division of the country in its 345 municipalities and which

municipalities show CRS IRS or DRS in each of the six years of data

Figure 34 Returns to scale by zone

Based on results for the whole period (Figure 34) the North has the highest proportion of

municipalities exhibiting DRS This suggests the need to reduce the size of municipalities splitting

those ldquotoo bigrdquo creating new administrative areas or giving more autonomy to current

municipalities25 The opposite occurs in the Centre-North area where municipalities mostly

exhibit IRS This indicates the need to merge municipalities An alternative strategy to the

amalgamation process is increasing inter-municipal cooperation (Balaguer-Coll et al 2019)

25 This has been the policy followed in Chile Although two new regions were created (XV in the North and XIV in the South) the number of municipalities has not changed

80

which seems to be a more plausible option in Chile Finally evidence on scale efficiency for the

Centre-South and South areas is not clear in terms of the adequate strategy to improve efficiency

Efficiencymeasure

Although most municipalities show scale inefficiencies (Figure 34) only a small proportion

of total inefficiency is associated to scale issues (Figure 33) Together this results justify not only

the use of the BCC model (efficiency scores under VRS) to capture municipal heterogeneity but

also highlights the need to look for other factors outside the control of local authorities which

could be influencing municipal performance

Table 33

Summary efficiency scores (VRS) by zone and region

Table 33 summarizes ES under VRS using data for the six years of CASEN survey A mean

efficiency score of 83 is found for the full sample and period This means that on average

inefficient municipalities can reduce the use of inputs by 17 to get the same current output By

81

comparing average ES per zone it can be concluded that municipalities in the North Centre-North

Centre-South and South could achieve the same level of output with 17 12 18 and 23 fewer

resources respectively Results also show that one third of the municipalities present an efficiency

score equal to one

Figure 35 shows the evolution of the mean ES for the four zones over the 12 years period

A clear drop in the efficiency level is observed in 2009 (the financial crisis year) excepting for the

North area Likewise although mean efficiency returned to its pre-crisis levels in 2014-2015 a

new drop in efficiency was experienced in 2016 It also seems that the 2010 earthquake did not

generate a significant effect on municipal efficiency Figure 35 also shows that although levels

of efficiency seem to differ among zones they follow a similar trend through time with the only

exception of the North which corresponds to the mining area In addition efficiency seems to be

significantly higher in the Centre-North area This is explained by the high mean level of efficiency

in region XIII which includes the countryrsquos capital city

Figure 35 Evolution mean efficiency scores (VRS) by zone

82

To know which and where are the efficient municipalities and if they are surrounded by

municipalities with a similar level of efficiency Appendix N has maps showing the ldquoefficiency

statusrdquo of each municipality that is whether they are efficient (ES = 1) or inefficient (ES lt 1)

Additionally Appendix O shows ldquoequal intervalsrdquo maps describing the spatial distribution of ES

among municipalities for each of the six years26 Results show that efficient municipalities can be

found all through the country the ldquoefficiency statusrdquo could change from one year to another and

municipalities with similar level-status of efficiency tend to cluster in space

342 Regression results

Exploratoryspatialanalysis

DEA efficiency scores and their geographical representations seem to show that municipal

efficiency presents a spatial clustering pattern This means that municipal performance could be

influenced not only by contextual factors of the county where municipality belongs but also by the

level of efficiency of neighbouring municipalities and their characteristics To test the significance

of the spatial dimension in municipal efficiency we use a cross-section of data considering the six-

year average of efficiency scores the Gini coefficient and the set of controls

We use the Moranrsquos I indicator to test for spatial autocorrelation Moranrsquos I is a measure of

the correlation between the level of efficiency in one municipality and its ldquospatial lagrdquo that is the

average level of efficiency in neighbouring municipalities We define as the relevant neighbours

for each municipality the 5-nearest municipalities This is obtained using the distances among the

26 An equal intervals map uses the same principle as a histogram to organize the observations into categories that divide the range of the variable into equal interval bins For the equal interval classification the value range between the lower and upper bound in each bin is constant across bins but the number of observations in each bin is typically not equal

83

polygonsrsquo centroids (latitude and longitude) of each county Results confirm that municipal

efficiency show a significant level of positive spatial autocorrelation This means that

municipalities tend to have neighbouring municipalities with similar performance

The positive spatial autocorrelation shown by municipal efficiency could be due to the

performance in one municipality is influenced by the performance in neighbouring municipalities

(spatial dependence in the variable itself) or due to structural differences among regions-zones

(spatial heterogeneity) To check the source of the spatial autocorrelation we run an OLS

regression of ES against income inequality and controls and then we test OLS residuals for spatial

autocorrelation Moranrsquos I over OLS residuals although significant is barely higher than zero (see

Appendix P) This means that the spatial effect itself is not a serious issue and can be handle for

instance including zone indicators variables hence we proceed to analyse the influence of income

inequality on LGE using non-spatial regression27

Cross‐sectionalanalysis

We start reporting censored regressions for each year in our panel Efficiency scores have

been rescaled to numbers between 0 and 100 to facilitate the interpretation of the results All

regressions include dummy variables for three of the four zones in which we have grouped Chilean

regions Results are in Table 3428 Income inequality shows a negative sign in all years which is

consistent with our hypothesis that inequality is negatively related to municipal efficiency

However only in three of the six years the effect of income inequality appears as statistically

27 In the case of having incorporated the spatial dimension the two most commonly used forms are including in the model the spatial lag of the dependent variable (spatial autoregressive model SAR) or the spatial lag of the error (spatial error model SEM) Following the method suggested by Anselin et al (1996) Lagrange Multiplier (LM) tests on the OLS residuals showed that the SAR model is preferred over the SEM Moranrsquos I LM tests and spatial regressions can be found in Appendix P 28 Regression results using OLS are in Appendix Q

84

significant Only the income level displays a significant and positive influence on efficiency for

the whole period A higher population density also consistently favours municipal efficiency On

the other hand as we expected a higher IDD makes it more difficult to achieve an efficient

performance29 Consistent with results in Pacheco et al (Pacheco et al 2013) municipal

efficiency show a significant an positive association with the MCF only in the first half of our

period of analysis with the second half showing an insignificant relationship

Table 34

Cross-sectional (censored) regressions

Paneldataanalysis

Estimation results for the six-year panel are reported in Table 35 Columns (1) and (2) show

the results for the pooled and random effects censored models only controlling for zone and year

29 The set of cross-sectional regressions was also run for each zone independently Results confirm that the set of significant contextual factors differs not only among years but also among geographic areas This support previous evidence suggesting that cross-sectional analysis should be treated with caution (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018b)

85

dummies Income inequality appears as non-significant Zone indicator variables confirm that

municipalities located in the Centre-South and South of the country display a lower average level

of efficiency compared to the Centre-North area Time dummies mostly show negative

coefficients This is a signal that shocks such as the GFC and the earthquake in 2010 may have

had a negative impact on efficiency but that impact was not permanent The results for the pooled

and RE models including the full set of controls are reported in columns (3) and (4) These results

show a significant negative influence of income inequality on LGE

When income inequality is instrumented by the variable pss_firms most of the coefficients

remain unchanged except for those associated with the income variables gini and log(income)

This result implies that our original model suffers for instance from the omitted variable bias

This means that LGE and income inequality are determined simultaneously by some variable not

included in our model Columns (5) and (6) show results using our instrument for income

inequality The ldquotrue coefficientrdquo of variable gini remains negative but the magnitude of the

relationship is higher The negative coefficient for gini implies on the one hand that municipalities

located in more unequal counties face more challenges to achieve an efficient management of

public resources On the other hand the coefficient in column (6) is close to one The interpretation

is that for each point of reduction in income inequality ceteris paribus LGE should increase in the

same proportion Next we discuss some of the results associated with the controls variables

Contrary to Pacheco et al (2013) income level has a positive coefficient meaning that richer

counties in terms of income per capita show higher efficiency This could be explained by higher

monitoring and increasing demands from citizen and taxpayers In addition it is expected a higher

efficiency in municipalities located in counties with a higher population density and those with a

lower proportion of land for agricultural use This result is mainly explained by municipalities

86

located in the Centre area The opposite happens with municipalities in the South implying that

they are too ldquosmallrdquo to take advantage of agglomeration economies There is also a limit for

agglomeration and scale economies which is shown by the negative coefficient of the variable

regcap although this coefficient loses its significance in the IV approaches30

Unexpectedly efficiency was found to be negatively associated with the variable education

This result is similar to the case of Czech municipalities (Šťastnaacute amp Gregor 2014) where

explanations include a weakened monitoring effect due to the fact that more educated citizens

present greater mobility and labour cost disadvantages for municipalities with better educated

labour force In Chile an additional explanation could be the relationship between education and

voter turnout Since 2012 voting is no longer mandatory in Chile This fact considerably reduced

voter turnout which in turn may have influenced the monitoring and control effect of more

educated voters For the case of variable IDD results show that local authorities in counties with

higher proportion of aging and young population (related to those in the active population) face a

greater challenge in their quest to offer public services efficiently

The influence of mcf is like that found by Pacheco et al (2013) with municipalities more

dependent on central transfers showing more efficiency31 Political influence captured by the

variable mayor did not show a significant effect This result is like other studies concluding that

the ideological position did not have a significant influence on efficiency (Benito et al 2010

Boetti et al 2009 Cordero Pedraja-Chaparro Pisaflores amp Polo 2017)

30 This negative coefficient suggests that the negative effects of agglomeration economies such as overcrowding pollution high cost of land and traffic congestion could predominate over the positive effects of scale economies in regional capitals 31 When the analysis is conducted for each zone independently MCF displays a negative influence in the North and Centre-North areas but a positive influence in the Centre-South and South areas These results confirm that on the one hand richer municipalities (those in the North and Centre-North) have less incentives for efficient management of their resources On the other hand results support the relevance of MCF helping poorer municipalities (those in the South) to reach their outcomes

87

Table 35

Panel data regressions

88

35 Conclusions

The trade-off between equity and efficiency is in the core of the economic discussion This

ldquoprinciplerdquo has been used by policymakers to prioritize the design of policies focused on economic

growth delaying those policies aimed at reducing economic inequalities This essay offers

empirical evidence of a negative relationship between inequality and efficiency that is a reduction

of income inequality could have positive effects on economic efficiency at least at the level of

local governments

We followed a traditional Two-Stage approach commonly used in the analysis of LGE We

compared cross-sectional and panel data results and we have added an instrumental variable

approach to give a causal interpretation to the link between efficiency and inequality We proposed

the use of a measure of natural resource dependence to instrumentalize the impact of income

inequality on LGE Given that our units of analysis are municipalities and not counties we argue

that our measure of NRD is correlated with income inequality and it does not have a direct

influence on LGE

We found that Chilean municipalities perform better than previous studies suggest

Municipal efficiency depicted significant levels of positive spatial autocorrelation and most of the

municipalities showed to be operating under increasing or decreasing returns to scale This would

imply that the policies generally used to improve efficiency such as amalgamation or cooperation

should be implemented observing the reality of each region and not as strategies at the national

level We also found that scale inefficiency explains a small proportion of the average total

inefficiency reason why the analysis of external factors that could affect the municipal efficiency

takes greater relevance

89

Income inequality plays an important part in explaining municipal efficiency In fact it was

found that reductions in income inequality could result in increases in municipal efficiency in a

similar proportion An unexpected finding was that the levels of education shows a negative

association with municipal performance This could be due to a low average level of education or

the existence of an omitted variable This variable could be the significant reduction in voting

turnout rates for local and national elections due to changes in the voting system during the period

of our analysis All in all our results may help to shed light on the potential consequences of

changes in contextual factors and the design of strategies aimed to increase municipal efficiency

in countries with similar characteristics to the Chilean economy For instance policies oriented to

take advantage of economies of scale can be formulated merging municipalities or establishing

networks in specific sectors such as education or health

Further work needs to be done both in measurement and in the explanation of differences in

municipal performance in Chile One area of future work will be to identify the factors that better

predict why municipalities operates under increasing decreasing or constant returns to scale

Multinomial logistic regression and the application of machine learning algorithms to SINIM data

sets appear as suitable methods for that purpose Intertemporal DEA (Drew amp Dollery 2015)

should be used to measure municipal efficiency capturing changes in total factor productivity In

addition municipalities operate under different levels of geographical authorities such as the

provincial mayor and the regional governor Hence it would be useful to know how each

municipality performs within each region-zone related to how performs to the whole country This

should be done conducting a metafrontier analysis (OrsquoDonnell Rao amp Battese 2008)

We have also identified through a cross sectional spatial exploratory analysis that on

average municipalities with similar levels of efficiency tend to cluster in space Regarding to

90

analyse the importance of contextual factors on municipal efficiency a deeper analysis should use

censored spatial models to check the significance of the spatial dimension in cross-sectional and

panel contexts Another interesting avenue for future research is associated with the negative

association found between LGE and education The significant reduction in votersacute turnout since

the law of automatic registration and voluntary voting in 2011 appears as a natural experiment to

analyse its effects on efficiency indicators such as municipal performance Incorporating variables

such as the voting turnout in each county or classifying municipalities based on individual

institutional political and economic characteristics could help to shed light on which of these

channels is the most relevant when analysing the impact of inequality on municipal efficiency

Finally we argued that an important part of the influence of income inequality over LGE

could be through its indirect effect on trust social capital and social cohesion The final essay will

delve deep in that relationship

91

Chapter 4 Social Cohesion Incivilities and Diversity

Evidence at the municipal level in Chile

41 Introduction

A deterioration in social cohesion could carry significant costs such as a reduction in

generalized trust between individuals and in institutions a society caught in a vicious circle of

inequality and citizens increasingly distanced from civic life (Uslaner 2011) A growing feeling

of frustration and discontentment can eventually translate into a social outbreak with uncertain

results This is precisely what have been happening in many countries around the world included

Chile

ldquoSocial cohesion is a state of affairs concerning both the vertical and the horizontal

interactions among members of society as characterized by a set of attitudes and norms that

includes trust a sense of belonging and the willingness to participate and help as well as their

behavioural manifestationsrdquo (Chan et al 2006) This definition highlights the multidimensionality

in the concept of social cohesion which has been measured using objective andor subjective

indicators of trust social norms solidarity willingness to participate in social and political groups

and feelings of belonging (Ariely 2014 Chan et al 2006) Multidimensionality also implies that

the impact of determinants of social cohesion such as economic and racial diversity could be

different for each of its various dimensions (Ariely 2014)

A common characteristic to all societies is that they are made up of different groups that

differ with respect to race ethnicity income religion language local identity etc The

92

Community Heterogeneity Thesis (Coffeacute amp Geys 2006) argues that individuals prefer to interact

with others that are like themselves Hence high levels of diversity particularly economic and

racial represent a complex scenario to maintain social cohesion One of the most common factors

adduced for social cohesion is income inequality with higher levels linked to lower levels of trust

(Ariely 2014 Rothstein amp Uslaner 2005)

Traditional measures of social cohesion may not be adequately capturing the deterioration

in social connections For instance measures of (lack of) trust include a strong subjective element

On the other hand proxies for social participation such as volunteering jobs or joining to social

organizations have not been supported by empirical evidence as a source of generalized social trust

(Rothstein amp Uslaner 2005) We proposed to use the rate of incivilities which we argue is a more

appropriate measure of the degree of worsening in the social context

Incivilities are those visible disorders in the public space that violate respectful social norms

and tend not to be treated as crimes by the criminal justice system There are two types of

incivilities social and physical Social incivilities include antisocial behaviours such as public

drinking noisy neighbours and fighting in public places Physical incivilities include among

others vandalism graffiti abandoned cars and garbage on the streets Because citizens and

political authorities cannot always distinguish between incivilities and crime they are usually

treated as an additional category of crime This implies that policies aimed to reduce incivilities

are generally based on punitive actions However theory and evidence on incivilities suggest that

factors explaining incivilities and crime could be different (Lewis 2017 Taylor 1999)

In Chile crime rates have shown a sustained downward trend after reaching its highest level

in 2011 On the other hand incivilities rate has shown a sustained upward trend which coincides

with the increasing victimization and feeling of insecurity in the population This has motivated

93

Chilean authorities based on the ldquoBroken Windows Theoryrdquo to propose new punitive actions (or

increase the severity of the current ones) to those who commit this type of antisocial behaviours

The ldquoBroken Windows Theoryrdquo states that higher rates of incivilities are a signal of social

disorganization which result in higher crime rates (J Q Wilson amp Kelling 1982) This is expected

to have consequences on familiesrsquo decisions such as moving away from public spaces or even

leaving their neighbourhoods

As far as we know there is no previous evidence about the potential causes of incivilities in

Chile Efforts to identify the factors explaining incivilities could help not only to reduce the risk

factors favouring violent and property crimes but also to guide interventions aimed to change

social behaviours and strengthen social cohesion in highly unequal societies Thus the main

contribution of the present study is to provide a deeper comprehension of the problem of incivilities

and how they can help to better understand the weakening of social cohesion that many

contemporary societies experience

We aim to offer the first evidence on the factors explaining the evolution and the differences

in incivilities rates in Chile We set up a panel for six years (2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and

2017) and 324 counties (1944 observations) We start exploring the evolution and geographical

distribution of incivilities Then we investigate whether economic and racial diversity after

controlling for other socioeconomic demographic and municipal characteristics can be regarded

as key predictors of incivilities

We use the Gini coefficient to proxy economic heterogeneity and the number of new visas

granted to foreigners as proportion of the county population as proxy for racial diversity The main

hypothesis is whether economic and racial diversity have a positive association with the rate of

incivilities In addition to the arguments regarding the ldquoCommunity Heterogeneity Thesisrdquo Taylor

94

(1999) and Skogan (1986 1999 2015) argue that incivilities are caused by inequality and the lack

of informal mechanisms of social control Based on the ldquoIncivilities Thesisrdquo the patterns of

incivilities should mirror the patterns of inequality (Taylor 1999) Then higher inequality should

be associated with higher physical and social vulnerability of the population This reduces social

control and increases social disorganization which triggers antisocial or negligent behaviours

Our main result reveals a strong positive association between the rate of incivilities and the

number of new visas granted per year The relationship with income inequality although also

positive seems to be less significant These findings give strong support to the ldquoCommunity

Heterogeneity Thesisrdquo and to a lesser extent to the ldquoIncivilities Thesisrdquo When the analysis is

disaggregated geographically racial diversity shows a clear positive effect The impact of income

inequality seems to be conditional depending on the level of income showing no effect in poorer

regions Results also show that the impact of economic and racial diversity differs by type of

incivility For example income inequality shows a strong association with ldquoStreet Tradingrdquo while

racial diversity with ldquoAlcohol Consumptionrdquo Two are the main policy implications On the one

hand a national strategy to address the problems associated with foreign immigration could help

to reduce incivilities For instance a joint effort between national and local authorities to curb

immigration and its distribution throughout the country On the other hand our results show that

the relationship between incivilities and economic diversity differs depending on the region or

geographical area Hence the impact on social cohesion of policies aimed to tackle economic

inequalities should be analysed in each specific context

The rate of incivilities also shows a negative association with the level of municipal financial

autonomy This implies that municipalities can effectively carry out policies to reduce incivilities

beyond the efforts of the central government Another important finding is that our results do not

95

support the hypothesis that a higher proportion of the young population is associated with higher

rates of incivilities Hence policies aimed to reduce incivilities should be focused on the causes of

incivilities rather than the criminalization of behaviours or stigmatization of specific population

groups

The structure of the chapter is as follows Section 42 outlines the relevant literature on social

cohesion and incivilities Section 43 describes the data variables and methodology and

establishes the hypotheses of the study Section 44 contains the results and discussions Section

45 presents the main conclusions

42 Related Literature

421 The Community Heterogeneity Thesis

The idea under ldquoThe Community Heterogeneity Thesisrdquo is that if individuals prefer to

interact with others who are similar to themselves in terms of income race or ethnicity high levels

of income inequality and racial diversity facilitate a context for lower tolerance and antisocial

behaviours lowering the ldquostaterdquo of social cohesion (Alesina 2000 Coffeacute amp Geys 2006 Letki

2008) Alessina and Ferrara (2002) give support to this hypothesis arguing that individuals have a

natural aversion to heterogeneity However the most popular explanation is the principle of

homophily people prefer to interact with others who share the same ethnic heritage have the same

social status and hence share experiences and tastes (Letki 2008 McPherson Smith-Lovin amp

Cook 2001 Tolsma et al 2009) For instance Delhey and Newton (2005) find for a sample of

60 countries that income inequality and ethnicity are strongly and negatively correlated with trust

Tolsma et al (2009) using data for Dutch neighbourhoods and municipalities find that social

cohesion is negatively and consistently affected by economic deprivation but not by ethnic

96

heterogeneity These authors also conclude that the effect of neighbourhood and municipal

characteristics on social cohesion depends on residentsrsquo income and educational level

Rothstein and Uslaner (2005) give two theoretical reasons why economic and racial diversity

should be causally related to social trust a key element of social cohesion First optimism about

the future makes less sense when there is more economic inequality which generally translates into

inequality of opportunities especially in areas such as education and the labour market Second

the distribution of resources and opportunities plays a key role in establishing the belief that people

share a common destiny and have similar fundamental values In highly unequal societies people

are likely to stick with their own kind Perceptions of injustice will reinforce negative stereotypes

of other groups making social trust and accommodation more difficult

Uslaner (2002 2011) and Uslaner and Brown (2005) find that high levels of inequality are

the single major factor driving down trust in people who are different from yourself Evidence for

USA finds that inequality is the strongest determinant of generalized trust over time (Rothstein amp

Uslaner 2005) Reducing inequality and then increasing generalized trust should have positive

consequences at the individual and aggregates levels At the individual level it may lead to greater

tolerance and more acts of altruism for people of different backgrounds At the aggregate level it

may lead to greater economic growth more redistribution from the rich to the poor and less

corruption (Uslaner 2002 2013) Letki (2008) argues that when neighbourhood socio-economic

context (apart from just an individualrsquos socioeconomic status) is considered it turns out to be the

main factor triggering negative attitudes and lack of trust in out-group members

The increasing diversity caused by immigration can also reduce the conditions necessary for

social cohesion (Ariely 2014 Holtug amp Mason 2010) Christel Kesler and Irene Bloemraad

(2010) find for nineteen advanced democracies between 1981 and 2000 that increasing migration

97

generally decreases trust civic engagement and political participation The authors also find that

in more equal countries with clear policies in favour of cultural minorities the negative effects of

migration are mitigated or even reversed Letki (2008) states that deprivation and disorder tend to

be strongly correlated with racial diversity Because we propose the use of the number of disorders

or antisocial behaviours known as ldquoincivilitiesrdquo as our measure of social cohesion we describe the

literature on incivilities in the next section

422 The literature on incivilities

The study of incivilities has been a continuing concern mainly for developed countries since

the 1980s The focus has changed from individual and psychological explanations to ecological

(contextual) and social explanations (Taylor 1999) The individual approach basically considered

perceptions of incivilities as an explanatory variable of fear of crime The ecological explanation

argues that indicators of economic disadvantage (eg income levels income inequality

unemployment rate and poverty rate) are the keys to understand a process of social disorganization

and lack of informal control These economic factors lead to higher rates of inappropriate or

negligent behaviours and ultimately to higher crime rates (Blau amp Blau 1982 Messner Rosenfeld

amp Baumer 2004 Phan Orsquobrien Mendolia amp Paloyo 2017 Sampson 1986)

The negative impact of incivilities is not merely reflected in its association with crime rates

(Skogan 2015) Physical and social incivilities could worsen neighbourhoods by affecting quality

of life perception of the environment and public and private behaviours Previous research has

indicated that a higher level of incivilities is associated with health problems (Branas et al 2011

Cohen et al 2000 Hill amp Angel 2005 Ross 2011 Ross amp Mirowsky 2001) greater

victimization and fear of crime (Brunton-Smith Jackson amp Sutherland 2014 Mijanovich amp

Weitzman 2003) and multiple negative economic effects For instance incivilities could be

98

related to a reduction in commercial activity lower investment in real estate reduction in house

prices (Skogan 2015) and population instability (Hipp 2010)

To describe the state of the art in the study of incivilities and their consequences Skogan

(2015) used the concept of untidiness to characterize the research on incivilities The study of

incivilities has had multiple approaches (economic ecological and psychological) Incivilities

have also been measured using multiple sources of information (police reports surveys trained

observation) which result in different measures (perceptions vs count data) However the question

about what specific factors have the strongest effect on incivilities has been overlooked and

perceptions about incivilities have been used mainly as a predictor of crime fear of crime and

victimization

There are two types of incivilities social and physical Social incivilities are a matter of

behaviour including groups of rowdy teens public drunkenness people fighting and street hassles

Physical incivilities involve visual signs of negligence and decay such as abandoned buildings

broken streetlights trash-filled lots and graffiti (Skogan 1999 2015 Taylor 1999) Three reasons

justify the distinction between physical and social incivilities First like multiple dimensions of

social cohesion different structural and social conditions could be responsible for different types

and categories of incivilities Second punitive sanctions are expected to have a greater impact on

physical than on social incivilities since the latter are more related to behaviours rooted in citizensrsquo

culture Third physical incivilities should be more related to absolute measures of economic

disadvantage (eg poverty or unemployment rates) and social incivilities to relative indicators of

economic disadvantage (eg such as income inequality) This line of research is based on the

ldquoincivilities thesisrdquo which states that to understand the distribution of disorders it is necesary to

analyse the patterns of structured inequalities (Skogan 1986 Taylor 1999)

99

423 The ldquoIncivilities Thesisrdquo

Incivilities theories began with a focus on psychological dynamics (Garofalo 1978) moved

forward to an interest in social psychological processes (J Q Wilson amp Kelling 1982) and finally

evolved into a focus on community dynamics and outcomes (Skogan 1999) Individual and group

behaviours in tandem with ecological features have been proposed as the key factors explaining

incivilities and their posterior influence on social control quality of life and more serious crime

(J Q Wilson amp Kelling 1982)

In terms of ecological factors particularly those related to economic conditions Skogan

(1986) was the first linking the distribution of incivilities to the patterns of structural inequality If

incivilities mirror inequality structure this will have consequences in residentsrsquo health and safety

due to its levels of vulnerability In addition structured inequality associated with the proportion

of the manufacturing sector (eg when fabrics tend to move from cities to farther areas) will be

related to higher social disorganization and differences between urban and rural areas (W J

Wilson 1996) In addition a persistent feeling of relative deprivation (persistently high levels of

income inequality) could lead to fellow inhabitants of the community to commit antisocial

behaviours showing their frustration with the current economic model

The literature on incivilities posits that their causes are different from those of crime (Lewis

2017) Unlike crime analysis especially property crimes information on the location where the

incivility takes place is the same as the location where the perpetrator resides To achieve a

comprehensive understanding of the different types of incivilities it is crucial to consider

incivilities data covering an entire territory and not just specific areas (Hooghe Vanhoutte

Hardyns amp Bircan 2010) If we add to this the availability of panel data it could be possible not

100

only to identify the main determinants of incivilities but also the causal mechanism from income

inequality towards incivilities rate

In Chile citizen security crime and delinquency are among the most significant issues for

citizens based on opinion polls Existing research has found weak evidence of a significant

relationship between crime and indicators of socio-economic disadvantage such as income

inequality and unemployment rate with significant effects only on property crime (Beyer amp

Vergara 2006 Nuntildeez Rivera Villavicencio amp Molina 2003 Rivera Gutieacuterrez amp Nuacutentildeez 2009)

Crime deterrence variables such as the probability of being caught or the number of police

resources have also shown ambiguous results (Beyer amp Vergara 2006 Rivera et al 2009

Vergara 2012) Evidence at the county level shows that crime is higher in urban counties those

with a lower mean income per capita and counties located in the North of the country In addition

at least half of the crimes reported in one county are perpetrated by criminals from other counties

(Rivera et al 2009) No studies could be found about the determinants of incivilities

4 3 Methodology

431 Period of analysis and data sample

Chile is a relatively small country in Latin America with a population of 18346018

inhabitants in 2017 The country is divided into 345 municipalities with on average 53104

inhabitants (median value 18705) Municipalities are the organ of the State Administration

responsible to solve local needs Municipalities are not only the relevant political and

administrative local unit of analysis but also they represent the feeling of lsquocommunityrsquo among

the inhabitants of each municipality (Hooghe et al 2010) Our data includes many sources of

101

heterogeneity among municipalities such as indicators of economic deprivation population

density demographic characteristics and whether the county is a regional or provincial capital

We use a sample of 324 municipalities covering most of the Chilean territory for the period

2006ndash17 Data on incivilities is obtained from the ldquoCentre of Studies and Analysis of Crimerdquo

which is part of the ldquoSubsecretaria de Prevencion del Delitordquo (SPD in its Spanish acronym) of the

Chilean government32 Information on income inequality and control variables is obtained from

the ldquoNational Socioeconomic Characterization Surveyrdquo (CASEN in its Spanish acronym) the

ldquoNational Institute of Statisticsrdquo (INE in its Spanish acronym) the ldquoNational Municipal

Information Systemrdquo (SINIM in its Spanish acronym) and the Immigration Department of the

Government of Chile Our panel only includes the years for which CASEN survey is available

2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017

432 Operationalisation of the response variable and exploratory analysis

Official Chilean records contain information for the total number of cases of incivilities per

year at the county level The number of cases is the sum of complains and detentions reported at

the police Our dependent variable 119894119899119888119894119907119894119897119894119905119894119890119904 correspond to the number of cases per year Due

to population differences comparisons between counties are made using the incivilities rate per

1000 population calculated as

119894119899119888119894119907_119903119886119905119890 lowast 1000 (41)

where 119894119899119888119894119907_119903119886119905119890 is the incivilities rate 119905 is the year 119894 the county and 119899 is the population of the

county per year

32 httpceadspdgovclestadisticas-delictuales

102

Figure 41 illustrates at the top the evolution of the total number (cases reported) of

incivilities and crimes at the country level for the period 2006-1733 At the bottom Figure 41

shows the evolution of the mean county rate per 1000 inhabitants We observe that both the number

of incivilities and the number of crimes has reached similar annual figures however average

county rates per 1000 population show different trends Crime rate displays a sustained fall after

reaching its pick in 2011 Incivilities average county rate which also reached a pick and posterior

drop in 2011 has recovered its upward trend since 2016 considerably exceeding the crime rate

Figure 41 Evolution number and rates of incivilities and crime (DMCS) in Chile 2006-2017

33 Crime refers to ldquocrimes of greater social connotationrdquo (DMCS in its Spanish acronym) which includes violent and property crimes

103

Chilean records classify incivilities in nine categories most of them associated with social

incivilities Summary statistics for the total and for each of the nine categories are presented in

Table 41 In addition Figure 42 shows the evolution of incivilities by category for the whole

period We see that the global trend in incivilities is mainly due to a substantial increase in ldquoStreet

Tradingrdquo and ldquoPublic Alcohol Consumptionrdquo A common element of Figures 41 and 42 is the

significant change in trend experienced by crimes and incivilities in 2011 That year the SPD

became dependent on the Ministry of Interior of the Chilean Government This event put the issue

of crime and delinquency within national priorities for the central government

Table 41

Summary statistics total count of incivilities and by category (full sample and period)

Unlike crime rates we do not expect significant cross-county spillover effects in incivilities

However the questions of where incivilities are concentrated and why they are there can be of

great interest (Skogan 2015) Figure 43 shows quantile maps for the rate of incivilities per 1000

inhabitants for the initial and final years in our panel

104

Figure 42 Evolution total number of incivilities by category

Figure 43 Spatial distribution of incivilities rate per 1000 inhabitants (2006 vs 2017)

105

We observe that the range of values has increased significantly from 2006 to 2017 but the

spatial distribution remains almost unchanged On the one hand high incivilities rates in the North

could be associated with the mining activity On the other hand high rates in the Centre area

(where the countyrsquos capital is located) could be related to the higher population density and the

concentration of the economic activity34

To see how the different types of incivilities are distributed throughout the country we have

grouped those similar categories in four groups ldquoPublic Damagerdquo (ldquoPublic Disturbsrdquo ldquoPublic

Damagerdquo ldquoOtherrdquo) ldquoThreatsrdquo (ldquoPublic Fightrdquo ldquoThreatsrdquo and ldquoAnnoying Noisesrdquo) ldquoAlcohol

Consumptionrdquo (ldquoPublic Alcohol Consumptionrdquo and ldquoDrunkennessrdquo) and ldquoStreet Tradingrdquo This

distinction in groups could be relevant if we expect different patterns and different effects of

community heterogeneity on social cohesion among counties For instance we expect higher

levels of Public Damage in big urban cities Street trading is more likely in urban cities but also in

tourist areas The spatial distribution of these four groups for the six-year-average rate per 1000

inhabitants can be found in Appendix R

433 Measures of community heterogeneity and control variables

Social cohesion income inequality and racial diversity are all ldquocommunityrdquo (not individual)

characteristics Thus to understand their relationship we need aggregated data at least at the

county-municipal level With more disaggregated data like at the suburbs level the required

heterogeneity among groups of citizens is lost (Wilkinson 1999) Like Coffeacute and Geys (2006) we

use the Gini coefficient to capture economic heterogeneity However instead of a measured for

34 We also analysed the spatial distribution of crime rates In general areas with high levels of incivilities not necessarily are associated with high levels of crime This could imply that factors explaining incivilities and crime are different

106

the diversity of nationalities we use the proportion of foreign population to capture racial

heterogeneity Income data is obtained from the CASEN survey The Gini coefficient is calculated

for each county and included through the variable gini Racial heterogeneity is included through

the variable foreign which is the annual number of new VISAS granted to foreigners as a

proportion of the county population Chile has experienced a significant increase in immigration

since 2011 Immigration has been concentrated in the metropolitan region and mining regions in

the North of the country We expect a positive relationship between immigration and incivilities

although as with the relationship between immigration and crime the foundations for this

hypothesis are not strong (Hooghe et al 2010 Sampson 2008)

Economic development is another explanation for social cohesion frequently appealed to

explain trust with wealthier societies considered to exhibit higher levels of trust (Delhey amp

Newton 2005) In this study we include the natural log of the mean household income per capita

log(income) We also include the poverty rate poverty and the unemployment rate

unemployment Unlike the variable log(income) these variables are expected to be positively

associated with the number of incivilities When a relative indicator of economic heterogeneity

such as income inequality is included as determinant of social cohesion we should expect less

effect from absolute indicators of economic disadvantage such as poverty and unemployment rates

(Hooghe et al 2010 Tolsma et al 2009)

Among demographic variables the percentage of inhabitants between 10 and 24 years old is

included through the variable youth The variable women defined as the proportion of the female

population in each county is also included Variable youth is expected to have an ambiguous effect

Although young people have lower victimization and report rates they also represent the group

more likely to commit antisocial behaviours when a community has a low capacity of self-

107

regulation (eg when there is low parental supervision) The female population is associated with

a higher report of incivilities related to the male population

It is argued that crime and incivilities are essentially urban problems (Christiansen 1960

Wirth 1938) We include the variable log(density) defined as the log of population density (the

number of inhabitants divided by the area of each county in square kilometres) and a dummy

variable capital indicating whether a county is an administrative capital (provincial or regional)

Two additional variables are included to capture the level of informal social control exerted

by families living in each municipality First the variable education which is defined as the

average years of education of people over 15 years old Second the variable housing which capture

the proportion of families which are owners of their housing unit Although education and housing

are related to both the possibility of reporting and committing an incivility we expect a negative

association with the rate of incivilities

In Chile crime has been mainly a problem faced by the police and the Central Government

Administration To control for current law enforcement policies we include the variable

deterrence defined as the number of arrests as a proportion of the total number of incivilities cases

In addition municipalities can develop their own initiatives to deal with crime and incivilities

depending on their capacity to generate its own resources The level of financial autonomy from

central transfers is captured by the variable autonomy This variable is obtained from SINIM and

it is defined as the proportion of the budget revenue of each municipality that comes from its own

permanent sources of revenues A categorical variable mayor is also included This variable

indicates whether the municipality mayor is supported by the ldquoLEFTrdquo or the ldquoRIGHTrdquo political

parties (related to those ldquoINDEPENDENTrdquo mayors)

108

Table 42 presents descriptive statistics for our measures of income and racial heterogeneity

and the set of numeric control variables The Pearson correlation among these variables is shown

in Appendix S

Table 42

Summary statistics numeric explanatory variables

434 Methods

The annual count of incivilities as is characteristic for count data is highly concentrated in

a relatively small range of values In addition the distribution is right-skewed due to the presence

of important outliers (counties with a high number of incivilities) Figure 44 shows the

distribution of the six-year average number of incivilities for each of the 15 regions in Chile35 We

observe that regions differ in the number of counties in which they are divided In addition

counties within each region show important differences in the number of incivilities For instance

35 Regions are ordered from left to right and from top to bottom in the way they are geographically distributed from North to South So the northernmost region of the country is the ldquoXVrdquo and the southernmost region is the ldquoXIIrdquo The Metropolitan region (where the countryrsquos capital is located) is region ldquoXIIIrdquo in the centre of the country (see Appendix C)

109

excepting the Metropolitan region ldquoXIIIrdquo most counties in regions located in the centre of the

country (middle row in Figure 44) show a range of incivilities between 0 and 2000 The number

of incivilities is considerably lower in counties located in the northern (top row in Figure 44) and

southern (bottom row in Figure 44) regions of the country compared to regions in the centre of

the country It also seems clear from Figure 44 that the number of incivilities does not follow a

normal distribution

Figure 44 Annual average number of incivilities per county

The number of incivilities can be better described by a Poisson distribution In this case the

number of incivilities is ldquothe countrdquo and the number of incivilities per year is ldquothe rate per unit

timerdquo We are interested in modelling the average number of incivilities per year usually called 120582

as a function of a set of contextual factors to explain differences in incivilities between and within

110

counties The main characteristic of the Poisson distribution is that the mean is equal to the

variance This implies that as the mean rate for a Poisson variable increases the variance also

increases The main implication is we cannot use OLS to model 120582 as a function of the set of

contextual factors because the equal variance assumption in linear regression is violated

The rate of incivilities between counties is not directly comparable due to population

differences We expect counties with more people to have more reports of incivilities since there

are more people who could be affected To capture differences in population which is called the

exposure of our response variable 120582 it is necessary to include a term on the right side of our model

called an offset We will use the log of the county population in thousands as our offset36

Additionally similar to the case of crime data incivilities show a significant degree of

overdispersion (variance higher than the mean) suggesting that there is more variation in the

response than the Poisson model implies37 We also model and regress incivilities assuming a

Negative Binomial distribution to address overdispersion An advantage of this approach is that it

introduces a dispersion parameter in addition to 120582 which gives the model more flexibility38

Considering as the response variable the count of incivilities per year the model can be

expressed as follow

120582 119890119909119901 120573 120573 119892119894119899119894 120573 119891119900119903119890119894119892119899 119883120574 120572 120579 (42)

36 If we think of 120582 as the average number of incivilities per year then represents the number per 1000

inhabitants so that the yearly count is adjusted to be comparable across counties of different sizes Adjusting the yearly count by population is equivalent to adding 119897119900119892 1199011199001199011199061198971198861199051198941199001198991000 to the right-hand side of the regression equation 37 Without adjusting for overdispersion we use incorrect artificially small standard errors leading to artificially small p-values for model coefficients 38 The Negative Binomial model posits selecting a 120582 (average number of incivilities) for each county and then generating a count using a Poisson random variable with the selected 120582 With this approach the counts will be more dispersed than would be expected for observations based on a single Poisson variable with rate 120582

111

where 120582 is the rate of incivilities 119883 is our vector of controls 120572prime119904 are county-specific constants

and 120579prime119904 are time-specific constants Accounting for differences in county population we have

119890119909119901 120573 120573 119892119894119899119894 119883120574 120572 120579 (43)

where 119901119900119901119906119897119886119905119894119900119899 is the county population per year Hence the model to be estimated using

Maximum Likelihood Estimation (MLE) is

119897119900119892 120582 120573 120573 119892119894119899119894 119883120574 120572 120579 119897119900119892 (44)

Finally to account for different effects depending on the type of incivilities we also run

equation (44) for each of the four groups of incivilities defined in section (432)

435 Hypotheses

Based on the community heterogeneity hypothesis the relationship between social cohesion

and diversity should be stronger for lower levels of income and less educated groups of people

(Tolsma et al 2009) Hence contrary to evidence for developed and more equal countries we

expect a significant positive association for the Chilean case where more than 50 of the

population is economically vulnerable (OECD 2017)

The main hypotheses to be tested in this essay is whether the number of incivilities is

positively associated with the level of economic and racial heterogeneity at the county level We

start analysing this association for the full sample and period Next we analyse whether the

relationship between incivilities and our measures of diversity differs by geographic area (region

or zone) Finally we check whether the effect of economic and racial diversity is different

depending on the group of incivilities

112

44 Results and Discussion

Overall our results show that the rate of incivilities displays a stronger and more significant

relationship with racial diversity than with economic heterogeneity This association differs for

different geographic areas and for different types of incivilities Absolute economic indicators

except for income show a significant but small effect Increases in the average levels of income

or education and more financial autonomy for municipalities seem to be effective ways to reduce

the rate of incivilities

We estimate equation (44) assuming that the number of incivilities follows a Poisson

distribution Regional and temporal heterogeneity are captured through the inclusion of dummy

variables for five years (with 2006 as the reference year) and fourteen regional dummies (with

region XIII as the reference region) Results are reported in Table 4339 This table is structured in

two blocks of regressions pooled models in columns (1)-(4) and fixed-effects models in columns

(5)-(8)40 The first column in each block only includes economic indicators relative and absolute

trying to test which ones are more relevant and whether incivilities tend to mirror income

inequality (the ldquoincivilities thesisrdquo) The second column adds the variable foreign to account for

the effect of racial diversity (Letki 2008) The third column includes education to check whether

the association between economic and racial diversity with social cohesion changes (gets less

significant) when we control for educational level (Tolsma et al 2009) The final column in each

block corresponds to the full model specification which includes the rest of controls

39 Pooled estimations were obtained using the R command glm() and compared with results obtained from the command poisson in STATA 15 Fixed effects and random effects models were estimated using the STATA command xtpoisson Negative Binomial models were estimated using the command glmnb() in the MASS package for R and commands nbreg and xtnbreg in STATA 15 Results for Negative Binomial regressions are in Appendix T 40 We have omitted results with random effects due to the literature on panel count data models suggest that the most robust estimator is Poisson regression with Fixed Effects (Santos Silva amp Tenreyro 2010 2011)

113

Table 43

Poisson regressions

114

The positive and significant coefficient for the variable gini besides being small it becomes

insignificant in the fixed effects specification which includes the full set of controls This result

does not seem to be enough evidence to support our hypothesis that more unequal counties display

higher rates of incivilities On the other hand racial diversity through the variable foreign shows

a consistent positive association with the rate of incivilities41 Together coefficients for gini and

foreign seems to support the ldquocommunity heterogeneity thesisrdquo (Letki 2008) but not the

ldquoincivilities thesisrdquo (Skogan 1999) To check this finding we run the pooled full model

specification for each region and results are shown in Table 44 where regions have been ordered

from North to South The sign of the coefficient of the variable gini differs for different regions

Moreover the relationship is insignificant in some of the most unequal regions which are in the

South of the country (VIII IX and XIV) This result rejects the hypothesis that incivilities mirror

structural income inequalities For the variable foreign 12 out of 15 regions confirm the positive

association with the rate of incivilities42

We also run our pooled full model separately for each group of incivilities defined at the end

of section (432) Income inequality keeps its significant but small association with each group of

incivilities (see Table 45) Our measure of racial diversity shows a stronger association with

ldquoAlcohol Consumptionrdquo related to ldquoPublic Damagerdquo and ldquoThreatsrdquo The link with ldquoStreet Tradingrdquo

appears as non-significant These results support our general finding that on the one hand racial

heterogeneity exert a more significant influence on the rate of incivilities than economic

41 To get the effects of the variables gini and foreign over the rate of incivilities per 1000 inhabitants we need to exponentiate their coefficients Thus an increase in one unit in the variable gini increases the rate of incivilities per 1000 inhabitantsrdquo in 1005 times (e^0005) in the pooled full model Similarly an increase in one point in variable foreign is expected to increase the ldquorate of incivilities per 1000 inhabitantsrdquo in 10876 times (e^0084) in the full pooled model and 10471 (e^0046) times in the full Fixed Effects model 42 Given that depending on the geographic location regions share certain characteristics the model was also run clustering regions in 4 zones (see Figure 31 in chapter 3) Results by zone are in Appendix U

115

heterogeneity On the other hand results confirm our hypothesis that the effect of diversity is

different for different types of incivilities

Table 44 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson models by region

Back to our general results in Table 43 the significant and negative coefficient of the

income variable and to a lesser extent the significant and positive coefficients of poverty and

unemployment provide evidence that absolute rather than relative economic indicators may be

more important explanations of the rate of incivilities This is opposite to evidence for the analysis

116

of crime rates such as in Hoodge (2010) and support the idea that determinants of incivilities are

different from those of crime Our results are also opposite to those for Dutch municipalities where

economic indicators turned out to be more important than ethnic heterogeneity (Tolsma et al

2009) The coefficient for the variable log(income) could be interpreted as counties with an income

level under the average face higher problems of antisocial behaviours such as incivilities In

addition as the income level moves far away from its average low level the problem of incivilities

is less relevant43 In terms of policy implications only those policies that achieve a significant

increase in the average level of county income seem to be effective in reducing incivilities and

strengthening social cohesion

Table 45 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson model by incivility group

43 We ran our model splitting the sample of counties in quintiles based on their income level The coefficient for the variable gini only showed a significant (and positive) coefficient for the second third and fourth quintile A non-significant coefficient for the first quintile could imply that other types of inequalities (eg health education) are more relevant in the poorest counties In the case of the fifth quintile (the richest group of counties) they have better facilities in terms of infrastructure police resources self-protection etc which could reduce the potential triggers of incivilities

117

The inclusion of the variable education significantly improved the goodness of fit of the

models and did not generate significant changes in the coefficients of our measures of economic

and racial diversity This result rejects the proposition that the relationship between social

cohesion and diversity becomes less strong when controlled by education (Tolsma et al 2009)

Additionally it highlights the topic of education as a relevant determinant of the rate of incivilities

and social cohesion

Among control variables there are also some important results Opposite to what we

expected the variable youth shows a negative or non-significant coefficient Although this result

could be due to the lack of ldquophysical incivilitiesrdquo in Chilean records it indicates that it is incorrect

to stereotype this group as the main responsible for high incivilities rates The significant and

negative coefficient of the variable autonomy in the fixed effects specification could also have

important policy implications It is a signal that local governments can play an important role in

reducing incivilities or complementing the efforts from the central government Another

interesting result is the significant coefficient of the variable housing The latter finding is

particularly important in the sense that a negative sign supports public policies oriented to increase

homeownership as effective ways to improve social cohesion However the small magnitude of

the coefficient that even showed the opposite sign in some model specifications could be

explained for the high level of segregation that these policies have generated in Chilean society

As mentioned in the Introduction and Literature Review so far only a few studies have

used measures of disorders or incivilities as dependent variable to explain changes in social

cohesion (Skogan 2015) In addition there is no evidence in Chile analysing the determinants of

incivilities separately from those of crimes The importance of our results on identifying the

importance of economic and racial diversity on social cohesion lies mainly in its generality An

118

important number of countries all around the world share a similar context characterized by high

levels of inequality and an explosive increase in immigration These countries are also

experiencing a worsening in social cohesion which increases the risk of a social outburst

4 5 Conclusions

The main goal of this essay was to determine whether differences in incivilities at the county

level mirror differences in income distribution and racial diversity Previous literature suggests a

positive and strong association between social cohesion and indicators of economic disadvantage

relative deprivation and racial diversity (Letki 2008 Tolsma et al 2009 Uslaner amp Brown 2005)

While not all our results were significant they showed helpful insights about how and where

economic and racial diversity are more likely to influence the rate of incivilities and social

cohesion

We used data for the period 2006ndash17 economic heterogeneity was measured through the

Gini coefficient at the county level and racial heterogeneity was proxied by the number of granted

visas to foreigners as proportion of county population We found strong evidence of a significant

and positive association between the rate of incivilities and racial diversity but not with income

inequality Contrary to previous evidence at the municipal level (Coffeacute amp Geys 2006 Tolsma et

al 2009) in general our results give support for the ldquohomophily principlerdquo and the ldquocommunity

heterogeneity hypothesisrdquo However results also showed that the effect of economic and racial

diversity varies throughout the Chilean regions and for the different types of incivilities

We also found that policies aimed at controlling the behaviour of young people did not have

strong empirical support In terms of the role that local governments may have in facing the

119

growing problem of incivilities we found evidence that efforts managed from the municipalities

can be an important complement to those from the central government

Future research should go further on the role of local authorities on incivilities and social

cohesion On the one hand municipalities could have a direct impact on social cohesion through

the implementation of programs complementary to those of central authorities oriented to reduce

incivilities and crime On the other hand social cohesion could be indirectly affected when local

authorities display an inefficient performance supplying public services to citizens or they are

recognized as corrupted institutions We suggest that policy makers from central government

should give local authorities a greater role in fighting antisocial behaviours and crime Evaluating

programs in specific municipalities could help to elucidate the causal effect of for instance higher

fiscal autonomy on the rate of incivilities

Another interesting area for future work will be to analyse how housing policies have

contributed to the phenomenon of segregation of Chilean society and in the process of weakening

social cohesion Finally our main result highlights the need of a deeper analysis of the impact that

foreign immigration is having in Chile For instance disaggregating information by country of

origin and the reasons why immigrants are arriving to the country or specific regions will surely

help to understand the impacts of immigration

120

Chapter 5 Conclusions

This thesis investigated in three essays the issue of income inequality in Chile using county-

level data for the period 2006-2017 The first essay supplied empirical evidence about the

importance of the degree of dependence on natural resources in terms of employment in explaining

cross-county differences in income inequality The second essay analysed the potential causal

effect that income inequality has on the level of technical efficiency of local governments

providing public goods and services Lastly the third essay studied the relationship between social

cohesion measured through the number of antisocial behaviours classified as ldquoincivilitiesrdquo and

the levels of income and racial heterogeneity

Findings from the first essay support the idea that the endowment of natural resources plays

a significant role in explaining income inequality in Chile However contrary to what most

theoretical and empirical evidence postulates our findings showed a robust negative association

between the two variables This means that the reduction experienced in Chile in the degree of

dependence on natural resources in terms of employment has contributed to the persistence of high

levels of income inequality The exploratory analysis indicated that income inequality shows a

general clustering process characterized by a significant and positive spatial autocorrelation

Regarding the previous evidence for Chile (Paredes et al 2016) the regression analysis confirmed

the relevance of the spatial dimension of income inequality through a process of spatial

heterogeneity giving less support to the existence of a process of spatial dependence (spillover

effect) in the variable itself

121

Essay 2 studied the potential trade-off between efficiency and equity analysing the influence

of income inequality on the efficiency of local governments at the municipal level To identify the

causal effect of income inequality on municipal efficiency we proposed the use of the proportion

of firms in the primary sector as an instrument for income inequality Findings confirmed our

hypothesis that efficiency is lower in more unequal counties This result suggests the non-existence

of the trade-off between equity and efficiency Hence policies intended to reduce inequality could

help to increase efficiency at least at the level of municipal local governments

The third essay analysed how social cohesion proxied by the rate of incivilities is associated

with the levels of economic diversity proxied by income inequality and the levels of racial

diversity proxied by the number of new visas grated as proportion of the county population

Findings gave strong support to the hypothesis that the rate of incivilities is positively related to

racial diversity and to a lesser extent to economic diversity In addition the rate of incivilities

appears negatively related to the degree of financial autonomy of municipalities This means that

local governments can effectively contribute to the reduction of incivilities which could help

reduce victimization and crime rates ultimately strengthening social cohesion

Taken together findings from essays 2 and 3 highlight the important role that income

inequality could play in other relevant economic and social dimensions These findings add to the

understanding of the potential consequences of income inequality particularly in natural resource

rich countries with persistently high levels of inequality

The present study has mainly investigated income inequality at the county level In addition

Chilean municipalities play an important role providing ldquoservices to peoplerdquo so our findings could

be applied in other highly unequal countries with a high degree of dependence on natural resources

and local governments with similar responsibilities For instance in Latin America apart from

122

Chile and Brazil there are no studies on the efficiency of local governments Other limitations are

associated with the availability of information For instance important indicators such as GDP per

capita are only available at the regional level and information of incomes is not available annually

In addition given the heterogeneity among municipalities some type of grouping of municipalities

should be performed before looking for causal relationships or conducting program evaluation

Despite these limitations we believe this study could be the basis for different strands of future

research on the topic of inequality local government efficiency and social cohesion

It was stated in chapter 2 based on the resource curse hypothesis literature there are two

elements that determine whether NR are a curse or blessing in terms of socioeconomic outcomes

First the curse is more likely in countries with weak political and governance institutions Second

different types of resources affect institutions differently with resources that are concentrated in

space so-called ldquopointrdquo resources tend to impair institutions while ldquodiffuserdquo resources do not

(Deacon 2011 Isham Woolcock Pritchett amp Busby 2005) Our results showed a negative

relationship between income inequality and our measure of natural resource dependence even after

controlling for zone fixed effects and for the level of government expenditure This result could

be interpreted as a signal that NR has a direct effect on income inequality in addition to the indirect

impact through market or institutional channels Using other potential institutional transmission

channels will shed light about the true effect that the endowment of natural resources has over

income inequality Variables that could capture these institutional channels include the level of

employment in the public sector measures of rule of law and corruption and changes in the

creation of new business in the secondary and tertiary sectors related to the primary sector

Based on results from chapter 3 most of the municipalities show scale inefficiencies One

immediate area for future work will involve using our set of contextual factors to predict the status

123

of municipalities in terms of scale inefficiencies Defining as dependent variable whether a

municipality shows constant decreasing or increasing returns to scale we could run a multinomial

logistic regression to predict municipal status For instance we would expect that a one-unit

increase in the Gini coefficient should increase the probability of scale inefficiencies (increasing

or decreasing returns to scale rather than constant returns to scale) Because the aim in this case

would be predicting a certain result in terms of returns to scale the next step should involve to

split the full sample in training and testing data sets and to use some resampling methods such as

bootstrapping This will allow us to evaluate the performance and accuracy of our model

predictions using different random samples of municipalities Results from Machine Learning

algorithms will help us to assess the generalizability of our results to other data sets

Future work should also benefit greatly by using data on different Latin American countries

to (1) compare the responsibilities of local governments (2) select a common set of inputs and

output to evaluate LGE (3) identify the relevance of scales inefficiencies in explaining differences

in performance and (4) analyse the influence of contextual characteristics over LGE Differences

in the main primary sector activity in each country such as oil in Brazil mining in Chile or Coffee

in Colombia could be responsible for differences in LGE among countries These differences could

be associated with sources of revenue management of expenditure and definitions of outputs or

contextual effects such as corrupted institutions or the delay in the development of other sectors

such as manufacturing or services

To delve deep on reasons explaining the social crisis experienced by Chilean society and

other countries one area of future work will be to analyse the relationship between diversity and

the origins of social revolutions Based on Tiruneh (2014) the three most important factors that

explain the onset of social revolutions are economic development regime type and state

124

ineffectiveness Interesting questions include whether the characteristics of Chilean context at the

end of 2019 are enough to trigger the transformation of the political and socioeconomic system

Social revolutions particularly violent revolutions are less likely in more democratic educated

and wealthy societies So it would be relevant to identify the factors explaining the violence that

has characterized the social crisis in Chile Finally the democratic regime has been maintained in

the last decades with changes between left and right governments This could imply that more

important than the regime has been the efficiency or ineffectiveness of the governments to satisfy

the needs of the population

Future work should also cover the disaggregation of information regarding foreign

population in terms of the reasons for new granted visas and the country of origin Official data

allows us to disaggregate whether the benefit is permanent (students and employees with contract)

or temporary Furthermore most of the new visas were traditionally granted to neighbouring

countries (Peru and Bolivia) a trend that has changed in the recent years to include countries such

as Colombia Venezuela and Haiti An analysis of how economic and social indicators have been

affected by changes in the composition of foreigners their reasons for immigrating to the country

and their geographical distribution have implications for economic policy at both the national and

local levels At the national level such analysis should be a key input when proposing changes to

the national immigration policy At the local level it could help define the role of municipalities

to assess the benefits and challenges of immigration These challenges are mainly related to the

provision of public goods and services such as health and education which in Chile are the

responsibility of the municipalities

The findings of this thesis suggest that policymakers should encourage policies that reduce

income inequality The key role that municipalities could play to strengthen social cohesion and

125

the increasingly important role that foreign population is acquiring in most modern societies are

also interesting avenues for future research However the picture is still incomplete and more

research is needed incorporating other dimensions of inequality This is essential if we want to

understand the reasons that could have triggered the social outbursts experienced by various

economies across the globe

126

Bibliography

Acemoglu D (1995) Reward structures and the allocation of talent European Economic Review 39(1) 17ndash33 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg1010160014-2921(94)00014-Q

Acemoglu D (2002) Technical Change Inequality and the Labor Market Journal of Economic Literature 40(1) 7ndash72 httpsdoiorg1012570022051026976

Acemoglu D Aghion P amp Violante G L (2001) Deunionization Technical Change and Inequality Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 55(1) 229ndash264 httpsdoiorg101016S0167-2231(01)00058-6

Acemoglu D Johnson S amp Robinson J A (2001) The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development An Empirical Investigation The American Economic Review 91(5) 1369ndash1401 httpsdoiorg101257aer9151369

Acemoglu D amp Robinson J A (2002) The Political Economy of the Kuznets Curve Review of Development Economics 6(2) 183ndash203 httpsdoiorg1011111467-936100149

Afonso A amp Fernandes S (2006) Measuring local government spending efficiency Evidence for the Lisbon region Regional Studies 40(1) 39ndash53 httpsdoiorg10108000343400500449937

Afonso A amp Fernandes S (2008) Assessing and explaining the relative efficiency of local government The Journal of Socio-Economics 37(5) 1946ndash1979 httpsdoiorg101016jsocec200703007

Afonso A Schuknecht L amp Tanzi V (2010) Income distribution determinants and public spending efficiency Journal of Economic Inequality 8(3) 367ndash389 httpsdoiorg101007s10888-010-9138-z

Akita T (2003) Decomposing regional income inequality in China and Indonesia using two-stage nested Theil decomposition method The Annals of Regional Science 37(1) 55ndash77 httpsdoiorg101007s001680200107

Alesina A (2000) Participation in heterogeneous communities The Quarterly Journal of Economics 115(3) 847ndash904 httpsdoiorg101162003355300554935

Alesina A amp La Ferrara E (2002) Who trusts others Journal of Public Economics 85(2) 207ndash234 httpsdoiorg101016S0047-2727(01)00084-6

Allcott H amp Keniston D (2014) Dutch Disease or Agglomeration The Local Economic Effects of Natural Resource Booms in Modern America (N W P N 20508 Ed) NBER Working Paper No 20508 (Vol w20508) NBER Working Paper No 20508 NBER Working Paper No 20508 httpsdoiorgNBER Working Paper No 20508

Andersen T M amp Maibom J (2020) The big trade-off between efficiency and equitymdashis it there Oxford Economic Papers 72(2) 391ndash411

127

Anselin L (1988) Spatial econometrics methods and models (Vol 4) DordrechtBoston Kluwer Academic Publishers

Anselin L amp Bera A K (1998) Spatial dependence in linear regression models with an introduction to spatial econometrics Statistics Textbooks and Monographs (Vol 155)

Anselin L Bera A K Florax R amp Yoon M J (1996) Simple diagnostic tests for spatial dependence Regional Science and Urban Economics 26(1) 77ndash104 httpsdoiorg1010160166-0462(95)02111-6

Antonelli M A amp De Bonis V (2018) The efficiency of social public expenditure in European countries a two-stage analysis Applied Economics 1ndash14 httpsdoiorg1010800003684620181489522

Aragoacuten F M amp Rud J P (2013) Natural Resources and Local Communities Evidence from a Peruvian Gold Mine American Economic Journal Economic Policy 5(2) 1ndash25 httpsdoiorg101257pol521

Ariely G (2014) Does Diversity Erode Social Cohesion Conceptual and Methodological Issues Political Studies 62(3) 573ndash595 httpsdoiorg1011111467-924812068

Armstrong H amp Taylor J (2000) Regional economics and policy (3rd ed) Oxford Blackwell

Aroca P amp Atienza M (2011) Economic implications of long distance commuting in the Chilean mining industry Resources Policy 36(3) 196ndash203 httpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201103004

Aroca P amp Bosch M (2000) Crecimiento convergencia y espacio en las regiones chilenas 1960 - 1998 Estudios de Economiacutea 27 199ndash224 Retrieved from httprepositoriouchileclbitstreamhandle2250127853Patricio_Arocapdfsequence=1

Ashworth J Geys B Heyndels B amp Wille F (2014) Competition in the political arena and local government performance Applied Economics 46(19) 2264ndash2276 httpsdoiorg101080000368462014899679

Atkinson A B (2015) Inequality What Can Be Done Harvard University Press

Auty R (1993) Sustaining development in mineral economies the resource curse thesis London [ua] Routledge

Auty R (2001) Resource abundance and economic development (R World Institute for Development Economics Ed) Oxford Oxford University Press

Badeeb R A Lean H H amp Clark J (2017) The evolution of the natural resource curse thesis A critical literature survey Resources Policy 51 123ndash134 httpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201610015

Balaguer-Coll M T Brun-Martos M I Maacuterquez-Ramos L amp Prior D (2019) Local government efficiency determinants and spatial interdependence Applied Economics

128

51(14) 1478ndash1494 httpsdoiorg1010800003684620181527458

Balaguer-Coll M T amp Prior D (2009) Short- and long-term evaluation of efficiency and quality An application to Spanish municipalities Applied Economics 41(23) 2991ndash3002 httpsdoiorg10108000036840701351923

Banker R D Charnes A amp Cooper W W (1984) Some models for estimating technical and scale inefficiencies in data envelopment analysis Management Science 30(9) 1078ndash1092

Beine M Coulombe S amp Vermeulen W N (2015) Dutch Disease and the Mitigation Effect of Migration Evidence from Canadian Provinces The Economic Journal 125(589) 1574ndash1615 httpsdoiorg101111ecoj12171

Benito B Bastida F amp Garciacutea J A (2010) Explaining differences in efficiency an application to Spanish municipalities Applied Economics 42(4) 515ndash528 httpsdoiorg10108000036840701675560

Berg A amp Ostry J (2011) Equality and efficiency Finance amp Development 48(3) 12ndash15

Berg A amp Ostry J (2017) Inequality and Unsustainable Growth Two Sides of the Same Coin IMF ECONOMIC REVIEW 65(4) 792ndash815 httpsdoiorg101057s41308-017-0030-8

Beyer H amp Vergara R (2006) Delincuencia en Chile Determinantes y rol de las poliacuteticas puacuteblicas Instituto de Economiacutea UC

Blanco L amp Grier R (2012) Natural resource dependence and the accumulation of physical and human capital in Latin America Resources Policy 37(3) 281ndash295 httpsdoiorghttpdoiorg101016jresourpol201201005

Blau J R amp Blau P M (1982) The cost of inequality Metropolitan structure and violent crime American Sociological Review 114ndash129

Boetti L Piacenza M amp Turati G (2009) Fiscal decentralization and spending efficiency of local governments An Empirical Investigation on a Sample Of 4

Boix C amp Posner D (1998) Social capital Explaining its origins and effects on government performance British Journal Of Political Science 28 686ndash693

Borge L E Parmer P amp Torvik R (2015) Local natural resource curse JOURNAL OF PUBLIC ECONOMICS 131 101ndash114 httpsdoiorg101016jjpubeco201509002

Borger B Kerstens K Moesen W amp Vanneste J (1994) Explaining differences in productive efficiency An application to Belgian municipalities Public Choice 80(3) 339ndash358 httpsdoiorg101007BF01053225

Bourguignon F amp Morrisson C (1990) Income distribution development and foreign trade A cross-sectional analysislowast European Economic Review 34(6) 1113ndash1132 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg1010160014-2921(90)90071-6

129

Branas C C Cheney R A MacDonald J M Tam V W Jackson T D amp Ten Have T R (2011) A difference-in-differences analysis of health safety and greening vacant urban space American Journal of Epidemiology 174(11) 1296ndash1306

Bravo J (2014) Fondo Comuacuten Municipal y su desincentivo a la recaudacioacuten en Chile Temas de La Agenda Legislativa-Centro de Poliacuteticas Puacuteblicas UC 9(68)

Browning E K amp Johnson W R (1984) The Trade-Off between Equality and Efficiency Journal of Political Economy 92(2) 175ndash203 httpsdoiorg101086261219

Brunnschweiler C N amp Bulte E H (2008) The resource curse revisited and revised A tale of paradoxes and red herrings Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 55(3) 248ndash264 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jjeem200708004

Brunori P Ferreira F H G amp Peragine V (2013) Inequality of opportunity income inequality and economic mobility Some international comparisons In Getting Development Right (pp 85ndash115) Springer

Brunton-Smith I Jackson J amp Sutherland A (2014) Bridging structure and perception On the neighbourhood ecology of beliefs and worries about violent crime British Journal of Criminology 54(4) 503ndash526

Bulte E H Damania R amp Deacon R T (2005) Resource intensity institutions and development World Development 33(7) 1029ndash1044 httpsdoiorg101016jworlddev200504004

Carmignani F (2013) Development outcomes resource abundance and the transmission through inequality Resource and Energy Economics 35(3) 412ndash428 httpsdoiorg101016jreseneeco201304007

Carmignani Fabrizio amp Avom D (2010) The social development effects of primary commodity export dependence Ecological Economics 70(2) 317ndash330 httpsdoiorg101016jecolecon201009003

Caselli F amp Michaels G (2013) Do Oil Windfalls Improve Living Standards Evidence from Brazil American Economic Journal Applied Economics 5(1) 208ndash238 httpsdoiorg101257app51208

Celebioglu F amp Dallrsquoerba S (2010) Spatial disparities across the regions of Turkey An exploratory spatial data analysis Annals of Regional Science 45(2) 379ndash400 httpsdoiorg101007s00168-009-0313-8

Chan J To H-P amp Chan E (2006) Reconsidering social cohesion Developing a definition and analytical framework for empirical research Social Indicators Research 75(2) 273ndash302

Charnes A Cooper W W amp Rhodes E (1978) Measuring the efficiency of decision making units European Journal of Operational Research 2(6) 429ndash444

130

Chi G amp Zhu J (2019) Spatial Regression Models for the Social Sciences SAGE Publications Retrieved from httpsbooksgooglecomaubooksid=zHGkvwEACAAJ

Christiansen K O (1960) Industrialization and urbanization in relation to crime and juvenile delinquency International Review of Criminal Policy 16 3ndash8

Cingano F (2014) Trends in income inequality and its impact on economic growth (Vol 163) Paris OECD Publishing httpsdoiorg1017875jxrjncwxv6j-en

Coelli T J Prasada Rao D S OrsquoDonnell C J amp Battese G E (2005) An introduction to efficiency and productivity analysis An Introduction to Efficiency and Productivity Analysis Springer Science amp Business Media httpsdoiorg101007b136381

Coffeacute H amp Geys B (2005) Institutional Performance and Social Capital An Application to the Local Government Level Journal of Urban Affairs 27(5) 485ndash501 httpsdoiorg101111j0735-2166200500249x

Coffeacute H amp Geys B (2006) Community Heterogeneity A Burden for the Creation of Social Capital Social Science Quarterly 87(5) 1053ndash1072 httpsdoiorg101111j1540-6237200600415x

Cohen D Spear S Scribner R Kissinger P Mason K amp Wildgen J (2000) ldquo Broken windowsrdquo and the risk of gonorrhea American Journal of Public Health 90(2) 230

Corden W M amp Neary J P (1982) Booming sector and de-industrialisation in a small open economy The Economic Journal 92(368) 825ndash848

Cordero J M Pedraja-Chaparro F Pisaflores E C amp Polo C (2017) Efficiency assessment of Portuguese municipalities using a conditional nonparametric approach Journal of Productivity Analysis 48(1) 1ndash24 httpsdoiorg101007s11123-017-0500-z

Croissant Y amp Millo G (2018) Panel Data Econometrics with R John Wiley amp Sons

Cust J amp Poelhekke S (2015) The Local Economic Impacts of Natural Resource Extraction 7 251ndash268 httpsdoiorg101146annurev-resource-100814-125106

da Cruz N F amp Marques R C (2014) Revisiting the determinants of local government performance Omega 44 91ndash103 httpsdoiorg101016JOMEGA201309002

Dauvin M amp Guerreiro D (2017) The Paradox of Plenty A Meta-Analysis World Development 94 httpsdoiorg101016jworlddev201701009

de Sousa M da C S Cribari-Neto F amp Stosic B D (2005) Explaining DEA technical efficiency scores in an outlier corrected environment the case of public services in Brazilian municipalities Brazilian Review of Econometrics 25(2) 287ndash313

Deacon R T (2011) The Political Economy of the Natural Resource Curse A Survey of Theory and Evidence Foundations and Trends in Microeconomics 111-208

Delhey J amp Newton K (2005) Predicting cross-national levels of social trust global pattern or

131

Nordic exceptionalism European Sociological Review 21(4) 311ndash327

Dlouhyacute M (2018) Measuring Geographic Inequalities Dealing with Multiple Health Resources by Data Envelopment Analysis Frontiers in Public Health 6 53 httpsdoiorg103389fpubh201800053

Dollery B Wallis J amp Akimov A (2010) One Size Does Not Fit All The Special Case of Remote Small Local Councils in Outback Queensland Local Government Studies 36(1) 21ndash42 httpsdoiorg10108003003930903435716

Domenech J (2008) Mineral resource abundance and regional growth in Spain 1860ndash2000 Journal of International Development The Journal of the Development Studies Association 20(8) 1122ndash1135

Doran J amp Jordan D (2016) Decomposing US regional income inequality from 1969 to 2009 Applied Economics Letters 23(11) 781ndash784 httpsdoiorg1010801350485120151109030

Drew J amp Dollery B (2015) The State of Things The Dynamic Efficiency of Australian State and Territories Economic Papers A Journal of Applied Economics and Policy 34(3) 165ndash176

Drew J Kortt M amp Dollery B (2015) What Determines Efficiency in Local Government A DEA Analysis of NSW Local Government Economic Papers A Journal of Applied Economics and Policy 34(4) 243ndash256 httpsdoiorg1011111759-344112118

Easterly W (2007) Inequality does cause underdevelopment Insights from a new instrument Journal of Development Economics 84(2) 755ndash776 httpsdoiorghttpdxdoiorg101016jjdeveco200611002

Ebert L amp La Menza T (2015) Chile copper and resource revenue A holistic approach to assessing commodity dependence Resources Policy 43(Supplement C) 101ndash111 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201410007

ElGindi T (2017) Natural resource dependency neoliberal globalization and income inequality Are they related A longitudinal study of developing countries (1980ndash2010) Current Sociology 65(1) 21ndash53 httpsdoiorg1011770011392116632031

Engerman S L amp Sokoloff K L (1994) Factor Endowments Institutions and Differential Paths of Growth Among New World Economies National Bureau of Economic Research

Engerman S L amp Sokoloff K L (1997) Factor endowments institutions and differential paths of growth among new world economies How Latin America Fell Behind 260ndash304

Engerman S L Sokoloff K L Urquiola M amp Acemoglu D (2002) Factor Endowments Inequality and Paths of Development among New World Economies [with Comments] EconomampxedA 3(1) 41ndash109 Retrieved from httpwwwjstororgezp01libraryquteduaustable20065432

132

Faumlre R Grosskopf S amp Lovell C A K (1985) The measurement of efficiency of production (Vol 6) Springer Science amp Business Media

Fleming D A amp Measham T G (2015a) Income Inequality across Australian Regions during the Mining Boom 2001-11 Australian Geographer 46(2) 203ndash216 httpsdoiorg1010800004918220151020596

Fleming D A amp Measham T G (2015b) Local economic impacts of an unconventional energy boom the coal seam gas industry in Australia Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 59(1) 78ndash94 httpsdoiorg1011111467-848912043

Fum R M amp Hodler R (2010) Natural resources and income inequality The role of ethnic divisions Economics Letters 107(3) 360ndash363 httpsdoiorg101016jeconlet201003008

Garofalo J (1978) The fear of crime Broadening our perspective

Geys B amp Moesen W (2009) Exploring Sources of Local Government Technical Inefficiency Evidence from Flemish Municipalities Public Finance and Management 9(1) 1ndash29

Goderis B amp Malone S W (2011) Natural Resource Booms and Inequality Theory and Evidence The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 113(2) 388ndash417 httpsdoiorg101111j1467-9442201101659x

Greene W H (2016) Productivity and Efficiency Analysis (W H Greene L Khalaf R Sickles M Veall amp M-C Voia Eds) (1st ed 20) Cham Springer International Publishing httpsdoiorg101007978-3-319-23228-7

Gustafsson B amp Shi L (2002) Income inequality within and across counties in rural China 1988 and 1995 Journal of Development Economics 69(1) 179ndash204 httpsdoiorg101016S0304-3878(02)00058-5

Gylfason T amp Zoega G (2003) Inequality and Economic Growth Do Natural Resources Matter In T T Eicher S (Ed) Inequality and Growth Theory and Policy Implications (pp 255ndash292) The MIT Press

Henningsen A (2010) Estimating Censored Regression Models in R using the censReg Package R Package Vignettes Collection 5(2) 12

Henningsen A (2019) censReg Censored Regression (Tobit) Models R package version 05-30 httpscranr-projectorgpackage=censReg Retrieved from httpscranr-projectorgpackage=censReg

Herrera S amp Pang G (2005) Efficiency of Public Spending in Developing Countriesthinsp An Efficiency Frontier Approach World Bank Washington DC

Hill T D amp Angel R J (2005) Neighborhood disorder psychological distress and heavy drinking Social Science amp Medicine 61(5) 965ndash975

133

httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jsocscimed200412027

Hipp J R (2010) RESIDENT PERCEPTIONS OF CRIME AND DISORDER HOW MUCH IS ldquoBIASrdquo AND HOW MUCH IS SOCIAL ENVIRONMENT DIFFERENCES Criminology 48(2) 475ndash508 httpsdoiorg101111j1745-9125201000193x

Holtug N amp Mason A (2010) Introduction Immigration diversity and social cohesion SAGE Publications Sage UK London England

Hooghe M Vanhoutte B Hardyns W amp Bircan T (2010) Unemployment Inequality Poverty and Crime Spatial Distribution Patterns of Criminal Acts in Belgium 2001ndash06 The British Journal of Criminology 51(1) 1ndash20 httpsdoiorg101093bjcazq067

Howie P amp Atakhanova Z (2014) Resource boom and inequality Kazakhstan as a case study Resources Policy 39(1) 71ndash79 httpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201311004

Isham J Woolcock M Pritchett L amp Busby G (2005) The Varieties of Resource Experience Natural Resource Export Structures and the Political Economy of Economic Growth The World Bank Economic Review 19(2) 141ndash174 httpsdoiorg101093wberlhi010

Jottier D Ashworth J amp Heyndels B (2012) Understanding Votersrsquo Preferences How the Electoratersquos Complexity Affects Prediction Accuracy and Wishful Thinking among Politicians with Respect to Election Outcomes Kyklos 65(3) 340ndash370 httpsdoiorg101111j1467-6435201200542x

Kanbur S M R amp Venables A (2005) Spatial inequality and development (R World Institute for Development Economics Ed) Oxford Oxford University Press

Kesler C amp Bloemraad I (2010) Does immigration erode social capital The conditional effects of immigration-generated diversity on trust membership and participation across 19 countries 1981ndash2000 Canadian Journal of Political ScienceRevue Canadienne de Science Politique 43(2) 319ndash347

Kuznets S (1955) Economic Growth and Income Inequality The American Economic Review 45(1) 1ndash28 Retrieved from httpwwwjstororgstable1811581

Lagos G amp Blanco E (2010) Mining and development in the region of Antofagasta Resources Policy 35(4) 265ndash275 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201007006

Leamer E E Maul H Rodriguez S amp Schott P K (1999) Does natural resource abundance increase Latin American income inequality Journal of Development Economics 59(1) 3ndash42 httpsdoiorg101016s0304-3878(99)00004-8

Leibbrandt M Finn A amp Woolard I (2012) Describing and decomposing post-apartheid income inequality in South Africa Development Southern Africa 29(1) 19ndash34 httpsdoiorg1010800376835X2012645639

134

Letki N (2008) Does Diversity Erode Social Cohesion Social Capital and Race in British Neighbourhoods Political Studies 56(1) 99ndash126 httpsdoiorg101111j1467-9248200700692x

Lewis D A (2017) Fear of crime Incivility and the production of a social problem Routledge

lo Storto C (2013) Evaluating Technical Efficiency of Italian Major Municipalities A Data Envelopment Analysis model Procedia - Social and Behavioral Sciences 81 346ndash350 httpsdoiorg101016JSBSPRO201306440

Loayza N amp Rigolini J (2016) The Local Impact of Mining on Poverty and Inequality Evidence from the Commodity Boom in Peru World Development 84 219ndash234 httpsdoiorg101016jworlddev201603005

Loayza N Teran A M y amp Rigolini J (2013) Poverty Inequality and the Local Natural Resource Curse World Bank Policy Research Working Paper (6366) httpsdoiorg1015961813-9450-6366

Loacutepez R amp Miller S J (2008) Chile The Unbearable Burden of Inequality World Development 36(12) 2679ndash2695 httpsdoiorg101016jworlddev200801012

Manzano O amp Rigobon R (2001) Resource Curse or Debt Overhang National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper Series No 8390 1 httpsdoiorghttpwwwnberorgpapersw9424bib

McPherson M Smith-Lovin L amp Cook J M (2001) Birds of a Feather Homophily in Social Networks Annual Review of Sociology 27(1) 415ndash444 httpsdoiorg101146annurevsoc271415

McQuestin D Drew J amp Dollery B (2018) Do Municipal Mergers Improve Technical Efficiency An Empirical Analysis of the 2008 Queensland Municipal Merger Program Australian Journal of Public Administration 77(3) 442ndash455 httpsdoiorg1011111467-850012286

Messner S F Rosenfeld R amp Baumer E P (2004) Dimensions of Social Capital and Rates of Criminal Homicide American Sociological Review 69(6) 882ndash903 httpsdoiorg101177000312240406900607

Michaels G (2011) THE LONG TERM CONSEQUENCES OF RESOURCE-BASED SPECIALISATION The Economic Journal 121(551) 31ndash57 httpsdoiorg101111j1468-0297201002402x

Mijanovich T amp Weitzman B C (2003) Which ldquobroken windowsrdquo matter School neighborhood and family characteristics associated with youthsrsquo feelings of unsafety Journal of Urban Health 80(3) 400ndash415

Mikušovaacute P (2015) An Application of DEA Methodology in Efficiency Measurement of the Czech Public Universities Procedia Economics and Finance 25 569ndash578 httpsdoiorg101016S2212-5671(15)00771-6

135

Milanovic B (2016) Global inequality Harvard University Press

Millo G amp Piras G (2012) splm Spatial panel data models in R Journal of Statistical Software 47(1) 1ndash38

Murphy K M amp Topel R H (2016) Human Capital Investment Inequality and Economic Growth JOURNAL OF LABOR ECONOMICS 34(2) S99ndashS127 httpsdoiorg101086683779

Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute I amp De Witte K (2018a) Local governmentsrsquo efficiency a systematic literature reviewmdashpart I International Transactions in Operational Research 25(2) 431ndash468 httpsdoiorg101111itor12364

Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute I amp De Witte K (2018b) Local governmentsrsquo efficiency a systematic literature reviewmdashpart II International Transactions in Operational Research 25(4) 1107ndash1136 httpsdoiorg101111itor12389

Nuntildeez J Rivera J Villavicencio X amp Molina O (2003) Determinantes socioeconoacutemicos y demograacuteficos del crimen en Chile Estudios de Economiacutea 30(1) 55ndash85

OrsquoDonnell C J Rao D S P amp Battese G E (2008) Metafrontier frameworks for the study of firm-level efficiencies and technology ratios Empirical Economics 34(2) 231ndash255 httpsdoiorg101007s00181-007-0119-4

Ocampo J A (2004) Latin Americarsquos Growth and Equity Frustrations During Structural Reforms The Journal of Economic Perspectives 18(2) 67ndash88 httpsdoiorg1012570895330041371349

OECD (2014) Focus on inequality and growth OECD

OECD (2017) Howrsquos Life 2017 Life Satisfaction Oecd httpsdoiorg101787how_life-2017-en

Ohtake F (2008) Inequality in Japan Asian Economic Policy Review 3(1) 87ndash109 httpsdoiorg101111j1748-3131200800093x

Okun A M (2015) Equality and efficiency the big tradeoff Washington DC Brookings Institution Press

Ortega B Sanjuaacuten J amp Casquero A (2017) Determinants of efficiency in reducing child mortality in developing countries The role of inequality and government effectiveness Health Care Management Science 20(4) 500ndash516 httpsdoiorg101007s10729-016-9367-1

Ostry J Berg A amp Tsangarides C (2014) Redistribution inequality and growth International Monetary Fund

Pacheco F Saacutenchez R amp Villena M (2013) Eficiencia de los Gobiernos Locales y sus Determinantes Un anaacutelisis de Fronteras Estocaacutesticas en Datos de Panel para

136

Municipalidades Chilenas Santiago de Chile Chile

Papyrakis E amp Raveh O (2014) An Empirical Analysis of a Regional Dutch Disease The Case of Canada Environmental and Resource Economics 58(2) 179ndash198 httpsdoiorg101007s10640-013-9698-z

Paredes D (2013) The Role of Human Capital Market Potential and Natural Amenities in Understanding Spatial Wage Disparities in Chile Spatial Economic Analysis 8(2) 154ndash175 httpsdoiorg101080174217722013774094

Paredes D Iturra V amp Lufin M (2016) A spatial decomposition of income inequality in Chile Regional Studies 50(5) 771ndash789

Phan P Van Orsquobrien M Mendolia S amp Paloyo A (2017) National pro-poor spending programmes and their effect on income inequality and poverty Evidence from Vietnam Applied Economics 49(55) 5579ndash5590 httpsdoiorg1010800003684620171313957

Podinovski V V (2004) Bridging the Gap between the Constant and Variable Returns-to-Scale Models Selective Proportionality in Data Envelopment Analysis The Journal of the Operational Research Society 55(3) 265ndash276 Retrieved from httpwwwjstororgstable4102006

Ravallion M (2005) On Measuring Aggregate Social Efficiency Economic Development and Cultural Change 53(2) 273ndash292 httpsdoiorg101086425380

Rehner J Baeza S A amp Barton J R (2014) Chilersquos resource-based export boom and its outcomes Regional specialization export stability and economic growth Geoforum 56(Supplement C) 35ndash45 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jgeoforum201406007

Rivera J Gutieacuterrez M amp Nuacutentildeez J (2009) Caracterizacioacuten socioeconoacutemica y espacial de la criminalidad en Chile Revista CEPAL

Ross C E (2011) Collective threat trust and the sense of personal control Journal of Health and Social Behavior 52(3) 287ndash296

Ross C E amp Mirowsky J (2001) Neighborhood disadvantage disorder and health Journal of Health and Social Behavior 258ndash276

Rothstein B amp Uslaner E M (2005) All for all Equality corruption and social trust World Politics 58(1) 41ndash72

Sachs J D amp Warner A M (2001) The curse of natural resources European Economic Review 45(4ndash6) 827ndash838 httpsdoiorg101016S0014-2921(01)00125-8

Salas R (2019) sinimr Chilean Municipalities Information System Wrapper Retrieved from httpsgithubcomrobsalascosinimr

Sampson R J (1986) Crime in Cities The Effects of Formal and Informal Social Control Crime and Justice 8 271ndash311

137

Sampson R J (2008) Rethinking crime and immigration Contexts 7(1) 28ndash33

Santos Silva J M C amp Tenreyro S (2010) On the existence of the maximum likelihood estimates in Poisson regression Economics Letters 107(2) 310ndash312 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jeconlet201002020

Santos Silva J M C amp Tenreyro S (2011) poisson Some convergence issues Stata Journal 11(2) 207ndash212 Retrieved from httpwwwstata-journalcomarticlehtmlarticle=st0225

Scott Z (2009) Decentralisation local development and social cohesion an analytical review GSDRC Research Paper 5

Sinha R P (2017) Fiscal Performance Benchmarking of Indian States-A Robust Frontier Approach The Central European Review of Economics and Management 1(4) 225ndash249

Skogan W (1986) Fear of crime and neighborhood change Crime and Justice 8 203ndash229

Skogan W (1999) Measuring what matters Crime disorder and fear In Measuring what matters Proceedings from the Policing Research Institute meetings (pp 37ndash53) National Institute of Justice Washington DC

Skogan W (2015) Disorder and Decline The State of Research Journal of Research in Crime and Delinquency 52(4) 464ndash485 httpsdoiorg1011770022427815577836

Šťastnaacute L amp Gregor M (2014) Public sector efficiency in transition and beyond evidence from Czech local governments Applied Economics 47(7) 1ndash20 httpsdoiorg101080000368462014978077

Tandon A (2005) Measuring Efficiency of Macro Systems An Application to Millennium Development Goal Attainment Asian Development Review 22(2) 108ndash125

Taylor R B (1999) The incivilities thesis Theory measurement and policy Measuring What Matters 65 88

Tigga N S amp Mishra U S (2015) On Measuring Technical Efficiency of the Health System in India An Application of Data Envelopment Analysis Journal of Health Management 17(3) 285ndash298 httpsdoiorg1011770972063415589229

Tinbergen J (1975) Demographic Development and the Exhaustion of Natural Resources Population and Development Review 1(1) 23ndash32 httpsdoiorg1023071972269

Tiruneh G (2014) Social Revolutions Their Causes Patterns and Phases SAGE Open 4(3) 2158244014548845 httpsdoiorg1011772158244014548845

Tolsma J Van der Meer T amp Gesthuizen M (2009) The impact of neighbourhood and municipality characteristics on social cohesion in the Netherlands Acta Politica 44(3) 286ndash313

Tsekeris Sotiris T Tsekeris T amp Papaioannou S (2018) Regional determinants of technical efficiency evidence from the Greek economy Regional Studies [London]thinsp Carfax

138

httpsdoiorg1010800034340420171390312

Uslaner E (2002) The moral foundations of trust Cambridge University Press

Uslaner E (2011) CORRUPTION AND INEQUALITY DICE Report 9(2) 20ndash24

Uslaner E (2013) Trust and corruption revisited how and why trust and corruption shape each other Quality amp Quantity 47(6) 3603ndash3608 httpsdoiorg101007s11135-012-9742-z

Uslaner E amp Brown M (2005) Inequality trust and civic engagement American Politics Research 33(6) 868ndash894

Van der Ploeg F (2011) Natural Resources Curse or Blessing Journal of Economic Literature 49(2) 366ndash420 httpsdoiorg101257jel492366

Vergara R (2012) Crime Prevention Programs Evidence From CHILE The Developing Economies 50(1) 1ndash24

Watkins M H (1963) A staple theory of economic growth Canadian Journal of Economics and Political ScienceRevue Canadienne de Economiques et Science Politique 29(2) 141ndash158

Wilkinson R G (1999) Income inequality social cohesion and health clarifying the theorymdasha reply to Muntaner and Lynch International Journal of Health Services 29(3) 525ndash543

Wilson J Q amp Kelling G L (1982) Broken windows Atlantic Monthly 249(3) 29ndash38

Wilson W J (1996) When Work Disappears Political Science Quarterly 111(4) 567ndash595 httpsdoiorg1023072152085

Wirth L (1938) Urbanism as a Way of Life American Journal of Sociology 44(1) 1ndash24

Worthington A amp Dollery B (2000) An empirical survey of frontier efficiency measurement techniques in local government Local Government Studies 26(2) 23ndash52 httpsdoiorg10108003003930008433988

Wu P-C Huang T-H amp Pan S-C (2014) Country Performance Evaluation The DEA Model Approach Social Indicators Research 118(2) 835ndash849 httpsdoiorg101007s11205-013-0443-3

Ye X Ma L Ye K Chen J amp Xie Q (2017) Analysis of Regional Inequality from Sectoral Structure Spatial Policy and Economic Development A Case Study of Chongqing China Sustainability 9(4) 633 Retrieved from httpwwwmdpicom2071-105094633

Yue W Z Zhang Y T Ye X Y Cheng Y Q amp Leipnik M R (2014) Dynamics of Multi-Scale Intra-Provincial Regional Inequality in Zhejiang China Sustainability 6(9) 5763ndash5784 httpsdoiorg103390su6095763

139

Appendices

Appendix A Summary statistics income inequality

Table A1

Summary statistics Gini coefficients by year and zone

140

Appendix B Summary statistics for NRD measures by region

Table B1

Summary statistics NRD measures by region

141

Appendix C Regional administrative division and defined zones

Figure C1 Geographical distribution of Chilean regions and 3 zones

142

Appendix D Summary statistics numeric controls and correlation matrix

Table D1

Summary Statistics Numeric Explanatory Variables

Figure D1 Correlation matrix numeric explanatory variables

143

Appendix E Static spatial panel models

Following Millo amp Piras (2012) a model including a spatial lag of the dependent variable and

spatial autoregressive disturbances but not spatial lags for the explanatory variable(s) is called

SARAR model A static spatial SARAR panel could be expressed as

119910 120582 119868 otimes119882 119910 119883120573 119906 (E1)

where y is an 119873 1 vector of observations on the dependent variable X is a 119873 119896 matrix of

observations on the non-stochastic exogenous regressors 119868 an identity matrix of dimension 119879 otimes

is the kronecker operator 119882 is the 119873 119873 spatial weights matrix of known constants whose

diagonal elements are set to zero and 120582 the corresponding spatial parameter44

The disturbance vector is the sum of two terms

119906 120580 otimes 119868 120583 120576 (E2)

where 120580 is a 119879 1 vector of ones 119868 an 119873 119873 identity matrix 120583 is a vector of time-invariant

individual specific effects (not spatially autocorrelated) and 120576 a vector of spatially autocorrelated

innovations that follow a spatial autoregressive process of the form

120576 120588 119868 otimes119882 120576 120584 (E3)

If we assume that spatial correlation applies to both the individual effects 120583 and the remainder

error components 120576 Kapoor et al (2007) propose that the disturbance term 119906 follows a first order

spatial autoregressive process of the form

119906 120588 119868 otimes119882 119906 120576 (E4)

44 Unlike ldquotraditional panelsrdquo which are organized as different time series for each cross-sectional unit ldquospatial panelsrdquo are organized as a series of cross-sections for each year

144

where 119882 is the spatial weights matrix and 119903ℎ119900 the corresponding spatial autoregressive

parameter To further allow for the innovations to be correlated over time the innovations vector

in Equation 7 follows an error component structure

120576 120580 otimes 119868 120583 120584 (E5)

where 120583 is the vector of cross-sectional specific effects 120584 a vector of innovations that vary

both over cross-sectional units and time periods 120580 is a vector of ones and 119868 an 119873 119873 identity

matrix45

Spatial panel models are usually estimated by Maximum Likelihood or GMM46 The SAR

SEM or SARAR models could be estimated with Random or Fixed effects For instance A fixed

effect spatial lag model can be written in stacked form as

119910 120582 119868 otimes119882 119910 120580 otimes 119868 120583 119883120573 120576 (E6)

where 120582 is the spatial autoregressive coefficient 119882 a non-stochastic spatial weights matrix

120580 a column vector of ones of dimension 119879 119868 an 119873 119873 identity matrix and 120576 sim 119873 0120590 On

the other hand a fixed effects spatial error model assuming the disturbance specification by

Kapoor et al (2007) can be written as

119910 120580119879 otimes 119868119873 120583 119883120573 119906119906 120588 119868119879 otimes119882119873 119906 120576

(E7)

where 120588 is the spatial autocorrelation coefficient and 120576 is a well-behaved error term

45 In the regression implementation the specification given by equations (22) and (3) is denoted by ldquobrdquo for ldquoBaltagirdquo On the other hand the specification given by equations (23) and (31) is denoted by ldquokkprdquo for ldquoKapoor Kelejian and Pruchardquo 46 We use the R package splm which allow both types of regression procedure

145

Appendix F Analysis OLS residuals cross-sectional (six-year average) analysis

Table F1

Analysis OLS residuals Anselin Method

Figure F1 Moran scatter plot OLS residuals

146

Appendix G Linear panel data models

Table G1

Panel regressions (non-spatial)

147

Appendix H Spatial panel models (Generalized Moments (GM) estimation)

Table H1

GM Spatial Models

148

Appendix I Inputs and outputs used in DEA analysis

Figure I1 Examples of inputs and outputs used to measure LGE (based on Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018)

149

Appendix J Technical and scale efficiency

Following lo Storto (2013) under an input-oriented specification assuming VRS with n

municipalities using k inputs to produce m outputs the DEA model for a given i-th municipality

is specified with the following mathematical programming problem

119898119894119899 120579119904119906119887119895119890119888119905 119905119900 119910 119884120582 0120579119909 119883120582 01198991prime120582 1  120582 0prime

Where 119910 is the column vector of the outputs and 119909 is the column vector of the inputs

Moreover we can define X as the (k times n) input matrix and Y as the (m times n) output matrix 120579 is a

scalar (that satisfies 120579 1) more specifically it is the efficiency score that measures technical

efficiency It measures the distance between a municipality and the efficiency frontier defined as

a linear combination of the best practice observations With 120579 1 the municipality is inside the

frontier (ie it is inefficient) while 120579 1 implies that the municipality is on the frontier (ie it is

efficient) The vector 120582 is an (n times 1) vector of constants that measures the weights used to compute

the location of an inefficient municipality if it were to become efficient

The total technical efficiency 119879119864 can be decomposed into pure technical efficiency

119879119864 and scale efficiency 119878119864 where 119878119864 119879119864 119879119864 (Coelli et al 2005) To find out

whether a municipality is scale efficient and qualify the type of returns of scale a DEA model

under non-increasing returns to scale 119879119864 is implemented where 119878119864 119879119864 119879119864 Hence

the following rule can be applied (Faumlre Grosskopf amp Lovell 1985)

bull If 119878119864 1 then a municipality is scale efficient both under CRS and VRS

bull If 119878119864 1 it operates under increasing returns to scale

bull If 119878119864 1 it operates under decreasing returns to scale

150

Appendix K Correlation matrix

Figure K1 Correlation matrix contextual factors

151

Appendix L Returns to scale by year and zone

Table L1

Returns to scale (percentage of municipalities)

152

Appendix M Returns to scale by year (maps)

Figure M1 Spatial distribution of returns to scale by county per year

153

Appendix N Efficiency status by year (maps)

Figure N1 Spatial distribution of efficient (E es = 1) and inefficient (I es lt 1) counties per year

154

Appendix O Spatial distribution efficiency scores by year (maps)

FigureO1 Custom breaks maps of efficiency scores (VRS) by county per year

155

Appendix P Analysis OLS residuals cross-sectional (six-year average) analysis

Table P1

Analysis OLS residuals Anselin Method

Figure P1 Moran scatter plot efficiency scores and OLS residuals

156

Table P2

OLS and spatial regression models for the six-year averaged data

157

Appendix Q OLS regressions for cross-sectional and panel data

Table Q1

OLS cross-sectional regression per year

158

Table Q2

OLS panel regressions Pooled random effects and instrumental variable

159

Appendix R Quantile maps incivilities rate by group (average total period)

Figure R1 Spatial distribution of incivilities by group (Average rate per 1000 inhabitants 2006-09-11-13-15-17)

160

Appendix S Correlation matrix numeric covariates

Figure S1 Correlation matrix numeric covariates

161

Appendix T Negative Binomial regressions

Table T1

Negative Binomial regressions

162

Appendix U Coefficients economic and racial diversity by geographical zone

Table U1

Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson models by geographic zone

Page 5: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted

iv

the growing feeling of social unrest in contemporary societies Economic diversity is proxied using

the Gini coefficient in each county and racial diversity through the number of new visas granted

as proportion of the county population Our findings show that incivilities are strongly associated

with racial diversity and to a lesser extent with economic diversity The rate of incivilities also

shows a negative association with the level of income and a positive relationship with poverty and

unemployment rates These results give empirical support to the idea that both relative and

absolute indicators of economic deprivation play an important role in understanding the growing

problem of incivilities in highly unequal economies like Chile Results also show that the rate of

incivilities is negatively related to the degree of financial autonomy of municipalities These

findings represent promising areas for central and local governments in the implementation of

policies aimed at increasing social cohesion through the reduction of incivilities and other types of

antisocial behaviours

v

Table of Contents

Keywords i

Abstract ii

Table of Contents v

List of Figures viii

List of Tables ix

List of Abbreviations x

Statement of Original Authorship xi

Acknowledgements xii

Chapter 1 Introduction 13

Income inequality and dependence on natural resources 14

Local government efficiency and income inequality 16

Social cohesion and economic diversity 19

Contributions 21

Thesis outline 23

Chapter 2 Natural Resources Curse or Blessing Evidence on Income Inequality at the County Level in Chile 24

21 Introduction 24

22 Inequality and Natural Resources 28 221 Theoretical Framework 28

Cross-country literature 29 Single country evidence 32

222 The relevance of the spatial approach 33

23 Research problem and hypotheses 35

24 Data and Methods 36 241 Operationalization of key variables 36 242 Control variables 40 243 Methods 41 244 Spatial Model Specification 43

25 Results 44 251 Exploratory Spatial Data Analysis (ESDA) 44 252 Cross-sectional analysis 45 253 Panel Data analysis 48

26 Discussion and conclusions 51

Chapter 3 The Impact of Income Inequality on the Efficiency of Municipalities in Chile 55

vi

31 Introduction 55

32 Related Literature 61 321 Measuring efficiency of local governments 61 322 Explaining differences in LGE 63 323 The trade-off between efficiency and equity 64

33 Methodology 66 331 Chilean Municipalities and period of analysis 66 332 Measuring municipal efficiency 68 333 Inputs and outputs used in DEA 70 334 Regression model 71 335 The instrument 75

34 Results and discussion 77 341 DEA results 77

Returns to scale 78 Efficiency measure 80

342 Regression results 82 Exploratory spatial analysis 82 Cross-sectional analysis 83 Panel data analysis 84

35 Conclusions 88

Chapter 4 Social Cohesion Incivilities and Diversity Evidence at the municipal level in Chile 91

41 Introduction 91

42 Related Literature 95 421 The Community Heterogeneity Thesis 95 422 The literature on incivilities 97 423 The ldquoIncivilities Thesisrdquo 99

4 3 Methodology 100 431 Period of analysis and data sample 100 432 Operationalisation of the response variable and exploratory analysis 101 433 Measures of community heterogeneity and control variables 105 434 Methods 108 435 Hypotheses 111

44 Results and Discussion 112

4 5 Conclusions 118

Chapter 5 Conclusions 120

Bibliography 126

Appendices 139

Appendix A Summary statistics income inequality 139

Appendix B Summary statistics for NRD measures by region 140

Appendix C Regional administrative division and defined zones 141

Appendix D Summary statistics numeric controls and correlation matrix 142

vii

Appendix E Static spatial panel models 143

Appendix F Analysis OLS residuals cross-sectional (six-year average) analysis 145

Appendix G Linear panel data models 146

Appendix H Spatial panel models (Generalized Moments (GM) estimation) 147

Appendix I Inputs and outputs used in DEA analysis 148

Appendix J Technical and scale efficiency 149

Appendix K Correlation matrix 150

Appendix L Returns to scale by year and zone 151

Appendix M Returns to scale by year (maps) 152

Appendix N Efficiency status by year (maps) 153

Appendix O Spatial distribution efficiency scores by year (maps) 154

Appendix P Analysis OLS residuals cross-sectional (six-year average) analysis 155

Appendix Q OLS regressions for cross-sectional and panel data 157

Appendix R Quantile maps incivilities rate by group (average total period) 159

Appendix S Correlation matrix numeric covariates 160

Appendix T Negative Binomial regressions 161

Appendix U Coefficients economic and racial diversity by geographical zone 162

viii

List of Figures

Figure 21 Average share in GDP of economic activities (2006ndash17) 37

Figure 22 Evolution of Gini coefficient and measures of NRD (2006ndash17) 38

Figure 23 Spatial distribution of Gini coefficient and NRD (2006ndash17) 39

Figure 23 Moran scatter plots for variables gini and pss_casen 45

Figure 31 Geographical distribution of Chilean regions and macrozones 74

Figure 32 Evolution of efficiency scores and the proportion of firms by sector 77

Figure 33 Evolution technical efficiency (TE) pure technical efficiency (PTE) and scale efficiency (SE) 78

Figure 34 Returns to scale by zone 79

Figure 35 Evolution mean efficiency scores (VRS) by zone 81

Figure 41 Evolution number and rates of incivilities and crime (DMCS) in Chile 2006-2017 102

Figure 42 Evolution total number of incivilities by category 104

Figure 43 Spatial distribution of incivilities rate per 1000 inhabitants (2006 vs 2017) 104

Figure 44 Annual average number of incivilities per county 109

Figure C1 Geographical distribution of Chilean regions and 3 zones 141

Figure D1 Correlation matrix numeric explanatory variables 142

Figure F1 Moran scatter plot OLS residuals 145

Figure I1 Examples of inputs and outputs used to measure LGE (based on Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018) 148

Figure K1 Correlation matrix contextual factors 150

Figure M1 Spatial distribution of returns to scale by county per year 152

Figure N1 Spatial distribution of efficient (E es = 1) and inefficient (I es lt 1) counties per year 153

FigureO1 Custom breaks maps of efficiency scores (VRS) by county per year 154

Figure P1 Moran scatter plot efficiency scores and OLS residuals 155

Figure R1 Spatial distribution of incivilities by group (Average rate per 1000 inhabitants 2006-09-11-13-15-17) 159

Figure S1 Correlation matrix numeric covariates 160

ix

List of Tables

Table 21 Cross-sectional Model Comparison (six-year average data) 47

Table 22 ML Spatial SAR Models 50

Table 23 ML Spatial SEM Models 50

Table 24 ML Spatial SARAR Models 51

Table 31 Descriptive statistics Inputs and Output variables used in DEA analysis 71

Table 32 Summary Statistics Numeric Contextual Factors 74

Table 33 Summary efficiency scores (VRS) by zone and region 80

Table 34 Cross-sectional (censored) regressions 84

Table 35 Panel data regressions 87

Table 41 Summary statistics total count of incivilities and by category (full sample and period) 103

Table 42 Summary statistics numeric explanatory variables 108

Table 43 Poisson regressions 113

Table 44 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson models by region 115

Table 45 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson model by incivility group 116

Table A1 Summary statistics Gini coefficients by year and zone 139

Table B1 Summary statistics NRD measures by region 140

Table D1 Summary Statistics Numeric Explanatory Variables 142

Table F1 Analysis OLS residuals Anselin Method 145

Table G1 Panel regressions (non-spatial) 146

Table H1 GM Spatial Models 147

Table L1 Returns to scale (percentage of municipalities) 151

Table P1 Analysis OLS residuals Anselin Method 155

Table P2 OLS and spatial regression models for the six-year averaged data 156

Table Q1 OLS cross-sectional regression per year 157

Table Q2 OLS panel regressions Pooled random effects and instrumental variable 158

Table T1 Negative Binomial regressions 161

Table U1 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson models by geographic zone 162

x

List of Abbreviations

Constant returns to scale CRS

Data envelopment analysis DEA

Decreasing returns to scale DRS

Efficiency scores ES

Exploratory spatial data analysis ESDA

Generalized methods of moments GMM

Gross Domestic Product GDP

Increasing returns to scale IRS

Local government efficiency LGE

Maximum likelihood ML

Municipal common fund MCF

Natural resource dependence NRD

Natural resource endowment NRE

Ordinary Least Squares OLS

Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development OECD

Own permanent revenues OPR

Resource curse hypothesis RCH

Spatial autoregressive model SAR

Spatial error model SEM

Variable returns to scale VRS

xi

Statement of Original Authorship

The work contained in this thesis has not been previously submitted to meet requirements

for an award at this or any other higher education institution To the best of my knowledge and

belief the thesis contains no material previously published or written by another person except

where due reference is made

Signature QUT Verified Signature

Date _________04092020_________

xii

Acknowledgements

First I would like to thank my wife Lilian who joined me in this challenge and patiently

supported me all these years I would also like to thank our family who always supported us from

Chile I especially thank my sister Silvia who took care of our house and dog

I am also grateful to my supervisory team Dr Radhika Lahiri and Dr Vincent Hoang who

supported and guided me in the process of making this thesis a reality

I also thank the Deans of the Faculty of Economics and Business at my beloved University

of Talca Dr Arcadio Cerda and Dr Rodrigo Herrera who trusted me and supported me in this

process In the same way I would like to thank all the support of the director of the Commercial

Engineering career Mr Milton Inostroza

Finally I would like to thank the government of Chile for the financial support that made

my stay and studies possible here at the Queensland University of Technology

13

Chapter 1 Introduction

Efficiency and equity issues are often considered together in the evaluation of economic

performance While higher efficiency usually measured by growth rates of income per capita

correlates with improvements in measures of well-being the link between inequality and well-

being is less clear This is reflected not only in the type and amount of research related to efficiency

and equity but also in the role that both play in the design of the economic policy For instance

several market-oriented countries have focused primarily on economic growth trusting in a trickle-

down process where financial benefits given to the wealthy are expected to ultimately benefit the

poor However despite the growing interest in the issue of inequality there is a considerable lack

of studies about its consequences

Although some level of inequality is inevitable or even necessary for economic activity this

study is motivated by the argument that relatively high levels of inequality can be associated with

many problems such as persistent unemployment increasing fiscal expenses indebtedness and

political instability (Berg amp Ostry 2011) Inequality can also have other severe social

consequences including increased crime rates teenage pregnancy obesity and fewer

opportunities for low-income households to invest in health and education (Atkinson 2015) In

addition when the role of money and concentration of economic power undermine political

outcomes inequality of opportunities hampers social and economic mobility trust and social

cohesion In summary inequality can increase the fragility of the economic and social situation in

a country reducing economic growth and making it less inclusive and sustainable

14

A country well-known for its market-oriented economy and high level of dependence on

natural resources is Chile Chilean success in terms of economic growth contrasts with its inability

to reduce the persistently high levels of social and economic inequality particularly in the last

three decades Using data for the 2006-2017 period and considering 324 out of 345 Chilean

counties this thesis presents three essays with empirical evidence aiming to explain the

phenomenon of persistent income inequality and some of its potential consequences The first

essay aims to analyse how the evolution and variability of income inequality throughout the

country are associated with the degree of natural resource dependence The second essay studies

the relevance of income inequality in explaining cross-county differences in the performance of

local governments (municipalities) Finally the third essay explores the link between social

cohesion and community heterogeneity highlighting the importance of economic and racial

diversity

Income inequality and dependence on natural resources

The first essay explores how cross-county differences in income inequality are associated

with differences in the degree of dependence on natural resources We use the Gini coefficient in

each county as our dependent variable and the proportion of employment in the primary sector as

our measure of natural resource dependence The main hypothesis is that income inequality should

be positively related to the degree of natural resource dependence To test our hypothesis we use

a spatial econometric approach This approach is motivated by the study of Paredes Iturra and

Lufin (2016) who explore the geographic heterogeneity of income inequality in Chile finding

evidence of a significant spatial dimension

15

The theoretical and empirical literature has mostly proposed a positive link between

inequality and natural resources Although most of the evidence corresponds to cross-country

comparisons there is also increasing body of research at the local level A rationale underpinning

the positive link suggested in the literature is that in natural resource-rich countries ownership is

concentrated in small groups and extraction activities require low-skilled workers (Gylfason amp

Zoega 2003 Leamer Maul Rodriguez amp Schott 1999) Another market-based argument often

labelled as the ldquoDutch Diseaserdquo proposes that natural resource windfalls could be associated with

a crowding-out effect on the manufacturing sector (Corden amp Neary 1982 Easterly 2007) This

process encourages rent-seeking behaviours discourages investment in physical and human

capital and delays the process of technology adoption and industrialization (Auty 2001 Bulte

Damania amp Deacon 2005 Gylfason amp Zoega 2003) The result could be a lower economic

growth which is the central idea under the ldquoResource Curse Hypothesisrdquo (Auty 1993 Sachs amp

Warner 2001)

An ldquoinstitutionalrdquo argument for the positive association between inequality and the

endowment of natural resources is based on the so-called ldquoParadox of Plentyrdquo (Borge Parmer amp

Torvik 2015 Dauvin amp Guerreiro 2017) The idea is that both national and local authorities have

less incentive to operate efficiently when they experience windfalls in their revenues for

instance from natural resources This could end with corrupted authorities exerting patronage

clientelism and designing public policies to favour specific groups of the population (Uslaner amp

Brown 2005) Evidence also suggests that the final effect of natural resource booms on income

inequality will depend on authoritiesrsquo capacity to manage these additional resources the extent of

commuting and migration among regions and the potential increase in the demand for non-tradable

16

goods which are intensive in unskilled workers (Aroca amp Atienza 2011 Cust amp Poelhekke 2015

Fleming amp Measham 2015b Howie amp Atakhanova 2014 Michaels 2011)

Contrary to most theoretical and empirical evidence we find that income inequality shows

a robust and significant negative association with our proxy for natural resource dependence This

result suggests that the process of transformation to an economy less dependent on natural

resources could have exacerbated rather than alleviated the persistence of income inequality The

decrease in the participation of the primary sector in employment in favour mainly of the tertiary

sector highlights the importance of the latter to explain the current high levels of inequality and its

future evolution Another important result is that spatial linear models show practically the same

results as traditional linear models This could be interpreted as the spatial dimension previously

found in income inequality is not the result of spatial dependence in the variable itself for instance

due to a process of spillover among counties Hence the usually found positive spatial

autocorrelation of income inequality (similar levels in neighbouring counties) could be explained

by spatial patterns in other variables or to the spatial heterogeneity that characterizes the Chilean

economy

Local government efficiency and income inequality

Essay 2 delves deep into the potential trade-off between efficiency and equity We measure

the efficiency of Chilean municipalities which correspond to the organizations in charge of

managing each county Municipal efficiency is understood as ldquotechnical efficiencyrdquo that is the

possibility that each municipality has reached the same level of outputs with less use of inputs

Then we analyse how income inequality controlling for other contextual factors such as

socioeconomic demographic geographical and political characteristics may help to explain

17

differences in municipal performance Our main hypothesis is that municipal efficiency is

inversely associated with income inequality Moreover we seek a causal interpretation of this

relationship

Municipal performance could be influenced by income inequality in direct and indirect ways

In a direct sense income inequality is used to capture the degree of heterogeneity and complexity

in the demand for public services that citizens exert over local authorities Hence higher levels of

income inequality should be associated with a more complex set of public services and therefore

with lower levels of municipal efficiency (Jottier Ashworth amp Heyndels 2012) Furthermore

when high levels of inequality exist the richest groups can exert a higher influence over local

authorities resulting in low quality and quantity of services for most of the population Among

indirect effects high and persistent inequality could be the source of corrupted institutions and

local authorities favouring themselves or specific groups This undermines citizensrsquo participation

in civic activities and their willingness to monitor municipal performance (Uslaner amp Brown

2005) Additionally the potential benefits of decentralization on the way local governments

deliver public services will be limited when the context is characterized by corrupted politicians

and a limited administrative and financial capacity (Scott 2009)

We measure municipal efficiency using an input-oriented Data Envelopment Analysis

(DEA) to obtain efficiency scores for our sample of 324 municipalities in each year from 2006 to

2017 Then we study the influence on municipal efficiency of income inequality and our set of

contextual factors using a panel of six years corresponding to those years for which household

income information is available 2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017 Our dependent variable

is the set of efficiency scores which are relative measures of efficiency They are relative to the

18

municipalities included in the sample and they do not imply that higher technical efficiency gains

cannot be achieved Thus we use both cross-sectional and panel censored regression models To

tackle endogeneity issues and suggest a causal interpretation we also propose using the proportion

of firms in the primary sector as an instrument for income inequality

We find an average efficiency score of 83 meaning that Chilean municipalities could

reduce the use of inputs by 17 without reducing their outputs We also measure municipal

efficiency under different assumptions related to returns to scale This allows us to disaggregate

technical efficiency to assess whether inefficiencies are due to management issues (pure technical

efficiency) or scale issues (scale efficiency) Although the results show that most municipalities

operate under increasing or decreasing returns to scale scale inefficiencies only explain a small

proportion of total municipal inefficiencies This highlights the need to look for contextual factors

outside the control of local authorities to explain differences in municipal performance

Geographical representations of our results in terms of returns to scale and efficiency scores

show some spatial clustering process among municipalities Spatial statistics tests confirm that

efficiency scores show a significant positive spatial autocorrelation This means that neighbouring

municipalities tend to show similar levels of efficiency This similar performance could be due to

a process of spatial dependence (eg efficiency spillovers among neighbouring municipalities) or

due to the existence of structural-geographical similarities (spatial heterogeneity) To assess the

spatial dimension in municipal efficiency abstracting from temporal fluctuations we use a cross-

section of data consisting of the six-year average for the variables in our panel After running a

regression of efficiency scores against the set of controls the analysis of OLS residuals shows that

the spatial autocorrelation is almost completely removed This means that the spatial pattern in

19

municipal efficiency can be explained (controlled) by other variables such as regional indicator

variables rather than efficiency itself Given this result we proceed to study the influence of

income inequality on municipal efficiency using traditional (non-spatial) regression analysis

In contrast to literature that emphasizes an equity-efficiency trade-off (Andersen amp Maibom

2020 Berg amp Ostry 2011 Browning amp Johnson 1984 Okun 2015) that is greater equality leads

to lower efficiency we find that municipal efficiency is inversely associated with income

inequality This implies that more equal counties are also those with higher municipal efficiency

Furthermore the coefficient of income inequality is close to one when we use the instrumental

variable approach This means that a reduction in income inequality ceteris paribus should be

associated with an increase in the same magnitude in municipal efficiency This result has strong

policy implications The non-existence of the trade-off suggests that there is more to be gained by

targeting policies towards the reduction of inequality than conventional theories suggest For

instance these policies may help increase the levels of efficiency and well-being at least at the

municipal level

Social cohesion and economic diversity

The third essay studies the relationship between the degree of social cohesion and diversity

in Chile Extant literature has argued that one of the main factors influencing social cohesion is

the degree of economic and ethnic-racial diversity within a society This diversity erodes social

cohesion reducing trust and corrupting institutions (Letki 2008 Rothstein amp Uslaner 2005

Tolsma Van der Meer amp Gesthuizen 2009 Uslaner 2011 2013)

To measure social cohesion scholars have traditionally used measures of social capital trust

or feelings of insecurity (Ariely 2014 Chan To amp Chan 2006 Letki 2008) We suggest the use

20

of the rate of incivilities per 1000 inhabitants as a proxy for social cohesion Incivilities correspond

to those antisocial behaviours (eg groups of rowdy teens and public drunkenness) or visible

neighbourhood conditions (eg graffiti and abandoned buildings) that tend not to be treated as

crime Using the rate of incivilities is arguably a more objective and reliable measure of social

cohesion particularly in countries where institutions of order and security are among the most

trusted An increase in the rate of incivilities rather than changes in crime rates should better

capture the worsening in social cohesion experienced in countries such as Chile where crime rates

are not growing but social conflicts are on the rise Thus the main hypothesis in this essay is that

the rate of incivilities (social cohesion) should be positively (negatively) associated with economic

and racial diversity

Using panel count data models we start analysing how differences in incivilities rates

between and within counties are associated with differences in indicators of relative and absolute

economic disadvantage We use the Gini coefficient of each county as our measure of economic

diversity Although we find a significant and positive association between the rate of incivilities

and the level of income inequality the magnitude of the link seems to be small Among absolute

indicators of economic disadvantage only the level of income shows a strong effect Next we

include our measure of racial diversity We use the number of new visas granted to foreigners as

a proportion of the county population Results show a significant and strong positive association

between the rate of incivilities and racial diversity

To check the robustness of our results we analyse the impact of our measures of economic

and racial diversity running our models separately for each Chilean region and clustering them

geographically We also split the total number of incivilities in four categories to see which type

21

of incivilities show the greatest association with our measures of diversity In general results

support the ldquocommunity heterogeneity hypothesisrdquo that higher community heterogeneity is

associated with higher rates of incivilities (Alesina amp La Ferrara 2002 Letki 2008 Tolsma et al

2009) However results do not support the ldquoincivilities thesisrdquo that the distribution of incivilities

tends to mirror the distribution of income inequality (Skogan 1999 Taylor 1999)

Three results stand out among the set of control variables First the level of education shows

and independent and significant negative association with the rate of incivilities This is in contrast

to previous studies where education acts mainly as a moderator of the effect of economic and racial

diversity on social cohesion (Tolsma et al 2009) The results also show that there is no significant

relationship between the rate of incivilities and the proportion of young population This is relevant

because policies aimed to reduce incivilities usually put the focus on specific groups such as young

people which are linked to physical and social incivilities when social control is weakened

Finally the degree of financial municipal autonomy also shows a significant negative association

with the rate of incivilities This result suggests that municipalities can contribute independently

or together with the central government to reduce incivilities and strengthen social cohesion

Contributions

The three essays in this thesis provide several important insights into the analysis of the

causes and consequences of income inequality particularly in the context of Chile ndash a typical

resource rich economy with persistently high levels of income inequality

Essay 1 advances the understanding of the relationship between income inequality and

natural resources in Chile extending the empirical analysis from the regional level to the county

level In addition the geographic heterogeneity of income inequality is explored with the inclusion

22

of alternative sources of spatial dependence as a potential dimension of the causal relationship

between income inequality and natural resources This essay demonstrates the relevance of natural

resources in explaining the persistence of income inequality even after controlling for other

socioeconomics and institutional factors Findings from this study have potential contribution not

only in the design of policies aimed to reduce income inequality but also in addressing the current

developmental bias between the metropolitan region and the rest of the country

Essay 2 is one of the first studies that undertake a longitudinal analysis of the effects of

income inequality on the efficiency of municipal governments in Chile To capture the role of the

municipal governments in the provision to local people of public services such as education and

health we specify several inputs and outputs in our efficiency model which is different from the

conventional specification in the existing literature For example the number of medical

consultations in public health facilities and the number of enrolled students in public schools are

used as outputs instead of general indicators such as county population Our empirical analysis

also utilises a larger sample of municipalities and covers a much longer period spanning from 2006

to 2017 This essay also investigates the contextual factors beyond the control of local authorities

that can explain variations in the efficiency of municipal governments across the country

Empirical findings from Essay 2 help us increase our understanding of the production

technology of municipalities the sources of inefficiencies and specifically the impact of income

inequality on the performance of local authorities The results deliver two main policy

implications First municipal inefficiencies in the provision of public goods and services differ

across Chilean municipalities In addition efficiency levels show some degree of spatial

autocorrelation This implies that policies such as amalgamation or cooperation among

23

municipalities could have effects beyond the municipalities involved which must be considered

Second the causal effect that income inequality has on municipal efficiency provides another

dimension into the design and implementation of development policies

Essay 3 explores for the first time the effects of economic and racial diversity on social

cohesion in Chile This essay considers incivilities as manifestation of social cohesion and

investigates as extant literature suggests whether indicators of relative economic disadvantage

such as income inequality are among the main factors driving social disorganization and social

unrest Empirical findings suggest that on the one hand economic heterogeneity captured by the

Gini coefficient has a disparate effect both in terms of magnitude and significance on the rate of

incivilities across the country On the other hand the impact of racial heterogeneity appears to be

stronger more significant and of a similar magnitude throughout the country Results also provide

new insights into the design of national policies addressing social disorders particularly those

policies focussed on specific groups of the population and the role of local authorities Overall the

findings provide an opportunity to advance the understanding of the process of weakening in the

social cohesion experienced in Chile and the conflicts that have risen from this process

Thesis outline

The remainder of the thesis is organized as follows Chapter 2 presents essay 1 examining

the association between income inequality and the degree of dependence on natural resources

Chapter 3 presents essay 2 which looks for a causal relationship between municipal efficiency and

income inequality Chapter 4 presents essay 3 analysing the relationship between social cohesion

and economic and racial diversity Finally Chapter 5 presents some concluding remarks

24

Chapter 2 Natural Resources Curse or Blessing Evidence on

Income Inequality at the County Level in Chile

21 Introduction

A phenomenon of increasing inequality of incomes and wealth in recent decades has been

documented by leading scholars and international organizations such as the International Monetary

Fund (Berg amp Ostry 2017 Ostry Berg amp Tsangarides 2014) and the Organization for Economic

Cooperation and Development (Cingano 2014) These efforts have placed the topic of inequality

at the top of the current economic debate recognizing inequality as a determinant not only of

economic growth but also of human development They also have highlighted the necessity for

more research on the drivers of inequality and mechanisms through which it manifests aiming to

design effective policies in reducing economic and social inequalities

Various factors have been analysed as the sources of high and increasing levels of inequality

Among the most significant factors are the levels of income at initial stages of economic

development (Kuznets 1955) Globalization (Milanovic 2016) skill-biased technological change

(Tinbergen 1975) investment in human capital (Murphy amp Topel 2016) institutions

redistributive policy and country-specific characteristics (Acemoglu 1995 2002 Acemoglu

Aghion amp Violante 2001 Acemoglu Johnson amp Robinson 2001) Our focus in this essay is on

the importance that the natural resource endowment (NRE) or lack thereof can play in the

determination of income disparities

25

This essay studies the patterns and evolution of income inequality in the context of a natural

resource-rich country Using the case of the Chilean economy we aim to understand and

disentangle how a phenomenon of high- and persistent-income inequality is related to the

endowment of natural resources that a country owns Chile is an interesting case to study because

despite showing a successful history of economic growth inequality among individuals and among

aggregated spatial units has shown a strong persistence (Paredes et al 2016) Furthermore Chile

has remained among the most unequal countries in the world1

Theory and empirical evidence do not establish a clear link between income inequality and

NRE In addition NRE has received considerably less attention (Auty 2001 ElGindi 2017) and

most of the evidence has been focused on cross-country comparisons For instance NRE can

influence inequality by determining its initial levels (Engerman amp Sokoloff 1994 1997

Engerman Sokoloff Urquiola amp Acemoglu 2002) shaping the evolution of institutions

(Acemoglu 2002) make the educational system less intellectually challenging and moulding the

structure of economic activity (Leamer et al 1999) So studying how cross-county differences in

NRE are associated with the distribution of income within a country has theoretical empirical and

policy implications

In this study we offer empirical evidence on the relationship between income inequality and

the endowment of natural resources using data at the county level in Chile for the period 2006-

2017 Income inequality is measured by the Gini coefficient The importance of NRE is proxied

using a measure of natural resource dependence (NRD) defined as the percentage of the total

1 A 2014 OECD report on income inequality (httpwwwoecdorgsocialincome-distribution-databasehtm) showed Chile as the country with the highest Gini coefficient of disposable income among OECD countries OECD also indicates Chile as the country with the widest gap between the richest 10 percent and the poorest 10 percent of countryrsquos population among its 34 members (OECD 2014)

26

employment in each county corresponding to the primary sector (agriculture forestry fishing and

mining)

The main hypothesis to be tested is whether income inequality is positively associated with

the degree of NRD The transmission mechanisms through which natural resources could influence

socioeconomic outcomes could be based on the market or institutions The market-based approach

argues that natural resource booms could be associated with an appreciation of the real exchange

rate and a crowding out effect over other more productive economic activities such as

manufacturing It could also delay the adoption of new technologies and reduce incentives to invest

in physical and human capital (Gylfason amp Zoega 2003) Based on the ldquoResource Curse

Hypothesisrdquo (RCH) natural resources could be a curse when the political and institutional

framework is weak and natural resources are concentrated in space such as oil and minerals

(Deacon 2011) 2 Among institutional channels a higher NRD or natural resource booms could

be associated with rent seeking misallocation of labour and entrepreneurial talent institutional

and political decline or even violent conflicts For instance the ldquoParadox of Plentyrdquo sustains that

windfalls of revenues as a consequence of resource booms could be related to a lack of incentives

to perform efficiently corruption patronage and local authorities favouring their voters or being

captured by the richest groups (Dauvin amp Guerreiro 2017) Hence a higher NRD or natural

resource booms could be the explanation not only for low levels of growth in regions more

dependent on natural resources but also it could be the root of income disparities

2 There is a wide strand of research on the Resource Curse Hypothesis however the evidence so far is not conclusive Evidence in favour of RCH has been mainly found in developing resource rich countries (Auty 1993 2001 Badeeb Lean amp Clark 2017 Blanco amp Grier 2012 Borge et al 2015 Brunnschweiler amp Bulte 2008 Sachs amp Warner 2001 Van der Ploeg 2011)

27

To test our hypothesis that is whether the levels of income inequality across counties are

positively associated with the degree of NRD we use a spatial econometric approach We use this

approach because attributes such as income inequality in one region may not be independent of

attributes in neighbouring regions (Armstrong amp Taylor 2000) This process of spatial dependence

invalidates the use of traditional (non-spatial) approaches

This study seeks to make two contributions to research First previous empirical evidence

shows a significant spatial dimension of income inequality in Chile (Paredes et al 2016)

However this dimension has been barely explored with most studies limiting the degree of

disaggregation to a regional scale (Aroca amp Bosch 2000) We use a spatial approach which makes

it possible to model and test the significance of the spatial dimension in the analysis of income

inequality and its relationship with other variables Second previous research for the Chilean

economy linking inequality with NRE has been mainly focused on explaining differences between

regions or the importance and effects of the mining-copper sector (Aroca amp Atienza 2011 Ebert

amp La Menza 2015 Lagos amp Blanco 2010 Rehner Baeza amp Barton 2014) We extend this

analysis using data for local economies Identifying and quantifying the impact of NRE on income

inequality at the county level is likely to be more informative for policies aiming to address the

current developmental bias between the metropolitan region and the rest of the country Moreover

the analysis of the role of natural resources in conjunction with other potential sources of inequality

may shed lights in understanding the persistence of the high levels of inequality observed in the

Chilean economy All in all this study could contribute to the design of policies that

simultaneously help reduce inequality increase efficiency and promote sustainable and inclusive

growth

28

Our main finding shows that after controlling for other potential sources of income

inequality such as educational level demographic characteristics and the level of public

government expenditure the degree of dependence on natural resources has a significant effect on

income inequality However contrary to our expectations the effect is negative This result

suggests that the natural or policy-driven process of transformation from primary and extractive

activities to manufacturing and service sectors imposes additional challenges to central and local

authorities aiming to reduce income inequality

In section 22 we review the literature on the relationship between income inequality and

natural resources In section 23 we establish our research problem and main hypothesis Section

24 describes our data and methods and section 25 the empirical results We finish with section

26 discussing our main results concluding and proposing avenues for future research

22 Inequality and Natural Resources

221 Theoretical Framework

Explanations for income inequality can be associated with individual institutional political

and contextual characteristics Individual characteristics include age gender and mainly the level

of education and skills of the population in the labour force For instance globalization and

technological change lead firms to increase the demand for skilled labour deepening income

inequality between skilled and unskilled workers (Atkinson 2015 Milanovic 2016 Tinbergen

1975) Among institutional characteristics labour unions collective bargaining and the minimum

wage have been suggested as explanations of income inequality (Acemoglu Aghion et al 2001

Atkinson 2015) Policy design associated with market regulation progressive taxation and

redistribution can also impact the levels and patterns of inequality

29

A key factor in understanding the levels and differences in income distribution within a

country may be its endowment of natural resources NRE shapes the structure of the economy

(Leamer et al 1999) it is associated with the creation of institutions that define the political

culture and it can also influence the performance of other sectors (Watkins 1963) In addition

NRE determines initial conditions market competition ownership over resources rent seeking

and the geographical concentration of the population and economic activity

Cross‐countryliterature

Bourguignon and Morrison (1990) introduce one of the earliest theoretical frameworks

describing the relationship between inequality and NRE They develop a small open economy

model where income distribution is a function of NRE ownership structure and trade protection

Giving cross-sectional evidence for a group of developing countries they conclude that the impact

of NRE particularly mineral resources and land depends on the number and size of the firms

whether they are public or private and the level of protection A higher concentration of production

in a few private firms a big share of production oriented to foreign instead of domestic markets

and protection increasing the relative price of scarce resources are some of the reasons explaining

why some countries are less egalitarian than others

NRE could also influence the evolution and levels of inequality by determining the initial

distribution of incomes This is known as the ldquoEngerman-Sokoloff Hypothesisrdquo (Engerman amp

Sokoloff 1997 Engerman et al 2002) In addition Leamer (1999) proposes that inequality and

development paths in each economy are a function of its economic structure which in turn depends

on ldquofundamentalsrdquo and ldquosymptomsrdquo On the one hand ldquofundamentalsrdquo refer to resource

endowment production structure closeness to markets and governments interventions On the

30

other hand ldquosymptomsrdquo are related to institutions employment structure and net export structure

Using this conceptual framework Leamer argues that natural Resource-Rich Countries (RRC) can

experience a higher level of inequality because can have a ldquodumbbell educational systemrdquo

ownership is concentrated in small groups and extraction activities require low-skilled workers

This implies fewer incentives to educate citizens until very late in the development process

resulting in human capital not prepared to take advantage of the process of technological progress

and delaying the emergence of more efficient and competitive sectors such as manufacturing and

services

Using 1980 and 1990 data for a group of countries classified according to land abundance

Leamer (1999) provides evidence showing that on the one hand land-scarce countries concentrate

their production and employment in sectors that promote equality such as capital-intensive

manufacturing chemical or machinery On the other hand countries abundant in natural resources

concentrate their production trade or employment in sectors that promote income inequality such

as the production of food beverages extraction activities or forestry

Gylfason and Zoega (2003) using a framework based on standard growth models also

proposed a positive relationship between NRE and inequality They assume that workers can work

in the primary sector or in the manufacturing (including services) sector In addition wage income

is equally distributed in the manufacturing sector but unequally in the primary sector (because of

initial distribution competition rent seeking etc) Therefore inequality will be greater when a

bigger proportion of labour is dedicated to extraction activities in the primary sector This

phenomenon is further amplified because of lower incentives to invest in physical and human

capital to adopt new technologies and to increase the share of the manufacturing sector

31

Diverse mechanisms explaining the link between NRE and inequality have been proposed

arguing that NRE determines simultaneously economic growth and inequality (Gylfason amp Zoega

2003) NRE could impact economic growth through the real exchange rate and the crowding-out

effect on manufacturing (ldquoDutch Diseaserdquo) reducing incentives to invest in physical and human

capital (Easterly 2007) and influencing the processes of technology adoption industrialization

and diversification of the economy in a manner that is less conducive to growth (Bulte et al 2005)

These potential explanations related to the called ldquoResource Curse Hypothesisrdquo do not have strong

empirical support (Auty 2001 Bulte et al 2005)

NRE may also influence economic growth through the quality of institutions (Acemoglu

1995 Acemoglu Aghion et al 2001 Acemoglu amp Robinson 2002 Engerman amp Sokoloff 1997

Engerman et al 2002) the concentration of ownership political power and rent-seeking NRE

acts by shaping institutional context and social infrastructure a phenomenon that is stronger when

resources are spatially concentrated such as minerals and plantations (Bulte et al 2005) NRE

could also have a significant effect on social cohesion and instability spreading its influence like

a disease (Brunori Ferreira amp Peragine 2013 Kanbur amp Venables 2005 Milanovic 2016

Ocampo 2004)

Considering a non-tradable sector intensive in unskilled workers Goderis and Malone

(2011) develop a model where the natural resources sector experiences an exogenous gift of

resource income They analyse the impact over income inequality of resource booms proxied by

changes in a commodity price index They conclude that inequality decreases in the short run but

increases after the initial reduction

32

Fum and Hodler (2010) show that natural resources increase inequality but this is

conditional on the level of ethnical polarization of society Carmignani (2013 2010) confirms this

positive relationship using different measures of dependence and abundance and goes further

arguing that inequality constitutes an indirect channel through which NRE affects human

development

Singlecountryevidence

Most of the studies about the relationship between inequality and NRE derive from cross-

country analyses Evidence for specific countries has been mainly based on case studies Howie

and Atakhanova (2014) based on the model of Goderis and Malone (2011) find for the case of

Kazakhstan that income and consumption inequality decreased significantly after booms in the oil-

and-gas sector because of resource booms increase the demand for non-tradable goods which are

intensive in unskilled workers The results depend on the level of rurality institutional quality

education levels and public spending on health and education Fleming and Measham (2015b

2015a) evaluate the impact of booms in the mining and oil sectors in Australia They find that a

boom in the mining sector increases income inequality due to commuting and migration among

regions This phenomenon can be exacerbated when the demanding access to natural resource

revenues is associated with the creation of more local administrative units (counties provinces and

even regions) but the government capacity is not simultaneously improved (Cust amp Poelhekke

2015 Michaels 2011) Furthermore the benefits that a region can receive in the form of fiscal

transfers can be more than compensated by the loses due to city-to-mine commuting such as the

case of mining regions in Chile (Aroca amp Atienza 2011)

33

Other studies at the local level have analysed the impact of the mining sector in Peru (Aragoacuten

amp Rud 2013 Loayza amp Rigolini 2016 Loayza Teran amp Rigolini 2013) Spain (Domenech

2008) and Canada (Papyrakis amp Raveh 2014) and the effects of oil windfalls in Brazil (Caselli amp

Michaels 2013)

In summary there is a wide range of potential mechanisms through which NRE could

influence income inequality Although most of them seem to suggest a positive relationship others

such as commuting and increased within-county demand for non-tradable goods and services

could lead to a negative association This highlights the need to know the sign of this association

in the Chilean economy where the trend shows a reduction in the degree of NRD After controlling

for other factors a positive link would support the argument that the reduction in the degree of

NRD has been relevant in the reduction experienced by income inequality in the same period

However a negative link would support the position that the reduction in NRD has contributed to

explain the persistence of income inequality and its slow reduction

222 The relevance of the spatial approach

Inequalities within countries are still the most important form of inequality from the political

point of view (Milanovic 2016) People from a geographic area within a country are influenced

and care most about their status relative to the people in other areas in the same country The

influence among regions involves multiple aspects (eg economic political and environmental)

These potential interactions have been traditionally ignored assuming independence among

observations related to different regions Moreover neglecting the process of spatial interaction in

key indicators of the economic and social performance of a country may mislead the design of the

public policy

34

The spatial dimension could play a significant role in understanding the distribution of

income within a country One strand of efforts aiming to capture the geographic heterogeneity of

inequality has been focussed on decomposing general indicators such as the Gini coefficient or the

Theil Index Evidence for different countries including the US (Doran amp Jordan 2016) China

(Akita 2003 Gustafsson amp Shi 2002 Ye Ma Ye Chen amp Xie 2017 Yue Zhang Ye Cheng

amp Leipnik 2014) Japan (Ohtake 2008) South Africa (Leibbrandt Finn amp Woolard 2012) and

Chile (Paredes et al 2016) shows that regional inequality is sensitive to the geographic scale of

analysis These studies also show a significant spatial component in the explanation of inequality

of income expenditure or gross domestic product for each country

Another strand explicitly uses exploratory spatial data analysis (ESDA) and spatial

econometrics ESDA has been used to provide new insights about the nature of regional disparities

of incomes and growth rates (Celebioglu amp Dallrsquoerba 2010 Yue et al 2014) Spatial econometric

models aim to assess and address the nature of the spatial effects These effects could be the result

of ldquospatial heterogeneityrdquo that is different relationships in distinct locations or ldquospatial

dependencerdquo which implies cross-sectional interactions (spillover effects) among units from

distinct but near locations

Spatial spillovers have been analysed to study both positive and negative spatial correlation

among less resource-abundant counties and resource-abundant counties On the one hand less

resource-abundant counties may experience positive spillovers because their industries supply

more goods and services to meet the increasing regional demand They can also be benefited from

positive agglomeration externalities and higher investment in private and public infrastructure

(Allcott amp Keniston 2014 Michaels 2011) On the other hand negative spillovers could be the

35

result of a high degree of interregional migration that limits the rise in wages and higher local

prices due to the increase in the share of the non-tradable sector In addition local governments

could have a limited capacity to translate the revenues from resource booms into effective public

policies promoting a sustained local development (Beine Coulombe amp Vermeulen 2015 Caselli

amp Michaels 2013 Papyrakis amp Raveh 2014)

23 Research problem and hypotheses

We can conclude from our overview of the literature that the theoretical and empirical

evidence about the link between inequality and natural resources is inconclusive This does not

make clear whether the process of reduction in the degree of dependence on natural resources

such as that experienced by the Chilean economy helps to explain the sustained but slow reduction

in income inequality or its high persistence

The research question guiding this study relates to how the natural resource endowment

determines the paths and structure of income inequality in natural resource-rich countries Using

the case of Chile the main hypotheses to be tested is whether a higher degree of dependence on

natural resources is associated with higher levels of income inequality To do that we use data at

the county level and we explicitly include the spatial dimension Our aim is to arrive at a more

comprehensive understanding of the drivers and transmission mechanisms explaining the

evolution and patterns shown by income inequality In addition we test whether the spatial

dimension plays a significant role in explaining differences in income distribution in Chile

36

24 Data and Methods

We use county-level data for the years 2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017 The reason

for not using contiguous years is that income data at the household level are only available every

two-three years from the Chilean National Socioeconomic Characterization Survey (CASEN in its

Spanish acronym)3 For the period 2006-2017 the Chilean administrative division considers 15

regions 54 provinces and 346 counties Data on income are available for 324 counties and six

years resulting in a panel with 1944 observations4

We start evaluating the spatial dimension in our data and analysing the link between

inequality and NRD using a cross-sectional setting To this end we use the ldquosix-year averagerdquo

(2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017) for our variables given the low time variability showed by

our measures of income inequality and NRD Results are then compared with those of a panel data

setting

241 Operationalization of key variables

The dependent variable in the present study income inequality at the county level is

measured calculating the Gini coefficient using three definitions of household income labour

autonomous and monetary income5 Labour income corresponds to the incomes obtained by all

members in the household excluding domestic service consisting of wages and salaries earnings

3 CASEN survey is conducted by the Chilean Ministry of Social Development covering topics such as education employment income and health CASEN is considered nationally representative and it is the main source for measures of inequality and poverty used for the design and evaluation of social policies in Chile 4 The six waves of CASEN for our study considered an average of 75599 households and 252081 individuals 5 The Gini coefficient is chosen because provides an overall estimate of income inequality It summarizes what proportion of the population gains what proportion of the total income The Gini coefficient can range between 0 (everyone in the population has the same income) and 1 (one person earns 100 per cent of the income in the community)

37

from independent work and self-provision of goods Autonomous income is the sum of labour

income and non-labour income (including capital income) consisting of rents interest and dividend

earnings pension healthcare benefits and other private transfers Finally monetary income is

defined as the sum of autonomous income and monetary subsidies which correspond to cash

transfers by the public sector through social programs Appendix A shows summary statistics for

the Gini coefficient of our three measures of income

The main independent variable in our study is the degree of dependence on natural resources

in each county To have an idea of the importance of each economic activity in the Chilean

economy particularly those activities related to natural resources Figure 21 shows their average

share in Chilean Gross Domestic Product (GDP) for the period 2006-17 We can observe that the

leading activities are those related to the primary sector especially mining and to the tertiary

sector where financial personal commerce restaurants and hotels services stand out The shares

of each economic activity in GDP vary significantly between Chilean regions and such

information is not available at the county level

Figure 21 Average share in GDP of economic activities (2006ndash17)

38

Leamer (1999) argues that when the main source of income is labour income (as indeed

happens for the Chilean case) using employment shares allows a better approach to measuring

dependence on natural resources Using employment data from CASEN survey we define our

measure of NRD as the employment in the primary sector (mining fishing forestry and

agriculture) as a percentage of the total employment in each county We name this variable

pss_casen where ldquopssrdquo stands for ldquoprimary sector sharerdquo We built other two proxies of NRD

using data from the ldquoServicio de Impuestos Internosrdquo (SII) which is the agency in charge of

collecting taxes in Chile The variable pss measures the percentage of employment in the primary

sector and the variable pss_firms measures the number of firms in the primary sector as a

percentage of the total number of firms in each county Appendix B shows summary statistics for

our three measures of NRD disaggregated by region

Figure 22 Evolution of Gini coefficient and measures of NRD (2006ndash17)

39

Figure 22 shows the evolution of our measure of inequality (using the Gini coefficient of

autonomous income) and our three potential proxies for NRD for the period 2006-2017 We

observe that both income inequality and the degree of NRD show a downward trend This seems

to support our hypothesis of a positive link between inequality and NRD however we need to

control of other sources of inequality before getting such a conclusion In what follows we use the

variable gini as our measure of income inequality capturing the Gini coefficient of autonomous

income Our measure of NRD is the variable pss_casen defined previously

Figure 23 Spatial distribution of Gini coefficient and NRD (2006ndash17)

Note Gini and NRD averages 2006-09-11-13-15-17 for 324 Chilean counties divided into five equal groups Source Own elaboration based on CASEN survey

40

Figure 23 shows quantile maps for income inequality (on the left) and NRD (on the right)

using the six-years average dataset6 On the one hand we observe that high levels of inequality

seem to be clustered in the Centre-South of the country where agriculture forestry and fishery are

the predominant economic activities Only isolated counties show high inequality in the Centre

(Metropolitan area where the countyrsquos capital is located) and North (Mining) areas On the other

hand our measure of NRD seems to show an opposite spatial pattern than income inequality with

high levels in the Centre and North of the country

242 Control variables

To control for county characteristics we use a set of socio-economic demographic and

institutional variables Economic factors are captured by the natural log of the mean autonomous

household income per capita (in thousands of Chilean pesos of 2017) lnincome the poverty rate

poverty the unemployment rate unemployment the percentage of the population living in rural

areas rural and the average years of education of the population over 15 years old education

Demographic factors include the proportion of the population in the labour force labour_force

and the natural log of population density (population divided by county area) lndensity

We also include the natural log of the total municipal public expenditure per capita

lnmuni_expenditure to control for municipal heterogeneity This heterogeneity is mainly related

to the capacity of municipalities to generate their own revenues In addition the richest

municipalities are in the Metropolitan region which concentrates economic power and around 40

6 After sorting a variable in ascending order quantile maps use the quantiles (quartiles quintiles deciles etc) as class breaks to divide the distribution of the variable where each class includes approximately the same number of observations (counties)

41

of the population This has basically implied a lag in the development of regions other than the

metropolitan region

The spatial distribution of our measures of income inequality and NRD displayed in Figure

23 seems to show different patterns in the North Centre and South of the country Appendix C

shows the administrative division of Chile in 15 regions and how we have grouped them in three

zones North Centre and South We consider as the ldquoCentrerdquo area that formed by the Metropolitan

region (XIII) and its two neighbouring regions V and VI Using the Centre area as our reference

we include in our analysis two dummy variables indicating whether a county is located in the North

area (regions XV I II III and IV) or South area (regions VII VIII IX XIV X XI and XII)

Appendix D shows summary statistics for the set of numeric control variables and the

correlation matrix between our measure of NRD pss_casen and the set of numeric controls

243 Methods

To assess and then consider the spatial nature of the data we need to define the set of relevant

neighbours for each country This is operationalized by building a matrix called ldquoWrdquo with a ldquo1rdquo

for neighbouring counties and a ldquo0rdquo for non-neighbouring counties We could build W using

contiguity-based (whether counties share a border or point) or geography-based (taking the

distances among the centroids of each county polygon) spatial weights Specifically we build a W

matrix considering the 5-nearest counties7 Two reasons explain the choice of k-nearest

neighbours First we cannot use a contiguity criterium because we do not have information about

all the counties and there are some geographically isolated counties Second given the significant

7 We assign a ldquo1rdquo to the five nearest counties to each county based on the distances among the polygon centroids Then W is ldquorow standardizedrdquo This facilitates the interpretation of the spatial lag of a variable as the ldquoweighted average valuerdquo of the same variable in neighbouring counties

42

differences in county areas (ldquobig countiesrdquo in northern and southern regions) using a distance-

band criterium with a not enough large distance band can lead to many ldquoislandsrdquo in extreme regions

and a multi-modal distribution for the number of neighbours

We start testing our inequality and NRD variables for spatial autocorrelation in order to

evaluate statistically the clustering patterns shown in Figure 23 Next we run an OLS regression

of inequality against NRD and our set of controls and we test the spatial autocorrelation of OLS

residuals If we cannot reject the null hypothesis of random spatial distribution we do not need

spatial models to analyse income inequality which would give contrasting evidence to previous

suggestions about the relevance of the spatial dimension of income inequality in Chile (Paredes

2013 Paredes et al 2016) If we find significant spatial autocorrelation in the OLS residuals this

justifies the use of spatial models and highlight the need to find the correct spatial structure8

If inequality in one county spillovers or influences inequality in neighbouring counties the

spatial lag of inequality should be included as an explanatory variable and we should use a spatial

autoregressive model (SAR) If some unobserved variable is the explanation for the clustering of

counties with similar inequality then this will be better captured including a spatial lag of the

errors and we should use a spatial error model (SEM) (Anselin 1988 Anselin amp Bera 1998)

Finally when our main explanatory variable or some of the controls show spatial autocorrelation

a spatial lag of the explanatory variable(s) should be included in our model

8 The existence of spatial autocorrelation violates the standard assumption of independence among observations needed for OLS regression This will result in OLS coefficients biased and inconsistent (Anselin 1988)

43

244 Spatial Model Specification

A model that includes the three forms of spatial dependence described above is called the

Cliff-Ord Model The model in its cross-sectional representation could be expressed as

119910 120582119882119910 119883120573 119882119883120574 119906 (21)

where

119906 120588119882119906 120576 (22)

119882 is our weight matrix that works as an NxN spatial lag operator9 Thus 119882119910 119882119883 and 119882119906

are the spatial lags for the dependent variable explanatory variables and the error term

respectively The parameter 120582 capture the spatial dependence in the dependent variable 120574 the

spatial dependence in the explanatory variables 120588 capture the spatial dependence in the error term

and 120598 is a vector of idiosyncratic errors For instance if ldquoyrdquo is income inequality and ldquoXrdquo a measure

of NRD the level of inequality in one county will be explained by the degree of NRD in the same

county 119883120573 the average degree of NRD in neighbouring counties 119882119883120574 the average level of

inequality in neighbouring counties 120582119882119910 and the average value of residuals in neighbouring

counties 12058811988211990610

From equations (21) and (22) the SAR and SEM models can be seen as special cases of

the Cliff-Ord representation after imposing restrictions over the spatial parameters 120582 120574 and 120588 For

the specification of the spatial panel models we follow the terminology by Croissant and Millo

9 The spatial lag is a weighted sum of the values observed at neighbouring locations 10 On the one hand the impact that income inequality in one county has over income inequality in neighbouring counties is called a ldquoglobal spilloverrdquo and it is associated with the feedback effect among neighbours (one county is its neighboursrsquo neighbourrdquo) on the other hand the influence that the degree of NRD in neighbouring counties has over inequality in one county is called a ldquolocal spilloverrdquo

44

(2018) Spatial panel models including the spatial lag of the dependent variable (SAR) the spatial

lag of the residuals (SEM) or both (SARAR) are described in Appendix E

25 Results

251 Exploratory Spatial Data Analysis (ESDA)

To analyse the significance of the spatial dimension in our data set we use the six-year

average of our variables Spatial autocorrelation is tested using the Moranrsquos I statistic11 Moranrsquos

I measures the correlation of one variable with itself in space12 Figure 24 shows the Moran scatter

plots where the standardized variable (Gini coefficient and NRD for each county) appears in the

horizontal axis against its spatial lag (average value in the 5-nearest neighbouring counties) The

Moranrsquos I (slope of the line in the Moran scatter plot) of income inequality shows a significant

positive spatial autocorrelation that is counties with high (low) inequality tend to be close to each

other

11 There are many statistics to formally test the significance of the spatial dimension in the distribution of our data The null hypothesis assumes spatial randomness which means that there is not spatial structure in the data so any spatial pattern is equally likely to occur and values in one location do not depend on values in other locations The alternative hypotheses can be the existence of positive or negative spatial autocorrelation Positive spatial autocorrelation means similar values in neighbouring locations (less variability than under spatial randomness) Negative spatial autocorrelation means dissimilar values in neighbouring locations (more variability than under spatial randomness) 12 Traditional measures of correlation such as the Pearsonrsquos coefficient measure the degree of linear correlation between two different variables Measures of spatial autocorrelation assess the correlation between the values of one variable in one location related to the values of the same variable in other neighbouring locations

45

Figure 23 Moran scatter plots for variables gini and pss_casen

Moranrsquos I is a measure of global spatial autocorrelation this means it is intended to capture

the clustering property of the entire data set To identify where are the significant hot-spots

(clusters of counties showing high income inequality) or cold-spots (clusters of counties showing

low income inequality) we need local indicators of spatial association (LISA) Using the local

Moranrsquos I (not reported) we find significant hot-spots in the South of the country (mainly

agricultural regions) and significant cold-spots in the Centre (Metropolitan area) of the country

The next step is to check whether the clustering pattern in inequality is the result of a process of

spatial dependence in the variable itself or it can be explained by other variables related to

inequality

252 Cross-sectional analysis

We start analysing differences in income inequality between counties using the six-year

average data and running an OLS regression for the model

119892119894119899119894 120573 120573 119901119904119904_119888119886119904119890119899 120573 119897119899119894119899119888119900119898119890 120573 119901119900119907119890119903119905119910 120573 119906119899119890119898119901119897119900119910119898119890119899119905 120573 119897119886119887119900119906119903_119891119900119903119888119890 120573 119890119889119906119888119886119905119894119900119899 120573 119897119899119889119890119899119904119894119905119910 120573 119903119906119903119886119897 120573 119897119899119898119906119899_119890119909119901119890119899119889119894119905119906119903119890 120573 119899119900119903119905ℎ 120573 119904119900119906119905ℎ

(23)

46

The Moran scatter plot and spatial statistical test of OLS residuals from equation (23) are

in Appendix F OLS residuals show a small but significant positive autocorrelation (Moranrsquos I =

0121) This means that income inequality continues showing a significant degree of spatial

autocorrelation after controlling for the set of covariates In addition robust Lagrange Multiplier

(LM) tests show that a spatial error model is preferred over a spatial lag model (Anselin Bera

Florax amp Yoon 1996)13 This means that income inequality tends to cluster in zones larger than a

county so the analysis should be performed on a larger scale such as provinces regions or macro

zones If the SAR model were preferred it would mean that income inequality in one county is

influenced by the level of income inequality in neighbouring counties To find the spatial structure

that best fits the clustering process of income inequality we run the full set of spatial model

specifications in a cross-sectional setting and results are shown in Table 21

Column 2 in Table 21 shows the results of our ldquoOLSrdquo model The ldquoSLXrdquo model includes

spatial dependence only through the explanatory variables The ldquoSARrdquo model includes the spatial

lag of the dependent variable as a regressor and the ldquoSEMrdquo model includes spatial dependence

through the error term The ldquoSARARrdquo model includes both the spatial lag of the response and the

errors and the ldquoSDMrdquo and ldquoSDEMrdquo are the extensions of the ldquoSARrdquo and ldquoSEMrdquo models

respectively including the spatial lag of the explanatory variables Finally a model including

spatial lags for the response errors and explanatory variables (the ldquoSARARXrdquo model) is shown in

the last column

13 Following the ldquoAnselin methodrdquo when both non robust LM tests are significant we should select between the robust LR tests From Table F1 in Appendix F only the robust LM test for the SEM model (RLMerr) appears as significant

47

Table 21

Cross-sectional Model Comparison (six-year average data)

48

Opposite to our hypothesis we observe a significant and negative coefficient for our measure

of NRD This means that counties more dependent on natural resources show lower levels of

inequality Education years population density and municipal expenditure per capita are also

negatively related to inequality On the other hand the level of income the poverty rate and the

proportion of the population living in rural areas show a positive relationship with income

inequality There is no significant influence of the unemployment rate and the proportion of the

population in the labour force In addition the SAR SEM and SARAR models show a

significantly higher average inequality in the South of the country related to the Centre area

The main finding from our cross-sectional analysis is that there is a significant and negative

relationship between inequality and NRD which is quite robust to the model specification

253 Panel Data analysis

Like the cross-sectional case we start estimating the panel without spatial effects Results

for the pooled fixed effects (FE) and random effects (RE) specifications of equation (3) are in

Appendix G Spatial models were estimated using Maximum Likelihood (ML) and Generalized

Moments (GM) and assuming that the spatial structure (W matrix) is the same for all years14

Tables 22 23 and 24 show results for the ML estimation of the SAR SEM and SARAR models

using the pooled FE and RE specifications Results for the GM estimation are in Appendix H

All our spatial models include time fixed effects In the case of the pooled and RE models they

additionally include indicator variables for those counties located in the North and South of the

country

14 In traditional (non-spatial) panels data are stacked as time series for each observational unit (county) In the case of spatial panels data are stacked as slice of cross-sections for each year in the panel

49

The main result is that the negative and significant effect of NRD on income inequality is

robust to most of the spatial panel specifications In addition the coefficient for the variable

pss_casen changes slightly among panel specifications (pooled FE and RE) but does not change

among spatial models (SAR SEM and SARAR)

Another important finding is related to the significance of the spatial dimension of income

inequality When spatial models cross-sectional or panel are compared to non-spatial models

there are no major differences in the magnitude of the coefficients or their significance This could

mean that the positive spatial autocorrelation shown by income inequality seems to be better

explained by a process of spatial heterogeneity rather than spatial dependence The practical

implication of this result is that including dummy variables for aggregated units (eg regions or

groups of regions) could be enough to control for the spatial dimension in the modelling and

analysis of income inequality

Among control variables years of education seems to be the main variable for the design of

long-term policies aimed at reducing inequality This result is in line with previous evidence for

cross-country studies (Leamer et al 1999) and specific countries (Howie amp Atakhanova 2014)

Municipal expenditure per capita also shows a significant and negative association with income

inequality in the pooled and RE spatial specifications This means that higher municipal

expenditure helps to reduce inequality between counties but its effect is more limited within

counties This result support the importance of local governments (Fleming amp Measham 2015a)

however the negative coefficient appears as evidence against the ldquoParadox of Plentyrdquo (Borge et

al 2015)

50

Table 22

ML Spatial SAR Models

Table 23

ML Spatial SEM Models

51

Table 24

ML Spatial SARAR Models

26 Discussion and conclusions

In this essay we delve deep into the sources of income inequality analysing its association

with the degree of dependence on natural resources using county-level data for the 2006ndash2017

period in Chile Given recent evidence for the Chilean economy suggesting a significant spatial

dimension we assess and incorporate explicitly the spatial structure of income inequality using

spatial methods We use cross-sectional and panel data to evaluate the significance of the spatial

dimension and we test whether NRD has a positive effect on income inequality

Contrary to what theory predicts NRD shows a significant and negative association with

income inequality This result is robust to the type of analysis (cross-sectional vs panel data) the

approach (spatial vs non-spatial) and the inclusion of different controls The negative and

significant coefficient implies that if the degree of NRD would not have experienced a 10 drop

during this period income inequality could have fallen in 2 additional points So the downward

trend in the participation of the primary sector in terms of employment in the Chilean economy

52

could be one of the main reasons explaining the high persistence in the levels of income inequality

This means that those areas that undergo a process of productive transformation mainly towards

the services sector would be facing greater problems to reduce inequality This process of

productive transformation natural or policy-driven highlights the importance of policies focused

on human capital and the role of local governments in reducing inequality

The main implication for policymakers is that a reduction in NRD does not help to reduce

inequality generating additional challenges for local and central governments in its attempt to

transform the structure of their economies to fewer dependent ones on natural resources The

finding of a significant spatial dimension suggests that defining macro zones capturing the spatial

heterogeneity in the data should be done before analysing the relationship among variables and the

design and evaluation of specific policies Particularly relevant in those areas experiencing a

reduction in NRD are migration commuting and the characteristics of the tertiary (services) sector

In addition our findings show that education and municipal expenditure could be effective policy

tools in the fight to reduce inequality in Chile

Although our results seem quite robust they do not allow us to make causal inferences about

the effect of NRD on income inequality However we could think of the following explanation to

explain the negative relationship found and the differences between geographical areas

Areas highly dependent on NR used to demand a high proportion of low-skill labour This

has change in sectors such as the mining sector in the northern area which has simultaneously

experienced an increase in activities related to the service sector such as retail restaurants

transport and housing However those services associated with more skilled labour such as the

finance sector remain concentrated in the capital region The reduction in the degree of NRD

(employment in extractive activities) implies lower labour force but more specialized with most

53

of the low-skilled labour transferred to a service sector characterized by low productivity and low

wages

Non-spatial models show that the North and South particularly the latter present

significantly higher levels of inequality This could be associated with the type of resources with

ldquopointrdquo resources such as minerals in the North and ldquodiffusedrdquo resources such as agriculture in the

South This translates into higher average incomes in the Centre and North areas and lower average

incomes in the South

The reduction in NRD implies not only a movement of the labour force from extractive

activities to manufacturing or services with the latter characterized by low productivity and low

salaries of the labour force We could also speculate that most of the high incomes move to the

central area where the economic power and ownership over firms and resources are concentrated

This would explain low inequality associated with higher average incomes in the central area and

high inequality associated with lower average incomes in the South A more in-depth analysis

capturing the mobility of wealth and labour force between counties or more aggregated areas is

needed to better understand the causal mechanism involved

Our findings open avenues for future research in different strands First studies on the causes

of income inequality should take the role of NRD into consideration which has been overlooked

so far Given that the spatial dimension of income inequality seems to be explained by a

phenomenon of spatial heterogeneity estimation strategies such as spatial regime models or

geographically weighted regression should be used (Chi amp Zhu 2019) Second the effect of NRD

on income inequality could manifest through different channels such as education fiscal transfers

and institutions We could extend our analysis to identify which of these competing channels is

the most relevant Transforming some continuous variables such as educational level to a

54

categorical variable or defining new indicator variables for instance whether a local government

shows or not an efficient performance we could classify counties in different groups and then

check whether there are differences or not in the relationship between income inequality and NRD

A third strand could be to disaggregate our measure of NRD for different industries This

would allow us to test differences among industries and to identify the sectors that promote greater

equality and which greater inequality Forth the analysis of the consequences of income inequality

on other economic and social phenomena such as efficiency economic growth and social cohesion

has a growing interest in researchers and policymakers Our findings suggest that to answer the

question of whether income inequality has a causal impact on other variables we could include a

measure of NRD as an instrument to address endogeneity issues For instance two interesting

topics for future research are the analysis of how differences in income inequality between counties

could help to explain differences in the level of efficiency of local governments and differences in

the degree of social cohesion (unrest) throughout the country Those are the issues to be addressed

in the next two essays

55

Chapter 3 The Impact of Income Inequality on the Efficiency of

Municipalities in Chile

31 Introduction

In Chile municipalities are the smallest administrative unit for which citizens choose their

local authorities playing an important role in the provision of public goods and services at the

local level Municipalities have a similar set of objectives but the level of financial resources

available to finance their activities is highly heterogeneous This could result in significant

differences in the levels of performance between municipalities Despite their importance there is

little empirical evidence about the efficiency of local governments in Chile This essay aims to

measure the technical efficiency of Chilean municipalities and to analyse how local characteristics

particularly those related to income distribution at the county level could help to explain

differences in municipal performance

Cross-country studies situate Chile as an efficient country in international comparisons about

efficiency of government spending (Herrera amp Pang 2005 Loacutepez amp Miller 2008) However

evidence for Chile at the local level is relatively sparse suggesting significant levels of

inefficiency For instance Pacheco Sanchez and Villena (2013) found a mean efficiency level of

around 70 using a sample of 309 municipalities for the period 2008-2010 This suggests that

municipalities could achieve the same level of output by reducing the usage of inputs by an average

of 30 Their study also showed that those municipalities more dependent on the central

56

government or those located in counties with lower income per capita are more efficient than their

counterparts

Most empirical research on Local Government Efficiency (LGE) has been conducted for

member countries of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) of

which Chile has been a member since 2010 In the case of European countries such as Spain and

Italy which share similar characteristics such as the monetary union and levels of GDP per head

efficiency studies have been mainly motivated by budgetary constraints (Balaguer-Coll Brun-

Martos Maacuterquez-Ramos amp Prior 2019 lo Storto 2013) The Chilean context differs in three

main ways from its OECD counterparts First except for the Metropolitan Region that concentrates

most of the population Chilean regions are highly dependent on natural resources Second Chile

is also characterized by one of the highest levels of income inequality among OECD countries

which contrast with the situation of developed natural resource-rich countries such as Australia

and Norway Third although budget constraints are also a relevant issue Chilean municipalities

have experienced a sustained increase in the level of financial resources and expenditure

Another relevant distinction when we benchmark the performance of municipalities across

different countries is the type of public services they provide On the one hand in most of the

countries included Chile the main role of local governments is to provide ldquoservices to peoplerdquo

such as public education and public health On the other hand there are countries such as Australia

where local governments mainly provide ldquoservices to propertyrdquo including waste management

maintenance of local roads and the provision of community facilities such as libraries swimming

pools and parks (Dollery Wallis amp Akimov 2010 Drew Kortt amp Dollery 2015 McQuestin

Drew amp Dollery 2018)

57

Despite contextual differences Chilean municipalities seem not to perform differently from

municipalities in other developed and natural resource-rich countries where income inequality is

significantly less than in Chile (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018a) This result highlights the

need to study the role of income inequality and the degree of dependence on natural resources over

LGE characteristics that have been largely overlooked in the literature

We measure and analyse differences in municipal performance using a two-stage approach

In the first stage we measure municipal efficiency using an input-oriented Data Envelopment

Analysis (DEA) to get a set of ldquoefficiency scoresrdquo In the second stage we regress efficiency scores

against our measure of income inequality controlling for a set of contextual factors describing the

economic socio-demographic and political context of each county

We use a sample of 324 municipalities for the period 2006-2017 During this period Chile

was divided into 346 counties belonging to 15 regions This period was characterized by important

external and internal shocks including the Global Financial Crisis (GFC) one of the biggest

earthquakes in Chilean history in 2010 and three municipal elections The availability of

information allows us to measure efficiency for the full period but the influence of contextual

factors is analysed using a panel of six years (2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017) for which

household income information is available

The main hypothesis tested in the second stage is whether higher levels of income inequality

are associated with lower levels of efficiency Previous evidence shows that when progress is not

evenly shared persistent within-country inequality reduces the effectiveness and efficiency of the

public sector (Ortega Sanjuaacuten amp Casquero 2017 Tandon 2005)

Income inequality has been used to control for a wide range of idiosyncratic factors

associated with historical institutional and cultural factors affecting efficiency (Greene 2016

58

Ortega et al 2017) For instance at the local level income inequality has been considered as an

indicator of economic heterogeneity in the population where higher inequality is associated with

a more heterogeneous set of conflicting demands for public services which adversely affect an

efficient provision (Ashworth Geys Heyndels amp Wille 2014 Geys amp Moesen 2009) Higher

levels of income inequality could also relate to economically privileged groups having a greater

capacity to influence the political system for their own benefit rather than that of the majority

When high inequality is persistent the feeling of frustration and disappointment in the population

could reduce not only trust and cooperation among individuals but also trust in institutions which

would negatively affect government efficiency (Boix amp Posner 1998 Coffeacute amp Geys 2005) For

instance national or local authorities could end exerting patronage and clientelism and showing

rising levels of corruption (Uslaner 2011 Uslaner amp Brown 2005)

One of the main gaps in extant literature is the need to conduct more analysis of LGE using

panel data taking into consideration endogeneity issues and controlling for unobserved

heterogeneity (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018a) To address the above we set-up a panel with

time and county-specific effects and we propose the use of a measure of natural resource

dependence (NRD) as an instrument for income inequality Based on the ldquoParadox of Plentyrdquo

fiscal revenues from natural resources windfalls could be associated with an over expansion of the

public sector fostering rent-seeking and corruption and reducing local government efficiency

(Dauvin amp Guerreiro 2017 Manzano amp Rigobon 2001) In the Chilean case most of the revenues

generated by local governments included those from natural resources end up in a common fund

which benefits all municipalities The aim of this common fund is precisely to reduce inequalities

among municipalities so although we do not expect a direct impact of natural resources on LGE

we could expect an indirect effect through other indicators particularly income inequality

59

As far as we know this is the first study analysing the influence of income inequality as a

determinant of municipal efficiency in Chile Moreover this is the first study in the context of a

natural resource-rich country which specifically suggests a measure of natural resource

dependence as an instrument to correct for endogeneity bias We propose the use of the proportion

of firms in the primary sector as proxy for the degree of NRD in each county We argue that this

variable is a better proxy than using the proportion of employment in the manufacturing sector

which has been proposed in previous studies (Alesina amp La Ferrara 2002) During the period

analysed our proxy remained relatively stable and showed a significant relationship with income

inequality In addition it is less likely that it has directly affected municipal efficiency

This study adds to the literature in two other ways First the extant literature suggests that

efficiency measurement could be highly sensitive to the chosen technique as well as the selection

of inputs and outputs (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018a) Inputs are usually proxied by a single

measure of total public expenditures and outputs by general proxies such as population andor the

number of businesses in each county We offer a novel approach for the selection of inputs and

outputs On the one hand we disaggregate government expenditures into four components

(operation personnel health and education) and we use the number of public schools and health

facilities in each county as a proxy for physical capital On the other hand we use four outputs

aiming to capture the wide variety of goods and services supplied by each municipality Through

this approach we aim to better describe the production function of each municipality capturing

not only the variety of inputs and outputs but also differences in size among municipalities

A third contribution relates to the measurement of LGE in the Chilean context We measure

technical and scale efficiency using a larger sample and a longer period This has empirical and

policy relevance On the one hand it helps us to select the correct DEA model and allows us to

60

determine the importance of scale inefficiencies as explanation for differences in municipal

performance On the other hand efficiency measures increase the information available for both

central and local governments to better understand the production technology that best describes

each municipality and to carry out policies to improve efficiency

We believe that our selection of inputs and outputs the use of a large dataset and the joint

analysis using cross-sectional and panel data provide a more accurate and robust analysis of

municipal efficiency Likewise knowing whether inequality has a significant influence on

municipal efficiency may provide useful insights and guidance for policymakers not only in Chile

but also for countries sharing similar characteristics

DEA results show an average level of technical efficiency (inefficiency) of around 83

(17) This means that municipalities could reduce on average a 17 the use of inputs without

reducing the outputs There are significant differences among geographic areas with the Centre

area (where the countyrsquos capital is located) displaying higher efficiency than the rest of the country

When municipal efficiency is measured under different assumptions about returns to scale results

reveal a production technology with variable returns to scales and around 75 of the

municipalities displaying scale inefficiencies However when technical efficiency is

disaggregated between pure technical efficiency and scale efficiency results show that scale

inefficiency explains a small proportion of the total municipal technical inefficiency This finding

justifies a deeper analysis of the reasons why municipalities could operate inefficiently and why

municipal performance could vary among municipalities

Efficiency scores also show a significant degree of positive spatial autocorrelation This

means that municipal efficiency shows a general clustering process with neighbouring

municipalities showing similar levels of efficiency A further analysis shows that most of the

61

spatial pattern in municipal efficiency is exogenous that is could be associated to other variables

Hence we conduct most of our regression analysis using traditional (non-spatial) methods and

leaving spatial regressions in the appendixes

Findings from cross-sectional and panel regressions support the hypothesis that municipal

performance is significantly and negatively associated with income inequality at the county level

The coefficient of income inequality is close to one which means that reductions in income

inequality ceteris paribus could be associated with increases in municipal efficiency in the same

proportion This result supports the strand of research arguing that there is not a trade-off at least

at the municipal level between equity and efficiency (Andersen amp Maibom 2020 Berg amp Ostry

2011 2017) The main policy implications are that authorities in more unequal counties would

face higher challenges to perform efficiently and policies pertaining to inequality and efficiency

should not be designed independently

The chapter is structured as follows Section 32 provides a brief literature review on related

local government efficiency Section 33 introduces the methodological background and empirical

models Section 34 presents the empirical results and discussions Section 35 concludes the

chapter

32 Related Literature

321 Measuring efficiency of local governments

Studies on measuring LGE can be grouped in those analysing the provision of single services

such as health or education and those assessing overall efficiency (lo Storto 2013) Once inputs

and outputs have been defined efficiency is measured using parametric andor non-parametric

techniques Among the former group Stochastic Frontier Analysis (SFA) seems to be preferred

62

by scholars aiming to measure efficiency and to analyse the link with environmental variables

using a single procedure (Pacheco et al 2013 Tsekeris Sotiris Tsekeris amp Papaioannou 2018)

On the non-parametric group Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA) is by far the most used technique

(Afonso amp Fernandes 2006 Balaguer-Coll amp Prior 2009 lo Storto 2013)

The selection of inputs and outputs depends not only on the aimed of the study (specific

sector vs whole measure of efficiency) but also on the role that municipalities play in different

countries There are countries such as Australia (Drew et al 2015) and Spain (Balaguer-Coll amp

Prior 2009) where local governments mainly supply services to ldquopropertyrdquo such as waste

management and road maintenance In these cases efficiency has been mainly measured using

total indicators of local government expenditure and outputs have been proxied using general

indicators such as population or number of business (Drew et al 2015) On the other hand in

countries such as Italy (lo Storto 2013) and Portugal (Afonso amp Fernandes 2008) in Europe or

Brazil (de Sousa Cribari-Neto amp Stosic 2005) and Chile (Pacheco et al 2013) in South America

municipalities mainly supply services to ldquopeoplerdquo Here in addition to financial expenditures or

revenues inputs have included the number of local government employees the number of schools

or the number of hospitals and health centres School-age population the number of students

enrolled in primary and secondary schools and the number of beds in hospitals have been

considered as outputs Based on the study of Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte (2018a) a wider list of

inputs and outputs used in previous studies can be found in Appendix I

Studies from different countries show important differences in the average efficiency scores

both between and within countries These studies also differ in the samples methodologies and

variables included A summary showing the range and variability of the mean efficiency scores

founds in countries all around the world can be found in Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte (2018a)

63

These authors also show that OECD natural resource-rich countries such as Australia Belgium

and Chile show similar results in terms of mean efficiency scores with LGE studies being less

frequent in Latin American countries

Measuring efficiency of local governments as decision-making units (DMU) presents many

challenges and difficulties (Borger Kerstens Moesen amp Vanneste 1994 Ravallion 2005)

Worthington and Dollery (2000) mention problems with the selection and measurement of inputs

the identification of different stakeholders the hidden characteristic of the ldquolocal government

technologyrdquo and the multidimensionality of the services provided by local governments All these

issues make difficult to identify and distinguish between outputs and outcomes with outputs

commonly proxied by general indicators such as county area or county population Because

efficiency measures are highly sensitive to the chosen technique and the selection of inputs and

outputs Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte (2018a) suggest formulating different specifications and

using less general and unspecified indicators Moreover the complexity in defining outputs and

the use of general indicators make more likely that contextual factors affect municipal efficiency

322 Explaining differences in LGE

To explain differences in local government performance researchers have basically

distinguished between ldquodiscretionaryrdquo and ldquonon-discretionaryrdquo factors Discretionary factors refer

to the degree of discretion of local authorities in the selection and management of inputs and

outputs On the other hand scholars have investigated the influence on LGE of contextual factors

beyond authoritiesrsquo control These factors reflective at the environment where municipalities

operate include economic socio-demographic geographic financial political and institutional

characteristics (da Cruz amp Marques 2014 Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018b)

64

In general the evidence about the influence of contextual factors has delivered mixed and

country-specific results (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018b) Sampaio de Sousa et al (2005)

using data for Brazilian municipalities finds that population density and urbanization rate have

strong positive effects on efficiency scores Benito et al (2010) show that lower levels of

efficiency of Spanish municipalities are associated with a greater economic level a less stable

population and a bigger size of the local government Afonso (2008) finds that per capita income

level and education are not significant factors influencing LGE of Portuguese municipalities He

also finds that municipalities in Northern areas show greater efficiency than their counterparts in

Southern areas More recently Tsekeris (2018) finds that spatial variations in efficiency in Greece

can be attributed to factors related to inter-regional market access specialization and sectoral

concentration resource-factor endowments and political factors among others Characteristics

describing each local government have also been used including municipal indebtedness (Benito

et al 2010) fiscal deficits (Sinha 2017) degree of fiscal autonomy (Boetti Piacenza amp Turati

2009) and individual characteristics of local authorities such as age gender and political ideology

Narboacuten‐Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte (2018b) conclude after analysing 63 articles that studies on the

influence of contextual factors have mostly used cross-sectional data with little attention to

endogeneity issues which makes any causal interpretation doubtful

323 The trade-off between efficiency and equity

The existence of a potential trade-off between efficiency and equity is in the core of

economic discussion (Andersen amp Maibom 2020 Berg amp Ostry 2011 Browning amp Johnson

1984 Okun 2015)15 The argument that economic growth (one of the most common efficiency

15 Redistributive policies distort incentives and lead to suboptimal outcomes and thus efficiency losses

65

measures) could be negatively affected in the search for greater equality has been translated not

only into economic policies that favour economic growth over those that reduce inequality but

also in the emphasis of scholarly research Thus theoretical and empirical research has been

mainly focussed on efficiency and policy implications of a great diversity of shocks and policies

leaving the analysis of inequality as one of measurement and mostly descriptive Additionally

empirical evidence of the trade-off is scant and inconclusive (Andersen amp Maibom 2020

Browning amp Johnson 1984)

Among economic contextual factors that could affect LGE income inequality has been

largely ignored An exception is a cross-country comparison conducted by Ortega (2017) who

analyses the role of inequality on government efficiency in developing countries He finds that

more unequal countries could have higher difficulties to achieve specific health outcomes Income

inequality has even been considered as part of the outputs to measure efficiency particularly for

the case of European and OECD countries (Afonso Schuknecht amp Tanzi 2010 Antonelli amp De

Bonis 2018)

At the local level income inequality has been mainly used as a proxy for the effect of income

heterogeneity Economic inequality could have a direct and an indirect effect on government

efficiency The direct effect poses that higher income inequality could reduce municipal efficiency

because it is associated with a more complex and competing set of public services demanded by

the population (Jottier et al 2012) The indirect effect puts the focus in the link between inequality

social capital and levels of corruption Economic diversity could reduce trust in people and

institutions when related to high and persistent levels of income inequality It could also affect the

willingness to participate in community and political groups the existence of a shared objective

by citizens and the perception of a prosperous future (Uslaner amp Brown 2005)

66

The evidence is ambiguous For instance Geys and Moesen (2009) find that income

inequality has little relation to efficiency of Flemish municipalities and Ashworth et al (2014)

find a negative relationship for the Norwegian case Findings also indicate that inequality is the

strongest determinant of trust and that trust has a greater effect on communal participation than on

political participation (Uslaner amp Brown 2005)

33 Methodology

We follow a two-stage approach widely used in this kind of analysis A DEA analysis is

conducted in the first stage to get efficiency scores for each municipality Then regression analysis

is conducted in the second stage aiming to identify contextual variables other than differences in

the management of inputs that can help to explain the heterogeneity in municipal performance

331 Chilean Municipalities and period of analysis

The territory of Chile is divided into regions and these into provinces which for purposes of

the local administration are divided into counties The local administration of each county resides

in a municipality which is administrated by a Mayor assisted by a Municipal Council16

Municipalities represent the decentralization of the central power in Chile They are autonomous

organizations with legal personality and own patrimony whose purpose is to satisfy the needs of

the local community and ensure their participation in the economic social and cultural progress of

the county Municipalities have a diversity of functions related to public health education and

social assistance among others

16 The Mayor and City Council are elected by suffrage for the citizens of the respective commune every 4 years

67

To achieve their goals two are the main sources of municipal incomes own permanent

revenues (OPR) and the Municipal Common Fund (MCF) OPR are incomes generated by the

county and they are an indicator of the self-financing capacity of each municipality OPR are not

subject to restrictions regarding their investment and they are mainly generated by territorial taxes

commercial patents and circulation permits17 The MCF is a fund that aims to redistribute

community income to ensure compliance with the purpose of the municipalities and their proper

functioning Sources to finance the MCF come from municipal revenues The distribution

mechanism of the fund is regulated by parameters such as whether municipalities generate OPR

per capita lower than the national average and the number of poor people in the commune in

relation to the number of poor people in the country

This study covers the period from 2006 to 2017 During this period Chile was divided into

15 regions 54 provinces and 346 counties18 Although the information on inputs and outputs is

available for the entire period information on contextual factors at the county level such as

household income is only available every two-three years In addition some counties are excluded

from household surveys due to their difficult access Hence we use a sample of 324 municipalities

to measure municipal efficiency for the whole period (3888 observations) However the analysis

of contextual factors is conducted for those years when household income information is available

2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017 (1944 observations)

17 The territorial tax is a tax on agricultural and non-agricultural real estate Specifically of this income only 40 is left to the municipality as its own financing while the remaining 60 is allocated to the MCF (in the case of the four largest communes- Santiago Providencia Las Condes and Vitacura-percentages are 35 and 65 respectively) Unlike the territorial tax commercial patents are regulated mainly by the municipality which chooses the rate to be charged subject to a range established by law and is responsible of their collection Finally regarding the circulation permits 375 is of municipal benefit while 645 is directed to the MCF 18 There are 346 counties managed by 345 municipalities where counties ldquoCabo de Hornosrdquo and ldquoAntaacuterticardquo are managed by the municipality of ldquoCabo de Hornosrdquo

68

332 Measuring municipal efficiency

Municipal efficiency is measured using Data Envelopment Analysis (Coelli Prasada Rao

OrsquoDonnell amp Battese 2005) This is a non-parametric approach that uses linear programming to

measure efficiency for a group of municipalities as decision making units (DMUrsquos) The main

advantage of using DEA and the reason why DEA is used for the case of Chilean municipalities

is its flexibility in handling multiple inputs and outputs without the need to specify a functional

form (Balaguer-Coll amp Prior 2009 Mikušovaacute 2015 Tigga amp Mishra 2015) Following Afonso

and Fernandes (2008) the relationship between inputs and outputs for each municipality could be

represented by the following equation

119884 119891 119883 119894 1 119899 (31)

In equation (31) 119884 is the set of outputs and 119883 the set of inputs for each of the n

municipalities Using linear programming the production frontier is constructed and a vector of

efficiency scores is obtained The frontier represents full technical efficiency mdash the point at which

the highest output occurs given specified inputs or the point at which the lowest amount of inputs

is used to produce a specified quantity of output Efficiency scores under DEA are relative

measures of efficiency They measure a municipalityrsquos efficiency against the other measured

municipalities in the sample and not a hypothetical lsquoperfect municipalityrsquo The further from the

frontier the less technically efficient a municipality is

We use an input-oriented approach because Chilean municipalities have a greater control

over the management of inputs relative to the outputs they have to manage Obtaining efficiency

scores requires an assumption about the returns to scale exhibited by each municipality When

DMUrsquos are homogeneous the CCR model (Charnes Cooper amp Rhodes 1978) which assumes

69

constant return-to-scale (CRS) is the appropriate specification The CCR model assumes full

proportionality between outputs and inputs and that DMUrsquos operate at their optimal When DMUrsquos

are highly heterogeneous as is the case with local governments in most countries it is not realistic

to assume complete proportionality between inputs and outputs nor that all DMUrsquos operate at their

optimum scale In this situation a variable returns-to-scale (VRS) or BCC model (Banker

Charnes amp Cooper 1984) is the preferred formulation

Assuming VRS imposes minimum restrictions on the efficient frontier and allows for

comparisons only among municipalities of similar scale (Coelli et al 2005 Wu Huang amp Pan

2014) This means that when we use the CCR model (assuming CRS) on a heterogeneous sample

of DMUrsquos the resulting measure of technical efficiency that we obtain is related not only to the

management of inputs but also to issues of scale19 To empirically check the validity of the VRS

assumption we measure technical efficiency under CRS VRS and non-increasing returns-to-scale

(NIRS) and we analyse the existence of scale inefficiencies This allows us to check the relevance

of scale effects as a potential explanation of differences in municipal efficiency Appendix J

shows the specification of the DEA model under VRS and how ldquototal technical efficiencyrdquo

(assuming CRS and therefore due to management and scale issues) could be disaggregated in ldquopure

technical efficiencyrdquo (under VRS and related only to management issues) and scale efficiency (due

to scale issues)

19 Assuming VRS can also lead to measurement problems such as overestimation of efficiency scores This is the case when an important proportion of DMUrsquos shows CRS so assuming VRS ignores the information about proportionality between inputs and outputs (Podinovski 2004)

70

333 Inputs and outputs used in DEA

Following the literature on local government expenditure efficiency (Afonso amp Fernandes

2008 de Sousa et al 2005 Dlouhyacute 2018 Tandon 2005 Tigga amp Mishra 2015) and trying to

reflect as well as possible the functioning of municipalities five inputs and four outputs were

selected Input and output data were obtained from the National System of Municipal Information

(SINIM in its Spanish acronym) and they are expressed in thousands of Chilean pesos of 201720

Inputs are Municipal Operational Expenditure X1 (including expenses on goods and

services social assistance investment and transfers to community organizations) Municipal

Personnel Expenditure X2 (including full time and part-time workers) Total Municipal

Expenditure in Education sector X3 Total Municipal Expenditure in Health sector X4 and the

Number of Municipal Buildings X5 (proxied by the number of public facilities in education and

health sectors)

Output variables were selected highlighting the relevance of education and health sectors

and trying to capture the wide range of local services provided by municipalities The variable

ldquoOwn Permanent Revenuesrdquo Y1 is used to capture the scale and diversity of municipal

activities21 The ldquoMonthly Average Enrolmentrdquo in municipal education establishments related to

the school-age population in each county Y2 is used as educational output As health output the

ldquoNumber of Medical Consultationsrdquo in public facilities Y3 is considered Finally the number of

community organizations Y4 is used as output reflecting the promotion of community

development by each municipality Table 31 shows the summary statistics of input and output

20 The data from SINIM database was mostly obtained using the sinimr package (Salas 2019) 21 According to SINIM database this variable aims to measure the management of the municipalityrsquos own resources with respect to the population of the commune

71

variables for the whole sample and period Inputs and outputs excepting the Monthly Average

Enrolment Y2 are measured in per capita terms using county population information from the

National Institute of Statistics (INE in its Spanish acronym)

Table 31

Descriptive statistics Inputs and Output variables used in DEA analysis

334 Regression model

Contextual factors could play an important role not only in explaining why some

municipalities operate inefficiently but also why municipal performance differs among them

These factors may affect municipal performance modifying incentives for local authorities to

operate efficiently and their capability to take advantage of economies of scale They also define

the conditions for cooperation or competition among municipalities and the citizensacute ability and

willingness to monitor local authorities (Afonso amp Fernandes 2008)

Information on income at the household level for each county was obtained from the

ldquoNational Socioeconomic Characterization Surveyrdquo (CASEN in its Spanish acronym) CASEN is

conducted every two-three years being the reason why consecutive years are not considered in

72

our regression analysis The other contextual factors used as controls were obtained from different

sources including SINIM INE and the ldquoServicio de Impuestos Internosrdquo (SII)22

Our main hypothesis is whether higher levels of income inequality are associated with lower

levels of municipal efficiency To test our hypothesis the empirical model is defined as

120579 120573 119892119894119899119894 119885 120573 120575 120572 120598 (32)

Where 120579 is the vector of DEA efficiency scores 119892119894119899119894 is the Gini coefficient of each

county 120575 are year-specific effects 120572 are county-specific constants 120598 is a vector of error terms

and 119885 is a vector of controls Next we discuss the motivation for these controls

The level of purchasing power of countiesrsquo citizens is proxied by the variable log(income)

which is the natural log of the mean household income per capita in thousands of Chilean pesos of

2017 On the one hand poorer counties could display higher efficiency due to their necessity to

take care of their constraint resources (Pacheco et al 2013) On the other hand richer counties

could show higher efficiency because richer citizens exert higher monitoring over local authorities

and demand better quality public services in return for their tax payments (Afonso et al 2010)

The possibility for municipalities to take advantage of economies of scale and urbanization is

captured by three variables First the variable log(density) which correspond to the natural log of

population density Second the dummy variable reg_cap indicating whether a county is a regional

capital or not Third the variable agroland which correspond to the proportion of land for

agricultural use which is informed to the SII We expect a positive effect of log(density) but

negative for regcap and agroland

22 The SII is the institution in charge of collecting taxes in Chile

73

Socio-demographic characteristics are captured including a Dependence Index IDD IDD

corresponds to the number of people under 15 years or over 65 years per 100 people in the active

population (those people between 15 and 65 years old) A higher proportion of young and older

population could be associated with a higher demand for municipal services relating to education

and health making harder to offer public services efficiently The citizensrsquo capacity to monitor

local authorities is proxied including the variable education (average years of education for the

population older than 15 years) and the variable housing (proportion of households which are

owners of the property where they live in each county) In both cases we expect a positive

association with LGE

Among municipal characteristics the variable professional (percentage of municipal

personnel with a professional degree) is used to control for the quality of municipal services and

it is expected a positive impact The variable mcf (proportion of total municipal income coming

from the MCF) is included to capture the influence of financial dependence on the central

government A higher dependence from MCF could be associated with higher efficiency when it

is linked to more control from central government (Worthington amp Dollery 2000) However when

MCF discourages the generation of own resources and proper management of resources from the

fund a lower efficiency should be expected (Bravo 2014) In addition the dummy variable mayor

is included to capture differences among mayors supported by the ldquoLEFTrdquo or the ldquoRIGHTrdquo

political parties related to those ldquoINDEPENDENTrdquo mayors

Table 32 report summary statistics for the set of numeric contextual factors and Appendix

K the corresponding correlation matrix Despite the high correlation between income and

education variables we include both in the regression section as they capture different county

characteristics

74

Table 32

Summary Statistics Numeric Contextual Factors

Figure 31 Geographical distribution of Chilean regions and macrozones

Previous evidence on growth and convergence of Chilean regions have found that regions

tend to cluster spatially (Aroca amp Bosch 2000) Aiming to capture this regional clustering process

75

and considering the high concentration in the number of municipalities and population in the

central area we group municipalities in four ldquozonesrdquo We define as reference the ldquoCentre-Northrdquo

zone consisting of regions XIII (where the countryrsquos capital is located) and its two neighbouring

regions V and VI The ldquoNorthrdquo zone includes regions XV I II III and IV The ldquoCentre-Southrdquo

zone includes regions VII VIII and IX Finally the ldquoSouthrdquo zone embraces regions XIV X XI

and XII Figure 31 displays the regional administrative division and zones considered in this

essay

Efficiency scores (ES) are limited to have values between 0 and 1 However they are relative

measures (relative to the sample of municipalities) This implies that when a municipality is on the

frontier (ES = 1) it does not mean that potentially larger technical efficiency gains cannot be made

Hence equation 32 is estimated using OLS and censored regressions We start running cross-

sectional regressions for each of the six years Then we compare the results with those from panel

regressions Because fixed-effects panel Tobit models could be affected by the incidental

parameters problem (Henningsen 2010 2019) we use random-effects panel Tobit models

including indicator variables for years and zones Finally to deal with the potential endogeneity

problem we also use an instrumental variable approach The instrument is described next

335 The instrument

Government effectiveness and income distribution are both structural components of

economies (Ortega et al 2017 Ravallion 2005) In the search for a causal interpretation for the

influence of income inequality on municipal efficiency we need an instrument which must be

correlated with the variable to be instrumented (in our case income inequality) and uncorrelated

with the error term in the efficiency equation (32) Previous literature has used as instruments for

Gini the number of townships governments in a previous period the percentage of revenues from

76

intergovernmental transfers in a previous period and the current share of the labour force in the

manufacturing sector (Alesina amp La Ferrara 2002) Using the share of the labour force in a specific

sector is unlikely to reduce the problem of endogeneity particularly in countries where local

governments supply mostly ldquoservices to peoplerdquo and the main source of income inequality is

labour income

We propose as an instrument the proportion of firms in the primary sector (mining fishing

forestry and agriculture)

119901119904119904_119891119894119903119898119904Number of firms in the primary sector

Total number of firms (33)

On the one hand this instrument is likely to be correlated with local income inequality in

natural resource-rich countries23 On the other hand we contend that our instrument is less likely

to be correlated with the error term in the efficiency equation First the main services supplied by

Chilean municipalities are services to people (health and education) not to firms Second most of

the revenues collected by municipalities included those associated with natural resources end up

in the municipal common fund whose objective is precisely to reduce inequalities among

municipalities Third services to firms are expected to be more significant with the tertiary sector

We argue that our instrument captures natural and structural conditions which directly

influence income inequality but it does not directly affect LGE Figure 32 shows the evolution

of the annual average efficiency score and the proportion of firms in the primary secondary

(manufacturing) and tertiary (services) sectors We observe that sectors shares have remained

relatively stable with a slight reduction in the participation of the primary sector in favour of the

23 Results confirm a significant association between income inequality and the degree of dependence on natural resources at the county level

77

tertiary sector by the end of the period This is contrary to the evolution of municipal efficiency

which shows a cyclical behaviour as will be shown in the next section

Figure 32 Evolution of efficiency scores and the proportion of firms by sector

34 Results and discussion

341 DEA results

Figure 33 displays the evolution of our three measures of efficiency Overall technical

efficiency pure technical efficiency and scale efficiency are around 78 83 and 95

respectively with fluctuations over the years Therefore around three quarters of the overall

78

inefficiency is attributed to inefficiency in the management of inputs and around one quarter to

scale inefficiencies24

Figure 33 Evolution technical efficiency (TE) pure technical efficiency (PTE) and scale efficiency (SE)

Returnstoscale

Figure 34 reports by zone and for the whole period the proportion of municipalities

showing CRS decreasing returns to scale (DRS) or increasing returns to scale (IRS) Most of the

municipalities operate under variable (increasing or decreasing) returns to scale which could be

explained by the high heterogeneity in size among municipalities A summary of RTS

disaggregated by year and zone is in Appendix L Policies oriented to increase efficiency usually

24 The average scale efficiency score of 95 means that municipalities could get an additional 5 of inputs saving if municipalities were able to change their size to achieve their optimal scale

79

consider amalgamation de-amalgamation or ways of cooperation among municipalities To have

a better idea about where and how feasible is the implementation of such policies Appendix M

shows maps with the administrative division of the country in its 345 municipalities and which

municipalities show CRS IRS or DRS in each of the six years of data

Figure 34 Returns to scale by zone

Based on results for the whole period (Figure 34) the North has the highest proportion of

municipalities exhibiting DRS This suggests the need to reduce the size of municipalities splitting

those ldquotoo bigrdquo creating new administrative areas or giving more autonomy to current

municipalities25 The opposite occurs in the Centre-North area where municipalities mostly

exhibit IRS This indicates the need to merge municipalities An alternative strategy to the

amalgamation process is increasing inter-municipal cooperation (Balaguer-Coll et al 2019)

25 This has been the policy followed in Chile Although two new regions were created (XV in the North and XIV in the South) the number of municipalities has not changed

80

which seems to be a more plausible option in Chile Finally evidence on scale efficiency for the

Centre-South and South areas is not clear in terms of the adequate strategy to improve efficiency

Efficiencymeasure

Although most municipalities show scale inefficiencies (Figure 34) only a small proportion

of total inefficiency is associated to scale issues (Figure 33) Together this results justify not only

the use of the BCC model (efficiency scores under VRS) to capture municipal heterogeneity but

also highlights the need to look for other factors outside the control of local authorities which

could be influencing municipal performance

Table 33

Summary efficiency scores (VRS) by zone and region

Table 33 summarizes ES under VRS using data for the six years of CASEN survey A mean

efficiency score of 83 is found for the full sample and period This means that on average

inefficient municipalities can reduce the use of inputs by 17 to get the same current output By

81

comparing average ES per zone it can be concluded that municipalities in the North Centre-North

Centre-South and South could achieve the same level of output with 17 12 18 and 23 fewer

resources respectively Results also show that one third of the municipalities present an efficiency

score equal to one

Figure 35 shows the evolution of the mean ES for the four zones over the 12 years period

A clear drop in the efficiency level is observed in 2009 (the financial crisis year) excepting for the

North area Likewise although mean efficiency returned to its pre-crisis levels in 2014-2015 a

new drop in efficiency was experienced in 2016 It also seems that the 2010 earthquake did not

generate a significant effect on municipal efficiency Figure 35 also shows that although levels

of efficiency seem to differ among zones they follow a similar trend through time with the only

exception of the North which corresponds to the mining area In addition efficiency seems to be

significantly higher in the Centre-North area This is explained by the high mean level of efficiency

in region XIII which includes the countryrsquos capital city

Figure 35 Evolution mean efficiency scores (VRS) by zone

82

To know which and where are the efficient municipalities and if they are surrounded by

municipalities with a similar level of efficiency Appendix N has maps showing the ldquoefficiency

statusrdquo of each municipality that is whether they are efficient (ES = 1) or inefficient (ES lt 1)

Additionally Appendix O shows ldquoequal intervalsrdquo maps describing the spatial distribution of ES

among municipalities for each of the six years26 Results show that efficient municipalities can be

found all through the country the ldquoefficiency statusrdquo could change from one year to another and

municipalities with similar level-status of efficiency tend to cluster in space

342 Regression results

Exploratoryspatialanalysis

DEA efficiency scores and their geographical representations seem to show that municipal

efficiency presents a spatial clustering pattern This means that municipal performance could be

influenced not only by contextual factors of the county where municipality belongs but also by the

level of efficiency of neighbouring municipalities and their characteristics To test the significance

of the spatial dimension in municipal efficiency we use a cross-section of data considering the six-

year average of efficiency scores the Gini coefficient and the set of controls

We use the Moranrsquos I indicator to test for spatial autocorrelation Moranrsquos I is a measure of

the correlation between the level of efficiency in one municipality and its ldquospatial lagrdquo that is the

average level of efficiency in neighbouring municipalities We define as the relevant neighbours

for each municipality the 5-nearest municipalities This is obtained using the distances among the

26 An equal intervals map uses the same principle as a histogram to organize the observations into categories that divide the range of the variable into equal interval bins For the equal interval classification the value range between the lower and upper bound in each bin is constant across bins but the number of observations in each bin is typically not equal

83

polygonsrsquo centroids (latitude and longitude) of each county Results confirm that municipal

efficiency show a significant level of positive spatial autocorrelation This means that

municipalities tend to have neighbouring municipalities with similar performance

The positive spatial autocorrelation shown by municipal efficiency could be due to the

performance in one municipality is influenced by the performance in neighbouring municipalities

(spatial dependence in the variable itself) or due to structural differences among regions-zones

(spatial heterogeneity) To check the source of the spatial autocorrelation we run an OLS

regression of ES against income inequality and controls and then we test OLS residuals for spatial

autocorrelation Moranrsquos I over OLS residuals although significant is barely higher than zero (see

Appendix P) This means that the spatial effect itself is not a serious issue and can be handle for

instance including zone indicators variables hence we proceed to analyse the influence of income

inequality on LGE using non-spatial regression27

Cross‐sectionalanalysis

We start reporting censored regressions for each year in our panel Efficiency scores have

been rescaled to numbers between 0 and 100 to facilitate the interpretation of the results All

regressions include dummy variables for three of the four zones in which we have grouped Chilean

regions Results are in Table 3428 Income inequality shows a negative sign in all years which is

consistent with our hypothesis that inequality is negatively related to municipal efficiency

However only in three of the six years the effect of income inequality appears as statistically

27 In the case of having incorporated the spatial dimension the two most commonly used forms are including in the model the spatial lag of the dependent variable (spatial autoregressive model SAR) or the spatial lag of the error (spatial error model SEM) Following the method suggested by Anselin et al (1996) Lagrange Multiplier (LM) tests on the OLS residuals showed that the SAR model is preferred over the SEM Moranrsquos I LM tests and spatial regressions can be found in Appendix P 28 Regression results using OLS are in Appendix Q

84

significant Only the income level displays a significant and positive influence on efficiency for

the whole period A higher population density also consistently favours municipal efficiency On

the other hand as we expected a higher IDD makes it more difficult to achieve an efficient

performance29 Consistent with results in Pacheco et al (Pacheco et al 2013) municipal

efficiency show a significant an positive association with the MCF only in the first half of our

period of analysis with the second half showing an insignificant relationship

Table 34

Cross-sectional (censored) regressions

Paneldataanalysis

Estimation results for the six-year panel are reported in Table 35 Columns (1) and (2) show

the results for the pooled and random effects censored models only controlling for zone and year

29 The set of cross-sectional regressions was also run for each zone independently Results confirm that the set of significant contextual factors differs not only among years but also among geographic areas This support previous evidence suggesting that cross-sectional analysis should be treated with caution (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018b)

85

dummies Income inequality appears as non-significant Zone indicator variables confirm that

municipalities located in the Centre-South and South of the country display a lower average level

of efficiency compared to the Centre-North area Time dummies mostly show negative

coefficients This is a signal that shocks such as the GFC and the earthquake in 2010 may have

had a negative impact on efficiency but that impact was not permanent The results for the pooled

and RE models including the full set of controls are reported in columns (3) and (4) These results

show a significant negative influence of income inequality on LGE

When income inequality is instrumented by the variable pss_firms most of the coefficients

remain unchanged except for those associated with the income variables gini and log(income)

This result implies that our original model suffers for instance from the omitted variable bias

This means that LGE and income inequality are determined simultaneously by some variable not

included in our model Columns (5) and (6) show results using our instrument for income

inequality The ldquotrue coefficientrdquo of variable gini remains negative but the magnitude of the

relationship is higher The negative coefficient for gini implies on the one hand that municipalities

located in more unequal counties face more challenges to achieve an efficient management of

public resources On the other hand the coefficient in column (6) is close to one The interpretation

is that for each point of reduction in income inequality ceteris paribus LGE should increase in the

same proportion Next we discuss some of the results associated with the controls variables

Contrary to Pacheco et al (2013) income level has a positive coefficient meaning that richer

counties in terms of income per capita show higher efficiency This could be explained by higher

monitoring and increasing demands from citizen and taxpayers In addition it is expected a higher

efficiency in municipalities located in counties with a higher population density and those with a

lower proportion of land for agricultural use This result is mainly explained by municipalities

86

located in the Centre area The opposite happens with municipalities in the South implying that

they are too ldquosmallrdquo to take advantage of agglomeration economies There is also a limit for

agglomeration and scale economies which is shown by the negative coefficient of the variable

regcap although this coefficient loses its significance in the IV approaches30

Unexpectedly efficiency was found to be negatively associated with the variable education

This result is similar to the case of Czech municipalities (Šťastnaacute amp Gregor 2014) where

explanations include a weakened monitoring effect due to the fact that more educated citizens

present greater mobility and labour cost disadvantages for municipalities with better educated

labour force In Chile an additional explanation could be the relationship between education and

voter turnout Since 2012 voting is no longer mandatory in Chile This fact considerably reduced

voter turnout which in turn may have influenced the monitoring and control effect of more

educated voters For the case of variable IDD results show that local authorities in counties with

higher proportion of aging and young population (related to those in the active population) face a

greater challenge in their quest to offer public services efficiently

The influence of mcf is like that found by Pacheco et al (2013) with municipalities more

dependent on central transfers showing more efficiency31 Political influence captured by the

variable mayor did not show a significant effect This result is like other studies concluding that

the ideological position did not have a significant influence on efficiency (Benito et al 2010

Boetti et al 2009 Cordero Pedraja-Chaparro Pisaflores amp Polo 2017)

30 This negative coefficient suggests that the negative effects of agglomeration economies such as overcrowding pollution high cost of land and traffic congestion could predominate over the positive effects of scale economies in regional capitals 31 When the analysis is conducted for each zone independently MCF displays a negative influence in the North and Centre-North areas but a positive influence in the Centre-South and South areas These results confirm that on the one hand richer municipalities (those in the North and Centre-North) have less incentives for efficient management of their resources On the other hand results support the relevance of MCF helping poorer municipalities (those in the South) to reach their outcomes

87

Table 35

Panel data regressions

88

35 Conclusions

The trade-off between equity and efficiency is in the core of the economic discussion This

ldquoprinciplerdquo has been used by policymakers to prioritize the design of policies focused on economic

growth delaying those policies aimed at reducing economic inequalities This essay offers

empirical evidence of a negative relationship between inequality and efficiency that is a reduction

of income inequality could have positive effects on economic efficiency at least at the level of

local governments

We followed a traditional Two-Stage approach commonly used in the analysis of LGE We

compared cross-sectional and panel data results and we have added an instrumental variable

approach to give a causal interpretation to the link between efficiency and inequality We proposed

the use of a measure of natural resource dependence to instrumentalize the impact of income

inequality on LGE Given that our units of analysis are municipalities and not counties we argue

that our measure of NRD is correlated with income inequality and it does not have a direct

influence on LGE

We found that Chilean municipalities perform better than previous studies suggest

Municipal efficiency depicted significant levels of positive spatial autocorrelation and most of the

municipalities showed to be operating under increasing or decreasing returns to scale This would

imply that the policies generally used to improve efficiency such as amalgamation or cooperation

should be implemented observing the reality of each region and not as strategies at the national

level We also found that scale inefficiency explains a small proportion of the average total

inefficiency reason why the analysis of external factors that could affect the municipal efficiency

takes greater relevance

89

Income inequality plays an important part in explaining municipal efficiency In fact it was

found that reductions in income inequality could result in increases in municipal efficiency in a

similar proportion An unexpected finding was that the levels of education shows a negative

association with municipal performance This could be due to a low average level of education or

the existence of an omitted variable This variable could be the significant reduction in voting

turnout rates for local and national elections due to changes in the voting system during the period

of our analysis All in all our results may help to shed light on the potential consequences of

changes in contextual factors and the design of strategies aimed to increase municipal efficiency

in countries with similar characteristics to the Chilean economy For instance policies oriented to

take advantage of economies of scale can be formulated merging municipalities or establishing

networks in specific sectors such as education or health

Further work needs to be done both in measurement and in the explanation of differences in

municipal performance in Chile One area of future work will be to identify the factors that better

predict why municipalities operates under increasing decreasing or constant returns to scale

Multinomial logistic regression and the application of machine learning algorithms to SINIM data

sets appear as suitable methods for that purpose Intertemporal DEA (Drew amp Dollery 2015)

should be used to measure municipal efficiency capturing changes in total factor productivity In

addition municipalities operate under different levels of geographical authorities such as the

provincial mayor and the regional governor Hence it would be useful to know how each

municipality performs within each region-zone related to how performs to the whole country This

should be done conducting a metafrontier analysis (OrsquoDonnell Rao amp Battese 2008)

We have also identified through a cross sectional spatial exploratory analysis that on

average municipalities with similar levels of efficiency tend to cluster in space Regarding to

90

analyse the importance of contextual factors on municipal efficiency a deeper analysis should use

censored spatial models to check the significance of the spatial dimension in cross-sectional and

panel contexts Another interesting avenue for future research is associated with the negative

association found between LGE and education The significant reduction in votersacute turnout since

the law of automatic registration and voluntary voting in 2011 appears as a natural experiment to

analyse its effects on efficiency indicators such as municipal performance Incorporating variables

such as the voting turnout in each county or classifying municipalities based on individual

institutional political and economic characteristics could help to shed light on which of these

channels is the most relevant when analysing the impact of inequality on municipal efficiency

Finally we argued that an important part of the influence of income inequality over LGE

could be through its indirect effect on trust social capital and social cohesion The final essay will

delve deep in that relationship

91

Chapter 4 Social Cohesion Incivilities and Diversity

Evidence at the municipal level in Chile

41 Introduction

A deterioration in social cohesion could carry significant costs such as a reduction in

generalized trust between individuals and in institutions a society caught in a vicious circle of

inequality and citizens increasingly distanced from civic life (Uslaner 2011) A growing feeling

of frustration and discontentment can eventually translate into a social outbreak with uncertain

results This is precisely what have been happening in many countries around the world included

Chile

ldquoSocial cohesion is a state of affairs concerning both the vertical and the horizontal

interactions among members of society as characterized by a set of attitudes and norms that

includes trust a sense of belonging and the willingness to participate and help as well as their

behavioural manifestationsrdquo (Chan et al 2006) This definition highlights the multidimensionality

in the concept of social cohesion which has been measured using objective andor subjective

indicators of trust social norms solidarity willingness to participate in social and political groups

and feelings of belonging (Ariely 2014 Chan et al 2006) Multidimensionality also implies that

the impact of determinants of social cohesion such as economic and racial diversity could be

different for each of its various dimensions (Ariely 2014)

A common characteristic to all societies is that they are made up of different groups that

differ with respect to race ethnicity income religion language local identity etc The

92

Community Heterogeneity Thesis (Coffeacute amp Geys 2006) argues that individuals prefer to interact

with others that are like themselves Hence high levels of diversity particularly economic and

racial represent a complex scenario to maintain social cohesion One of the most common factors

adduced for social cohesion is income inequality with higher levels linked to lower levels of trust

(Ariely 2014 Rothstein amp Uslaner 2005)

Traditional measures of social cohesion may not be adequately capturing the deterioration

in social connections For instance measures of (lack of) trust include a strong subjective element

On the other hand proxies for social participation such as volunteering jobs or joining to social

organizations have not been supported by empirical evidence as a source of generalized social trust

(Rothstein amp Uslaner 2005) We proposed to use the rate of incivilities which we argue is a more

appropriate measure of the degree of worsening in the social context

Incivilities are those visible disorders in the public space that violate respectful social norms

and tend not to be treated as crimes by the criminal justice system There are two types of

incivilities social and physical Social incivilities include antisocial behaviours such as public

drinking noisy neighbours and fighting in public places Physical incivilities include among

others vandalism graffiti abandoned cars and garbage on the streets Because citizens and

political authorities cannot always distinguish between incivilities and crime they are usually

treated as an additional category of crime This implies that policies aimed to reduce incivilities

are generally based on punitive actions However theory and evidence on incivilities suggest that

factors explaining incivilities and crime could be different (Lewis 2017 Taylor 1999)

In Chile crime rates have shown a sustained downward trend after reaching its highest level

in 2011 On the other hand incivilities rate has shown a sustained upward trend which coincides

with the increasing victimization and feeling of insecurity in the population This has motivated

93

Chilean authorities based on the ldquoBroken Windows Theoryrdquo to propose new punitive actions (or

increase the severity of the current ones) to those who commit this type of antisocial behaviours

The ldquoBroken Windows Theoryrdquo states that higher rates of incivilities are a signal of social

disorganization which result in higher crime rates (J Q Wilson amp Kelling 1982) This is expected

to have consequences on familiesrsquo decisions such as moving away from public spaces or even

leaving their neighbourhoods

As far as we know there is no previous evidence about the potential causes of incivilities in

Chile Efforts to identify the factors explaining incivilities could help not only to reduce the risk

factors favouring violent and property crimes but also to guide interventions aimed to change

social behaviours and strengthen social cohesion in highly unequal societies Thus the main

contribution of the present study is to provide a deeper comprehension of the problem of incivilities

and how they can help to better understand the weakening of social cohesion that many

contemporary societies experience

We aim to offer the first evidence on the factors explaining the evolution and the differences

in incivilities rates in Chile We set up a panel for six years (2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and

2017) and 324 counties (1944 observations) We start exploring the evolution and geographical

distribution of incivilities Then we investigate whether economic and racial diversity after

controlling for other socioeconomic demographic and municipal characteristics can be regarded

as key predictors of incivilities

We use the Gini coefficient to proxy economic heterogeneity and the number of new visas

granted to foreigners as proportion of the county population as proxy for racial diversity The main

hypothesis is whether economic and racial diversity have a positive association with the rate of

incivilities In addition to the arguments regarding the ldquoCommunity Heterogeneity Thesisrdquo Taylor

94

(1999) and Skogan (1986 1999 2015) argue that incivilities are caused by inequality and the lack

of informal mechanisms of social control Based on the ldquoIncivilities Thesisrdquo the patterns of

incivilities should mirror the patterns of inequality (Taylor 1999) Then higher inequality should

be associated with higher physical and social vulnerability of the population This reduces social

control and increases social disorganization which triggers antisocial or negligent behaviours

Our main result reveals a strong positive association between the rate of incivilities and the

number of new visas granted per year The relationship with income inequality although also

positive seems to be less significant These findings give strong support to the ldquoCommunity

Heterogeneity Thesisrdquo and to a lesser extent to the ldquoIncivilities Thesisrdquo When the analysis is

disaggregated geographically racial diversity shows a clear positive effect The impact of income

inequality seems to be conditional depending on the level of income showing no effect in poorer

regions Results also show that the impact of economic and racial diversity differs by type of

incivility For example income inequality shows a strong association with ldquoStreet Tradingrdquo while

racial diversity with ldquoAlcohol Consumptionrdquo Two are the main policy implications On the one

hand a national strategy to address the problems associated with foreign immigration could help

to reduce incivilities For instance a joint effort between national and local authorities to curb

immigration and its distribution throughout the country On the other hand our results show that

the relationship between incivilities and economic diversity differs depending on the region or

geographical area Hence the impact on social cohesion of policies aimed to tackle economic

inequalities should be analysed in each specific context

The rate of incivilities also shows a negative association with the level of municipal financial

autonomy This implies that municipalities can effectively carry out policies to reduce incivilities

beyond the efforts of the central government Another important finding is that our results do not

95

support the hypothesis that a higher proportion of the young population is associated with higher

rates of incivilities Hence policies aimed to reduce incivilities should be focused on the causes of

incivilities rather than the criminalization of behaviours or stigmatization of specific population

groups

The structure of the chapter is as follows Section 42 outlines the relevant literature on social

cohesion and incivilities Section 43 describes the data variables and methodology and

establishes the hypotheses of the study Section 44 contains the results and discussions Section

45 presents the main conclusions

42 Related Literature

421 The Community Heterogeneity Thesis

The idea under ldquoThe Community Heterogeneity Thesisrdquo is that if individuals prefer to

interact with others who are similar to themselves in terms of income race or ethnicity high levels

of income inequality and racial diversity facilitate a context for lower tolerance and antisocial

behaviours lowering the ldquostaterdquo of social cohesion (Alesina 2000 Coffeacute amp Geys 2006 Letki

2008) Alessina and Ferrara (2002) give support to this hypothesis arguing that individuals have a

natural aversion to heterogeneity However the most popular explanation is the principle of

homophily people prefer to interact with others who share the same ethnic heritage have the same

social status and hence share experiences and tastes (Letki 2008 McPherson Smith-Lovin amp

Cook 2001 Tolsma et al 2009) For instance Delhey and Newton (2005) find for a sample of

60 countries that income inequality and ethnicity are strongly and negatively correlated with trust

Tolsma et al (2009) using data for Dutch neighbourhoods and municipalities find that social

cohesion is negatively and consistently affected by economic deprivation but not by ethnic

96

heterogeneity These authors also conclude that the effect of neighbourhood and municipal

characteristics on social cohesion depends on residentsrsquo income and educational level

Rothstein and Uslaner (2005) give two theoretical reasons why economic and racial diversity

should be causally related to social trust a key element of social cohesion First optimism about

the future makes less sense when there is more economic inequality which generally translates into

inequality of opportunities especially in areas such as education and the labour market Second

the distribution of resources and opportunities plays a key role in establishing the belief that people

share a common destiny and have similar fundamental values In highly unequal societies people

are likely to stick with their own kind Perceptions of injustice will reinforce negative stereotypes

of other groups making social trust and accommodation more difficult

Uslaner (2002 2011) and Uslaner and Brown (2005) find that high levels of inequality are

the single major factor driving down trust in people who are different from yourself Evidence for

USA finds that inequality is the strongest determinant of generalized trust over time (Rothstein amp

Uslaner 2005) Reducing inequality and then increasing generalized trust should have positive

consequences at the individual and aggregates levels At the individual level it may lead to greater

tolerance and more acts of altruism for people of different backgrounds At the aggregate level it

may lead to greater economic growth more redistribution from the rich to the poor and less

corruption (Uslaner 2002 2013) Letki (2008) argues that when neighbourhood socio-economic

context (apart from just an individualrsquos socioeconomic status) is considered it turns out to be the

main factor triggering negative attitudes and lack of trust in out-group members

The increasing diversity caused by immigration can also reduce the conditions necessary for

social cohesion (Ariely 2014 Holtug amp Mason 2010) Christel Kesler and Irene Bloemraad

(2010) find for nineteen advanced democracies between 1981 and 2000 that increasing migration

97

generally decreases trust civic engagement and political participation The authors also find that

in more equal countries with clear policies in favour of cultural minorities the negative effects of

migration are mitigated or even reversed Letki (2008) states that deprivation and disorder tend to

be strongly correlated with racial diversity Because we propose the use of the number of disorders

or antisocial behaviours known as ldquoincivilitiesrdquo as our measure of social cohesion we describe the

literature on incivilities in the next section

422 The literature on incivilities

The study of incivilities has been a continuing concern mainly for developed countries since

the 1980s The focus has changed from individual and psychological explanations to ecological

(contextual) and social explanations (Taylor 1999) The individual approach basically considered

perceptions of incivilities as an explanatory variable of fear of crime The ecological explanation

argues that indicators of economic disadvantage (eg income levels income inequality

unemployment rate and poverty rate) are the keys to understand a process of social disorganization

and lack of informal control These economic factors lead to higher rates of inappropriate or

negligent behaviours and ultimately to higher crime rates (Blau amp Blau 1982 Messner Rosenfeld

amp Baumer 2004 Phan Orsquobrien Mendolia amp Paloyo 2017 Sampson 1986)

The negative impact of incivilities is not merely reflected in its association with crime rates

(Skogan 2015) Physical and social incivilities could worsen neighbourhoods by affecting quality

of life perception of the environment and public and private behaviours Previous research has

indicated that a higher level of incivilities is associated with health problems (Branas et al 2011

Cohen et al 2000 Hill amp Angel 2005 Ross 2011 Ross amp Mirowsky 2001) greater

victimization and fear of crime (Brunton-Smith Jackson amp Sutherland 2014 Mijanovich amp

Weitzman 2003) and multiple negative economic effects For instance incivilities could be

98

related to a reduction in commercial activity lower investment in real estate reduction in house

prices (Skogan 2015) and population instability (Hipp 2010)

To describe the state of the art in the study of incivilities and their consequences Skogan

(2015) used the concept of untidiness to characterize the research on incivilities The study of

incivilities has had multiple approaches (economic ecological and psychological) Incivilities

have also been measured using multiple sources of information (police reports surveys trained

observation) which result in different measures (perceptions vs count data) However the question

about what specific factors have the strongest effect on incivilities has been overlooked and

perceptions about incivilities have been used mainly as a predictor of crime fear of crime and

victimization

There are two types of incivilities social and physical Social incivilities are a matter of

behaviour including groups of rowdy teens public drunkenness people fighting and street hassles

Physical incivilities involve visual signs of negligence and decay such as abandoned buildings

broken streetlights trash-filled lots and graffiti (Skogan 1999 2015 Taylor 1999) Three reasons

justify the distinction between physical and social incivilities First like multiple dimensions of

social cohesion different structural and social conditions could be responsible for different types

and categories of incivilities Second punitive sanctions are expected to have a greater impact on

physical than on social incivilities since the latter are more related to behaviours rooted in citizensrsquo

culture Third physical incivilities should be more related to absolute measures of economic

disadvantage (eg poverty or unemployment rates) and social incivilities to relative indicators of

economic disadvantage (eg such as income inequality) This line of research is based on the

ldquoincivilities thesisrdquo which states that to understand the distribution of disorders it is necesary to

analyse the patterns of structured inequalities (Skogan 1986 Taylor 1999)

99

423 The ldquoIncivilities Thesisrdquo

Incivilities theories began with a focus on psychological dynamics (Garofalo 1978) moved

forward to an interest in social psychological processes (J Q Wilson amp Kelling 1982) and finally

evolved into a focus on community dynamics and outcomes (Skogan 1999) Individual and group

behaviours in tandem with ecological features have been proposed as the key factors explaining

incivilities and their posterior influence on social control quality of life and more serious crime

(J Q Wilson amp Kelling 1982)

In terms of ecological factors particularly those related to economic conditions Skogan

(1986) was the first linking the distribution of incivilities to the patterns of structural inequality If

incivilities mirror inequality structure this will have consequences in residentsrsquo health and safety

due to its levels of vulnerability In addition structured inequality associated with the proportion

of the manufacturing sector (eg when fabrics tend to move from cities to farther areas) will be

related to higher social disorganization and differences between urban and rural areas (W J

Wilson 1996) In addition a persistent feeling of relative deprivation (persistently high levels of

income inequality) could lead to fellow inhabitants of the community to commit antisocial

behaviours showing their frustration with the current economic model

The literature on incivilities posits that their causes are different from those of crime (Lewis

2017) Unlike crime analysis especially property crimes information on the location where the

incivility takes place is the same as the location where the perpetrator resides To achieve a

comprehensive understanding of the different types of incivilities it is crucial to consider

incivilities data covering an entire territory and not just specific areas (Hooghe Vanhoutte

Hardyns amp Bircan 2010) If we add to this the availability of panel data it could be possible not

100

only to identify the main determinants of incivilities but also the causal mechanism from income

inequality towards incivilities rate

In Chile citizen security crime and delinquency are among the most significant issues for

citizens based on opinion polls Existing research has found weak evidence of a significant

relationship between crime and indicators of socio-economic disadvantage such as income

inequality and unemployment rate with significant effects only on property crime (Beyer amp

Vergara 2006 Nuntildeez Rivera Villavicencio amp Molina 2003 Rivera Gutieacuterrez amp Nuacutentildeez 2009)

Crime deterrence variables such as the probability of being caught or the number of police

resources have also shown ambiguous results (Beyer amp Vergara 2006 Rivera et al 2009

Vergara 2012) Evidence at the county level shows that crime is higher in urban counties those

with a lower mean income per capita and counties located in the North of the country In addition

at least half of the crimes reported in one county are perpetrated by criminals from other counties

(Rivera et al 2009) No studies could be found about the determinants of incivilities

4 3 Methodology

431 Period of analysis and data sample

Chile is a relatively small country in Latin America with a population of 18346018

inhabitants in 2017 The country is divided into 345 municipalities with on average 53104

inhabitants (median value 18705) Municipalities are the organ of the State Administration

responsible to solve local needs Municipalities are not only the relevant political and

administrative local unit of analysis but also they represent the feeling of lsquocommunityrsquo among

the inhabitants of each municipality (Hooghe et al 2010) Our data includes many sources of

101

heterogeneity among municipalities such as indicators of economic deprivation population

density demographic characteristics and whether the county is a regional or provincial capital

We use a sample of 324 municipalities covering most of the Chilean territory for the period

2006ndash17 Data on incivilities is obtained from the ldquoCentre of Studies and Analysis of Crimerdquo

which is part of the ldquoSubsecretaria de Prevencion del Delitordquo (SPD in its Spanish acronym) of the

Chilean government32 Information on income inequality and control variables is obtained from

the ldquoNational Socioeconomic Characterization Surveyrdquo (CASEN in its Spanish acronym) the

ldquoNational Institute of Statisticsrdquo (INE in its Spanish acronym) the ldquoNational Municipal

Information Systemrdquo (SINIM in its Spanish acronym) and the Immigration Department of the

Government of Chile Our panel only includes the years for which CASEN survey is available

2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017

432 Operationalisation of the response variable and exploratory analysis

Official Chilean records contain information for the total number of cases of incivilities per

year at the county level The number of cases is the sum of complains and detentions reported at

the police Our dependent variable 119894119899119888119894119907119894119897119894119905119894119890119904 correspond to the number of cases per year Due

to population differences comparisons between counties are made using the incivilities rate per

1000 population calculated as

119894119899119888119894119907_119903119886119905119890 lowast 1000 (41)

where 119894119899119888119894119907_119903119886119905119890 is the incivilities rate 119905 is the year 119894 the county and 119899 is the population of the

county per year

32 httpceadspdgovclestadisticas-delictuales

102

Figure 41 illustrates at the top the evolution of the total number (cases reported) of

incivilities and crimes at the country level for the period 2006-1733 At the bottom Figure 41

shows the evolution of the mean county rate per 1000 inhabitants We observe that both the number

of incivilities and the number of crimes has reached similar annual figures however average

county rates per 1000 population show different trends Crime rate displays a sustained fall after

reaching its pick in 2011 Incivilities average county rate which also reached a pick and posterior

drop in 2011 has recovered its upward trend since 2016 considerably exceeding the crime rate

Figure 41 Evolution number and rates of incivilities and crime (DMCS) in Chile 2006-2017

33 Crime refers to ldquocrimes of greater social connotationrdquo (DMCS in its Spanish acronym) which includes violent and property crimes

103

Chilean records classify incivilities in nine categories most of them associated with social

incivilities Summary statistics for the total and for each of the nine categories are presented in

Table 41 In addition Figure 42 shows the evolution of incivilities by category for the whole

period We see that the global trend in incivilities is mainly due to a substantial increase in ldquoStreet

Tradingrdquo and ldquoPublic Alcohol Consumptionrdquo A common element of Figures 41 and 42 is the

significant change in trend experienced by crimes and incivilities in 2011 That year the SPD

became dependent on the Ministry of Interior of the Chilean Government This event put the issue

of crime and delinquency within national priorities for the central government

Table 41

Summary statistics total count of incivilities and by category (full sample and period)

Unlike crime rates we do not expect significant cross-county spillover effects in incivilities

However the questions of where incivilities are concentrated and why they are there can be of

great interest (Skogan 2015) Figure 43 shows quantile maps for the rate of incivilities per 1000

inhabitants for the initial and final years in our panel

104

Figure 42 Evolution total number of incivilities by category

Figure 43 Spatial distribution of incivilities rate per 1000 inhabitants (2006 vs 2017)

105

We observe that the range of values has increased significantly from 2006 to 2017 but the

spatial distribution remains almost unchanged On the one hand high incivilities rates in the North

could be associated with the mining activity On the other hand high rates in the Centre area

(where the countyrsquos capital is located) could be related to the higher population density and the

concentration of the economic activity34

To see how the different types of incivilities are distributed throughout the country we have

grouped those similar categories in four groups ldquoPublic Damagerdquo (ldquoPublic Disturbsrdquo ldquoPublic

Damagerdquo ldquoOtherrdquo) ldquoThreatsrdquo (ldquoPublic Fightrdquo ldquoThreatsrdquo and ldquoAnnoying Noisesrdquo) ldquoAlcohol

Consumptionrdquo (ldquoPublic Alcohol Consumptionrdquo and ldquoDrunkennessrdquo) and ldquoStreet Tradingrdquo This

distinction in groups could be relevant if we expect different patterns and different effects of

community heterogeneity on social cohesion among counties For instance we expect higher

levels of Public Damage in big urban cities Street trading is more likely in urban cities but also in

tourist areas The spatial distribution of these four groups for the six-year-average rate per 1000

inhabitants can be found in Appendix R

433 Measures of community heterogeneity and control variables

Social cohesion income inequality and racial diversity are all ldquocommunityrdquo (not individual)

characteristics Thus to understand their relationship we need aggregated data at least at the

county-municipal level With more disaggregated data like at the suburbs level the required

heterogeneity among groups of citizens is lost (Wilkinson 1999) Like Coffeacute and Geys (2006) we

use the Gini coefficient to capture economic heterogeneity However instead of a measured for

34 We also analysed the spatial distribution of crime rates In general areas with high levels of incivilities not necessarily are associated with high levels of crime This could imply that factors explaining incivilities and crime are different

106

the diversity of nationalities we use the proportion of foreign population to capture racial

heterogeneity Income data is obtained from the CASEN survey The Gini coefficient is calculated

for each county and included through the variable gini Racial heterogeneity is included through

the variable foreign which is the annual number of new VISAS granted to foreigners as a

proportion of the county population Chile has experienced a significant increase in immigration

since 2011 Immigration has been concentrated in the metropolitan region and mining regions in

the North of the country We expect a positive relationship between immigration and incivilities

although as with the relationship between immigration and crime the foundations for this

hypothesis are not strong (Hooghe et al 2010 Sampson 2008)

Economic development is another explanation for social cohesion frequently appealed to

explain trust with wealthier societies considered to exhibit higher levels of trust (Delhey amp

Newton 2005) In this study we include the natural log of the mean household income per capita

log(income) We also include the poverty rate poverty and the unemployment rate

unemployment Unlike the variable log(income) these variables are expected to be positively

associated with the number of incivilities When a relative indicator of economic heterogeneity

such as income inequality is included as determinant of social cohesion we should expect less

effect from absolute indicators of economic disadvantage such as poverty and unemployment rates

(Hooghe et al 2010 Tolsma et al 2009)

Among demographic variables the percentage of inhabitants between 10 and 24 years old is

included through the variable youth The variable women defined as the proportion of the female

population in each county is also included Variable youth is expected to have an ambiguous effect

Although young people have lower victimization and report rates they also represent the group

more likely to commit antisocial behaviours when a community has a low capacity of self-

107

regulation (eg when there is low parental supervision) The female population is associated with

a higher report of incivilities related to the male population

It is argued that crime and incivilities are essentially urban problems (Christiansen 1960

Wirth 1938) We include the variable log(density) defined as the log of population density (the

number of inhabitants divided by the area of each county in square kilometres) and a dummy

variable capital indicating whether a county is an administrative capital (provincial or regional)

Two additional variables are included to capture the level of informal social control exerted

by families living in each municipality First the variable education which is defined as the

average years of education of people over 15 years old Second the variable housing which capture

the proportion of families which are owners of their housing unit Although education and housing

are related to both the possibility of reporting and committing an incivility we expect a negative

association with the rate of incivilities

In Chile crime has been mainly a problem faced by the police and the Central Government

Administration To control for current law enforcement policies we include the variable

deterrence defined as the number of arrests as a proportion of the total number of incivilities cases

In addition municipalities can develop their own initiatives to deal with crime and incivilities

depending on their capacity to generate its own resources The level of financial autonomy from

central transfers is captured by the variable autonomy This variable is obtained from SINIM and

it is defined as the proportion of the budget revenue of each municipality that comes from its own

permanent sources of revenues A categorical variable mayor is also included This variable

indicates whether the municipality mayor is supported by the ldquoLEFTrdquo or the ldquoRIGHTrdquo political

parties (related to those ldquoINDEPENDENTrdquo mayors)

108

Table 42 presents descriptive statistics for our measures of income and racial heterogeneity

and the set of numeric control variables The Pearson correlation among these variables is shown

in Appendix S

Table 42

Summary statistics numeric explanatory variables

434 Methods

The annual count of incivilities as is characteristic for count data is highly concentrated in

a relatively small range of values In addition the distribution is right-skewed due to the presence

of important outliers (counties with a high number of incivilities) Figure 44 shows the

distribution of the six-year average number of incivilities for each of the 15 regions in Chile35 We

observe that regions differ in the number of counties in which they are divided In addition

counties within each region show important differences in the number of incivilities For instance

35 Regions are ordered from left to right and from top to bottom in the way they are geographically distributed from North to South So the northernmost region of the country is the ldquoXVrdquo and the southernmost region is the ldquoXIIrdquo The Metropolitan region (where the countryrsquos capital is located) is region ldquoXIIIrdquo in the centre of the country (see Appendix C)

109

excepting the Metropolitan region ldquoXIIIrdquo most counties in regions located in the centre of the

country (middle row in Figure 44) show a range of incivilities between 0 and 2000 The number

of incivilities is considerably lower in counties located in the northern (top row in Figure 44) and

southern (bottom row in Figure 44) regions of the country compared to regions in the centre of

the country It also seems clear from Figure 44 that the number of incivilities does not follow a

normal distribution

Figure 44 Annual average number of incivilities per county

The number of incivilities can be better described by a Poisson distribution In this case the

number of incivilities is ldquothe countrdquo and the number of incivilities per year is ldquothe rate per unit

timerdquo We are interested in modelling the average number of incivilities per year usually called 120582

as a function of a set of contextual factors to explain differences in incivilities between and within

110

counties The main characteristic of the Poisson distribution is that the mean is equal to the

variance This implies that as the mean rate for a Poisson variable increases the variance also

increases The main implication is we cannot use OLS to model 120582 as a function of the set of

contextual factors because the equal variance assumption in linear regression is violated

The rate of incivilities between counties is not directly comparable due to population

differences We expect counties with more people to have more reports of incivilities since there

are more people who could be affected To capture differences in population which is called the

exposure of our response variable 120582 it is necessary to include a term on the right side of our model

called an offset We will use the log of the county population in thousands as our offset36

Additionally similar to the case of crime data incivilities show a significant degree of

overdispersion (variance higher than the mean) suggesting that there is more variation in the

response than the Poisson model implies37 We also model and regress incivilities assuming a

Negative Binomial distribution to address overdispersion An advantage of this approach is that it

introduces a dispersion parameter in addition to 120582 which gives the model more flexibility38

Considering as the response variable the count of incivilities per year the model can be

expressed as follow

120582 119890119909119901 120573 120573 119892119894119899119894 120573 119891119900119903119890119894119892119899 119883120574 120572 120579 (42)

36 If we think of 120582 as the average number of incivilities per year then represents the number per 1000

inhabitants so that the yearly count is adjusted to be comparable across counties of different sizes Adjusting the yearly count by population is equivalent to adding 119897119900119892 1199011199001199011199061198971198861199051198941199001198991000 to the right-hand side of the regression equation 37 Without adjusting for overdispersion we use incorrect artificially small standard errors leading to artificially small p-values for model coefficients 38 The Negative Binomial model posits selecting a 120582 (average number of incivilities) for each county and then generating a count using a Poisson random variable with the selected 120582 With this approach the counts will be more dispersed than would be expected for observations based on a single Poisson variable with rate 120582

111

where 120582 is the rate of incivilities 119883 is our vector of controls 120572prime119904 are county-specific constants

and 120579prime119904 are time-specific constants Accounting for differences in county population we have

119890119909119901 120573 120573 119892119894119899119894 119883120574 120572 120579 (43)

where 119901119900119901119906119897119886119905119894119900119899 is the county population per year Hence the model to be estimated using

Maximum Likelihood Estimation (MLE) is

119897119900119892 120582 120573 120573 119892119894119899119894 119883120574 120572 120579 119897119900119892 (44)

Finally to account for different effects depending on the type of incivilities we also run

equation (44) for each of the four groups of incivilities defined in section (432)

435 Hypotheses

Based on the community heterogeneity hypothesis the relationship between social cohesion

and diversity should be stronger for lower levels of income and less educated groups of people

(Tolsma et al 2009) Hence contrary to evidence for developed and more equal countries we

expect a significant positive association for the Chilean case where more than 50 of the

population is economically vulnerable (OECD 2017)

The main hypotheses to be tested in this essay is whether the number of incivilities is

positively associated with the level of economic and racial heterogeneity at the county level We

start analysing this association for the full sample and period Next we analyse whether the

relationship between incivilities and our measures of diversity differs by geographic area (region

or zone) Finally we check whether the effect of economic and racial diversity is different

depending on the group of incivilities

112

44 Results and Discussion

Overall our results show that the rate of incivilities displays a stronger and more significant

relationship with racial diversity than with economic heterogeneity This association differs for

different geographic areas and for different types of incivilities Absolute economic indicators

except for income show a significant but small effect Increases in the average levels of income

or education and more financial autonomy for municipalities seem to be effective ways to reduce

the rate of incivilities

We estimate equation (44) assuming that the number of incivilities follows a Poisson

distribution Regional and temporal heterogeneity are captured through the inclusion of dummy

variables for five years (with 2006 as the reference year) and fourteen regional dummies (with

region XIII as the reference region) Results are reported in Table 4339 This table is structured in

two blocks of regressions pooled models in columns (1)-(4) and fixed-effects models in columns

(5)-(8)40 The first column in each block only includes economic indicators relative and absolute

trying to test which ones are more relevant and whether incivilities tend to mirror income

inequality (the ldquoincivilities thesisrdquo) The second column adds the variable foreign to account for

the effect of racial diversity (Letki 2008) The third column includes education to check whether

the association between economic and racial diversity with social cohesion changes (gets less

significant) when we control for educational level (Tolsma et al 2009) The final column in each

block corresponds to the full model specification which includes the rest of controls

39 Pooled estimations were obtained using the R command glm() and compared with results obtained from the command poisson in STATA 15 Fixed effects and random effects models were estimated using the STATA command xtpoisson Negative Binomial models were estimated using the command glmnb() in the MASS package for R and commands nbreg and xtnbreg in STATA 15 Results for Negative Binomial regressions are in Appendix T 40 We have omitted results with random effects due to the literature on panel count data models suggest that the most robust estimator is Poisson regression with Fixed Effects (Santos Silva amp Tenreyro 2010 2011)

113

Table 43

Poisson regressions

114

The positive and significant coefficient for the variable gini besides being small it becomes

insignificant in the fixed effects specification which includes the full set of controls This result

does not seem to be enough evidence to support our hypothesis that more unequal counties display

higher rates of incivilities On the other hand racial diversity through the variable foreign shows

a consistent positive association with the rate of incivilities41 Together coefficients for gini and

foreign seems to support the ldquocommunity heterogeneity thesisrdquo (Letki 2008) but not the

ldquoincivilities thesisrdquo (Skogan 1999) To check this finding we run the pooled full model

specification for each region and results are shown in Table 44 where regions have been ordered

from North to South The sign of the coefficient of the variable gini differs for different regions

Moreover the relationship is insignificant in some of the most unequal regions which are in the

South of the country (VIII IX and XIV) This result rejects the hypothesis that incivilities mirror

structural income inequalities For the variable foreign 12 out of 15 regions confirm the positive

association with the rate of incivilities42

We also run our pooled full model separately for each group of incivilities defined at the end

of section (432) Income inequality keeps its significant but small association with each group of

incivilities (see Table 45) Our measure of racial diversity shows a stronger association with

ldquoAlcohol Consumptionrdquo related to ldquoPublic Damagerdquo and ldquoThreatsrdquo The link with ldquoStreet Tradingrdquo

appears as non-significant These results support our general finding that on the one hand racial

heterogeneity exert a more significant influence on the rate of incivilities than economic

41 To get the effects of the variables gini and foreign over the rate of incivilities per 1000 inhabitants we need to exponentiate their coefficients Thus an increase in one unit in the variable gini increases the rate of incivilities per 1000 inhabitantsrdquo in 1005 times (e^0005) in the pooled full model Similarly an increase in one point in variable foreign is expected to increase the ldquorate of incivilities per 1000 inhabitantsrdquo in 10876 times (e^0084) in the full pooled model and 10471 (e^0046) times in the full Fixed Effects model 42 Given that depending on the geographic location regions share certain characteristics the model was also run clustering regions in 4 zones (see Figure 31 in chapter 3) Results by zone are in Appendix U

115

heterogeneity On the other hand results confirm our hypothesis that the effect of diversity is

different for different types of incivilities

Table 44 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson models by region

Back to our general results in Table 43 the significant and negative coefficient of the

income variable and to a lesser extent the significant and positive coefficients of poverty and

unemployment provide evidence that absolute rather than relative economic indicators may be

more important explanations of the rate of incivilities This is opposite to evidence for the analysis

116

of crime rates such as in Hoodge (2010) and support the idea that determinants of incivilities are

different from those of crime Our results are also opposite to those for Dutch municipalities where

economic indicators turned out to be more important than ethnic heterogeneity (Tolsma et al

2009) The coefficient for the variable log(income) could be interpreted as counties with an income

level under the average face higher problems of antisocial behaviours such as incivilities In

addition as the income level moves far away from its average low level the problem of incivilities

is less relevant43 In terms of policy implications only those policies that achieve a significant

increase in the average level of county income seem to be effective in reducing incivilities and

strengthening social cohesion

Table 45 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson model by incivility group

43 We ran our model splitting the sample of counties in quintiles based on their income level The coefficient for the variable gini only showed a significant (and positive) coefficient for the second third and fourth quintile A non-significant coefficient for the first quintile could imply that other types of inequalities (eg health education) are more relevant in the poorest counties In the case of the fifth quintile (the richest group of counties) they have better facilities in terms of infrastructure police resources self-protection etc which could reduce the potential triggers of incivilities

117

The inclusion of the variable education significantly improved the goodness of fit of the

models and did not generate significant changes in the coefficients of our measures of economic

and racial diversity This result rejects the proposition that the relationship between social

cohesion and diversity becomes less strong when controlled by education (Tolsma et al 2009)

Additionally it highlights the topic of education as a relevant determinant of the rate of incivilities

and social cohesion

Among control variables there are also some important results Opposite to what we

expected the variable youth shows a negative or non-significant coefficient Although this result

could be due to the lack of ldquophysical incivilitiesrdquo in Chilean records it indicates that it is incorrect

to stereotype this group as the main responsible for high incivilities rates The significant and

negative coefficient of the variable autonomy in the fixed effects specification could also have

important policy implications It is a signal that local governments can play an important role in

reducing incivilities or complementing the efforts from the central government Another

interesting result is the significant coefficient of the variable housing The latter finding is

particularly important in the sense that a negative sign supports public policies oriented to increase

homeownership as effective ways to improve social cohesion However the small magnitude of

the coefficient that even showed the opposite sign in some model specifications could be

explained for the high level of segregation that these policies have generated in Chilean society

As mentioned in the Introduction and Literature Review so far only a few studies have

used measures of disorders or incivilities as dependent variable to explain changes in social

cohesion (Skogan 2015) In addition there is no evidence in Chile analysing the determinants of

incivilities separately from those of crimes The importance of our results on identifying the

importance of economic and racial diversity on social cohesion lies mainly in its generality An

118

important number of countries all around the world share a similar context characterized by high

levels of inequality and an explosive increase in immigration These countries are also

experiencing a worsening in social cohesion which increases the risk of a social outburst

4 5 Conclusions

The main goal of this essay was to determine whether differences in incivilities at the county

level mirror differences in income distribution and racial diversity Previous literature suggests a

positive and strong association between social cohesion and indicators of economic disadvantage

relative deprivation and racial diversity (Letki 2008 Tolsma et al 2009 Uslaner amp Brown 2005)

While not all our results were significant they showed helpful insights about how and where

economic and racial diversity are more likely to influence the rate of incivilities and social

cohesion

We used data for the period 2006ndash17 economic heterogeneity was measured through the

Gini coefficient at the county level and racial heterogeneity was proxied by the number of granted

visas to foreigners as proportion of county population We found strong evidence of a significant

and positive association between the rate of incivilities and racial diversity but not with income

inequality Contrary to previous evidence at the municipal level (Coffeacute amp Geys 2006 Tolsma et

al 2009) in general our results give support for the ldquohomophily principlerdquo and the ldquocommunity

heterogeneity hypothesisrdquo However results also showed that the effect of economic and racial

diversity varies throughout the Chilean regions and for the different types of incivilities

We also found that policies aimed at controlling the behaviour of young people did not have

strong empirical support In terms of the role that local governments may have in facing the

119

growing problem of incivilities we found evidence that efforts managed from the municipalities

can be an important complement to those from the central government

Future research should go further on the role of local authorities on incivilities and social

cohesion On the one hand municipalities could have a direct impact on social cohesion through

the implementation of programs complementary to those of central authorities oriented to reduce

incivilities and crime On the other hand social cohesion could be indirectly affected when local

authorities display an inefficient performance supplying public services to citizens or they are

recognized as corrupted institutions We suggest that policy makers from central government

should give local authorities a greater role in fighting antisocial behaviours and crime Evaluating

programs in specific municipalities could help to elucidate the causal effect of for instance higher

fiscal autonomy on the rate of incivilities

Another interesting area for future work will be to analyse how housing policies have

contributed to the phenomenon of segregation of Chilean society and in the process of weakening

social cohesion Finally our main result highlights the need of a deeper analysis of the impact that

foreign immigration is having in Chile For instance disaggregating information by country of

origin and the reasons why immigrants are arriving to the country or specific regions will surely

help to understand the impacts of immigration

120

Chapter 5 Conclusions

This thesis investigated in three essays the issue of income inequality in Chile using county-

level data for the period 2006-2017 The first essay supplied empirical evidence about the

importance of the degree of dependence on natural resources in terms of employment in explaining

cross-county differences in income inequality The second essay analysed the potential causal

effect that income inequality has on the level of technical efficiency of local governments

providing public goods and services Lastly the third essay studied the relationship between social

cohesion measured through the number of antisocial behaviours classified as ldquoincivilitiesrdquo and

the levels of income and racial heterogeneity

Findings from the first essay support the idea that the endowment of natural resources plays

a significant role in explaining income inequality in Chile However contrary to what most

theoretical and empirical evidence postulates our findings showed a robust negative association

between the two variables This means that the reduction experienced in Chile in the degree of

dependence on natural resources in terms of employment has contributed to the persistence of high

levels of income inequality The exploratory analysis indicated that income inequality shows a

general clustering process characterized by a significant and positive spatial autocorrelation

Regarding the previous evidence for Chile (Paredes et al 2016) the regression analysis confirmed

the relevance of the spatial dimension of income inequality through a process of spatial

heterogeneity giving less support to the existence of a process of spatial dependence (spillover

effect) in the variable itself

121

Essay 2 studied the potential trade-off between efficiency and equity analysing the influence

of income inequality on the efficiency of local governments at the municipal level To identify the

causal effect of income inequality on municipal efficiency we proposed the use of the proportion

of firms in the primary sector as an instrument for income inequality Findings confirmed our

hypothesis that efficiency is lower in more unequal counties This result suggests the non-existence

of the trade-off between equity and efficiency Hence policies intended to reduce inequality could

help to increase efficiency at least at the level of municipal local governments

The third essay analysed how social cohesion proxied by the rate of incivilities is associated

with the levels of economic diversity proxied by income inequality and the levels of racial

diversity proxied by the number of new visas grated as proportion of the county population

Findings gave strong support to the hypothesis that the rate of incivilities is positively related to

racial diversity and to a lesser extent to economic diversity In addition the rate of incivilities

appears negatively related to the degree of financial autonomy of municipalities This means that

local governments can effectively contribute to the reduction of incivilities which could help

reduce victimization and crime rates ultimately strengthening social cohesion

Taken together findings from essays 2 and 3 highlight the important role that income

inequality could play in other relevant economic and social dimensions These findings add to the

understanding of the potential consequences of income inequality particularly in natural resource

rich countries with persistently high levels of inequality

The present study has mainly investigated income inequality at the county level In addition

Chilean municipalities play an important role providing ldquoservices to peoplerdquo so our findings could

be applied in other highly unequal countries with a high degree of dependence on natural resources

and local governments with similar responsibilities For instance in Latin America apart from

122

Chile and Brazil there are no studies on the efficiency of local governments Other limitations are

associated with the availability of information For instance important indicators such as GDP per

capita are only available at the regional level and information of incomes is not available annually

In addition given the heterogeneity among municipalities some type of grouping of municipalities

should be performed before looking for causal relationships or conducting program evaluation

Despite these limitations we believe this study could be the basis for different strands of future

research on the topic of inequality local government efficiency and social cohesion

It was stated in chapter 2 based on the resource curse hypothesis literature there are two

elements that determine whether NR are a curse or blessing in terms of socioeconomic outcomes

First the curse is more likely in countries with weak political and governance institutions Second

different types of resources affect institutions differently with resources that are concentrated in

space so-called ldquopointrdquo resources tend to impair institutions while ldquodiffuserdquo resources do not

(Deacon 2011 Isham Woolcock Pritchett amp Busby 2005) Our results showed a negative

relationship between income inequality and our measure of natural resource dependence even after

controlling for zone fixed effects and for the level of government expenditure This result could

be interpreted as a signal that NR has a direct effect on income inequality in addition to the indirect

impact through market or institutional channels Using other potential institutional transmission

channels will shed light about the true effect that the endowment of natural resources has over

income inequality Variables that could capture these institutional channels include the level of

employment in the public sector measures of rule of law and corruption and changes in the

creation of new business in the secondary and tertiary sectors related to the primary sector

Based on results from chapter 3 most of the municipalities show scale inefficiencies One

immediate area for future work will involve using our set of contextual factors to predict the status

123

of municipalities in terms of scale inefficiencies Defining as dependent variable whether a

municipality shows constant decreasing or increasing returns to scale we could run a multinomial

logistic regression to predict municipal status For instance we would expect that a one-unit

increase in the Gini coefficient should increase the probability of scale inefficiencies (increasing

or decreasing returns to scale rather than constant returns to scale) Because the aim in this case

would be predicting a certain result in terms of returns to scale the next step should involve to

split the full sample in training and testing data sets and to use some resampling methods such as

bootstrapping This will allow us to evaluate the performance and accuracy of our model

predictions using different random samples of municipalities Results from Machine Learning

algorithms will help us to assess the generalizability of our results to other data sets

Future work should also benefit greatly by using data on different Latin American countries

to (1) compare the responsibilities of local governments (2) select a common set of inputs and

output to evaluate LGE (3) identify the relevance of scales inefficiencies in explaining differences

in performance and (4) analyse the influence of contextual characteristics over LGE Differences

in the main primary sector activity in each country such as oil in Brazil mining in Chile or Coffee

in Colombia could be responsible for differences in LGE among countries These differences could

be associated with sources of revenue management of expenditure and definitions of outputs or

contextual effects such as corrupted institutions or the delay in the development of other sectors

such as manufacturing or services

To delve deep on reasons explaining the social crisis experienced by Chilean society and

other countries one area of future work will be to analyse the relationship between diversity and

the origins of social revolutions Based on Tiruneh (2014) the three most important factors that

explain the onset of social revolutions are economic development regime type and state

124

ineffectiveness Interesting questions include whether the characteristics of Chilean context at the

end of 2019 are enough to trigger the transformation of the political and socioeconomic system

Social revolutions particularly violent revolutions are less likely in more democratic educated

and wealthy societies So it would be relevant to identify the factors explaining the violence that

has characterized the social crisis in Chile Finally the democratic regime has been maintained in

the last decades with changes between left and right governments This could imply that more

important than the regime has been the efficiency or ineffectiveness of the governments to satisfy

the needs of the population

Future work should also cover the disaggregation of information regarding foreign

population in terms of the reasons for new granted visas and the country of origin Official data

allows us to disaggregate whether the benefit is permanent (students and employees with contract)

or temporary Furthermore most of the new visas were traditionally granted to neighbouring

countries (Peru and Bolivia) a trend that has changed in the recent years to include countries such

as Colombia Venezuela and Haiti An analysis of how economic and social indicators have been

affected by changes in the composition of foreigners their reasons for immigrating to the country

and their geographical distribution have implications for economic policy at both the national and

local levels At the national level such analysis should be a key input when proposing changes to

the national immigration policy At the local level it could help define the role of municipalities

to assess the benefits and challenges of immigration These challenges are mainly related to the

provision of public goods and services such as health and education which in Chile are the

responsibility of the municipalities

The findings of this thesis suggest that policymakers should encourage policies that reduce

income inequality The key role that municipalities could play to strengthen social cohesion and

125

the increasingly important role that foreign population is acquiring in most modern societies are

also interesting avenues for future research However the picture is still incomplete and more

research is needed incorporating other dimensions of inequality This is essential if we want to

understand the reasons that could have triggered the social outbursts experienced by various

economies across the globe

126

Bibliography

Acemoglu D (1995) Reward structures and the allocation of talent European Economic Review 39(1) 17ndash33 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg1010160014-2921(94)00014-Q

Acemoglu D (2002) Technical Change Inequality and the Labor Market Journal of Economic Literature 40(1) 7ndash72 httpsdoiorg1012570022051026976

Acemoglu D Aghion P amp Violante G L (2001) Deunionization Technical Change and Inequality Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 55(1) 229ndash264 httpsdoiorg101016S0167-2231(01)00058-6

Acemoglu D Johnson S amp Robinson J A (2001) The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development An Empirical Investigation The American Economic Review 91(5) 1369ndash1401 httpsdoiorg101257aer9151369

Acemoglu D amp Robinson J A (2002) The Political Economy of the Kuznets Curve Review of Development Economics 6(2) 183ndash203 httpsdoiorg1011111467-936100149

Afonso A amp Fernandes S (2006) Measuring local government spending efficiency Evidence for the Lisbon region Regional Studies 40(1) 39ndash53 httpsdoiorg10108000343400500449937

Afonso A amp Fernandes S (2008) Assessing and explaining the relative efficiency of local government The Journal of Socio-Economics 37(5) 1946ndash1979 httpsdoiorg101016jsocec200703007

Afonso A Schuknecht L amp Tanzi V (2010) Income distribution determinants and public spending efficiency Journal of Economic Inequality 8(3) 367ndash389 httpsdoiorg101007s10888-010-9138-z

Akita T (2003) Decomposing regional income inequality in China and Indonesia using two-stage nested Theil decomposition method The Annals of Regional Science 37(1) 55ndash77 httpsdoiorg101007s001680200107

Alesina A (2000) Participation in heterogeneous communities The Quarterly Journal of Economics 115(3) 847ndash904 httpsdoiorg101162003355300554935

Alesina A amp La Ferrara E (2002) Who trusts others Journal of Public Economics 85(2) 207ndash234 httpsdoiorg101016S0047-2727(01)00084-6

Allcott H amp Keniston D (2014) Dutch Disease or Agglomeration The Local Economic Effects of Natural Resource Booms in Modern America (N W P N 20508 Ed) NBER Working Paper No 20508 (Vol w20508) NBER Working Paper No 20508 NBER Working Paper No 20508 httpsdoiorgNBER Working Paper No 20508

Andersen T M amp Maibom J (2020) The big trade-off between efficiency and equitymdashis it there Oxford Economic Papers 72(2) 391ndash411

127

Anselin L (1988) Spatial econometrics methods and models (Vol 4) DordrechtBoston Kluwer Academic Publishers

Anselin L amp Bera A K (1998) Spatial dependence in linear regression models with an introduction to spatial econometrics Statistics Textbooks and Monographs (Vol 155)

Anselin L Bera A K Florax R amp Yoon M J (1996) Simple diagnostic tests for spatial dependence Regional Science and Urban Economics 26(1) 77ndash104 httpsdoiorg1010160166-0462(95)02111-6

Antonelli M A amp De Bonis V (2018) The efficiency of social public expenditure in European countries a two-stage analysis Applied Economics 1ndash14 httpsdoiorg1010800003684620181489522

Aragoacuten F M amp Rud J P (2013) Natural Resources and Local Communities Evidence from a Peruvian Gold Mine American Economic Journal Economic Policy 5(2) 1ndash25 httpsdoiorg101257pol521

Ariely G (2014) Does Diversity Erode Social Cohesion Conceptual and Methodological Issues Political Studies 62(3) 573ndash595 httpsdoiorg1011111467-924812068

Armstrong H amp Taylor J (2000) Regional economics and policy (3rd ed) Oxford Blackwell

Aroca P amp Atienza M (2011) Economic implications of long distance commuting in the Chilean mining industry Resources Policy 36(3) 196ndash203 httpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201103004

Aroca P amp Bosch M (2000) Crecimiento convergencia y espacio en las regiones chilenas 1960 - 1998 Estudios de Economiacutea 27 199ndash224 Retrieved from httprepositoriouchileclbitstreamhandle2250127853Patricio_Arocapdfsequence=1

Ashworth J Geys B Heyndels B amp Wille F (2014) Competition in the political arena and local government performance Applied Economics 46(19) 2264ndash2276 httpsdoiorg101080000368462014899679

Atkinson A B (2015) Inequality What Can Be Done Harvard University Press

Auty R (1993) Sustaining development in mineral economies the resource curse thesis London [ua] Routledge

Auty R (2001) Resource abundance and economic development (R World Institute for Development Economics Ed) Oxford Oxford University Press

Badeeb R A Lean H H amp Clark J (2017) The evolution of the natural resource curse thesis A critical literature survey Resources Policy 51 123ndash134 httpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201610015

Balaguer-Coll M T Brun-Martos M I Maacuterquez-Ramos L amp Prior D (2019) Local government efficiency determinants and spatial interdependence Applied Economics

128

51(14) 1478ndash1494 httpsdoiorg1010800003684620181527458

Balaguer-Coll M T amp Prior D (2009) Short- and long-term evaluation of efficiency and quality An application to Spanish municipalities Applied Economics 41(23) 2991ndash3002 httpsdoiorg10108000036840701351923

Banker R D Charnes A amp Cooper W W (1984) Some models for estimating technical and scale inefficiencies in data envelopment analysis Management Science 30(9) 1078ndash1092

Beine M Coulombe S amp Vermeulen W N (2015) Dutch Disease and the Mitigation Effect of Migration Evidence from Canadian Provinces The Economic Journal 125(589) 1574ndash1615 httpsdoiorg101111ecoj12171

Benito B Bastida F amp Garciacutea J A (2010) Explaining differences in efficiency an application to Spanish municipalities Applied Economics 42(4) 515ndash528 httpsdoiorg10108000036840701675560

Berg A amp Ostry J (2011) Equality and efficiency Finance amp Development 48(3) 12ndash15

Berg A amp Ostry J (2017) Inequality and Unsustainable Growth Two Sides of the Same Coin IMF ECONOMIC REVIEW 65(4) 792ndash815 httpsdoiorg101057s41308-017-0030-8

Beyer H amp Vergara R (2006) Delincuencia en Chile Determinantes y rol de las poliacuteticas puacuteblicas Instituto de Economiacutea UC

Blanco L amp Grier R (2012) Natural resource dependence and the accumulation of physical and human capital in Latin America Resources Policy 37(3) 281ndash295 httpsdoiorghttpdoiorg101016jresourpol201201005

Blau J R amp Blau P M (1982) The cost of inequality Metropolitan structure and violent crime American Sociological Review 114ndash129

Boetti L Piacenza M amp Turati G (2009) Fiscal decentralization and spending efficiency of local governments An Empirical Investigation on a Sample Of 4

Boix C amp Posner D (1998) Social capital Explaining its origins and effects on government performance British Journal Of Political Science 28 686ndash693

Borge L E Parmer P amp Torvik R (2015) Local natural resource curse JOURNAL OF PUBLIC ECONOMICS 131 101ndash114 httpsdoiorg101016jjpubeco201509002

Borger B Kerstens K Moesen W amp Vanneste J (1994) Explaining differences in productive efficiency An application to Belgian municipalities Public Choice 80(3) 339ndash358 httpsdoiorg101007BF01053225

Bourguignon F amp Morrisson C (1990) Income distribution development and foreign trade A cross-sectional analysislowast European Economic Review 34(6) 1113ndash1132 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg1010160014-2921(90)90071-6

129

Branas C C Cheney R A MacDonald J M Tam V W Jackson T D amp Ten Have T R (2011) A difference-in-differences analysis of health safety and greening vacant urban space American Journal of Epidemiology 174(11) 1296ndash1306

Bravo J (2014) Fondo Comuacuten Municipal y su desincentivo a la recaudacioacuten en Chile Temas de La Agenda Legislativa-Centro de Poliacuteticas Puacuteblicas UC 9(68)

Browning E K amp Johnson W R (1984) The Trade-Off between Equality and Efficiency Journal of Political Economy 92(2) 175ndash203 httpsdoiorg101086261219

Brunnschweiler C N amp Bulte E H (2008) The resource curse revisited and revised A tale of paradoxes and red herrings Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 55(3) 248ndash264 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jjeem200708004

Brunori P Ferreira F H G amp Peragine V (2013) Inequality of opportunity income inequality and economic mobility Some international comparisons In Getting Development Right (pp 85ndash115) Springer

Brunton-Smith I Jackson J amp Sutherland A (2014) Bridging structure and perception On the neighbourhood ecology of beliefs and worries about violent crime British Journal of Criminology 54(4) 503ndash526

Bulte E H Damania R amp Deacon R T (2005) Resource intensity institutions and development World Development 33(7) 1029ndash1044 httpsdoiorg101016jworlddev200504004

Carmignani F (2013) Development outcomes resource abundance and the transmission through inequality Resource and Energy Economics 35(3) 412ndash428 httpsdoiorg101016jreseneeco201304007

Carmignani Fabrizio amp Avom D (2010) The social development effects of primary commodity export dependence Ecological Economics 70(2) 317ndash330 httpsdoiorg101016jecolecon201009003

Caselli F amp Michaels G (2013) Do Oil Windfalls Improve Living Standards Evidence from Brazil American Economic Journal Applied Economics 5(1) 208ndash238 httpsdoiorg101257app51208

Celebioglu F amp Dallrsquoerba S (2010) Spatial disparities across the regions of Turkey An exploratory spatial data analysis Annals of Regional Science 45(2) 379ndash400 httpsdoiorg101007s00168-009-0313-8

Chan J To H-P amp Chan E (2006) Reconsidering social cohesion Developing a definition and analytical framework for empirical research Social Indicators Research 75(2) 273ndash302

Charnes A Cooper W W amp Rhodes E (1978) Measuring the efficiency of decision making units European Journal of Operational Research 2(6) 429ndash444

130

Chi G amp Zhu J (2019) Spatial Regression Models for the Social Sciences SAGE Publications Retrieved from httpsbooksgooglecomaubooksid=zHGkvwEACAAJ

Christiansen K O (1960) Industrialization and urbanization in relation to crime and juvenile delinquency International Review of Criminal Policy 16 3ndash8

Cingano F (2014) Trends in income inequality and its impact on economic growth (Vol 163) Paris OECD Publishing httpsdoiorg1017875jxrjncwxv6j-en

Coelli T J Prasada Rao D S OrsquoDonnell C J amp Battese G E (2005) An introduction to efficiency and productivity analysis An Introduction to Efficiency and Productivity Analysis Springer Science amp Business Media httpsdoiorg101007b136381

Coffeacute H amp Geys B (2005) Institutional Performance and Social Capital An Application to the Local Government Level Journal of Urban Affairs 27(5) 485ndash501 httpsdoiorg101111j0735-2166200500249x

Coffeacute H amp Geys B (2006) Community Heterogeneity A Burden for the Creation of Social Capital Social Science Quarterly 87(5) 1053ndash1072 httpsdoiorg101111j1540-6237200600415x

Cohen D Spear S Scribner R Kissinger P Mason K amp Wildgen J (2000) ldquo Broken windowsrdquo and the risk of gonorrhea American Journal of Public Health 90(2) 230

Corden W M amp Neary J P (1982) Booming sector and de-industrialisation in a small open economy The Economic Journal 92(368) 825ndash848

Cordero J M Pedraja-Chaparro F Pisaflores E C amp Polo C (2017) Efficiency assessment of Portuguese municipalities using a conditional nonparametric approach Journal of Productivity Analysis 48(1) 1ndash24 httpsdoiorg101007s11123-017-0500-z

Croissant Y amp Millo G (2018) Panel Data Econometrics with R John Wiley amp Sons

Cust J amp Poelhekke S (2015) The Local Economic Impacts of Natural Resource Extraction 7 251ndash268 httpsdoiorg101146annurev-resource-100814-125106

da Cruz N F amp Marques R C (2014) Revisiting the determinants of local government performance Omega 44 91ndash103 httpsdoiorg101016JOMEGA201309002

Dauvin M amp Guerreiro D (2017) The Paradox of Plenty A Meta-Analysis World Development 94 httpsdoiorg101016jworlddev201701009

de Sousa M da C S Cribari-Neto F amp Stosic B D (2005) Explaining DEA technical efficiency scores in an outlier corrected environment the case of public services in Brazilian municipalities Brazilian Review of Econometrics 25(2) 287ndash313

Deacon R T (2011) The Political Economy of the Natural Resource Curse A Survey of Theory and Evidence Foundations and Trends in Microeconomics 111-208

Delhey J amp Newton K (2005) Predicting cross-national levels of social trust global pattern or

131

Nordic exceptionalism European Sociological Review 21(4) 311ndash327

Dlouhyacute M (2018) Measuring Geographic Inequalities Dealing with Multiple Health Resources by Data Envelopment Analysis Frontiers in Public Health 6 53 httpsdoiorg103389fpubh201800053

Dollery B Wallis J amp Akimov A (2010) One Size Does Not Fit All The Special Case of Remote Small Local Councils in Outback Queensland Local Government Studies 36(1) 21ndash42 httpsdoiorg10108003003930903435716

Domenech J (2008) Mineral resource abundance and regional growth in Spain 1860ndash2000 Journal of International Development The Journal of the Development Studies Association 20(8) 1122ndash1135

Doran J amp Jordan D (2016) Decomposing US regional income inequality from 1969 to 2009 Applied Economics Letters 23(11) 781ndash784 httpsdoiorg1010801350485120151109030

Drew J amp Dollery B (2015) The State of Things The Dynamic Efficiency of Australian State and Territories Economic Papers A Journal of Applied Economics and Policy 34(3) 165ndash176

Drew J Kortt M amp Dollery B (2015) What Determines Efficiency in Local Government A DEA Analysis of NSW Local Government Economic Papers A Journal of Applied Economics and Policy 34(4) 243ndash256 httpsdoiorg1011111759-344112118

Easterly W (2007) Inequality does cause underdevelopment Insights from a new instrument Journal of Development Economics 84(2) 755ndash776 httpsdoiorghttpdxdoiorg101016jjdeveco200611002

Ebert L amp La Menza T (2015) Chile copper and resource revenue A holistic approach to assessing commodity dependence Resources Policy 43(Supplement C) 101ndash111 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201410007

ElGindi T (2017) Natural resource dependency neoliberal globalization and income inequality Are they related A longitudinal study of developing countries (1980ndash2010) Current Sociology 65(1) 21ndash53 httpsdoiorg1011770011392116632031

Engerman S L amp Sokoloff K L (1994) Factor Endowments Institutions and Differential Paths of Growth Among New World Economies National Bureau of Economic Research

Engerman S L amp Sokoloff K L (1997) Factor endowments institutions and differential paths of growth among new world economies How Latin America Fell Behind 260ndash304

Engerman S L Sokoloff K L Urquiola M amp Acemoglu D (2002) Factor Endowments Inequality and Paths of Development among New World Economies [with Comments] EconomampxedA 3(1) 41ndash109 Retrieved from httpwwwjstororgezp01libraryquteduaustable20065432

132

Faumlre R Grosskopf S amp Lovell C A K (1985) The measurement of efficiency of production (Vol 6) Springer Science amp Business Media

Fleming D A amp Measham T G (2015a) Income Inequality across Australian Regions during the Mining Boom 2001-11 Australian Geographer 46(2) 203ndash216 httpsdoiorg1010800004918220151020596

Fleming D A amp Measham T G (2015b) Local economic impacts of an unconventional energy boom the coal seam gas industry in Australia Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 59(1) 78ndash94 httpsdoiorg1011111467-848912043

Fum R M amp Hodler R (2010) Natural resources and income inequality The role of ethnic divisions Economics Letters 107(3) 360ndash363 httpsdoiorg101016jeconlet201003008

Garofalo J (1978) The fear of crime Broadening our perspective

Geys B amp Moesen W (2009) Exploring Sources of Local Government Technical Inefficiency Evidence from Flemish Municipalities Public Finance and Management 9(1) 1ndash29

Goderis B amp Malone S W (2011) Natural Resource Booms and Inequality Theory and Evidence The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 113(2) 388ndash417 httpsdoiorg101111j1467-9442201101659x

Greene W H (2016) Productivity and Efficiency Analysis (W H Greene L Khalaf R Sickles M Veall amp M-C Voia Eds) (1st ed 20) Cham Springer International Publishing httpsdoiorg101007978-3-319-23228-7

Gustafsson B amp Shi L (2002) Income inequality within and across counties in rural China 1988 and 1995 Journal of Development Economics 69(1) 179ndash204 httpsdoiorg101016S0304-3878(02)00058-5

Gylfason T amp Zoega G (2003) Inequality and Economic Growth Do Natural Resources Matter In T T Eicher S (Ed) Inequality and Growth Theory and Policy Implications (pp 255ndash292) The MIT Press

Henningsen A (2010) Estimating Censored Regression Models in R using the censReg Package R Package Vignettes Collection 5(2) 12

Henningsen A (2019) censReg Censored Regression (Tobit) Models R package version 05-30 httpscranr-projectorgpackage=censReg Retrieved from httpscranr-projectorgpackage=censReg

Herrera S amp Pang G (2005) Efficiency of Public Spending in Developing Countriesthinsp An Efficiency Frontier Approach World Bank Washington DC

Hill T D amp Angel R J (2005) Neighborhood disorder psychological distress and heavy drinking Social Science amp Medicine 61(5) 965ndash975

133

httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jsocscimed200412027

Hipp J R (2010) RESIDENT PERCEPTIONS OF CRIME AND DISORDER HOW MUCH IS ldquoBIASrdquo AND HOW MUCH IS SOCIAL ENVIRONMENT DIFFERENCES Criminology 48(2) 475ndash508 httpsdoiorg101111j1745-9125201000193x

Holtug N amp Mason A (2010) Introduction Immigration diversity and social cohesion SAGE Publications Sage UK London England

Hooghe M Vanhoutte B Hardyns W amp Bircan T (2010) Unemployment Inequality Poverty and Crime Spatial Distribution Patterns of Criminal Acts in Belgium 2001ndash06 The British Journal of Criminology 51(1) 1ndash20 httpsdoiorg101093bjcazq067

Howie P amp Atakhanova Z (2014) Resource boom and inequality Kazakhstan as a case study Resources Policy 39(1) 71ndash79 httpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201311004

Isham J Woolcock M Pritchett L amp Busby G (2005) The Varieties of Resource Experience Natural Resource Export Structures and the Political Economy of Economic Growth The World Bank Economic Review 19(2) 141ndash174 httpsdoiorg101093wberlhi010

Jottier D Ashworth J amp Heyndels B (2012) Understanding Votersrsquo Preferences How the Electoratersquos Complexity Affects Prediction Accuracy and Wishful Thinking among Politicians with Respect to Election Outcomes Kyklos 65(3) 340ndash370 httpsdoiorg101111j1467-6435201200542x

Kanbur S M R amp Venables A (2005) Spatial inequality and development (R World Institute for Development Economics Ed) Oxford Oxford University Press

Kesler C amp Bloemraad I (2010) Does immigration erode social capital The conditional effects of immigration-generated diversity on trust membership and participation across 19 countries 1981ndash2000 Canadian Journal of Political ScienceRevue Canadienne de Science Politique 43(2) 319ndash347

Kuznets S (1955) Economic Growth and Income Inequality The American Economic Review 45(1) 1ndash28 Retrieved from httpwwwjstororgstable1811581

Lagos G amp Blanco E (2010) Mining and development in the region of Antofagasta Resources Policy 35(4) 265ndash275 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201007006

Leamer E E Maul H Rodriguez S amp Schott P K (1999) Does natural resource abundance increase Latin American income inequality Journal of Development Economics 59(1) 3ndash42 httpsdoiorg101016s0304-3878(99)00004-8

Leibbrandt M Finn A amp Woolard I (2012) Describing and decomposing post-apartheid income inequality in South Africa Development Southern Africa 29(1) 19ndash34 httpsdoiorg1010800376835X2012645639

134

Letki N (2008) Does Diversity Erode Social Cohesion Social Capital and Race in British Neighbourhoods Political Studies 56(1) 99ndash126 httpsdoiorg101111j1467-9248200700692x

Lewis D A (2017) Fear of crime Incivility and the production of a social problem Routledge

lo Storto C (2013) Evaluating Technical Efficiency of Italian Major Municipalities A Data Envelopment Analysis model Procedia - Social and Behavioral Sciences 81 346ndash350 httpsdoiorg101016JSBSPRO201306440

Loayza N amp Rigolini J (2016) The Local Impact of Mining on Poverty and Inequality Evidence from the Commodity Boom in Peru World Development 84 219ndash234 httpsdoiorg101016jworlddev201603005

Loayza N Teran A M y amp Rigolini J (2013) Poverty Inequality and the Local Natural Resource Curse World Bank Policy Research Working Paper (6366) httpsdoiorg1015961813-9450-6366

Loacutepez R amp Miller S J (2008) Chile The Unbearable Burden of Inequality World Development 36(12) 2679ndash2695 httpsdoiorg101016jworlddev200801012

Manzano O amp Rigobon R (2001) Resource Curse or Debt Overhang National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper Series No 8390 1 httpsdoiorghttpwwwnberorgpapersw9424bib

McPherson M Smith-Lovin L amp Cook J M (2001) Birds of a Feather Homophily in Social Networks Annual Review of Sociology 27(1) 415ndash444 httpsdoiorg101146annurevsoc271415

McQuestin D Drew J amp Dollery B (2018) Do Municipal Mergers Improve Technical Efficiency An Empirical Analysis of the 2008 Queensland Municipal Merger Program Australian Journal of Public Administration 77(3) 442ndash455 httpsdoiorg1011111467-850012286

Messner S F Rosenfeld R amp Baumer E P (2004) Dimensions of Social Capital and Rates of Criminal Homicide American Sociological Review 69(6) 882ndash903 httpsdoiorg101177000312240406900607

Michaels G (2011) THE LONG TERM CONSEQUENCES OF RESOURCE-BASED SPECIALISATION The Economic Journal 121(551) 31ndash57 httpsdoiorg101111j1468-0297201002402x

Mijanovich T amp Weitzman B C (2003) Which ldquobroken windowsrdquo matter School neighborhood and family characteristics associated with youthsrsquo feelings of unsafety Journal of Urban Health 80(3) 400ndash415

Mikušovaacute P (2015) An Application of DEA Methodology in Efficiency Measurement of the Czech Public Universities Procedia Economics and Finance 25 569ndash578 httpsdoiorg101016S2212-5671(15)00771-6

135

Milanovic B (2016) Global inequality Harvard University Press

Millo G amp Piras G (2012) splm Spatial panel data models in R Journal of Statistical Software 47(1) 1ndash38

Murphy K M amp Topel R H (2016) Human Capital Investment Inequality and Economic Growth JOURNAL OF LABOR ECONOMICS 34(2) S99ndashS127 httpsdoiorg101086683779

Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute I amp De Witte K (2018a) Local governmentsrsquo efficiency a systematic literature reviewmdashpart I International Transactions in Operational Research 25(2) 431ndash468 httpsdoiorg101111itor12364

Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute I amp De Witte K (2018b) Local governmentsrsquo efficiency a systematic literature reviewmdashpart II International Transactions in Operational Research 25(4) 1107ndash1136 httpsdoiorg101111itor12389

Nuntildeez J Rivera J Villavicencio X amp Molina O (2003) Determinantes socioeconoacutemicos y demograacuteficos del crimen en Chile Estudios de Economiacutea 30(1) 55ndash85

OrsquoDonnell C J Rao D S P amp Battese G E (2008) Metafrontier frameworks for the study of firm-level efficiencies and technology ratios Empirical Economics 34(2) 231ndash255 httpsdoiorg101007s00181-007-0119-4

Ocampo J A (2004) Latin Americarsquos Growth and Equity Frustrations During Structural Reforms The Journal of Economic Perspectives 18(2) 67ndash88 httpsdoiorg1012570895330041371349

OECD (2014) Focus on inequality and growth OECD

OECD (2017) Howrsquos Life 2017 Life Satisfaction Oecd httpsdoiorg101787how_life-2017-en

Ohtake F (2008) Inequality in Japan Asian Economic Policy Review 3(1) 87ndash109 httpsdoiorg101111j1748-3131200800093x

Okun A M (2015) Equality and efficiency the big tradeoff Washington DC Brookings Institution Press

Ortega B Sanjuaacuten J amp Casquero A (2017) Determinants of efficiency in reducing child mortality in developing countries The role of inequality and government effectiveness Health Care Management Science 20(4) 500ndash516 httpsdoiorg101007s10729-016-9367-1

Ostry J Berg A amp Tsangarides C (2014) Redistribution inequality and growth International Monetary Fund

Pacheco F Saacutenchez R amp Villena M (2013) Eficiencia de los Gobiernos Locales y sus Determinantes Un anaacutelisis de Fronteras Estocaacutesticas en Datos de Panel para

136

Municipalidades Chilenas Santiago de Chile Chile

Papyrakis E amp Raveh O (2014) An Empirical Analysis of a Regional Dutch Disease The Case of Canada Environmental and Resource Economics 58(2) 179ndash198 httpsdoiorg101007s10640-013-9698-z

Paredes D (2013) The Role of Human Capital Market Potential and Natural Amenities in Understanding Spatial Wage Disparities in Chile Spatial Economic Analysis 8(2) 154ndash175 httpsdoiorg101080174217722013774094

Paredes D Iturra V amp Lufin M (2016) A spatial decomposition of income inequality in Chile Regional Studies 50(5) 771ndash789

Phan P Van Orsquobrien M Mendolia S amp Paloyo A (2017) National pro-poor spending programmes and their effect on income inequality and poverty Evidence from Vietnam Applied Economics 49(55) 5579ndash5590 httpsdoiorg1010800003684620171313957

Podinovski V V (2004) Bridging the Gap between the Constant and Variable Returns-to-Scale Models Selective Proportionality in Data Envelopment Analysis The Journal of the Operational Research Society 55(3) 265ndash276 Retrieved from httpwwwjstororgstable4102006

Ravallion M (2005) On Measuring Aggregate Social Efficiency Economic Development and Cultural Change 53(2) 273ndash292 httpsdoiorg101086425380

Rehner J Baeza S A amp Barton J R (2014) Chilersquos resource-based export boom and its outcomes Regional specialization export stability and economic growth Geoforum 56(Supplement C) 35ndash45 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jgeoforum201406007

Rivera J Gutieacuterrez M amp Nuacutentildeez J (2009) Caracterizacioacuten socioeconoacutemica y espacial de la criminalidad en Chile Revista CEPAL

Ross C E (2011) Collective threat trust and the sense of personal control Journal of Health and Social Behavior 52(3) 287ndash296

Ross C E amp Mirowsky J (2001) Neighborhood disadvantage disorder and health Journal of Health and Social Behavior 258ndash276

Rothstein B amp Uslaner E M (2005) All for all Equality corruption and social trust World Politics 58(1) 41ndash72

Sachs J D amp Warner A M (2001) The curse of natural resources European Economic Review 45(4ndash6) 827ndash838 httpsdoiorg101016S0014-2921(01)00125-8

Salas R (2019) sinimr Chilean Municipalities Information System Wrapper Retrieved from httpsgithubcomrobsalascosinimr

Sampson R J (1986) Crime in Cities The Effects of Formal and Informal Social Control Crime and Justice 8 271ndash311

137

Sampson R J (2008) Rethinking crime and immigration Contexts 7(1) 28ndash33

Santos Silva J M C amp Tenreyro S (2010) On the existence of the maximum likelihood estimates in Poisson regression Economics Letters 107(2) 310ndash312 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jeconlet201002020

Santos Silva J M C amp Tenreyro S (2011) poisson Some convergence issues Stata Journal 11(2) 207ndash212 Retrieved from httpwwwstata-journalcomarticlehtmlarticle=st0225

Scott Z (2009) Decentralisation local development and social cohesion an analytical review GSDRC Research Paper 5

Sinha R P (2017) Fiscal Performance Benchmarking of Indian States-A Robust Frontier Approach The Central European Review of Economics and Management 1(4) 225ndash249

Skogan W (1986) Fear of crime and neighborhood change Crime and Justice 8 203ndash229

Skogan W (1999) Measuring what matters Crime disorder and fear In Measuring what matters Proceedings from the Policing Research Institute meetings (pp 37ndash53) National Institute of Justice Washington DC

Skogan W (2015) Disorder and Decline The State of Research Journal of Research in Crime and Delinquency 52(4) 464ndash485 httpsdoiorg1011770022427815577836

Šťastnaacute L amp Gregor M (2014) Public sector efficiency in transition and beyond evidence from Czech local governments Applied Economics 47(7) 1ndash20 httpsdoiorg101080000368462014978077

Tandon A (2005) Measuring Efficiency of Macro Systems An Application to Millennium Development Goal Attainment Asian Development Review 22(2) 108ndash125

Taylor R B (1999) The incivilities thesis Theory measurement and policy Measuring What Matters 65 88

Tigga N S amp Mishra U S (2015) On Measuring Technical Efficiency of the Health System in India An Application of Data Envelopment Analysis Journal of Health Management 17(3) 285ndash298 httpsdoiorg1011770972063415589229

Tinbergen J (1975) Demographic Development and the Exhaustion of Natural Resources Population and Development Review 1(1) 23ndash32 httpsdoiorg1023071972269

Tiruneh G (2014) Social Revolutions Their Causes Patterns and Phases SAGE Open 4(3) 2158244014548845 httpsdoiorg1011772158244014548845

Tolsma J Van der Meer T amp Gesthuizen M (2009) The impact of neighbourhood and municipality characteristics on social cohesion in the Netherlands Acta Politica 44(3) 286ndash313

Tsekeris Sotiris T Tsekeris T amp Papaioannou S (2018) Regional determinants of technical efficiency evidence from the Greek economy Regional Studies [London]thinsp Carfax

138

httpsdoiorg1010800034340420171390312

Uslaner E (2002) The moral foundations of trust Cambridge University Press

Uslaner E (2011) CORRUPTION AND INEQUALITY DICE Report 9(2) 20ndash24

Uslaner E (2013) Trust and corruption revisited how and why trust and corruption shape each other Quality amp Quantity 47(6) 3603ndash3608 httpsdoiorg101007s11135-012-9742-z

Uslaner E amp Brown M (2005) Inequality trust and civic engagement American Politics Research 33(6) 868ndash894

Van der Ploeg F (2011) Natural Resources Curse or Blessing Journal of Economic Literature 49(2) 366ndash420 httpsdoiorg101257jel492366

Vergara R (2012) Crime Prevention Programs Evidence From CHILE The Developing Economies 50(1) 1ndash24

Watkins M H (1963) A staple theory of economic growth Canadian Journal of Economics and Political ScienceRevue Canadienne de Economiques et Science Politique 29(2) 141ndash158

Wilkinson R G (1999) Income inequality social cohesion and health clarifying the theorymdasha reply to Muntaner and Lynch International Journal of Health Services 29(3) 525ndash543

Wilson J Q amp Kelling G L (1982) Broken windows Atlantic Monthly 249(3) 29ndash38

Wilson W J (1996) When Work Disappears Political Science Quarterly 111(4) 567ndash595 httpsdoiorg1023072152085

Wirth L (1938) Urbanism as a Way of Life American Journal of Sociology 44(1) 1ndash24

Worthington A amp Dollery B (2000) An empirical survey of frontier efficiency measurement techniques in local government Local Government Studies 26(2) 23ndash52 httpsdoiorg10108003003930008433988

Wu P-C Huang T-H amp Pan S-C (2014) Country Performance Evaluation The DEA Model Approach Social Indicators Research 118(2) 835ndash849 httpsdoiorg101007s11205-013-0443-3

Ye X Ma L Ye K Chen J amp Xie Q (2017) Analysis of Regional Inequality from Sectoral Structure Spatial Policy and Economic Development A Case Study of Chongqing China Sustainability 9(4) 633 Retrieved from httpwwwmdpicom2071-105094633

Yue W Z Zhang Y T Ye X Y Cheng Y Q amp Leipnik M R (2014) Dynamics of Multi-Scale Intra-Provincial Regional Inequality in Zhejiang China Sustainability 6(9) 5763ndash5784 httpsdoiorg103390su6095763

139

Appendices

Appendix A Summary statistics income inequality

Table A1

Summary statistics Gini coefficients by year and zone

140

Appendix B Summary statistics for NRD measures by region

Table B1

Summary statistics NRD measures by region

141

Appendix C Regional administrative division and defined zones

Figure C1 Geographical distribution of Chilean regions and 3 zones

142

Appendix D Summary statistics numeric controls and correlation matrix

Table D1

Summary Statistics Numeric Explanatory Variables

Figure D1 Correlation matrix numeric explanatory variables

143

Appendix E Static spatial panel models

Following Millo amp Piras (2012) a model including a spatial lag of the dependent variable and

spatial autoregressive disturbances but not spatial lags for the explanatory variable(s) is called

SARAR model A static spatial SARAR panel could be expressed as

119910 120582 119868 otimes119882 119910 119883120573 119906 (E1)

where y is an 119873 1 vector of observations on the dependent variable X is a 119873 119896 matrix of

observations on the non-stochastic exogenous regressors 119868 an identity matrix of dimension 119879 otimes

is the kronecker operator 119882 is the 119873 119873 spatial weights matrix of known constants whose

diagonal elements are set to zero and 120582 the corresponding spatial parameter44

The disturbance vector is the sum of two terms

119906 120580 otimes 119868 120583 120576 (E2)

where 120580 is a 119879 1 vector of ones 119868 an 119873 119873 identity matrix 120583 is a vector of time-invariant

individual specific effects (not spatially autocorrelated) and 120576 a vector of spatially autocorrelated

innovations that follow a spatial autoregressive process of the form

120576 120588 119868 otimes119882 120576 120584 (E3)

If we assume that spatial correlation applies to both the individual effects 120583 and the remainder

error components 120576 Kapoor et al (2007) propose that the disturbance term 119906 follows a first order

spatial autoregressive process of the form

119906 120588 119868 otimes119882 119906 120576 (E4)

44 Unlike ldquotraditional panelsrdquo which are organized as different time series for each cross-sectional unit ldquospatial panelsrdquo are organized as a series of cross-sections for each year

144

where 119882 is the spatial weights matrix and 119903ℎ119900 the corresponding spatial autoregressive

parameter To further allow for the innovations to be correlated over time the innovations vector

in Equation 7 follows an error component structure

120576 120580 otimes 119868 120583 120584 (E5)

where 120583 is the vector of cross-sectional specific effects 120584 a vector of innovations that vary

both over cross-sectional units and time periods 120580 is a vector of ones and 119868 an 119873 119873 identity

matrix45

Spatial panel models are usually estimated by Maximum Likelihood or GMM46 The SAR

SEM or SARAR models could be estimated with Random or Fixed effects For instance A fixed

effect spatial lag model can be written in stacked form as

119910 120582 119868 otimes119882 119910 120580 otimes 119868 120583 119883120573 120576 (E6)

where 120582 is the spatial autoregressive coefficient 119882 a non-stochastic spatial weights matrix

120580 a column vector of ones of dimension 119879 119868 an 119873 119873 identity matrix and 120576 sim 119873 0120590 On

the other hand a fixed effects spatial error model assuming the disturbance specification by

Kapoor et al (2007) can be written as

119910 120580119879 otimes 119868119873 120583 119883120573 119906119906 120588 119868119879 otimes119882119873 119906 120576

(E7)

where 120588 is the spatial autocorrelation coefficient and 120576 is a well-behaved error term

45 In the regression implementation the specification given by equations (22) and (3) is denoted by ldquobrdquo for ldquoBaltagirdquo On the other hand the specification given by equations (23) and (31) is denoted by ldquokkprdquo for ldquoKapoor Kelejian and Pruchardquo 46 We use the R package splm which allow both types of regression procedure

145

Appendix F Analysis OLS residuals cross-sectional (six-year average) analysis

Table F1

Analysis OLS residuals Anselin Method

Figure F1 Moran scatter plot OLS residuals

146

Appendix G Linear panel data models

Table G1

Panel regressions (non-spatial)

147

Appendix H Spatial panel models (Generalized Moments (GM) estimation)

Table H1

GM Spatial Models

148

Appendix I Inputs and outputs used in DEA analysis

Figure I1 Examples of inputs and outputs used to measure LGE (based on Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018)

149

Appendix J Technical and scale efficiency

Following lo Storto (2013) under an input-oriented specification assuming VRS with n

municipalities using k inputs to produce m outputs the DEA model for a given i-th municipality

is specified with the following mathematical programming problem

119898119894119899 120579119904119906119887119895119890119888119905 119905119900 119910 119884120582 0120579119909 119883120582 01198991prime120582 1  120582 0prime

Where 119910 is the column vector of the outputs and 119909 is the column vector of the inputs

Moreover we can define X as the (k times n) input matrix and Y as the (m times n) output matrix 120579 is a

scalar (that satisfies 120579 1) more specifically it is the efficiency score that measures technical

efficiency It measures the distance between a municipality and the efficiency frontier defined as

a linear combination of the best practice observations With 120579 1 the municipality is inside the

frontier (ie it is inefficient) while 120579 1 implies that the municipality is on the frontier (ie it is

efficient) The vector 120582 is an (n times 1) vector of constants that measures the weights used to compute

the location of an inefficient municipality if it were to become efficient

The total technical efficiency 119879119864 can be decomposed into pure technical efficiency

119879119864 and scale efficiency 119878119864 where 119878119864 119879119864 119879119864 (Coelli et al 2005) To find out

whether a municipality is scale efficient and qualify the type of returns of scale a DEA model

under non-increasing returns to scale 119879119864 is implemented where 119878119864 119879119864 119879119864 Hence

the following rule can be applied (Faumlre Grosskopf amp Lovell 1985)

bull If 119878119864 1 then a municipality is scale efficient both under CRS and VRS

bull If 119878119864 1 it operates under increasing returns to scale

bull If 119878119864 1 it operates under decreasing returns to scale

150

Appendix K Correlation matrix

Figure K1 Correlation matrix contextual factors

151

Appendix L Returns to scale by year and zone

Table L1

Returns to scale (percentage of municipalities)

152

Appendix M Returns to scale by year (maps)

Figure M1 Spatial distribution of returns to scale by county per year

153

Appendix N Efficiency status by year (maps)

Figure N1 Spatial distribution of efficient (E es = 1) and inefficient (I es lt 1) counties per year

154

Appendix O Spatial distribution efficiency scores by year (maps)

FigureO1 Custom breaks maps of efficiency scores (VRS) by county per year

155

Appendix P Analysis OLS residuals cross-sectional (six-year average) analysis

Table P1

Analysis OLS residuals Anselin Method

Figure P1 Moran scatter plot efficiency scores and OLS residuals

156

Table P2

OLS and spatial regression models for the six-year averaged data

157

Appendix Q OLS regressions for cross-sectional and panel data

Table Q1

OLS cross-sectional regression per year

158

Table Q2

OLS panel regressions Pooled random effects and instrumental variable

159

Appendix R Quantile maps incivilities rate by group (average total period)

Figure R1 Spatial distribution of incivilities by group (Average rate per 1000 inhabitants 2006-09-11-13-15-17)

160

Appendix S Correlation matrix numeric covariates

Figure S1 Correlation matrix numeric covariates

161

Appendix T Negative Binomial regressions

Table T1

Negative Binomial regressions

162

Appendix U Coefficients economic and racial diversity by geographical zone

Table U1

Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson models by geographic zone

Page 6: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted

v

Table of Contents

Keywords i

Abstract ii

Table of Contents v

List of Figures viii

List of Tables ix

List of Abbreviations x

Statement of Original Authorship xi

Acknowledgements xii

Chapter 1 Introduction 13

Income inequality and dependence on natural resources 14

Local government efficiency and income inequality 16

Social cohesion and economic diversity 19

Contributions 21

Thesis outline 23

Chapter 2 Natural Resources Curse or Blessing Evidence on Income Inequality at the County Level in Chile 24

21 Introduction 24

22 Inequality and Natural Resources 28 221 Theoretical Framework 28

Cross-country literature 29 Single country evidence 32

222 The relevance of the spatial approach 33

23 Research problem and hypotheses 35

24 Data and Methods 36 241 Operationalization of key variables 36 242 Control variables 40 243 Methods 41 244 Spatial Model Specification 43

25 Results 44 251 Exploratory Spatial Data Analysis (ESDA) 44 252 Cross-sectional analysis 45 253 Panel Data analysis 48

26 Discussion and conclusions 51

Chapter 3 The Impact of Income Inequality on the Efficiency of Municipalities in Chile 55

vi

31 Introduction 55

32 Related Literature 61 321 Measuring efficiency of local governments 61 322 Explaining differences in LGE 63 323 The trade-off between efficiency and equity 64

33 Methodology 66 331 Chilean Municipalities and period of analysis 66 332 Measuring municipal efficiency 68 333 Inputs and outputs used in DEA 70 334 Regression model 71 335 The instrument 75

34 Results and discussion 77 341 DEA results 77

Returns to scale 78 Efficiency measure 80

342 Regression results 82 Exploratory spatial analysis 82 Cross-sectional analysis 83 Panel data analysis 84

35 Conclusions 88

Chapter 4 Social Cohesion Incivilities and Diversity Evidence at the municipal level in Chile 91

41 Introduction 91

42 Related Literature 95 421 The Community Heterogeneity Thesis 95 422 The literature on incivilities 97 423 The ldquoIncivilities Thesisrdquo 99

4 3 Methodology 100 431 Period of analysis and data sample 100 432 Operationalisation of the response variable and exploratory analysis 101 433 Measures of community heterogeneity and control variables 105 434 Methods 108 435 Hypotheses 111

44 Results and Discussion 112

4 5 Conclusions 118

Chapter 5 Conclusions 120

Bibliography 126

Appendices 139

Appendix A Summary statistics income inequality 139

Appendix B Summary statistics for NRD measures by region 140

Appendix C Regional administrative division and defined zones 141

Appendix D Summary statistics numeric controls and correlation matrix 142

vii

Appendix E Static spatial panel models 143

Appendix F Analysis OLS residuals cross-sectional (six-year average) analysis 145

Appendix G Linear panel data models 146

Appendix H Spatial panel models (Generalized Moments (GM) estimation) 147

Appendix I Inputs and outputs used in DEA analysis 148

Appendix J Technical and scale efficiency 149

Appendix K Correlation matrix 150

Appendix L Returns to scale by year and zone 151

Appendix M Returns to scale by year (maps) 152

Appendix N Efficiency status by year (maps) 153

Appendix O Spatial distribution efficiency scores by year (maps) 154

Appendix P Analysis OLS residuals cross-sectional (six-year average) analysis 155

Appendix Q OLS regressions for cross-sectional and panel data 157

Appendix R Quantile maps incivilities rate by group (average total period) 159

Appendix S Correlation matrix numeric covariates 160

Appendix T Negative Binomial regressions 161

Appendix U Coefficients economic and racial diversity by geographical zone 162

viii

List of Figures

Figure 21 Average share in GDP of economic activities (2006ndash17) 37

Figure 22 Evolution of Gini coefficient and measures of NRD (2006ndash17) 38

Figure 23 Spatial distribution of Gini coefficient and NRD (2006ndash17) 39

Figure 23 Moran scatter plots for variables gini and pss_casen 45

Figure 31 Geographical distribution of Chilean regions and macrozones 74

Figure 32 Evolution of efficiency scores and the proportion of firms by sector 77

Figure 33 Evolution technical efficiency (TE) pure technical efficiency (PTE) and scale efficiency (SE) 78

Figure 34 Returns to scale by zone 79

Figure 35 Evolution mean efficiency scores (VRS) by zone 81

Figure 41 Evolution number and rates of incivilities and crime (DMCS) in Chile 2006-2017 102

Figure 42 Evolution total number of incivilities by category 104

Figure 43 Spatial distribution of incivilities rate per 1000 inhabitants (2006 vs 2017) 104

Figure 44 Annual average number of incivilities per county 109

Figure C1 Geographical distribution of Chilean regions and 3 zones 141

Figure D1 Correlation matrix numeric explanatory variables 142

Figure F1 Moran scatter plot OLS residuals 145

Figure I1 Examples of inputs and outputs used to measure LGE (based on Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018) 148

Figure K1 Correlation matrix contextual factors 150

Figure M1 Spatial distribution of returns to scale by county per year 152

Figure N1 Spatial distribution of efficient (E es = 1) and inefficient (I es lt 1) counties per year 153

FigureO1 Custom breaks maps of efficiency scores (VRS) by county per year 154

Figure P1 Moran scatter plot efficiency scores and OLS residuals 155

Figure R1 Spatial distribution of incivilities by group (Average rate per 1000 inhabitants 2006-09-11-13-15-17) 159

Figure S1 Correlation matrix numeric covariates 160

ix

List of Tables

Table 21 Cross-sectional Model Comparison (six-year average data) 47

Table 22 ML Spatial SAR Models 50

Table 23 ML Spatial SEM Models 50

Table 24 ML Spatial SARAR Models 51

Table 31 Descriptive statistics Inputs and Output variables used in DEA analysis 71

Table 32 Summary Statistics Numeric Contextual Factors 74

Table 33 Summary efficiency scores (VRS) by zone and region 80

Table 34 Cross-sectional (censored) regressions 84

Table 35 Panel data regressions 87

Table 41 Summary statistics total count of incivilities and by category (full sample and period) 103

Table 42 Summary statistics numeric explanatory variables 108

Table 43 Poisson regressions 113

Table 44 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson models by region 115

Table 45 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson model by incivility group 116

Table A1 Summary statistics Gini coefficients by year and zone 139

Table B1 Summary statistics NRD measures by region 140

Table D1 Summary Statistics Numeric Explanatory Variables 142

Table F1 Analysis OLS residuals Anselin Method 145

Table G1 Panel regressions (non-spatial) 146

Table H1 GM Spatial Models 147

Table L1 Returns to scale (percentage of municipalities) 151

Table P1 Analysis OLS residuals Anselin Method 155

Table P2 OLS and spatial regression models for the six-year averaged data 156

Table Q1 OLS cross-sectional regression per year 157

Table Q2 OLS panel regressions Pooled random effects and instrumental variable 158

Table T1 Negative Binomial regressions 161

Table U1 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson models by geographic zone 162

x

List of Abbreviations

Constant returns to scale CRS

Data envelopment analysis DEA

Decreasing returns to scale DRS

Efficiency scores ES

Exploratory spatial data analysis ESDA

Generalized methods of moments GMM

Gross Domestic Product GDP

Increasing returns to scale IRS

Local government efficiency LGE

Maximum likelihood ML

Municipal common fund MCF

Natural resource dependence NRD

Natural resource endowment NRE

Ordinary Least Squares OLS

Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development OECD

Own permanent revenues OPR

Resource curse hypothesis RCH

Spatial autoregressive model SAR

Spatial error model SEM

Variable returns to scale VRS

xi

Statement of Original Authorship

The work contained in this thesis has not been previously submitted to meet requirements

for an award at this or any other higher education institution To the best of my knowledge and

belief the thesis contains no material previously published or written by another person except

where due reference is made

Signature QUT Verified Signature

Date _________04092020_________

xii

Acknowledgements

First I would like to thank my wife Lilian who joined me in this challenge and patiently

supported me all these years I would also like to thank our family who always supported us from

Chile I especially thank my sister Silvia who took care of our house and dog

I am also grateful to my supervisory team Dr Radhika Lahiri and Dr Vincent Hoang who

supported and guided me in the process of making this thesis a reality

I also thank the Deans of the Faculty of Economics and Business at my beloved University

of Talca Dr Arcadio Cerda and Dr Rodrigo Herrera who trusted me and supported me in this

process In the same way I would like to thank all the support of the director of the Commercial

Engineering career Mr Milton Inostroza

Finally I would like to thank the government of Chile for the financial support that made

my stay and studies possible here at the Queensland University of Technology

13

Chapter 1 Introduction

Efficiency and equity issues are often considered together in the evaluation of economic

performance While higher efficiency usually measured by growth rates of income per capita

correlates with improvements in measures of well-being the link between inequality and well-

being is less clear This is reflected not only in the type and amount of research related to efficiency

and equity but also in the role that both play in the design of the economic policy For instance

several market-oriented countries have focused primarily on economic growth trusting in a trickle-

down process where financial benefits given to the wealthy are expected to ultimately benefit the

poor However despite the growing interest in the issue of inequality there is a considerable lack

of studies about its consequences

Although some level of inequality is inevitable or even necessary for economic activity this

study is motivated by the argument that relatively high levels of inequality can be associated with

many problems such as persistent unemployment increasing fiscal expenses indebtedness and

political instability (Berg amp Ostry 2011) Inequality can also have other severe social

consequences including increased crime rates teenage pregnancy obesity and fewer

opportunities for low-income households to invest in health and education (Atkinson 2015) In

addition when the role of money and concentration of economic power undermine political

outcomes inequality of opportunities hampers social and economic mobility trust and social

cohesion In summary inequality can increase the fragility of the economic and social situation in

a country reducing economic growth and making it less inclusive and sustainable

14

A country well-known for its market-oriented economy and high level of dependence on

natural resources is Chile Chilean success in terms of economic growth contrasts with its inability

to reduce the persistently high levels of social and economic inequality particularly in the last

three decades Using data for the 2006-2017 period and considering 324 out of 345 Chilean

counties this thesis presents three essays with empirical evidence aiming to explain the

phenomenon of persistent income inequality and some of its potential consequences The first

essay aims to analyse how the evolution and variability of income inequality throughout the

country are associated with the degree of natural resource dependence The second essay studies

the relevance of income inequality in explaining cross-county differences in the performance of

local governments (municipalities) Finally the third essay explores the link between social

cohesion and community heterogeneity highlighting the importance of economic and racial

diversity

Income inequality and dependence on natural resources

The first essay explores how cross-county differences in income inequality are associated

with differences in the degree of dependence on natural resources We use the Gini coefficient in

each county as our dependent variable and the proportion of employment in the primary sector as

our measure of natural resource dependence The main hypothesis is that income inequality should

be positively related to the degree of natural resource dependence To test our hypothesis we use

a spatial econometric approach This approach is motivated by the study of Paredes Iturra and

Lufin (2016) who explore the geographic heterogeneity of income inequality in Chile finding

evidence of a significant spatial dimension

15

The theoretical and empirical literature has mostly proposed a positive link between

inequality and natural resources Although most of the evidence corresponds to cross-country

comparisons there is also increasing body of research at the local level A rationale underpinning

the positive link suggested in the literature is that in natural resource-rich countries ownership is

concentrated in small groups and extraction activities require low-skilled workers (Gylfason amp

Zoega 2003 Leamer Maul Rodriguez amp Schott 1999) Another market-based argument often

labelled as the ldquoDutch Diseaserdquo proposes that natural resource windfalls could be associated with

a crowding-out effect on the manufacturing sector (Corden amp Neary 1982 Easterly 2007) This

process encourages rent-seeking behaviours discourages investment in physical and human

capital and delays the process of technology adoption and industrialization (Auty 2001 Bulte

Damania amp Deacon 2005 Gylfason amp Zoega 2003) The result could be a lower economic

growth which is the central idea under the ldquoResource Curse Hypothesisrdquo (Auty 1993 Sachs amp

Warner 2001)

An ldquoinstitutionalrdquo argument for the positive association between inequality and the

endowment of natural resources is based on the so-called ldquoParadox of Plentyrdquo (Borge Parmer amp

Torvik 2015 Dauvin amp Guerreiro 2017) The idea is that both national and local authorities have

less incentive to operate efficiently when they experience windfalls in their revenues for

instance from natural resources This could end with corrupted authorities exerting patronage

clientelism and designing public policies to favour specific groups of the population (Uslaner amp

Brown 2005) Evidence also suggests that the final effect of natural resource booms on income

inequality will depend on authoritiesrsquo capacity to manage these additional resources the extent of

commuting and migration among regions and the potential increase in the demand for non-tradable

16

goods which are intensive in unskilled workers (Aroca amp Atienza 2011 Cust amp Poelhekke 2015

Fleming amp Measham 2015b Howie amp Atakhanova 2014 Michaels 2011)

Contrary to most theoretical and empirical evidence we find that income inequality shows

a robust and significant negative association with our proxy for natural resource dependence This

result suggests that the process of transformation to an economy less dependent on natural

resources could have exacerbated rather than alleviated the persistence of income inequality The

decrease in the participation of the primary sector in employment in favour mainly of the tertiary

sector highlights the importance of the latter to explain the current high levels of inequality and its

future evolution Another important result is that spatial linear models show practically the same

results as traditional linear models This could be interpreted as the spatial dimension previously

found in income inequality is not the result of spatial dependence in the variable itself for instance

due to a process of spillover among counties Hence the usually found positive spatial

autocorrelation of income inequality (similar levels in neighbouring counties) could be explained

by spatial patterns in other variables or to the spatial heterogeneity that characterizes the Chilean

economy

Local government efficiency and income inequality

Essay 2 delves deep into the potential trade-off between efficiency and equity We measure

the efficiency of Chilean municipalities which correspond to the organizations in charge of

managing each county Municipal efficiency is understood as ldquotechnical efficiencyrdquo that is the

possibility that each municipality has reached the same level of outputs with less use of inputs

Then we analyse how income inequality controlling for other contextual factors such as

socioeconomic demographic geographical and political characteristics may help to explain

17

differences in municipal performance Our main hypothesis is that municipal efficiency is

inversely associated with income inequality Moreover we seek a causal interpretation of this

relationship

Municipal performance could be influenced by income inequality in direct and indirect ways

In a direct sense income inequality is used to capture the degree of heterogeneity and complexity

in the demand for public services that citizens exert over local authorities Hence higher levels of

income inequality should be associated with a more complex set of public services and therefore

with lower levels of municipal efficiency (Jottier Ashworth amp Heyndels 2012) Furthermore

when high levels of inequality exist the richest groups can exert a higher influence over local

authorities resulting in low quality and quantity of services for most of the population Among

indirect effects high and persistent inequality could be the source of corrupted institutions and

local authorities favouring themselves or specific groups This undermines citizensrsquo participation

in civic activities and their willingness to monitor municipal performance (Uslaner amp Brown

2005) Additionally the potential benefits of decentralization on the way local governments

deliver public services will be limited when the context is characterized by corrupted politicians

and a limited administrative and financial capacity (Scott 2009)

We measure municipal efficiency using an input-oriented Data Envelopment Analysis

(DEA) to obtain efficiency scores for our sample of 324 municipalities in each year from 2006 to

2017 Then we study the influence on municipal efficiency of income inequality and our set of

contextual factors using a panel of six years corresponding to those years for which household

income information is available 2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017 Our dependent variable

is the set of efficiency scores which are relative measures of efficiency They are relative to the

18

municipalities included in the sample and they do not imply that higher technical efficiency gains

cannot be achieved Thus we use both cross-sectional and panel censored regression models To

tackle endogeneity issues and suggest a causal interpretation we also propose using the proportion

of firms in the primary sector as an instrument for income inequality

We find an average efficiency score of 83 meaning that Chilean municipalities could

reduce the use of inputs by 17 without reducing their outputs We also measure municipal

efficiency under different assumptions related to returns to scale This allows us to disaggregate

technical efficiency to assess whether inefficiencies are due to management issues (pure technical

efficiency) or scale issues (scale efficiency) Although the results show that most municipalities

operate under increasing or decreasing returns to scale scale inefficiencies only explain a small

proportion of total municipal inefficiencies This highlights the need to look for contextual factors

outside the control of local authorities to explain differences in municipal performance

Geographical representations of our results in terms of returns to scale and efficiency scores

show some spatial clustering process among municipalities Spatial statistics tests confirm that

efficiency scores show a significant positive spatial autocorrelation This means that neighbouring

municipalities tend to show similar levels of efficiency This similar performance could be due to

a process of spatial dependence (eg efficiency spillovers among neighbouring municipalities) or

due to the existence of structural-geographical similarities (spatial heterogeneity) To assess the

spatial dimension in municipal efficiency abstracting from temporal fluctuations we use a cross-

section of data consisting of the six-year average for the variables in our panel After running a

regression of efficiency scores against the set of controls the analysis of OLS residuals shows that

the spatial autocorrelation is almost completely removed This means that the spatial pattern in

19

municipal efficiency can be explained (controlled) by other variables such as regional indicator

variables rather than efficiency itself Given this result we proceed to study the influence of

income inequality on municipal efficiency using traditional (non-spatial) regression analysis

In contrast to literature that emphasizes an equity-efficiency trade-off (Andersen amp Maibom

2020 Berg amp Ostry 2011 Browning amp Johnson 1984 Okun 2015) that is greater equality leads

to lower efficiency we find that municipal efficiency is inversely associated with income

inequality This implies that more equal counties are also those with higher municipal efficiency

Furthermore the coefficient of income inequality is close to one when we use the instrumental

variable approach This means that a reduction in income inequality ceteris paribus should be

associated with an increase in the same magnitude in municipal efficiency This result has strong

policy implications The non-existence of the trade-off suggests that there is more to be gained by

targeting policies towards the reduction of inequality than conventional theories suggest For

instance these policies may help increase the levels of efficiency and well-being at least at the

municipal level

Social cohesion and economic diversity

The third essay studies the relationship between the degree of social cohesion and diversity

in Chile Extant literature has argued that one of the main factors influencing social cohesion is

the degree of economic and ethnic-racial diversity within a society This diversity erodes social

cohesion reducing trust and corrupting institutions (Letki 2008 Rothstein amp Uslaner 2005

Tolsma Van der Meer amp Gesthuizen 2009 Uslaner 2011 2013)

To measure social cohesion scholars have traditionally used measures of social capital trust

or feelings of insecurity (Ariely 2014 Chan To amp Chan 2006 Letki 2008) We suggest the use

20

of the rate of incivilities per 1000 inhabitants as a proxy for social cohesion Incivilities correspond

to those antisocial behaviours (eg groups of rowdy teens and public drunkenness) or visible

neighbourhood conditions (eg graffiti and abandoned buildings) that tend not to be treated as

crime Using the rate of incivilities is arguably a more objective and reliable measure of social

cohesion particularly in countries where institutions of order and security are among the most

trusted An increase in the rate of incivilities rather than changes in crime rates should better

capture the worsening in social cohesion experienced in countries such as Chile where crime rates

are not growing but social conflicts are on the rise Thus the main hypothesis in this essay is that

the rate of incivilities (social cohesion) should be positively (negatively) associated with economic

and racial diversity

Using panel count data models we start analysing how differences in incivilities rates

between and within counties are associated with differences in indicators of relative and absolute

economic disadvantage We use the Gini coefficient of each county as our measure of economic

diversity Although we find a significant and positive association between the rate of incivilities

and the level of income inequality the magnitude of the link seems to be small Among absolute

indicators of economic disadvantage only the level of income shows a strong effect Next we

include our measure of racial diversity We use the number of new visas granted to foreigners as

a proportion of the county population Results show a significant and strong positive association

between the rate of incivilities and racial diversity

To check the robustness of our results we analyse the impact of our measures of economic

and racial diversity running our models separately for each Chilean region and clustering them

geographically We also split the total number of incivilities in four categories to see which type

21

of incivilities show the greatest association with our measures of diversity In general results

support the ldquocommunity heterogeneity hypothesisrdquo that higher community heterogeneity is

associated with higher rates of incivilities (Alesina amp La Ferrara 2002 Letki 2008 Tolsma et al

2009) However results do not support the ldquoincivilities thesisrdquo that the distribution of incivilities

tends to mirror the distribution of income inequality (Skogan 1999 Taylor 1999)

Three results stand out among the set of control variables First the level of education shows

and independent and significant negative association with the rate of incivilities This is in contrast

to previous studies where education acts mainly as a moderator of the effect of economic and racial

diversity on social cohesion (Tolsma et al 2009) The results also show that there is no significant

relationship between the rate of incivilities and the proportion of young population This is relevant

because policies aimed to reduce incivilities usually put the focus on specific groups such as young

people which are linked to physical and social incivilities when social control is weakened

Finally the degree of financial municipal autonomy also shows a significant negative association

with the rate of incivilities This result suggests that municipalities can contribute independently

or together with the central government to reduce incivilities and strengthen social cohesion

Contributions

The three essays in this thesis provide several important insights into the analysis of the

causes and consequences of income inequality particularly in the context of Chile ndash a typical

resource rich economy with persistently high levels of income inequality

Essay 1 advances the understanding of the relationship between income inequality and

natural resources in Chile extending the empirical analysis from the regional level to the county

level In addition the geographic heterogeneity of income inequality is explored with the inclusion

22

of alternative sources of spatial dependence as a potential dimension of the causal relationship

between income inequality and natural resources This essay demonstrates the relevance of natural

resources in explaining the persistence of income inequality even after controlling for other

socioeconomics and institutional factors Findings from this study have potential contribution not

only in the design of policies aimed to reduce income inequality but also in addressing the current

developmental bias between the metropolitan region and the rest of the country

Essay 2 is one of the first studies that undertake a longitudinal analysis of the effects of

income inequality on the efficiency of municipal governments in Chile To capture the role of the

municipal governments in the provision to local people of public services such as education and

health we specify several inputs and outputs in our efficiency model which is different from the

conventional specification in the existing literature For example the number of medical

consultations in public health facilities and the number of enrolled students in public schools are

used as outputs instead of general indicators such as county population Our empirical analysis

also utilises a larger sample of municipalities and covers a much longer period spanning from 2006

to 2017 This essay also investigates the contextual factors beyond the control of local authorities

that can explain variations in the efficiency of municipal governments across the country

Empirical findings from Essay 2 help us increase our understanding of the production

technology of municipalities the sources of inefficiencies and specifically the impact of income

inequality on the performance of local authorities The results deliver two main policy

implications First municipal inefficiencies in the provision of public goods and services differ

across Chilean municipalities In addition efficiency levels show some degree of spatial

autocorrelation This implies that policies such as amalgamation or cooperation among

23

municipalities could have effects beyond the municipalities involved which must be considered

Second the causal effect that income inequality has on municipal efficiency provides another

dimension into the design and implementation of development policies

Essay 3 explores for the first time the effects of economic and racial diversity on social

cohesion in Chile This essay considers incivilities as manifestation of social cohesion and

investigates as extant literature suggests whether indicators of relative economic disadvantage

such as income inequality are among the main factors driving social disorganization and social

unrest Empirical findings suggest that on the one hand economic heterogeneity captured by the

Gini coefficient has a disparate effect both in terms of magnitude and significance on the rate of

incivilities across the country On the other hand the impact of racial heterogeneity appears to be

stronger more significant and of a similar magnitude throughout the country Results also provide

new insights into the design of national policies addressing social disorders particularly those

policies focussed on specific groups of the population and the role of local authorities Overall the

findings provide an opportunity to advance the understanding of the process of weakening in the

social cohesion experienced in Chile and the conflicts that have risen from this process

Thesis outline

The remainder of the thesis is organized as follows Chapter 2 presents essay 1 examining

the association between income inequality and the degree of dependence on natural resources

Chapter 3 presents essay 2 which looks for a causal relationship between municipal efficiency and

income inequality Chapter 4 presents essay 3 analysing the relationship between social cohesion

and economic and racial diversity Finally Chapter 5 presents some concluding remarks

24

Chapter 2 Natural Resources Curse or Blessing Evidence on

Income Inequality at the County Level in Chile

21 Introduction

A phenomenon of increasing inequality of incomes and wealth in recent decades has been

documented by leading scholars and international organizations such as the International Monetary

Fund (Berg amp Ostry 2017 Ostry Berg amp Tsangarides 2014) and the Organization for Economic

Cooperation and Development (Cingano 2014) These efforts have placed the topic of inequality

at the top of the current economic debate recognizing inequality as a determinant not only of

economic growth but also of human development They also have highlighted the necessity for

more research on the drivers of inequality and mechanisms through which it manifests aiming to

design effective policies in reducing economic and social inequalities

Various factors have been analysed as the sources of high and increasing levels of inequality

Among the most significant factors are the levels of income at initial stages of economic

development (Kuznets 1955) Globalization (Milanovic 2016) skill-biased technological change

(Tinbergen 1975) investment in human capital (Murphy amp Topel 2016) institutions

redistributive policy and country-specific characteristics (Acemoglu 1995 2002 Acemoglu

Aghion amp Violante 2001 Acemoglu Johnson amp Robinson 2001) Our focus in this essay is on

the importance that the natural resource endowment (NRE) or lack thereof can play in the

determination of income disparities

25

This essay studies the patterns and evolution of income inequality in the context of a natural

resource-rich country Using the case of the Chilean economy we aim to understand and

disentangle how a phenomenon of high- and persistent-income inequality is related to the

endowment of natural resources that a country owns Chile is an interesting case to study because

despite showing a successful history of economic growth inequality among individuals and among

aggregated spatial units has shown a strong persistence (Paredes et al 2016) Furthermore Chile

has remained among the most unequal countries in the world1

Theory and empirical evidence do not establish a clear link between income inequality and

NRE In addition NRE has received considerably less attention (Auty 2001 ElGindi 2017) and

most of the evidence has been focused on cross-country comparisons For instance NRE can

influence inequality by determining its initial levels (Engerman amp Sokoloff 1994 1997

Engerman Sokoloff Urquiola amp Acemoglu 2002) shaping the evolution of institutions

(Acemoglu 2002) make the educational system less intellectually challenging and moulding the

structure of economic activity (Leamer et al 1999) So studying how cross-county differences in

NRE are associated with the distribution of income within a country has theoretical empirical and

policy implications

In this study we offer empirical evidence on the relationship between income inequality and

the endowment of natural resources using data at the county level in Chile for the period 2006-

2017 Income inequality is measured by the Gini coefficient The importance of NRE is proxied

using a measure of natural resource dependence (NRD) defined as the percentage of the total

1 A 2014 OECD report on income inequality (httpwwwoecdorgsocialincome-distribution-databasehtm) showed Chile as the country with the highest Gini coefficient of disposable income among OECD countries OECD also indicates Chile as the country with the widest gap between the richest 10 percent and the poorest 10 percent of countryrsquos population among its 34 members (OECD 2014)

26

employment in each county corresponding to the primary sector (agriculture forestry fishing and

mining)

The main hypothesis to be tested is whether income inequality is positively associated with

the degree of NRD The transmission mechanisms through which natural resources could influence

socioeconomic outcomes could be based on the market or institutions The market-based approach

argues that natural resource booms could be associated with an appreciation of the real exchange

rate and a crowding out effect over other more productive economic activities such as

manufacturing It could also delay the adoption of new technologies and reduce incentives to invest

in physical and human capital (Gylfason amp Zoega 2003) Based on the ldquoResource Curse

Hypothesisrdquo (RCH) natural resources could be a curse when the political and institutional

framework is weak and natural resources are concentrated in space such as oil and minerals

(Deacon 2011) 2 Among institutional channels a higher NRD or natural resource booms could

be associated with rent seeking misallocation of labour and entrepreneurial talent institutional

and political decline or even violent conflicts For instance the ldquoParadox of Plentyrdquo sustains that

windfalls of revenues as a consequence of resource booms could be related to a lack of incentives

to perform efficiently corruption patronage and local authorities favouring their voters or being

captured by the richest groups (Dauvin amp Guerreiro 2017) Hence a higher NRD or natural

resource booms could be the explanation not only for low levels of growth in regions more

dependent on natural resources but also it could be the root of income disparities

2 There is a wide strand of research on the Resource Curse Hypothesis however the evidence so far is not conclusive Evidence in favour of RCH has been mainly found in developing resource rich countries (Auty 1993 2001 Badeeb Lean amp Clark 2017 Blanco amp Grier 2012 Borge et al 2015 Brunnschweiler amp Bulte 2008 Sachs amp Warner 2001 Van der Ploeg 2011)

27

To test our hypothesis that is whether the levels of income inequality across counties are

positively associated with the degree of NRD we use a spatial econometric approach We use this

approach because attributes such as income inequality in one region may not be independent of

attributes in neighbouring regions (Armstrong amp Taylor 2000) This process of spatial dependence

invalidates the use of traditional (non-spatial) approaches

This study seeks to make two contributions to research First previous empirical evidence

shows a significant spatial dimension of income inequality in Chile (Paredes et al 2016)

However this dimension has been barely explored with most studies limiting the degree of

disaggregation to a regional scale (Aroca amp Bosch 2000) We use a spatial approach which makes

it possible to model and test the significance of the spatial dimension in the analysis of income

inequality and its relationship with other variables Second previous research for the Chilean

economy linking inequality with NRE has been mainly focused on explaining differences between

regions or the importance and effects of the mining-copper sector (Aroca amp Atienza 2011 Ebert

amp La Menza 2015 Lagos amp Blanco 2010 Rehner Baeza amp Barton 2014) We extend this

analysis using data for local economies Identifying and quantifying the impact of NRE on income

inequality at the county level is likely to be more informative for policies aiming to address the

current developmental bias between the metropolitan region and the rest of the country Moreover

the analysis of the role of natural resources in conjunction with other potential sources of inequality

may shed lights in understanding the persistence of the high levels of inequality observed in the

Chilean economy All in all this study could contribute to the design of policies that

simultaneously help reduce inequality increase efficiency and promote sustainable and inclusive

growth

28

Our main finding shows that after controlling for other potential sources of income

inequality such as educational level demographic characteristics and the level of public

government expenditure the degree of dependence on natural resources has a significant effect on

income inequality However contrary to our expectations the effect is negative This result

suggests that the natural or policy-driven process of transformation from primary and extractive

activities to manufacturing and service sectors imposes additional challenges to central and local

authorities aiming to reduce income inequality

In section 22 we review the literature on the relationship between income inequality and

natural resources In section 23 we establish our research problem and main hypothesis Section

24 describes our data and methods and section 25 the empirical results We finish with section

26 discussing our main results concluding and proposing avenues for future research

22 Inequality and Natural Resources

221 Theoretical Framework

Explanations for income inequality can be associated with individual institutional political

and contextual characteristics Individual characteristics include age gender and mainly the level

of education and skills of the population in the labour force For instance globalization and

technological change lead firms to increase the demand for skilled labour deepening income

inequality between skilled and unskilled workers (Atkinson 2015 Milanovic 2016 Tinbergen

1975) Among institutional characteristics labour unions collective bargaining and the minimum

wage have been suggested as explanations of income inequality (Acemoglu Aghion et al 2001

Atkinson 2015) Policy design associated with market regulation progressive taxation and

redistribution can also impact the levels and patterns of inequality

29

A key factor in understanding the levels and differences in income distribution within a

country may be its endowment of natural resources NRE shapes the structure of the economy

(Leamer et al 1999) it is associated with the creation of institutions that define the political

culture and it can also influence the performance of other sectors (Watkins 1963) In addition

NRE determines initial conditions market competition ownership over resources rent seeking

and the geographical concentration of the population and economic activity

Cross‐countryliterature

Bourguignon and Morrison (1990) introduce one of the earliest theoretical frameworks

describing the relationship between inequality and NRE They develop a small open economy

model where income distribution is a function of NRE ownership structure and trade protection

Giving cross-sectional evidence for a group of developing countries they conclude that the impact

of NRE particularly mineral resources and land depends on the number and size of the firms

whether they are public or private and the level of protection A higher concentration of production

in a few private firms a big share of production oriented to foreign instead of domestic markets

and protection increasing the relative price of scarce resources are some of the reasons explaining

why some countries are less egalitarian than others

NRE could also influence the evolution and levels of inequality by determining the initial

distribution of incomes This is known as the ldquoEngerman-Sokoloff Hypothesisrdquo (Engerman amp

Sokoloff 1997 Engerman et al 2002) In addition Leamer (1999) proposes that inequality and

development paths in each economy are a function of its economic structure which in turn depends

on ldquofundamentalsrdquo and ldquosymptomsrdquo On the one hand ldquofundamentalsrdquo refer to resource

endowment production structure closeness to markets and governments interventions On the

30

other hand ldquosymptomsrdquo are related to institutions employment structure and net export structure

Using this conceptual framework Leamer argues that natural Resource-Rich Countries (RRC) can

experience a higher level of inequality because can have a ldquodumbbell educational systemrdquo

ownership is concentrated in small groups and extraction activities require low-skilled workers

This implies fewer incentives to educate citizens until very late in the development process

resulting in human capital not prepared to take advantage of the process of technological progress

and delaying the emergence of more efficient and competitive sectors such as manufacturing and

services

Using 1980 and 1990 data for a group of countries classified according to land abundance

Leamer (1999) provides evidence showing that on the one hand land-scarce countries concentrate

their production and employment in sectors that promote equality such as capital-intensive

manufacturing chemical or machinery On the other hand countries abundant in natural resources

concentrate their production trade or employment in sectors that promote income inequality such

as the production of food beverages extraction activities or forestry

Gylfason and Zoega (2003) using a framework based on standard growth models also

proposed a positive relationship between NRE and inequality They assume that workers can work

in the primary sector or in the manufacturing (including services) sector In addition wage income

is equally distributed in the manufacturing sector but unequally in the primary sector (because of

initial distribution competition rent seeking etc) Therefore inequality will be greater when a

bigger proportion of labour is dedicated to extraction activities in the primary sector This

phenomenon is further amplified because of lower incentives to invest in physical and human

capital to adopt new technologies and to increase the share of the manufacturing sector

31

Diverse mechanisms explaining the link between NRE and inequality have been proposed

arguing that NRE determines simultaneously economic growth and inequality (Gylfason amp Zoega

2003) NRE could impact economic growth through the real exchange rate and the crowding-out

effect on manufacturing (ldquoDutch Diseaserdquo) reducing incentives to invest in physical and human

capital (Easterly 2007) and influencing the processes of technology adoption industrialization

and diversification of the economy in a manner that is less conducive to growth (Bulte et al 2005)

These potential explanations related to the called ldquoResource Curse Hypothesisrdquo do not have strong

empirical support (Auty 2001 Bulte et al 2005)

NRE may also influence economic growth through the quality of institutions (Acemoglu

1995 Acemoglu Aghion et al 2001 Acemoglu amp Robinson 2002 Engerman amp Sokoloff 1997

Engerman et al 2002) the concentration of ownership political power and rent-seeking NRE

acts by shaping institutional context and social infrastructure a phenomenon that is stronger when

resources are spatially concentrated such as minerals and plantations (Bulte et al 2005) NRE

could also have a significant effect on social cohesion and instability spreading its influence like

a disease (Brunori Ferreira amp Peragine 2013 Kanbur amp Venables 2005 Milanovic 2016

Ocampo 2004)

Considering a non-tradable sector intensive in unskilled workers Goderis and Malone

(2011) develop a model where the natural resources sector experiences an exogenous gift of

resource income They analyse the impact over income inequality of resource booms proxied by

changes in a commodity price index They conclude that inequality decreases in the short run but

increases after the initial reduction

32

Fum and Hodler (2010) show that natural resources increase inequality but this is

conditional on the level of ethnical polarization of society Carmignani (2013 2010) confirms this

positive relationship using different measures of dependence and abundance and goes further

arguing that inequality constitutes an indirect channel through which NRE affects human

development

Singlecountryevidence

Most of the studies about the relationship between inequality and NRE derive from cross-

country analyses Evidence for specific countries has been mainly based on case studies Howie

and Atakhanova (2014) based on the model of Goderis and Malone (2011) find for the case of

Kazakhstan that income and consumption inequality decreased significantly after booms in the oil-

and-gas sector because of resource booms increase the demand for non-tradable goods which are

intensive in unskilled workers The results depend on the level of rurality institutional quality

education levels and public spending on health and education Fleming and Measham (2015b

2015a) evaluate the impact of booms in the mining and oil sectors in Australia They find that a

boom in the mining sector increases income inequality due to commuting and migration among

regions This phenomenon can be exacerbated when the demanding access to natural resource

revenues is associated with the creation of more local administrative units (counties provinces and

even regions) but the government capacity is not simultaneously improved (Cust amp Poelhekke

2015 Michaels 2011) Furthermore the benefits that a region can receive in the form of fiscal

transfers can be more than compensated by the loses due to city-to-mine commuting such as the

case of mining regions in Chile (Aroca amp Atienza 2011)

33

Other studies at the local level have analysed the impact of the mining sector in Peru (Aragoacuten

amp Rud 2013 Loayza amp Rigolini 2016 Loayza Teran amp Rigolini 2013) Spain (Domenech

2008) and Canada (Papyrakis amp Raveh 2014) and the effects of oil windfalls in Brazil (Caselli amp

Michaels 2013)

In summary there is a wide range of potential mechanisms through which NRE could

influence income inequality Although most of them seem to suggest a positive relationship others

such as commuting and increased within-county demand for non-tradable goods and services

could lead to a negative association This highlights the need to know the sign of this association

in the Chilean economy where the trend shows a reduction in the degree of NRD After controlling

for other factors a positive link would support the argument that the reduction in the degree of

NRD has been relevant in the reduction experienced by income inequality in the same period

However a negative link would support the position that the reduction in NRD has contributed to

explain the persistence of income inequality and its slow reduction

222 The relevance of the spatial approach

Inequalities within countries are still the most important form of inequality from the political

point of view (Milanovic 2016) People from a geographic area within a country are influenced

and care most about their status relative to the people in other areas in the same country The

influence among regions involves multiple aspects (eg economic political and environmental)

These potential interactions have been traditionally ignored assuming independence among

observations related to different regions Moreover neglecting the process of spatial interaction in

key indicators of the economic and social performance of a country may mislead the design of the

public policy

34

The spatial dimension could play a significant role in understanding the distribution of

income within a country One strand of efforts aiming to capture the geographic heterogeneity of

inequality has been focussed on decomposing general indicators such as the Gini coefficient or the

Theil Index Evidence for different countries including the US (Doran amp Jordan 2016) China

(Akita 2003 Gustafsson amp Shi 2002 Ye Ma Ye Chen amp Xie 2017 Yue Zhang Ye Cheng

amp Leipnik 2014) Japan (Ohtake 2008) South Africa (Leibbrandt Finn amp Woolard 2012) and

Chile (Paredes et al 2016) shows that regional inequality is sensitive to the geographic scale of

analysis These studies also show a significant spatial component in the explanation of inequality

of income expenditure or gross domestic product for each country

Another strand explicitly uses exploratory spatial data analysis (ESDA) and spatial

econometrics ESDA has been used to provide new insights about the nature of regional disparities

of incomes and growth rates (Celebioglu amp Dallrsquoerba 2010 Yue et al 2014) Spatial econometric

models aim to assess and address the nature of the spatial effects These effects could be the result

of ldquospatial heterogeneityrdquo that is different relationships in distinct locations or ldquospatial

dependencerdquo which implies cross-sectional interactions (spillover effects) among units from

distinct but near locations

Spatial spillovers have been analysed to study both positive and negative spatial correlation

among less resource-abundant counties and resource-abundant counties On the one hand less

resource-abundant counties may experience positive spillovers because their industries supply

more goods and services to meet the increasing regional demand They can also be benefited from

positive agglomeration externalities and higher investment in private and public infrastructure

(Allcott amp Keniston 2014 Michaels 2011) On the other hand negative spillovers could be the

35

result of a high degree of interregional migration that limits the rise in wages and higher local

prices due to the increase in the share of the non-tradable sector In addition local governments

could have a limited capacity to translate the revenues from resource booms into effective public

policies promoting a sustained local development (Beine Coulombe amp Vermeulen 2015 Caselli

amp Michaels 2013 Papyrakis amp Raveh 2014)

23 Research problem and hypotheses

We can conclude from our overview of the literature that the theoretical and empirical

evidence about the link between inequality and natural resources is inconclusive This does not

make clear whether the process of reduction in the degree of dependence on natural resources

such as that experienced by the Chilean economy helps to explain the sustained but slow reduction

in income inequality or its high persistence

The research question guiding this study relates to how the natural resource endowment

determines the paths and structure of income inequality in natural resource-rich countries Using

the case of Chile the main hypotheses to be tested is whether a higher degree of dependence on

natural resources is associated with higher levels of income inequality To do that we use data at

the county level and we explicitly include the spatial dimension Our aim is to arrive at a more

comprehensive understanding of the drivers and transmission mechanisms explaining the

evolution and patterns shown by income inequality In addition we test whether the spatial

dimension plays a significant role in explaining differences in income distribution in Chile

36

24 Data and Methods

We use county-level data for the years 2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017 The reason

for not using contiguous years is that income data at the household level are only available every

two-three years from the Chilean National Socioeconomic Characterization Survey (CASEN in its

Spanish acronym)3 For the period 2006-2017 the Chilean administrative division considers 15

regions 54 provinces and 346 counties Data on income are available for 324 counties and six

years resulting in a panel with 1944 observations4

We start evaluating the spatial dimension in our data and analysing the link between

inequality and NRD using a cross-sectional setting To this end we use the ldquosix-year averagerdquo

(2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017) for our variables given the low time variability showed by

our measures of income inequality and NRD Results are then compared with those of a panel data

setting

241 Operationalization of key variables

The dependent variable in the present study income inequality at the county level is

measured calculating the Gini coefficient using three definitions of household income labour

autonomous and monetary income5 Labour income corresponds to the incomes obtained by all

members in the household excluding domestic service consisting of wages and salaries earnings

3 CASEN survey is conducted by the Chilean Ministry of Social Development covering topics such as education employment income and health CASEN is considered nationally representative and it is the main source for measures of inequality and poverty used for the design and evaluation of social policies in Chile 4 The six waves of CASEN for our study considered an average of 75599 households and 252081 individuals 5 The Gini coefficient is chosen because provides an overall estimate of income inequality It summarizes what proportion of the population gains what proportion of the total income The Gini coefficient can range between 0 (everyone in the population has the same income) and 1 (one person earns 100 per cent of the income in the community)

37

from independent work and self-provision of goods Autonomous income is the sum of labour

income and non-labour income (including capital income) consisting of rents interest and dividend

earnings pension healthcare benefits and other private transfers Finally monetary income is

defined as the sum of autonomous income and monetary subsidies which correspond to cash

transfers by the public sector through social programs Appendix A shows summary statistics for

the Gini coefficient of our three measures of income

The main independent variable in our study is the degree of dependence on natural resources

in each county To have an idea of the importance of each economic activity in the Chilean

economy particularly those activities related to natural resources Figure 21 shows their average

share in Chilean Gross Domestic Product (GDP) for the period 2006-17 We can observe that the

leading activities are those related to the primary sector especially mining and to the tertiary

sector where financial personal commerce restaurants and hotels services stand out The shares

of each economic activity in GDP vary significantly between Chilean regions and such

information is not available at the county level

Figure 21 Average share in GDP of economic activities (2006ndash17)

38

Leamer (1999) argues that when the main source of income is labour income (as indeed

happens for the Chilean case) using employment shares allows a better approach to measuring

dependence on natural resources Using employment data from CASEN survey we define our

measure of NRD as the employment in the primary sector (mining fishing forestry and

agriculture) as a percentage of the total employment in each county We name this variable

pss_casen where ldquopssrdquo stands for ldquoprimary sector sharerdquo We built other two proxies of NRD

using data from the ldquoServicio de Impuestos Internosrdquo (SII) which is the agency in charge of

collecting taxes in Chile The variable pss measures the percentage of employment in the primary

sector and the variable pss_firms measures the number of firms in the primary sector as a

percentage of the total number of firms in each county Appendix B shows summary statistics for

our three measures of NRD disaggregated by region

Figure 22 Evolution of Gini coefficient and measures of NRD (2006ndash17)

39

Figure 22 shows the evolution of our measure of inequality (using the Gini coefficient of

autonomous income) and our three potential proxies for NRD for the period 2006-2017 We

observe that both income inequality and the degree of NRD show a downward trend This seems

to support our hypothesis of a positive link between inequality and NRD however we need to

control of other sources of inequality before getting such a conclusion In what follows we use the

variable gini as our measure of income inequality capturing the Gini coefficient of autonomous

income Our measure of NRD is the variable pss_casen defined previously

Figure 23 Spatial distribution of Gini coefficient and NRD (2006ndash17)

Note Gini and NRD averages 2006-09-11-13-15-17 for 324 Chilean counties divided into five equal groups Source Own elaboration based on CASEN survey

40

Figure 23 shows quantile maps for income inequality (on the left) and NRD (on the right)

using the six-years average dataset6 On the one hand we observe that high levels of inequality

seem to be clustered in the Centre-South of the country where agriculture forestry and fishery are

the predominant economic activities Only isolated counties show high inequality in the Centre

(Metropolitan area where the countyrsquos capital is located) and North (Mining) areas On the other

hand our measure of NRD seems to show an opposite spatial pattern than income inequality with

high levels in the Centre and North of the country

242 Control variables

To control for county characteristics we use a set of socio-economic demographic and

institutional variables Economic factors are captured by the natural log of the mean autonomous

household income per capita (in thousands of Chilean pesos of 2017) lnincome the poverty rate

poverty the unemployment rate unemployment the percentage of the population living in rural

areas rural and the average years of education of the population over 15 years old education

Demographic factors include the proportion of the population in the labour force labour_force

and the natural log of population density (population divided by county area) lndensity

We also include the natural log of the total municipal public expenditure per capita

lnmuni_expenditure to control for municipal heterogeneity This heterogeneity is mainly related

to the capacity of municipalities to generate their own revenues In addition the richest

municipalities are in the Metropolitan region which concentrates economic power and around 40

6 After sorting a variable in ascending order quantile maps use the quantiles (quartiles quintiles deciles etc) as class breaks to divide the distribution of the variable where each class includes approximately the same number of observations (counties)

41

of the population This has basically implied a lag in the development of regions other than the

metropolitan region

The spatial distribution of our measures of income inequality and NRD displayed in Figure

23 seems to show different patterns in the North Centre and South of the country Appendix C

shows the administrative division of Chile in 15 regions and how we have grouped them in three

zones North Centre and South We consider as the ldquoCentrerdquo area that formed by the Metropolitan

region (XIII) and its two neighbouring regions V and VI Using the Centre area as our reference

we include in our analysis two dummy variables indicating whether a county is located in the North

area (regions XV I II III and IV) or South area (regions VII VIII IX XIV X XI and XII)

Appendix D shows summary statistics for the set of numeric control variables and the

correlation matrix between our measure of NRD pss_casen and the set of numeric controls

243 Methods

To assess and then consider the spatial nature of the data we need to define the set of relevant

neighbours for each country This is operationalized by building a matrix called ldquoWrdquo with a ldquo1rdquo

for neighbouring counties and a ldquo0rdquo for non-neighbouring counties We could build W using

contiguity-based (whether counties share a border or point) or geography-based (taking the

distances among the centroids of each county polygon) spatial weights Specifically we build a W

matrix considering the 5-nearest counties7 Two reasons explain the choice of k-nearest

neighbours First we cannot use a contiguity criterium because we do not have information about

all the counties and there are some geographically isolated counties Second given the significant

7 We assign a ldquo1rdquo to the five nearest counties to each county based on the distances among the polygon centroids Then W is ldquorow standardizedrdquo This facilitates the interpretation of the spatial lag of a variable as the ldquoweighted average valuerdquo of the same variable in neighbouring counties

42

differences in county areas (ldquobig countiesrdquo in northern and southern regions) using a distance-

band criterium with a not enough large distance band can lead to many ldquoislandsrdquo in extreme regions

and a multi-modal distribution for the number of neighbours

We start testing our inequality and NRD variables for spatial autocorrelation in order to

evaluate statistically the clustering patterns shown in Figure 23 Next we run an OLS regression

of inequality against NRD and our set of controls and we test the spatial autocorrelation of OLS

residuals If we cannot reject the null hypothesis of random spatial distribution we do not need

spatial models to analyse income inequality which would give contrasting evidence to previous

suggestions about the relevance of the spatial dimension of income inequality in Chile (Paredes

2013 Paredes et al 2016) If we find significant spatial autocorrelation in the OLS residuals this

justifies the use of spatial models and highlight the need to find the correct spatial structure8

If inequality in one county spillovers or influences inequality in neighbouring counties the

spatial lag of inequality should be included as an explanatory variable and we should use a spatial

autoregressive model (SAR) If some unobserved variable is the explanation for the clustering of

counties with similar inequality then this will be better captured including a spatial lag of the

errors and we should use a spatial error model (SEM) (Anselin 1988 Anselin amp Bera 1998)

Finally when our main explanatory variable or some of the controls show spatial autocorrelation

a spatial lag of the explanatory variable(s) should be included in our model

8 The existence of spatial autocorrelation violates the standard assumption of independence among observations needed for OLS regression This will result in OLS coefficients biased and inconsistent (Anselin 1988)

43

244 Spatial Model Specification

A model that includes the three forms of spatial dependence described above is called the

Cliff-Ord Model The model in its cross-sectional representation could be expressed as

119910 120582119882119910 119883120573 119882119883120574 119906 (21)

where

119906 120588119882119906 120576 (22)

119882 is our weight matrix that works as an NxN spatial lag operator9 Thus 119882119910 119882119883 and 119882119906

are the spatial lags for the dependent variable explanatory variables and the error term

respectively The parameter 120582 capture the spatial dependence in the dependent variable 120574 the

spatial dependence in the explanatory variables 120588 capture the spatial dependence in the error term

and 120598 is a vector of idiosyncratic errors For instance if ldquoyrdquo is income inequality and ldquoXrdquo a measure

of NRD the level of inequality in one county will be explained by the degree of NRD in the same

county 119883120573 the average degree of NRD in neighbouring counties 119882119883120574 the average level of

inequality in neighbouring counties 120582119882119910 and the average value of residuals in neighbouring

counties 12058811988211990610

From equations (21) and (22) the SAR and SEM models can be seen as special cases of

the Cliff-Ord representation after imposing restrictions over the spatial parameters 120582 120574 and 120588 For

the specification of the spatial panel models we follow the terminology by Croissant and Millo

9 The spatial lag is a weighted sum of the values observed at neighbouring locations 10 On the one hand the impact that income inequality in one county has over income inequality in neighbouring counties is called a ldquoglobal spilloverrdquo and it is associated with the feedback effect among neighbours (one county is its neighboursrsquo neighbourrdquo) on the other hand the influence that the degree of NRD in neighbouring counties has over inequality in one county is called a ldquolocal spilloverrdquo

44

(2018) Spatial panel models including the spatial lag of the dependent variable (SAR) the spatial

lag of the residuals (SEM) or both (SARAR) are described in Appendix E

25 Results

251 Exploratory Spatial Data Analysis (ESDA)

To analyse the significance of the spatial dimension in our data set we use the six-year

average of our variables Spatial autocorrelation is tested using the Moranrsquos I statistic11 Moranrsquos

I measures the correlation of one variable with itself in space12 Figure 24 shows the Moran scatter

plots where the standardized variable (Gini coefficient and NRD for each county) appears in the

horizontal axis against its spatial lag (average value in the 5-nearest neighbouring counties) The

Moranrsquos I (slope of the line in the Moran scatter plot) of income inequality shows a significant

positive spatial autocorrelation that is counties with high (low) inequality tend to be close to each

other

11 There are many statistics to formally test the significance of the spatial dimension in the distribution of our data The null hypothesis assumes spatial randomness which means that there is not spatial structure in the data so any spatial pattern is equally likely to occur and values in one location do not depend on values in other locations The alternative hypotheses can be the existence of positive or negative spatial autocorrelation Positive spatial autocorrelation means similar values in neighbouring locations (less variability than under spatial randomness) Negative spatial autocorrelation means dissimilar values in neighbouring locations (more variability than under spatial randomness) 12 Traditional measures of correlation such as the Pearsonrsquos coefficient measure the degree of linear correlation between two different variables Measures of spatial autocorrelation assess the correlation between the values of one variable in one location related to the values of the same variable in other neighbouring locations

45

Figure 23 Moran scatter plots for variables gini and pss_casen

Moranrsquos I is a measure of global spatial autocorrelation this means it is intended to capture

the clustering property of the entire data set To identify where are the significant hot-spots

(clusters of counties showing high income inequality) or cold-spots (clusters of counties showing

low income inequality) we need local indicators of spatial association (LISA) Using the local

Moranrsquos I (not reported) we find significant hot-spots in the South of the country (mainly

agricultural regions) and significant cold-spots in the Centre (Metropolitan area) of the country

The next step is to check whether the clustering pattern in inequality is the result of a process of

spatial dependence in the variable itself or it can be explained by other variables related to

inequality

252 Cross-sectional analysis

We start analysing differences in income inequality between counties using the six-year

average data and running an OLS regression for the model

119892119894119899119894 120573 120573 119901119904119904_119888119886119904119890119899 120573 119897119899119894119899119888119900119898119890 120573 119901119900119907119890119903119905119910 120573 119906119899119890119898119901119897119900119910119898119890119899119905 120573 119897119886119887119900119906119903_119891119900119903119888119890 120573 119890119889119906119888119886119905119894119900119899 120573 119897119899119889119890119899119904119894119905119910 120573 119903119906119903119886119897 120573 119897119899119898119906119899_119890119909119901119890119899119889119894119905119906119903119890 120573 119899119900119903119905ℎ 120573 119904119900119906119905ℎ

(23)

46

The Moran scatter plot and spatial statistical test of OLS residuals from equation (23) are

in Appendix F OLS residuals show a small but significant positive autocorrelation (Moranrsquos I =

0121) This means that income inequality continues showing a significant degree of spatial

autocorrelation after controlling for the set of covariates In addition robust Lagrange Multiplier

(LM) tests show that a spatial error model is preferred over a spatial lag model (Anselin Bera

Florax amp Yoon 1996)13 This means that income inequality tends to cluster in zones larger than a

county so the analysis should be performed on a larger scale such as provinces regions or macro

zones If the SAR model were preferred it would mean that income inequality in one county is

influenced by the level of income inequality in neighbouring counties To find the spatial structure

that best fits the clustering process of income inequality we run the full set of spatial model

specifications in a cross-sectional setting and results are shown in Table 21

Column 2 in Table 21 shows the results of our ldquoOLSrdquo model The ldquoSLXrdquo model includes

spatial dependence only through the explanatory variables The ldquoSARrdquo model includes the spatial

lag of the dependent variable as a regressor and the ldquoSEMrdquo model includes spatial dependence

through the error term The ldquoSARARrdquo model includes both the spatial lag of the response and the

errors and the ldquoSDMrdquo and ldquoSDEMrdquo are the extensions of the ldquoSARrdquo and ldquoSEMrdquo models

respectively including the spatial lag of the explanatory variables Finally a model including

spatial lags for the response errors and explanatory variables (the ldquoSARARXrdquo model) is shown in

the last column

13 Following the ldquoAnselin methodrdquo when both non robust LM tests are significant we should select between the robust LR tests From Table F1 in Appendix F only the robust LM test for the SEM model (RLMerr) appears as significant

47

Table 21

Cross-sectional Model Comparison (six-year average data)

48

Opposite to our hypothesis we observe a significant and negative coefficient for our measure

of NRD This means that counties more dependent on natural resources show lower levels of

inequality Education years population density and municipal expenditure per capita are also

negatively related to inequality On the other hand the level of income the poverty rate and the

proportion of the population living in rural areas show a positive relationship with income

inequality There is no significant influence of the unemployment rate and the proportion of the

population in the labour force In addition the SAR SEM and SARAR models show a

significantly higher average inequality in the South of the country related to the Centre area

The main finding from our cross-sectional analysis is that there is a significant and negative

relationship between inequality and NRD which is quite robust to the model specification

253 Panel Data analysis

Like the cross-sectional case we start estimating the panel without spatial effects Results

for the pooled fixed effects (FE) and random effects (RE) specifications of equation (3) are in

Appendix G Spatial models were estimated using Maximum Likelihood (ML) and Generalized

Moments (GM) and assuming that the spatial structure (W matrix) is the same for all years14

Tables 22 23 and 24 show results for the ML estimation of the SAR SEM and SARAR models

using the pooled FE and RE specifications Results for the GM estimation are in Appendix H

All our spatial models include time fixed effects In the case of the pooled and RE models they

additionally include indicator variables for those counties located in the North and South of the

country

14 In traditional (non-spatial) panels data are stacked as time series for each observational unit (county) In the case of spatial panels data are stacked as slice of cross-sections for each year in the panel

49

The main result is that the negative and significant effect of NRD on income inequality is

robust to most of the spatial panel specifications In addition the coefficient for the variable

pss_casen changes slightly among panel specifications (pooled FE and RE) but does not change

among spatial models (SAR SEM and SARAR)

Another important finding is related to the significance of the spatial dimension of income

inequality When spatial models cross-sectional or panel are compared to non-spatial models

there are no major differences in the magnitude of the coefficients or their significance This could

mean that the positive spatial autocorrelation shown by income inequality seems to be better

explained by a process of spatial heterogeneity rather than spatial dependence The practical

implication of this result is that including dummy variables for aggregated units (eg regions or

groups of regions) could be enough to control for the spatial dimension in the modelling and

analysis of income inequality

Among control variables years of education seems to be the main variable for the design of

long-term policies aimed at reducing inequality This result is in line with previous evidence for

cross-country studies (Leamer et al 1999) and specific countries (Howie amp Atakhanova 2014)

Municipal expenditure per capita also shows a significant and negative association with income

inequality in the pooled and RE spatial specifications This means that higher municipal

expenditure helps to reduce inequality between counties but its effect is more limited within

counties This result support the importance of local governments (Fleming amp Measham 2015a)

however the negative coefficient appears as evidence against the ldquoParadox of Plentyrdquo (Borge et

al 2015)

50

Table 22

ML Spatial SAR Models

Table 23

ML Spatial SEM Models

51

Table 24

ML Spatial SARAR Models

26 Discussion and conclusions

In this essay we delve deep into the sources of income inequality analysing its association

with the degree of dependence on natural resources using county-level data for the 2006ndash2017

period in Chile Given recent evidence for the Chilean economy suggesting a significant spatial

dimension we assess and incorporate explicitly the spatial structure of income inequality using

spatial methods We use cross-sectional and panel data to evaluate the significance of the spatial

dimension and we test whether NRD has a positive effect on income inequality

Contrary to what theory predicts NRD shows a significant and negative association with

income inequality This result is robust to the type of analysis (cross-sectional vs panel data) the

approach (spatial vs non-spatial) and the inclusion of different controls The negative and

significant coefficient implies that if the degree of NRD would not have experienced a 10 drop

during this period income inequality could have fallen in 2 additional points So the downward

trend in the participation of the primary sector in terms of employment in the Chilean economy

52

could be one of the main reasons explaining the high persistence in the levels of income inequality

This means that those areas that undergo a process of productive transformation mainly towards

the services sector would be facing greater problems to reduce inequality This process of

productive transformation natural or policy-driven highlights the importance of policies focused

on human capital and the role of local governments in reducing inequality

The main implication for policymakers is that a reduction in NRD does not help to reduce

inequality generating additional challenges for local and central governments in its attempt to

transform the structure of their economies to fewer dependent ones on natural resources The

finding of a significant spatial dimension suggests that defining macro zones capturing the spatial

heterogeneity in the data should be done before analysing the relationship among variables and the

design and evaluation of specific policies Particularly relevant in those areas experiencing a

reduction in NRD are migration commuting and the characteristics of the tertiary (services) sector

In addition our findings show that education and municipal expenditure could be effective policy

tools in the fight to reduce inequality in Chile

Although our results seem quite robust they do not allow us to make causal inferences about

the effect of NRD on income inequality However we could think of the following explanation to

explain the negative relationship found and the differences between geographical areas

Areas highly dependent on NR used to demand a high proportion of low-skill labour This

has change in sectors such as the mining sector in the northern area which has simultaneously

experienced an increase in activities related to the service sector such as retail restaurants

transport and housing However those services associated with more skilled labour such as the

finance sector remain concentrated in the capital region The reduction in the degree of NRD

(employment in extractive activities) implies lower labour force but more specialized with most

53

of the low-skilled labour transferred to a service sector characterized by low productivity and low

wages

Non-spatial models show that the North and South particularly the latter present

significantly higher levels of inequality This could be associated with the type of resources with

ldquopointrdquo resources such as minerals in the North and ldquodiffusedrdquo resources such as agriculture in the

South This translates into higher average incomes in the Centre and North areas and lower average

incomes in the South

The reduction in NRD implies not only a movement of the labour force from extractive

activities to manufacturing or services with the latter characterized by low productivity and low

salaries of the labour force We could also speculate that most of the high incomes move to the

central area where the economic power and ownership over firms and resources are concentrated

This would explain low inequality associated with higher average incomes in the central area and

high inequality associated with lower average incomes in the South A more in-depth analysis

capturing the mobility of wealth and labour force between counties or more aggregated areas is

needed to better understand the causal mechanism involved

Our findings open avenues for future research in different strands First studies on the causes

of income inequality should take the role of NRD into consideration which has been overlooked

so far Given that the spatial dimension of income inequality seems to be explained by a

phenomenon of spatial heterogeneity estimation strategies such as spatial regime models or

geographically weighted regression should be used (Chi amp Zhu 2019) Second the effect of NRD

on income inequality could manifest through different channels such as education fiscal transfers

and institutions We could extend our analysis to identify which of these competing channels is

the most relevant Transforming some continuous variables such as educational level to a

54

categorical variable or defining new indicator variables for instance whether a local government

shows or not an efficient performance we could classify counties in different groups and then

check whether there are differences or not in the relationship between income inequality and NRD

A third strand could be to disaggregate our measure of NRD for different industries This

would allow us to test differences among industries and to identify the sectors that promote greater

equality and which greater inequality Forth the analysis of the consequences of income inequality

on other economic and social phenomena such as efficiency economic growth and social cohesion

has a growing interest in researchers and policymakers Our findings suggest that to answer the

question of whether income inequality has a causal impact on other variables we could include a

measure of NRD as an instrument to address endogeneity issues For instance two interesting

topics for future research are the analysis of how differences in income inequality between counties

could help to explain differences in the level of efficiency of local governments and differences in

the degree of social cohesion (unrest) throughout the country Those are the issues to be addressed

in the next two essays

55

Chapter 3 The Impact of Income Inequality on the Efficiency of

Municipalities in Chile

31 Introduction

In Chile municipalities are the smallest administrative unit for which citizens choose their

local authorities playing an important role in the provision of public goods and services at the

local level Municipalities have a similar set of objectives but the level of financial resources

available to finance their activities is highly heterogeneous This could result in significant

differences in the levels of performance between municipalities Despite their importance there is

little empirical evidence about the efficiency of local governments in Chile This essay aims to

measure the technical efficiency of Chilean municipalities and to analyse how local characteristics

particularly those related to income distribution at the county level could help to explain

differences in municipal performance

Cross-country studies situate Chile as an efficient country in international comparisons about

efficiency of government spending (Herrera amp Pang 2005 Loacutepez amp Miller 2008) However

evidence for Chile at the local level is relatively sparse suggesting significant levels of

inefficiency For instance Pacheco Sanchez and Villena (2013) found a mean efficiency level of

around 70 using a sample of 309 municipalities for the period 2008-2010 This suggests that

municipalities could achieve the same level of output by reducing the usage of inputs by an average

of 30 Their study also showed that those municipalities more dependent on the central

56

government or those located in counties with lower income per capita are more efficient than their

counterparts

Most empirical research on Local Government Efficiency (LGE) has been conducted for

member countries of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) of

which Chile has been a member since 2010 In the case of European countries such as Spain and

Italy which share similar characteristics such as the monetary union and levels of GDP per head

efficiency studies have been mainly motivated by budgetary constraints (Balaguer-Coll Brun-

Martos Maacuterquez-Ramos amp Prior 2019 lo Storto 2013) The Chilean context differs in three

main ways from its OECD counterparts First except for the Metropolitan Region that concentrates

most of the population Chilean regions are highly dependent on natural resources Second Chile

is also characterized by one of the highest levels of income inequality among OECD countries

which contrast with the situation of developed natural resource-rich countries such as Australia

and Norway Third although budget constraints are also a relevant issue Chilean municipalities

have experienced a sustained increase in the level of financial resources and expenditure

Another relevant distinction when we benchmark the performance of municipalities across

different countries is the type of public services they provide On the one hand in most of the

countries included Chile the main role of local governments is to provide ldquoservices to peoplerdquo

such as public education and public health On the other hand there are countries such as Australia

where local governments mainly provide ldquoservices to propertyrdquo including waste management

maintenance of local roads and the provision of community facilities such as libraries swimming

pools and parks (Dollery Wallis amp Akimov 2010 Drew Kortt amp Dollery 2015 McQuestin

Drew amp Dollery 2018)

57

Despite contextual differences Chilean municipalities seem not to perform differently from

municipalities in other developed and natural resource-rich countries where income inequality is

significantly less than in Chile (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018a) This result highlights the

need to study the role of income inequality and the degree of dependence on natural resources over

LGE characteristics that have been largely overlooked in the literature

We measure and analyse differences in municipal performance using a two-stage approach

In the first stage we measure municipal efficiency using an input-oriented Data Envelopment

Analysis (DEA) to get a set of ldquoefficiency scoresrdquo In the second stage we regress efficiency scores

against our measure of income inequality controlling for a set of contextual factors describing the

economic socio-demographic and political context of each county

We use a sample of 324 municipalities for the period 2006-2017 During this period Chile

was divided into 346 counties belonging to 15 regions This period was characterized by important

external and internal shocks including the Global Financial Crisis (GFC) one of the biggest

earthquakes in Chilean history in 2010 and three municipal elections The availability of

information allows us to measure efficiency for the full period but the influence of contextual

factors is analysed using a panel of six years (2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017) for which

household income information is available

The main hypothesis tested in the second stage is whether higher levels of income inequality

are associated with lower levels of efficiency Previous evidence shows that when progress is not

evenly shared persistent within-country inequality reduces the effectiveness and efficiency of the

public sector (Ortega Sanjuaacuten amp Casquero 2017 Tandon 2005)

Income inequality has been used to control for a wide range of idiosyncratic factors

associated with historical institutional and cultural factors affecting efficiency (Greene 2016

58

Ortega et al 2017) For instance at the local level income inequality has been considered as an

indicator of economic heterogeneity in the population where higher inequality is associated with

a more heterogeneous set of conflicting demands for public services which adversely affect an

efficient provision (Ashworth Geys Heyndels amp Wille 2014 Geys amp Moesen 2009) Higher

levels of income inequality could also relate to economically privileged groups having a greater

capacity to influence the political system for their own benefit rather than that of the majority

When high inequality is persistent the feeling of frustration and disappointment in the population

could reduce not only trust and cooperation among individuals but also trust in institutions which

would negatively affect government efficiency (Boix amp Posner 1998 Coffeacute amp Geys 2005) For

instance national or local authorities could end exerting patronage and clientelism and showing

rising levels of corruption (Uslaner 2011 Uslaner amp Brown 2005)

One of the main gaps in extant literature is the need to conduct more analysis of LGE using

panel data taking into consideration endogeneity issues and controlling for unobserved

heterogeneity (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018a) To address the above we set-up a panel with

time and county-specific effects and we propose the use of a measure of natural resource

dependence (NRD) as an instrument for income inequality Based on the ldquoParadox of Plentyrdquo

fiscal revenues from natural resources windfalls could be associated with an over expansion of the

public sector fostering rent-seeking and corruption and reducing local government efficiency

(Dauvin amp Guerreiro 2017 Manzano amp Rigobon 2001) In the Chilean case most of the revenues

generated by local governments included those from natural resources end up in a common fund

which benefits all municipalities The aim of this common fund is precisely to reduce inequalities

among municipalities so although we do not expect a direct impact of natural resources on LGE

we could expect an indirect effect through other indicators particularly income inequality

59

As far as we know this is the first study analysing the influence of income inequality as a

determinant of municipal efficiency in Chile Moreover this is the first study in the context of a

natural resource-rich country which specifically suggests a measure of natural resource

dependence as an instrument to correct for endogeneity bias We propose the use of the proportion

of firms in the primary sector as proxy for the degree of NRD in each county We argue that this

variable is a better proxy than using the proportion of employment in the manufacturing sector

which has been proposed in previous studies (Alesina amp La Ferrara 2002) During the period

analysed our proxy remained relatively stable and showed a significant relationship with income

inequality In addition it is less likely that it has directly affected municipal efficiency

This study adds to the literature in two other ways First the extant literature suggests that

efficiency measurement could be highly sensitive to the chosen technique as well as the selection

of inputs and outputs (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018a) Inputs are usually proxied by a single

measure of total public expenditures and outputs by general proxies such as population andor the

number of businesses in each county We offer a novel approach for the selection of inputs and

outputs On the one hand we disaggregate government expenditures into four components

(operation personnel health and education) and we use the number of public schools and health

facilities in each county as a proxy for physical capital On the other hand we use four outputs

aiming to capture the wide variety of goods and services supplied by each municipality Through

this approach we aim to better describe the production function of each municipality capturing

not only the variety of inputs and outputs but also differences in size among municipalities

A third contribution relates to the measurement of LGE in the Chilean context We measure

technical and scale efficiency using a larger sample and a longer period This has empirical and

policy relevance On the one hand it helps us to select the correct DEA model and allows us to

60

determine the importance of scale inefficiencies as explanation for differences in municipal

performance On the other hand efficiency measures increase the information available for both

central and local governments to better understand the production technology that best describes

each municipality and to carry out policies to improve efficiency

We believe that our selection of inputs and outputs the use of a large dataset and the joint

analysis using cross-sectional and panel data provide a more accurate and robust analysis of

municipal efficiency Likewise knowing whether inequality has a significant influence on

municipal efficiency may provide useful insights and guidance for policymakers not only in Chile

but also for countries sharing similar characteristics

DEA results show an average level of technical efficiency (inefficiency) of around 83

(17) This means that municipalities could reduce on average a 17 the use of inputs without

reducing the outputs There are significant differences among geographic areas with the Centre

area (where the countyrsquos capital is located) displaying higher efficiency than the rest of the country

When municipal efficiency is measured under different assumptions about returns to scale results

reveal a production technology with variable returns to scales and around 75 of the

municipalities displaying scale inefficiencies However when technical efficiency is

disaggregated between pure technical efficiency and scale efficiency results show that scale

inefficiency explains a small proportion of the total municipal technical inefficiency This finding

justifies a deeper analysis of the reasons why municipalities could operate inefficiently and why

municipal performance could vary among municipalities

Efficiency scores also show a significant degree of positive spatial autocorrelation This

means that municipal efficiency shows a general clustering process with neighbouring

municipalities showing similar levels of efficiency A further analysis shows that most of the

61

spatial pattern in municipal efficiency is exogenous that is could be associated to other variables

Hence we conduct most of our regression analysis using traditional (non-spatial) methods and

leaving spatial regressions in the appendixes

Findings from cross-sectional and panel regressions support the hypothesis that municipal

performance is significantly and negatively associated with income inequality at the county level

The coefficient of income inequality is close to one which means that reductions in income

inequality ceteris paribus could be associated with increases in municipal efficiency in the same

proportion This result supports the strand of research arguing that there is not a trade-off at least

at the municipal level between equity and efficiency (Andersen amp Maibom 2020 Berg amp Ostry

2011 2017) The main policy implications are that authorities in more unequal counties would

face higher challenges to perform efficiently and policies pertaining to inequality and efficiency

should not be designed independently

The chapter is structured as follows Section 32 provides a brief literature review on related

local government efficiency Section 33 introduces the methodological background and empirical

models Section 34 presents the empirical results and discussions Section 35 concludes the

chapter

32 Related Literature

321 Measuring efficiency of local governments

Studies on measuring LGE can be grouped in those analysing the provision of single services

such as health or education and those assessing overall efficiency (lo Storto 2013) Once inputs

and outputs have been defined efficiency is measured using parametric andor non-parametric

techniques Among the former group Stochastic Frontier Analysis (SFA) seems to be preferred

62

by scholars aiming to measure efficiency and to analyse the link with environmental variables

using a single procedure (Pacheco et al 2013 Tsekeris Sotiris Tsekeris amp Papaioannou 2018)

On the non-parametric group Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA) is by far the most used technique

(Afonso amp Fernandes 2006 Balaguer-Coll amp Prior 2009 lo Storto 2013)

The selection of inputs and outputs depends not only on the aimed of the study (specific

sector vs whole measure of efficiency) but also on the role that municipalities play in different

countries There are countries such as Australia (Drew et al 2015) and Spain (Balaguer-Coll amp

Prior 2009) where local governments mainly supply services to ldquopropertyrdquo such as waste

management and road maintenance In these cases efficiency has been mainly measured using

total indicators of local government expenditure and outputs have been proxied using general

indicators such as population or number of business (Drew et al 2015) On the other hand in

countries such as Italy (lo Storto 2013) and Portugal (Afonso amp Fernandes 2008) in Europe or

Brazil (de Sousa Cribari-Neto amp Stosic 2005) and Chile (Pacheco et al 2013) in South America

municipalities mainly supply services to ldquopeoplerdquo Here in addition to financial expenditures or

revenues inputs have included the number of local government employees the number of schools

or the number of hospitals and health centres School-age population the number of students

enrolled in primary and secondary schools and the number of beds in hospitals have been

considered as outputs Based on the study of Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte (2018a) a wider list of

inputs and outputs used in previous studies can be found in Appendix I

Studies from different countries show important differences in the average efficiency scores

both between and within countries These studies also differ in the samples methodologies and

variables included A summary showing the range and variability of the mean efficiency scores

founds in countries all around the world can be found in Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte (2018a)

63

These authors also show that OECD natural resource-rich countries such as Australia Belgium

and Chile show similar results in terms of mean efficiency scores with LGE studies being less

frequent in Latin American countries

Measuring efficiency of local governments as decision-making units (DMU) presents many

challenges and difficulties (Borger Kerstens Moesen amp Vanneste 1994 Ravallion 2005)

Worthington and Dollery (2000) mention problems with the selection and measurement of inputs

the identification of different stakeholders the hidden characteristic of the ldquolocal government

technologyrdquo and the multidimensionality of the services provided by local governments All these

issues make difficult to identify and distinguish between outputs and outcomes with outputs

commonly proxied by general indicators such as county area or county population Because

efficiency measures are highly sensitive to the chosen technique and the selection of inputs and

outputs Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte (2018a) suggest formulating different specifications and

using less general and unspecified indicators Moreover the complexity in defining outputs and

the use of general indicators make more likely that contextual factors affect municipal efficiency

322 Explaining differences in LGE

To explain differences in local government performance researchers have basically

distinguished between ldquodiscretionaryrdquo and ldquonon-discretionaryrdquo factors Discretionary factors refer

to the degree of discretion of local authorities in the selection and management of inputs and

outputs On the other hand scholars have investigated the influence on LGE of contextual factors

beyond authoritiesrsquo control These factors reflective at the environment where municipalities

operate include economic socio-demographic geographic financial political and institutional

characteristics (da Cruz amp Marques 2014 Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018b)

64

In general the evidence about the influence of contextual factors has delivered mixed and

country-specific results (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018b) Sampaio de Sousa et al (2005)

using data for Brazilian municipalities finds that population density and urbanization rate have

strong positive effects on efficiency scores Benito et al (2010) show that lower levels of

efficiency of Spanish municipalities are associated with a greater economic level a less stable

population and a bigger size of the local government Afonso (2008) finds that per capita income

level and education are not significant factors influencing LGE of Portuguese municipalities He

also finds that municipalities in Northern areas show greater efficiency than their counterparts in

Southern areas More recently Tsekeris (2018) finds that spatial variations in efficiency in Greece

can be attributed to factors related to inter-regional market access specialization and sectoral

concentration resource-factor endowments and political factors among others Characteristics

describing each local government have also been used including municipal indebtedness (Benito

et al 2010) fiscal deficits (Sinha 2017) degree of fiscal autonomy (Boetti Piacenza amp Turati

2009) and individual characteristics of local authorities such as age gender and political ideology

Narboacuten‐Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte (2018b) conclude after analysing 63 articles that studies on the

influence of contextual factors have mostly used cross-sectional data with little attention to

endogeneity issues which makes any causal interpretation doubtful

323 The trade-off between efficiency and equity

The existence of a potential trade-off between efficiency and equity is in the core of

economic discussion (Andersen amp Maibom 2020 Berg amp Ostry 2011 Browning amp Johnson

1984 Okun 2015)15 The argument that economic growth (one of the most common efficiency

15 Redistributive policies distort incentives and lead to suboptimal outcomes and thus efficiency losses

65

measures) could be negatively affected in the search for greater equality has been translated not

only into economic policies that favour economic growth over those that reduce inequality but

also in the emphasis of scholarly research Thus theoretical and empirical research has been

mainly focussed on efficiency and policy implications of a great diversity of shocks and policies

leaving the analysis of inequality as one of measurement and mostly descriptive Additionally

empirical evidence of the trade-off is scant and inconclusive (Andersen amp Maibom 2020

Browning amp Johnson 1984)

Among economic contextual factors that could affect LGE income inequality has been

largely ignored An exception is a cross-country comparison conducted by Ortega (2017) who

analyses the role of inequality on government efficiency in developing countries He finds that

more unequal countries could have higher difficulties to achieve specific health outcomes Income

inequality has even been considered as part of the outputs to measure efficiency particularly for

the case of European and OECD countries (Afonso Schuknecht amp Tanzi 2010 Antonelli amp De

Bonis 2018)

At the local level income inequality has been mainly used as a proxy for the effect of income

heterogeneity Economic inequality could have a direct and an indirect effect on government

efficiency The direct effect poses that higher income inequality could reduce municipal efficiency

because it is associated with a more complex and competing set of public services demanded by

the population (Jottier et al 2012) The indirect effect puts the focus in the link between inequality

social capital and levels of corruption Economic diversity could reduce trust in people and

institutions when related to high and persistent levels of income inequality It could also affect the

willingness to participate in community and political groups the existence of a shared objective

by citizens and the perception of a prosperous future (Uslaner amp Brown 2005)

66

The evidence is ambiguous For instance Geys and Moesen (2009) find that income

inequality has little relation to efficiency of Flemish municipalities and Ashworth et al (2014)

find a negative relationship for the Norwegian case Findings also indicate that inequality is the

strongest determinant of trust and that trust has a greater effect on communal participation than on

political participation (Uslaner amp Brown 2005)

33 Methodology

We follow a two-stage approach widely used in this kind of analysis A DEA analysis is

conducted in the first stage to get efficiency scores for each municipality Then regression analysis

is conducted in the second stage aiming to identify contextual variables other than differences in

the management of inputs that can help to explain the heterogeneity in municipal performance

331 Chilean Municipalities and period of analysis

The territory of Chile is divided into regions and these into provinces which for purposes of

the local administration are divided into counties The local administration of each county resides

in a municipality which is administrated by a Mayor assisted by a Municipal Council16

Municipalities represent the decentralization of the central power in Chile They are autonomous

organizations with legal personality and own patrimony whose purpose is to satisfy the needs of

the local community and ensure their participation in the economic social and cultural progress of

the county Municipalities have a diversity of functions related to public health education and

social assistance among others

16 The Mayor and City Council are elected by suffrage for the citizens of the respective commune every 4 years

67

To achieve their goals two are the main sources of municipal incomes own permanent

revenues (OPR) and the Municipal Common Fund (MCF) OPR are incomes generated by the

county and they are an indicator of the self-financing capacity of each municipality OPR are not

subject to restrictions regarding their investment and they are mainly generated by territorial taxes

commercial patents and circulation permits17 The MCF is a fund that aims to redistribute

community income to ensure compliance with the purpose of the municipalities and their proper

functioning Sources to finance the MCF come from municipal revenues The distribution

mechanism of the fund is regulated by parameters such as whether municipalities generate OPR

per capita lower than the national average and the number of poor people in the commune in

relation to the number of poor people in the country

This study covers the period from 2006 to 2017 During this period Chile was divided into

15 regions 54 provinces and 346 counties18 Although the information on inputs and outputs is

available for the entire period information on contextual factors at the county level such as

household income is only available every two-three years In addition some counties are excluded

from household surveys due to their difficult access Hence we use a sample of 324 municipalities

to measure municipal efficiency for the whole period (3888 observations) However the analysis

of contextual factors is conducted for those years when household income information is available

2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017 (1944 observations)

17 The territorial tax is a tax on agricultural and non-agricultural real estate Specifically of this income only 40 is left to the municipality as its own financing while the remaining 60 is allocated to the MCF (in the case of the four largest communes- Santiago Providencia Las Condes and Vitacura-percentages are 35 and 65 respectively) Unlike the territorial tax commercial patents are regulated mainly by the municipality which chooses the rate to be charged subject to a range established by law and is responsible of their collection Finally regarding the circulation permits 375 is of municipal benefit while 645 is directed to the MCF 18 There are 346 counties managed by 345 municipalities where counties ldquoCabo de Hornosrdquo and ldquoAntaacuterticardquo are managed by the municipality of ldquoCabo de Hornosrdquo

68

332 Measuring municipal efficiency

Municipal efficiency is measured using Data Envelopment Analysis (Coelli Prasada Rao

OrsquoDonnell amp Battese 2005) This is a non-parametric approach that uses linear programming to

measure efficiency for a group of municipalities as decision making units (DMUrsquos) The main

advantage of using DEA and the reason why DEA is used for the case of Chilean municipalities

is its flexibility in handling multiple inputs and outputs without the need to specify a functional

form (Balaguer-Coll amp Prior 2009 Mikušovaacute 2015 Tigga amp Mishra 2015) Following Afonso

and Fernandes (2008) the relationship between inputs and outputs for each municipality could be

represented by the following equation

119884 119891 119883 119894 1 119899 (31)

In equation (31) 119884 is the set of outputs and 119883 the set of inputs for each of the n

municipalities Using linear programming the production frontier is constructed and a vector of

efficiency scores is obtained The frontier represents full technical efficiency mdash the point at which

the highest output occurs given specified inputs or the point at which the lowest amount of inputs

is used to produce a specified quantity of output Efficiency scores under DEA are relative

measures of efficiency They measure a municipalityrsquos efficiency against the other measured

municipalities in the sample and not a hypothetical lsquoperfect municipalityrsquo The further from the

frontier the less technically efficient a municipality is

We use an input-oriented approach because Chilean municipalities have a greater control

over the management of inputs relative to the outputs they have to manage Obtaining efficiency

scores requires an assumption about the returns to scale exhibited by each municipality When

DMUrsquos are homogeneous the CCR model (Charnes Cooper amp Rhodes 1978) which assumes

69

constant return-to-scale (CRS) is the appropriate specification The CCR model assumes full

proportionality between outputs and inputs and that DMUrsquos operate at their optimal When DMUrsquos

are highly heterogeneous as is the case with local governments in most countries it is not realistic

to assume complete proportionality between inputs and outputs nor that all DMUrsquos operate at their

optimum scale In this situation a variable returns-to-scale (VRS) or BCC model (Banker

Charnes amp Cooper 1984) is the preferred formulation

Assuming VRS imposes minimum restrictions on the efficient frontier and allows for

comparisons only among municipalities of similar scale (Coelli et al 2005 Wu Huang amp Pan

2014) This means that when we use the CCR model (assuming CRS) on a heterogeneous sample

of DMUrsquos the resulting measure of technical efficiency that we obtain is related not only to the

management of inputs but also to issues of scale19 To empirically check the validity of the VRS

assumption we measure technical efficiency under CRS VRS and non-increasing returns-to-scale

(NIRS) and we analyse the existence of scale inefficiencies This allows us to check the relevance

of scale effects as a potential explanation of differences in municipal efficiency Appendix J

shows the specification of the DEA model under VRS and how ldquototal technical efficiencyrdquo

(assuming CRS and therefore due to management and scale issues) could be disaggregated in ldquopure

technical efficiencyrdquo (under VRS and related only to management issues) and scale efficiency (due

to scale issues)

19 Assuming VRS can also lead to measurement problems such as overestimation of efficiency scores This is the case when an important proportion of DMUrsquos shows CRS so assuming VRS ignores the information about proportionality between inputs and outputs (Podinovski 2004)

70

333 Inputs and outputs used in DEA

Following the literature on local government expenditure efficiency (Afonso amp Fernandes

2008 de Sousa et al 2005 Dlouhyacute 2018 Tandon 2005 Tigga amp Mishra 2015) and trying to

reflect as well as possible the functioning of municipalities five inputs and four outputs were

selected Input and output data were obtained from the National System of Municipal Information

(SINIM in its Spanish acronym) and they are expressed in thousands of Chilean pesos of 201720

Inputs are Municipal Operational Expenditure X1 (including expenses on goods and

services social assistance investment and transfers to community organizations) Municipal

Personnel Expenditure X2 (including full time and part-time workers) Total Municipal

Expenditure in Education sector X3 Total Municipal Expenditure in Health sector X4 and the

Number of Municipal Buildings X5 (proxied by the number of public facilities in education and

health sectors)

Output variables were selected highlighting the relevance of education and health sectors

and trying to capture the wide range of local services provided by municipalities The variable

ldquoOwn Permanent Revenuesrdquo Y1 is used to capture the scale and diversity of municipal

activities21 The ldquoMonthly Average Enrolmentrdquo in municipal education establishments related to

the school-age population in each county Y2 is used as educational output As health output the

ldquoNumber of Medical Consultationsrdquo in public facilities Y3 is considered Finally the number of

community organizations Y4 is used as output reflecting the promotion of community

development by each municipality Table 31 shows the summary statistics of input and output

20 The data from SINIM database was mostly obtained using the sinimr package (Salas 2019) 21 According to SINIM database this variable aims to measure the management of the municipalityrsquos own resources with respect to the population of the commune

71

variables for the whole sample and period Inputs and outputs excepting the Monthly Average

Enrolment Y2 are measured in per capita terms using county population information from the

National Institute of Statistics (INE in its Spanish acronym)

Table 31

Descriptive statistics Inputs and Output variables used in DEA analysis

334 Regression model

Contextual factors could play an important role not only in explaining why some

municipalities operate inefficiently but also why municipal performance differs among them

These factors may affect municipal performance modifying incentives for local authorities to

operate efficiently and their capability to take advantage of economies of scale They also define

the conditions for cooperation or competition among municipalities and the citizensacute ability and

willingness to monitor local authorities (Afonso amp Fernandes 2008)

Information on income at the household level for each county was obtained from the

ldquoNational Socioeconomic Characterization Surveyrdquo (CASEN in its Spanish acronym) CASEN is

conducted every two-three years being the reason why consecutive years are not considered in

72

our regression analysis The other contextual factors used as controls were obtained from different

sources including SINIM INE and the ldquoServicio de Impuestos Internosrdquo (SII)22

Our main hypothesis is whether higher levels of income inequality are associated with lower

levels of municipal efficiency To test our hypothesis the empirical model is defined as

120579 120573 119892119894119899119894 119885 120573 120575 120572 120598 (32)

Where 120579 is the vector of DEA efficiency scores 119892119894119899119894 is the Gini coefficient of each

county 120575 are year-specific effects 120572 are county-specific constants 120598 is a vector of error terms

and 119885 is a vector of controls Next we discuss the motivation for these controls

The level of purchasing power of countiesrsquo citizens is proxied by the variable log(income)

which is the natural log of the mean household income per capita in thousands of Chilean pesos of

2017 On the one hand poorer counties could display higher efficiency due to their necessity to

take care of their constraint resources (Pacheco et al 2013) On the other hand richer counties

could show higher efficiency because richer citizens exert higher monitoring over local authorities

and demand better quality public services in return for their tax payments (Afonso et al 2010)

The possibility for municipalities to take advantage of economies of scale and urbanization is

captured by three variables First the variable log(density) which correspond to the natural log of

population density Second the dummy variable reg_cap indicating whether a county is a regional

capital or not Third the variable agroland which correspond to the proportion of land for

agricultural use which is informed to the SII We expect a positive effect of log(density) but

negative for regcap and agroland

22 The SII is the institution in charge of collecting taxes in Chile

73

Socio-demographic characteristics are captured including a Dependence Index IDD IDD

corresponds to the number of people under 15 years or over 65 years per 100 people in the active

population (those people between 15 and 65 years old) A higher proportion of young and older

population could be associated with a higher demand for municipal services relating to education

and health making harder to offer public services efficiently The citizensrsquo capacity to monitor

local authorities is proxied including the variable education (average years of education for the

population older than 15 years) and the variable housing (proportion of households which are

owners of the property where they live in each county) In both cases we expect a positive

association with LGE

Among municipal characteristics the variable professional (percentage of municipal

personnel with a professional degree) is used to control for the quality of municipal services and

it is expected a positive impact The variable mcf (proportion of total municipal income coming

from the MCF) is included to capture the influence of financial dependence on the central

government A higher dependence from MCF could be associated with higher efficiency when it

is linked to more control from central government (Worthington amp Dollery 2000) However when

MCF discourages the generation of own resources and proper management of resources from the

fund a lower efficiency should be expected (Bravo 2014) In addition the dummy variable mayor

is included to capture differences among mayors supported by the ldquoLEFTrdquo or the ldquoRIGHTrdquo

political parties related to those ldquoINDEPENDENTrdquo mayors

Table 32 report summary statistics for the set of numeric contextual factors and Appendix

K the corresponding correlation matrix Despite the high correlation between income and

education variables we include both in the regression section as they capture different county

characteristics

74

Table 32

Summary Statistics Numeric Contextual Factors

Figure 31 Geographical distribution of Chilean regions and macrozones

Previous evidence on growth and convergence of Chilean regions have found that regions

tend to cluster spatially (Aroca amp Bosch 2000) Aiming to capture this regional clustering process

75

and considering the high concentration in the number of municipalities and population in the

central area we group municipalities in four ldquozonesrdquo We define as reference the ldquoCentre-Northrdquo

zone consisting of regions XIII (where the countryrsquos capital is located) and its two neighbouring

regions V and VI The ldquoNorthrdquo zone includes regions XV I II III and IV The ldquoCentre-Southrdquo

zone includes regions VII VIII and IX Finally the ldquoSouthrdquo zone embraces regions XIV X XI

and XII Figure 31 displays the regional administrative division and zones considered in this

essay

Efficiency scores (ES) are limited to have values between 0 and 1 However they are relative

measures (relative to the sample of municipalities) This implies that when a municipality is on the

frontier (ES = 1) it does not mean that potentially larger technical efficiency gains cannot be made

Hence equation 32 is estimated using OLS and censored regressions We start running cross-

sectional regressions for each of the six years Then we compare the results with those from panel

regressions Because fixed-effects panel Tobit models could be affected by the incidental

parameters problem (Henningsen 2010 2019) we use random-effects panel Tobit models

including indicator variables for years and zones Finally to deal with the potential endogeneity

problem we also use an instrumental variable approach The instrument is described next

335 The instrument

Government effectiveness and income distribution are both structural components of

economies (Ortega et al 2017 Ravallion 2005) In the search for a causal interpretation for the

influence of income inequality on municipal efficiency we need an instrument which must be

correlated with the variable to be instrumented (in our case income inequality) and uncorrelated

with the error term in the efficiency equation (32) Previous literature has used as instruments for

Gini the number of townships governments in a previous period the percentage of revenues from

76

intergovernmental transfers in a previous period and the current share of the labour force in the

manufacturing sector (Alesina amp La Ferrara 2002) Using the share of the labour force in a specific

sector is unlikely to reduce the problem of endogeneity particularly in countries where local

governments supply mostly ldquoservices to peoplerdquo and the main source of income inequality is

labour income

We propose as an instrument the proportion of firms in the primary sector (mining fishing

forestry and agriculture)

119901119904119904_119891119894119903119898119904Number of firms in the primary sector

Total number of firms (33)

On the one hand this instrument is likely to be correlated with local income inequality in

natural resource-rich countries23 On the other hand we contend that our instrument is less likely

to be correlated with the error term in the efficiency equation First the main services supplied by

Chilean municipalities are services to people (health and education) not to firms Second most of

the revenues collected by municipalities included those associated with natural resources end up

in the municipal common fund whose objective is precisely to reduce inequalities among

municipalities Third services to firms are expected to be more significant with the tertiary sector

We argue that our instrument captures natural and structural conditions which directly

influence income inequality but it does not directly affect LGE Figure 32 shows the evolution

of the annual average efficiency score and the proportion of firms in the primary secondary

(manufacturing) and tertiary (services) sectors We observe that sectors shares have remained

relatively stable with a slight reduction in the participation of the primary sector in favour of the

23 Results confirm a significant association between income inequality and the degree of dependence on natural resources at the county level

77

tertiary sector by the end of the period This is contrary to the evolution of municipal efficiency

which shows a cyclical behaviour as will be shown in the next section

Figure 32 Evolution of efficiency scores and the proportion of firms by sector

34 Results and discussion

341 DEA results

Figure 33 displays the evolution of our three measures of efficiency Overall technical

efficiency pure technical efficiency and scale efficiency are around 78 83 and 95

respectively with fluctuations over the years Therefore around three quarters of the overall

78

inefficiency is attributed to inefficiency in the management of inputs and around one quarter to

scale inefficiencies24

Figure 33 Evolution technical efficiency (TE) pure technical efficiency (PTE) and scale efficiency (SE)

Returnstoscale

Figure 34 reports by zone and for the whole period the proportion of municipalities

showing CRS decreasing returns to scale (DRS) or increasing returns to scale (IRS) Most of the

municipalities operate under variable (increasing or decreasing) returns to scale which could be

explained by the high heterogeneity in size among municipalities A summary of RTS

disaggregated by year and zone is in Appendix L Policies oriented to increase efficiency usually

24 The average scale efficiency score of 95 means that municipalities could get an additional 5 of inputs saving if municipalities were able to change their size to achieve their optimal scale

79

consider amalgamation de-amalgamation or ways of cooperation among municipalities To have

a better idea about where and how feasible is the implementation of such policies Appendix M

shows maps with the administrative division of the country in its 345 municipalities and which

municipalities show CRS IRS or DRS in each of the six years of data

Figure 34 Returns to scale by zone

Based on results for the whole period (Figure 34) the North has the highest proportion of

municipalities exhibiting DRS This suggests the need to reduce the size of municipalities splitting

those ldquotoo bigrdquo creating new administrative areas or giving more autonomy to current

municipalities25 The opposite occurs in the Centre-North area where municipalities mostly

exhibit IRS This indicates the need to merge municipalities An alternative strategy to the

amalgamation process is increasing inter-municipal cooperation (Balaguer-Coll et al 2019)

25 This has been the policy followed in Chile Although two new regions were created (XV in the North and XIV in the South) the number of municipalities has not changed

80

which seems to be a more plausible option in Chile Finally evidence on scale efficiency for the

Centre-South and South areas is not clear in terms of the adequate strategy to improve efficiency

Efficiencymeasure

Although most municipalities show scale inefficiencies (Figure 34) only a small proportion

of total inefficiency is associated to scale issues (Figure 33) Together this results justify not only

the use of the BCC model (efficiency scores under VRS) to capture municipal heterogeneity but

also highlights the need to look for other factors outside the control of local authorities which

could be influencing municipal performance

Table 33

Summary efficiency scores (VRS) by zone and region

Table 33 summarizes ES under VRS using data for the six years of CASEN survey A mean

efficiency score of 83 is found for the full sample and period This means that on average

inefficient municipalities can reduce the use of inputs by 17 to get the same current output By

81

comparing average ES per zone it can be concluded that municipalities in the North Centre-North

Centre-South and South could achieve the same level of output with 17 12 18 and 23 fewer

resources respectively Results also show that one third of the municipalities present an efficiency

score equal to one

Figure 35 shows the evolution of the mean ES for the four zones over the 12 years period

A clear drop in the efficiency level is observed in 2009 (the financial crisis year) excepting for the

North area Likewise although mean efficiency returned to its pre-crisis levels in 2014-2015 a

new drop in efficiency was experienced in 2016 It also seems that the 2010 earthquake did not

generate a significant effect on municipal efficiency Figure 35 also shows that although levels

of efficiency seem to differ among zones they follow a similar trend through time with the only

exception of the North which corresponds to the mining area In addition efficiency seems to be

significantly higher in the Centre-North area This is explained by the high mean level of efficiency

in region XIII which includes the countryrsquos capital city

Figure 35 Evolution mean efficiency scores (VRS) by zone

82

To know which and where are the efficient municipalities and if they are surrounded by

municipalities with a similar level of efficiency Appendix N has maps showing the ldquoefficiency

statusrdquo of each municipality that is whether they are efficient (ES = 1) or inefficient (ES lt 1)

Additionally Appendix O shows ldquoequal intervalsrdquo maps describing the spatial distribution of ES

among municipalities for each of the six years26 Results show that efficient municipalities can be

found all through the country the ldquoefficiency statusrdquo could change from one year to another and

municipalities with similar level-status of efficiency tend to cluster in space

342 Regression results

Exploratoryspatialanalysis

DEA efficiency scores and their geographical representations seem to show that municipal

efficiency presents a spatial clustering pattern This means that municipal performance could be

influenced not only by contextual factors of the county where municipality belongs but also by the

level of efficiency of neighbouring municipalities and their characteristics To test the significance

of the spatial dimension in municipal efficiency we use a cross-section of data considering the six-

year average of efficiency scores the Gini coefficient and the set of controls

We use the Moranrsquos I indicator to test for spatial autocorrelation Moranrsquos I is a measure of

the correlation between the level of efficiency in one municipality and its ldquospatial lagrdquo that is the

average level of efficiency in neighbouring municipalities We define as the relevant neighbours

for each municipality the 5-nearest municipalities This is obtained using the distances among the

26 An equal intervals map uses the same principle as a histogram to organize the observations into categories that divide the range of the variable into equal interval bins For the equal interval classification the value range between the lower and upper bound in each bin is constant across bins but the number of observations in each bin is typically not equal

83

polygonsrsquo centroids (latitude and longitude) of each county Results confirm that municipal

efficiency show a significant level of positive spatial autocorrelation This means that

municipalities tend to have neighbouring municipalities with similar performance

The positive spatial autocorrelation shown by municipal efficiency could be due to the

performance in one municipality is influenced by the performance in neighbouring municipalities

(spatial dependence in the variable itself) or due to structural differences among regions-zones

(spatial heterogeneity) To check the source of the spatial autocorrelation we run an OLS

regression of ES against income inequality and controls and then we test OLS residuals for spatial

autocorrelation Moranrsquos I over OLS residuals although significant is barely higher than zero (see

Appendix P) This means that the spatial effect itself is not a serious issue and can be handle for

instance including zone indicators variables hence we proceed to analyse the influence of income

inequality on LGE using non-spatial regression27

Cross‐sectionalanalysis

We start reporting censored regressions for each year in our panel Efficiency scores have

been rescaled to numbers between 0 and 100 to facilitate the interpretation of the results All

regressions include dummy variables for three of the four zones in which we have grouped Chilean

regions Results are in Table 3428 Income inequality shows a negative sign in all years which is

consistent with our hypothesis that inequality is negatively related to municipal efficiency

However only in three of the six years the effect of income inequality appears as statistically

27 In the case of having incorporated the spatial dimension the two most commonly used forms are including in the model the spatial lag of the dependent variable (spatial autoregressive model SAR) or the spatial lag of the error (spatial error model SEM) Following the method suggested by Anselin et al (1996) Lagrange Multiplier (LM) tests on the OLS residuals showed that the SAR model is preferred over the SEM Moranrsquos I LM tests and spatial regressions can be found in Appendix P 28 Regression results using OLS are in Appendix Q

84

significant Only the income level displays a significant and positive influence on efficiency for

the whole period A higher population density also consistently favours municipal efficiency On

the other hand as we expected a higher IDD makes it more difficult to achieve an efficient

performance29 Consistent with results in Pacheco et al (Pacheco et al 2013) municipal

efficiency show a significant an positive association with the MCF only in the first half of our

period of analysis with the second half showing an insignificant relationship

Table 34

Cross-sectional (censored) regressions

Paneldataanalysis

Estimation results for the six-year panel are reported in Table 35 Columns (1) and (2) show

the results for the pooled and random effects censored models only controlling for zone and year

29 The set of cross-sectional regressions was also run for each zone independently Results confirm that the set of significant contextual factors differs not only among years but also among geographic areas This support previous evidence suggesting that cross-sectional analysis should be treated with caution (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018b)

85

dummies Income inequality appears as non-significant Zone indicator variables confirm that

municipalities located in the Centre-South and South of the country display a lower average level

of efficiency compared to the Centre-North area Time dummies mostly show negative

coefficients This is a signal that shocks such as the GFC and the earthquake in 2010 may have

had a negative impact on efficiency but that impact was not permanent The results for the pooled

and RE models including the full set of controls are reported in columns (3) and (4) These results

show a significant negative influence of income inequality on LGE

When income inequality is instrumented by the variable pss_firms most of the coefficients

remain unchanged except for those associated with the income variables gini and log(income)

This result implies that our original model suffers for instance from the omitted variable bias

This means that LGE and income inequality are determined simultaneously by some variable not

included in our model Columns (5) and (6) show results using our instrument for income

inequality The ldquotrue coefficientrdquo of variable gini remains negative but the magnitude of the

relationship is higher The negative coefficient for gini implies on the one hand that municipalities

located in more unequal counties face more challenges to achieve an efficient management of

public resources On the other hand the coefficient in column (6) is close to one The interpretation

is that for each point of reduction in income inequality ceteris paribus LGE should increase in the

same proportion Next we discuss some of the results associated with the controls variables

Contrary to Pacheco et al (2013) income level has a positive coefficient meaning that richer

counties in terms of income per capita show higher efficiency This could be explained by higher

monitoring and increasing demands from citizen and taxpayers In addition it is expected a higher

efficiency in municipalities located in counties with a higher population density and those with a

lower proportion of land for agricultural use This result is mainly explained by municipalities

86

located in the Centre area The opposite happens with municipalities in the South implying that

they are too ldquosmallrdquo to take advantage of agglomeration economies There is also a limit for

agglomeration and scale economies which is shown by the negative coefficient of the variable

regcap although this coefficient loses its significance in the IV approaches30

Unexpectedly efficiency was found to be negatively associated with the variable education

This result is similar to the case of Czech municipalities (Šťastnaacute amp Gregor 2014) where

explanations include a weakened monitoring effect due to the fact that more educated citizens

present greater mobility and labour cost disadvantages for municipalities with better educated

labour force In Chile an additional explanation could be the relationship between education and

voter turnout Since 2012 voting is no longer mandatory in Chile This fact considerably reduced

voter turnout which in turn may have influenced the monitoring and control effect of more

educated voters For the case of variable IDD results show that local authorities in counties with

higher proportion of aging and young population (related to those in the active population) face a

greater challenge in their quest to offer public services efficiently

The influence of mcf is like that found by Pacheco et al (2013) with municipalities more

dependent on central transfers showing more efficiency31 Political influence captured by the

variable mayor did not show a significant effect This result is like other studies concluding that

the ideological position did not have a significant influence on efficiency (Benito et al 2010

Boetti et al 2009 Cordero Pedraja-Chaparro Pisaflores amp Polo 2017)

30 This negative coefficient suggests that the negative effects of agglomeration economies such as overcrowding pollution high cost of land and traffic congestion could predominate over the positive effects of scale economies in regional capitals 31 When the analysis is conducted for each zone independently MCF displays a negative influence in the North and Centre-North areas but a positive influence in the Centre-South and South areas These results confirm that on the one hand richer municipalities (those in the North and Centre-North) have less incentives for efficient management of their resources On the other hand results support the relevance of MCF helping poorer municipalities (those in the South) to reach their outcomes

87

Table 35

Panel data regressions

88

35 Conclusions

The trade-off between equity and efficiency is in the core of the economic discussion This

ldquoprinciplerdquo has been used by policymakers to prioritize the design of policies focused on economic

growth delaying those policies aimed at reducing economic inequalities This essay offers

empirical evidence of a negative relationship between inequality and efficiency that is a reduction

of income inequality could have positive effects on economic efficiency at least at the level of

local governments

We followed a traditional Two-Stage approach commonly used in the analysis of LGE We

compared cross-sectional and panel data results and we have added an instrumental variable

approach to give a causal interpretation to the link between efficiency and inequality We proposed

the use of a measure of natural resource dependence to instrumentalize the impact of income

inequality on LGE Given that our units of analysis are municipalities and not counties we argue

that our measure of NRD is correlated with income inequality and it does not have a direct

influence on LGE

We found that Chilean municipalities perform better than previous studies suggest

Municipal efficiency depicted significant levels of positive spatial autocorrelation and most of the

municipalities showed to be operating under increasing or decreasing returns to scale This would

imply that the policies generally used to improve efficiency such as amalgamation or cooperation

should be implemented observing the reality of each region and not as strategies at the national

level We also found that scale inefficiency explains a small proportion of the average total

inefficiency reason why the analysis of external factors that could affect the municipal efficiency

takes greater relevance

89

Income inequality plays an important part in explaining municipal efficiency In fact it was

found that reductions in income inequality could result in increases in municipal efficiency in a

similar proportion An unexpected finding was that the levels of education shows a negative

association with municipal performance This could be due to a low average level of education or

the existence of an omitted variable This variable could be the significant reduction in voting

turnout rates for local and national elections due to changes in the voting system during the period

of our analysis All in all our results may help to shed light on the potential consequences of

changes in contextual factors and the design of strategies aimed to increase municipal efficiency

in countries with similar characteristics to the Chilean economy For instance policies oriented to

take advantage of economies of scale can be formulated merging municipalities or establishing

networks in specific sectors such as education or health

Further work needs to be done both in measurement and in the explanation of differences in

municipal performance in Chile One area of future work will be to identify the factors that better

predict why municipalities operates under increasing decreasing or constant returns to scale

Multinomial logistic regression and the application of machine learning algorithms to SINIM data

sets appear as suitable methods for that purpose Intertemporal DEA (Drew amp Dollery 2015)

should be used to measure municipal efficiency capturing changes in total factor productivity In

addition municipalities operate under different levels of geographical authorities such as the

provincial mayor and the regional governor Hence it would be useful to know how each

municipality performs within each region-zone related to how performs to the whole country This

should be done conducting a metafrontier analysis (OrsquoDonnell Rao amp Battese 2008)

We have also identified through a cross sectional spatial exploratory analysis that on

average municipalities with similar levels of efficiency tend to cluster in space Regarding to

90

analyse the importance of contextual factors on municipal efficiency a deeper analysis should use

censored spatial models to check the significance of the spatial dimension in cross-sectional and

panel contexts Another interesting avenue for future research is associated with the negative

association found between LGE and education The significant reduction in votersacute turnout since

the law of automatic registration and voluntary voting in 2011 appears as a natural experiment to

analyse its effects on efficiency indicators such as municipal performance Incorporating variables

such as the voting turnout in each county or classifying municipalities based on individual

institutional political and economic characteristics could help to shed light on which of these

channels is the most relevant when analysing the impact of inequality on municipal efficiency

Finally we argued that an important part of the influence of income inequality over LGE

could be through its indirect effect on trust social capital and social cohesion The final essay will

delve deep in that relationship

91

Chapter 4 Social Cohesion Incivilities and Diversity

Evidence at the municipal level in Chile

41 Introduction

A deterioration in social cohesion could carry significant costs such as a reduction in

generalized trust between individuals and in institutions a society caught in a vicious circle of

inequality and citizens increasingly distanced from civic life (Uslaner 2011) A growing feeling

of frustration and discontentment can eventually translate into a social outbreak with uncertain

results This is precisely what have been happening in many countries around the world included

Chile

ldquoSocial cohesion is a state of affairs concerning both the vertical and the horizontal

interactions among members of society as characterized by a set of attitudes and norms that

includes trust a sense of belonging and the willingness to participate and help as well as their

behavioural manifestationsrdquo (Chan et al 2006) This definition highlights the multidimensionality

in the concept of social cohesion which has been measured using objective andor subjective

indicators of trust social norms solidarity willingness to participate in social and political groups

and feelings of belonging (Ariely 2014 Chan et al 2006) Multidimensionality also implies that

the impact of determinants of social cohesion such as economic and racial diversity could be

different for each of its various dimensions (Ariely 2014)

A common characteristic to all societies is that they are made up of different groups that

differ with respect to race ethnicity income religion language local identity etc The

92

Community Heterogeneity Thesis (Coffeacute amp Geys 2006) argues that individuals prefer to interact

with others that are like themselves Hence high levels of diversity particularly economic and

racial represent a complex scenario to maintain social cohesion One of the most common factors

adduced for social cohesion is income inequality with higher levels linked to lower levels of trust

(Ariely 2014 Rothstein amp Uslaner 2005)

Traditional measures of social cohesion may not be adequately capturing the deterioration

in social connections For instance measures of (lack of) trust include a strong subjective element

On the other hand proxies for social participation such as volunteering jobs or joining to social

organizations have not been supported by empirical evidence as a source of generalized social trust

(Rothstein amp Uslaner 2005) We proposed to use the rate of incivilities which we argue is a more

appropriate measure of the degree of worsening in the social context

Incivilities are those visible disorders in the public space that violate respectful social norms

and tend not to be treated as crimes by the criminal justice system There are two types of

incivilities social and physical Social incivilities include antisocial behaviours such as public

drinking noisy neighbours and fighting in public places Physical incivilities include among

others vandalism graffiti abandoned cars and garbage on the streets Because citizens and

political authorities cannot always distinguish between incivilities and crime they are usually

treated as an additional category of crime This implies that policies aimed to reduce incivilities

are generally based on punitive actions However theory and evidence on incivilities suggest that

factors explaining incivilities and crime could be different (Lewis 2017 Taylor 1999)

In Chile crime rates have shown a sustained downward trend after reaching its highest level

in 2011 On the other hand incivilities rate has shown a sustained upward trend which coincides

with the increasing victimization and feeling of insecurity in the population This has motivated

93

Chilean authorities based on the ldquoBroken Windows Theoryrdquo to propose new punitive actions (or

increase the severity of the current ones) to those who commit this type of antisocial behaviours

The ldquoBroken Windows Theoryrdquo states that higher rates of incivilities are a signal of social

disorganization which result in higher crime rates (J Q Wilson amp Kelling 1982) This is expected

to have consequences on familiesrsquo decisions such as moving away from public spaces or even

leaving their neighbourhoods

As far as we know there is no previous evidence about the potential causes of incivilities in

Chile Efforts to identify the factors explaining incivilities could help not only to reduce the risk

factors favouring violent and property crimes but also to guide interventions aimed to change

social behaviours and strengthen social cohesion in highly unequal societies Thus the main

contribution of the present study is to provide a deeper comprehension of the problem of incivilities

and how they can help to better understand the weakening of social cohesion that many

contemporary societies experience

We aim to offer the first evidence on the factors explaining the evolution and the differences

in incivilities rates in Chile We set up a panel for six years (2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and

2017) and 324 counties (1944 observations) We start exploring the evolution and geographical

distribution of incivilities Then we investigate whether economic and racial diversity after

controlling for other socioeconomic demographic and municipal characteristics can be regarded

as key predictors of incivilities

We use the Gini coefficient to proxy economic heterogeneity and the number of new visas

granted to foreigners as proportion of the county population as proxy for racial diversity The main

hypothesis is whether economic and racial diversity have a positive association with the rate of

incivilities In addition to the arguments regarding the ldquoCommunity Heterogeneity Thesisrdquo Taylor

94

(1999) and Skogan (1986 1999 2015) argue that incivilities are caused by inequality and the lack

of informal mechanisms of social control Based on the ldquoIncivilities Thesisrdquo the patterns of

incivilities should mirror the patterns of inequality (Taylor 1999) Then higher inequality should

be associated with higher physical and social vulnerability of the population This reduces social

control and increases social disorganization which triggers antisocial or negligent behaviours

Our main result reveals a strong positive association between the rate of incivilities and the

number of new visas granted per year The relationship with income inequality although also

positive seems to be less significant These findings give strong support to the ldquoCommunity

Heterogeneity Thesisrdquo and to a lesser extent to the ldquoIncivilities Thesisrdquo When the analysis is

disaggregated geographically racial diversity shows a clear positive effect The impact of income

inequality seems to be conditional depending on the level of income showing no effect in poorer

regions Results also show that the impact of economic and racial diversity differs by type of

incivility For example income inequality shows a strong association with ldquoStreet Tradingrdquo while

racial diversity with ldquoAlcohol Consumptionrdquo Two are the main policy implications On the one

hand a national strategy to address the problems associated with foreign immigration could help

to reduce incivilities For instance a joint effort between national and local authorities to curb

immigration and its distribution throughout the country On the other hand our results show that

the relationship between incivilities and economic diversity differs depending on the region or

geographical area Hence the impact on social cohesion of policies aimed to tackle economic

inequalities should be analysed in each specific context

The rate of incivilities also shows a negative association with the level of municipal financial

autonomy This implies that municipalities can effectively carry out policies to reduce incivilities

beyond the efforts of the central government Another important finding is that our results do not

95

support the hypothesis that a higher proportion of the young population is associated with higher

rates of incivilities Hence policies aimed to reduce incivilities should be focused on the causes of

incivilities rather than the criminalization of behaviours or stigmatization of specific population

groups

The structure of the chapter is as follows Section 42 outlines the relevant literature on social

cohesion and incivilities Section 43 describes the data variables and methodology and

establishes the hypotheses of the study Section 44 contains the results and discussions Section

45 presents the main conclusions

42 Related Literature

421 The Community Heterogeneity Thesis

The idea under ldquoThe Community Heterogeneity Thesisrdquo is that if individuals prefer to

interact with others who are similar to themselves in terms of income race or ethnicity high levels

of income inequality and racial diversity facilitate a context for lower tolerance and antisocial

behaviours lowering the ldquostaterdquo of social cohesion (Alesina 2000 Coffeacute amp Geys 2006 Letki

2008) Alessina and Ferrara (2002) give support to this hypothesis arguing that individuals have a

natural aversion to heterogeneity However the most popular explanation is the principle of

homophily people prefer to interact with others who share the same ethnic heritage have the same

social status and hence share experiences and tastes (Letki 2008 McPherson Smith-Lovin amp

Cook 2001 Tolsma et al 2009) For instance Delhey and Newton (2005) find for a sample of

60 countries that income inequality and ethnicity are strongly and negatively correlated with trust

Tolsma et al (2009) using data for Dutch neighbourhoods and municipalities find that social

cohesion is negatively and consistently affected by economic deprivation but not by ethnic

96

heterogeneity These authors also conclude that the effect of neighbourhood and municipal

characteristics on social cohesion depends on residentsrsquo income and educational level

Rothstein and Uslaner (2005) give two theoretical reasons why economic and racial diversity

should be causally related to social trust a key element of social cohesion First optimism about

the future makes less sense when there is more economic inequality which generally translates into

inequality of opportunities especially in areas such as education and the labour market Second

the distribution of resources and opportunities plays a key role in establishing the belief that people

share a common destiny and have similar fundamental values In highly unequal societies people

are likely to stick with their own kind Perceptions of injustice will reinforce negative stereotypes

of other groups making social trust and accommodation more difficult

Uslaner (2002 2011) and Uslaner and Brown (2005) find that high levels of inequality are

the single major factor driving down trust in people who are different from yourself Evidence for

USA finds that inequality is the strongest determinant of generalized trust over time (Rothstein amp

Uslaner 2005) Reducing inequality and then increasing generalized trust should have positive

consequences at the individual and aggregates levels At the individual level it may lead to greater

tolerance and more acts of altruism for people of different backgrounds At the aggregate level it

may lead to greater economic growth more redistribution from the rich to the poor and less

corruption (Uslaner 2002 2013) Letki (2008) argues that when neighbourhood socio-economic

context (apart from just an individualrsquos socioeconomic status) is considered it turns out to be the

main factor triggering negative attitudes and lack of trust in out-group members

The increasing diversity caused by immigration can also reduce the conditions necessary for

social cohesion (Ariely 2014 Holtug amp Mason 2010) Christel Kesler and Irene Bloemraad

(2010) find for nineteen advanced democracies between 1981 and 2000 that increasing migration

97

generally decreases trust civic engagement and political participation The authors also find that

in more equal countries with clear policies in favour of cultural minorities the negative effects of

migration are mitigated or even reversed Letki (2008) states that deprivation and disorder tend to

be strongly correlated with racial diversity Because we propose the use of the number of disorders

or antisocial behaviours known as ldquoincivilitiesrdquo as our measure of social cohesion we describe the

literature on incivilities in the next section

422 The literature on incivilities

The study of incivilities has been a continuing concern mainly for developed countries since

the 1980s The focus has changed from individual and psychological explanations to ecological

(contextual) and social explanations (Taylor 1999) The individual approach basically considered

perceptions of incivilities as an explanatory variable of fear of crime The ecological explanation

argues that indicators of economic disadvantage (eg income levels income inequality

unemployment rate and poverty rate) are the keys to understand a process of social disorganization

and lack of informal control These economic factors lead to higher rates of inappropriate or

negligent behaviours and ultimately to higher crime rates (Blau amp Blau 1982 Messner Rosenfeld

amp Baumer 2004 Phan Orsquobrien Mendolia amp Paloyo 2017 Sampson 1986)

The negative impact of incivilities is not merely reflected in its association with crime rates

(Skogan 2015) Physical and social incivilities could worsen neighbourhoods by affecting quality

of life perception of the environment and public and private behaviours Previous research has

indicated that a higher level of incivilities is associated with health problems (Branas et al 2011

Cohen et al 2000 Hill amp Angel 2005 Ross 2011 Ross amp Mirowsky 2001) greater

victimization and fear of crime (Brunton-Smith Jackson amp Sutherland 2014 Mijanovich amp

Weitzman 2003) and multiple negative economic effects For instance incivilities could be

98

related to a reduction in commercial activity lower investment in real estate reduction in house

prices (Skogan 2015) and population instability (Hipp 2010)

To describe the state of the art in the study of incivilities and their consequences Skogan

(2015) used the concept of untidiness to characterize the research on incivilities The study of

incivilities has had multiple approaches (economic ecological and psychological) Incivilities

have also been measured using multiple sources of information (police reports surveys trained

observation) which result in different measures (perceptions vs count data) However the question

about what specific factors have the strongest effect on incivilities has been overlooked and

perceptions about incivilities have been used mainly as a predictor of crime fear of crime and

victimization

There are two types of incivilities social and physical Social incivilities are a matter of

behaviour including groups of rowdy teens public drunkenness people fighting and street hassles

Physical incivilities involve visual signs of negligence and decay such as abandoned buildings

broken streetlights trash-filled lots and graffiti (Skogan 1999 2015 Taylor 1999) Three reasons

justify the distinction between physical and social incivilities First like multiple dimensions of

social cohesion different structural and social conditions could be responsible for different types

and categories of incivilities Second punitive sanctions are expected to have a greater impact on

physical than on social incivilities since the latter are more related to behaviours rooted in citizensrsquo

culture Third physical incivilities should be more related to absolute measures of economic

disadvantage (eg poverty or unemployment rates) and social incivilities to relative indicators of

economic disadvantage (eg such as income inequality) This line of research is based on the

ldquoincivilities thesisrdquo which states that to understand the distribution of disorders it is necesary to

analyse the patterns of structured inequalities (Skogan 1986 Taylor 1999)

99

423 The ldquoIncivilities Thesisrdquo

Incivilities theories began with a focus on psychological dynamics (Garofalo 1978) moved

forward to an interest in social psychological processes (J Q Wilson amp Kelling 1982) and finally

evolved into a focus on community dynamics and outcomes (Skogan 1999) Individual and group

behaviours in tandem with ecological features have been proposed as the key factors explaining

incivilities and their posterior influence on social control quality of life and more serious crime

(J Q Wilson amp Kelling 1982)

In terms of ecological factors particularly those related to economic conditions Skogan

(1986) was the first linking the distribution of incivilities to the patterns of structural inequality If

incivilities mirror inequality structure this will have consequences in residentsrsquo health and safety

due to its levels of vulnerability In addition structured inequality associated with the proportion

of the manufacturing sector (eg when fabrics tend to move from cities to farther areas) will be

related to higher social disorganization and differences between urban and rural areas (W J

Wilson 1996) In addition a persistent feeling of relative deprivation (persistently high levels of

income inequality) could lead to fellow inhabitants of the community to commit antisocial

behaviours showing their frustration with the current economic model

The literature on incivilities posits that their causes are different from those of crime (Lewis

2017) Unlike crime analysis especially property crimes information on the location where the

incivility takes place is the same as the location where the perpetrator resides To achieve a

comprehensive understanding of the different types of incivilities it is crucial to consider

incivilities data covering an entire territory and not just specific areas (Hooghe Vanhoutte

Hardyns amp Bircan 2010) If we add to this the availability of panel data it could be possible not

100

only to identify the main determinants of incivilities but also the causal mechanism from income

inequality towards incivilities rate

In Chile citizen security crime and delinquency are among the most significant issues for

citizens based on opinion polls Existing research has found weak evidence of a significant

relationship between crime and indicators of socio-economic disadvantage such as income

inequality and unemployment rate with significant effects only on property crime (Beyer amp

Vergara 2006 Nuntildeez Rivera Villavicencio amp Molina 2003 Rivera Gutieacuterrez amp Nuacutentildeez 2009)

Crime deterrence variables such as the probability of being caught or the number of police

resources have also shown ambiguous results (Beyer amp Vergara 2006 Rivera et al 2009

Vergara 2012) Evidence at the county level shows that crime is higher in urban counties those

with a lower mean income per capita and counties located in the North of the country In addition

at least half of the crimes reported in one county are perpetrated by criminals from other counties

(Rivera et al 2009) No studies could be found about the determinants of incivilities

4 3 Methodology

431 Period of analysis and data sample

Chile is a relatively small country in Latin America with a population of 18346018

inhabitants in 2017 The country is divided into 345 municipalities with on average 53104

inhabitants (median value 18705) Municipalities are the organ of the State Administration

responsible to solve local needs Municipalities are not only the relevant political and

administrative local unit of analysis but also they represent the feeling of lsquocommunityrsquo among

the inhabitants of each municipality (Hooghe et al 2010) Our data includes many sources of

101

heterogeneity among municipalities such as indicators of economic deprivation population

density demographic characteristics and whether the county is a regional or provincial capital

We use a sample of 324 municipalities covering most of the Chilean territory for the period

2006ndash17 Data on incivilities is obtained from the ldquoCentre of Studies and Analysis of Crimerdquo

which is part of the ldquoSubsecretaria de Prevencion del Delitordquo (SPD in its Spanish acronym) of the

Chilean government32 Information on income inequality and control variables is obtained from

the ldquoNational Socioeconomic Characterization Surveyrdquo (CASEN in its Spanish acronym) the

ldquoNational Institute of Statisticsrdquo (INE in its Spanish acronym) the ldquoNational Municipal

Information Systemrdquo (SINIM in its Spanish acronym) and the Immigration Department of the

Government of Chile Our panel only includes the years for which CASEN survey is available

2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017

432 Operationalisation of the response variable and exploratory analysis

Official Chilean records contain information for the total number of cases of incivilities per

year at the county level The number of cases is the sum of complains and detentions reported at

the police Our dependent variable 119894119899119888119894119907119894119897119894119905119894119890119904 correspond to the number of cases per year Due

to population differences comparisons between counties are made using the incivilities rate per

1000 population calculated as

119894119899119888119894119907_119903119886119905119890 lowast 1000 (41)

where 119894119899119888119894119907_119903119886119905119890 is the incivilities rate 119905 is the year 119894 the county and 119899 is the population of the

county per year

32 httpceadspdgovclestadisticas-delictuales

102

Figure 41 illustrates at the top the evolution of the total number (cases reported) of

incivilities and crimes at the country level for the period 2006-1733 At the bottom Figure 41

shows the evolution of the mean county rate per 1000 inhabitants We observe that both the number

of incivilities and the number of crimes has reached similar annual figures however average

county rates per 1000 population show different trends Crime rate displays a sustained fall after

reaching its pick in 2011 Incivilities average county rate which also reached a pick and posterior

drop in 2011 has recovered its upward trend since 2016 considerably exceeding the crime rate

Figure 41 Evolution number and rates of incivilities and crime (DMCS) in Chile 2006-2017

33 Crime refers to ldquocrimes of greater social connotationrdquo (DMCS in its Spanish acronym) which includes violent and property crimes

103

Chilean records classify incivilities in nine categories most of them associated with social

incivilities Summary statistics for the total and for each of the nine categories are presented in

Table 41 In addition Figure 42 shows the evolution of incivilities by category for the whole

period We see that the global trend in incivilities is mainly due to a substantial increase in ldquoStreet

Tradingrdquo and ldquoPublic Alcohol Consumptionrdquo A common element of Figures 41 and 42 is the

significant change in trend experienced by crimes and incivilities in 2011 That year the SPD

became dependent on the Ministry of Interior of the Chilean Government This event put the issue

of crime and delinquency within national priorities for the central government

Table 41

Summary statistics total count of incivilities and by category (full sample and period)

Unlike crime rates we do not expect significant cross-county spillover effects in incivilities

However the questions of where incivilities are concentrated and why they are there can be of

great interest (Skogan 2015) Figure 43 shows quantile maps for the rate of incivilities per 1000

inhabitants for the initial and final years in our panel

104

Figure 42 Evolution total number of incivilities by category

Figure 43 Spatial distribution of incivilities rate per 1000 inhabitants (2006 vs 2017)

105

We observe that the range of values has increased significantly from 2006 to 2017 but the

spatial distribution remains almost unchanged On the one hand high incivilities rates in the North

could be associated with the mining activity On the other hand high rates in the Centre area

(where the countyrsquos capital is located) could be related to the higher population density and the

concentration of the economic activity34

To see how the different types of incivilities are distributed throughout the country we have

grouped those similar categories in four groups ldquoPublic Damagerdquo (ldquoPublic Disturbsrdquo ldquoPublic

Damagerdquo ldquoOtherrdquo) ldquoThreatsrdquo (ldquoPublic Fightrdquo ldquoThreatsrdquo and ldquoAnnoying Noisesrdquo) ldquoAlcohol

Consumptionrdquo (ldquoPublic Alcohol Consumptionrdquo and ldquoDrunkennessrdquo) and ldquoStreet Tradingrdquo This

distinction in groups could be relevant if we expect different patterns and different effects of

community heterogeneity on social cohesion among counties For instance we expect higher

levels of Public Damage in big urban cities Street trading is more likely in urban cities but also in

tourist areas The spatial distribution of these four groups for the six-year-average rate per 1000

inhabitants can be found in Appendix R

433 Measures of community heterogeneity and control variables

Social cohesion income inequality and racial diversity are all ldquocommunityrdquo (not individual)

characteristics Thus to understand their relationship we need aggregated data at least at the

county-municipal level With more disaggregated data like at the suburbs level the required

heterogeneity among groups of citizens is lost (Wilkinson 1999) Like Coffeacute and Geys (2006) we

use the Gini coefficient to capture economic heterogeneity However instead of a measured for

34 We also analysed the spatial distribution of crime rates In general areas with high levels of incivilities not necessarily are associated with high levels of crime This could imply that factors explaining incivilities and crime are different

106

the diversity of nationalities we use the proportion of foreign population to capture racial

heterogeneity Income data is obtained from the CASEN survey The Gini coefficient is calculated

for each county and included through the variable gini Racial heterogeneity is included through

the variable foreign which is the annual number of new VISAS granted to foreigners as a

proportion of the county population Chile has experienced a significant increase in immigration

since 2011 Immigration has been concentrated in the metropolitan region and mining regions in

the North of the country We expect a positive relationship between immigration and incivilities

although as with the relationship between immigration and crime the foundations for this

hypothesis are not strong (Hooghe et al 2010 Sampson 2008)

Economic development is another explanation for social cohesion frequently appealed to

explain trust with wealthier societies considered to exhibit higher levels of trust (Delhey amp

Newton 2005) In this study we include the natural log of the mean household income per capita

log(income) We also include the poverty rate poverty and the unemployment rate

unemployment Unlike the variable log(income) these variables are expected to be positively

associated with the number of incivilities When a relative indicator of economic heterogeneity

such as income inequality is included as determinant of social cohesion we should expect less

effect from absolute indicators of economic disadvantage such as poverty and unemployment rates

(Hooghe et al 2010 Tolsma et al 2009)

Among demographic variables the percentage of inhabitants between 10 and 24 years old is

included through the variable youth The variable women defined as the proportion of the female

population in each county is also included Variable youth is expected to have an ambiguous effect

Although young people have lower victimization and report rates they also represent the group

more likely to commit antisocial behaviours when a community has a low capacity of self-

107

regulation (eg when there is low parental supervision) The female population is associated with

a higher report of incivilities related to the male population

It is argued that crime and incivilities are essentially urban problems (Christiansen 1960

Wirth 1938) We include the variable log(density) defined as the log of population density (the

number of inhabitants divided by the area of each county in square kilometres) and a dummy

variable capital indicating whether a county is an administrative capital (provincial or regional)

Two additional variables are included to capture the level of informal social control exerted

by families living in each municipality First the variable education which is defined as the

average years of education of people over 15 years old Second the variable housing which capture

the proportion of families which are owners of their housing unit Although education and housing

are related to both the possibility of reporting and committing an incivility we expect a negative

association with the rate of incivilities

In Chile crime has been mainly a problem faced by the police and the Central Government

Administration To control for current law enforcement policies we include the variable

deterrence defined as the number of arrests as a proportion of the total number of incivilities cases

In addition municipalities can develop their own initiatives to deal with crime and incivilities

depending on their capacity to generate its own resources The level of financial autonomy from

central transfers is captured by the variable autonomy This variable is obtained from SINIM and

it is defined as the proportion of the budget revenue of each municipality that comes from its own

permanent sources of revenues A categorical variable mayor is also included This variable

indicates whether the municipality mayor is supported by the ldquoLEFTrdquo or the ldquoRIGHTrdquo political

parties (related to those ldquoINDEPENDENTrdquo mayors)

108

Table 42 presents descriptive statistics for our measures of income and racial heterogeneity

and the set of numeric control variables The Pearson correlation among these variables is shown

in Appendix S

Table 42

Summary statistics numeric explanatory variables

434 Methods

The annual count of incivilities as is characteristic for count data is highly concentrated in

a relatively small range of values In addition the distribution is right-skewed due to the presence

of important outliers (counties with a high number of incivilities) Figure 44 shows the

distribution of the six-year average number of incivilities for each of the 15 regions in Chile35 We

observe that regions differ in the number of counties in which they are divided In addition

counties within each region show important differences in the number of incivilities For instance

35 Regions are ordered from left to right and from top to bottom in the way they are geographically distributed from North to South So the northernmost region of the country is the ldquoXVrdquo and the southernmost region is the ldquoXIIrdquo The Metropolitan region (where the countryrsquos capital is located) is region ldquoXIIIrdquo in the centre of the country (see Appendix C)

109

excepting the Metropolitan region ldquoXIIIrdquo most counties in regions located in the centre of the

country (middle row in Figure 44) show a range of incivilities between 0 and 2000 The number

of incivilities is considerably lower in counties located in the northern (top row in Figure 44) and

southern (bottom row in Figure 44) regions of the country compared to regions in the centre of

the country It also seems clear from Figure 44 that the number of incivilities does not follow a

normal distribution

Figure 44 Annual average number of incivilities per county

The number of incivilities can be better described by a Poisson distribution In this case the

number of incivilities is ldquothe countrdquo and the number of incivilities per year is ldquothe rate per unit

timerdquo We are interested in modelling the average number of incivilities per year usually called 120582

as a function of a set of contextual factors to explain differences in incivilities between and within

110

counties The main characteristic of the Poisson distribution is that the mean is equal to the

variance This implies that as the mean rate for a Poisson variable increases the variance also

increases The main implication is we cannot use OLS to model 120582 as a function of the set of

contextual factors because the equal variance assumption in linear regression is violated

The rate of incivilities between counties is not directly comparable due to population

differences We expect counties with more people to have more reports of incivilities since there

are more people who could be affected To capture differences in population which is called the

exposure of our response variable 120582 it is necessary to include a term on the right side of our model

called an offset We will use the log of the county population in thousands as our offset36

Additionally similar to the case of crime data incivilities show a significant degree of

overdispersion (variance higher than the mean) suggesting that there is more variation in the

response than the Poisson model implies37 We also model and regress incivilities assuming a

Negative Binomial distribution to address overdispersion An advantage of this approach is that it

introduces a dispersion parameter in addition to 120582 which gives the model more flexibility38

Considering as the response variable the count of incivilities per year the model can be

expressed as follow

120582 119890119909119901 120573 120573 119892119894119899119894 120573 119891119900119903119890119894119892119899 119883120574 120572 120579 (42)

36 If we think of 120582 as the average number of incivilities per year then represents the number per 1000

inhabitants so that the yearly count is adjusted to be comparable across counties of different sizes Adjusting the yearly count by population is equivalent to adding 119897119900119892 1199011199001199011199061198971198861199051198941199001198991000 to the right-hand side of the regression equation 37 Without adjusting for overdispersion we use incorrect artificially small standard errors leading to artificially small p-values for model coefficients 38 The Negative Binomial model posits selecting a 120582 (average number of incivilities) for each county and then generating a count using a Poisson random variable with the selected 120582 With this approach the counts will be more dispersed than would be expected for observations based on a single Poisson variable with rate 120582

111

where 120582 is the rate of incivilities 119883 is our vector of controls 120572prime119904 are county-specific constants

and 120579prime119904 are time-specific constants Accounting for differences in county population we have

119890119909119901 120573 120573 119892119894119899119894 119883120574 120572 120579 (43)

where 119901119900119901119906119897119886119905119894119900119899 is the county population per year Hence the model to be estimated using

Maximum Likelihood Estimation (MLE) is

119897119900119892 120582 120573 120573 119892119894119899119894 119883120574 120572 120579 119897119900119892 (44)

Finally to account for different effects depending on the type of incivilities we also run

equation (44) for each of the four groups of incivilities defined in section (432)

435 Hypotheses

Based on the community heterogeneity hypothesis the relationship between social cohesion

and diversity should be stronger for lower levels of income and less educated groups of people

(Tolsma et al 2009) Hence contrary to evidence for developed and more equal countries we

expect a significant positive association for the Chilean case where more than 50 of the

population is economically vulnerable (OECD 2017)

The main hypotheses to be tested in this essay is whether the number of incivilities is

positively associated with the level of economic and racial heterogeneity at the county level We

start analysing this association for the full sample and period Next we analyse whether the

relationship between incivilities and our measures of diversity differs by geographic area (region

or zone) Finally we check whether the effect of economic and racial diversity is different

depending on the group of incivilities

112

44 Results and Discussion

Overall our results show that the rate of incivilities displays a stronger and more significant

relationship with racial diversity than with economic heterogeneity This association differs for

different geographic areas and for different types of incivilities Absolute economic indicators

except for income show a significant but small effect Increases in the average levels of income

or education and more financial autonomy for municipalities seem to be effective ways to reduce

the rate of incivilities

We estimate equation (44) assuming that the number of incivilities follows a Poisson

distribution Regional and temporal heterogeneity are captured through the inclusion of dummy

variables for five years (with 2006 as the reference year) and fourteen regional dummies (with

region XIII as the reference region) Results are reported in Table 4339 This table is structured in

two blocks of regressions pooled models in columns (1)-(4) and fixed-effects models in columns

(5)-(8)40 The first column in each block only includes economic indicators relative and absolute

trying to test which ones are more relevant and whether incivilities tend to mirror income

inequality (the ldquoincivilities thesisrdquo) The second column adds the variable foreign to account for

the effect of racial diversity (Letki 2008) The third column includes education to check whether

the association between economic and racial diversity with social cohesion changes (gets less

significant) when we control for educational level (Tolsma et al 2009) The final column in each

block corresponds to the full model specification which includes the rest of controls

39 Pooled estimations were obtained using the R command glm() and compared with results obtained from the command poisson in STATA 15 Fixed effects and random effects models were estimated using the STATA command xtpoisson Negative Binomial models were estimated using the command glmnb() in the MASS package for R and commands nbreg and xtnbreg in STATA 15 Results for Negative Binomial regressions are in Appendix T 40 We have omitted results with random effects due to the literature on panel count data models suggest that the most robust estimator is Poisson regression with Fixed Effects (Santos Silva amp Tenreyro 2010 2011)

113

Table 43

Poisson regressions

114

The positive and significant coefficient for the variable gini besides being small it becomes

insignificant in the fixed effects specification which includes the full set of controls This result

does not seem to be enough evidence to support our hypothesis that more unequal counties display

higher rates of incivilities On the other hand racial diversity through the variable foreign shows

a consistent positive association with the rate of incivilities41 Together coefficients for gini and

foreign seems to support the ldquocommunity heterogeneity thesisrdquo (Letki 2008) but not the

ldquoincivilities thesisrdquo (Skogan 1999) To check this finding we run the pooled full model

specification for each region and results are shown in Table 44 where regions have been ordered

from North to South The sign of the coefficient of the variable gini differs for different regions

Moreover the relationship is insignificant in some of the most unequal regions which are in the

South of the country (VIII IX and XIV) This result rejects the hypothesis that incivilities mirror

structural income inequalities For the variable foreign 12 out of 15 regions confirm the positive

association with the rate of incivilities42

We also run our pooled full model separately for each group of incivilities defined at the end

of section (432) Income inequality keeps its significant but small association with each group of

incivilities (see Table 45) Our measure of racial diversity shows a stronger association with

ldquoAlcohol Consumptionrdquo related to ldquoPublic Damagerdquo and ldquoThreatsrdquo The link with ldquoStreet Tradingrdquo

appears as non-significant These results support our general finding that on the one hand racial

heterogeneity exert a more significant influence on the rate of incivilities than economic

41 To get the effects of the variables gini and foreign over the rate of incivilities per 1000 inhabitants we need to exponentiate their coefficients Thus an increase in one unit in the variable gini increases the rate of incivilities per 1000 inhabitantsrdquo in 1005 times (e^0005) in the pooled full model Similarly an increase in one point in variable foreign is expected to increase the ldquorate of incivilities per 1000 inhabitantsrdquo in 10876 times (e^0084) in the full pooled model and 10471 (e^0046) times in the full Fixed Effects model 42 Given that depending on the geographic location regions share certain characteristics the model was also run clustering regions in 4 zones (see Figure 31 in chapter 3) Results by zone are in Appendix U

115

heterogeneity On the other hand results confirm our hypothesis that the effect of diversity is

different for different types of incivilities

Table 44 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson models by region

Back to our general results in Table 43 the significant and negative coefficient of the

income variable and to a lesser extent the significant and positive coefficients of poverty and

unemployment provide evidence that absolute rather than relative economic indicators may be

more important explanations of the rate of incivilities This is opposite to evidence for the analysis

116

of crime rates such as in Hoodge (2010) and support the idea that determinants of incivilities are

different from those of crime Our results are also opposite to those for Dutch municipalities where

economic indicators turned out to be more important than ethnic heterogeneity (Tolsma et al

2009) The coefficient for the variable log(income) could be interpreted as counties with an income

level under the average face higher problems of antisocial behaviours such as incivilities In

addition as the income level moves far away from its average low level the problem of incivilities

is less relevant43 In terms of policy implications only those policies that achieve a significant

increase in the average level of county income seem to be effective in reducing incivilities and

strengthening social cohesion

Table 45 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson model by incivility group

43 We ran our model splitting the sample of counties in quintiles based on their income level The coefficient for the variable gini only showed a significant (and positive) coefficient for the second third and fourth quintile A non-significant coefficient for the first quintile could imply that other types of inequalities (eg health education) are more relevant in the poorest counties In the case of the fifth quintile (the richest group of counties) they have better facilities in terms of infrastructure police resources self-protection etc which could reduce the potential triggers of incivilities

117

The inclusion of the variable education significantly improved the goodness of fit of the

models and did not generate significant changes in the coefficients of our measures of economic

and racial diversity This result rejects the proposition that the relationship between social

cohesion and diversity becomes less strong when controlled by education (Tolsma et al 2009)

Additionally it highlights the topic of education as a relevant determinant of the rate of incivilities

and social cohesion

Among control variables there are also some important results Opposite to what we

expected the variable youth shows a negative or non-significant coefficient Although this result

could be due to the lack of ldquophysical incivilitiesrdquo in Chilean records it indicates that it is incorrect

to stereotype this group as the main responsible for high incivilities rates The significant and

negative coefficient of the variable autonomy in the fixed effects specification could also have

important policy implications It is a signal that local governments can play an important role in

reducing incivilities or complementing the efforts from the central government Another

interesting result is the significant coefficient of the variable housing The latter finding is

particularly important in the sense that a negative sign supports public policies oriented to increase

homeownership as effective ways to improve social cohesion However the small magnitude of

the coefficient that even showed the opposite sign in some model specifications could be

explained for the high level of segregation that these policies have generated in Chilean society

As mentioned in the Introduction and Literature Review so far only a few studies have

used measures of disorders or incivilities as dependent variable to explain changes in social

cohesion (Skogan 2015) In addition there is no evidence in Chile analysing the determinants of

incivilities separately from those of crimes The importance of our results on identifying the

importance of economic and racial diversity on social cohesion lies mainly in its generality An

118

important number of countries all around the world share a similar context characterized by high

levels of inequality and an explosive increase in immigration These countries are also

experiencing a worsening in social cohesion which increases the risk of a social outburst

4 5 Conclusions

The main goal of this essay was to determine whether differences in incivilities at the county

level mirror differences in income distribution and racial diversity Previous literature suggests a

positive and strong association between social cohesion and indicators of economic disadvantage

relative deprivation and racial diversity (Letki 2008 Tolsma et al 2009 Uslaner amp Brown 2005)

While not all our results were significant they showed helpful insights about how and where

economic and racial diversity are more likely to influence the rate of incivilities and social

cohesion

We used data for the period 2006ndash17 economic heterogeneity was measured through the

Gini coefficient at the county level and racial heterogeneity was proxied by the number of granted

visas to foreigners as proportion of county population We found strong evidence of a significant

and positive association between the rate of incivilities and racial diversity but not with income

inequality Contrary to previous evidence at the municipal level (Coffeacute amp Geys 2006 Tolsma et

al 2009) in general our results give support for the ldquohomophily principlerdquo and the ldquocommunity

heterogeneity hypothesisrdquo However results also showed that the effect of economic and racial

diversity varies throughout the Chilean regions and for the different types of incivilities

We also found that policies aimed at controlling the behaviour of young people did not have

strong empirical support In terms of the role that local governments may have in facing the

119

growing problem of incivilities we found evidence that efforts managed from the municipalities

can be an important complement to those from the central government

Future research should go further on the role of local authorities on incivilities and social

cohesion On the one hand municipalities could have a direct impact on social cohesion through

the implementation of programs complementary to those of central authorities oriented to reduce

incivilities and crime On the other hand social cohesion could be indirectly affected when local

authorities display an inefficient performance supplying public services to citizens or they are

recognized as corrupted institutions We suggest that policy makers from central government

should give local authorities a greater role in fighting antisocial behaviours and crime Evaluating

programs in specific municipalities could help to elucidate the causal effect of for instance higher

fiscal autonomy on the rate of incivilities

Another interesting area for future work will be to analyse how housing policies have

contributed to the phenomenon of segregation of Chilean society and in the process of weakening

social cohesion Finally our main result highlights the need of a deeper analysis of the impact that

foreign immigration is having in Chile For instance disaggregating information by country of

origin and the reasons why immigrants are arriving to the country or specific regions will surely

help to understand the impacts of immigration

120

Chapter 5 Conclusions

This thesis investigated in three essays the issue of income inequality in Chile using county-

level data for the period 2006-2017 The first essay supplied empirical evidence about the

importance of the degree of dependence on natural resources in terms of employment in explaining

cross-county differences in income inequality The second essay analysed the potential causal

effect that income inequality has on the level of technical efficiency of local governments

providing public goods and services Lastly the third essay studied the relationship between social

cohesion measured through the number of antisocial behaviours classified as ldquoincivilitiesrdquo and

the levels of income and racial heterogeneity

Findings from the first essay support the idea that the endowment of natural resources plays

a significant role in explaining income inequality in Chile However contrary to what most

theoretical and empirical evidence postulates our findings showed a robust negative association

between the two variables This means that the reduction experienced in Chile in the degree of

dependence on natural resources in terms of employment has contributed to the persistence of high

levels of income inequality The exploratory analysis indicated that income inequality shows a

general clustering process characterized by a significant and positive spatial autocorrelation

Regarding the previous evidence for Chile (Paredes et al 2016) the regression analysis confirmed

the relevance of the spatial dimension of income inequality through a process of spatial

heterogeneity giving less support to the existence of a process of spatial dependence (spillover

effect) in the variable itself

121

Essay 2 studied the potential trade-off between efficiency and equity analysing the influence

of income inequality on the efficiency of local governments at the municipal level To identify the

causal effect of income inequality on municipal efficiency we proposed the use of the proportion

of firms in the primary sector as an instrument for income inequality Findings confirmed our

hypothesis that efficiency is lower in more unequal counties This result suggests the non-existence

of the trade-off between equity and efficiency Hence policies intended to reduce inequality could

help to increase efficiency at least at the level of municipal local governments

The third essay analysed how social cohesion proxied by the rate of incivilities is associated

with the levels of economic diversity proxied by income inequality and the levels of racial

diversity proxied by the number of new visas grated as proportion of the county population

Findings gave strong support to the hypothesis that the rate of incivilities is positively related to

racial diversity and to a lesser extent to economic diversity In addition the rate of incivilities

appears negatively related to the degree of financial autonomy of municipalities This means that

local governments can effectively contribute to the reduction of incivilities which could help

reduce victimization and crime rates ultimately strengthening social cohesion

Taken together findings from essays 2 and 3 highlight the important role that income

inequality could play in other relevant economic and social dimensions These findings add to the

understanding of the potential consequences of income inequality particularly in natural resource

rich countries with persistently high levels of inequality

The present study has mainly investigated income inequality at the county level In addition

Chilean municipalities play an important role providing ldquoservices to peoplerdquo so our findings could

be applied in other highly unequal countries with a high degree of dependence on natural resources

and local governments with similar responsibilities For instance in Latin America apart from

122

Chile and Brazil there are no studies on the efficiency of local governments Other limitations are

associated with the availability of information For instance important indicators such as GDP per

capita are only available at the regional level and information of incomes is not available annually

In addition given the heterogeneity among municipalities some type of grouping of municipalities

should be performed before looking for causal relationships or conducting program evaluation

Despite these limitations we believe this study could be the basis for different strands of future

research on the topic of inequality local government efficiency and social cohesion

It was stated in chapter 2 based on the resource curse hypothesis literature there are two

elements that determine whether NR are a curse or blessing in terms of socioeconomic outcomes

First the curse is more likely in countries with weak political and governance institutions Second

different types of resources affect institutions differently with resources that are concentrated in

space so-called ldquopointrdquo resources tend to impair institutions while ldquodiffuserdquo resources do not

(Deacon 2011 Isham Woolcock Pritchett amp Busby 2005) Our results showed a negative

relationship between income inequality and our measure of natural resource dependence even after

controlling for zone fixed effects and for the level of government expenditure This result could

be interpreted as a signal that NR has a direct effect on income inequality in addition to the indirect

impact through market or institutional channels Using other potential institutional transmission

channels will shed light about the true effect that the endowment of natural resources has over

income inequality Variables that could capture these institutional channels include the level of

employment in the public sector measures of rule of law and corruption and changes in the

creation of new business in the secondary and tertiary sectors related to the primary sector

Based on results from chapter 3 most of the municipalities show scale inefficiencies One

immediate area for future work will involve using our set of contextual factors to predict the status

123

of municipalities in terms of scale inefficiencies Defining as dependent variable whether a

municipality shows constant decreasing or increasing returns to scale we could run a multinomial

logistic regression to predict municipal status For instance we would expect that a one-unit

increase in the Gini coefficient should increase the probability of scale inefficiencies (increasing

or decreasing returns to scale rather than constant returns to scale) Because the aim in this case

would be predicting a certain result in terms of returns to scale the next step should involve to

split the full sample in training and testing data sets and to use some resampling methods such as

bootstrapping This will allow us to evaluate the performance and accuracy of our model

predictions using different random samples of municipalities Results from Machine Learning

algorithms will help us to assess the generalizability of our results to other data sets

Future work should also benefit greatly by using data on different Latin American countries

to (1) compare the responsibilities of local governments (2) select a common set of inputs and

output to evaluate LGE (3) identify the relevance of scales inefficiencies in explaining differences

in performance and (4) analyse the influence of contextual characteristics over LGE Differences

in the main primary sector activity in each country such as oil in Brazil mining in Chile or Coffee

in Colombia could be responsible for differences in LGE among countries These differences could

be associated with sources of revenue management of expenditure and definitions of outputs or

contextual effects such as corrupted institutions or the delay in the development of other sectors

such as manufacturing or services

To delve deep on reasons explaining the social crisis experienced by Chilean society and

other countries one area of future work will be to analyse the relationship between diversity and

the origins of social revolutions Based on Tiruneh (2014) the three most important factors that

explain the onset of social revolutions are economic development regime type and state

124

ineffectiveness Interesting questions include whether the characteristics of Chilean context at the

end of 2019 are enough to trigger the transformation of the political and socioeconomic system

Social revolutions particularly violent revolutions are less likely in more democratic educated

and wealthy societies So it would be relevant to identify the factors explaining the violence that

has characterized the social crisis in Chile Finally the democratic regime has been maintained in

the last decades with changes between left and right governments This could imply that more

important than the regime has been the efficiency or ineffectiveness of the governments to satisfy

the needs of the population

Future work should also cover the disaggregation of information regarding foreign

population in terms of the reasons for new granted visas and the country of origin Official data

allows us to disaggregate whether the benefit is permanent (students and employees with contract)

or temporary Furthermore most of the new visas were traditionally granted to neighbouring

countries (Peru and Bolivia) a trend that has changed in the recent years to include countries such

as Colombia Venezuela and Haiti An analysis of how economic and social indicators have been

affected by changes in the composition of foreigners their reasons for immigrating to the country

and their geographical distribution have implications for economic policy at both the national and

local levels At the national level such analysis should be a key input when proposing changes to

the national immigration policy At the local level it could help define the role of municipalities

to assess the benefits and challenges of immigration These challenges are mainly related to the

provision of public goods and services such as health and education which in Chile are the

responsibility of the municipalities

The findings of this thesis suggest that policymakers should encourage policies that reduce

income inequality The key role that municipalities could play to strengthen social cohesion and

125

the increasingly important role that foreign population is acquiring in most modern societies are

also interesting avenues for future research However the picture is still incomplete and more

research is needed incorporating other dimensions of inequality This is essential if we want to

understand the reasons that could have triggered the social outbursts experienced by various

economies across the globe

126

Bibliography

Acemoglu D (1995) Reward structures and the allocation of talent European Economic Review 39(1) 17ndash33 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg1010160014-2921(94)00014-Q

Acemoglu D (2002) Technical Change Inequality and the Labor Market Journal of Economic Literature 40(1) 7ndash72 httpsdoiorg1012570022051026976

Acemoglu D Aghion P amp Violante G L (2001) Deunionization Technical Change and Inequality Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 55(1) 229ndash264 httpsdoiorg101016S0167-2231(01)00058-6

Acemoglu D Johnson S amp Robinson J A (2001) The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development An Empirical Investigation The American Economic Review 91(5) 1369ndash1401 httpsdoiorg101257aer9151369

Acemoglu D amp Robinson J A (2002) The Political Economy of the Kuznets Curve Review of Development Economics 6(2) 183ndash203 httpsdoiorg1011111467-936100149

Afonso A amp Fernandes S (2006) Measuring local government spending efficiency Evidence for the Lisbon region Regional Studies 40(1) 39ndash53 httpsdoiorg10108000343400500449937

Afonso A amp Fernandes S (2008) Assessing and explaining the relative efficiency of local government The Journal of Socio-Economics 37(5) 1946ndash1979 httpsdoiorg101016jsocec200703007

Afonso A Schuknecht L amp Tanzi V (2010) Income distribution determinants and public spending efficiency Journal of Economic Inequality 8(3) 367ndash389 httpsdoiorg101007s10888-010-9138-z

Akita T (2003) Decomposing regional income inequality in China and Indonesia using two-stage nested Theil decomposition method The Annals of Regional Science 37(1) 55ndash77 httpsdoiorg101007s001680200107

Alesina A (2000) Participation in heterogeneous communities The Quarterly Journal of Economics 115(3) 847ndash904 httpsdoiorg101162003355300554935

Alesina A amp La Ferrara E (2002) Who trusts others Journal of Public Economics 85(2) 207ndash234 httpsdoiorg101016S0047-2727(01)00084-6

Allcott H amp Keniston D (2014) Dutch Disease or Agglomeration The Local Economic Effects of Natural Resource Booms in Modern America (N W P N 20508 Ed) NBER Working Paper No 20508 (Vol w20508) NBER Working Paper No 20508 NBER Working Paper No 20508 httpsdoiorgNBER Working Paper No 20508

Andersen T M amp Maibom J (2020) The big trade-off between efficiency and equitymdashis it there Oxford Economic Papers 72(2) 391ndash411

127

Anselin L (1988) Spatial econometrics methods and models (Vol 4) DordrechtBoston Kluwer Academic Publishers

Anselin L amp Bera A K (1998) Spatial dependence in linear regression models with an introduction to spatial econometrics Statistics Textbooks and Monographs (Vol 155)

Anselin L Bera A K Florax R amp Yoon M J (1996) Simple diagnostic tests for spatial dependence Regional Science and Urban Economics 26(1) 77ndash104 httpsdoiorg1010160166-0462(95)02111-6

Antonelli M A amp De Bonis V (2018) The efficiency of social public expenditure in European countries a two-stage analysis Applied Economics 1ndash14 httpsdoiorg1010800003684620181489522

Aragoacuten F M amp Rud J P (2013) Natural Resources and Local Communities Evidence from a Peruvian Gold Mine American Economic Journal Economic Policy 5(2) 1ndash25 httpsdoiorg101257pol521

Ariely G (2014) Does Diversity Erode Social Cohesion Conceptual and Methodological Issues Political Studies 62(3) 573ndash595 httpsdoiorg1011111467-924812068

Armstrong H amp Taylor J (2000) Regional economics and policy (3rd ed) Oxford Blackwell

Aroca P amp Atienza M (2011) Economic implications of long distance commuting in the Chilean mining industry Resources Policy 36(3) 196ndash203 httpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201103004

Aroca P amp Bosch M (2000) Crecimiento convergencia y espacio en las regiones chilenas 1960 - 1998 Estudios de Economiacutea 27 199ndash224 Retrieved from httprepositoriouchileclbitstreamhandle2250127853Patricio_Arocapdfsequence=1

Ashworth J Geys B Heyndels B amp Wille F (2014) Competition in the political arena and local government performance Applied Economics 46(19) 2264ndash2276 httpsdoiorg101080000368462014899679

Atkinson A B (2015) Inequality What Can Be Done Harvard University Press

Auty R (1993) Sustaining development in mineral economies the resource curse thesis London [ua] Routledge

Auty R (2001) Resource abundance and economic development (R World Institute for Development Economics Ed) Oxford Oxford University Press

Badeeb R A Lean H H amp Clark J (2017) The evolution of the natural resource curse thesis A critical literature survey Resources Policy 51 123ndash134 httpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201610015

Balaguer-Coll M T Brun-Martos M I Maacuterquez-Ramos L amp Prior D (2019) Local government efficiency determinants and spatial interdependence Applied Economics

128

51(14) 1478ndash1494 httpsdoiorg1010800003684620181527458

Balaguer-Coll M T amp Prior D (2009) Short- and long-term evaluation of efficiency and quality An application to Spanish municipalities Applied Economics 41(23) 2991ndash3002 httpsdoiorg10108000036840701351923

Banker R D Charnes A amp Cooper W W (1984) Some models for estimating technical and scale inefficiencies in data envelopment analysis Management Science 30(9) 1078ndash1092

Beine M Coulombe S amp Vermeulen W N (2015) Dutch Disease and the Mitigation Effect of Migration Evidence from Canadian Provinces The Economic Journal 125(589) 1574ndash1615 httpsdoiorg101111ecoj12171

Benito B Bastida F amp Garciacutea J A (2010) Explaining differences in efficiency an application to Spanish municipalities Applied Economics 42(4) 515ndash528 httpsdoiorg10108000036840701675560

Berg A amp Ostry J (2011) Equality and efficiency Finance amp Development 48(3) 12ndash15

Berg A amp Ostry J (2017) Inequality and Unsustainable Growth Two Sides of the Same Coin IMF ECONOMIC REVIEW 65(4) 792ndash815 httpsdoiorg101057s41308-017-0030-8

Beyer H amp Vergara R (2006) Delincuencia en Chile Determinantes y rol de las poliacuteticas puacuteblicas Instituto de Economiacutea UC

Blanco L amp Grier R (2012) Natural resource dependence and the accumulation of physical and human capital in Latin America Resources Policy 37(3) 281ndash295 httpsdoiorghttpdoiorg101016jresourpol201201005

Blau J R amp Blau P M (1982) The cost of inequality Metropolitan structure and violent crime American Sociological Review 114ndash129

Boetti L Piacenza M amp Turati G (2009) Fiscal decentralization and spending efficiency of local governments An Empirical Investigation on a Sample Of 4

Boix C amp Posner D (1998) Social capital Explaining its origins and effects on government performance British Journal Of Political Science 28 686ndash693

Borge L E Parmer P amp Torvik R (2015) Local natural resource curse JOURNAL OF PUBLIC ECONOMICS 131 101ndash114 httpsdoiorg101016jjpubeco201509002

Borger B Kerstens K Moesen W amp Vanneste J (1994) Explaining differences in productive efficiency An application to Belgian municipalities Public Choice 80(3) 339ndash358 httpsdoiorg101007BF01053225

Bourguignon F amp Morrisson C (1990) Income distribution development and foreign trade A cross-sectional analysislowast European Economic Review 34(6) 1113ndash1132 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg1010160014-2921(90)90071-6

129

Branas C C Cheney R A MacDonald J M Tam V W Jackson T D amp Ten Have T R (2011) A difference-in-differences analysis of health safety and greening vacant urban space American Journal of Epidemiology 174(11) 1296ndash1306

Bravo J (2014) Fondo Comuacuten Municipal y su desincentivo a la recaudacioacuten en Chile Temas de La Agenda Legislativa-Centro de Poliacuteticas Puacuteblicas UC 9(68)

Browning E K amp Johnson W R (1984) The Trade-Off between Equality and Efficiency Journal of Political Economy 92(2) 175ndash203 httpsdoiorg101086261219

Brunnschweiler C N amp Bulte E H (2008) The resource curse revisited and revised A tale of paradoxes and red herrings Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 55(3) 248ndash264 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jjeem200708004

Brunori P Ferreira F H G amp Peragine V (2013) Inequality of opportunity income inequality and economic mobility Some international comparisons In Getting Development Right (pp 85ndash115) Springer

Brunton-Smith I Jackson J amp Sutherland A (2014) Bridging structure and perception On the neighbourhood ecology of beliefs and worries about violent crime British Journal of Criminology 54(4) 503ndash526

Bulte E H Damania R amp Deacon R T (2005) Resource intensity institutions and development World Development 33(7) 1029ndash1044 httpsdoiorg101016jworlddev200504004

Carmignani F (2013) Development outcomes resource abundance and the transmission through inequality Resource and Energy Economics 35(3) 412ndash428 httpsdoiorg101016jreseneeco201304007

Carmignani Fabrizio amp Avom D (2010) The social development effects of primary commodity export dependence Ecological Economics 70(2) 317ndash330 httpsdoiorg101016jecolecon201009003

Caselli F amp Michaels G (2013) Do Oil Windfalls Improve Living Standards Evidence from Brazil American Economic Journal Applied Economics 5(1) 208ndash238 httpsdoiorg101257app51208

Celebioglu F amp Dallrsquoerba S (2010) Spatial disparities across the regions of Turkey An exploratory spatial data analysis Annals of Regional Science 45(2) 379ndash400 httpsdoiorg101007s00168-009-0313-8

Chan J To H-P amp Chan E (2006) Reconsidering social cohesion Developing a definition and analytical framework for empirical research Social Indicators Research 75(2) 273ndash302

Charnes A Cooper W W amp Rhodes E (1978) Measuring the efficiency of decision making units European Journal of Operational Research 2(6) 429ndash444

130

Chi G amp Zhu J (2019) Spatial Regression Models for the Social Sciences SAGE Publications Retrieved from httpsbooksgooglecomaubooksid=zHGkvwEACAAJ

Christiansen K O (1960) Industrialization and urbanization in relation to crime and juvenile delinquency International Review of Criminal Policy 16 3ndash8

Cingano F (2014) Trends in income inequality and its impact on economic growth (Vol 163) Paris OECD Publishing httpsdoiorg1017875jxrjncwxv6j-en

Coelli T J Prasada Rao D S OrsquoDonnell C J amp Battese G E (2005) An introduction to efficiency and productivity analysis An Introduction to Efficiency and Productivity Analysis Springer Science amp Business Media httpsdoiorg101007b136381

Coffeacute H amp Geys B (2005) Institutional Performance and Social Capital An Application to the Local Government Level Journal of Urban Affairs 27(5) 485ndash501 httpsdoiorg101111j0735-2166200500249x

Coffeacute H amp Geys B (2006) Community Heterogeneity A Burden for the Creation of Social Capital Social Science Quarterly 87(5) 1053ndash1072 httpsdoiorg101111j1540-6237200600415x

Cohen D Spear S Scribner R Kissinger P Mason K amp Wildgen J (2000) ldquo Broken windowsrdquo and the risk of gonorrhea American Journal of Public Health 90(2) 230

Corden W M amp Neary J P (1982) Booming sector and de-industrialisation in a small open economy The Economic Journal 92(368) 825ndash848

Cordero J M Pedraja-Chaparro F Pisaflores E C amp Polo C (2017) Efficiency assessment of Portuguese municipalities using a conditional nonparametric approach Journal of Productivity Analysis 48(1) 1ndash24 httpsdoiorg101007s11123-017-0500-z

Croissant Y amp Millo G (2018) Panel Data Econometrics with R John Wiley amp Sons

Cust J amp Poelhekke S (2015) The Local Economic Impacts of Natural Resource Extraction 7 251ndash268 httpsdoiorg101146annurev-resource-100814-125106

da Cruz N F amp Marques R C (2014) Revisiting the determinants of local government performance Omega 44 91ndash103 httpsdoiorg101016JOMEGA201309002

Dauvin M amp Guerreiro D (2017) The Paradox of Plenty A Meta-Analysis World Development 94 httpsdoiorg101016jworlddev201701009

de Sousa M da C S Cribari-Neto F amp Stosic B D (2005) Explaining DEA technical efficiency scores in an outlier corrected environment the case of public services in Brazilian municipalities Brazilian Review of Econometrics 25(2) 287ndash313

Deacon R T (2011) The Political Economy of the Natural Resource Curse A Survey of Theory and Evidence Foundations and Trends in Microeconomics 111-208

Delhey J amp Newton K (2005) Predicting cross-national levels of social trust global pattern or

131

Nordic exceptionalism European Sociological Review 21(4) 311ndash327

Dlouhyacute M (2018) Measuring Geographic Inequalities Dealing with Multiple Health Resources by Data Envelopment Analysis Frontiers in Public Health 6 53 httpsdoiorg103389fpubh201800053

Dollery B Wallis J amp Akimov A (2010) One Size Does Not Fit All The Special Case of Remote Small Local Councils in Outback Queensland Local Government Studies 36(1) 21ndash42 httpsdoiorg10108003003930903435716

Domenech J (2008) Mineral resource abundance and regional growth in Spain 1860ndash2000 Journal of International Development The Journal of the Development Studies Association 20(8) 1122ndash1135

Doran J amp Jordan D (2016) Decomposing US regional income inequality from 1969 to 2009 Applied Economics Letters 23(11) 781ndash784 httpsdoiorg1010801350485120151109030

Drew J amp Dollery B (2015) The State of Things The Dynamic Efficiency of Australian State and Territories Economic Papers A Journal of Applied Economics and Policy 34(3) 165ndash176

Drew J Kortt M amp Dollery B (2015) What Determines Efficiency in Local Government A DEA Analysis of NSW Local Government Economic Papers A Journal of Applied Economics and Policy 34(4) 243ndash256 httpsdoiorg1011111759-344112118

Easterly W (2007) Inequality does cause underdevelopment Insights from a new instrument Journal of Development Economics 84(2) 755ndash776 httpsdoiorghttpdxdoiorg101016jjdeveco200611002

Ebert L amp La Menza T (2015) Chile copper and resource revenue A holistic approach to assessing commodity dependence Resources Policy 43(Supplement C) 101ndash111 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201410007

ElGindi T (2017) Natural resource dependency neoliberal globalization and income inequality Are they related A longitudinal study of developing countries (1980ndash2010) Current Sociology 65(1) 21ndash53 httpsdoiorg1011770011392116632031

Engerman S L amp Sokoloff K L (1994) Factor Endowments Institutions and Differential Paths of Growth Among New World Economies National Bureau of Economic Research

Engerman S L amp Sokoloff K L (1997) Factor endowments institutions and differential paths of growth among new world economies How Latin America Fell Behind 260ndash304

Engerman S L Sokoloff K L Urquiola M amp Acemoglu D (2002) Factor Endowments Inequality and Paths of Development among New World Economies [with Comments] EconomampxedA 3(1) 41ndash109 Retrieved from httpwwwjstororgezp01libraryquteduaustable20065432

132

Faumlre R Grosskopf S amp Lovell C A K (1985) The measurement of efficiency of production (Vol 6) Springer Science amp Business Media

Fleming D A amp Measham T G (2015a) Income Inequality across Australian Regions during the Mining Boom 2001-11 Australian Geographer 46(2) 203ndash216 httpsdoiorg1010800004918220151020596

Fleming D A amp Measham T G (2015b) Local economic impacts of an unconventional energy boom the coal seam gas industry in Australia Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 59(1) 78ndash94 httpsdoiorg1011111467-848912043

Fum R M amp Hodler R (2010) Natural resources and income inequality The role of ethnic divisions Economics Letters 107(3) 360ndash363 httpsdoiorg101016jeconlet201003008

Garofalo J (1978) The fear of crime Broadening our perspective

Geys B amp Moesen W (2009) Exploring Sources of Local Government Technical Inefficiency Evidence from Flemish Municipalities Public Finance and Management 9(1) 1ndash29

Goderis B amp Malone S W (2011) Natural Resource Booms and Inequality Theory and Evidence The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 113(2) 388ndash417 httpsdoiorg101111j1467-9442201101659x

Greene W H (2016) Productivity and Efficiency Analysis (W H Greene L Khalaf R Sickles M Veall amp M-C Voia Eds) (1st ed 20) Cham Springer International Publishing httpsdoiorg101007978-3-319-23228-7

Gustafsson B amp Shi L (2002) Income inequality within and across counties in rural China 1988 and 1995 Journal of Development Economics 69(1) 179ndash204 httpsdoiorg101016S0304-3878(02)00058-5

Gylfason T amp Zoega G (2003) Inequality and Economic Growth Do Natural Resources Matter In T T Eicher S (Ed) Inequality and Growth Theory and Policy Implications (pp 255ndash292) The MIT Press

Henningsen A (2010) Estimating Censored Regression Models in R using the censReg Package R Package Vignettes Collection 5(2) 12

Henningsen A (2019) censReg Censored Regression (Tobit) Models R package version 05-30 httpscranr-projectorgpackage=censReg Retrieved from httpscranr-projectorgpackage=censReg

Herrera S amp Pang G (2005) Efficiency of Public Spending in Developing Countriesthinsp An Efficiency Frontier Approach World Bank Washington DC

Hill T D amp Angel R J (2005) Neighborhood disorder psychological distress and heavy drinking Social Science amp Medicine 61(5) 965ndash975

133

httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jsocscimed200412027

Hipp J R (2010) RESIDENT PERCEPTIONS OF CRIME AND DISORDER HOW MUCH IS ldquoBIASrdquo AND HOW MUCH IS SOCIAL ENVIRONMENT DIFFERENCES Criminology 48(2) 475ndash508 httpsdoiorg101111j1745-9125201000193x

Holtug N amp Mason A (2010) Introduction Immigration diversity and social cohesion SAGE Publications Sage UK London England

Hooghe M Vanhoutte B Hardyns W amp Bircan T (2010) Unemployment Inequality Poverty and Crime Spatial Distribution Patterns of Criminal Acts in Belgium 2001ndash06 The British Journal of Criminology 51(1) 1ndash20 httpsdoiorg101093bjcazq067

Howie P amp Atakhanova Z (2014) Resource boom and inequality Kazakhstan as a case study Resources Policy 39(1) 71ndash79 httpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201311004

Isham J Woolcock M Pritchett L amp Busby G (2005) The Varieties of Resource Experience Natural Resource Export Structures and the Political Economy of Economic Growth The World Bank Economic Review 19(2) 141ndash174 httpsdoiorg101093wberlhi010

Jottier D Ashworth J amp Heyndels B (2012) Understanding Votersrsquo Preferences How the Electoratersquos Complexity Affects Prediction Accuracy and Wishful Thinking among Politicians with Respect to Election Outcomes Kyklos 65(3) 340ndash370 httpsdoiorg101111j1467-6435201200542x

Kanbur S M R amp Venables A (2005) Spatial inequality and development (R World Institute for Development Economics Ed) Oxford Oxford University Press

Kesler C amp Bloemraad I (2010) Does immigration erode social capital The conditional effects of immigration-generated diversity on trust membership and participation across 19 countries 1981ndash2000 Canadian Journal of Political ScienceRevue Canadienne de Science Politique 43(2) 319ndash347

Kuznets S (1955) Economic Growth and Income Inequality The American Economic Review 45(1) 1ndash28 Retrieved from httpwwwjstororgstable1811581

Lagos G amp Blanco E (2010) Mining and development in the region of Antofagasta Resources Policy 35(4) 265ndash275 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201007006

Leamer E E Maul H Rodriguez S amp Schott P K (1999) Does natural resource abundance increase Latin American income inequality Journal of Development Economics 59(1) 3ndash42 httpsdoiorg101016s0304-3878(99)00004-8

Leibbrandt M Finn A amp Woolard I (2012) Describing and decomposing post-apartheid income inequality in South Africa Development Southern Africa 29(1) 19ndash34 httpsdoiorg1010800376835X2012645639

134

Letki N (2008) Does Diversity Erode Social Cohesion Social Capital and Race in British Neighbourhoods Political Studies 56(1) 99ndash126 httpsdoiorg101111j1467-9248200700692x

Lewis D A (2017) Fear of crime Incivility and the production of a social problem Routledge

lo Storto C (2013) Evaluating Technical Efficiency of Italian Major Municipalities A Data Envelopment Analysis model Procedia - Social and Behavioral Sciences 81 346ndash350 httpsdoiorg101016JSBSPRO201306440

Loayza N amp Rigolini J (2016) The Local Impact of Mining on Poverty and Inequality Evidence from the Commodity Boom in Peru World Development 84 219ndash234 httpsdoiorg101016jworlddev201603005

Loayza N Teran A M y amp Rigolini J (2013) Poverty Inequality and the Local Natural Resource Curse World Bank Policy Research Working Paper (6366) httpsdoiorg1015961813-9450-6366

Loacutepez R amp Miller S J (2008) Chile The Unbearable Burden of Inequality World Development 36(12) 2679ndash2695 httpsdoiorg101016jworlddev200801012

Manzano O amp Rigobon R (2001) Resource Curse or Debt Overhang National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper Series No 8390 1 httpsdoiorghttpwwwnberorgpapersw9424bib

McPherson M Smith-Lovin L amp Cook J M (2001) Birds of a Feather Homophily in Social Networks Annual Review of Sociology 27(1) 415ndash444 httpsdoiorg101146annurevsoc271415

McQuestin D Drew J amp Dollery B (2018) Do Municipal Mergers Improve Technical Efficiency An Empirical Analysis of the 2008 Queensland Municipal Merger Program Australian Journal of Public Administration 77(3) 442ndash455 httpsdoiorg1011111467-850012286

Messner S F Rosenfeld R amp Baumer E P (2004) Dimensions of Social Capital and Rates of Criminal Homicide American Sociological Review 69(6) 882ndash903 httpsdoiorg101177000312240406900607

Michaels G (2011) THE LONG TERM CONSEQUENCES OF RESOURCE-BASED SPECIALISATION The Economic Journal 121(551) 31ndash57 httpsdoiorg101111j1468-0297201002402x

Mijanovich T amp Weitzman B C (2003) Which ldquobroken windowsrdquo matter School neighborhood and family characteristics associated with youthsrsquo feelings of unsafety Journal of Urban Health 80(3) 400ndash415

Mikušovaacute P (2015) An Application of DEA Methodology in Efficiency Measurement of the Czech Public Universities Procedia Economics and Finance 25 569ndash578 httpsdoiorg101016S2212-5671(15)00771-6

135

Milanovic B (2016) Global inequality Harvard University Press

Millo G amp Piras G (2012) splm Spatial panel data models in R Journal of Statistical Software 47(1) 1ndash38

Murphy K M amp Topel R H (2016) Human Capital Investment Inequality and Economic Growth JOURNAL OF LABOR ECONOMICS 34(2) S99ndashS127 httpsdoiorg101086683779

Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute I amp De Witte K (2018a) Local governmentsrsquo efficiency a systematic literature reviewmdashpart I International Transactions in Operational Research 25(2) 431ndash468 httpsdoiorg101111itor12364

Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute I amp De Witte K (2018b) Local governmentsrsquo efficiency a systematic literature reviewmdashpart II International Transactions in Operational Research 25(4) 1107ndash1136 httpsdoiorg101111itor12389

Nuntildeez J Rivera J Villavicencio X amp Molina O (2003) Determinantes socioeconoacutemicos y demograacuteficos del crimen en Chile Estudios de Economiacutea 30(1) 55ndash85

OrsquoDonnell C J Rao D S P amp Battese G E (2008) Metafrontier frameworks for the study of firm-level efficiencies and technology ratios Empirical Economics 34(2) 231ndash255 httpsdoiorg101007s00181-007-0119-4

Ocampo J A (2004) Latin Americarsquos Growth and Equity Frustrations During Structural Reforms The Journal of Economic Perspectives 18(2) 67ndash88 httpsdoiorg1012570895330041371349

OECD (2014) Focus on inequality and growth OECD

OECD (2017) Howrsquos Life 2017 Life Satisfaction Oecd httpsdoiorg101787how_life-2017-en

Ohtake F (2008) Inequality in Japan Asian Economic Policy Review 3(1) 87ndash109 httpsdoiorg101111j1748-3131200800093x

Okun A M (2015) Equality and efficiency the big tradeoff Washington DC Brookings Institution Press

Ortega B Sanjuaacuten J amp Casquero A (2017) Determinants of efficiency in reducing child mortality in developing countries The role of inequality and government effectiveness Health Care Management Science 20(4) 500ndash516 httpsdoiorg101007s10729-016-9367-1

Ostry J Berg A amp Tsangarides C (2014) Redistribution inequality and growth International Monetary Fund

Pacheco F Saacutenchez R amp Villena M (2013) Eficiencia de los Gobiernos Locales y sus Determinantes Un anaacutelisis de Fronteras Estocaacutesticas en Datos de Panel para

136

Municipalidades Chilenas Santiago de Chile Chile

Papyrakis E amp Raveh O (2014) An Empirical Analysis of a Regional Dutch Disease The Case of Canada Environmental and Resource Economics 58(2) 179ndash198 httpsdoiorg101007s10640-013-9698-z

Paredes D (2013) The Role of Human Capital Market Potential and Natural Amenities in Understanding Spatial Wage Disparities in Chile Spatial Economic Analysis 8(2) 154ndash175 httpsdoiorg101080174217722013774094

Paredes D Iturra V amp Lufin M (2016) A spatial decomposition of income inequality in Chile Regional Studies 50(5) 771ndash789

Phan P Van Orsquobrien M Mendolia S amp Paloyo A (2017) National pro-poor spending programmes and their effect on income inequality and poverty Evidence from Vietnam Applied Economics 49(55) 5579ndash5590 httpsdoiorg1010800003684620171313957

Podinovski V V (2004) Bridging the Gap between the Constant and Variable Returns-to-Scale Models Selective Proportionality in Data Envelopment Analysis The Journal of the Operational Research Society 55(3) 265ndash276 Retrieved from httpwwwjstororgstable4102006

Ravallion M (2005) On Measuring Aggregate Social Efficiency Economic Development and Cultural Change 53(2) 273ndash292 httpsdoiorg101086425380

Rehner J Baeza S A amp Barton J R (2014) Chilersquos resource-based export boom and its outcomes Regional specialization export stability and economic growth Geoforum 56(Supplement C) 35ndash45 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jgeoforum201406007

Rivera J Gutieacuterrez M amp Nuacutentildeez J (2009) Caracterizacioacuten socioeconoacutemica y espacial de la criminalidad en Chile Revista CEPAL

Ross C E (2011) Collective threat trust and the sense of personal control Journal of Health and Social Behavior 52(3) 287ndash296

Ross C E amp Mirowsky J (2001) Neighborhood disadvantage disorder and health Journal of Health and Social Behavior 258ndash276

Rothstein B amp Uslaner E M (2005) All for all Equality corruption and social trust World Politics 58(1) 41ndash72

Sachs J D amp Warner A M (2001) The curse of natural resources European Economic Review 45(4ndash6) 827ndash838 httpsdoiorg101016S0014-2921(01)00125-8

Salas R (2019) sinimr Chilean Municipalities Information System Wrapper Retrieved from httpsgithubcomrobsalascosinimr

Sampson R J (1986) Crime in Cities The Effects of Formal and Informal Social Control Crime and Justice 8 271ndash311

137

Sampson R J (2008) Rethinking crime and immigration Contexts 7(1) 28ndash33

Santos Silva J M C amp Tenreyro S (2010) On the existence of the maximum likelihood estimates in Poisson regression Economics Letters 107(2) 310ndash312 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jeconlet201002020

Santos Silva J M C amp Tenreyro S (2011) poisson Some convergence issues Stata Journal 11(2) 207ndash212 Retrieved from httpwwwstata-journalcomarticlehtmlarticle=st0225

Scott Z (2009) Decentralisation local development and social cohesion an analytical review GSDRC Research Paper 5

Sinha R P (2017) Fiscal Performance Benchmarking of Indian States-A Robust Frontier Approach The Central European Review of Economics and Management 1(4) 225ndash249

Skogan W (1986) Fear of crime and neighborhood change Crime and Justice 8 203ndash229

Skogan W (1999) Measuring what matters Crime disorder and fear In Measuring what matters Proceedings from the Policing Research Institute meetings (pp 37ndash53) National Institute of Justice Washington DC

Skogan W (2015) Disorder and Decline The State of Research Journal of Research in Crime and Delinquency 52(4) 464ndash485 httpsdoiorg1011770022427815577836

Šťastnaacute L amp Gregor M (2014) Public sector efficiency in transition and beyond evidence from Czech local governments Applied Economics 47(7) 1ndash20 httpsdoiorg101080000368462014978077

Tandon A (2005) Measuring Efficiency of Macro Systems An Application to Millennium Development Goal Attainment Asian Development Review 22(2) 108ndash125

Taylor R B (1999) The incivilities thesis Theory measurement and policy Measuring What Matters 65 88

Tigga N S amp Mishra U S (2015) On Measuring Technical Efficiency of the Health System in India An Application of Data Envelopment Analysis Journal of Health Management 17(3) 285ndash298 httpsdoiorg1011770972063415589229

Tinbergen J (1975) Demographic Development and the Exhaustion of Natural Resources Population and Development Review 1(1) 23ndash32 httpsdoiorg1023071972269

Tiruneh G (2014) Social Revolutions Their Causes Patterns and Phases SAGE Open 4(3) 2158244014548845 httpsdoiorg1011772158244014548845

Tolsma J Van der Meer T amp Gesthuizen M (2009) The impact of neighbourhood and municipality characteristics on social cohesion in the Netherlands Acta Politica 44(3) 286ndash313

Tsekeris Sotiris T Tsekeris T amp Papaioannou S (2018) Regional determinants of technical efficiency evidence from the Greek economy Regional Studies [London]thinsp Carfax

138

httpsdoiorg1010800034340420171390312

Uslaner E (2002) The moral foundations of trust Cambridge University Press

Uslaner E (2011) CORRUPTION AND INEQUALITY DICE Report 9(2) 20ndash24

Uslaner E (2013) Trust and corruption revisited how and why trust and corruption shape each other Quality amp Quantity 47(6) 3603ndash3608 httpsdoiorg101007s11135-012-9742-z

Uslaner E amp Brown M (2005) Inequality trust and civic engagement American Politics Research 33(6) 868ndash894

Van der Ploeg F (2011) Natural Resources Curse or Blessing Journal of Economic Literature 49(2) 366ndash420 httpsdoiorg101257jel492366

Vergara R (2012) Crime Prevention Programs Evidence From CHILE The Developing Economies 50(1) 1ndash24

Watkins M H (1963) A staple theory of economic growth Canadian Journal of Economics and Political ScienceRevue Canadienne de Economiques et Science Politique 29(2) 141ndash158

Wilkinson R G (1999) Income inequality social cohesion and health clarifying the theorymdasha reply to Muntaner and Lynch International Journal of Health Services 29(3) 525ndash543

Wilson J Q amp Kelling G L (1982) Broken windows Atlantic Monthly 249(3) 29ndash38

Wilson W J (1996) When Work Disappears Political Science Quarterly 111(4) 567ndash595 httpsdoiorg1023072152085

Wirth L (1938) Urbanism as a Way of Life American Journal of Sociology 44(1) 1ndash24

Worthington A amp Dollery B (2000) An empirical survey of frontier efficiency measurement techniques in local government Local Government Studies 26(2) 23ndash52 httpsdoiorg10108003003930008433988

Wu P-C Huang T-H amp Pan S-C (2014) Country Performance Evaluation The DEA Model Approach Social Indicators Research 118(2) 835ndash849 httpsdoiorg101007s11205-013-0443-3

Ye X Ma L Ye K Chen J amp Xie Q (2017) Analysis of Regional Inequality from Sectoral Structure Spatial Policy and Economic Development A Case Study of Chongqing China Sustainability 9(4) 633 Retrieved from httpwwwmdpicom2071-105094633

Yue W Z Zhang Y T Ye X Y Cheng Y Q amp Leipnik M R (2014) Dynamics of Multi-Scale Intra-Provincial Regional Inequality in Zhejiang China Sustainability 6(9) 5763ndash5784 httpsdoiorg103390su6095763

139

Appendices

Appendix A Summary statistics income inequality

Table A1

Summary statistics Gini coefficients by year and zone

140

Appendix B Summary statistics for NRD measures by region

Table B1

Summary statistics NRD measures by region

141

Appendix C Regional administrative division and defined zones

Figure C1 Geographical distribution of Chilean regions and 3 zones

142

Appendix D Summary statistics numeric controls and correlation matrix

Table D1

Summary Statistics Numeric Explanatory Variables

Figure D1 Correlation matrix numeric explanatory variables

143

Appendix E Static spatial panel models

Following Millo amp Piras (2012) a model including a spatial lag of the dependent variable and

spatial autoregressive disturbances but not spatial lags for the explanatory variable(s) is called

SARAR model A static spatial SARAR panel could be expressed as

119910 120582 119868 otimes119882 119910 119883120573 119906 (E1)

where y is an 119873 1 vector of observations on the dependent variable X is a 119873 119896 matrix of

observations on the non-stochastic exogenous regressors 119868 an identity matrix of dimension 119879 otimes

is the kronecker operator 119882 is the 119873 119873 spatial weights matrix of known constants whose

diagonal elements are set to zero and 120582 the corresponding spatial parameter44

The disturbance vector is the sum of two terms

119906 120580 otimes 119868 120583 120576 (E2)

where 120580 is a 119879 1 vector of ones 119868 an 119873 119873 identity matrix 120583 is a vector of time-invariant

individual specific effects (not spatially autocorrelated) and 120576 a vector of spatially autocorrelated

innovations that follow a spatial autoregressive process of the form

120576 120588 119868 otimes119882 120576 120584 (E3)

If we assume that spatial correlation applies to both the individual effects 120583 and the remainder

error components 120576 Kapoor et al (2007) propose that the disturbance term 119906 follows a first order

spatial autoregressive process of the form

119906 120588 119868 otimes119882 119906 120576 (E4)

44 Unlike ldquotraditional panelsrdquo which are organized as different time series for each cross-sectional unit ldquospatial panelsrdquo are organized as a series of cross-sections for each year

144

where 119882 is the spatial weights matrix and 119903ℎ119900 the corresponding spatial autoregressive

parameter To further allow for the innovations to be correlated over time the innovations vector

in Equation 7 follows an error component structure

120576 120580 otimes 119868 120583 120584 (E5)

where 120583 is the vector of cross-sectional specific effects 120584 a vector of innovations that vary

both over cross-sectional units and time periods 120580 is a vector of ones and 119868 an 119873 119873 identity

matrix45

Spatial panel models are usually estimated by Maximum Likelihood or GMM46 The SAR

SEM or SARAR models could be estimated with Random or Fixed effects For instance A fixed

effect spatial lag model can be written in stacked form as

119910 120582 119868 otimes119882 119910 120580 otimes 119868 120583 119883120573 120576 (E6)

where 120582 is the spatial autoregressive coefficient 119882 a non-stochastic spatial weights matrix

120580 a column vector of ones of dimension 119879 119868 an 119873 119873 identity matrix and 120576 sim 119873 0120590 On

the other hand a fixed effects spatial error model assuming the disturbance specification by

Kapoor et al (2007) can be written as

119910 120580119879 otimes 119868119873 120583 119883120573 119906119906 120588 119868119879 otimes119882119873 119906 120576

(E7)

where 120588 is the spatial autocorrelation coefficient and 120576 is a well-behaved error term

45 In the regression implementation the specification given by equations (22) and (3) is denoted by ldquobrdquo for ldquoBaltagirdquo On the other hand the specification given by equations (23) and (31) is denoted by ldquokkprdquo for ldquoKapoor Kelejian and Pruchardquo 46 We use the R package splm which allow both types of regression procedure

145

Appendix F Analysis OLS residuals cross-sectional (six-year average) analysis

Table F1

Analysis OLS residuals Anselin Method

Figure F1 Moran scatter plot OLS residuals

146

Appendix G Linear panel data models

Table G1

Panel regressions (non-spatial)

147

Appendix H Spatial panel models (Generalized Moments (GM) estimation)

Table H1

GM Spatial Models

148

Appendix I Inputs and outputs used in DEA analysis

Figure I1 Examples of inputs and outputs used to measure LGE (based on Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018)

149

Appendix J Technical and scale efficiency

Following lo Storto (2013) under an input-oriented specification assuming VRS with n

municipalities using k inputs to produce m outputs the DEA model for a given i-th municipality

is specified with the following mathematical programming problem

119898119894119899 120579119904119906119887119895119890119888119905 119905119900 119910 119884120582 0120579119909 119883120582 01198991prime120582 1  120582 0prime

Where 119910 is the column vector of the outputs and 119909 is the column vector of the inputs

Moreover we can define X as the (k times n) input matrix and Y as the (m times n) output matrix 120579 is a

scalar (that satisfies 120579 1) more specifically it is the efficiency score that measures technical

efficiency It measures the distance between a municipality and the efficiency frontier defined as

a linear combination of the best practice observations With 120579 1 the municipality is inside the

frontier (ie it is inefficient) while 120579 1 implies that the municipality is on the frontier (ie it is

efficient) The vector 120582 is an (n times 1) vector of constants that measures the weights used to compute

the location of an inefficient municipality if it were to become efficient

The total technical efficiency 119879119864 can be decomposed into pure technical efficiency

119879119864 and scale efficiency 119878119864 where 119878119864 119879119864 119879119864 (Coelli et al 2005) To find out

whether a municipality is scale efficient and qualify the type of returns of scale a DEA model

under non-increasing returns to scale 119879119864 is implemented where 119878119864 119879119864 119879119864 Hence

the following rule can be applied (Faumlre Grosskopf amp Lovell 1985)

bull If 119878119864 1 then a municipality is scale efficient both under CRS and VRS

bull If 119878119864 1 it operates under increasing returns to scale

bull If 119878119864 1 it operates under decreasing returns to scale

150

Appendix K Correlation matrix

Figure K1 Correlation matrix contextual factors

151

Appendix L Returns to scale by year and zone

Table L1

Returns to scale (percentage of municipalities)

152

Appendix M Returns to scale by year (maps)

Figure M1 Spatial distribution of returns to scale by county per year

153

Appendix N Efficiency status by year (maps)

Figure N1 Spatial distribution of efficient (E es = 1) and inefficient (I es lt 1) counties per year

154

Appendix O Spatial distribution efficiency scores by year (maps)

FigureO1 Custom breaks maps of efficiency scores (VRS) by county per year

155

Appendix P Analysis OLS residuals cross-sectional (six-year average) analysis

Table P1

Analysis OLS residuals Anselin Method

Figure P1 Moran scatter plot efficiency scores and OLS residuals

156

Table P2

OLS and spatial regression models for the six-year averaged data

157

Appendix Q OLS regressions for cross-sectional and panel data

Table Q1

OLS cross-sectional regression per year

158

Table Q2

OLS panel regressions Pooled random effects and instrumental variable

159

Appendix R Quantile maps incivilities rate by group (average total period)

Figure R1 Spatial distribution of incivilities by group (Average rate per 1000 inhabitants 2006-09-11-13-15-17)

160

Appendix S Correlation matrix numeric covariates

Figure S1 Correlation matrix numeric covariates

161

Appendix T Negative Binomial regressions

Table T1

Negative Binomial regressions

162

Appendix U Coefficients economic and racial diversity by geographical zone

Table U1

Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson models by geographic zone

Page 7: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted

vi

31 Introduction 55

32 Related Literature 61 321 Measuring efficiency of local governments 61 322 Explaining differences in LGE 63 323 The trade-off between efficiency and equity 64

33 Methodology 66 331 Chilean Municipalities and period of analysis 66 332 Measuring municipal efficiency 68 333 Inputs and outputs used in DEA 70 334 Regression model 71 335 The instrument 75

34 Results and discussion 77 341 DEA results 77

Returns to scale 78 Efficiency measure 80

342 Regression results 82 Exploratory spatial analysis 82 Cross-sectional analysis 83 Panel data analysis 84

35 Conclusions 88

Chapter 4 Social Cohesion Incivilities and Diversity Evidence at the municipal level in Chile 91

41 Introduction 91

42 Related Literature 95 421 The Community Heterogeneity Thesis 95 422 The literature on incivilities 97 423 The ldquoIncivilities Thesisrdquo 99

4 3 Methodology 100 431 Period of analysis and data sample 100 432 Operationalisation of the response variable and exploratory analysis 101 433 Measures of community heterogeneity and control variables 105 434 Methods 108 435 Hypotheses 111

44 Results and Discussion 112

4 5 Conclusions 118

Chapter 5 Conclusions 120

Bibliography 126

Appendices 139

Appendix A Summary statistics income inequality 139

Appendix B Summary statistics for NRD measures by region 140

Appendix C Regional administrative division and defined zones 141

Appendix D Summary statistics numeric controls and correlation matrix 142

vii

Appendix E Static spatial panel models 143

Appendix F Analysis OLS residuals cross-sectional (six-year average) analysis 145

Appendix G Linear panel data models 146

Appendix H Spatial panel models (Generalized Moments (GM) estimation) 147

Appendix I Inputs and outputs used in DEA analysis 148

Appendix J Technical and scale efficiency 149

Appendix K Correlation matrix 150

Appendix L Returns to scale by year and zone 151

Appendix M Returns to scale by year (maps) 152

Appendix N Efficiency status by year (maps) 153

Appendix O Spatial distribution efficiency scores by year (maps) 154

Appendix P Analysis OLS residuals cross-sectional (six-year average) analysis 155

Appendix Q OLS regressions for cross-sectional and panel data 157

Appendix R Quantile maps incivilities rate by group (average total period) 159

Appendix S Correlation matrix numeric covariates 160

Appendix T Negative Binomial regressions 161

Appendix U Coefficients economic and racial diversity by geographical zone 162

viii

List of Figures

Figure 21 Average share in GDP of economic activities (2006ndash17) 37

Figure 22 Evolution of Gini coefficient and measures of NRD (2006ndash17) 38

Figure 23 Spatial distribution of Gini coefficient and NRD (2006ndash17) 39

Figure 23 Moran scatter plots for variables gini and pss_casen 45

Figure 31 Geographical distribution of Chilean regions and macrozones 74

Figure 32 Evolution of efficiency scores and the proportion of firms by sector 77

Figure 33 Evolution technical efficiency (TE) pure technical efficiency (PTE) and scale efficiency (SE) 78

Figure 34 Returns to scale by zone 79

Figure 35 Evolution mean efficiency scores (VRS) by zone 81

Figure 41 Evolution number and rates of incivilities and crime (DMCS) in Chile 2006-2017 102

Figure 42 Evolution total number of incivilities by category 104

Figure 43 Spatial distribution of incivilities rate per 1000 inhabitants (2006 vs 2017) 104

Figure 44 Annual average number of incivilities per county 109

Figure C1 Geographical distribution of Chilean regions and 3 zones 141

Figure D1 Correlation matrix numeric explanatory variables 142

Figure F1 Moran scatter plot OLS residuals 145

Figure I1 Examples of inputs and outputs used to measure LGE (based on Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018) 148

Figure K1 Correlation matrix contextual factors 150

Figure M1 Spatial distribution of returns to scale by county per year 152

Figure N1 Spatial distribution of efficient (E es = 1) and inefficient (I es lt 1) counties per year 153

FigureO1 Custom breaks maps of efficiency scores (VRS) by county per year 154

Figure P1 Moran scatter plot efficiency scores and OLS residuals 155

Figure R1 Spatial distribution of incivilities by group (Average rate per 1000 inhabitants 2006-09-11-13-15-17) 159

Figure S1 Correlation matrix numeric covariates 160

ix

List of Tables

Table 21 Cross-sectional Model Comparison (six-year average data) 47

Table 22 ML Spatial SAR Models 50

Table 23 ML Spatial SEM Models 50

Table 24 ML Spatial SARAR Models 51

Table 31 Descriptive statistics Inputs and Output variables used in DEA analysis 71

Table 32 Summary Statistics Numeric Contextual Factors 74

Table 33 Summary efficiency scores (VRS) by zone and region 80

Table 34 Cross-sectional (censored) regressions 84

Table 35 Panel data regressions 87

Table 41 Summary statistics total count of incivilities and by category (full sample and period) 103

Table 42 Summary statistics numeric explanatory variables 108

Table 43 Poisson regressions 113

Table 44 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson models by region 115

Table 45 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson model by incivility group 116

Table A1 Summary statistics Gini coefficients by year and zone 139

Table B1 Summary statistics NRD measures by region 140

Table D1 Summary Statistics Numeric Explanatory Variables 142

Table F1 Analysis OLS residuals Anselin Method 145

Table G1 Panel regressions (non-spatial) 146

Table H1 GM Spatial Models 147

Table L1 Returns to scale (percentage of municipalities) 151

Table P1 Analysis OLS residuals Anselin Method 155

Table P2 OLS and spatial regression models for the six-year averaged data 156

Table Q1 OLS cross-sectional regression per year 157

Table Q2 OLS panel regressions Pooled random effects and instrumental variable 158

Table T1 Negative Binomial regressions 161

Table U1 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson models by geographic zone 162

x

List of Abbreviations

Constant returns to scale CRS

Data envelopment analysis DEA

Decreasing returns to scale DRS

Efficiency scores ES

Exploratory spatial data analysis ESDA

Generalized methods of moments GMM

Gross Domestic Product GDP

Increasing returns to scale IRS

Local government efficiency LGE

Maximum likelihood ML

Municipal common fund MCF

Natural resource dependence NRD

Natural resource endowment NRE

Ordinary Least Squares OLS

Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development OECD

Own permanent revenues OPR

Resource curse hypothesis RCH

Spatial autoregressive model SAR

Spatial error model SEM

Variable returns to scale VRS

xi

Statement of Original Authorship

The work contained in this thesis has not been previously submitted to meet requirements

for an award at this or any other higher education institution To the best of my knowledge and

belief the thesis contains no material previously published or written by another person except

where due reference is made

Signature QUT Verified Signature

Date _________04092020_________

xii

Acknowledgements

First I would like to thank my wife Lilian who joined me in this challenge and patiently

supported me all these years I would also like to thank our family who always supported us from

Chile I especially thank my sister Silvia who took care of our house and dog

I am also grateful to my supervisory team Dr Radhika Lahiri and Dr Vincent Hoang who

supported and guided me in the process of making this thesis a reality

I also thank the Deans of the Faculty of Economics and Business at my beloved University

of Talca Dr Arcadio Cerda and Dr Rodrigo Herrera who trusted me and supported me in this

process In the same way I would like to thank all the support of the director of the Commercial

Engineering career Mr Milton Inostroza

Finally I would like to thank the government of Chile for the financial support that made

my stay and studies possible here at the Queensland University of Technology

13

Chapter 1 Introduction

Efficiency and equity issues are often considered together in the evaluation of economic

performance While higher efficiency usually measured by growth rates of income per capita

correlates with improvements in measures of well-being the link between inequality and well-

being is less clear This is reflected not only in the type and amount of research related to efficiency

and equity but also in the role that both play in the design of the economic policy For instance

several market-oriented countries have focused primarily on economic growth trusting in a trickle-

down process where financial benefits given to the wealthy are expected to ultimately benefit the

poor However despite the growing interest in the issue of inequality there is a considerable lack

of studies about its consequences

Although some level of inequality is inevitable or even necessary for economic activity this

study is motivated by the argument that relatively high levels of inequality can be associated with

many problems such as persistent unemployment increasing fiscal expenses indebtedness and

political instability (Berg amp Ostry 2011) Inequality can also have other severe social

consequences including increased crime rates teenage pregnancy obesity and fewer

opportunities for low-income households to invest in health and education (Atkinson 2015) In

addition when the role of money and concentration of economic power undermine political

outcomes inequality of opportunities hampers social and economic mobility trust and social

cohesion In summary inequality can increase the fragility of the economic and social situation in

a country reducing economic growth and making it less inclusive and sustainable

14

A country well-known for its market-oriented economy and high level of dependence on

natural resources is Chile Chilean success in terms of economic growth contrasts with its inability

to reduce the persistently high levels of social and economic inequality particularly in the last

three decades Using data for the 2006-2017 period and considering 324 out of 345 Chilean

counties this thesis presents three essays with empirical evidence aiming to explain the

phenomenon of persistent income inequality and some of its potential consequences The first

essay aims to analyse how the evolution and variability of income inequality throughout the

country are associated with the degree of natural resource dependence The second essay studies

the relevance of income inequality in explaining cross-county differences in the performance of

local governments (municipalities) Finally the third essay explores the link between social

cohesion and community heterogeneity highlighting the importance of economic and racial

diversity

Income inequality and dependence on natural resources

The first essay explores how cross-county differences in income inequality are associated

with differences in the degree of dependence on natural resources We use the Gini coefficient in

each county as our dependent variable and the proportion of employment in the primary sector as

our measure of natural resource dependence The main hypothesis is that income inequality should

be positively related to the degree of natural resource dependence To test our hypothesis we use

a spatial econometric approach This approach is motivated by the study of Paredes Iturra and

Lufin (2016) who explore the geographic heterogeneity of income inequality in Chile finding

evidence of a significant spatial dimension

15

The theoretical and empirical literature has mostly proposed a positive link between

inequality and natural resources Although most of the evidence corresponds to cross-country

comparisons there is also increasing body of research at the local level A rationale underpinning

the positive link suggested in the literature is that in natural resource-rich countries ownership is

concentrated in small groups and extraction activities require low-skilled workers (Gylfason amp

Zoega 2003 Leamer Maul Rodriguez amp Schott 1999) Another market-based argument often

labelled as the ldquoDutch Diseaserdquo proposes that natural resource windfalls could be associated with

a crowding-out effect on the manufacturing sector (Corden amp Neary 1982 Easterly 2007) This

process encourages rent-seeking behaviours discourages investment in physical and human

capital and delays the process of technology adoption and industrialization (Auty 2001 Bulte

Damania amp Deacon 2005 Gylfason amp Zoega 2003) The result could be a lower economic

growth which is the central idea under the ldquoResource Curse Hypothesisrdquo (Auty 1993 Sachs amp

Warner 2001)

An ldquoinstitutionalrdquo argument for the positive association between inequality and the

endowment of natural resources is based on the so-called ldquoParadox of Plentyrdquo (Borge Parmer amp

Torvik 2015 Dauvin amp Guerreiro 2017) The idea is that both national and local authorities have

less incentive to operate efficiently when they experience windfalls in their revenues for

instance from natural resources This could end with corrupted authorities exerting patronage

clientelism and designing public policies to favour specific groups of the population (Uslaner amp

Brown 2005) Evidence also suggests that the final effect of natural resource booms on income

inequality will depend on authoritiesrsquo capacity to manage these additional resources the extent of

commuting and migration among regions and the potential increase in the demand for non-tradable

16

goods which are intensive in unskilled workers (Aroca amp Atienza 2011 Cust amp Poelhekke 2015

Fleming amp Measham 2015b Howie amp Atakhanova 2014 Michaels 2011)

Contrary to most theoretical and empirical evidence we find that income inequality shows

a robust and significant negative association with our proxy for natural resource dependence This

result suggests that the process of transformation to an economy less dependent on natural

resources could have exacerbated rather than alleviated the persistence of income inequality The

decrease in the participation of the primary sector in employment in favour mainly of the tertiary

sector highlights the importance of the latter to explain the current high levels of inequality and its

future evolution Another important result is that spatial linear models show practically the same

results as traditional linear models This could be interpreted as the spatial dimension previously

found in income inequality is not the result of spatial dependence in the variable itself for instance

due to a process of spillover among counties Hence the usually found positive spatial

autocorrelation of income inequality (similar levels in neighbouring counties) could be explained

by spatial patterns in other variables or to the spatial heterogeneity that characterizes the Chilean

economy

Local government efficiency and income inequality

Essay 2 delves deep into the potential trade-off between efficiency and equity We measure

the efficiency of Chilean municipalities which correspond to the organizations in charge of

managing each county Municipal efficiency is understood as ldquotechnical efficiencyrdquo that is the

possibility that each municipality has reached the same level of outputs with less use of inputs

Then we analyse how income inequality controlling for other contextual factors such as

socioeconomic demographic geographical and political characteristics may help to explain

17

differences in municipal performance Our main hypothesis is that municipal efficiency is

inversely associated with income inequality Moreover we seek a causal interpretation of this

relationship

Municipal performance could be influenced by income inequality in direct and indirect ways

In a direct sense income inequality is used to capture the degree of heterogeneity and complexity

in the demand for public services that citizens exert over local authorities Hence higher levels of

income inequality should be associated with a more complex set of public services and therefore

with lower levels of municipal efficiency (Jottier Ashworth amp Heyndels 2012) Furthermore

when high levels of inequality exist the richest groups can exert a higher influence over local

authorities resulting in low quality and quantity of services for most of the population Among

indirect effects high and persistent inequality could be the source of corrupted institutions and

local authorities favouring themselves or specific groups This undermines citizensrsquo participation

in civic activities and their willingness to monitor municipal performance (Uslaner amp Brown

2005) Additionally the potential benefits of decentralization on the way local governments

deliver public services will be limited when the context is characterized by corrupted politicians

and a limited administrative and financial capacity (Scott 2009)

We measure municipal efficiency using an input-oriented Data Envelopment Analysis

(DEA) to obtain efficiency scores for our sample of 324 municipalities in each year from 2006 to

2017 Then we study the influence on municipal efficiency of income inequality and our set of

contextual factors using a panel of six years corresponding to those years for which household

income information is available 2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017 Our dependent variable

is the set of efficiency scores which are relative measures of efficiency They are relative to the

18

municipalities included in the sample and they do not imply that higher technical efficiency gains

cannot be achieved Thus we use both cross-sectional and panel censored regression models To

tackle endogeneity issues and suggest a causal interpretation we also propose using the proportion

of firms in the primary sector as an instrument for income inequality

We find an average efficiency score of 83 meaning that Chilean municipalities could

reduce the use of inputs by 17 without reducing their outputs We also measure municipal

efficiency under different assumptions related to returns to scale This allows us to disaggregate

technical efficiency to assess whether inefficiencies are due to management issues (pure technical

efficiency) or scale issues (scale efficiency) Although the results show that most municipalities

operate under increasing or decreasing returns to scale scale inefficiencies only explain a small

proportion of total municipal inefficiencies This highlights the need to look for contextual factors

outside the control of local authorities to explain differences in municipal performance

Geographical representations of our results in terms of returns to scale and efficiency scores

show some spatial clustering process among municipalities Spatial statistics tests confirm that

efficiency scores show a significant positive spatial autocorrelation This means that neighbouring

municipalities tend to show similar levels of efficiency This similar performance could be due to

a process of spatial dependence (eg efficiency spillovers among neighbouring municipalities) or

due to the existence of structural-geographical similarities (spatial heterogeneity) To assess the

spatial dimension in municipal efficiency abstracting from temporal fluctuations we use a cross-

section of data consisting of the six-year average for the variables in our panel After running a

regression of efficiency scores against the set of controls the analysis of OLS residuals shows that

the spatial autocorrelation is almost completely removed This means that the spatial pattern in

19

municipal efficiency can be explained (controlled) by other variables such as regional indicator

variables rather than efficiency itself Given this result we proceed to study the influence of

income inequality on municipal efficiency using traditional (non-spatial) regression analysis

In contrast to literature that emphasizes an equity-efficiency trade-off (Andersen amp Maibom

2020 Berg amp Ostry 2011 Browning amp Johnson 1984 Okun 2015) that is greater equality leads

to lower efficiency we find that municipal efficiency is inversely associated with income

inequality This implies that more equal counties are also those with higher municipal efficiency

Furthermore the coefficient of income inequality is close to one when we use the instrumental

variable approach This means that a reduction in income inequality ceteris paribus should be

associated with an increase in the same magnitude in municipal efficiency This result has strong

policy implications The non-existence of the trade-off suggests that there is more to be gained by

targeting policies towards the reduction of inequality than conventional theories suggest For

instance these policies may help increase the levels of efficiency and well-being at least at the

municipal level

Social cohesion and economic diversity

The third essay studies the relationship between the degree of social cohesion and diversity

in Chile Extant literature has argued that one of the main factors influencing social cohesion is

the degree of economic and ethnic-racial diversity within a society This diversity erodes social

cohesion reducing trust and corrupting institutions (Letki 2008 Rothstein amp Uslaner 2005

Tolsma Van der Meer amp Gesthuizen 2009 Uslaner 2011 2013)

To measure social cohesion scholars have traditionally used measures of social capital trust

or feelings of insecurity (Ariely 2014 Chan To amp Chan 2006 Letki 2008) We suggest the use

20

of the rate of incivilities per 1000 inhabitants as a proxy for social cohesion Incivilities correspond

to those antisocial behaviours (eg groups of rowdy teens and public drunkenness) or visible

neighbourhood conditions (eg graffiti and abandoned buildings) that tend not to be treated as

crime Using the rate of incivilities is arguably a more objective and reliable measure of social

cohesion particularly in countries where institutions of order and security are among the most

trusted An increase in the rate of incivilities rather than changes in crime rates should better

capture the worsening in social cohesion experienced in countries such as Chile where crime rates

are not growing but social conflicts are on the rise Thus the main hypothesis in this essay is that

the rate of incivilities (social cohesion) should be positively (negatively) associated with economic

and racial diversity

Using panel count data models we start analysing how differences in incivilities rates

between and within counties are associated with differences in indicators of relative and absolute

economic disadvantage We use the Gini coefficient of each county as our measure of economic

diversity Although we find a significant and positive association between the rate of incivilities

and the level of income inequality the magnitude of the link seems to be small Among absolute

indicators of economic disadvantage only the level of income shows a strong effect Next we

include our measure of racial diversity We use the number of new visas granted to foreigners as

a proportion of the county population Results show a significant and strong positive association

between the rate of incivilities and racial diversity

To check the robustness of our results we analyse the impact of our measures of economic

and racial diversity running our models separately for each Chilean region and clustering them

geographically We also split the total number of incivilities in four categories to see which type

21

of incivilities show the greatest association with our measures of diversity In general results

support the ldquocommunity heterogeneity hypothesisrdquo that higher community heterogeneity is

associated with higher rates of incivilities (Alesina amp La Ferrara 2002 Letki 2008 Tolsma et al

2009) However results do not support the ldquoincivilities thesisrdquo that the distribution of incivilities

tends to mirror the distribution of income inequality (Skogan 1999 Taylor 1999)

Three results stand out among the set of control variables First the level of education shows

and independent and significant negative association with the rate of incivilities This is in contrast

to previous studies where education acts mainly as a moderator of the effect of economic and racial

diversity on social cohesion (Tolsma et al 2009) The results also show that there is no significant

relationship between the rate of incivilities and the proportion of young population This is relevant

because policies aimed to reduce incivilities usually put the focus on specific groups such as young

people which are linked to physical and social incivilities when social control is weakened

Finally the degree of financial municipal autonomy also shows a significant negative association

with the rate of incivilities This result suggests that municipalities can contribute independently

or together with the central government to reduce incivilities and strengthen social cohesion

Contributions

The three essays in this thesis provide several important insights into the analysis of the

causes and consequences of income inequality particularly in the context of Chile ndash a typical

resource rich economy with persistently high levels of income inequality

Essay 1 advances the understanding of the relationship between income inequality and

natural resources in Chile extending the empirical analysis from the regional level to the county

level In addition the geographic heterogeneity of income inequality is explored with the inclusion

22

of alternative sources of spatial dependence as a potential dimension of the causal relationship

between income inequality and natural resources This essay demonstrates the relevance of natural

resources in explaining the persistence of income inequality even after controlling for other

socioeconomics and institutional factors Findings from this study have potential contribution not

only in the design of policies aimed to reduce income inequality but also in addressing the current

developmental bias between the metropolitan region and the rest of the country

Essay 2 is one of the first studies that undertake a longitudinal analysis of the effects of

income inequality on the efficiency of municipal governments in Chile To capture the role of the

municipal governments in the provision to local people of public services such as education and

health we specify several inputs and outputs in our efficiency model which is different from the

conventional specification in the existing literature For example the number of medical

consultations in public health facilities and the number of enrolled students in public schools are

used as outputs instead of general indicators such as county population Our empirical analysis

also utilises a larger sample of municipalities and covers a much longer period spanning from 2006

to 2017 This essay also investigates the contextual factors beyond the control of local authorities

that can explain variations in the efficiency of municipal governments across the country

Empirical findings from Essay 2 help us increase our understanding of the production

technology of municipalities the sources of inefficiencies and specifically the impact of income

inequality on the performance of local authorities The results deliver two main policy

implications First municipal inefficiencies in the provision of public goods and services differ

across Chilean municipalities In addition efficiency levels show some degree of spatial

autocorrelation This implies that policies such as amalgamation or cooperation among

23

municipalities could have effects beyond the municipalities involved which must be considered

Second the causal effect that income inequality has on municipal efficiency provides another

dimension into the design and implementation of development policies

Essay 3 explores for the first time the effects of economic and racial diversity on social

cohesion in Chile This essay considers incivilities as manifestation of social cohesion and

investigates as extant literature suggests whether indicators of relative economic disadvantage

such as income inequality are among the main factors driving social disorganization and social

unrest Empirical findings suggest that on the one hand economic heterogeneity captured by the

Gini coefficient has a disparate effect both in terms of magnitude and significance on the rate of

incivilities across the country On the other hand the impact of racial heterogeneity appears to be

stronger more significant and of a similar magnitude throughout the country Results also provide

new insights into the design of national policies addressing social disorders particularly those

policies focussed on specific groups of the population and the role of local authorities Overall the

findings provide an opportunity to advance the understanding of the process of weakening in the

social cohesion experienced in Chile and the conflicts that have risen from this process

Thesis outline

The remainder of the thesis is organized as follows Chapter 2 presents essay 1 examining

the association between income inequality and the degree of dependence on natural resources

Chapter 3 presents essay 2 which looks for a causal relationship between municipal efficiency and

income inequality Chapter 4 presents essay 3 analysing the relationship between social cohesion

and economic and racial diversity Finally Chapter 5 presents some concluding remarks

24

Chapter 2 Natural Resources Curse or Blessing Evidence on

Income Inequality at the County Level in Chile

21 Introduction

A phenomenon of increasing inequality of incomes and wealth in recent decades has been

documented by leading scholars and international organizations such as the International Monetary

Fund (Berg amp Ostry 2017 Ostry Berg amp Tsangarides 2014) and the Organization for Economic

Cooperation and Development (Cingano 2014) These efforts have placed the topic of inequality

at the top of the current economic debate recognizing inequality as a determinant not only of

economic growth but also of human development They also have highlighted the necessity for

more research on the drivers of inequality and mechanisms through which it manifests aiming to

design effective policies in reducing economic and social inequalities

Various factors have been analysed as the sources of high and increasing levels of inequality

Among the most significant factors are the levels of income at initial stages of economic

development (Kuznets 1955) Globalization (Milanovic 2016) skill-biased technological change

(Tinbergen 1975) investment in human capital (Murphy amp Topel 2016) institutions

redistributive policy and country-specific characteristics (Acemoglu 1995 2002 Acemoglu

Aghion amp Violante 2001 Acemoglu Johnson amp Robinson 2001) Our focus in this essay is on

the importance that the natural resource endowment (NRE) or lack thereof can play in the

determination of income disparities

25

This essay studies the patterns and evolution of income inequality in the context of a natural

resource-rich country Using the case of the Chilean economy we aim to understand and

disentangle how a phenomenon of high- and persistent-income inequality is related to the

endowment of natural resources that a country owns Chile is an interesting case to study because

despite showing a successful history of economic growth inequality among individuals and among

aggregated spatial units has shown a strong persistence (Paredes et al 2016) Furthermore Chile

has remained among the most unequal countries in the world1

Theory and empirical evidence do not establish a clear link between income inequality and

NRE In addition NRE has received considerably less attention (Auty 2001 ElGindi 2017) and

most of the evidence has been focused on cross-country comparisons For instance NRE can

influence inequality by determining its initial levels (Engerman amp Sokoloff 1994 1997

Engerman Sokoloff Urquiola amp Acemoglu 2002) shaping the evolution of institutions

(Acemoglu 2002) make the educational system less intellectually challenging and moulding the

structure of economic activity (Leamer et al 1999) So studying how cross-county differences in

NRE are associated with the distribution of income within a country has theoretical empirical and

policy implications

In this study we offer empirical evidence on the relationship between income inequality and

the endowment of natural resources using data at the county level in Chile for the period 2006-

2017 Income inequality is measured by the Gini coefficient The importance of NRE is proxied

using a measure of natural resource dependence (NRD) defined as the percentage of the total

1 A 2014 OECD report on income inequality (httpwwwoecdorgsocialincome-distribution-databasehtm) showed Chile as the country with the highest Gini coefficient of disposable income among OECD countries OECD also indicates Chile as the country with the widest gap between the richest 10 percent and the poorest 10 percent of countryrsquos population among its 34 members (OECD 2014)

26

employment in each county corresponding to the primary sector (agriculture forestry fishing and

mining)

The main hypothesis to be tested is whether income inequality is positively associated with

the degree of NRD The transmission mechanisms through which natural resources could influence

socioeconomic outcomes could be based on the market or institutions The market-based approach

argues that natural resource booms could be associated with an appreciation of the real exchange

rate and a crowding out effect over other more productive economic activities such as

manufacturing It could also delay the adoption of new technologies and reduce incentives to invest

in physical and human capital (Gylfason amp Zoega 2003) Based on the ldquoResource Curse

Hypothesisrdquo (RCH) natural resources could be a curse when the political and institutional

framework is weak and natural resources are concentrated in space such as oil and minerals

(Deacon 2011) 2 Among institutional channels a higher NRD or natural resource booms could

be associated with rent seeking misallocation of labour and entrepreneurial talent institutional

and political decline or even violent conflicts For instance the ldquoParadox of Plentyrdquo sustains that

windfalls of revenues as a consequence of resource booms could be related to a lack of incentives

to perform efficiently corruption patronage and local authorities favouring their voters or being

captured by the richest groups (Dauvin amp Guerreiro 2017) Hence a higher NRD or natural

resource booms could be the explanation not only for low levels of growth in regions more

dependent on natural resources but also it could be the root of income disparities

2 There is a wide strand of research on the Resource Curse Hypothesis however the evidence so far is not conclusive Evidence in favour of RCH has been mainly found in developing resource rich countries (Auty 1993 2001 Badeeb Lean amp Clark 2017 Blanco amp Grier 2012 Borge et al 2015 Brunnschweiler amp Bulte 2008 Sachs amp Warner 2001 Van der Ploeg 2011)

27

To test our hypothesis that is whether the levels of income inequality across counties are

positively associated with the degree of NRD we use a spatial econometric approach We use this

approach because attributes such as income inequality in one region may not be independent of

attributes in neighbouring regions (Armstrong amp Taylor 2000) This process of spatial dependence

invalidates the use of traditional (non-spatial) approaches

This study seeks to make two contributions to research First previous empirical evidence

shows a significant spatial dimension of income inequality in Chile (Paredes et al 2016)

However this dimension has been barely explored with most studies limiting the degree of

disaggregation to a regional scale (Aroca amp Bosch 2000) We use a spatial approach which makes

it possible to model and test the significance of the spatial dimension in the analysis of income

inequality and its relationship with other variables Second previous research for the Chilean

economy linking inequality with NRE has been mainly focused on explaining differences between

regions or the importance and effects of the mining-copper sector (Aroca amp Atienza 2011 Ebert

amp La Menza 2015 Lagos amp Blanco 2010 Rehner Baeza amp Barton 2014) We extend this

analysis using data for local economies Identifying and quantifying the impact of NRE on income

inequality at the county level is likely to be more informative for policies aiming to address the

current developmental bias between the metropolitan region and the rest of the country Moreover

the analysis of the role of natural resources in conjunction with other potential sources of inequality

may shed lights in understanding the persistence of the high levels of inequality observed in the

Chilean economy All in all this study could contribute to the design of policies that

simultaneously help reduce inequality increase efficiency and promote sustainable and inclusive

growth

28

Our main finding shows that after controlling for other potential sources of income

inequality such as educational level demographic characteristics and the level of public

government expenditure the degree of dependence on natural resources has a significant effect on

income inequality However contrary to our expectations the effect is negative This result

suggests that the natural or policy-driven process of transformation from primary and extractive

activities to manufacturing and service sectors imposes additional challenges to central and local

authorities aiming to reduce income inequality

In section 22 we review the literature on the relationship between income inequality and

natural resources In section 23 we establish our research problem and main hypothesis Section

24 describes our data and methods and section 25 the empirical results We finish with section

26 discussing our main results concluding and proposing avenues for future research

22 Inequality and Natural Resources

221 Theoretical Framework

Explanations for income inequality can be associated with individual institutional political

and contextual characteristics Individual characteristics include age gender and mainly the level

of education and skills of the population in the labour force For instance globalization and

technological change lead firms to increase the demand for skilled labour deepening income

inequality between skilled and unskilled workers (Atkinson 2015 Milanovic 2016 Tinbergen

1975) Among institutional characteristics labour unions collective bargaining and the minimum

wage have been suggested as explanations of income inequality (Acemoglu Aghion et al 2001

Atkinson 2015) Policy design associated with market regulation progressive taxation and

redistribution can also impact the levels and patterns of inequality

29

A key factor in understanding the levels and differences in income distribution within a

country may be its endowment of natural resources NRE shapes the structure of the economy

(Leamer et al 1999) it is associated with the creation of institutions that define the political

culture and it can also influence the performance of other sectors (Watkins 1963) In addition

NRE determines initial conditions market competition ownership over resources rent seeking

and the geographical concentration of the population and economic activity

Cross‐countryliterature

Bourguignon and Morrison (1990) introduce one of the earliest theoretical frameworks

describing the relationship between inequality and NRE They develop a small open economy

model where income distribution is a function of NRE ownership structure and trade protection

Giving cross-sectional evidence for a group of developing countries they conclude that the impact

of NRE particularly mineral resources and land depends on the number and size of the firms

whether they are public or private and the level of protection A higher concentration of production

in a few private firms a big share of production oriented to foreign instead of domestic markets

and protection increasing the relative price of scarce resources are some of the reasons explaining

why some countries are less egalitarian than others

NRE could also influence the evolution and levels of inequality by determining the initial

distribution of incomes This is known as the ldquoEngerman-Sokoloff Hypothesisrdquo (Engerman amp

Sokoloff 1997 Engerman et al 2002) In addition Leamer (1999) proposes that inequality and

development paths in each economy are a function of its economic structure which in turn depends

on ldquofundamentalsrdquo and ldquosymptomsrdquo On the one hand ldquofundamentalsrdquo refer to resource

endowment production structure closeness to markets and governments interventions On the

30

other hand ldquosymptomsrdquo are related to institutions employment structure and net export structure

Using this conceptual framework Leamer argues that natural Resource-Rich Countries (RRC) can

experience a higher level of inequality because can have a ldquodumbbell educational systemrdquo

ownership is concentrated in small groups and extraction activities require low-skilled workers

This implies fewer incentives to educate citizens until very late in the development process

resulting in human capital not prepared to take advantage of the process of technological progress

and delaying the emergence of more efficient and competitive sectors such as manufacturing and

services

Using 1980 and 1990 data for a group of countries classified according to land abundance

Leamer (1999) provides evidence showing that on the one hand land-scarce countries concentrate

their production and employment in sectors that promote equality such as capital-intensive

manufacturing chemical or machinery On the other hand countries abundant in natural resources

concentrate their production trade or employment in sectors that promote income inequality such

as the production of food beverages extraction activities or forestry

Gylfason and Zoega (2003) using a framework based on standard growth models also

proposed a positive relationship between NRE and inequality They assume that workers can work

in the primary sector or in the manufacturing (including services) sector In addition wage income

is equally distributed in the manufacturing sector but unequally in the primary sector (because of

initial distribution competition rent seeking etc) Therefore inequality will be greater when a

bigger proportion of labour is dedicated to extraction activities in the primary sector This

phenomenon is further amplified because of lower incentives to invest in physical and human

capital to adopt new technologies and to increase the share of the manufacturing sector

31

Diverse mechanisms explaining the link between NRE and inequality have been proposed

arguing that NRE determines simultaneously economic growth and inequality (Gylfason amp Zoega

2003) NRE could impact economic growth through the real exchange rate and the crowding-out

effect on manufacturing (ldquoDutch Diseaserdquo) reducing incentives to invest in physical and human

capital (Easterly 2007) and influencing the processes of technology adoption industrialization

and diversification of the economy in a manner that is less conducive to growth (Bulte et al 2005)

These potential explanations related to the called ldquoResource Curse Hypothesisrdquo do not have strong

empirical support (Auty 2001 Bulte et al 2005)

NRE may also influence economic growth through the quality of institutions (Acemoglu

1995 Acemoglu Aghion et al 2001 Acemoglu amp Robinson 2002 Engerman amp Sokoloff 1997

Engerman et al 2002) the concentration of ownership political power and rent-seeking NRE

acts by shaping institutional context and social infrastructure a phenomenon that is stronger when

resources are spatially concentrated such as minerals and plantations (Bulte et al 2005) NRE

could also have a significant effect on social cohesion and instability spreading its influence like

a disease (Brunori Ferreira amp Peragine 2013 Kanbur amp Venables 2005 Milanovic 2016

Ocampo 2004)

Considering a non-tradable sector intensive in unskilled workers Goderis and Malone

(2011) develop a model where the natural resources sector experiences an exogenous gift of

resource income They analyse the impact over income inequality of resource booms proxied by

changes in a commodity price index They conclude that inequality decreases in the short run but

increases after the initial reduction

32

Fum and Hodler (2010) show that natural resources increase inequality but this is

conditional on the level of ethnical polarization of society Carmignani (2013 2010) confirms this

positive relationship using different measures of dependence and abundance and goes further

arguing that inequality constitutes an indirect channel through which NRE affects human

development

Singlecountryevidence

Most of the studies about the relationship between inequality and NRE derive from cross-

country analyses Evidence for specific countries has been mainly based on case studies Howie

and Atakhanova (2014) based on the model of Goderis and Malone (2011) find for the case of

Kazakhstan that income and consumption inequality decreased significantly after booms in the oil-

and-gas sector because of resource booms increase the demand for non-tradable goods which are

intensive in unskilled workers The results depend on the level of rurality institutional quality

education levels and public spending on health and education Fleming and Measham (2015b

2015a) evaluate the impact of booms in the mining and oil sectors in Australia They find that a

boom in the mining sector increases income inequality due to commuting and migration among

regions This phenomenon can be exacerbated when the demanding access to natural resource

revenues is associated with the creation of more local administrative units (counties provinces and

even regions) but the government capacity is not simultaneously improved (Cust amp Poelhekke

2015 Michaels 2011) Furthermore the benefits that a region can receive in the form of fiscal

transfers can be more than compensated by the loses due to city-to-mine commuting such as the

case of mining regions in Chile (Aroca amp Atienza 2011)

33

Other studies at the local level have analysed the impact of the mining sector in Peru (Aragoacuten

amp Rud 2013 Loayza amp Rigolini 2016 Loayza Teran amp Rigolini 2013) Spain (Domenech

2008) and Canada (Papyrakis amp Raveh 2014) and the effects of oil windfalls in Brazil (Caselli amp

Michaels 2013)

In summary there is a wide range of potential mechanisms through which NRE could

influence income inequality Although most of them seem to suggest a positive relationship others

such as commuting and increased within-county demand for non-tradable goods and services

could lead to a negative association This highlights the need to know the sign of this association

in the Chilean economy where the trend shows a reduction in the degree of NRD After controlling

for other factors a positive link would support the argument that the reduction in the degree of

NRD has been relevant in the reduction experienced by income inequality in the same period

However a negative link would support the position that the reduction in NRD has contributed to

explain the persistence of income inequality and its slow reduction

222 The relevance of the spatial approach

Inequalities within countries are still the most important form of inequality from the political

point of view (Milanovic 2016) People from a geographic area within a country are influenced

and care most about their status relative to the people in other areas in the same country The

influence among regions involves multiple aspects (eg economic political and environmental)

These potential interactions have been traditionally ignored assuming independence among

observations related to different regions Moreover neglecting the process of spatial interaction in

key indicators of the economic and social performance of a country may mislead the design of the

public policy

34

The spatial dimension could play a significant role in understanding the distribution of

income within a country One strand of efforts aiming to capture the geographic heterogeneity of

inequality has been focussed on decomposing general indicators such as the Gini coefficient or the

Theil Index Evidence for different countries including the US (Doran amp Jordan 2016) China

(Akita 2003 Gustafsson amp Shi 2002 Ye Ma Ye Chen amp Xie 2017 Yue Zhang Ye Cheng

amp Leipnik 2014) Japan (Ohtake 2008) South Africa (Leibbrandt Finn amp Woolard 2012) and

Chile (Paredes et al 2016) shows that regional inequality is sensitive to the geographic scale of

analysis These studies also show a significant spatial component in the explanation of inequality

of income expenditure or gross domestic product for each country

Another strand explicitly uses exploratory spatial data analysis (ESDA) and spatial

econometrics ESDA has been used to provide new insights about the nature of regional disparities

of incomes and growth rates (Celebioglu amp Dallrsquoerba 2010 Yue et al 2014) Spatial econometric

models aim to assess and address the nature of the spatial effects These effects could be the result

of ldquospatial heterogeneityrdquo that is different relationships in distinct locations or ldquospatial

dependencerdquo which implies cross-sectional interactions (spillover effects) among units from

distinct but near locations

Spatial spillovers have been analysed to study both positive and negative spatial correlation

among less resource-abundant counties and resource-abundant counties On the one hand less

resource-abundant counties may experience positive spillovers because their industries supply

more goods and services to meet the increasing regional demand They can also be benefited from

positive agglomeration externalities and higher investment in private and public infrastructure

(Allcott amp Keniston 2014 Michaels 2011) On the other hand negative spillovers could be the

35

result of a high degree of interregional migration that limits the rise in wages and higher local

prices due to the increase in the share of the non-tradable sector In addition local governments

could have a limited capacity to translate the revenues from resource booms into effective public

policies promoting a sustained local development (Beine Coulombe amp Vermeulen 2015 Caselli

amp Michaels 2013 Papyrakis amp Raveh 2014)

23 Research problem and hypotheses

We can conclude from our overview of the literature that the theoretical and empirical

evidence about the link between inequality and natural resources is inconclusive This does not

make clear whether the process of reduction in the degree of dependence on natural resources

such as that experienced by the Chilean economy helps to explain the sustained but slow reduction

in income inequality or its high persistence

The research question guiding this study relates to how the natural resource endowment

determines the paths and structure of income inequality in natural resource-rich countries Using

the case of Chile the main hypotheses to be tested is whether a higher degree of dependence on

natural resources is associated with higher levels of income inequality To do that we use data at

the county level and we explicitly include the spatial dimension Our aim is to arrive at a more

comprehensive understanding of the drivers and transmission mechanisms explaining the

evolution and patterns shown by income inequality In addition we test whether the spatial

dimension plays a significant role in explaining differences in income distribution in Chile

36

24 Data and Methods

We use county-level data for the years 2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017 The reason

for not using contiguous years is that income data at the household level are only available every

two-three years from the Chilean National Socioeconomic Characterization Survey (CASEN in its

Spanish acronym)3 For the period 2006-2017 the Chilean administrative division considers 15

regions 54 provinces and 346 counties Data on income are available for 324 counties and six

years resulting in a panel with 1944 observations4

We start evaluating the spatial dimension in our data and analysing the link between

inequality and NRD using a cross-sectional setting To this end we use the ldquosix-year averagerdquo

(2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017) for our variables given the low time variability showed by

our measures of income inequality and NRD Results are then compared with those of a panel data

setting

241 Operationalization of key variables

The dependent variable in the present study income inequality at the county level is

measured calculating the Gini coefficient using three definitions of household income labour

autonomous and monetary income5 Labour income corresponds to the incomes obtained by all

members in the household excluding domestic service consisting of wages and salaries earnings

3 CASEN survey is conducted by the Chilean Ministry of Social Development covering topics such as education employment income and health CASEN is considered nationally representative and it is the main source for measures of inequality and poverty used for the design and evaluation of social policies in Chile 4 The six waves of CASEN for our study considered an average of 75599 households and 252081 individuals 5 The Gini coefficient is chosen because provides an overall estimate of income inequality It summarizes what proportion of the population gains what proportion of the total income The Gini coefficient can range between 0 (everyone in the population has the same income) and 1 (one person earns 100 per cent of the income in the community)

37

from independent work and self-provision of goods Autonomous income is the sum of labour

income and non-labour income (including capital income) consisting of rents interest and dividend

earnings pension healthcare benefits and other private transfers Finally monetary income is

defined as the sum of autonomous income and monetary subsidies which correspond to cash

transfers by the public sector through social programs Appendix A shows summary statistics for

the Gini coefficient of our three measures of income

The main independent variable in our study is the degree of dependence on natural resources

in each county To have an idea of the importance of each economic activity in the Chilean

economy particularly those activities related to natural resources Figure 21 shows their average

share in Chilean Gross Domestic Product (GDP) for the period 2006-17 We can observe that the

leading activities are those related to the primary sector especially mining and to the tertiary

sector where financial personal commerce restaurants and hotels services stand out The shares

of each economic activity in GDP vary significantly between Chilean regions and such

information is not available at the county level

Figure 21 Average share in GDP of economic activities (2006ndash17)

38

Leamer (1999) argues that when the main source of income is labour income (as indeed

happens for the Chilean case) using employment shares allows a better approach to measuring

dependence on natural resources Using employment data from CASEN survey we define our

measure of NRD as the employment in the primary sector (mining fishing forestry and

agriculture) as a percentage of the total employment in each county We name this variable

pss_casen where ldquopssrdquo stands for ldquoprimary sector sharerdquo We built other two proxies of NRD

using data from the ldquoServicio de Impuestos Internosrdquo (SII) which is the agency in charge of

collecting taxes in Chile The variable pss measures the percentage of employment in the primary

sector and the variable pss_firms measures the number of firms in the primary sector as a

percentage of the total number of firms in each county Appendix B shows summary statistics for

our three measures of NRD disaggregated by region

Figure 22 Evolution of Gini coefficient and measures of NRD (2006ndash17)

39

Figure 22 shows the evolution of our measure of inequality (using the Gini coefficient of

autonomous income) and our three potential proxies for NRD for the period 2006-2017 We

observe that both income inequality and the degree of NRD show a downward trend This seems

to support our hypothesis of a positive link between inequality and NRD however we need to

control of other sources of inequality before getting such a conclusion In what follows we use the

variable gini as our measure of income inequality capturing the Gini coefficient of autonomous

income Our measure of NRD is the variable pss_casen defined previously

Figure 23 Spatial distribution of Gini coefficient and NRD (2006ndash17)

Note Gini and NRD averages 2006-09-11-13-15-17 for 324 Chilean counties divided into five equal groups Source Own elaboration based on CASEN survey

40

Figure 23 shows quantile maps for income inequality (on the left) and NRD (on the right)

using the six-years average dataset6 On the one hand we observe that high levels of inequality

seem to be clustered in the Centre-South of the country where agriculture forestry and fishery are

the predominant economic activities Only isolated counties show high inequality in the Centre

(Metropolitan area where the countyrsquos capital is located) and North (Mining) areas On the other

hand our measure of NRD seems to show an opposite spatial pattern than income inequality with

high levels in the Centre and North of the country

242 Control variables

To control for county characteristics we use a set of socio-economic demographic and

institutional variables Economic factors are captured by the natural log of the mean autonomous

household income per capita (in thousands of Chilean pesos of 2017) lnincome the poverty rate

poverty the unemployment rate unemployment the percentage of the population living in rural

areas rural and the average years of education of the population over 15 years old education

Demographic factors include the proportion of the population in the labour force labour_force

and the natural log of population density (population divided by county area) lndensity

We also include the natural log of the total municipal public expenditure per capita

lnmuni_expenditure to control for municipal heterogeneity This heterogeneity is mainly related

to the capacity of municipalities to generate their own revenues In addition the richest

municipalities are in the Metropolitan region which concentrates economic power and around 40

6 After sorting a variable in ascending order quantile maps use the quantiles (quartiles quintiles deciles etc) as class breaks to divide the distribution of the variable where each class includes approximately the same number of observations (counties)

41

of the population This has basically implied a lag in the development of regions other than the

metropolitan region

The spatial distribution of our measures of income inequality and NRD displayed in Figure

23 seems to show different patterns in the North Centre and South of the country Appendix C

shows the administrative division of Chile in 15 regions and how we have grouped them in three

zones North Centre and South We consider as the ldquoCentrerdquo area that formed by the Metropolitan

region (XIII) and its two neighbouring regions V and VI Using the Centre area as our reference

we include in our analysis two dummy variables indicating whether a county is located in the North

area (regions XV I II III and IV) or South area (regions VII VIII IX XIV X XI and XII)

Appendix D shows summary statistics for the set of numeric control variables and the

correlation matrix between our measure of NRD pss_casen and the set of numeric controls

243 Methods

To assess and then consider the spatial nature of the data we need to define the set of relevant

neighbours for each country This is operationalized by building a matrix called ldquoWrdquo with a ldquo1rdquo

for neighbouring counties and a ldquo0rdquo for non-neighbouring counties We could build W using

contiguity-based (whether counties share a border or point) or geography-based (taking the

distances among the centroids of each county polygon) spatial weights Specifically we build a W

matrix considering the 5-nearest counties7 Two reasons explain the choice of k-nearest

neighbours First we cannot use a contiguity criterium because we do not have information about

all the counties and there are some geographically isolated counties Second given the significant

7 We assign a ldquo1rdquo to the five nearest counties to each county based on the distances among the polygon centroids Then W is ldquorow standardizedrdquo This facilitates the interpretation of the spatial lag of a variable as the ldquoweighted average valuerdquo of the same variable in neighbouring counties

42

differences in county areas (ldquobig countiesrdquo in northern and southern regions) using a distance-

band criterium with a not enough large distance band can lead to many ldquoislandsrdquo in extreme regions

and a multi-modal distribution for the number of neighbours

We start testing our inequality and NRD variables for spatial autocorrelation in order to

evaluate statistically the clustering patterns shown in Figure 23 Next we run an OLS regression

of inequality against NRD and our set of controls and we test the spatial autocorrelation of OLS

residuals If we cannot reject the null hypothesis of random spatial distribution we do not need

spatial models to analyse income inequality which would give contrasting evidence to previous

suggestions about the relevance of the spatial dimension of income inequality in Chile (Paredes

2013 Paredes et al 2016) If we find significant spatial autocorrelation in the OLS residuals this

justifies the use of spatial models and highlight the need to find the correct spatial structure8

If inequality in one county spillovers or influences inequality in neighbouring counties the

spatial lag of inequality should be included as an explanatory variable and we should use a spatial

autoregressive model (SAR) If some unobserved variable is the explanation for the clustering of

counties with similar inequality then this will be better captured including a spatial lag of the

errors and we should use a spatial error model (SEM) (Anselin 1988 Anselin amp Bera 1998)

Finally when our main explanatory variable or some of the controls show spatial autocorrelation

a spatial lag of the explanatory variable(s) should be included in our model

8 The existence of spatial autocorrelation violates the standard assumption of independence among observations needed for OLS regression This will result in OLS coefficients biased and inconsistent (Anselin 1988)

43

244 Spatial Model Specification

A model that includes the three forms of spatial dependence described above is called the

Cliff-Ord Model The model in its cross-sectional representation could be expressed as

119910 120582119882119910 119883120573 119882119883120574 119906 (21)

where

119906 120588119882119906 120576 (22)

119882 is our weight matrix that works as an NxN spatial lag operator9 Thus 119882119910 119882119883 and 119882119906

are the spatial lags for the dependent variable explanatory variables and the error term

respectively The parameter 120582 capture the spatial dependence in the dependent variable 120574 the

spatial dependence in the explanatory variables 120588 capture the spatial dependence in the error term

and 120598 is a vector of idiosyncratic errors For instance if ldquoyrdquo is income inequality and ldquoXrdquo a measure

of NRD the level of inequality in one county will be explained by the degree of NRD in the same

county 119883120573 the average degree of NRD in neighbouring counties 119882119883120574 the average level of

inequality in neighbouring counties 120582119882119910 and the average value of residuals in neighbouring

counties 12058811988211990610

From equations (21) and (22) the SAR and SEM models can be seen as special cases of

the Cliff-Ord representation after imposing restrictions over the spatial parameters 120582 120574 and 120588 For

the specification of the spatial panel models we follow the terminology by Croissant and Millo

9 The spatial lag is a weighted sum of the values observed at neighbouring locations 10 On the one hand the impact that income inequality in one county has over income inequality in neighbouring counties is called a ldquoglobal spilloverrdquo and it is associated with the feedback effect among neighbours (one county is its neighboursrsquo neighbourrdquo) on the other hand the influence that the degree of NRD in neighbouring counties has over inequality in one county is called a ldquolocal spilloverrdquo

44

(2018) Spatial panel models including the spatial lag of the dependent variable (SAR) the spatial

lag of the residuals (SEM) or both (SARAR) are described in Appendix E

25 Results

251 Exploratory Spatial Data Analysis (ESDA)

To analyse the significance of the spatial dimension in our data set we use the six-year

average of our variables Spatial autocorrelation is tested using the Moranrsquos I statistic11 Moranrsquos

I measures the correlation of one variable with itself in space12 Figure 24 shows the Moran scatter

plots where the standardized variable (Gini coefficient and NRD for each county) appears in the

horizontal axis against its spatial lag (average value in the 5-nearest neighbouring counties) The

Moranrsquos I (slope of the line in the Moran scatter plot) of income inequality shows a significant

positive spatial autocorrelation that is counties with high (low) inequality tend to be close to each

other

11 There are many statistics to formally test the significance of the spatial dimension in the distribution of our data The null hypothesis assumes spatial randomness which means that there is not spatial structure in the data so any spatial pattern is equally likely to occur and values in one location do not depend on values in other locations The alternative hypotheses can be the existence of positive or negative spatial autocorrelation Positive spatial autocorrelation means similar values in neighbouring locations (less variability than under spatial randomness) Negative spatial autocorrelation means dissimilar values in neighbouring locations (more variability than under spatial randomness) 12 Traditional measures of correlation such as the Pearsonrsquos coefficient measure the degree of linear correlation between two different variables Measures of spatial autocorrelation assess the correlation between the values of one variable in one location related to the values of the same variable in other neighbouring locations

45

Figure 23 Moran scatter plots for variables gini and pss_casen

Moranrsquos I is a measure of global spatial autocorrelation this means it is intended to capture

the clustering property of the entire data set To identify where are the significant hot-spots

(clusters of counties showing high income inequality) or cold-spots (clusters of counties showing

low income inequality) we need local indicators of spatial association (LISA) Using the local

Moranrsquos I (not reported) we find significant hot-spots in the South of the country (mainly

agricultural regions) and significant cold-spots in the Centre (Metropolitan area) of the country

The next step is to check whether the clustering pattern in inequality is the result of a process of

spatial dependence in the variable itself or it can be explained by other variables related to

inequality

252 Cross-sectional analysis

We start analysing differences in income inequality between counties using the six-year

average data and running an OLS regression for the model

119892119894119899119894 120573 120573 119901119904119904_119888119886119904119890119899 120573 119897119899119894119899119888119900119898119890 120573 119901119900119907119890119903119905119910 120573 119906119899119890119898119901119897119900119910119898119890119899119905 120573 119897119886119887119900119906119903_119891119900119903119888119890 120573 119890119889119906119888119886119905119894119900119899 120573 119897119899119889119890119899119904119894119905119910 120573 119903119906119903119886119897 120573 119897119899119898119906119899_119890119909119901119890119899119889119894119905119906119903119890 120573 119899119900119903119905ℎ 120573 119904119900119906119905ℎ

(23)

46

The Moran scatter plot and spatial statistical test of OLS residuals from equation (23) are

in Appendix F OLS residuals show a small but significant positive autocorrelation (Moranrsquos I =

0121) This means that income inequality continues showing a significant degree of spatial

autocorrelation after controlling for the set of covariates In addition robust Lagrange Multiplier

(LM) tests show that a spatial error model is preferred over a spatial lag model (Anselin Bera

Florax amp Yoon 1996)13 This means that income inequality tends to cluster in zones larger than a

county so the analysis should be performed on a larger scale such as provinces regions or macro

zones If the SAR model were preferred it would mean that income inequality in one county is

influenced by the level of income inequality in neighbouring counties To find the spatial structure

that best fits the clustering process of income inequality we run the full set of spatial model

specifications in a cross-sectional setting and results are shown in Table 21

Column 2 in Table 21 shows the results of our ldquoOLSrdquo model The ldquoSLXrdquo model includes

spatial dependence only through the explanatory variables The ldquoSARrdquo model includes the spatial

lag of the dependent variable as a regressor and the ldquoSEMrdquo model includes spatial dependence

through the error term The ldquoSARARrdquo model includes both the spatial lag of the response and the

errors and the ldquoSDMrdquo and ldquoSDEMrdquo are the extensions of the ldquoSARrdquo and ldquoSEMrdquo models

respectively including the spatial lag of the explanatory variables Finally a model including

spatial lags for the response errors and explanatory variables (the ldquoSARARXrdquo model) is shown in

the last column

13 Following the ldquoAnselin methodrdquo when both non robust LM tests are significant we should select between the robust LR tests From Table F1 in Appendix F only the robust LM test for the SEM model (RLMerr) appears as significant

47

Table 21

Cross-sectional Model Comparison (six-year average data)

48

Opposite to our hypothesis we observe a significant and negative coefficient for our measure

of NRD This means that counties more dependent on natural resources show lower levels of

inequality Education years population density and municipal expenditure per capita are also

negatively related to inequality On the other hand the level of income the poverty rate and the

proportion of the population living in rural areas show a positive relationship with income

inequality There is no significant influence of the unemployment rate and the proportion of the

population in the labour force In addition the SAR SEM and SARAR models show a

significantly higher average inequality in the South of the country related to the Centre area

The main finding from our cross-sectional analysis is that there is a significant and negative

relationship between inequality and NRD which is quite robust to the model specification

253 Panel Data analysis

Like the cross-sectional case we start estimating the panel without spatial effects Results

for the pooled fixed effects (FE) and random effects (RE) specifications of equation (3) are in

Appendix G Spatial models were estimated using Maximum Likelihood (ML) and Generalized

Moments (GM) and assuming that the spatial structure (W matrix) is the same for all years14

Tables 22 23 and 24 show results for the ML estimation of the SAR SEM and SARAR models

using the pooled FE and RE specifications Results for the GM estimation are in Appendix H

All our spatial models include time fixed effects In the case of the pooled and RE models they

additionally include indicator variables for those counties located in the North and South of the

country

14 In traditional (non-spatial) panels data are stacked as time series for each observational unit (county) In the case of spatial panels data are stacked as slice of cross-sections for each year in the panel

49

The main result is that the negative and significant effect of NRD on income inequality is

robust to most of the spatial panel specifications In addition the coefficient for the variable

pss_casen changes slightly among panel specifications (pooled FE and RE) but does not change

among spatial models (SAR SEM and SARAR)

Another important finding is related to the significance of the spatial dimension of income

inequality When spatial models cross-sectional or panel are compared to non-spatial models

there are no major differences in the magnitude of the coefficients or their significance This could

mean that the positive spatial autocorrelation shown by income inequality seems to be better

explained by a process of spatial heterogeneity rather than spatial dependence The practical

implication of this result is that including dummy variables for aggregated units (eg regions or

groups of regions) could be enough to control for the spatial dimension in the modelling and

analysis of income inequality

Among control variables years of education seems to be the main variable for the design of

long-term policies aimed at reducing inequality This result is in line with previous evidence for

cross-country studies (Leamer et al 1999) and specific countries (Howie amp Atakhanova 2014)

Municipal expenditure per capita also shows a significant and negative association with income

inequality in the pooled and RE spatial specifications This means that higher municipal

expenditure helps to reduce inequality between counties but its effect is more limited within

counties This result support the importance of local governments (Fleming amp Measham 2015a)

however the negative coefficient appears as evidence against the ldquoParadox of Plentyrdquo (Borge et

al 2015)

50

Table 22

ML Spatial SAR Models

Table 23

ML Spatial SEM Models

51

Table 24

ML Spatial SARAR Models

26 Discussion and conclusions

In this essay we delve deep into the sources of income inequality analysing its association

with the degree of dependence on natural resources using county-level data for the 2006ndash2017

period in Chile Given recent evidence for the Chilean economy suggesting a significant spatial

dimension we assess and incorporate explicitly the spatial structure of income inequality using

spatial methods We use cross-sectional and panel data to evaluate the significance of the spatial

dimension and we test whether NRD has a positive effect on income inequality

Contrary to what theory predicts NRD shows a significant and negative association with

income inequality This result is robust to the type of analysis (cross-sectional vs panel data) the

approach (spatial vs non-spatial) and the inclusion of different controls The negative and

significant coefficient implies that if the degree of NRD would not have experienced a 10 drop

during this period income inequality could have fallen in 2 additional points So the downward

trend in the participation of the primary sector in terms of employment in the Chilean economy

52

could be one of the main reasons explaining the high persistence in the levels of income inequality

This means that those areas that undergo a process of productive transformation mainly towards

the services sector would be facing greater problems to reduce inequality This process of

productive transformation natural or policy-driven highlights the importance of policies focused

on human capital and the role of local governments in reducing inequality

The main implication for policymakers is that a reduction in NRD does not help to reduce

inequality generating additional challenges for local and central governments in its attempt to

transform the structure of their economies to fewer dependent ones on natural resources The

finding of a significant spatial dimension suggests that defining macro zones capturing the spatial

heterogeneity in the data should be done before analysing the relationship among variables and the

design and evaluation of specific policies Particularly relevant in those areas experiencing a

reduction in NRD are migration commuting and the characteristics of the tertiary (services) sector

In addition our findings show that education and municipal expenditure could be effective policy

tools in the fight to reduce inequality in Chile

Although our results seem quite robust they do not allow us to make causal inferences about

the effect of NRD on income inequality However we could think of the following explanation to

explain the negative relationship found and the differences between geographical areas

Areas highly dependent on NR used to demand a high proportion of low-skill labour This

has change in sectors such as the mining sector in the northern area which has simultaneously

experienced an increase in activities related to the service sector such as retail restaurants

transport and housing However those services associated with more skilled labour such as the

finance sector remain concentrated in the capital region The reduction in the degree of NRD

(employment in extractive activities) implies lower labour force but more specialized with most

53

of the low-skilled labour transferred to a service sector characterized by low productivity and low

wages

Non-spatial models show that the North and South particularly the latter present

significantly higher levels of inequality This could be associated with the type of resources with

ldquopointrdquo resources such as minerals in the North and ldquodiffusedrdquo resources such as agriculture in the

South This translates into higher average incomes in the Centre and North areas and lower average

incomes in the South

The reduction in NRD implies not only a movement of the labour force from extractive

activities to manufacturing or services with the latter characterized by low productivity and low

salaries of the labour force We could also speculate that most of the high incomes move to the

central area where the economic power and ownership over firms and resources are concentrated

This would explain low inequality associated with higher average incomes in the central area and

high inequality associated with lower average incomes in the South A more in-depth analysis

capturing the mobility of wealth and labour force between counties or more aggregated areas is

needed to better understand the causal mechanism involved

Our findings open avenues for future research in different strands First studies on the causes

of income inequality should take the role of NRD into consideration which has been overlooked

so far Given that the spatial dimension of income inequality seems to be explained by a

phenomenon of spatial heterogeneity estimation strategies such as spatial regime models or

geographically weighted regression should be used (Chi amp Zhu 2019) Second the effect of NRD

on income inequality could manifest through different channels such as education fiscal transfers

and institutions We could extend our analysis to identify which of these competing channels is

the most relevant Transforming some continuous variables such as educational level to a

54

categorical variable or defining new indicator variables for instance whether a local government

shows or not an efficient performance we could classify counties in different groups and then

check whether there are differences or not in the relationship between income inequality and NRD

A third strand could be to disaggregate our measure of NRD for different industries This

would allow us to test differences among industries and to identify the sectors that promote greater

equality and which greater inequality Forth the analysis of the consequences of income inequality

on other economic and social phenomena such as efficiency economic growth and social cohesion

has a growing interest in researchers and policymakers Our findings suggest that to answer the

question of whether income inequality has a causal impact on other variables we could include a

measure of NRD as an instrument to address endogeneity issues For instance two interesting

topics for future research are the analysis of how differences in income inequality between counties

could help to explain differences in the level of efficiency of local governments and differences in

the degree of social cohesion (unrest) throughout the country Those are the issues to be addressed

in the next two essays

55

Chapter 3 The Impact of Income Inequality on the Efficiency of

Municipalities in Chile

31 Introduction

In Chile municipalities are the smallest administrative unit for which citizens choose their

local authorities playing an important role in the provision of public goods and services at the

local level Municipalities have a similar set of objectives but the level of financial resources

available to finance their activities is highly heterogeneous This could result in significant

differences in the levels of performance between municipalities Despite their importance there is

little empirical evidence about the efficiency of local governments in Chile This essay aims to

measure the technical efficiency of Chilean municipalities and to analyse how local characteristics

particularly those related to income distribution at the county level could help to explain

differences in municipal performance

Cross-country studies situate Chile as an efficient country in international comparisons about

efficiency of government spending (Herrera amp Pang 2005 Loacutepez amp Miller 2008) However

evidence for Chile at the local level is relatively sparse suggesting significant levels of

inefficiency For instance Pacheco Sanchez and Villena (2013) found a mean efficiency level of

around 70 using a sample of 309 municipalities for the period 2008-2010 This suggests that

municipalities could achieve the same level of output by reducing the usage of inputs by an average

of 30 Their study also showed that those municipalities more dependent on the central

56

government or those located in counties with lower income per capita are more efficient than their

counterparts

Most empirical research on Local Government Efficiency (LGE) has been conducted for

member countries of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) of

which Chile has been a member since 2010 In the case of European countries such as Spain and

Italy which share similar characteristics such as the monetary union and levels of GDP per head

efficiency studies have been mainly motivated by budgetary constraints (Balaguer-Coll Brun-

Martos Maacuterquez-Ramos amp Prior 2019 lo Storto 2013) The Chilean context differs in three

main ways from its OECD counterparts First except for the Metropolitan Region that concentrates

most of the population Chilean regions are highly dependent on natural resources Second Chile

is also characterized by one of the highest levels of income inequality among OECD countries

which contrast with the situation of developed natural resource-rich countries such as Australia

and Norway Third although budget constraints are also a relevant issue Chilean municipalities

have experienced a sustained increase in the level of financial resources and expenditure

Another relevant distinction when we benchmark the performance of municipalities across

different countries is the type of public services they provide On the one hand in most of the

countries included Chile the main role of local governments is to provide ldquoservices to peoplerdquo

such as public education and public health On the other hand there are countries such as Australia

where local governments mainly provide ldquoservices to propertyrdquo including waste management

maintenance of local roads and the provision of community facilities such as libraries swimming

pools and parks (Dollery Wallis amp Akimov 2010 Drew Kortt amp Dollery 2015 McQuestin

Drew amp Dollery 2018)

57

Despite contextual differences Chilean municipalities seem not to perform differently from

municipalities in other developed and natural resource-rich countries where income inequality is

significantly less than in Chile (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018a) This result highlights the

need to study the role of income inequality and the degree of dependence on natural resources over

LGE characteristics that have been largely overlooked in the literature

We measure and analyse differences in municipal performance using a two-stage approach

In the first stage we measure municipal efficiency using an input-oriented Data Envelopment

Analysis (DEA) to get a set of ldquoefficiency scoresrdquo In the second stage we regress efficiency scores

against our measure of income inequality controlling for a set of contextual factors describing the

economic socio-demographic and political context of each county

We use a sample of 324 municipalities for the period 2006-2017 During this period Chile

was divided into 346 counties belonging to 15 regions This period was characterized by important

external and internal shocks including the Global Financial Crisis (GFC) one of the biggest

earthquakes in Chilean history in 2010 and three municipal elections The availability of

information allows us to measure efficiency for the full period but the influence of contextual

factors is analysed using a panel of six years (2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017) for which

household income information is available

The main hypothesis tested in the second stage is whether higher levels of income inequality

are associated with lower levels of efficiency Previous evidence shows that when progress is not

evenly shared persistent within-country inequality reduces the effectiveness and efficiency of the

public sector (Ortega Sanjuaacuten amp Casquero 2017 Tandon 2005)

Income inequality has been used to control for a wide range of idiosyncratic factors

associated with historical institutional and cultural factors affecting efficiency (Greene 2016

58

Ortega et al 2017) For instance at the local level income inequality has been considered as an

indicator of economic heterogeneity in the population where higher inequality is associated with

a more heterogeneous set of conflicting demands for public services which adversely affect an

efficient provision (Ashworth Geys Heyndels amp Wille 2014 Geys amp Moesen 2009) Higher

levels of income inequality could also relate to economically privileged groups having a greater

capacity to influence the political system for their own benefit rather than that of the majority

When high inequality is persistent the feeling of frustration and disappointment in the population

could reduce not only trust and cooperation among individuals but also trust in institutions which

would negatively affect government efficiency (Boix amp Posner 1998 Coffeacute amp Geys 2005) For

instance national or local authorities could end exerting patronage and clientelism and showing

rising levels of corruption (Uslaner 2011 Uslaner amp Brown 2005)

One of the main gaps in extant literature is the need to conduct more analysis of LGE using

panel data taking into consideration endogeneity issues and controlling for unobserved

heterogeneity (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018a) To address the above we set-up a panel with

time and county-specific effects and we propose the use of a measure of natural resource

dependence (NRD) as an instrument for income inequality Based on the ldquoParadox of Plentyrdquo

fiscal revenues from natural resources windfalls could be associated with an over expansion of the

public sector fostering rent-seeking and corruption and reducing local government efficiency

(Dauvin amp Guerreiro 2017 Manzano amp Rigobon 2001) In the Chilean case most of the revenues

generated by local governments included those from natural resources end up in a common fund

which benefits all municipalities The aim of this common fund is precisely to reduce inequalities

among municipalities so although we do not expect a direct impact of natural resources on LGE

we could expect an indirect effect through other indicators particularly income inequality

59

As far as we know this is the first study analysing the influence of income inequality as a

determinant of municipal efficiency in Chile Moreover this is the first study in the context of a

natural resource-rich country which specifically suggests a measure of natural resource

dependence as an instrument to correct for endogeneity bias We propose the use of the proportion

of firms in the primary sector as proxy for the degree of NRD in each county We argue that this

variable is a better proxy than using the proportion of employment in the manufacturing sector

which has been proposed in previous studies (Alesina amp La Ferrara 2002) During the period

analysed our proxy remained relatively stable and showed a significant relationship with income

inequality In addition it is less likely that it has directly affected municipal efficiency

This study adds to the literature in two other ways First the extant literature suggests that

efficiency measurement could be highly sensitive to the chosen technique as well as the selection

of inputs and outputs (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018a) Inputs are usually proxied by a single

measure of total public expenditures and outputs by general proxies such as population andor the

number of businesses in each county We offer a novel approach for the selection of inputs and

outputs On the one hand we disaggregate government expenditures into four components

(operation personnel health and education) and we use the number of public schools and health

facilities in each county as a proxy for physical capital On the other hand we use four outputs

aiming to capture the wide variety of goods and services supplied by each municipality Through

this approach we aim to better describe the production function of each municipality capturing

not only the variety of inputs and outputs but also differences in size among municipalities

A third contribution relates to the measurement of LGE in the Chilean context We measure

technical and scale efficiency using a larger sample and a longer period This has empirical and

policy relevance On the one hand it helps us to select the correct DEA model and allows us to

60

determine the importance of scale inefficiencies as explanation for differences in municipal

performance On the other hand efficiency measures increase the information available for both

central and local governments to better understand the production technology that best describes

each municipality and to carry out policies to improve efficiency

We believe that our selection of inputs and outputs the use of a large dataset and the joint

analysis using cross-sectional and panel data provide a more accurate and robust analysis of

municipal efficiency Likewise knowing whether inequality has a significant influence on

municipal efficiency may provide useful insights and guidance for policymakers not only in Chile

but also for countries sharing similar characteristics

DEA results show an average level of technical efficiency (inefficiency) of around 83

(17) This means that municipalities could reduce on average a 17 the use of inputs without

reducing the outputs There are significant differences among geographic areas with the Centre

area (where the countyrsquos capital is located) displaying higher efficiency than the rest of the country

When municipal efficiency is measured under different assumptions about returns to scale results

reveal a production technology with variable returns to scales and around 75 of the

municipalities displaying scale inefficiencies However when technical efficiency is

disaggregated between pure technical efficiency and scale efficiency results show that scale

inefficiency explains a small proportion of the total municipal technical inefficiency This finding

justifies a deeper analysis of the reasons why municipalities could operate inefficiently and why

municipal performance could vary among municipalities

Efficiency scores also show a significant degree of positive spatial autocorrelation This

means that municipal efficiency shows a general clustering process with neighbouring

municipalities showing similar levels of efficiency A further analysis shows that most of the

61

spatial pattern in municipal efficiency is exogenous that is could be associated to other variables

Hence we conduct most of our regression analysis using traditional (non-spatial) methods and

leaving spatial regressions in the appendixes

Findings from cross-sectional and panel regressions support the hypothesis that municipal

performance is significantly and negatively associated with income inequality at the county level

The coefficient of income inequality is close to one which means that reductions in income

inequality ceteris paribus could be associated with increases in municipal efficiency in the same

proportion This result supports the strand of research arguing that there is not a trade-off at least

at the municipal level between equity and efficiency (Andersen amp Maibom 2020 Berg amp Ostry

2011 2017) The main policy implications are that authorities in more unequal counties would

face higher challenges to perform efficiently and policies pertaining to inequality and efficiency

should not be designed independently

The chapter is structured as follows Section 32 provides a brief literature review on related

local government efficiency Section 33 introduces the methodological background and empirical

models Section 34 presents the empirical results and discussions Section 35 concludes the

chapter

32 Related Literature

321 Measuring efficiency of local governments

Studies on measuring LGE can be grouped in those analysing the provision of single services

such as health or education and those assessing overall efficiency (lo Storto 2013) Once inputs

and outputs have been defined efficiency is measured using parametric andor non-parametric

techniques Among the former group Stochastic Frontier Analysis (SFA) seems to be preferred

62

by scholars aiming to measure efficiency and to analyse the link with environmental variables

using a single procedure (Pacheco et al 2013 Tsekeris Sotiris Tsekeris amp Papaioannou 2018)

On the non-parametric group Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA) is by far the most used technique

(Afonso amp Fernandes 2006 Balaguer-Coll amp Prior 2009 lo Storto 2013)

The selection of inputs and outputs depends not only on the aimed of the study (specific

sector vs whole measure of efficiency) but also on the role that municipalities play in different

countries There are countries such as Australia (Drew et al 2015) and Spain (Balaguer-Coll amp

Prior 2009) where local governments mainly supply services to ldquopropertyrdquo such as waste

management and road maintenance In these cases efficiency has been mainly measured using

total indicators of local government expenditure and outputs have been proxied using general

indicators such as population or number of business (Drew et al 2015) On the other hand in

countries such as Italy (lo Storto 2013) and Portugal (Afonso amp Fernandes 2008) in Europe or

Brazil (de Sousa Cribari-Neto amp Stosic 2005) and Chile (Pacheco et al 2013) in South America

municipalities mainly supply services to ldquopeoplerdquo Here in addition to financial expenditures or

revenues inputs have included the number of local government employees the number of schools

or the number of hospitals and health centres School-age population the number of students

enrolled in primary and secondary schools and the number of beds in hospitals have been

considered as outputs Based on the study of Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte (2018a) a wider list of

inputs and outputs used in previous studies can be found in Appendix I

Studies from different countries show important differences in the average efficiency scores

both between and within countries These studies also differ in the samples methodologies and

variables included A summary showing the range and variability of the mean efficiency scores

founds in countries all around the world can be found in Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte (2018a)

63

These authors also show that OECD natural resource-rich countries such as Australia Belgium

and Chile show similar results in terms of mean efficiency scores with LGE studies being less

frequent in Latin American countries

Measuring efficiency of local governments as decision-making units (DMU) presents many

challenges and difficulties (Borger Kerstens Moesen amp Vanneste 1994 Ravallion 2005)

Worthington and Dollery (2000) mention problems with the selection and measurement of inputs

the identification of different stakeholders the hidden characteristic of the ldquolocal government

technologyrdquo and the multidimensionality of the services provided by local governments All these

issues make difficult to identify and distinguish between outputs and outcomes with outputs

commonly proxied by general indicators such as county area or county population Because

efficiency measures are highly sensitive to the chosen technique and the selection of inputs and

outputs Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte (2018a) suggest formulating different specifications and

using less general and unspecified indicators Moreover the complexity in defining outputs and

the use of general indicators make more likely that contextual factors affect municipal efficiency

322 Explaining differences in LGE

To explain differences in local government performance researchers have basically

distinguished between ldquodiscretionaryrdquo and ldquonon-discretionaryrdquo factors Discretionary factors refer

to the degree of discretion of local authorities in the selection and management of inputs and

outputs On the other hand scholars have investigated the influence on LGE of contextual factors

beyond authoritiesrsquo control These factors reflective at the environment where municipalities

operate include economic socio-demographic geographic financial political and institutional

characteristics (da Cruz amp Marques 2014 Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018b)

64

In general the evidence about the influence of contextual factors has delivered mixed and

country-specific results (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018b) Sampaio de Sousa et al (2005)

using data for Brazilian municipalities finds that population density and urbanization rate have

strong positive effects on efficiency scores Benito et al (2010) show that lower levels of

efficiency of Spanish municipalities are associated with a greater economic level a less stable

population and a bigger size of the local government Afonso (2008) finds that per capita income

level and education are not significant factors influencing LGE of Portuguese municipalities He

also finds that municipalities in Northern areas show greater efficiency than their counterparts in

Southern areas More recently Tsekeris (2018) finds that spatial variations in efficiency in Greece

can be attributed to factors related to inter-regional market access specialization and sectoral

concentration resource-factor endowments and political factors among others Characteristics

describing each local government have also been used including municipal indebtedness (Benito

et al 2010) fiscal deficits (Sinha 2017) degree of fiscal autonomy (Boetti Piacenza amp Turati

2009) and individual characteristics of local authorities such as age gender and political ideology

Narboacuten‐Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte (2018b) conclude after analysing 63 articles that studies on the

influence of contextual factors have mostly used cross-sectional data with little attention to

endogeneity issues which makes any causal interpretation doubtful

323 The trade-off between efficiency and equity

The existence of a potential trade-off between efficiency and equity is in the core of

economic discussion (Andersen amp Maibom 2020 Berg amp Ostry 2011 Browning amp Johnson

1984 Okun 2015)15 The argument that economic growth (one of the most common efficiency

15 Redistributive policies distort incentives and lead to suboptimal outcomes and thus efficiency losses

65

measures) could be negatively affected in the search for greater equality has been translated not

only into economic policies that favour economic growth over those that reduce inequality but

also in the emphasis of scholarly research Thus theoretical and empirical research has been

mainly focussed on efficiency and policy implications of a great diversity of shocks and policies

leaving the analysis of inequality as one of measurement and mostly descriptive Additionally

empirical evidence of the trade-off is scant and inconclusive (Andersen amp Maibom 2020

Browning amp Johnson 1984)

Among economic contextual factors that could affect LGE income inequality has been

largely ignored An exception is a cross-country comparison conducted by Ortega (2017) who

analyses the role of inequality on government efficiency in developing countries He finds that

more unequal countries could have higher difficulties to achieve specific health outcomes Income

inequality has even been considered as part of the outputs to measure efficiency particularly for

the case of European and OECD countries (Afonso Schuknecht amp Tanzi 2010 Antonelli amp De

Bonis 2018)

At the local level income inequality has been mainly used as a proxy for the effect of income

heterogeneity Economic inequality could have a direct and an indirect effect on government

efficiency The direct effect poses that higher income inequality could reduce municipal efficiency

because it is associated with a more complex and competing set of public services demanded by

the population (Jottier et al 2012) The indirect effect puts the focus in the link between inequality

social capital and levels of corruption Economic diversity could reduce trust in people and

institutions when related to high and persistent levels of income inequality It could also affect the

willingness to participate in community and political groups the existence of a shared objective

by citizens and the perception of a prosperous future (Uslaner amp Brown 2005)

66

The evidence is ambiguous For instance Geys and Moesen (2009) find that income

inequality has little relation to efficiency of Flemish municipalities and Ashworth et al (2014)

find a negative relationship for the Norwegian case Findings also indicate that inequality is the

strongest determinant of trust and that trust has a greater effect on communal participation than on

political participation (Uslaner amp Brown 2005)

33 Methodology

We follow a two-stage approach widely used in this kind of analysis A DEA analysis is

conducted in the first stage to get efficiency scores for each municipality Then regression analysis

is conducted in the second stage aiming to identify contextual variables other than differences in

the management of inputs that can help to explain the heterogeneity in municipal performance

331 Chilean Municipalities and period of analysis

The territory of Chile is divided into regions and these into provinces which for purposes of

the local administration are divided into counties The local administration of each county resides

in a municipality which is administrated by a Mayor assisted by a Municipal Council16

Municipalities represent the decentralization of the central power in Chile They are autonomous

organizations with legal personality and own patrimony whose purpose is to satisfy the needs of

the local community and ensure their participation in the economic social and cultural progress of

the county Municipalities have a diversity of functions related to public health education and

social assistance among others

16 The Mayor and City Council are elected by suffrage for the citizens of the respective commune every 4 years

67

To achieve their goals two are the main sources of municipal incomes own permanent

revenues (OPR) and the Municipal Common Fund (MCF) OPR are incomes generated by the

county and they are an indicator of the self-financing capacity of each municipality OPR are not

subject to restrictions regarding their investment and they are mainly generated by territorial taxes

commercial patents and circulation permits17 The MCF is a fund that aims to redistribute

community income to ensure compliance with the purpose of the municipalities and their proper

functioning Sources to finance the MCF come from municipal revenues The distribution

mechanism of the fund is regulated by parameters such as whether municipalities generate OPR

per capita lower than the national average and the number of poor people in the commune in

relation to the number of poor people in the country

This study covers the period from 2006 to 2017 During this period Chile was divided into

15 regions 54 provinces and 346 counties18 Although the information on inputs and outputs is

available for the entire period information on contextual factors at the county level such as

household income is only available every two-three years In addition some counties are excluded

from household surveys due to their difficult access Hence we use a sample of 324 municipalities

to measure municipal efficiency for the whole period (3888 observations) However the analysis

of contextual factors is conducted for those years when household income information is available

2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017 (1944 observations)

17 The territorial tax is a tax on agricultural and non-agricultural real estate Specifically of this income only 40 is left to the municipality as its own financing while the remaining 60 is allocated to the MCF (in the case of the four largest communes- Santiago Providencia Las Condes and Vitacura-percentages are 35 and 65 respectively) Unlike the territorial tax commercial patents are regulated mainly by the municipality which chooses the rate to be charged subject to a range established by law and is responsible of their collection Finally regarding the circulation permits 375 is of municipal benefit while 645 is directed to the MCF 18 There are 346 counties managed by 345 municipalities where counties ldquoCabo de Hornosrdquo and ldquoAntaacuterticardquo are managed by the municipality of ldquoCabo de Hornosrdquo

68

332 Measuring municipal efficiency

Municipal efficiency is measured using Data Envelopment Analysis (Coelli Prasada Rao

OrsquoDonnell amp Battese 2005) This is a non-parametric approach that uses linear programming to

measure efficiency for a group of municipalities as decision making units (DMUrsquos) The main

advantage of using DEA and the reason why DEA is used for the case of Chilean municipalities

is its flexibility in handling multiple inputs and outputs without the need to specify a functional

form (Balaguer-Coll amp Prior 2009 Mikušovaacute 2015 Tigga amp Mishra 2015) Following Afonso

and Fernandes (2008) the relationship between inputs and outputs for each municipality could be

represented by the following equation

119884 119891 119883 119894 1 119899 (31)

In equation (31) 119884 is the set of outputs and 119883 the set of inputs for each of the n

municipalities Using linear programming the production frontier is constructed and a vector of

efficiency scores is obtained The frontier represents full technical efficiency mdash the point at which

the highest output occurs given specified inputs or the point at which the lowest amount of inputs

is used to produce a specified quantity of output Efficiency scores under DEA are relative

measures of efficiency They measure a municipalityrsquos efficiency against the other measured

municipalities in the sample and not a hypothetical lsquoperfect municipalityrsquo The further from the

frontier the less technically efficient a municipality is

We use an input-oriented approach because Chilean municipalities have a greater control

over the management of inputs relative to the outputs they have to manage Obtaining efficiency

scores requires an assumption about the returns to scale exhibited by each municipality When

DMUrsquos are homogeneous the CCR model (Charnes Cooper amp Rhodes 1978) which assumes

69

constant return-to-scale (CRS) is the appropriate specification The CCR model assumes full

proportionality between outputs and inputs and that DMUrsquos operate at their optimal When DMUrsquos

are highly heterogeneous as is the case with local governments in most countries it is not realistic

to assume complete proportionality between inputs and outputs nor that all DMUrsquos operate at their

optimum scale In this situation a variable returns-to-scale (VRS) or BCC model (Banker

Charnes amp Cooper 1984) is the preferred formulation

Assuming VRS imposes minimum restrictions on the efficient frontier and allows for

comparisons only among municipalities of similar scale (Coelli et al 2005 Wu Huang amp Pan

2014) This means that when we use the CCR model (assuming CRS) on a heterogeneous sample

of DMUrsquos the resulting measure of technical efficiency that we obtain is related not only to the

management of inputs but also to issues of scale19 To empirically check the validity of the VRS

assumption we measure technical efficiency under CRS VRS and non-increasing returns-to-scale

(NIRS) and we analyse the existence of scale inefficiencies This allows us to check the relevance

of scale effects as a potential explanation of differences in municipal efficiency Appendix J

shows the specification of the DEA model under VRS and how ldquototal technical efficiencyrdquo

(assuming CRS and therefore due to management and scale issues) could be disaggregated in ldquopure

technical efficiencyrdquo (under VRS and related only to management issues) and scale efficiency (due

to scale issues)

19 Assuming VRS can also lead to measurement problems such as overestimation of efficiency scores This is the case when an important proportion of DMUrsquos shows CRS so assuming VRS ignores the information about proportionality between inputs and outputs (Podinovski 2004)

70

333 Inputs and outputs used in DEA

Following the literature on local government expenditure efficiency (Afonso amp Fernandes

2008 de Sousa et al 2005 Dlouhyacute 2018 Tandon 2005 Tigga amp Mishra 2015) and trying to

reflect as well as possible the functioning of municipalities five inputs and four outputs were

selected Input and output data were obtained from the National System of Municipal Information

(SINIM in its Spanish acronym) and they are expressed in thousands of Chilean pesos of 201720

Inputs are Municipal Operational Expenditure X1 (including expenses on goods and

services social assistance investment and transfers to community organizations) Municipal

Personnel Expenditure X2 (including full time and part-time workers) Total Municipal

Expenditure in Education sector X3 Total Municipal Expenditure in Health sector X4 and the

Number of Municipal Buildings X5 (proxied by the number of public facilities in education and

health sectors)

Output variables were selected highlighting the relevance of education and health sectors

and trying to capture the wide range of local services provided by municipalities The variable

ldquoOwn Permanent Revenuesrdquo Y1 is used to capture the scale and diversity of municipal

activities21 The ldquoMonthly Average Enrolmentrdquo in municipal education establishments related to

the school-age population in each county Y2 is used as educational output As health output the

ldquoNumber of Medical Consultationsrdquo in public facilities Y3 is considered Finally the number of

community organizations Y4 is used as output reflecting the promotion of community

development by each municipality Table 31 shows the summary statistics of input and output

20 The data from SINIM database was mostly obtained using the sinimr package (Salas 2019) 21 According to SINIM database this variable aims to measure the management of the municipalityrsquos own resources with respect to the population of the commune

71

variables for the whole sample and period Inputs and outputs excepting the Monthly Average

Enrolment Y2 are measured in per capita terms using county population information from the

National Institute of Statistics (INE in its Spanish acronym)

Table 31

Descriptive statistics Inputs and Output variables used in DEA analysis

334 Regression model

Contextual factors could play an important role not only in explaining why some

municipalities operate inefficiently but also why municipal performance differs among them

These factors may affect municipal performance modifying incentives for local authorities to

operate efficiently and their capability to take advantage of economies of scale They also define

the conditions for cooperation or competition among municipalities and the citizensacute ability and

willingness to monitor local authorities (Afonso amp Fernandes 2008)

Information on income at the household level for each county was obtained from the

ldquoNational Socioeconomic Characterization Surveyrdquo (CASEN in its Spanish acronym) CASEN is

conducted every two-three years being the reason why consecutive years are not considered in

72

our regression analysis The other contextual factors used as controls were obtained from different

sources including SINIM INE and the ldquoServicio de Impuestos Internosrdquo (SII)22

Our main hypothesis is whether higher levels of income inequality are associated with lower

levels of municipal efficiency To test our hypothesis the empirical model is defined as

120579 120573 119892119894119899119894 119885 120573 120575 120572 120598 (32)

Where 120579 is the vector of DEA efficiency scores 119892119894119899119894 is the Gini coefficient of each

county 120575 are year-specific effects 120572 are county-specific constants 120598 is a vector of error terms

and 119885 is a vector of controls Next we discuss the motivation for these controls

The level of purchasing power of countiesrsquo citizens is proxied by the variable log(income)

which is the natural log of the mean household income per capita in thousands of Chilean pesos of

2017 On the one hand poorer counties could display higher efficiency due to their necessity to

take care of their constraint resources (Pacheco et al 2013) On the other hand richer counties

could show higher efficiency because richer citizens exert higher monitoring over local authorities

and demand better quality public services in return for their tax payments (Afonso et al 2010)

The possibility for municipalities to take advantage of economies of scale and urbanization is

captured by three variables First the variable log(density) which correspond to the natural log of

population density Second the dummy variable reg_cap indicating whether a county is a regional

capital or not Third the variable agroland which correspond to the proportion of land for

agricultural use which is informed to the SII We expect a positive effect of log(density) but

negative for regcap and agroland

22 The SII is the institution in charge of collecting taxes in Chile

73

Socio-demographic characteristics are captured including a Dependence Index IDD IDD

corresponds to the number of people under 15 years or over 65 years per 100 people in the active

population (those people between 15 and 65 years old) A higher proportion of young and older

population could be associated with a higher demand for municipal services relating to education

and health making harder to offer public services efficiently The citizensrsquo capacity to monitor

local authorities is proxied including the variable education (average years of education for the

population older than 15 years) and the variable housing (proportion of households which are

owners of the property where they live in each county) In both cases we expect a positive

association with LGE

Among municipal characteristics the variable professional (percentage of municipal

personnel with a professional degree) is used to control for the quality of municipal services and

it is expected a positive impact The variable mcf (proportion of total municipal income coming

from the MCF) is included to capture the influence of financial dependence on the central

government A higher dependence from MCF could be associated with higher efficiency when it

is linked to more control from central government (Worthington amp Dollery 2000) However when

MCF discourages the generation of own resources and proper management of resources from the

fund a lower efficiency should be expected (Bravo 2014) In addition the dummy variable mayor

is included to capture differences among mayors supported by the ldquoLEFTrdquo or the ldquoRIGHTrdquo

political parties related to those ldquoINDEPENDENTrdquo mayors

Table 32 report summary statistics for the set of numeric contextual factors and Appendix

K the corresponding correlation matrix Despite the high correlation between income and

education variables we include both in the regression section as they capture different county

characteristics

74

Table 32

Summary Statistics Numeric Contextual Factors

Figure 31 Geographical distribution of Chilean regions and macrozones

Previous evidence on growth and convergence of Chilean regions have found that regions

tend to cluster spatially (Aroca amp Bosch 2000) Aiming to capture this regional clustering process

75

and considering the high concentration in the number of municipalities and population in the

central area we group municipalities in four ldquozonesrdquo We define as reference the ldquoCentre-Northrdquo

zone consisting of regions XIII (where the countryrsquos capital is located) and its two neighbouring

regions V and VI The ldquoNorthrdquo zone includes regions XV I II III and IV The ldquoCentre-Southrdquo

zone includes regions VII VIII and IX Finally the ldquoSouthrdquo zone embraces regions XIV X XI

and XII Figure 31 displays the regional administrative division and zones considered in this

essay

Efficiency scores (ES) are limited to have values between 0 and 1 However they are relative

measures (relative to the sample of municipalities) This implies that when a municipality is on the

frontier (ES = 1) it does not mean that potentially larger technical efficiency gains cannot be made

Hence equation 32 is estimated using OLS and censored regressions We start running cross-

sectional regressions for each of the six years Then we compare the results with those from panel

regressions Because fixed-effects panel Tobit models could be affected by the incidental

parameters problem (Henningsen 2010 2019) we use random-effects panel Tobit models

including indicator variables for years and zones Finally to deal with the potential endogeneity

problem we also use an instrumental variable approach The instrument is described next

335 The instrument

Government effectiveness and income distribution are both structural components of

economies (Ortega et al 2017 Ravallion 2005) In the search for a causal interpretation for the

influence of income inequality on municipal efficiency we need an instrument which must be

correlated with the variable to be instrumented (in our case income inequality) and uncorrelated

with the error term in the efficiency equation (32) Previous literature has used as instruments for

Gini the number of townships governments in a previous period the percentage of revenues from

76

intergovernmental transfers in a previous period and the current share of the labour force in the

manufacturing sector (Alesina amp La Ferrara 2002) Using the share of the labour force in a specific

sector is unlikely to reduce the problem of endogeneity particularly in countries where local

governments supply mostly ldquoservices to peoplerdquo and the main source of income inequality is

labour income

We propose as an instrument the proportion of firms in the primary sector (mining fishing

forestry and agriculture)

119901119904119904_119891119894119903119898119904Number of firms in the primary sector

Total number of firms (33)

On the one hand this instrument is likely to be correlated with local income inequality in

natural resource-rich countries23 On the other hand we contend that our instrument is less likely

to be correlated with the error term in the efficiency equation First the main services supplied by

Chilean municipalities are services to people (health and education) not to firms Second most of

the revenues collected by municipalities included those associated with natural resources end up

in the municipal common fund whose objective is precisely to reduce inequalities among

municipalities Third services to firms are expected to be more significant with the tertiary sector

We argue that our instrument captures natural and structural conditions which directly

influence income inequality but it does not directly affect LGE Figure 32 shows the evolution

of the annual average efficiency score and the proportion of firms in the primary secondary

(manufacturing) and tertiary (services) sectors We observe that sectors shares have remained

relatively stable with a slight reduction in the participation of the primary sector in favour of the

23 Results confirm a significant association between income inequality and the degree of dependence on natural resources at the county level

77

tertiary sector by the end of the period This is contrary to the evolution of municipal efficiency

which shows a cyclical behaviour as will be shown in the next section

Figure 32 Evolution of efficiency scores and the proportion of firms by sector

34 Results and discussion

341 DEA results

Figure 33 displays the evolution of our three measures of efficiency Overall technical

efficiency pure technical efficiency and scale efficiency are around 78 83 and 95

respectively with fluctuations over the years Therefore around three quarters of the overall

78

inefficiency is attributed to inefficiency in the management of inputs and around one quarter to

scale inefficiencies24

Figure 33 Evolution technical efficiency (TE) pure technical efficiency (PTE) and scale efficiency (SE)

Returnstoscale

Figure 34 reports by zone and for the whole period the proportion of municipalities

showing CRS decreasing returns to scale (DRS) or increasing returns to scale (IRS) Most of the

municipalities operate under variable (increasing or decreasing) returns to scale which could be

explained by the high heterogeneity in size among municipalities A summary of RTS

disaggregated by year and zone is in Appendix L Policies oriented to increase efficiency usually

24 The average scale efficiency score of 95 means that municipalities could get an additional 5 of inputs saving if municipalities were able to change their size to achieve their optimal scale

79

consider amalgamation de-amalgamation or ways of cooperation among municipalities To have

a better idea about where and how feasible is the implementation of such policies Appendix M

shows maps with the administrative division of the country in its 345 municipalities and which

municipalities show CRS IRS or DRS in each of the six years of data

Figure 34 Returns to scale by zone

Based on results for the whole period (Figure 34) the North has the highest proportion of

municipalities exhibiting DRS This suggests the need to reduce the size of municipalities splitting

those ldquotoo bigrdquo creating new administrative areas or giving more autonomy to current

municipalities25 The opposite occurs in the Centre-North area where municipalities mostly

exhibit IRS This indicates the need to merge municipalities An alternative strategy to the

amalgamation process is increasing inter-municipal cooperation (Balaguer-Coll et al 2019)

25 This has been the policy followed in Chile Although two new regions were created (XV in the North and XIV in the South) the number of municipalities has not changed

80

which seems to be a more plausible option in Chile Finally evidence on scale efficiency for the

Centre-South and South areas is not clear in terms of the adequate strategy to improve efficiency

Efficiencymeasure

Although most municipalities show scale inefficiencies (Figure 34) only a small proportion

of total inefficiency is associated to scale issues (Figure 33) Together this results justify not only

the use of the BCC model (efficiency scores under VRS) to capture municipal heterogeneity but

also highlights the need to look for other factors outside the control of local authorities which

could be influencing municipal performance

Table 33

Summary efficiency scores (VRS) by zone and region

Table 33 summarizes ES under VRS using data for the six years of CASEN survey A mean

efficiency score of 83 is found for the full sample and period This means that on average

inefficient municipalities can reduce the use of inputs by 17 to get the same current output By

81

comparing average ES per zone it can be concluded that municipalities in the North Centre-North

Centre-South and South could achieve the same level of output with 17 12 18 and 23 fewer

resources respectively Results also show that one third of the municipalities present an efficiency

score equal to one

Figure 35 shows the evolution of the mean ES for the four zones over the 12 years period

A clear drop in the efficiency level is observed in 2009 (the financial crisis year) excepting for the

North area Likewise although mean efficiency returned to its pre-crisis levels in 2014-2015 a

new drop in efficiency was experienced in 2016 It also seems that the 2010 earthquake did not

generate a significant effect on municipal efficiency Figure 35 also shows that although levels

of efficiency seem to differ among zones they follow a similar trend through time with the only

exception of the North which corresponds to the mining area In addition efficiency seems to be

significantly higher in the Centre-North area This is explained by the high mean level of efficiency

in region XIII which includes the countryrsquos capital city

Figure 35 Evolution mean efficiency scores (VRS) by zone

82

To know which and where are the efficient municipalities and if they are surrounded by

municipalities with a similar level of efficiency Appendix N has maps showing the ldquoefficiency

statusrdquo of each municipality that is whether they are efficient (ES = 1) or inefficient (ES lt 1)

Additionally Appendix O shows ldquoequal intervalsrdquo maps describing the spatial distribution of ES

among municipalities for each of the six years26 Results show that efficient municipalities can be

found all through the country the ldquoefficiency statusrdquo could change from one year to another and

municipalities with similar level-status of efficiency tend to cluster in space

342 Regression results

Exploratoryspatialanalysis

DEA efficiency scores and their geographical representations seem to show that municipal

efficiency presents a spatial clustering pattern This means that municipal performance could be

influenced not only by contextual factors of the county where municipality belongs but also by the

level of efficiency of neighbouring municipalities and their characteristics To test the significance

of the spatial dimension in municipal efficiency we use a cross-section of data considering the six-

year average of efficiency scores the Gini coefficient and the set of controls

We use the Moranrsquos I indicator to test for spatial autocorrelation Moranrsquos I is a measure of

the correlation between the level of efficiency in one municipality and its ldquospatial lagrdquo that is the

average level of efficiency in neighbouring municipalities We define as the relevant neighbours

for each municipality the 5-nearest municipalities This is obtained using the distances among the

26 An equal intervals map uses the same principle as a histogram to organize the observations into categories that divide the range of the variable into equal interval bins For the equal interval classification the value range between the lower and upper bound in each bin is constant across bins but the number of observations in each bin is typically not equal

83

polygonsrsquo centroids (latitude and longitude) of each county Results confirm that municipal

efficiency show a significant level of positive spatial autocorrelation This means that

municipalities tend to have neighbouring municipalities with similar performance

The positive spatial autocorrelation shown by municipal efficiency could be due to the

performance in one municipality is influenced by the performance in neighbouring municipalities

(spatial dependence in the variable itself) or due to structural differences among regions-zones

(spatial heterogeneity) To check the source of the spatial autocorrelation we run an OLS

regression of ES against income inequality and controls and then we test OLS residuals for spatial

autocorrelation Moranrsquos I over OLS residuals although significant is barely higher than zero (see

Appendix P) This means that the spatial effect itself is not a serious issue and can be handle for

instance including zone indicators variables hence we proceed to analyse the influence of income

inequality on LGE using non-spatial regression27

Cross‐sectionalanalysis

We start reporting censored regressions for each year in our panel Efficiency scores have

been rescaled to numbers between 0 and 100 to facilitate the interpretation of the results All

regressions include dummy variables for three of the four zones in which we have grouped Chilean

regions Results are in Table 3428 Income inequality shows a negative sign in all years which is

consistent with our hypothesis that inequality is negatively related to municipal efficiency

However only in three of the six years the effect of income inequality appears as statistically

27 In the case of having incorporated the spatial dimension the two most commonly used forms are including in the model the spatial lag of the dependent variable (spatial autoregressive model SAR) or the spatial lag of the error (spatial error model SEM) Following the method suggested by Anselin et al (1996) Lagrange Multiplier (LM) tests on the OLS residuals showed that the SAR model is preferred over the SEM Moranrsquos I LM tests and spatial regressions can be found in Appendix P 28 Regression results using OLS are in Appendix Q

84

significant Only the income level displays a significant and positive influence on efficiency for

the whole period A higher population density also consistently favours municipal efficiency On

the other hand as we expected a higher IDD makes it more difficult to achieve an efficient

performance29 Consistent with results in Pacheco et al (Pacheco et al 2013) municipal

efficiency show a significant an positive association with the MCF only in the first half of our

period of analysis with the second half showing an insignificant relationship

Table 34

Cross-sectional (censored) regressions

Paneldataanalysis

Estimation results for the six-year panel are reported in Table 35 Columns (1) and (2) show

the results for the pooled and random effects censored models only controlling for zone and year

29 The set of cross-sectional regressions was also run for each zone independently Results confirm that the set of significant contextual factors differs not only among years but also among geographic areas This support previous evidence suggesting that cross-sectional analysis should be treated with caution (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018b)

85

dummies Income inequality appears as non-significant Zone indicator variables confirm that

municipalities located in the Centre-South and South of the country display a lower average level

of efficiency compared to the Centre-North area Time dummies mostly show negative

coefficients This is a signal that shocks such as the GFC and the earthquake in 2010 may have

had a negative impact on efficiency but that impact was not permanent The results for the pooled

and RE models including the full set of controls are reported in columns (3) and (4) These results

show a significant negative influence of income inequality on LGE

When income inequality is instrumented by the variable pss_firms most of the coefficients

remain unchanged except for those associated with the income variables gini and log(income)

This result implies that our original model suffers for instance from the omitted variable bias

This means that LGE and income inequality are determined simultaneously by some variable not

included in our model Columns (5) and (6) show results using our instrument for income

inequality The ldquotrue coefficientrdquo of variable gini remains negative but the magnitude of the

relationship is higher The negative coefficient for gini implies on the one hand that municipalities

located in more unequal counties face more challenges to achieve an efficient management of

public resources On the other hand the coefficient in column (6) is close to one The interpretation

is that for each point of reduction in income inequality ceteris paribus LGE should increase in the

same proportion Next we discuss some of the results associated with the controls variables

Contrary to Pacheco et al (2013) income level has a positive coefficient meaning that richer

counties in terms of income per capita show higher efficiency This could be explained by higher

monitoring and increasing demands from citizen and taxpayers In addition it is expected a higher

efficiency in municipalities located in counties with a higher population density and those with a

lower proportion of land for agricultural use This result is mainly explained by municipalities

86

located in the Centre area The opposite happens with municipalities in the South implying that

they are too ldquosmallrdquo to take advantage of agglomeration economies There is also a limit for

agglomeration and scale economies which is shown by the negative coefficient of the variable

regcap although this coefficient loses its significance in the IV approaches30

Unexpectedly efficiency was found to be negatively associated with the variable education

This result is similar to the case of Czech municipalities (Šťastnaacute amp Gregor 2014) where

explanations include a weakened monitoring effect due to the fact that more educated citizens

present greater mobility and labour cost disadvantages for municipalities with better educated

labour force In Chile an additional explanation could be the relationship between education and

voter turnout Since 2012 voting is no longer mandatory in Chile This fact considerably reduced

voter turnout which in turn may have influenced the monitoring and control effect of more

educated voters For the case of variable IDD results show that local authorities in counties with

higher proportion of aging and young population (related to those in the active population) face a

greater challenge in their quest to offer public services efficiently

The influence of mcf is like that found by Pacheco et al (2013) with municipalities more

dependent on central transfers showing more efficiency31 Political influence captured by the

variable mayor did not show a significant effect This result is like other studies concluding that

the ideological position did not have a significant influence on efficiency (Benito et al 2010

Boetti et al 2009 Cordero Pedraja-Chaparro Pisaflores amp Polo 2017)

30 This negative coefficient suggests that the negative effects of agglomeration economies such as overcrowding pollution high cost of land and traffic congestion could predominate over the positive effects of scale economies in regional capitals 31 When the analysis is conducted for each zone independently MCF displays a negative influence in the North and Centre-North areas but a positive influence in the Centre-South and South areas These results confirm that on the one hand richer municipalities (those in the North and Centre-North) have less incentives for efficient management of their resources On the other hand results support the relevance of MCF helping poorer municipalities (those in the South) to reach their outcomes

87

Table 35

Panel data regressions

88

35 Conclusions

The trade-off between equity and efficiency is in the core of the economic discussion This

ldquoprinciplerdquo has been used by policymakers to prioritize the design of policies focused on economic

growth delaying those policies aimed at reducing economic inequalities This essay offers

empirical evidence of a negative relationship between inequality and efficiency that is a reduction

of income inequality could have positive effects on economic efficiency at least at the level of

local governments

We followed a traditional Two-Stage approach commonly used in the analysis of LGE We

compared cross-sectional and panel data results and we have added an instrumental variable

approach to give a causal interpretation to the link between efficiency and inequality We proposed

the use of a measure of natural resource dependence to instrumentalize the impact of income

inequality on LGE Given that our units of analysis are municipalities and not counties we argue

that our measure of NRD is correlated with income inequality and it does not have a direct

influence on LGE

We found that Chilean municipalities perform better than previous studies suggest

Municipal efficiency depicted significant levels of positive spatial autocorrelation and most of the

municipalities showed to be operating under increasing or decreasing returns to scale This would

imply that the policies generally used to improve efficiency such as amalgamation or cooperation

should be implemented observing the reality of each region and not as strategies at the national

level We also found that scale inefficiency explains a small proportion of the average total

inefficiency reason why the analysis of external factors that could affect the municipal efficiency

takes greater relevance

89

Income inequality plays an important part in explaining municipal efficiency In fact it was

found that reductions in income inequality could result in increases in municipal efficiency in a

similar proportion An unexpected finding was that the levels of education shows a negative

association with municipal performance This could be due to a low average level of education or

the existence of an omitted variable This variable could be the significant reduction in voting

turnout rates for local and national elections due to changes in the voting system during the period

of our analysis All in all our results may help to shed light on the potential consequences of

changes in contextual factors and the design of strategies aimed to increase municipal efficiency

in countries with similar characteristics to the Chilean economy For instance policies oriented to

take advantage of economies of scale can be formulated merging municipalities or establishing

networks in specific sectors such as education or health

Further work needs to be done both in measurement and in the explanation of differences in

municipal performance in Chile One area of future work will be to identify the factors that better

predict why municipalities operates under increasing decreasing or constant returns to scale

Multinomial logistic regression and the application of machine learning algorithms to SINIM data

sets appear as suitable methods for that purpose Intertemporal DEA (Drew amp Dollery 2015)

should be used to measure municipal efficiency capturing changes in total factor productivity In

addition municipalities operate under different levels of geographical authorities such as the

provincial mayor and the regional governor Hence it would be useful to know how each

municipality performs within each region-zone related to how performs to the whole country This

should be done conducting a metafrontier analysis (OrsquoDonnell Rao amp Battese 2008)

We have also identified through a cross sectional spatial exploratory analysis that on

average municipalities with similar levels of efficiency tend to cluster in space Regarding to

90

analyse the importance of contextual factors on municipal efficiency a deeper analysis should use

censored spatial models to check the significance of the spatial dimension in cross-sectional and

panel contexts Another interesting avenue for future research is associated with the negative

association found between LGE and education The significant reduction in votersacute turnout since

the law of automatic registration and voluntary voting in 2011 appears as a natural experiment to

analyse its effects on efficiency indicators such as municipal performance Incorporating variables

such as the voting turnout in each county or classifying municipalities based on individual

institutional political and economic characteristics could help to shed light on which of these

channels is the most relevant when analysing the impact of inequality on municipal efficiency

Finally we argued that an important part of the influence of income inequality over LGE

could be through its indirect effect on trust social capital and social cohesion The final essay will

delve deep in that relationship

91

Chapter 4 Social Cohesion Incivilities and Diversity

Evidence at the municipal level in Chile

41 Introduction

A deterioration in social cohesion could carry significant costs such as a reduction in

generalized trust between individuals and in institutions a society caught in a vicious circle of

inequality and citizens increasingly distanced from civic life (Uslaner 2011) A growing feeling

of frustration and discontentment can eventually translate into a social outbreak with uncertain

results This is precisely what have been happening in many countries around the world included

Chile

ldquoSocial cohesion is a state of affairs concerning both the vertical and the horizontal

interactions among members of society as characterized by a set of attitudes and norms that

includes trust a sense of belonging and the willingness to participate and help as well as their

behavioural manifestationsrdquo (Chan et al 2006) This definition highlights the multidimensionality

in the concept of social cohesion which has been measured using objective andor subjective

indicators of trust social norms solidarity willingness to participate in social and political groups

and feelings of belonging (Ariely 2014 Chan et al 2006) Multidimensionality also implies that

the impact of determinants of social cohesion such as economic and racial diversity could be

different for each of its various dimensions (Ariely 2014)

A common characteristic to all societies is that they are made up of different groups that

differ with respect to race ethnicity income religion language local identity etc The

92

Community Heterogeneity Thesis (Coffeacute amp Geys 2006) argues that individuals prefer to interact

with others that are like themselves Hence high levels of diversity particularly economic and

racial represent a complex scenario to maintain social cohesion One of the most common factors

adduced for social cohesion is income inequality with higher levels linked to lower levels of trust

(Ariely 2014 Rothstein amp Uslaner 2005)

Traditional measures of social cohesion may not be adequately capturing the deterioration

in social connections For instance measures of (lack of) trust include a strong subjective element

On the other hand proxies for social participation such as volunteering jobs or joining to social

organizations have not been supported by empirical evidence as a source of generalized social trust

(Rothstein amp Uslaner 2005) We proposed to use the rate of incivilities which we argue is a more

appropriate measure of the degree of worsening in the social context

Incivilities are those visible disorders in the public space that violate respectful social norms

and tend not to be treated as crimes by the criminal justice system There are two types of

incivilities social and physical Social incivilities include antisocial behaviours such as public

drinking noisy neighbours and fighting in public places Physical incivilities include among

others vandalism graffiti abandoned cars and garbage on the streets Because citizens and

political authorities cannot always distinguish between incivilities and crime they are usually

treated as an additional category of crime This implies that policies aimed to reduce incivilities

are generally based on punitive actions However theory and evidence on incivilities suggest that

factors explaining incivilities and crime could be different (Lewis 2017 Taylor 1999)

In Chile crime rates have shown a sustained downward trend after reaching its highest level

in 2011 On the other hand incivilities rate has shown a sustained upward trend which coincides

with the increasing victimization and feeling of insecurity in the population This has motivated

93

Chilean authorities based on the ldquoBroken Windows Theoryrdquo to propose new punitive actions (or

increase the severity of the current ones) to those who commit this type of antisocial behaviours

The ldquoBroken Windows Theoryrdquo states that higher rates of incivilities are a signal of social

disorganization which result in higher crime rates (J Q Wilson amp Kelling 1982) This is expected

to have consequences on familiesrsquo decisions such as moving away from public spaces or even

leaving their neighbourhoods

As far as we know there is no previous evidence about the potential causes of incivilities in

Chile Efforts to identify the factors explaining incivilities could help not only to reduce the risk

factors favouring violent and property crimes but also to guide interventions aimed to change

social behaviours and strengthen social cohesion in highly unequal societies Thus the main

contribution of the present study is to provide a deeper comprehension of the problem of incivilities

and how they can help to better understand the weakening of social cohesion that many

contemporary societies experience

We aim to offer the first evidence on the factors explaining the evolution and the differences

in incivilities rates in Chile We set up a panel for six years (2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and

2017) and 324 counties (1944 observations) We start exploring the evolution and geographical

distribution of incivilities Then we investigate whether economic and racial diversity after

controlling for other socioeconomic demographic and municipal characteristics can be regarded

as key predictors of incivilities

We use the Gini coefficient to proxy economic heterogeneity and the number of new visas

granted to foreigners as proportion of the county population as proxy for racial diversity The main

hypothesis is whether economic and racial diversity have a positive association with the rate of

incivilities In addition to the arguments regarding the ldquoCommunity Heterogeneity Thesisrdquo Taylor

94

(1999) and Skogan (1986 1999 2015) argue that incivilities are caused by inequality and the lack

of informal mechanisms of social control Based on the ldquoIncivilities Thesisrdquo the patterns of

incivilities should mirror the patterns of inequality (Taylor 1999) Then higher inequality should

be associated with higher physical and social vulnerability of the population This reduces social

control and increases social disorganization which triggers antisocial or negligent behaviours

Our main result reveals a strong positive association between the rate of incivilities and the

number of new visas granted per year The relationship with income inequality although also

positive seems to be less significant These findings give strong support to the ldquoCommunity

Heterogeneity Thesisrdquo and to a lesser extent to the ldquoIncivilities Thesisrdquo When the analysis is

disaggregated geographically racial diversity shows a clear positive effect The impact of income

inequality seems to be conditional depending on the level of income showing no effect in poorer

regions Results also show that the impact of economic and racial diversity differs by type of

incivility For example income inequality shows a strong association with ldquoStreet Tradingrdquo while

racial diversity with ldquoAlcohol Consumptionrdquo Two are the main policy implications On the one

hand a national strategy to address the problems associated with foreign immigration could help

to reduce incivilities For instance a joint effort between national and local authorities to curb

immigration and its distribution throughout the country On the other hand our results show that

the relationship between incivilities and economic diversity differs depending on the region or

geographical area Hence the impact on social cohesion of policies aimed to tackle economic

inequalities should be analysed in each specific context

The rate of incivilities also shows a negative association with the level of municipal financial

autonomy This implies that municipalities can effectively carry out policies to reduce incivilities

beyond the efforts of the central government Another important finding is that our results do not

95

support the hypothesis that a higher proportion of the young population is associated with higher

rates of incivilities Hence policies aimed to reduce incivilities should be focused on the causes of

incivilities rather than the criminalization of behaviours or stigmatization of specific population

groups

The structure of the chapter is as follows Section 42 outlines the relevant literature on social

cohesion and incivilities Section 43 describes the data variables and methodology and

establishes the hypotheses of the study Section 44 contains the results and discussions Section

45 presents the main conclusions

42 Related Literature

421 The Community Heterogeneity Thesis

The idea under ldquoThe Community Heterogeneity Thesisrdquo is that if individuals prefer to

interact with others who are similar to themselves in terms of income race or ethnicity high levels

of income inequality and racial diversity facilitate a context for lower tolerance and antisocial

behaviours lowering the ldquostaterdquo of social cohesion (Alesina 2000 Coffeacute amp Geys 2006 Letki

2008) Alessina and Ferrara (2002) give support to this hypothesis arguing that individuals have a

natural aversion to heterogeneity However the most popular explanation is the principle of

homophily people prefer to interact with others who share the same ethnic heritage have the same

social status and hence share experiences and tastes (Letki 2008 McPherson Smith-Lovin amp

Cook 2001 Tolsma et al 2009) For instance Delhey and Newton (2005) find for a sample of

60 countries that income inequality and ethnicity are strongly and negatively correlated with trust

Tolsma et al (2009) using data for Dutch neighbourhoods and municipalities find that social

cohesion is negatively and consistently affected by economic deprivation but not by ethnic

96

heterogeneity These authors also conclude that the effect of neighbourhood and municipal

characteristics on social cohesion depends on residentsrsquo income and educational level

Rothstein and Uslaner (2005) give two theoretical reasons why economic and racial diversity

should be causally related to social trust a key element of social cohesion First optimism about

the future makes less sense when there is more economic inequality which generally translates into

inequality of opportunities especially in areas such as education and the labour market Second

the distribution of resources and opportunities plays a key role in establishing the belief that people

share a common destiny and have similar fundamental values In highly unequal societies people

are likely to stick with their own kind Perceptions of injustice will reinforce negative stereotypes

of other groups making social trust and accommodation more difficult

Uslaner (2002 2011) and Uslaner and Brown (2005) find that high levels of inequality are

the single major factor driving down trust in people who are different from yourself Evidence for

USA finds that inequality is the strongest determinant of generalized trust over time (Rothstein amp

Uslaner 2005) Reducing inequality and then increasing generalized trust should have positive

consequences at the individual and aggregates levels At the individual level it may lead to greater

tolerance and more acts of altruism for people of different backgrounds At the aggregate level it

may lead to greater economic growth more redistribution from the rich to the poor and less

corruption (Uslaner 2002 2013) Letki (2008) argues that when neighbourhood socio-economic

context (apart from just an individualrsquos socioeconomic status) is considered it turns out to be the

main factor triggering negative attitudes and lack of trust in out-group members

The increasing diversity caused by immigration can also reduce the conditions necessary for

social cohesion (Ariely 2014 Holtug amp Mason 2010) Christel Kesler and Irene Bloemraad

(2010) find for nineteen advanced democracies between 1981 and 2000 that increasing migration

97

generally decreases trust civic engagement and political participation The authors also find that

in more equal countries with clear policies in favour of cultural minorities the negative effects of

migration are mitigated or even reversed Letki (2008) states that deprivation and disorder tend to

be strongly correlated with racial diversity Because we propose the use of the number of disorders

or antisocial behaviours known as ldquoincivilitiesrdquo as our measure of social cohesion we describe the

literature on incivilities in the next section

422 The literature on incivilities

The study of incivilities has been a continuing concern mainly for developed countries since

the 1980s The focus has changed from individual and psychological explanations to ecological

(contextual) and social explanations (Taylor 1999) The individual approach basically considered

perceptions of incivilities as an explanatory variable of fear of crime The ecological explanation

argues that indicators of economic disadvantage (eg income levels income inequality

unemployment rate and poverty rate) are the keys to understand a process of social disorganization

and lack of informal control These economic factors lead to higher rates of inappropriate or

negligent behaviours and ultimately to higher crime rates (Blau amp Blau 1982 Messner Rosenfeld

amp Baumer 2004 Phan Orsquobrien Mendolia amp Paloyo 2017 Sampson 1986)

The negative impact of incivilities is not merely reflected in its association with crime rates

(Skogan 2015) Physical and social incivilities could worsen neighbourhoods by affecting quality

of life perception of the environment and public and private behaviours Previous research has

indicated that a higher level of incivilities is associated with health problems (Branas et al 2011

Cohen et al 2000 Hill amp Angel 2005 Ross 2011 Ross amp Mirowsky 2001) greater

victimization and fear of crime (Brunton-Smith Jackson amp Sutherland 2014 Mijanovich amp

Weitzman 2003) and multiple negative economic effects For instance incivilities could be

98

related to a reduction in commercial activity lower investment in real estate reduction in house

prices (Skogan 2015) and population instability (Hipp 2010)

To describe the state of the art in the study of incivilities and their consequences Skogan

(2015) used the concept of untidiness to characterize the research on incivilities The study of

incivilities has had multiple approaches (economic ecological and psychological) Incivilities

have also been measured using multiple sources of information (police reports surveys trained

observation) which result in different measures (perceptions vs count data) However the question

about what specific factors have the strongest effect on incivilities has been overlooked and

perceptions about incivilities have been used mainly as a predictor of crime fear of crime and

victimization

There are two types of incivilities social and physical Social incivilities are a matter of

behaviour including groups of rowdy teens public drunkenness people fighting and street hassles

Physical incivilities involve visual signs of negligence and decay such as abandoned buildings

broken streetlights trash-filled lots and graffiti (Skogan 1999 2015 Taylor 1999) Three reasons

justify the distinction between physical and social incivilities First like multiple dimensions of

social cohesion different structural and social conditions could be responsible for different types

and categories of incivilities Second punitive sanctions are expected to have a greater impact on

physical than on social incivilities since the latter are more related to behaviours rooted in citizensrsquo

culture Third physical incivilities should be more related to absolute measures of economic

disadvantage (eg poverty or unemployment rates) and social incivilities to relative indicators of

economic disadvantage (eg such as income inequality) This line of research is based on the

ldquoincivilities thesisrdquo which states that to understand the distribution of disorders it is necesary to

analyse the patterns of structured inequalities (Skogan 1986 Taylor 1999)

99

423 The ldquoIncivilities Thesisrdquo

Incivilities theories began with a focus on psychological dynamics (Garofalo 1978) moved

forward to an interest in social psychological processes (J Q Wilson amp Kelling 1982) and finally

evolved into a focus on community dynamics and outcomes (Skogan 1999) Individual and group

behaviours in tandem with ecological features have been proposed as the key factors explaining

incivilities and their posterior influence on social control quality of life and more serious crime

(J Q Wilson amp Kelling 1982)

In terms of ecological factors particularly those related to economic conditions Skogan

(1986) was the first linking the distribution of incivilities to the patterns of structural inequality If

incivilities mirror inequality structure this will have consequences in residentsrsquo health and safety

due to its levels of vulnerability In addition structured inequality associated with the proportion

of the manufacturing sector (eg when fabrics tend to move from cities to farther areas) will be

related to higher social disorganization and differences between urban and rural areas (W J

Wilson 1996) In addition a persistent feeling of relative deprivation (persistently high levels of

income inequality) could lead to fellow inhabitants of the community to commit antisocial

behaviours showing their frustration with the current economic model

The literature on incivilities posits that their causes are different from those of crime (Lewis

2017) Unlike crime analysis especially property crimes information on the location where the

incivility takes place is the same as the location where the perpetrator resides To achieve a

comprehensive understanding of the different types of incivilities it is crucial to consider

incivilities data covering an entire territory and not just specific areas (Hooghe Vanhoutte

Hardyns amp Bircan 2010) If we add to this the availability of panel data it could be possible not

100

only to identify the main determinants of incivilities but also the causal mechanism from income

inequality towards incivilities rate

In Chile citizen security crime and delinquency are among the most significant issues for

citizens based on opinion polls Existing research has found weak evidence of a significant

relationship between crime and indicators of socio-economic disadvantage such as income

inequality and unemployment rate with significant effects only on property crime (Beyer amp

Vergara 2006 Nuntildeez Rivera Villavicencio amp Molina 2003 Rivera Gutieacuterrez amp Nuacutentildeez 2009)

Crime deterrence variables such as the probability of being caught or the number of police

resources have also shown ambiguous results (Beyer amp Vergara 2006 Rivera et al 2009

Vergara 2012) Evidence at the county level shows that crime is higher in urban counties those

with a lower mean income per capita and counties located in the North of the country In addition

at least half of the crimes reported in one county are perpetrated by criminals from other counties

(Rivera et al 2009) No studies could be found about the determinants of incivilities

4 3 Methodology

431 Period of analysis and data sample

Chile is a relatively small country in Latin America with a population of 18346018

inhabitants in 2017 The country is divided into 345 municipalities with on average 53104

inhabitants (median value 18705) Municipalities are the organ of the State Administration

responsible to solve local needs Municipalities are not only the relevant political and

administrative local unit of analysis but also they represent the feeling of lsquocommunityrsquo among

the inhabitants of each municipality (Hooghe et al 2010) Our data includes many sources of

101

heterogeneity among municipalities such as indicators of economic deprivation population

density demographic characteristics and whether the county is a regional or provincial capital

We use a sample of 324 municipalities covering most of the Chilean territory for the period

2006ndash17 Data on incivilities is obtained from the ldquoCentre of Studies and Analysis of Crimerdquo

which is part of the ldquoSubsecretaria de Prevencion del Delitordquo (SPD in its Spanish acronym) of the

Chilean government32 Information on income inequality and control variables is obtained from

the ldquoNational Socioeconomic Characterization Surveyrdquo (CASEN in its Spanish acronym) the

ldquoNational Institute of Statisticsrdquo (INE in its Spanish acronym) the ldquoNational Municipal

Information Systemrdquo (SINIM in its Spanish acronym) and the Immigration Department of the

Government of Chile Our panel only includes the years for which CASEN survey is available

2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017

432 Operationalisation of the response variable and exploratory analysis

Official Chilean records contain information for the total number of cases of incivilities per

year at the county level The number of cases is the sum of complains and detentions reported at

the police Our dependent variable 119894119899119888119894119907119894119897119894119905119894119890119904 correspond to the number of cases per year Due

to population differences comparisons between counties are made using the incivilities rate per

1000 population calculated as

119894119899119888119894119907_119903119886119905119890 lowast 1000 (41)

where 119894119899119888119894119907_119903119886119905119890 is the incivilities rate 119905 is the year 119894 the county and 119899 is the population of the

county per year

32 httpceadspdgovclestadisticas-delictuales

102

Figure 41 illustrates at the top the evolution of the total number (cases reported) of

incivilities and crimes at the country level for the period 2006-1733 At the bottom Figure 41

shows the evolution of the mean county rate per 1000 inhabitants We observe that both the number

of incivilities and the number of crimes has reached similar annual figures however average

county rates per 1000 population show different trends Crime rate displays a sustained fall after

reaching its pick in 2011 Incivilities average county rate which also reached a pick and posterior

drop in 2011 has recovered its upward trend since 2016 considerably exceeding the crime rate

Figure 41 Evolution number and rates of incivilities and crime (DMCS) in Chile 2006-2017

33 Crime refers to ldquocrimes of greater social connotationrdquo (DMCS in its Spanish acronym) which includes violent and property crimes

103

Chilean records classify incivilities in nine categories most of them associated with social

incivilities Summary statistics for the total and for each of the nine categories are presented in

Table 41 In addition Figure 42 shows the evolution of incivilities by category for the whole

period We see that the global trend in incivilities is mainly due to a substantial increase in ldquoStreet

Tradingrdquo and ldquoPublic Alcohol Consumptionrdquo A common element of Figures 41 and 42 is the

significant change in trend experienced by crimes and incivilities in 2011 That year the SPD

became dependent on the Ministry of Interior of the Chilean Government This event put the issue

of crime and delinquency within national priorities for the central government

Table 41

Summary statistics total count of incivilities and by category (full sample and period)

Unlike crime rates we do not expect significant cross-county spillover effects in incivilities

However the questions of where incivilities are concentrated and why they are there can be of

great interest (Skogan 2015) Figure 43 shows quantile maps for the rate of incivilities per 1000

inhabitants for the initial and final years in our panel

104

Figure 42 Evolution total number of incivilities by category

Figure 43 Spatial distribution of incivilities rate per 1000 inhabitants (2006 vs 2017)

105

We observe that the range of values has increased significantly from 2006 to 2017 but the

spatial distribution remains almost unchanged On the one hand high incivilities rates in the North

could be associated with the mining activity On the other hand high rates in the Centre area

(where the countyrsquos capital is located) could be related to the higher population density and the

concentration of the economic activity34

To see how the different types of incivilities are distributed throughout the country we have

grouped those similar categories in four groups ldquoPublic Damagerdquo (ldquoPublic Disturbsrdquo ldquoPublic

Damagerdquo ldquoOtherrdquo) ldquoThreatsrdquo (ldquoPublic Fightrdquo ldquoThreatsrdquo and ldquoAnnoying Noisesrdquo) ldquoAlcohol

Consumptionrdquo (ldquoPublic Alcohol Consumptionrdquo and ldquoDrunkennessrdquo) and ldquoStreet Tradingrdquo This

distinction in groups could be relevant if we expect different patterns and different effects of

community heterogeneity on social cohesion among counties For instance we expect higher

levels of Public Damage in big urban cities Street trading is more likely in urban cities but also in

tourist areas The spatial distribution of these four groups for the six-year-average rate per 1000

inhabitants can be found in Appendix R

433 Measures of community heterogeneity and control variables

Social cohesion income inequality and racial diversity are all ldquocommunityrdquo (not individual)

characteristics Thus to understand their relationship we need aggregated data at least at the

county-municipal level With more disaggregated data like at the suburbs level the required

heterogeneity among groups of citizens is lost (Wilkinson 1999) Like Coffeacute and Geys (2006) we

use the Gini coefficient to capture economic heterogeneity However instead of a measured for

34 We also analysed the spatial distribution of crime rates In general areas with high levels of incivilities not necessarily are associated with high levels of crime This could imply that factors explaining incivilities and crime are different

106

the diversity of nationalities we use the proportion of foreign population to capture racial

heterogeneity Income data is obtained from the CASEN survey The Gini coefficient is calculated

for each county and included through the variable gini Racial heterogeneity is included through

the variable foreign which is the annual number of new VISAS granted to foreigners as a

proportion of the county population Chile has experienced a significant increase in immigration

since 2011 Immigration has been concentrated in the metropolitan region and mining regions in

the North of the country We expect a positive relationship between immigration and incivilities

although as with the relationship between immigration and crime the foundations for this

hypothesis are not strong (Hooghe et al 2010 Sampson 2008)

Economic development is another explanation for social cohesion frequently appealed to

explain trust with wealthier societies considered to exhibit higher levels of trust (Delhey amp

Newton 2005) In this study we include the natural log of the mean household income per capita

log(income) We also include the poverty rate poverty and the unemployment rate

unemployment Unlike the variable log(income) these variables are expected to be positively

associated with the number of incivilities When a relative indicator of economic heterogeneity

such as income inequality is included as determinant of social cohesion we should expect less

effect from absolute indicators of economic disadvantage such as poverty and unemployment rates

(Hooghe et al 2010 Tolsma et al 2009)

Among demographic variables the percentage of inhabitants between 10 and 24 years old is

included through the variable youth The variable women defined as the proportion of the female

population in each county is also included Variable youth is expected to have an ambiguous effect

Although young people have lower victimization and report rates they also represent the group

more likely to commit antisocial behaviours when a community has a low capacity of self-

107

regulation (eg when there is low parental supervision) The female population is associated with

a higher report of incivilities related to the male population

It is argued that crime and incivilities are essentially urban problems (Christiansen 1960

Wirth 1938) We include the variable log(density) defined as the log of population density (the

number of inhabitants divided by the area of each county in square kilometres) and a dummy

variable capital indicating whether a county is an administrative capital (provincial or regional)

Two additional variables are included to capture the level of informal social control exerted

by families living in each municipality First the variable education which is defined as the

average years of education of people over 15 years old Second the variable housing which capture

the proportion of families which are owners of their housing unit Although education and housing

are related to both the possibility of reporting and committing an incivility we expect a negative

association with the rate of incivilities

In Chile crime has been mainly a problem faced by the police and the Central Government

Administration To control for current law enforcement policies we include the variable

deterrence defined as the number of arrests as a proportion of the total number of incivilities cases

In addition municipalities can develop their own initiatives to deal with crime and incivilities

depending on their capacity to generate its own resources The level of financial autonomy from

central transfers is captured by the variable autonomy This variable is obtained from SINIM and

it is defined as the proportion of the budget revenue of each municipality that comes from its own

permanent sources of revenues A categorical variable mayor is also included This variable

indicates whether the municipality mayor is supported by the ldquoLEFTrdquo or the ldquoRIGHTrdquo political

parties (related to those ldquoINDEPENDENTrdquo mayors)

108

Table 42 presents descriptive statistics for our measures of income and racial heterogeneity

and the set of numeric control variables The Pearson correlation among these variables is shown

in Appendix S

Table 42

Summary statistics numeric explanatory variables

434 Methods

The annual count of incivilities as is characteristic for count data is highly concentrated in

a relatively small range of values In addition the distribution is right-skewed due to the presence

of important outliers (counties with a high number of incivilities) Figure 44 shows the

distribution of the six-year average number of incivilities for each of the 15 regions in Chile35 We

observe that regions differ in the number of counties in which they are divided In addition

counties within each region show important differences in the number of incivilities For instance

35 Regions are ordered from left to right and from top to bottom in the way they are geographically distributed from North to South So the northernmost region of the country is the ldquoXVrdquo and the southernmost region is the ldquoXIIrdquo The Metropolitan region (where the countryrsquos capital is located) is region ldquoXIIIrdquo in the centre of the country (see Appendix C)

109

excepting the Metropolitan region ldquoXIIIrdquo most counties in regions located in the centre of the

country (middle row in Figure 44) show a range of incivilities between 0 and 2000 The number

of incivilities is considerably lower in counties located in the northern (top row in Figure 44) and

southern (bottom row in Figure 44) regions of the country compared to regions in the centre of

the country It also seems clear from Figure 44 that the number of incivilities does not follow a

normal distribution

Figure 44 Annual average number of incivilities per county

The number of incivilities can be better described by a Poisson distribution In this case the

number of incivilities is ldquothe countrdquo and the number of incivilities per year is ldquothe rate per unit

timerdquo We are interested in modelling the average number of incivilities per year usually called 120582

as a function of a set of contextual factors to explain differences in incivilities between and within

110

counties The main characteristic of the Poisson distribution is that the mean is equal to the

variance This implies that as the mean rate for a Poisson variable increases the variance also

increases The main implication is we cannot use OLS to model 120582 as a function of the set of

contextual factors because the equal variance assumption in linear regression is violated

The rate of incivilities between counties is not directly comparable due to population

differences We expect counties with more people to have more reports of incivilities since there

are more people who could be affected To capture differences in population which is called the

exposure of our response variable 120582 it is necessary to include a term on the right side of our model

called an offset We will use the log of the county population in thousands as our offset36

Additionally similar to the case of crime data incivilities show a significant degree of

overdispersion (variance higher than the mean) suggesting that there is more variation in the

response than the Poisson model implies37 We also model and regress incivilities assuming a

Negative Binomial distribution to address overdispersion An advantage of this approach is that it

introduces a dispersion parameter in addition to 120582 which gives the model more flexibility38

Considering as the response variable the count of incivilities per year the model can be

expressed as follow

120582 119890119909119901 120573 120573 119892119894119899119894 120573 119891119900119903119890119894119892119899 119883120574 120572 120579 (42)

36 If we think of 120582 as the average number of incivilities per year then represents the number per 1000

inhabitants so that the yearly count is adjusted to be comparable across counties of different sizes Adjusting the yearly count by population is equivalent to adding 119897119900119892 1199011199001199011199061198971198861199051198941199001198991000 to the right-hand side of the regression equation 37 Without adjusting for overdispersion we use incorrect artificially small standard errors leading to artificially small p-values for model coefficients 38 The Negative Binomial model posits selecting a 120582 (average number of incivilities) for each county and then generating a count using a Poisson random variable with the selected 120582 With this approach the counts will be more dispersed than would be expected for observations based on a single Poisson variable with rate 120582

111

where 120582 is the rate of incivilities 119883 is our vector of controls 120572prime119904 are county-specific constants

and 120579prime119904 are time-specific constants Accounting for differences in county population we have

119890119909119901 120573 120573 119892119894119899119894 119883120574 120572 120579 (43)

where 119901119900119901119906119897119886119905119894119900119899 is the county population per year Hence the model to be estimated using

Maximum Likelihood Estimation (MLE) is

119897119900119892 120582 120573 120573 119892119894119899119894 119883120574 120572 120579 119897119900119892 (44)

Finally to account for different effects depending on the type of incivilities we also run

equation (44) for each of the four groups of incivilities defined in section (432)

435 Hypotheses

Based on the community heterogeneity hypothesis the relationship between social cohesion

and diversity should be stronger for lower levels of income and less educated groups of people

(Tolsma et al 2009) Hence contrary to evidence for developed and more equal countries we

expect a significant positive association for the Chilean case where more than 50 of the

population is economically vulnerable (OECD 2017)

The main hypotheses to be tested in this essay is whether the number of incivilities is

positively associated with the level of economic and racial heterogeneity at the county level We

start analysing this association for the full sample and period Next we analyse whether the

relationship between incivilities and our measures of diversity differs by geographic area (region

or zone) Finally we check whether the effect of economic and racial diversity is different

depending on the group of incivilities

112

44 Results and Discussion

Overall our results show that the rate of incivilities displays a stronger and more significant

relationship with racial diversity than with economic heterogeneity This association differs for

different geographic areas and for different types of incivilities Absolute economic indicators

except for income show a significant but small effect Increases in the average levels of income

or education and more financial autonomy for municipalities seem to be effective ways to reduce

the rate of incivilities

We estimate equation (44) assuming that the number of incivilities follows a Poisson

distribution Regional and temporal heterogeneity are captured through the inclusion of dummy

variables for five years (with 2006 as the reference year) and fourteen regional dummies (with

region XIII as the reference region) Results are reported in Table 4339 This table is structured in

two blocks of regressions pooled models in columns (1)-(4) and fixed-effects models in columns

(5)-(8)40 The first column in each block only includes economic indicators relative and absolute

trying to test which ones are more relevant and whether incivilities tend to mirror income

inequality (the ldquoincivilities thesisrdquo) The second column adds the variable foreign to account for

the effect of racial diversity (Letki 2008) The third column includes education to check whether

the association between economic and racial diversity with social cohesion changes (gets less

significant) when we control for educational level (Tolsma et al 2009) The final column in each

block corresponds to the full model specification which includes the rest of controls

39 Pooled estimations were obtained using the R command glm() and compared with results obtained from the command poisson in STATA 15 Fixed effects and random effects models were estimated using the STATA command xtpoisson Negative Binomial models were estimated using the command glmnb() in the MASS package for R and commands nbreg and xtnbreg in STATA 15 Results for Negative Binomial regressions are in Appendix T 40 We have omitted results with random effects due to the literature on panel count data models suggest that the most robust estimator is Poisson regression with Fixed Effects (Santos Silva amp Tenreyro 2010 2011)

113

Table 43

Poisson regressions

114

The positive and significant coefficient for the variable gini besides being small it becomes

insignificant in the fixed effects specification which includes the full set of controls This result

does not seem to be enough evidence to support our hypothesis that more unequal counties display

higher rates of incivilities On the other hand racial diversity through the variable foreign shows

a consistent positive association with the rate of incivilities41 Together coefficients for gini and

foreign seems to support the ldquocommunity heterogeneity thesisrdquo (Letki 2008) but not the

ldquoincivilities thesisrdquo (Skogan 1999) To check this finding we run the pooled full model

specification for each region and results are shown in Table 44 where regions have been ordered

from North to South The sign of the coefficient of the variable gini differs for different regions

Moreover the relationship is insignificant in some of the most unequal regions which are in the

South of the country (VIII IX and XIV) This result rejects the hypothesis that incivilities mirror

structural income inequalities For the variable foreign 12 out of 15 regions confirm the positive

association with the rate of incivilities42

We also run our pooled full model separately for each group of incivilities defined at the end

of section (432) Income inequality keeps its significant but small association with each group of

incivilities (see Table 45) Our measure of racial diversity shows a stronger association with

ldquoAlcohol Consumptionrdquo related to ldquoPublic Damagerdquo and ldquoThreatsrdquo The link with ldquoStreet Tradingrdquo

appears as non-significant These results support our general finding that on the one hand racial

heterogeneity exert a more significant influence on the rate of incivilities than economic

41 To get the effects of the variables gini and foreign over the rate of incivilities per 1000 inhabitants we need to exponentiate their coefficients Thus an increase in one unit in the variable gini increases the rate of incivilities per 1000 inhabitantsrdquo in 1005 times (e^0005) in the pooled full model Similarly an increase in one point in variable foreign is expected to increase the ldquorate of incivilities per 1000 inhabitantsrdquo in 10876 times (e^0084) in the full pooled model and 10471 (e^0046) times in the full Fixed Effects model 42 Given that depending on the geographic location regions share certain characteristics the model was also run clustering regions in 4 zones (see Figure 31 in chapter 3) Results by zone are in Appendix U

115

heterogeneity On the other hand results confirm our hypothesis that the effect of diversity is

different for different types of incivilities

Table 44 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson models by region

Back to our general results in Table 43 the significant and negative coefficient of the

income variable and to a lesser extent the significant and positive coefficients of poverty and

unemployment provide evidence that absolute rather than relative economic indicators may be

more important explanations of the rate of incivilities This is opposite to evidence for the analysis

116

of crime rates such as in Hoodge (2010) and support the idea that determinants of incivilities are

different from those of crime Our results are also opposite to those for Dutch municipalities where

economic indicators turned out to be more important than ethnic heterogeneity (Tolsma et al

2009) The coefficient for the variable log(income) could be interpreted as counties with an income

level under the average face higher problems of antisocial behaviours such as incivilities In

addition as the income level moves far away from its average low level the problem of incivilities

is less relevant43 In terms of policy implications only those policies that achieve a significant

increase in the average level of county income seem to be effective in reducing incivilities and

strengthening social cohesion

Table 45 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson model by incivility group

43 We ran our model splitting the sample of counties in quintiles based on their income level The coefficient for the variable gini only showed a significant (and positive) coefficient for the second third and fourth quintile A non-significant coefficient for the first quintile could imply that other types of inequalities (eg health education) are more relevant in the poorest counties In the case of the fifth quintile (the richest group of counties) they have better facilities in terms of infrastructure police resources self-protection etc which could reduce the potential triggers of incivilities

117

The inclusion of the variable education significantly improved the goodness of fit of the

models and did not generate significant changes in the coefficients of our measures of economic

and racial diversity This result rejects the proposition that the relationship between social

cohesion and diversity becomes less strong when controlled by education (Tolsma et al 2009)

Additionally it highlights the topic of education as a relevant determinant of the rate of incivilities

and social cohesion

Among control variables there are also some important results Opposite to what we

expected the variable youth shows a negative or non-significant coefficient Although this result

could be due to the lack of ldquophysical incivilitiesrdquo in Chilean records it indicates that it is incorrect

to stereotype this group as the main responsible for high incivilities rates The significant and

negative coefficient of the variable autonomy in the fixed effects specification could also have

important policy implications It is a signal that local governments can play an important role in

reducing incivilities or complementing the efforts from the central government Another

interesting result is the significant coefficient of the variable housing The latter finding is

particularly important in the sense that a negative sign supports public policies oriented to increase

homeownership as effective ways to improve social cohesion However the small magnitude of

the coefficient that even showed the opposite sign in some model specifications could be

explained for the high level of segregation that these policies have generated in Chilean society

As mentioned in the Introduction and Literature Review so far only a few studies have

used measures of disorders or incivilities as dependent variable to explain changes in social

cohesion (Skogan 2015) In addition there is no evidence in Chile analysing the determinants of

incivilities separately from those of crimes The importance of our results on identifying the

importance of economic and racial diversity on social cohesion lies mainly in its generality An

118

important number of countries all around the world share a similar context characterized by high

levels of inequality and an explosive increase in immigration These countries are also

experiencing a worsening in social cohesion which increases the risk of a social outburst

4 5 Conclusions

The main goal of this essay was to determine whether differences in incivilities at the county

level mirror differences in income distribution and racial diversity Previous literature suggests a

positive and strong association between social cohesion and indicators of economic disadvantage

relative deprivation and racial diversity (Letki 2008 Tolsma et al 2009 Uslaner amp Brown 2005)

While not all our results were significant they showed helpful insights about how and where

economic and racial diversity are more likely to influence the rate of incivilities and social

cohesion

We used data for the period 2006ndash17 economic heterogeneity was measured through the

Gini coefficient at the county level and racial heterogeneity was proxied by the number of granted

visas to foreigners as proportion of county population We found strong evidence of a significant

and positive association between the rate of incivilities and racial diversity but not with income

inequality Contrary to previous evidence at the municipal level (Coffeacute amp Geys 2006 Tolsma et

al 2009) in general our results give support for the ldquohomophily principlerdquo and the ldquocommunity

heterogeneity hypothesisrdquo However results also showed that the effect of economic and racial

diversity varies throughout the Chilean regions and for the different types of incivilities

We also found that policies aimed at controlling the behaviour of young people did not have

strong empirical support In terms of the role that local governments may have in facing the

119

growing problem of incivilities we found evidence that efforts managed from the municipalities

can be an important complement to those from the central government

Future research should go further on the role of local authorities on incivilities and social

cohesion On the one hand municipalities could have a direct impact on social cohesion through

the implementation of programs complementary to those of central authorities oriented to reduce

incivilities and crime On the other hand social cohesion could be indirectly affected when local

authorities display an inefficient performance supplying public services to citizens or they are

recognized as corrupted institutions We suggest that policy makers from central government

should give local authorities a greater role in fighting antisocial behaviours and crime Evaluating

programs in specific municipalities could help to elucidate the causal effect of for instance higher

fiscal autonomy on the rate of incivilities

Another interesting area for future work will be to analyse how housing policies have

contributed to the phenomenon of segregation of Chilean society and in the process of weakening

social cohesion Finally our main result highlights the need of a deeper analysis of the impact that

foreign immigration is having in Chile For instance disaggregating information by country of

origin and the reasons why immigrants are arriving to the country or specific regions will surely

help to understand the impacts of immigration

120

Chapter 5 Conclusions

This thesis investigated in three essays the issue of income inequality in Chile using county-

level data for the period 2006-2017 The first essay supplied empirical evidence about the

importance of the degree of dependence on natural resources in terms of employment in explaining

cross-county differences in income inequality The second essay analysed the potential causal

effect that income inequality has on the level of technical efficiency of local governments

providing public goods and services Lastly the third essay studied the relationship between social

cohesion measured through the number of antisocial behaviours classified as ldquoincivilitiesrdquo and

the levels of income and racial heterogeneity

Findings from the first essay support the idea that the endowment of natural resources plays

a significant role in explaining income inequality in Chile However contrary to what most

theoretical and empirical evidence postulates our findings showed a robust negative association

between the two variables This means that the reduction experienced in Chile in the degree of

dependence on natural resources in terms of employment has contributed to the persistence of high

levels of income inequality The exploratory analysis indicated that income inequality shows a

general clustering process characterized by a significant and positive spatial autocorrelation

Regarding the previous evidence for Chile (Paredes et al 2016) the regression analysis confirmed

the relevance of the spatial dimension of income inequality through a process of spatial

heterogeneity giving less support to the existence of a process of spatial dependence (spillover

effect) in the variable itself

121

Essay 2 studied the potential trade-off between efficiency and equity analysing the influence

of income inequality on the efficiency of local governments at the municipal level To identify the

causal effect of income inequality on municipal efficiency we proposed the use of the proportion

of firms in the primary sector as an instrument for income inequality Findings confirmed our

hypothesis that efficiency is lower in more unequal counties This result suggests the non-existence

of the trade-off between equity and efficiency Hence policies intended to reduce inequality could

help to increase efficiency at least at the level of municipal local governments

The third essay analysed how social cohesion proxied by the rate of incivilities is associated

with the levels of economic diversity proxied by income inequality and the levels of racial

diversity proxied by the number of new visas grated as proportion of the county population

Findings gave strong support to the hypothesis that the rate of incivilities is positively related to

racial diversity and to a lesser extent to economic diversity In addition the rate of incivilities

appears negatively related to the degree of financial autonomy of municipalities This means that

local governments can effectively contribute to the reduction of incivilities which could help

reduce victimization and crime rates ultimately strengthening social cohesion

Taken together findings from essays 2 and 3 highlight the important role that income

inequality could play in other relevant economic and social dimensions These findings add to the

understanding of the potential consequences of income inequality particularly in natural resource

rich countries with persistently high levels of inequality

The present study has mainly investigated income inequality at the county level In addition

Chilean municipalities play an important role providing ldquoservices to peoplerdquo so our findings could

be applied in other highly unequal countries with a high degree of dependence on natural resources

and local governments with similar responsibilities For instance in Latin America apart from

122

Chile and Brazil there are no studies on the efficiency of local governments Other limitations are

associated with the availability of information For instance important indicators such as GDP per

capita are only available at the regional level and information of incomes is not available annually

In addition given the heterogeneity among municipalities some type of grouping of municipalities

should be performed before looking for causal relationships or conducting program evaluation

Despite these limitations we believe this study could be the basis for different strands of future

research on the topic of inequality local government efficiency and social cohesion

It was stated in chapter 2 based on the resource curse hypothesis literature there are two

elements that determine whether NR are a curse or blessing in terms of socioeconomic outcomes

First the curse is more likely in countries with weak political and governance institutions Second

different types of resources affect institutions differently with resources that are concentrated in

space so-called ldquopointrdquo resources tend to impair institutions while ldquodiffuserdquo resources do not

(Deacon 2011 Isham Woolcock Pritchett amp Busby 2005) Our results showed a negative

relationship between income inequality and our measure of natural resource dependence even after

controlling for zone fixed effects and for the level of government expenditure This result could

be interpreted as a signal that NR has a direct effect on income inequality in addition to the indirect

impact through market or institutional channels Using other potential institutional transmission

channels will shed light about the true effect that the endowment of natural resources has over

income inequality Variables that could capture these institutional channels include the level of

employment in the public sector measures of rule of law and corruption and changes in the

creation of new business in the secondary and tertiary sectors related to the primary sector

Based on results from chapter 3 most of the municipalities show scale inefficiencies One

immediate area for future work will involve using our set of contextual factors to predict the status

123

of municipalities in terms of scale inefficiencies Defining as dependent variable whether a

municipality shows constant decreasing or increasing returns to scale we could run a multinomial

logistic regression to predict municipal status For instance we would expect that a one-unit

increase in the Gini coefficient should increase the probability of scale inefficiencies (increasing

or decreasing returns to scale rather than constant returns to scale) Because the aim in this case

would be predicting a certain result in terms of returns to scale the next step should involve to

split the full sample in training and testing data sets and to use some resampling methods such as

bootstrapping This will allow us to evaluate the performance and accuracy of our model

predictions using different random samples of municipalities Results from Machine Learning

algorithms will help us to assess the generalizability of our results to other data sets

Future work should also benefit greatly by using data on different Latin American countries

to (1) compare the responsibilities of local governments (2) select a common set of inputs and

output to evaluate LGE (3) identify the relevance of scales inefficiencies in explaining differences

in performance and (4) analyse the influence of contextual characteristics over LGE Differences

in the main primary sector activity in each country such as oil in Brazil mining in Chile or Coffee

in Colombia could be responsible for differences in LGE among countries These differences could

be associated with sources of revenue management of expenditure and definitions of outputs or

contextual effects such as corrupted institutions or the delay in the development of other sectors

such as manufacturing or services

To delve deep on reasons explaining the social crisis experienced by Chilean society and

other countries one area of future work will be to analyse the relationship between diversity and

the origins of social revolutions Based on Tiruneh (2014) the three most important factors that

explain the onset of social revolutions are economic development regime type and state

124

ineffectiveness Interesting questions include whether the characteristics of Chilean context at the

end of 2019 are enough to trigger the transformation of the political and socioeconomic system

Social revolutions particularly violent revolutions are less likely in more democratic educated

and wealthy societies So it would be relevant to identify the factors explaining the violence that

has characterized the social crisis in Chile Finally the democratic regime has been maintained in

the last decades with changes between left and right governments This could imply that more

important than the regime has been the efficiency or ineffectiveness of the governments to satisfy

the needs of the population

Future work should also cover the disaggregation of information regarding foreign

population in terms of the reasons for new granted visas and the country of origin Official data

allows us to disaggregate whether the benefit is permanent (students and employees with contract)

or temporary Furthermore most of the new visas were traditionally granted to neighbouring

countries (Peru and Bolivia) a trend that has changed in the recent years to include countries such

as Colombia Venezuela and Haiti An analysis of how economic and social indicators have been

affected by changes in the composition of foreigners their reasons for immigrating to the country

and their geographical distribution have implications for economic policy at both the national and

local levels At the national level such analysis should be a key input when proposing changes to

the national immigration policy At the local level it could help define the role of municipalities

to assess the benefits and challenges of immigration These challenges are mainly related to the

provision of public goods and services such as health and education which in Chile are the

responsibility of the municipalities

The findings of this thesis suggest that policymakers should encourage policies that reduce

income inequality The key role that municipalities could play to strengthen social cohesion and

125

the increasingly important role that foreign population is acquiring in most modern societies are

also interesting avenues for future research However the picture is still incomplete and more

research is needed incorporating other dimensions of inequality This is essential if we want to

understand the reasons that could have triggered the social outbursts experienced by various

economies across the globe

126

Bibliography

Acemoglu D (1995) Reward structures and the allocation of talent European Economic Review 39(1) 17ndash33 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg1010160014-2921(94)00014-Q

Acemoglu D (2002) Technical Change Inequality and the Labor Market Journal of Economic Literature 40(1) 7ndash72 httpsdoiorg1012570022051026976

Acemoglu D Aghion P amp Violante G L (2001) Deunionization Technical Change and Inequality Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 55(1) 229ndash264 httpsdoiorg101016S0167-2231(01)00058-6

Acemoglu D Johnson S amp Robinson J A (2001) The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development An Empirical Investigation The American Economic Review 91(5) 1369ndash1401 httpsdoiorg101257aer9151369

Acemoglu D amp Robinson J A (2002) The Political Economy of the Kuznets Curve Review of Development Economics 6(2) 183ndash203 httpsdoiorg1011111467-936100149

Afonso A amp Fernandes S (2006) Measuring local government spending efficiency Evidence for the Lisbon region Regional Studies 40(1) 39ndash53 httpsdoiorg10108000343400500449937

Afonso A amp Fernandes S (2008) Assessing and explaining the relative efficiency of local government The Journal of Socio-Economics 37(5) 1946ndash1979 httpsdoiorg101016jsocec200703007

Afonso A Schuknecht L amp Tanzi V (2010) Income distribution determinants and public spending efficiency Journal of Economic Inequality 8(3) 367ndash389 httpsdoiorg101007s10888-010-9138-z

Akita T (2003) Decomposing regional income inequality in China and Indonesia using two-stage nested Theil decomposition method The Annals of Regional Science 37(1) 55ndash77 httpsdoiorg101007s001680200107

Alesina A (2000) Participation in heterogeneous communities The Quarterly Journal of Economics 115(3) 847ndash904 httpsdoiorg101162003355300554935

Alesina A amp La Ferrara E (2002) Who trusts others Journal of Public Economics 85(2) 207ndash234 httpsdoiorg101016S0047-2727(01)00084-6

Allcott H amp Keniston D (2014) Dutch Disease or Agglomeration The Local Economic Effects of Natural Resource Booms in Modern America (N W P N 20508 Ed) NBER Working Paper No 20508 (Vol w20508) NBER Working Paper No 20508 NBER Working Paper No 20508 httpsdoiorgNBER Working Paper No 20508

Andersen T M amp Maibom J (2020) The big trade-off between efficiency and equitymdashis it there Oxford Economic Papers 72(2) 391ndash411

127

Anselin L (1988) Spatial econometrics methods and models (Vol 4) DordrechtBoston Kluwer Academic Publishers

Anselin L amp Bera A K (1998) Spatial dependence in linear regression models with an introduction to spatial econometrics Statistics Textbooks and Monographs (Vol 155)

Anselin L Bera A K Florax R amp Yoon M J (1996) Simple diagnostic tests for spatial dependence Regional Science and Urban Economics 26(1) 77ndash104 httpsdoiorg1010160166-0462(95)02111-6

Antonelli M A amp De Bonis V (2018) The efficiency of social public expenditure in European countries a two-stage analysis Applied Economics 1ndash14 httpsdoiorg1010800003684620181489522

Aragoacuten F M amp Rud J P (2013) Natural Resources and Local Communities Evidence from a Peruvian Gold Mine American Economic Journal Economic Policy 5(2) 1ndash25 httpsdoiorg101257pol521

Ariely G (2014) Does Diversity Erode Social Cohesion Conceptual and Methodological Issues Political Studies 62(3) 573ndash595 httpsdoiorg1011111467-924812068

Armstrong H amp Taylor J (2000) Regional economics and policy (3rd ed) Oxford Blackwell

Aroca P amp Atienza M (2011) Economic implications of long distance commuting in the Chilean mining industry Resources Policy 36(3) 196ndash203 httpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201103004

Aroca P amp Bosch M (2000) Crecimiento convergencia y espacio en las regiones chilenas 1960 - 1998 Estudios de Economiacutea 27 199ndash224 Retrieved from httprepositoriouchileclbitstreamhandle2250127853Patricio_Arocapdfsequence=1

Ashworth J Geys B Heyndels B amp Wille F (2014) Competition in the political arena and local government performance Applied Economics 46(19) 2264ndash2276 httpsdoiorg101080000368462014899679

Atkinson A B (2015) Inequality What Can Be Done Harvard University Press

Auty R (1993) Sustaining development in mineral economies the resource curse thesis London [ua] Routledge

Auty R (2001) Resource abundance and economic development (R World Institute for Development Economics Ed) Oxford Oxford University Press

Badeeb R A Lean H H amp Clark J (2017) The evolution of the natural resource curse thesis A critical literature survey Resources Policy 51 123ndash134 httpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201610015

Balaguer-Coll M T Brun-Martos M I Maacuterquez-Ramos L amp Prior D (2019) Local government efficiency determinants and spatial interdependence Applied Economics

128

51(14) 1478ndash1494 httpsdoiorg1010800003684620181527458

Balaguer-Coll M T amp Prior D (2009) Short- and long-term evaluation of efficiency and quality An application to Spanish municipalities Applied Economics 41(23) 2991ndash3002 httpsdoiorg10108000036840701351923

Banker R D Charnes A amp Cooper W W (1984) Some models for estimating technical and scale inefficiencies in data envelopment analysis Management Science 30(9) 1078ndash1092

Beine M Coulombe S amp Vermeulen W N (2015) Dutch Disease and the Mitigation Effect of Migration Evidence from Canadian Provinces The Economic Journal 125(589) 1574ndash1615 httpsdoiorg101111ecoj12171

Benito B Bastida F amp Garciacutea J A (2010) Explaining differences in efficiency an application to Spanish municipalities Applied Economics 42(4) 515ndash528 httpsdoiorg10108000036840701675560

Berg A amp Ostry J (2011) Equality and efficiency Finance amp Development 48(3) 12ndash15

Berg A amp Ostry J (2017) Inequality and Unsustainable Growth Two Sides of the Same Coin IMF ECONOMIC REVIEW 65(4) 792ndash815 httpsdoiorg101057s41308-017-0030-8

Beyer H amp Vergara R (2006) Delincuencia en Chile Determinantes y rol de las poliacuteticas puacuteblicas Instituto de Economiacutea UC

Blanco L amp Grier R (2012) Natural resource dependence and the accumulation of physical and human capital in Latin America Resources Policy 37(3) 281ndash295 httpsdoiorghttpdoiorg101016jresourpol201201005

Blau J R amp Blau P M (1982) The cost of inequality Metropolitan structure and violent crime American Sociological Review 114ndash129

Boetti L Piacenza M amp Turati G (2009) Fiscal decentralization and spending efficiency of local governments An Empirical Investigation on a Sample Of 4

Boix C amp Posner D (1998) Social capital Explaining its origins and effects on government performance British Journal Of Political Science 28 686ndash693

Borge L E Parmer P amp Torvik R (2015) Local natural resource curse JOURNAL OF PUBLIC ECONOMICS 131 101ndash114 httpsdoiorg101016jjpubeco201509002

Borger B Kerstens K Moesen W amp Vanneste J (1994) Explaining differences in productive efficiency An application to Belgian municipalities Public Choice 80(3) 339ndash358 httpsdoiorg101007BF01053225

Bourguignon F amp Morrisson C (1990) Income distribution development and foreign trade A cross-sectional analysislowast European Economic Review 34(6) 1113ndash1132 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg1010160014-2921(90)90071-6

129

Branas C C Cheney R A MacDonald J M Tam V W Jackson T D amp Ten Have T R (2011) A difference-in-differences analysis of health safety and greening vacant urban space American Journal of Epidemiology 174(11) 1296ndash1306

Bravo J (2014) Fondo Comuacuten Municipal y su desincentivo a la recaudacioacuten en Chile Temas de La Agenda Legislativa-Centro de Poliacuteticas Puacuteblicas UC 9(68)

Browning E K amp Johnson W R (1984) The Trade-Off between Equality and Efficiency Journal of Political Economy 92(2) 175ndash203 httpsdoiorg101086261219

Brunnschweiler C N amp Bulte E H (2008) The resource curse revisited and revised A tale of paradoxes and red herrings Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 55(3) 248ndash264 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jjeem200708004

Brunori P Ferreira F H G amp Peragine V (2013) Inequality of opportunity income inequality and economic mobility Some international comparisons In Getting Development Right (pp 85ndash115) Springer

Brunton-Smith I Jackson J amp Sutherland A (2014) Bridging structure and perception On the neighbourhood ecology of beliefs and worries about violent crime British Journal of Criminology 54(4) 503ndash526

Bulte E H Damania R amp Deacon R T (2005) Resource intensity institutions and development World Development 33(7) 1029ndash1044 httpsdoiorg101016jworlddev200504004

Carmignani F (2013) Development outcomes resource abundance and the transmission through inequality Resource and Energy Economics 35(3) 412ndash428 httpsdoiorg101016jreseneeco201304007

Carmignani Fabrizio amp Avom D (2010) The social development effects of primary commodity export dependence Ecological Economics 70(2) 317ndash330 httpsdoiorg101016jecolecon201009003

Caselli F amp Michaels G (2013) Do Oil Windfalls Improve Living Standards Evidence from Brazil American Economic Journal Applied Economics 5(1) 208ndash238 httpsdoiorg101257app51208

Celebioglu F amp Dallrsquoerba S (2010) Spatial disparities across the regions of Turkey An exploratory spatial data analysis Annals of Regional Science 45(2) 379ndash400 httpsdoiorg101007s00168-009-0313-8

Chan J To H-P amp Chan E (2006) Reconsidering social cohesion Developing a definition and analytical framework for empirical research Social Indicators Research 75(2) 273ndash302

Charnes A Cooper W W amp Rhodes E (1978) Measuring the efficiency of decision making units European Journal of Operational Research 2(6) 429ndash444

130

Chi G amp Zhu J (2019) Spatial Regression Models for the Social Sciences SAGE Publications Retrieved from httpsbooksgooglecomaubooksid=zHGkvwEACAAJ

Christiansen K O (1960) Industrialization and urbanization in relation to crime and juvenile delinquency International Review of Criminal Policy 16 3ndash8

Cingano F (2014) Trends in income inequality and its impact on economic growth (Vol 163) Paris OECD Publishing httpsdoiorg1017875jxrjncwxv6j-en

Coelli T J Prasada Rao D S OrsquoDonnell C J amp Battese G E (2005) An introduction to efficiency and productivity analysis An Introduction to Efficiency and Productivity Analysis Springer Science amp Business Media httpsdoiorg101007b136381

Coffeacute H amp Geys B (2005) Institutional Performance and Social Capital An Application to the Local Government Level Journal of Urban Affairs 27(5) 485ndash501 httpsdoiorg101111j0735-2166200500249x

Coffeacute H amp Geys B (2006) Community Heterogeneity A Burden for the Creation of Social Capital Social Science Quarterly 87(5) 1053ndash1072 httpsdoiorg101111j1540-6237200600415x

Cohen D Spear S Scribner R Kissinger P Mason K amp Wildgen J (2000) ldquo Broken windowsrdquo and the risk of gonorrhea American Journal of Public Health 90(2) 230

Corden W M amp Neary J P (1982) Booming sector and de-industrialisation in a small open economy The Economic Journal 92(368) 825ndash848

Cordero J M Pedraja-Chaparro F Pisaflores E C amp Polo C (2017) Efficiency assessment of Portuguese municipalities using a conditional nonparametric approach Journal of Productivity Analysis 48(1) 1ndash24 httpsdoiorg101007s11123-017-0500-z

Croissant Y amp Millo G (2018) Panel Data Econometrics with R John Wiley amp Sons

Cust J amp Poelhekke S (2015) The Local Economic Impacts of Natural Resource Extraction 7 251ndash268 httpsdoiorg101146annurev-resource-100814-125106

da Cruz N F amp Marques R C (2014) Revisiting the determinants of local government performance Omega 44 91ndash103 httpsdoiorg101016JOMEGA201309002

Dauvin M amp Guerreiro D (2017) The Paradox of Plenty A Meta-Analysis World Development 94 httpsdoiorg101016jworlddev201701009

de Sousa M da C S Cribari-Neto F amp Stosic B D (2005) Explaining DEA technical efficiency scores in an outlier corrected environment the case of public services in Brazilian municipalities Brazilian Review of Econometrics 25(2) 287ndash313

Deacon R T (2011) The Political Economy of the Natural Resource Curse A Survey of Theory and Evidence Foundations and Trends in Microeconomics 111-208

Delhey J amp Newton K (2005) Predicting cross-national levels of social trust global pattern or

131

Nordic exceptionalism European Sociological Review 21(4) 311ndash327

Dlouhyacute M (2018) Measuring Geographic Inequalities Dealing with Multiple Health Resources by Data Envelopment Analysis Frontiers in Public Health 6 53 httpsdoiorg103389fpubh201800053

Dollery B Wallis J amp Akimov A (2010) One Size Does Not Fit All The Special Case of Remote Small Local Councils in Outback Queensland Local Government Studies 36(1) 21ndash42 httpsdoiorg10108003003930903435716

Domenech J (2008) Mineral resource abundance and regional growth in Spain 1860ndash2000 Journal of International Development The Journal of the Development Studies Association 20(8) 1122ndash1135

Doran J amp Jordan D (2016) Decomposing US regional income inequality from 1969 to 2009 Applied Economics Letters 23(11) 781ndash784 httpsdoiorg1010801350485120151109030

Drew J amp Dollery B (2015) The State of Things The Dynamic Efficiency of Australian State and Territories Economic Papers A Journal of Applied Economics and Policy 34(3) 165ndash176

Drew J Kortt M amp Dollery B (2015) What Determines Efficiency in Local Government A DEA Analysis of NSW Local Government Economic Papers A Journal of Applied Economics and Policy 34(4) 243ndash256 httpsdoiorg1011111759-344112118

Easterly W (2007) Inequality does cause underdevelopment Insights from a new instrument Journal of Development Economics 84(2) 755ndash776 httpsdoiorghttpdxdoiorg101016jjdeveco200611002

Ebert L amp La Menza T (2015) Chile copper and resource revenue A holistic approach to assessing commodity dependence Resources Policy 43(Supplement C) 101ndash111 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201410007

ElGindi T (2017) Natural resource dependency neoliberal globalization and income inequality Are they related A longitudinal study of developing countries (1980ndash2010) Current Sociology 65(1) 21ndash53 httpsdoiorg1011770011392116632031

Engerman S L amp Sokoloff K L (1994) Factor Endowments Institutions and Differential Paths of Growth Among New World Economies National Bureau of Economic Research

Engerman S L amp Sokoloff K L (1997) Factor endowments institutions and differential paths of growth among new world economies How Latin America Fell Behind 260ndash304

Engerman S L Sokoloff K L Urquiola M amp Acemoglu D (2002) Factor Endowments Inequality and Paths of Development among New World Economies [with Comments] EconomampxedA 3(1) 41ndash109 Retrieved from httpwwwjstororgezp01libraryquteduaustable20065432

132

Faumlre R Grosskopf S amp Lovell C A K (1985) The measurement of efficiency of production (Vol 6) Springer Science amp Business Media

Fleming D A amp Measham T G (2015a) Income Inequality across Australian Regions during the Mining Boom 2001-11 Australian Geographer 46(2) 203ndash216 httpsdoiorg1010800004918220151020596

Fleming D A amp Measham T G (2015b) Local economic impacts of an unconventional energy boom the coal seam gas industry in Australia Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 59(1) 78ndash94 httpsdoiorg1011111467-848912043

Fum R M amp Hodler R (2010) Natural resources and income inequality The role of ethnic divisions Economics Letters 107(3) 360ndash363 httpsdoiorg101016jeconlet201003008

Garofalo J (1978) The fear of crime Broadening our perspective

Geys B amp Moesen W (2009) Exploring Sources of Local Government Technical Inefficiency Evidence from Flemish Municipalities Public Finance and Management 9(1) 1ndash29

Goderis B amp Malone S W (2011) Natural Resource Booms and Inequality Theory and Evidence The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 113(2) 388ndash417 httpsdoiorg101111j1467-9442201101659x

Greene W H (2016) Productivity and Efficiency Analysis (W H Greene L Khalaf R Sickles M Veall amp M-C Voia Eds) (1st ed 20) Cham Springer International Publishing httpsdoiorg101007978-3-319-23228-7

Gustafsson B amp Shi L (2002) Income inequality within and across counties in rural China 1988 and 1995 Journal of Development Economics 69(1) 179ndash204 httpsdoiorg101016S0304-3878(02)00058-5

Gylfason T amp Zoega G (2003) Inequality and Economic Growth Do Natural Resources Matter In T T Eicher S (Ed) Inequality and Growth Theory and Policy Implications (pp 255ndash292) The MIT Press

Henningsen A (2010) Estimating Censored Regression Models in R using the censReg Package R Package Vignettes Collection 5(2) 12

Henningsen A (2019) censReg Censored Regression (Tobit) Models R package version 05-30 httpscranr-projectorgpackage=censReg Retrieved from httpscranr-projectorgpackage=censReg

Herrera S amp Pang G (2005) Efficiency of Public Spending in Developing Countriesthinsp An Efficiency Frontier Approach World Bank Washington DC

Hill T D amp Angel R J (2005) Neighborhood disorder psychological distress and heavy drinking Social Science amp Medicine 61(5) 965ndash975

133

httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jsocscimed200412027

Hipp J R (2010) RESIDENT PERCEPTIONS OF CRIME AND DISORDER HOW MUCH IS ldquoBIASrdquo AND HOW MUCH IS SOCIAL ENVIRONMENT DIFFERENCES Criminology 48(2) 475ndash508 httpsdoiorg101111j1745-9125201000193x

Holtug N amp Mason A (2010) Introduction Immigration diversity and social cohesion SAGE Publications Sage UK London England

Hooghe M Vanhoutte B Hardyns W amp Bircan T (2010) Unemployment Inequality Poverty and Crime Spatial Distribution Patterns of Criminal Acts in Belgium 2001ndash06 The British Journal of Criminology 51(1) 1ndash20 httpsdoiorg101093bjcazq067

Howie P amp Atakhanova Z (2014) Resource boom and inequality Kazakhstan as a case study Resources Policy 39(1) 71ndash79 httpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201311004

Isham J Woolcock M Pritchett L amp Busby G (2005) The Varieties of Resource Experience Natural Resource Export Structures and the Political Economy of Economic Growth The World Bank Economic Review 19(2) 141ndash174 httpsdoiorg101093wberlhi010

Jottier D Ashworth J amp Heyndels B (2012) Understanding Votersrsquo Preferences How the Electoratersquos Complexity Affects Prediction Accuracy and Wishful Thinking among Politicians with Respect to Election Outcomes Kyklos 65(3) 340ndash370 httpsdoiorg101111j1467-6435201200542x

Kanbur S M R amp Venables A (2005) Spatial inequality and development (R World Institute for Development Economics Ed) Oxford Oxford University Press

Kesler C amp Bloemraad I (2010) Does immigration erode social capital The conditional effects of immigration-generated diversity on trust membership and participation across 19 countries 1981ndash2000 Canadian Journal of Political ScienceRevue Canadienne de Science Politique 43(2) 319ndash347

Kuznets S (1955) Economic Growth and Income Inequality The American Economic Review 45(1) 1ndash28 Retrieved from httpwwwjstororgstable1811581

Lagos G amp Blanco E (2010) Mining and development in the region of Antofagasta Resources Policy 35(4) 265ndash275 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201007006

Leamer E E Maul H Rodriguez S amp Schott P K (1999) Does natural resource abundance increase Latin American income inequality Journal of Development Economics 59(1) 3ndash42 httpsdoiorg101016s0304-3878(99)00004-8

Leibbrandt M Finn A amp Woolard I (2012) Describing and decomposing post-apartheid income inequality in South Africa Development Southern Africa 29(1) 19ndash34 httpsdoiorg1010800376835X2012645639

134

Letki N (2008) Does Diversity Erode Social Cohesion Social Capital and Race in British Neighbourhoods Political Studies 56(1) 99ndash126 httpsdoiorg101111j1467-9248200700692x

Lewis D A (2017) Fear of crime Incivility and the production of a social problem Routledge

lo Storto C (2013) Evaluating Technical Efficiency of Italian Major Municipalities A Data Envelopment Analysis model Procedia - Social and Behavioral Sciences 81 346ndash350 httpsdoiorg101016JSBSPRO201306440

Loayza N amp Rigolini J (2016) The Local Impact of Mining on Poverty and Inequality Evidence from the Commodity Boom in Peru World Development 84 219ndash234 httpsdoiorg101016jworlddev201603005

Loayza N Teran A M y amp Rigolini J (2013) Poverty Inequality and the Local Natural Resource Curse World Bank Policy Research Working Paper (6366) httpsdoiorg1015961813-9450-6366

Loacutepez R amp Miller S J (2008) Chile The Unbearable Burden of Inequality World Development 36(12) 2679ndash2695 httpsdoiorg101016jworlddev200801012

Manzano O amp Rigobon R (2001) Resource Curse or Debt Overhang National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper Series No 8390 1 httpsdoiorghttpwwwnberorgpapersw9424bib

McPherson M Smith-Lovin L amp Cook J M (2001) Birds of a Feather Homophily in Social Networks Annual Review of Sociology 27(1) 415ndash444 httpsdoiorg101146annurevsoc271415

McQuestin D Drew J amp Dollery B (2018) Do Municipal Mergers Improve Technical Efficiency An Empirical Analysis of the 2008 Queensland Municipal Merger Program Australian Journal of Public Administration 77(3) 442ndash455 httpsdoiorg1011111467-850012286

Messner S F Rosenfeld R amp Baumer E P (2004) Dimensions of Social Capital and Rates of Criminal Homicide American Sociological Review 69(6) 882ndash903 httpsdoiorg101177000312240406900607

Michaels G (2011) THE LONG TERM CONSEQUENCES OF RESOURCE-BASED SPECIALISATION The Economic Journal 121(551) 31ndash57 httpsdoiorg101111j1468-0297201002402x

Mijanovich T amp Weitzman B C (2003) Which ldquobroken windowsrdquo matter School neighborhood and family characteristics associated with youthsrsquo feelings of unsafety Journal of Urban Health 80(3) 400ndash415

Mikušovaacute P (2015) An Application of DEA Methodology in Efficiency Measurement of the Czech Public Universities Procedia Economics and Finance 25 569ndash578 httpsdoiorg101016S2212-5671(15)00771-6

135

Milanovic B (2016) Global inequality Harvard University Press

Millo G amp Piras G (2012) splm Spatial panel data models in R Journal of Statistical Software 47(1) 1ndash38

Murphy K M amp Topel R H (2016) Human Capital Investment Inequality and Economic Growth JOURNAL OF LABOR ECONOMICS 34(2) S99ndashS127 httpsdoiorg101086683779

Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute I amp De Witte K (2018a) Local governmentsrsquo efficiency a systematic literature reviewmdashpart I International Transactions in Operational Research 25(2) 431ndash468 httpsdoiorg101111itor12364

Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute I amp De Witte K (2018b) Local governmentsrsquo efficiency a systematic literature reviewmdashpart II International Transactions in Operational Research 25(4) 1107ndash1136 httpsdoiorg101111itor12389

Nuntildeez J Rivera J Villavicencio X amp Molina O (2003) Determinantes socioeconoacutemicos y demograacuteficos del crimen en Chile Estudios de Economiacutea 30(1) 55ndash85

OrsquoDonnell C J Rao D S P amp Battese G E (2008) Metafrontier frameworks for the study of firm-level efficiencies and technology ratios Empirical Economics 34(2) 231ndash255 httpsdoiorg101007s00181-007-0119-4

Ocampo J A (2004) Latin Americarsquos Growth and Equity Frustrations During Structural Reforms The Journal of Economic Perspectives 18(2) 67ndash88 httpsdoiorg1012570895330041371349

OECD (2014) Focus on inequality and growth OECD

OECD (2017) Howrsquos Life 2017 Life Satisfaction Oecd httpsdoiorg101787how_life-2017-en

Ohtake F (2008) Inequality in Japan Asian Economic Policy Review 3(1) 87ndash109 httpsdoiorg101111j1748-3131200800093x

Okun A M (2015) Equality and efficiency the big tradeoff Washington DC Brookings Institution Press

Ortega B Sanjuaacuten J amp Casquero A (2017) Determinants of efficiency in reducing child mortality in developing countries The role of inequality and government effectiveness Health Care Management Science 20(4) 500ndash516 httpsdoiorg101007s10729-016-9367-1

Ostry J Berg A amp Tsangarides C (2014) Redistribution inequality and growth International Monetary Fund

Pacheco F Saacutenchez R amp Villena M (2013) Eficiencia de los Gobiernos Locales y sus Determinantes Un anaacutelisis de Fronteras Estocaacutesticas en Datos de Panel para

136

Municipalidades Chilenas Santiago de Chile Chile

Papyrakis E amp Raveh O (2014) An Empirical Analysis of a Regional Dutch Disease The Case of Canada Environmental and Resource Economics 58(2) 179ndash198 httpsdoiorg101007s10640-013-9698-z

Paredes D (2013) The Role of Human Capital Market Potential and Natural Amenities in Understanding Spatial Wage Disparities in Chile Spatial Economic Analysis 8(2) 154ndash175 httpsdoiorg101080174217722013774094

Paredes D Iturra V amp Lufin M (2016) A spatial decomposition of income inequality in Chile Regional Studies 50(5) 771ndash789

Phan P Van Orsquobrien M Mendolia S amp Paloyo A (2017) National pro-poor spending programmes and their effect on income inequality and poverty Evidence from Vietnam Applied Economics 49(55) 5579ndash5590 httpsdoiorg1010800003684620171313957

Podinovski V V (2004) Bridging the Gap between the Constant and Variable Returns-to-Scale Models Selective Proportionality in Data Envelopment Analysis The Journal of the Operational Research Society 55(3) 265ndash276 Retrieved from httpwwwjstororgstable4102006

Ravallion M (2005) On Measuring Aggregate Social Efficiency Economic Development and Cultural Change 53(2) 273ndash292 httpsdoiorg101086425380

Rehner J Baeza S A amp Barton J R (2014) Chilersquos resource-based export boom and its outcomes Regional specialization export stability and economic growth Geoforum 56(Supplement C) 35ndash45 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jgeoforum201406007

Rivera J Gutieacuterrez M amp Nuacutentildeez J (2009) Caracterizacioacuten socioeconoacutemica y espacial de la criminalidad en Chile Revista CEPAL

Ross C E (2011) Collective threat trust and the sense of personal control Journal of Health and Social Behavior 52(3) 287ndash296

Ross C E amp Mirowsky J (2001) Neighborhood disadvantage disorder and health Journal of Health and Social Behavior 258ndash276

Rothstein B amp Uslaner E M (2005) All for all Equality corruption and social trust World Politics 58(1) 41ndash72

Sachs J D amp Warner A M (2001) The curse of natural resources European Economic Review 45(4ndash6) 827ndash838 httpsdoiorg101016S0014-2921(01)00125-8

Salas R (2019) sinimr Chilean Municipalities Information System Wrapper Retrieved from httpsgithubcomrobsalascosinimr

Sampson R J (1986) Crime in Cities The Effects of Formal and Informal Social Control Crime and Justice 8 271ndash311

137

Sampson R J (2008) Rethinking crime and immigration Contexts 7(1) 28ndash33

Santos Silva J M C amp Tenreyro S (2010) On the existence of the maximum likelihood estimates in Poisson regression Economics Letters 107(2) 310ndash312 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jeconlet201002020

Santos Silva J M C amp Tenreyro S (2011) poisson Some convergence issues Stata Journal 11(2) 207ndash212 Retrieved from httpwwwstata-journalcomarticlehtmlarticle=st0225

Scott Z (2009) Decentralisation local development and social cohesion an analytical review GSDRC Research Paper 5

Sinha R P (2017) Fiscal Performance Benchmarking of Indian States-A Robust Frontier Approach The Central European Review of Economics and Management 1(4) 225ndash249

Skogan W (1986) Fear of crime and neighborhood change Crime and Justice 8 203ndash229

Skogan W (1999) Measuring what matters Crime disorder and fear In Measuring what matters Proceedings from the Policing Research Institute meetings (pp 37ndash53) National Institute of Justice Washington DC

Skogan W (2015) Disorder and Decline The State of Research Journal of Research in Crime and Delinquency 52(4) 464ndash485 httpsdoiorg1011770022427815577836

Šťastnaacute L amp Gregor M (2014) Public sector efficiency in transition and beyond evidence from Czech local governments Applied Economics 47(7) 1ndash20 httpsdoiorg101080000368462014978077

Tandon A (2005) Measuring Efficiency of Macro Systems An Application to Millennium Development Goal Attainment Asian Development Review 22(2) 108ndash125

Taylor R B (1999) The incivilities thesis Theory measurement and policy Measuring What Matters 65 88

Tigga N S amp Mishra U S (2015) On Measuring Technical Efficiency of the Health System in India An Application of Data Envelopment Analysis Journal of Health Management 17(3) 285ndash298 httpsdoiorg1011770972063415589229

Tinbergen J (1975) Demographic Development and the Exhaustion of Natural Resources Population and Development Review 1(1) 23ndash32 httpsdoiorg1023071972269

Tiruneh G (2014) Social Revolutions Their Causes Patterns and Phases SAGE Open 4(3) 2158244014548845 httpsdoiorg1011772158244014548845

Tolsma J Van der Meer T amp Gesthuizen M (2009) The impact of neighbourhood and municipality characteristics on social cohesion in the Netherlands Acta Politica 44(3) 286ndash313

Tsekeris Sotiris T Tsekeris T amp Papaioannou S (2018) Regional determinants of technical efficiency evidence from the Greek economy Regional Studies [London]thinsp Carfax

138

httpsdoiorg1010800034340420171390312

Uslaner E (2002) The moral foundations of trust Cambridge University Press

Uslaner E (2011) CORRUPTION AND INEQUALITY DICE Report 9(2) 20ndash24

Uslaner E (2013) Trust and corruption revisited how and why trust and corruption shape each other Quality amp Quantity 47(6) 3603ndash3608 httpsdoiorg101007s11135-012-9742-z

Uslaner E amp Brown M (2005) Inequality trust and civic engagement American Politics Research 33(6) 868ndash894

Van der Ploeg F (2011) Natural Resources Curse or Blessing Journal of Economic Literature 49(2) 366ndash420 httpsdoiorg101257jel492366

Vergara R (2012) Crime Prevention Programs Evidence From CHILE The Developing Economies 50(1) 1ndash24

Watkins M H (1963) A staple theory of economic growth Canadian Journal of Economics and Political ScienceRevue Canadienne de Economiques et Science Politique 29(2) 141ndash158

Wilkinson R G (1999) Income inequality social cohesion and health clarifying the theorymdasha reply to Muntaner and Lynch International Journal of Health Services 29(3) 525ndash543

Wilson J Q amp Kelling G L (1982) Broken windows Atlantic Monthly 249(3) 29ndash38

Wilson W J (1996) When Work Disappears Political Science Quarterly 111(4) 567ndash595 httpsdoiorg1023072152085

Wirth L (1938) Urbanism as a Way of Life American Journal of Sociology 44(1) 1ndash24

Worthington A amp Dollery B (2000) An empirical survey of frontier efficiency measurement techniques in local government Local Government Studies 26(2) 23ndash52 httpsdoiorg10108003003930008433988

Wu P-C Huang T-H amp Pan S-C (2014) Country Performance Evaluation The DEA Model Approach Social Indicators Research 118(2) 835ndash849 httpsdoiorg101007s11205-013-0443-3

Ye X Ma L Ye K Chen J amp Xie Q (2017) Analysis of Regional Inequality from Sectoral Structure Spatial Policy and Economic Development A Case Study of Chongqing China Sustainability 9(4) 633 Retrieved from httpwwwmdpicom2071-105094633

Yue W Z Zhang Y T Ye X Y Cheng Y Q amp Leipnik M R (2014) Dynamics of Multi-Scale Intra-Provincial Regional Inequality in Zhejiang China Sustainability 6(9) 5763ndash5784 httpsdoiorg103390su6095763

139

Appendices

Appendix A Summary statistics income inequality

Table A1

Summary statistics Gini coefficients by year and zone

140

Appendix B Summary statistics for NRD measures by region

Table B1

Summary statistics NRD measures by region

141

Appendix C Regional administrative division and defined zones

Figure C1 Geographical distribution of Chilean regions and 3 zones

142

Appendix D Summary statistics numeric controls and correlation matrix

Table D1

Summary Statistics Numeric Explanatory Variables

Figure D1 Correlation matrix numeric explanatory variables

143

Appendix E Static spatial panel models

Following Millo amp Piras (2012) a model including a spatial lag of the dependent variable and

spatial autoregressive disturbances but not spatial lags for the explanatory variable(s) is called

SARAR model A static spatial SARAR panel could be expressed as

119910 120582 119868 otimes119882 119910 119883120573 119906 (E1)

where y is an 119873 1 vector of observations on the dependent variable X is a 119873 119896 matrix of

observations on the non-stochastic exogenous regressors 119868 an identity matrix of dimension 119879 otimes

is the kronecker operator 119882 is the 119873 119873 spatial weights matrix of known constants whose

diagonal elements are set to zero and 120582 the corresponding spatial parameter44

The disturbance vector is the sum of two terms

119906 120580 otimes 119868 120583 120576 (E2)

where 120580 is a 119879 1 vector of ones 119868 an 119873 119873 identity matrix 120583 is a vector of time-invariant

individual specific effects (not spatially autocorrelated) and 120576 a vector of spatially autocorrelated

innovations that follow a spatial autoregressive process of the form

120576 120588 119868 otimes119882 120576 120584 (E3)

If we assume that spatial correlation applies to both the individual effects 120583 and the remainder

error components 120576 Kapoor et al (2007) propose that the disturbance term 119906 follows a first order

spatial autoregressive process of the form

119906 120588 119868 otimes119882 119906 120576 (E4)

44 Unlike ldquotraditional panelsrdquo which are organized as different time series for each cross-sectional unit ldquospatial panelsrdquo are organized as a series of cross-sections for each year

144

where 119882 is the spatial weights matrix and 119903ℎ119900 the corresponding spatial autoregressive

parameter To further allow for the innovations to be correlated over time the innovations vector

in Equation 7 follows an error component structure

120576 120580 otimes 119868 120583 120584 (E5)

where 120583 is the vector of cross-sectional specific effects 120584 a vector of innovations that vary

both over cross-sectional units and time periods 120580 is a vector of ones and 119868 an 119873 119873 identity

matrix45

Spatial panel models are usually estimated by Maximum Likelihood or GMM46 The SAR

SEM or SARAR models could be estimated with Random or Fixed effects For instance A fixed

effect spatial lag model can be written in stacked form as

119910 120582 119868 otimes119882 119910 120580 otimes 119868 120583 119883120573 120576 (E6)

where 120582 is the spatial autoregressive coefficient 119882 a non-stochastic spatial weights matrix

120580 a column vector of ones of dimension 119879 119868 an 119873 119873 identity matrix and 120576 sim 119873 0120590 On

the other hand a fixed effects spatial error model assuming the disturbance specification by

Kapoor et al (2007) can be written as

119910 120580119879 otimes 119868119873 120583 119883120573 119906119906 120588 119868119879 otimes119882119873 119906 120576

(E7)

where 120588 is the spatial autocorrelation coefficient and 120576 is a well-behaved error term

45 In the regression implementation the specification given by equations (22) and (3) is denoted by ldquobrdquo for ldquoBaltagirdquo On the other hand the specification given by equations (23) and (31) is denoted by ldquokkprdquo for ldquoKapoor Kelejian and Pruchardquo 46 We use the R package splm which allow both types of regression procedure

145

Appendix F Analysis OLS residuals cross-sectional (six-year average) analysis

Table F1

Analysis OLS residuals Anselin Method

Figure F1 Moran scatter plot OLS residuals

146

Appendix G Linear panel data models

Table G1

Panel regressions (non-spatial)

147

Appendix H Spatial panel models (Generalized Moments (GM) estimation)

Table H1

GM Spatial Models

148

Appendix I Inputs and outputs used in DEA analysis

Figure I1 Examples of inputs and outputs used to measure LGE (based on Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018)

149

Appendix J Technical and scale efficiency

Following lo Storto (2013) under an input-oriented specification assuming VRS with n

municipalities using k inputs to produce m outputs the DEA model for a given i-th municipality

is specified with the following mathematical programming problem

119898119894119899 120579119904119906119887119895119890119888119905 119905119900 119910 119884120582 0120579119909 119883120582 01198991prime120582 1  120582 0prime

Where 119910 is the column vector of the outputs and 119909 is the column vector of the inputs

Moreover we can define X as the (k times n) input matrix and Y as the (m times n) output matrix 120579 is a

scalar (that satisfies 120579 1) more specifically it is the efficiency score that measures technical

efficiency It measures the distance between a municipality and the efficiency frontier defined as

a linear combination of the best practice observations With 120579 1 the municipality is inside the

frontier (ie it is inefficient) while 120579 1 implies that the municipality is on the frontier (ie it is

efficient) The vector 120582 is an (n times 1) vector of constants that measures the weights used to compute

the location of an inefficient municipality if it were to become efficient

The total technical efficiency 119879119864 can be decomposed into pure technical efficiency

119879119864 and scale efficiency 119878119864 where 119878119864 119879119864 119879119864 (Coelli et al 2005) To find out

whether a municipality is scale efficient and qualify the type of returns of scale a DEA model

under non-increasing returns to scale 119879119864 is implemented where 119878119864 119879119864 119879119864 Hence

the following rule can be applied (Faumlre Grosskopf amp Lovell 1985)

bull If 119878119864 1 then a municipality is scale efficient both under CRS and VRS

bull If 119878119864 1 it operates under increasing returns to scale

bull If 119878119864 1 it operates under decreasing returns to scale

150

Appendix K Correlation matrix

Figure K1 Correlation matrix contextual factors

151

Appendix L Returns to scale by year and zone

Table L1

Returns to scale (percentage of municipalities)

152

Appendix M Returns to scale by year (maps)

Figure M1 Spatial distribution of returns to scale by county per year

153

Appendix N Efficiency status by year (maps)

Figure N1 Spatial distribution of efficient (E es = 1) and inefficient (I es lt 1) counties per year

154

Appendix O Spatial distribution efficiency scores by year (maps)

FigureO1 Custom breaks maps of efficiency scores (VRS) by county per year

155

Appendix P Analysis OLS residuals cross-sectional (six-year average) analysis

Table P1

Analysis OLS residuals Anselin Method

Figure P1 Moran scatter plot efficiency scores and OLS residuals

156

Table P2

OLS and spatial regression models for the six-year averaged data

157

Appendix Q OLS regressions for cross-sectional and panel data

Table Q1

OLS cross-sectional regression per year

158

Table Q2

OLS panel regressions Pooled random effects and instrumental variable

159

Appendix R Quantile maps incivilities rate by group (average total period)

Figure R1 Spatial distribution of incivilities by group (Average rate per 1000 inhabitants 2006-09-11-13-15-17)

160

Appendix S Correlation matrix numeric covariates

Figure S1 Correlation matrix numeric covariates

161

Appendix T Negative Binomial regressions

Table T1

Negative Binomial regressions

162

Appendix U Coefficients economic and racial diversity by geographical zone

Table U1

Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson models by geographic zone

Page 8: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted

vii

Appendix E Static spatial panel models 143

Appendix F Analysis OLS residuals cross-sectional (six-year average) analysis 145

Appendix G Linear panel data models 146

Appendix H Spatial panel models (Generalized Moments (GM) estimation) 147

Appendix I Inputs and outputs used in DEA analysis 148

Appendix J Technical and scale efficiency 149

Appendix K Correlation matrix 150

Appendix L Returns to scale by year and zone 151

Appendix M Returns to scale by year (maps) 152

Appendix N Efficiency status by year (maps) 153

Appendix O Spatial distribution efficiency scores by year (maps) 154

Appendix P Analysis OLS residuals cross-sectional (six-year average) analysis 155

Appendix Q OLS regressions for cross-sectional and panel data 157

Appendix R Quantile maps incivilities rate by group (average total period) 159

Appendix S Correlation matrix numeric covariates 160

Appendix T Negative Binomial regressions 161

Appendix U Coefficients economic and racial diversity by geographical zone 162

viii

List of Figures

Figure 21 Average share in GDP of economic activities (2006ndash17) 37

Figure 22 Evolution of Gini coefficient and measures of NRD (2006ndash17) 38

Figure 23 Spatial distribution of Gini coefficient and NRD (2006ndash17) 39

Figure 23 Moran scatter plots for variables gini and pss_casen 45

Figure 31 Geographical distribution of Chilean regions and macrozones 74

Figure 32 Evolution of efficiency scores and the proportion of firms by sector 77

Figure 33 Evolution technical efficiency (TE) pure technical efficiency (PTE) and scale efficiency (SE) 78

Figure 34 Returns to scale by zone 79

Figure 35 Evolution mean efficiency scores (VRS) by zone 81

Figure 41 Evolution number and rates of incivilities and crime (DMCS) in Chile 2006-2017 102

Figure 42 Evolution total number of incivilities by category 104

Figure 43 Spatial distribution of incivilities rate per 1000 inhabitants (2006 vs 2017) 104

Figure 44 Annual average number of incivilities per county 109

Figure C1 Geographical distribution of Chilean regions and 3 zones 141

Figure D1 Correlation matrix numeric explanatory variables 142

Figure F1 Moran scatter plot OLS residuals 145

Figure I1 Examples of inputs and outputs used to measure LGE (based on Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018) 148

Figure K1 Correlation matrix contextual factors 150

Figure M1 Spatial distribution of returns to scale by county per year 152

Figure N1 Spatial distribution of efficient (E es = 1) and inefficient (I es lt 1) counties per year 153

FigureO1 Custom breaks maps of efficiency scores (VRS) by county per year 154

Figure P1 Moran scatter plot efficiency scores and OLS residuals 155

Figure R1 Spatial distribution of incivilities by group (Average rate per 1000 inhabitants 2006-09-11-13-15-17) 159

Figure S1 Correlation matrix numeric covariates 160

ix

List of Tables

Table 21 Cross-sectional Model Comparison (six-year average data) 47

Table 22 ML Spatial SAR Models 50

Table 23 ML Spatial SEM Models 50

Table 24 ML Spatial SARAR Models 51

Table 31 Descriptive statistics Inputs and Output variables used in DEA analysis 71

Table 32 Summary Statistics Numeric Contextual Factors 74

Table 33 Summary efficiency scores (VRS) by zone and region 80

Table 34 Cross-sectional (censored) regressions 84

Table 35 Panel data regressions 87

Table 41 Summary statistics total count of incivilities and by category (full sample and period) 103

Table 42 Summary statistics numeric explanatory variables 108

Table 43 Poisson regressions 113

Table 44 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson models by region 115

Table 45 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson model by incivility group 116

Table A1 Summary statistics Gini coefficients by year and zone 139

Table B1 Summary statistics NRD measures by region 140

Table D1 Summary Statistics Numeric Explanatory Variables 142

Table F1 Analysis OLS residuals Anselin Method 145

Table G1 Panel regressions (non-spatial) 146

Table H1 GM Spatial Models 147

Table L1 Returns to scale (percentage of municipalities) 151

Table P1 Analysis OLS residuals Anselin Method 155

Table P2 OLS and spatial regression models for the six-year averaged data 156

Table Q1 OLS cross-sectional regression per year 157

Table Q2 OLS panel regressions Pooled random effects and instrumental variable 158

Table T1 Negative Binomial regressions 161

Table U1 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson models by geographic zone 162

x

List of Abbreviations

Constant returns to scale CRS

Data envelopment analysis DEA

Decreasing returns to scale DRS

Efficiency scores ES

Exploratory spatial data analysis ESDA

Generalized methods of moments GMM

Gross Domestic Product GDP

Increasing returns to scale IRS

Local government efficiency LGE

Maximum likelihood ML

Municipal common fund MCF

Natural resource dependence NRD

Natural resource endowment NRE

Ordinary Least Squares OLS

Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development OECD

Own permanent revenues OPR

Resource curse hypothesis RCH

Spatial autoregressive model SAR

Spatial error model SEM

Variable returns to scale VRS

xi

Statement of Original Authorship

The work contained in this thesis has not been previously submitted to meet requirements

for an award at this or any other higher education institution To the best of my knowledge and

belief the thesis contains no material previously published or written by another person except

where due reference is made

Signature QUT Verified Signature

Date _________04092020_________

xii

Acknowledgements

First I would like to thank my wife Lilian who joined me in this challenge and patiently

supported me all these years I would also like to thank our family who always supported us from

Chile I especially thank my sister Silvia who took care of our house and dog

I am also grateful to my supervisory team Dr Radhika Lahiri and Dr Vincent Hoang who

supported and guided me in the process of making this thesis a reality

I also thank the Deans of the Faculty of Economics and Business at my beloved University

of Talca Dr Arcadio Cerda and Dr Rodrigo Herrera who trusted me and supported me in this

process In the same way I would like to thank all the support of the director of the Commercial

Engineering career Mr Milton Inostroza

Finally I would like to thank the government of Chile for the financial support that made

my stay and studies possible here at the Queensland University of Technology

13

Chapter 1 Introduction

Efficiency and equity issues are often considered together in the evaluation of economic

performance While higher efficiency usually measured by growth rates of income per capita

correlates with improvements in measures of well-being the link between inequality and well-

being is less clear This is reflected not only in the type and amount of research related to efficiency

and equity but also in the role that both play in the design of the economic policy For instance

several market-oriented countries have focused primarily on economic growth trusting in a trickle-

down process where financial benefits given to the wealthy are expected to ultimately benefit the

poor However despite the growing interest in the issue of inequality there is a considerable lack

of studies about its consequences

Although some level of inequality is inevitable or even necessary for economic activity this

study is motivated by the argument that relatively high levels of inequality can be associated with

many problems such as persistent unemployment increasing fiscal expenses indebtedness and

political instability (Berg amp Ostry 2011) Inequality can also have other severe social

consequences including increased crime rates teenage pregnancy obesity and fewer

opportunities for low-income households to invest in health and education (Atkinson 2015) In

addition when the role of money and concentration of economic power undermine political

outcomes inequality of opportunities hampers social and economic mobility trust and social

cohesion In summary inequality can increase the fragility of the economic and social situation in

a country reducing economic growth and making it less inclusive and sustainable

14

A country well-known for its market-oriented economy and high level of dependence on

natural resources is Chile Chilean success in terms of economic growth contrasts with its inability

to reduce the persistently high levels of social and economic inequality particularly in the last

three decades Using data for the 2006-2017 period and considering 324 out of 345 Chilean

counties this thesis presents three essays with empirical evidence aiming to explain the

phenomenon of persistent income inequality and some of its potential consequences The first

essay aims to analyse how the evolution and variability of income inequality throughout the

country are associated with the degree of natural resource dependence The second essay studies

the relevance of income inequality in explaining cross-county differences in the performance of

local governments (municipalities) Finally the third essay explores the link between social

cohesion and community heterogeneity highlighting the importance of economic and racial

diversity

Income inequality and dependence on natural resources

The first essay explores how cross-county differences in income inequality are associated

with differences in the degree of dependence on natural resources We use the Gini coefficient in

each county as our dependent variable and the proportion of employment in the primary sector as

our measure of natural resource dependence The main hypothesis is that income inequality should

be positively related to the degree of natural resource dependence To test our hypothesis we use

a spatial econometric approach This approach is motivated by the study of Paredes Iturra and

Lufin (2016) who explore the geographic heterogeneity of income inequality in Chile finding

evidence of a significant spatial dimension

15

The theoretical and empirical literature has mostly proposed a positive link between

inequality and natural resources Although most of the evidence corresponds to cross-country

comparisons there is also increasing body of research at the local level A rationale underpinning

the positive link suggested in the literature is that in natural resource-rich countries ownership is

concentrated in small groups and extraction activities require low-skilled workers (Gylfason amp

Zoega 2003 Leamer Maul Rodriguez amp Schott 1999) Another market-based argument often

labelled as the ldquoDutch Diseaserdquo proposes that natural resource windfalls could be associated with

a crowding-out effect on the manufacturing sector (Corden amp Neary 1982 Easterly 2007) This

process encourages rent-seeking behaviours discourages investment in physical and human

capital and delays the process of technology adoption and industrialization (Auty 2001 Bulte

Damania amp Deacon 2005 Gylfason amp Zoega 2003) The result could be a lower economic

growth which is the central idea under the ldquoResource Curse Hypothesisrdquo (Auty 1993 Sachs amp

Warner 2001)

An ldquoinstitutionalrdquo argument for the positive association between inequality and the

endowment of natural resources is based on the so-called ldquoParadox of Plentyrdquo (Borge Parmer amp

Torvik 2015 Dauvin amp Guerreiro 2017) The idea is that both national and local authorities have

less incentive to operate efficiently when they experience windfalls in their revenues for

instance from natural resources This could end with corrupted authorities exerting patronage

clientelism and designing public policies to favour specific groups of the population (Uslaner amp

Brown 2005) Evidence also suggests that the final effect of natural resource booms on income

inequality will depend on authoritiesrsquo capacity to manage these additional resources the extent of

commuting and migration among regions and the potential increase in the demand for non-tradable

16

goods which are intensive in unskilled workers (Aroca amp Atienza 2011 Cust amp Poelhekke 2015

Fleming amp Measham 2015b Howie amp Atakhanova 2014 Michaels 2011)

Contrary to most theoretical and empirical evidence we find that income inequality shows

a robust and significant negative association with our proxy for natural resource dependence This

result suggests that the process of transformation to an economy less dependent on natural

resources could have exacerbated rather than alleviated the persistence of income inequality The

decrease in the participation of the primary sector in employment in favour mainly of the tertiary

sector highlights the importance of the latter to explain the current high levels of inequality and its

future evolution Another important result is that spatial linear models show practically the same

results as traditional linear models This could be interpreted as the spatial dimension previously

found in income inequality is not the result of spatial dependence in the variable itself for instance

due to a process of spillover among counties Hence the usually found positive spatial

autocorrelation of income inequality (similar levels in neighbouring counties) could be explained

by spatial patterns in other variables or to the spatial heterogeneity that characterizes the Chilean

economy

Local government efficiency and income inequality

Essay 2 delves deep into the potential trade-off between efficiency and equity We measure

the efficiency of Chilean municipalities which correspond to the organizations in charge of

managing each county Municipal efficiency is understood as ldquotechnical efficiencyrdquo that is the

possibility that each municipality has reached the same level of outputs with less use of inputs

Then we analyse how income inequality controlling for other contextual factors such as

socioeconomic demographic geographical and political characteristics may help to explain

17

differences in municipal performance Our main hypothesis is that municipal efficiency is

inversely associated with income inequality Moreover we seek a causal interpretation of this

relationship

Municipal performance could be influenced by income inequality in direct and indirect ways

In a direct sense income inequality is used to capture the degree of heterogeneity and complexity

in the demand for public services that citizens exert over local authorities Hence higher levels of

income inequality should be associated with a more complex set of public services and therefore

with lower levels of municipal efficiency (Jottier Ashworth amp Heyndels 2012) Furthermore

when high levels of inequality exist the richest groups can exert a higher influence over local

authorities resulting in low quality and quantity of services for most of the population Among

indirect effects high and persistent inequality could be the source of corrupted institutions and

local authorities favouring themselves or specific groups This undermines citizensrsquo participation

in civic activities and their willingness to monitor municipal performance (Uslaner amp Brown

2005) Additionally the potential benefits of decentralization on the way local governments

deliver public services will be limited when the context is characterized by corrupted politicians

and a limited administrative and financial capacity (Scott 2009)

We measure municipal efficiency using an input-oriented Data Envelopment Analysis

(DEA) to obtain efficiency scores for our sample of 324 municipalities in each year from 2006 to

2017 Then we study the influence on municipal efficiency of income inequality and our set of

contextual factors using a panel of six years corresponding to those years for which household

income information is available 2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017 Our dependent variable

is the set of efficiency scores which are relative measures of efficiency They are relative to the

18

municipalities included in the sample and they do not imply that higher technical efficiency gains

cannot be achieved Thus we use both cross-sectional and panel censored regression models To

tackle endogeneity issues and suggest a causal interpretation we also propose using the proportion

of firms in the primary sector as an instrument for income inequality

We find an average efficiency score of 83 meaning that Chilean municipalities could

reduce the use of inputs by 17 without reducing their outputs We also measure municipal

efficiency under different assumptions related to returns to scale This allows us to disaggregate

technical efficiency to assess whether inefficiencies are due to management issues (pure technical

efficiency) or scale issues (scale efficiency) Although the results show that most municipalities

operate under increasing or decreasing returns to scale scale inefficiencies only explain a small

proportion of total municipal inefficiencies This highlights the need to look for contextual factors

outside the control of local authorities to explain differences in municipal performance

Geographical representations of our results in terms of returns to scale and efficiency scores

show some spatial clustering process among municipalities Spatial statistics tests confirm that

efficiency scores show a significant positive spatial autocorrelation This means that neighbouring

municipalities tend to show similar levels of efficiency This similar performance could be due to

a process of spatial dependence (eg efficiency spillovers among neighbouring municipalities) or

due to the existence of structural-geographical similarities (spatial heterogeneity) To assess the

spatial dimension in municipal efficiency abstracting from temporal fluctuations we use a cross-

section of data consisting of the six-year average for the variables in our panel After running a

regression of efficiency scores against the set of controls the analysis of OLS residuals shows that

the spatial autocorrelation is almost completely removed This means that the spatial pattern in

19

municipal efficiency can be explained (controlled) by other variables such as regional indicator

variables rather than efficiency itself Given this result we proceed to study the influence of

income inequality on municipal efficiency using traditional (non-spatial) regression analysis

In contrast to literature that emphasizes an equity-efficiency trade-off (Andersen amp Maibom

2020 Berg amp Ostry 2011 Browning amp Johnson 1984 Okun 2015) that is greater equality leads

to lower efficiency we find that municipal efficiency is inversely associated with income

inequality This implies that more equal counties are also those with higher municipal efficiency

Furthermore the coefficient of income inequality is close to one when we use the instrumental

variable approach This means that a reduction in income inequality ceteris paribus should be

associated with an increase in the same magnitude in municipal efficiency This result has strong

policy implications The non-existence of the trade-off suggests that there is more to be gained by

targeting policies towards the reduction of inequality than conventional theories suggest For

instance these policies may help increase the levels of efficiency and well-being at least at the

municipal level

Social cohesion and economic diversity

The third essay studies the relationship between the degree of social cohesion and diversity

in Chile Extant literature has argued that one of the main factors influencing social cohesion is

the degree of economic and ethnic-racial diversity within a society This diversity erodes social

cohesion reducing trust and corrupting institutions (Letki 2008 Rothstein amp Uslaner 2005

Tolsma Van der Meer amp Gesthuizen 2009 Uslaner 2011 2013)

To measure social cohesion scholars have traditionally used measures of social capital trust

or feelings of insecurity (Ariely 2014 Chan To amp Chan 2006 Letki 2008) We suggest the use

20

of the rate of incivilities per 1000 inhabitants as a proxy for social cohesion Incivilities correspond

to those antisocial behaviours (eg groups of rowdy teens and public drunkenness) or visible

neighbourhood conditions (eg graffiti and abandoned buildings) that tend not to be treated as

crime Using the rate of incivilities is arguably a more objective and reliable measure of social

cohesion particularly in countries where institutions of order and security are among the most

trusted An increase in the rate of incivilities rather than changes in crime rates should better

capture the worsening in social cohesion experienced in countries such as Chile where crime rates

are not growing but social conflicts are on the rise Thus the main hypothesis in this essay is that

the rate of incivilities (social cohesion) should be positively (negatively) associated with economic

and racial diversity

Using panel count data models we start analysing how differences in incivilities rates

between and within counties are associated with differences in indicators of relative and absolute

economic disadvantage We use the Gini coefficient of each county as our measure of economic

diversity Although we find a significant and positive association between the rate of incivilities

and the level of income inequality the magnitude of the link seems to be small Among absolute

indicators of economic disadvantage only the level of income shows a strong effect Next we

include our measure of racial diversity We use the number of new visas granted to foreigners as

a proportion of the county population Results show a significant and strong positive association

between the rate of incivilities and racial diversity

To check the robustness of our results we analyse the impact of our measures of economic

and racial diversity running our models separately for each Chilean region and clustering them

geographically We also split the total number of incivilities in four categories to see which type

21

of incivilities show the greatest association with our measures of diversity In general results

support the ldquocommunity heterogeneity hypothesisrdquo that higher community heterogeneity is

associated with higher rates of incivilities (Alesina amp La Ferrara 2002 Letki 2008 Tolsma et al

2009) However results do not support the ldquoincivilities thesisrdquo that the distribution of incivilities

tends to mirror the distribution of income inequality (Skogan 1999 Taylor 1999)

Three results stand out among the set of control variables First the level of education shows

and independent and significant negative association with the rate of incivilities This is in contrast

to previous studies where education acts mainly as a moderator of the effect of economic and racial

diversity on social cohesion (Tolsma et al 2009) The results also show that there is no significant

relationship between the rate of incivilities and the proportion of young population This is relevant

because policies aimed to reduce incivilities usually put the focus on specific groups such as young

people which are linked to physical and social incivilities when social control is weakened

Finally the degree of financial municipal autonomy also shows a significant negative association

with the rate of incivilities This result suggests that municipalities can contribute independently

or together with the central government to reduce incivilities and strengthen social cohesion

Contributions

The three essays in this thesis provide several important insights into the analysis of the

causes and consequences of income inequality particularly in the context of Chile ndash a typical

resource rich economy with persistently high levels of income inequality

Essay 1 advances the understanding of the relationship between income inequality and

natural resources in Chile extending the empirical analysis from the regional level to the county

level In addition the geographic heterogeneity of income inequality is explored with the inclusion

22

of alternative sources of spatial dependence as a potential dimension of the causal relationship

between income inequality and natural resources This essay demonstrates the relevance of natural

resources in explaining the persistence of income inequality even after controlling for other

socioeconomics and institutional factors Findings from this study have potential contribution not

only in the design of policies aimed to reduce income inequality but also in addressing the current

developmental bias between the metropolitan region and the rest of the country

Essay 2 is one of the first studies that undertake a longitudinal analysis of the effects of

income inequality on the efficiency of municipal governments in Chile To capture the role of the

municipal governments in the provision to local people of public services such as education and

health we specify several inputs and outputs in our efficiency model which is different from the

conventional specification in the existing literature For example the number of medical

consultations in public health facilities and the number of enrolled students in public schools are

used as outputs instead of general indicators such as county population Our empirical analysis

also utilises a larger sample of municipalities and covers a much longer period spanning from 2006

to 2017 This essay also investigates the contextual factors beyond the control of local authorities

that can explain variations in the efficiency of municipal governments across the country

Empirical findings from Essay 2 help us increase our understanding of the production

technology of municipalities the sources of inefficiencies and specifically the impact of income

inequality on the performance of local authorities The results deliver two main policy

implications First municipal inefficiencies in the provision of public goods and services differ

across Chilean municipalities In addition efficiency levels show some degree of spatial

autocorrelation This implies that policies such as amalgamation or cooperation among

23

municipalities could have effects beyond the municipalities involved which must be considered

Second the causal effect that income inequality has on municipal efficiency provides another

dimension into the design and implementation of development policies

Essay 3 explores for the first time the effects of economic and racial diversity on social

cohesion in Chile This essay considers incivilities as manifestation of social cohesion and

investigates as extant literature suggests whether indicators of relative economic disadvantage

such as income inequality are among the main factors driving social disorganization and social

unrest Empirical findings suggest that on the one hand economic heterogeneity captured by the

Gini coefficient has a disparate effect both in terms of magnitude and significance on the rate of

incivilities across the country On the other hand the impact of racial heterogeneity appears to be

stronger more significant and of a similar magnitude throughout the country Results also provide

new insights into the design of national policies addressing social disorders particularly those

policies focussed on specific groups of the population and the role of local authorities Overall the

findings provide an opportunity to advance the understanding of the process of weakening in the

social cohesion experienced in Chile and the conflicts that have risen from this process

Thesis outline

The remainder of the thesis is organized as follows Chapter 2 presents essay 1 examining

the association between income inequality and the degree of dependence on natural resources

Chapter 3 presents essay 2 which looks for a causal relationship between municipal efficiency and

income inequality Chapter 4 presents essay 3 analysing the relationship between social cohesion

and economic and racial diversity Finally Chapter 5 presents some concluding remarks

24

Chapter 2 Natural Resources Curse or Blessing Evidence on

Income Inequality at the County Level in Chile

21 Introduction

A phenomenon of increasing inequality of incomes and wealth in recent decades has been

documented by leading scholars and international organizations such as the International Monetary

Fund (Berg amp Ostry 2017 Ostry Berg amp Tsangarides 2014) and the Organization for Economic

Cooperation and Development (Cingano 2014) These efforts have placed the topic of inequality

at the top of the current economic debate recognizing inequality as a determinant not only of

economic growth but also of human development They also have highlighted the necessity for

more research on the drivers of inequality and mechanisms through which it manifests aiming to

design effective policies in reducing economic and social inequalities

Various factors have been analysed as the sources of high and increasing levels of inequality

Among the most significant factors are the levels of income at initial stages of economic

development (Kuznets 1955) Globalization (Milanovic 2016) skill-biased technological change

(Tinbergen 1975) investment in human capital (Murphy amp Topel 2016) institutions

redistributive policy and country-specific characteristics (Acemoglu 1995 2002 Acemoglu

Aghion amp Violante 2001 Acemoglu Johnson amp Robinson 2001) Our focus in this essay is on

the importance that the natural resource endowment (NRE) or lack thereof can play in the

determination of income disparities

25

This essay studies the patterns and evolution of income inequality in the context of a natural

resource-rich country Using the case of the Chilean economy we aim to understand and

disentangle how a phenomenon of high- and persistent-income inequality is related to the

endowment of natural resources that a country owns Chile is an interesting case to study because

despite showing a successful history of economic growth inequality among individuals and among

aggregated spatial units has shown a strong persistence (Paredes et al 2016) Furthermore Chile

has remained among the most unequal countries in the world1

Theory and empirical evidence do not establish a clear link between income inequality and

NRE In addition NRE has received considerably less attention (Auty 2001 ElGindi 2017) and

most of the evidence has been focused on cross-country comparisons For instance NRE can

influence inequality by determining its initial levels (Engerman amp Sokoloff 1994 1997

Engerman Sokoloff Urquiola amp Acemoglu 2002) shaping the evolution of institutions

(Acemoglu 2002) make the educational system less intellectually challenging and moulding the

structure of economic activity (Leamer et al 1999) So studying how cross-county differences in

NRE are associated with the distribution of income within a country has theoretical empirical and

policy implications

In this study we offer empirical evidence on the relationship between income inequality and

the endowment of natural resources using data at the county level in Chile for the period 2006-

2017 Income inequality is measured by the Gini coefficient The importance of NRE is proxied

using a measure of natural resource dependence (NRD) defined as the percentage of the total

1 A 2014 OECD report on income inequality (httpwwwoecdorgsocialincome-distribution-databasehtm) showed Chile as the country with the highest Gini coefficient of disposable income among OECD countries OECD also indicates Chile as the country with the widest gap between the richest 10 percent and the poorest 10 percent of countryrsquos population among its 34 members (OECD 2014)

26

employment in each county corresponding to the primary sector (agriculture forestry fishing and

mining)

The main hypothesis to be tested is whether income inequality is positively associated with

the degree of NRD The transmission mechanisms through which natural resources could influence

socioeconomic outcomes could be based on the market or institutions The market-based approach

argues that natural resource booms could be associated with an appreciation of the real exchange

rate and a crowding out effect over other more productive economic activities such as

manufacturing It could also delay the adoption of new technologies and reduce incentives to invest

in physical and human capital (Gylfason amp Zoega 2003) Based on the ldquoResource Curse

Hypothesisrdquo (RCH) natural resources could be a curse when the political and institutional

framework is weak and natural resources are concentrated in space such as oil and minerals

(Deacon 2011) 2 Among institutional channels a higher NRD or natural resource booms could

be associated with rent seeking misallocation of labour and entrepreneurial talent institutional

and political decline or even violent conflicts For instance the ldquoParadox of Plentyrdquo sustains that

windfalls of revenues as a consequence of resource booms could be related to a lack of incentives

to perform efficiently corruption patronage and local authorities favouring their voters or being

captured by the richest groups (Dauvin amp Guerreiro 2017) Hence a higher NRD or natural

resource booms could be the explanation not only for low levels of growth in regions more

dependent on natural resources but also it could be the root of income disparities

2 There is a wide strand of research on the Resource Curse Hypothesis however the evidence so far is not conclusive Evidence in favour of RCH has been mainly found in developing resource rich countries (Auty 1993 2001 Badeeb Lean amp Clark 2017 Blanco amp Grier 2012 Borge et al 2015 Brunnschweiler amp Bulte 2008 Sachs amp Warner 2001 Van der Ploeg 2011)

27

To test our hypothesis that is whether the levels of income inequality across counties are

positively associated with the degree of NRD we use a spatial econometric approach We use this

approach because attributes such as income inequality in one region may not be independent of

attributes in neighbouring regions (Armstrong amp Taylor 2000) This process of spatial dependence

invalidates the use of traditional (non-spatial) approaches

This study seeks to make two contributions to research First previous empirical evidence

shows a significant spatial dimension of income inequality in Chile (Paredes et al 2016)

However this dimension has been barely explored with most studies limiting the degree of

disaggregation to a regional scale (Aroca amp Bosch 2000) We use a spatial approach which makes

it possible to model and test the significance of the spatial dimension in the analysis of income

inequality and its relationship with other variables Second previous research for the Chilean

economy linking inequality with NRE has been mainly focused on explaining differences between

regions or the importance and effects of the mining-copper sector (Aroca amp Atienza 2011 Ebert

amp La Menza 2015 Lagos amp Blanco 2010 Rehner Baeza amp Barton 2014) We extend this

analysis using data for local economies Identifying and quantifying the impact of NRE on income

inequality at the county level is likely to be more informative for policies aiming to address the

current developmental bias between the metropolitan region and the rest of the country Moreover

the analysis of the role of natural resources in conjunction with other potential sources of inequality

may shed lights in understanding the persistence of the high levels of inequality observed in the

Chilean economy All in all this study could contribute to the design of policies that

simultaneously help reduce inequality increase efficiency and promote sustainable and inclusive

growth

28

Our main finding shows that after controlling for other potential sources of income

inequality such as educational level demographic characteristics and the level of public

government expenditure the degree of dependence on natural resources has a significant effect on

income inequality However contrary to our expectations the effect is negative This result

suggests that the natural or policy-driven process of transformation from primary and extractive

activities to manufacturing and service sectors imposes additional challenges to central and local

authorities aiming to reduce income inequality

In section 22 we review the literature on the relationship between income inequality and

natural resources In section 23 we establish our research problem and main hypothesis Section

24 describes our data and methods and section 25 the empirical results We finish with section

26 discussing our main results concluding and proposing avenues for future research

22 Inequality and Natural Resources

221 Theoretical Framework

Explanations for income inequality can be associated with individual institutional political

and contextual characteristics Individual characteristics include age gender and mainly the level

of education and skills of the population in the labour force For instance globalization and

technological change lead firms to increase the demand for skilled labour deepening income

inequality between skilled and unskilled workers (Atkinson 2015 Milanovic 2016 Tinbergen

1975) Among institutional characteristics labour unions collective bargaining and the minimum

wage have been suggested as explanations of income inequality (Acemoglu Aghion et al 2001

Atkinson 2015) Policy design associated with market regulation progressive taxation and

redistribution can also impact the levels and patterns of inequality

29

A key factor in understanding the levels and differences in income distribution within a

country may be its endowment of natural resources NRE shapes the structure of the economy

(Leamer et al 1999) it is associated with the creation of institutions that define the political

culture and it can also influence the performance of other sectors (Watkins 1963) In addition

NRE determines initial conditions market competition ownership over resources rent seeking

and the geographical concentration of the population and economic activity

Cross‐countryliterature

Bourguignon and Morrison (1990) introduce one of the earliest theoretical frameworks

describing the relationship between inequality and NRE They develop a small open economy

model where income distribution is a function of NRE ownership structure and trade protection

Giving cross-sectional evidence for a group of developing countries they conclude that the impact

of NRE particularly mineral resources and land depends on the number and size of the firms

whether they are public or private and the level of protection A higher concentration of production

in a few private firms a big share of production oriented to foreign instead of domestic markets

and protection increasing the relative price of scarce resources are some of the reasons explaining

why some countries are less egalitarian than others

NRE could also influence the evolution and levels of inequality by determining the initial

distribution of incomes This is known as the ldquoEngerman-Sokoloff Hypothesisrdquo (Engerman amp

Sokoloff 1997 Engerman et al 2002) In addition Leamer (1999) proposes that inequality and

development paths in each economy are a function of its economic structure which in turn depends

on ldquofundamentalsrdquo and ldquosymptomsrdquo On the one hand ldquofundamentalsrdquo refer to resource

endowment production structure closeness to markets and governments interventions On the

30

other hand ldquosymptomsrdquo are related to institutions employment structure and net export structure

Using this conceptual framework Leamer argues that natural Resource-Rich Countries (RRC) can

experience a higher level of inequality because can have a ldquodumbbell educational systemrdquo

ownership is concentrated in small groups and extraction activities require low-skilled workers

This implies fewer incentives to educate citizens until very late in the development process

resulting in human capital not prepared to take advantage of the process of technological progress

and delaying the emergence of more efficient and competitive sectors such as manufacturing and

services

Using 1980 and 1990 data for a group of countries classified according to land abundance

Leamer (1999) provides evidence showing that on the one hand land-scarce countries concentrate

their production and employment in sectors that promote equality such as capital-intensive

manufacturing chemical or machinery On the other hand countries abundant in natural resources

concentrate their production trade or employment in sectors that promote income inequality such

as the production of food beverages extraction activities or forestry

Gylfason and Zoega (2003) using a framework based on standard growth models also

proposed a positive relationship between NRE and inequality They assume that workers can work

in the primary sector or in the manufacturing (including services) sector In addition wage income

is equally distributed in the manufacturing sector but unequally in the primary sector (because of

initial distribution competition rent seeking etc) Therefore inequality will be greater when a

bigger proportion of labour is dedicated to extraction activities in the primary sector This

phenomenon is further amplified because of lower incentives to invest in physical and human

capital to adopt new technologies and to increase the share of the manufacturing sector

31

Diverse mechanisms explaining the link between NRE and inequality have been proposed

arguing that NRE determines simultaneously economic growth and inequality (Gylfason amp Zoega

2003) NRE could impact economic growth through the real exchange rate and the crowding-out

effect on manufacturing (ldquoDutch Diseaserdquo) reducing incentives to invest in physical and human

capital (Easterly 2007) and influencing the processes of technology adoption industrialization

and diversification of the economy in a manner that is less conducive to growth (Bulte et al 2005)

These potential explanations related to the called ldquoResource Curse Hypothesisrdquo do not have strong

empirical support (Auty 2001 Bulte et al 2005)

NRE may also influence economic growth through the quality of institutions (Acemoglu

1995 Acemoglu Aghion et al 2001 Acemoglu amp Robinson 2002 Engerman amp Sokoloff 1997

Engerman et al 2002) the concentration of ownership political power and rent-seeking NRE

acts by shaping institutional context and social infrastructure a phenomenon that is stronger when

resources are spatially concentrated such as minerals and plantations (Bulte et al 2005) NRE

could also have a significant effect on social cohesion and instability spreading its influence like

a disease (Brunori Ferreira amp Peragine 2013 Kanbur amp Venables 2005 Milanovic 2016

Ocampo 2004)

Considering a non-tradable sector intensive in unskilled workers Goderis and Malone

(2011) develop a model where the natural resources sector experiences an exogenous gift of

resource income They analyse the impact over income inequality of resource booms proxied by

changes in a commodity price index They conclude that inequality decreases in the short run but

increases after the initial reduction

32

Fum and Hodler (2010) show that natural resources increase inequality but this is

conditional on the level of ethnical polarization of society Carmignani (2013 2010) confirms this

positive relationship using different measures of dependence and abundance and goes further

arguing that inequality constitutes an indirect channel through which NRE affects human

development

Singlecountryevidence

Most of the studies about the relationship between inequality and NRE derive from cross-

country analyses Evidence for specific countries has been mainly based on case studies Howie

and Atakhanova (2014) based on the model of Goderis and Malone (2011) find for the case of

Kazakhstan that income and consumption inequality decreased significantly after booms in the oil-

and-gas sector because of resource booms increase the demand for non-tradable goods which are

intensive in unskilled workers The results depend on the level of rurality institutional quality

education levels and public spending on health and education Fleming and Measham (2015b

2015a) evaluate the impact of booms in the mining and oil sectors in Australia They find that a

boom in the mining sector increases income inequality due to commuting and migration among

regions This phenomenon can be exacerbated when the demanding access to natural resource

revenues is associated with the creation of more local administrative units (counties provinces and

even regions) but the government capacity is not simultaneously improved (Cust amp Poelhekke

2015 Michaels 2011) Furthermore the benefits that a region can receive in the form of fiscal

transfers can be more than compensated by the loses due to city-to-mine commuting such as the

case of mining regions in Chile (Aroca amp Atienza 2011)

33

Other studies at the local level have analysed the impact of the mining sector in Peru (Aragoacuten

amp Rud 2013 Loayza amp Rigolini 2016 Loayza Teran amp Rigolini 2013) Spain (Domenech

2008) and Canada (Papyrakis amp Raveh 2014) and the effects of oil windfalls in Brazil (Caselli amp

Michaels 2013)

In summary there is a wide range of potential mechanisms through which NRE could

influence income inequality Although most of them seem to suggest a positive relationship others

such as commuting and increased within-county demand for non-tradable goods and services

could lead to a negative association This highlights the need to know the sign of this association

in the Chilean economy where the trend shows a reduction in the degree of NRD After controlling

for other factors a positive link would support the argument that the reduction in the degree of

NRD has been relevant in the reduction experienced by income inequality in the same period

However a negative link would support the position that the reduction in NRD has contributed to

explain the persistence of income inequality and its slow reduction

222 The relevance of the spatial approach

Inequalities within countries are still the most important form of inequality from the political

point of view (Milanovic 2016) People from a geographic area within a country are influenced

and care most about their status relative to the people in other areas in the same country The

influence among regions involves multiple aspects (eg economic political and environmental)

These potential interactions have been traditionally ignored assuming independence among

observations related to different regions Moreover neglecting the process of spatial interaction in

key indicators of the economic and social performance of a country may mislead the design of the

public policy

34

The spatial dimension could play a significant role in understanding the distribution of

income within a country One strand of efforts aiming to capture the geographic heterogeneity of

inequality has been focussed on decomposing general indicators such as the Gini coefficient or the

Theil Index Evidence for different countries including the US (Doran amp Jordan 2016) China

(Akita 2003 Gustafsson amp Shi 2002 Ye Ma Ye Chen amp Xie 2017 Yue Zhang Ye Cheng

amp Leipnik 2014) Japan (Ohtake 2008) South Africa (Leibbrandt Finn amp Woolard 2012) and

Chile (Paredes et al 2016) shows that regional inequality is sensitive to the geographic scale of

analysis These studies also show a significant spatial component in the explanation of inequality

of income expenditure or gross domestic product for each country

Another strand explicitly uses exploratory spatial data analysis (ESDA) and spatial

econometrics ESDA has been used to provide new insights about the nature of regional disparities

of incomes and growth rates (Celebioglu amp Dallrsquoerba 2010 Yue et al 2014) Spatial econometric

models aim to assess and address the nature of the spatial effects These effects could be the result

of ldquospatial heterogeneityrdquo that is different relationships in distinct locations or ldquospatial

dependencerdquo which implies cross-sectional interactions (spillover effects) among units from

distinct but near locations

Spatial spillovers have been analysed to study both positive and negative spatial correlation

among less resource-abundant counties and resource-abundant counties On the one hand less

resource-abundant counties may experience positive spillovers because their industries supply

more goods and services to meet the increasing regional demand They can also be benefited from

positive agglomeration externalities and higher investment in private and public infrastructure

(Allcott amp Keniston 2014 Michaels 2011) On the other hand negative spillovers could be the

35

result of a high degree of interregional migration that limits the rise in wages and higher local

prices due to the increase in the share of the non-tradable sector In addition local governments

could have a limited capacity to translate the revenues from resource booms into effective public

policies promoting a sustained local development (Beine Coulombe amp Vermeulen 2015 Caselli

amp Michaels 2013 Papyrakis amp Raveh 2014)

23 Research problem and hypotheses

We can conclude from our overview of the literature that the theoretical and empirical

evidence about the link between inequality and natural resources is inconclusive This does not

make clear whether the process of reduction in the degree of dependence on natural resources

such as that experienced by the Chilean economy helps to explain the sustained but slow reduction

in income inequality or its high persistence

The research question guiding this study relates to how the natural resource endowment

determines the paths and structure of income inequality in natural resource-rich countries Using

the case of Chile the main hypotheses to be tested is whether a higher degree of dependence on

natural resources is associated with higher levels of income inequality To do that we use data at

the county level and we explicitly include the spatial dimension Our aim is to arrive at a more

comprehensive understanding of the drivers and transmission mechanisms explaining the

evolution and patterns shown by income inequality In addition we test whether the spatial

dimension plays a significant role in explaining differences in income distribution in Chile

36

24 Data and Methods

We use county-level data for the years 2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017 The reason

for not using contiguous years is that income data at the household level are only available every

two-three years from the Chilean National Socioeconomic Characterization Survey (CASEN in its

Spanish acronym)3 For the period 2006-2017 the Chilean administrative division considers 15

regions 54 provinces and 346 counties Data on income are available for 324 counties and six

years resulting in a panel with 1944 observations4

We start evaluating the spatial dimension in our data and analysing the link between

inequality and NRD using a cross-sectional setting To this end we use the ldquosix-year averagerdquo

(2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017) for our variables given the low time variability showed by

our measures of income inequality and NRD Results are then compared with those of a panel data

setting

241 Operationalization of key variables

The dependent variable in the present study income inequality at the county level is

measured calculating the Gini coefficient using three definitions of household income labour

autonomous and monetary income5 Labour income corresponds to the incomes obtained by all

members in the household excluding domestic service consisting of wages and salaries earnings

3 CASEN survey is conducted by the Chilean Ministry of Social Development covering topics such as education employment income and health CASEN is considered nationally representative and it is the main source for measures of inequality and poverty used for the design and evaluation of social policies in Chile 4 The six waves of CASEN for our study considered an average of 75599 households and 252081 individuals 5 The Gini coefficient is chosen because provides an overall estimate of income inequality It summarizes what proportion of the population gains what proportion of the total income The Gini coefficient can range between 0 (everyone in the population has the same income) and 1 (one person earns 100 per cent of the income in the community)

37

from independent work and self-provision of goods Autonomous income is the sum of labour

income and non-labour income (including capital income) consisting of rents interest and dividend

earnings pension healthcare benefits and other private transfers Finally monetary income is

defined as the sum of autonomous income and monetary subsidies which correspond to cash

transfers by the public sector through social programs Appendix A shows summary statistics for

the Gini coefficient of our three measures of income

The main independent variable in our study is the degree of dependence on natural resources

in each county To have an idea of the importance of each economic activity in the Chilean

economy particularly those activities related to natural resources Figure 21 shows their average

share in Chilean Gross Domestic Product (GDP) for the period 2006-17 We can observe that the

leading activities are those related to the primary sector especially mining and to the tertiary

sector where financial personal commerce restaurants and hotels services stand out The shares

of each economic activity in GDP vary significantly between Chilean regions and such

information is not available at the county level

Figure 21 Average share in GDP of economic activities (2006ndash17)

38

Leamer (1999) argues that when the main source of income is labour income (as indeed

happens for the Chilean case) using employment shares allows a better approach to measuring

dependence on natural resources Using employment data from CASEN survey we define our

measure of NRD as the employment in the primary sector (mining fishing forestry and

agriculture) as a percentage of the total employment in each county We name this variable

pss_casen where ldquopssrdquo stands for ldquoprimary sector sharerdquo We built other two proxies of NRD

using data from the ldquoServicio de Impuestos Internosrdquo (SII) which is the agency in charge of

collecting taxes in Chile The variable pss measures the percentage of employment in the primary

sector and the variable pss_firms measures the number of firms in the primary sector as a

percentage of the total number of firms in each county Appendix B shows summary statistics for

our three measures of NRD disaggregated by region

Figure 22 Evolution of Gini coefficient and measures of NRD (2006ndash17)

39

Figure 22 shows the evolution of our measure of inequality (using the Gini coefficient of

autonomous income) and our three potential proxies for NRD for the period 2006-2017 We

observe that both income inequality and the degree of NRD show a downward trend This seems

to support our hypothesis of a positive link between inequality and NRD however we need to

control of other sources of inequality before getting such a conclusion In what follows we use the

variable gini as our measure of income inequality capturing the Gini coefficient of autonomous

income Our measure of NRD is the variable pss_casen defined previously

Figure 23 Spatial distribution of Gini coefficient and NRD (2006ndash17)

Note Gini and NRD averages 2006-09-11-13-15-17 for 324 Chilean counties divided into five equal groups Source Own elaboration based on CASEN survey

40

Figure 23 shows quantile maps for income inequality (on the left) and NRD (on the right)

using the six-years average dataset6 On the one hand we observe that high levels of inequality

seem to be clustered in the Centre-South of the country where agriculture forestry and fishery are

the predominant economic activities Only isolated counties show high inequality in the Centre

(Metropolitan area where the countyrsquos capital is located) and North (Mining) areas On the other

hand our measure of NRD seems to show an opposite spatial pattern than income inequality with

high levels in the Centre and North of the country

242 Control variables

To control for county characteristics we use a set of socio-economic demographic and

institutional variables Economic factors are captured by the natural log of the mean autonomous

household income per capita (in thousands of Chilean pesos of 2017) lnincome the poverty rate

poverty the unemployment rate unemployment the percentage of the population living in rural

areas rural and the average years of education of the population over 15 years old education

Demographic factors include the proportion of the population in the labour force labour_force

and the natural log of population density (population divided by county area) lndensity

We also include the natural log of the total municipal public expenditure per capita

lnmuni_expenditure to control for municipal heterogeneity This heterogeneity is mainly related

to the capacity of municipalities to generate their own revenues In addition the richest

municipalities are in the Metropolitan region which concentrates economic power and around 40

6 After sorting a variable in ascending order quantile maps use the quantiles (quartiles quintiles deciles etc) as class breaks to divide the distribution of the variable where each class includes approximately the same number of observations (counties)

41

of the population This has basically implied a lag in the development of regions other than the

metropolitan region

The spatial distribution of our measures of income inequality and NRD displayed in Figure

23 seems to show different patterns in the North Centre and South of the country Appendix C

shows the administrative division of Chile in 15 regions and how we have grouped them in three

zones North Centre and South We consider as the ldquoCentrerdquo area that formed by the Metropolitan

region (XIII) and its two neighbouring regions V and VI Using the Centre area as our reference

we include in our analysis two dummy variables indicating whether a county is located in the North

area (regions XV I II III and IV) or South area (regions VII VIII IX XIV X XI and XII)

Appendix D shows summary statistics for the set of numeric control variables and the

correlation matrix between our measure of NRD pss_casen and the set of numeric controls

243 Methods

To assess and then consider the spatial nature of the data we need to define the set of relevant

neighbours for each country This is operationalized by building a matrix called ldquoWrdquo with a ldquo1rdquo

for neighbouring counties and a ldquo0rdquo for non-neighbouring counties We could build W using

contiguity-based (whether counties share a border or point) or geography-based (taking the

distances among the centroids of each county polygon) spatial weights Specifically we build a W

matrix considering the 5-nearest counties7 Two reasons explain the choice of k-nearest

neighbours First we cannot use a contiguity criterium because we do not have information about

all the counties and there are some geographically isolated counties Second given the significant

7 We assign a ldquo1rdquo to the five nearest counties to each county based on the distances among the polygon centroids Then W is ldquorow standardizedrdquo This facilitates the interpretation of the spatial lag of a variable as the ldquoweighted average valuerdquo of the same variable in neighbouring counties

42

differences in county areas (ldquobig countiesrdquo in northern and southern regions) using a distance-

band criterium with a not enough large distance band can lead to many ldquoislandsrdquo in extreme regions

and a multi-modal distribution for the number of neighbours

We start testing our inequality and NRD variables for spatial autocorrelation in order to

evaluate statistically the clustering patterns shown in Figure 23 Next we run an OLS regression

of inequality against NRD and our set of controls and we test the spatial autocorrelation of OLS

residuals If we cannot reject the null hypothesis of random spatial distribution we do not need

spatial models to analyse income inequality which would give contrasting evidence to previous

suggestions about the relevance of the spatial dimension of income inequality in Chile (Paredes

2013 Paredes et al 2016) If we find significant spatial autocorrelation in the OLS residuals this

justifies the use of spatial models and highlight the need to find the correct spatial structure8

If inequality in one county spillovers or influences inequality in neighbouring counties the

spatial lag of inequality should be included as an explanatory variable and we should use a spatial

autoregressive model (SAR) If some unobserved variable is the explanation for the clustering of

counties with similar inequality then this will be better captured including a spatial lag of the

errors and we should use a spatial error model (SEM) (Anselin 1988 Anselin amp Bera 1998)

Finally when our main explanatory variable or some of the controls show spatial autocorrelation

a spatial lag of the explanatory variable(s) should be included in our model

8 The existence of spatial autocorrelation violates the standard assumption of independence among observations needed for OLS regression This will result in OLS coefficients biased and inconsistent (Anselin 1988)

43

244 Spatial Model Specification

A model that includes the three forms of spatial dependence described above is called the

Cliff-Ord Model The model in its cross-sectional representation could be expressed as

119910 120582119882119910 119883120573 119882119883120574 119906 (21)

where

119906 120588119882119906 120576 (22)

119882 is our weight matrix that works as an NxN spatial lag operator9 Thus 119882119910 119882119883 and 119882119906

are the spatial lags for the dependent variable explanatory variables and the error term

respectively The parameter 120582 capture the spatial dependence in the dependent variable 120574 the

spatial dependence in the explanatory variables 120588 capture the spatial dependence in the error term

and 120598 is a vector of idiosyncratic errors For instance if ldquoyrdquo is income inequality and ldquoXrdquo a measure

of NRD the level of inequality in one county will be explained by the degree of NRD in the same

county 119883120573 the average degree of NRD in neighbouring counties 119882119883120574 the average level of

inequality in neighbouring counties 120582119882119910 and the average value of residuals in neighbouring

counties 12058811988211990610

From equations (21) and (22) the SAR and SEM models can be seen as special cases of

the Cliff-Ord representation after imposing restrictions over the spatial parameters 120582 120574 and 120588 For

the specification of the spatial panel models we follow the terminology by Croissant and Millo

9 The spatial lag is a weighted sum of the values observed at neighbouring locations 10 On the one hand the impact that income inequality in one county has over income inequality in neighbouring counties is called a ldquoglobal spilloverrdquo and it is associated with the feedback effect among neighbours (one county is its neighboursrsquo neighbourrdquo) on the other hand the influence that the degree of NRD in neighbouring counties has over inequality in one county is called a ldquolocal spilloverrdquo

44

(2018) Spatial panel models including the spatial lag of the dependent variable (SAR) the spatial

lag of the residuals (SEM) or both (SARAR) are described in Appendix E

25 Results

251 Exploratory Spatial Data Analysis (ESDA)

To analyse the significance of the spatial dimension in our data set we use the six-year

average of our variables Spatial autocorrelation is tested using the Moranrsquos I statistic11 Moranrsquos

I measures the correlation of one variable with itself in space12 Figure 24 shows the Moran scatter

plots where the standardized variable (Gini coefficient and NRD for each county) appears in the

horizontal axis against its spatial lag (average value in the 5-nearest neighbouring counties) The

Moranrsquos I (slope of the line in the Moran scatter plot) of income inequality shows a significant

positive spatial autocorrelation that is counties with high (low) inequality tend to be close to each

other

11 There are many statistics to formally test the significance of the spatial dimension in the distribution of our data The null hypothesis assumes spatial randomness which means that there is not spatial structure in the data so any spatial pattern is equally likely to occur and values in one location do not depend on values in other locations The alternative hypotheses can be the existence of positive or negative spatial autocorrelation Positive spatial autocorrelation means similar values in neighbouring locations (less variability than under spatial randomness) Negative spatial autocorrelation means dissimilar values in neighbouring locations (more variability than under spatial randomness) 12 Traditional measures of correlation such as the Pearsonrsquos coefficient measure the degree of linear correlation between two different variables Measures of spatial autocorrelation assess the correlation between the values of one variable in one location related to the values of the same variable in other neighbouring locations

45

Figure 23 Moran scatter plots for variables gini and pss_casen

Moranrsquos I is a measure of global spatial autocorrelation this means it is intended to capture

the clustering property of the entire data set To identify where are the significant hot-spots

(clusters of counties showing high income inequality) or cold-spots (clusters of counties showing

low income inequality) we need local indicators of spatial association (LISA) Using the local

Moranrsquos I (not reported) we find significant hot-spots in the South of the country (mainly

agricultural regions) and significant cold-spots in the Centre (Metropolitan area) of the country

The next step is to check whether the clustering pattern in inequality is the result of a process of

spatial dependence in the variable itself or it can be explained by other variables related to

inequality

252 Cross-sectional analysis

We start analysing differences in income inequality between counties using the six-year

average data and running an OLS regression for the model

119892119894119899119894 120573 120573 119901119904119904_119888119886119904119890119899 120573 119897119899119894119899119888119900119898119890 120573 119901119900119907119890119903119905119910 120573 119906119899119890119898119901119897119900119910119898119890119899119905 120573 119897119886119887119900119906119903_119891119900119903119888119890 120573 119890119889119906119888119886119905119894119900119899 120573 119897119899119889119890119899119904119894119905119910 120573 119903119906119903119886119897 120573 119897119899119898119906119899_119890119909119901119890119899119889119894119905119906119903119890 120573 119899119900119903119905ℎ 120573 119904119900119906119905ℎ

(23)

46

The Moran scatter plot and spatial statistical test of OLS residuals from equation (23) are

in Appendix F OLS residuals show a small but significant positive autocorrelation (Moranrsquos I =

0121) This means that income inequality continues showing a significant degree of spatial

autocorrelation after controlling for the set of covariates In addition robust Lagrange Multiplier

(LM) tests show that a spatial error model is preferred over a spatial lag model (Anselin Bera

Florax amp Yoon 1996)13 This means that income inequality tends to cluster in zones larger than a

county so the analysis should be performed on a larger scale such as provinces regions or macro

zones If the SAR model were preferred it would mean that income inequality in one county is

influenced by the level of income inequality in neighbouring counties To find the spatial structure

that best fits the clustering process of income inequality we run the full set of spatial model

specifications in a cross-sectional setting and results are shown in Table 21

Column 2 in Table 21 shows the results of our ldquoOLSrdquo model The ldquoSLXrdquo model includes

spatial dependence only through the explanatory variables The ldquoSARrdquo model includes the spatial

lag of the dependent variable as a regressor and the ldquoSEMrdquo model includes spatial dependence

through the error term The ldquoSARARrdquo model includes both the spatial lag of the response and the

errors and the ldquoSDMrdquo and ldquoSDEMrdquo are the extensions of the ldquoSARrdquo and ldquoSEMrdquo models

respectively including the spatial lag of the explanatory variables Finally a model including

spatial lags for the response errors and explanatory variables (the ldquoSARARXrdquo model) is shown in

the last column

13 Following the ldquoAnselin methodrdquo when both non robust LM tests are significant we should select between the robust LR tests From Table F1 in Appendix F only the robust LM test for the SEM model (RLMerr) appears as significant

47

Table 21

Cross-sectional Model Comparison (six-year average data)

48

Opposite to our hypothesis we observe a significant and negative coefficient for our measure

of NRD This means that counties more dependent on natural resources show lower levels of

inequality Education years population density and municipal expenditure per capita are also

negatively related to inequality On the other hand the level of income the poverty rate and the

proportion of the population living in rural areas show a positive relationship with income

inequality There is no significant influence of the unemployment rate and the proportion of the

population in the labour force In addition the SAR SEM and SARAR models show a

significantly higher average inequality in the South of the country related to the Centre area

The main finding from our cross-sectional analysis is that there is a significant and negative

relationship between inequality and NRD which is quite robust to the model specification

253 Panel Data analysis

Like the cross-sectional case we start estimating the panel without spatial effects Results

for the pooled fixed effects (FE) and random effects (RE) specifications of equation (3) are in

Appendix G Spatial models were estimated using Maximum Likelihood (ML) and Generalized

Moments (GM) and assuming that the spatial structure (W matrix) is the same for all years14

Tables 22 23 and 24 show results for the ML estimation of the SAR SEM and SARAR models

using the pooled FE and RE specifications Results for the GM estimation are in Appendix H

All our spatial models include time fixed effects In the case of the pooled and RE models they

additionally include indicator variables for those counties located in the North and South of the

country

14 In traditional (non-spatial) panels data are stacked as time series for each observational unit (county) In the case of spatial panels data are stacked as slice of cross-sections for each year in the panel

49

The main result is that the negative and significant effect of NRD on income inequality is

robust to most of the spatial panel specifications In addition the coefficient for the variable

pss_casen changes slightly among panel specifications (pooled FE and RE) but does not change

among spatial models (SAR SEM and SARAR)

Another important finding is related to the significance of the spatial dimension of income

inequality When spatial models cross-sectional or panel are compared to non-spatial models

there are no major differences in the magnitude of the coefficients or their significance This could

mean that the positive spatial autocorrelation shown by income inequality seems to be better

explained by a process of spatial heterogeneity rather than spatial dependence The practical

implication of this result is that including dummy variables for aggregated units (eg regions or

groups of regions) could be enough to control for the spatial dimension in the modelling and

analysis of income inequality

Among control variables years of education seems to be the main variable for the design of

long-term policies aimed at reducing inequality This result is in line with previous evidence for

cross-country studies (Leamer et al 1999) and specific countries (Howie amp Atakhanova 2014)

Municipal expenditure per capita also shows a significant and negative association with income

inequality in the pooled and RE spatial specifications This means that higher municipal

expenditure helps to reduce inequality between counties but its effect is more limited within

counties This result support the importance of local governments (Fleming amp Measham 2015a)

however the negative coefficient appears as evidence against the ldquoParadox of Plentyrdquo (Borge et

al 2015)

50

Table 22

ML Spatial SAR Models

Table 23

ML Spatial SEM Models

51

Table 24

ML Spatial SARAR Models

26 Discussion and conclusions

In this essay we delve deep into the sources of income inequality analysing its association

with the degree of dependence on natural resources using county-level data for the 2006ndash2017

period in Chile Given recent evidence for the Chilean economy suggesting a significant spatial

dimension we assess and incorporate explicitly the spatial structure of income inequality using

spatial methods We use cross-sectional and panel data to evaluate the significance of the spatial

dimension and we test whether NRD has a positive effect on income inequality

Contrary to what theory predicts NRD shows a significant and negative association with

income inequality This result is robust to the type of analysis (cross-sectional vs panel data) the

approach (spatial vs non-spatial) and the inclusion of different controls The negative and

significant coefficient implies that if the degree of NRD would not have experienced a 10 drop

during this period income inequality could have fallen in 2 additional points So the downward

trend in the participation of the primary sector in terms of employment in the Chilean economy

52

could be one of the main reasons explaining the high persistence in the levels of income inequality

This means that those areas that undergo a process of productive transformation mainly towards

the services sector would be facing greater problems to reduce inequality This process of

productive transformation natural or policy-driven highlights the importance of policies focused

on human capital and the role of local governments in reducing inequality

The main implication for policymakers is that a reduction in NRD does not help to reduce

inequality generating additional challenges for local and central governments in its attempt to

transform the structure of their economies to fewer dependent ones on natural resources The

finding of a significant spatial dimension suggests that defining macro zones capturing the spatial

heterogeneity in the data should be done before analysing the relationship among variables and the

design and evaluation of specific policies Particularly relevant in those areas experiencing a

reduction in NRD are migration commuting and the characteristics of the tertiary (services) sector

In addition our findings show that education and municipal expenditure could be effective policy

tools in the fight to reduce inequality in Chile

Although our results seem quite robust they do not allow us to make causal inferences about

the effect of NRD on income inequality However we could think of the following explanation to

explain the negative relationship found and the differences between geographical areas

Areas highly dependent on NR used to demand a high proportion of low-skill labour This

has change in sectors such as the mining sector in the northern area which has simultaneously

experienced an increase in activities related to the service sector such as retail restaurants

transport and housing However those services associated with more skilled labour such as the

finance sector remain concentrated in the capital region The reduction in the degree of NRD

(employment in extractive activities) implies lower labour force but more specialized with most

53

of the low-skilled labour transferred to a service sector characterized by low productivity and low

wages

Non-spatial models show that the North and South particularly the latter present

significantly higher levels of inequality This could be associated with the type of resources with

ldquopointrdquo resources such as minerals in the North and ldquodiffusedrdquo resources such as agriculture in the

South This translates into higher average incomes in the Centre and North areas and lower average

incomes in the South

The reduction in NRD implies not only a movement of the labour force from extractive

activities to manufacturing or services with the latter characterized by low productivity and low

salaries of the labour force We could also speculate that most of the high incomes move to the

central area where the economic power and ownership over firms and resources are concentrated

This would explain low inequality associated with higher average incomes in the central area and

high inequality associated with lower average incomes in the South A more in-depth analysis

capturing the mobility of wealth and labour force between counties or more aggregated areas is

needed to better understand the causal mechanism involved

Our findings open avenues for future research in different strands First studies on the causes

of income inequality should take the role of NRD into consideration which has been overlooked

so far Given that the spatial dimension of income inequality seems to be explained by a

phenomenon of spatial heterogeneity estimation strategies such as spatial regime models or

geographically weighted regression should be used (Chi amp Zhu 2019) Second the effect of NRD

on income inequality could manifest through different channels such as education fiscal transfers

and institutions We could extend our analysis to identify which of these competing channels is

the most relevant Transforming some continuous variables such as educational level to a

54

categorical variable or defining new indicator variables for instance whether a local government

shows or not an efficient performance we could classify counties in different groups and then

check whether there are differences or not in the relationship between income inequality and NRD

A third strand could be to disaggregate our measure of NRD for different industries This

would allow us to test differences among industries and to identify the sectors that promote greater

equality and which greater inequality Forth the analysis of the consequences of income inequality

on other economic and social phenomena such as efficiency economic growth and social cohesion

has a growing interest in researchers and policymakers Our findings suggest that to answer the

question of whether income inequality has a causal impact on other variables we could include a

measure of NRD as an instrument to address endogeneity issues For instance two interesting

topics for future research are the analysis of how differences in income inequality between counties

could help to explain differences in the level of efficiency of local governments and differences in

the degree of social cohesion (unrest) throughout the country Those are the issues to be addressed

in the next two essays

55

Chapter 3 The Impact of Income Inequality on the Efficiency of

Municipalities in Chile

31 Introduction

In Chile municipalities are the smallest administrative unit for which citizens choose their

local authorities playing an important role in the provision of public goods and services at the

local level Municipalities have a similar set of objectives but the level of financial resources

available to finance their activities is highly heterogeneous This could result in significant

differences in the levels of performance between municipalities Despite their importance there is

little empirical evidence about the efficiency of local governments in Chile This essay aims to

measure the technical efficiency of Chilean municipalities and to analyse how local characteristics

particularly those related to income distribution at the county level could help to explain

differences in municipal performance

Cross-country studies situate Chile as an efficient country in international comparisons about

efficiency of government spending (Herrera amp Pang 2005 Loacutepez amp Miller 2008) However

evidence for Chile at the local level is relatively sparse suggesting significant levels of

inefficiency For instance Pacheco Sanchez and Villena (2013) found a mean efficiency level of

around 70 using a sample of 309 municipalities for the period 2008-2010 This suggests that

municipalities could achieve the same level of output by reducing the usage of inputs by an average

of 30 Their study also showed that those municipalities more dependent on the central

56

government or those located in counties with lower income per capita are more efficient than their

counterparts

Most empirical research on Local Government Efficiency (LGE) has been conducted for

member countries of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) of

which Chile has been a member since 2010 In the case of European countries such as Spain and

Italy which share similar characteristics such as the monetary union and levels of GDP per head

efficiency studies have been mainly motivated by budgetary constraints (Balaguer-Coll Brun-

Martos Maacuterquez-Ramos amp Prior 2019 lo Storto 2013) The Chilean context differs in three

main ways from its OECD counterparts First except for the Metropolitan Region that concentrates

most of the population Chilean regions are highly dependent on natural resources Second Chile

is also characterized by one of the highest levels of income inequality among OECD countries

which contrast with the situation of developed natural resource-rich countries such as Australia

and Norway Third although budget constraints are also a relevant issue Chilean municipalities

have experienced a sustained increase in the level of financial resources and expenditure

Another relevant distinction when we benchmark the performance of municipalities across

different countries is the type of public services they provide On the one hand in most of the

countries included Chile the main role of local governments is to provide ldquoservices to peoplerdquo

such as public education and public health On the other hand there are countries such as Australia

where local governments mainly provide ldquoservices to propertyrdquo including waste management

maintenance of local roads and the provision of community facilities such as libraries swimming

pools and parks (Dollery Wallis amp Akimov 2010 Drew Kortt amp Dollery 2015 McQuestin

Drew amp Dollery 2018)

57

Despite contextual differences Chilean municipalities seem not to perform differently from

municipalities in other developed and natural resource-rich countries where income inequality is

significantly less than in Chile (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018a) This result highlights the

need to study the role of income inequality and the degree of dependence on natural resources over

LGE characteristics that have been largely overlooked in the literature

We measure and analyse differences in municipal performance using a two-stage approach

In the first stage we measure municipal efficiency using an input-oriented Data Envelopment

Analysis (DEA) to get a set of ldquoefficiency scoresrdquo In the second stage we regress efficiency scores

against our measure of income inequality controlling for a set of contextual factors describing the

economic socio-demographic and political context of each county

We use a sample of 324 municipalities for the period 2006-2017 During this period Chile

was divided into 346 counties belonging to 15 regions This period was characterized by important

external and internal shocks including the Global Financial Crisis (GFC) one of the biggest

earthquakes in Chilean history in 2010 and three municipal elections The availability of

information allows us to measure efficiency for the full period but the influence of contextual

factors is analysed using a panel of six years (2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017) for which

household income information is available

The main hypothesis tested in the second stage is whether higher levels of income inequality

are associated with lower levels of efficiency Previous evidence shows that when progress is not

evenly shared persistent within-country inequality reduces the effectiveness and efficiency of the

public sector (Ortega Sanjuaacuten amp Casquero 2017 Tandon 2005)

Income inequality has been used to control for a wide range of idiosyncratic factors

associated with historical institutional and cultural factors affecting efficiency (Greene 2016

58

Ortega et al 2017) For instance at the local level income inequality has been considered as an

indicator of economic heterogeneity in the population where higher inequality is associated with

a more heterogeneous set of conflicting demands for public services which adversely affect an

efficient provision (Ashworth Geys Heyndels amp Wille 2014 Geys amp Moesen 2009) Higher

levels of income inequality could also relate to economically privileged groups having a greater

capacity to influence the political system for their own benefit rather than that of the majority

When high inequality is persistent the feeling of frustration and disappointment in the population

could reduce not only trust and cooperation among individuals but also trust in institutions which

would negatively affect government efficiency (Boix amp Posner 1998 Coffeacute amp Geys 2005) For

instance national or local authorities could end exerting patronage and clientelism and showing

rising levels of corruption (Uslaner 2011 Uslaner amp Brown 2005)

One of the main gaps in extant literature is the need to conduct more analysis of LGE using

panel data taking into consideration endogeneity issues and controlling for unobserved

heterogeneity (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018a) To address the above we set-up a panel with

time and county-specific effects and we propose the use of a measure of natural resource

dependence (NRD) as an instrument for income inequality Based on the ldquoParadox of Plentyrdquo

fiscal revenues from natural resources windfalls could be associated with an over expansion of the

public sector fostering rent-seeking and corruption and reducing local government efficiency

(Dauvin amp Guerreiro 2017 Manzano amp Rigobon 2001) In the Chilean case most of the revenues

generated by local governments included those from natural resources end up in a common fund

which benefits all municipalities The aim of this common fund is precisely to reduce inequalities

among municipalities so although we do not expect a direct impact of natural resources on LGE

we could expect an indirect effect through other indicators particularly income inequality

59

As far as we know this is the first study analysing the influence of income inequality as a

determinant of municipal efficiency in Chile Moreover this is the first study in the context of a

natural resource-rich country which specifically suggests a measure of natural resource

dependence as an instrument to correct for endogeneity bias We propose the use of the proportion

of firms in the primary sector as proxy for the degree of NRD in each county We argue that this

variable is a better proxy than using the proportion of employment in the manufacturing sector

which has been proposed in previous studies (Alesina amp La Ferrara 2002) During the period

analysed our proxy remained relatively stable and showed a significant relationship with income

inequality In addition it is less likely that it has directly affected municipal efficiency

This study adds to the literature in two other ways First the extant literature suggests that

efficiency measurement could be highly sensitive to the chosen technique as well as the selection

of inputs and outputs (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018a) Inputs are usually proxied by a single

measure of total public expenditures and outputs by general proxies such as population andor the

number of businesses in each county We offer a novel approach for the selection of inputs and

outputs On the one hand we disaggregate government expenditures into four components

(operation personnel health and education) and we use the number of public schools and health

facilities in each county as a proxy for physical capital On the other hand we use four outputs

aiming to capture the wide variety of goods and services supplied by each municipality Through

this approach we aim to better describe the production function of each municipality capturing

not only the variety of inputs and outputs but also differences in size among municipalities

A third contribution relates to the measurement of LGE in the Chilean context We measure

technical and scale efficiency using a larger sample and a longer period This has empirical and

policy relevance On the one hand it helps us to select the correct DEA model and allows us to

60

determine the importance of scale inefficiencies as explanation for differences in municipal

performance On the other hand efficiency measures increase the information available for both

central and local governments to better understand the production technology that best describes

each municipality and to carry out policies to improve efficiency

We believe that our selection of inputs and outputs the use of a large dataset and the joint

analysis using cross-sectional and panel data provide a more accurate and robust analysis of

municipal efficiency Likewise knowing whether inequality has a significant influence on

municipal efficiency may provide useful insights and guidance for policymakers not only in Chile

but also for countries sharing similar characteristics

DEA results show an average level of technical efficiency (inefficiency) of around 83

(17) This means that municipalities could reduce on average a 17 the use of inputs without

reducing the outputs There are significant differences among geographic areas with the Centre

area (where the countyrsquos capital is located) displaying higher efficiency than the rest of the country

When municipal efficiency is measured under different assumptions about returns to scale results

reveal a production technology with variable returns to scales and around 75 of the

municipalities displaying scale inefficiencies However when technical efficiency is

disaggregated between pure technical efficiency and scale efficiency results show that scale

inefficiency explains a small proportion of the total municipal technical inefficiency This finding

justifies a deeper analysis of the reasons why municipalities could operate inefficiently and why

municipal performance could vary among municipalities

Efficiency scores also show a significant degree of positive spatial autocorrelation This

means that municipal efficiency shows a general clustering process with neighbouring

municipalities showing similar levels of efficiency A further analysis shows that most of the

61

spatial pattern in municipal efficiency is exogenous that is could be associated to other variables

Hence we conduct most of our regression analysis using traditional (non-spatial) methods and

leaving spatial regressions in the appendixes

Findings from cross-sectional and panel regressions support the hypothesis that municipal

performance is significantly and negatively associated with income inequality at the county level

The coefficient of income inequality is close to one which means that reductions in income

inequality ceteris paribus could be associated with increases in municipal efficiency in the same

proportion This result supports the strand of research arguing that there is not a trade-off at least

at the municipal level between equity and efficiency (Andersen amp Maibom 2020 Berg amp Ostry

2011 2017) The main policy implications are that authorities in more unequal counties would

face higher challenges to perform efficiently and policies pertaining to inequality and efficiency

should not be designed independently

The chapter is structured as follows Section 32 provides a brief literature review on related

local government efficiency Section 33 introduces the methodological background and empirical

models Section 34 presents the empirical results and discussions Section 35 concludes the

chapter

32 Related Literature

321 Measuring efficiency of local governments

Studies on measuring LGE can be grouped in those analysing the provision of single services

such as health or education and those assessing overall efficiency (lo Storto 2013) Once inputs

and outputs have been defined efficiency is measured using parametric andor non-parametric

techniques Among the former group Stochastic Frontier Analysis (SFA) seems to be preferred

62

by scholars aiming to measure efficiency and to analyse the link with environmental variables

using a single procedure (Pacheco et al 2013 Tsekeris Sotiris Tsekeris amp Papaioannou 2018)

On the non-parametric group Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA) is by far the most used technique

(Afonso amp Fernandes 2006 Balaguer-Coll amp Prior 2009 lo Storto 2013)

The selection of inputs and outputs depends not only on the aimed of the study (specific

sector vs whole measure of efficiency) but also on the role that municipalities play in different

countries There are countries such as Australia (Drew et al 2015) and Spain (Balaguer-Coll amp

Prior 2009) where local governments mainly supply services to ldquopropertyrdquo such as waste

management and road maintenance In these cases efficiency has been mainly measured using

total indicators of local government expenditure and outputs have been proxied using general

indicators such as population or number of business (Drew et al 2015) On the other hand in

countries such as Italy (lo Storto 2013) and Portugal (Afonso amp Fernandes 2008) in Europe or

Brazil (de Sousa Cribari-Neto amp Stosic 2005) and Chile (Pacheco et al 2013) in South America

municipalities mainly supply services to ldquopeoplerdquo Here in addition to financial expenditures or

revenues inputs have included the number of local government employees the number of schools

or the number of hospitals and health centres School-age population the number of students

enrolled in primary and secondary schools and the number of beds in hospitals have been

considered as outputs Based on the study of Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte (2018a) a wider list of

inputs and outputs used in previous studies can be found in Appendix I

Studies from different countries show important differences in the average efficiency scores

both between and within countries These studies also differ in the samples methodologies and

variables included A summary showing the range and variability of the mean efficiency scores

founds in countries all around the world can be found in Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte (2018a)

63

These authors also show that OECD natural resource-rich countries such as Australia Belgium

and Chile show similar results in terms of mean efficiency scores with LGE studies being less

frequent in Latin American countries

Measuring efficiency of local governments as decision-making units (DMU) presents many

challenges and difficulties (Borger Kerstens Moesen amp Vanneste 1994 Ravallion 2005)

Worthington and Dollery (2000) mention problems with the selection and measurement of inputs

the identification of different stakeholders the hidden characteristic of the ldquolocal government

technologyrdquo and the multidimensionality of the services provided by local governments All these

issues make difficult to identify and distinguish between outputs and outcomes with outputs

commonly proxied by general indicators such as county area or county population Because

efficiency measures are highly sensitive to the chosen technique and the selection of inputs and

outputs Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte (2018a) suggest formulating different specifications and

using less general and unspecified indicators Moreover the complexity in defining outputs and

the use of general indicators make more likely that contextual factors affect municipal efficiency

322 Explaining differences in LGE

To explain differences in local government performance researchers have basically

distinguished between ldquodiscretionaryrdquo and ldquonon-discretionaryrdquo factors Discretionary factors refer

to the degree of discretion of local authorities in the selection and management of inputs and

outputs On the other hand scholars have investigated the influence on LGE of contextual factors

beyond authoritiesrsquo control These factors reflective at the environment where municipalities

operate include economic socio-demographic geographic financial political and institutional

characteristics (da Cruz amp Marques 2014 Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018b)

64

In general the evidence about the influence of contextual factors has delivered mixed and

country-specific results (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018b) Sampaio de Sousa et al (2005)

using data for Brazilian municipalities finds that population density and urbanization rate have

strong positive effects on efficiency scores Benito et al (2010) show that lower levels of

efficiency of Spanish municipalities are associated with a greater economic level a less stable

population and a bigger size of the local government Afonso (2008) finds that per capita income

level and education are not significant factors influencing LGE of Portuguese municipalities He

also finds that municipalities in Northern areas show greater efficiency than their counterparts in

Southern areas More recently Tsekeris (2018) finds that spatial variations in efficiency in Greece

can be attributed to factors related to inter-regional market access specialization and sectoral

concentration resource-factor endowments and political factors among others Characteristics

describing each local government have also been used including municipal indebtedness (Benito

et al 2010) fiscal deficits (Sinha 2017) degree of fiscal autonomy (Boetti Piacenza amp Turati

2009) and individual characteristics of local authorities such as age gender and political ideology

Narboacuten‐Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte (2018b) conclude after analysing 63 articles that studies on the

influence of contextual factors have mostly used cross-sectional data with little attention to

endogeneity issues which makes any causal interpretation doubtful

323 The trade-off between efficiency and equity

The existence of a potential trade-off between efficiency and equity is in the core of

economic discussion (Andersen amp Maibom 2020 Berg amp Ostry 2011 Browning amp Johnson

1984 Okun 2015)15 The argument that economic growth (one of the most common efficiency

15 Redistributive policies distort incentives and lead to suboptimal outcomes and thus efficiency losses

65

measures) could be negatively affected in the search for greater equality has been translated not

only into economic policies that favour economic growth over those that reduce inequality but

also in the emphasis of scholarly research Thus theoretical and empirical research has been

mainly focussed on efficiency and policy implications of a great diversity of shocks and policies

leaving the analysis of inequality as one of measurement and mostly descriptive Additionally

empirical evidence of the trade-off is scant and inconclusive (Andersen amp Maibom 2020

Browning amp Johnson 1984)

Among economic contextual factors that could affect LGE income inequality has been

largely ignored An exception is a cross-country comparison conducted by Ortega (2017) who

analyses the role of inequality on government efficiency in developing countries He finds that

more unequal countries could have higher difficulties to achieve specific health outcomes Income

inequality has even been considered as part of the outputs to measure efficiency particularly for

the case of European and OECD countries (Afonso Schuknecht amp Tanzi 2010 Antonelli amp De

Bonis 2018)

At the local level income inequality has been mainly used as a proxy for the effect of income

heterogeneity Economic inequality could have a direct and an indirect effect on government

efficiency The direct effect poses that higher income inequality could reduce municipal efficiency

because it is associated with a more complex and competing set of public services demanded by

the population (Jottier et al 2012) The indirect effect puts the focus in the link between inequality

social capital and levels of corruption Economic diversity could reduce trust in people and

institutions when related to high and persistent levels of income inequality It could also affect the

willingness to participate in community and political groups the existence of a shared objective

by citizens and the perception of a prosperous future (Uslaner amp Brown 2005)

66

The evidence is ambiguous For instance Geys and Moesen (2009) find that income

inequality has little relation to efficiency of Flemish municipalities and Ashworth et al (2014)

find a negative relationship for the Norwegian case Findings also indicate that inequality is the

strongest determinant of trust and that trust has a greater effect on communal participation than on

political participation (Uslaner amp Brown 2005)

33 Methodology

We follow a two-stage approach widely used in this kind of analysis A DEA analysis is

conducted in the first stage to get efficiency scores for each municipality Then regression analysis

is conducted in the second stage aiming to identify contextual variables other than differences in

the management of inputs that can help to explain the heterogeneity in municipal performance

331 Chilean Municipalities and period of analysis

The territory of Chile is divided into regions and these into provinces which for purposes of

the local administration are divided into counties The local administration of each county resides

in a municipality which is administrated by a Mayor assisted by a Municipal Council16

Municipalities represent the decentralization of the central power in Chile They are autonomous

organizations with legal personality and own patrimony whose purpose is to satisfy the needs of

the local community and ensure their participation in the economic social and cultural progress of

the county Municipalities have a diversity of functions related to public health education and

social assistance among others

16 The Mayor and City Council are elected by suffrage for the citizens of the respective commune every 4 years

67

To achieve their goals two are the main sources of municipal incomes own permanent

revenues (OPR) and the Municipal Common Fund (MCF) OPR are incomes generated by the

county and they are an indicator of the self-financing capacity of each municipality OPR are not

subject to restrictions regarding their investment and they are mainly generated by territorial taxes

commercial patents and circulation permits17 The MCF is a fund that aims to redistribute

community income to ensure compliance with the purpose of the municipalities and their proper

functioning Sources to finance the MCF come from municipal revenues The distribution

mechanism of the fund is regulated by parameters such as whether municipalities generate OPR

per capita lower than the national average and the number of poor people in the commune in

relation to the number of poor people in the country

This study covers the period from 2006 to 2017 During this period Chile was divided into

15 regions 54 provinces and 346 counties18 Although the information on inputs and outputs is

available for the entire period information on contextual factors at the county level such as

household income is only available every two-three years In addition some counties are excluded

from household surveys due to their difficult access Hence we use a sample of 324 municipalities

to measure municipal efficiency for the whole period (3888 observations) However the analysis

of contextual factors is conducted for those years when household income information is available

2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017 (1944 observations)

17 The territorial tax is a tax on agricultural and non-agricultural real estate Specifically of this income only 40 is left to the municipality as its own financing while the remaining 60 is allocated to the MCF (in the case of the four largest communes- Santiago Providencia Las Condes and Vitacura-percentages are 35 and 65 respectively) Unlike the territorial tax commercial patents are regulated mainly by the municipality which chooses the rate to be charged subject to a range established by law and is responsible of their collection Finally regarding the circulation permits 375 is of municipal benefit while 645 is directed to the MCF 18 There are 346 counties managed by 345 municipalities where counties ldquoCabo de Hornosrdquo and ldquoAntaacuterticardquo are managed by the municipality of ldquoCabo de Hornosrdquo

68

332 Measuring municipal efficiency

Municipal efficiency is measured using Data Envelopment Analysis (Coelli Prasada Rao

OrsquoDonnell amp Battese 2005) This is a non-parametric approach that uses linear programming to

measure efficiency for a group of municipalities as decision making units (DMUrsquos) The main

advantage of using DEA and the reason why DEA is used for the case of Chilean municipalities

is its flexibility in handling multiple inputs and outputs without the need to specify a functional

form (Balaguer-Coll amp Prior 2009 Mikušovaacute 2015 Tigga amp Mishra 2015) Following Afonso

and Fernandes (2008) the relationship between inputs and outputs for each municipality could be

represented by the following equation

119884 119891 119883 119894 1 119899 (31)

In equation (31) 119884 is the set of outputs and 119883 the set of inputs for each of the n

municipalities Using linear programming the production frontier is constructed and a vector of

efficiency scores is obtained The frontier represents full technical efficiency mdash the point at which

the highest output occurs given specified inputs or the point at which the lowest amount of inputs

is used to produce a specified quantity of output Efficiency scores under DEA are relative

measures of efficiency They measure a municipalityrsquos efficiency against the other measured

municipalities in the sample and not a hypothetical lsquoperfect municipalityrsquo The further from the

frontier the less technically efficient a municipality is

We use an input-oriented approach because Chilean municipalities have a greater control

over the management of inputs relative to the outputs they have to manage Obtaining efficiency

scores requires an assumption about the returns to scale exhibited by each municipality When

DMUrsquos are homogeneous the CCR model (Charnes Cooper amp Rhodes 1978) which assumes

69

constant return-to-scale (CRS) is the appropriate specification The CCR model assumes full

proportionality between outputs and inputs and that DMUrsquos operate at their optimal When DMUrsquos

are highly heterogeneous as is the case with local governments in most countries it is not realistic

to assume complete proportionality between inputs and outputs nor that all DMUrsquos operate at their

optimum scale In this situation a variable returns-to-scale (VRS) or BCC model (Banker

Charnes amp Cooper 1984) is the preferred formulation

Assuming VRS imposes minimum restrictions on the efficient frontier and allows for

comparisons only among municipalities of similar scale (Coelli et al 2005 Wu Huang amp Pan

2014) This means that when we use the CCR model (assuming CRS) on a heterogeneous sample

of DMUrsquos the resulting measure of technical efficiency that we obtain is related not only to the

management of inputs but also to issues of scale19 To empirically check the validity of the VRS

assumption we measure technical efficiency under CRS VRS and non-increasing returns-to-scale

(NIRS) and we analyse the existence of scale inefficiencies This allows us to check the relevance

of scale effects as a potential explanation of differences in municipal efficiency Appendix J

shows the specification of the DEA model under VRS and how ldquototal technical efficiencyrdquo

(assuming CRS and therefore due to management and scale issues) could be disaggregated in ldquopure

technical efficiencyrdquo (under VRS and related only to management issues) and scale efficiency (due

to scale issues)

19 Assuming VRS can also lead to measurement problems such as overestimation of efficiency scores This is the case when an important proportion of DMUrsquos shows CRS so assuming VRS ignores the information about proportionality between inputs and outputs (Podinovski 2004)

70

333 Inputs and outputs used in DEA

Following the literature on local government expenditure efficiency (Afonso amp Fernandes

2008 de Sousa et al 2005 Dlouhyacute 2018 Tandon 2005 Tigga amp Mishra 2015) and trying to

reflect as well as possible the functioning of municipalities five inputs and four outputs were

selected Input and output data were obtained from the National System of Municipal Information

(SINIM in its Spanish acronym) and they are expressed in thousands of Chilean pesos of 201720

Inputs are Municipal Operational Expenditure X1 (including expenses on goods and

services social assistance investment and transfers to community organizations) Municipal

Personnel Expenditure X2 (including full time and part-time workers) Total Municipal

Expenditure in Education sector X3 Total Municipal Expenditure in Health sector X4 and the

Number of Municipal Buildings X5 (proxied by the number of public facilities in education and

health sectors)

Output variables were selected highlighting the relevance of education and health sectors

and trying to capture the wide range of local services provided by municipalities The variable

ldquoOwn Permanent Revenuesrdquo Y1 is used to capture the scale and diversity of municipal

activities21 The ldquoMonthly Average Enrolmentrdquo in municipal education establishments related to

the school-age population in each county Y2 is used as educational output As health output the

ldquoNumber of Medical Consultationsrdquo in public facilities Y3 is considered Finally the number of

community organizations Y4 is used as output reflecting the promotion of community

development by each municipality Table 31 shows the summary statistics of input and output

20 The data from SINIM database was mostly obtained using the sinimr package (Salas 2019) 21 According to SINIM database this variable aims to measure the management of the municipalityrsquos own resources with respect to the population of the commune

71

variables for the whole sample and period Inputs and outputs excepting the Monthly Average

Enrolment Y2 are measured in per capita terms using county population information from the

National Institute of Statistics (INE in its Spanish acronym)

Table 31

Descriptive statistics Inputs and Output variables used in DEA analysis

334 Regression model

Contextual factors could play an important role not only in explaining why some

municipalities operate inefficiently but also why municipal performance differs among them

These factors may affect municipal performance modifying incentives for local authorities to

operate efficiently and their capability to take advantage of economies of scale They also define

the conditions for cooperation or competition among municipalities and the citizensacute ability and

willingness to monitor local authorities (Afonso amp Fernandes 2008)

Information on income at the household level for each county was obtained from the

ldquoNational Socioeconomic Characterization Surveyrdquo (CASEN in its Spanish acronym) CASEN is

conducted every two-three years being the reason why consecutive years are not considered in

72

our regression analysis The other contextual factors used as controls were obtained from different

sources including SINIM INE and the ldquoServicio de Impuestos Internosrdquo (SII)22

Our main hypothesis is whether higher levels of income inequality are associated with lower

levels of municipal efficiency To test our hypothesis the empirical model is defined as

120579 120573 119892119894119899119894 119885 120573 120575 120572 120598 (32)

Where 120579 is the vector of DEA efficiency scores 119892119894119899119894 is the Gini coefficient of each

county 120575 are year-specific effects 120572 are county-specific constants 120598 is a vector of error terms

and 119885 is a vector of controls Next we discuss the motivation for these controls

The level of purchasing power of countiesrsquo citizens is proxied by the variable log(income)

which is the natural log of the mean household income per capita in thousands of Chilean pesos of

2017 On the one hand poorer counties could display higher efficiency due to their necessity to

take care of their constraint resources (Pacheco et al 2013) On the other hand richer counties

could show higher efficiency because richer citizens exert higher monitoring over local authorities

and demand better quality public services in return for their tax payments (Afonso et al 2010)

The possibility for municipalities to take advantage of economies of scale and urbanization is

captured by three variables First the variable log(density) which correspond to the natural log of

population density Second the dummy variable reg_cap indicating whether a county is a regional

capital or not Third the variable agroland which correspond to the proportion of land for

agricultural use which is informed to the SII We expect a positive effect of log(density) but

negative for regcap and agroland

22 The SII is the institution in charge of collecting taxes in Chile

73

Socio-demographic characteristics are captured including a Dependence Index IDD IDD

corresponds to the number of people under 15 years or over 65 years per 100 people in the active

population (those people between 15 and 65 years old) A higher proportion of young and older

population could be associated with a higher demand for municipal services relating to education

and health making harder to offer public services efficiently The citizensrsquo capacity to monitor

local authorities is proxied including the variable education (average years of education for the

population older than 15 years) and the variable housing (proportion of households which are

owners of the property where they live in each county) In both cases we expect a positive

association with LGE

Among municipal characteristics the variable professional (percentage of municipal

personnel with a professional degree) is used to control for the quality of municipal services and

it is expected a positive impact The variable mcf (proportion of total municipal income coming

from the MCF) is included to capture the influence of financial dependence on the central

government A higher dependence from MCF could be associated with higher efficiency when it

is linked to more control from central government (Worthington amp Dollery 2000) However when

MCF discourages the generation of own resources and proper management of resources from the

fund a lower efficiency should be expected (Bravo 2014) In addition the dummy variable mayor

is included to capture differences among mayors supported by the ldquoLEFTrdquo or the ldquoRIGHTrdquo

political parties related to those ldquoINDEPENDENTrdquo mayors

Table 32 report summary statistics for the set of numeric contextual factors and Appendix

K the corresponding correlation matrix Despite the high correlation between income and

education variables we include both in the regression section as they capture different county

characteristics

74

Table 32

Summary Statistics Numeric Contextual Factors

Figure 31 Geographical distribution of Chilean regions and macrozones

Previous evidence on growth and convergence of Chilean regions have found that regions

tend to cluster spatially (Aroca amp Bosch 2000) Aiming to capture this regional clustering process

75

and considering the high concentration in the number of municipalities and population in the

central area we group municipalities in four ldquozonesrdquo We define as reference the ldquoCentre-Northrdquo

zone consisting of regions XIII (where the countryrsquos capital is located) and its two neighbouring

regions V and VI The ldquoNorthrdquo zone includes regions XV I II III and IV The ldquoCentre-Southrdquo

zone includes regions VII VIII and IX Finally the ldquoSouthrdquo zone embraces regions XIV X XI

and XII Figure 31 displays the regional administrative division and zones considered in this

essay

Efficiency scores (ES) are limited to have values between 0 and 1 However they are relative

measures (relative to the sample of municipalities) This implies that when a municipality is on the

frontier (ES = 1) it does not mean that potentially larger technical efficiency gains cannot be made

Hence equation 32 is estimated using OLS and censored regressions We start running cross-

sectional regressions for each of the six years Then we compare the results with those from panel

regressions Because fixed-effects panel Tobit models could be affected by the incidental

parameters problem (Henningsen 2010 2019) we use random-effects panel Tobit models

including indicator variables for years and zones Finally to deal with the potential endogeneity

problem we also use an instrumental variable approach The instrument is described next

335 The instrument

Government effectiveness and income distribution are both structural components of

economies (Ortega et al 2017 Ravallion 2005) In the search for a causal interpretation for the

influence of income inequality on municipal efficiency we need an instrument which must be

correlated with the variable to be instrumented (in our case income inequality) and uncorrelated

with the error term in the efficiency equation (32) Previous literature has used as instruments for

Gini the number of townships governments in a previous period the percentage of revenues from

76

intergovernmental transfers in a previous period and the current share of the labour force in the

manufacturing sector (Alesina amp La Ferrara 2002) Using the share of the labour force in a specific

sector is unlikely to reduce the problem of endogeneity particularly in countries where local

governments supply mostly ldquoservices to peoplerdquo and the main source of income inequality is

labour income

We propose as an instrument the proportion of firms in the primary sector (mining fishing

forestry and agriculture)

119901119904119904_119891119894119903119898119904Number of firms in the primary sector

Total number of firms (33)

On the one hand this instrument is likely to be correlated with local income inequality in

natural resource-rich countries23 On the other hand we contend that our instrument is less likely

to be correlated with the error term in the efficiency equation First the main services supplied by

Chilean municipalities are services to people (health and education) not to firms Second most of

the revenues collected by municipalities included those associated with natural resources end up

in the municipal common fund whose objective is precisely to reduce inequalities among

municipalities Third services to firms are expected to be more significant with the tertiary sector

We argue that our instrument captures natural and structural conditions which directly

influence income inequality but it does not directly affect LGE Figure 32 shows the evolution

of the annual average efficiency score and the proportion of firms in the primary secondary

(manufacturing) and tertiary (services) sectors We observe that sectors shares have remained

relatively stable with a slight reduction in the participation of the primary sector in favour of the

23 Results confirm a significant association between income inequality and the degree of dependence on natural resources at the county level

77

tertiary sector by the end of the period This is contrary to the evolution of municipal efficiency

which shows a cyclical behaviour as will be shown in the next section

Figure 32 Evolution of efficiency scores and the proportion of firms by sector

34 Results and discussion

341 DEA results

Figure 33 displays the evolution of our three measures of efficiency Overall technical

efficiency pure technical efficiency and scale efficiency are around 78 83 and 95

respectively with fluctuations over the years Therefore around three quarters of the overall

78

inefficiency is attributed to inefficiency in the management of inputs and around one quarter to

scale inefficiencies24

Figure 33 Evolution technical efficiency (TE) pure technical efficiency (PTE) and scale efficiency (SE)

Returnstoscale

Figure 34 reports by zone and for the whole period the proportion of municipalities

showing CRS decreasing returns to scale (DRS) or increasing returns to scale (IRS) Most of the

municipalities operate under variable (increasing or decreasing) returns to scale which could be

explained by the high heterogeneity in size among municipalities A summary of RTS

disaggregated by year and zone is in Appendix L Policies oriented to increase efficiency usually

24 The average scale efficiency score of 95 means that municipalities could get an additional 5 of inputs saving if municipalities were able to change their size to achieve their optimal scale

79

consider amalgamation de-amalgamation or ways of cooperation among municipalities To have

a better idea about where and how feasible is the implementation of such policies Appendix M

shows maps with the administrative division of the country in its 345 municipalities and which

municipalities show CRS IRS or DRS in each of the six years of data

Figure 34 Returns to scale by zone

Based on results for the whole period (Figure 34) the North has the highest proportion of

municipalities exhibiting DRS This suggests the need to reduce the size of municipalities splitting

those ldquotoo bigrdquo creating new administrative areas or giving more autonomy to current

municipalities25 The opposite occurs in the Centre-North area where municipalities mostly

exhibit IRS This indicates the need to merge municipalities An alternative strategy to the

amalgamation process is increasing inter-municipal cooperation (Balaguer-Coll et al 2019)

25 This has been the policy followed in Chile Although two new regions were created (XV in the North and XIV in the South) the number of municipalities has not changed

80

which seems to be a more plausible option in Chile Finally evidence on scale efficiency for the

Centre-South and South areas is not clear in terms of the adequate strategy to improve efficiency

Efficiencymeasure

Although most municipalities show scale inefficiencies (Figure 34) only a small proportion

of total inefficiency is associated to scale issues (Figure 33) Together this results justify not only

the use of the BCC model (efficiency scores under VRS) to capture municipal heterogeneity but

also highlights the need to look for other factors outside the control of local authorities which

could be influencing municipal performance

Table 33

Summary efficiency scores (VRS) by zone and region

Table 33 summarizes ES under VRS using data for the six years of CASEN survey A mean

efficiency score of 83 is found for the full sample and period This means that on average

inefficient municipalities can reduce the use of inputs by 17 to get the same current output By

81

comparing average ES per zone it can be concluded that municipalities in the North Centre-North

Centre-South and South could achieve the same level of output with 17 12 18 and 23 fewer

resources respectively Results also show that one third of the municipalities present an efficiency

score equal to one

Figure 35 shows the evolution of the mean ES for the four zones over the 12 years period

A clear drop in the efficiency level is observed in 2009 (the financial crisis year) excepting for the

North area Likewise although mean efficiency returned to its pre-crisis levels in 2014-2015 a

new drop in efficiency was experienced in 2016 It also seems that the 2010 earthquake did not

generate a significant effect on municipal efficiency Figure 35 also shows that although levels

of efficiency seem to differ among zones they follow a similar trend through time with the only

exception of the North which corresponds to the mining area In addition efficiency seems to be

significantly higher in the Centre-North area This is explained by the high mean level of efficiency

in region XIII which includes the countryrsquos capital city

Figure 35 Evolution mean efficiency scores (VRS) by zone

82

To know which and where are the efficient municipalities and if they are surrounded by

municipalities with a similar level of efficiency Appendix N has maps showing the ldquoefficiency

statusrdquo of each municipality that is whether they are efficient (ES = 1) or inefficient (ES lt 1)

Additionally Appendix O shows ldquoequal intervalsrdquo maps describing the spatial distribution of ES

among municipalities for each of the six years26 Results show that efficient municipalities can be

found all through the country the ldquoefficiency statusrdquo could change from one year to another and

municipalities with similar level-status of efficiency tend to cluster in space

342 Regression results

Exploratoryspatialanalysis

DEA efficiency scores and their geographical representations seem to show that municipal

efficiency presents a spatial clustering pattern This means that municipal performance could be

influenced not only by contextual factors of the county where municipality belongs but also by the

level of efficiency of neighbouring municipalities and their characteristics To test the significance

of the spatial dimension in municipal efficiency we use a cross-section of data considering the six-

year average of efficiency scores the Gini coefficient and the set of controls

We use the Moranrsquos I indicator to test for spatial autocorrelation Moranrsquos I is a measure of

the correlation between the level of efficiency in one municipality and its ldquospatial lagrdquo that is the

average level of efficiency in neighbouring municipalities We define as the relevant neighbours

for each municipality the 5-nearest municipalities This is obtained using the distances among the

26 An equal intervals map uses the same principle as a histogram to organize the observations into categories that divide the range of the variable into equal interval bins For the equal interval classification the value range between the lower and upper bound in each bin is constant across bins but the number of observations in each bin is typically not equal

83

polygonsrsquo centroids (latitude and longitude) of each county Results confirm that municipal

efficiency show a significant level of positive spatial autocorrelation This means that

municipalities tend to have neighbouring municipalities with similar performance

The positive spatial autocorrelation shown by municipal efficiency could be due to the

performance in one municipality is influenced by the performance in neighbouring municipalities

(spatial dependence in the variable itself) or due to structural differences among regions-zones

(spatial heterogeneity) To check the source of the spatial autocorrelation we run an OLS

regression of ES against income inequality and controls and then we test OLS residuals for spatial

autocorrelation Moranrsquos I over OLS residuals although significant is barely higher than zero (see

Appendix P) This means that the spatial effect itself is not a serious issue and can be handle for

instance including zone indicators variables hence we proceed to analyse the influence of income

inequality on LGE using non-spatial regression27

Cross‐sectionalanalysis

We start reporting censored regressions for each year in our panel Efficiency scores have

been rescaled to numbers between 0 and 100 to facilitate the interpretation of the results All

regressions include dummy variables for three of the four zones in which we have grouped Chilean

regions Results are in Table 3428 Income inequality shows a negative sign in all years which is

consistent with our hypothesis that inequality is negatively related to municipal efficiency

However only in three of the six years the effect of income inequality appears as statistically

27 In the case of having incorporated the spatial dimension the two most commonly used forms are including in the model the spatial lag of the dependent variable (spatial autoregressive model SAR) or the spatial lag of the error (spatial error model SEM) Following the method suggested by Anselin et al (1996) Lagrange Multiplier (LM) tests on the OLS residuals showed that the SAR model is preferred over the SEM Moranrsquos I LM tests and spatial regressions can be found in Appendix P 28 Regression results using OLS are in Appendix Q

84

significant Only the income level displays a significant and positive influence on efficiency for

the whole period A higher population density also consistently favours municipal efficiency On

the other hand as we expected a higher IDD makes it more difficult to achieve an efficient

performance29 Consistent with results in Pacheco et al (Pacheco et al 2013) municipal

efficiency show a significant an positive association with the MCF only in the first half of our

period of analysis with the second half showing an insignificant relationship

Table 34

Cross-sectional (censored) regressions

Paneldataanalysis

Estimation results for the six-year panel are reported in Table 35 Columns (1) and (2) show

the results for the pooled and random effects censored models only controlling for zone and year

29 The set of cross-sectional regressions was also run for each zone independently Results confirm that the set of significant contextual factors differs not only among years but also among geographic areas This support previous evidence suggesting that cross-sectional analysis should be treated with caution (Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018b)

85

dummies Income inequality appears as non-significant Zone indicator variables confirm that

municipalities located in the Centre-South and South of the country display a lower average level

of efficiency compared to the Centre-North area Time dummies mostly show negative

coefficients This is a signal that shocks such as the GFC and the earthquake in 2010 may have

had a negative impact on efficiency but that impact was not permanent The results for the pooled

and RE models including the full set of controls are reported in columns (3) and (4) These results

show a significant negative influence of income inequality on LGE

When income inequality is instrumented by the variable pss_firms most of the coefficients

remain unchanged except for those associated with the income variables gini and log(income)

This result implies that our original model suffers for instance from the omitted variable bias

This means that LGE and income inequality are determined simultaneously by some variable not

included in our model Columns (5) and (6) show results using our instrument for income

inequality The ldquotrue coefficientrdquo of variable gini remains negative but the magnitude of the

relationship is higher The negative coefficient for gini implies on the one hand that municipalities

located in more unequal counties face more challenges to achieve an efficient management of

public resources On the other hand the coefficient in column (6) is close to one The interpretation

is that for each point of reduction in income inequality ceteris paribus LGE should increase in the

same proportion Next we discuss some of the results associated with the controls variables

Contrary to Pacheco et al (2013) income level has a positive coefficient meaning that richer

counties in terms of income per capita show higher efficiency This could be explained by higher

monitoring and increasing demands from citizen and taxpayers In addition it is expected a higher

efficiency in municipalities located in counties with a higher population density and those with a

lower proportion of land for agricultural use This result is mainly explained by municipalities

86

located in the Centre area The opposite happens with municipalities in the South implying that

they are too ldquosmallrdquo to take advantage of agglomeration economies There is also a limit for

agglomeration and scale economies which is shown by the negative coefficient of the variable

regcap although this coefficient loses its significance in the IV approaches30

Unexpectedly efficiency was found to be negatively associated with the variable education

This result is similar to the case of Czech municipalities (Šťastnaacute amp Gregor 2014) where

explanations include a weakened monitoring effect due to the fact that more educated citizens

present greater mobility and labour cost disadvantages for municipalities with better educated

labour force In Chile an additional explanation could be the relationship between education and

voter turnout Since 2012 voting is no longer mandatory in Chile This fact considerably reduced

voter turnout which in turn may have influenced the monitoring and control effect of more

educated voters For the case of variable IDD results show that local authorities in counties with

higher proportion of aging and young population (related to those in the active population) face a

greater challenge in their quest to offer public services efficiently

The influence of mcf is like that found by Pacheco et al (2013) with municipalities more

dependent on central transfers showing more efficiency31 Political influence captured by the

variable mayor did not show a significant effect This result is like other studies concluding that

the ideological position did not have a significant influence on efficiency (Benito et al 2010

Boetti et al 2009 Cordero Pedraja-Chaparro Pisaflores amp Polo 2017)

30 This negative coefficient suggests that the negative effects of agglomeration economies such as overcrowding pollution high cost of land and traffic congestion could predominate over the positive effects of scale economies in regional capitals 31 When the analysis is conducted for each zone independently MCF displays a negative influence in the North and Centre-North areas but a positive influence in the Centre-South and South areas These results confirm that on the one hand richer municipalities (those in the North and Centre-North) have less incentives for efficient management of their resources On the other hand results support the relevance of MCF helping poorer municipalities (those in the South) to reach their outcomes

87

Table 35

Panel data regressions

88

35 Conclusions

The trade-off between equity and efficiency is in the core of the economic discussion This

ldquoprinciplerdquo has been used by policymakers to prioritize the design of policies focused on economic

growth delaying those policies aimed at reducing economic inequalities This essay offers

empirical evidence of a negative relationship between inequality and efficiency that is a reduction

of income inequality could have positive effects on economic efficiency at least at the level of

local governments

We followed a traditional Two-Stage approach commonly used in the analysis of LGE We

compared cross-sectional and panel data results and we have added an instrumental variable

approach to give a causal interpretation to the link between efficiency and inequality We proposed

the use of a measure of natural resource dependence to instrumentalize the impact of income

inequality on LGE Given that our units of analysis are municipalities and not counties we argue

that our measure of NRD is correlated with income inequality and it does not have a direct

influence on LGE

We found that Chilean municipalities perform better than previous studies suggest

Municipal efficiency depicted significant levels of positive spatial autocorrelation and most of the

municipalities showed to be operating under increasing or decreasing returns to scale This would

imply that the policies generally used to improve efficiency such as amalgamation or cooperation

should be implemented observing the reality of each region and not as strategies at the national

level We also found that scale inefficiency explains a small proportion of the average total

inefficiency reason why the analysis of external factors that could affect the municipal efficiency

takes greater relevance

89

Income inequality plays an important part in explaining municipal efficiency In fact it was

found that reductions in income inequality could result in increases in municipal efficiency in a

similar proportion An unexpected finding was that the levels of education shows a negative

association with municipal performance This could be due to a low average level of education or

the existence of an omitted variable This variable could be the significant reduction in voting

turnout rates for local and national elections due to changes in the voting system during the period

of our analysis All in all our results may help to shed light on the potential consequences of

changes in contextual factors and the design of strategies aimed to increase municipal efficiency

in countries with similar characteristics to the Chilean economy For instance policies oriented to

take advantage of economies of scale can be formulated merging municipalities or establishing

networks in specific sectors such as education or health

Further work needs to be done both in measurement and in the explanation of differences in

municipal performance in Chile One area of future work will be to identify the factors that better

predict why municipalities operates under increasing decreasing or constant returns to scale

Multinomial logistic regression and the application of machine learning algorithms to SINIM data

sets appear as suitable methods for that purpose Intertemporal DEA (Drew amp Dollery 2015)

should be used to measure municipal efficiency capturing changes in total factor productivity In

addition municipalities operate under different levels of geographical authorities such as the

provincial mayor and the regional governor Hence it would be useful to know how each

municipality performs within each region-zone related to how performs to the whole country This

should be done conducting a metafrontier analysis (OrsquoDonnell Rao amp Battese 2008)

We have also identified through a cross sectional spatial exploratory analysis that on

average municipalities with similar levels of efficiency tend to cluster in space Regarding to

90

analyse the importance of contextual factors on municipal efficiency a deeper analysis should use

censored spatial models to check the significance of the spatial dimension in cross-sectional and

panel contexts Another interesting avenue for future research is associated with the negative

association found between LGE and education The significant reduction in votersacute turnout since

the law of automatic registration and voluntary voting in 2011 appears as a natural experiment to

analyse its effects on efficiency indicators such as municipal performance Incorporating variables

such as the voting turnout in each county or classifying municipalities based on individual

institutional political and economic characteristics could help to shed light on which of these

channels is the most relevant when analysing the impact of inequality on municipal efficiency

Finally we argued that an important part of the influence of income inequality over LGE

could be through its indirect effect on trust social capital and social cohesion The final essay will

delve deep in that relationship

91

Chapter 4 Social Cohesion Incivilities and Diversity

Evidence at the municipal level in Chile

41 Introduction

A deterioration in social cohesion could carry significant costs such as a reduction in

generalized trust between individuals and in institutions a society caught in a vicious circle of

inequality and citizens increasingly distanced from civic life (Uslaner 2011) A growing feeling

of frustration and discontentment can eventually translate into a social outbreak with uncertain

results This is precisely what have been happening in many countries around the world included

Chile

ldquoSocial cohesion is a state of affairs concerning both the vertical and the horizontal

interactions among members of society as characterized by a set of attitudes and norms that

includes trust a sense of belonging and the willingness to participate and help as well as their

behavioural manifestationsrdquo (Chan et al 2006) This definition highlights the multidimensionality

in the concept of social cohesion which has been measured using objective andor subjective

indicators of trust social norms solidarity willingness to participate in social and political groups

and feelings of belonging (Ariely 2014 Chan et al 2006) Multidimensionality also implies that

the impact of determinants of social cohesion such as economic and racial diversity could be

different for each of its various dimensions (Ariely 2014)

A common characteristic to all societies is that they are made up of different groups that

differ with respect to race ethnicity income religion language local identity etc The

92

Community Heterogeneity Thesis (Coffeacute amp Geys 2006) argues that individuals prefer to interact

with others that are like themselves Hence high levels of diversity particularly economic and

racial represent a complex scenario to maintain social cohesion One of the most common factors

adduced for social cohesion is income inequality with higher levels linked to lower levels of trust

(Ariely 2014 Rothstein amp Uslaner 2005)

Traditional measures of social cohesion may not be adequately capturing the deterioration

in social connections For instance measures of (lack of) trust include a strong subjective element

On the other hand proxies for social participation such as volunteering jobs or joining to social

organizations have not been supported by empirical evidence as a source of generalized social trust

(Rothstein amp Uslaner 2005) We proposed to use the rate of incivilities which we argue is a more

appropriate measure of the degree of worsening in the social context

Incivilities are those visible disorders in the public space that violate respectful social norms

and tend not to be treated as crimes by the criminal justice system There are two types of

incivilities social and physical Social incivilities include antisocial behaviours such as public

drinking noisy neighbours and fighting in public places Physical incivilities include among

others vandalism graffiti abandoned cars and garbage on the streets Because citizens and

political authorities cannot always distinguish between incivilities and crime they are usually

treated as an additional category of crime This implies that policies aimed to reduce incivilities

are generally based on punitive actions However theory and evidence on incivilities suggest that

factors explaining incivilities and crime could be different (Lewis 2017 Taylor 1999)

In Chile crime rates have shown a sustained downward trend after reaching its highest level

in 2011 On the other hand incivilities rate has shown a sustained upward trend which coincides

with the increasing victimization and feeling of insecurity in the population This has motivated

93

Chilean authorities based on the ldquoBroken Windows Theoryrdquo to propose new punitive actions (or

increase the severity of the current ones) to those who commit this type of antisocial behaviours

The ldquoBroken Windows Theoryrdquo states that higher rates of incivilities are a signal of social

disorganization which result in higher crime rates (J Q Wilson amp Kelling 1982) This is expected

to have consequences on familiesrsquo decisions such as moving away from public spaces or even

leaving their neighbourhoods

As far as we know there is no previous evidence about the potential causes of incivilities in

Chile Efforts to identify the factors explaining incivilities could help not only to reduce the risk

factors favouring violent and property crimes but also to guide interventions aimed to change

social behaviours and strengthen social cohesion in highly unequal societies Thus the main

contribution of the present study is to provide a deeper comprehension of the problem of incivilities

and how they can help to better understand the weakening of social cohesion that many

contemporary societies experience

We aim to offer the first evidence on the factors explaining the evolution and the differences

in incivilities rates in Chile We set up a panel for six years (2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and

2017) and 324 counties (1944 observations) We start exploring the evolution and geographical

distribution of incivilities Then we investigate whether economic and racial diversity after

controlling for other socioeconomic demographic and municipal characteristics can be regarded

as key predictors of incivilities

We use the Gini coefficient to proxy economic heterogeneity and the number of new visas

granted to foreigners as proportion of the county population as proxy for racial diversity The main

hypothesis is whether economic and racial diversity have a positive association with the rate of

incivilities In addition to the arguments regarding the ldquoCommunity Heterogeneity Thesisrdquo Taylor

94

(1999) and Skogan (1986 1999 2015) argue that incivilities are caused by inequality and the lack

of informal mechanisms of social control Based on the ldquoIncivilities Thesisrdquo the patterns of

incivilities should mirror the patterns of inequality (Taylor 1999) Then higher inequality should

be associated with higher physical and social vulnerability of the population This reduces social

control and increases social disorganization which triggers antisocial or negligent behaviours

Our main result reveals a strong positive association between the rate of incivilities and the

number of new visas granted per year The relationship with income inequality although also

positive seems to be less significant These findings give strong support to the ldquoCommunity

Heterogeneity Thesisrdquo and to a lesser extent to the ldquoIncivilities Thesisrdquo When the analysis is

disaggregated geographically racial diversity shows a clear positive effect The impact of income

inequality seems to be conditional depending on the level of income showing no effect in poorer

regions Results also show that the impact of economic and racial diversity differs by type of

incivility For example income inequality shows a strong association with ldquoStreet Tradingrdquo while

racial diversity with ldquoAlcohol Consumptionrdquo Two are the main policy implications On the one

hand a national strategy to address the problems associated with foreign immigration could help

to reduce incivilities For instance a joint effort between national and local authorities to curb

immigration and its distribution throughout the country On the other hand our results show that

the relationship between incivilities and economic diversity differs depending on the region or

geographical area Hence the impact on social cohesion of policies aimed to tackle economic

inequalities should be analysed in each specific context

The rate of incivilities also shows a negative association with the level of municipal financial

autonomy This implies that municipalities can effectively carry out policies to reduce incivilities

beyond the efforts of the central government Another important finding is that our results do not

95

support the hypothesis that a higher proportion of the young population is associated with higher

rates of incivilities Hence policies aimed to reduce incivilities should be focused on the causes of

incivilities rather than the criminalization of behaviours or stigmatization of specific population

groups

The structure of the chapter is as follows Section 42 outlines the relevant literature on social

cohesion and incivilities Section 43 describes the data variables and methodology and

establishes the hypotheses of the study Section 44 contains the results and discussions Section

45 presents the main conclusions

42 Related Literature

421 The Community Heterogeneity Thesis

The idea under ldquoThe Community Heterogeneity Thesisrdquo is that if individuals prefer to

interact with others who are similar to themselves in terms of income race or ethnicity high levels

of income inequality and racial diversity facilitate a context for lower tolerance and antisocial

behaviours lowering the ldquostaterdquo of social cohesion (Alesina 2000 Coffeacute amp Geys 2006 Letki

2008) Alessina and Ferrara (2002) give support to this hypothesis arguing that individuals have a

natural aversion to heterogeneity However the most popular explanation is the principle of

homophily people prefer to interact with others who share the same ethnic heritage have the same

social status and hence share experiences and tastes (Letki 2008 McPherson Smith-Lovin amp

Cook 2001 Tolsma et al 2009) For instance Delhey and Newton (2005) find for a sample of

60 countries that income inequality and ethnicity are strongly and negatively correlated with trust

Tolsma et al (2009) using data for Dutch neighbourhoods and municipalities find that social

cohesion is negatively and consistently affected by economic deprivation but not by ethnic

96

heterogeneity These authors also conclude that the effect of neighbourhood and municipal

characteristics on social cohesion depends on residentsrsquo income and educational level

Rothstein and Uslaner (2005) give two theoretical reasons why economic and racial diversity

should be causally related to social trust a key element of social cohesion First optimism about

the future makes less sense when there is more economic inequality which generally translates into

inequality of opportunities especially in areas such as education and the labour market Second

the distribution of resources and opportunities plays a key role in establishing the belief that people

share a common destiny and have similar fundamental values In highly unequal societies people

are likely to stick with their own kind Perceptions of injustice will reinforce negative stereotypes

of other groups making social trust and accommodation more difficult

Uslaner (2002 2011) and Uslaner and Brown (2005) find that high levels of inequality are

the single major factor driving down trust in people who are different from yourself Evidence for

USA finds that inequality is the strongest determinant of generalized trust over time (Rothstein amp

Uslaner 2005) Reducing inequality and then increasing generalized trust should have positive

consequences at the individual and aggregates levels At the individual level it may lead to greater

tolerance and more acts of altruism for people of different backgrounds At the aggregate level it

may lead to greater economic growth more redistribution from the rich to the poor and less

corruption (Uslaner 2002 2013) Letki (2008) argues that when neighbourhood socio-economic

context (apart from just an individualrsquos socioeconomic status) is considered it turns out to be the

main factor triggering negative attitudes and lack of trust in out-group members

The increasing diversity caused by immigration can also reduce the conditions necessary for

social cohesion (Ariely 2014 Holtug amp Mason 2010) Christel Kesler and Irene Bloemraad

(2010) find for nineteen advanced democracies between 1981 and 2000 that increasing migration

97

generally decreases trust civic engagement and political participation The authors also find that

in more equal countries with clear policies in favour of cultural minorities the negative effects of

migration are mitigated or even reversed Letki (2008) states that deprivation and disorder tend to

be strongly correlated with racial diversity Because we propose the use of the number of disorders

or antisocial behaviours known as ldquoincivilitiesrdquo as our measure of social cohesion we describe the

literature on incivilities in the next section

422 The literature on incivilities

The study of incivilities has been a continuing concern mainly for developed countries since

the 1980s The focus has changed from individual and psychological explanations to ecological

(contextual) and social explanations (Taylor 1999) The individual approach basically considered

perceptions of incivilities as an explanatory variable of fear of crime The ecological explanation

argues that indicators of economic disadvantage (eg income levels income inequality

unemployment rate and poverty rate) are the keys to understand a process of social disorganization

and lack of informal control These economic factors lead to higher rates of inappropriate or

negligent behaviours and ultimately to higher crime rates (Blau amp Blau 1982 Messner Rosenfeld

amp Baumer 2004 Phan Orsquobrien Mendolia amp Paloyo 2017 Sampson 1986)

The negative impact of incivilities is not merely reflected in its association with crime rates

(Skogan 2015) Physical and social incivilities could worsen neighbourhoods by affecting quality

of life perception of the environment and public and private behaviours Previous research has

indicated that a higher level of incivilities is associated with health problems (Branas et al 2011

Cohen et al 2000 Hill amp Angel 2005 Ross 2011 Ross amp Mirowsky 2001) greater

victimization and fear of crime (Brunton-Smith Jackson amp Sutherland 2014 Mijanovich amp

Weitzman 2003) and multiple negative economic effects For instance incivilities could be

98

related to a reduction in commercial activity lower investment in real estate reduction in house

prices (Skogan 2015) and population instability (Hipp 2010)

To describe the state of the art in the study of incivilities and their consequences Skogan

(2015) used the concept of untidiness to characterize the research on incivilities The study of

incivilities has had multiple approaches (economic ecological and psychological) Incivilities

have also been measured using multiple sources of information (police reports surveys trained

observation) which result in different measures (perceptions vs count data) However the question

about what specific factors have the strongest effect on incivilities has been overlooked and

perceptions about incivilities have been used mainly as a predictor of crime fear of crime and

victimization

There are two types of incivilities social and physical Social incivilities are a matter of

behaviour including groups of rowdy teens public drunkenness people fighting and street hassles

Physical incivilities involve visual signs of negligence and decay such as abandoned buildings

broken streetlights trash-filled lots and graffiti (Skogan 1999 2015 Taylor 1999) Three reasons

justify the distinction between physical and social incivilities First like multiple dimensions of

social cohesion different structural and social conditions could be responsible for different types

and categories of incivilities Second punitive sanctions are expected to have a greater impact on

physical than on social incivilities since the latter are more related to behaviours rooted in citizensrsquo

culture Third physical incivilities should be more related to absolute measures of economic

disadvantage (eg poverty or unemployment rates) and social incivilities to relative indicators of

economic disadvantage (eg such as income inequality) This line of research is based on the

ldquoincivilities thesisrdquo which states that to understand the distribution of disorders it is necesary to

analyse the patterns of structured inequalities (Skogan 1986 Taylor 1999)

99

423 The ldquoIncivilities Thesisrdquo

Incivilities theories began with a focus on psychological dynamics (Garofalo 1978) moved

forward to an interest in social psychological processes (J Q Wilson amp Kelling 1982) and finally

evolved into a focus on community dynamics and outcomes (Skogan 1999) Individual and group

behaviours in tandem with ecological features have been proposed as the key factors explaining

incivilities and their posterior influence on social control quality of life and more serious crime

(J Q Wilson amp Kelling 1982)

In terms of ecological factors particularly those related to economic conditions Skogan

(1986) was the first linking the distribution of incivilities to the patterns of structural inequality If

incivilities mirror inequality structure this will have consequences in residentsrsquo health and safety

due to its levels of vulnerability In addition structured inequality associated with the proportion

of the manufacturing sector (eg when fabrics tend to move from cities to farther areas) will be

related to higher social disorganization and differences between urban and rural areas (W J

Wilson 1996) In addition a persistent feeling of relative deprivation (persistently high levels of

income inequality) could lead to fellow inhabitants of the community to commit antisocial

behaviours showing their frustration with the current economic model

The literature on incivilities posits that their causes are different from those of crime (Lewis

2017) Unlike crime analysis especially property crimes information on the location where the

incivility takes place is the same as the location where the perpetrator resides To achieve a

comprehensive understanding of the different types of incivilities it is crucial to consider

incivilities data covering an entire territory and not just specific areas (Hooghe Vanhoutte

Hardyns amp Bircan 2010) If we add to this the availability of panel data it could be possible not

100

only to identify the main determinants of incivilities but also the causal mechanism from income

inequality towards incivilities rate

In Chile citizen security crime and delinquency are among the most significant issues for

citizens based on opinion polls Existing research has found weak evidence of a significant

relationship between crime and indicators of socio-economic disadvantage such as income

inequality and unemployment rate with significant effects only on property crime (Beyer amp

Vergara 2006 Nuntildeez Rivera Villavicencio amp Molina 2003 Rivera Gutieacuterrez amp Nuacutentildeez 2009)

Crime deterrence variables such as the probability of being caught or the number of police

resources have also shown ambiguous results (Beyer amp Vergara 2006 Rivera et al 2009

Vergara 2012) Evidence at the county level shows that crime is higher in urban counties those

with a lower mean income per capita and counties located in the North of the country In addition

at least half of the crimes reported in one county are perpetrated by criminals from other counties

(Rivera et al 2009) No studies could be found about the determinants of incivilities

4 3 Methodology

431 Period of analysis and data sample

Chile is a relatively small country in Latin America with a population of 18346018

inhabitants in 2017 The country is divided into 345 municipalities with on average 53104

inhabitants (median value 18705) Municipalities are the organ of the State Administration

responsible to solve local needs Municipalities are not only the relevant political and

administrative local unit of analysis but also they represent the feeling of lsquocommunityrsquo among

the inhabitants of each municipality (Hooghe et al 2010) Our data includes many sources of

101

heterogeneity among municipalities such as indicators of economic deprivation population

density demographic characteristics and whether the county is a regional or provincial capital

We use a sample of 324 municipalities covering most of the Chilean territory for the period

2006ndash17 Data on incivilities is obtained from the ldquoCentre of Studies and Analysis of Crimerdquo

which is part of the ldquoSubsecretaria de Prevencion del Delitordquo (SPD in its Spanish acronym) of the

Chilean government32 Information on income inequality and control variables is obtained from

the ldquoNational Socioeconomic Characterization Surveyrdquo (CASEN in its Spanish acronym) the

ldquoNational Institute of Statisticsrdquo (INE in its Spanish acronym) the ldquoNational Municipal

Information Systemrdquo (SINIM in its Spanish acronym) and the Immigration Department of the

Government of Chile Our panel only includes the years for which CASEN survey is available

2006 2009 2011 2013 2015 and 2017

432 Operationalisation of the response variable and exploratory analysis

Official Chilean records contain information for the total number of cases of incivilities per

year at the county level The number of cases is the sum of complains and detentions reported at

the police Our dependent variable 119894119899119888119894119907119894119897119894119905119894119890119904 correspond to the number of cases per year Due

to population differences comparisons between counties are made using the incivilities rate per

1000 population calculated as

119894119899119888119894119907_119903119886119905119890 lowast 1000 (41)

where 119894119899119888119894119907_119903119886119905119890 is the incivilities rate 119905 is the year 119894 the county and 119899 is the population of the

county per year

32 httpceadspdgovclestadisticas-delictuales

102

Figure 41 illustrates at the top the evolution of the total number (cases reported) of

incivilities and crimes at the country level for the period 2006-1733 At the bottom Figure 41

shows the evolution of the mean county rate per 1000 inhabitants We observe that both the number

of incivilities and the number of crimes has reached similar annual figures however average

county rates per 1000 population show different trends Crime rate displays a sustained fall after

reaching its pick in 2011 Incivilities average county rate which also reached a pick and posterior

drop in 2011 has recovered its upward trend since 2016 considerably exceeding the crime rate

Figure 41 Evolution number and rates of incivilities and crime (DMCS) in Chile 2006-2017

33 Crime refers to ldquocrimes of greater social connotationrdquo (DMCS in its Spanish acronym) which includes violent and property crimes

103

Chilean records classify incivilities in nine categories most of them associated with social

incivilities Summary statistics for the total and for each of the nine categories are presented in

Table 41 In addition Figure 42 shows the evolution of incivilities by category for the whole

period We see that the global trend in incivilities is mainly due to a substantial increase in ldquoStreet

Tradingrdquo and ldquoPublic Alcohol Consumptionrdquo A common element of Figures 41 and 42 is the

significant change in trend experienced by crimes and incivilities in 2011 That year the SPD

became dependent on the Ministry of Interior of the Chilean Government This event put the issue

of crime and delinquency within national priorities for the central government

Table 41

Summary statistics total count of incivilities and by category (full sample and period)

Unlike crime rates we do not expect significant cross-county spillover effects in incivilities

However the questions of where incivilities are concentrated and why they are there can be of

great interest (Skogan 2015) Figure 43 shows quantile maps for the rate of incivilities per 1000

inhabitants for the initial and final years in our panel

104

Figure 42 Evolution total number of incivilities by category

Figure 43 Spatial distribution of incivilities rate per 1000 inhabitants (2006 vs 2017)

105

We observe that the range of values has increased significantly from 2006 to 2017 but the

spatial distribution remains almost unchanged On the one hand high incivilities rates in the North

could be associated with the mining activity On the other hand high rates in the Centre area

(where the countyrsquos capital is located) could be related to the higher population density and the

concentration of the economic activity34

To see how the different types of incivilities are distributed throughout the country we have

grouped those similar categories in four groups ldquoPublic Damagerdquo (ldquoPublic Disturbsrdquo ldquoPublic

Damagerdquo ldquoOtherrdquo) ldquoThreatsrdquo (ldquoPublic Fightrdquo ldquoThreatsrdquo and ldquoAnnoying Noisesrdquo) ldquoAlcohol

Consumptionrdquo (ldquoPublic Alcohol Consumptionrdquo and ldquoDrunkennessrdquo) and ldquoStreet Tradingrdquo This

distinction in groups could be relevant if we expect different patterns and different effects of

community heterogeneity on social cohesion among counties For instance we expect higher

levels of Public Damage in big urban cities Street trading is more likely in urban cities but also in

tourist areas The spatial distribution of these four groups for the six-year-average rate per 1000

inhabitants can be found in Appendix R

433 Measures of community heterogeneity and control variables

Social cohesion income inequality and racial diversity are all ldquocommunityrdquo (not individual)

characteristics Thus to understand their relationship we need aggregated data at least at the

county-municipal level With more disaggregated data like at the suburbs level the required

heterogeneity among groups of citizens is lost (Wilkinson 1999) Like Coffeacute and Geys (2006) we

use the Gini coefficient to capture economic heterogeneity However instead of a measured for

34 We also analysed the spatial distribution of crime rates In general areas with high levels of incivilities not necessarily are associated with high levels of crime This could imply that factors explaining incivilities and crime are different

106

the diversity of nationalities we use the proportion of foreign population to capture racial

heterogeneity Income data is obtained from the CASEN survey The Gini coefficient is calculated

for each county and included through the variable gini Racial heterogeneity is included through

the variable foreign which is the annual number of new VISAS granted to foreigners as a

proportion of the county population Chile has experienced a significant increase in immigration

since 2011 Immigration has been concentrated in the metropolitan region and mining regions in

the North of the country We expect a positive relationship between immigration and incivilities

although as with the relationship between immigration and crime the foundations for this

hypothesis are not strong (Hooghe et al 2010 Sampson 2008)

Economic development is another explanation for social cohesion frequently appealed to

explain trust with wealthier societies considered to exhibit higher levels of trust (Delhey amp

Newton 2005) In this study we include the natural log of the mean household income per capita

log(income) We also include the poverty rate poverty and the unemployment rate

unemployment Unlike the variable log(income) these variables are expected to be positively

associated with the number of incivilities When a relative indicator of economic heterogeneity

such as income inequality is included as determinant of social cohesion we should expect less

effect from absolute indicators of economic disadvantage such as poverty and unemployment rates

(Hooghe et al 2010 Tolsma et al 2009)

Among demographic variables the percentage of inhabitants between 10 and 24 years old is

included through the variable youth The variable women defined as the proportion of the female

population in each county is also included Variable youth is expected to have an ambiguous effect

Although young people have lower victimization and report rates they also represent the group

more likely to commit antisocial behaviours when a community has a low capacity of self-

107

regulation (eg when there is low parental supervision) The female population is associated with

a higher report of incivilities related to the male population

It is argued that crime and incivilities are essentially urban problems (Christiansen 1960

Wirth 1938) We include the variable log(density) defined as the log of population density (the

number of inhabitants divided by the area of each county in square kilometres) and a dummy

variable capital indicating whether a county is an administrative capital (provincial or regional)

Two additional variables are included to capture the level of informal social control exerted

by families living in each municipality First the variable education which is defined as the

average years of education of people over 15 years old Second the variable housing which capture

the proportion of families which are owners of their housing unit Although education and housing

are related to both the possibility of reporting and committing an incivility we expect a negative

association with the rate of incivilities

In Chile crime has been mainly a problem faced by the police and the Central Government

Administration To control for current law enforcement policies we include the variable

deterrence defined as the number of arrests as a proportion of the total number of incivilities cases

In addition municipalities can develop their own initiatives to deal with crime and incivilities

depending on their capacity to generate its own resources The level of financial autonomy from

central transfers is captured by the variable autonomy This variable is obtained from SINIM and

it is defined as the proportion of the budget revenue of each municipality that comes from its own

permanent sources of revenues A categorical variable mayor is also included This variable

indicates whether the municipality mayor is supported by the ldquoLEFTrdquo or the ldquoRIGHTrdquo political

parties (related to those ldquoINDEPENDENTrdquo mayors)

108

Table 42 presents descriptive statistics for our measures of income and racial heterogeneity

and the set of numeric control variables The Pearson correlation among these variables is shown

in Appendix S

Table 42

Summary statistics numeric explanatory variables

434 Methods

The annual count of incivilities as is characteristic for count data is highly concentrated in

a relatively small range of values In addition the distribution is right-skewed due to the presence

of important outliers (counties with a high number of incivilities) Figure 44 shows the

distribution of the six-year average number of incivilities for each of the 15 regions in Chile35 We

observe that regions differ in the number of counties in which they are divided In addition

counties within each region show important differences in the number of incivilities For instance

35 Regions are ordered from left to right and from top to bottom in the way they are geographically distributed from North to South So the northernmost region of the country is the ldquoXVrdquo and the southernmost region is the ldquoXIIrdquo The Metropolitan region (where the countryrsquos capital is located) is region ldquoXIIIrdquo in the centre of the country (see Appendix C)

109

excepting the Metropolitan region ldquoXIIIrdquo most counties in regions located in the centre of the

country (middle row in Figure 44) show a range of incivilities between 0 and 2000 The number

of incivilities is considerably lower in counties located in the northern (top row in Figure 44) and

southern (bottom row in Figure 44) regions of the country compared to regions in the centre of

the country It also seems clear from Figure 44 that the number of incivilities does not follow a

normal distribution

Figure 44 Annual average number of incivilities per county

The number of incivilities can be better described by a Poisson distribution In this case the

number of incivilities is ldquothe countrdquo and the number of incivilities per year is ldquothe rate per unit

timerdquo We are interested in modelling the average number of incivilities per year usually called 120582

as a function of a set of contextual factors to explain differences in incivilities between and within

110

counties The main characteristic of the Poisson distribution is that the mean is equal to the

variance This implies that as the mean rate for a Poisson variable increases the variance also

increases The main implication is we cannot use OLS to model 120582 as a function of the set of

contextual factors because the equal variance assumption in linear regression is violated

The rate of incivilities between counties is not directly comparable due to population

differences We expect counties with more people to have more reports of incivilities since there

are more people who could be affected To capture differences in population which is called the

exposure of our response variable 120582 it is necessary to include a term on the right side of our model

called an offset We will use the log of the county population in thousands as our offset36

Additionally similar to the case of crime data incivilities show a significant degree of

overdispersion (variance higher than the mean) suggesting that there is more variation in the

response than the Poisson model implies37 We also model and regress incivilities assuming a

Negative Binomial distribution to address overdispersion An advantage of this approach is that it

introduces a dispersion parameter in addition to 120582 which gives the model more flexibility38

Considering as the response variable the count of incivilities per year the model can be

expressed as follow

120582 119890119909119901 120573 120573 119892119894119899119894 120573 119891119900119903119890119894119892119899 119883120574 120572 120579 (42)

36 If we think of 120582 as the average number of incivilities per year then represents the number per 1000

inhabitants so that the yearly count is adjusted to be comparable across counties of different sizes Adjusting the yearly count by population is equivalent to adding 119897119900119892 1199011199001199011199061198971198861199051198941199001198991000 to the right-hand side of the regression equation 37 Without adjusting for overdispersion we use incorrect artificially small standard errors leading to artificially small p-values for model coefficients 38 The Negative Binomial model posits selecting a 120582 (average number of incivilities) for each county and then generating a count using a Poisson random variable with the selected 120582 With this approach the counts will be more dispersed than would be expected for observations based on a single Poisson variable with rate 120582

111

where 120582 is the rate of incivilities 119883 is our vector of controls 120572prime119904 are county-specific constants

and 120579prime119904 are time-specific constants Accounting for differences in county population we have

119890119909119901 120573 120573 119892119894119899119894 119883120574 120572 120579 (43)

where 119901119900119901119906119897119886119905119894119900119899 is the county population per year Hence the model to be estimated using

Maximum Likelihood Estimation (MLE) is

119897119900119892 120582 120573 120573 119892119894119899119894 119883120574 120572 120579 119897119900119892 (44)

Finally to account for different effects depending on the type of incivilities we also run

equation (44) for each of the four groups of incivilities defined in section (432)

435 Hypotheses

Based on the community heterogeneity hypothesis the relationship between social cohesion

and diversity should be stronger for lower levels of income and less educated groups of people

(Tolsma et al 2009) Hence contrary to evidence for developed and more equal countries we

expect a significant positive association for the Chilean case where more than 50 of the

population is economically vulnerable (OECD 2017)

The main hypotheses to be tested in this essay is whether the number of incivilities is

positively associated with the level of economic and racial heterogeneity at the county level We

start analysing this association for the full sample and period Next we analyse whether the

relationship between incivilities and our measures of diversity differs by geographic area (region

or zone) Finally we check whether the effect of economic and racial diversity is different

depending on the group of incivilities

112

44 Results and Discussion

Overall our results show that the rate of incivilities displays a stronger and more significant

relationship with racial diversity than with economic heterogeneity This association differs for

different geographic areas and for different types of incivilities Absolute economic indicators

except for income show a significant but small effect Increases in the average levels of income

or education and more financial autonomy for municipalities seem to be effective ways to reduce

the rate of incivilities

We estimate equation (44) assuming that the number of incivilities follows a Poisson

distribution Regional and temporal heterogeneity are captured through the inclusion of dummy

variables for five years (with 2006 as the reference year) and fourteen regional dummies (with

region XIII as the reference region) Results are reported in Table 4339 This table is structured in

two blocks of regressions pooled models in columns (1)-(4) and fixed-effects models in columns

(5)-(8)40 The first column in each block only includes economic indicators relative and absolute

trying to test which ones are more relevant and whether incivilities tend to mirror income

inequality (the ldquoincivilities thesisrdquo) The second column adds the variable foreign to account for

the effect of racial diversity (Letki 2008) The third column includes education to check whether

the association between economic and racial diversity with social cohesion changes (gets less

significant) when we control for educational level (Tolsma et al 2009) The final column in each

block corresponds to the full model specification which includes the rest of controls

39 Pooled estimations were obtained using the R command glm() and compared with results obtained from the command poisson in STATA 15 Fixed effects and random effects models were estimated using the STATA command xtpoisson Negative Binomial models were estimated using the command glmnb() in the MASS package for R and commands nbreg and xtnbreg in STATA 15 Results for Negative Binomial regressions are in Appendix T 40 We have omitted results with random effects due to the literature on panel count data models suggest that the most robust estimator is Poisson regression with Fixed Effects (Santos Silva amp Tenreyro 2010 2011)

113

Table 43

Poisson regressions

114

The positive and significant coefficient for the variable gini besides being small it becomes

insignificant in the fixed effects specification which includes the full set of controls This result

does not seem to be enough evidence to support our hypothesis that more unequal counties display

higher rates of incivilities On the other hand racial diversity through the variable foreign shows

a consistent positive association with the rate of incivilities41 Together coefficients for gini and

foreign seems to support the ldquocommunity heterogeneity thesisrdquo (Letki 2008) but not the

ldquoincivilities thesisrdquo (Skogan 1999) To check this finding we run the pooled full model

specification for each region and results are shown in Table 44 where regions have been ordered

from North to South The sign of the coefficient of the variable gini differs for different regions

Moreover the relationship is insignificant in some of the most unequal regions which are in the

South of the country (VIII IX and XIV) This result rejects the hypothesis that incivilities mirror

structural income inequalities For the variable foreign 12 out of 15 regions confirm the positive

association with the rate of incivilities42

We also run our pooled full model separately for each group of incivilities defined at the end

of section (432) Income inequality keeps its significant but small association with each group of

incivilities (see Table 45) Our measure of racial diversity shows a stronger association with

ldquoAlcohol Consumptionrdquo related to ldquoPublic Damagerdquo and ldquoThreatsrdquo The link with ldquoStreet Tradingrdquo

appears as non-significant These results support our general finding that on the one hand racial

heterogeneity exert a more significant influence on the rate of incivilities than economic

41 To get the effects of the variables gini and foreign over the rate of incivilities per 1000 inhabitants we need to exponentiate their coefficients Thus an increase in one unit in the variable gini increases the rate of incivilities per 1000 inhabitantsrdquo in 1005 times (e^0005) in the pooled full model Similarly an increase in one point in variable foreign is expected to increase the ldquorate of incivilities per 1000 inhabitantsrdquo in 10876 times (e^0084) in the full pooled model and 10471 (e^0046) times in the full Fixed Effects model 42 Given that depending on the geographic location regions share certain characteristics the model was also run clustering regions in 4 zones (see Figure 31 in chapter 3) Results by zone are in Appendix U

115

heterogeneity On the other hand results confirm our hypothesis that the effect of diversity is

different for different types of incivilities

Table 44 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson models by region

Back to our general results in Table 43 the significant and negative coefficient of the

income variable and to a lesser extent the significant and positive coefficients of poverty and

unemployment provide evidence that absolute rather than relative economic indicators may be

more important explanations of the rate of incivilities This is opposite to evidence for the analysis

116

of crime rates such as in Hoodge (2010) and support the idea that determinants of incivilities are

different from those of crime Our results are also opposite to those for Dutch municipalities where

economic indicators turned out to be more important than ethnic heterogeneity (Tolsma et al

2009) The coefficient for the variable log(income) could be interpreted as counties with an income

level under the average face higher problems of antisocial behaviours such as incivilities In

addition as the income level moves far away from its average low level the problem of incivilities

is less relevant43 In terms of policy implications only those policies that achieve a significant

increase in the average level of county income seem to be effective in reducing incivilities and

strengthening social cohesion

Table 45 Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson model by incivility group

43 We ran our model splitting the sample of counties in quintiles based on their income level The coefficient for the variable gini only showed a significant (and positive) coefficient for the second third and fourth quintile A non-significant coefficient for the first quintile could imply that other types of inequalities (eg health education) are more relevant in the poorest counties In the case of the fifth quintile (the richest group of counties) they have better facilities in terms of infrastructure police resources self-protection etc which could reduce the potential triggers of incivilities

117

The inclusion of the variable education significantly improved the goodness of fit of the

models and did not generate significant changes in the coefficients of our measures of economic

and racial diversity This result rejects the proposition that the relationship between social

cohesion and diversity becomes less strong when controlled by education (Tolsma et al 2009)

Additionally it highlights the topic of education as a relevant determinant of the rate of incivilities

and social cohesion

Among control variables there are also some important results Opposite to what we

expected the variable youth shows a negative or non-significant coefficient Although this result

could be due to the lack of ldquophysical incivilitiesrdquo in Chilean records it indicates that it is incorrect

to stereotype this group as the main responsible for high incivilities rates The significant and

negative coefficient of the variable autonomy in the fixed effects specification could also have

important policy implications It is a signal that local governments can play an important role in

reducing incivilities or complementing the efforts from the central government Another

interesting result is the significant coefficient of the variable housing The latter finding is

particularly important in the sense that a negative sign supports public policies oriented to increase

homeownership as effective ways to improve social cohesion However the small magnitude of

the coefficient that even showed the opposite sign in some model specifications could be

explained for the high level of segregation that these policies have generated in Chilean society

As mentioned in the Introduction and Literature Review so far only a few studies have

used measures of disorders or incivilities as dependent variable to explain changes in social

cohesion (Skogan 2015) In addition there is no evidence in Chile analysing the determinants of

incivilities separately from those of crimes The importance of our results on identifying the

importance of economic and racial diversity on social cohesion lies mainly in its generality An

118

important number of countries all around the world share a similar context characterized by high

levels of inequality and an explosive increase in immigration These countries are also

experiencing a worsening in social cohesion which increases the risk of a social outburst

4 5 Conclusions

The main goal of this essay was to determine whether differences in incivilities at the county

level mirror differences in income distribution and racial diversity Previous literature suggests a

positive and strong association between social cohesion and indicators of economic disadvantage

relative deprivation and racial diversity (Letki 2008 Tolsma et al 2009 Uslaner amp Brown 2005)

While not all our results were significant they showed helpful insights about how and where

economic and racial diversity are more likely to influence the rate of incivilities and social

cohesion

We used data for the period 2006ndash17 economic heterogeneity was measured through the

Gini coefficient at the county level and racial heterogeneity was proxied by the number of granted

visas to foreigners as proportion of county population We found strong evidence of a significant

and positive association between the rate of incivilities and racial diversity but not with income

inequality Contrary to previous evidence at the municipal level (Coffeacute amp Geys 2006 Tolsma et

al 2009) in general our results give support for the ldquohomophily principlerdquo and the ldquocommunity

heterogeneity hypothesisrdquo However results also showed that the effect of economic and racial

diversity varies throughout the Chilean regions and for the different types of incivilities

We also found that policies aimed at controlling the behaviour of young people did not have

strong empirical support In terms of the role that local governments may have in facing the

119

growing problem of incivilities we found evidence that efforts managed from the municipalities

can be an important complement to those from the central government

Future research should go further on the role of local authorities on incivilities and social

cohesion On the one hand municipalities could have a direct impact on social cohesion through

the implementation of programs complementary to those of central authorities oriented to reduce

incivilities and crime On the other hand social cohesion could be indirectly affected when local

authorities display an inefficient performance supplying public services to citizens or they are

recognized as corrupted institutions We suggest that policy makers from central government

should give local authorities a greater role in fighting antisocial behaviours and crime Evaluating

programs in specific municipalities could help to elucidate the causal effect of for instance higher

fiscal autonomy on the rate of incivilities

Another interesting area for future work will be to analyse how housing policies have

contributed to the phenomenon of segregation of Chilean society and in the process of weakening

social cohesion Finally our main result highlights the need of a deeper analysis of the impact that

foreign immigration is having in Chile For instance disaggregating information by country of

origin and the reasons why immigrants are arriving to the country or specific regions will surely

help to understand the impacts of immigration

120

Chapter 5 Conclusions

This thesis investigated in three essays the issue of income inequality in Chile using county-

level data for the period 2006-2017 The first essay supplied empirical evidence about the

importance of the degree of dependence on natural resources in terms of employment in explaining

cross-county differences in income inequality The second essay analysed the potential causal

effect that income inequality has on the level of technical efficiency of local governments

providing public goods and services Lastly the third essay studied the relationship between social

cohesion measured through the number of antisocial behaviours classified as ldquoincivilitiesrdquo and

the levels of income and racial heterogeneity

Findings from the first essay support the idea that the endowment of natural resources plays

a significant role in explaining income inequality in Chile However contrary to what most

theoretical and empirical evidence postulates our findings showed a robust negative association

between the two variables This means that the reduction experienced in Chile in the degree of

dependence on natural resources in terms of employment has contributed to the persistence of high

levels of income inequality The exploratory analysis indicated that income inequality shows a

general clustering process characterized by a significant and positive spatial autocorrelation

Regarding the previous evidence for Chile (Paredes et al 2016) the regression analysis confirmed

the relevance of the spatial dimension of income inequality through a process of spatial

heterogeneity giving less support to the existence of a process of spatial dependence (spillover

effect) in the variable itself

121

Essay 2 studied the potential trade-off between efficiency and equity analysing the influence

of income inequality on the efficiency of local governments at the municipal level To identify the

causal effect of income inequality on municipal efficiency we proposed the use of the proportion

of firms in the primary sector as an instrument for income inequality Findings confirmed our

hypothesis that efficiency is lower in more unequal counties This result suggests the non-existence

of the trade-off between equity and efficiency Hence policies intended to reduce inequality could

help to increase efficiency at least at the level of municipal local governments

The third essay analysed how social cohesion proxied by the rate of incivilities is associated

with the levels of economic diversity proxied by income inequality and the levels of racial

diversity proxied by the number of new visas grated as proportion of the county population

Findings gave strong support to the hypothesis that the rate of incivilities is positively related to

racial diversity and to a lesser extent to economic diversity In addition the rate of incivilities

appears negatively related to the degree of financial autonomy of municipalities This means that

local governments can effectively contribute to the reduction of incivilities which could help

reduce victimization and crime rates ultimately strengthening social cohesion

Taken together findings from essays 2 and 3 highlight the important role that income

inequality could play in other relevant economic and social dimensions These findings add to the

understanding of the potential consequences of income inequality particularly in natural resource

rich countries with persistently high levels of inequality

The present study has mainly investigated income inequality at the county level In addition

Chilean municipalities play an important role providing ldquoservices to peoplerdquo so our findings could

be applied in other highly unequal countries with a high degree of dependence on natural resources

and local governments with similar responsibilities For instance in Latin America apart from

122

Chile and Brazil there are no studies on the efficiency of local governments Other limitations are

associated with the availability of information For instance important indicators such as GDP per

capita are only available at the regional level and information of incomes is not available annually

In addition given the heterogeneity among municipalities some type of grouping of municipalities

should be performed before looking for causal relationships or conducting program evaluation

Despite these limitations we believe this study could be the basis for different strands of future

research on the topic of inequality local government efficiency and social cohesion

It was stated in chapter 2 based on the resource curse hypothesis literature there are two

elements that determine whether NR are a curse or blessing in terms of socioeconomic outcomes

First the curse is more likely in countries with weak political and governance institutions Second

different types of resources affect institutions differently with resources that are concentrated in

space so-called ldquopointrdquo resources tend to impair institutions while ldquodiffuserdquo resources do not

(Deacon 2011 Isham Woolcock Pritchett amp Busby 2005) Our results showed a negative

relationship between income inequality and our measure of natural resource dependence even after

controlling for zone fixed effects and for the level of government expenditure This result could

be interpreted as a signal that NR has a direct effect on income inequality in addition to the indirect

impact through market or institutional channels Using other potential institutional transmission

channels will shed light about the true effect that the endowment of natural resources has over

income inequality Variables that could capture these institutional channels include the level of

employment in the public sector measures of rule of law and corruption and changes in the

creation of new business in the secondary and tertiary sectors related to the primary sector

Based on results from chapter 3 most of the municipalities show scale inefficiencies One

immediate area for future work will involve using our set of contextual factors to predict the status

123

of municipalities in terms of scale inefficiencies Defining as dependent variable whether a

municipality shows constant decreasing or increasing returns to scale we could run a multinomial

logistic regression to predict municipal status For instance we would expect that a one-unit

increase in the Gini coefficient should increase the probability of scale inefficiencies (increasing

or decreasing returns to scale rather than constant returns to scale) Because the aim in this case

would be predicting a certain result in terms of returns to scale the next step should involve to

split the full sample in training and testing data sets and to use some resampling methods such as

bootstrapping This will allow us to evaluate the performance and accuracy of our model

predictions using different random samples of municipalities Results from Machine Learning

algorithms will help us to assess the generalizability of our results to other data sets

Future work should also benefit greatly by using data on different Latin American countries

to (1) compare the responsibilities of local governments (2) select a common set of inputs and

output to evaluate LGE (3) identify the relevance of scales inefficiencies in explaining differences

in performance and (4) analyse the influence of contextual characteristics over LGE Differences

in the main primary sector activity in each country such as oil in Brazil mining in Chile or Coffee

in Colombia could be responsible for differences in LGE among countries These differences could

be associated with sources of revenue management of expenditure and definitions of outputs or

contextual effects such as corrupted institutions or the delay in the development of other sectors

such as manufacturing or services

To delve deep on reasons explaining the social crisis experienced by Chilean society and

other countries one area of future work will be to analyse the relationship between diversity and

the origins of social revolutions Based on Tiruneh (2014) the three most important factors that

explain the onset of social revolutions are economic development regime type and state

124

ineffectiveness Interesting questions include whether the characteristics of Chilean context at the

end of 2019 are enough to trigger the transformation of the political and socioeconomic system

Social revolutions particularly violent revolutions are less likely in more democratic educated

and wealthy societies So it would be relevant to identify the factors explaining the violence that

has characterized the social crisis in Chile Finally the democratic regime has been maintained in

the last decades with changes between left and right governments This could imply that more

important than the regime has been the efficiency or ineffectiveness of the governments to satisfy

the needs of the population

Future work should also cover the disaggregation of information regarding foreign

population in terms of the reasons for new granted visas and the country of origin Official data

allows us to disaggregate whether the benefit is permanent (students and employees with contract)

or temporary Furthermore most of the new visas were traditionally granted to neighbouring

countries (Peru and Bolivia) a trend that has changed in the recent years to include countries such

as Colombia Venezuela and Haiti An analysis of how economic and social indicators have been

affected by changes in the composition of foreigners their reasons for immigrating to the country

and their geographical distribution have implications for economic policy at both the national and

local levels At the national level such analysis should be a key input when proposing changes to

the national immigration policy At the local level it could help define the role of municipalities

to assess the benefits and challenges of immigration These challenges are mainly related to the

provision of public goods and services such as health and education which in Chile are the

responsibility of the municipalities

The findings of this thesis suggest that policymakers should encourage policies that reduce

income inequality The key role that municipalities could play to strengthen social cohesion and

125

the increasingly important role that foreign population is acquiring in most modern societies are

also interesting avenues for future research However the picture is still incomplete and more

research is needed incorporating other dimensions of inequality This is essential if we want to

understand the reasons that could have triggered the social outbursts experienced by various

economies across the globe

126

Bibliography

Acemoglu D (1995) Reward structures and the allocation of talent European Economic Review 39(1) 17ndash33 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg1010160014-2921(94)00014-Q

Acemoglu D (2002) Technical Change Inequality and the Labor Market Journal of Economic Literature 40(1) 7ndash72 httpsdoiorg1012570022051026976

Acemoglu D Aghion P amp Violante G L (2001) Deunionization Technical Change and Inequality Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 55(1) 229ndash264 httpsdoiorg101016S0167-2231(01)00058-6

Acemoglu D Johnson S amp Robinson J A (2001) The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development An Empirical Investigation The American Economic Review 91(5) 1369ndash1401 httpsdoiorg101257aer9151369

Acemoglu D amp Robinson J A (2002) The Political Economy of the Kuznets Curve Review of Development Economics 6(2) 183ndash203 httpsdoiorg1011111467-936100149

Afonso A amp Fernandes S (2006) Measuring local government spending efficiency Evidence for the Lisbon region Regional Studies 40(1) 39ndash53 httpsdoiorg10108000343400500449937

Afonso A amp Fernandes S (2008) Assessing and explaining the relative efficiency of local government The Journal of Socio-Economics 37(5) 1946ndash1979 httpsdoiorg101016jsocec200703007

Afonso A Schuknecht L amp Tanzi V (2010) Income distribution determinants and public spending efficiency Journal of Economic Inequality 8(3) 367ndash389 httpsdoiorg101007s10888-010-9138-z

Akita T (2003) Decomposing regional income inequality in China and Indonesia using two-stage nested Theil decomposition method The Annals of Regional Science 37(1) 55ndash77 httpsdoiorg101007s001680200107

Alesina A (2000) Participation in heterogeneous communities The Quarterly Journal of Economics 115(3) 847ndash904 httpsdoiorg101162003355300554935

Alesina A amp La Ferrara E (2002) Who trusts others Journal of Public Economics 85(2) 207ndash234 httpsdoiorg101016S0047-2727(01)00084-6

Allcott H amp Keniston D (2014) Dutch Disease or Agglomeration The Local Economic Effects of Natural Resource Booms in Modern America (N W P N 20508 Ed) NBER Working Paper No 20508 (Vol w20508) NBER Working Paper No 20508 NBER Working Paper No 20508 httpsdoiorgNBER Working Paper No 20508

Andersen T M amp Maibom J (2020) The big trade-off between efficiency and equitymdashis it there Oxford Economic Papers 72(2) 391ndash411

127

Anselin L (1988) Spatial econometrics methods and models (Vol 4) DordrechtBoston Kluwer Academic Publishers

Anselin L amp Bera A K (1998) Spatial dependence in linear regression models with an introduction to spatial econometrics Statistics Textbooks and Monographs (Vol 155)

Anselin L Bera A K Florax R amp Yoon M J (1996) Simple diagnostic tests for spatial dependence Regional Science and Urban Economics 26(1) 77ndash104 httpsdoiorg1010160166-0462(95)02111-6

Antonelli M A amp De Bonis V (2018) The efficiency of social public expenditure in European countries a two-stage analysis Applied Economics 1ndash14 httpsdoiorg1010800003684620181489522

Aragoacuten F M amp Rud J P (2013) Natural Resources and Local Communities Evidence from a Peruvian Gold Mine American Economic Journal Economic Policy 5(2) 1ndash25 httpsdoiorg101257pol521

Ariely G (2014) Does Diversity Erode Social Cohesion Conceptual and Methodological Issues Political Studies 62(3) 573ndash595 httpsdoiorg1011111467-924812068

Armstrong H amp Taylor J (2000) Regional economics and policy (3rd ed) Oxford Blackwell

Aroca P amp Atienza M (2011) Economic implications of long distance commuting in the Chilean mining industry Resources Policy 36(3) 196ndash203 httpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201103004

Aroca P amp Bosch M (2000) Crecimiento convergencia y espacio en las regiones chilenas 1960 - 1998 Estudios de Economiacutea 27 199ndash224 Retrieved from httprepositoriouchileclbitstreamhandle2250127853Patricio_Arocapdfsequence=1

Ashworth J Geys B Heyndels B amp Wille F (2014) Competition in the political arena and local government performance Applied Economics 46(19) 2264ndash2276 httpsdoiorg101080000368462014899679

Atkinson A B (2015) Inequality What Can Be Done Harvard University Press

Auty R (1993) Sustaining development in mineral economies the resource curse thesis London [ua] Routledge

Auty R (2001) Resource abundance and economic development (R World Institute for Development Economics Ed) Oxford Oxford University Press

Badeeb R A Lean H H amp Clark J (2017) The evolution of the natural resource curse thesis A critical literature survey Resources Policy 51 123ndash134 httpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201610015

Balaguer-Coll M T Brun-Martos M I Maacuterquez-Ramos L amp Prior D (2019) Local government efficiency determinants and spatial interdependence Applied Economics

128

51(14) 1478ndash1494 httpsdoiorg1010800003684620181527458

Balaguer-Coll M T amp Prior D (2009) Short- and long-term evaluation of efficiency and quality An application to Spanish municipalities Applied Economics 41(23) 2991ndash3002 httpsdoiorg10108000036840701351923

Banker R D Charnes A amp Cooper W W (1984) Some models for estimating technical and scale inefficiencies in data envelopment analysis Management Science 30(9) 1078ndash1092

Beine M Coulombe S amp Vermeulen W N (2015) Dutch Disease and the Mitigation Effect of Migration Evidence from Canadian Provinces The Economic Journal 125(589) 1574ndash1615 httpsdoiorg101111ecoj12171

Benito B Bastida F amp Garciacutea J A (2010) Explaining differences in efficiency an application to Spanish municipalities Applied Economics 42(4) 515ndash528 httpsdoiorg10108000036840701675560

Berg A amp Ostry J (2011) Equality and efficiency Finance amp Development 48(3) 12ndash15

Berg A amp Ostry J (2017) Inequality and Unsustainable Growth Two Sides of the Same Coin IMF ECONOMIC REVIEW 65(4) 792ndash815 httpsdoiorg101057s41308-017-0030-8

Beyer H amp Vergara R (2006) Delincuencia en Chile Determinantes y rol de las poliacuteticas puacuteblicas Instituto de Economiacutea UC

Blanco L amp Grier R (2012) Natural resource dependence and the accumulation of physical and human capital in Latin America Resources Policy 37(3) 281ndash295 httpsdoiorghttpdoiorg101016jresourpol201201005

Blau J R amp Blau P M (1982) The cost of inequality Metropolitan structure and violent crime American Sociological Review 114ndash129

Boetti L Piacenza M amp Turati G (2009) Fiscal decentralization and spending efficiency of local governments An Empirical Investigation on a Sample Of 4

Boix C amp Posner D (1998) Social capital Explaining its origins and effects on government performance British Journal Of Political Science 28 686ndash693

Borge L E Parmer P amp Torvik R (2015) Local natural resource curse JOURNAL OF PUBLIC ECONOMICS 131 101ndash114 httpsdoiorg101016jjpubeco201509002

Borger B Kerstens K Moesen W amp Vanneste J (1994) Explaining differences in productive efficiency An application to Belgian municipalities Public Choice 80(3) 339ndash358 httpsdoiorg101007BF01053225

Bourguignon F amp Morrisson C (1990) Income distribution development and foreign trade A cross-sectional analysislowast European Economic Review 34(6) 1113ndash1132 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg1010160014-2921(90)90071-6

129

Branas C C Cheney R A MacDonald J M Tam V W Jackson T D amp Ten Have T R (2011) A difference-in-differences analysis of health safety and greening vacant urban space American Journal of Epidemiology 174(11) 1296ndash1306

Bravo J (2014) Fondo Comuacuten Municipal y su desincentivo a la recaudacioacuten en Chile Temas de La Agenda Legislativa-Centro de Poliacuteticas Puacuteblicas UC 9(68)

Browning E K amp Johnson W R (1984) The Trade-Off between Equality and Efficiency Journal of Political Economy 92(2) 175ndash203 httpsdoiorg101086261219

Brunnschweiler C N amp Bulte E H (2008) The resource curse revisited and revised A tale of paradoxes and red herrings Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 55(3) 248ndash264 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jjeem200708004

Brunori P Ferreira F H G amp Peragine V (2013) Inequality of opportunity income inequality and economic mobility Some international comparisons In Getting Development Right (pp 85ndash115) Springer

Brunton-Smith I Jackson J amp Sutherland A (2014) Bridging structure and perception On the neighbourhood ecology of beliefs and worries about violent crime British Journal of Criminology 54(4) 503ndash526

Bulte E H Damania R amp Deacon R T (2005) Resource intensity institutions and development World Development 33(7) 1029ndash1044 httpsdoiorg101016jworlddev200504004

Carmignani F (2013) Development outcomes resource abundance and the transmission through inequality Resource and Energy Economics 35(3) 412ndash428 httpsdoiorg101016jreseneeco201304007

Carmignani Fabrizio amp Avom D (2010) The social development effects of primary commodity export dependence Ecological Economics 70(2) 317ndash330 httpsdoiorg101016jecolecon201009003

Caselli F amp Michaels G (2013) Do Oil Windfalls Improve Living Standards Evidence from Brazil American Economic Journal Applied Economics 5(1) 208ndash238 httpsdoiorg101257app51208

Celebioglu F amp Dallrsquoerba S (2010) Spatial disparities across the regions of Turkey An exploratory spatial data analysis Annals of Regional Science 45(2) 379ndash400 httpsdoiorg101007s00168-009-0313-8

Chan J To H-P amp Chan E (2006) Reconsidering social cohesion Developing a definition and analytical framework for empirical research Social Indicators Research 75(2) 273ndash302

Charnes A Cooper W W amp Rhodes E (1978) Measuring the efficiency of decision making units European Journal of Operational Research 2(6) 429ndash444

130

Chi G amp Zhu J (2019) Spatial Regression Models for the Social Sciences SAGE Publications Retrieved from httpsbooksgooglecomaubooksid=zHGkvwEACAAJ

Christiansen K O (1960) Industrialization and urbanization in relation to crime and juvenile delinquency International Review of Criminal Policy 16 3ndash8

Cingano F (2014) Trends in income inequality and its impact on economic growth (Vol 163) Paris OECD Publishing httpsdoiorg1017875jxrjncwxv6j-en

Coelli T J Prasada Rao D S OrsquoDonnell C J amp Battese G E (2005) An introduction to efficiency and productivity analysis An Introduction to Efficiency and Productivity Analysis Springer Science amp Business Media httpsdoiorg101007b136381

Coffeacute H amp Geys B (2005) Institutional Performance and Social Capital An Application to the Local Government Level Journal of Urban Affairs 27(5) 485ndash501 httpsdoiorg101111j0735-2166200500249x

Coffeacute H amp Geys B (2006) Community Heterogeneity A Burden for the Creation of Social Capital Social Science Quarterly 87(5) 1053ndash1072 httpsdoiorg101111j1540-6237200600415x

Cohen D Spear S Scribner R Kissinger P Mason K amp Wildgen J (2000) ldquo Broken windowsrdquo and the risk of gonorrhea American Journal of Public Health 90(2) 230

Corden W M amp Neary J P (1982) Booming sector and de-industrialisation in a small open economy The Economic Journal 92(368) 825ndash848

Cordero J M Pedraja-Chaparro F Pisaflores E C amp Polo C (2017) Efficiency assessment of Portuguese municipalities using a conditional nonparametric approach Journal of Productivity Analysis 48(1) 1ndash24 httpsdoiorg101007s11123-017-0500-z

Croissant Y amp Millo G (2018) Panel Data Econometrics with R John Wiley amp Sons

Cust J amp Poelhekke S (2015) The Local Economic Impacts of Natural Resource Extraction 7 251ndash268 httpsdoiorg101146annurev-resource-100814-125106

da Cruz N F amp Marques R C (2014) Revisiting the determinants of local government performance Omega 44 91ndash103 httpsdoiorg101016JOMEGA201309002

Dauvin M amp Guerreiro D (2017) The Paradox of Plenty A Meta-Analysis World Development 94 httpsdoiorg101016jworlddev201701009

de Sousa M da C S Cribari-Neto F amp Stosic B D (2005) Explaining DEA technical efficiency scores in an outlier corrected environment the case of public services in Brazilian municipalities Brazilian Review of Econometrics 25(2) 287ndash313

Deacon R T (2011) The Political Economy of the Natural Resource Curse A Survey of Theory and Evidence Foundations and Trends in Microeconomics 111-208

Delhey J amp Newton K (2005) Predicting cross-national levels of social trust global pattern or

131

Nordic exceptionalism European Sociological Review 21(4) 311ndash327

Dlouhyacute M (2018) Measuring Geographic Inequalities Dealing with Multiple Health Resources by Data Envelopment Analysis Frontiers in Public Health 6 53 httpsdoiorg103389fpubh201800053

Dollery B Wallis J amp Akimov A (2010) One Size Does Not Fit All The Special Case of Remote Small Local Councils in Outback Queensland Local Government Studies 36(1) 21ndash42 httpsdoiorg10108003003930903435716

Domenech J (2008) Mineral resource abundance and regional growth in Spain 1860ndash2000 Journal of International Development The Journal of the Development Studies Association 20(8) 1122ndash1135

Doran J amp Jordan D (2016) Decomposing US regional income inequality from 1969 to 2009 Applied Economics Letters 23(11) 781ndash784 httpsdoiorg1010801350485120151109030

Drew J amp Dollery B (2015) The State of Things The Dynamic Efficiency of Australian State and Territories Economic Papers A Journal of Applied Economics and Policy 34(3) 165ndash176

Drew J Kortt M amp Dollery B (2015) What Determines Efficiency in Local Government A DEA Analysis of NSW Local Government Economic Papers A Journal of Applied Economics and Policy 34(4) 243ndash256 httpsdoiorg1011111759-344112118

Easterly W (2007) Inequality does cause underdevelopment Insights from a new instrument Journal of Development Economics 84(2) 755ndash776 httpsdoiorghttpdxdoiorg101016jjdeveco200611002

Ebert L amp La Menza T (2015) Chile copper and resource revenue A holistic approach to assessing commodity dependence Resources Policy 43(Supplement C) 101ndash111 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201410007

ElGindi T (2017) Natural resource dependency neoliberal globalization and income inequality Are they related A longitudinal study of developing countries (1980ndash2010) Current Sociology 65(1) 21ndash53 httpsdoiorg1011770011392116632031

Engerman S L amp Sokoloff K L (1994) Factor Endowments Institutions and Differential Paths of Growth Among New World Economies National Bureau of Economic Research

Engerman S L amp Sokoloff K L (1997) Factor endowments institutions and differential paths of growth among new world economies How Latin America Fell Behind 260ndash304

Engerman S L Sokoloff K L Urquiola M amp Acemoglu D (2002) Factor Endowments Inequality and Paths of Development among New World Economies [with Comments] EconomampxedA 3(1) 41ndash109 Retrieved from httpwwwjstororgezp01libraryquteduaustable20065432

132

Faumlre R Grosskopf S amp Lovell C A K (1985) The measurement of efficiency of production (Vol 6) Springer Science amp Business Media

Fleming D A amp Measham T G (2015a) Income Inequality across Australian Regions during the Mining Boom 2001-11 Australian Geographer 46(2) 203ndash216 httpsdoiorg1010800004918220151020596

Fleming D A amp Measham T G (2015b) Local economic impacts of an unconventional energy boom the coal seam gas industry in Australia Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 59(1) 78ndash94 httpsdoiorg1011111467-848912043

Fum R M amp Hodler R (2010) Natural resources and income inequality The role of ethnic divisions Economics Letters 107(3) 360ndash363 httpsdoiorg101016jeconlet201003008

Garofalo J (1978) The fear of crime Broadening our perspective

Geys B amp Moesen W (2009) Exploring Sources of Local Government Technical Inefficiency Evidence from Flemish Municipalities Public Finance and Management 9(1) 1ndash29

Goderis B amp Malone S W (2011) Natural Resource Booms and Inequality Theory and Evidence The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 113(2) 388ndash417 httpsdoiorg101111j1467-9442201101659x

Greene W H (2016) Productivity and Efficiency Analysis (W H Greene L Khalaf R Sickles M Veall amp M-C Voia Eds) (1st ed 20) Cham Springer International Publishing httpsdoiorg101007978-3-319-23228-7

Gustafsson B amp Shi L (2002) Income inequality within and across counties in rural China 1988 and 1995 Journal of Development Economics 69(1) 179ndash204 httpsdoiorg101016S0304-3878(02)00058-5

Gylfason T amp Zoega G (2003) Inequality and Economic Growth Do Natural Resources Matter In T T Eicher S (Ed) Inequality and Growth Theory and Policy Implications (pp 255ndash292) The MIT Press

Henningsen A (2010) Estimating Censored Regression Models in R using the censReg Package R Package Vignettes Collection 5(2) 12

Henningsen A (2019) censReg Censored Regression (Tobit) Models R package version 05-30 httpscranr-projectorgpackage=censReg Retrieved from httpscranr-projectorgpackage=censReg

Herrera S amp Pang G (2005) Efficiency of Public Spending in Developing Countriesthinsp An Efficiency Frontier Approach World Bank Washington DC

Hill T D amp Angel R J (2005) Neighborhood disorder psychological distress and heavy drinking Social Science amp Medicine 61(5) 965ndash975

133

httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jsocscimed200412027

Hipp J R (2010) RESIDENT PERCEPTIONS OF CRIME AND DISORDER HOW MUCH IS ldquoBIASrdquo AND HOW MUCH IS SOCIAL ENVIRONMENT DIFFERENCES Criminology 48(2) 475ndash508 httpsdoiorg101111j1745-9125201000193x

Holtug N amp Mason A (2010) Introduction Immigration diversity and social cohesion SAGE Publications Sage UK London England

Hooghe M Vanhoutte B Hardyns W amp Bircan T (2010) Unemployment Inequality Poverty and Crime Spatial Distribution Patterns of Criminal Acts in Belgium 2001ndash06 The British Journal of Criminology 51(1) 1ndash20 httpsdoiorg101093bjcazq067

Howie P amp Atakhanova Z (2014) Resource boom and inequality Kazakhstan as a case study Resources Policy 39(1) 71ndash79 httpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201311004

Isham J Woolcock M Pritchett L amp Busby G (2005) The Varieties of Resource Experience Natural Resource Export Structures and the Political Economy of Economic Growth The World Bank Economic Review 19(2) 141ndash174 httpsdoiorg101093wberlhi010

Jottier D Ashworth J amp Heyndels B (2012) Understanding Votersrsquo Preferences How the Electoratersquos Complexity Affects Prediction Accuracy and Wishful Thinking among Politicians with Respect to Election Outcomes Kyklos 65(3) 340ndash370 httpsdoiorg101111j1467-6435201200542x

Kanbur S M R amp Venables A (2005) Spatial inequality and development (R World Institute for Development Economics Ed) Oxford Oxford University Press

Kesler C amp Bloemraad I (2010) Does immigration erode social capital The conditional effects of immigration-generated diversity on trust membership and participation across 19 countries 1981ndash2000 Canadian Journal of Political ScienceRevue Canadienne de Science Politique 43(2) 319ndash347

Kuznets S (1955) Economic Growth and Income Inequality The American Economic Review 45(1) 1ndash28 Retrieved from httpwwwjstororgstable1811581

Lagos G amp Blanco E (2010) Mining and development in the region of Antofagasta Resources Policy 35(4) 265ndash275 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jresourpol201007006

Leamer E E Maul H Rodriguez S amp Schott P K (1999) Does natural resource abundance increase Latin American income inequality Journal of Development Economics 59(1) 3ndash42 httpsdoiorg101016s0304-3878(99)00004-8

Leibbrandt M Finn A amp Woolard I (2012) Describing and decomposing post-apartheid income inequality in South Africa Development Southern Africa 29(1) 19ndash34 httpsdoiorg1010800376835X2012645639

134

Letki N (2008) Does Diversity Erode Social Cohesion Social Capital and Race in British Neighbourhoods Political Studies 56(1) 99ndash126 httpsdoiorg101111j1467-9248200700692x

Lewis D A (2017) Fear of crime Incivility and the production of a social problem Routledge

lo Storto C (2013) Evaluating Technical Efficiency of Italian Major Municipalities A Data Envelopment Analysis model Procedia - Social and Behavioral Sciences 81 346ndash350 httpsdoiorg101016JSBSPRO201306440

Loayza N amp Rigolini J (2016) The Local Impact of Mining on Poverty and Inequality Evidence from the Commodity Boom in Peru World Development 84 219ndash234 httpsdoiorg101016jworlddev201603005

Loayza N Teran A M y amp Rigolini J (2013) Poverty Inequality and the Local Natural Resource Curse World Bank Policy Research Working Paper (6366) httpsdoiorg1015961813-9450-6366

Loacutepez R amp Miller S J (2008) Chile The Unbearable Burden of Inequality World Development 36(12) 2679ndash2695 httpsdoiorg101016jworlddev200801012

Manzano O amp Rigobon R (2001) Resource Curse or Debt Overhang National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper Series No 8390 1 httpsdoiorghttpwwwnberorgpapersw9424bib

McPherson M Smith-Lovin L amp Cook J M (2001) Birds of a Feather Homophily in Social Networks Annual Review of Sociology 27(1) 415ndash444 httpsdoiorg101146annurevsoc271415

McQuestin D Drew J amp Dollery B (2018) Do Municipal Mergers Improve Technical Efficiency An Empirical Analysis of the 2008 Queensland Municipal Merger Program Australian Journal of Public Administration 77(3) 442ndash455 httpsdoiorg1011111467-850012286

Messner S F Rosenfeld R amp Baumer E P (2004) Dimensions of Social Capital and Rates of Criminal Homicide American Sociological Review 69(6) 882ndash903 httpsdoiorg101177000312240406900607

Michaels G (2011) THE LONG TERM CONSEQUENCES OF RESOURCE-BASED SPECIALISATION The Economic Journal 121(551) 31ndash57 httpsdoiorg101111j1468-0297201002402x

Mijanovich T amp Weitzman B C (2003) Which ldquobroken windowsrdquo matter School neighborhood and family characteristics associated with youthsrsquo feelings of unsafety Journal of Urban Health 80(3) 400ndash415

Mikušovaacute P (2015) An Application of DEA Methodology in Efficiency Measurement of the Czech Public Universities Procedia Economics and Finance 25 569ndash578 httpsdoiorg101016S2212-5671(15)00771-6

135

Milanovic B (2016) Global inequality Harvard University Press

Millo G amp Piras G (2012) splm Spatial panel data models in R Journal of Statistical Software 47(1) 1ndash38

Murphy K M amp Topel R H (2016) Human Capital Investment Inequality and Economic Growth JOURNAL OF LABOR ECONOMICS 34(2) S99ndashS127 httpsdoiorg101086683779

Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute I amp De Witte K (2018a) Local governmentsrsquo efficiency a systematic literature reviewmdashpart I International Transactions in Operational Research 25(2) 431ndash468 httpsdoiorg101111itor12364

Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute I amp De Witte K (2018b) Local governmentsrsquo efficiency a systematic literature reviewmdashpart II International Transactions in Operational Research 25(4) 1107ndash1136 httpsdoiorg101111itor12389

Nuntildeez J Rivera J Villavicencio X amp Molina O (2003) Determinantes socioeconoacutemicos y demograacuteficos del crimen en Chile Estudios de Economiacutea 30(1) 55ndash85

OrsquoDonnell C J Rao D S P amp Battese G E (2008) Metafrontier frameworks for the study of firm-level efficiencies and technology ratios Empirical Economics 34(2) 231ndash255 httpsdoiorg101007s00181-007-0119-4

Ocampo J A (2004) Latin Americarsquos Growth and Equity Frustrations During Structural Reforms The Journal of Economic Perspectives 18(2) 67ndash88 httpsdoiorg1012570895330041371349

OECD (2014) Focus on inequality and growth OECD

OECD (2017) Howrsquos Life 2017 Life Satisfaction Oecd httpsdoiorg101787how_life-2017-en

Ohtake F (2008) Inequality in Japan Asian Economic Policy Review 3(1) 87ndash109 httpsdoiorg101111j1748-3131200800093x

Okun A M (2015) Equality and efficiency the big tradeoff Washington DC Brookings Institution Press

Ortega B Sanjuaacuten J amp Casquero A (2017) Determinants of efficiency in reducing child mortality in developing countries The role of inequality and government effectiveness Health Care Management Science 20(4) 500ndash516 httpsdoiorg101007s10729-016-9367-1

Ostry J Berg A amp Tsangarides C (2014) Redistribution inequality and growth International Monetary Fund

Pacheco F Saacutenchez R amp Villena M (2013) Eficiencia de los Gobiernos Locales y sus Determinantes Un anaacutelisis de Fronteras Estocaacutesticas en Datos de Panel para

136

Municipalidades Chilenas Santiago de Chile Chile

Papyrakis E amp Raveh O (2014) An Empirical Analysis of a Regional Dutch Disease The Case of Canada Environmental and Resource Economics 58(2) 179ndash198 httpsdoiorg101007s10640-013-9698-z

Paredes D (2013) The Role of Human Capital Market Potential and Natural Amenities in Understanding Spatial Wage Disparities in Chile Spatial Economic Analysis 8(2) 154ndash175 httpsdoiorg101080174217722013774094

Paredes D Iturra V amp Lufin M (2016) A spatial decomposition of income inequality in Chile Regional Studies 50(5) 771ndash789

Phan P Van Orsquobrien M Mendolia S amp Paloyo A (2017) National pro-poor spending programmes and their effect on income inequality and poverty Evidence from Vietnam Applied Economics 49(55) 5579ndash5590 httpsdoiorg1010800003684620171313957

Podinovski V V (2004) Bridging the Gap between the Constant and Variable Returns-to-Scale Models Selective Proportionality in Data Envelopment Analysis The Journal of the Operational Research Society 55(3) 265ndash276 Retrieved from httpwwwjstororgstable4102006

Ravallion M (2005) On Measuring Aggregate Social Efficiency Economic Development and Cultural Change 53(2) 273ndash292 httpsdoiorg101086425380

Rehner J Baeza S A amp Barton J R (2014) Chilersquos resource-based export boom and its outcomes Regional specialization export stability and economic growth Geoforum 56(Supplement C) 35ndash45 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jgeoforum201406007

Rivera J Gutieacuterrez M amp Nuacutentildeez J (2009) Caracterizacioacuten socioeconoacutemica y espacial de la criminalidad en Chile Revista CEPAL

Ross C E (2011) Collective threat trust and the sense of personal control Journal of Health and Social Behavior 52(3) 287ndash296

Ross C E amp Mirowsky J (2001) Neighborhood disadvantage disorder and health Journal of Health and Social Behavior 258ndash276

Rothstein B amp Uslaner E M (2005) All for all Equality corruption and social trust World Politics 58(1) 41ndash72

Sachs J D amp Warner A M (2001) The curse of natural resources European Economic Review 45(4ndash6) 827ndash838 httpsdoiorg101016S0014-2921(01)00125-8

Salas R (2019) sinimr Chilean Municipalities Information System Wrapper Retrieved from httpsgithubcomrobsalascosinimr

Sampson R J (1986) Crime in Cities The Effects of Formal and Informal Social Control Crime and Justice 8 271ndash311

137

Sampson R J (2008) Rethinking crime and immigration Contexts 7(1) 28ndash33

Santos Silva J M C amp Tenreyro S (2010) On the existence of the maximum likelihood estimates in Poisson regression Economics Letters 107(2) 310ndash312 httpsdoiorghttpsdoiorg101016jeconlet201002020

Santos Silva J M C amp Tenreyro S (2011) poisson Some convergence issues Stata Journal 11(2) 207ndash212 Retrieved from httpwwwstata-journalcomarticlehtmlarticle=st0225

Scott Z (2009) Decentralisation local development and social cohesion an analytical review GSDRC Research Paper 5

Sinha R P (2017) Fiscal Performance Benchmarking of Indian States-A Robust Frontier Approach The Central European Review of Economics and Management 1(4) 225ndash249

Skogan W (1986) Fear of crime and neighborhood change Crime and Justice 8 203ndash229

Skogan W (1999) Measuring what matters Crime disorder and fear In Measuring what matters Proceedings from the Policing Research Institute meetings (pp 37ndash53) National Institute of Justice Washington DC

Skogan W (2015) Disorder and Decline The State of Research Journal of Research in Crime and Delinquency 52(4) 464ndash485 httpsdoiorg1011770022427815577836

Šťastnaacute L amp Gregor M (2014) Public sector efficiency in transition and beyond evidence from Czech local governments Applied Economics 47(7) 1ndash20 httpsdoiorg101080000368462014978077

Tandon A (2005) Measuring Efficiency of Macro Systems An Application to Millennium Development Goal Attainment Asian Development Review 22(2) 108ndash125

Taylor R B (1999) The incivilities thesis Theory measurement and policy Measuring What Matters 65 88

Tigga N S amp Mishra U S (2015) On Measuring Technical Efficiency of the Health System in India An Application of Data Envelopment Analysis Journal of Health Management 17(3) 285ndash298 httpsdoiorg1011770972063415589229

Tinbergen J (1975) Demographic Development and the Exhaustion of Natural Resources Population and Development Review 1(1) 23ndash32 httpsdoiorg1023071972269

Tiruneh G (2014) Social Revolutions Their Causes Patterns and Phases SAGE Open 4(3) 2158244014548845 httpsdoiorg1011772158244014548845

Tolsma J Van der Meer T amp Gesthuizen M (2009) The impact of neighbourhood and municipality characteristics on social cohesion in the Netherlands Acta Politica 44(3) 286ndash313

Tsekeris Sotiris T Tsekeris T amp Papaioannou S (2018) Regional determinants of technical efficiency evidence from the Greek economy Regional Studies [London]thinsp Carfax

138

httpsdoiorg1010800034340420171390312

Uslaner E (2002) The moral foundations of trust Cambridge University Press

Uslaner E (2011) CORRUPTION AND INEQUALITY DICE Report 9(2) 20ndash24

Uslaner E (2013) Trust and corruption revisited how and why trust and corruption shape each other Quality amp Quantity 47(6) 3603ndash3608 httpsdoiorg101007s11135-012-9742-z

Uslaner E amp Brown M (2005) Inequality trust and civic engagement American Politics Research 33(6) 868ndash894

Van der Ploeg F (2011) Natural Resources Curse or Blessing Journal of Economic Literature 49(2) 366ndash420 httpsdoiorg101257jel492366

Vergara R (2012) Crime Prevention Programs Evidence From CHILE The Developing Economies 50(1) 1ndash24

Watkins M H (1963) A staple theory of economic growth Canadian Journal of Economics and Political ScienceRevue Canadienne de Economiques et Science Politique 29(2) 141ndash158

Wilkinson R G (1999) Income inequality social cohesion and health clarifying the theorymdasha reply to Muntaner and Lynch International Journal of Health Services 29(3) 525ndash543

Wilson J Q amp Kelling G L (1982) Broken windows Atlantic Monthly 249(3) 29ndash38

Wilson W J (1996) When Work Disappears Political Science Quarterly 111(4) 567ndash595 httpsdoiorg1023072152085

Wirth L (1938) Urbanism as a Way of Life American Journal of Sociology 44(1) 1ndash24

Worthington A amp Dollery B (2000) An empirical survey of frontier efficiency measurement techniques in local government Local Government Studies 26(2) 23ndash52 httpsdoiorg10108003003930008433988

Wu P-C Huang T-H amp Pan S-C (2014) Country Performance Evaluation The DEA Model Approach Social Indicators Research 118(2) 835ndash849 httpsdoiorg101007s11205-013-0443-3

Ye X Ma L Ye K Chen J amp Xie Q (2017) Analysis of Regional Inequality from Sectoral Structure Spatial Policy and Economic Development A Case Study of Chongqing China Sustainability 9(4) 633 Retrieved from httpwwwmdpicom2071-105094633

Yue W Z Zhang Y T Ye X Y Cheng Y Q amp Leipnik M R (2014) Dynamics of Multi-Scale Intra-Provincial Regional Inequality in Zhejiang China Sustainability 6(9) 5763ndash5784 httpsdoiorg103390su6095763

139

Appendices

Appendix A Summary statistics income inequality

Table A1

Summary statistics Gini coefficients by year and zone

140

Appendix B Summary statistics for NRD measures by region

Table B1

Summary statistics NRD measures by region

141

Appendix C Regional administrative division and defined zones

Figure C1 Geographical distribution of Chilean regions and 3 zones

142

Appendix D Summary statistics numeric controls and correlation matrix

Table D1

Summary Statistics Numeric Explanatory Variables

Figure D1 Correlation matrix numeric explanatory variables

143

Appendix E Static spatial panel models

Following Millo amp Piras (2012) a model including a spatial lag of the dependent variable and

spatial autoregressive disturbances but not spatial lags for the explanatory variable(s) is called

SARAR model A static spatial SARAR panel could be expressed as

119910 120582 119868 otimes119882 119910 119883120573 119906 (E1)

where y is an 119873 1 vector of observations on the dependent variable X is a 119873 119896 matrix of

observations on the non-stochastic exogenous regressors 119868 an identity matrix of dimension 119879 otimes

is the kronecker operator 119882 is the 119873 119873 spatial weights matrix of known constants whose

diagonal elements are set to zero and 120582 the corresponding spatial parameter44

The disturbance vector is the sum of two terms

119906 120580 otimes 119868 120583 120576 (E2)

where 120580 is a 119879 1 vector of ones 119868 an 119873 119873 identity matrix 120583 is a vector of time-invariant

individual specific effects (not spatially autocorrelated) and 120576 a vector of spatially autocorrelated

innovations that follow a spatial autoregressive process of the form

120576 120588 119868 otimes119882 120576 120584 (E3)

If we assume that spatial correlation applies to both the individual effects 120583 and the remainder

error components 120576 Kapoor et al (2007) propose that the disturbance term 119906 follows a first order

spatial autoregressive process of the form

119906 120588 119868 otimes119882 119906 120576 (E4)

44 Unlike ldquotraditional panelsrdquo which are organized as different time series for each cross-sectional unit ldquospatial panelsrdquo are organized as a series of cross-sections for each year

144

where 119882 is the spatial weights matrix and 119903ℎ119900 the corresponding spatial autoregressive

parameter To further allow for the innovations to be correlated over time the innovations vector

in Equation 7 follows an error component structure

120576 120580 otimes 119868 120583 120584 (E5)

where 120583 is the vector of cross-sectional specific effects 120584 a vector of innovations that vary

both over cross-sectional units and time periods 120580 is a vector of ones and 119868 an 119873 119873 identity

matrix45

Spatial panel models are usually estimated by Maximum Likelihood or GMM46 The SAR

SEM or SARAR models could be estimated with Random or Fixed effects For instance A fixed

effect spatial lag model can be written in stacked form as

119910 120582 119868 otimes119882 119910 120580 otimes 119868 120583 119883120573 120576 (E6)

where 120582 is the spatial autoregressive coefficient 119882 a non-stochastic spatial weights matrix

120580 a column vector of ones of dimension 119879 119868 an 119873 119873 identity matrix and 120576 sim 119873 0120590 On

the other hand a fixed effects spatial error model assuming the disturbance specification by

Kapoor et al (2007) can be written as

119910 120580119879 otimes 119868119873 120583 119883120573 119906119906 120588 119868119879 otimes119882119873 119906 120576

(E7)

where 120588 is the spatial autocorrelation coefficient and 120576 is a well-behaved error term

45 In the regression implementation the specification given by equations (22) and (3) is denoted by ldquobrdquo for ldquoBaltagirdquo On the other hand the specification given by equations (23) and (31) is denoted by ldquokkprdquo for ldquoKapoor Kelejian and Pruchardquo 46 We use the R package splm which allow both types of regression procedure

145

Appendix F Analysis OLS residuals cross-sectional (six-year average) analysis

Table F1

Analysis OLS residuals Anselin Method

Figure F1 Moran scatter plot OLS residuals

146

Appendix G Linear panel data models

Table G1

Panel regressions (non-spatial)

147

Appendix H Spatial panel models (Generalized Moments (GM) estimation)

Table H1

GM Spatial Models

148

Appendix I Inputs and outputs used in DEA analysis

Figure I1 Examples of inputs and outputs used to measure LGE (based on Narboacuten-Perpintildeaacute amp De Witte 2018)

149

Appendix J Technical and scale efficiency

Following lo Storto (2013) under an input-oriented specification assuming VRS with n

municipalities using k inputs to produce m outputs the DEA model for a given i-th municipality

is specified with the following mathematical programming problem

119898119894119899 120579119904119906119887119895119890119888119905 119905119900 119910 119884120582 0120579119909 119883120582 01198991prime120582 1  120582 0prime

Where 119910 is the column vector of the outputs and 119909 is the column vector of the inputs

Moreover we can define X as the (k times n) input matrix and Y as the (m times n) output matrix 120579 is a

scalar (that satisfies 120579 1) more specifically it is the efficiency score that measures technical

efficiency It measures the distance between a municipality and the efficiency frontier defined as

a linear combination of the best practice observations With 120579 1 the municipality is inside the

frontier (ie it is inefficient) while 120579 1 implies that the municipality is on the frontier (ie it is

efficient) The vector 120582 is an (n times 1) vector of constants that measures the weights used to compute

the location of an inefficient municipality if it were to become efficient

The total technical efficiency 119879119864 can be decomposed into pure technical efficiency

119879119864 and scale efficiency 119878119864 where 119878119864 119879119864 119879119864 (Coelli et al 2005) To find out

whether a municipality is scale efficient and qualify the type of returns of scale a DEA model

under non-increasing returns to scale 119879119864 is implemented where 119878119864 119879119864 119879119864 Hence

the following rule can be applied (Faumlre Grosskopf amp Lovell 1985)

bull If 119878119864 1 then a municipality is scale efficient both under CRS and VRS

bull If 119878119864 1 it operates under increasing returns to scale

bull If 119878119864 1 it operates under decreasing returns to scale

150

Appendix K Correlation matrix

Figure K1 Correlation matrix contextual factors

151

Appendix L Returns to scale by year and zone

Table L1

Returns to scale (percentage of municipalities)

152

Appendix M Returns to scale by year (maps)

Figure M1 Spatial distribution of returns to scale by county per year

153

Appendix N Efficiency status by year (maps)

Figure N1 Spatial distribution of efficient (E es = 1) and inefficient (I es lt 1) counties per year

154

Appendix O Spatial distribution efficiency scores by year (maps)

FigureO1 Custom breaks maps of efficiency scores (VRS) by county per year

155

Appendix P Analysis OLS residuals cross-sectional (six-year average) analysis

Table P1

Analysis OLS residuals Anselin Method

Figure P1 Moran scatter plot efficiency scores and OLS residuals

156

Table P2

OLS and spatial regression models for the six-year averaged data

157

Appendix Q OLS regressions for cross-sectional and panel data

Table Q1

OLS cross-sectional regression per year

158

Table Q2

OLS panel regressions Pooled random effects and instrumental variable

159

Appendix R Quantile maps incivilities rate by group (average total period)

Figure R1 Spatial distribution of incivilities by group (Average rate per 1000 inhabitants 2006-09-11-13-15-17)

160

Appendix S Correlation matrix numeric covariates

Figure S1 Correlation matrix numeric covariates

161

Appendix T Negative Binomial regressions

Table T1

Negative Binomial regressions

162

Appendix U Coefficients economic and racial diversity by geographical zone

Table U1

Coefficients economic and racial diversity in pooled Poisson models by geographic zone

Page 9: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 10: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 11: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 12: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 13: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 14: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 15: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 16: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 17: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 18: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 19: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 20: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 21: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 22: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 23: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 24: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 25: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 26: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 27: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 28: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 29: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 30: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 31: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 32: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 33: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 34: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 35: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 36: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 37: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 38: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 39: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 40: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 41: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 42: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 43: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 44: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 45: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 46: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 47: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 48: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 49: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 50: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 51: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 52: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 53: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 54: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 55: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 56: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 57: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 58: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 59: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 60: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 61: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 62: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 63: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 64: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 65: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 66: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 67: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 68: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 69: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 70: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 71: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 72: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 73: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 74: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 75: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 76: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 77: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 78: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 79: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 80: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 81: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 82: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 83: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 84: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 85: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 86: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 87: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 88: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 89: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 90: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 91: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 92: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 93: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 94: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 95: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 96: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 97: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 98: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 99: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 100: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 101: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 102: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 103: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 104: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 105: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 106: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 107: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 108: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 109: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 110: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 111: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 112: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 113: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 114: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 115: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 116: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 117: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 118: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 119: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 120: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 121: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 122: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 123: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 124: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 125: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 126: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 127: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 128: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 129: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 130: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 131: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 132: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 133: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 134: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 135: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 136: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 137: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 138: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 139: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 140: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 141: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 142: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 143: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 144: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 145: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 146: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 147: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 148: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 149: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 150: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 151: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 152: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 153: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 154: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 155: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 156: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 157: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 158: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 159: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 160: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 161: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 162: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted
Page 163: Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries ......Income Inequality in Natural Resource-Rich Countries: Empirical Evidence from Chile Javier Beltrán M.Sc. (Economics) Submitted