165
HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green Oxfam GB, Strategic Adviser Consultation draft October 2015 Not for publication. For more information, or to comment on the text, contact Anna Coryndon [email protected] or Duncan Green [email protected]

How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

a

Citation preview

Page 1: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS

Duncan Green

Oxfam GB, Strategic Adviser

Consultation draft October 2015

Not for publication. For more information, or to comment on the text, contact Anna Coryndon [email protected] or Duncan Green [email protected]

Page 2: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

2

Contents Introduction ................................................................................................. 3

1 Change is about power and politics .......................................................... 6

2 Complexity changes the way we think about working in systems ........... 17

3 How states change .................................................................................. 30

4 Courts and the rule of law ....................................................................... 40

5 Democracy and political parties .............................................................. 46

6 The international system ........................................................................ 61

7 Transnational corporations ..................................................................... 72

8 Norms and change .................................................................................. 85

9 Citizen activism and civil society ........................................................... 101

10 Advocacy ............................................................................................. 116

11 Leaders and leadership ....................................................................... 133

12 Pulling it all together ........................................................................... 146

Conclusion ............................................................................................... 164

Page 3: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

3

Introduction

I was moved to write this book out of a combination of excitement, fascination and

frustration: excitement at the speed and grandeur of many of the social changes occurring

today – continents rising from poverty, multitudes gaining access to literacy and decent

healthcare for the first time, women in dozens of countries winning rights, respect and

power. Working at Oxfam gives me an extraordinary and privileged ringside seat from

which to appreciate both the bigger picture and the individual stories of inspiring activists

across the globe.

At the same time, I became increasingly fascinated by the inner workings of change, in

particular efforts to understand change through understanding systems and power.

Perhaps it is the legacy of a long-distant physics degree, but at times in the last few years,

it has felt like something like a unified field theory of development is emerging from

these discussions.

But my daily excitement has been laced with frustration when I see activists take steps

that seem destined to fail. Within months of joining Oxfam in 2004, I was witness to two

examples, one big and one small. On an induction field visit to Vietnam, I was taken to

see our work with Hmong villagers in the North. As we drove to the remote home of this

impoverished ethnic minority, we passed the first, more intrepid backpackers starting to

arrive in the area. The Hmong produce wonderful textiles, and it was obvious that a

tourist boom was in the offing. Yet our project consisted of training villagers to keep their

prized water buffalo warm and well during the winter (involving rubbing them regularly

with alcohol, among other things). There is nothing wrong with working on livestock, but

what were we doing to help them prepare for the coming influx of tourists? When

challenged, our local (non-Hmong, middle class Vietnamese) staff replied that they

wanted to ‗protect‘ the villagers‘ traditional ways against the invasion of the outside

world.

On a grander scale, I had growing misgivings about an enormous, global campaign

Oxfam was then leading that implied global activism around trade, debt, aid and climate

change could somehow ‗Make Poverty History‘. The campaign seemed to gravely

downplay the primacy of national politics, an argument I developed a couple of years

later in a book, From Poverty to Power: How Active Citizens and Effective States can

Page 4: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

4

Change the World. As part of that effort, we commissioned a paper from Roman

Krznaric,1 which showed that different academic disciplines operate with separate and

often conflicting theories of change – there is no ‗department of change studies‘ to which

we can turn for help. I was intrigued, and set out some rather rudimentary ideas about

‗how change happens‘ in an annex to the book, marking the starting point for a prolonged

conversation which led eventually to this book.

This book is for activists who want to change the world. A narrow interpretation would

say that means people engaged in protest movements and campaigns around topics as

disparate as climate change and disabled peoples‘ rights, usually on the margins of ‗the

system‘, people who from the days of the abolitionists have been vital in making change

happen. But the list of ‗change agents‘ (English is sadly devoid of non-clunky descriptors

in this field) is much wider. I include reformers inside the system, such as politicians

(both elected and unelected), public officials and enlightened business people. And the

civic world beyond formal institutions is far too rich to narrow down to a single category

of ‗campaigners‘. Faith groups, community leaders or the many self-help organizations

that women form are all often influential players. Even within aid organizations, those

engaged in what we call ‗programmes‘ – funding or running projects to create jobs or

improve health and education services, or responding to emergencies such as wars or

earthquakes – are just as involved in seeking change as campaigners. When I use the

word ‗activists‘ I mean all of the above.

The inter-relationships between such activists is often fraught, partly because people

bring their own worldviews to the question of how change happens. Do we prefer conflict

(‗speaking truth to power‘) or cooperation (‗winning friends and influencing people‘)?

Do we see progress everywhere, and seek to accelerate its path, or do we see (in our

darker, more honest moments) a quixotic struggle against power and injustice that is

ultimately doomed to defeat? Do we believe lasting and legitimate change is primarily

driven by the accumulation of power at grassroots/individual level, through organization

and challenging norms and beliefs? Or by reforms at the levels of laws, policies,

institutions, companies and elites? Or by identifying and supporting ‗enlightened

leaders‘? Do we think the aim of development is to include poor people in the benefits of

modernity (money economy, technology, mobility) or to defend other cultures and

traditions and build an alternative? Do we want to make the current system function

better, or do we seek something that tackles the deeper structures of power?

1 R. Krznaric, 2007, How Change Happens: Interdisciplinary perspectives for human development

Page 5: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

5

The discussion of development is dominated by economists. They write the big books

and influence what is and is not on the agenda. But there is more to life (and

development) than economics. This book takes as its starting point Amartya Sen‘s

brilliant redefinition of development as the freedoms to be and to do,2 and discusses

political and social change, as well as some of development‘s economic aspects.

The purpose of the book is not to provide a manual – indeed one of its conclusions is that

the search for checklists of how to bring about change is one of the things that are

holding us back. Instead it offers a combination of analysis, questions and case studies,

with the aim of helping readers to look afresh at the enthralling processes of change

going on all around them, as well as the obstacles, and to gain some new energy and

ideas about how to contribute.

2 A. Sen, Development as Freedom

Page 6: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

6

1 Change is about power and politics

‘Power without love is reckless and abusive, and love without power is

sentimental and anaemic.’ Dr. Martin Luther King, Jr.

‘The purpose of getting power is to give it away.’ Aneurin Bevan

A reliable conversation opener for people working in development is ‗what was your

moment of conversion – the event that triggered your commitment to progressive

change?‘ One memorable reply I heard came from someone who is now a terribly

respectable development analyst: was ‗I was off my face on ecstasy, dancing in a

university club, and suddenly felt a great wave of love for people everywhere‘.

My own moment of conversion did not involve banned substances, but it did take place at

oxygen-deprived high altitude, in a small village on the shores of Lake Titicaca in Peru.

As a rather lost post-college backpacker, I found myself in the home of a charismatic

activist named Tito Castro. Tito was a lapsed Jesuit seminarian who had decided to

devote himself to raising awareness among Peru‘s indigenous people. He arrived in the

village with a library of books on politics, economics, sociology and indigenous rights,

and when I met him he was lending out books and running discussion groups for local

leaders.

Tito took me to meet the villagers and introduced me to Peru‘s history of apartheid-like

racial discrimination. And he explained how, by organizing, indigenous people can win

greater control over their lives. By the time I went on my way, I was filled with an

exhilarating sense of a big and heroic struggle for justice, and I duly found a niche as a

human rights activist working on Chile and Central America. Tito later became mayor of

the nearest city, Puno, and eventually a sociology professor at Lima‘s Catholic

University.

What Tito showed me was empowerment in real time, when lightbulbs go on in the heads

of people who had previously felt shackled by their lot, and they begin to take action to

change it. Such small, personal events often lie at the heart of the tides of social and

political change that will be discussed in this book.

Empowerment is one of the most ubiquitous buzzwords in the lexicon of development

activists. Many, however, shy away from the word from which the term derives: power.

Power, which allows one person or institution is able to command the resources or

Page 7: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

7

actions of another, was central to Tito‘s understanding of Peruvian society and it should

be so for all activists.

The most evident and most discussed form of power is what we might call ‗visible

power‘. This is the world of politics and authority, policed by laws, violence and money.

It gets a bad press, conjuring images of repression, force, coercion, discrimination,

corruption and abuse. But visible power is also necessary to do good, whether to

implement enlightened public policies or to prevent acts of violence by the strong against

the weak.

Activists seeking social and political change usually focus their efforts on those who

wield visible power, presidents, prime ministers and CEOs, since they hold apparent

authority over the matter at hand. Yet the hierarchy of visible power is underpinned by

subtle interactions among a more diverse set of players. ‗Hidden power‘ describes what

goes on behind the scenes: the lobbyists, the corporate chequebooks, the Old Boys

Network. Hidden power also comprises the shared view of what those in power consider

sensible or reasonable in public debate. Any environmentalist who has sat across the table

from government officials or mainstream economists and dared to question the

advisability of unlimited economic growth in a resource-constrained world will have met

the blank faces that confront anyone breaching those boundaries.

In 2002 a senior White House aide to President George W. Bush memorably captured the

role of hidden power in an interview with journalist Ron Suskind. The aide pointed out

that the journalist was ―in what we call the reality-based community‖, made up of people

who believe that solutions emerge from the ―judicious study of discernible reality.‖ But

―that‘s not the way the world really works any more. We‘re an empire now, and when we

act, we create our own reality.‖3 Hidden power poses a huge challenge to the notion that

amassing research and evidence is enough to change government policy. Discussion of

research often takes place parallel to a shadow world of combat between competing

narratives that have little basis or interest in evidence.

Even more insidious than ‗hidden power‘ is ‗invisible power‘, which causes the relatively

powerless to internalise and accept their condition. A Guatemalan Mayan woman

summed up the nature of invisible power: ―Why do we not speak now? We did when we

were children. We have internalised repression. They gave us the words: ‗stupid‘; ‗you

3 Quoted in ‘Good and Bad Power: The Ideals and Betrayals of Government’, Geoff Mulgan, 2006

Page 8: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

8

can‘t‘; ‗you don‘t know‘, ‗poor thing - you are a woman‘.‖4 In the words of French

philosopher Michel Foucault, ‗There is no need for arms, physical violence, material

constraints. Just a gaze. An inspecting gaze, which each individual will end up

interiorizing to the point that he is his own overseer.‖5

Invisible power often determines the capacity of change movements to influence visible

and hidden power. It shapes the belief systems about what is ‗normal‘ or ‗natural‘,

leading some groups to exclude themselves, as when women blame themselves for their

abuse, or poor people for their poverty. Altering invisible power (‗empowerment‘) is a

long-term proposition, achieved through the sort of awareness-raising Tito Castro

promoted to build self-esteem and local leadership. Because the targets of such

campaigns are the inner lives of many individuals, cultural initiatives and mass media can

play important roles, as has been the case in the rapid progress in respect for women‘s

rights in recent decades. Chapter eight discusses how such shifts are reflected in the

evolution of ‗norms‘ – ideas of what is natural, acceptable or right, an area that I feel

receives far too little attention in development debates.

No such thing as a power vacuum

Rich ecosystems of power exist in the most unpropitious of circumstances. Eastern

Congo is often seen as a failed state, with the population suffering from anarchic

violence. But to call that a ‗power vacuum‘ is a highly misleading caricature. Power is

everywhere, and it is multifaceted.

During a visit in 2014, I met one village official, Kabuya Muhemeri, in his ‗office‘: tin

roof and floor of volcanic rubble; no glass in windows; bare plank walls covered with

heavily logoed NGO and UN posters on sexual violence, torture, HIV and land rights,

and a hand-drawn map of the area. On his desk, the classic tools of the functionary: a

rubber stamp, a mobile phone and a pile of files and notebooks.

He had been in the post since 2008. He laughed when asked if the state gives him

training: ‗We rely on the NGOs for that. They help us with what the law says – don‘t

torture, don‘t lock people up for unpaid debts. There are lots of rights and laws I didn‘t

know.‘ In his world, state officials and customary authorities are all part of public

4 [quoted in Pearce 2006]

5 (Foucault 1980a: 155)

Page 9: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

9

administration. ‗The chefferie (traditional authority) collects the taxes. I report to the

mwami (traditional leader) as well as to the ministry.‘

Later, I talked to a traditional leader, on the veranda of his rather smart house at the top of

a steep mud path. The chief spoke softly, radiating authority and cradling his two mobile

telephones. ‗I‘ve been chief for 20 years, my father was chief before me. The state

authorities are in charge of roads and bridges, tax is collected from shops, restaurants and

markets by the chef de cheferie, [his superior in the traditional hierarchy]. I encourage the

population to pay.‘

Several other poles of power vie with civil and traditional authorities: armed groups, the

army, the police, humanitarian agencies, faith organizations, civil society organizations,

even sports clubs. Despite the contradictions among them, these centres of power and

trust sometimes coincide and all can play a role in solving the region‘s pressing

problems.6 We‘ll examine the interactions among such poles of power in some detail in

chapter three.

Power and change

Contemplating the full panoply of visible, hidden and invisible power that supports the

status quo can be dispiriting, inducing feelings of helplessness before the Leviathan.

Fresh back from my life-changing moment in Tito‘s house, I spent many fruitless

mornings standing outside the US embassy in London, protesting against Washington‘s

policies in Latin America. Our motley scatter of placards and banners contrasted

painfully with the vast power encapsulated in the great blank face of the building, topped

by a huge bronze eagle glowering down at us. I didn‘t feel very powerful.

Fortunately, other ways of thinking about power highlight the opportunities and

possibilities for change. Jo Rowlands, based on her work on women‘s empowerment in

Honduras, identified a different scheme that encapsulates this more optimistic approach:

Power within: personal self confidence and a sense of rights and entitlement

Power with: collective power, through organization, solidarity and joint action

Power to: meaning effective choice, the capability to decide actions and carry

them out

Power over: the power of hierarchy and domination, as described above.

6 power analysis in DRC

Page 10: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

10

This ‗four-powers‘ model suggests a more comprehensive approach to promoting change

than simply addressing visible power and decrying hidden and invisible power. Unless

people first develop a sense of self-confidence and a belief in their own rights (power

within), efforts to help them organize (power with) and demand a say (power to) may not

bear fruit. As Tito showed in his Peruvian idyll, personal empowerment can be the first

step on the path to social transformation.

‗Power within‘ has proved to be remarkably important in the field of women‘s rights. In

South Asia, We Can is an extraordinary campaign on violence against women launched

in late 2004. At last count it had signed up some four million women and men to be

‗change makers‘ – advocates for an end to violence in their homes and communities.

Apart from its scale, We Can is distinctive in that it does not target policies, laws or the

authorities (visible power). Instead, it uses dialogue and example to change attitudes and

beliefs at the level of individuals and communities (invisible power). And it‘s viral. Each

change maker talks to friends and neighbours, and tries to persuade them to change and

become change makers as well.7

According to Selvaranjani Mukkaiah, a We Can Change Maker in Badulla, Sri Lanka,

acquiring ‗power within‘ is life-changing: ―To me change is the killing of fear. For

example, someone may know how to sing but will not sing. Someone or something needs

to kindle the fire in you and kill the fear that stops you from changing. I have killed the

fear of talking and that is a change for me.‖

‗Power within‘ often morphs rapidly into ‗power with‘ and ‗power to‘. In Nepal, women

taking part in Community Discussion Classes (CDCs) moved swiftly from learning to

action. Fed up with being subjected to domestic violence by their drunken husbands,

CDC women in Sorahawa, Bardiya District, decided to impose a 500 Rupee fine (rising

for further offences) on any man who beat his wife or female members of the household

after he had been warned not to do so by the community. ‗Now, our husbands go off

quietly to sleep fearing that they may have to lose face on account of community level

insults and also cough up the fine.‘8

Traditionally leery of ‗politics‘, many NGOs, faith organizations and others over-invest

in individual empowerment, and fail to support the next step from individual to collective

empowerment or take on those who oppress the disempowered through their hidden and

7 We Can Citizen activism case study

8 Raising Her Voice, Nepal Case Study

Page 11: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

11

visible power. Their wariness is understandable: collective action tends to be rather more

unruly than the orderly workshops that are NGOs‘ staple. In fact, before imposing the

fine for domestic violence, several of the Nepalese women‘s groups discussed earlier

decided that the best way to curb their husband‘s alcoholism was to burn down the stores

selling them drink.9

Robert Chambers, one of the most interesting and original thinkers in development, has

come up with a crude but extremely useful way to keep power in mind when going about

your daily business. In any relationship, ask yourself who are the ‗uppers‘ and who the

‗lowers‘10

and how that affects their behaviours. Chambers‘ schema also captures an

awkward fact: what do a congenital wife beater, a devout Christian or Muslim, and a

lifelong trade union or NGO activist have in common? They can all be the same person;

the same individuals can be uppers in one context and lowers in another.

Given power‘s central role in determining both stasis and change, I find its absence from

the development lexicon remarkable. The aid landscape is littered with terms that avoid

the uncomfortable truth that in any relationship, power is seldom distributed fairly.

Apparently neutral words like ‗consultation‘, ‗stakeholders‘, ‗dialogue‘, ‗inclusivity‘

paper over the underlying power dynamics between conflicting interests, which can

determine people‘s capacity even to participate, never mind influence outcomes. The

landmark Paris Declaration on Aid Effectiveness agreed by government aid donors and

recipients in 2005 uses the words partner and partnership 96 times, but power not once.11

Even though donors increasingly accept the futility of pursuing purely technical solutions

that ignore political realities, their increased willingness to discuss politics has still not

extended to talking about power. Instead, there seems an inbuilt tendency (I‘m not sure

whether conscious or unconscious) to rely on formal procedures, often focussed narrowly

on the economics of politics – for example, the way incentives can shape behaviour. Such

‗political economy analysis‘ misses what is distinctively political about politics – power,

interests, agency, ideas, the subtleties of building and sustaining coalitions, and the role

of shocks and accident.12

9 RHV Nepal case study

10 R. Chambers, http://oxfamblogs.org/fp2p/robert-chambers-on-the-fifth-power-the-power-to-

empower/ 11

(Chambers p108) 12

From Political Economy to Political Analysis, David Hudson and Adrian Leftwich, June 2014

Page 12: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

12

I wonder if the reluctance to address power explicitly in the aid world comes from

viewing power as a zero sum game. In some circumstances giving power to some does

mean taking it away from others. Economic power stemming from extreme wealth for

example may be diminished by taxation or regulation. However, the ‗four powers‘ model

shows that is not always the case. As a result of the We Can programme, men reported

marked improvements in their own quality of life from respecting women‘s rights in the

home; unsurprisingly, the sex improved too, according to some.

Of course, women‘s empowerment can also provoke anger and violence in men.

Empowerment is not so much a single event, as a process taking place in a system full of

feedback loops. How the powerful react to the empowerment of ‗lowers‘ can determine

whether conflict or cooperation will ensue.13

Using power analysis

A number of the larger NGOs in the aid world, however, have come to the realisation that

their cherished projects on the ground were at best producing islands of success in a sea

of failure as a result of bad government policies. The futility of promoting ‗livelihoods

projects‘ that help poor communities benefit from markets, when those same markets

were being battered by government debt crises and spending cutbacks, provoked

understandable frustration, and over the past twenty years NGO efforts to change public

policy through advocacy and campaigns have mushroomed.

For these activists, power is a central concern. For them, both the visible-hidden-invisible

scheme and the ‗four powers‘ model can help identify what we do or do not know about a

system, prompting an exploration of pertinent questions, be it Why are small farmers

poor? or Why doesn‘t the government spend more on local schools?

Activists informed by such a power analysis can select a more appropriate strategy by

addressing other questions: Will it be lobbying in the corridors of power, protesting in the

street, or providing low profile, long-term support for grassroots organizations or public

education? Still more questions will sharpen the strategy: Who does the minister or CEO

actually listen to? Is he or she persuaded by research, stories, media coverage or the

opinion of peers? Discussing power in its various forms is also helpful in challenging

assumptions about citizen apathy: Why don‘t they protest more?

13 http://oxfamblogs.org/fp2p/is-power-a-zero-sum-game-does-womens-empowerment-lead-to-

increased-domestic-violence/

Page 13: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

13

Power analysis can also help activists identify a wider range of potential allies. All too

often, we tend to default to working with ‗people like us‘, when alliances with unusual

suspects (corporations, faith leaders, academics) can be more effective. Finally, power

analysis can help us consider on upcoming events that may open the door to change: Is an

election in the offing? What influence would a drought or hurricane have on people‘s

attitudes?

To move from a general exploration of power to specific plans for influencing its

redistribution on any given issue, we need to identify the key players and map where they

stand on the matter at hand: Who are the main actors involved (poor communities,

decision makers, private sector companies)? What other individuals or institutions

(media, religious institutions, intellectuals, traditional leaders) are relevant and

influential? Which are potential allies? Which are blockers? And which are ‗shifters‘,

potentially important players who can be convinced to support the change?

When activists draw up a list of these ‗stakeholders‘, we often initially describe a

sparsely populated landscape (‗the state‘, ‗people‘s organizations‘). However, closer

scrutiny normally uncovers a much more complex ecosystem. In 2014 I asked a group of

Tajik activists and aid workers to list the stakeholders on water and sanitation in a typical

village. Initially they identified only state authorities and villagers‘ water associations,

then one added, ‗Who you turn to depends on the issue: for policy you go to the village

head; for health problems to the doctor; if you have bad dreams, you go to the mullah.‘

The group ended up plotting the influence and level of interest of appointed and elected

village officials, the school principal, mullah, doctor, respected village elders, women‘s

groups, community organizations, state employees, ‗educated people‘ and ‗relatives (and

lovers!) of powerful people‘. All were seen as potential allies in improving the

lamentable provision of water and sanitation.14

Once the actors are identified, we need to discuss:

Alliances: What combination of likely and unlikely allies will maximise the chances of

success? A traditional partnership between activist organizations or relationships with

sympathetic individuals in government ministries or a joint approach with private-sector

companies?

14 village power analysis in Tajikistan

Page 14: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

14

Approach: What is most likely to influence the target individuals and institutions whose

support is needed to bring about change? Does the barrier to change lie in laws and

policies, or in social norms, attitudes and beliefs? Or is the issue rooted in conflicting

interests and thus require political mobilisation to demonstrate clout?

Events: Is change most likely to occur around a specific event, (e.g. an election

campaign, the death of a leader, a natural disaster or an economic crisis)? How do we

prepare for and respond rapidly to the opportunities created by such ‗shocks‘?

Why change doesn’t happen

The questions raised in a power analysis are complicated ones, requiring careful thought,

but they are essential if we are to formulate realistic hypotheses about how a desired

change might occur. Although this book is about ‗how change happens‘, often the

important question is ‗Why doesn’t change happen?‘ I find that one useful way to get at

the roots of the ‗i-word‘ (inertia) is through three other ‗i-words‘: interests, ideas and

institutions. A combination of these often underlies the failure to achieve change, even

when evidence makes a compelling case.

Interests: Systems fail to change because powerful players stand to lose money or status

from the reform, and are adept at blocking it. Especially when a small number of players

stand to lose a lot, whereas a large number of players stand to gain a little, the blockers

are likely to be much better organized than the proponents. Billions of people could

benefit from a reduction in carbon emissions that reduces the threat of climate change,

but they will have to overcome opposition from big fossil fuel companies first.

Ideas: Often inertia is rooted in the conceptions and prejudices held by decision-makers,

even when their own material interest is not at risk. In Malawi, researchers found that

ideas about ‗the poor‘ – the 'deserving' vs. the 'undeserving' poor – had a significant

impact on their willingness to support cash transfers to people living in poverty. The

elites interviewed – which included civil society, religious leaders and academics, as well

as politicians, bureaucrats and private sector leaders – all believed that redistributive

policies make the poor lazy (or lazier). The overwhelming evidence for the effectiveness

of cash transfers made no difference; neither did the fact that the elites stand to lose little

from such reforms (and could even gain electorally, in the case of politicians).15

15 Heather Marquette, pers comms

Page 15: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

15

Institutions: Sometimes the obstacle to change lies in the institutions through which

decisions are made or implemented. Even when no-one in particular benefits materially

from defending the status quo, management systems and corporate culture can be

powerful obstacles to change. Although I love Oxfam dearly, I also wrestle with its

institutional blockages, including multi-layered processes of sign off, and a tendency to

make decisions in ever-expanding loops of emails where it is never clear who has the

final say. I guess I need to work on my internal power analysis.

The glacial pace of progress on climate change illustrates all 3 i‘s to a depressing extent:

vested interests such as fossil fuel companies energetically lobby to frustrate attempts to

reduce carbon emissions and support spurious ‗science‘ to throw mud at the evidence that

underpins the call for action; an unshakable belief in the value of economic growth limits

any attempts to imagine a ‗beyond-growth‘ approach to the economy, and a global

institutional system governed by national politicians with short time horizons is poorly

suited to solving the greatest collective action problem in history.

Conclusion

Walk into any household, village, boardroom or government office, and you will enter a

subtle and pervasive force field of power that links and influences everyone present.

Friends and enemies, parents and children, bosses and employees, rulers and ruled. No

matter the political system, power is always present. As the joke from the Soviet era put

it: Under capitalism, man exploits man. Under socialism, it‘s the other way around.

Studying and understanding that force field is an essential part of trying to influence

change. Though largely invisible to the newcomer, power sets parameters on how social

and political relationships evolve. Who are likely allies or enemies of change? Who are

the uppers and lowers in this relationship? Who listens or defers to whom? How have

they treated each other in the past?

Starting with power should induce a welcome sense of optimism about the possibilities

for change. Many of the great success stories in human progress – universal suffrage,

access to knowledge, freedom from sickness, oppression and hunger, are at their root, a

story of the progressive redistribution of power.

Thinking in terms of power brings the true drama of development to life. In contrast to

the drab portrayal of poor people as passive ‗victims‘ (of disasters, or poverty, or famine)

or as ―beneficiaries‖ (of aid, or social services), ‗empowerment‘ places poor people‘s

own actions centre stage. In the words of Bangladeshi academic Naila Kabeer, ―From a

Page 16: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

16

state of powerlessness that manifests itself in a feeling of ‗I cannot‘; activism contains an

element of collective self-confidence that results in a feeling of ‗We can‘.‖

I have come to believe that ‗power analysis‘ is an essential prerequisite for any conscious

effort to bring about change, and yet is often carried out in a perfunctory way, depicting

an impoverished political landscape (‗them and us‘) that misses any number of potential

allies and tactics to bring about change. Good power analysis needs to tackle power in its

many manifestations – visible, hidden, invisible; power within, with, to and over. It takes

time, and is never complete. Only by grasping the subtleties of power and its constant

flux can we understand and influence the wider system. The next chapter takes us further,

delving into the systems within which power operates, and the ‗systems thinking‘ that can

help us understand social and political change.

Page 17: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

17

2 Complexity changes the way we think about working in systems

‘The future is a dance between patterns and events‘ Embracing Complexity16

‘We will cross the river by feeling the stones under our feet, one by one’ Deng Xiaoping‘s

recipe for China‘s take off

The Arab Spring (and ensuing winter), the 2008 Global Financial Crisis, the fall of the

Berlin Wall: big political changes are often sudden and unforeseeable, despite the false

prophets who pop up to claim that they predicted them all along. Even at a personal level,

change is largely unpredictable: how many of us can say our lives have gone according to

the plans we had as 16-year-olds?

The essential mystery of the future poses a huge challenge to activists. If change is only

explicable in the rear-view mirror, how can we envision, let alone achieve, the future

changes we seek? How can we be sure our proposals for change will make things better,

and not fall victim to the curse of unintended consequences? Of the many concepts

people employ to grapple with such questions, I find ‗systems‘ and ‗complexity‘ two of

the most helpful.

A ‗system‘ is an interconnected set of elements coherently organized in a way that

achieves something. It is more than the sum of its parts: a body is more than an aggregate

of individual cells; a university is not merely an agglomeration of individual students,

professors and buildings; an ecosystem is not just a set of individual plants or animals.17

A defining property of systems is complexity: because of the sheer number of

relationships and feedback loops among its many elements, a system cannot be reduced

to simple chains of cause and effect. Think of a crowd on a city street, or a flock of

starlings wheeling in the sky at dusk. Even with supercomputers, it is impossible to

predict the movement of any given person or starling, but there is order; amazingly few

collisions occur even on the most crowded streets.

16 J. Boulton, P. Allen, C. Bowman, Embracing Complexity: Strategic Perspectives for an Age of Turbulence,

2015 17

Donella Meadows, see Systems – Donella Meadows review

Page 18: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

18

I initially got interested in systems by collecting stories of change while researching my

book From Poverty to Power (2008). In particular, a visit to India‘s Bundelkhand region

to learn how the poor fishing communities of Tikamgarh had won the rights to more than

100 large ponds provided a light-bulb moment on the numerous factors interacting to

create change. First, a technological shift triggered changes in behaviour: the introduction

of new varieties of fish, which made the ponds more profitable, induced landlords to

seize ponds that had been communal. The fishing communities fought back and a series

of violent clashes both radicalised people and built pressure for government action.

Thanks to support from enlightened politicians and NGOs, new laws were passed and the

police amazed everyone by enforcing them. The communities themselves, who

tenaciously faced down a violent campaign of intimidation, were the real heroes of the

story, and they won.18

Why did the various actors in this struggle act as they did? What transformed the relative

power of each? The answers are anything but apparent. Tikamgarh, and similar long

term-lasting transformations such as (see the story of Bolivia‘s Chiquitanos, discussed in

chapter XX), highlighted a basic fact about change: it often only makes sense in the rear

view mirror. Hindsight produces a neat narrative sequence of cause and effect, but in real

time, change is often the highly unpredictable result of the interaction between structures

such as state institutions, the agency of communities and individuals, and the broader

context of shifts in technology, environment, demography or norms.19

The way we commonly think about change often fails to acknowledge the complexity of

social, political and economic systems. Many of the mental models we use are linear – ‗if

A, then B‘ – with profound consequences in terms of failure, frustration and missed

opportunities.

Let me illustrate with a metaphor. Baking a cake is a linear ‗simple‘ system. All I need to

do is find a recipe, buy the ingredients, make sure the oven is working, mix, bake et

voila! Some cakes are better than others (mine wouldn‘t win any prizes), but the basic

approach is fixed, replicable and reasonably reliable. However bad your cake, you‘ll

probably be able to eat it.

18 From Poverty to Power, 2008, p146

19 In From Poverty to Power I developed this concept into a simple model for analysing processes of

change. This book builds on those initial ideas. From Poverty to Power, 2008, Annex A: How Change Happens, p. 432.

Page 19: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

19

Baking a cake is also a fairly accurate metaphor for the approach of many governments,

aid agencies and activist organizations. They decide on a goal (the cake), pick a well-

established method (the recipe), find some partners and allies (the ingredients), and off

they go.

The trouble is that real life rarely bakes like a cake. Engaging a complex system is more

like raising a child. What fate would await your new baby if you decided to go linear and

design a project plan setting out your activities, assumptions, outputs and outcomes for

the next twenty years and then blindly followed it? Nothing good, probably.

Instead, parents make it up as they go along. And so they should. Raising a child is

iterative, endlessly testing your assumptions about right and wrong, constantly adapting

to the evolving nature of the child and his or her relationship with you and others. Despite

all the ‗best practice‘ guides preying on the insecurity of new parents, child-rearing is

devoid of any ‗right way‘ of doing things. What really helps parents is experience (the

second kid is usually easier), and the advice and reassurance of people who‘ve been

through it themselves – ‗mentoring‘ in management speak. Working in complex systems

requires the same kind of iterative, collaborative and flexible approach.

My own relationship with systems thinking is shaped by the neural pathways of my

undergraduate degree in physics: while much of the initial study material was highly

linear in nature (Newtonian mechanics), the course rapidly moved on to the more mind-

bending world of quantum mechanics, wave particle duality, relativity and Heisenberg‘s

uncertainty principle. That background equipped me for subsequently embracing the

ambiguity, unpredictability and complexity that lie at the heart of systems thinking. It is

probably no accident that two of the three authors of the book Embracing Complexity

quoted at the start of this chapter are also lapsed physicists.

Once I began thinking about systems, I started to see complexity and unpredictable

‗emergent change‘ everywhere. The rest of this chapter suggests ways systems thinking

may lead us to act and think differently. Let‘s start with economics.

Page 20: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

20

Systems, economics and development

‘Beware of geeks bearing formulas’ Warren Buffett20

After my initial introduction to systems thinking through discussions with communities

in Tikamgarh and elsewhere, some great books helped me flesh out the ideas. They

included Hernando de Soto‘s Mystery of Capital21

– a brilliant description of how

property rights in successful economies emerge organically from gold rushes and other

economic events, and The Origin of Wealth22

by Eric Beinhocker, which caused me to

completely rethink my view of economics.

Beinhocker argues that back in the nineteenth century, the discipline that became

mainstream economics took a tragic wrong turn when its adherents chose physics rather

than evolution as the basis for its thinking. Its mental models stress stability and

equilibrium (balls in bowls disturbed, then rolling back to rest), whereas real economies

are profoundly unstable. They grow and evolve as technologies rise and fall, firms start

up or go bust, countries wax and wane.

Replace Isaac Newton with Charles Darwin, and economies start to make much more

sense. Firms, ideas and institutions obey the basic mechanisms of evolution. First comes

variation (or differentiation), the endless frenetic churn of human activity, as we attempt

to come up with the next big idea, new technology, trendier restaurant, catchier tune.

Then comes selection: people either like/buy your idea, or they don‘t. Next comes

amplification: if your app is popular, more and more people buy your product, the

company grows and becomes more powerful. And a new round of variation occurs within

the bounds of your successful experiment or as competitors try to wipe you out.

Evolution lies at the heart of what economist Joseph Schumpeter called the ‗creative

destruction‘ of capitalism, and its dynamism explains why the centrally planned

economies in the last century could not compete.

The Origin of Wealth argues that if companies want to survive in such a system, they

should ‗bring evolution inside and get the wheels of differentiation, selection and

amplification spinning within a company. Rather than thinking of strategy as a single

plan built on predictions of the future, we should think of strategy as a portfolio of

20 Annual letter to Shareholders, http://www.nytimes.com/2009/03/01/business/01buffett.html

21 H. de Soto, The Mystery of Capital, 2000

22 E. Beinhocker, The Origin of Wealth, 2005

Page 21: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

21

experiments that competes and evolves over time.‘23

The same reasoning should apply to

activist organizations, and in chapter thirteen I venture some thoughts as to how Oxfam

might do so.24

Systems thinking raises some awkward questions for me regarding economic policy. In

my years doing policy advocacy on trade and globalization, the works of economists like

Ha-Joon Chang and Dani Rodrik had fully convinced me of the need for the state to play

a hands-on role in economic development through some form of industrial policy. Put in

its crudest form, industrial policy boils down to ‗picking winners‘ – as the South Korean

state did when it decided to shift its economy into shipbuilding and then electronics. That

worked in South Korea and a handful of other ‗developmental states‘, but failed in many

others to produce modern, competitive companies because businesses used their

connections to lobby for unwarranted state subsidies and protection from imports. Critics

of industrial policy love to quote the aphorism ‗governments are hopeless at picking

winners, but losers are really good at picking governments‘.

Systems thinking sheds light on these failures. However, it is a short step from accepting

the systems thinking mantra that ‗evolution is cleverer than you are‘25

to arguing in

favour of laissez-faire policies that leaves it entirely up the market what will be produced

and where. Is systems thinking inherently pro-liberalization and anti-state intervention?

In order to embrace Eric must I abandon Ha-Joon?

Going back to issues of power helps square the circle. Even if markets start off with a

‗level playing field‘, they self-organize into complex structures that reward winners and

punish losers in the ‗positive feedback loops‘ that are a common feature of systems. In

the absence of state regulation, markets lead to ever increasing concentration – survival

of the fattest, rather than the fittest – and with it growing polarization and unfairness.26

One role of the state is to keep the playing field as level as possible, for example through

competition policy, ensuring access to information, enhancing general technological

skills or providing credit and other support for small firms to overcome the imbalance of

power. While evolution is blind to the future, states can sometimes see disaster coming,

as in the case of climate change, and take evasive action.

23 Ibid.

24 Link to wrap up chapter

25 Known as Orgel’s Second Rule, after evolutionary biologist Leslie Orgel.

26 Boulton, Allen and Bowman, Embracing Complexity

Page 22: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

22

This suggests that systems thinking is compatible with a broad role for the state in

creating a general legal and political ‗enabling environment‘ to encourage businesses,

avert foreseeable threats and prevent rising inequality. Countries such as Taiwan and

Malaysia have indeed pursued this strategy successfully. But directly picking winners à la

South Korea is much harder to reconcile with a systems approach. How the South Korean

state managed to conduct a successful linear intervention in a complex system, where so

many other governments failed is discussed in more depth in chapter three.

Institutions and complex systems

In complex systems, institutions impose some order on the chaotic push and pull of life.

When well designed, institutions humanize and encourage the dynamism of systems,

without stifling them. They moderate the harsher edges of Darwinism, and ensure that the

system retains diversity and innovation, rather than falling prey to monopoly and

stagnation.

Institutions not only regulate and moderate complexity, but are shaped by it. On closer

inspection, states and other institutions that may initially look like monoliths from the

outside, exhibit a high degree of internal complexity and some unpredictability. The life

of institutions is also influenced by a characteristic feature of change in complex systems:

it is often discontinuous, with periods of slow change punctuated by spikes of disorder

and transformation. For people on the receiving end, such ‗shocks‘ can be traumatic –

wars, financial crises and natural disasters exert a terrible human toll. But historically,

they have also been a fertile breeding ground for institutional renewal.

Much of the institutional framework we take for granted today was born of the trauma of

the Great Depression and World War II. The disastrous failures of policy that led to these

twin catastrophes profoundly affected the thinking of political and economic leaders

across the world, triggering a vastly expanded role for government in managing the

economy and addressing social ills as well as precipitating the decolonization of large

parts of the globe.

Similarly, in the 1970s the sharp rise in oil prices (and consequent economic stagnation

and runaway inflation) marked the end of the post-war ‗Golden Age‘ and gave rise to a

turn away from government regulation and to the idealization of the ‗free market‘. Even

in sclerotic Communist systems, shocks have led the way to radical shifts. In Vietnam,

for example, the near collapse of the economy in the 1980s led to a China-style swing

towards the market, known as Doi Moi (discussed in chapter XX).

Page 23: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

23

Previously unthinkable reforms and transformations become possible when social,

political or economic relations are disrupted by crisis. At the popular level, crises can

trigger mass movements demanding change. Political leaders are forced to question their

long-held assumptions about what constitutes ‗sound‘ policies, and are more willing to

take the risks associated with innovation, as the status quo suddenly appears less worth

defending.

Naomi Klein, in her 2007 book The Shock Doctrine,27

argues that the Right has

traditionally used shocks much better than the Left, especially in recent decades. Milton

Friedman, the father of monetarist economics, wrote: ‗Only a crisis – actual or perceived

– produces real change. When that crisis occurs, the actions that are taken depend on the

ideas that are lying around. That, I believe, is our basic function: to develop alternatives

to existing policies, to keep them alive and available until the politically impossible

becomes politically inevitable‘.28

Klein cites the example of the way proponents of private education managed to turn even

Hurricane Katrina to their advantage: ‗Within 19 months, New Orleans‘ public school

system had been almost completely replaced by privately run charter schools.‘ According

to the American Enterprise Institute ‗Katrina accomplished in a day what Louisiana

school reformers couldn‘t do after years of trying.‘

NGOs are not always so nimble in spotting and seizing such opportunities. Three months

into the 2011 Egyptian Revolution, I attended a meeting of Oxfam International‘s CEOs,

at which the initial debate was over whether the uprising in Tahrir Square was likely to

lead to a humanitarian crisis. Only after some hours did the penny drop that the protests,

upheaval and overthrow of an oppressive regime was also a huge potential opportunity, at

which point the assembled big cheeses showed admirable speed in allocating budgets for

supporting civil society activists in Egypt, and backing it up with advocacy at the Arab

League and elsewhere. But by then valuable months had already passed; soon the

optimism of Revolution gave way to the violence and misery of repression.

Some progressive activists engaged in policy advocacy are better attuned to Milton

Friedman‘s lesson. Within weeks of the appalling Rana Plaza factory collapse in

Bangladesh that killed over 1,100 people in April 2013, an international ‗Accord on Fire

27 N. Klein, The Shock Doctrine, 2007

28 Friedman, Capitalism and Freedom, ix

Page 24: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

24

and Building Safety in Bangladesh‘29

was signed and delivered.30

A five-year legally

binding agreement between global companies, retailers and trade unions, the Accord

mandates some astounding breakthroughs: an independent inspection program supported

by the brand-name companies and involving workers and trade unions; the public

disclosure of all factories, inspection reports and corrective action plans; a commitment

by signatory brands to fund improvements and maintain sourcing relationships;

democratically elected health and safety committees in all factories; and worker

empowerment through an extensive training program, complaints mechanism and the

right to refuse unsafe work.

Several factors help explain how this particularly grisly ‗shock as opportunity‘ drove

rapid movement toward better regulation:

A forum on labour rights in Bangladesh (the Ethical Trading Initiative) had

already built a high degree of trust between traditional antagonists (companies,

unions and NGOs). Trust allowed people to get on the phone to each other right

away.

Prior work, ongoing on since 2011, had sketched the outline of a potential accord;

the Rana Plaza disaster massively escalated the pressure to act on it.

A nascent national process (the National Action Plan for Fire Safety) gave

outsiders something to support and build on.

Energetic leadership from two new international trade

unions (IndustriAll and UNI Global Union) helped get the right people in the

room.

Thus, perhaps we should add to Friedman‘s dictum to keep alternatives alive and available:

progressive activists also need to build trust and connections among the key individuals who

could implement the desired change.

The world is complex – so what?

Many activists are, above all, doers, keen to change the world, starting today. They

instinctively reject the first lesson of systems thinking: look long and hard before you

leap. They get itchy with anything that smacks of ivory tower ‗beard stroking‘ and worry

29 http://bangladeshaccord.org/

30 http://oxfamblogs.org/fp2p/will-horror-and-over-a-thousand-dead-be-a-watershed-moment-for-

bangladesh/

Page 25: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

25

about ‗analysis paralysis‘. I think they are wrong. My advice would be to take a deep

breath, put your sense of urgency to one side for a moment, and become a ‗reflectivist‘

who, in the words of Ben Ramalingam, ‗maps, observes, and listens to the system to

identify the spaces where change is already happening and try to encourage and nurture

them.‘31

That said, another lesson of systems thinking is that you cannot understand and plan

everything in advance. Systems thinking prizes learning by doing and failing. It is not

another blueprint or set of best-practice guidelines – in fact, it shows that tick-box

approaches are unlikely to be of much use. If each situation is different, so must be the

response. In a phrase that has repeatedly popped into my head when writing this book,

one of the founders of systems thinking, Donella Meadows, talks of the need to learn to

‗dance with systems.‘32

Thinking in systems makes for some surprising principles for how to bring about change:

Relinquish control: A traditional command-and-control stance is ill-suited to complex

systems: it reduces diversity, stifles innovation and adaptability, and slows down

response times to changing circumstances. A default option of ‗don‘t control unless there

is good reason to do so‘ may be more productive than the more common ‗control unless

there is a reason not to‘.

Seek fast and ongoing feedback: If you don‘t know what is going to happen, you have

to detect changes in real time, especially when the windows of opportunity around such

changes are short-lived. That means having (or developing) acute antennae, embedded in

multiple networks, to pick up signals of change and transmit them to your organization.

Be flexible: Your organization‘s culture should thank the staff who alert it to such signals

of change, and should be ready to shelve the previous plan in order to respond to

emerging events. In the world of humanitarian response, this approach is standard,

whereas in long-term aid programmes or campaigns people are often reluctant to shift

gears, or simply unaware that new opportunities have opened up.

Celebrate failure: In a complex system, it is highly unlikely you will get things right from

the outset, or that they will stay right (think back to raising a child). You and your

colleagues have to be ready to discuss and learn from failure, rather than sweep it under the

31 Ramalingam, ‘Aid on the Edge of Chaos’

32 ‘Thinking in Systems’, by Donella Meadows

Page 26: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

26

carpet. Fast feedback on your own impact is thus just as important as feedback on the world

outside, not least to detect unintended consequences – if people are keeping chickens in the

latrines you are building, you probably need to go back to the drawing board.33

Improve your rules of thumb: When the US Marines go into combat (an archetypal

complex system), they use rules of thumb (stay in contact, take the high ground, keep

moving) rather than detailed ‗best-practice guidelines‘. Activists do too (Have we thought

about gender? What is the government doing?), but these are often tacit, and so are not

questioned, tested or improved upon.

Undertake multiple parallel experiments: Activists hate failure – no-one wants to think

they‘ve wasted their time, or wake up to newspaper headlines about money lost or

‗wasted‘ on failed projects. Compare this risk aversion to a venture capitalist who backs

ten projects knowing that nine will fail, and he or she will make enough money on the

tenth to more than compensate for the rest.

Convene and broker relationships: One positive outcome of applying systems thinking

to a failed approach is insight into who might be better positioned to devise a successful

one. Bringing dissimilar local players together to find their own solutions is a useful role

for foreign aid organizations. Effective convening and brokering requires understanding

who should be invited to the table: Which players have, or could have, their hands on the

levers of change? Providing them with a space for interchange outside of their home

institutions encourages them to think in new ways.

Focus on positive deviance: Achieving successful change in complex systems is

inherently hard to plan or predict, since multiple interactions and feedback loops produce

a spread of positive and negative results. Identifying and studying results that are

particularly good or particularly bad works with the grain of such a system, and can shine

a light on the road to follow.

If this advice sounds a bit abstract, here are four examples of development projects that

put systems thinking into practice.

33 Tim Harford, in his book Adapt: Why Success Always Starts with Failure, proposes a ‘three step recipe

for successful adapting: try new things, in the expectation that some will fail; make failure survivable, because it will be common; and make sure that you know when you have failed…… distinguishing success from failure, oddly, can be the hardest task of all’.

Page 27: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

27

Chukua Hatua (‗take action‘ in Swahili) is an Oxfam project in Tanzania explicitly

modelled on evolutionary theory, aimed at improving the accountability of local

authorities to their citizens. In the first phase, lots of different hares were set loose, from

‗farmer animators‘ organizing peasant communities to engage with their village

committees, to ‗active musicians‘ spreading the word about the benefits of participation

to primary school student councils which give children a first taste of activism. The

project agreed in advance that this experiment in variation would be followed at a

predetermined date by selection, in which communities, partners and Oxfam staff sat

down and identified the most successful variants – farmer animators proved the most

promising. These were then expanded, and further tweaks and variations encouraged.

Initial results are impressive.34

A group of ‗development entrepreneurs‘ in the Philippines,35

set up by The Asia

Foundation pursues reforms in education, taxation, civil aviation regulation and property

rights by working in small teams (echoing Amazon‘s Jeff Bezos: ‗If it takes more than

two pizzas to feed the team, it is too big‘). The teams comprise a leader, technical

analysts (e.g. lawyers), lobbyists with good political skills and networks, and ‗insiders‘

with deep knowledge and experience in the reform area (e.g. former civil servants). Such

teams can respond rapidly to events and new opportunities, making a number of ‗small

bets‘ and then dropping the experiments that go nowhere.

Every two months, Oxfam‘s TajWSS project to improve Tajikistan‘s dismal water and sanitation

systems (mentioned in chapter one), convenes everyone involved: 17 government ministries and

agencies, several UN bodies, international NGOs, aid agencies, academics, journalists, Tajik civil

society organizations, private companies and parliamentarians. Rather than a master plan, the

freewheeling discussion of this motley grouping has given birth to innovative partial solutions.

For example, local officials have found companies willing to help with local chlorination and

local banks to help finance water systems. But its biggest victory so far is a new Water Law that

establishes who is in charge, who is responsible for regulation, who is the service provider.

According to TajWSS activist Ghazi Kelani ‗We didn‘t draft it – it has been there for years in

34 Ref Chukua Hatua paper published version

35 http://oxfamblogs.org/fp2p/is-this-the-best-paper-yet-on-doing-development-differentlythinking-and-

working-politically/

Page 28: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

28

somebody‘s drawer. The network raised the importance of having a law, someone dug it up and

we decided it was good enough for a start.‘36

In his book on systems thinking and aid, Ben Ramalingam recounts a classic case of

‗positive deviance‘ from Vietnam. In December 1991, Jerry and Monique Sternin arrived

in Vietnam to work in four communities with 2,000 under-three year olds, 63 per cent of

whom were malnourished. The Sternins sent teams of volunteers to observe in homes

where children were poor but well-fed, and found that in every case, the mother or father

was collecting a number of tiny shrimps, crabs, or snails – making for a portion ‗the size

of one joint of one finger‘ – from the rice paddies and adding these to the child‘s diet.

The positive deviant families also instructed the home babysitter to feed the child four or

even five times a day, in contrast to most families who fed young children only before

parents headed to the rice fields early in the morning and in the late afternoon after

returning from a working day. Results were shared on a board in the town hall, and the

charts quickly became a focus of attention and buzz. A few short weeks later, some 40

per cent of the children had already been fully rehabilitated, and a further 20 per cent

were well on the way. By the end of the first year, half the children had participated and

80 per cent were rehabilitated.

Conclusion

I believe activists should conceive of the arena of their work, be it a village, a city, an

institution or a country as a complex system, pervaded by relations of power. To achieve

change we need to enhance our understanding of that system, and then shape our actions

to fit. We need to work at grasping the history and inner workings of whatever

community, issue or institution we are trying to influence. Then we must use that

understanding to analyse how those players interact, and regularly update that power

analysis. We need to build relationships with all those involved in driving (or blocking)

change. Finally, we must become comfortable with ambiguity and uncertainty, while

maintaining the energy and determination to succeed.

Incorporating systems thinking into our activism will require a profound overhaul in the

way most of us think, feel and act. It won‘t be easy, but it is entirely possible, as I hope I

have shown. Once we learn to ‗dance with the system‘, no other partner will do.

36 Ref my TajWSS case study – need to publish it as background paper

Page 29: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

29

The themes in these first two chapters on power and systems will resurface regularly in

the remaining chapters of this book. Next, we examine the institutions that operate in

such systems, starting with the state.

Page 30: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

30

3 How states change

Kabuya Muhemeri, the young chef de poste in the dusty and periodically bloody town of

Kitchanga in the Eastern Congo, whom I mentioned in chapter one, sits at the bottom of

the official pecking order. Though he works out of a wood cabin with a tin roof, a rough

floor of volcanic rubble and no glass in the windows, he is part of a monumental edifice

that shapes the fates and futures of the world‘s peoples: the state.

The German philosopher Georg Hegel described the state as a ‗work of art‘. If not art,

these gigantic enterprises are certainly works of conscious design, collective

manifestations of the human imagination.37

To a greater or lesser degree, states ensure the

provision of health, education, water, and sanitation; they guarantee rights, security, the

rule of law, and social and economic stability; they arbitrate in the inevitable disputes

between individuals and groups; they regulate, develop, and upgrade the economy; they

organize the defence of national territory.

Looking around the developing world today, strong states like China, Rwanda or Ethiopia

are producing growth and prosperity. More inclusive states, such as Indonesia, Ghana or

Bolivia, may be less stellar in economic terms, but their peoples enjoy a wider range of

rights and freedoms. The worst deprivation and suffering often coincide with states that

are weak and therefore unable to guarantee basic security, services or freedom: in

Somalia, South Sudan and the Eastern Congo state failure has condemned millions of

people to poverty, violence and premature death.

My own views on the state have evolved from indifference to hostility to admiration.

Growing up in 1970s Britain, I was surrounded by a state languishing in the midst of

stagflation, industrial unrest and an aura of historical decline. Everything exciting (anti-

nuclear protests, the burgeoning environmental and feminist movements, the cathartic

anarchism of punk) was happening outside the channels of government. The state was

boring and I took it for granted. Living in Chile and Argentina in the early 1980s, I saw a

far bleaker picture: beribboned dictators in sunglasses, and friends in permanent pain

over the whereabouts of their ‗disappeared‘ relatives.

37 G. Mulgan, op. cit.

Page 31: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

31

Later in the decade, I moved to Nicaragua before the sheen came off the Sandinista

revolution, and saw the upsurge in social and economic freedoms a progressive state

could achieve. Then writing about Latin America‘s slide into debt crisis and ill-conceived

liberalizing market reforms in the 1980s and 1990s, I was struck by the contrast between

the continent‘s long-term economic malaise and the state-driven ‗Asian Miracle‘ of East

Asia‘s tiger economies. Friendship and collaboration with Korean economist Ha-Joon

Chang completed my conversion to the positive role of the state in development, which

led to the focus on ‗effective states‘ in my 2008 book, From Poverty to Power.

States may be ubiquitous, but they are far from static. A constant process of conflict and

bargaining shapes their contours and responsibilities. This chapter briefly reviews the

ways in which states drive change in society and how states themselves change. Later

chapters will look at how activists can in turn influence states.

How do states drive change?

States influence the lives of their citizens through laws, rules and policies, decisions on

taxation and spending and public messaging that influences norms and beliefs. In

ministries, town halls, courtrooms and central banks, the machinery of states grinds

relentlessly on, in stark contrast to the peaks and troughs of other drivers of change, such

as war and protest. Here are a few ways states can help empower people:

Regulate and upgrade the economy to deliver inclusive, pro-poor growth that

liberates them from hunger and want and provides them with the means to acquire

education, voice and agency;

Provide access to quality healthcare, education, water and sanitation, along with

some form of social protection;

Guarantee the rights and voice of poor and excluded groups so that the benefits of

economic growth trickle down;

Create an enabling institutional environment for empowerment, for example

through legislation that facilitates organizing and access to information, or

through decentralization and other participatory governance reforms, or through

easing access to communications technologies;

Guarantee the right to vote, access to justice and a free media also enhances the

enabling environment;

Respond positively when poor people exercise their voice, agency and desire to

organize, rather than attempt to suppress them.

Page 32: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

32

Naturally there is a gulf between what states can do in theory and what they actually do

in practice. History can help elucidate why some states pursue the public good, while

others behave like ‗stationary bandits‘,38

and most lie somewhere in between.

How states have evolved

In evolutionary terms, states are a comparatively recent addition to the family and kinship

groups that have been the basic building block of human society since homo sapiens

emerged from Africa some 100,000 years ago. China was the first to create a

recognizably modern state, in the shape of the uniform, merit-based bureaucracy in the

third century BC. By contrast, modern states did not emerge in Europe until some 2,000

years later, following two centuries of wars that whittled 500 political entities down into

a couple of dozen nation states.39

States rise and fall; prolonged periods of institutional inertia are punctuated by crises and

sudden change. Over time, however, states have expanded, both in remit and size.40

States that once confined themselves to conscripting and taxing their citizens now seek to

influence many aspects of their lives. In 1870, states typically absorbed around 11 per

cent of GDP in developed countries. This rose to 28 per cent in 1960 and 42 per cent in

2006.41

In his monumental history of the state,42

Francis Fukuyama argues that ‗the miracle of

modern politics‘ lies in achieving an uneasy balance between three pillars: effective

centralized administration (civil service), the rule of law (courts) and accountability

mechanisms (elected government and parliamentary oversight). Adopting that

framework, this chapter discusses the civil service, and subsequent ones will cover the

law and democracy.

Balance among these three elements is a miracle because they are often in conflict – for

example, central administrations seek to maximise their power, while courts and

38 M. Olson, Dictatorship, Democracy, and Development, The American Political Science Review, Vol. 87,

No. 3 (Sep., 1993), pp. 567-576 39

Fukuyama, 2011, p19 & 328 40 ADD STATS FOR LT GROWTH OF SPENDING/GDP IN RICH COUNTRIES, AND SPREAD

TODAY BETWEEN HICS, MICS AND LICS

41 OECD in Figures 2007.

42 Fukuyama, 2011 and 2014

Page 33: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

33

parliaments seek to limit it. Societies have also always wrestled with a tendency for the

efficient ‗impersonal‘ bureaucracies that characterize effective states to backslide, as civil

servants, judges and politicians seek to capture the benefits of power for themselves, their

families and friends.

Fukuyama argues that the UK in the nineteenth century was the first to put in place a

balance of all three pillars. He also finds comfort in the history of the US, which suffered

mind-boggling levels of patronage and corruption in the nineteenth century, yet in the

fifty years prior to World War II managed to turn the US government into a relatively

effective bureaucracy.

Drivers of change

The evolution of modern states has taken centuries, in a tortured and often bloody process

far removed from the staid world of technocratic ‗state building‘ promoted by today‘s aid

donors. Historically, war has been one of the great drivers of state evolution; in the words

of social historian Charles Tilly, ‗war made the state and the state made war‘.43

The first

proper state was forged amid carnage on the battlefields of China, and a similar

bloodbath gave birth to modern European states and many others across the globe.

War posed existential threats that forced elites to pool their efforts, accept restraints on

their individual power, and embrace change. It led to the introduction and expansion of

taxation, which in turn required a state bureaucracy to collect and administer the revenue.

And it laid the foundation for a social contract between citizen and state based on

security: the former provided soldiers and money in return for for the latter‘s protection.

The two world wars of the twentieth century vastly expanded the obligations of citizens

and states to each other.

Wars (or the threat of them) are one example of what the economists Daron Acemoglu

and James A. Robinson call ‗critical junctures‘44

, major events that also include

epidemics (the Black Death transformed Europe‘s economy in the fourteenth century)

and financial meltdowns. Another such juncture is a ‗resource shock‘ that finances a

feeding frenzy (as in Nigeria), a period of boom and prosperity (as in Botswana) or a

cycle of overspending, indebtedness and financial crisis (as seems to be happening in

Ghana after its recent oil finds).

43 Tilly, 1990: 54

44 Acemoglu and Robinson, ‘Why Nations Fail’, p101

Page 34: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

34

Critical junctures act as catalysts of change, rearranging the patterns of alliances and

allegiances that underpin political order, but also transforming ideas on everything from

the role of the state in providing welfare to the rights of women or African Americans

(both strongly influenced by World War II).

Longer term, less visible processes than war also create evolutionary pressures on the

state. Economic growth can create new poles of power: it can throw up new entrants to

elites, who demand preferential policies. And it can lay the basis for new social

movements, such as burgeoning middle classes, who demand civil rights and denounce

corruption, or trade unions and urban slum dwellers who fight for improved state services

and livelihoods.

Based on his observations in several Mexican municipalities, political scientist Jonathan

Fox found that progress depended on a cycle of conflict and cooperation – a conflict

would break out, and then a more progressive section of local state officials would talk to

more approachable protest leaders and a period of reform would ensue. When those

reforms ran out of steam, or new issues emerged, conflict would re-emerge and the cycle

would begin again, a process he described as ‗interaction between the thickening of civil

society and state reformist initiatives‘.45

Another polisci guru, Sidney Tarrow, sees a

similar dynamic of repression, partial victories leading to reform, and demobilisation,

repeating itself in Europe over the last two centuries.46

Even the most repressive states cannot ignore such movements for long. Confucius wrote

that every ruler needs arms, food and trust, but that if any of these had to be forfeited, the

first two should be given up before the last. Even unelected governments need a degree of

trust to do their day-to-day work. Without it laws will more often be evaded and broken,

taxes harder to raise, and information harder to gather.

Highly conservative state institutions that resist change even when the world around them

has long moved on lose effectiveness and legitimacy. Blatant patronage can have the

same effect. In Liberia years of entrenched corruption had so eroded the public trust that

even dire warnings about Ebola‘s lethal contagion were seen as a cynical attempt to

solicit and ‗eat‘ international donations.47

Fukuyama ends his history of the state with an

45 Jonathan Fox, Accountability Politics: Power and Voice in Rural Mexico, OUP, 2007

46 Sidney Tarrow, Power in Movement: Social Movements and Contentious Politics, 2

nd ed, 1998

47 http://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/monkey-cage/wp/2015/08/07/ebolas-rapid-spread-terrified-

us-a-year-ago-what-did-it-teach-us-about-west-africa/

Page 35: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

35

impassioned denunciation of US ‗vetocracy‘, paralyzed by vested interests. Left to fester,

such decay acts like the build-up of pressures in the earth‘s crust preceding an

earthquake.

Although the more tangible crises, protests and conflicts understandably draw our

attention, most political change happens through deals behind closed doors that seek to

accommodate change and avert mass violence. South Africa‘s transition to non-racial

democracy involved a wide range of pacts, deals and ‗accords‘ struck between major

political forces, as well as powerful economic interests, the labour movement and civil

society groups.

The lessons history can provide regarding how states arise, evolve and ultimately decay

are of more than academic interest, as the 2003 invasion of Iraq graphically

demonstrated. A profoundly ahistorical assumption – that democracy and a market

economy would miraculously fill the vacuum left by the removal of Saddam Hussein and

his regime – underpinned the invasion. In both blood and treasure, that error carried a

high price the world continues to pay.

The impact of colonialism

Successive waves of European colonization had a significant impact in shaping the

evolution of states in today‘s developing countries. Britain, France, Spain, the

Netherlands and others took over existing states or created new ones where none had

previously existed. In Latin America Spain usurped the militarist state structures of the

Aztec and Incan Empires in order to rule over their conquered subjects, leaving a legacy

of hierarchical unresponsive bureaucracies.

Similarly, in prized Asian colonies such as India or Singapore, whose wealth and trade

underwrote the British Empire and Britain‘s industrialization, the colonisers invested

significantly in the national army and civil service to suit their purposes, institutions that

lived on after independence. China and East Asia‘s long history of strong states provided

a basis for rebuilding upon decolonization. Africa was another story; the pillage of its

people by the slave trade required no state institutions and, with the exception of South

Africa, the continent appeared to offer little wealth and myriad difficulties for the

colonizers. As a result, the Europeans opted for indirect rule with few settlers and fewer

Page 36: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

36

state institutions. The least developed parts of the world today are those that lacked either

strong indigenous state institutions or transplanted settler-based ones.48

The state today

Nearly all developing countries reflect the dynamic interplay of ancient political

traditions and those imposed by European colonizers. Each state is unique and any

typology is inevitably unsatisfactory, because particular states tick more than box, move

between categories over time, or because different regions within a state behave in

different ways. Nevertheless, I find it helpful to think of today‘s developing country

states in three broad groupings, which I call developmental states, patrimonial states and

fragile/conflict affected states.

Developmental states have an effective centralized state apparatus, but often suffer from

weak rule of law and low levels of accountability or democracy. Many of them emerged

where state institutions pre-date European takeover (Japan, Mexico, China) or where

European institutions fully displaced native ones (South Africa, Argentina, Uruguay,

Brazil, Cuba). Over the last fifty years, developmental states like South Korea, Taiwan,

Singapore and Malaysia made huge strides in terms of economic growth and poverty

reduction. These latter four are closest to the classical description of the state set out by

the German sociologist Max Weber, namely an efficient, merit-based civil service that

manages to avoid capture by vested interests and guides the national economy in a

process of sustained upgrading. Some observers include Botswana, Rwanda, Ethiopia and

Chile in the category.

There is some overlap between developmental states and the ones I call ‗patrimonial,‘

which bear very little resemblance to the Weberian ideal. These are deeply inefficient,

with high levels of patronage and corruption, as officials and leaders put self and kin

before citizens and country. Such states lie along a spectrum from vampire to ruminant:

at one extreme, corrupt governments suck the blood out of the economy and give nothing

back; at the other end a degree of ‗eating‘ at least produces something useful.

The third grouping of ‗fragile and conflict affected states‘ can barely control the national

territory, or are wracked by conflict and violence. There, nothing seems to work, public

services are negligible, the rule of law practically nonexistent. Citizens do not even enjoy

the basic right not to be shot by marauding armed gangs. Over the course of this century,

48 F. Fukuyama, Political Order and Political Decay, 2014, p33

Page 37: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

37

such states will be home to an increasing proportion of the world‘s people living in

poverty and therefore a growing focus for aid agencies.

The world in which today‘s states operate is also changing fast. In some ways, traditional

nation states are becoming too small for the big things, and too big for the small things.

The ‗big things‘ – problems without passports such as climate change, migration,

international criminal networks or tax evasion – have been pushed upwards to regional

and global bodies such as the EU, African Union or UN. At the same time, ‗small things‘

like public services and policing have been pushed downward to municipal and

provincial levels. Cities in Colombia or South Africa are starting to look like ‗municipal

developmental states‘.49

Anyone thinking about how states drive change, or can in turn be

influenced, needs to understand how these different tiers function and influence each

other.

When and how are today’s states changing?

Economic growth and war continue to be primary drivers of state change. Economic

growth creates expectations of change, both among booming middle classes that resent

restrictions on freedom of expression, and among workers and peasants who seek a fairer

distribution of income. The 1980s famine and civil war preceded Ethiopia‘s economic

takeoff under Prime Minister Meles Zenawi; an economic meltdown triggered Vietnam‘s

Doi Moi reforms;50

and Rwanda‘s 1994 genocide and civil war led to the country‘s

remarkable transformation under the autocratic rule of Paul Kagame.

While many pressures contribute to political transitions (involvement of opposition

political parties or the military, foreign intervention, and so on) the presence of strong

and cohesive non-violent civic coalitions has proven vital in recent years. Since the

1980s, successive waves of civil society protest contributed to the overthrow of military

governments across Latin America, the downfall of Communist and authoritarian regimes

in Eastern Europe and Central Asia, the removal of dictators in the Philippines and

Indonesia, the end of apartheid in South Africa, and the upheavals of the Arab Spring.

Tactics have included boycotts, mass protests, blockades, strikes, and civil disobedience.

Over the last thirty years aid agencies and international financial institutions have

devoted considerable attention to changing state institutions, but their efforts to drive

49 http://oxfamblogs.org/fp2p/are-progressive-cities-the-key-to-solving-our-toughest-global-challenges/

50 http://oxfamblogs.org/fp2p/how-does-change-happen-in-vietnam/

Page 38: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

38

‗good governance‘ have met with few successes. Governments with no intention of

abandoning patronage politics have often run rings around well-intentioned donors,

passing rules and creating institutions that look good on paper, but are in practice entirely

cosmetic. At one point, Uganda had the best anti-corruption laws in the world, (it scored

99/100 in one league table), yet came 126th

in the 2008 Transparency International

Corruption Perceptions Index.51

Some academics claim the failure of aid-financed state reform is due to Western donors‘

tendency to graft liberal-democratic and free-market institutions onto countries with very

different traditions.52

And in fact successful cases reformed not by following some

Washington or London-decreed ‗best practice‘, but by creating hybrid institutions that

combine elements of traditional, nationally specific institutions with good ideas from

outside.

Here is an example from French-speaking West Africa, where many Muslim parents

pulled their children out of secular schools and sent them to private religious schools.

After vainly attempting to suppress the flourishing parallel world of private education,

the governments of Mali, Niger and Senegal decided instead to ‗go with the grain‘ by

bringing unofficial schools more squarely into the formal state system and at the same

time reforming the official system by introducing religious education in state schools.

Preliminary indications suggest that the success rate of the hybrid schools is as good as or

better than that of the previous French-style schools.53

According to Harvard‘s Matt

Andrews, such hybrid solutions are best sought by local interests; outsiders can help

identify, highlight and explore problems and create opportunities for local actors to find

their own locally relevant solutions.54

Conclusion

States are ramshackle institutions; in fact, they are families of institutions, each of which

has its own procedures, norms and values. Even the most apparently monolithic

dictatorship is on closer inspection, nothing of the sort. The solidity of presidential

51 UPDATE

52 D Booth and D Cammack, Governance for Development in Africa, 2013, p123

53 http://oxfamblogs.org/fp2p/harnessing-religion-to-improve-education-in-africa/ The reforms have not

exacerbated gender imbalances. At primary school level, for example, girls outnumber boys, sometimes significantly. 54

M. Andrews, Limits to Institutional Reform in Development,

Page 39: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

39

palaces and halls of the people is in fact ephemeral, built upon the shifting sands of

legitimacy and events. When I lived in Argentina, the military dictatorship appeared

impregnable, yet within a few short years economic crisis eroded its middle class support

and military defeat in the Falklands led to its downfall.

States exemplify the challenges of complexity. The interactions, alliances and disputes

between politicians and civil servants, between one ministry and another, or between

different tiers of government, and how each of them in turn respond to citizen demand

and other external pressures, provide the political landscape upon which decisions are

made. Learning to ‗dance with the system‘, understanding how decisions are made, how

power, both formal and informal is distributed and shifts over time, is an essential first

step for anyone wishing to influence the state.

In democracies, two key structures provide entry points for citizens into the labyrinth of

state politics: the courts and political parties. We turn to them now.

Page 40: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

40

4 Courts and the rule of law55

A couple of years ago, I visited a homeless shelter next to Nigambodh Ghat, the main

crematorium in central Delhi, the capital of India. The shelter was built on the banks of

the polluted Yamuna River, on land shunned by other residents, due to the clouds of

smoke from burning bodies rising from the open-air pyres next door. While those flames

lit up the night, a hundred men of all ages sat cross-legged on their sleeping mats, talking

to charismatic activist Harsh Mander about depression and drug rehab. They all seem to

be drunk or high, which made the meeting slightly nerve wracking.

Inhospitable as the shelter seemed, it provided these homeless men with a place to sleep

and a fixed address. After the meeting, Harsh, who is also commissioner to the Supreme

Court on the right to food, roped me in to hand out passbooks. Tomorrow, clutching their

proof of address (even if it does say ‗homeless shelter‘) they will all go down to the bank

to open accounts. In a month‘s time they will get biometric ID cards, the digital gateways

to rations, cash transfers and an official identity.

The shelter exists because in 2011 the Indian Supreme Court decreed that there should be

one homeless shelter for every 100,000 residents. According to Harsh the Supreme Court

is the most effective arm of government on social policy. ‗I‘d been talking to government

for years on homelessness without result. I wrote a letter to the Supreme Court saying

people were dying in the Delhi winter, and this is the result.‘

India made me rethink my attitude to the law (and most lawyers), which had previously

seemed a stupefying combination of boring procedures and alienating language. It‘s

worth thinking about what happens in its absence. No-one has captured that better than

Thomas Hobbes, in The Leviathan, published in 1651:

‗Without Law there is no place for Industry, because the fruit thereof is uncertain; and

consequently no Culture of the Earth, no Navigation, nor use of the commodities that

may be imported by sea; no commodious Building, no instruments of moving and

removing such things as require much force; no Knowledge of the face of the Earth, no

account of Time, no Arts, no Letters, no Society; and which is worst of all, continual fear

55 SHOULD THIS CHAPTER INCLUDE MORE ON INTERNATIONAL LAW AND HOW IT DIFFERS/INFLUENCES

NATIONAL SYSTEMS?

Page 41: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

41

and danger of violent death; and the life of people, solitary, poor, nasty, brutish and

short.‘

Even before meeting Harsh, my lightbulb moment came when a young Spanish lawyer,

explained to me, ‗You must understand, the state sees the world through the eyes of the

law‘. Her words have stuck with me, giving meaning to those endless news items on

judicial reviews, test cases and supreme-court rulings: the law is how the state sees the

world, how it learns and how it evolves.

In most wealthy countries, the law is taken for granted. It protects rights, imposes duties,

and sets a framework for the conduct of almost every social, political and economic

activity. It punishes offenders, compensates the injured and enforces agreements. In

addition, it endeavours to guarantee justice, promote freedom, uphold the rule of law and

provide security.

In many developing countries, things are rather messier. Courts and lawyers are often in

the pockets of wealthy elites, and the laws themselves are structured to protect the

privileged. What‘s more, formal legal systems coexist with ‗customary law‘, a

community-level justice system not codified by the state, that derives its legitimacy from

local mores, values and traditions. Customary law regulates important aspects of daily

life, such as access to land and water, and family issues such as inheritance and marriage.

For many poor communities, customary systems are physically more accessible, use

familiar procedures and language, and are more affordable than the lawyers, fees and

bribes of the courts. According to the World Bank, in Sierra Leone, about 85 percent of

the population fell under customary law as of 2003, while customary tenure affects 90

percent of land transactions in Mozambique and Ghana.56

But, like any other institution, customary law reflects imbalances in power and reinforces

existing hierarchies: elites turn it to their advantage and it typically excludes women and

other marginalized groups. English legal traditions, now in use across the English-

speaking world, evolved out of such a customary system (known as ‗common law‘).

Spanish and French legal traditions, (in use throughout their former colonies) in contrast,

were imposed by centralized dictatorships that sought to eradicate local customary law.

56 WDR 2006

Page 42: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

42

Like many institutions that at first sight appear fixed and monolithic, the law is in

constant flux. Not only are old laws replaced by new, but the interpretation of laws

evolves, including the weight assigned to customary systems. In the words of renowned

US Supreme Court justice Oliver Wendell Holmes, ‗The law embodies the story of a

nation‘s development through many centuries, and it cannot be dealt with as if it

contained only the axioms and corollaries of a book of mathematics‘.57

In democratic countries a nation‘s laws evolve to reflect shifting needs and values, in

concert with changes in society and the economy, sometimes playing catch-up with

changes underway and other times acting as a driver of change. In recent decades,

international law embodied in treaties such as the UN Convention on the Rights of the

Child, the International Labour Organization‘s Convention 169 (on the rights of

indigenous and tribal peoples) or the World Trade Organization‘s many treaties, have

sparked legal change at the national level, erecting new boundaries on the actions of

governments and individuals deemed appropriate. The impact of international law is

discussed in more detail in chapter six.

The law as a driver of change

When it comes to using formal legal systems to promote development, it is hard to beat

India, which combines a sclerotic legislature, a fitfully interested government, and a

hyperactive legal system committed to ‗judicial activism‘. As in the case of the homeless

shelter, social activists in India often try to get the Supreme Court to rule that the

government must do something, and then mobilize people to ensure implementation of

the ruling. On the rights to food or education, for example, the Court has been the

impetus for some of the country‘s best known progressive legislation.

That culture filters down to the grassroots. Activist talk is dotted with references to PIL –

public interest litigation. Women in slums told me they were bringing claims under

India‘s Right to Information Act to find out what their children‘s schools should be

providing, or who is actually in charge of the community toilets, which had been shut for

the last seven years.

But not all activists are as well connected as homeless advocate Harsh Mander, and not

all PILs are progressive. Plenty of industry lobbyists use the tactic, leading to an overall

57 R Wacks, Law, A Very Short Introduction, 2008

Page 43: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

43

environment characterized by abrupt and unpredictable policy changes. Judicial activism

also tends to be incredibly slow and clunky. According to a Ministry of Finance study

from the 1990s, to settle the backlog of 25 million cases in India‘s courts will take 324

years at the current disposal rate.58

I doubt things have got much better since.

The courts are often one of the few institutions that stand up to autocracy. Until 1994

apartheid South Africa essentially had no written constitution or bill of rights. The white-

ruled parliament was supreme, and no court had the power to strike down its laws – no

matter how unjust or unfair. But South Africa‘s courts had the power to interpret

legislation, which they used to blunt some of the more notorious apartheid laws. The

Legal Resources Centre, a public interest law firm, won rulings from the country‘s

highest courts, for example, to reverse the policy that had prevented the families of black

urban workers from joining them in ‗white‘ cities. Another human rights organization,

Lawyers for Human Rights, provided free defence counsel for hundreds of illiterate

people being prosecuted for transgressing the apartheid system‘s oppressive laws.59

Without the efforts of these organizations, the lawyers who worked for them and their

supporters in other countries, South Africa‘s courts would have lost all legitimacy in the

eyes of black South Africans. Instead, the legal system went on to play an important role

in interpreting South Africa‘s post-apartheid constitution.60

South Africa also exemplifies another aspect of the law – it is not immune to influence by

elites (that much we know), but it can also be influenced by what happens on the streets:

As I watched fascinated as women‘s organizations sang and danced outside courts trying

cases of domestic violence, I was told that it was good tactics – such protests greatly

increase the chances of success.

The Legal Resources Centre is one of thousands of small, dedicated legal aid and legal

rights organizations around the world. I confess I have sometimes been sceptical of

activists lugging huge, tattered statute books full of impenetrable legal jargon to

workshops in workplaces and shantytowns, but their sheer persistence and prevalence

suggests that a focus on the legal rights of the poor must achieve some results. A 2002

survey in Ecuador found that women‘s use of legal aid clinics to help with separation and

divorce reduced the probability of severe physical violence after separation by 17

58 Gurcharan Das, India Grows By Night (Penguin Books India, 2012).

59 UNDP, Human Development Report 2002: Deepening Democracy in a Fragmented World

60 R Wacks, Law, A Very Short Introduction, 2008

Page 44: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

44

percent. Legal aid clients also raised their chances of obtaining a child-support award by

20 percent.61

Yet inequality in access to justice remains profound. A UN Commission in 2008 found

that four billion people (over half the world‘s population) are robbed of the chance to

better their lives and climb out of poverty, because they are excluded from the rule of

law.62

Many legal activists believe the best hope for closing this gap lies in hybrid

institutions that combine aspects of customary law already present among poor

communities, with modern legal institutions that guarantee fairness and transparency.63

One of the most painful examples of inequality before the law is the treatment of poor

people at the hands of the police. Once notorious for links to death squads and the

assassination of street children and other ‗undesirables‘,64

Brazil‘s police are now at the

forefront of innovation. The introduction of women only police stations beginning in the

1980s met with such success, they have now spread to 15 countries in Latin America,

Africa and Asia. Most commonly the stations address family violence, particularly

physical violence and threats, as well as sexual violence. They are often staffed by

specially trained female personnel and aim to improve the ability of the police to respond

to the unique needs of women. In India, a study found that the establishment of 188

women‘s police stations resulted in a 23 per cent increase in reporting of crimes against

women and children and a higher conviction rate.65

Is the law pro-poor?

There is a character in Shakespeare‘s Henry VI who declares ‗The first thing we do, let's

kill all the lawyers.‘ However tempting, I think he‘s wrong. A World Bank study on the

use of the courts to enforce rights to healthcare and education in Brazil, India, Indonesia,

South Africa and Nigeria66

asked if resort to the legal system makes governments more

accountable (because they are forced to fulfil their promises) or less (because courts are

often the preserve of the rich). The trade-offs can be complicated: in Costa Rica, a single

decision by the Supreme Court led to an 80 per cent reduction in mortality rates among

61 World Bank, World Development Report 2006, Access to Justice

62 ‘Making the Law Work for Everyone: Report of the Commission on Legal Empowerment of the Poor’, UN, 2008

63 Customary Justice: Perspectives on Legal Empowerment Janine Ubink, Editor Thomas McInerney, Series Editor,

2011 64

G. Dimenstein, Brazil: War on Children, 1991 65

http://www.endvawnow.org/en/articles/1093-womens-police-stations-units.html 66

World Bank, Courting Social Justice, 2009

Page 45: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

45

AIDS patients, but obliged the health system to spend 8 per cent of its medicines budget

to treat just 0.012 per cent of its patients.

The study concluded that a legal system works best when there are large gaps between

what laws and constitutions promise and what governments are currently delivering, and

where governments have the capacity to undertake remedies.

My own conclusion is that the legal system, like almost any other institution you care to

name, is not a level playing field. The rich and powerful can hire better lawyers, can

lobby law-makers, and generally get a better deal. But not always – if people organize,

build the right coalitions, pursue the right argument and tactics, laws and lawyers can bite

back, governments and Big Men can lose cases. And since such disparities of power and

influence apply to any other institution you care to name, the law will remain an essential

weapon in the armoury of activists around the world.

Page 46: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

46

5 Democracy and political parties

Governments elected by universal suffrage were perhaps the greatest political innovation

of the twentieth century. In 1900, New Zealand was the world‘s only country with a

government elected by all its adult citizens. By contrast, in the first 12 years of this

century, elections were held in all but five countries with populations over half a million

(the holdouts were China, Eritrea, Qatar, Saudi Arabia and United Arab Emirates).67

Not

that elections are any guarantee of full democracy – in poor countries and rich,

authoritarians pay it a back-handed compliment by staging polls and manipulating the

media from behind the scenes to remain in power. These days even bad guys have to play

the democracy game.

Democracy‘s current travails do not end there. Repeatedly over the last 15 years, it has

advanced only fitfully, with frequent retreats in confusion. Protestors mass in the main

square, defying an authoritarian government, and the world‘s cameras zoom in. The

regime collapses; the media applaud and move on, declaring another victory for progress.

But it seems only occasionally can a new regime make a clean break with the top-down

structures and traditions it inherits. All too often, it falls under the control of a new set of

tyrants, or the old guard returns. Democracy remains an elusive ideal.

My awareness of democracy‘s failings may stem from becoming politically conscious

during an earlier example of democracy‘s periodic identity crises. Che Guevara died a

martyr‘s death in the Bolivian mountains when I was nine, but his legacy hung over the

1970s, when US-backed military thugs ruled nearly every country in Latin America and

Che‘s iconic portrait adorned a thousand student bedsits.

Not only did both revolutionaries and dictators eschew democracy, so did the US

Secretary of State Henry Kissinger. When the United States helped Chile‘s generals

overthrow the elected leftwing government of Salvador Allende, he explained: ‗I don't

see why we need to stand by and watch a country go communist due to the

irresponsibility of its people‘. For a progressive young Brit like me, the 1979 election of

Margaret Thatcher was a deeply alienating moment that threw into question the value of

democracy. My spirits were only saved when the Sandinista Revolution swept Nicaragua

67 10 killer facts on democracy and elections

Page 47: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

47

just two months later with an eruption of energy and social progress. I headed off to Latin

America.

The excitement and chaos of Latin American politics was enthralling after the grey,

depressing debates back home. And despite the two years I spent living under military

dictatorship in Argentina and Chile in the early 1980s, I confess I was more attracted to

the revolutionaries of Central America than the uninspiring lawyers and political parties

trying to restore democracy farther south. In El Salvador‘s and Guatemala‘s civil wars,

the heroes carried rifles and fought in the mountains, while elections seemed little more

than a PR stunt aimed at keeping money flowing from the US Congress.

Over the course of that decade, I rediscovered democracy‘s virtues. The Sandinistas held

regular elections and eventually accepted defeat at the polls in 1990. The Salvadoran

guerrillas made peace and eventually won power through the ballot box. A wave of

democratic renewal saw dictators fall across Latin America, followed by new

democracies in post-Communist Europe, and the liberation of South Africa from

apartheid in the 1990s. Maybe democracy wasn‘t in such a crisis after all.

This chapter reviews the nature and evolution of democracy and how it can drive change,

then goes on to explore a topic often overlooked in development – the role of political

parties.

How has democracy evolved?

In 1991, political scientist Samuel Huntington identified three major ‗waves‘ of

democratisation in the modern world. The first began in the 1820s with the widening of

suffrage in the United States and continued for nearly a century, leaving 29 democracies

in its wake. Fascism and communism‘s ‗reverse wave‘ reduced their number to 11 by

1941, at which point President Franklin Roosevelt worried that it might not be possible to

shield ‗the great flame of democracy from the blackout of barbarism‘.68

A second wave

began after World War II, and by 1962 the number of democratic states in the world

rebounded to 36.

Huntington‘s ‗third wave‘ began in Portugal in 1974, then tumbled dictators in Greece

and Spain and subsequently across Latin America. The mid-1980s and early 1990s saw

democratisation in the Philippines, Korea, Taiwan, Bangladesh and Nepal. The collapse

68 What’s Gone Wrong with Democracy? The Economist, March 2014

Page 48: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

48

of the Soviet Union in 1991 prompted competitive elections in most of Eastern Europe,

whilst Benin and South Africa began a fourth wave in Africa in 1990. By 2014, Freedom

House, a US think tank, classified 125 of the world‘s 196 countries as electoral

democracies, compared to only 69 in 1990.69

In addition to its widening geographical spread, democracy has become more innovative,

decentralizing power to municipalities,70

using digitization to increase the reach and

reliability of citizen registration, or encouraging local public consultations on how to

allocate spending.

The idea of democracy has been around at least since ancient Athens, and yet it did not

become institutionalized anywhere until the end of the eighteenth century. That suggests

some kind of link to the Industrial Revolution and the subsequent exponential economic

growth. Outside the petro-states, the richest 25 countries (as ranked by the World Bank)

are also fully established democracies. In fact, a democratic regime has never fallen prey

to authoritarianism after a certain income level is reached (US$6,055 per capita).71

According to political scientists, once the immediate need to satisfy survival needs is

achieved, people move on to more intangible goals, such as rights and voice and a seat at

the table of government. South Korea and Taiwan appear to support the thesis that

growth creates a middle class, which in turns lead to transitions from one-party or

military rule to a multiparty system.

American analysts in particular argue that growth will sow the seeds of inevitable reform

in one-party systems with severe restrictions on civil and political rights, such as China or

Ethiopia.72

Comparing the economic performance of China and the United States over the

last 40 years, this seems a heroic assumption, to say the least.

The link between growth and democracy raises another, more subtle question: Middle

classes around the world are being hollowed out by technology and rising inequality.

What kind of democracy will flourish in societies dominated by the wealthiest one per

cent?

69 https://freedomhouse.org/report/freedom-world-2015/discarding-democracy-return-iron-fist#.VcMUkHFViko 70 http://oxfamblogs.org/fp2p/are-progressive-cities-the-key-to-solving-our-toughest-global-challenges/ 71 Rocha Menocal, op cit 72 Acemoglu and Robinson, Why Nations Fail

Page 49: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

49

More recently, concerns have arisen over a ‗democratic recession‘, with democratic states

backsliding on democratic freedoms, undoing some of the achievements of the last thirty

years. Thirty-one per cent of countries can be described as ‗authoritarian regimes‘ today,

while only 15 per cent of countries are ―full democracies‘; the rest lie somewhere in

between.73

According to Freedom House, global democratic freedoms in 2014 declined for the ninth

consecutive year.74

Explanations include the successful rise of China, offering a non-

democratic alternative model to autocrats everywhere, and the tarnishing of the Western

democratic brand by the 2008 financial crisis and political gridlock in Europe and the

United States. Other former jewels in the democratic crown, such as South Africa, have

also lost their lustre. Few would now echo the hubristic US State Department report in

2000, which crowed that ‗it seems that now, at long last, democracy is triumphant.‘ 75

Does democracy lead to development?

The Greek roots of ‗democracy‘ mean ‗rule by the people‘. Modern understandings of the

word include guarantees of universal suffrage and basic human rights, a separation of

powers between governments, law-makers and courts, and a free press. Although most

modern democracies are republics, with an elected head of state, a handful are

constitutional monarchies, like the UK, where I live.

According to the great Indian economist Amartya Sen, the value of democracy includes

its direct contribution to human freedoms, its instrumental role in ensuring that

governments listen to their peoples and its influence in building the kinds of humane

values needed in a decent society.76

Naturally, reality often falls well short of these ideals. Often, democracy exists as a thin

veneer of Western concepts, a set of formal institutions, while the state‘s practice is

profoundly undemocratic. In Africa, leaders have got better at organizing apparently

73 Alina Rocha Menocal, 10 Killer Facts on elections and democracy [NEED ORIGINAL SOURCE] 74 https://freedomhouse.org/report/freedom-world-2015/discarding-democracy-return-iron-fist#.VcMUkHFViko 75 Economist, March 2014 [NEED ORIGINAL SOURCE] 76 Sen, Development as Freedom, 1999. p148

Page 50: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

50

competitive elections, without actually letting go of the reins of power.77

Since 2000,

only 14 of 51 states in Sub-Saharan Africa have seen power transferred between political

parties.78

Some critics see democracy as an exercise in pacification, undertaken to tame messy,

loud and unruly movements into the relatively ordered contests of elections and

manifestos. Far from transforming the world, elites introduced elections to ensure that

nothing fundamental changes. As a peasant farmer in Baluchistan, Pakistan, told

researchers, ‗During elections, they [the politicians] visit us individually to pocket

maximum votes, but afterwards they avoid us and we feel evil-smelling. First they hug

us, and later our sweat and grime repels them‘.79

Because democracies require an element of consent – defeated candidates must accept

their defeat – it is more difficult for democratic governments to pursue radical change,

something that frustrates both Left and Right. A democratic regime is less likely to get

away with the free-market ‗surgery without anaesthetic‘ carried out by the Pinochet

dictatorship in Chile or with the expropriation of lands and businesses carried out under

Fidel Castro in Cuba.

Democracy is a conservative system of power, but it is also radical in its promotion of

individual rights.80

And it exists in a state of permanent tension with the construction of

an effective state. The basis of effective government is a meritocratic civil service making

decisions based on the long-term interests of the country, as in Singapore under autocrat

Lee Kuan Yew. The fundamental principle of democracy, in contrast, is one person one

vote, and that person may want short-term benefits rather than long-term progress.

Transitions from more authoritarian rule can grow bloody. The collapse of Iraq showed

what can happen when the dictatorial lid is removed from a political and social pressure

cooker of politics, religion and clan. In the absence of an effective state, democratic

freedoms can accentuate the cleavages in society, replicating them in political parties and

factions, and end up being profoundly destabilizing.

77 V Songwe, From strong men to strong institutions: An assessment of Africa’s transition towards more political contestability, 2015 78 Rocha Menocal, op cit [NEED ORIGINAL OFFICIAL SOURCE] 79 B. Knight, H. Chigudu, and R. Tandon (2002) op. cit., p.76. 80 Adrian Leftwich, Democracy and Development, New Political Economy, Vol 7, #2, 2002,

Page 51: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

51

As a middle-income country, Iraq is something of an anomaly. Economist Paul Collier

claims to have demonstrated that ‗Democracies get safer as income rises, whereas

autocracies get more dangerous‘. He calculates above a per capita GDP of $2700 per

annum, democracy systematically reduces the risk of political violence, while below that

level, democracy makes society more dangerous. However, Collier is referring to

political violence, not the kind of social violence that bedevils many middle income

countries with high levels of inequality – there, the link with income is much more

complicated.81

Thomas Carothers, a political scientist at the Carnegie Endowment, has

identified five factors that determine whether a transition to democracy is likely to be

successful. In general, the wealthier a country is, the better will be its chances; Countries

whose national wealth comes mainly from highly concentrated sources (such as oil or

mineral deposits) tend to experience significant difficulties with democratization;

Countries where the population is divided along ethnic, religious, tribal, or clan lines

often have a harder time with democratization than more homogeneous societies;

Countries with little record of political pluralism almost always struggle; Countries in

regions or sub-regions where most or all of the countries are non-democratic find

democratization more elusive than do countries in more democratic neighbourhoods.82

Jean Dreze and Amartya Sen famously argued that no substantial famine has ever

occurred in an independent and democratic country with a free press.83

Those institutions

guarantee a minimum level of feedback and accountability that obliges governments to

avoid precipitating a famine (which generally only occurs under a particularly

incompetent or absent state).

Beyond the mere avoidance of catastrophe, however, democracy is no guarantee of

progress. Where broader democratic culture or politics is weak or absent, the poor may be

able to vote, but can only hope leaders are willing or able to act in their interests. Yet

even in relatively undemocratic systems competitive elections can provide a vehicle for

those seeking to enhance the effectiveness of state institutions. As noted in chapter one,

81 Collier, Wars, Guns and Votes: Democracy in Dangerous Places, 2009 82 How Democracies Emerge, Thomas Carothers, Journal of Democracy, January 2007, Volume 18, Number 1 83 Dreze and Sen, 1989

Page 52: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

52

during Zambia‘s 2011 elections, a civil society campaign secured a significant rise in

healthcare spending.84

And India‘s landmark 2005 legislation that guarantees rural citizens 100 days of unskilled

employment per year on public works programmes, came about thanks to a critical

electoral juncture. In the 2003 legislative assembly elections, the Congress Party suffered

a demoralising loss in Rajasthan and other states, leading most to believe it had no chance

in the 2004 general election. Impending political defeat weakened the resistance of fiscal

conservatives in the Congress leadership and the employment guarantee was included in

the 2004 Congress national manifesto. After its surprise victory that year, the party‘s

leadership needed to rapidly cobble together a programme. The employment guarantee

was not only ready to go, but removing it would have endangered its coalition with

leftwing parties. Not surprisingly, it still took a determined campaign – involving a 50-

day march across the country‘s poorest districts, sit-in protests, direct contacts with

politicians and public hearings – to get a decent employment policy finally approved.85

Political parties

Considering the importance of political parties to these examples of breakthroughs in

Zambia and India, it is somewhat odd that they are usually overlooked in discussions of

democracy and development. Parties provide citizens with an essential link to

government, allowing them to accumulate ‗power with‘ to influence the decisions that

affect their lives. At their heart, political parties are election machines, vehicles for

fielding candidates and marshalling votes. In the process, they reconcile and represent the

interests and viewpoints of numerous individuals and groups in society; they recruit and

train future leaders; and above all, they hold government accountable and organize

opposition.86

Unfortunately, the reality is often rather less impressive. A memorable film of Chico

Mendes, the Brazilian rubber-tappers‘ leader, shows him running as a Workers‘ Party

candidate for state deputy in 1986. As he strolls down the main street in his home town of

Xapuri, greeting his many friends and acquaintances, a stream of local people come up to

84 Oxfam, 2013, WIN in Action, Vote Health for All, Case Study from Zambia [published?] 85 Ian Macauslan re update and give latest stats from NREGA on reach 86 Vicky Randall, Political Parties and Democratic Developmental86 States

Page 53: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

53

ask how much he is paying for votes. When he explains that he had no money, they

wander off, bemused. He lost the election.87

In many countries, parties and the parliaments or congresses they constitute are

unrepresentative and frequently beholden to powerful interests for their jobs. Women are

notoriously under-represented, occupying only 22 per cent of parliamentary seats

worldwide in 2015.88

Political parties are frequently starved of funds and the basic skills

needed to carry out their functions. While parties are sometimes isolated from civil

society organisations, media, private sector, and trade unions, more frequently parties

command their unwavering, if clandestine, allegiance. Partisan politics is deeply

ingrained in much of the democratic world, even if most NGOs and unions would prefer

not to publicize their political leanings.

Some political parties were created by social movements, whether religious (India‘s BJP;

Europe‘s Christian Democrats, the Middle East‘s Islamist parties) or social (Bolivia‘s

MAS, Brazil‘s PT); others were set up by a government already in power (Mexico‘s PRI

and the various phantom opposition parties it created); some draw on ethnic or regional

affiliation (many of Kenya‘s parties) or are personal vehicles for charismatic leaders

(Argentina‘s Peronists, Thailand‘s Thai Rak Thai).89

Parties come in a bewildering range of shapes and sizes. Some are ‗Toyota‘ parties,

whose leaders and followers could fit into a single car; others are mass-based

organizations with thousands of organizers. Some represent the interests of just a few

wealthy businessmen; others speak for millions of impoverished and marginalized

people. Some have little ideological basis beyond the vaguest commitment to generic

democratic principles; others hold to a strict program of positions inspired by religion.

Some have origins as peace movements, others as armed insurgencies.90

From social movement to political party

Parties that emerged from social movements, trade unions and other organizations of the

poor have been responsible for some inspiring breakthroughs in countries South Africa,

87 D Green, Faces of Latin America, 1991, p104 88 http://www.ipu.org/wmn-e/world.htm 89 Political Parties and Democratic Developmental States, Vicky Randall, Development Policy Review, September 2007 90 Thomas Carothers, Confronting the Weakest Link: Aiding PPs in New Democracies, 2006

Page 54: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

54

Brazil, Bolivia, India and elsewhere. A recent example is India‘s Aam Aadmi Party

(AAP, or the ‗Common Man‘s Party‘), which grew out of an anti-corruption protest

sparked by a 2011 hunger strike by Anna Hazare, a renowned and self-consciously

Gandhian protestor. 91

His action helped force the introduction of anti-corruption

legislation, but the movement lost momentum and media interest in the energy-sapping

labyrinths of parliamentary procedure. The leaders realized they needed to recast the

movement as a political party to mobilize for the longer-term grind of political reform.

Barely a year after its founding, the AAP came second in Delhi Assembly elections, and

in 2015 it won 67 out of 70 assembly seats.92

The AAP‘s story is fairly typical: social movements tend to rise and fall in sudden bursts

of protest, but achieving reform requires long-term engagement with the state. However,

the decision to found a political party usually raises fundamental questions within a social

movement. Much of the debate comes down to legitimacy. Civil society organizations

find it hard to make any legitimate claim to represent the will of the people because no-

one has elected them. But many civil society activists argue that playing the electoral

game entails compromises that inevitably tarnish the clarity of the message and the moral

legitimacy of a protest movement. To found the AAP leaders had to split from Hazare.

Similar tensions have dogged South Africa‘s ANC, Brazil‘s Workers‘ Party and Bolivia‘s

Movement to Socialism, all of which emerged from coalitions of social movements and

came to rule the country.

Patronage v programmes

In terms of their impact on democracy and development, a crucial distinction is between

personalist and programmatic parties: those designed to achieve power and influence for

one or more ‗big men‘, using patronage to reward supporters and bind them to the leader,

versus those that stand for a particular political, economic and social programme. In

practice of course, parties lie on a spectrum in between the two poles, but the distinction

remains important.

91 P. Sharma, From India Against Corruption to the Aam Aadmi Party: Social Movements, Political Parties and Citizen Engagement in India, in R. Cordenillo & S van der Staak, Political Parties And Citizen Movements In Asia And Europe, 2014 92 Update from Wikipedia

Page 55: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

55

Personalist parties are almost universal, perhaps reflecting Francis Fukuyama‘s argument

that in evolutionary terms, kin and family usually come before any other form of personal

loyalty.93

The strength of ethnic, tribal, regional or religious identities certainly trumps

ideology across Sub-Saharan Africa, as it does in many immigrant communities in

Europe and North America.94

Personalist, patronage-based parties make a mockery of platforms and policy positions as

party hacks shop around for the best deal. Debates over the content of election manifestos

are often only pale echoes of their Western counterparts. According to one study of

Kenya: ‗nearly all party manifestos look alike, often using the same phraseology, and

even identical paragraphs... The larger parties are often keen not to produce their policies

and other documents too early before an election for fear that others will simply copy

those documents with impunity‘.95

In Argentina Peronist presidents seem to be able to convince their followers to support

entirely contradictory policies, from free market liberalization (Carlos Menem) to state

intervention (Néstor, then Cristina Kirchner). In Brazil, around a third of legislators in the

Chamber of Deputies switch party during each four-year term.96

Patronage politics also

makes it easier for new entrants to create parties, provided they have a large initial stake

to buy support, as Berlusconi did in Italy. The developing world in particular has seen an

accelerating rate of party ‗churn‘: instead of relatively stable party systems, new parties

linked to particular candidates rise and fall each election, a phenomenon encouraged by

widespread disenchantment with their more traditional rivals.

The currency of patronage is jobs and cash, memorably summed up by Michela Wrong in

the title of her book, ‗It‘s Our Turn to Eat‘:97

election means a new set of snouts in the

trough, as resources are siphoned off from contracts and government budgets for

supporters, with leaders taking their slice. As well as squandering resources, stuffing

93 93 Francis Fukuyama, the Origins of Political Order 94 Matthew Lockwood, however, argues that rapid decolonisation meant that the new generation of independence leaders did not have time to build more programmatic parties. Lockwood, the State They’re In 95 Political Parties and Democratic Developmental States, Vicky Randall, Development Policy Review, September 2007 96 Vicky Randall, Political Parties and Democratic Developmental States 97 M. Wrong, it’s Our Turn to Eat: the Story of a Kenyan Whistle Blower, 2009,

Page 56: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

56

government jobs with unqualified supporters has often proved disastrous in terms of

efficiency and accountability.

Given such problems, it is hardly surprising that in opinion polls worldwide, political

parties languish at the bottom of public approval ratings, alongside journalists and estate

agents, or their local equivalents. There is a notable gulf between the stardust of

democracy itself (still widely popular) and the contempt generally felt for political

parties.

Nothing accentuates the endless battle between personalist and programmatic approaches

more than a major natural resource find. Unless institutions and the rule of law are solidly

in place, the prospect of millions of dollars suddenly spouting from the ground can spark

a battle among political leaders for access to the new wealth and the leverage it brings.

Not every country is as lucky as Botswana, which had an effective government and laws

in place before it discovered diamonds, and so was able to avoid a spoils war. At the

opposite end of the spectrum lies Nigeria, where systematic looting of its vast oil wealth

has severely undermined any attempt to build an accountable democracy.

The widespread problems of corruption and patronage are compounded by something I

have always found baffling: the apparent inability of countries to establish a fair and

transparent system of party and campaign financing. At $6 billion ($51 per vote cast), the

2012 US elections cost 120 times more than the UK 2010 vote ($50 million, $1.68 per

vote cast). Even the violence-scarred 2007 elections in Kenya cost $10 million ($1.01 per

vote cast). By some estimates, the total expenditure across all political parties in the 2009

Indian national election was US$ 3 billion ($7.20 per vote cast).98

This is big money, and

in the absence of state funding for political parties or election campaigns,99

elections

spark a frenetic hustle to raise cash. In such circumstances a relatively small amount of

money can buy an inordinate degree of political influence.

How parties change and how they drive change

The question then arises, when and how do personalist parties become more

programmatic? One study identified economic growth and the rising middle class arguing

that ‗Educated, higher-income individuals prefer programmatic‘ parties. It also identified

periods of economic crisis as windows of opportunity to increase the programmatic

98 P. Sharma, op cit 99 Rocha Menocal, op cit

Page 57: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

57

content of political debates.100

However, there is a gloomier side to this diagnosis – in

poor countries, leaders may simply find it more efficient to get elected through patronage

networks because votes can be bought more cheaply and strong religious, ethnic or other

community ties make buying votes much easier than trying to persuade the public of the

virtues of this or that programme. Patronage is practical.

Political parties often pass through a cycle of growth and decay. A charismatic new

leader bursts onto the scene, or a social movement turns itself into a clean, inspiring new

party; supporters rally to the flag of a new kind of politics. The AAP, like Podemos in

Spain or Syriza in Greece, has shown huge mobilizing power and a commitment to a new

way of doing politics: non-hierarchical, internally democratic, financially transparent and

free of big money or dynasty politics. But it proves remarkably hard to maintain that

coherence and dynamism, and upon consolidation most face difficult choices,

compromise and decline.

In Latin America Brazil‘s Workers Party (PT) passed through such a cycle. Born from

independent trade unions, social movements and others, and led by the charismatic union

leader José Ignacio da Silva (known to all as Lula), the PT was created in 1980 initially to

protest against military rule, then to turn civil society demands into a long-term political

programme. It won municipal elections and, after several narrow defeats, the national

vote in 2003.

The PT brought an exhilarating burst of energy and legitimacy into an otherwise decayed

political system. But then the compromises of power (for example using bribes to steer

laws through an opposition-dominated Congress) brought an inevitable loss of mobilizing

power. The logic of government took over from that of protest and community

mobilization, eroding the very things that made the PT different. By 2015, Lula had

retired, citizens were protesting against the PT government and its approval ratings were

plummeting. If new parties are doomed to pass through such a cycle, the question

remains how much they achieve before their honeymoon fades. In the case of the PT,

those gains were substantial reductions in hunger, poverty and inequality.101

That cycle is not predestined however, and parties that have hit a slump are often able to

reinvent themselves, through a combination of new leadership, internal reform, policy

100 Politics Meets Policies The Emergence of Programmatic Political Parties, International IDEA, 2014 101 Sue Branford and Jan Rocha: Brazil and the Workers’ Party: From Euphoria to Despair

Page 58: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

58

rethinks and reconnecting with the vibrancy of grassroots organization. Simply waiting

for the current power holders to go through the cycle and duly fade away is unlikely to

work however – unless ousted parties recover their dynamism, new players are likely to

arrive to fill the vacuum.

An equally compelling example comes from the Philippines, where politics is deeply

polarized. On the one hand, the formal democratic institutions are run by elite families

through a deeply embedded system of patronage. On the other hand, the country has a

strong civil society that has brought down presidents and that takes pride in the peaceful,

non-violent manner in which its political influence is exercised.

Since its founding in 1998, a party known as Akbayan has combined the tactics of social

movements and parliamentary engagement to achieve significant political reforms. In

2010, after Benigno Simeon Aquino III won the presidency with Akbayan‘s support,

several prominent Akbayan figures were appointed to senior roles in the administration.

Over the ensuing five years, Akbayan helped win new laws on reproductive health and

agrarian reform.102

The PT or Akbayan were obliged to carry out progressive reforms because they owed

their election to the organized citizens who had provided them with funding and votes

during the campaign. The party is the vehicle through which organized citizens wielded

their clout. The same could be said of India‘s Congress party and their championing of

the rural employment guarantee.

Democracy v development

Writing these last three chapters has forced me to confront some painful dilemmas, born

of the gaps between how I might prefer change to be and the lessons I draw from my

research and personal experience. Chief among these is whether development at different

stages is best served by authoritarianism or democracy. In other words, whether civil and

political freedoms promote or retard the achievement of the economic freedoms

conferred by rising incomes.

Meles Zenawi was a remarkable man. A victorious rebel leader, he was Ethiopia‘s ruler

from 1991 until his death in 2012, first as president of the transitional government and

102 Ch4: S. Gacad, Reforming the Political Party System in the Philippines: The Akbayan Citizens’ Action Party In R. Cordenillo & S van der Staak, Political Parties And Citizen Movements In Asia And Europe, 2014

Page 59: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

59

then as prime minister. Somehow, he took time out from running the country to do an

MBA at Britain‘s Open University, achieving one of its best ever results. Like many

nation builders, Meles was no soft-hearted democrat. His government clamped down on

dissent by jailing the opposition and, during violence after the 2005 election, was accused

of killing some 200 protesters and injuring hundreds more.103

Meles‘ approach to his day job was laid out in his MBA dissertation, entitled ‗African

Development: Dead Ends and New Beginnings‘,104

which makes the case for

authoritarian rule in order to kickstart development. Acknowledging that patronage and

rent-seeking are the enemies of both growth and democracy, he not unreasonably posits

that democratic politics tend to be ‗riddled with patronage and rent-seeking‘. Then he

wonders rhetorically, ‗How can the developmental state clean up the mess of patronage

and rent-seeking [at the beginning]...by anything other than undemocratic means?‘

While Meles‘ stance may seem self-serving, such views are echoed by a number of

scholars, some of whom embrace an authoritarian option as the only feasible path to

development.105,106

Fortunately, the evidence is not entirely on the side of the autocrats.

In terms of the economy, cross-country comparisons show that on average, there appears

to be no growth advantage (or disadvantage) in being authoritarian. Autocracies do

account for some of development‘s success stories, but they have also been responsible

for innumerable dismal failures. In Latin America, I saw the hyperinflation inflicted by

military rule in the 1980s that went hand in hand with their cruel human rights abuses.

In terms of systems, dictatorships are distinguished from democracies by their absence of

feedback systems and constraints – a dictator dictates, after all. With untrammelled

power, a leader can conduct necessary reforms, often leading to growth spurts, but should

the situation change, or should they simply get it wrong, there is no-one who can force

them to alter course. Economies under autocracies are thus characterized by booms and

busts, whereas democracies, with their often exasperating degree of feedback and

103 http://news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/world/africa/6067386.stm 104 http://africanidea.org/m_zenawi_aug_9_2006.pdf 105 Booth, D. (2011) Governance for Development in Africa: Building on What Works, Africa Power and Politics policy brief 01 106 http://oxfamblogs.org/fp2p/authoritarianism-goes-global-the-rise-of-the-despots-and-their-apologists/

Page 60: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

60

constraint, have historically proved better at avoiding the extremes, producing a smoother

ride.107

Secondly, while some autocracies have produced economic growth, other elements like

citizen activism and democracy are equally essential to achieve development in the wider

sense – an accumulation of freedoms ‗to do and to be‘, not just the freedom to eat and

consume.108

It is not for nothing that in countries at similar stages of development,

democracies spend 25 to 50 per cent more than autocracies on public goods and

services.109

My painful conclusion is that there may indeed be a conflict between growth and

freedoms, but the trade-offs between them seem to be changing over time. Cultural shifts

in attitudes toward human rights, as well as technological changes in access to

information, have heightened people‘s desire for democratic participation and their

rejection of restrictions on their freedom. As I hope the examples in this chapter have

shown, democracy can answer Meles‘ very pertinent question. As for me, I always end

up agreeing with Winston Churchill‘s aphorism that ‗democracy is the worst form of

government … except all those others that have been tried‘.

107 T. Kelsall, State of the Art: Authoritarianism, Democracy and Development, 2014 108 Sen, 1999 109 THIS IS AN OLD STAT (FROM FP2P) – FIND A MORE RECENT ONE?

Page 61: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

61

6 The international system

‗Shame!‘ roared the bearded activist, pointing an accusing finger as, uncomfortably

besuited, I wended my way through the police lines. Attending an international trade

conference as a civil society delegate was supposed to be a routine induction to

CAFOD‘s work in international institutions. However, the 1999 World Trade

Organisation (WTO) ministerial in Seattle was anything but routine. Trapped between

tear gas-spraying robocops and enraged protesters, we NGO lobbyists from the U.K. had

to take refuge with the British government delegates in their swanky conference centre

offices. And that proved a great chance to build relationships and trust. It probably wasn‘t

what my placard-wielding accuser intended, but as it turned out he was very helpful.

For me Seattle marked the beginning of several years of lobbying on global trade rules.

Working alongside government delegations from Pakistan, the Philippines and many

others, plus a plethora of fellow NGO policy wonks and academics, provided me with a

great introduction to the complex dynamics of the international system, as well as a

privileged vantage point for observing the impact on it of events, long-term trends and

shifts in norms and ideas.

The key event in those years was the 9/11 attack on New York‘s World Trade Center,

which took place just weeks before the WTO ministerial that followed the debacle in

Seattle. Jittery delegates in Doha flinched whenever planes flew near the conference

centre. Along with berobed Qatari staff, the delegates and I watched on TV screens in the

conference hall as U.S. troops took Kabul in response to the attack. In this febrile

atmosphere, governments rallied behind the international system and launched an

ambitious ‗Doha Development Round‘ of trade talks.

At the ministerial in Cancun two years later, however, the longer-term trend of declining

U.S. and European power came to the fore. Protest movements in the U.S. and Europe

had helped weaken the rich countries‘ resolve, but more importantly, newly assertive

developing country blocs refused to sign on to the ‗submerging powers‘ agendas on

agriculture and investment, and the talks fell apart in spectacular fashion.

To my surprise and delight, ideas also played a key role in the evolution of the trade

debate, especially the academic counter-attack against the crude ‗if it moves, liberalize it‘

Page 62: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

62

impulse that had dominated in the late 1990s.110

With the rich countries in retreat on the

intellectual and political realms, the round remains on life support a decade and a half

after the hype of Doha.

The evolution of the multilateral system

At first sight, the international system is an extraordinary success story. Every day sees

huge amounts of largely smooth interchange between nation states: people cross borders;

emails, letters and postcards arrive at the correct destination; freighters load and unload

containers of goods in foreign ports in an ever-expanding cycle of global trade. We only

notice when those relatively unencumbered processes are interrupted, as in Europe‘s

migration meltdown, which is dominating the headlines as I write. Remarkably, these

smoothly functioning exchanges occur under a fairly loose system of governance – a

combination of norms, rules, procedures and institutions – and without any recognized

world government.

The first attempt to bring order to international relations came in Europe after the defeat

of Napoleon in 1815. The victorious powers set up a ‗Concert for Europe‘ which, though

it had no written rules and no permanent institutions, offered a forum for negotiating

differences. It successfully limited warfare in Europe for much of the nineteenth century,

accommodating the unification and rise of Germany and Italy, before collapsing in World

War I.

Ever since the founding of the Red Cross in 1863, discussions on international

governance have been driven by efforts to regulate the use of violence, and the

international system has evolved primarily in response to war. World War I led to the

creation of the League of Nations, an idealistic and ill-fated attempt to build a ‗world

parliament‘. And World War II bequeathed the basic institutions that make up the

international system today. The United Nations, unlike the League, fuses global

democracy (the General Assembly) with Great Power politics (the Security Council).

And to stem the economic nationalism that helped destroy the League, the World Bank,

the International Monetary Fund and the predecessor to the WTO seek economic

coordination.

110 See, for example, Dani Rodrik, The Global Governance of Trade as if Development Really Mattered,

2001 or Ha-Joon Chang, Kicking Away the Ladder

Page 63: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

63

Seventy years on, with increasing signs of sclerosis and strain, the UN, World Bank and

IMF, joined by the WTO in 1995, sit atop a burgeoning and complex system of

international governance. And I mean complex: during the course of the twentieth

century, over 38,000 International organizations were founded, almost half of them in its

last two decades.111

The characteristics of complex systems discussed in chapter two apply strongly to the

international system: the future is unforeseeable; events drive policy at least as often as

the reverse; unintended consequences abound. For anyone working to influence the

system, fast feedback loops and thinking on your feet are likely to be more useful than

brilliantly designed Grand Plans.

The United Nations is a sprawling system unto itself. It consists of three core bodies set

up in 1945, the General Assembly, the Security Council and the Secretariat, subsequently

joined by numerous ‗specialized agencies‘, such as the World Health Organisation

(1948), the UN High Commissioner for Refugees (1950), the UN Conference on Trade

and Development (1964) and the UN Development Programme (1965) and UN Women

(2010).112

While constitutionally part of the UN system, the International Monetary Fund and the

World Bank were set up in a radically different manner. The UN system works largely

on the principle of ‗one country, one vote‘ (with the notable exception of the Security

Council), whereas decisions at the multilateral financial organisations are generally taken

on the basis of ‗one dollar, one vote‘, guaranteeing the dominance of the United States

and other major donors.113

At U.S. insistence, the organisations were located in

Washington, within walking distance of the White House, rather than with the UN in

New York.

111 T. Weiss, Global Governance, 2013, p. 16

112 Anthony Payne, The Global Politics of Unequal Development, 2005, chapter 5

113 One exception is the arm of the World Bank that lends to low-income countries, the International Development Association (IDA). Technically, this has a different structure to the main board of the Bank, and poor countries get 41 per cent of the vote in decisions made by the IDA board. However, only a few of these countries are involved in setting the agreements that decide the IDA’s policies, a process that takes place every three years. Here, as everywhere at the IFIs, it is the large donors who really make all the significant decisions.

Page 64: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

64

In my time as a minor NGO irritant114

in the world of international institutions, I was

struck by the divide between the seedy offices and frustrating bureaucracy of the UN and

the swanky digs and smart efficiency of the Bank and Fund. I received a graphic

demonstration of this in 2013, when I gave talks about blogging to staff at the UNDP and

World Bank. At the UN, timorous staff debated whether they were even allowed to blog,

for fear of offending one or another member state. At the World Bank, the self-confident

and amused response to my request to meet its bloggers was ‗tricky, there are 300 of

them‘.115

Former UNDP head Mark Malloch Brown beautifully captures the culture clash between

the Bretton Woods Institutions and the UN: ‗UNDP was poor, and the World Bank was

rich; UNDP did not always apply the bank‘s development rigour to its projects. But it had

one undeniable advantage: developing countries considered it to be on their side. Unlike

the heavily Washington-based World Bank staff, most UNDP staff were in the field close

to their clients. At its best it lived on development instinct, where the Bank lived on

intellect.‘116

The international financial institutions are staffed by technocrats who pride

themselves on promoting ‗policy over politics‘. Being largely insulated from the demands

of national politics does allow them to take on difficult problems without having to court

public support. But that same insulation often means the policies they propose are out of

touch with the political restrictions national leaders face.

Between the World Bank and the IMF there are unappetising turf wars and also genuine

differences, especially in the realm of ideas. After the 1998 Asian financial crisis, for

example, the IMF wanted to pressure countries to cut spending, while the World Bank

thought they should reflate. Both the Fund and the Bank play a significant role as

‗knowledge brokers‘, conducting and publishing research that shapes thinking about

development and economic policy in countries around the world, so these battles over

ideas matter. Even within each institution, divisions and arguments are constant.

Powerful epistemic tribes such as the neoclassical economists slug it out with heterodox

economists and others on issues such as governance or livelihoods. The outcomes of such

battles can edge the institutions into new areas of work or approaches. Seemingly

abstruse, technical discussions can have serious consequences for people living in

114 For a first-hand account by someone close to the centre of the action, read Mark Malloch Brown’s

excellent book, The Unfinished Global Revolution. M. Malloch Brown, The Unfinished Global Revolution, The Limits of Nations and the Pursuit of a New Politics, 2011 115

http://oxfamblogs.org/fp2p/blogging-in-big-bureaucracies-round-two-the-view-from-the-world-bank/ 116

Malloch Brown, p. 117

Page 65: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

65

poverty, as in the whether to demand that countries impose user fees for primary health

services, which after nearly two decades has yet to be entirely resolved.117

The political

isolation of technocrats helps explain why, despite raging internal debates, international

institutions are loath to change, and evolve only slowly. A study of the World Bank‘s

Development Economics Vice Presidency (DEC) concluded that its role was one of

‗paradigm maintenance‘, defending and perpetuating an orthodox form of neoclassical

economics through an interlocking set of ‗drivers of inertia‘, including hiring preferences,

promotion and the selective enforcement of rules. Dissident research generally undergoes

stricter external review with occasional rejection, or disappears into a Kafkaesque limbo

where it is never signed off for publication. Dissidents are labelled ‗idiosyncratic‘,

‗disaffected‘ and otherwise deemed misfits, while the Bank‘s External Affairs

Department gets behind the ‗good guys‘, showering them with high profile speaking and

writing opportunities.118

That said, and despite the dreams of the mandarins at the World Bank and IMF, debates

over the right purpose and policies to improve the human condition are profoundly

shaped by what is going on in the economy and politics of the world outside. Their chief

executives are appointed by the European and American governments and the prevailing

mood in Washington and London weighs heavily on the inclination or ability of the

institutions to enact reform.

In response to events, but equally due to the glacial pace of reform in existing

institutions, new elements continue being grafted onto the basic architecture of the

international system. The failure of UN peacekeeping to prevent massacres in Bosnia and

Rwanda in the 1990s led to the founding of the International Criminal Court in 2002 and

an increasingly assertive role for UN peacekeepers in crises justified by a 2005

agreement on the ‗responsibility to protect‘ civilians from genocide, war crimes, ethnic

cleansing and crimes against humanity. The inability of the IMF and World Bank to

reflect the long-term decline of Europe‘s power in their governance structures prompted

China, India, Brazil and other rising economic powers to create their own Asian

Infrastructure Investment Bank in 2014.

117 Oxfam has been deeply involved in this debate. See, for example, http://policy-

practice.oxfam.org.uk/publications/investing-for-the-few-the-ifcs-health-in-africa-initiative-325654 118

http://oxfamblogs.org/fp2p/the-art-of-paradigm-maintenance-has-anything-changed-at-the-world-bank/

Page 66: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

66

My own highly peripheral engagement is also a sign of another evolution in the

international system – the rise of networks. States remain the main players, but they are

increasingly surrounded by, and forced to engage with, representatives of the private

sector, NGOs, philanthrocapitalists such as Bill and Melinda Gates, and policy-savvy

academics, in what Francis Fukuyama calls a ‗multi-multilateral system‘.119

Networks

among these new players have given rise to public-private initiatives such as the Global

Fund to Fight AIDS, Tuberculosis and Malaria or the Global Alliance for Vaccines and

Immunization.

The influence of non-governmental actors in global governance is perhaps most baldly

demonstrated by the WTO‘s Agreement on Trade-Related Intellectual Property, which

was concocted in 1996 largely at the behest of the pharmaceutical industry to extend the

period they hold monopoly rights to their products. NGOs, too, have achieved remarkable

clout by joining the policy debate underway among technocrats at the Bank and Fund,

and by working to win the political support of national governments for new

initiatives.120

When the Control Arms campaign was launched in 2003 by a coalition of development

and human rights NGOs, only three governments (Mali, Costa Rica and Cambodia)

would publicly associate themselves with the call for an Arms Trade Treaty. Undeterred,

the campaign developed a wide range of allies, including companies in the defence

industry that saw themselves as the ‗responsible end‘ of the arms industry, retired

generals and former war correspondents, financial investors, people wounded by small

arms and more. Lining up on the other side, were the United States (the only country

publicly opposed until 2009) and other weapons-dealing states (Russia, China, and

Middle Eastern countries), plus the National Rifle Association and associated pro-gun

groups.

The campaign‘s initial strategy was to get one government in each region of the world to

champion the ATT, and convince others to follow their lead in a snowball effect. Direct

lobbying won individual converts within governments, but it was mass petitions and

other public campaigning activities that made support for the ATT politically feasible. By

mid-2005, the snowball was rolling: at the Biennial meeting of the UN Programme of

119 F. Fukuyama,The Paradox of International Action, 2006

120 WHAT’S BEST EXAMPLE OF NGOS INFLUENCING BWI POLICY?

Page 67: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

67

Action on Small Arms, 55 states voiced support; by the end of 2006, 153 countries voted

in favour of moving towards a treaty. Fluid dialogue between campaigners and

governments made for a dynamic process that culminated when the ATT became

international law on Christmas Eve, 2014.121

International knowledge networks (comprising academics, policy makers and the

research arms of international institutions) can be as influential as NGOs on the arms

trade or TNCs on patents. Scientists and other scholars have successfully organized

global networks on health, weather and standards for well over a century. The

International Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) is in many ways a modern expression of a

perhaps nineteenth-century belief in the power of scientific knowledge to solve

humanity‘s most pressing problems. Like the technocrats of the World Bank and IMF,

they prefer to stand aloof from politics yet, when politics becomes the obstacle to

progress, such networks can act politically, as in the timing of the release of IPCC

reports.

Clearly the international system has changed since the days when the world‘s

governments sat down behind closed doors to negotiate rules on the use of violence. The

power to approve new restrictions the behaviour of states remains with those sovereign

entities. And they retain the power to implement and enforce such rules or not. But the

genesis of ideas and norms, and the motive to address them at the negotiating table, now

involves a much broader range of actors.

How the international system drives change

Given that most of the decisions that matter are ultimately taken by national

governments, it is not surprising that many technocrats at international institutions (and

not a few activists) yearn for the international system to acquire the ‗hard power‘ to

compel governments to act. They are drawn to those few bodies that can exercise such

influence: the UN Security Council, the IMF and the WTO, plus (to a lesser degree) the

International Criminal Court and the various treaty bodies.

UN sanctions can seek to weaken oppressive regimes, the IMF can try to impose public

spending cuts and tax increases, and the WTO can authorize fines to enforce drastic trade

liberalization. But such ‗hard power‘ has limits. International institutions can offer carrots

121 Update on ratification at final draft

Page 68: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

68

(aid and climate finance) and international law has a few sticks, but powerful countries

can ignore the rulings of international bodies or apply them selectively, while less

powerful governments often say yes and do nothing.

An underestimated strength of the international system is its ‗soft power‘: the ideas and

norms that filter down to societies and states via the UN‘s specialized agencies and

conventions. These are spread via peer pressure, research and knowledge and ‗bully

pulpits‘ in Washington or New York to frame what constitutes ‗good policy‘. One

example of such ‗thought leadership‘ is the Human Development Report, first published

by the UNDP in 1990. The HDR pioneered a rethinking of poverty and development

away from narrow definitions of income and economic performance; its broader focus on

the multiple aspects of well/ill-being has been accepted by much of the aid and

development sector today.

As discussed in chapter eight, the UN‘s most profound influence may well be its role in

agreeing and promoting the evolving norms that govern human society on everything

from the treatment of women, children or indigenous people to attitudes to corruption or

warfare.

The MDGs and SDGs: what happens when technocrats ignore politics Nothing better illustrates the gulf between a largely technocratic international system and

the realities of power and politics on the ground than the three years of discussions on a

successor to the Millennium Development Goals, agreed in 2000, and mostly expiring in

2015. As far as I could tell, a large group of UN technocrats were debating metrics and

indicators, while a huge panoply of NGO and other lobbyists were trying to shoehorn

‗their‘ issue onto an ever-expanding agenda.

The debate almost invariably conflated correlation and causation. Because poverty has

indeed been halved, many people argued the MDGs were a success, sidestepping the

awkward truth that the main reason behind global progress on poverty was the

extraordinary advance of China. And no-one argued that the Chinese government got up

every morning and asked ‗How can we achieve the MDGs today?‘

It is particularly baffling that almost no serious research has been done to establish

causation. When Columbia University‘s Elham Seyedsayamdost did so, surveying 50

Page 69: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

69

countries‘ implemention of the MDGs, she found that the goals had no apparent influence

on how governments spent their money.122

Yet at no point in the debate over the MDGs‘

successor, now known as the Sustainable Development Goals, did anyone ask what kind

of design might enable the SDGs to exert traction at the national level, or what lessons

could be learned from the success or failure of the hundreds of other global conventions

and agreements (the ILO alone has 190 of them).

Of course, by drawing attention to development issues such global discussions have some

value, especially insofar as they influence norms. Nevertheless, the relegation of national

traction, power and politics from the SDG debate seems an extraordinary failure.123

The

SDG process also made me highly sceptical about any sentence beginning with the words

‗we can‘, as in ‗we can end poverty/abolish hunger/eradicate this or that disease‘. The

‗we‘ is an imaginary construct, an exercise in technocratic ‗if-I-ruled-the-world‘ thinking

that ignores who will take and implement the decisions necessary to achieve any given

goal, not to mention the constraints those decision-makers face.124

Conclusion: How much does the multilateral system

matter?

It is easy to become disillusioned with the international system and its unappealing mix

of power politics, legalistic nitpicking and apolitical technocracy. When I first joined the

development NGOs, I stalked the pressrooms and NGO fringe events at summits and

international conferences, seduced by their aura of power and importance. Summits

generate a kind of Stockholm Syndrome even among marginal NGO types in attendance:

too many meetings, too little sleep and endless arguments over the fine print of

declarations can convince you that the fate of the world lies in changing ‗should‘ to

‗shall‘ in paragraph 2.b.iii.

I remember how disheartening it was when I finally got to ‗speak truth to power‘ at a UN

meeting in Geneva, only to watch my carefully honed speech disappear into the

cavernous room full of delegates chatting to each other and occasionally tuning in to the

122 http://oxfamblogs.org/fp2p/have-the-mdgs-affected-developing-country-policies-and-spending-

findings-of-new-50-country-study/ 123

http://policy-practice.oxfam.org.uk/publications/how-can-a-post-2015-agreement-drive-real-change-revised-edition-the-political-e-250371 124

http://oxfamblogs.org/fp2p/incantations-inclusive-growth-and-the-illusory-we-whatever-happened-to-politics-in-the-post-2015-process/

Page 70: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

70

simultaneous translation. It brought to mind a renowned phrase of UN Secretary-General

Dag Hammarskjöld, ‗The United Nations was not created to take mankind to heaven, but

to save humanity from hell.‘ That year, 2005, marked a personal watershed – after Make

Poverty History and yet another WTO summit in Hong Kong, I dropped out of the

frontline of NGO advocacy.

Disillusion is tempting because so many of the system‘s strengths are frustratingly

intangible. Activists want certainty – institutions with teeth that can compel the bad guys

to mend their ways and make good, progressive things happen. But over time I have

become convinced the strongest suit of the international system lies in soft power:

influence over norms and ideas, rather than specific policies. Though these are certainly

insufficient to address the pressing problems of our world, they are crucial in shaping the

future.

I also understand the beguiling allure of a technocratic approach that holds itself above

politics. It‘s no wonder the IMF and WTO prefer secret agreements that bind states

behind closed doors. National politics more often than not punishes leaders who seek to

address the challenges humanity faces, especially when they engage the international

system to do so. And it seems to reward those who turn their backs on anything but

domestic affairs.

Mark Malloch Brown calls it ‗the Gordon Brown problem‘. At the onset of the financial

crisis in 2008, U.K. finance minister Brown showed extraordinary leadership at the G7

and G20 in pushing for public investment to avert an even greater global meltdown. Yet

his political reward was negligible because, though action had to be global, votes

remained national, with little credit (and lots of brickbats) for leaders engaging in foreign

policy, even if it involves saving the world (as Brown inadvertently claimed).125

Politics may seem to point in one direction, the needs of humanity in another, but in the

end, I believe that politics, flawed as it is, is all we have. Only when national

governments find it politically advantageous to do so will they take action on collective

problems like climate change, pandemics, crime, weapons proliferation, migration or

race-to-the-bottom competition between nations on taxation. A key role for activists is to

tackle the Gordon Brown problem, working to transform the national debate so that

political leaders will step up to these challenges.

125 Malloch Brown p.199

Page 71: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

71

Growing up in the West of England, national elections in the Bath constituency where I

lived were enlivened by a classic English eccentric. Posters would appear saying ‗vote for

Gilbert Young, World Government Party‘. (The party's other proposals included

turning Buckingham Palace into a home for old age pensioners.) Young never won more

than a few hundred votes, and his party died with him in 1998, but as global collective

action problems become more pressing, and a soft, normative response increasingly

insufficient, he may end up being proved right after all.

Making the international system work is essential to the survival of our species. And that

could quite possibly include a move from global governance to global government in

some form. World government may seem politically impossible, but then so have many

other features of today‘s world, before they came to be seen first as inevitable, then as

natural. Perhaps one day, Gilbert Young will be lauded as a prophet in the 1970s

wilderness.

Page 72: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

72

7 Transnational corporations126

Brian was in an expansive mood. Relaxing over a beer in the Bangladeshi capital of

Dhaka, he explained why he had abandoned a British émigré‘s retirement in Florida to

run a large garment factory, where some 2,000 women churned out sportswear for Nike.

‗I‘m not doing this for the money – I don‘t need it‘, he mused. ‗It‘s providing jobs for all

those women that makes it worthwhile.‘

I was in an awkward position. Thanks to Brian, I had earlier toured the factory (off limits

to most visiting NGOs), now I was bonding with him as a fellow Brit, but I could hardly

let this pass. After a quick calculation, I made a mischievous suggestion: ‗Well why don‘t

you give your salary to the women? It would double their wages -- all 2,000 of them!‘

‗No way‘, he retorted. ‗It‘s all about keeping count.‘ At his level, salary is more about

status than income.

Staying friends with Brian wasn‘t the only source of awkwardness that day. I was

researching a report for a campaign on exploitative transnationals. Yet the garment

workers I interviewed, both onsite and off, had told me how much they prized working at

the clean, modern factory in one of Dhaka‘s export processing zones. It was infinitely

preferable to a sewing job in one of the dingy, dangerous local factories in downtown

Dhaka, the women said, let alone a life of domestic servitude back in the village.

Because global brands like Nike are ubiquitous, they epitomize widespread concern about

globalization and have become the favoured target of campaigners. Transnational

corporations (TNCs) certainly hold significant power. The TNC universe now spans

some 103,000 parent companies with over 886,000 foreign affiliates.127

In 2014, these

generated an estimated $7.9 trillion in value added and employed some 75 million

workers. The total sales of TNCs‘ foreign affiliates rose from $4.7 to $36.4 trillion

between 1990 and 2014.128

126 I’M A BIT DISSATISFIED WITH THIS CHAPTER – NEED MORE ON HOW TNCS MAKE CHANGE HAPPEN,

AND HOW THEY THEMSELVES CHANGE. SOURCES OR IDEAS PLEASE! 127

http://www.unctad.org/sections/dite_dir/docs/WIR11_web%20tab%2034.pdf – any more recent stats? 128

UNCTAD, World Investment Report 2015, pp. ix and 18

Page 73: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

73

Anxiety over their sheer size has prompted quite a few critics to presume corporations

rule the world.129

One of the most widely visited posts on my From Poverty to Power

blog is a World Bank table that shows the world‘s top 100 economies: 53 are countries

(measured by GDP), 34 are cities (ditto) and 13 are corporations (measured by

turnover).130

Strictly speaking, this is comparing apples and pears; companies‘ value

added is a better (and lower) measure than turnover. But it remains a fact that a number

of firms rival medium-sized countries in economic might.

The reach of their operations has turned large TNCs into significant players in economic

change, as well as influential players in political and social change. For better or worse,

corporations have, among other things, transformed local and regional economies,

rewritten the rulebook governing their operations and, as Brian said, helped spark

women‘s emancipation in countries around the world. Over time they have evolved as

institutions, becoming more sensitive to public opinion regarding their social and

environmental impact.

Some background

The East India Company, established in 1600 with a trading empire that encircled the

globe, was the mother of modern TNCs.131

Its imports of spices, textiles and teas wrought

a lifestyle revolution in the United Kingdom, but the company also became a byword for

corporate malpractice and general skulduggery, conquering nations and ruling over

millions with its private army. When China tried to stop the company from flooding the

country with smuggled narcotics, two Opium Wars ensued.

The East India Company pioneered the cycle of corruption, bubbles and bail-outs that has

been all too frequent in the corporate landscape in recent years. It also launched the

shareholder model of corporate ownership, which allowed companies to burst beyond the

bounds set by family wealth and capacity. The last third of the nineteenth century saw an

explosion of new corporations in Europe and the United States.132

129 D. Korten, When Corporations Rule the World, 2001

130 http://oxfamblogs.org/fp2p/the-worlds-top-100-economies-53-countries-34-cities-and-13-

corporations/ 131

N. Robins, the Corporation that Changed the World: How the East India Company shaped the Modern Multinational, 2012 132

Multinational Corporations, Columbia Business School briefing, https://www0.gsb.columbia.edu/faculty/bkogut/files/Chapter_in_smelser-Baltes_2001.pdf

Page 74: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

74

Across the developing world, recognizably modern TNCs initially concentrated on

transport, building railways to facilitate the extraction of raw materials and the marketing

of their manufactures. Soon, TNCs expanded into communications (telephones, radio,

movies), energy (oil, gas, electricity)133

and subsequently manufacturing.134

The first wave of global TNC expansion peaked just before global markets fragmented in

the Great Depression and World War Two. In the post-war era, TNCs‘ expanded again,

although the larger developing countries in Latin America and later Africa limited their

operations in order to protect nascent local industry. Widespread nationalizations made

TNCs much more wary of investing.135

In the wake of the oil shock of the 1970s and the debt crisis that followed, policies shifted

as developing-country governments increasingly competed for foreign investment. TNC

expansion this time began with manufacturing and extractive industries, but really took

off in the 1990s in services – finance, management consultants, tourism, hotels and fast

food. As of 2014, services accounted for 63 per cent of global foreign direct investment,

more than twice the share of manufacturing (26 per cent). The primary sector (farms,

mines, gas and oil) contributed less than 10 per cent.136

The past thirty years has also seen the rise of new TNCs from emerging economies in

South and East Asia and Latin America. According to the UN, ‗developing Asia‘ (i.e.

excluding Japan) now invests abroad more than any other region.137

Compared with their

developed-country counterparts, southern TNCs are more likely to be state-or family-

owned and many are based in the primary sector or resource-based manufacturing, such

as iron, steel, and cement.138

All the major players in African telecommunications are

from other developing countries.139

133 AD Chandler, Mazlish, B., 2005, Leviathans: Multinational Corporations and the New Global History

134 AD Chandler, Mazlish, B., 2005, Leviathans: Multinational Corporations and the New Global History,

p.20 135

AD Chandler, Mazlish, B., 2005, Leviathans: Multinational Corporations and the New Global History, p.40 136

UNCTAD, World Investment Report 2015, p.12 137

Other strong economies like Taiwan and Northern Italy have relied more on networks of small and medium enterprises, and failed to produce many global companies. UNCTAD, World Investment Report 2015, p. ix 138 UNCTAD, World Investment Report 2006. 139 A. Goldstein (2005) ‘Emerging Multinationals in the Global Economy: Data Trends, Policy Issues, and Research Questions’, OECD Development Centre.

Page 75: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

75

Southern TNCs have also become major investors in northern economies. In the UK,

India‘s Tata Steel now owns Corus while Tata Motors owns Jaguar; Brazil‘s Vale mining

conglomerate bought Canada‘s second largest mining company, Inco, in 2006; Mexico‘s

dynamic cement company Cemex has built a global network through mergers and

acquisitions. Chinese companies‘ attempts to buy US firms have provoked a nationalist

backlash on several occasions.

While China‘s growing investment in Africa (and its less publicised surge in Southeast

Asia and Latin America) is best known in the extractive industries, in fact Chinese firms

have taken on a significant number of infrastructure projects deemed too risky by

European or US firms.140

In Sierra Leone in 2005, within two years of the end of a

bloody civil war, China was already investing $270 million in hotel construction and

tourism.141

The acronym ‗TNC‘ is somewhat misleading, since few are genuinely transnational: most

retain a high degree of linkage to their home countries, particularly in terms of where

decision-making power lies and the high-value end of research and design is located.

That home identity shapes their corporate culture, leading to hybrid forms: when

Japanese TNCs set up a factory in Europe, they blend Japanese and European work

practices.142

When a Chinese company builds roads in Africa, it even imports Chinese

workers.143

Developing-country TNCs are more likely to use ‗intermediate‘ technologies that are

more labour-intensive and so create more jobs.144

Like their northern counterparts, their

performance on social and environmental responsibility varies widely.

Most modern TNCs bear little resemblance to the vertically integrated corporations of

yesteryear, where for example United Fruit directly owned and managed its banana

plantations and Ford its factories. Today TNCs sit atop complex ‗global production

networks‘, coordinating a web of interconnected firms in multiple locations, through a

mind-boggling combination of subcontracting, outsourcing, offshoring, partnerships and

140 http://www.chinaafricarealstory.com/

141 http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/hi/africa/3694043.stm 142

P. Dicken, Global Shift: Mapping the Changing Contours of the World Economy, 6th

ed, 2011, p. 122 143

http://www.reuters.com/article/2013/07/21/africa-china-idUSL6N0FI3TE20130721 144 OECD (2006) ‘Developing Country Multinationals: South–South Investment Comes of Age’.

Page 76: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

76

mergers and acquisitions.145

According to the UN, global production networks accounted

for 80 per cent of international trade in 2012.146

How TNCs make change

In 20XX I visited a Dutch-owned flower farm in Ethiopia‘s Rift Valley, Herburg Roses

Ethiopia plc. The farm was enormous – rows of identical green plastic greenhouses, each

a kilometre in length, covering a total of 325 hectares and counting. Following a

regrettably hurried conversation with the managers and a quick chat with some workers, I

was left with a series of unasked or unanswered questions, what the French call pensées

d’escalier (‗thoughts on the stairs‘).

Herburg‘s operation employs 26 people per hectare to grow its flowers, which is a lot

more than can make a living from a hectare of any other of Ethiopia‘s crops. And judging

by the long lines outside the farm gates Ethiopians want to work there. Flowers also bring

in vital foreign exchange. The Ethiopian government requires a minimum investment of

€0.08 per flower exported. Herburg alone exports 80 million roses a year, which means

€6.4 million for Ethiopia. Of course, since a dozen roses costs £40 in a UK supermarket,

or €3.91 per rose, 97 per cent of the final value never reaches Ethiopia.

Herberg built a gleaming hospital, free to all employees, plus a nursery and primary

school. The company is regularly audited and certified on both its environmental and

social performance. But Herburg was granted a five-year tax holiday (that runs out next

year) and after that it will probably make sure its profits accrue in Holland or some tax

haven, so that little corporation tax will ever be paid in Ethiopia.

Oxfam undertook a more rigorous assessment of the ‗poverty footprint‘147,148

of a number

of companies. One study showed strikingly that more than half of the 300,000 jobs

Unilever‘s operations generate in Indonesia are in the company‘s ‗downstream‘

distribution and retail chain, and only about one-third in the part that makes inputs for the

145 NEED MORE ON WHO MAKES WHAT DECISIONS ARE MADE IN TNCS INVOLVED IN GLOBAL

PRODUCTION NETWORKS 146

World Investment Report 2013 147

http://www.oxfamamerica.org/static/oa3/files/coca-cola-sab-miller-poverty-footprint-dec-2011.pdf 148

http://oxfamilibrary.openrepository.com/oxfam/bitstream/10546/290820/8/rr-exploring-links-ipl-poverty-footprint-090513-summ-en.pdf

Page 77: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

77

company‘s products (campaigners‘ usual focus).149

And, as at Herberg, the Oxfam studies

confirmed that TNC employment is often better paid than most. However, wages,

conditions and the right to organize were found to be weakest in the more informal parts

of a company‘s operations, away from the comparatively ordered world of permanent

employees.

Beyond the direct impact in capital investment, jobs and taxes (when they pay them), the

training for local staff TNCs provide and the technology they introduce can spill over into

the local economy, especially when companies source materials and services from local

suppliers. And many TNCs provide products and services that people living in poverty

not only want, but can use to improve their lives.150

Southern-based companies have proven adept at producing and marketing products for

poorer consumers. Chinese electronics companies such as TCL make $50 colour

television sets in India and Viet Nam.151

In Tanzania, the Swahili name for cheap motor-

bike rickshaws is ‗bajaji‘, a corruption of Bajaj – the Indian firm that makes them. When

India‘s Tata Motors launched its $2,500 ‗people‘s car‘ in 2008 it followed in the

footsteps of the Volkswagen Beetle or the Model T Ford, promising to bring cars to new

generations of consumers in the rest of the developing world.152

TNCs do not only follow consumers‘ desires; they also attempt shape them, often to

resemble those of the former colonialist powers (think McDonald‘s), and sometimes in

ways that are controversial. Perhaps the most notorious is Nestlé‘s effort to persuade

mothers in poor countries to abandon breast-feeding in favour of formula milk, despite

the expense and the risks arising from dirty water. It sparked a global boycott that did

lasting damage to the company‘s previously impressive reputation.

While many firms are diligent in obeying the law and treating their employees and

customers with respect, others abuse their power, causing lasting negative effects on the

environment, public health and local politics that undermine the potential for

development. Organizations like Global Witness publish regular exposes of corporate

destruction of the environment; tax campaigners point to TNCs‘ widespread avoidance of

149 J. Clay (2006) ‘Exploring the Links Between International Business and Poverty Reduction: A Case Study of Unilever in Indonesia’, Oxford: Oxfam GB, Oxfam Novib, Unilever. 150

C.K. Prahalad, 2004, The Fortune at the Bottom of the Pyramid 151 ‘FDI Trends’, World Bank Public Policy for the Private Sector Journal, September 2005, World Bank. See http://rru.worldbank.org/documents/publicpolicyjournal/273palmade_anayiotas.pdf 152 http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/hi/business/7180396.stm

Page 78: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

78

taxation; anti-sweatshop activists highlight labour abuses. World Bank figures suggest

that $1 trillion in bribes is paid annually by international companies to secure lucrative

deals.153

TNCs and government policy

Corporations welcome the creative bit of the market‘s ‗creative destruction‘, the constant

evolutionary churn as new ideas, products and companies rise and fall, which provides

the raw material companies can turn into global empires (I still remember the first time

someone recommended Google‘s nice clean search engine homepage). But they do

everything they can to avoid the destruction part, including a plentiful resort to ‗rigged

rules and double standards‘, in the words of one Oxfam report.154

TNCs have lobbied extensively for government handouts, patent protection, exclusive

contracts, tax breaks, trade rules and other state interventions that may favour their

bottom lines. As one foreign banker admitted to the Wall Street Journal at the time of the

Latin American debt crisis of the 1980s, ‗We foreign bankers are for the free market

system when we are out to make a buck and believe in the state when we‘re about to lose

a buck.‘155

When it comes to specific regulation that restricts their freedom to operate as they please,

most corporate executives fight tooth and nail to block it, often driven by their belief in

the innate goodness of their companies or the innate inefficiency of government. From

laws on minimum wage, health and safety, or freedom of association to rules on product

quality, corporate governance or consumer protection, corporate stonewalling has been

nearly universal. Most TNCs view state industrial policy – such as South Korea‘s, which

protected and encouraged fledgling industries until they were ready to compete on the

world market – as anathema and will deploy their impressive lobby apparatus to block or

dismantle them.156

The nature of the deals struck between particular governments and TNCs is shaped by

their relative bargaining power. If the host country has something the TNC wants

153 In 2004

153, the World Bank estimated that over 60 per cent of multinational corporations paid

undocumented bribes in non-OECD countries to procure contracts. World Bank, www.worldbank.org/wbi/governance/pdf/icac_hk_survey_results_5_06.pdf. 154

Oxfam, Rigged Rules and Double Standards, 2002 155 Wall Street Journal, 24 May 1985. 156

HJ Chang, Kicking Away the Ladder

Page 79: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

79

(markets, skilled labour, access to export markets), the government‘s hand is stronger and

it will be able to insist on benefits for local people and firms. The more desperate the

government, the harder the bargain a TNC can drive.

Because corporations want reliable infrastructure, a healthy, educated workforce and

sizable domestic markets, direct investment is heavily concentrated in richer countries,

which are also the ones that can bargain effectively: Brazil, China, India, Mexico, and the

Russian Federation received 42 per cent of FDI inflows to developing countries in

2010.157

By contrast, the poorest states are easily bullied with threats of moving

somewhere else. The painful paradox implied is that the more a government needs

foreign investment, the worse the deal it is likely get. However, the balance of power

tends to shift over time: a TNC is most powerful in initial negotiations, less so once it has

invested capital and is less likely to leave.

International institutions (discussed in chapter six) often intervene to set the rules and

shape the balance of power between states and TNCs. While the relatively weak UN

agencies provide training and advice to buttress state capacity, the powerful World Bank

and IMF impose loan conditions that protect TNCs from what they view as interference

by the state. Loan conditions have included such measures as elimination of capital

controls and export taxes, unilateral tariff reductions and privatization of state companies

and public services. Since the 1990s, a web of bilateral investment treaties and regional

and global (WTO) trade agreements has further constrained states‘ ability to regulate

TNC behaviour, for example by proscribing the basic elements of industrial policy.

Corporate lobbying behind closed doors is a key driver of the way trade agreements have

evolved. On one of my first visits to the WTO, I burst out laughing when one besuited

gent introduced himself in a meeting with officials by saying ‗I‘m from British

Invisibles‘. It turned out he was speaking for a powerful association of finance firms that

was an extremely effective lobby; true to its name, the general public was largely

oblivious of its existence.

One of the most vigorous lobbyists at both global and national levels is the

pharmaceutical sector. In the USA, pharmaceutical companies employ 3,000 lobbyists

and spend millions to influence national laws and the US position in trade negotiations.158

157 Calculated from http://www.unctad.org/sections/dite_dir/docs/WIR11_web%20tab%201.pdf, http://data.worldbank.org UPDATE? 158

J. Stiglitz (2006) Making Globalization Work.

Page 80: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

80

In the Uruguay Round that led to the creation of the WTO in 1995, the pharmaceutical

lobby steamrollered through an agreement on intellectual property whose implications

were unclear to many of those involved. Only after it came into effect did developing

countries realise they had signed up to a major extension of corporate monopolies and

high-priced drugs that would amount to a death sentence for thousands of sick and dying

people.

Although national and international action by groups like South Africa‘s Treatment

Action Campaign have drawn attention to the problem and helped prompt the more

enlightened drug companies to reduce some prices, intellectual property rules still

provide extraordinary opportunities for profiteering. In 2015, the company Turing

became notorious when it raised the price of Daraprim, a 62-year-old treatment for a

dangerous parasitic infection, to $750 (£488) a pill from $13.50 (£8.79). The medicine

once sold for $1 a pill.159

How do TNCs change?

We activists are often tempted to exaggerate our impact on corporate behaviour. More

weighty factors arise from the web of regulation, relationships and responsibilities in

which TNCs are immersed. Activist civil society organizations are players in this web,

known collectively by the unfortunate term ‗stakeholders‘ (which always makes me think

of people trying to kill a vampire) but it also includes shareholders, customers, the state

and other companies.

Above all, corporate executives are subject to the bottom line – if the company loses

money, it will go bust or be bought out. That brutal discipline can be a source of

dynamism and innovation, yet as business strategist Simon Levitt argues, TNCs‘ default

mode is to defend the status quo or at least delay change as long as possible.160

The

greater their capital investment (e.g. oil companies‘ fixed investments in drilling rigs), the

more they will resist change.

Levitt identifies four factors corporations have evaluated before supporting progressive

change: protecting their brand (especially important for consumer goods companies); the

economic cost; the likelihood of impending change in government policy (companies

159 http://www.theguardian.com/business/2015/sep/23/us-pharmaceutical-firm-to-roll-back-5000-price-

hike-on-drug 160

S. Levitt, ‘Under what conditions to TNCs lobby for change?’, mimeo

Page 81: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

81

may decide to jump before they are pushed); and whether the firm stands to gain relative

to its current or potential future competitors. Beyond such cost/benefit calculations,

leadership matters in overcoming inertia and inspiring a commitment to change; notable

figures like Paul Polman (Unilever) and Andrew Whitty (GSK) have had system-wide

influence over how companies think about their social and environmental role.161

These factors play out within longer-term tidal shifts. Technology is the most obvious –

the expansion of TNCs to their present pre-eminence has been driven by successive

waves of technological progress in transport, communications and production that first

allowed them to trade across geographical distances, then create a global assembly line

for their products, and most recently to manage complex global production networks.

Economic development is another, as TNCs increasingly see China, India and others as

lucrative markets, rather than primarily as enormous reservoirs of cheap labour.

Other long-term shifts are more subtle. The very idea of what a corporation should be and

do has evolved over time. In a 1970 article entitled ‗The Social Responsibility of

Business is to Increase its Profits‘, economist Milton Friedman accused promoters of

corporate social responsibility of ‗preaching pure and unadulterated socialism.‘162

Few

companies today would agree. The norms governing corporate behaviour (much like

human behaviour) have evolved, partly through peer pressure among executives. At the

annual gathering of corporate titans in the Swiss skiing resort of Davos, ‗masters of the

universe‘ swap notes and influence each other, providing an annual snapshot of a global

conversation to which ordinary mortals are seldom admitted.

Though Friedman‘s words now seem to emanate from a bygone age, shareholders and

owners still hold the most power to shape a company‘s actions. That may be why some of

the more progressive companies are not publicly listed, but are owned by families or

foundations that are able to take a longer-term view than investors seeking to maximise

quarterly returns, which is often incompatible with pursuing social and environmental

goals.163

161 S. Levitt, ‘Under what conditions do TNCs lobby for change?’, mimeo

162 ‘The Social Responsibility of Business is to Increase its Profits’, New York Times Magazine, September

13, 1970 163

http://oxfamblogs.org/fp2p/how-businesses-can-save-the-world-when-their-shareholders-arent-breathing-down-their-neck/

Page 82: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

82

There are differences among shareholders. Some years ago, I ran a small NGO called Just

Pensions, which lobbied pension funds to take just such a long-term view. Several of

them agreed that to provide decent pensions for their members, often decades into the

future, they should be concerned about the destruction wrought by climate change, the

business impacts of poverty in development countries and other long-term threats. 164

In companies where workers have managed to organize, trade unions can exert

significant influence, especially regarding wages and working conditions. However,

unions have struggled to ‗transnationalize‘ along with their employers, linking up

workers in different countries, and to organize within global production networks

characterized by subcontracting and outsourcing.

Corporations with brand names are highly sensitive to the views of consumers, since bad

publicity can destroy overnight brands painstakingly built up over decades. Activists have

found success with high-profile campaigns, such as the Nestlé boycott noted above, and

with more nuanced engagement, in which civil society organizations use the threat of

consumer pressure to persuade companies to improve their social and environmental

record.

Corporate social responsibility as a strategy

Geoff, a senior manager in a major UK supermarket, wandered over to me after the

meeting with a startling proposition. ‗Do you think you NGOs could campaign a bit

harder against us? My board is thinking of cutting my budget.‘ I sat with Geoff on the

multi-stakeholder Ethical Trading Initiative to promote labour rights and decent working

conditions in his and other firms‘ global supply chains. It seems he needed a credible

threat (and some dark arts) to keep his company engaged.

That conversation took place in the early 2000s, during a wave of ‗corporate social

responsibility‘ (CSR) that has since spread across much of the private sector. CSR is

controversial: denounced as corporate spin by opponents, it is held up by supporters as a

market-friendly alternative to inefficient government regulation. I was definitely in the

supporter camp.

The ETI was my first real experience of ‗convening and brokering‘, although we didn‘t

use the term back then. It was uncomfortable: although we were friendly, the initiative

164 NEED TO ADJUST THE MENTION OF JUST PENSIONS IN CHAPTER TEN TO TAKE INTO ACCOUNT THE

MENTION HERE

Page 83: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

83

relied on a mix of confrontation and cooperation (as Geoff clearly recognized). The

unions hated having to cede a place at the table to NGOs, whom they regarded as middle-

class interlopers trespassing on their traditional dialogue with employers, but they had to

accept that it was the charities that brought the supermarkets to the table.

One basic lesson I learned at the ETI was not to lump all corporations together. The

initiative had its share of leaders and laggards (I won‘t start naming names), and the trick

was to use the former to put pressure on the latter – nothing galvanizes action like being

shamed in front of your peers and rivals. I also learned that CSR departments rarely have

much clout in the corporation as a whole. Their power depends highly on the credibility

of the threat of bad publicity (thus Geoff‘s unusual request) and the personal inclinations

of the top executives.

My time at the ETI gave me a lasting respect for the dynamism and seriousness of the

people who run TNCs. Once you get past the spinners in the CSR or corporate

communications teams, the people you find tend to want results and can be can be as

concerned about world problems as any activist. Suited and booted in a central London

cafe, I once tried to recruit a new garment retailer. I deployed my best corporate speak,

stressing the business case for CSR – recruiting better people, keeping them longer, better

supply chain management, avoiding damage to reputation and brand. The exasperated

executive interrupted me: ‗Forget all that, I just want to make the world better for my

grandchildren‘. I still remember my sense of shame.

Conclusions

The developmental impact of TNCs is often oversold: they don‘t rule the world, and the

jobs they create are dwarfed by the numbers of people working on farms, in street

markets or for small businesses. But they wield significant power, both to directly shape

government policies and international rules, and to get inside people‘s heads (both

decision makers and the public) to shape the norms and attitudes that are form the subject

of the next chapter.

Some TNCs will destroy the environment or abuse the rights of workers and consumers.

Their depredations need to be restrained by law and public pressure.

But overall, large international companies have the potential to be much more positive

players for development, to pay their taxes, help upgrade the skills and technologies of

poor countries, to pressure for clean, rule-based and responsive government.

Page 84: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

84

How might they move faster and further in that direction? Taking a systems approach,

change will come quicker if those seeking it are ready to seize the windows of

opportunity provided by crises and critical junctures, build fast feedback loops to reward

positive steps, and highlight negative ones, and are ready to work in coalitions of

‗unusual suspects‘ (consumers, investors, trade unions, business associations).

In many sectors, leading companies are already on their way. The challenge there is to

push them along, while working with them and other stakeholders to ensure peer pressure

and state action encourage the rest to catch up.

Page 85: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

85

8 Norms and change

Over a beer in a remote corner of Bolivia, Miguel Rivera, a Chiquitano activist,

confessed, ‗A sense of our rights came from outside, from political leaders and ILO

Convention 169. It was important, it made our indigenous part wake up.‘165

It wasn‘t the kind of conversation you have every day and, to be honest, I didn‘t entirely

welcome it. I had trekked deep into the Bolivian interior to find out how social change

happened in the exotic (to me) world of Latin America‘s indigenous movement, and here

was a grassroots activist quoting the stuffy, Geneva-based International Labour

Organisation, telling me his people‘s success was partly down to those international

talking shops of which I had previously been so dismissive.

At least the setting lived up to expectations. The Chiquitanos are best known outside

Bolivia from the 1986 film The Mission, which recounts how they became (and remain)

adept Baroque musicians who built extraordinary huge white and orange churches that

still attract tourists to the region, despite suffering some of the worst depredations of

European colonialism.

The conversation with Miguel in the sweltering heat of the summer of 2006 helped shape

my initial thinking on how change happens and has stayed with me ever since. He

educated me about the importance of social norms - the explicit or implicit rules

specifying what behaviours are acceptable in society. What people see as normal,

desirable or aberrant determines their sense of right and wrong, and can both drive and

hold back the search for social justice.

Norms come in all shapes and sizes, whether social, legal or moral, and they exhibit a

subtle contradiction, which they share with institutions like the state or transnational

corporations: they are both static and changing. At any given moment, most norms

appear fixed; people see them as a ‗given‘, a pre-existing, eternal, social reality. Without

that sense of fixity, norms would not provide what they must, namely stable standards of

conduct to guide the choices of those subject to them. Yet, at the same time, norms are

165 Author interview, 2006.

Page 86: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

86

continuously evolving. Even law – the most codified, formal subset of norms – is

constantly changing.166

Over time the extent to which norms change is extraordinary. Two hundred years ago,

slavery and colonization were seen as the natural order of things (at least in Europe). Men

ruled dictatorially over women and parents over their children. States were

unencumbered in their conduct of war; today they are partly circumscribed by rules.

Entire bodies of international law – human rights, environment – did not even exist a

century ago. As these timelines suggest, normative change is deep and slow, often

measured in generations or centuries. For that reason it sometimes passes relatively

unobserved and unappreciated by activists or politicians who think in the three- or four-

year cycles of elections and campaigns.

How norms drive change

For much of human history, norms have mostly evolved organically in local and national

communities. Over the last century, however, a formal process for debating, agreeing,

codifying and implementing global norms has come into being, housed within a number

of international institutions, such as the UN and the International Labour Organization so

revered by Miguel Rivera.

Today that normative framework advances through a bewildering proliferation of

conferences, ‗high level panels‘, international targets such as the Sustainable

Development Goals, treaties and conventions, a merry-go-round I often prefer to avoid,

due to the prevalence of rhetoric and platitude over substance. My aversion is probably

unjustified. The body of international agreements that has emerged from them captures

the world‘s evolving understanding of its condition, building our sense of belonging to

one ‗humanity‘. It nudges attitudes forward on everything from whether bribery is

acceptable or parents have the right to beat their children, to discrimination against

migrant workers, indigenous people or those living with disability, or what activity

should be considered as ‗work‘.

Very little of this involves ‗hard law‘, enforceable in the courts with fines and sentences –

the International Criminal Court and (to a lesser extent) the WTO are exceptions. Most is

‗soft law‘, setting a standard that national movements can use to rally for changes in

national legislation and public attitudes. As noted in chapter four, legislative reform can

166 W. Sandholtz & K Stiles, International Norms and Cycles of Change, 2009

Page 87: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

87

help promote norm changes, especially when it reflects a shift in thinking that is already

underway in the population at large.

A good example of how international agreements both reflect and lead changes in public

attitudes is the Convention on the Elimination of All Forms of Discrimination Against

Women. Adopted in 1979 by the UN General Assembly, CEDAW is often described as

an international bill of rights for women. It defines what constitutes discrimination

against women and obliges states to commit themselves to a series of measures,

including:

to incorporate the principle of equality of men and women in their legal system,

abolish all discriminatory laws and adopt appropriate ones prohibiting

discrimination against women;

to establish tribunals and other public institutions to ensure the effective

protection of women against discrimination; and

to ensure elimination of all acts of discrimination against women by persons,

organizations or enterprises.

CEDAW and the agreements that emerged from the 1994 International Conference on

Population and Development in Cairo and the 1995 World Conference on Women in

Beijing created a normative framework that national movements used to exert steady

upwards pressure on respect for women‘s rights in public attitudes and in legislation. At

the time of writing, 189 countries worldwide have ratified CEDAW.167

My personal moment of conversion regarding the central role of international law in

changing norms came with the 1989 Convention on the Rights of the Child. This treaty

obliges ratifying governments to protect children from discrimination, to ensure that their

best interests are of primary consideration in policy-making, to ensure their survival and

development, and remarkably to ‗assure to the child who is capable of forming his or her

own views the right to express those views freely in all matters affecting the child.‘ The

CRC rapidly proved something of a phenomenon in international law, becoming the most

widely and rapidly ratified human rights treaty in history. Only three countries, Somalia,

South Sudan and the United States, have not ratified.168

167 http://www.un.org/womenwatch/daw/cedaw/, accessed 28 August 2015

168 https://www.hrw.org/news/2014/11/17/25th-anniversary-convention-rights-child

Page 88: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

88

A few years after the Convention came into force, Save the Children sent me to Latin

America and the Caribbean to research a book on its impact. Across Latin America,

ratification had triggered a spate of new ‗children‘s codes‘ such as Brazil‘s Child and

Adolescent Statute (ECA) and child rights defenders like Peru‘s Demunas (Defensoria

Municipal para Ninos y Adolescentes). Most progress was achieved (both in law and,

more importantly in the lives of children) where domestic movements of children and

their supporters were strong enough to put pressure on governments from below, to

match the pressure from above exerted by the existence of the Convention.

Across the region, I had hundreds of conversations with activists, both children and

adults, who were using the CRC as the basis for their campaigns. Along with Philippe

Aries‘ paradigm-changing book Centuries of Childhood,169

they changed my view of the

nature of childhood and the roles, rights and responsibilities of children. As the father of

two young kids of my own at the time, I became acutely aware of the need to respect the

voice and agency of children themselves. Working children told me how much they

valued contributing to their family‘s welfare; street kids laughed while boasting about

their ability to get what they could from the various organizations intent on ‗rescuing‘

them (‗the food‘s better there, but they make you pray‘). Of course, working children also

complained of exploitation and the difficulties of combining work and school, and the

street kids were often drugged up and miserable, but the sense of agency remained.

When the book was published, I learned that challenging norms about something as

deeply personal as our attitudes towards children can provoke very powerful reactions.

Trade unions accused me of justifying child exploitation, street child organizations of

undermining their work. They preferred a notion of childhood as an innocent ‗walled

garden‘ in need of protection.

How norms evolve

Women‘s roles have undergone massive changes over the last century. What has been the

main factor behind this shift: the right to vote or employment outside the home, the

invention of the washing machine, girls‘ education, new forms of contraception, access to

information or the women‘s movement? The answer of course is all of the above and

more. Each of these factors has both shaped and been shaped by the evolving norms on

women‘s roles.

169 P. Aries, Centuries of Childhood: A Social History of Family Life, 1965

Page 89: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

89

I saw the impact of technology and trade for myself in Bangladesh. At 7.30 am every

morning, the streets of the capital, Dhaka, light up as a Technicolor tide of young women

in vivid saris emerge from the slums en route to the many mouldering factories that line

the streets of the city. The women remain there until well into the night, cutting and

stitching clothes for export.

Observing the thousands of women on the move, I struggled to maintain my activist‘s

disapproval of globalization and its ‗exploitation‘ of cheap labour. The women were

laughing, engaged and eager. Subsequent conversations in their shanty town huts

confirmed the importance and desirability of jobs in the garment factories. Outsiders tend

to focus (with considerable justification) on the low wages, long hours and workplace

dangers affecting millions of women in Bangladesh‘s garment industry. The women

certainly talked and complained about these, but they also praised the benefits that

earning an income brings at home in terms of a redistribution of power: women can now

leave the house without male permission and they exercise more of a voice in household

decisions; girl children are more valued than before.

As you would expect in a complex system such as the global garment trade, the factories

did not head for Dhaka intent on liberating Bangladesh‘s women – as everywhere else,

the evolution of gender norms was an accidental by-product of structural changes in the

economy. And other factors such as urbanization and the spread of television, with its

soap opera portrayals of ‗modern‘ and largely urban women, also played a part. In rural

India, the introduction of cable television in the early 2000s led to significant reported

increases in women‘s autonomy, a fall in the acceptability of domestic violence and

decreases in preference for male offspring. Researchers also found increases in female

school enrolment, decreased dropout rates and decreases in the number of children

women have. The correlation was striking – between 45 and 70 per cent of the difference

between rural and urban areas disappeared within two years of cable‘s introduction.170

As with many other aspects of change within systems, ‗critical junctures‘ such as wars or

political and economic crises play a significant role in norm shifts. In the US, the

experience of blacks and whites fighting alongside each other in World War II helped

galvanize the civil rights movement. More recently, protest movements such as Occupy,

170 Jensen, R. and Oster, E. (2007) ‘The Power of TV: Cable Television and Women's Status in India’.

Working Paper 13305. Cambridge, MA: NBER

Page 90: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

90

and increased attention to inequality from political leaders, the IMF and campaigners,

suggest the global financial crisis that began in 2008 is helping to change attitudes.

Norms v self-interest

Sometimes norms shift because they get backing from a constituency that spots an

opportunity for greater power or wealth, as when businesses became aware of the ‗pink

pound‘ and suddenly developed a deep interest in gay rights. For politicians the incentive

is votes. In the US, after decades of normative activism on gay rights and equal marriage,

polls in 2011 finally showed US public support for same-sex marriage exceeding 50 per

cent for the first time. Politicians took notice. In just one week in April 2013, six U.S.

senators performed U-turns and declared their support for marriage equality.171

Institutions, whether of the state or beyond, have their own cultures and normative

frameworks, which may affect how they respond to changes in public attitudes. In the to

and fro of debate over the WTO‘s Doha Round, where I spent much of the early 2000s, it

was striking how often self-interest and norms coincided: Europe argued the merits of

free trade in sectors where its exports were competitive, but suddenly felt moved by

issues of food security when defending its agricultural subsidies. India opposed the use of

patents to limit access to medicines, which just happened to also further the interests of

its vibrant generic (off-patent) pharmaceutical industry. The resulting dialogue of the deaf

used to remind me of Upton Sinclair‘s remark, ‗It is difficult to get a man

to understand something, when his salary depends upon his not understanding it.‘172

Normative change is seldom smooth.173

As I found on child rights, changing norms can

provoke a violent backlash, especially from those whose power is threatened. When

women get paid jobs for the first time it may improve relationships at home, but it can

also threaten male domination and exacerbate domestic violence; gay rights activists are

brutally persecuted in many countries across Africa, some even suffering murder and the

horrors of ‗corrective rape‘.

171 http://oxfamblogs.org/fp2p/how-change-happens-what-can-we-learn-from-the-same-sex-marriage-

movement-in-the-us/ 172

Upton Sinclair, I, Candidate for Governor: And How I Got Licked, 1935 173

Researchers call the process ‘a cycle linking actions to disputes, disputes to arguments and arguments to norm change’. W. Sandholtz & K Stiles, International Norms and Cycles of Change, 2009

Page 91: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

91

Norm change at the individual level

If soap opera characters can help transform gender norms in villages in India, even more

powerful is the existence of role models closer to home. In South Asia, the ‗We Can‘

campaign (mentioned in chapter one) to end violence against women works through

people-to-people contact and a massive network of over 1,800 civil society organisations

in Bangladesh, Sri Lanka, India, Nepal, Pakistan, and Afghanistan.174

Individual ‗change

makers‘ sign up to the campaign, promising to change themselves and to influence their

family, friends, and neighbours. To the organizers‘ surprise, half of the nearly four

million change makers who signed on over the course of seven years were men, an

affirmation of the campaign‘s premise that real change is possible, and that men too find

their traditional gender roles unsatisfactory.175

We Can largely bypassed the formal world of state action, but states too can have a

transformative impact. In 1993, the Indian government introduced a law calling for one

third of village council leader positions in village councils (Panchayat) to be reserved for

women. At the time, many sceptics argued that influential men would place their wives in

the position and manage from behind the scenes. However, researchers subsequently

found that the presence of women in local positions of power was having a profound

impact on gender norms: adolescent girls in villages with female leaders in two election

cycles were more likely to want to marry after age 18, less likely to want to be a

housewife or have their occupation determined by their in-laws and more likely to want a

job requiring education. Parents were less likely to believe in-laws should determine

girls‘ occupations. The gender gap in adolescent educational attainment was erased and

the gender gap in time spent on household chores closed by 18 whole minutes, reflecting

girls spending less time on these activities.176

Religion and norms

I am a lifelong atheist, but decades of working on Latin America, and eight years working

for the Catholic aid agency CAFOD, have left me with an abiding respect and interest in

the role of faith in development – to the point where my ‗what about religion?‘ comments

have become a bit of a joke within Oxfam. In Latin America, I saw the power of liberation

174 www.wecanendvaw.org/index.htm

175 Ref We Can Citizen activism case study

176 Beaman, L., Duflo, E., Pande, R. and Topalova, P. (2012) ‘Female Leadership Raises Aspirations and

Educational Attainment for Girls: A Policy Experiment in India’. Science 335(6068): 582-586.

Page 92: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

92

theology and the heroism of thousands of church activists, nuns and priests who confronted

military dictatorships, often at huge personal cost. When I worked at CAFOD, I used to

receive messages such as ‗Sorry [Sister] Pat can‘t make the meeting – she‘s been arrested

again‘ (for chaining herself to the railings outside the Ministry of Defence, in protest at

nuclear weapons). I acquired a deep respect for indomitable nuns everywhere.

Religion is probably the most powerful force in shaping an individual‘s norms. In many

communities, people trust their local church, mosque, or temple more than any other

institution. While secularisation has been a notable feature of European life over the past

50 years, in much of the rest of the world religious institutions remain at the centre of

community life. Many countries have seen a rise in religious fervour, perhaps because

faiths can bring solace and security, especially when livelihoods and cultures are

challenged by globalisation or emigration from settled rural communities to the chaos of

the shantytown.

Although public attention often focuses on conflicts between faiths, perhaps more

remarkable is how much they have in common. The so-called ‗golden rule‘ which in

Islam is expressed as ‗No man is a true believer unless he desireth for his brother that

which he desireth for himself.‘ (Azizullah – Hadith 150) has remarkably close parallels in

the scriptures of every major religion. When representatives of nine world faiths –

Bahá‘ís, Buddhists, Christians, Hindus, Jains, Jews, Muslims, Sikhs, and Taoists –

attended a World Faiths and Development Conference in 1998, they revealed a startling

degree of consensus about some of life‘s deepest truths:

Material gain alone cannot lead to true development: economic activities are

inter-related with all other aspects of life.

The whole world belongs to God. Human beings have no right to act in a harmful

way to other living creatures.

Everyone is of equal worth.

People‘s well-being and their very identity are rooted in their spiritual, social, and

cultural traditions.

Social cohesion is essential for true development.

Societies (and the world) must be run on the basis of equity and justice.177

177 W. Tyndale (1998) ‘Key Issues for Development: A Discussion Paper for the Contribution by the World

Faiths Development Dialogue (WFDD) to the World Bank’s World Development Report 2001’.

Page 93: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

93

These essential affirmations underlie attitudes, beliefs, and personal behaviour, including

activism. In southern Africa, I have come across many powerful and charismatic women

who run community projects helping those living with HIV or orphaned by AIDS. Most

are active church-goers and draw on their faith for inspiration and comfort in what is

often an exhausting and thankless task.

However, a profound ambiguity characterises the interaction between faith and politics.

While Marx saw religion as ‗the opium of the people‘, blinding us to the true nature of

our oppression, and Gramsci saw it as a means through which elites could construct and

maintain their domination, Durkheim portrayed it as a way of building a collective

identity that promotes social cohesion and stability.178

In different places at different

times, religion can encourage or discourage activism, promote conformity or challenge it,

foment love or hatred.

Nowhere is this contradictory role more evident than in relation to women‘s rights.

Fundamentalists of virtually all religions view the emancipation of women as profoundly

disturbing, giving rise, for example, to the curious alliance of the Vatican, the Iranian

government, and the US government to block international progress on sexual and

reproductive rights.

But the traffic is not all one way. Despite the opposition of their respective religious

hierarchies, women activists in both Muslim and Christian communities have

reinterpreted Islamic and Catholic scriptures in accordance with women‘s rights, leading

to a new approach to the faith. In 2004 women‘s organizations in Morocco won a

remarkable victory when Parliament unanimously approved a new Islamic Family Code

that radically strengthened the rights of women. The reforms included the right to decide

legal matters without the guardianship of a male, equal responsibility over the household

and children, and the need for consent from both husband and wife to dissolve a

marriage.

Throughout the campaign, activists opted to work within the framework of Islam, arguing

that the conservative interpretation enshrined in family law ran counter to the true spirit

of the Koran. According to activist Rabéa Naciri: ‗We chose not to separate the universal

human rights framework from the religious framework. We maintained that Islam is not

opposed to women‘s equality and dignity and should not be presented as such… Islamic

178 E. Tomalin (2007) ‘Sociology, Religion and Development: Literature Review’, University of Birmingham,

UK.

Page 94: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

94

law is a human and historical production, and consequently is able to evolve, to fulfil the

current needs of Muslim men and women.‘179

Norm changes and government

National governments have significant power to influence the norms that people embrace

in their lives and actions, but in so doing they must perform something of a balancing act.

Part of the art of outstanding leaders such as Gandhi or Nelson Mandela lies in their

ability to go beyond merely reflecting the views and norms of the public, and instead

influence them for the better. But if they depart too far from the normative universe of the

public, the elastic that binds citizens and leaders can snap altogether.

A friend of mine, working for the Cuban Communist Party newspaper Granma, once

worried that her article repeated itself. ‗Fidel says that repetition is a revolutionary

virtue,‘ she was solemnly advised. The same argument applies to politicians of other

persuasions - the endless repetition of simple messages may be one of the most off-

putting aspects of politicians‘ daily lives, but it is a vital part of their role in challenging

old norms and cementing new ones. Of course, politicians can also reinforce old norms

that should change by whipping up hatred against ethnic minorities or desperate migrants

and refugees.

An increasing part of governments‘ interaction with citizens involves shaping and using

norms. Particularly in the richer countries, this includes a daily avalanche of ‗nudges‘ to

change people‘s personal behaviour (regarding obesity/healthy diet, smoking, don‘t drink

and drive, etc.). In the United States, telling high users of energy how their consumption

compared with that of their neighbours prompted them to use less180

. In the United

Kingdom, telling residents that most neighbours had already paid their taxes, led payment

rates to rise by around 15 per cent.181

But government is rarely the original source of new norms. In fact, the ideas for many of

what we now consider the core features of the state (e.g. social protection, education,

healthcare) were incubated by activists outside the state before being taken up by the

state, as were the rules of war and the principles of child rights. A similar process is now

179 From Poverty to Power, p. 67

180 http://www.economist.com/node/21551032

181 http://www.theguardian.com/politics/2013/may/02/nudge-unit-has-it-worked

Page 95: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

95

occurring regarding environmental stewardship, data transparency and disabled people‘s

rights182

.

The international system can certainly help to change norms both among the public and

political leadership. Occasionally the sanctions of ‗hard law‘ can be deployed – for

example the International Criminal Court – but more commonly international figures

offer rewards for compliance, including public recognition (a visit from Angelina Jolie or

David Beckham always helps), and sanctions for failure. International diplomacy‘s daily

round of discussion and persuasion has a significant influence on the ideas that shape

leaders‘ thinking (every leader wants a selfie with the US president). When the problem

is the capacity to introduce and implement new laws, aid donors and others can also

provide technical assistance.

A study of how governments come to adopt and implement new human rights norms

identified five stages: repression (violent or otherwise); denial (authorities refuse to

acknowledge the issue); tactical concessions (just enough to keep international and

domestic critics quiet); prescriptive status (starting to adopt the spirit of the new norm by

ratifying international treaties, changing domestic laws, or setting up new institutions)

and rule-consistent behaviour, (putting mechanisms in place to ensure governments and

other players respect the new norms).183

Large corporations facing pressures on labour

rights or environmental safeguards go through much the same journey. In the words of

Mahatma Gandhi, ‗First they ignore you, then they laugh at you, then they fight you, then

you win.‘

To try and identify what factors drive change in government policies on violence against

women, Laurel Weldon and Mala Htun painstakingly constructed the mother of all

databases, covering 70 countries over four decades (1975 to 2005). It included various

kinds of state action (legal and administrative reforms, protection and prevention, training

for officials), and a number of other relevant factors, such as the presence of women

legislators, GDP per capita and the nature of the political regime.

Their findings bear out the importance of the pincer movement of social pressure from

below, accompanying the international mechanisms of the UN: ‗Countries with the

strongest feminist movements tend, other things being equal, to have more

182 http://oxfamblogs.org/fp2p/whats-next-for-the-rapidly-growing-global-disabled-peoples-movement/

183 T Risse, S Ropp, K Sikkink (eds) The Persisent Power of Human Rights: From Commitment to

Compliance, 2013

Page 96: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

96

comprehensive policies on violence against women than those with weaker or non-

existent movements. This plays a more important role than left-wing parties, numbers of

women legislators, or even national wealth. These movements can make the difference

between having a critical legal reform or funding for shelters or training for the police,

and not having it.‘184

Htun and Weldon also found that governments, like US energy users

and UK taxpayers, are particularly susceptible to unfavourable comparisons with their

neighbours.

Are norms neutral?

Human rights activists often defend themselves against charges of imposing alien values

on other cultures by arguing that anything the UN agrees must, by virtue of its global

nature, be a universal norm. I have never found that argument convincing. The general

flow of normative change in the UN and elsewhere in the international system reflects

imbalances of power – Western norms ‗trickle down‘ via the UN, and undoubtedly

influence how people in other countries see the world, but there is much less evidence of

the reverse taking place. How many Western leaders have been influenced in their

understanding of rights by a conversation with someone in Africa, Asia or Latin

America?

Charges of Western powers using normative change as an instrument of foreign policy

have not been helped by some of the cruder forms of support for democratization and

market liberalization by US think-tanks and others in the so-called ‗colour revolutions‘ in

the former Soviet Bloc (the Georgian Rose Revolution in 2003, the Ukrainian Orange

Revolution in 2004 and the Kyrgyzstani Tulip Revolution in 2005).185

However, norms that emerge from the international system are never simply imposed.

They are fiercely debated, compromises are struck, modifications are made. Moreover, as

the balance of power shifts in the international system, it seems very likely that the

normative traffic will become less one way – perhaps China will become more influential

on issues of social cohesion, or Latin America on the importance of collective rights,

rather than the individual variety favoured by Western powers. In areas where the West

has historically failed, such as stewardship of the environment, or reducing inequality, a

184 http://journals.cambridge.org/repo_A86U0PVC

185 S. Stewart, Democracy Promotion and the 'Colour Revolutions' 2013

Page 97: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

97

greater degree of pluralism in the evolution of international norms could be particularly

positive.

Female genital mutilation

The movement against Female Genital Mutilation (FGM) is a good example of activism

to transform a destructive social norm. Female genital cutting, which involves full or

partial removal of a girl‘s external genitals, serves no medical purpose and has many

harmful consequences. And yet the practice is widespread. The UN estimates that

worldwide 125 million women and girls are currently living with the consequences of

FGM. A further 30 million girls are at risk of being cut in the next decade across

29 known practising countries in Africa and the Middle East. However, this figure

underestimates the real number of girls affected, because other countries (e.g. Indonesia)

are not included.186

Though FGM has been going on for centuries, it now faces a major normative shift

driven by pioneering national and grassroots campaigners such as Efua Dorkenoo, a

Ghanaian–British academic and midwife who wrote one of the earliest reports on FGM,

published in 1980, and campaigned tirelessly up to her death in 2014.187

The World Health Organisation rejected a UN request to investigate FGM in 1958,

arguing that it was a cultural, rather than medical, issue. When campaigners reframed

FGM as a health rights issue some decades later, they gained the adherence of a group of

powerful and ‗neutral‘ champions: doctors. In 1997, WHO, UNICEF and the UN

Population Fund issued an influential joint statement calling FGM a violation of the

rights of women and girls to ‗the highest attainable standard of health‘, helping to

persuade at least fourteen African countries to outlaw FGM. Yet prevalence remains high

– over 90 per cent of women are mutilated in half a dozen countries, including

Somalia.188

187 As Stella Efua Graham with Scilla McLean (eds), Female Circumcision, Excision, and

Infibulation (Minority Rights Group Report 47, 1980) 188

A Brysk, Changing Hearts and Minds: sexual politics and human rights, in T Risse, S Ropp, K Sikkink (eds) The Persisent Power of Human Rights: From Commitment to Compliance, 2013.

Page 98: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

98

Researchers Gerry Mackie and John Lejeune189

studied national movements against FGM

in Egypt, Ethiopia, Kenya, Senegal, and Sudan, and compared them to another, broadly

similar, effort against the Chinese practice of binding women‘s feet to enforce chastity

and fidelity by limiting women‘s physical mobility.

Like FGM, foot-binding was both medically unjustifiable and deeply entrenched in urban

and coastal China at the beginning of the twentieth century. First, reformers educated the

population by informing them that that the rest of the world did not bind women‘s feet.

This presented the natural-foot alternative as thinkable and doable. Second, they

explained the advantages of natural feet and the disadvantages of bound feet. And finally,

they formed ―natural foot societies‖ whose members pledged not to allow their sons to

marry women with bound feet, as well as not to bind their daughter‘s feet. The reformers‘

strategy brought a thousand years of practice to an end in a single generation.

Anti-FGM movements in Africa face similar obstacles: Families carry out FGM in order

to ensure the marriageability and status of their daughters, so a family‘s choices depend

on those of other families in that community. If a single family ends FGM, their daughter

is destined to not be married or to have a poor marriage. In other words, FGM is a classic

collective action problem, in which everyone must move together to reach a solution (not

unlike climate change requiring all nations to curb carbon emissions).

In Senegal, reformers found a solution. When a relatively small critical mass of first

movers conditionally resolves to abandon FGM, these families have a strong incentive to

recruit the remaining members of their community to join them, until a tipping point is

reached and whole communities abandon the practice. Four thousand Senegalese villages

have declared themselves FGM free.190

Making the commitment public helps: in 2000, the Ethiopian development organization

KMG began holding public weddings of couples who chose to break with the tradition.

As many as 2,000 people attended the first wedding, including 317 girls who had not

undergone the practice serving as bridesmaids. During the ceremony, the bride and

bridesmaids wore signs that read ‗I will not be circumcised. Learn from me!‘ The groom

wore his own placard saying ‗I am happy to marry an uncircumcised woman.‘ Thanks to

189 Mackie, G. and LeJeune, J. (2009) ‘Social Dynamics of Abandonment of Harmful Practices: A New Look

at the Theory’. Special Series on Social Norms and Harmful Practices. Innocenti Working Paper 2009-06. Florence: UNICEF Innocenti Research Centre 190

A Brysk, Changing Hearts and Minds: sexual politics and human rights, in T Risse, S Ropp, K Sikkink (eds) The Persisent Power of Human Rights: From Commitment to Compliance, 2013.

Page 99: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

99

such campaigns and government action, younger mothers in Ethiopia are nearly five

times less likely to have a daughter cut than older mothers. Reported support for cutting

halved from 60 per cent in 2000 to 31 per cent in 2005. 191

However, activists‘ emphasis on health, which was so effective at the international level,

led some Senegalese parents to turn to medical practitioners for a ‗safer FGM‘ rather than

abandoning it altogether. Where activists introduced broad discussions about human

rights (in both Senegal and Ethiopia) that trumped the more narrow discussion of health.

The researchers concluded that parents decide to perform FGM because failure to do so

brings shame and social exclusion to girls and their families. Once an alternative becomes

possible and people realize that the community might be better off without FGM, this

most basic value – to do what is best for their children – motivates communities to

abandon the harmful practice.

Conclusion

To test these ideas, it is worth thinking through how norm shifts could take place on one

of the most pressing issues or our times – climate change. What would it take for driving

a car or exceeding personal emissions of X tonnes of CO2 per year to become as socially

unacceptable as smoking or child abuse? A combination of academic research and

international processes such as the glacial negotiations at the UN could (if they pick up

speed) affect the public understanding of personal responsibility and exert pressure for

governments to act. National leaders could respond with public messaging, advice to

schools on how to teach climate change and environmental responsibility, while backing

this up with laws and regulations. Those regulations might include carbon pricing, which

would help drive technological breakthroughs in areas such as renewable energy. Faith

groups could emphasize stewardship and personal responsibility – in 2015 some of the

most encouraging progress on climate change came from a Papal Encyclical on the

Environment192

and an impassioned appeal for action from a network of Islamic

Scholars.193

191 A Brysk, Changing Hearts and Minds: sexual politics and human rights, in T Risse, S Ropp, K Sikkink (eds)

The Persisent Power of Human Rights: From Commitment to Compliance, 2013. 192

http://www.catholic.com/blog/jimmy-akin/pope-francis%E2%80%99s-environmental-encyclical-13-things-to-know-and-share 193

http://www.economist.com/blogs/erasmus/2015/08/islam-and-ecology

Page 100: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

100

All this could be backed by activist organizations pursuing a range of actions from

litigation and other campaigns against carbon polluters, to using culture to spread the

word, to We Can style viral citizen-to-citizen networking.

Far fetched? It pretty much describes how big norm changes from the abolition of slavery

onward have come about. Activists and others interested in bringing about change should

surely, therefore, pay close attention to the way such norms are established and evolve

over time. In practice, this seldom happens: we campaigners and lobbyists focus on the

tangible – laws and policies, spending commitments, public statements of this and that. In

so doing, we are often driven by the desire to measure our impact (and thus prove our

effectiveness), or by a frustration with the vagueness of ‗talking shops‘ about rights and

norms. Whatever the cause, that neglect is a big mistake: while we must focus on the

tangible to communicate and to campaign, norms should lie at the heart of our deeper

understanding of how change happens.

We activists also need to be more aware of our own norms, which colour our ability to

understand the world. Interviewing children across Latin America and the Caribbean,

trying to understand their extraordinary precocity (as well as vulnerability) compared to

children in my own society, made me question my understanding of childhood. I came to

distrust adults‘ standard narratives of the ‗Oliver Twist v Lord of the Flies‘, in which

children are either innocents awaiting ruin or beasts in need of taming. Instead, I became

fascinating by the internal world of children and the way it evolves over time. As for

whether it improved the way I treated my own children, you would of course have to ask

them.

Page 101: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

101

9 Citizen activism194 and civil society

It‘s hard to imagine a more precious timeslot in a politician‘s calendar than three days

before a general election, yet a May 2015 ‗Citizens Assembly‘ in a cavernous London

Church hall attracted two of the United Kingdom‘s three main party leaders, while the

governing Conservatives fielded a high level stand-in for David Cameron. The politicians

submitted themselves to being grilled before 2,500 activists from Citizens UK, a

community organization. The audience was a kaleidoscope of multicultural Britain,

drawn from faith groups, schools, networks of asylum seekers and refugees, and other

grassroots institutions. The politicians were allowed just four minutes each to make their

pitches and were then cross-examined in detail by the audience. Vague or evasive

answers were challenged, promises were extracted, and I‘m pretty sure the politicians

ended up making extra commitments under pressure from the crowd.195

A decade earlier, on the other side of the world, I sat in lowland Bolivia with Jeronima

Quiviquivi, a colleague of the indigenous activist mentioned in chapter eight. Sitting

outside her new house on the edge of the village of Monteverde in the muggy heat of a

tropical afternoon, surrounded by several of her six young children, she recalled the

struggles of her people, the Chiquitano Indians. ‗My father never realised about our

rights. We just did what the white people told us, only they could be in power, be

president. We couldn‘t even go into the town centre, people swore at us. But then we got

our own organisation and elected our own leaders and that‘s when we realised we had

rights.‘

The Chiquitanos‘ story became a formative moment for me, as I struggled to disentangle

their extraordinary story of change. Organising themselves first under the guise of a

soccer league – the only way they could meet and talk with Chiquitanos from other

villages – the indigenous activists fought for things that mattered to them: land,

education, rights, a political voice. Today the Chiquitanos have seized the positions of

what was once white power: they have their own mayors and senators and, in La Paz,

South America‘s first ever indigenous president, Evo Morales. And with power came the

promise of precious land: after a ten-year campaign, on 3 July 2007 the Chiquitanos of

194 DECIDED TO USE ‘CITIZEN ACTIVISM’ AS (MARGINALLY) LESS CLUNKY THAN ACTIVE CITIZENSHIP.

195 http://oxfamblogs.org/fp2p/active-citizens-holding-britains-politicians-to-account-why-isnt-the-rest-

of-the-uk-election-campaign-more-like-this/

Page 102: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

102

Monteverde clinched an agreement with the government that granted them a ‗land of

communal origin‘ of one million hectares.196

Whether in the UK or Bolivia, active, organised citizens play a central role in making

change happen. Across the globe, poor men and women shrug off the exhaustion of long

days spent earning a living or raising families, to head off to community meetings to

discuss, organize and take action. They do so for any number of reasons – to feed their

families, improve their neighbourhoods, in response to their sense of what is right and

wrong, or because working together in a common cause is fulfilling.

Several factors drive the exponential growth of citizen activism across the developing

world: rapid increases in literacy and access to education (particularly for women), a

greater openness to political activity, and the spread of new norms regarding rights and

justice. As discussed in the last chapter, normative shifts too play a vital role: the

Chiquitanos rode the wave of rising indigenous identity across the Americas, partly

driven by the reaction to the 1992 quincentenary of Christopher Columbus‘ ‗arrival‘ in

the Americas. Whereas previously they had seen themselves as peasant farmers, they

came to self-identify as indigenous people, and make common cause with the more

powerful indigenous peoples of Bolivia‘s highlands.

In many countries, urbanization has also contributed: with exchanges of opinions and

information on every street corner, urbanites are more likely to get involved. Cities are

vividly political places, dense with social movements demanding housing, schools,

clinics, or decent water and sanitation. Protest and conflict abound, between workers and

employers or service providers and users.

So too has technology, in particular the spread of social media and mobile phones, which

greatly expand the possibilities of networking across large groups of people. Their impact

amid the chaos of street protests, however, seems greatly exaggerated by the digirati. One

study found that 93 per cent of communications between activists in Cairo‘s Tahrir

Square at the height of the 2011 protests were face-to-face.197

At this point, I have a confession to make: the wave of citizen activism does not include

me. In fact, I am one of the most inactive citizens I know. I hate confrontation and

conflict; I barely know my own neighbours; I‘m not a ‗joiner‘. Nevertheless, people who

196 Eduardo Caceres/Bolivia office to check still OK to use

197 Mike Edwards p85

Page 103: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

103

behave very differently have long inspired and fascinated me. First, Latin America‘s

brave community organizers and freedom fighters, and then at Oxfam the great activists

from around the world I have had the privilege to meet. Hypocrisy? Perhaps. I will just

have to live with the gulf that separates their lifestyles from mine. At least my son Calum

works as a Citizens UK community organiser in Peckham198

in South London, where he

lives. Does that get me off the hook?

What is citizen activism?

Citizen activism certainly includes political activism, but it can be much more. A good

definition would be any individual action with social consequences, and much of it

involves collective activity, including participation in faith groups or neighbourhood

associations, producer organizations and trade unions, village savings and loan groups,

funeral societies and a panoply of others. Such participation is an assertion of power, and

is both an end in itself – a crucial kind of freedom – and a means to get the different

institutions of society (the state, the market, the community and the family) to respect

people‘s rights and meet their needs. Active citizens provide vital feedback to state

decision-makers, exert pressure for reform, or solve their problems themselves, bypassing

state systems altogether.

Such ‗social capital‘ is often as valuable as cash or skills. World Bank research in

Indonesia found that membership in local associations had a bigger impact on household

welfare than education.199

By one estimate, voluntary associations the world over have

become key providers of human services (especially health and welfare), and now

constitute a $2.2 trillion industry in just the 40 countries that were sampled.200

The local organisations people form – known in development jargon as Civil Society

Organizations (CSOs) – complement more traditional links of clan, caste or religion.

Coming together in CSOs helps citizens nourish the stock of trust and co-operation on

which all societies depend.201

Of course, citizens‘ groups can also reinforce discrimination, fear, and mistrust; called

‗uncivil society‘ by some, their activities can sometimes spill over into violence, as in the

198 http://www.citizensuk.org/peckham_votes_yes_to_launching_peckham_citizens

199 Ref Mike Edwards p92

200 Edwards p 13, ftnote 15

201 J. Howell and J. Pearce (2001) op. cit., p.31.

Page 104: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

104

case of religious or racist pogroms, soccer hooligans or paramilitary organisations. At the

time of Rwanda‘s 1994 genocide, the country had the highest density of voluntary

associations in sub-Saharan Africa.202

Nor are CSOs immune from the wider power inequalities in society. Men often dominate

them, as do powerful groups based on ethnicity or caste. CSOs of hitherto marginalised

groups have often emerged as splinters from mixed organisations, when women or

indigenous or HIV-positive people found that their specific concerns continually

evaporated from the agenda.

CSOs‘ work is often local and below the media radar, pushing authorities to install street

lighting, pave the roads or invest in schools and clinics. CSOs often run such services

themselves, along with public education programmes on everything from hand washing

to labour rights. Even in the chaotic, dangerous world of the Eastern Congo (DRC),

Community Protection Committees made up of six men and six women elected by their

villages have brought new-found confidence and resilience to conflict-affected

communities. They identify the main threats and actions to mitigate them. When people

are forced to flee renewed fighting, these committees are often instrumental in getting

people organized in their new refugee camps.203

Citizen activism and protest

Since the 1980s, CSOs have become prominent in the global media for a very different

role: leading protest movements that have ousted dozens of authoritarian regimes across

Latin America, Eastern Europe and Central Asia, removed dictators in the Philippines

and Indonesia, ended apartheid in South Africa and most recently brought down

oppressive governments in Tunisia, Egypt and Libya. Many autocrats must live in fear

that one day tear gas from the protests outside will invade the comfort of the presidential

palace, as thousands of citizens gather in the square to demand justice, vowing to remain

until they get it.204

While other factors contribute to political transitions (involvement of the formal political

opposition or the military, foreign intervention and so on), boycotts, mass protests,

202 Mike Edwards, p51

203 D. Green, Community Protection Committees in Democratic Republic of Congo (Oxfam, January 2015)

204 Carothers post

Page 105: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

105

blockades, strikes and other civil disobedience by cohesive non-violent civic coalitions

has proven vital.

Protest movements exhibit a particular rhythm and structure. One historian of European

social movements sees them as passing through ‗cycles of contention‘205

– a dynamic of

sudden explosions of protest, followed by repression, partial victories leading to reform,

then demobilisation – repeating itself over the last two centuries. The response to protest

is often repression, but laced with reform. As conflict collapses and militants retire to lick

their wounds, many of their gains are reversed; nevertheless, they leave behind

incremental expansions in participation, changes in popular culture and residual networks

that lay a groundwork for future protest. Open conflict is a season for sowing, but the

reaping often comes in the periods of demobilisation that follow, by latecomers to the

cause and reformers among elites and officialdom.

While outsiders often see protest movements as homogeneous (journalists and politicians

often lament their lack of easily-identifiable leaders), on closer inspection, they exhibit a

degree of granularity. They contain smaller, more durable organizations that emerge at

vital moments, and then disperse. According to Oxfam‘s Ihab El Sakkout, Cairo‘s Tahrir

Square in 2011 was no exception: ‗On 2nd and 3rd of February, when the protestors were

attacked viciously by regime thugs, the Muslim brotherhood and organized groups of

soccer fans played a key role in defending the square (principally by being able to convey

quick decisions via their groups, showing extreme courage and discipline under attack,

quickly building barricades, managing counter-attacks, etc.), which helped to turn those

in the square from a mass of individuals into a cohesive group able to defend itself.‘206

Moises Naim207

identified some common elements in twenty-first century movements:

they were triggered by minor incidents, they did not have clear leaders or chains of

command, they were entirely unforeseen, and they took place in successful economies.

Naim also noted that the protests became huge when government tried to suppress them,

which may be why such movements often fizzle out in democracies.

205 Tarrow, 1998, p. 24

206 Blog on 2011 Egyptian Revolution

207 Protest movements in 6 countries

Page 106: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

106

Citizen activism and markets

The day-to-day efforts of citizens‘ associations are more mundane than the overthrow of

governments, but they are equally important to making change. Millions of factory

workers, state employees and small-scale farmers around the world have long realized

that the best way to get a good deal out of markets is to get organized. Trade unions,

producer associations, cooperatives and small business associations play a vital role in

boosting their bargaining power. Although their immediate aim is to get a better deal

from markets, many move on to lobbying for better regulation or opposing the excessive

behind-the-scenes power of vested interests.

These organizations can get better terms for credit, share the cost of expensive machinery

like tractors, and process and market their produce more efficiently, thereby getting

gaining a far greater share of the final market price. To get a better deal from markets,

they often take up lobbying governments for better regulation, or opposing the excessive

behind-the-scenes power of vested interests.

Trade unions have been at the forefront of the struggle for workers‘ rights for over two

centuries, winning huge advances regarding wages and working conditions, the rights to

collective bargaining and freedom of association, holidays, pensions and a panoply of

others.208

Many of unions‘ achievements have been rolled back in recent decades, as corporations

and their allies in international institutions and government have gutted hard-won labour

legislation in many countries. Worker organisations continue to face repression and

violence; union leaders around the world confront harassment, rape and murder. Two

countries in every five have serious or severe restrictions on the core right to freedom of

association.209

In part due to entrenched attitudes in the labour movement that women are temporary,

secondary, or less valuable workers, women‘s organisations have come to the fore in

struggling to improve working conditions for the millions of women now employed in

factories in developing countries, especially in export processing zones (EPZs), where unions

208 The International Labour Organization has so far agreed 189 Conventions on almost every aspect of

working life. 209

ILO (2001) ‘Reducing the Decent Work Deficit: A Global Challenge’, Geneva, International Labour Conference 89

th Session, 2001, Report of the Director General, p.9. [asked Rachel Wilshaw for update,

1.9.15]

Page 107: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

107

are banned. In Nicaragua, the María Elena Cuadra Movement of Employed and Unemployed

Women (MEC) and its 2,000 volunteers helped to win the country‘s first National Health and

Safety Law in 2007, with increased site inspections in EPZ factories to ensure compliance, as

well as human rights training for mid-level private sector managers.210

On plantations

growing table grapes and other fruit for export, where women make up most of the labourers,

women‘s organisations have also stepped into the fray. In South Africa, the Women on Farms

Project helped isolated seasonal workers form an organisation to demand a minimum daily

wage; after a 2013 strike, the women won a 52 per cent pay increase.211

Despite the efforts of women‘s groups and unions, approximately 90 per cent of the world

labour force is unorganised, and union membership is declining in direct proportion to the

growth of the informal economy. Unions have struggled to reach people working within

homes or without contracts, who are determined to hang on to even meagre jobs.

The number of independent producer organisations, in contrast, has mushroomed in

recent decades.212

Between 1982 and 2002 the number of villages in Burkina Faso that

had them rose from 21 per cent to 91 per cent.213

In Nigeria, the number of co-operatives

nearly doubled between 1990 and 2005.214

By 1998 65 per cent of all rural households in

India belonged to a co-operative society.215,216

The afternoon I spent with two hundred Indian fishing families in 2006 greatly influenced

my thinking on how change happens, and just how important it is for brave men and

women to challenge the powers that be. As we sat under giant shade trees on the banks of

a dried-up lake in the Bundelkhand region, birdsong and voices pierced the dry heat. A

small pond choked with lilies was all that remained of the waters once teeming with fish,

built by kings over 800 years ago and recently restored by the community.

210 For further examples of organising in the informal economy, see www.wiego.org.

211 http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/world-africa-21324275

212 For an overview of the issues facing producer organisations, see C. Penrose-Buckley (2007) Producer

Organisations: A Guide to Developing Collective Rural Enterprises, Oxford: Oxfam GB. 213

J.L. Arcand (2004) in M.R. Mercoiret and J.M. Mfou’ou (2006) ‘Rural Producers Organizations for Pro-poor Sustainable Agricultural Development’, paper for World Development Report 2008 workshop, Paris 2006, Washington DC: World Bank. 214

Research by Leuven University cited in Proceedings Report, Corporate Governance and Co-operatives, Peer Review Workshop, London, 8 February 2007. 215

U.S. Awasthi (2001) ‘Resurgence of Co-operative Movement through Innovations’, Co-op Dialogue, 11(2) 21–6. 216 ANY MORE RECENT STATS?

Page 108: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

108

The land was parched, but the story was uplifting. ‗Previously we covered our faces in

public,‘ one woman laughed. ‗Now we talk back, even to our fathers-in-law.‘ And not

just fathers-in-law. These people had come on an extraordinary journey, winning

unprecedented rights to the fishponds, and transforming their own lives along the way.

Landlords and their contractors traditionally controlled most fishponds in the

impoverished region, but today the 45,000 fishing families of the Bundelkhand seem to

be gaining the upper hand in a long struggle for the right to fish and to use the fertile land

exposed when the ponds dry out.

In the early 1990s new varieties of fish and the practice of stocking ponds with fish fry

raised in nurseries greatly increased yields. Rather than favouring the poor, however,

technological improvement prompted landlords and contractors to seize even the smallest

of the region‘s 1,300 ponds. Protests led the Fisheries Minister of Madhya Pradesh, who

was from a fishing community, to push through legislation in 1996 that granted leases to

fishers‘ co-operatives. A wave of organisation in poor fishing communities followed,

with support from a local NGO, Vikalp.

Landlords retaliated by setting up bogus co-operatives of their own and using other tricks

to get around the legislation, and when that failed they resorted to violence. In a

particularly bloody struggle over Achrumata Pond, a pitched battle ended with thugs

hired by landlords steal villagers‘ fish and burning down their huts.

On their endless visits to police stations in search of justice in the Achrumata case co-

operative leaders met sympathetic outsiders who helped them convince the police to

accept an official complaint. Although the police did no more than that, simply opening

the case was seen as an unprecedented symbolic blow to the landlords, and it galvanised

the fishing communities. Six villages marched to Achrumata and in a confrontation in

which three people were seriously injured and houses were burned, won the pond back

from the thugs.

As their self-confidence grew, communities seized several other ponds, and launched a

campaign to persuade the authorities to enforce the law. After my visit, that campaign

met with success, and by 2012 184 pond cooperatives were thriving businesses fishing

and rearing fish fry.217

217 Source: author visit, October 2006, checked and updated in 2012

Page 109: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

109

Civil society and the state: opponents or collaborators?

Where the political system is viewed as inclusive and legitimate, much of the activity of

CSOs is channelled into the formal politics of elections or in democracy‘s daily ‗public

conversation‘ about laws and state policy. Many CSOs have ties to political parties, at

least at election time, and can be important vehicles for marshalling votes in poor

countries and rich alike.

On another visit to India in 2012, grassroots activists in the slums of the city of Lucknow

told me the first stage in winning political clout is to convince the lowest rank of elected

officials, known as ‗corporators‘, the slum is worthy of being designated a ‗notified

slum,‘ and so appear on the political and fiscal map. Corporators then distribute voting

cards; the voter cards are the only identity papers many residents have.

In the eyes of slum dwellers, the corporators are the most approachable, but least

powerful politicians. Above them only a few members of the state assembly are willing

to talk to them. ‗The officials are worse, especially the low-level ones, they ignore us or

demand bribes. At least corporators listen, even if they don‘t do anything.‘ Asked why

they vote, one responded, ―We‘re positive if our candidate wins, they will provide basic

services. When it doesn‘t happen, we‘re disappointed, but then we wait five years and

vote for someone else. What else can we do?‘218

Nevertheless, CSOs are hardly the complacent instruments of politicians. They have

spawned crowd-source websites, such as ‗ipaidabribe.com‘ in Kenya219

and India,220

to

help expose corruption by corporate lobbyists, clientilist political networks and the like.

Many now monitor government spending, painstakingly analysing what is promised and

what is delivered, and seeking to influence budget allocations. In Israel, for example,

activists from different social movements set up the Adva Centre, a non-governmental

organisation (NGO) that uses a combination of analysis, parliamentary lobbying, popular

education and media campaigns to promote equal rights for Mizrahi Jews, women, and

Arab citizens.221

218 Author visit, 2012

219 http://ipaidabribe.or.ke/

220 http://www.ipaidabribe.com/#gsc.tab=0

221 Need update?

Page 110: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

110

Lobbying government can be a disillusioning experience, as I found when talking to

CSOs in South Africa.222

‗Party hacks get parachuted into senior administrative jobs,

lacking the capacity or interest to perform them properly,‘ one activist told me. ‗You look

at the giant that is government and it‘s so difficult to navigate. You never quite know

where to push, (and nor do the officials!). You invest hugely in building intimate

relationships only to find they‘ve moved department and you have to start all over again.‘

And CSOs have given rise to new political parties, much as trade unions created political

parties to represent their interests in countries such as the United Kingdom. In Bolivia

and Brazil, social movements came together to found respectively the Movement For

Socialism (MAS) and the Workers Party (PT), both of which subsequently came to power

and enacted major progressive reforms (discussed in chapter four). However such links to

government can undermine CSOs as institutions – their leadership poached to join a new

government, or their reputation tarnished by association with the inevitable compromises

of political office.

Civil society can also play an important, if less visible, role in more closed political

systems, where research and demonstration projects are often more effective and less

risky than the more noisy avenues of campaigns and public protest.223

Officials in such

systems are sometimes more willing to listen to evidence of what isn‘t working because

they don‘t have to worry about adverse press coverage or buying political support. In

Russia, for example, disability campaigners lobbied successfully to change badly

designed laws on benefits by explaining the problems behind closed doors.224

Working at local level can yield results even in apparently unpropitious areas such as

women‘s rights in Pakistan225

, because the imbalance of power between activists and the

state is less extreme and relationships are easier to establish. Municipal authorities are

often key; in Indonesia and Brazil, participatory budgeting started in villages and towns

before spreading more widely, while Brazil‘s renowned Bolsa Familia social welfare

programme began life as an experiment under progressive municipal governments.

As noted in chapter two, effectively engaging the state means understanding its internal

structures and incentive systems. Publicly congratulating officials and politicians when

222 How to build local government accountability in South Africa? A conversation with partners, 2012

223 http://oxfamblogs.org/fp2p/how-can-you-do-influencing-work-in-strong-authoritarian-states/

224 http://oxfamblogs.org/fp2p/advocacy-v-service-delivery-in-russia/

225 Ref RHV case study

Page 111: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

111

they do something right (rather than immediately moving the goalposts and issuing new

demands) can help build trust. Framing demands in ways that make sense to politicians

can greatly improve the chances of success.

A review of 200 citizens‘ anti-corruption projects in 53 countries found that success

relied on identifying allies among officials and politicians who could act as champions

and sources of inside intelligence.226

An in-depth evaluation of efforts to influence state

services in South Africa, Mexico, Tanzania and Brazil agreed on champions and stressed

the role of alliances with the media, academics and other players as activists dig in for the

long haul.227

State support for citizen activism

Civil society can help the state become more effective, and states can in turn promote

citizen activism by strengthening the different kinds of power discussed in chapter one.228

Issuing birth certificates or other official registration to members of excluded groups

(lower castes, indigenous, the elderly, the disabled, migrants) can bolster their individual

identity (‗power within‘). So can public education on discriminatory norms and values,

and laws that guarantee equitable access to assets and opportunities, not to mention

preventing violence against women and other forms of intimidation.

The state can also help build the capacity of interest- and identity-based organizations

and create an enabling environment for excluded groups to organise and represent their

interests (‗power with‘). Affirmative action for the political representation of

disadvantaged groups, as well as initiatives and reforms that promote transparency and

accountability, can strengthen citizens‘ ability to take action (‗power to‘).

Finally, states can play an important role in curtailing ‗power over‘: the excessive

concentration of influence and its use against excluded groups and individuals.

Strengthening poor people‘s access to the legal system can cut across all these categories

and encourage a reformist rather than a revolutionary approach to citizen activism.

Sometimes state support is unwitting. In Bolivia, the Chiquitanos‘ cause was

unexpectedly boosted by the structural adjustment policies of the 1980s, which

226 Ref Citizens Against Corruption,

227 http://oxfamblogs.org/fp2p/watching-the-ups-and-downs-of-accountability-work-four-new-real-time-

studies/ 228

Green, D. & King, S., ‘What can Governments do to Empower Poor People?’, Oxfam, 2013.

Page 112: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

112

dramatically reversed three decades of state intervention and improvements in social

rights. Not only did these radical measures galvanise protest movements across Bolivia,

they sent traditionally militant tin miners, sacked under the scheme, across the country in

search of work. The miners‘ organizing skills were soon brought to bear in new struggles,

including that of the Chiquitanos.

Crackdown on civil society space

Many states are increasingly pursuing the exact opposite of empowering their citizens. In

what is partly a backhanded acknowledgement of growing civil society strength, more

than fifty countries in recent years have enacted or seriously considered legislative or

other restrictions on the ability of CSOs to organize and operate. As Russia‘s Vladimir

Putin chillingly explained, ‗If you get permission, you go and march.…Go without

permission, and you will be hit on the head with batons.‘229

Other government measures

impede or block foreign funding for civil society groups, or harass external aid groups

offering civil society support.230

Foreign funding for CSOs in some of the ‗regime change‘ uprisings in Central Asia and

Eastern Europe made them easy targets for accusations of foreign interference. Moreover,

many of the CSOs that were founded in the 1990s and 2000s boom years have weak

governance and accountability structures, allowing governments to question their

legitimacy.231

Governments may also be inspired by the models of non-democratic

systems, such as China‘s. Or perhaps it is just convenient. In 2012 even Canada‘s elected

government labelled environmental groups ‗foreign-financed terrorists‘ for opposing an

oil pipeline, and moved to shut them down. Whether such reasons are justifications or

mere excuses, the net result is that citizen activism, an important contributor to the

progress of social, political and economic freedom in recent decades, is coming under

increasing threat in dozens of countries.

229 quoted by Reuters, August 2010, defending a recent crackdown on pro-democracy protesters.

230 Carothers and Brechenmacher, Carnegie Endowment for International Peace, Closing Space:

Democracy and Human Rights Support Under Fire 231

http://oxfamblogs.org/fp2p/5-trends-that-explain-why-civil-society-space-is-under-assault-around-the-world/

Page 113: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

113

Aid and citizen activism

If the rising voice and influence of civil society is widely recognized, quite how aid agencies

should support it, if at all, is far from clear.232

A hundred years ago, during the Mexican

Revolution, President Alvaro Obregón is said to have caustically observed that ‗No general can

withstand a cannonade of 50,000 pesos,‘233

and much the same appears to apply to some CSOs.

Based on research in Pakistan, Masooda Bano234

argues that aid often erodes the cooperation that

underpins CSOs. When foreign money flows in, the unpaid activists that form the core of such

organizations can lose trust in their leaders, whom they now suspect of pocketing aid dollars. In

Bosnia, my conversations with CSOs suggest that even their supporters view them as little more

than ‗briefcase CSOs‘, only interested in winning funding.235

I find such conversations painful, as

they force me to acknowledge that the aid dollars that I have spent so many years advocating for

can in some circumstances do more harm than good.

While chucking money at CSOs may be killing with kindness, there are more subtle ways

that outsiders can support citizen activism.236

As part of the initial research for this book,

I researched ten case studies of Oxfam‘s work on citizen activism,237

ranging from

grassroots women‘s empowerment to global campaigns on the arms trade. Here are a few

lessons for success I drew from such work:238

1. The right partners are indispensable: Whether programmes flourish or fail depends

in large part on the local CSOs who work with northern aid agencies. Good partners bring

an understanding of local context and culture, have long-term relations of trust with poor

communities and well-developed networks with those in positions of local power; they

will carry on working in the area long after the outside agency has moved on.

232 http://axoquen.8k.com/biografias/obregonsa.html

233 Morris, Stephen D. (1992), ‘Corrupción y política en el México contemporáneo’. Mexico, Editorial Siglo

XXI 234

Bano, Breakdown in Pakistan, 2012 235

http://oxfamblogs.org/fp2p/building-civil-society-after-a-traumatic-civil-war-dilemmas-and-ideas-in-bosnia-and-herzegovina/ 236

http://oxfamblogs.org/fp2p/can-donors-support-civil-society-activism-without-destroying-it-some-great-evidence-from-nigeria/ 237

http://policy-practice.oxfam.org.uk/our-work/citizen-states/active-citizenship-case-studies 238

http://policy-practice.oxfam.org.uk/publications/promoting-active-citizenship-what-have-we-learned-from-10-case-studies-of-oxfam-338431

Page 114: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

114

2. Don’t neglect ‘power within’: Building the power of citizens often starts with their

self-confidence and assertiveness, especially regarding gender rights.239,240

‗Power

within‘ allows citizens to build ‗power with‘ in the form of organizations.

3. Build the grains of change: Success in building citizen activism usually involves

identifying and working with its constituent ‗grains‘ – the more durable organizations

within movements241

– such as trade unions in Indonesia, or even incubating new ones,

like the Women‘s Leadership Groups in Pakistan.242

These groups are best placed to

survive, adapt and flourish in the complex systems of social change.

4. Building citizen activism takes time: Gathering individual organisations into a social

movement is painstaking work, requiring sustained investment of time and empathy.

Many of the timelines for the case studies show work stretching back over a decade or

more – far longer than the typical aid funding arrangement.

5. Think about working with faith groups: As we have seen, many people living in

poverty place enormous trust in religious institutions, which are often central to the

construction of norms and values, including those that promote or inhibit citizen activism.

6. Conflict v cooperation: Serious change is seldom entirely peaceful. But conflict

carries huge risks for people living in poverty, whether physical or material. In the most

high-risk environments, programmes opted explicitly for a ‗softly softly‘ approach;

elsewhere, lobbying mixed with confrontation and protest proved effective.

Conclusion

Active citizens are the unsung heroes of how change happens, putting the demos in

democracy,243

holding governments to account, making states and markets work better

and, occasionally, erupting onto our TV screens to drive tyrants and thieves from power.

They do so through a complex ecosystem of actions and organizations that repays careful

study, if we are to understand (let alone influence or support) processes of progressive

change around the world.

240

http://policy-practice.oxfam.org.uk/publications/the-raising-her-voice-nepal-programme-338476 242

http://policy-practice.oxfam.org.uk/publications/the-raising-her-voice-pakistan-programme-338443 243

The word democracy comes from the Greek ‘demos’ (people) and ‘kratos’ (power).

Page 115: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

115

Citizen activism is an archetypal example of the redistribution of power. When

previously isolated individuals come together, they can achieve ‗power with‘. To do so,

they may have to go through a moment of personal awakening to their rights and voice

(‗power within‘). The CSOs that emerge from such a process can act as rafts, citizen

activism navigating the unpredictable waters of change. They naturally adapt to shifts,

grab opportunities, seek friends and allies, as well as frequently showing remarkable

courage in the face of danger. For CSO members, this is their life, not a project or a plan.

Viewing civil society and its organizations as an ecosystem suggests a role for outsiders

as ‗ecosystem gardeners‘, nurturing diversity and resilience and focusing on the ‗enabling

environment‘ (such as laws that support, rather than impede) or systemic issues such as

access to information or finance. Such a role implies that outsiders should stand by CSOs

through thick and thin, in an extended act of solidarity, as they cope with emerging

events, no matter if they shift direction or focus. The aid industry‘s focus on short-term,

measurable results, however, makes such an approach ever more difficult.

We will return to the role of outsider organizations in the final section of the book. First,

we turn to the broader role of advocacy in making change happen.

Page 116: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

116

10 Advocacy

The bacon sandwiches were to die for. They sat alluringly at the entrance to the

‗breakfast meeting‘ at Number 11 Downing St, the residence of then Chancellor of the

Exchequer Gordon Brown. But the risks of grabbing one on my way in were too high –

lobbying the second biggest fish in the UK government was scary enough without bacon

fat dribbling down my chin. I walked resolutely by. Such are the heroic sacrifices of the

lobbyist.

The occasion was one of Brown‘s periodic breakfasts with faith groups (I was working

for the Catholic aid agency, CAFOD, at the time). About 30 people were around the

table, each of us given two minutes to pitch whatever was on our minds. I was there with

an obscure-but-important issue in the nascent Doha round of talks at the World Trade

Organization: the European Union (which at the WTO negotiates on behalf of the UK)

was intent on adding investment to the already overloaded agenda, probably to distract

attention from Europe‘s notorious Common Agricultural Policy. A large number of

developing country governments were opposed, backed by international NGOs.

I was armed with a short summary of the arguments and academic evidence for our

position.244

As the paper made its way round the table, I used my two minutes to

summarize its contents. When it reached him, Brown scribbled something on the paper

and the spotlight moved on. I later discovered that as he left the room, he said to his

officials ‗Why are we supporting this?‘ The UK subsequently distanced itself from the

EU position, a small victory, but as good as it gets for an NGO lobbyist.

A couple of months later, this seemingly obscure topic was a major factor in the

spectacular collapse of the WTO summit in Cancún. The media room was a shouting,

shoving, frenzy of journalists on deadline, desperate to find someone to interview; some

were even interviewing each other. I was in spin-doctor mode, regurgitating the same

sound bite – ‗the EU is chief suspect #1 and #2 for the collapse‘ – to anyone who would

listen. We were hoping to pre-empt the inevitable attempt to blame either developing

244 https://www.actionaid.org.uk/sites/default/files/doc_lib/10_1_six_arguments_wto.pdf

Page 117: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

117

countries or NGOs for the collapse. My quote made the Guardian, so CAFOD was

happy.245

Dodging bacon sarnies in Downing Street or spinning at global trade summits are hardly

the kinds of activities the public normally associates with international NGOs. When

CAFOD asked its youth supporters for a picture of its work, they drew cartoons of nuns

throwing bags of food out of planes. But over the last 20 years CAFOD, Oxfam and

others have devoted a rising proportion of their efforts to influencing government policy

through campaigns and lobbying.

The turn toward policy work came partly as a result of hard lessons learned during the

1980s and 90s heyday of World Bank structural adjustment programmes, when it became

apparent there was little point in constructing islands of project success only to see them

swept away by a tidal wave of bad public policy decisions. Growing size, capacity and

self-confidence no doubt also played a role.

The rise of campaigns and lobbying has produced a proliferation of training manuals and

toolkits, some of which can be found on this book‘s website. Organizations such as

Oxfam now also provide considerable support to local groups to develop their advocacy

skills – generally known by the rather condescending term (to my ears, anyway) of

‗capacity building‘. This chapter will steer clear of the fine detail, and instead sketch in

the broader nature of the beast, as well as address some of the dilemmas it poses for

activists who want to bring about change.

First, some definitions: ‗Advocacy‘ is the process of influencing decision-makers to

change their policies and practices, attitudes or behaviours. ‗Campaigning‘ usually refers

to mobilising the public or influencing their attitudes and behaviours on certain issues.

And ‗lobbying‘ is going directly to policymakers to get them to do something regarding a

particular issue. For simplicity, I will use ‗advocacy‘ as an umbrella term for both

campaigning and lobbying.

The tactics employed usually fall somewhere along a continuum from sitting down with

those in power to help sort out a problem (at the ‗insider‘ end) to mayhem in the street (at

245 http://www.theguardian.com/world/2003/sep/15/business.politics

Page 118: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

118

the ‗outsider‘ end). One study defined five points on that spectrum: cooperation –

education – persuasion – litigation – contestation.246

Advocacy will typically involve a combination of these elements, and the balance shifts

over time. One reason Gordon Brown was willing to listen to me prattle on about trade

rules was the public pressure and media coverage generated by campaigners in the Trade

Justice Movement, a large, noisy and media-savvy civil society coalition. Often a public

campaign is required to get an issue onto the table, at which point a more insider

approach can help move it towards a decision on policy or spending. And public action

may be needed at any stage to prevent backsliding and foot-dragging.

When it comes to campaigning, the playbook was pretty much written two centuries ago,

after a dozen people met in a print shop in London‘s End, brought together by Thomas

Clarkson, a 27-year-old Quaker. Thus began a campaign to end slavery that lasted fifty

years, brilliantly captured in Adam Hochschild‘s book Bury the Chains.247

The

abolitionists invented virtually every modern campaign tactic, including posters, political

book tours, consumer boycotts, investigative reporting and petitions. Fast forward two

centuries, and today‘s energetic activism on issues from climate change to disabled

people‘s rights, corruption or same-sex marriage is built on the same foundations created

by Clarkson and his colleagues.

The abolition campaign suffered tensions between outsiders like Clarkson and insiders

like William Wilberforce, the movement‘s Parliamentary champion, and was buffeted by

events (the French Revolution, the Napoleonic Wars) in ways that would be instantly

recognizable to modern campaigners. And like today, history has a habit of crediting

high-profile Northern campaigners, rather than the slaves themselves, who rose up

against their oppressors. The victorious rebellion led by Toussaint L‘Ouverture in Haiti

created a Vietnam-style war that bankrupted France and led to the deaths of 45,000 of the

89,000-strong British Army in the West Indies.

246 Miller and Covey (1997), Advocacy Sourcebook: Frameworks for Planning, Action and Reflection.

Institute for Development Research (IDR), USA. 247

Ref Bury the Chains’

Page 119: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

119

Choosing lobby targets

Advocacy typically targets the institutions described in this book, be they formal (states,

the courts, political parties, private corporations and international bodies) or informal

(norms and public attitudes). During my brief spell as a civil servant at DFID, I witnessed

good and bad advocacy in action in the space of a morning spent shadowing the Secretary

of State, Hilary Benn. The Minister‘s first visitor was an NGO (which shall remain

nameless) that seemed content to bask in the presence of power, with no clear asks

beyond ‗We hope you will take a strong position on labour rights‘. Benn was charming

and kind, small talk took up most of the time and nothing was agreed.

A few hours later, the Fairtrade Foundation bustled in, led by its dynamic boss Harriet

Lamb. She politely curtailed the introductions, gave the Minister some of the

Foundation‘s new products to play with and moved on to a series of specific asks: ‗Since

Asda‘s headquarters are in your constituency, Minister, it would be really helpful if you

could sign a letter asking them to do more on Fairtrade – we would be happy to draft it

for you‘. As she left the room, Benn turned to me and said ‗We‘re funding those people‘,

a promise we ‗civil serpents‘ subsequently managed to turn into a £750,000 grant.

Harriet‘s half hour was well spent because she followed the rules of good lobbying: know

what your targets can and can‘t deliver; treat them like human beings; persuade by

appealing both to altruism and self-interest.

Often advocates are unable to reach decision-makers themselves, and instead focus on

those who have access. These ‗influentials‘ can be found not just among those officially

part of a decision-maker‘s immediate circle. They include journalists, members of

parliament, donors, faith and business leaders, public intellectuals (usually academics)

and key people in other government departments or trade unions.

Perhaps the most impressive (if disturbing) exercise I ever witnessed of ‗influencing the

influentials‘ came during an internal British Government seminar in the run-up to the

2009 climate change summit in Copenhagen. The Foreign Office hired former

Greenpeace campaigners to help it identify a hundred individuals from the Indian elite

best placed to influence India‘s climate change policy; for each of them, they put together

a dossier on how best to persuade them to act.

Page 120: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

120

Retired influentials, whom I call ‗grey panthers‘,248

can make great advocates.

The Amnesty International Business Group was founded by a classic old-man-in-a-

hurry, Sir Geoffrey Chandler, a former senior manager at Royal Dutch/Shell who was

more than willing to march into boardrooms and unleash his cut-glass accent to promote

human rights in the private sector. Such people understand how to get around internal

obstacles and spot management excuses for inaction, but the brand risk posed by a bunch

of stroppy pensioners doing their own thing would challenge any organization.249

When the advocacy target is the public at large, star power can draw massive attention to

an issue. I have worked with some great ‗celebrities‘ over the years, like Bill Nighy

(Robin Hood Tax) and Gael García Bernal (global trade rules), who lent themselves with

dedication and humility. In Peru, celebrity chefs have been at the forefront of changing

public attitudes towards the merits of traditional Peruvian foods (burger culture is

depressingly omnipresent in Latin America).250

And celebrities aren‘t the only way to reach the public. In Tanzania, a reality TV show,

‗Female Food Heroes‘, raises awareness of the country‘s women food producers. A jury

composed of TV viewers, experts and civil society partners choose the winner from

among some 20 contestants who spend three weeks on the program, which became an

unlikely national hit; fans reportedly include the agriculture minister.251

Tactics

The range of possible advocacy tactics is limited only by the imagination of the

advocates: street protest, litigation, insider persuasion, media campaigns, demonstration

projects and many more. Key considerations when choosing include the appropriate

balance of conflict and cooperation, the construction of alliances and the nature of the

message.

In his delightful book Blueprint for Revolution, Srjdja Popovic, a leader of the Serbian

uprising that overthrew Slobodan Milosevic, surveys tactics from non-violent protest

movements around the world and concludes that food is one of the best entry points.

248 http://oxfamblogs.org/fp2p/are-grey-panthers-the-next-big-thing-in-campaigning/

249 The Amnesty group was wound up in 2007, partly because, as one insider told me, ‘a semi-

autonomous group of grey eminences was rather more than [NGO managers] were prepared to accept’. 250

http://munchies.vice.com/articles/even-perus-top-chefs-are-addicted-to-fast-food 251

https://www.oxfam.org/en/tanzania/bahati-muriga-jacob-female-food-hero-2014

Page 121: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

121

Activists have built movements around cottage cheese (Israel), rice pudding (Maldives)

and, most famously, salt (Gandhi) and tea (US). ‗Food has a special way of getting people

to come together‘, he writes, and is low-risk in dangerous places.

But there are other small starters too: In San Francisco, future mayor Harvey Milk‘s

political career took off when he switched from campaigning for gay rights to

campaigning against dog shit in city parks. The trick is to to learn what people really care

about, even if it‘s not top of your priority list. If you don‘t, you will only rally the people

who already believe in what you have to say – a great way for coming tenth at anything

(as Harvey Milk initially did).252

Tone and language matter too. I find that a combination of tactical self-deprecation and

humour can disarm critics expecting a bout of self-righteous NGO finger-wagging. The

British comedian Mark Thomas specializes in the subversive use of humour. Dressed as

cartoon character Shaun the Sheep, he recently protested the privatisation of public space

by walking up and down outside the London Stock Exchange in the square owned by

Mitsubishi. Baffled security men ended up wrestling a cartoon character to the ground on

camera, before frogmarching him from the square, bizarrely addressing him as ‗Shaun‘

throughout.253

Humour can add an edge even in altogether riskier protests. In Aleppo, Syrian protestors

buried loudspeakers broadcasting anti-regime messages in smelly dustbins, so the police

would make themselves look ridiculous, and less scary, rummaging around to find

them.254

Often, however, such movements succeed when they provoke repression from the

authorities, which acts as a catalyst for further protest and can motivate reformers within

government. As Martin Luther King, Jr. wrote in 1967 about how police beating

demonstrators in a few places propelled national civil rights legislation: ‗Sound effort in a

single city such as Birmingham or Selma, produced situations that symbolized the evil

everywhere and inflamed public opinion against it. Where the spotlight illuminated the

evil, a legislative remedy was soon obtained that applied everywhere.‘

252 Popovic op cit

253 Mark Thomas, Trespass, Edinburgh Fringe, 2015

254 Popovic op cit

Page 122: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

122

Under undemocratic regimes campaigners often stick close to the ‗insider‘ end of the

spectrum, given the obvious risks of public dissent. But in 2013 a coalition of Vietnamese

NGOs, media and individual experts showed that even ‗politically sensitive‘ issues like

land law can be raised publicly. The coalition sought, among other reforms, to limit

compulsory land acquisition by the state and provide secure land tenure. Finding allies in

local government and (state-owned) media, and using a mix of persuasion and publicity,

the campaign won these provisions and raised prospects for further policy changes in

coming years.255

Critical junctures

As discussed in chapter two, change often emerges from ‗critical junctures‘ – windows of

opportunity provided by failures, crises, changes in leadership, natural disasters or

conflicts. At such times decision-makers and the public may become painfully aware of

the inadequacies of the status quo and cast around for new ideas. A well-prepared

advocacy campaign can spot and respond to such moments, with striking results.

Take the Tobin Tax. In 1972, Nobel laureate economist James Tobin suggested

introducing a small tax on all financial transactions between different currencies. This, he

argued, would curb short-term speculation and raise a lot of money for good causes, such

as development assistance. The idea got nowhere, but continued bubbling on the margins

of political debate for over three decades and resurfaced during the 1998 Asian financial

crisis in no small part thanks to some dedicated NGOs, such as War On Want and Stamp

Out Poverty. I was a half-hearted supporter256

(the tax made sense as a fund-raising

device, but I wasn‘t convinced it would stabilize currency markets), which led to some

tricky domestic moments as my wife was running War on Want at the time.

It took the global financial crisis of 2008 and some inspired advocacy to bring the Tobin

Tax in from the cold. Crushed by debt repayments, finance ministers were desperate for

new sources of revenue for their cash-strapped governments, while opponents of the tax,

such as banks and currency traders, had suddenly become political pariahs. The shock

had transformed the landscape of power and politics, drastically changing what was

considered ‗sensible‘ or ‗realistic‘ in economic policy.

255 http://oxfamblogs.org/fp2p/can-you-only-do-advocacy-in-formal-democracies-lessons-from-6-multi-

stakeholder-initiatives-in-vietnam/ 256

D. Green, 1999, Capital Punishment: Making International Finance Work for the World’s Poor, CAFOD

Page 123: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

123

A coalition of trade unions, church groups and NGOs cleverly rebranded the Tobin Tax

as the ‗Robin Hood Tax‘ and waged public campaigns across Europe featuring a series of

hilarious videos by top filmmakers and actors. By 2011, the European Commission had

proposed a Europe-wide tax on financial transactions. Though whittled down to 11

countries257

it was scheduled to come into force in 2016 and represents a historic

breakthrough as the first truly international tax.258

Spotting and responding to critical junctures is just as important in developing-country

advocacy. In 2002, the Malawian chapter of a regional women‘s rights NGO, Women in

Law Southern Africa (WILSA) proposed and drafted legislation on violence against

women, but got nowhere promoting it to government. Three years down the line, the

media reported a spate of incidents of violence from across the country, ranging from

wife-killing to grievous bodily harm and rape. Oxfam‘s Malawi team put out a press

statement condemning the violence and calling on key leaders to take action. A range of

different groups echoed Oxfam‘s message, most strikingly the Blantyre police, who

drove up to Oxfam‘s offices in a van with loudspeakers on top broadcasting messages

against gender-based violence.

The Ministry of Gender seized the opportunity to reintroduce the abandoned legislation.

A well-connected NGO volunteered to ask traditional chiefs to lobby Parliament on the

day the bill was to be tabled. The charismatic Minister of Gender (and future president)

Joyce Banda personally lobbied alongside the president to garner support from cabinet

colleagues and the leader of the opposition. Following a very difficult debate in

parliament, with opponents accusing the bill‘s supporters of attacking Malawi‘s culture, it

passed.

Coalitions and alliances

The press conference was a disaster. It was scheduled late in the working day, long after

all the European and American journalists attending the 2001 Doha WTO ministerial had

filed their pieces and retired to the bar (this was a happier time in journalism, before the

advent of 24-hour news). What‘s more, the developing-country delegations that

organized it chose a dull technical title that belied the importance of the issue – how to

257 Update in 2016

258 http://ec.europa.eu/taxation_customs/taxation/other_taxes/financial_sector/index_en.htm

Page 124: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

124

protect poor farmers from being crushed by an avalanche of cheap, often subsidised food

imports. Hardly anyone showed up.

After a hurried discussion, the policy and media teams from international NGOs offered

to rerun the event. The ‗alliance of food insecure developing economies‘259

was

rechristened ‗the G33‘ (no journalist wanted to be blindsided by a new ‗G‘), a suitably

eye-catching title and news release was bashed out, and NGO press officers fanned out to

round up their contacts in the media room. The next day‘s event, on exactly the same

topic, was standing room only. The delegates purred with satisfaction and gave

barnstorming presentations.

Activists working alongside government delegates in the WTO are just one example of a

recurring pattern: uncomfortable alliances with ‗unusual suspects‘. We NGOs were

worried about supporting governments with questionable human rights records, and the

governments were highly suspicious of NGOs that had criticised them in the past. But

both sides saw potential in a tactical alliance on an issue they agreed on.

Advocacy is rarely conducted by a single organization - there is safety (and power) in

numbers and strength in unity. One of the skills of a good advocate is knowing how to

construct effective alliances – and to differentiate between soul-sapping talking shops and

powerful engines of change. Similar organizations, such as peasant producers or

women‘s savings groups, sometimes ally effectively, but more interesting things can

happen when unusual suspects join forces: civil society organizations with private sector

companies, for example, or with middle-class philanthropists, sympathetic state bodies or

faith-based organizations.

I was involved in one such ‗multi-stakeholder‘ exercise when I sat on the board of the

Ethical Trading Initiative (discussed in chapter seven). The board was tripartite,

consisting of equal numbers from big supermarkets and garment companies, international

trade unions and NGOs. Building trust was not easy, but it felt far more productive than

arguing fine points of policy in an NGO coalition. As well as being the main event in

terms of change, the corporates brought an extraordinary sense of can-do to the table.

‗How long would it take to make all our products fair trade?‘ wondered one major

supermarket. The unions were suspicious of NGOs muscling in on their patch, but

brought a deep understanding of workplace conditions around the world and the long-

259 Need to find out what G33 originally called itself in Doha – Shishir? Doha notebooks?

Page 125: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

125

term nature of change. The ETI has endured and had real impact, for example in

responding to Bangladesh‘s Rana Plaza disaster (noted in chapter two).

Working in such alliances can involve an element of holding your nose. After the BP

Deepwater Horizon disaster in 2010, Oxfam and its local partners were determined to

seize a classic critical juncture to ensure the reconstruction effort benefited the poor

coastal communities disproportionately affected by the oil spill. Big prizes required big

compromises. Oxfam worked closely with people whose views differed profoundly on

almost everything except the response to the oil spill, including private companies and

conservative evangelical church leaders, and even spent $120,000 on lobbyists who had

access to Republican politicians. Campaigners had a hard time swallowing it, but they

won investment in vulnerable communities and preferential hiring of local people.260

Implementation gaps

Because getting new laws onto the statute books is so difficult, many campaigns zero in

on enforcement of laws and policies that already exist, but are not being implemented.

Decision-makers have a harder time publicly opposing things they have themselves

approved. Getting down among the weeds of existing legislation and policy can be

unattractive to campaigners seeking more fundamental ‗transformative‘ change and it can

be highly technical. But done right, it can set the stage for larger changes.

In the early 2000s, I ran a small NGO called Just Pensions, set up by NGOs and finance

houses to promote ‗socially responsible investment‘ after the British government required

all pension funds to report on the extent to which they took into account ethical, social

and environmental considerations. All they had to do was file a report, but few had done

it. No-one was going to take to the streets to demand action on reporting requirements,

but the implementation gap got us in the door of a number of large pension funds and it

helped build a broader movement to challenge the long-term impact of their investments,

which at that point amounted to £800 billion, including a sizeable portion of the stock

market.261

Another example is from India‘s new and heavily forested state of Chhattisgarh, home to

some of India‘s ‗tribals‘ – marginalized traditional communities that live from forest

260 http://policy-practice.oxfam.org.uk/publications/advocating-for-gulf-coast-restoration-in-the-wake-of-

the-deepwater-horizon-oil-338441 261

Green, Just Pensions: Socially Responsible Investment and international Development, May 2001

Page 126: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

126

products. Despite the protection of the 2006 Forest Rights Act, their livelihoods were

under threat from mining and other commercial activities. An impressive local NGO,

Chaupal, launched an advocacy campaign to mobilize forest communities based on this

‗implementation gap‘. After negotiations, petitioning and protest, backed up by solid

research, dozens of villages have gained the forest and grazing rights promised under the

Act.262

The role of research

Research can be an effective weapon in the advocate‘s armoury. Pleas to Gordon Brown

over the Downing Street breakfast table would have had little impact without credible

analysis to back them up. My colleagues Ricardo Fuentes, Deborah Hardoon and Nick

Galasso, have hogged headlines and shaped the policy discussion at recent Davos

business summits with ‗killer facts‘ on the extreme levels of inequality in the

contemporary world. At last count, the 80 richest individuals on earth owned as much

wealth as the poorest half of global population, 3.5 billion people.263

As noted in chapter three, good research may be more persuasive in closed political

systems like China‘s, Russia‘s and Vietnam‘s, where government technocrats and

political leaders are more insulated from the political pressures and horse-trading that

characterize democracies.

In contrast, the importance of research to advocacy in democracies is often exaggerated.

Decisions are made rather more often on the basis of power, institutional inertia, received

wisdoms and vested interest than by a dispassionate review of the evidence. During my

brief spell working in DFID‘s International Trade Department, we received a visit from a

senior official at the Treasury, worried that we were going off message. ‗I am happy to

discuss UK trade policy‘, he declared, ‗but first we should agree that there are certain

universal truths: trade liberalization leads to more trade; more trade leads to less poverty‘.

Both claims were highly debatable, but no-one was going to change the mandarin‘s habit

of regurgitating what he had learned at university some decades back. I recalled Keynes‘

wonderful line: ‗Practical men who believe themselves to be quite exempt from any

intellectual influence, are usually the slaves of some defunct economist. Madmen in

262 http://policy-practice.oxfam.org.uk/publications/the-chhattisgarh-community-forest-rights-project-

india-338434 263

http://policy-practice.oxfam.org.uk/publications/wealth-having-it-all-and-wanting-more-338125

Page 127: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

127

authority, who hear voices in the air, are distilling their frenzy from some academic

scribbler of a few years back.‘ Not much room for evidence-based policy making there.

It is always possible, of course, that madmen in authority can be persuaded to change

their minds, but it is uphill work: a steady drip-drip of contrary evidence, public criticism,

pressure from their peers and exposure to failures and crises all help. In the end, I fear

that really deep-rooted ideas only change with generational turnover.

Messages and messengers

Advocacy has lifted much from the field of advertising, since it is a form of

salesmanship. An essential lesson is to craft the message to fit the audience. Here is how

WaterAid adapts its argument in favour of investment in water and sanitation for

different Tanzanian advocacy targets:264

Finance Ministers: ‗A small investment in clean drinking water and low-cost

sanitation facilities will yield a large return in relation to child and adult health

and survival.‘

Parliamentarians: ‗When asked poor people put access to water as one of their top

three priorities, if not their top priority.‘

Health professionals: ‗65 per cent of infant deaths from diarrhoeal diseases, like

cholera, in developing countries could be prevented by providing safe water and

sanitation. Environmental improvements like sanitation have bigger impacts and

lower costs than curative medicines.‘

Broadcast media and the press: ‗Wangai is six years old. His mother walks five

kilometres each morning to the nearest clean water point to collect drinking water

for the family. However, when Wangai and his friends are thirsty, they drink from

the nearby riverbed. That‘s also where the cattle and goats drink. Wangai‘s family

have no latrine and use the riverbed in the early morning before it is light. Wangai

has two brothers and one sister: he had another two sisters but both died of

dysentery before they were four years old. Wangai has visited his cousin who

lives in the nearby town, where there is a good water supply and each house has a

latrine. He has seen that his cousin‘s family do not fall ill and his aunt has lost no

babies because of sickness. He wishes there were similar facilities in his village.‘

264 Water Aid: The Advocacy Sourcebook

Page 128: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

128

General public: ‗Clean water saves lives: Each village should have at least one

borehole and adequate latrines. Talk to your local councillor today to find out how

you can help to bring life-saving facilities to your own village and see your

children flourish.‘

The messenger is often as important as the message. African activists speaking about the

challenges of development carry far more weight with most people than white academics,

however long their publications list. Government ministers listen to other government

ministers, the World Bank, or their supervisor from university days; captains of industry

are likely to listen to (and believe) something from a fellow master of the universe (like

Amnesty‘s Sir Geoffrey) or a leader of their church, rather than a nerdy researcher or

zealous campaigner.

Advocacy swims in the shark-infested waters of power and politics, so it is hardly

surprising that it is fraught with dangers, tensions and difficult judgements. Who decides

what a campaign should try to reform? What gives them the right to do so? Who are

campaigners accountable to if the reforms they win turn out to make things worse for

poor people, not better? Doesn‘t campaigning merely continue the marginalization of

poor people from the corridors of power? Let‘s explore some of these dilemmas.

The role of outsiders

Given that social and political change are largely ‗endogenous‘ phenomena – driven by

internal forces and players – is it proper for the aid industry to try to influence affairs in a

country that is not one‘s own? Is there truth in the accusation frequently made by

developing country governments that aid workers are simply stooges of a foreign power?

Think back to the example of ex-Greenpeace campaigners advising the British Foreign

Office. However laudable their intentions, how would the effort to change India‘s climate

change policy be seen by Indian politicians and activists? How would Her Majesty‘s

Government (let alone the British press) react if the Indian government used similar

tactics to change UK policy on, say, migration?

Alex de Waal argues that to get media coverage and governments‘ attention, Western

campaigners dumb down the complex realities of messy conflicts into simple narratives

of good and bad to be remedied by simple solutions (preferably deliverable by the

Page 129: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

129

West).265

Such narratives squeeze out the more nuanced views of local people and the

deeper, underlying causes of conflict, and end up promoting superficial victories rather

than real change.

Exhibit A is ‗Kony2012‘ – a campaign by a US NGO for military intervention by the

United States to defeat Ugandan warlord Joseph Kony, which went viral. The ‗hashtag

activism‘ of #BringBackOurGirls (for the return of 200 Nigerian schoolgirls abducted by

Boko Haram) also showed the limits of outsider outrage with no insider links or

understanding. Both campaigns made a huge splash in Western media and activist circles,

but had little or no impact on the ground.

My doubts about global campaigns began while I was working on the WTO at CAFOD. I

was on a roll, generating press coverage and loving being on the inside track. Then my

colleague Henry Northover burst my bubble by asking why I thought trade rules were

more important than his area of work - the World Bank and IMF ‗structural adjustment‘

policies that were slashing public spending and causing serious hardship in much of

Africa. I had no answer.

The massive global campaign Make Poverty History, which targeted the policies of the

WTO and the World Bank and IMF, not to mention the G8, launched in 2005, increased

my doubts. The implicit premise that tackling aid, debt and trade could end poverty

seemed at odds with my growing fascination with politics and change at a national

level.266

That said, I have come round to believing global campaigns can bring added value,

particularly when the obstacle to change resides outside the country in question, such as

the policies of the world‘s powers, transnational corporations, or international

institutions. Global campaigns can‘t solve an entrenched national dilemma, but they can

stop an international activity that is clearly causing harm. A good example is the Arms

Trade Treaty discussed in chapter six. Campaigns can tackle global ‗collective action

problems‘ like climate change that require concerted action by several or all countries to

succeed. Or ending the ‗race to the bottom‘ when countries try to undercut each other to

attract investment by lowering taxes.

265 Add ref when published Alex de Waal, Advocacy in Conflict

266 My book From Poverty to Power (2008) in many ways was an implicit critique of Make Poverty History.

Page 130: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

130

Foreign organizations can also be an asset in national campaigns where the levers of

change are susceptible to outside pressure. To improve wages and conditions for workers

in Indonesia‘s vast network of sportswear factories, the Indonesia Labour Rights Project

(ILRP) provided support to local trade unions and others and managed to broker

conversations between them and companies making brand-name sports gear for export.

When the talks were only getting workers suspended or dismissed, the project mobilized

its supporters in the countries that were buying the factories‘ shoes. Under pressure from

consumers, the companies sat down with the international campaigners (including

Oxfam), viewing them as non-partisan, therefore reasonable, while viewing local NGOs

as too pro-union.

Thanks largely to ILRP‘s efforts, an industry-wide Protocol on Freedom of Association

was signed in 2011. Within two years 71 suppliers of Adidas, Nike, New Balance, Puma,

Asics and Pentlands had signed on and the number of workers covered exceeded

700,000. The protocol also had the happy side-effect of improving communication

between the brands and the unions.267

Organizing exchanges between activists working on similar issues in different countries

is another useful role for outsiders, especially when the people involved are from broadly

comparable countries in terms of development. Oxfam‘s Raising Her Voice programme

promotes visits among women‘s rights activists in 17 countries to swap notes and

ideas.268

The We Can programme discussed in chapter two was born as an Indian

adaptation of work on violence against women in Uganda.269

Most outside organizations doing advocacy in developing countries agonize over their

legitimacy. The trick is to tread carefully, act humbly and learn from your mistakes.

Insiders v outsiders

An enduring tension exists between ‗outsider‘ and ‗insider‘ activists. Suppose you have

uncovered some dirt on a corporate target and written a hard-hitting briefing on it. You

need to give the corporate a chance to see it before publication. The outsider would hand

267 By exposing the vulnerability of Nike’s brand, the Indonesia campaign played an important part in the

company’s 2011 decision to reduce exposure to toxins (toluene) in all its factories and in 2012 (along with adidas) to limit the use of short-term contracts. http://policy-practice.oxfam.org.uk/publications/the-indonesian-labour-rights-project-338442 268

http://policy-practice.oxfam.org.uk/publications/the-raising-her-voice-global-programme-338444 269

http://policy-practice.oxfam.org.uk/publications/the-we-can-campaign-in-south-asia-338472

Page 131: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

131

it over the day before you launch, so that the company is caught all but unaware and a

good press story is assured. The insider, on the other hand, would do so several weeks in

advance, hoping they may take action to clean up the problem and avoid a public scandal.

The outsider prizes the opportunity to build public awareness of the wider issue, while

the insider favours maintaining good relations and sorting out a specific problem.

Such conflicts often reflect a deeper political chasm between the reformist and the

radical. Objectively, both play important roles. Outsiders and radicals keep important

issues alive and fight to get new ones onto the table. They work in public, where mass

mobilisation often needs stark, unchanging messages. Insiders, on the other hand, take

issues forward into the necessary fudges involved when turning ideas into policies.

Unsurprisingly, outsiders often think the insiders are sell-outs who muddy the waters

through compromise or hijack their issues, while insiders often view outsiders as

politically naïve purists who make any progress impossible.

Conflict and cooperation are often both required to achieve change; good campaigners

seek a creative tension in their relationship with the institution or individual they are

trying to influence, to be seen as both friend and critic, capable of doing damage as well

as rewarding progress.

The balance between insider and outsider tactics varies over the course of a campaign,

imposing real strains on activists, because of the very different tactics and language each

uses. In the conflict phase, these are often polarising and confrontational (us v them; good

guys v bad) and the alliances are likely to be more horizontal (among like-minded

groups). By contrast, in the cooperation phase, the language and tactics are more

propositional, and alliances need to be forged with actors in other spheres. Messy

compromises replace clarion calls for revolution.

In practice, individual activists tend to prefer one or the other of the two mindsets, and

find it hard to change gears. Many tacitly opt for a division of labour, specializing in

either the conflict or the cooperation phase. I am a co-operator: conflict makes me

anxious and I like ambiguity; yet I have friends and colleagues who much prefer the

clarity and adrenaline of a good punch-up.

Such tensions become particularly acute when the disagreement is between ‗outsiders‘ in

the South, and ‗insiders‘ in international NGOs. In 1999, on the eve of winning debt

relief for dozens of developing countries, the international Jubilee 2000 movement fell

apart in acrimony, with Southern activists accusing Northern lobbyists of losing sight of

politics in their obsession with policy. It brought home to me how divisive ‗success‘ can

Page 132: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

132

be – what looks like victory to a reformist can easily appear as betrayal to a more radical

mindset.

These tensions echo a more fundamental (and largely insoluble) dilemma: expediency

versus long-term transformation. In The Leopard, a wonderful novel by Giuseppe Tomasi

di Lampedusa set in civil war and revolution in nineteenth-century Italy, Don Fabrizio

Corbera, Prince of Salina, wearily observes ‗Everything must change so that everything

can stay the same.‘ Is that the case with piecemeal reforms? Does signing off on limited

land reform in the Philippines, for example, legitimize the current distribution of power,

forestalling deeper transformational change? My own view is that a reform that also

expands the voice of poor and excluded people is worth pursuing. I am too old and

impatient (and perhaps too European) to hold out for ‗all or nothing‘ approaches, which

sadly often end up with the latter.

Conclusion

Criticism is salutary. Advocacy can fail or backfire when campaigners become stuck in a

hubristic bubble of tactics and media hits, and lose touch with the views and needs of the

supposed ‗beneficiaries‘ of their frenetic activities. Advocates need to be acutely

conscious of their own power and position in the system, and the biases and behaviours

those induce. They need deep connections with local communities, including hiring and

promoting local staff rather than ex-pats. More subtly, good advocacy requires a mindset

that finds each different context fascinating, that embraces ambiguity and complexity,

that tries to learn from mistakes and respond to changing events, and yet manages to

maintain the energy needed to win.

Activism is never easy, and will always be beset with arguments over tactics and

tensions. As I hope the examples in this book demonstrate, intelligent, inclusive and

respectful advocacy has huge potential to drive positive change for large numbers of

people who are getting a raw deal from the current system. Getting advocacy right

requires political maturity, the right combination of tactics and allies, and making the

most of windows of opportunity as they come along. Finding that path often comes down

to leadership, to which we now turn.

Page 133: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

133

11 Leaders and leadership

‘Men make their own history, but they do not make it as they please; they do not make it

under self-selected circumstances, but under circumstances existing already, given and

transmitted from the past. The tradition of all dead generations weighs like a nightmare

on the brains of the living.’ Karl Marx270

Joseph Sungi MP is known throughout Papua New Guinea‘s remote Nuku district simply

as ‗the Member‘. He is a Big Man in every sense, oozing authority and confidence, his

bull neck and large frame squeezed into a dapper pin-striped suit. Joe is a man on a

mission, and that mission is roads. Using the discretionary funds at every MP‘s disposal,

he plans to build all-weather roads to every one of Nuku‘s 84 wards by the next election

in 2017.

‗When we went home for Christmas we had to walk the last seven kilometres to get to

our villages. Our kids don‘t want to go back home any more. In my village I said, this is

the last time I walk here – next time I‘ll be in a car. So I made sure the road was built, to

show I am a man of my word. Then the people are convinced.‘

Travelling with Joe‘s team in Nuku, I see plenty of evidence that his obsession is bearing

fruit. The district has bought 13 shiny yellow pieces of earth moving equipment and hired

a civil engineer; work is underway.

Joe has tapped a nerve. Everyone I speak with, from government officials to church and

women‘s groups at ward level, is enthusiastic: roads allow farmers to get their cocoa to

market, reduce the costs of resupplying schools and clinics, help retain teachers and

nurses reluctant to work in isolated locations. Of course, roads are no panacea: women

and church leaders worry about negative influences, such as drugs and disobedience,

which they blame on the improved links. Women farmers say they can now get their

crops to Nuku‘s main town, but find no buyers and end up bringing them home again.

Joe‘s other priority is even more groundbreaking: he has handed a large wad of local

funding directly over to the wards, US$10,000 each, to spend as they please. In P.N.G.

this is revolutionary – the Big Man is handing over money even to villages that didn’t

Page 134: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

134

vote for him. More traditional spending patterns are on display in the yard of the District

Administrator‘s office in Nuku, where four land cruisers are parked, the first instalment

of some 20 vehicles the previous MP allegedly handed out to his cronies, which are now

being confiscated.

Like a giant magnet surrounding by iron filings, Joe‘s leadership seems to have built a

sense of optimism and common purpose. At every level of society, from the village

committee or women‘s savings group to great nation-builders, leaders reinforce group

identity and cohesion, and mobilize collective effort toward shared goals. Successful

leaders know how to inspire and motivate, and they intuitively understand that to turn a

vision and a mobilized following into a transformational force they, as leaders, must

retain that difficult-to-define quality known as legitimacy.271

Over the years, I‘ve been lucky enough to spend time with hundreds of leaders in dozens

of countries, from ministers and senior officials to grassroots activists who galvanize

their communities to work for the common good and even to take great risks holding

corrupt officials or companies to account.

The shelves of airport bookshops groan under the weight of homages to corporate titans,

promising to distil the secrets of leadership and success for the rest of us. And the subject

fascinated great thinkers of the more distant past, who analyzed the use of violence, the

role of luck and whether it is better to be loved or feared.272

Plato and Machiavelli lined

up behind political expertise and the concentration of power; Aristotle, Cicero and

Montesquieu argued for constitutional limits on leaders‘ power. Beyond the Western

bubble, few thinkers placed such unreserved confidence in leadership as Confucius, who

saw it as the originating and sustaining force behind good politics: ‗Let there be the

proper men and their good political order will flourish; but without such men, their

political order decays and ceases.‘273

Activists and academics, however, tend to downplay the role of leadership in driving

change. Development Studies as a discipline has little to say about the Big Man in the

271 R. Rotberg, Transformative Political Leadership, 2012, p.19

272 “Western Political Thought,” Nannerl O Keohane, chapter in The Oxford Handbook of Political

Leadership, 2014 273

Confucius, The Doctrine of the Mean, circa 500 BCE, quoted in Confucianism, Joseph Chan and Elton

Chan, in The Oxford Handbook of Political Leadership, 2014

Page 135: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

135

presidential palace, and even less about leadership from below – that which emerges in

citizens‘ movements, voluntary associations, trade unions, faith organizations and indeed

in every walk of life.

I suspect that ideological bias lies behind the academy‘s neglect of leadership. Marxists

(and more generally, positivists and structuralists) think in terms of masses and

institutions, rather than individuals. Socialist historians like E.P. Thompson proposed a

‗history from below,‘274

in which leaders may strut the stage, claiming to be making

history, but in reality are mere flotsam on a sea of political, technological, economic and

social change that makes or destroys them.

At the other extreme are rational choice thinkers such as Gary Becker,275

who see society

and the economy as a set of ‗utility-maximising individuals‘ with little need for leaders

(or followers). And progressives uncomfortable with the elitism of a ‘big man‘ theory of

human history that excludes all women and most male followers fall somewhere in

between. Aid technocrats avoid discussions of leadership, because it rapidly gets political

and clouds the seductive purity of ‗evidence-based policy making‘.

Leadership in my view is central to any understanding of how change happens. Whether

in business, politics or social change, leaders are at the interface between structure and

agency, striving to leave their mark on the institutions, cultures and traditions in which

they live and work.

Understanding leadership at the top

Joe Sungi is no revolutionary. He is a ‗transactional leader‘ trying to make the system

work for his constituents, and in Papua New Guinea that is an uphill task. More than a

decade of continuous high growth has raised per capita GDP by 150 per cent, yet PNG

has not achieved a single one of the Millennium Development Goals for reducing

poverty, improving access to education or other indicators of social progress. It shares

that dubious distinction only with Zimbabwe and North Korea (the MDGs that is, not the

growth); in terms of turning growth into development, PNG is a strong candidate for the

world‘s worst underachiever. At the heart of that failure, I‘d argue, stands politics: most

of PNG‘s Big Men are more concerned with strengthening their own power and fortune

than with building roads or other essential public goods.

274 http://www.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2013/dec/31/history-under-attack-ep-thompson

275 Is he the best example of a rational choice theorist? Check with Ricardo

Page 136: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

136

Some leaders have managed to become more transformational than transactional,

drastically altering the balance of power in their societies. Nelson Mandela in South

Africa, Gandhi in India, Martin Luther King in the US or Julius Nyerere in Tanzania all

emerged at ‗critical junctures‘ in history – moments of abrupt change, crisis or external

threat – and they seized the opportunity. When structural constraints to action become

weaker, great leaders can help remake societies, rather than simply make them work a bit

better.

Even in the absence of crisis, leaders in developing countries often have more potential to

transform society. Where institutions are relatively weak, force of will and personality

can help build national culture, laws and political institutions, including the checks and

balances on the power of future leaders. Perhaps that is why early leaders often achieve

mythic status as the founders of the nation – Bismarck, Washington, Lee Kuan Yew,

Ataturk, Mandela. Those that follow may look like puny pen-pushers by comparison,

hemmed in as they are by compromises, institutions and rules.

But that relative absence of constraints also increases the potential for damage. ‗The

constitutions is what I say it is,‘ Robert Mugabe declared in 1999. Some leaders enter

power with the best of intentions, but cling on long after their sell-by date. When Barack

Obama addressed the African Union in 2015, he declared, ‗Nobody should be president

for life.‘276

The public gallery reportedly erupted in cheers, while the front rows

maintained a stony silence. At the time in Africa, there were nine leaders (and one

monarch) who had ruled for over 20 years. (And yes, NGOs can suffer from the same

malady.)

Leadership and institutions

If strong institutions are an indicator of development, then the success of a leader can be

measured by the institutional legacy he or she leaves. Good leaders breathe life into

institutions; bad leaders destroy or stifle them. I began writing this chapter the week a

truly transformative political leader died, Singapore‘s Lee Kuan Yew, and the obit pages

were filled with praise for his achievements (albeit laced with criticism for his record on

human rights). The Economist glowed: ‗A tribute to Mr Lee‘s nation-building was the

absence of any flicker from the stock market on news of his death.… [T]hanks largely to

276 http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/world-africa-33691468

Page 137: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

137

Mr Lee, Singapore‘s institutions are strong, its governance honest, effective—and

dull.‘277

An article in the same edition entitled ‗King Paul278

‘ presented a contrasting portrait of

one of Africa‘s most celebrated contemporary leaders, Paul Kagame, the Rwandan

president: ‗In history‘s judgment, leaders are only as good as the successors they groom.

Mr Kagame has sacked or chased away just about everyone around him who could take

over. Some have fled the country and a few have died in mysterious circumstances;

others went to prison.‘

One explanation for the differences between Lee and Kagame may lie in how they came

to power – Kagame, as a former rebel commander, introduced the top-down disciplines

of military authority, along with its rejection of dissidence and pluralism. That path was

shared by Ethiopia‘s Meles Zenawi, Cuba‘s Fidel Castro and China‘s Mao Tse Tung. Lee

Kuan Yew, on the other hand, was a lawyer who led Singapore‘s non-violent

independence movement. A similar case was José Figueres, the coffee farmer who led

Costa Rica‘s 1948 revolution that abolished the army and set the country on a democratic

path. The military men were willing to use brute force to stay in control and achieve the

changes they sought, while the civilians preferred the law and institutions.

What do leaders do?

The system delivers for Joe Sungi because he knows how decisions get made in the

capital, Port Moresby – which tables to bang, which favours to call in. Joe says, ‗The key

is you talk to people. I don‘t write letters – I do the talking! Most of what I do is informal,

I owe it all to informal relationships.‘

Like many leaders, Joe gets things moving, but leaves the finishing to others. One of his

key men is Kenny Myeni, a jovial, bearded engineer whom Joe managed to lure from a

comfortable job with British American Tobacco to run the road-building programme.

Funds are often in short supply laughs Kenny, but ‗the Member knows where the money

is. We provide the documentation and the Member does the talking‘.

277 http://www.economist.com/news/asia/21647333-island-state-mourns-its-founding-father-its-politics-

changing-after-patriarch 278

http://www.economist.com/news/middle-east-and-africa/21647365-successful-man-no-successor-king-paul?zid=309&ah=80dcf288b8561b012f603b9fd9577f0e

Page 138: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

138

Sungi exemplifies the two-level game that leaders have to play – building bridges among

constituencies and driving bargains with those in power – while constantly maintaining

and boosting followers‘ morale. They must lead but look constantly over their shoulder

because, as a Malawian proverb puts it, ‗A leader without followers is simply someone

taking a walk‘.

Indeed, ‗great leaders‘ are often created by their followers and by the historical moment

(both forces beyond their control); their rise only appears inevitable with hindsight.

Churchill was revered by the British during World War II, but ridiculed beforehand and

unceremoniously dumped at the ballot box once the war was over.

But as Marx‘s famous quote at the start of this chapter makes clear, leaders are more than

pawns of circumstance. Success stems from their ability to understand the tide of power,

politics and events, seize moments of opportunity, build coalitions and organize

movements for change. Successful leaders make the most of whatever room for

manoeuvre exists, capitalising on luck and events to pull levers and push things along.

They understand the nature of formal and informal power in their societies, because

anything they achieve involves navigating within those structures, even if their aim is to

bend or break them. Politics is, after all, the art of the possible.

It‘s easy to forget that when Nelson Mandela was finally released from prison in the early

1990s, South Africa was teetering on a knife‘s edge. Fighting between Inkatha and ANC

supporters threatened to tip over into civil war; fragile state status beckoned. At one early

event, ANC supporters called for Mandela to ‗give us weapons. No peace‘. 279

Mandela

told his fired-up supporters, ‗Listen to me. I am your leader. I am going to give you

leadership. If you are going to kill innocent people, you don‘t belong in the ANC.‘ What

would have happened if he had opted for the populist route and stoked the fires?

Mandela was no King Canute, standing futilely against the tides of history. He was an

expert navigator, now forging personal or political alliances with erstwhile enemies, now

publicly denouncing attempts to pervert or prevent the transition to black majority rule.

He built unity among the different factions of the ANC, and turned it from a protest

movement into a dominant ruling party.

Leaders understand the power of symbolism in building mass movements, a language

parallel to and separate from the policy detail preferred by officials and academics.

279 Rotberg, p. 40

Page 139: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

139

Rather than confront the British on their own terms, Mahatma Gandhi wrong-footed

colonial authorities with small personal acts like collecting salt and spinning cotton on a

simple spinning wheel to highlight the search for self sufficiency and independence. The

spinning wheel even appeared on an early version of the Indian flag.280

Mandela too had

a talent for the meaningful, heart-stopping gesture, reaching out to white South Africans

by wearing the Springbok rugby shirt or travelling to a remote Afrikaner community to

take tea with the 94-year-old widow of Henrik Verwoerd, a key architect of apartheid.281

Both Mandela and Gandhi demonstrated that humility and ethical probity can convey

more political legitimacy than displays of intelligence or expertise.

Most of us have seen the variety of ways leaders navigate power at our jobs. I have

worked under ‗bull-in-a-china shop‘ bosses trying to force their will on reluctant

organizations, charismatic visionaries who inspire and motivate but leave the detail to

others, and subtle backseat drivers who drip ideas steadily into the corporate bloodstream

without ever taking credit. I suppose these all have their places, but I confess my

temperament is certainly not suited for either of the first two approaches. Any influence I

exert had better occur through the osmosis of suggestion.

Discussions of leaders and leadership customarily fixate on the people at the top – the

habits and psychologies of CEOs and presidents, be they saints or sinners. But leaders are

everywhere, nowhere more than in the movements for change active in poor communities

across the world.

Leadership from below

Penha was an imposing figure, a big confident woman who rose to become president of

the Alagoa Grande Rural Workers‘ Union in Brazil‘s drought-prone and poverty-ridden

Northeast. When I visited in 1990, I looked on as Pehna tried to persuade an

impoverished farming community to join the union. Pot-bellied children with skinny

arms played at the feet of adults as the banter and serious talk rolled easily along. Penha

guided the conversation with a blend of authority, humour and kindness, letting others

speak and enjoying their jokes, as the impromptu discussion developed into a full-blown

community meeting about the causes of poverty in Brazil and the need to organize to

280 https://makarandimpressions.wordpress.com/2015/01/30/mahatma-gandhi-the-true-revolutionary/

281 Rotberg, p.63

Page 140: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

140

demand rights to the land. As dusk fell, the meeting turned to music and dance, in honour

of the visitors.282

Later on, she told me her life story, the words half lost in the drumming of a sudden

downpour, which turned the street into a river bearing rubbish from the nearby market. A

broken home, starting work at age seven, a mother who died from tuberculosis when

Penha was twelve, early marriage and the struggle to feed her six children. To that point

it was the story of countless poor Latin American women.

Penha was able to turn her personal courage and determination into leadership thanks to a

lucky encounter with a charismatic leader named Margarida Maria Alves, who first

introduced her to the union. When Margarida was murdered, probably by local

landowners, Penha took over.

Often, what casts people into leadership is participation in an organization rather than the

influence of a mentor. In dozens of countries across several continents, I have met

grassroots leaders inspired by their faith and equipped with skills by their experiences in

choirs or as preachers, both Christian and Muslim.283

Scripture helped them form a

personal narrative about the sources of their deprivation and repression, galvanizing them

into action.

Unlike those at the top of society, social movement leaders have little money and few

threats with which to control or reward their followers. They rely heavily on their ability

to communicate understanding of the lives of others and belief in the value of collective

action to address common problems. They foster their followers‘ sense of ‗power within‘,

buttressed by a vision of a better future that justifies taking action, even when to do so at

best takes up poor people‘s scarce time and energy and at worst puts their lives at risk.

Strengthening community organization is often insufficient to win access to land, funding

or respect. Grassroots leaders must also play the same two-level game as Joe Sungi,

building alliances with other organizations and cutting deals with people in positions of

power. One of the functions of such leaders is to ‗create space‘ for others. Chinese

philosopher Lao Tzu put it this way in the sixth century BCE: ‗A leader is best

when people barely know that he exists, not so good when people obey and acclaim him,

282 Duncan Green, Faces of Latin America, 2011

283 MORE PERSONAL STORIES TO COME FROM PACIFIC TRIP, 11/15

Page 141: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

141

worst when they despise him. But of a good leader, who talks little, when his work is

done, his aims fulfilled, they will all say, ‗We did this ourselves.‘284

In the recent protest movements of the Arab Spring, some observers viewed the very lack

of identifiable leaders as a strength, since none could be co-opted or attacked. If a

movement has no head, how can it be beheaded? It seemed somehow more pure and

genuinely of the masses to have no leaders instead of a grand personality who achieves

celebrity status. But such ‗anti-leadership‘ ideas285

have their limitations. When the cycle

moves on from protest and conflict to cooperation and reform, someone has to engage

with those in power to maximise whatever gains have been won through protest.

Headless movements cannot cut deals.

Many of the greatest national leaders rose from the grassroots. The transformational

presidents of Brazil and Bolivia (Lula and Evo Morales) started out as a trade union and

peasant leader, respectively. Martin Luther King was a local preacher. A combination of

the historical moment and their personal qualities propelled them to global prominence.

But for every such rising star, there are thousands of Penhas, unsung heroes organizing

their fellow citizens in the struggle for change.

Women and leadership

Joe Sungi typifies a leadership style – individualistic, confrontational, public (‗I do the

talking!‘) – which seems particularly male. Penha‘s approach was altogether more

inclusive; she listened as much or more than she spoke. Women often bring different

qualities to leadership than men, with greater attention to collaboration, collective

decision-making, and above all, relationship building.

According to scholar Srilatha Batliwala, feminist leadership goes beyond such

longstanding stereotypes.286

Rather than seek a more efficient management of the social

status quo, she says, feminist leaders work to transform relations of power. By sharing

authority within their own organizational structures, they create an alternative model of

how power can be exercised. Given Joe Sungi‘s bid to build support by handing decision-

making power over to local councils, perhaps his style is not so male after all.

284 Tao Te Ching, Chapter 17

285 Anti-leaders(hip) in Social Movement Organizations: The case of autonomous grassroots groups Neil

Sutherland, Christopher Land and Steffen Böhm, Organization, 2013 286

http://www.uc.edu/content/dam/uc/ucwc/docs/CREA.pdf

Page 142: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

142

Pakistan is well known for its highly articulate and influential women, but also notorious

for the severe restrictions placed on women‘s personal and political liberties. In each of

30 districts across Pakistan, Oxfam invited 50 women linked to a broad cross-section of

community and civil society organizations and representing different political parties, to

meet regularly. The objective was to break down the isolation many felt and build mutual

trust. These Women Leaders Groups rapidly took up a range of local problems, such as

violations of women‘s employment rights, cases of domestic violence, sexual abuse in

local schools and custody rights after separation. They became a driving force behind a

national Women‘s Manifesto presented to all political parties; 90 participants ran for

political office in the 2013 election.287

That experience confirmed that women‘s leadership can be galvanized by collective

discussion. But what kinds of women become grassroots leaders in the first place? A

study by the Overseas Development Institute identified some common factors: Many are

married, have some professional training and work in ‗nurturing‘ or community-related

occupations like teaching or social work. Many enjoy the psychological and financial

support of close family members, as well as the encouragement of role models (women in

public office or active in women‘s civic movements).288

Leaders and leadership are the catalyst that turn discontent or aspiration into action and

achievement. Yet leadership, particularly of women, is often given far lower priority by

aid agencies and scholars than other factors, such as the provision of health, education or

infrastructure. Outsiders have a role in spotting, nurturing and protecting leaders, but first

they need to be much clearer on how leadership emerges – the role of government, faith

groups, education, norms and any number of other factors, and how leaders interact with

other actors and institutions to galvanize change.

Education and leadership

The Development Leadership Program 289

is researching what causes individual leaders to

stretch their loyalties beyond their immediate family, region, class or ethnicity. Initial

results underscore the importance of education in cooking what they call the ‗secret

287 http://policy-practice.oxfam.org.uk/publications/the-raising-her-voice-pakistan-programme-338443

288 http://www.odi.org/sites/odi.org.uk/files/odi-assets/publications-opinion-files/9623.pdf

289 http://www.dlprog.org/ DLP is funded by the Australian Government, which also provided support for

this book.

Page 143: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

143

sauce‘ of leadership that can drive, rather than block, development.290

In-depth interviews

with 27 leaders of Ghana‘s transformation since the late 1980s revealed three common

elements they learned in school:

Core values – moral purpose and commitment to serving the nation, respect and

tolerance, honesty, integrity and fairness;

Ways of working – critical thinking and analytical insight, collaboration and

conflict-resolution, consultation and teamwork, goal-orientation and a strong

sense of responsibility, discipline, focus and determination, courage and agency;

and

Technical skills – the ‗hard‘ skills, expertise and knowledge which leaders need if

they are to drive change.

An analysis of a wider group of 117 Ghanaian leaders showed that 96 per cent had

attended either an elite secondary school or higher education establishment and 74 per

cent had attended both. These schools are based on the British model, with a strong dose

of Christian ideology, and, given relatively meritocratic access, attending one ensures

social mobility. The study claims an important factor was that the schools were

residential.

A brilliant DLP paper by Sarah Phillips291

highlighted the role of the Sheekh Secondary

School in the intriguing ‗natural experiment‘ of Somaliland, which split off from the

chaos of Somalia in the 1990s. Set up by Richard Darlington, who fought in World War

II as the commander of the British Army‘s Somaliland Protectorate contingent, Sheekh

took only fifty students a year and trained them in leadership and critical thought

(Darlington borrowed from the curriculum of his elite English private school, Harrow).

The school also stresses student intake from all clans, especially the more marginalized

ones. Sheekh provided three out of four presidents of the new nation, along with

numerous vice presidents and cabinet members.

Joe Sungi‘s life story echoes their findings. The son of subsistence farmers, well down

the clan hierarchy, he was educated at an Australian Catholic mission school, and then a

290 Brannelly, L., Lewis, L. and Ndaruhutse, S. (2011a) “Higher education and the formation of

developmental elites: a literature review and preliminary data analysis,” Developmental Leadership Program Research Paper 10 291

http://www.dlprog.org/ftp/download/Public%20Folder/Political%20Settlements%20and%20State%20Formation%20-%20the%20Case%20of%20Somaliland.pdf

Page 144: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

144

boarding school for the best and brightest kids from around the country. He traces his

sense of public ethics to that school. Upon graduation, he entered the public service as an

agricultural extension agent, managed to win an international scholarship to do a masters

degree in the Philippines, and rose to become the top administrator in the province before

deciding to go into politics.

Joe laments that one of the unintended consequences of the spread of secondary

education is that kids now go to high school in their own communities, rather than being

forced to board with the best and brightest from around his fragmented country. He is

urging the government to consider introducing elite public boarding schools based on the

French Lycee system to recreate the lost leadership crucible of his youth.

These are uncomfortable findings for activists in the development industry. Advocating

for elite boarding schools, even with meritocratic entry, smacks of old English

colonialism (Ghana, Somaliland and PNG are former British colonies) and feel distinctly

regressive compared to getting every child into a primary school, never mind boarding

schools‘ reputation for abuse. Yet this research makes the very plausible point that elite

boarding schools tend to produce more and better leaders. In my experience, when there

is this kind of clash between head and heart, the issue usually merits further thought. We

need to pin down what aspects of elite education lead to more capable, publicly-minded

leaders, and how those can be incorporated into modern school systems.

The DLP‘s findings on education are important, but can only be part of a much wider

story. For example, what determines whether leaders pursue the common good or cling to

power regardless? My honest opinion is that we really don‘t know. The old adage that

‗power corrupts, and absolute power corrupts absolutely‘ seems terribly defeatist, and

ignores the many leaders who do great things and then step down when the time comes

(whether from the presidency or the local union branch). ‗More research needed‘, I guess

– always a welcome conclusion for academics.

Conclusion

Leaders are archetypal navigators of complex systems. They can ‗see‘ how power is

distributed and fought over in society, and spot opportunities to seize and shape the tide

of events. And they are critical to how change happens. One can only wonder what would

have occurred had Nelson Mandela died on Robben Island or Gandhi stayed on in South

Africa.

Page 145: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

145

For institutions promoting change, training and supporting leaders should be an attractive

proposition. It is pleasingly tangible and puts a human face on the often amorphous

process of development. But few aid agencies explicitly invest in people. Scholarships

are commonplace in education, but stop as soon as a person leaves school or university.

Why not emulate the few schemes that identify and back outstanding individuals, such as

the MacArthur Foundation Fellowship?292

Or offer work experience, internships or

teaching opportunities for students in the disciplines where tomorrow‘s progressive

leaders are most likely to study?

Among activists, many of whom have a deep commitment to egalitarianism, words like

leadership and leader elicit mixed feelings. Most of us would prefer to build the capacity

of organizations rather than invest directly in individuals with high potential. Indeed,

even talking in terms of high-potential individuals can feel somehow contrary to

principles of fairness and equality.

That may be why we have neglected leadership in our thinking (if not our practice).

Addressing leadership much more systematically need not imply being seduced by

simplistic ‗big man‘ approaches to politics and change. On the contrary, acknowledging

the crucial role leaders play in bringing about change just may amplify the voices of

groups that currently go unheard.

292 http://www.macfound.org/programs/fellows/

Page 146: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

146

12 Pulling it all together

Diagnosing what‘s wrong is always a lot easier than suggesting what to do about it, but

we now come to the inevitable ‗so what‘ section. If the previous chapters are broadly

correct regarding the nature and dynamics of change, what should we activists do

differently? This chapter sets out some implications for how we think and act, and

considers what such an approach might mean for large organizations in the field of

international development.

The lexicon of aid and development is a bubbling morass of buzzwords and fuzzwords

(like buzzwords, only more fuzzy). One of the more recent additions is the phrase

‗theories of change‘. In meetings and documents, people earnestly enquire ‗what‘s your

theory of change?‘ You‘re in trouble if you don‘t have an answer, although I find

replying ‗I don‘t know, what‘s yours?‘ can induce a satisfying fit of spluttering and panic

in my tormentor.

One could consider the thrust of this book to be a theory of change. Theories of change

locate a programme, project or campaign within a wider analysis of how change comes

about. They articulate and challenge our assumptions and acknowledge the influence of

wider systems and actors. The concept remains fuzzy, partly because the idea originated

from two very different approaches: evaluation, (trying to clarify the links between

project inputs and outcomes) and social action, especially participatory social action.

At the risk of gross generalization, for the first group theories of change are a tool with

which to develop more complete and accurate chains of cause and effect. For the second

such linear thinking (if we do X then we will achieve Y) is largely a wild goose chase;

they view the concept as an aid to understanding complex adaptive systems. Naturally,

there is a spectrum of approaches between these two poles, and they often co-

exist uncomfortably within individuals and organizations.

Craig Valters suggests theories of change can provide a more flexible alternative to

working with conventional planning tools, such as logical frameworks (logframes),

especially for complex programmes and contexts. 293

Viewing a theory-of-change

approach as a dynamic process rather than a static document allows for assumptions to be

293 Valters (2015) – Theories of Change: time for a radical approach to learning in development [check

final title]

Page 147: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

147

regularly challenged and updated, which requires a continual back and forth between

emerging evidence from the changing local context and the theory on which the

programme is based.

My experience so far suggests a theory of change is best used when individual staff are

seeking to challenge their own cognitive constraints and adherence to particular ways of

thinking. In other words, personnel need to be willing to ask fundamental questions, and

the institutions they work for must be prepared to alter the direction of the programme.

The institutional cultures of few organisations are well adapted to such questioning and

will likely need to evolve.

Should it become widespread, a theory-of-change approach could shift the centre of

gravity from monitoring and evaluating (primarily to satisfy funders) to learning (which

allows us to improve our work as we go along). To remain useful however, theories of

change will have to fend off three forces that are ubiquitous in the aid business.

First, the pull of the top-down approach, whereby the philosopher kings (or at least

consultants) from universities and think-tanks contemplate a political and economic

system and derive the perfect theory of change without actually talking to anyone on the

ground. Aid donors already produce ever-more elaborate ‗political economy analyses,‘

which often seem to pay more attention to the economy than the politics294

and seem to

induce a helpless acceptance of the status quo.

Another risk is the ‗toolkit temptation‘. People working in aid and development, like

activists in general, are busy, stressed people who need support. Most do not take kindly

to being told ‗every situation is different – go study yours, and come up with some stuff

to try‘. They want an idea of where to begin, what questions to ask, what success looks

like. This natural instinct has prompted a proliferation of ‗toolkits‘ and best-practice

guidelines. In this book I have tried to find a middle course that provides some help for

would-be activists, but insists that, ultimately, their plans and actions have to be tailored

to their own contexts. Other approaches (including the logframe) started out with the

same noble intentions, only to be boiled down in the crucible of bureaucracy and time

pressure into largely uniform checklists. Will theories of change and my attempt at

organizing my thoughts also become little more than a logframe on steroids?

294 From Political Economy to Political Analysis, David Hudson and Adrian Leftwich, June 2014

Page 148: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

148

The third and final risk is the demand for evidence of quick results and value for money.

While accountability is necessary to justify aid spending to taxpayers and to learn and

improve, the top-down pressure for results, primarily from aid donors, can have some

deeply negative consequences for the way theories of change play out in practice. It is

much easier to ‗prove‘ results by assuming the world is linear, reinforcing the ‗if x, then

y‘ mindset. Moreover, the need to prove results in order to obtain funding pushes aid

agencies to work on issues where such ‗islands of linearity‘ are to be found (e.g. bednets,

vaccines), rather than working on those that may matter more (e.g. women‘s

empowerment, fighting corruption), which tend to be harder and more expensive to

measure. I would even blame the results agenda for skewing aid towards autocracies,

because they are better equipped than democracies to provide the certainty craved by

donors.295

With these caveats in mind, I will now sketch out the elements of a theory of change

based on the concepts outlined in this book.

Start with power

Power is one certainty in an uncertain world. Whatever the issue we are thinking about

and seeking to change, everyone involved will be linked by a subtle and pervasive force

field of power. Power analysis – understanding the nature of the power in question, how

it is distributed and how it might be disrupted and redistributed – is the subtext to most

efforts to bring about change. Rising literacy, women‘s rights, healthier lives, the spread

of democracy, all are expressions of the progressive expansion of power to those

previously excluded from its exercise.

Power is an iceberg in which the visible power that dominates the headlines is only part

of the story; below the waterline lurk hidden power (behind the scenes) and invisible

power (values and norms) which are often just as influential in determining what happens

and may offer the best route to bring about change.

Power can oppress, but it can also liberate. Over the years, I have heard hundreds of

accounts of ‗light-bulb moments‘ of empowerment, whether personal realizations of

rights and ‗power within‘, or the coming together of poor and marginalized communities

295 http://oxfamblogs.org/fp2p/best-practice-and-linear-thinking-favour-autocracies-so-what-do-we-do-

instead/

Page 149: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

149

to achieve ‗power with‘. Some of these stories are shared in this book or on the

accompanying website.

A good power analysis should lay bare at least part of the force field of power. It should

identify the players, how they relate to each other, who or what they are influenced by

(peer persuasion or rivalry? evidence? protest?). It should highlight the recurring blind

spots in activists‘ understanding of the world, such as the way we all too often ignore

central significance of faith organizations, trade unions or traditional leaders in the lives

of the people we are trying to support.

A power analysis should suggest strategies for engaging with the key public or private

institutions that drive or block change. It should dissolve the monoliths of ‗the state‘ or

‗big business‘ or ‗the international system‘ into turbulent networks full of potential allies

as well as opponents. A power analysis should also help us understand why change

doesn‘t happen - the forces of inertia and paradigm maintenance, usually born of the

three i‘s mentioned in chapter one (interests, ideas and institutional cultures). Weakening

and dislodging those forces is frequently a part of change strategies.

In analysing power, ‗we‘ are not lofty, disinterested observers. Power flows within our

own organizations; it influences our relations with partners and allies. We make decisions

at least partly based on our default models of the world and assumptions not based on

evidence. An examination of the nature and individual power within ourselves and the

use of power within our organizations are important elements in designing effective

strategies for change. In aid organizations I suspect such an analysis might infer that

power needs to shift from expats to local staff and partners, who are far better placed to

understand power in their countries and to make the programme more ‗politically smart,

locally led‘, as the Overseas Development Institute puts it.296

Asking the right questions

People become activists not to analyze the world, but to change it. We can grow rather

impatient with reflection (one Oxfam head of advocacy dismissed my job as head of

research as ‗beard stroking‘). Consequently, a common weakness of change strategies is a

failure to understand the system and thus an inability to ‗dance with the system‘. Making

the effort to become ‗reflectivists‘ as well as activists, to study and become intimate with

the complex interwoven elements that characterize any system is essential, before we

296 Politically smart locally led devt

Page 150: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

150

jump in with a campaign or a project. But how much study is enough? At what point does

it tip over into ‗analysis paralysis‘, where the next step is always to commission another

study, rather than actually do anything?

No amount of upfront analysis will enable us to predict the erratic behaviour of a

complex system, just as all those clever economists and political scientists failed to

predict the 2008 financial crash or the Arab Spring. The purpose of initial study is to

enable us to place our bets intelligently. The crucial decisions come after that: how we

continue to ‗study‘ during the course of our efforts, and adjust according to our ongoing

learning.

Dancing with complex systems is like navigating through traffic – success depends on

fast feedback to detect new situations and having the ability to respond quickly (a

pedestrian has stepped out into traffic – hit the brake!). If I tried to drive across London

with a pre-planned route and velocity, and no adjustments according to feedback, I would

be lucky to get to the end of the street. We have to spot new windows of opportunity,

learn from failure, develop useful rules of thumb to guide decision-making, and take

multiple small bets until we find something that works. Analysis of the system, then, is

not a one-off upfront engagement, but a continual process of analysing and reanalysing

the context in which the programme or campaign operates.

I began discussing how change happens with my colleagues by devising typologies of the

kinds of strategy we employ for different situations. I soon discovered that no typology

seemed to fit the reality of any particular situation. More broadly, I found the effort to

produce ‗toolkits‘ or ‗best practice guides‘ is often incompatible with the kinds of

systems thinking I believe underpins effective activism. The best change agents make it

up as they go along.

But making it up as you go along requires a considerable degree of self-confidence and

chutzpah, a level of intellectual independence our educational systems do not always

prepare us for – not to mention a degree of flexibility that few organizations will tolerate.

Activists need models they can follow, both as guidance and as a fallback should things

go wrong.

Instead of typologies and checklists, I have settled on a combination of questions and

case studies (lots of them). Together these can act as an engine of imagination, expanding

the range of potential approaches. Here are some of those questions, organized into four

categories that reflect the broad stages of most change efforts.

Page 151: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

151

Context and power analysis

What problem are you trying to address? Is it specific (e.g. improving livelihoods for a

group of women farmers) or systemic (changing government policy or prevailing

norms)? Is it primarily economic, political, social or a combination? Local, national or

global?

What is your understanding of the origins of that problem? Who has the ability to solve

it? Does the barrier to change lie in laws and policies, or in social norms, attitudes and

beliefs? Or is the issue rooted in conflicting interests?

Have you considered a positive deviance study to explore where the problem has already

been solved and how?

What redistribution of power does the change involve? Is it primarily about ‗power

within‘ (e.g. empowering women to become more active social agents), ‗power with‘

(collective organization) or ‗power to‘ (e.g. supporting CSO advocacy)?

What are the key forces driving or blocking such a change? What economic or political

interests are threatened or promoted by it? Which groups are drivers or blockers or

undecided? Is their power formal (e.g. elected politicians) or informal (traditional leaders,

influential individuals)? Is it visible (rules and force) or invisible (norms and values in

peoples‘ heads) or hidden (behind-the-scenes influence)?

Which individuals play key roles, either as allies or opponents?

Change hypotheses

What are your hypotheses for how the change is likely to come about in the absence of

any action by you? Will it occur through existing institutions, or is change likely to

require greater disruption, even conflict (e.g. the Arab Spring)?

What existing alliances (e.g. between officials or politicians, private sector, media, faith

leaders or civil society) are blocking or driving the change?

Page 152: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

152

Can you foresee any likely critical junctures297

when change is more likely to occur (e.g.

new governments, changes of leadership, election timetables)?

Change strategies

This is where you enter the fray. Who are your core partners? Are they civil society

organizations or ‗unusual suspects‘ (e.g. faith organizations, private sector bodies)?

What alliances could you or your partners create or join forces with to drive the change

(e.g. with sympathetic officials or politicians, private sector, media, faith leaders or

CSOs)?

What tactics are most likely to alter the views of the individuals and institutions whose

support is needed to bring about change? (e.g. rigorous research, a successful pilot

project, street demonstrations, leadership training, multiple parallel experiments)? How

can you prepare in advance for any critical junctures, foreseeable or not (e.g. get

research 90 per cent done, set up networks that can be rapidly activated in response to a

flood or scandal)?

Can you identify implementation gaps, institutions, policies or budgets that have already

been agreed but exist purely on paper? Focussing on closing such gaps reduces the

likelihood of overt opposition and are fertile ground for quick wins, which can have a

galvanizing effect – plucking a few low-hanging fruit is great for morale, motivation and

momentum.

Feedback systems and course corrections

What feedback systems do you have in place to spot other critical junctures as they

emerge?

What feedback systems do you have in place to monitor your own work, spot failures, and

change course (e.g. a regular ‗time out‘ where everyone involved meets, discusses

progress and agrees course corrections)?

5 http://oxfamblogs.org/fp2p/why-why-nations-fail-fails-mostly-review-of-acemoglu-and-robinsons-big-

new-book/

Page 153: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

153

Figure 1: The power and change cycle

Figure 1 illustrates the flow from analysis to action. The cycle of course is no magic

formula, just an aid to thought that describes a way of working. Nor is it a linear

sequence – different stages often take place in parallel. No organization I have come

across does all of this, though different elements of the approach flourish in parts of

Oxfam‘s work: governance projects tend to have a sophisticated power analysis;

advocacy and campaigns have good feedback systems to respond to events and

opportunities, as does emergency response work. Power analysis is often used to sharpen

thinking and practice, or to understand and codify new approaches that have sprung up

spontaneously or through individual initiative. Periodic reviews of context and power

help keep programmes nimble and aware, and help prepare new staff for their jobs.

The essential point is to remain embedded in the context, observing how the system

evolves, how events occur, and then alter the power analysis (and the programme)

accordingly. The power and change cycle differs from conventional project planning

cycles in three ways: it pays much more attention to context analysis, both in advance and

ongoing; it encourages multiple strategies, rather than a single linear approach, and it

views failure, iteration and adaptation as expected and necessary, rather than a regrettable

exception.

Context and Power Analysis

Change Hypotheses

Design change strategies

Implement, monitor and make course corrections

Page 154: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

154

Implications for organizations

Few would-be change agents act solely as individuals. Most people trying to bring about

political or social change work through organizations of one sort or another. Those

organizations can allow activists to achieve ‗power with‘, but they can also hinder or

entirely frustrate the kinds of shift necessary to make change happen. They too need to

change.

This final section discusses the sector I know best: aid and development organizations

seeking to help end poverty and injustice. To realize their potential large aid

organizations (Oxfam GB, for whom I work, spends about £300m a year on its charitable

activities298,299

) will need internal structures, incentives and cultures that acknowledge the

distribution of power, that work with the grain of complex systems, and that galvanize

and amplify the best efforts of their employees.300

301In a world that is changing fast, aid organizations are understandably wracked with

uncertainty and self-doubt. Beyond the well-documented rebalancing of the world‘s

economy from West to East lie several other trends that propel the development sector

toward something of an existential crisis. Official aid is in decline relative to domestic

resource mobilization, since developing countries are getting much better at taxing

citizens and foreign investors (especially natural resource companies). Aid is also falling

relative to private investment and relative to remittances from overseas migrants, which

currently bring in nearly four times the volume of aid.

At the same time, the more brutal problems of famine and disease have been attenuated

(for the moment), and in their place poor countries face social and health issues once seen

as largely ‗Northern‘ problems; ageing, obesity, alcohol and tobacco addiction, mental

illness, the illicit drug trade and road traffic accidents all now affect considerably more

people in developing countries than, say, malaria.

298

http://www.oxfam.org.uk/~/media/Files/OGB/What%20we%20do/About%20us/Plans%20reports%20and%20policies/6651Annual_Report_201415WEB.ashx 299

WHAT’S TOTAL FIGURE FOR OI? 300

This chapter draws on my 2015 paper ‘Fit for the Future? Development trends and the role of international NGOs.’ http://policy-practice.oxfam.org.uk/publications/fit-for-the-future-development-trends-and-the-role-of-international-ngos-556585 301

CD CUT SOME OF THE NEXT FEW PAGES ON THE CHANGING WORLD CONTEXT FOR INGOS IF CHAPTER LENGTH IS AN ISSUE

Page 155: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

155

The migration of health problems is symptomatic of a deeper historical shift. The division

of the world into a rich ‗North‘ and an impoverished ‗South‘, never very convincing, has

become ever more blurred. The rise of East Asia and other ‗emerging markets‘ has

populated the once-wide gap between rich and poor countries. Increased inequality within

countries has accentuated the incidence of ‗South-in-the-North‘ pockets of

marginalization and exclusion in rich countries, as well as ‗North-in-the-South‘ islands of

extreme privilege in poor ones.

In addition, problems that do not lend themselves to exclusively national solutions, and

therefore require ‗one world‘ collective action, have become ever more pressing: climate

change and other planetary boundaries, the arms trade, international tax dodging,

corporate malpractice. The toughest issues increasingly get kicked upstairs to heads of

government and to bodies like the G7 or G20, where there is little capacity to do much

more than react: a ‗G Zero‘ inability to address global problems at the international level.

Urgent questions of conflict, trade disputes or humanitarian emergencies crowd out

essential ones, with long-term risk management giving way to fire-fighting the crisis of

the day. 302

Such changes have been accompanied by an upheaval in international development‘s cast

list. Besides the rise of new actors like Saudi Arabia and China, hitherto-ignored players

are finally being recognized: citizens of developing countries and their governments. The

latter are increasingly successful in their efforts to reduce poverty and provide the basic

services people need to work their way out of poverty. What‘s more, sub-national bodies

(such as city councils or provincial authorities) are often at the forefront of innovation on

environmental and social issues,303

driven in part by an upsurge in urban social

movements.

The increasing economic and political power of many Southern states has been matched

by an upsurge in citizens‘ voice and activism. Mass literacy, better healthcare and

urbanization have underpinned a rise in mass political engagement, which has both fed

and been fed by the spread of governments chosen through elections. Girls‘ education

and women‘s increasing role in the paid workforce have prompted and been reinforced

by a rise in women‘s participation in mainstream politics and in social and women‘s

movements.

302 Evans (2015)

303 Cole (2014)

Page 156: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

156

Citizen activism is often a result of economic growth that prompts an expansion of both

the middle class and an increasingly vocal domestic private sector. Many political

scientists304

and some economists305

see a booming middle class as a key driver of

democracy and human rights, although it should be remembered that the middle class can

also present fierce resistance to reforms that would benefit poor people at their expense.

South–South interactions that completely bypass the traditional powers (and international

NGOs‘ home countries) are increasingly important, including government-to-government

contacts, the rise of Southern transnational corporations and the growing role of

Diasporas in their countries of origin. BRAC International306

has become the first major

Southern international NGO, with a €75m turnover in 2014, providing a low-wage

alternative to conventional Northern service delivery NGOs.307

One indication of the new muscle of Southern civil society is the role of citizen activism

in political upheavals over the past fifteen years.308

Interestingly, the larger organizations

that partner with international NGOs have tended to stand aloof from such overtly

political activies, ceding the terrain to a diversity of grassroots CSOs (neighbourhood

associations or cultural groups, for example, or soccer club supporters) on the one hand,

or, on the other, to what might be called middle-class civil society: the media, university

student unions or private sector associations. At the same time, more than 50 countries

have enacted or seriously considered restrictions on the ability of local CSOs to organize

and operate.309

New technologies have acted as multipliers for the emergence of civil society.

Increasingly, poor people have identity documents and mobile telephones with which

they can access services and broadcast their opinions. New technologies are also

challenging the traditional charity structure of most aid agencies. The GiveDirectly

charity310

has built up an $18 million turnover in just three years by putting 91 cents of

every donated dollar directly onto the SIM card of a Kenyan living in poverty. Avaaz311

304 Acemoglu and Robinson (2012)

305 Levy (2014)

306 http://www.bracinternational.nl/en/

307 Green (2010)

308 Carothers and Brechenmacher (2014)

309 Ibid.

310 www.givedirectly.org/

311 www.avaaz.org/en/

Page 157: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

157

offers a similar example of disruptive innovation in online campaigning that bypasses the

aid industry.

Reflecting these shifts, the aid conversation has changed. Supporters used to be happy

with signing monthly cheques to a trusted international NGO and the odd letter to an MP.

Now they want to see where their money goes and engage on their own terms. Donors

governments wanted international NGOs to deliver agreed projects; now they don‘t care

who delivers as long as they get value for money and quantifiable results. Local NGOs

used to compete for funding available through international NGOs; now they want direct

access to donor funds and greater control. National governments encouraged donors to

provide aid and services through NGOs; now they don‘t want foreign meddlers and are

happy with no-strings-attached Chinese assistance. Private companies wanted

international NGOs to validate their efforts at corporate social responsibility; now they

want partnership with these international NGOs or the chance to win donor contracts for

themselves.

Even in the area of emergency response, long the home of white ‗angel of mercy‘ aid

stereotypes, the ground is shifting rapidly. Once defined by the delivery of goods and

services at a time of crisis, humanitarian relief now includes efforts to strengthen states‘

capacity to address emergencies. The new actors are even challenging humanitarian

agencies‘ guiding principles of neutrality, impartiality and independence, especially since

some NGOs began to back military adventures invoked in the name of the ‗responsibility

to protect‘. Recipient nations are increasingly assertive in saying what aid should be

provided, to whom and how. Access for humanitarian agencies is becoming more

restricted and ‗no go‘ countries more common.

These changes in the development landscape pose some big and very challenging

questions to aid organizations. Can the ideas about how change happens sketched out in

this book help?

How to apply systems thinking

Let‘s recall from chapter two some key implications of systems thinking for

organizations trying to effect change:

Look long and hard before you act, and then keep looking

Relinquish control

Seek fast and ongoing feedback

Be flexible

Page 158: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

158

Celebrate failure

Improve your rules of thumb

Undertake multiple parallel experiments

Convene and broker relationships

Focus on positive deviance.

The first is a natural for most large aid agencies; in fact, some of them look so long and

hard they never get round to acting. Their long hard look, however, is often less about

understanding and adapting to the peculiarities of power in the local context than

ensuring the course of action chosen falls within pre-defined parameters. The secret lies

in learning enough about the situation to start work along reasonable lines, and then keep

looking, adapting as you learn on the go, as the context evolves.

Because international NGOs must be accountable for money spent and for the impact of

that spending, the drive to micro-manage every operation is understandable. But in a

complex system a more productive approach may be ‗don‘t control unless there is good

reason to‘. Local staff and partners should have a fairly free rein to apply their deeper

understanding to the programme. An aid organization should be capable of continually

picking up signals of change in the local context, including its own impact, and be

flexible enough to adapt or even shelve the previous plan if events so require. 312

In

addition, organizations should welcome candid discussions among staff, so as to learn

from failure, rather than sweep it under the carpet.

Advances in information and communications technology should facilitate such

capacities, but aid groups have been slow to change business models. Where is the

equivalent of TripAdvisor for the development sector?

Since the path to success is unknowable in advance, funding agencies could mimic

venture capitalists and back ten projects knowing that nine will fail, while the remaining

one goes stellar. But in development work there is rarely a clear bottom line. The

success/failure dichotomy may not be an appropriate way for international NGOs to

judge their performance. Almost every programme or change process produces both

successes and failures. Isn‘t it more important to identify elements within a programme

that are not working and fix them en route? There is a temporal issue here too. As

development veterans who return to countries after long absences will attest, local staff in

312 http://oxfamblogs.org/fp2p/do-aid-and-development-need-their-own-tripadvisor-feedback-system/

Page 159: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

159

programmes once deemed ‗failures‘ often turn up years later at the heart of success

stories. Failure, it turns out, is also a complex process.

The freewheeling approach to project management this implies may sound unwieldy.

‗Rules of thumb‘ – identifying key questions to ask to keep a project on track – can help

make it work. Many experienced activists do this in practice, asking such questions as

‗Who is in the room? Have we thought about gender, or livelihoods? Do we know what

success looks like? Such rules of thumb too must be continually challenged, tested and

improved upon.

Given that change is non-linear and inherently unpredictable, and solutions to problems

must be discovered afresh in each new situation rather than ‗rolled out,‘ it would seem

the interventions international NGOs undertake, are unreplicable (they fail to ‗go to

scale‘ in NGO parlance). As seen in the examples discussed in chapter two, convening

the relevant stakeholders and brokering a relationship among them in an open-ended

process of experimentation, failure and adaptation is one way, not only to find solutions,

but to lever a bigger change.313

A richer ecosystem of stakeholders expands both the

universe of ideas for finding solutions, and the number of channels through which

successful solutions can take hold and spread. Such leverage emerges out of developing a

web of mutually beneficial relationships and alliances, which may be local, regional or

global. Besides convening and brokering, agencies can use campaigns and advocacy,

private sector collaborations and research to help leverage changes at scale.

The keys to project success often lie outside the project itself, elsewhere in the system.

Agencies can often discover those keys by identifying and studying ‗outliers‘ – results

that are particularly good or bad.314

This ‗positive deviance‘ approach is also a good way

to promote innovation.

How to promote innovation

In complex, fast-changing systems, today‘s ‗best practice toolkit‘ is likely to become

tomorrow‘s redundant fax machine. Innovation, therefore, becomes essential to success,

presenting something of a conundrum for large aid organizations with their numerous

procedures, reporting requirements and accountability chains. Besides positive deviance,

here are some other ideas for how they might achieve and maintain innovation:

313 http://oxfamblogs.org/fp2p/is-the-best-way-to-be-innovative-not-to-try/

314 Green (2013b)

Page 160: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

160

Collaboration (especially with unusual suspects): Joint ventures and incubators allow

organizations to engage other capabilities and start-ups.

If you see a good idea, steal it: Major tech companies buy-in innovation through

mergers and acquisitions of emergent start-ups. Something similar, but less systematic,

happens in development, as the ideas of small campaigns and NGOs are picked up by

larger NGOs and even governments. Could this be made more explicit?

‘Skunkworks’: Google allows its employees 20 per cent time for personal projects.

International NGOs could take a page from Google‘s book and create spaces free from

standard organizational procedures to incentivize ‗intrapreneurs‘.

People not projects: As suggested in chapter nine, there may be a case for investing

more in spotting, nurturing and promoting individuals, rather than funding only projects

(which individuals are then obliged to devise). Besides identifying potential leaders early

on, international NGOs could promote an enabling environment in which more and better

leaders are likely to emerge. Options to be tested could include university partnerships,

scholarships, competitions, leadership training and mentoring.

Spinning off successful innovations as start-ups: The hugely successful independent

magazine New Internationalist began life as an Oxfam/Christian Aid project. Spin-offs

can innovate and experiment, free from the constraints of being part of a large

bureaucracy. The McDonalds burger chain may not be an obvious place to look for

inspiration, but one option that is already showing signs of success is ‗social franchising‘,

where an NGO develops a basic ‗project in a box‘ that individuals and local groups can

pick up and adapt315

. Spin-offs could be one way for international NGOs to maintain the

momentum of an exciting project innovation, though it carries organizational costs in

terms of ‗losing‘ success stories.

Ecosystem management: Mike Edwards likens civil society to a diverse ecosystem.316

Yet international NGO support for civil society more often resembles monoculture –

finding and funding partners that ‗look like us‘ in terms of their institutional structure and

way of seeing the world. Edwards argues that international NGOs ought to see

themselves as ‗ecosystem gardeners‘, looking for vigorous local plants, whatever their

origins (civil society, faith-based, private sector, none of the above) and focus on the

315 http://oxfamblogs.org/fp2p/what-can-aid-agencies-learn-from-mcdonalds/

316 Edwards (2014)

Page 161: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

161

‗enabling environment‘ – the fertility of the political and institutional soil in which those

organizations grow. Large aid agencies, for example, could fund ecosystem

intermediaries, which in turn could administer hundreds of small grants. They could

provide equity for spin-off organizations or seed money for groups to raise resources

locally (an echo of governments‘ shift to ‗domestic resource mobilization‘).

Examples of most of these approaches can already be found in the work of many

international NGOs, but they don‘t always spread. One of my biggest frustrations at

Oxfam has been how seldom great new approaches and ideas (including many described

in this book) have been picked up, replicated and adapted elsewhere. Harking back to the

3i‘s explanation of inertia, I suspect the problem lies not in interests or ideas, but in the

institutional culture: aid agencies need to devise incentives for identifying and

encouraging innovation.

What to influence and where

Advocacy will likely remain a key role of international NGOs, but the policies they seek

to change may shift. Since the interaction between states and diverse domestic players

will play an ever more central role in national and local development, big agencies should

leave most issues to them. Here are some thoughts on where advocacy by international

NGOs could bring particular added value.

Global governance: International organizations could choose to focus on the growing

number of collective action problems that have so far stymied the chaotic institutions of

global governance. As noted above, examples include climate change, the narcotics trade

and restrictive intellectual property rules.

Global citizenship and norm shifts: International organizations have a fitful

engagement with debates on social norms and citizen rights. Although measuring

effectiveness is a challenge, striving to accelerate normative shifts that enhance the rights

of groups currently facing discrimination is an important activity that lends itself to an

international approach.

Rich-country policies: The Washington-based Center for Global Development has made

a virtue lobbying for policy improvements in rich countries as a way to promote

development. In areas such as climate change, aid policy or tax havens, there is certainly

scope for international NGOs to expand their engagement, as well as for taking on new

and pressing topics such as migration policy.

Page 162: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

162

Local-to-global linking: International NGOs are well positioned to undertrake

convening and brokering that span national borders, for example, via multi-stakeholder

initiatives in global supply chains, such as the Ethical Trading Initiative.317

On the new

generation of health challenges in developing countries, such as obesity, tobacco and road

traffic accidents, international NGOs could play a useful initial role by facilitating contact

and exchanges between Southern and Northern campaigners who have a track record of

success.

Mobilize international support for national struggles: International funding and

political pressure can make an enormous difference in Southern campaigns for change.

International NGOs could train and deploy what John Gaventa and Rajesh Tandon call

‗hybrid mediators‘, people who manage to simultaneously stay rooted in community

struggles and navigate the international system, moving between them and speaking both

their languages with equal facility.318

A Northern presence could also enhance South–

South exchanges between activists.319

Alert networks: Thanks to their on-the-ground presence in developing countries through

partners or direct programming, international NGOs could specialize in spotting new

trends and successful innovations, or raising the alarm when necessary (e.g. where

governments are cracking down on civil society organizations). A couple of ideas for

improving NGOs ‗early warning systems‘ might be a monthly ring-round of 1,000 key

informants or a big data-scraping exercise to spot words appearing more frequently on

Twitter or in email subject headings.

The question of scale

Can you take a supertanker white-water rafting? 320

The agility of ‗guerrilla‘

organizations like Global Witness, and the single-issue focus of institutions like the

Ethical Trading Initiative make them prime candidates for adopting the new ways of

thinking and working discussed in this chapter. But major international NGOs have

advantages too: their large knowledge bases and economies of scale.

317 http://www.ethicaltrade.org/

318 Gaventa and Tandon (2010)

319 Oxfam Raising Her Voice programme, http://policy-practice.oxfam.org.uk/our-work/citizen-

states/raising-her-voice 320

Slim (2013), Green (2014) /

Page 163: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

163

Scale allows organizations to experiment and exchange ideas between countries and

programmes. And when it comes to influence, small is seldom beautiful: governments are

more likely to listen to bigger players, particularly when they have ‗skin in the game‘ in

the form of programmes and staff on the ground. What kind of hybrid combination of

scale and subsidiarity provides the optimal blend of flexibility and clout?

One option might be a ‗conscious uncoupling‘ in which a large international organization

transitions from a supertanker to a flotilla, with a medium-sized mother ship and a fleet of

small, independent spin-offs and start-ups. As noted above, the smaller, more nimble

crafts could include individuals in addition to projects. A flotilla structure could

potentially conserve the advantages of scale while fostering the agility and innovation

that is essential to success.

Page 164: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

164

Conclusion321

As long ago as the sixth century BCE, the Greek philosopher Heraclitus noted, ‗There is

nothing permanent except change.‘ Change, however, is not primarily about ‗us‘. The

first lesson for activists is humility. Technology, prices, demography and sheer accident

can play far more important roles in driving change than the actions of would-be change

agents.

That said, activists can make an important difference. We put new questions into the

endlessly churning stream of public debate, and we can help those on the sharp end raise

their voices, shifting some degree of power from those who have too much to those who

have too little.

Such work is a joy, a privilege, and a responsibility. We will have more impact if we

think hard, try new, uncomfortable things, question our own power and privilege, and are

prepared to acknowledge and learn from our failures, all the while continuing to work

with the zeal and commitment that characterize activists everywhere.

Researching and writing this book have convinced me that my organization, Oxfam,

along with so many others involved in promoting progressive change around the world,

needs to change. We have to become smarter, quicker to react and more effective. If we

don‘t, then just like any other sclerotic company that resists change, new, bolder start-ups

will enter the fray and eat our lunch (which may be no bad thing, of course).

Researching and writing this book has also changed me in ways I probably won‘t fully

understand for some time. I have always felt a tension between the desire to be a

‗finisher‘ – dotting the i‘s and crossing the t‘s – and the urge to move on to new ideas, to

grab the next shiny shell on the beach. At university, I studied physics but moonlighted

for lectures on Joyce and Eliot, and wrote truly execrable poetry. My personality

assessments in things like the Myers Briggs test are a mess. Most of the time, I don‘t

know what I think or, like the Queen in Alice in Wonderland, I seem to hold entirely

contradictory opinions at the same time.

321 PROVISIONAL - MAY WELL EXPAND THIS IN LIGHT OF CONSULTATION

Page 165: How Change Happens Consultation Draft 281015 En

HOW CHANGE HAPPENS Duncan Green – consultation draft October 2015 – not for publication

165

Somehow, the act of writing made me acknowledge that ambiguity and grow comfortable

with it. You would think that writing a book, with its words fixed forever and its

pretensions to authority, would be anathema to ambiguity, complexity and change.

Luckily books these days are no longer tablets of stone, rather the more time-consuming

part of a wider conversation. In this case, the conversation will continue after publication

on my From Poverty to Power blog and on the How Change Happens website. I look

forward to hearing your thoughts and arguments on all of the issues raised in this book –

and to changing my mind, preferably several times before breakfast.