FILM FINANCE 2

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/13/2019 FILM FINANCE 2

    1/31

    At the Movies: The Economics of Exhibition Contracts

    Darren Filson, David Switzer, and Portia Besocke

    June 17, 2004

    Contact info: Darren Filson (Corresponding Author), Associate Professor of Economics, Departmentof Economics, Claremont Graduate University, 160 E. Tenth St., Claremont, CA 91711; ph: (909) 621-8782;fax: (909) 621-8460; email: [email protected]. David Switzer is a Ph.D. Candidate at WashingtonUniversity in St. Louis. Portia Besocke is a Ph.D. Candidate at Claremont Graduate University. We thankFernando Fabre, Alfredo Nava, and Paola Rodriguez for background research that contributed to this paper.We thank Darlene Chisholm and Doug Whitford for comments. Filson thanks the Fletcher Jones Foundation,the John M. Olin Foundation, and the National Association of Scholars for financial support.

  • 8/13/2019 FILM FINANCE 2

    2/31

    At the Movies: The Economics of Exhibition Contracts

    Abstract: We describe a real-world profit sharing contract - the movie exhibition contract -

    and consider alternative explanations for its use. Two explanations based on difficulties with

    forecasting fit the facts better than asymmetric information models. The first emphasizes

    two-sided risk aversion; the second emphasizes measurement costs. Transaction costs and

    long-term relationships also affect contractual practices. We use an original data set of all

    exhibition contracts involving thirteen theaters owned by a prominent St. Louis exhibitor

    over a two-year period to inform our theories and test hypotheses.

    JEL Codes: L14: Transactional Relationships and Contracts; D45: Licensing;L82: Indus-

    try Studies: Entertainment

    Keywords: risk sharing, relational contract, principal agent, motion picture, film

    1. Introduction

    The literature on profit sharing stresses asymmetric information. Profit sharing occurs when

    a party has private information that cannot be credibly revealed or when a partys actions

    cannot be observed. Economists avoid taste-based explanations such as risk sharing (Stigler

    and Becker 1977) and other factors that may lead to sharing, such as measurement costs.

    We describe a real-world sharing contract that is widely used - the movie exhibition

    contract - and argue that asymmetric information is not the main cause of sharing. Two

    explanations based on difficulties with forecasting revenue fit the facts better. The first is

    that movie distributors (studios or independent distributors) and exhibitors (theater owners)

    are both risk averse and exhibition contracts are designed to share risk. The second is that

    the sharing rules accompanied by ex post adjustments economize on measurement costs.

    Transaction costs and long-term relationships also affect contractual practices. We use an

    original data set of 2,769 exhibition contracts to inform our models and test hypotheses.

    The data includes all contracts involving thirteen theaters owned by Wehrenberg Theatres,

    a prominent St. Louis exhibitor, over roughly two years. Our models explain the sharing

    2

  • 8/13/2019 FILM FINANCE 2

    3/31

    that occurs and the conditions that lead to adjustments, and our findings may be relevant

    for other contracting environments.

    Our explanations for the features of exhibition contracts complement those of De Vany

    and Eckert (1991) and De Vany and Walls (1996), who emphasize that difficulties with

    forecasting demand necessitate the use of short-term contingency-rich contracts. Some other

    work on non-exhibition aspects of the movie business also compares asymmetric information

    models to alternatives. Ravid (1999) tests and rejects a model of asymmetric information at

    the project selection stage. Ravid and Basuroy (2004) consider risk aversion at the project

    selection stage. Chisholm (1993, 1997) and Weinstein (1998) compare principal agent models

    to alternatives in studies of contracts between studios and talent.

    In the next subsection we describe the basic features of modern exhibition contracts.1 In

    the subsection after that we describe how the sharing rules evolved over time and argue that

    asymmetric information does not explain the sharing rules. Section 2 contains our models,

    Section 3 contains our empirical work, and Section 4 concludes.

    1.1. The Modern Movie Exhibition Contract

    The unit of analysis for the contracts we describe is a single movie in a single theater (a

    theater is a building which may contain multiple auditoriums). While there is typically a

    boilerplate contract between each distributor and exhibitor that specifies general conditions

    that apply to all individual contracts, terms such as sharing rules and run lengths vary by

    movie and theater. A typical run ends after four to eight weeks, but the run may be adjusted

    after early revenues are observed, and holdover clauses may be used to extend the run as

    long as revenue is sufficiently high. De Vany and Eckert (1991) and De Vany and Walls

    (1996) attribute adjustable runs to imprecise forecasts.

    1 Modern exhibition contracts have been described by De Vany and Eckert (1991), De Vany and Walls(1996), and Borcherding and Filson (2001). We also benefited from several conversations with industryparticipants, particularly D. Barry Reardon, past-president of Warner Bros. Distributing Corporation anda former executive of both Paramount Pictures and General Cinema Corporation; Doug Whitford, theexecutive at Wehrenberg Theatres in charge of negotiating film rental contracts; and Mike Doban of Trans-Lux Cinema Consulting. We also benefited from several articles in The Movie Business Book, edited byJason E. Squire. The authors of the articles were, at the time of writing, prominent industry participants,and include among others D. Barry Reardon; Stanley H. Durwood, chairman and chief executive officer ofAMC Entertainment Inc.; A. Alan Friedberg, chairman of Loews Theatres, a subsidiary of Sony PicturesEntertainment; and A. D. Murphy, financial editor and reporter for Daily Variety andVariety.

    3

  • 8/13/2019 FILM FINANCE 2

    4/31

    We focus on explaining the peculiar revenue sharing rule that is common in modern

    contracts. While some contracts are aggregate deals, in which each sides percentage

    share remains fixed throughout the run, most are sliding scale deals. In a sliding scale

    deal, each week, the distributor gets the maximum of two possible payments: 1) 90% of the

    movies weekly ticket revenue over the house nut, which is a flat payment to the exhibitor;

    2) a floor payment, some percentage of the weekly ticket revenue that typically declines

    according to a sliding scale as the weeks go by - perhaps 70% in the first week, 60% by

    the third week, and as low as 30% at the end of the run. If the parties anticipate that

    revenue might peak in the second or later weeks (which can occur when the movie opens

    before a holiday weekend, for example) the contract includes a best weeks clause that

    ensures that the high floor payments are associated with the high demand weeks. Most of

    the time the floor is relevant; the 90/10 provision applies only for hits early in their runs. The

    exhibitors payofffunction for one week associated with such a contract is graphed in Figure 1.

    Interestingly, concession revenue is not shared - the exhibitor gets it all. This is not a trivial

    oversight as concessions typically account for approximately half of an exhibitors profit.

    Most deals are firm term, which indicates that both parties expect to be compensated

    according to floors or aggregate shares that are specified at the beginning of the run. In

    contrast, flexible deals have boilerplate terms that are rarely enforced, and the exhibitor

    determines the appropriate shares as revenue is observed. In either case, terms may be

    adjusted during the run or after it ends; for flexible deals this is common and for firm

    deals it is rare. We ignore the firm-flexible distinction in most of our analysis and focus on

    explaining floors with sliding scales, best weeks clauses, the 90/10 provision, and the nature

    of adjustments.

    Other factors affect our modeling assumptions. Most contracts result from negotiations

    (Friedberg 1992; Reardon 1992). The courts favored competitive bidding at the time of

    theParamountdecrees of the 1940s and 50s, but even when bids are used they are points

    of departure for negotiations. Given this, our models emphasize bargaining rather than

    auctions. Friedberg (1992) notes that distributors cannot simply choose the highest bid

    because multiple factors matter, including local demographics, the location, and the decor.

    Exhibitor bids typically include 1) a schedule of ticket prices; 2) the number of shows for

    4

  • 8/13/2019 FILM FINANCE 2

    5/31

    weekdays and weekends; and 3) the screen number and the number of seats in the auditorium

    in which the picture will play. Practitioners tell us these are guidelines only; 2) and 3) are

    difficult for distributors to monitor and none of the three terms are enforced. However, ticket

    prices are typically constant across movies and time at the theater level (except for daily

    matinee prices).2 Given this, ticket prices are exogenous in most of our analysis. Our models

    consider a theater with only one auditorium. Given this, we do not endogenize the allocation

    of movies to time slots and auditoriums.3 However, in our empirical analysis we consider the

    impacts of such allocation decisions.

    1.2. The Evolution of Revenue Sharing

    Our conversations with practitioners (see fn.1) and historical analyses such as Hanssen (2000,2002) allow us to describe how sharing rules evolved and explain why sliding scale rules are

    used today. Originally movies were short, silent, low-cost, relatively non-differentiated prod-

    ucts that were sold to exhibitors outright. As feature films were introduced, production

    budgets rose and consumers became more selective. Avoiding downside risk became impor-

    tant. Murphy (1992) notes that percentage rentals were introduced to justify the investment

    risk. With the arrival of sound in the late 1920s, production budgets rose more and the vari-

    ance of movie revenue (and profi

    t) increased (Sedgwick and Pokorny 1998; Hanssen 2002).Revenue sharing became increasingly common.4 The distributors share of ticket revenue

    rose as budgets rose, from roughly 20% early on, to 25% in the 1920s, 33% in the 1960s, and

    45% in the 1990s. Shares varied by movie and theater.

    2 Practitioners provide several explanations for inflexible ticket prices. Exhibitors want to avoid menu costsand eliminate consumer uncertainty about what the movie will cost. Exhibitors do not increase prices of hitsbecause they are engaged in repeat business with local consumers, and the potential loss of goodwill fromincreased prices outweighs the potential gain. Charging different prices for different movies at multiplexesnecessitates employing monitors to ensure that consumers see the movies they pay for. Even offering mid-

    week discounts may lead to more time shifting than new demand. Not all analysts or practitioners agreethat inflexible prices are optimal (see Orbach and Einav 2001), although it seems unlikely that such an easy-to-exploit profit opportunity would persist. Some practioners have experimented with non-uniform prices inthe U.S. in the recent past but inflexible prices remain the norm.

    3 Filson (2004) provides a dynamic model that includes allocation decisions within a multiplex.4 Hanssen (2002) describes how exhibitor inputs were less important for big-budget movies, particularly

    after sound. As a result there was less need to make the exhibitor the residual claimant. However, this leavesopen the question of why the distributor was not made the full residual claimant. Hanssen (2002) arguesthat exhibitors needed incentives to provide local inputs. We evaluate this argument below - it may havebeen relevant in the 1920s but does not appear to explain revenue sharing today.

    5

  • 8/13/2019 FILM FINANCE 2

    6/31

  • 8/13/2019 FILM FINANCE 2

    7/31

    rules are similar whether blind bidding is used or not.6 When comparing contracts in states

    with blind bidding to those in states without Blumenthal (1988) focuses on the guarantee

    because it is the most variable element of the bid vector.

    Is incentive provision important? Bhattacharyya and Lafontaine (1995) show that simple

    sharing rules can be optimal when double-sided moral hazard exists, and their model could

    be applied to movie exhibition. Distributors must advertise and promote the movie, while

    exhibitors must hire employees and do some local advertising. Neither partys activities

    are easy to monitor. Kenney and Klein (1983) and Hanssen (2002) point out that sharing

    contracts provide incentives for exhibitors to keep theaters clean and take other actions

    which are hard to monitor but that may increase ticket revenue. Are these effects the reason

    for revenue sharing? We argue that long-run relationships between exhibitors, customers,

    and distributors reduce the need for incentive contracts - reputational concerns provide

    incentives. For example, an unclean theater loses repeat business with local consumers.

    Even if distributors paid flat payments to the exhibitor, a new contract would be negotiated

    each time a new movie was released. Thus, payments to the exhibitor could quickly fall if

    the theater lost customers. Therefore, the exhibitor would have the incentive to keep the

    theater clean in the absence of a sharing rule. Given this, the distributor could simply rent

    the auditorium at a flat rental rate using a four walls contract. Such contracts have been

    used, but only rarely - sharing is the norm. In our conversations with practitioners, we found

    absolutely no support for the notion that revenue sharing encourages theater cleanliness or

    any other standard good business practices.7

    Our models of risk sharing and measurement costs are consistent with what firms claim

    6 Exhibitor objections contributed to regulations prohibiting blind bidding, but De Vany and Eckert (1991fn. 77) explain that the main objections were to bidding itself (exhibitors preferred negotiations) and theaccompanying guarantees, which were nonrefundable upfront payments from the exhibitor to the distributor.Like many contract terms, guarantees were originally introduced to protect one party against downside risk.In this case, the risk was that the exhibitor would go bankrupt, taking the revenues and the print (the copyof the movie). Guarantees are almost never used today and even refundable advances (which ensure that theexhibitor does not lose money on a movie that does not earn its advance) are rare. Information technologyfacilitates paying the distributor early in the run from revenues, so advances are unnecessary.

    7 Of course, building a reputation may not be costless, and it may take time before a new exhibitordevelops a reputation for cleanliness and other good business practices. Our point is that the exhibitor hasthe incentive to bear these costs regardless of whether the exhibition contract uses a sharing rule or a flatpayment; the exhibitors main concern is to build and maintain customer goodwill.

    7

  • 8/13/2019 FILM FINANCE 2

    8/31

    they are doing and explanations based on asymmetric information appear inadequate. How-

    ever, our explanations raise a question. Given that movie-specific risk is primarily idiosyn-

    cratic, and given that standard finance theory suggests that firms should ignore idiosyncratic

    risk, why do distributors and exhibitors care about movie-specific risk? We note that in con-

    trast to standard finance theory, most firms care about idiosyncratic risk. For example,

    risk-neutral firms would not buy insurance because insurance premiums are not actuarially

    neutral, and yet corporations spend more money on insurance premiums than they pay out

    in dividends (Mayers and Smith 1982; Martin 1988). It is beyond the scope of this paper

    to explain why firms alleviate idiosyncratic risk, but most analyses emphasize stakeholder

    risk aversion (see Smith and Stulz 1985, De Alessi 1987, DeMarzo and Duffie 1995, and

    Tufano 1996). For example, insurance shifts the risk of bankruptcy away from employees

    who cannot diversify toward shareholders who can, and by doing so it encourages employees

    to make firm-specific investments. Alleviating idiosyncratic risk also encourages some share-

    holders to become large undiversified shareholders, who then perform monitoring that aids

    all investors. In the movie industry, revenue sharing contracts play this role.8

    2. Models

    2.1. The Risk Sharing Model

    Here we present a simple risk sharing model that explains the basic features of the sharing

    rule. The sharing rule evolved when single-auditorium theaters were the norm, and our

    model has one distributor with one movie and one exhibitor with one auditorium. We ignore

    costs and focus on revenues; this is reasonable because when the movie is placed in the

    theater most of the distributors costs are sunk and most of the exhibitors costs are fixed.

    For now, suppose the distributor designs a contract for a single week, and assume that both

    players take the ticket price pas given (this is reasonable; see Subsection 1.1). Given p and

    8 Note that movie-specific risk may be very hard to insure using third-party insurance. Distributorsand exhibitors have industry know-how that third parties lack, and as a result they may be best-suited tobear movie-specific risk. Dekom (1992) summarizes the industry attitude: In the case of major studios,avoiding risks (by taking serious downside protection) is simply not a business plan.... If the managementhas insufficient confidence in its own abilities to choose and distribute motion pictures, perhaps they shouldfind solace in another industry.

    8

  • 8/13/2019 FILM FINANCE 2

    9/31

    the theaters weekly capacity N ,attendance during the week, nt, is determined according to

    a probability density function Pr(nt|p, N, t). The game proceeds as follows: The distributor

    proposes a contract wt(pnt). If the exhibitor accepts the contract then it shows the movie

    and gets paid accordingly. If it does not accept the contract it receives its reservation utility

    Ue . In reality U

    e would be determined by competiting distributors movies (opportunity

    costs), but for simplicity assume that Ue is exogenous. For now, ignore concession revenue;

    we discuss it below in Subsection 2.3.

    The distributor chooseswt(pnt)to maximize its expected utility subject to the exhibitors

    participation constraint:

    max{wt(pnt)}Nnt=0

    E(Ud) =N

    Xnt=0

    Ud(pnt wt(pnt))Pr(nt|p, N, t) (2.1)

    s.t. E(Ue) =NX

    nt=0

    Ue(wt(pnt)) Pr(nt|p, N, t) U

    e (2.2)

    where Ud(.) andUe(.) are the distributors and exhibitors utility functions and E(.) is the

    expectation operator. The first-order condition implies that at each value ofnt,

    U0

    d(pnt wt(pnt)) = tU0

    e(wt(pnt)), (2.3)

    where t is the Lagrange multiplier.9 Differentiating both sides with respect to nt yields the

    slope of the revenue-sharing rule:

    w0t(pnt) = U

    00

    d (pnt wt(pnt))

    U00

    d (pnt wt(pnt)) + tU00

    e(wt(pnt)) (2.4)

    Risk aversion implies that the second derivatives of both utility functions are negative,

    9

    Expression (2.3) is similar to the first-order condition in several classic papers on risk sharing. Borch(1962) was the first to characterize the first-order condition for optimal risk sharing. Stiglitz (1974) andLeland (1978) consider constant relative risk aversion, which we discuss presently. A first-order conditionsimilar to (2.3) can be derived from a Nash bargaining model where both players have exogenous outsideoptions. Nash bargaining solves: max{wt(pnt)}Nnt=0

    [E(Ud)U

    d ][E(Ue)U

    e ]1, where Ud is the distributors

    reservation utility and measures relative bargaining power. At the solution the marginal utilities areproportional to each other as in (2.3). Thus, the shape of the optimal contract does not depend critically onrelative bargaining power. When= 1, the distributor has all of the bargaining power and the problem isidentical to solving (2.1) subject to (2.2).

    9

  • 8/13/2019 FILM FINANCE 2

    10/31

    which implies that the slope of the sharing rule is positive. However, the change in the slope

    of the sharing rule as nt changes depends on the third derivatives of the utility functions.

    Thus, we require additional assumptions to replicate the pattern in Figure 1. Suppose both

    parties have constant relative risk aversion (CRRA): Ud

    (x) =xd and Ue(x) =xe, where xis

    money and dand eare the coefficients that measure relative risk aversion. These functions

    have several plausible properties: the marginal utility is positive and diminishing as long as

    i < 1; relative risk aversion, xU00(x)

    U0(x) , is constant; and absolute risk aversion, U

    00(x)U0(x)

    , is

    decreasing in the money payoffas long as i < 1. We follow the standard principal-agent

    model (Mas-Colell et al. 1995) and assume that the contract proposer (the distributor) is

    less risk averse than the other party (the exhibitor). However, we assume that both parties

    are risk averse.10

    Assumption 1: Both parties have CRRA utility and 0 < e < d

  • 8/13/2019 FILM FINANCE 2

    11/31

    wt(pnt) rises. Thus, the optimal sharing rule has a diminishing slope as in Figure 1.11

    We cannot solve for wt(pnt) analytically, but we can compute it numerically using realistic

    parameters for urban theaters (provided by the sources in fn. 1). Assume the capacity

    per showing is 250 and there are four showings per day: N= 7000. The ticket price p= 7.

    Given Nand p, the maximum weekly ticket revenue is $49,000. Friedberg (1992) and Murphy

    (1992) suggest this is a reasonable upper bound. We choose the remaining parameters, d,

    e, and t, in a rough attempt to minimize the distance between the payments the model

    generates and the real-world payments graphed in Figure 1. We set d = .75, e = .5, and

    t= 21.The optimal contract is graphed in Figure 2.

    Result 1: The optimal sharing rule has a diminishing slope, as in the real-world contract.

    If we consider multiple weeks, the model explains floors with sliding scales and best-weeks

    clauses. Suppose that at the beginning of the movies run, the distributor solves (2.1) for

    each week based on a forecast ofPr(nt|p, N, t). The solution is an optimal wt(pnt) for each

    week. Typically, pnt is expected to fall over time.12 Given this, the exhibitors share ofpnt

    must rise in order for the exhibitor to obtain utility Ue each week. Formally, this results

    from an increase in t,since the risk aversion parameters, prices, and other variables do not

    change over the life of the movie.13 When t rises the entire sharing rule becomes steeper,

    whereas in reality only the floors do and the 90/10 split remains a possibility. However,

    the floor is virtually always the relevant payment in later weeks so it is reasonable that the

    real-world parties reduce transaction costs by not revising the 90/10 provision.

    Result 2: If attendance is expected to fall over time, the exhibitors share of revenue must

    rise over time in order for the exhibitor to obtain utility Ue each week (which is required in

    order for the exhibitor to continue to show the movie). Thus, the optimal sharing rule has

    a floor with a sliding scale, as in the real-world contract.

    Result 3: If attendance is expected to peak in the second or later weeks, the exhibitors

    share of revenue initially falls and then rises in order for the exhibitor to obtain utility Ue

    11 Note that ifd= e, the exhibitor receives a constant share of ticket revenue.12 De Vany and Eckert (1991), De Vany and Walls (1996, 1999), Sawhney and Eliashberg (1996), and

    Eliashberg et al. (2000) examine time series of ticket revenue. Typically, revenue per screen falls over time.13 The multiplier t measures the distributors expected marginal utility from a change in U

    e . Duringlow-revenue weeks the distributor gets less revenue at each level ofnt (because the exhibitor must continueto receive Ue ). Given that Ud(.) is strictly concave, this implies that t is higher during such weeks.

    11

  • 8/13/2019 FILM FINANCE 2

    12/31

    each week. Thus, the optimal sharing rule explains the best weeks clause that occasionally

    appears in real-world contracts.

    Note that even with perfect forecasting, the exhibitors payment would adjust over time

    in order for it to obtain Ue

    . Thus, conditional on sharing, adjustments to the floor may

    be explained by exhibitor opportunity costs that are roughly constant. However, with per-

    fect forecasting there would be no need for revenue sharing; flat payments would suffice.

    Even with unpredictability, if one party is not risk averse, a flat payment could be used to

    compensate the risk averse party, as long as the appropriate payment could be calculated.

    In sum, our model explains concave sharing rules, floor payments with sliding scales,

    and best weeks clauses. However, the real-world contract is simpler than the model so far

    suggests because it typically specifies a single floor percentage for each week rather than a

    mapping from revenues to the floor percentage.14 Thus, transaction costs and the possibility

    of ex post adjustments matter. As in many other contractual environments, parties use

    simple fractions (see Young and Burke 2001). Most contracts include the 90/10 provision,

    andfloors adjust by five or ten percentage points, not the one or two that marginal analysis

    would suggest.15 Suppose that both parties agree on an interval that is likely to contain the

    weekly revenues and choose the floor using (2.5) adjusted to the nearest whole 5%. Both

    parties agree that if, once they observe revenue, they learn that their forecast was grossly in

    error, they will re-evaluate the shares using (2.5). This contract economizes on transaction

    costs if negotiating appropriate payments for unlikely contingencies ex ante is costly relative

    to the expected cost associated with ex post adjustments (which takes into account both

    how unlikely the contingency is and the ex post transaction costs). In this case, the model

    yields two predictions:

    Result 4: Ex post adjustments occur only when the movie performs much better or much

    worse than expected.

    Result 5: Adjustments favor the distributor when the movie performs better than expected

    14 Occasionally more complex contingent shares are used and they have the features our model suggests:the exhibitors share is higher when revenue is lower. Also, flexible deals allow the percentage shares todepend on revenues.

    15 Difficulties with forecasting partly account for coarse percentages. However, even flexible deals involvecoarse percentages. Thus, minimizing transaction costs associated with quibbling also plays a role.

    12

  • 8/13/2019 FILM FINANCE 2

    13/31

    and favor the exhibitor when the movie performs worse than expected.

    This approach also explains the 90/10 provision. Ex post transaction costs would be

    higher when there is more profit to fight over - when profit is low not much can be gained

    by quibbling. In order to avoid high ex post transaction costs in the event of a surprise

    blockbuster hit, industry participants have adopted the standard practice (and therefore the

    low-transaction-cost practice) of including the 90/10 provision in most contracts.

    Can a principal-agent model generate our results? Yes, but the required assumptions

    are not realistic. We argued in Subsection 1.2 that exhibitors do not require contractual

    incentives to incur effort. However, even if we assume incentives are required, in a principal

    agent model the slope of the optimal sharing rule is steeper when it is more important for

    the exhibitor to incur effort. Thus, Result 1 requires that exhibitor effort is more important

    at low revenue levels. Results 2 and 3 require that exhibitor effort is more important in low

    revenue weeks than in high revenue weeks, whereas the opposite is true in reality. Further,

    typical piecewise linear sharing rules in principal agent models include flat payments from

    one party to the other - shares provide incentives and the flat payment adjusts to ensure that

    the agent receives its reservation utility. Other than the house nut in the 90/10 provision,

    flat payments are not a feature of modern exhibition contracts.

    2.2. The Measurement Costs Model

    Here we show that a simple cooperative model that emphasizes ex ante and ex post measure-

    ment difficulties can also generate Results 1-5. Again we consider one distributor with one

    movie and one exhibitor with one auditorium, and we begin by considering a single week. To

    ease the notational burden we suppress the time subscripts. Suppose both parties agree the

    movie is expected to earn = d+e,wheredis the distributors contribution and eis the

    exhibitors contribution; d

    is due to the movie per se, whereas e

    is due to theater-specific

    attributes, such as location, size, decor, and so on. Suppose there are two shocks that affect

    revenue. The first is a movie-specific shock d that does not depend on any theater-specific

    attributes; it reflects difficulties with forecasting how the movie will be received by audiences

    in general. The second shock accounts for all other sources of randomness that affect movie

    attendance. The movies weekly revenue pnis given by

    13

  • 8/13/2019 FILM FINANCE 2

    14/31

  • 8/13/2019 FILM FINANCE 2

    15/31

    2.3. Concession Revenue, Pricing, and Long-term Relationships

    Why is concession revenue not shared? In the aggregate, concession revenue is close to

    being a deterministic function of attendance. Given this, a sharing rule based on attendance

    (or ticket revenue, given that p is fixed) approximates one that includes concession revenue.

    Further, concession revenue is difficult for distributors to monitor, particularly in a multiplex

    where it is difficult to attribute concession revenue to the various movies showing at once.

    When the monitoring cost is weighed against the small gain from sharing concession revenue,

    the parties prefer contracts based solely on ticket revenue.16

    Interestingly, leaving concession revenue out of the contract creates a problem: the ex-

    hibitor may wish to reduce p after signing the contract. Given the sharing rule, the exhibitor

    bears only its percentage of lost ticket revenue but obtains the entire gain from increased

    concession revenue that results from higher attendance. On the other hand, the distributor

    wants to maximize ticket revenue and does not care about concession revenue, so it prefers

    a higher p. The parties cannot setp in the contract because courts frown on vertical price

    restraints.17 The parties could divorce the distributors payment from p by basing it on

    attendance rather than ticket revenue, but such per capitaclauses are rare (De Vany and

    Eckert 1991; Friedberg 1992). The main solution relies on long-term relationships. The

    exhibitor gains from adjusting p only if the adjustment occurs after the contract is signed.If the exhibitor adjusts p before the contract is signed then the distributor will simply argue

    to change the sharing rule to ensure that the exhibitor still gets its reservation utility. Given

    that exhibitors include their proposed pin their initial bid, a subsequent adjustment would

    violate an implicit contract. Such behavior could cause the distributor (and perhaps others

    as well) to punish the exhibitor in the future. This encourages exhibitors to keep pup.

    16 Including concession revenue and monitoring costs in the above models is straightforward. Consider the

    risk sharing model. Denote concession revenue by c, the exhibitors share by wc(c), and assume that c isa (possibly random) function of attendance n. Suppose that including concession revenue in the contractrequires a monitoring cost ofm. In this case, the distributor compares its expected utility from maximizing(2.1) subject to (2.2) to the modified problem where its utility is based on pn + cw(pn)wc(c)m,theexhibitors is based on w(pn) + wc(c),and the expected utility calculations consider any randomness in thedetermination ofc. Clearly ifc is a deterministic function ofn, there is no gain to includingc in the contract.Even if this is not the case, ifm is sufficiently high the distributor prefers leaving cout of the contract.

    17 Many economists believe that vertical restraints should be permitted, partly because they can helpresolve agency problems (for a discussion see Carlton and Perloff1994).

    15

  • 8/13/2019 FILM FINANCE 2

    16/31

    3. Wehrenberg Theatres Contracts

    Our data is provided by Wehrenberg Theatres of St. Louis, Missouri. To avoid revealing

    proprietary information, all of the dollar values have been rescaled. Relative comparisons

    across theaters, contracts, time, and so on are entirely valid, but the levels are deliber-

    ately misstated. Further, we do not reveal distributor identities. Wehrenberg Theatres was

    founded in 1906 and currently operates thirteen theaters of various sizes in the St. Louis

    area, primarily in the suburbs. Wehrenberg has two main competitors that are concentrated

    in the city center: AMC operates four theaters and St. Louis Cinema operates two. In

    2001-2002, Wehrenberg accounted for approximately 68% of the ticket revenues collected by

    the 19 theaters, which is in proportion to its capacity.

    We have data on all movies playing in a Wehrenberg theater as of 8/31/01 and all movies

    that opened on or before 5/8/03. There are 308 movies and 2,769 contracts (each theater

    has a separate contract for each movie). Table 1 lists by theater the number of screens,

    the seating capacity, the number of contracts (which equals the number of movies shown),

    the average revenue per contract, and the exhibitors average percentage share. Table 1

    also provides a breakdown of the contracts into the four possible types. Clearly, the vast

    majority of contracts employ sliding scales, and most are firm term. The sharing rules vary

    substantially by movie and theater. For example, in sliding scale deals the exhibitors share

    ranges from 23-70% in week 1, 30-70% in week 4, and 40-70% in week 8. Run lengths depend

    on performance and vary from 1 to 28 weeks in our data; the average run length is 5 weeks.

    During the period, 21 distributors supply movies to Wehrenbergs theaters. The group in-

    cludes all of the large distributors (Buena Vista, Fox, Miramax, Paramount, Sony, Universal,

    Warner Brothers) and several smaller ones. Table 2 lists by distributor the number of movies

    placed in Wehrenbergs theaters during the period and the total number of contracts. The

    distributors are ranked according to the number of movies provided, from largest to smallest.

    The fifth column shows that average ticket revenue per contract varies substantially across

    distributors. This is to be expected; every movie is different, theater demographics differ,

    seasons differ, competition from other movies differs, and so on. The seventh column shows

    that distributors tend to receive slightly higher average shares when average ticket revenue

    16

  • 8/13/2019 FILM FINANCE 2

    17/31

    is higher. This is consistent with our models; distributors receive most of the gains when

    ticket revenue is high. On average, the distributor obtains 54% of cumulative ticket revenue.

    Table 2 also provides a breakdown of what types of contracts each distributor uses. Most

    use sliding scale deals exclusively and display a preference for either firm or flexible deals.

    3.1. Concave Sharing Rules

    The 90/10 provision is included in 86% of the contracts. Thus, most contracts exhibit the

    curvature suggested by Result 1 and depicted in Figures 1 and 2. However, 90/10 rarely

    applies. The distributor was compensated according to 90/10 for at least one week during the

    movies run in only 3% of the contracts. The provision applies for only the biggest hits in the

    biggest theaters, and even then for only one or two weeks of the run. The set of contracts thatlack the 90/10 provision includes virtually all of the aggregate deals and a small percentage

    of the sliding scale deals. In our models, the 90/10 provision is a transaction-cost minimizing

    device that anticipates the adjustment that would occur if it were not in place. Given this,

    our models suggest parties would leave the provision out only if they anticipate low revenues.

    The data on sliding scale deals supports this view. For example, the average total revenue

    per contract for sliding scale firm-term deals with the 90/10 provision is $22,455; for those

    without, $13,233. This diff

    erence is statistically signifi

    cant at the 1% level (t stat 4.87;1% critical value 2.58). For brevity we do not report additional comparisons, but results

    are similar for the sliding scale flexible deals and for comparisons at the theater level. We

    discuss aggregate deals below in Subsection 3.4.

    3.2. Revenue Sharing and Run Lengths

    Our models suggest that revenue sharing is used to share risks and economize on measure-

    ment costs. Of course, many sharing rules could accomplish these goals; Result 2 suggeststhat sliding scale rules are prevalent because they provide the exhibitor with the incentive

    to keep the movie longer. In this subsection, we evaluate this claim. We must be careful

    when applying the models to data, because the models assume the exhibitor has a constant

    reservation utility, whereas in a modern multiplex, Ue (or e) changes systematically over

    the life of the contract. When a movie first opens, it competes for the best auditoriums

    17

  • 8/13/2019 FILM FINANCE 2

    18/31

    and time slots; Ue is quite high. Later in the run, the movie is relegated to the smaller

    auditoriums where the opportunity cost is much lower.18 However, our arguments here do

    not depend on Ue being constant over a movies run.

    We show that if run lengths are unaffected by the form of the sharing rule, the par-

    ties could achieve essentially the same stream of revenues using a much simpler rule that

    eliminates transaction costs. Table 3 reports results from OLS regressions of the exhibitors

    portion of cumulative revenue for each movie (after any adjustment) on a constant and the

    movies total revenue, by theater. By construction in OLS, the estimated residuals sum to

    zero. Thus, each theater (and the distributors at each theater, as a group) would have re-

    ceived exactly the same cumulative money payoffs during the sample period if compensated

    using the regression line instead of the real-world contracts. The regression line suggests a

    simple linear rule that would be constant across movies and time for each theater: a flat

    fee (given by the constant term) plus a share of the movies revenue (given by the slope

    coefficient). For example, for every movie placed in the Arnold theater, Wehrenberg could

    require a flat payment of $876 and 42% of the movies revenues. There would be no need to

    negotiate terms for each movie or adjust terms ex post.

    If run lengths are unaffected, why not use this linear rule? Perhaps distributors would

    not want a one-size-fits-all rule. We re-ran the regressions in Table 3 while including dummy

    variables to allow the flat payments and shares to vary by distributor for the largest ten

    distributors. Wald tests of the null hypothesis that all of these effects were zero were accepted

    in all but one of the theaters. This suggests that each distributors cumulative revenues would

    not be affected much by a switch to the linear rule, holding run lengths constant.

    Another possibility is that while cumulative revenues would be unaffected, the flow of

    revenues would be drastically altered. This is not the case. The R-squared is at least .95 in

    every case in Table 3; the unexplained variance is small. As an example, Figure 3 compares

    Wehrenbergs weekly revenue from the Arnold theater to what it would have been under

    our linear rule with the flat fee paid in four weekly installments. It is difficult to distinguish

    18 The change in the opportunity cost is sometimes reflected in the house nut. The house nut declines overthe run in about 6% of the contracts. The decline in the nut also reflects the decline in the number of prints(copies of the movie) required as the movie is shown less often.

    18

  • 8/13/2019 FILM FINANCE 2

    19/31

    the two cash flow series. Given the wide fluctuations in theater revenue, it is unlikely that

    the relatively small deviations associated with switching to the linear rule would deter the

    exhibitor from adopting it. Figure 4 shows that the same is true for Distributor 1 at the

    Arnold theater. These figures are representative - moving from the relatively complex movie-

    by-movie rules to our simple linear rule has little effect on any theaters or distributors cash

    flows, and the effects remain small when aggregated to the firm level.

    Finally, note that our rule could only improve resource allocation, because it ensures

    that the exhibitor optimizes by maximizing total revenue. Under the current sharing rules,

    it is possible that more favorable terms on a worse movie might encourage the exhibitor to

    allocate movies to screens and run times in an inefficient (non total-revenue maximizing)

    way. In conclusion, it seems likely that the main reason why our simple linear rule is not

    used is that such a rule would encourage the exhibitor to shorten the run length.

    3.3. Best Weeks Clauses

    Result 3 suggests that best weeks clauses are used when it is possible that movie performance

    might improve over time. Best weeks clauses are relatively rare; they are used in only 8% of

    the contracts in our data, and only five distributors use them during the period we examine.

    Evidence supports Result 3. In contracts without best weeks clauses, weekly revenue peaksafter the opening week in only 6% of the cases. In contracts with best weeks clauses, weekly

    revenue peaks after the opening week in 23% of the cases. This difference is statistically

    significant at the 1% level (t stat 9.08, 1% critical value 2.58). Thus, there is a strong

    positive correlation between the use of a best weeks clause and the likelihood that a movie

    reaches its peak performance after the opening week.

    3.4. Aggregate Deals

    As we noted above, aggregate deals are used in a small percentage of cases. Table 2 shows

    that three large, one medium size, and three small distributors occasionally use aggregate

    deals; no distributor relies on them exclusively and most never use them. Practitioners tell

    us that some distributors use aggregate deals when the evolution of revenue is particularly

    difficult to predict, and our data supports this view. In such a case it may be difficult to

    19

  • 8/13/2019 FILM FINANCE 2

    20/31

    determine an appropriate schedule of floor payments in advance, and the distributor may

    not want to leave the choice up to the exhibitor, as in a flexible sliding scale deal.19 For the

    distributors who sometimes use aggregate deals, we computed the ratio of week2 to week1

    total revenues and week3 to week1 total revenues for every contract. Then we grouped the

    contracts into sliding scale deals vs. aggregate deals. While the mean ratios are virtually

    identical (.63 vs. .64 for week2 to week1; .39 vs. .40 for week3 to week1) the variances are

    substantially higher for aggregate deals (.040 vs. .053 for week2 to week1; .042 vs. .090 for

    week3-week1). F tests of the null hypothesis that the variances are equal are rejected at the

    1% level in both cases (F statistics: 1.32, 2.14; 1% critical value

  • 8/13/2019 FILM FINANCE 2

    21/31

    3.5. Ex Post Adjustments

    All types of deals may be adjusted, and adjustments may favor either party. Here we count

    any departure from the initial schedule of floors or aggregate shares as an adjustment.21

    This differs from actual adjustments only in that we count cases where 90/10 applies as

    adjustments favoring the distributor. This is sensible given our models; the 90/10 provision

    is a transaction-cost minimizing device that anticipates the adjustment that would occur if

    it were not in place. Flexible deals are more likely to be adjusted. Given our definition, 11%

    of sliding scale firm-term deals get adjusted, along with 41% of sliding scale flexible deals,

    13% of aggregate firm-term deals, and 82% of aggregate flexible deals.

    In our models, adjustments occur when a movie does much better or worse than expected.

    Expectations vary by movie and theater and we cannot measure them directly. However,

    we can assess Results 4 and 5 by comparing revenue outcomes. We divide contracts into

    three categories: no adjustment, an adjustment favoring the distributor, and an adjustment

    favoring the exhibitor. If the probability of an adjustment is independent of the initial

    expectation, then the average expected revenue in each category should be the same in a

    large sample. Given this, we can compare the averageactual revenue in each category to

    measure the departures from expectations. More realistically, departures from expectations

    may be i.i.d. zero-mean shocks with heteroscedastic variances, where the variance tends tobe higher when expected revenue is higher. In this case, contracts with higher expected

    revenues are more likely to be adjusted. However, even in this case we can assume that the

    average expected revenue is the same in the two cases where adjustments occur.

    The exhibitors average revenue per contract from sliding scale firm-term deals with

    no adjustment is $8,933; with an adjustment favoring the distributor, $26,641; with an

    adjustment favoring the exhibitor, $7,723. The last two averages are significantly different

    at the 1% level (t stat 6.86; 1% critical value 2.58). The facts are consistent with Results4 and 5: adjustments favor the distributor when the movie does much better than average

    21 Measuring adjustments for flexible deals requires some subtlety. As we noted in Subsection 1.1, ina flexible deal neither party expects to be compensated using the formal boilerplate terms. Instead, theexhibitor determines the payments as revenue is observed, and we use this schedule as our measure of theinitial schedule rather than the boilerplate terms. Final settlements occur 21-30 days after the run is over,and adjustments may occur at that point.

    21

  • 8/13/2019 FILM FINANCE 2

    22/31

    and favor the exhibitor when the movie does worse than average. Note that the average

    revenue when adjustments favor the exhibitor is only slightly below the average revenue

    when no adjustments occur. This is consistent with our argument in the previous paragraph

    that adjustments are more likely when expectations are high. For brevity we do not report

    additional comparisons, but results are similar for the other types of deals, comparisons at

    the theater level, and comparisons where we exclude cases where 90/10 applies.

    4. Conclusion

    Our results suggest that exhibition contracts evolved to help distributors and exhibitors share

    risks and overcome measurement problems and not to overcome asymmetric information

    problems. Our models explain several contractual features including concave revenue sharing

    rules, floors with sliding scales, best weeks clauses, and ex post adjustments. Other features

    of the environment also affect contracts: concession revenue is not shared because it is

    difficult for distributors to monitor, and long-run relationships that exhibitors have with

    distributors and consumers explain several practices.

    Why were modern sharing rules not used when the industry began? Initially movies

    were low-cost non-differentiated products; demand was fairly predictable and the cash flow

    consequences of a flop were not serious. Given this, the transaction costs associated with

    complex sharing rules were not worth bearing. Revenue sharing requires that distributors

    monitor exhibitors, and monitoring is worthwhile only if the expected benefit is sufficiently

    high. Even after sound, cheap B movies and movies shown in third, fourth, and fifth run

    theaters were not leased using sharing rules (Hanssen 2002). Over time movies became more

    differentiated, budgets grew, and risks increased. This trend continued through the 1950s

    when studios stopped making B movies in response to the emergence of television, and it

    became more worthwhile to adopt increasingly complex sharing rules.

    Although our models are designed to explain exhibition contracts in the movie business,

    many of the insights obtained apply to other goods with large upfront costs and uncer-

    tain demand such as new books and music. Other contracting environments also involve

    unpredictability, two-sided risk aversion, and measurement costs. Future research should in-

    22

  • 8/13/2019 FILM FINANCE 2

    23/31

    vestigate the effects of two-sided risk aversion and measurement problems on contract terms

    in greater depth and explain how levels of risk aversion differ across firms. An explana-

    tion may require considering firm-level cash flows in a dynamic environment. Firms avoid

    downside risks, and the stability of their cash flows determines how important it is to avoid

    downside risks. In the movie exhibition market, exhibitors have less control over their cash

    outflows than distributors. Operating a theater involves mainly fixed costs that cannot be

    avoided without exiting. On the other hand, distributors can avoid costs by delaying new

    movie projects, adjusting production and promotion budgets, sharing costs with outside in-

    vestors, or compensating talent using sharing rules. These differences may make exhibitors

    more reluctant to bear downside revenue risk than distributors.22

    References

    [1] Ackerberg, D.A. and M. Botticini. Endogenous Matching and the Empirical Determi-

    nants of Contract Form Journal of Political Economy110 no.3 (June 2002): 564-91.

    [2] Bhattacharyya, S., and F. Lafontaine. Double-Sided Moral Hazard and the Nature of

    Share ContractsRAND Journal of Economics26 no.4 (Winter 1995): 761-781.

    [3] Blumenthal, M.A. Auctions with Constrained Information: Blind Bidding for MotionPicturesThe Review of Economics and Statistics (1988): 191-198.

    [4] Borch, K. Equilibrium in a Reinsurance MarketEconometrica 30 (1962): 424-44.

    [5] Borcherding, T.E., and D. Filson. Conflicts of Interest in the Hollywood Film Industry:

    Coming to America - Tales from the Casting Couch, Gross and Net, in a Risky Business

    in Davis, M., and A. Stark, eds. Conflict of Interest in the Professions (New York:

    Oxford University Press, 2001).

    [6] Carlton, D.W., and J.M. Perloff. Modern Industrial Organization (2nd. ed. New York:

    Harper Collins, 1994).

    22 It is also possible that stakeholder risk aversion differs between firms. Future research could explorethe relation between stakeholder risk aversion, firm characteristics, and contracts. Ackerberg and Botticini(2002) provide insight into how this might be done when risk aversion cannot be observed directly. Hartoget al. (2002) describe how surveys can reveal levels of risk aversion.

    23

  • 8/13/2019 FILM FINANCE 2

    24/31

    [7] Chisholm, D. Asset Specificity and Long-term Contracts: The Case of the Motion

    Pictures IndustryEastern Economic Journal19 no.2 (Spring 1993): 143-55.

    [8] Chisholm, D. Profit-Sharing Versus Fixed-Payment Contracts: Evidence from the Mo-

    tion Pictures Industry Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization 13 no.1 (1997):

    169-201.

    [9] De Alessi, L. Why Corporations InsureEconomic Inquiry25 no.3 (July 1987): 429-38.

    [10] Dekom, P.J. Movies, Money and Madness in Squire, Jason E., ed.The Movie Business

    Book, 2nd ed. (New York: Fireside, 1992).

    [11] DeMarzo, P.M., and D. Duffie. Corporate Incentives for Hedging and Hedge Account-

    ingReview of Financial Studies8:3 (Fall 1995): 743-71.

    [12] De Vany, A.S., and R.D. Eckert. Motion Picture Antitrust: The Paramount Cases

    RevisitedResearch in Law and Economics 14 (1991): 51-112.

    [13] De Vany, A.S., and D.W. Walls. Bose-Einstein Dynamics and Adaptive Contracting

    in the Motion Picture Industry The Economic Journal (1996): 1493-1514.

    [14] De Vany, A.S., and D.W. Walls Uncertainty in the Movies: Does Star Power Reducethe Terror of the Box Office? Journal of Cultural Economics (Nov. 1999): 285-318.

    [15] Eliashberg, J., J. Jonker, M.S. Sawhney, and B. Wierenga. MOVIEMOD: An Imple-

    mentable Decision-Support System for Prerelease Market Evaluation of Motion Pic-

    turesMarketing Science19 no.3 (Summer 2000): 226-43.

    [16] Filson, D. Dynamic Common Agency, Vertical Integration, and Investment: The Eco-

    nomics of Movie Distribution Claremont Graduate University working paper, 2004.

    [17] Friedberg, A.A. The Theatrical Exhibitor in Squire, Jason E., ed.The Movie Business

    Book, 2nd ed. (New York: Fireside, 1992).

    [18] Hanssen, F.A. The Block-Booking of Films Reexamined Journal of Law and Eco-

    nomics (October 2000): 395-426.

    24

  • 8/13/2019 FILM FINANCE 2

    25/31

    [19] Hanssen, F.A. Revenue-Sharing in Movie Exhibition and the Arrival of SoundEco-

    nomic Inquiry40 no.3 (July 2002): 380-402.

    [20] Hartog, J., A. Ferrer-i-Carbonell, and N. Jonker. Linking Measured Risk Aversion to

    Individual Characteristics Kyklos55 no.1 (2002): 3-26.

    [21] Kenny, R.W., and B. Klein. The Economics of Block Booking Journal of Law and

    Economics (October 1983): 497-540.

    [22] Leland, H.E. Optimal Risk Sharing and the Leasing of Natural Resources with Appli-

    cation to Oil and Gas Leasing on the OCS Quarterly Journal of Economics(August

    1978): 413-437.

    [23] Martin, R.E. Franchising and Risk ManagementAmerican Economic Review78 no.5

    (December 1988): 954-68.

    [24] Mas-Colell, A., M.D. Whinston, and J.R. Green. Microeconomic Theory (New York:

    Oxford University Press, 1995).

    [25] Mayers, D. and C.W. Smith, Jr. On the Corporate Demand for InsuranceJournal of

    Business55 (April 1982): 281-96.

    [26] Murphy, A.D. Distribution and Exhibition: An Overview in Squire, Jason E., ed.The

    Movie Business Book, 2nd ed. (New York: Fireside, 1992).

    [27] Orbach, B.Y. and L. Einav. Uniform Prices for Differentiated Goods: The Case of the

    Movie-Theater Industry Harvard Olin Discussion Paper 337, 2001.

    [28] Ravid, S.A. Information, Blockbusters, and Stars: A Study of the Film Industry

    Journal of Business72 no. 4 (October 1999): 463-492.

    [29] Ravid, S.A, and S. Basuroy. Managerial Objectives, the R-Rating Puzzle, and the

    Production of Violent Films forthcoming, Journal of Business (2004).

    [30] Reardon, D.B. The Studio Distributor in Squire, Jason E., ed.The Movie Business

    Book, 2nd ed. (New York: Fireside, 1992).

    25

  • 8/13/2019 FILM FINANCE 2

    26/31

  • 8/13/2019 FILM FINANCE 2

    27/31

    27

  • 8/13/2019 FILM FINANCE 2

    28/31

    28

    Figure 3. Wehrenberg Weekly Revenue Comparison for Arnold TheaterArnold Theater - Weekly Revenue Comparison

    $5,000

    $10,000

    $15,000

    $20,000

    $25,000

    $30,000

    $35,000

    $40,000

    8/31/01

    9/30/01

    10/31/01

    11/30/01

    12/31/01

    1/31/02

    2/28/02

    3/31/02

    4/30/02

    5/31/02

    6/30/02

    7/31/02

    8/31/02

    9/30/02

    10/31/02

    11/30/02

    12/31/02

    1/31/03

    2/28/03

    3/31/03

    4/30/03

    A ct ual Li nea r Rule

    Figure 4. Distributor 1 Weekly Revenue Comparison for Arnold TheaterDistributor 1 - Weekly Revenue Comparison

    $0

    $5,000

    $10,000

    $15,000

    $20,000

    $25,000

    8/31/01

    9/30/01

    10/31/01

    11/30/01

    12/31/01

    1/31/02

    2/28/02

    3/31/02

    4/30/02

    5/31/02

    6/30/02

    7/31/02

    8/31/02

    9/30/02

    10/31/02

    11/30/02

    12/31/02

    1/31/03

    2/28/03

    3/31/03

    4/30/03

    Ac tua l Linea r R ul e

  • 8/13/2019 FILM FINANCE 2

    29/31

    29

    Table 1. Theater Characteristics

    Percent of Contracts that are:Average Exhibitor

    Sliding Scale Aggregate

    Theater Screens Total

    Seating

    Contracts

    Revenueper

    contract*

    % Shareper

    contract

    Firm Flexible Firm Flexible

    Arnold 14 2,164 243 7,982 47 59 30 9 1

    Clarkson 6 1,357 154 6,136 46 59 31 8 2

    DesPeres 14 2,447 256 11,354 46 61 29 9 1

    Eureka 6 1,039 179 2,021 49 61 28 10 1

    HallsFerry 13 2,526 127 2,063 50 65 29 6 1

    Jamestown 14 2,254 265 11,534 46 58 31 9 1

    Kenrick 8 1,899 136 6,482 48 54 35 10 1

    MidRivers 14 2,505 250 12,775 46 59 30 9 2

    Northwest 9 2,254 223 3,035 48 58 30 11 1

    OFallon 15 2,583 200 16,618 45 57 32 11 2

    Ronnies 20 3,625 294 20,986 45 59 31 9 1

    St. Charles 18 3,720 284 12,865 45 59 31 9 1

    St. Clair 10 2,197 158 8,020 48 56 32 10 2

    Wehrenberg 161 30,570 2,769 10,342 46 59 31 9 1

    * Revenues have been rescaled to preserve proprietary information.

    All percentages and rankings remain intact.

  • 8/13/2019 FILM FINANCE 2

    30/31

    30

    Table 2. Distributor Contract Characteristics

    Distributors Total Average Percent of Contracts that are:

    Total Distributor

    Contracts Revenue Revenue Rental Sliding Scale Aggregate

    per Rate

    Movies Contracts movie

    per

    contract*

    per

    contract* (%) Firm Flexible Firm Flexible

    1 44 441 10 21,184 11,643 55 98 2 0 0

    2 39 396 10 21,772 12,243 56 71 1 29 0

    3 34 325 10 30,567 16,685 55 12 88 0 0

    4 34 336 10 24,789 14,063 57 99 1 0 0

    5 31 202 7 15,627 7,773 50 12 77 0 10

    6 27 275 10 16,727 8,414 50 25 75 0 0

    7 27 229 8 24,191 13,175 54 96 0 4 0

    8 19 166 9 34,717 18,522 53 25 0 75 0

    9 14 131 9 13,586 7,199 53 8 92 0 0

    10 13 130 10 31,683 17,866 56 100 0 0 0

    11 7 47 7 4,830 2,145 44 40 43 17 0

    12 5 41 8 8,401 3,998 48 20 56 0 24

    13 3 8 3 16,049 7,351 46 88 13 0 0

    14 2 14 7 46,714 21,881 47 0 57 0 43

    15 2 10 5 3,767 1,729 46 100 0 0 0

    16 2 3 2 16,566 7,514 45 33 67 0 0

    17 1 2 2 6,128 2,778 45 0 100 0 0

    18 1 1 1 5,505 2,697 49 0 100 0 0

    19 1 4 4 1,180 526 45 100 0 0 0

    20 1 3 3 2,592 1,192 46 0 100 0 0

    21 1 5 5 12,715 5,295 42 0 100 0 0

    All Distributors 308 2,769 9 22,651 12,309 54 59 31 9 1

    * Revenues have been rescaled to preserve proprietary information.

    All percentages and rankings remain intact.

  • 8/13/2019 FILM FINANCE 2

    31/31

    Table 3. Linear RegressionsDependent Variable: Exhibitors Cumulative Revenue per Movie by TheaterTable entry: Estimated Coefficient (White Std. Errors in parentheses)

    Theater Constant

    Total Revenue

    per Movie byTheater R

    2

    Arnold 876*** 0.42*** 0.98

    243 Obs (115) (0.0092)

    Clarkson 274** 0.44*** 0.95

    154 Obs (126) (0.015)

    DesPeres 812*** 0.43*** 0.98

    256 Obs (204) (0.012)

    Eureka 109*** 0.46*** 0.97

    179 Obs (31) (0.012)HallsFerry 86* 0.48*** 0.98

    127 Obs (45) (0.015)

    Jamestown 853*** 0.43*** 0.97

    265 Obs (197) (0.011)

    Kenrick 339*** 0.46*** 0.98

    136 Obs (93) (0.0095)

    MidRivers 1,329*** 0.41*** 0.98

    250 Obs (163) (0.0079)

    Northwest 101** 0.47*** 0.97223 Obs (49) (0.012)

    OFallon 1,909*** 0.39*** 0.97

    200 Obs (368) (0.013)

    Ronnies 2,075*** 0.40*** 0.97

    294 Obs (405) (0.012)

    St. Charles 1,158*** 0.41*** 0.97

    284 Obs (303) (0.015)

    St. Clair 636*** 0.44*** 0.97

    158 Obs (227) (0.018)

    * Significant at the 10% level **Significant at the 5% level ***Significant at the 1% level