24
Fair burden sharing: The possible role of the Greenhouse Development Rights Framework Dr. Paul Baer Assistant Professor School of Public Policy Georgia Institute of Technology Co-founder, EcoEquity Australia National University, Canberra 1 July, 2011

Fair burden sharing: The possible role of the Greenhouse Development Rights Framework

  • Upload
    chung

  • View
    26

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

Fair burden sharing: The possible role of the Greenhouse Development Rights Framework. Dr. Paul Baer Assistant Professor School of Public Policy Georgia Institute of Technology Co-founder, EcoEquity. Australia National University, Canberra 1 July, 2011. - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Citation preview

Page 1: Fair burden sharing: The possible role of the Greenhouse Development Rights Framework

Fair burden sharing:The possible role of the Greenhouse

Development Rights Framework

Dr. Paul BaerAssistant Professor

School of Public Policy Georgia Institute of Technology

Co-founder, EcoEquity

Australia National University, Canberra1 July, 2011

Page 2: Fair burden sharing: The possible role of the Greenhouse Development Rights Framework

The Greenhouse Development Rights Framework

AuthorsPaul Baer (EcoEquity)Tom Athansiou (EcoEquity)Sivan Kartha (Stockholm Environment Institute)Eric Kemp-Benedict (SEI)

Key Supporters have includedChristian Aid (UK)Oxfam (International)European APRODEV Network The Heinrich Böll Foundation (Germany) MISTRA Foundation CLIPORE Programme (Sweden)Stockholm Environment Institute (International)Rockefeller Brothers Fund (USA)Town Creek Foundation (USA)

www.GreenhouseDevelopmentRights.org

Page 3: Fair burden sharing: The possible role of the Greenhouse Development Rights Framework

GDRs: roots

• Authors were originally supporters of equal per capita allocations/contraction and convergence– Basis of founding of EcoEquity in 2000, book “Dead Heat”

• Following the CAN “Bali Equity Summit” in 2002, we tried to develop “per capita plus” – per capita modified to take account of national circumstances

• This turned out to be impractical, so we returned to the “right to development”

• First presented in 2004, reached maturity with publication of first edition in 2007

Page 4: Fair burden sharing: The possible role of the Greenhouse Development Rights Framework

The climate challenge: in three steps

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050

Annu

al c

arbo

n di

oxid

e em

issi

ons

(GtC

O2/

yr)

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050

Annu

al c

arbo

n di

oxid

e em

issi

ons

(GtC

O2/

yr)

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050

Annu

al c

arbo

n di

oxid

e em

issi

ons

(GtC

O2/

yr)

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050

Annu

al c

arbo

n di

oxid

e em

issi

ons

(GtC

O2/

yr)

Page 5: Fair burden sharing: The possible role of the Greenhouse Development Rights Framework

Per capita emissions allocated according to “contraction and convergence” (2030 convergence year) under an emissions pathway (based on Den Elzen et al. 2007) designed to stabilize atmospheric GHG concentrations at 450 ppm CO2-equivalent.

Page 6: Fair burden sharing: The possible role of the Greenhouse Development Rights Framework

Greenhouse Development Rights overview

• A global climate policy framework for “burden sharing”• Assigns obligations to countries based on aggregating the

wealth and GHG emissions of their citizens– “Capacity” (ability to pay)– and “responsibility” (contribution to the problem)– Combined “Responsibility and Capacity Indicator” (RCI)

• Excludes from consideration the wealth and emissions of poor individuals, below a “development threshold”

• Rich individuals are treated equally (have obligations) wherever they live

• In principle, an individually-based “right to development”

Page 7: Fair burden sharing: The possible role of the Greenhouse Development Rights Framework

The ethical basis of GDRs• Based on cosmopolitan egalitarianism

– Individuals not countries are bearers of rights and obligations (in theory)

– Countries are treated as aggregates of individuals– Individuals treated the same regardless of where they are born

• An idealist/constructivist account of politics and international relations– Ideas matter– Individual action matters– Countries act out of normative beliefs as well as self interest

(and self-interest is subject to “construction”)

Page 8: Fair burden sharing: The possible role of the Greenhouse Development Rights Framework

Defining and measuring capacity

• Capacity is a moral term: “resources that can be contributed without undue sacrifice”

• This raises the classic question of the “efficiency” with which resources are converted to welfare

• Historically captured by ideas of “basic needs”, luxuries, etc.

• Makes sense at an individual level• Our definition: per capita income over $7500

“development threshold”

Page 9: Fair burden sharing: The possible role of the Greenhouse Development Rights Framework

Defining and measuring responsibility

• Responsibility is an ambiguous term– Moral responsibility is not the same as causal

responsibility– Collective (e.g., national) responsibility is

problematic in many ways• Nonetheless, “polluter pays” and other

versions of responsibility have strong support• Our definition: cumulative CO2 emissions from

fossil fuels (and cement) since 1990

Page 10: Fair burden sharing: The possible role of the Greenhouse Development Rights Framework

10

Income and Capacity income distributions (relative to a “development threshold”)

Page 11: Fair burden sharing: The possible role of the Greenhouse Development Rights Framework

Emissions and Responsibility fossil CO2 (since 1990) (showing portion defined as

“responsibility”)

11

Page 12: Fair burden sharing: The possible role of the Greenhouse Development Rights Framework

 

Population (% of global)

Income($US / capita)

Capacity (% of global)

Responsibility (% of global)

RCI(% of global)

United States 4.6% 44,706 35.6% 30.9% 33.3%

EU 27 7.3% 24,175 28.1% 20.8% 24.4%

- EU 15 5.8% 28,573 26.7% 18.3% 22.5%

Australia 0.3% 33,880 1.4% 2.0% 1.7%

Japan 1.8% 48,065 14.3% 5.9% 10.1%

Russia 2.0% 3,566 0.9% 6.0% 3.4%

China 19.6% 2,683 2.9% 4.0% 3.4%

India 17.6% 860 0.1% 0.1% 0.1%

South Africa 0.7% 4,541 0.3% 1.0% 0.7%

Brazil 2.8% 5,119 1.5% 5.4% 3.4%

LDCs 11.4% 453 0.0% 0.4% 0.2%

Annex I 19% 27,617 84.6% 71.2% 77.9%

Non-Annex I 81.4% 2,353 15.4% 28.8% 22.1%

World 1 7,061 100% 100% 100%

National obligations based on national “capacity” and

“responsibility”

Page 13: Fair burden sharing: The possible role of the Greenhouse Development Rights Framework

National obligations (based on “responsibility” and “capacity”) over

time2010 2020 2030

Population (% of global)

Income($US / capita)

Capacity (% of global)

Responsibility (% of global)

RCI(% of

global)

RCI (% of

global)

RCI (% of

global)

EU 27 7.3% 24,175 28.1% 20.8% 24.4% 22.1% 18.7%

- EU 15 5.8% 28,573 26.7% 18.3% 22.5% 20.0% 16.6%

- EU +12 1.5% 7,074 1.3% 2.5% 1.9% 2.1% 2.1%

United States 4.6% 44,706 35.6% 30.9% 33.3% 30.0% 25.6%

Japan 1.8% 48,065 14.3% 5.9% 10.1% 8.5% 6.5%

Russia 2.0% 3,566 0.9% 6.0% 3.4% 3.6% 3.9%

China 19.6% 2,683 2.9% 4.0% 3.4% 7.9% 13.5%

India 17.6% 860 0.1% 0.1% 0.1% 0.4% 1.2%

South Africa 0.7% 4,541 0.3% 1.0% 0.7% 0.7% 0.9%

Brazil 2.8% 5,119 1.5% 5.4% 3.4% 3.5% 3.8%

LDCs 11.4% 453 0.0% 0.4% 0.2% 0.2% 0.4%

Annex I 19% 27,617 84.6% 71.2% 77.9% 70.5% 60.7%

Non-Annex I 81.4% 2,353 15.4% 28.8% 22.1% 29.5% 39.3%

World 1 7,061 100% 100% 100% 100% 100.0%

Page 14: Fair burden sharing: The possible role of the Greenhouse Development Rights Framework

Allocating global mitigation obligationsamong countries according to responsibility & capacity

14

Page 15: Fair burden sharing: The possible role of the Greenhouse Development Rights Framework

Implications for United States

US mitigation obligation amounts to a reduction target exceeding 100% after ~2025 (“negative emission allocation”).

15

Page 16: Fair burden sharing: The possible role of the Greenhouse Development Rights Framework

Implications for United States

Here, physical domestic reductions (~25% below 1990 by 2020) are only part of the total US obligation. The rest would be met internationally.

16

Page 17: Fair burden sharing: The possible role of the Greenhouse Development Rights Framework

17

Implications for China中国的测算结果

Page 18: Fair burden sharing: The possible role of the Greenhouse Development Rights Framework

18

A fraction of China's reduction, (and most of the reductions in the South) are driven by industrialized country reduction commitments.

Implications for China中国的测算结果

Page 19: Fair burden sharing: The possible role of the Greenhouse Development Rights Framework

National Obligations in 2020 (for climate costs = 1% of GWP)

Per capitaIncome

($/capita)

NationalCapacity(Billion $)

NationalObligation(Billion $)

NationalObligation(% GDP)

Ave. climate cost per

person above dev threshold

EU 27 $38,385         $15,563 $ 216 1.12% $436

- EU 15 $41,424         $13,723 $ 188 1.12% $468

- EU +12 $25,981         $ 1,840 $ 28 1.09% $300

United States $53,671         $15,661 $ 275 1.51% $841

Japan $40,771         $ 4,139 $ 62 1.23% $504

Russia $22,052         $ 1,927 $ 41 1.40% $326

China $9,468         $ 5,932 $ 98 0.73% $169

India $4,374         $ 972 $ 11 0.19% $58

South Africa $14,010         $ 422 $ 10 1.42% $395

Mexico $14,642         $ 1,009 $ 15 0.84% $207

LDCs $1,567         $ 82 $ 1 0.06% $58

Annex I $38,425         $40,722 $ 652 1.29% $529

Non-Annex I $6,998         $18,667 $ 292 0.66% $180

High Income $44,365         $40,993 $ 655 1.33% $602

Middle Income $8,797         $18,190 $ 286 0.69% $149

Low Income $2,022         $ 206 $ 3 0.08% $51

World $12,415         $59,388 $ 944 1.00% $330

Page 20: Fair burden sharing: The possible role of the Greenhouse Development Rights Framework

Climate obligations, imagined as a (mildly progressive) tax

   

  Total global costs (mitigation and adaptation) 

0.5% of GWP 1.0% of GWP 2.0% of GWP     

Country incomemarginal tax rate

average tax rate

annual tax

marginal tax rate

average tax rate

annual tax

marginal tax rate

average

tax rateannual

taxUS $7,500 0.00% 0.00% $0 0.00% 0.00% $0 0.00% 0.00% $0 US $15,000 0.88% 0.44% $65 1.75% 0.87% $131 3.50% 1.74% $261 US $30,000 0.88% 0.66% $197 1.75% 1.31% $393 3.50% 2.62% $786 US $60,000 0.88% 0.77% $459 1.75% 1.53% $918 3.50% 3.06% $1,836

US $120,00

0 0.88% 0.82% $978 1.75% 1.63% $1,956 3.50% 3.26% $3,912 Ireland $7,500 0.00% 0.00% $0 0.00% 0.00% $0 0.00% 0.00% $0 Ireland $15,000 0.66% 0.33% $50 1.33% 0.66% $100 2.65% 1.33% $199 Ireland $30,000 0.66% 0.50% $149 1.33% 1.00% $299 2.65% 1.99% $597 Ireland $60,000 0.66% 0.58% $348 1.33% 1.16% $697 2.65% 2.32% $1,393

Ireland$120,00

0 0.66% 0.62% $747 1.33% 1.24% $1,493 2.65% 2.49% $2,986 Sweden $7,500 0.00% 0.00% $0 0.00% 0.00% $0 0.00% 0.00% $0 Sweden $15,000 0.58% 0.29% $43 1.15% 0.58% $87 2.30% 1.15% $173 Sweden $30,000 0.58% 0.44% $131 1.15% 0.87% $261 2.30% 1.74% $522 Sweden $60,000 0.58% 0.51% $303 1.15% 1.01% $606 2.30% 2.02% $1,212

Sweden$120,00

0 0.58% 0.54% $648 1.15% 1.08% $1,296 2.30% 2.16% $2,592 Note that EC effort-sharing proposal imagines global mitigation costs of €175 billion, or about ¼% of the EC’s projected 2020 Gross World Product

Page 21: Fair burden sharing: The possible role of the Greenhouse Development Rights Framework

GDRs: Strengths• It is by some standards relatively simple• It is specific and complete: it can actually be used to produce

numbers. • In theory it actually does protect the right to development - the

necessary costs for each country are borne only by the “already developed”

• Compared to resource sharing proposals, it actually addresses adaptation costs

• By assigning obligations to rich people in poor countries, it answers a primary criticism of Annex-based proposals

• It has been developed organically by a team that is closely integrated with both civil society networks (CAN) and academic and policy networks

Page 22: Fair burden sharing: The possible role of the Greenhouse Development Rights Framework

GDRs: Weaknesses• It is by some standards relatively complex• Even the numbers it produces are subject to a wide range of

“uncertainties” (e.g., baselines)• It doesn’t directly account for variation in national abatement

cost curves• It produces unbelievably large obligations for developed

countries• The individual approach to “the right to development” is

problematic– much of what is required for “development” are collective (public

goods)– GDRs offers no guarantee that national policies will reflect

underlying principles

Page 23: Fair burden sharing: The possible role of the Greenhouse Development Rights Framework

GDRs: political usefulness?

• It could, in theory, form the basis of a global treaty– Hah!

• In a “pledge and review” world, it can be used to measure national pledges against an equity benchmark– Requires some belief that its numbers are defensibly

fair• It could provide the basis for domestic campaigns

to increase national ambition

Page 24: Fair burden sharing: The possible role of the Greenhouse Development Rights Framework

GDRs: Questions

• Does our overall method produce a result that is defensibly fair?

• Is there a better way to define capacity?• Is there a better way to define responsibility? • Is there a better way to combine them?• Do our models of application (tons, dollars) make sense? • Does one make more sense than another?• How can our proposal be politically useful? • What problems are generic to any equity framework,

and what are specific to GDRs?