118
ENDOGENOUS-ALTERNATIVE PRODUCTION IN LATIN AMERICA AN ALTERNATIVE HYPOTHESIS TO INFORMAL SECTOR ANALYSIS Nchamah Miller OCT 2008

Endogenous Alternative Production

  • Upload
    gerardo

  • View
    25

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

Endogenous Alternative production in Latin America. An alternative hypothesis to informal sector analysis. Miller Nchamah (2008)

Citation preview

  • ENDOGENOUS-ALTERNATIVE PRODUCTION IN LATIN AMERICA

    AN ALTERNATIVE HYPOTHESIS TO INFORMAL SECTOR ANALYSIS

    Nchamah Miller

    OCT 2008

  • ii

    Abstract

    The hypothesis proposed in this thesis advocates the view that capitalism as a

    system of production is undergoing drastic changes which affect the current

    economic and political conjuncture and indicate a transition away from

    capitalism. This thesis examines those changes which occur at the level of

    history which support this thesis and correspond to mutations to material

    social relations as they manifest specifically in regard to agrarian areas. The

    historical period examined is the last quarter of the 20th century and beginning

    of the 21st as it relates to these social relations of production in Brazil, Bolivia,

    Colombia and Mexico.

    The purpose of this work is to propose a different conceptualization of relations

    of production that more adequately describes the areas examined and which

    the author refers to as endogenous-alternative production. This hypothesis

    stems from a critique of the work by Hernando De Soto and Victor Tokman in

    relation to the informal sector in Latin America.

  • iii

    Dedication

    Table of Contents

    1.0 Introduction ....................................................................................................................................... 1

    2.0 Approaches to the formal sector and contemporary capitalism ..................................................... 10

    2.1 Rethinking Capitalism and the ex-capitalist transition ................................................................ 11

    2.2 The Formal Sector ........................................................................................................................... 22

    2.2.1 Part A Hernando De Soto and the Formal Sector ......................................................................... 22

    2.3 Beyond Regulation Tokman and PREALC .................................................................................... 30

    3.0 The discourse of the informal economy .......................................................................................... 37

    3.1 Genealogy of the conception of the informal sector.................................................................... 37

    3.2 A new institutionalist view of the informal economy de Soto ...................................................... 44

    3.3 Tokman and PREALC beyond regulation the informal economy ............................................... 55

    4.0 Endogenous-alternative production: making the case in Latin America 69

    4.1 Khra ............................................................................................................................................... 71

    4.2 Endogenous-alternative production ................................................................................................ 76

  • iv

    4.2.1 Adjunctive Processes ....................................................................................................................... 78

    4.2.1.1 Goods in endogenous-alternative production 80

    4.3 Social Protest Movements ............................................................................................................... 85

    4.3.1 Bolivia - adjunctive processes and violent de-commodification given the retreat of

    capitalist production in areas or sectors considered non-profitable ............................................... 89

    4.3.2 Brazil collective struggles grounded by social protest movements whose material

    base has a long standing endogenous-alternative production ....................................................... 92

    4.3.3 Colombia the trans-acculturation of capitalist consumerism ................................................... 93

    4.3.4 Mexico - non-commodification effectively sustained through cultural, traditional and

    new social practices ........................................................................................................................ 96

    4.4 Conclusion ....................................................................................................................................... 99

    5.0 Post-scriptum ................................................................................................................................ 100

    6.0 References ..................................................................................................................................... 108

    List of Tables

    Table 1: Sectors of the informal economy: ...................................................................................................... 49

    Table 2: Population and hours worked and informal sector contribution to GDP ...................................... 50

  • 1

    Introduction

    An integral component of the work in this thesis which corresponds to my critique of the discourse on

    informal sector/economy derives from the following general statement:

    An alternative more nuanced theorization of capitalism and levels of analysis1 points against a

    reductionist view of economic and social exchange in the manner articulated in informal sector/economy

    analysis because this analysis does not capture either the effects of complex political processes, nor does it

    differentiate between these and normative regulatory and legal institutional conditioning, in short: prevailing

    informal sector/economy analyses do not contemplate any ramifications in these relations which arise out of

    non-capitalist goods and service production.

    The kernel of my task in this thesis is to provide a framework which problematizes current conceptions

    of capitalist accumulation. This will provide me with the theoretical grounding to engage in an analytical

    refutation of several aspects of the theoretical models contemplated by Latin American Informalists, mainly

    Hernando de Soto (De Soto 1989; De Soto 2002, 273) and Victor E. Tokman (Tokman 1992; Tokman 2006, 13).

    In respect of their conceptions of the formal sector, this also involves an examination of their specific

    methodologies and specific taxonometric formulations for the informal economy.

    I believe my contribution in this thesis consists of both my effort to challenge the conception of the

    informal sector and in theorizing a new schema of endogenous-alternative production which I locate

    historically in Latin America (since this is my area of current research and which also coincides with that

    investigated by both de Soto and Tokman during the same time period, the last two decades of the 20th

    and

    first decade of the 21st

    century). The order of the chapters in this thesis follows the outline of my argument. I

    begin Chapter 1 by presenting a working hypothesis only; since it is beyond the scope of this thesis to give a

    1 I use levels of analysis in the sense developed by Robert Albritton and the Unoist Marxian school of thought

    (Albritton 1991a).

  • 2

    theoretical explication for what I deem constitutes the current stage of capitalist accumulation. In reading the

    work of several Marxist thinkers, this led me to further consider whether, as a result of drastic changes in the

    patterns of accumulation of capital, this signals a different stage for accumulation. I answer this in the

    affirmative, on my part, and then I look closely at the work of several Marxist thinkers who have commenced

    theorizing an ex-capitalist transition, or aspects of it, which could relate to this category.2

    Although initially it may seem a severe contradiction in my argument, since I constantly refer to the

    term capitalism, I respond that despite falling within the camp which theoretically examines this ex-

    capitalist transition it is a completely different matter because when engaging at the level of historical

    analysis we examine how capitalist relations operationalize the logic of the expansion of value. Hence, in

    this thesis when I refer to capitalism I am referring to the social relations which attend to a political-

    economic analysis at the level of history. In other words, the point which I endeavour to defend is that there is

    a vast conceptual difference when theorizing the ex-capitalist transition at the mid-range level of analysis to

    punctuate the differentia specifica of different stages of accumulation. Nevertheless, the analysis of what

    occurs at the level of history is quite distinct and even though we can theoretically posit an ex-capitalist

    transition, still, at the level of history, social relations may display the retracted effects of a previous stage of

    accumulation. This is simply because the breaks in periodization are not clean and are in fact historically

    diffused over periods of time.

    At the level of history, social relations refract the logic of the expansion of value by the intermediation

    of autonomous practices embodied in ideological, political and legal institutions (for example, the power of the

    state is used to give legal sanction to a set of property relations). How this logic refracts in history depends on

    2 I try to give the reader an idea of what this transition very generally entails but I do not go into an in-depth

    formulation and analysis of the ex-capitalist transition since this would be a work which be would required in

    a lengthier treatise. I refer the reader particularly to the work of Thomas Sekine, John Bell and Richard Westra,

    although I differ in terms of characterizing the specific of its periodization, but this is a theoretical point which

    is of very minor relevance to the present discussion (Bell and Sekine 2001, 37-55). I am also influenced by the

    theory of the fall of the profit rate in the work of Robert Brenner (Brenner 2006, 369).

  • 3

    the phase of accumulation, the type of nation state and the economic and extra-economic practices it adopts.

    Close examination of previous stages of accumulation reveals how the logic of the expansion of value is

    disrupted by all manner of social mediations (Albritton 1991a).

    Following this rationale, I contend that this logic is even more disrupted in the current stage of the ex

    capitalist transition. In other words, the expansion of value directly into social relations is further countered by

    all manner of complex cultural, political, ideological and legal subjective manifestations that open possibilities

    for changes not contemplated in previous stages of sustained accumulation.3 My analysis looks at whether

    there are institutional practices which signal changes in these practices and if these can be attributed to a

    dysfunction in accumulation, which I argue signal, but are not the causal factors which trigger the ex-

    capitalist transition.

    In the second section of Chapter 2, I look at the work of both de Soto and Tokman and their specific

    conceptualizations of the formal sector. Here, I critically examine de Sotos argument that the informal

    economy is constituted within a realm of illegality that acts to subvert the legal mechanism which prevents

    access to the economic system (De Soto 1989, xx). In his view both the formal sector and informal economy

    have been prevalent as institutions through out a long trajectory in history. Next, I expand on why, in Tokmans

    model, legal regulation is the principal mechanism of regulation between the formal sector and informal

    economies, which emerge on account of the fragmentation of the labour force, as a consequence of the crises

    of employment brought by neo-liberal restructuring and, previous to that, the failure of the import substitution

    industrialization (ISI model) in the global south.

    In the last four decades, a growing number of analyses have been developed to explain modalities of

    socio-economic exchange outside of wage relations, which have been attributed to self-provisioning, micro-

    3 I should also make the point, naturally, that I am not arguing that the disruptions to the expansion of value

    are causal to the ex-capitalist transition.

  • 4

    enterprise, or the black market particularly as these prevails in the global south.4 In Chapter 3 I look at the

    genealogy of this body of literature and examine why the discourse of the informal economy engages with a

    specific problematique5 which centres on explicating the socio-economic relations of populations living in

    poverty in many regions of the world today.6 Given the recent explosion of analyses on this topic, and for

    purposes of narrowing the scope of this thesis, I limit my discussion to what I believe are the two main

    4 Along with other scholars, I use the term global south to indicate the economic disparateness in the third

    world locally and at the level of the nation state, and also to indicate the political dependency of the global

    south to the dominant global north. This conception allows integrating into the analysis the disparities which

    also occur within the global north (for example, some areas of the southern states of the US, and the aboriginal

    communities of Canada), which are also comprised within the global south. Therefore, the terms north and

    south are not geographically limiting. A further nuancing is made by differentiating between third world

    societies which are located in the global south, and fourth world societies which are located in the global north

    although the term is also used to define absolutely impoverished nations in the south . For example Hoogvelt

    also claims that the geographical polarization has been replaced with a social one (Hoogvelt 2001, 14-42).

    5 Problematique or problematica is a word of Latin roots used in contemporary romance languages to express

    the confluence of set of problems yet to be fully articulated, hence, it denotes the emergence of ideas, concepts

    and contradictions to create epistemological foundations or to express, at another level, those conjunctural

    problems yet to be analyzed (some of which may be in the process of yet being defined and explicated). A

    problematic is, as it were, the beginning of a process of understanding and defining questions.

    6 Competing conceptions of the social economy have been developed by other thinkers, for example Polanyi

    (Mingione 1991, 85-87) prior to the concepts of the informal sector / economy which are sometimes used

    mistakenly as homonyms for the social economy. Because the concept of social economy has been used within

    very distinct frameworks and is not counter-positioned to a formal sector I am not including its analysis

    within this thesis. The work on the social economy coincides in part with my analysis in that many of its

    proponents position the social economy in relation to the social relations of capitalism but differs in that many

    thinkers primarily use the concept in relation to the global north. A different conception of the social economy

    is made by thinkers of Cuba and China, and an examination of these is also beyond the scope of this thesis

    (Acevedo Fals 2006; Reyes Fernandez 2006). In Venezuela the conception of the social economy ties directly to

    state policy and to constitutional and political changes to attain participatory democracy in progressive

    changes proposed by the Bolivarian Republic of Venezuela (Navarro 2008). In Venezuela the concept of the

    social economy also ties to work on endogenous development see footnote 10.

  • 5

    approaches which have emerged from the genealogy of the discourse - that of the informal sector and informal

    economy7- with respect to Latin America and which are exemplified in the work of de Soto and Tokman.

    Although Informalists8 and I share the same intellectual curiosity epistemologically, we position

    ourselves very differently in relation to the problematique i.e. the lacuna in theorizing the socio-economic

    relations of populations located theoretically at the interstices of the so-called formal sector by Informalists,

    and viewed through the lens of a stage of capitalism in my case. Methodologically we also have different

    approaches. First, Informalist analysis of the informal sector/economy is, with very few exceptions, based on

    direct empirical analysis. This quantitative analysis is at the same time automatically delimited by the

    ascriptions of criteria derived from normative readings of the informal sector. Second, spatially locating

    (through a priori criteria), and further categorizing populations constantly displaced (as are those living in

    poverty in the global south) merely reflects control groups used in defining statistical population records but

    cannot render a reading of the complex factors which vitiate these relations.9 Over and above these

    7 By discourse I refer to the all the literature, debates and critiques, pamphlets and media coverage in every

    language in which the terms informal sector/economy are appropriated, but in many cases this is characterized

    by a lack of a shared approach. Only in a few attempts have there been efforts to frame research within an

    explicitly constructed theoretical framework and, in general, most of the discussion has taken place to the

    measure that the term has been inserted into language practices but through different signifiers. Chapter 3 is

    dedicated to this discussion.

    8 In this thesis I use the word Informalists to signal those thinkers, researchers and, in general, proponents of

    both the conception of the informal sector or economy. Informalists do not differentiate between either of

    these standpoints.

    9 Bourgeois economists have admitted to this problem: This discussion of alternative perspectives on

    informality brings into sharp focus the question of the most appropriate way to define and measure the

    informal sector. This is a question which has attracted little or no detailed attention in the literature. The

    purpose of the present paper is to attempt to redress this. This lack of attention may arise from the paucity of

    data on a sector which by its nature is problematic to define. Thus researchers tend to fall back on the

    pragmatic and judicial use of data on employment status and sectoral affiliation. There is little discussion of

    the sensitivity of any conclusions drawn to issues of measurement and definition (Rossini and Thomas 1990,

    125-135). Also, *t+he size of the informal sector can be estimated differently depending on how the concept of

    informality operationalizes and what empirical information is relevant and available for the particular purpose.

    The information below presents general guidelines on informal sector measurement as well as examples of

  • 6

    methodological considerations, the main thrust of Chapter 3, however, is to look at what account de Soto and

    Tokman give of the informal economy. In the main, de Soto proposes that the informal economy is constituted

    within a realm of illegality and the black market through specific institutions in modern society and has been

    prevalent throughout a long trajectory in history. Tokman, on the other hand, argues that this informal

    economy emerges in modern society given contemporary social relations and ties to the market and wage

    relations mediated directly by legal regulation.

    The last section of Chapter 3 signals why, unlike Informalists, I do not use quantitative data, primarily

    relying on a reading of historical records gathered by contemporary historians who do not emphasize

    quantitative methods in their work. I believe the advantage in approaching the problematique through

    historical records allows me to pose wider questions which are not limited to specific data and therefore

    confined to taxonometric criteria. Curiously, and although in general terms we necessarily reach different

    conclusions, I have found points of commonality. In particular I can say this of de Soto: in his work he questions

    the sole mediation of relation by an extraneous normative regulation (the state) and proposes other vectors of

    analysis particularly internal (to the informal sectors) such as cultural norms and their inter-relation with state

    normative apparatus.

    While I also posit a dominant structural relation, capitalism, this does not correspond to a dominant

    variable. The category which I propose as an alternative to the informal sector/economy - endogenous-

    alternative production - derives causally from a multiplicity of factors reflected from the social relations of

    capitalism. The general term of reference in my approach is only limited by the questions I ask and which touch

    directly on those aspects derived from the problematique i.e. the analysis of socio-economic activity of social

    actors living in poverty in different socio-topographical spaces at the interstices of capitalism, specifically in

    Latin America.

    empirical work where the estimates of the size of the unofficial economy and informal sector were used (The

    World Bank Group 2006).

  • 7

    The work of Informalists, both theoretical and empirical, has reaffirmed my view that in contemporary

    society, when looking more closely at the data available on informal sector or economies, there are clear

    indications of the configuration of what I call endogenous-alternative production10

    . Ironically, there are

    indications of clear political activity present, yet latent, in Informalist analysis. Political activity is not weighted,

    given their specific quantitative methods. However, their research shows that in informal economies there are

    clear patterns not only of political activity but that, in fact, such activities tie to non-capitalist goods and

    service production (de Sotos work particularly provides fascinating examples of this, which I expand on in

    Chapter 3.)

    Granted, these inter-relations appear to be of minor interest to Informalists who, instead, focus their

    work on describing these so-called subsidiary economies in terms of the degree of delimitation by legal barriers

    and income creating activities. Thus, in general, any expression of non-conformity, or struggle, against the

    state legal or labour regulatory apparatus is deemed by Informalists to be a social response directed against

    legal barriers to gain admittance within a formal sector. Informalists do not conceive these manifestations of

    political struggle to be against historic manifestations of political and socio-economic institutions which refract

    the logic of profit within relations in history. On elaborating the thesis on endogenous-alternative production, I

    propose to make this differentiation clearer and suggest that in the normal course of events, at any given time,

    economic exchange is embedded within predetermining political relations (not only in terms of non-capitalist

    goods and service production) as it attains in the global south.

    The problem that I then face in chapter 3 is how to frame the potentiality of endogenous-alternative

    production in analytical terms that can be articulated with the theoretical framework offered in Chapter 2. The

    analysis and critique of the discourse of the informal economy led me to consider the following questions. How

    10 The term desarrollo endgeno (endogenous development) is quite different from what I propose in my

    theory on endogenous-alternative production. Endogenous development ties either to bourgeois conceptions

    of development or, in the case of Venezuela, to alternative forms of development that tie directly with

    proposed changes to state policy as it attends to internal development and market relations in general (Ochoa

    Arias, 2005, 1).

  • 8

    and to what extent does capitalism penetrate non-capitalist goods and service production? Does there exist, at

    the level of history, a new schema of production for populations located in the global south and how does this

    link with capitalist commodities in terms of inputs and outputs?

    I also had to look at providing a theoretical explanation for unaccounted changes in patterns which

    social relations were evincing if even a scintilla of credence were to be given, while not necessarily ascribing to

    the arguments or conclusions offered by Informalists, but which some of their data provided. However, I was

    led to reflect that if, on the one hand the hypothesis of the ex-capitalist transition had some value, and if

    historical data (as well as empirical data) signalled the opening of new social spaces, there was a conceptual

    need to provide a theory of whether a new schema of production is in the processes of emerging - this is what I

    call endogenous-alternative production. This theory flows from the question which asks whether, to the extent

    that social actors at the interstices of the global south have devised an alternative schema of production, this

    can be understood as a collective social response to a confluence of a complex economic, cultural and political

    practices which is also located within a matrix of hierarchies derived from cultural mores and practices.11

    In chapter 4, I present my thesis on endogenous-alternative production with three purposes in mind:

    (a) to answer the questions I believe touch on the problematique investigated in the informal economy

    discourse; (b) to undertake a comparative analysis between endogenous-alternative production at the level of

    history (because I believe this roughly corresponds to the empirical analysis of the informal economy in

    Informalist approaches); and (c) to argue against the rationale which explicates socio-economic relations in

    terms of what I deem to be a taxonometric straight-jacket in social analysis in the last two decades of the past

    century and the beginning of the 21st

    century in Latin America. The basic assumption taken in my general view

    is that new relations of production are emerging at the sites where capitalism did not fully penetrate societies

    such as those located in the global south. The question is how, at the level of history, does this inhere in

    11 For example: patriarchal, matriarchal and racial conflicts due to cultural practices of age privileging and age-

    or ethnic discrimination.

  • 9

    endogenous-alternative production and which adjunctive processes arise on account of two conflicting

    tendencies in the global south?

    As a partial response, my argument contends that in these new spaces complex political activities also

    contain inherited cultural conceptions of ethical relations and given that many social actions are mediated by

    these imperatives (which generate both political and ethical motivations or constraints) this may cause

    contradictions or conflicts in interpretations of normative structures (the case of the cultivation of, what has

    been branded as illicit crops in Colombia and Bolivia is an example which is expanded on in Chapter 4). To

    explain the mediation between endogenous-alternative production I develop another concept, adjunctive

    processes. I use this concept to: (a) denote that there is an articulation and mediation between endogenous-

    alternative production, and the contradictions which arise from market relations, specifically those which

    attend to the links with capitalist commodities, as inputs, and refraction (see chapter 2 for a definition of this

    term) and of capitalist institutional practices; and (b) to explicate and compare modalities of production such

    as non-capitalist goods-and-service production and capitalist relations of production.

    Historically contextualizing endogenous-alternative production requires punctuating how it differs

    from non-capitalist goods and service production and I give examples of this taken from Brazil and Mexico. I

    will attempt to expand on this general argument and give examples taken from historical analysis of Bolivia,

    Brazil, Colombia and Mexico from the work of several Latin American historians.

    The concluding Chapter 5 will be more in the line with a self-critique of the task I have attempted in

    this thesis. I, therefore, am the first to concede that this is a first very general attempt to offer an alternative

    conception to the discourse on the informal sector/economy: and, therefore, is a completely different approach

    to the analysis of the complex changes taking place in the socio-economic relations of those peoples who

    through civil war or famine (or other natural or social causes) the United Nations considers to be displaced

    persons in contemporary Latin America.

  • 10

    Approaches to the formal sector and contemporary capitalism

    The rationale behind this chapter is that rather than making a quantitative/qualitative assessment of

    each potential area of study (the informal economies), I first look at the arguments which ground the formal

    sector and how these a priori assumptions embedded within them apply to the later inscription of the

    informal economy.12

    My purpose here is to examine the hypotheses presented by Hernando De Soto and

    Victor E. Tokman and their theories touching on what dominant social relations attend to economic enterprise

    and how these are configured within the last quarters of the 20th

    century in Peru and Latin America in general.

    I focus on their explications of the type of mediations within the formal sector, and how they theorize modern

    society and the economic conjuncture in elaborating their specific theoretical frameworks and its application

    to their particular conceptions of the informal economy. At the same time, I use this discussion to punctuate

    why and how our approaches differ and the implications of these differentia specifica in the work of De Soto

    and Tokman on the formal sector and mine on the contemporary phase of capitalism.

    Since I will be comparing each of our respective theoretical frameworks I begin this chapter with a

    section on rethinking capitalism, and I present my hypothesis on capitalism as part of my review and analysis

    of what I believe are the limitations of the formal/informal paradigm. My purpose is two fold. First, I will

    present a hypothesis on the consequences of what has been referred to by some Marxist Unoists as the ex-

    capitalist transition based on the argument that in order to begin explicating the dramatic changes which are

    taking place at the interstices of capitalism, generally the global south and specifically Latin America, the

    possibility that we have entered into a phase of ex-capitalist transition should at least be contemplated.13

    I

    12 In Chapter 3 I shall engage in the differentiation between the informal sector and informal economy.

    13 By ex-capitalist transition I refer to a very long transition and I do not mean that all of a sudden the

    practices and institutions of capitalism cease to operate. What I wish to signify is that deep struggles emerge

    against these and slowly their effectiveness withers. The social relations and processes which aid the

    momentum of capitalist logic are slowly becoming ineffectual and have ceased to be effective, particularly at

    its weakest point (where it has been least strong), and specifically in areas at the interstices of capitalism. But,

  • 11

    discuss these aspects in the first section of this chapter by engaging in a discussion of the economic

    conjuncture, explaining why the logic of the Law of Value does not fully penetrate social relations at the level of

    history and even less so on those relations at the interstices of capitalism (in this case Latin America).14

    The last

    section addresses my second objective in this chapter which is to examine and contrast the theoretical

    frameworks advocated by Hernando de Soto and Victor Tokman, particularly, since both examine the same

    problematique as outlined in Chapter 1, but offer opposing renditions of what constitutes the relations of the

    formal sector.

    Rethinking Capitalism and the ex-capitalist transition

    The conception of capitalism utilized here suggests that the logic of the expansion of value only

    refracts, and does so unevenly, at the level of history, contingency and need.15

    Part of the problem with other

    perspectives like De Soto and Tokmans arises because they fail at least to make a distinction between an

    abstract level and relations at the level of history. On their part the universal and the particular are articulated

    as part of the lived reality and when they speak of for example modern society or the formal sector, even the

    informal economy they actually wish to imply that although this may sound abstract it is the organic and

    natural formation of contemporary human relations. Naturally, in the chapters that follow in this thesis I

    as can be expected, what grows stronger, for a while, is the US military complex (which aims at truncating the

    emergence of other social schemas of production), until the economy can no longer supply the resources to

    prolong the sustainability of this complex.

    14 I am not the first Latin American to engage in this debate. Ernesto Guevara, during the 1960s, participated in

    a critical debate on the workings of the Law of Value in societies in transition, and this led to what in Cuba

    became knows as el gran debate. Also, Guevara was very attentive to Marxs discussion on phases of

    transition in his later years when discussing Russia (Guevara 2006, 31-33).

    15 Again this was part of the great debate in Cuba: the extent to which social economies refracted the logic of

    the Law of Value and could interfere or circumvent with its workings. In this debate the works of Rosa

    Luxemburg and Nicolai Bukharin were hotly debated (Mora 2006, 17-28).

  • 12

    intend to dispute this methodological reductionist artifice and the reader will decide whether my argument

    deserves consideration.

    Whereas, in the approach advocated here, we can theoretically conceive that capital accumulates on

    account of the logic of the Law of Value: yet, to explicate how this occurs at the level of history, requires

    separating the conception of this logic from its reflection in the materiality of social relations. One of the

    advantages of this approach is that there is an allowance made for the complexity of other human motivations

    and contingency.16

    In the Unoist approach, which frames my analysis, there is such a separation between the

    epistemology of each of Marxs categories in Capital and that which we aim to observe at the level of history.

    The work of this thesis pertains particularly to the level of history and political economy; therefore, I

    will refrain as much as possible from engaging at an abstract level of analysis and the dialectical relation of

    these categories proposed by Marx. The argument on the contemporary configuration of capitalism are made

    at two levels: (a) the mid-range level which means an analysis of the relatively autonomous practices 17

    in the

    current stage (which involves an analysis of the US nation state and the ways in which it exerts its power as the

    16 An example of how we explicate abstract mediations in contrast to understanding the mediations at the level

    of history comes from Marx analysis in Capital. In chapters one and two he explicates the nature of the

    complex opposition and inter-relation between value/use-value and exchange value as abstractions taken from

    the circulation of commodities, but in order to explain their materiality he also provides a concretization of

    their materiality by way of the commodity and the social relations of capitalism in history. His empirical

    example is 20 yards of linen equal l coat are not merely to show a differentiation in materiality but to depict

    how through in history relations of production have a materiality in commodities (Marx 1990, 125-187). At the

    same time he expresses dialectically (abstractly) the relation between use-value, exchange value, and the

    expansion of value. This abstract discussion pertains to what in Unoist thought pertains to the first level of

    analysis, but in this thesis I do not contemplate an analysis at this abstract level and will be restricted to the

    mid range level and the third level: that pertaining to history and political economy.

    17 The concept of relatively autonomous practices allows specifying actions taken by capitalist institutions

    (political, legal or ideological) to support or undermine capitalist accumulation at a specific stage of

    accumulation and how these refract onto capitalist goods and services production (Albritton 1991a2, 32, 36).

    This level of analysis is specifically useful because it stands in contrast to the institutionalist approach taken by

    De Soto, and in the case of my work allows specifying those institutions pertaining to mid range level analysis

    (eg.: eg. corporations, nation state policies) and those pertaining to specific historic instantiations, such as

    trade unions and other politically constituted groups.

  • 13

    primary global hegemon),18

    in order to establish the inter-relation between the hegemonic practices of the US

    and the complex of economic and extra-economic relatively autonomous practices of nation states in Latin

    America; and, (b) a level which grosso modo corresponds to the so-called informal economies, which I posit as

    the history of social relations at the interstice of capitalism. At the level of history, particularly at the interstices

    of capitalism, the expansion of value meets with all manner of social contradictions and barriers, and is

    therefore not the sole constitutive factor of socio-economic exchange and production.

    Non-capitalist goods and service production occurs where labour relations are not subsumed to

    capitalist wage relations, and the means of production are necessarily owned by the workers. (I am hesitant to

    refer to the manufacture in contemporary sites in the global south of this type of production either as petty

    bourgeois production or even less informal sectors, for reasons which will become apparent in the analysis of

    endogenous-alternative production, see Chapter 4). This can be readily seen from the following example. In the

    production of goods at the interstices of capitalism, the manufacturing process may utilize mass produced

    commodities (eg. the flour for tortillas) and the goods produced are either for self provisioning within small

    communities or sold to outside merchant sectors and even directly by street vendors. Although the ultimate

    good is made through non-capitalist labour relations, the inputs utilized (since they are produced by agri-

    business) are bearers of the marks of refraction of the logic of profit and through this mechanism and money

    exchange, non-capitalist good and service production is tied to capitalist production.19

    This example is given to

    indicate the latent refraction of capitalist penetration (through commodities) at the interstices of capitalism.

    Looked at another way, the social relations of capitalism do not have an equivalent expression in non-capitalist

    forms of production of goods and services, but they are often linked to them through commodity forms of

    exchange, including money.

    18 I prefer to use an understanding of the term hegemon offered by Brenner because it captures the subtleties,

    along with the internal and external contradictions of the nation state which I find the term imperialism

    completely elides (Brenner 2006, 248- 271-280).

    19 I change this terminology to make specific distinctions in Chapter 4.

  • 14

    However, several questions come to mind with this illustration, starting with whether the flour is

    crucially needed by communities for their survival, or whether they have alternative inputs to produce these

    goods. To what degree is this is so? Can these communities find an alternate input which reduces their

    dependence on capitalist commodities as inputs and how might these choices affect their social relations?

    Another question is whether these exchanges organize collectives or only latently influence the actions of

    members in which this production takes take place. While Marxs argument that commodity production is the

    central organizing unit of capitalism applies to capitalistically produced commodities only (Marx 1990, 124-

    177) it opens up another question relating to the degree that its logic of social relations penetrates

    communities located at the interstices of capitalism.

    The problem this thesis contemplates involves examining how and which barriers emerge to the

    refraction of this logic in history at the interstices of capitalism, and addressing it requires locating the phase of

    capitalist accumulation currently prevailing, the type of nation state characteristic of this phase, and the

    economic and extra-economic practices the state adopts to facilitate accumulation in this phase. This analysis

    necessitates a specification of the historical epoch being examined as well as engaging in a mid-range level of

    analysis to examine how, through a given set of relatively autonomous practices, the Law of Value is

    refracted onto the level of history. This also involves exploring the extent to which the economic sphere

    remains dominant and how it imbricates onto political, ideological and legal practices (Albritton 1991a2, 32,

    36). This approach to periodizing capitalist accumulation and disentangling the analysis of relatively

    autonomous practices from the analysis of social relations at the level history is informed by the work of

    Unoist Marxists.20

    There are different positions with respect to periodizing the ex-capitalist transition,21

    however, I

    take the view that this occurred in or around the energy crisis of the seventies when the US hegemon readily

    20 The work of Robert Albritton, John Bell, Thomas Sekine and Richard Westra.

    21 I should point out that by ex-capitalist transition I refer to a very long transition and I do not mean that the

    relatively autonomous practices, and institutions of capitalism all of a sudden cease to operate, what I wish

  • 15

    admitted that it could no longer rely on an inexhaustible source of cheap oil, and there was a veritable crisis of

    confidence in the ability to maintain its consumerism.22

    It is doubtful whether the US could continue to support

    its internal consumerist automobile market based on the gas guzzling automotive industry it had developed as

    its primary use-value for accumulation (Albritton 1991c, 226). Added to this, the oil crisis forced changes in

    consumption patterns which affected the USs ability to compete with the European and Japanese emerging

    automotive industries which had the technologies required for an automotive sector with lesser gasoline use.23

    Actually, even prior to the 1980s and specifically after that period, the US entered into a downturn period

    manifested historically by the drop in profit rates and characterized by periods of short equity booms and

    bubble bursts (Brenner 2004, 57-71). In addition, the US was forced to re-configure its internal structural and

    political state power dynamics because the economic crisis had also translated into a crisis of its authority

    (Soederberg 2004, 62).

    The deepening of the crisis occurred through the Asian financial collapse in the late 1990s which also

    signalled an economic structural transition. As a consequence, I argue that a new political, though no longer

    pre-eminently economic, hegemonic form has emerged which can no longer be consolidated entirely by the US

    but requires the additional consolidated political power of the G-7. In an attempt to attenuate the crisis, the G-

    7 slowly built the necessary economic institutions, politically attempting to reconfigure both their economic

    and political domination through a global neoliberal apparatus. It aimed at re-imposing conditions favourable

    to signify is that slowly their effectiveness withers, that capitalist logic penetration does not gather momentum where it has been least strong, specifically in the areas at the interstices of capitalism. But, as can be expected what grows stronger, for a while is the US military complex, until the economy no longer can supply the resources to prolong the sustainability of this complex.

    22 I adhere to Albrittons periodization of the different phases of capitalism and his conception that the stage of

    consumerism commenced broadly the 1920s to 1960s (Albritton 1991, b223). I but differ however on what is

    happening in the contemporary phase.

    23 This is a simplification on my part, in effect Japan and Europe adopted changes which affected not only those

    between capital and labour but also the relation of technology in production. An analysis whether this

    constituted the first move away from the Fordist production paradigm to post-Fordism, or whether this

    suggestion is inaccurate is beyond the scope of this thesis. I thank John Simoulidis of York University for

    pointing to my lack of clarity in this regard.

  • 16

    to accumulation through the mediation of the New International Financial Architecture (NIFA), which

    developed out of the Financial Stability Forum (FSF), in part, by consolidating a set of international standards

    and codes referred to as the Reports on the Observances and Standards Codes (ROSCs) (Soederberg 2004, 1-

    28).24

    The NIFA set of institutions did not alleviate the causes of the crisis (namely an absolutely

    unsustainable and ferocious appetite for colonial natural resource extraction required for industrial production,

    the decrease in GDP and excess capacity) and its measures were merely palliative, aimed at dealing with the

    permutations and combinations of capital as it corporations fled from region to region, to and fro between

    industrial, financial sector and banking sectors as multinationals rushed to impede the slide of industrial profit

    rates in their investment portfolios. These machinations, in sum, gave the appearance of an overall increase in

    accumulation (Brenner 2006, xxiv, 145, 159). And this gave the nation state architects of the NIFA the

    confidence to believe that there was no crisis, especially not in the global north.

    Sustainable accumulation in the global north required three fundamental material conditions without

    which it is doubtful that, at this stage, bourgeois corporations could meet their input needs (but these would

    nevertheless deepen the crises further), namely: (a) obeisant dependent nation states of the global south; (b)

    the supply of cheap skilled labour (particularly for mining, communications and IT technology) and unskilled

    labour (in maquiladoras for consumer goods) in the so called free trade zones producing mass non-essential

    commodities; and, (c) the capture of these obeisant states as suppliers of natural resources to the global

    north.25

    24 I argue in Chapter 3 that the application of the conception of an informal sector becomes an intrinsic

    component of this standardization.

    25 In previous stages of accumulation the ransacking of natural resources was not tied to the sustainability of

    the economies, nor accumulation, after that, in my opinion, the two oil crises of 1973 and 1979 demonstrate

    that without this natural resource the economies of the global north would go into a tailspin dive. In the global

    south oil exploration took place, at that time, mainly only by US corporations operating in the global south and

    it was these corporations, not the states where these resources were located which now acquired the power

  • 17

    I contend that something is seriously amiss when neither the economic or extra-economic practices of

    the US state nor the availability of growing opportunities for foreign direct investment (FDI) are sufficient to

    even sustain even a semblance that these are a viable solution to their problems, and that these can no longer

    be contained within their borders. To make matters worse, and under the pretext of the global war on

    terrorism, the US has not been prepared to lose its ranking as the sole politico-military hegemon, and it

    remains committed to flexing its military muscle to guarantee secure access to territories of compliant and

    even non-compliant foreign nation states to further US colonial ambitions.26

    All of these are causally related to

    the implementation of neoliberal policies (this is, admittedly, a simplification of the problems because an

    analysis of US geo-political strategies in the current phase of capitalist development is far beyond the purview

    of this paper).

    It is my hypothesis that after the 1980s, capitalism as the paradigm for the expansion of value finds

    limited expression through the purely economic function of financial institutions and multinationals. Au

    contraire, capitalist profiteering depends more and more on political and international legal institutions, as

    well as military power, to pave the way for financial, banking and production operations, in order to make

    actual and tangible profits (recent scandals show why some of the financial statements of US corporations

    either mystical or virtual tales (Markham 2006, 742). Therefore, it becomes relevant to contemplate the

    possibility that rather than entering into a new stage of accumulation we may be entering into a phase of ex-

    capitalist transition (Bell and Sekine 2001, 37-55).27

    I recognise that it is challenging to think in terms which

    problematize the conception of the sustained accumulation of capitalism as usual, or the havoc and

    within that region to decide where further exploration would take place, and that the formation of OPEC

    served those interests, although in appearance OPEC functioned as a monopoly. The nation states of the global

    south had not yet developed gas guzzling infrastructures.

    26 I use colonialism because this form of power counts on the support of locals and does not require massive

    movements of population of the dominant power which I attach to imperialism. I also use this term because

    the word colonialism connotes resistance from those being colonized, again, something which may be lost in

    the semantics of imperialism.

    27 There are some differences between the periodization in my approach and John Bells and Thomas Sekines.

  • 18

    contradictions brought about by the neoliberal apparatus with the object of naturalizing market relations and

    mitigating the effects of the current crisis.28

    Nevertheless, it is my contention that thinking in these terms

    allows problematizing the conception which equates capitalist economic production and exchange relations

    with political relations such as the so-called new imperialism or the neoliberal apparatus to the relations of

    capitalism and impedes an analysis of the degree to which relatively autonomous practices refract the Law of

    Value and the degree of extra-economic intervention required on the part of political and legal institutions to

    sustain accumulation.

    I am quite cognizant of the voluminous work required to present a full argument on the ex-capitalist

    transition and to keep matters within a reasonable length I propose presenting my argument in terms of the

    following syllogism.29

    If capital accumulation is unsustainable and if failing relatively autonomous practices

    rather than alleviate, feed this crisis (particularly those practices attending to political, legal and ideological

    articulations), then capitalism is not sustainable on its own logic, its own social relations or mode of

    production. Therefore, either new practices emerge which lead to this transition or other efforts to restore

    capitalism are undertaken which may further aggravate the waves of crises. It follows that if capital

    accumulation is unsustainable and is fed by failing relatively autonomous practices (particularly those

    attending to political, legal and ideological articulations) these must create dysfunctional mediations which

    destabilize accumulation and investigating how these reflect onto each historic conjuncture helps us to

    understand the nature of the ex-capitalist transition.

    Assuming the above, capitalism as a social relation and system of production is showing signs of

    fatigue and may even be no longer sustainable, but this does not mean that the capitalist webs of political and

    28 I remember when I began work on this thesis and mentioned a crisis and recession and the merriment many

    had at my suggestion that finally capitalism was showing structural cracks.

    29 There are many other arguments which apply to theorizing the phase of ex-capitalist transition (Bell and

    Sekine 2001, 37-55). My gratitude to Richard Westra who allowed me to read the draft of his work Political

    Economy and Globalization (London: Routledge 2009 forthcoming) and which has been influential in the

    elaboration of the hypothesis of the ex-capitalist transition.

  • 19

    ideological power and legal institutional arrangements protecting private property automatically cease to

    operate. As a matter of fact, it leaves socially inerasable palimpsest of domination processes. This explains

    why I argue that the transition is a long historic process which has many contradictions, especially ones that

    even enhance the ability of different blocs of investment capital to survive. The difference is that once the ex-

    capitalist transition commences to the point that relatively autonomous practices become more stringent and

    corporations, government agencies, nation states will act as if the contradictions that emerge are natural

    and can be controlled politically, the closer the waves of booms and bubbles. 30

    This thesis has another corollary: when capitalism is viable, a set of relatively autonomous practices

    (each depending on the phase of accumulation) are inserted to prop accumulation and these refract a

    particular response into the third world such as so-called development programs. But if capitalism is no longer

    viable, it stands to reason that the old set of practices can no longer reconstitute a failing economy and

    therefore can no longer achieve the same results and therefore capitalist social relations become less and less

    viable. Because of this, in the post 1980s era, capitalism as the paradigm for the expansion of value through

    social relations, found limited expression through the purely economic function of financial institutions and

    multinationals, and it had to depend on the authority of political and international legal institutions along with

    military power to pave the way for financial, banking and production operations. Of course, there were profits

    in some sectors but this is quite different from maintaining the magnitude of accumulation.

    I contend that the result of this long wave of crises evidences the failure of the capitalist venture to

    reconfigure such conditions which are propitious to its reproduction and all that appears relatively operational

    at this juncture are stock market exchanges, which depend as they do on state economic policies, but these are

    on a collision course with economic institutions (such as the fragility of the US banking system) and other

    political and legal practices internal to the US. Since accumulation has, at the very least, been diminished, if not

    30 The correlation between the oil crisis of 2008 and the managed drop of the US dollar coupled to the

    increase of the price of oil is an example.

  • 20

    actually retarded, the US opts for political measures to stave off the waves of crises.31

    What is important here

    is the impact of such a crisis of accumulation onto social relations at the interstices of capitalism and the

    manner in which its consequences diffuse into both the political and economic spaces of the global south which

    is the area of concern in this thesis.

    Truncated relatively autonomous practices refract new dysfunctional forms of mediation and link to

    the level of history and impact negatively on those populations who bear the brunt of these crises. For example

    the US Federal Reserve may believe it is in control of interest rates, but private Banks use this to their own

    advantage and have gone on a spree of sub-prime non-collateral mortgage lending which defeat any policies

    of the Federal Reserve. We can no longer afford to think in terms of accumulation as usual taking place

    despite all indicators pointing otherwise. Although many contend that arguments for a transition are

    theoretical straw men, the question is why is there evidence that we are arriving at a time when accumulation

    is retarding and this is creating social havoc in many areas of the planet?32

    The global south, however, is only

    the recipient of the refraction of these inadequacies and the blundering of relatively autonomous practices

    and what cannot be denied, even by Informalists, is that, as a result, dramatic changes have occurred to the

    social relations in the global south.

    In the consumerist phase of accumulation, the great divide between the global north and global south

    became more pronounced (this can be established by the geometric distancing in the GINI indices between

    advanced capitalist countries and those in the global south from the period 1960s -1980s and the figures for

    today which indicate a geometric differential between them).33

    I take the position that this shows the nature of

    31 Certainly the work of Robert Brenner is ground breaking in that it anticipates such a possibility and it may be

    a disservice not engaging more fully with his work but the focus of this thesis is at another level that which

    pertains to the social relations at the interstices of capitalism (Brenner 2006, 369).

    32 The fact that accounting practices of corporations have been conceived to show as rosy a panorama of their

    accounts as possible makes this all the more sinister.

    33 The GINI index reflects the ratios between nation states and their respective GINI coefficient. This coefficient

    is a measure of income inequality, with 0 being everyone having the same income, and 1 being one person

  • 21

    the crisis in the ex-capitalist transition in which an even greater punctuated division grows between the global

    north and south.34

    At the same time, vested interests run so deeply engrained (whose influence will remain

    secure, unless there is a general bankruptcy) that no one can hazard a guess as to how long the global north

    will be able to sustain its ideological construct that both NIFA and Trans-national corporations are the vehicles

    to achieve global economic growth and development.

    NIFAs unwritten goal is to exert political domination over the global south through a union of

    financial institutions, multinational corporations and the adoption of neoliberal policies by nation states.

    However, the consequences of this union has had disastrous effects in the global south since the partners,

    transnational corporations and neo liberal institutions, inevitably ran into a collision path in the global south as

    they have attempted to neo-colonize (privatize) the area and pirate natural resources. Its legacy is a fatal and

    chronic crisis of unemployment in the global south which is the thematic that opened the investigations and

    research on informal sectors which I address in the following chapters.

    In the first phase of the ex-capitalist transition, capitalist accumulation is no longer the means

    through which, in and of itself, the social reproduction of vast populations now drawn into the web of

    capitalism is secured, particularly in the global south. Given such a crisis, should this not alter the way we view

    the changes which accrue in social relations in non-capitalist goods and services production given their inter-

    meditations with capitalism in a full blown crisis? I argue that, in a very ironic way, the research which

    spawned the discourse on the informal economy (although positing an alternative view to capitalism which is

    viewed simply as modern society) has attempted to answer this question. In the following section I look at the

    work of two Informalists whose work aims at answering this and other questions pertaining to the social

    relations of displaced populations in Latin America.

    having all income and everyone else has none. Data available from GINI: GINI index; UN: Data from the United

    Nations Development Programme.

    34 There are nuances between my appropriation of this concept and that proposed in the work of other Marxist

    Unoists which are not relevant to this discussion.

  • 22

    The Formal Sector

    In general, most approaches to the informal economy share a conception of a general formal sector

    and particular site specific informal sectors which operate in tandem with the formal sector. However, there

    are crucial differences between the different approaches to the formal sector, particularly with respect to the

    following issues: (a) the nature of relations of the informal sector to conceptions of institutions; (b) regulation,

    exploitation and human agency; (c) exceptionality portrayed as a social mechanism for a second economy

    vitiated by legal structures; and (d) the types of gender relations comprised in the units of organization of these

    sectors/economies. It is quite beyond the scope of this thesis to engage with all these approaches, and I limit

    my work to the analysis of research by Informalists who engage specifically with elaborating a conception of

    the formal sector and the apparatus of inter-mediation between the formal sector and the informal economy.

    I will focus on the work of Hernando De Soto (working with the ILD) and Tokman (working with PREALC).

    Although I disagree with many of their contentions with respect to the formal sector, I should mention that

    despite my strong critique I am indebted to these thinkers because without their work I could not have

    developed my thesis on endogenous-alternative production which I theorize in Chapter 4.

    Part A Hernando De Soto and the Formal Sector

    Simply put a new problematique emerges in contemporary attempts to explain what constitutes and

    comprises the informal sector and integral to defining this set of problems is explicating the relationship and

    linkages between the formal sector vis--vis informal economies. However much I may critique De Sotos work,

    I recognize his attempt to delineate these relations at a theoretical level and to frame his case study of the

    informal economy in Peru within that framework.35

    In what follows I engage with three of the fundamental

    35 In Chapter 3 I will explain why this had not been the practice in research on the informal sector.

  • 23

    concepts which delineate his conception of his dominant category of modern Peruvian society and how these

    are articulated: the market, the nation state, and the formal sector.

    Fundamental to De Sotos thinking is the notion that the market is a natural, homogenous, social

    universal relation which ideally should harmoniously mediate the relations within both the formal sector and

    informal economy, were it not for excessive legal barriers. Given these barriers, not only has there been an

    impediment to the free market, but these barriers have also created extreme economic disparities between

    modern society and the informal economy sectors. He makes two further points: first he argues that bad

    laws act as barriers for the entry into the formal sector by any social actor not connected to the mercantilist

    entrepreneurial formal sector or landowners (De Soto 2002, 189, 202, 208). Secondly he argues that Peruvian

    society is far from being a market economy Peruvian society is configured juridico-politically by a mercantilist

    nation state (De Soto 2002, 14, 201).

    By mercantilism De Soto identifies the excessive legal regulation of the state as having precise

    commercial redistributive and discriminatory purposes intended solely to favour the privileges of the

    commercial and landed classes. This system is geared to maintaining levels of wealth, but does not generate or

    reinforce the freedom of market relations. To a great extent, then, Peruvian mercantilism is not democratic

    capitalism, but the epicentre for machinations of merchant monopoly activity aided by the state legal

    apparatus (De Soto 2002, xx). Mercantilism is primarily a system centered on maintaining and arbitrating

    between competing claims for monopoly merchant rights and which does not generate the freedom of

    market relations. In other words, that which functions in lieu of the market is a bureaucratic mercantilist legal

    state apparatus which has two main functions: (a) to administer state decrees and policies through the

    mechanism of a redistributive super-bureaucracy which acts instrumentally to secure the interests of these

    monopoly entrepreneurial merchants; and (b) to protect the commercial interests of the entrepreneurial

    classes through the device of excessive dirigiste regulation. He argues that, in Peru, mercantilism has existed

    and progressed since colonization by the Spaniards and is characterized by authoritarian law making; an

    economic system in which the state intervenes directly; obstructive, detailed and dirigiste regulation for the

  • 24

    economy; poor or non existent enterprise for those who do not have close ties with the government; unwieldy

    bureaucracies, and a population which organizes around distributive combines and powerful professional

    organizations (De Soto 1989, 208).

    In this view, mercantilism differs from market relations in that the former is comprised of specific

    merchant and juridico-legal practices with a high incidence of commercial monopolies in collusion with the

    nation states legal regulatory apparatus; whereas in market societies there is little regulation of the economy.

    The formal sector emerged in Peru to the measure that Peruvian elites36

    adopted European commercial

    mercantilist practices and integrated mercantilism into the normative apparatus which functioned to protect

    their merchant interests (Douglas North in (De Soto 2002, 177-179). In Peru, this sector has gradually

    developed in conjunction with the criollo redistributive institutional tradition operating solely to protect

    property rights of the merchant monopolies and the elite latifundistas (De Soto 2002, 202-210, 303).

    On its part, the Peruvian state has developed a mechanism for a regime of governance by presidential

    decrees utilized to control all aspects of the economy acting as a legal regulatory apparatus. Yet, De Soto is

    careful to note the tensions between the formal sector and the Peruvian state. On the one hand, the formal

    sector has been constituted through a mercantilist redistributive tradition and in this regard the role of the

    state has traditionally been to arbitrate between competing mercantilist blocs of the formal sector. On the

    other hand, the state, as an institution, has a long history of enacting economic policies and legal norms in

    order to preserve the economic and legal interests of the formal elites. But the elites do not rely solely on the

    state for arbitration and have separate institutions, which De Soto calls redistributive combines, used to

    settle individual commercial differences and organize monopolies (De Soto 2002, 13, 26, 63, 189, 201, 242).

    In many respects De Soto believes the social problems of Peru originate from the relation between the

    formal sector and the mercantilist state bureaucratic apparatus on account of the barriers erected between the

    36 They are the old business elite and commercial entrepreneurs, who De Soto calls formal business people

    (De Soto 2002, 13).

  • 25

    formal and informal economies to the sole benefit of the formal sector (De Soto 1989, 133-188). He believes

    the lack of social equity on account of the dominance of merchant elite monopolies and property is supported

    by a tradition of bad laws and that the social problems in Peru can only be remedied if there are drastic

    changes to these bad laws. This system of law is the main barrier to the market economy and any access to

    this market would require completely revamping the regulatory state apparatus (De Soto 2002, 174 246-246).

    In conclusion there are three important claims attached to De Sotos theory of the formal sector: (a)

    that the social relations of Peru have not been penetrated by market relations (he avoids the term capitalism);

    (b) this has been prevented by the regulatory barriers erected by the mercantilist Peruvian state; and (c) as a

    result of the recombination of economic mercantilist practices and excessive dirigiste economic polices of the

    state, the entrepreneurial elite has been successful in monopolizing private property interests to the point that

    they have been successful in separately creating their own emporium and regnum to consolidate all aspects of

    economic endeavour and exchange in Peru.

    Explicating De Sotos standpoint requires pointing to his influence by, and appropriation of, the North

    American New Institutionalist approach which basically defines institutions as formal or informal procedures,

    norms and conventions embedded in the organizational structure of the polity. New Institutionalists assume

    that individuals adhere to certain patterns of behaviour because any other alternative would make them

    worse off (this is the equilibrium point): 37

    also, they emphasize the highly-interactive and mutually-

    constitutive character of the relationship between institutions and individual action (Hall and Taylor 1996, 938

    and 948). De Soto is also particularly influenced by Douglas Norths approach to the historical development of

    institutions on account of path dependency. Such paths are produced when the state administration adopts

    norms, standards, and regulations which over time become entrenched to the point that they become social

    habits. On account of this path dependency institutionalized practices are very difficult to alter. For this reason

    37 This aspect will become relevant in De Sotos discussion of the informal sector in Chapter 3.

  • 26

    the formal sector is an integral part of the path which emerged in Peruvian society once they adopted

    European commercial mercantilist practices (Douglas North in De Soto 2002, 177-179).

    The first problem with this new institutionalist paradigm is that if, in general, everything social only

    evolves into an institution as opposed to say social movements; then, De Soto is left to explain the nature of

    market relations, production, and distribution only within the framework of their being institutions. A second

    problem arises when he differentiates Latin America from western society in terms that westerners enjoy

    freedom as economic agents to participate in market relations (whereas I would argue there is no such realm

    of freedom). Thirdly, by positing mercantilism as the dominant relation which attends internally to Peru, De

    Soto is left without a mechanism to explain power relations between the global north and south and the global

    economy.

    But De Soto finds an alternative theory to explicate market relations. He resorts to the artifice that the

    market is the sole homogenous natural organic system in modern society and the vehicle to freedom and

    democracy. By this ruse, all of a sudden the market is beyond critique (i.e. idealized) simply through his

    claiming it to be the realm of democracy and freedom. In responding to this point I draw on my argument

    respecting the refraction of the Law of Value to the mid-range level through relatively autonomous practices

    (a quasi-equivalent to institutions) and in turn to a third level corresponding to direct political economic

    analysis of history. Although De Sotos approach to institutions does have some valid points (the power they

    exert is real), he is unable to disentangle the practices of these institutions at an analytical level from economic

    and extra-economic practices. He therefore has to resort to idealization of the market because, unless he

    resorts to bourgeois economic theory to explain the economic conjuncture (which he does not, other than

    through his adoption of the concept of the informal economy) and thus he is left with the sole option of

    idealizing these relations, in terms of the economy, which is quite distinct in his thinking from the formal sector.

    In other words, the market is the realization of the ideal and the formal sector is the institutionalization

    through mercantilist practices of the barriers to this idea.

  • 27

    A secondary effect of his reasoning is produced when he selects from the following choices of

    conceiving social relations in the formal sector as either purely economic, both economic and political or solely

    political: he chooses the latter, thus avoiding having to explain why he does not explicate the articulation of the

    formal sector with market relations. He simply claims the latter do not exist because they are subsumed to the

    imperative of the mercantilist regime of the elites which he views as being solely politically constituted. As a

    result the category, formal sector, is a quasi-historical, quasi-political sphere with merchant exchange, which is

    populated by a prototypical social actor, the merchant elite, leaving one to wonder who does the real work.

    Who works in this formal sector, only merchants? Who buys their wares, only merchants?

    There is some disingenuousness on the part of De Soto in extricating the Peruvian formal sector from

    the effects of FDI investment, its subordination to the dictates of institutions such as the IMF and World Bank

    and ignoring the contradictions involved with the fact that Peruvian exports are primarily comprised of natural

    resources.38

    Very pointedly, he dismisses contemporary scholarship which argues that Latin America is

    generally an area in which first colonialism and now transnational corporations have heavily exploited the

    people and ransacked natural resources. This is a serious flaw because one look at Perus trade balance is

    sufficiently indicative of its dependence upon the export of its resources, while at the same time being the

    recipient of large blocks of foreign direct investment.39

    Instead, when this problem is viewed as a point of

    analysis at a mid-range level, then, strictly speaking, transnational corporations along with some intervention

    38 I see FDI as a euphemism for neo-colonization processes which continue the ransacking of resources and

    exploitation of populations which began under Spanish colonization (Martin 2007, 217); but now have the

    patina and credentials of development while in collusion with local political and economic power brokers.

    39 Figures for 2000-2005 show that Peru has maintained a trade deficit despite its heavy exports of copper,

    gold and fishmeal, and that the main recipient of these goods is the US. These figures also show the US as

    being the main supplier of consumer goods imported into Peru (Economist Intelligence Unit, Nov 23 2005). This

    begs the question of how repatriation of profits is reflected in these accounts and whether these are tied to a

    differential foreign exchange rate and, furthermore, of how the role of tariffs on protected imports is

    connected to FDI. These types of questions challenge the theory that the Peruvian economy is dominated by a

    formal sector comprised only of criollo elites.

  • 28

    by dominant nation states of the global north become the primary instruments of neo-colonization of the

    global south in their quest for the three elementary components of capitalist production: cheap labour, natural

    resources and agricultural products.

    De Soto speaks as if all local criollo profits (national elites) were reinvested within the Peruvian

    formal sector and blatantly ignores the fact that criollo elites have the ability to export their venture capitals

    to the global north. In actuality, the flight of local venture capital has been a serious problem throughout Latin

    America and has resulted from the efforts on the part of elites to invest in hard currencies. With this move,

    criollo venture capital is tied to the vagaries of the financial markets of the global north and thus, criollo elites

    lose whatever vestiges of merchant independence they would have had otherwise, and now become

    completely immersed in every crisis facing the global north.

    The formal/modern sector framework is set up in such a way that it ignores the causal factors

    attending to the exploitation of labour and natural resources as a result of the devastating effects of neo-

    colonization of Perus society. De Soto appears too concerned with analyzing the relationship between

    mercantilism and the formal sector while ignoring the nefarious effects on Perus economy of the shenanigans

    of direct foreign investment. Add to this the schizophrenia of the IMF and WB, at one time demanding

    development through the copycat industrialization scheme of criollo import substitution industries (ISI) where

    foreign markets were not opened for these products, and now the counter-intuitive move to ISI through neo-

    liberal decentralization which De Soto advocates in his position against regulation.

    De Sotos conception of the formal sector is an exaggerated glossing over what constitutes the driving

    force behind Perus economy, primarily comprised of exports provided by foreign mining corporations

    (particularly gold and copper) and fisheries production (in 1994 Peru became the worlds second-largest fishing

    nation earning one billion US dollars in export earnings (Economist Intelligence Unit , Nov 23 2005). By

    delimiting the formal sector to an institutional form, De Soto also glosses over the political economy of Peru

  • 29

    and the extent to which these industries are fully under foreign control.40

    Granted, it is completely beyond the

    scope of this thesis to enter into an analysis of the effects of the exports of the mining and fishing industries to

    the Peruvian economy, but one would expect that, since De Soto is making an argument for the formal sector,

    he would at least engage with some of the more obvious contradictions of the Peruvian economy (although

    perhaps he puts himself in this position by chauvinistically attributing a totalizing self-contained merchant

    structure in his conception of the Peruvian formal sector). This will be discussed in Chapter 3 on the informal

    economy, his interest centers on one economic indicator, the amount of GDP produced by the formal sector

    and lack of statistics on the informal economy. This focus makes him appear indifferent to what constitutes the

    dynamic or the working relationship between the entrepreneurial class and the workers that sustain that

    sector, since one will have to assume it is not all completely mechanized.

    To conclude, in order to achieve clarity and if we are to think of the specificities of nation states and

    their internal economies, unless there is a conception of the social relations which attend to capitalism, in any

    of its phases, and a distinction is made between the linkages between political and economic institutions and

    their specific practices within these phases, it is quite easy to conflate very different causations into the

    analysis of social conditions such as occurs in the analysis of the formal economy in Peru by De Soto, where

    everything takes place either within the formal sector, or the informal economy in conformity with their

    respective institutional paths.

    40 Newmont Mining Corp. (NEM) has a 51.35% stake in Yanacocha, while Buenaventura SAA holds a 43.65%

    share in what is one of the world's largest gold mines. The World Bank's International Finance Corp. holds the

    rest. The Anta mina operation went into commercial production in late 2001, requiring an investment of more

    than $2.0 billion. Its owners are: BHP Billiton with a 33.75% stake; Miranda Inc.-Falconbridge (NERD) with

    another 33.75%; Tack Cominco Corp. (TEK.B.T) with 22.5% and Mitsubishi Corp. (MIB.TO) with 10% (Kozak

    2007).

  • 30

    In the next section I engage with Tokmans work which I consider a critical response to De Soto, and

    which is of particular interest in the context of this discussion since he also is a Peruvian who engages with the

    problematique at the level of the informal economy in Peru and Latin America.

    Beyond Regulation Tokman and PREALC

    Tokman sees the problem of earlier research on the informal sector and De Sotos own work as rooted

    in the false compartmentalization and dichotomous relation between the formal and informal economy (see

    Chapter 3 for the genealogy of these concepts). In formulating his theoretical framework, Tokman uses the

    formal sector and modern sector as homonyms being comprised of business and merchant activity both of

    which operate in the realm of legality and being conjunctural both are mediated by the juridico legal

    regulatory apparatus of the nation state. His work contrasts directly with De Sotos in that he articulates a

    clearer conception of, at least what he believes, constitutes the internal relations of the formal sector and

    recognizes that these are neither segregated nor occur in a vacuum apart from the informal economy.

    For Tokman the formal economy structurally organizes production and productive work-forces at a

    global level. He suggests that after the 1980s this sector adopted a different flexible schema of production,

    the effects of which have been causally implicated in the severe fragmentation of the labour force.41

    He

    suggests that the prime motivating factor in the move towards flexibility in the formal economy derived from

    the need to reduce labour costs. The aim of flexibility in production was to decentralize away from vast

    industrial sites into smaller units of production which could be located where costs would be at the lowest

    level. Flexibility and decentralization created a massive surplus population of workers, giving the formal

    41 By fragmentation he intends the displacement of the workers outside the wage relation to temporary work,

    if and when available, outside production within a tertiary service sector or self provisioning activities. The

    labour force becomes fragmented as it becomes redundant to industrial production whereby these workers

    only alternative is to find income opportunities through non-waged part time contract work or investing in

    micro-enterprise.

  • 31

    economy the opportunity to open or change production sites at will. Tokman argues that labour costs have

    been kept low because the formal economy has, through its regulatory apparatus, been successful in erecting

    blocks that have tended to stall, avoid or diminish trade union power in opposing this restructuring and

    outsourcing of work projects. In addition, he argues that the onset of new technologies has further decreased

    the reliance of the formal sector on living labour (Tokman 1992, 3-5).

    For Tokman there are two vectors of regulation that impact on relations in the economy, these being:

    (a) the commercial and industrial sectors private norms and standards; and (b) the state regulatory apparatus

    (Tokman 1992, 4-5). Tokman takes the view that in developing countries competitive pressures of excess labour

    push down incomes and generate subsistence activities that are not linked to expanding modern sectors, but

    cater to low income markets which lack access to capital, technology and skills (Tokman 1992, 4). He argues

    that socio-economic activities do not converge in polarized forms, rather, they take place in a continuum of

    legality within which the formal economy is located as the dominant sphere of economic enterprise. This

    continuum expresses the relationship between the formal and informal economy in terms of legality and

    illegality and Tokman argues that both formal and informal economies fall within a grey area of this

    continuum. (Tokman 1992, 4-4).

    With this methodological premise, I believe Tokman aims to solve the problem of the non-equivalence

    of two very distinct social relations (a problem which results in juxtaposing them within a dichotomous

    relationship, such as occurs in the work of De Soto), economic exchange and the conformance to legal norms.

    Contrary to De Soto, he suggests that a graduated horizontal continuum explains the necessary differentiations

    in the realm between legality and illegality42

    and the market expresses other relations which cannot be

    captured within the intra-relationship, formal/informal sector. For Tokm