90
Employee participation and company performance

Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

  • Upload
    dokiet

  • View
    214

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

Employee participation and

company performance

Page 2: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

This publication can be provided in alternative formats, suchas large print, Braille, audiotape and on disk. Please contact:Communications Department, Joseph Rowntree Foundation,The Homestead, 40 Water End, York YO30 6WP.Tel: 01904 615905. Email: [email protected]

Page 3: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

Employee participation andcompany performanceA review of the literature

Juliette Summers and Jeff Hyman

Page 4: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

The Joseph Rowntree Foundation has supported this project as part of its programme of researchand innovative development projects, which it hopes will be of value to policy makers, practitionersand service users. The facts presented and views expressed in this report are, however, those of theauthors and not necessarily those of the Foundation.

Joseph Rowntree FoundationThe Homestead40 Water EndYork YO30 6WPWebsite: www.jrf.org.uk

© University of Aberdeen 2005

First published 2005 by the Joseph Rowntree Foundation

All rights reserved. Reproduction of this report by photocopying or electronic means for non-commercial purposes is permitted. Otherwise, no part of this report may be reproduced, adapted,stored in a retrieval system or transmitted by any means, electronic, mechanical, photocopying, orotherwise without the prior written permission of the Joseph Rowntree Foundation.

ISBN 1 85935 298 7 (paperback)ISBN 1 85935 299 5 (pdf: available at www.jrf.org.uk)

Work and Opportunity Series No. 33

A CIP catalogue record for this report is available from the British Library.

Cover design by Adkins Design

Prepared and printed by:York Publishing Services Ltd64 Hallfield RoadLayerthorpeYork YO31 7ZQTel: 01904 430033; Fax: 01904 430868; Website: www.yps-publishing.co.uk

Further copies of this report, or any other JRF publication, can be obtained either from the JRF website(www.jrf.org.uk/bookshop/) or from our distributor, York Publishing Services Ltd, at the above address.

Page 5: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

Contents

1 Introduction 1The new economy 1Financial and work-related participation 2Background to growing interest in participation and its effects 4

2 Claims made for employee participation 8Economic rationale 8Social rationale 11Governmental rationale 12

3 Outcomes of participation 14Contradictory evidence 14Explanatory processes for different outcomes 16Degree of employee influence 23Generalisability of participation effects 33Participation and workplace equality 35Summary 43Note 44

4 Policy implications and conclusions 45Implications of government policy and proposals 45Implications for equal opportunity 47Implications of European policy 49

5 Conclusions 52

Bibliography 54

Appendix 1: Methodological problems 70

Appendix 2: Further research 72

Appendix 3: Glossary of terms 74

Page 6: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the
Page 7: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

1

The new economy

The past 20 years have seen vast and possiblyunprecedented change in all the majoreconomies. These changes have been welldocumented and embrace the widespreadadoption of information technologies,deregulation of both product and labourmarkets, decline of heavy manufacturing andascendancy of service industries and growingglobal competition for the provision of goodsand services. Continuous change in product andservice markets combined with tighteningquality demands require employers to seekmore efficient and flexible means of production.They seek the often contradictory elements ofemployee commitment and disposability, oftendisguised by terms such as ‘employability’ and‘new employment contract’.

Partly in response to these economicdemands and partly as a consequence of othersocietal shifts, there have been correspondingchanges in the composition and activities of theworkforce. Most obvious has been the decline intrade union membership, activity and influence(Cully et al. 1999, pp. 85–96). A further shift isthat the labour force is becoming increasinglyqualified as older non-qualified staff give wayto growing ranks of university and college-educated newcomers to the labour market(Wolf, 2002). Also apparent is the rise in theproportion of women in the paid labour market(Wolf, 2002, pp. 24–5) and, associated with this,growing emphasis on part-time and flexibleforms of labour (Wolf, 2002, pp. 33, 143). A morediverse, potentially less secure, workforce alsoraises questions of equality of treatment andrights at work, with the danger that minority orvulnerable groups will lack the resources to

participate effectively in workplace affairs,thereby reinforcing their peripheral status.While these have been global trends, it is in theUK that these shifts have been especiallymarked.

Many recent publications reflect and confirmthese changes. Representative books includeScarborough (1996) and Newell et al. (2002),both of which deal with the challenges toorganisations of managing knowledge work orexpertise, and the Open University Reader onManaging Knowledge (Little et al., 2002). Stewart(1997) is quoted at the opening of this book:

Intellectual capital – not natural resources,machinery, or even financial capital – has becomethe one indispensable asset of corporations.(Little et al., 2002, p. 1)

For employers of scarce and highly-qualifiedlabour, commitment, rather than control, hasostensibly become the key objective of peoplemanagement (see Walton, 1985).

Under these changing conditions, it is notsurprising that concern by employers, policymakers and employees themselves insafeguarding and promoting their interests hasbeen reflected in different approaches toemployee participation. Governments mustbalance the needs of a competitive economywith welfare of their citizens. Employers seekproductive efficiency and recognise that themeans to this is increasingly locked in the headsof the people they employ. Well-qualifiedemployees seek elusive objectives of jobsatisfaction, stability and life-enhancingemployment while a more pressing priority forless advantaged and more vulnerableemployees may simply be to gain secureemployment and reasonable treatment from

1 Introduction

Page 8: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

2

Employee participation and company performance

their employers. The rise of global institutionspresents other problems for workers ascorporate decisions become more distant fromthe staff that they employ: a decision made toclose a plant in one country may have beenmade many thousands of miles away with littleopportunity for indigenous employees tocombat or even question decisions thatdramatically affect their lives. Detachment fromthe company may also represent a problem forgrowing numbers of homeworkers and forthose whose jobs demand high levels ofmobility (Doyle and Nathan, 2001; Felsteadet al., 2003).

Employee participation can therefore be seenas an umbrella title under which can be found awide range of practices, potentially servingdifferent interests. Any exploration of ‘employeeparticipation’ has therefore to encompass termsas wide-ranging as industrial democracy, co-operatives, employee share schemes, employeeinvolvement, human resource management(HRM) and high-commitment work practices,collective bargaining, employee empowerment,team working and partnership to capture thefull picture of participation in the UK(definitions of these terms can be found in theglossary in Appendix 3 of this report). There areobvious problems associated with having somany different interpretations, not least thatthese terms are frequently used interchangeablyand have different meanings for differentdisciplines and authors. In consequence,outcomes associated with differentinterpretations of participation also vary andadvantage accruing to one social partner maynot necessarily be perceived or welcomed asuniversally advantageous by other partnerswith interest in the employment relationship. In

other words, participation can be seen as‘contested terrain’.

Financial and work-related participation

Operationally, the term ‘employee participation’can be divided into two primary categories:financial and work-related participation.

Financial participation

Financial participation schemes take two maindimensions and both are important from apolicy perspective. The first approach involvesdistribution of shares to employees, based onthe assumption that share ownership inducespositive attitudinal and behavioural responses.In Britain, share-based schemes can be classifiedinto two principal approaches, one whereemployees are offered shareholdings as part ofremuneration and a second where employeeshave an option to buy shares in their owncompany. The first of the distributive schemeswas introduced in 1978 as the so-calledapproved deferred share trust (ADST)programme in which companies distributeshares according to a stipulated formula to allfull-time employees who satisfy eligibilitycriteria. The option approach, first introduced in1980, allows employees to buy shares in theircompanies at favourable rates through anInland Revenue approved savings institution,such as a building society. Both approaches havesubsequently been improved financially andparticipation has been extended to part-timeemployees. A derivative option approach wasthe much derided (though heavily patronised)and now terminated ‘discretionary’ (or‘executive’) share option scheme, which wasavailable only to specified (usually senior)

Page 9: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

3

Introduction

personnel by invitation. This scheme wasintroduced in 1984 and replaced in 1996 withthe more broadly based company share optionplans. In 1989, the first employee shareownership plans (ESOPs) were given statutoryapproval to go alongside ESOPs founded on acombination of earlier legislation and commonlaw precedents (see Pendleton et al., 1995a, 1998;Pendleton, 2001). These schemes can offer muchhigher share proportions to employees than theoriginal Inland Revenue approved all-employeeschemes and perhaps, for that reason, havefailed to gain much popularity with employers.Details of these main approaches can be foundin the glossary in Appendix 3.

A second dimension of financialparticipation concerns flexibility of pay, wherean element of remuneration varies withprofitability or other appropriate performancemeasures. A recent example was cash-basedprofit-related pay (PRP), in which income taxrelief was offered to schemes that met InlandRevenue requirements. Some 14,500 schemeswere active at their peak in 1997, with tax reliefcalculated at £1.5 billion (IDS, 1998). Theescalation in the loss of income tax promptedthe Government to phase out tax relief on PRP,concluding in January 2000 with no furtherrelief.

Work-related participation

Work-related participation comes in a numberof forms: individual or collective, and direct (i.e.face-to-face) or indirect (i.e. via a representative)participation. These can be grouped into two

main types of work-related participation:traditional collective participation, which aimsfor a more equitable distribution of powerthroughout the organisation, and ‘new’ forms of

participation, which are more direct andindividualised and have tended to grow out ofmanagement strategies, such as HRM, aimed tosecure employee commitment to organisationalobjectives through sophisticated communicationprocedures and individualised reward anddevelopmental initiatives such as performanceappraisal linked to performance-related pay.

Possibly the most clear-cut example oftraditional collective participation is the co-operative, where participation includes bothownership and control elements (Pencavel,2001). However, relatively few employees workin co-operatives and the bulk of the literature onemployee participation deals with the moreconventionally organised and owned firms thathave introduced participation measures. Ofthese firms, the ones that provide for employeeshare ownership (ESOP) most closelyapproximates the co-operative, with itsemphasis on employee ownership. However,unlike the co-operative, the ESOP form does notguarantee equitable collective participation,such as one-person-one-vote or majorityemployee ownership (Pendleton, 2001). ESOPsin the UK have varied from 100 per centemployee ownership to insignificant levels ofworker ownership or involvement (Pendletonet al., 1995a). Unlike most other forms ofcollective participation, co-operatives, becauseof the small size of the majority of co-operatives(an average of under ten workers) tend to usedirect forms of collective participation. Inaddition, for reasons of economies of scale interms of numbers of workers and also from apolicy perspective, indirect collectiveparticipation is the principal collectiveparticipation form. Collective bargaining, forinstance, still covers 45 per cent of enterprises in

Page 10: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

4

Employee participation and company performance

the UK (Cully et al., 1999), though theproportion of employees covered by negotiatedagreements has been in continuous decline sincethe early 1980s (Heery et al., 2003). Collectivebargaining permits employee participation innegotiations via elected representatives or full-time officials, usually as part of a trade unionnetwork. Other forms of indirect collectiveparticipation can include social partnershipagreements with trade unions, works councils,co-determination agreements and jointconsultation committees.

Second, there are the ‘new’ forms ofparticipation, which are predominantly direct,such as briefings groups, and individual innature, e.g. attitude surveys or suggestionschemes. Most of these forms are conflated intothe term employee involvement, or employeeempowerment, and most of them can beincluded under HRM strategies or approaches.These forms of direct participation have becomemore important to managers seeking to gainvoluntary commitment from employees toorganisational goals (Walton, 1985) at times ofheightened competitive pressures and workinsecurity. As we indicated in Chapter 1, anassociated impulse propelling managerstowards a commitment-based regime derivesfrom the growth of so-called knowledge sectorsof the economy in which the means ofproduction are ‘locked in the head’ of valuedemployees (Castells, 2000). Hence, considerableacademic and managerial attention has beenaddressed in recent years to the identificationand value of ‘high-commitment work practices’(see, for example, Huselid, 1995), especially innew knowledge-based sectors of the economy(Frenkel et al., 1999).

Levels of participation

In addition to the forms of work-relatedparticipation outlined above, employeeparticipation in conventionally owned andorganised firms can be task-related (i.e. at thework station) or strategic (i.e. at board orcorporate level), and participation at either ofthese levels can be communicative, consultativeor negotiative (for a full discussion on formsand processes of participation see Heller et al.,1998).

Background to growing interest in

participation and its effects

The growing emphasis on all forms of flexibilityin industry in response to competitivepressures, subsequent changes in workorganisation and the current political climate isreflected in the emerging models ofparticipation. These models tend to reflect (andpromote) both the individualisation of theemployment relationship, and the newpartnerships being encouraged betweenemployees, unions and employers.

Market liberalisation

Over the past 20 years, the employmentrelations climate in the UK has alteredsignificantly. The Conservative Governments’(1979–97) philosophy of ‘market liberalisation’provided the political agenda behind substantialderegulation of the labour market along withthe privatisation of many state-controlledindustries. A DTI report, Burdens on Business

(DTI, 1985), argued that the burdens imposed bycentral and local government regulations hadseriously curtailed business growth and

Page 11: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

5

Introduction

expansion, particularly for small firms. TheWhite Paper Lifting the Burden (DTI, 1985)facilitated deregulation in some 80 areasidentified in Burdens on Business. Nevertheless, ayear later, another White Paper, Building

Businesses … Not Barriers (Department ofEmployment, 1986), argued that ‘the morepeople can concentrate their energies onrunning their businesses efficiently, the betterfor jobs’ and recommended another 81proposals for deregulation. Those regulationsthat were left were placed under continuousscrutiny by special Deregulation Units, whichhad been established in individual governmentdepartments to assist the Enterprise andDeregulation Unit, a central task force forderegulation located in the then Department ofEmployment. A substantial component of thispolitical agenda included the encouragement ofemployee share ownership in order to lubricatethe sell-off of publicly owned companies andutilities to the private sector. In addition,participation in the form of flexible pay,especially performance and profit-related payschemes, were encouraged as a means to loosenwage rigidity and to encourage flexibility in thelabour market.

Workplace relations

As a result of market liberalisation policies, majorchanges have taken place in the form and degreeof workplace relations. Trade unions have seensignificant reductions in their influence andmembership, and there can be little doubt that,since the 1980s, we have witnessed afundamental transformation of labour relationsin the UK. The coverage of union representationand collective agreements has shrunk, but,initially, shop-floor trade unionism appeared to

hold up in the private sector, at least in majormanufacturing plants. Signs of the erosion ofcollective bargaining increased towards the endof the 1980s, when a significant contraction in thecoverage of collective agreements, a narrowing ofthe scope of bargaining and a decline in thedepth of union involvement were reported. Somedramatic examples of institutionaldeconstruction were in the public sector, whereunions were marginalised and in some casescompletely excluded (Winterton and Winterton,1993). Consequently, collective bargaining in itstraditional form has been significantly weakened:for example, union recognition fell from 66 percent in 1984 to 47 per cent in 1998, andworkplaces with no union members increasedfrom just 27 per cent in 1984 to 47 per cent in 1998(Cully et al., 1999). Union membership has alsobeen in constant decline since 1980, onlyreversing slightly in 1999–2000, but notsufficiently to influence membership density (i.e.the proportion of the unionised workforce),which has been in continuous decline for aquarter of a century. By 2001, union densitycovered just over one in four of the workingpopulation (Waddington, 2003, p. 220).

However, it is significant that data from theWorkplace Employee Relations Survey 1998(WERS98) also suggests that the future fororganisational performance may lie with theunions. WERS98 reports a positive associationbetween high performance and a strong,recognised union, and also between partnershiporganisations and high productivity growth(Cully et al., 1999). Set against this background,recent inclusion of the trade unions ingovernment consultation exercises is asignificant step. In the UK Employment Action

Plan (EAP) for 1998 (DfEE, 1998), the most

Page 12: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

6

Employee participation and company performance

significant examples of the use of socialpartnership in the formation of policy were: theEAP itself; the Fairness at Work White Paper(DTI, 1998); the National Minimum Wage (LowPay Commission); and the Working TimeDirective. In all examples, the TUC and the CBIwere included at the consultation stages and allhave subsequently been formally enacted.

‘New’ participation

Mirroring the decline in traditional sectors ofthe economy where collective bargainingflourished, the proportion of companies using‘new’ forms of employee participation has beengrowing in the UK (Cully et al., 1999). Withgovernment tax incentive support, employershave continued to be encouraged to adoptemployee share allocation systems.Encouragement of financial participation hasbeen accompanied by the spread of ‘newmanagement’ philosophies and strategies.According to WERS98, well over half ofworkplaces with over 25 employees have five ormore of a possible 16 ‘new’ management and

participation practices (Table 1). However, forsmaller firms, only 28 per cent exhibit thesetendencies (Table 2). The spread of newmanagement practices is demonstrated by theWERS98 survey, where ‘only 2 per cent ofmanagers reported none of these practices orschemes in place whatsoever’ (Cully et al., 1999,p. 11). However, employee respondents wereless enthusiastic than their managers aboutthese measures.

Accompanying these changes has been ascramble among the parties involved in theemployment relationship (employer, employeeand state) to claim the meaning and form of‘participation’. When it comes to therestructuring of work organisation, the TUC andCBI share the view that workplace partnershipsare a positive move in the promotion of newforms of work organisation, thoughuncertainties remain as to what partnershipmight actually mean to both parties. They doagree, though, that this new form will ‘becharacterised by high performance, high skilllevels and high trust between workers and their

Table 1 Use of ‘new’ management practices and employee participation schemes

New management practice % of workplaces over 25 workers

Most employees work in formally designated teams 65Operates a system of team briefing for groups of employees 61Staff attitude survey conducted in the last five years 45Problem-solving groups (e.g. quality circles) 42Regular meetings of entire workforce 37Profit-sharing scheme operated for non-managerial employees 30Workplace-level joint consultative committee 28Most supervisors trained in employee relations skills 27Employee share ownership scheme for non-managerial employees 15Individual performance-related pay for non-managerial employees 11

Source: Cully et al. (1999)

Page 13: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

7

Introduction

employers’ (DfEE, 1998, p. 31), including‘flexibility in working time’ (DfEE, 1998, p. 32),thus ensuring ‘flexibility with security’.

The social partners also called on theGovernment to promote and disseminate best-practice models, including the furtherdevelopment of effective relationships between

the social partners, an action that has beenreflected in the establishment of the DTIPartnership Fund, which disburses grants up tothe value of £50,000 to assist organisations todevelop partnership arrangements. To date (July2003) some 160 projects have been approved,supported by £5 million of funding.

Table 2 Small-firm employee involvement and employee relations

New management practice % of workplacesbetween 10 and 25 workers

No ‘new’ management practices or employee involvement schemes 8Five or more of these practices or schemes 28Joint consultative committee at workplace 17Union presence 22Union recognition 12Worker representative at workplace 10Employees with high or very high job satisfaction 61High productivity 33

Source: Cully et al. (1999)

Page 14: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

8

There are numerous different rationales forintroducing employee participation, oftencompeting. Poutsma (2001) identified fourdominant approaches embracing humanistic,power-sharing, organisational efficiency andredistribution of results rationales. These can besubsumed under three main operationalrationales, namely economic, social andgovernmental. Each rationale derives fromdifferent conceptual bases, such that predictedoutcomes of participative initiatives can varyaccordingly. Each position will be considered inturn.

Economic rationale

The literature provides ample evidence of thesuccessful use of participation to improveoverall company performance. However, it isthe means by which participation influencescompany performance that provides the crucialexplanatory factors. The association has beenmade, based on some evidence, thatparticipation alters employee attitudes to workand to management, increasing employeeassociation with management values andconsequently improving employee motivationto work towards achieving these goals. There isalso some evidence that management attitudestowards employees may also be favourablyinfluenced by participative regimes underwhich managers and supervisors adopt more‘facilitative’ approaches towards theirsubordinates (Marchington, 2000).

Conversely, in what will be seen as adominant theme, other studies have indicatedlittle impact from participative regimes, whether

financial or work-related, while others suggestthat any productivity enhancements may beattributable to pressures from other economicand organisational factors such asorganisational downsizing.

Financial participation

An economic rationale is most closely associatedwith financial participation. Financialparticipation measures promise to exertfundamentally positive effects at the workplacethrough removing, or at least blurring,boundaries between employer and employee byoffering the latter ‘a stake in the firm’ (Creighet al., 1981). Shareholder status is believed topositively influence the behaviour of individualemployees towards the organisation (Bradleyand Nejad, 1989), while loosening collectivistties. Employee share ownership and a stake incompany profitability produce a feeling ofownership (Pendleton, 2001) and this can leadto positive employee orientations and highlevels of commitment. While financialparticipation can provide a route to results-based remuneration for employees, it has beennoted by Heller et al. (1998, p. 20) that ‘employeeowned companies are often undemocratic, sinceemployees have few control rights’ under thesesystems of participation.

A considerable amount of statistical researchhas been undertaken to examine links betweenshare schemes with company performance (see,for example, Logue and Yates 2001). A recentNorth American study by Sesil et al. (2002) isespecially relevant, as it examined the role ofshare schemes in a set of ‘new economy’knowledge-based companies, i.e. those

2 Claims made for employee

participation

Page 15: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

9

Claims made for employee participation

companies predicted to become dominant in theUK economy. The second area of relevance isbased on the assumption that knowledgeworkers will be in a favourable position toinfluence company performance (Newell et al.,2002; Sesil et al., 2002, p. 274). Comparing sharescheme companies with their non-sharecounterparts, the authors found greater addedvalue per employee, but not greater new-knowledge generation (Sesil et al., 2002, p. 289).They also offered a number of caveats to theirstudy: the mechanisms for the higher addedvalue were not known; also, while added valuewas higher, it was not known whether the sharescheme was the causal factor. The authors alsomake a valid general point: ‘the “arrow ofcausality” issue plagues research of this typeand there are no easy ways to address the issue’(Sesil et al., 2002, p. 290). Third, there were dataand measurement shortcomings in that theresearchers could not be certain that theschemes were broad based, i.e. distributed to amajority of staff.

A number of American studies have beenconducted by share scheme evangelists, keen todemonstrate associations between shares andperformance. Thus Logue and Yates (2001), whodedicate their book to employee owners ‘whoare building a better way of doing businessevery day’, aim to identify the ‘best’ employeeownership practices to ensure optimum levelsof economic performance. Examining a sampleof 270 mainly small companies, positive linksbetween share schemes and companyperformance were found. There were doubts,however: material was gathered from seniormanagers who were instrumental in theestablishment of the scheme. More worrying,perhaps, was that other intervening variables

(such as threats of shutdown or takeover)appeared to influence the associations.

A further worry with these generally ‘rosy’images of share schemes is that very few studieshave examined their impact in adverseconditions. In the USA, for example, rather thanshares enriching employees for their retirement,the Enron collapse has effectively impoverishedthem. Also the collapse of United Airlines, aprominent employee-owned company, hasprompted serious questions as to whether thelevels of employee shareholding contributed tothe company’s collapse(www.ownershipassociates.com/united_questions.shtm). Less dramatically, inthe UK some company share values havedeclined substantially in the past few months.London Bridge Software, a ‘knowledge’company, employs 200 people and offered shareoptions to employees. Share values peaked at£10 in August 2000 but, by November 2002, hadsubsided to a value of 35p, provoking acompany executive to comment in The Guardian

newspaper that: ‘their options are underwater atthe moment ... It is something we are looking at– how do we keep these people incentivised?’.

Work-related participation

From another perspective, decision-makingparticipation may enhance employee–employerco-operation through team working,communication and other ‘supportive humanresource polices’ (Levine, 1995; Blasi et al., 1996).It is frequently assumed in the managementliterature that the informational effects ofparticipative forms of work organisation leadnot only to more worker participation inorganisational decision making, but also, as aconsequence, to greater job satisfaction, higher

Page 16: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

10

Employee participation and company performance

employee motivation and a harmonious labourrelations climate (Thornley, 1981; Bradley andGelb, 1983; Cressey and Williams, 1990).

Another argument in favour ofmanagement’s enforced move towardsincreased employee participation, and theassumed changes it brings about in employeebehaviour, is the growing emphasis placed oncustomer service, which calls on committedemployees rather than coerced labour toprovide. According to Ramsay et al. (1998, p. 3),service ‘requires employee internalisation of amanagement-designed culture of commitment ifit is not to be based on exhausting andexpensive supervision’ (see also Jones andSvejnar, 1982; Defourney et al., 1985; Cohen andQuarrey, 1986; Estrin et al., 1987; Jones, 1987;Tyson and Levine, 1990; Bonin et al., 1993;Cotton, 1993; Bryson and Millward, 1997).

Improved company performance

Consequent benefits for the employer springfrom the assumption that workers will want towork harder and more efficiently as a result ofgreater organisational commitment, which inturn stimulates greater worker flexibility andquality of output. The employer also benefitsfrom the opportunity to harness workers’knowledge and experience. Workers will knowthe most efficient way of organising their work,resulting in optimum productivity (Cooke,1994), and management will benefit from theaddition of ‘valuable information about worktasks’ (Bryson and Millward, 1997, p. 29) andthe ability to access worker talents in decisionmaking (Jones, 1987). Under company-inspiredfinancial participation schemes, organisationalperformance may benefit without the scheme

posing any obvious threat to management.The sum of these changes is seen to be an

improvement in employee productivity andflexibility, and thus in company performance.The claim by Fernie and Metcalf (1995) thatunion presence adversely affects productivityrepresents one common view of ‘new’participative measures as a means to increaseproductivity; however, this view is challengedby many observers. One example of ‘new’participation is Japanese-style management,which is often presented as an alternative to

adversarial collective bargaining. This managementstyle is typified by low levels of unionisation,low levels of apparent conflict and relativelyhigh levels of work participation in local (i.e.work-station or task-level) decision making.This form of employee involvement ispurported to lead to increased levels offunctional flexibility (Cressey and Williams,1990).

Participation reduces company costs

There is evidence that both financial and work-related participation can deter or delay quitsfrom the company and lower absenteeism rates.Wilson and Peel (1990) found that shareschemes reduce labour turnover. A decrease inlabour turnover will reduce recruitment andtraining costs for the organisation (Kessler andPurcell, 1992). Cost savings may result fromreductions in absenteeism rates. Furthermore, amore harmonious labour relations climate isalso claimed to reduce costs to the company ofindustrial disagreements and to permit thefaster acceptance and implementation oforganisational change.

Page 17: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

11

Claims made for employee participation

Based on these expectations, managementcan be seen to have a primarily economicrationale for the introduction of participationinto the workplace. Nevertheless, there are stilla wide range of participation measures formanagement to choose from, collective orindividual, direct or indirect.

Social rationale

Participation and quality of working life

Not all management-led initiatives have directeconomic gains as their sole or primary focus,for it is clear that managers and employers canintroduce participation in order to also improveworking conditions (Osterman, 1994), while therare few are willing to hand ownership and(perhaps) control of their firms to the workforce,as with, for example, the Scott BaderCommonwealth and Tullis Russell paper mills.However, for participation schemes with asocial rationale to succeed, attitude changesamong all management, as well as workers, arecrucial.

Participation improves equality

Unlike most management rationales forintroducing participation, socially focusedefforts centre also on the democratic and equalopportunities (between workers and betweenworkers and management) basis forparticipation, as in, for example, co-operatives.

Role of the unions

The social rationale is also strong inparticipation initiatives that have relied onunion support, e.g. management/employeebuyouts. These forms of participation are oftenthe result of bargained outcomes between the

main interest groups, management and tradeunion and therefore combine social witheconomic rationales. Employee buyouts in theUK in their most recent form have beenestablished as ESOPs, the majority of which inthe last ten to 15 years have been the result ofthe privatisation of the bus industry (Pendleton,2001). However, this form of social participationhas proved to be relatively unstable and short-lived, with the majority of the bus ESOPsreturning to conventional ownership(Pendleton, 2001; Summers, 2004). Thisdemonstrates a long-standing problem facingsome worker-led participation schemes, thatthey are inclined to ‘degenerate’ intoconventionally organised firms (Pencavel, 2001).This hypothesis maintains that a democratic,participative firm will invariably fail to survivein this form and will degenerate into aconventionally organised and controlledenterprise in order to remain economicallyviable (Jensen and Meckling, 1979). Whereemployee ownership schemes are designed asjob-save efforts (see Pendleton et al., 1995a),economic necessities often overtake the social,either resulting in firm closure (such as the BennCo-ops, and Fakenham Enterprises) or sale to anew owner.

Union involvement in ‘new’ forms ofparticipation, without ownership, tends to fallinto the category of social partnership

arrangements. Both the TUC and the CBIsupport partnership moves (DfEE, 1998)because they encompass both economic and thesocial rationales. For this reason, governmentparticipation policy is also focused onpromoting social partnership programmes, suchas Partnerships at Work, as we saw above.

Page 18: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

12

Employee participation and company performance

Governmental rationale

Wider effects

Government interventions in participationencompass both the economic and socialrationales and are designed to have nation-wideeffects that benefit the wider community. Thegovernment rationale behind the introduction ofparticipation policies is therefore to improve

national economic efficiency while also enhancingthe work experience. Because participation isbelieved to offer benefits from both social andeconomic perspectives, it is not surprising thatboth the Conservative and Labour Governmentshave supported the growth of employeeparticipation, though from rather differentperspectives.

UK policy

Recent policy moves in the UK, such as theEmployment Relations Act 1999, the UK

Employment Action Plan (DfEE, 1998), theCompetitiveness White Paper and theChancellor’s Pre-Budget Statement (HM Treasury,1998a) have variously addressed issues ofemployee participation. However, theseinitiatives follow notably different ideologicalpaths to previous participation-oriented policyproposals. The first significant appearance ofpolicy was the 1977 Bullock Report (Bullock,1977), shortly followed by the then LabourGovernment’s 1978 White Paper on IndustrialDemocracy. Both papers emphasisedrepresentative forms of employee participation;the Report, supported by the majority ofmembers of the Bullock Committee, suggestedthe introduction of worker directors andemphasised the ‘essential role of trade union

organisations in the process of industrialdemocracy’. However, the CBI and TUC failedto agree over the contents of the report (Cresseyet al., 1981, p. 2) and, a year later, a thirdIndustrial Democracy White Paper glossed overthe role of collective bargaining but stressed therole of employee involvement in ‘thedevelopment of corporate strategy’. With thearrival of a Conservative Government in 1979,participation policies took a markedly differentturn. Participation became focused onindividual efforts linked to organisationalflexibility, especially through individualshareholding, which was helped along by theraft of privatisations during the 1980s. TheGovernment’s negative attitude towards tradeunions also meant that traditional collectiveroutes to participation were weakened andmanagement-led efforts were encouraged,especially those directed at communication andtask-level decision making, for example,through team work. With the return of a LabourGovernment in 1997, a more diverseparticipation policy has re-emerged, though innoticeably restrained and voluntaristic forms.While individual shareholding (or‘stakeholding’) remains an important policyelement, the Government’s rhetoric of‘flexibility with security’ has led it to adopt a‘third way’ philosophy. This has meant bothcontinuity and change, with policies supportingboth direct, individual participation and alsorepresentative forms of participation throughthe promotion of a new relationship betweenemployers and trade unions – ‘socialpartnerships’ (Guest and Peccei, 2001).

Page 19: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

13

Claims made for employee participation

European Union policy

On a wider scale than UK legislative attempts,the EU has established a long-standing interestin employee participation. As in Britain, manyinitiatives foundered on differences betweenemployer and union bodies complicated at theEuropean level by conflicting member stateperspectives (Gill and Krieger, 2000). In 1975,the EU published a Green Paper on Employee

Participation in Company Structure (COM [75]150), which emphasised that ‘decisions taken byor in the enterprise can have a substantial effecton [workers’] economic circumstances’. Morerecently, in 1994, it passed a Directive, resultingfrom the Social Chapter of the Maastricht Treaty,

on ‘The Establishment of European Committeesor Procedures in Community-scaleUndertakings and Community-scale Groups ofUndertakings for the Purposes of Informing andConsulting Employees’, i.e. European workscouncils (EWCs). Of particular importance forrecent policy debates was the UK stance on theSocial Chapter, acceptance of which obligedmany firms in the UK to consult andcommunicate systematically with theirworkforce (Kersley and Martin, 1997). The TUCestimated that, with the UK opt-in, nearly 150multinational companies operating in the UKneeded to introduce consultation through theintroduction of EWCs.

Page 20: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

14

This chapter considers the effects ofparticipation schemes, not all of which achievethe outcomes desired by their originators. Theevidence for contradictory effects is examined,followed by an examination of the complexprocesses involved in translating employeeparticipation into improved companyperformance. The impact that different types ofparticipation have on these processes is theninvestigated, focusing on participation schemeswith different degrees of employee influenceand on whether participation is individualisedor collective.

Contradictory evidence

The literature supplies an impressive body ofwork that has found no association, or anegative association, between participation andcompany performance (Kelly and Kelly, 1991;Ben-Ner and Jones, 1995; Vaughan-Whitehead,1995). Even some of the literature endorsingparticipation as a means to improvedperformance offers qualified support. Forexample, Estrin et al. (1987) found that theproductivity effects of participation variedbetween industrial sectors. While they foundthat participation had an overall positive effect,the effect was not significant for the footwearindustry and only slight for the clothing sector.This variation in outcome also seems to dependsomewhat on the type of participationinvestigated. For example, Defourney et al.(1985) found that the productivity enhancementresults of co-operation were strongest inconverted firms and less so in organisationsfounded as co-operatives. This may suggest thatthe relative increase in employee influence andparticipation is an important explanatory factor.

However, Doucouliagos (1995), who also founddifferent outcomes for different forms ofparticipation, found that labour-managed firmsdemonstrated a (small) rise in productivity,whereas participation had no discernible effecton productivity in ‘participatory capitalistfirms’. This could suggest that the absolutedegree of employee influence and participationexplains some of the successes of participationschemes. Furthermore, Jones’ (1987) findings,that enforced co-determination had a negativeeffect on productivity, provides another possibleexplanatory route, that coerced participationmay not be effective.

There are also doubts about the impact ofemployee share schemes. Ramsay’s (1977)seminal work on cycles of participationcontended that management interest and actionin employee share schemes are stimulatedunder strong economic conditions and, byextension, strong labour markets and unionpotential to mobilise. Once the threat tomanagement authority passes, managementinterest in participation declines accordingly.Marchington, however, expressed doubts aboutthe cycles thesis, pointing out that the 1980s sawa big increase in participative initiatives at atime when unions were under serious politicaland economic pressure. He and his colleagueshave suggested an alternative explanation formanagement action, namely waves ofparticipation, suggesting that any participationinitiative has a life cycle in terms of influence,starting small, surging to an optimum effect,before subsiding and being overlapped bysubsequent initiatives (Ackers et al., 1992;Marchington et al., 1993).

Data examined over a considerable timeperiod, between WERS90 and WERS98, also

3 Outcomes of participation

Page 21: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

15

Outcomes of participation

suggest some contradictory results forparticipation and company performance claims.Addison and Belfield’s (2001) comparativeanalysis of the two datasets found that, whileemployee involvement increases were positivelyassociated with productivity levels for the 1990dataset, this was not replicated in the 1998survey results. On the other hand, the negativeeffect of unionism on productivity observed byFernie and Metcalf (1995, cited in Addison andBelfield, 2001) is to some extent reversed in the1998 dataset where the ‘coefficient estimate forthe union variable is both positive andstatistically significant in the productivitychange equation’ but most favourable for the‘weakest form of union presence’ (Addision andBelfield, 2001, p. 349). Furthermore, the 1998survey did not support the findings fromWERS90 (McNabb and Whitfield, 1998, p. 184,cited in Addison and Belfield, 2001) that the useof downward communication throughmanagement structures was associated withimproved financial performance.

Yet, there is some consistency between thesurveys, for example the positive associationbetween reduced quit rates and unionrecognition is replicated across the datasets,1 asis the association for reduced quit rates andproblem-solving groups. Also, WERS98supports the 1990 survey results, which found apositive effect on productivity levels andchanges in productivity for briefing groups.However, Addison and Belfield’s primaryconclusion from their analysis of thedeterminants of organisational performanceacross the two surveys is that ‘the principalregularity in estimates based on the WERS98and WERS90 surveys is their lack of consistency’(Addison and Belfield, 2001, p. 356). A significant

explanation for this suggested by Addison andBelfield is that organisations that had adoptedemployee involvement in time for the 1990survey may have been operating in differenteconomic conditions to 1998 and so the resultsof employee involvement for 1990 may not havebeen achievable to those adopting theseschemes later that decade, since ‘the incidenceof worker representation schemes is not muchchanged, yet their impact on firm performanceappears to have been’ (Addison and Belfield,2001, p. 358). This lends support to the notionthat other factors, beyond simple or singleschemes, are at play – in this instance, theexternal environment (be it social, economic orpolitical changes).

But the question remains, why should thetype of participation introduced affectperformance differently? This body ofcontradictory evidence is not surprising giventhe often considerable lack of attention paid tothe mechanisms by which employeeparticipation influences performance and theassumptions made about causality, linkingparticipation to attitude change, then to changesin behaviour and, finally, to improvedperformance. These processes are all toofrequently shrouded in questionableassumptions about the nature of the workplaceand the causal effects of participationprogrammes. Of particular concern areassumptions made about change in employeeattitudes, especially that participation inducesgreater employee association with managementvalues and that this will also improveemployment relations within the workplace. Ifthis assumption proves fragile, it sheds doubton the assumed positive links betweenparticipation and performance. A further

Page 22: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

16

Employee participation and company performance

assumption, which is rarely contested, is thegeneralisability of participation schemesbetween different workplaces, industrial sectorsand sizes of enterprise. Finally, of concern forthe social outcomes of participation is theassumption that participation affects allemployees identically, regardless of gender, age,race and contract status.

A more detailed consideration of potentialmethodological problems to be confrontedwhen researching participation andperformance can be found in Appendix 1.

Explanatory processes for different

outcomes

External environment

One explanation for these uncertainties is thatparticipation schemes are not isolated from theeffects of the external environment. For firmsfaced with economic pressures, the sidelining ofparticipatory measures can be part of cost-cutting exercises. Ramsay (1977) poses anexplanation for apparent ‘cycles’ inparticipatory efforts, by hypothesising thatparticipation is a management response toincreased worker resistance to managementcontrol. Participation is therefore introduced asa means to regain management legitimacy and,once worker resistance is headed off,management can quietly lose interest in theparticipation programmes. Without a strongenvironment of worker resistance, an insecureenvironment accompanied by restructuringmeasures and the possibility or threat of joblosses will be likely to induce employeecompliance with participation programmes, andnot the attitude changes necessary for employeecommitment to the organisation. Such

contradictory restructuring measures mayobscure or even negate any positive outcomesassociated with participation (Brown et al., 1993;White et al. 2003, p. 188).

Attitude and behaviour change

A crucial assumption in the managementliterature is that participation can affect changesin employee attitudes and behaviour, thusimproving company performance. There are anumber of contended areas along this causalpath; the association between participation andattitude change; the association betweenattitude change and changes in employeebehaviour; and the association between attitudechange and company performance. WhileBryson and Millward (1997, p. 64) have foundthat there is ‘little evidence’ that participationcan alter attitudes and behaviour, other studiesprovide more qualified results. Keef (1998, p. 73)found that share ownership ‘did not result inthe expected improvement in attitudes’,however it has been contended that the positivemotivational effects attributed to shareownership will only be triggered by ‘significant’shareholdings (Hyman, J., 2000). Pendleton et al.(1998) agree that, when the level of ownership issufficient to produce ‘feelings of ownership’,higher levels of commitment and satisfactionare observable. It is perhaps not surprisingtherefore that research indicates that, contrary tomanagement hopes, employees may regardtheir shares as a gratuity or bonus offered tothem by their employers (Bell and Hanson,1987; Baddon et al., 1989), and not as sufficientto create feelings of ownership. Other studieshave found that attitude and behaviouralchanges are not uniform and differ betweenforms of participation used and between

Page 23: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

17

Outcomes of participation

different employees. Batt and Appelbaum (1995)found that performance enhancement was mostassociated with self-managed teams. Ben-Nerand Jones (1995) discovered that financial orcontrol rewards affected different employees;some workers exhibited a more instrumentalapproach to participation and thereforeresponded better to financial rewards, othersresponded more positively when they wereoffered extra control over their jobs, or a say incompany decisions.

Of all the assumptions made in theliterature, the least questioned is the linkbetween attitude change and behaviour change(Pendleton et al., 1998). Pendleton et al. point outthat positive attitudes towards employeeownership do not necessarily equate with morepositive attitudes to work. Guest et al. (1993)have also criticised the frequent use of thisdubious assumption in the literature. If thevalidity of this process is questioned, it thencasts doubt on the link between participation,attitudes and performance. If participation mayfail to produce attitude changes in employees itmay also fail to induce behavioural changesassociated with reducing company costs, e.g.reductions in absenteeism and labour turnover.Adam’s (1991) study is a further example of theambiguities of the association between attitudeand behaviour. The introduction of participationin the form of quality circles was found to haveno significant impact on employee attitudestowards quality, but still managed to affectbehavioural changes, resulting in improvedproductivity.

Individualism and collectivismUnder the combined influence of governmentpolicy and organisational shifts to a people-

management policy that emphasises individualcontribution and rewards, there has been anuntested assumption of a movement fromcollectivist orientations and values amongemployees to a more individualistic orientation.In other words, it is assumed that employeeattitudes have been influenced by both externaland internal climates and hence are morereceptive to unitarist approaches. Employerreflections of this shift have been demonstratedby a raft of ‘individually focused HRM practices... focused primarily on managing thecontribution and commitment of individuals’(Roche, 2001, p. 184). By implication, ifemployees shift from collectivist attitudes andtheir association with mutual protection ofgroup (or class) interests, the unitarist culturesand policies being adopted or promoted bymany organisations are less likely to be resistedand, indeed, may be welcomed.

Nevertheless, there is still argument as to theextent of decline in employee collectivism withits roots in union organisation andrepresentation, notwithstanding observabledeclines in union membership and activity overrecent years. The decline in union membershiphas flattened out, and in some sectors,membership is increasing. Some commentatorspoint out that resistance to managementinitiatives is still being expressed and thatdecline in union membership does not equateautomatically with a shift away from collectivistvalues and attitudes to ones of passiveaccommodation to unitarist managementpolicies (see, for example, Bradley et al., 2000 fora summary).

Participation and harmony at work

Just as the literature casts doubt on theassociation between participation and attitude

Page 24: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

18

Employee participation and company performance

change, another associated and questionableassumption is that participation will in turninduce a more harmonious labour relationsclimate. While participation may be used tobuild on and improve existing employmentrelations to the benefit of both parties, e.g.perhaps with social partnership programmes,there is some evidence that certain types ofparticipation schemes, and the wayparticipation is implemented, can produce orincrease worker dissatisfaction with theorganisation. In fact, evidence suggests thatthere is no necessary causal connection betweenparticipation and changes to employmentrelations climates. There is a neglected body ofliterature, straddling the labour relations andco-operatives fields, which claims thatparticipation can increase levels of conflict infirms (Tynan, 1980c; Gamson and Levine, 1984;Mellor et al., 1988; Forsyth, 1990), instead ofreducing it as the proponents of Japanese-stylelabour relations or HRM claim. If this is in factthe case then the causal assumptions found inmuch of the literature – that participationinduces a more harmonious labour relationsclimate and thus leads to attitude changesamong the workforce resulting in a moremotivated and ultimately more productive andcreative workforce – are called into seriousdoubt. Another contention that questions thecausal link between harmony and performanceis presented by Fernie and Metcalf (1995). Theyconclude that harmonious industrial relationsdo not necessarily lead to improved companyeconomic performance and demonstrate thatstudies have shown that participation canimprove performance without engendering aharmonious industrial relations climate (Fernieand Metcalf, 1995, p. 405). This is in line with

Forsyth’s (1990) contention that conflict is anecessary process in building group cohesion,which cannot occur ‘until intergroup hostilityhas surfaced, been confronted and resolved’(Forsyth, 1990, p. 385). The untested assumptionin much of the literature is that group cohesionis an integral factor of effective team working,through the establishment of group norms andpeer pressures that prevent free riders.

Worker participation, teams and performance

Teams, while not necessarily offering a highlevel of employee participation in organisationaldecision making, are an important considerationgiven the often uncritically assumed linkbetween team working and attitudinal changein favour of management/organisational goals.

Team working, for instance, is suggested tohave a positive impact on employees (Petersand Waterman, 1982), especially in improvedrelations (Cressey and Williams, 1990), aidingconflict handling (Garavan and Morley, 1992),changing employee attitudes and behaviours(Levine, 1995), and in building trust andimproving communications (Blasi et al., 1996;Oakland, 1996 cited in Knights and McCabe,2000), all of which are critical elements along theparticipation-perception-performance causalpath. Work-related control is therefore alleged toalter employee attitudes through increasedinvolvement in organisational decision makingand, through this means, to align employeevalues with organisational goals (Summers,2004). Once employee values and motivationsare in concert with management andorganisational objectives, it is assumed thatemployees will then work ‘harder and better’than before, thus resulting in improvedorganisational performance.

Page 25: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

19

Outcomes of participation

Team working achieves this attitudinalchange through what is known as ‘normative’or ‘concertive’ (Barker, 1993) control, whichoperates between team members. Workundertaken by Findlay et al. (2000) and byThompson and Wallace (1996) has distinguishedbetween three dimensions of team work: thetechnical, governance and normativedimensions, where the normative dimensionrefers to the ‘socialization of team members andchanges in attitudes and behaviours’ (Findlayet al., 2000, p. 1550). This process of attitudecontrol and alignment is also assumed to reducethe need for managerial supervision of teams,thus reducing the direct staffing costs of theorganisation. Another means by which teamworking is assumed to influence organisationalperformance is via increased employeediscretion and empowerment in decisionmaking (Lawler, 1986, cited in Ramsay et al.,2000), accessing employee bodies of knowledge.

However, research has questioned thepursuit and value of normative control (Sinclair,1992; Barker, 1993; Sewell, 1998; Findlay et al.,2000; Knights and McCabe, 2000). So, forexample, tensions arising from team-workingsituations are reported by Knights and McCabe,who state that:

The various powers exercised by a teamworkingdiscourse do not necessarily assume acoherence, co-ordination and consistency onewith another. The resulting ambiguities,discrepancies and tensions may readily beexploited by employees.(Knights and McCabe, 2000, p. 1487)

Moreover, the normative control conditionsunder which team members operate, while

perhaps securing performance improvements,have been shown to have less positive effects onworker well-being and autonomy (Barker, 1993;Summers, 2004). Authors such as Sinclair (1992)have therefore warned against the ‘tyranny’ ofthe dominant team ideology.

Further, work undertaken from a labourprocess perspective, while agreeing that teamworking can influence employee behaviours atwork and thus result in changes to performance,questions whether these behavioural changesare presaged on attitudinal changes or onincreased levels of insecurity and fear within theworkplace (Ramsay et al., 2000, Harley, 2001).

Ramsay et al.’s (2000) work using WERS98examined the labour process argument that‘high-involvement’ work systems (see below),including team working, produced performanceimprovements through ‘work intensification,offloading of task controls, and increased jobstrain’ (Ramsay et al., 2000, p. 501). However,while their analysis found support for somerelationship between high-performance worksystems and workplace performance, thisoperated via neither the participation-perception-performance nor the participation-behaviour-performance models. This suggeststhat perhaps other variables are at work, whichthis analysis of WERS98 failed to identify. Inaddition, Ramsay et al. (2000, p. 522)hypothesise that ‘managements may simply beincompetent … at implementing andmaintaining innovative approaches’, thusexplaining the lack of causal mechanisms found.Harley’s (2001) work, also using WERS98,which examined team working and employeedecision-making changes, also found nostatistical association, thus also questioning the

Page 26: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

20

Employee participation and company performance

assumed link between increases in employeediscretion at work producing changes in workerattitudes in favour of the organisation.

While the evidence provided by theliterature is supportive of the possibility of apositive relationship between team working andorganisational performance improvements, itcasts doubts both on the desirability ofnormative integration and on the causal pathsassumed by both advocates and critics of teamworking. These are important considerationsgiven the growth in the use of team working inthe UK, and the suggestions of harmonisationand unitarisation of team members’ values,especially where ‘for management,teamworking represents a potential means ofdelivering a wide range of benefits’ (Bacon andBlyton, 2000, p. 1426).

High-involvement and high-commitment

work practices

Walton’s (1985) recognition that, in the moderneconomy, employers need to rethink theirrelations with employees beyond simplyexerting control has been reflected in thewidespread adoption of empowerment andteam-working programmes. Empowermentinitiatives have generally been held to exertquestionable impact on employee motivation orcompany performance, largely because theyoffer little ‘power’ to employees; security ofemployment (a critical element of Walton’sformulation) has been largely absent; andtraining was neither offered to ‘empowered’employees nor to their supervisory staff, manyof whom felt threatened by perceivedundermining of their authority and risk to theirpositions posed by ‘delayering’ and

restructuring (see, for example, Cunninghamet al., 1996).

More recent developments have been basedon the research of Huselid (1995) who hasattempted to identify a substantive link betweenbundles of progressive HR practices andcompany performance. Huselid identified anumber of ‘high-performance work practices orsystems’ (HPWP or HPWS) embracing‘employee skills and organisational structures’and motivational expressions. The former,sometimes presented as high-commitment workpractices (HCWP) or high-involvement workpractices (HIWP), included a number ofparticipative elements such as quality ofworking life programmes, employee attitudesurveys, profit sharing, etc. The initial studyinvolved distribution to some 3,500 companiesin the USA of a questionnaire, from whichHuselid also gathered company performancedata. Huczynski and Buchanan (2001, p.686)summarised the main findings as follows.

• Organisations with HPWP had higherlevels of productivity and financialperformance.

• Organisations with HPWP in theemployee skills and organisationalstructure category had lower employeeturnover.

• A significant proportion of the positiveeffect of HPWP on financial performanceis attributable to lower turnover or higherproductivity.

• HPWP contributes $18,500 in shareholderand almost $4,000 per employee inadditional profits.

Page 27: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

21

Outcomes of participation

Nevertheless, these authors note a numberof methodological shortcomings in this study:

• difficult to establish causality throughsnapshot survey method

• technical problems in subjecting surveydata to sophisticated statistical analysis

• findings based on commercial enterprisesonly

• organisational performance defined interms of financial indicators – measuresdo not extend to individual and socialwell-being

• definition of HPWP omits otherapproaches and techniques.

Like Huselid, Pfeffer (1998) draws similarconclusions on the value of progressive peoplemanagement policies, claiming that ‘profitsthrough people’ are largely attributable to asmall grouping of people-management policies,including a number of participative elementssuch as self-managed team working.

In a ten-year longitudinal study of HPWP inover 100 UK manufacturing companies,Patterson et al. (1997) also found positive linksbetween company culture and HR practicespromoting employee welfare and organisationalperformance. They found that overall jobsatisfaction and organisational commitmentwere positively linked to high companyproductivity. Again, Huczynski and Buchanan(2001) identify methodological shortcomings; inthis case the study was narrowly based onsmall- and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs)(up to 1,000 employees) in the manufacturingsector only.

Surprisingly perhaps in management texts,commitment is unquestionably assumed as apredicted employee response, represented bysome performance measure, to bundles ofprogressive employment practices that includetechniques such as team working, trainingprovision or employee share schemes.Notwithstanding this indeterminacy, themanagement literature has been dominated byits attempts to identify those people-management practices that in combination mayserve to enhance some measure of performancethrough a ‘commitment’ whose meaning isseldom defined or even questioned.Interestingly, according to Legge (2001, p. 30),one of the most authoritative of researchers intoHCWP, David Guest, avoids the issue byconflating motivation with commitment.Motivation, with its long association withsatisfying observable needs, may be expected tobe more amenable to management-inspiredinitiatives. However, few other human resourcemanagement studies attempt a closeexamination of the concept. Cully et al. (1999,p. 284) refer to high-commitment practices asinnovative work practices, ‘a term which has no“settled meaning”’.

One aim of the management investigator hasbeen to identify which practices and whichcombinations of practices might be associatedwith positive performance outcomes. Apartfrom making no effort to ascribe any meaning tocommitment, attempts to link HCWP withperformance outcomes have been beset withdifficulties. The number and type of individualpractices can vary widely: as Legge (2001)points out, 15 practices are identified in theWERS study (Cully et al., 1999, p. 285), while

Page 28: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

22

Employee participation and company performance

other studies are more restrictive in theiridentification and inclusion of commitment-related practices: moreover, few practices arecommon to the different studies. Othershortcomings are identified: measurement ofpractice effects differ; there is uncertainty aboutwhether individual practices such asperformance-related pay are associated withpositive or negative effects; and theeffectiveness or competence with which thepractice is exercised is seldom assessed (Legge,2001, pp. 25–6). Ramsay et al.’s analysis of WERSalso offered poor levels of managerialcompetence as a potential explanatory factor forthe authors’ reservations about the effects of theHPWS model (Ramsay et al., 2000, p. 522).Further, performance can be examined indiverse ways and affected by the ever-presentcomplication of influence by interveningvariables.

From an empirical perspective also, there areconsiderable doubts about the extent and depth,either of the coverage of purportedcommitment-inducing cultures and practices orthe depth of employee response to thesepractices. Non-union workplaces in particularhave been conspicuous by their lack ofcoverage. In a recent review, Kessler and Purcell(2003, p. 331) conclude that ‘non-union formsare unlikely to pursue such a high-commitmentor developmental approach for the bulk of theirworkforce’. Both the 1992 and 1998 workplacesurveys (Workplace Industrial Relations Survey[WIRS] and WERS), arrived at similarconclusions for the majority of workplaces: ‘thediffusion of high-commitment managementpractices was not especially widespread’ (Cullyet al., 1999, p. 295). These findings receivefurther endorsement from recent Economic and

Social Research Council (ESRC) studies. Onestudy of 835 organisations concludes that ‘mostmanagers pay only lip service to the idea thatmost people are their most important assets’(reported in Taylor, 2002, p. 24). Taylor alsoreports that a study by Guest and his colleaguesfound only minute proportions of purportedhigh-commitment practices were being adoptedby most employers (Taylor, 2002, p. 25). Trainingand development, also seen as a contributor to‘securing employee motivation andcommitment towards organizational goals’(Heyes, 1996, p. 351), are frequently neglectedby companies ‘whose principal focus is on cost-centred competitive strategies’ (Keep andRainbird, 2003).

The extent to which ‘employee voice’ isbeing articulated has been questioned, despiteits positive association with employeeorientations. The Change in Employer Practicessurvey, commissioned by the ESRC, found that,while more appraisal, surveillance and controlover individual employees was apparent, ‘otherevidence ... in the survey indicates only modestadvance in the extension of worker voice’(Taylor, 2002). These ‘advances’ tended to beinformational and communicative rather thannegotiative or even consultative, leading Taylorto conclude pessimistically that establishments‘have a long way to go before they can enabletheir employees to enjoy access to anymeaningful participation in the workplace ofeven the most limited kind’.

Other studies also raise doubts. Ramsayet al.’s (2000) analysis of the 1998 WERS studyquestions the validity of the ‘widely-heldassumption that positive performance outcomesfrom HPWS flow via positive employeeoutcomes’. They indeed go further, cautioning

Page 29: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

23

Outcomes of participation

against ‘theorizations of work organization thatgive primacy to employee orientations to workas an exploratory variable for organizationalperformance and which are so common inmainstream managerial literature’ (Ramsayet al., 2000, p. 521). From national surveysconducted in 1992 and 2000, White et al. (2003,pp. 191–2) conclude that ‘our evidence clearlyshows that employees do not always benefitfrom high-performance work practices’,especially in relationship to work–life balance.A major study by Guest et al. (2003) showedlittle evidence of links between HR practicesand productivity or performance change.

Thus, while there are some signs that HPWPcan be linked to positive performanceindicators, the evidence is not conclusive, andthe dynamics of relations between the variablesand relationship to context are little understoodat present. Moreover, it must be rememberedthat strategic adoption of these practices is notyet widespread in the UK, being largely foundin larger workplaces with personnel specialistsand integrated employee development plans(Cully et al., 1999, pp. 80–2). Furthermore,companies may have policies that, because ofoperational or other reasons, are not necessarilypractised by line managers, especially wheresenior management support is not forthcoming(Guest, 1989; Brewster et al., 1981).

Degree of employee influence

Low-degree influence

The literature clearly indicates that theintroduction of some forms of participation canhave little positive effect on companyperformance. Part of the explanation for this isthe level of participation offered to employees –

whether it is consultation or decision-makingrights – and the level this is operated at, boardor work station. Low degrees of participationwith little employee autonomy have beenidentified as reasons for disappointingparticipation results. This has been observed insome firms where, after an initial ‘honeymoon’period, the workforce has expressed moredissatisfaction with the firm than before theintroduction of participation, because of theraised and unmet expectations of employeeinfluence (Kruse and Blasi, 1995). The scope ofparticipation schemes may be so limited as tosimply irritate the workforce, thus failing tomeet their expectations. A workforce may alsofeel resentful about the amount of time, effortand increased responsibility involved in aparticipation scheme (Bryson and Millward,1997; McNabb and Whitfield, 1998), especially ifthey see little return from management. Onepossible explanation for these discrepancies canbe gleaned from views from the shop floor,which suggest that participation schemes havehad little effect on communications betweenemployees and management. Patterson et al.’s(1997) study found that employees felt that,while management placed emphasis on qualitygoods and services, little emphasis was placedon participation and communication. This maygo some way towards explaining Adam’s (1991)findings on the limited impact of quality circles.Ackroyd and Procter (1998) support thisalternative view of the UK situation with theircontention that in fact very little has actuallychanged in employee relations. They find thatemployee relations have not moved towards‘softer’ measures, such as communications andemployee motivation, but in fact have movedtowards ‘harder’ measures. This hypothesis is

Page 30: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

24

Employee participation and company performance

supported by the WERS98 findings; employeeswere less likely to report improvements incommunications with management than theirmanagers were.

These shortcomings suggest that the role ofthe trade unions remains significant, althoughthis contention has to be measured against a(possible) shift in worker identification awayfrom unions. Krieger and O’Kelly (1998) alsofound that the presence of a trade union wasimportant. It meant that higher degrees ofemployee influence were associated withindividualised, direct participation, and that thissituation produced significant cost-cuttingresults. Where participation is only in onedirection, from the top down (e.g. throughbriefing meetings), workers may feel that theirviews are not being considered or given anyweight, therefore, while they feel indifferentabout the increased communication from thetop, this may be accompanied by increasedhostility towards management. Marchingtonet al. (1989) found a number of instances whereteam briefing, often heralded as a cornerstone toworkplace communication, was ineffective.Where one-way communication is from thebottom up, for example through suggestionschemes, workers may then feel thatmanagement is using their suggestions with norewards seen by employees. Overalldisillusionment within the workforce couldtherefore rebound on management plans. Inother circumstances, where schemes have beenintroduced without prior worker consideration,resentment may be the overriding attitudinalchange, not contentment.

Sisson and Frohlich’s (1998) results supportthe thesis that low-degree influence is unlikelyto produce glowing results. In their recent

analysis of the Employee direct Participation inOrganisation Change (EPOC) survey they foundthat, where employees were expected to actmore autonomously and take on responsibilitywithout any increases in employee influence,then participation had no significant impact.They also found that the effects of participationon increases in output were strongest whereemployee participation involved a high degreeof influence. Of particular interest is theirconclusion that team work has a significanteffect only when associated with high degrees ofemployee influence. On the other hand, toreduce absenteeism, low levels of influencewere found to be the most effective means. Thishas implications for company choice ofparticipation scheme – depending on whetherthe primary motive is to reduce costs or toimprove output. However, Sisson and Frohlich(1998) concluded that consultative forms ofparticipation ‘are more likely to be associatedwith positive employment trends’ than moredelegative forms of participation.

High-degree influence

Where participation in conventionally ownedand organised firms occurs at strategic decision-making levels, and is more than merelyconsultative, many of the problems associatedwith low-degree influence forms ofparticipation are bypassed. However, otherproblems may appear in these circumstances.Hartley (1992, p. 302) maintains that employeeowners (i.e. high-degree influence participation)will be unwilling to ‘make hard decisions’ or todiscipline colleagues, and furthermore thatfactionalism will develop. Hartley (1992)continues that employees may be unwilling totake orders from managers, because employee

Page 31: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

25

Outcomes of participation

views formally hold equivalent weight in thedecision-making process. Further, where there isa significant element of employee ownership, amanager may feel constrained from exercisingauthority or from requesting an employee-owner to perform certain tasks.

Ben-Ner and Jones (1995) suggest thatdecision-making rights without financialrewards for workers could mean that employeesdo not take care when taking decisions, whichcould therefore adversely affect companyperformance. Jones (1987) and Defourney et al.(1985) agree that worker involvement indecision making could result in poorerdecisions, because workers are assumed to beless skilled or competent in this task (or theyface potential conflicts of interest, for exampleas board members on pension fund trusts).There is also the contention that, whereemployees have decision-making rights, theirdecisions will be income-maximising and notprofit-oriented (Bartlett, 1994), though Bonin et

al. (1993) consider this view over-simplistic.Ben-Ner and Jones (1995) also contend that,where workers have control rights but nofinancial return rights, they will seek to improveworking conditions. This, Ben-Ner and Jonesassume, will adversely affect companyefficiency. However, this could also be seen as ameans to increase worker loyalty to thecompany, thereby improving workerperformance and reducing labour turnover.Furthermore, employee involvement in decisionmaking may increase the amount of timedecision making takes, thus disadvantagingfirms in highly competitive markets. Jones(1987) takes a different tack and warns that,with enforced strategic-level participation – forexample, legislation for co-determination –

managers may reduce their input and effort indecision making, resulting in poorer companyperformance. However, Jones goes on to addthat worker involvement in and acceptance ofdecisions can reduce implementation problems,therefore lowering costs and improvingadaptability.

Individualised participation

The contention that participation may amplifyconflict also depends on the type ofcommunication process used, whether it isindividual-unitarist or collective-pluralist.Where participation is introduced to promoteemployee acceptance of management’s values,and in doing so attempts to bypass traditionalcollective grievance expression mechanisms,such as trade unions, the productive andorganised expression of dissatisfaction andconflict can be weakened or removed. Keenoy(1992, p. 107) points out that, even where everyeffort has been made to engender a harmoniousworking climate, ‘adversarial attitudes andrelations can often carry over from previouswork socialisation’. Therefore adversarialrelations, established suspicions and mistrustcan remain intact, while the resolution ofproblems may be hindered by a lack ofappropriate structures. Alternatively, wheremanagement has introduced participation, evenwhere no overt hostility was previouslyexpressed, the very introduction of the schememay encourage employees to questionmanagement decisions over their working livesthat otherwise would have been acceptedwithout overt conflict. The possibilities ofraising grievances within meetings may alsoresult in more personally directeddisagreements, as grievances can now be

Page 32: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

26

Employee participation and company performance

directed at a person rather than an impersonalorganisation. Plus, the ‘new’ participationmeasures often seek to formalise the informalcommunications channels within a firm and toattach workers’ informal channels tomanagement. But there is no evidence thatformalising informal relations works (Brysonand Millward, 1997) and it can be costly.

lndividualisation of relations can,furthermore, result ‘in the feeling thatcommunication would now be impossible’ withthe ‘loss of a common cause’ (Thelen, 1970, p. 5).Thelen’s study of a Chicago community housinggroup found that, as the group fragmented andmembers became more individualistic, theybecame ‘more and more determined by self-concern’ (Thelen, 1970, p. 7), ceased to work as acoherent group and had less commitment to thegroup. Because there were no channels ‘forconstructive action to relieve frustration’(Thelen, 1970, p. 7), the isolation of manymembers was expressed in the rise in gossip,rumours, dishonesty and corruption. Therefore,a participation programme that aims to promotethe individual nature of the employmentrelationship, perhaps with the intention todisplace collective relations, may find itselffaced with a dissatisfied and unco-operativeworkforce, resulting in a lack of team workingand an environment of increased suspicion.Claims are also made for negative effects ofindividual financial participation schemes, suchas all-employee share schemes. Managers mayfeel less incentive to supervise if they feel thatthey are not receiving the full remunerativebenefits of this activity (Alchian and Demsetz,1972; Blasi et al., 1996, p. 63). Unless employeesco-operate, there may be an individual tendencyto shirk, as all employees receive an equal

proportion of gain irrespective of individualcontribution. Even in an enterprise as dynamicas Microsoft (30 per cent annual revenueincreases and rapidly declining costs), negativeeffects can be identified. Greg Maffei, ChiefFinancial Officer for the company,acknowledges that a fall in the share pricewould make it much harder to recruit the‘bright young graduates’ it needs, as shareoptions have formed a significant proportion ofthe benefits package. Moreover, ‘we have a hugeproblem ... we have overpaid lots of peoplebecause stock options don’t differentiatebetween the really good and the less goodemployee’ (quoted in Guardian Online, 1998).

Collective participation

Even when considering the most formallycollective form of participative workorganisation, the co-operative firm,inharmonious employee relations have beenreported. Paton (1978) reminds us that collectivedirect participation, in contrast to the collectiverepresentative participation practised by tradeunions, can approximate adversarial relations inits outcomes. In situations where workers areallowed to ‘raise any question in meetings’ theoutcome is ‘closer to the practice of collectivebargaining’ in that relations then becomeconfrontational. However, rather thanestablishing a collective solidarity, ‘employees’concerns are promoted in a fragmented andnegative way’ with the result that ‘it mayappear to employees that they are listened to,lectured and then ignored’ (Paton, 1978, p. 28).Where collective participation is understood asan open acceptance of both employee andmanagement values, e.g. as possibly in a socialpartnership approach, then organised

Page 33: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

27

Outcomes of participation

expression of dissatisfaction is available, as isthe power to do something about it.

Some authors have associated conflict withinco-operative firms with their demise (Emerson,1982; Rhoades, 1984; Pencavel, 2001), whichraises questions about whether collectiveparticipation in its extreme forms may lead to thedissolution of the firm. Taking the basicassumptions in a different direction are theproponents of ‘degeneration theory’. Thissuggests causality in the opposite direction, withthe most efficient firms being the leastparticipative. Part of the grounds for this debatelie in the various reasons why participationschemes and employee ownership areestablished. For some firms, employee ownershipis the last option in the face of plant closure. Inthese situations, the firm may be terminallyunprofitable and employee ownershipinconsequential to its ultimate closure.

Union recognition and company performance

No one disputes that a wide range ofintervening variables can influence companyperformance. The role of trade unions isespecially contentious, as public policy can bebased on the underlying assumptions regardingtheir influence (MacInnes, 1987). Neo-classicaleconomic theory posits a negative relationshipbetween unions and economic performance,based on unions’ monopoly capacity to distortlabour market relations and to universallyimprove terms and conditions for their members(Nolan and O’Donnell, 2003, pp. 490–2). Criticsof this approach argue that unions act asintermediary institutions, which, by providing achannel for employee grievances and collectiveparticipation, serve as positive contributors toorganisational performance (Freeman and

Medoff, 1984).Empirical evidence for the effects of unions

on company performance is mixed. Whileanalysis of WERS90 (Fernie and Metcalf, 1995)indicated a largely negative relationshipbetween unionism and organisational economicperformance, results from the equivalent 1998survey (Cully et al., 1999) indicate a positiverelationship between union presence andrecognition and high productivity growth.Nevertheless, there is some variation; forexample, the presence of joint consultativecommittees had a negative effect onproductivity while union recognition itself hada positive impact (however, both variables arenegatively associated with absenteeism rates)(Addison and Belfield, 2001). The same dataalso report a negative association betweenunion recognition and low pay, and betweenlow-paying organisations and low productivitygrowth (TUC, 1999a; see also McNabb andWhitfield, 2000; Rubery and Edwards, 2003).Table 3 indicates associations betweenbargaining coverage and productivity across anumber of European countries.

However, since the 1998 WorkplaceEmployee Relations Survey, legislative changeshave been enacted resulting in increasedrecognition rights for trade unions, and thisimpact on organisations and their performancewill in future need to be studied, since thegrowing positive impact of unionism onorganisational performance reported in WERS98may have been the result of either reduced or

augmented union power and influence in theworkplace. If either hypothesis holds, then theEmployment Relations Act 1999 will haveimportant implications for the relationshipbetween unionism and performance.

Page 34: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

28

Employee participation and company performance

In addition, the differences exhibited by thetwo surveys may be accounted for by differenteconomic environments, by representativeparticipation schemes having long-term effectsor growing effects on organisationalperformance, by changes to worker attitudesand expectations, skills or educational levels, orby the initial costs of representativeparticipation negating any positive performanceoutcomes on overall profit levels.

The principles of partnership agreements

The current UK Government has lent its supportstrongly to the notion of partnership in theworkplace. Not only is partnership a significant(if voluntary) part of the approach to theEmployment Relations Act 1999, its practice isalso supported by DTI research:

All the case study firms featured in the studyasserted that the adoption of partnership basedwork practices has helped them to achieveenhanced business performance.(Knell, 1999)

Support is also expressed by the TUC, whichhas published (TUC, 1999b, 2001, 2002; also seewww.tuc.org.uk/pi/partnership.htm) and

publicised its ‘six principles of partnership’,which are (in the order presented by the TUC):

• a shared commitment to the success of theorganisation

• a commitment by the employer toemployment security in return for whichthe union agrees to a higher level offunctional flexibility in the workplace

• a renewed focus on the quality ofworking life, giving workers access toopportunities to improve their skills,focusing attention on improving jobcontent and enriching the quality of work

• openness and a willingness to shareinformation; so, for example, employerswill share with unions and workers theirthoughts about the future when they areat the ‘glint in the eye’ stage

• adding value – unions, workers andemployers must see that partnership isdelivering measurable improvements

• a recognition by both the union andemployer that they each have differentand legitimate interests.

Table 3 Bargaining coverage and workplace productivity compared

1996 workplace productivity Bargaining coverage 1994(GDP per hour worked) (or nearest year) (%)

Belgium 129 90France 123 95Netherlands 119 81Italy 119 82Germany 109 92UK 100 47

Source: TUC (1999a)

Page 35: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

29

Outcomes of participation

Government and unions aside, the key UKpressure group supporting partnership at workis the Involvement and ParticipationAssociation (IPA). This association has alsooutlined four principles of partnership (IPA,1997, p. 4, cited in Guest and Peccei, 2001),which overlap with those of the TUC:

• security and flexibility

• sharing financial success

• developing good communication andconsultation

• representative and employee voice.

Nevertheless, within the academic literature,there are distinct cleavages of views onpartnership arrangements. This is perhaps notsurprising as there is ‘no agreed definition orconceptualization of partnership in either theacademic or the policy literature’ (Guest andPeccei 2001, p. 208). So, in analysing the effectsof partnership, there may be a definitionalproblem over the issues and processes andrelated outcomes under examination. However,in terms of union–management partnershipagreements, two broad camps may beidentified.

First, there are proponents of partnershipwho view it as ‘a means of union renewal and ofextending employee participation’ (Roche andGeary, 2002) through joint decision making,premised on strong, independent unions. Thisview sees partnership as engendering mutualbenefits for both parties, via a causal path ofemployee attitude change, resulting inimproved organisational performance. Themechanism for achieving this is through

improvements to the psychological contract(Guest and Peccei, 2001), which will ‘have botha direct and indirect impact on productivity,quality and innovation, which in turn will affectsales and financial results’ (Guest and Peccei,2001, p. 216; see also Delaney and Huselid,1996). But this attitude change is premised on abetter quality of working life for workers, givingthem more influence in decision making.Consequently, it has been assumed thatsupervisory requirements will be reduced sinceemployee commitment and loyalty to thecompany will increase with partnership, thusdirectly cutting staffing costs (Cutcher-Gershenfield and Verma, 1994, cited in Guestand Peccei, 2001).

The second approach is typified by thecritics or opponents of partnership who see thisas a means for management to extend theirinfluence over organisational matters anddecision making through the incorporation andmoderation of unions (Taylor and Ramsay,1998). Persistent doubts have also been voicedby Streeck (1992, 1994,1995, cited in Roche andGeary, 2002), who contends that, since thesenew forms of management–employeepartnership are voluntary, they are ‘inherentlyunstable and unlikely to prosper in the longterm … [due to] a deep asymmetry of powerbetween management and organised labour’(Roche and Geary, 2002, p. 662), and wheremanagement’s support for partnership ispremised on it serving business needs. Thisapproach is reminiscent of Ramsay’s (1977)‘cycles of control’ thesis, and has significantimplications for organisational performancelinked to partnership agreements.

Page 36: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

30

Employee participation and company performance

Empirical evidence

Strongly positive endorsement of thepartnership approach comes from the TUCitself. Its analysis of the WERS98 resultssuggests that partnership organisations makefewer employees redundant, rarely declarecompulsory redundancies, have average rates ofpay around £50 a week higher than non-partnership organisations and have shorterworking hours (TUC Partnership Institute webpage, accessed 2003, www.tuc.org.uk/theme/index.cfm?theme=partnership). However, thesepurported effects do not account for thedirection of causality, since the organisationsmay have offered these benefits beforepartnership was established, or may haveoffered them irrespective of partnership.Therefore, do partnership firms provideemployee benefits and welfare as a result ofpartnership? Alternatively, does the existence ofbenefits indicate the presence of a strong tradeunion, which can deal on a equal power footingwithin a partnership agreement and thereforeproduce the productivity gains through higherlevels of trust premised on a more equaldistribution of power?

In addition to the TUC’s WERS analysis,empirical evidence from Roche and Geary’s(2002) study of partnership at the Irish AirportsAuthority (Aer Rianta) also suggests a positiveoutcome for both parties, supporting the mutualgains thesis. The Principles of ConstructiveParticipation by which the agreement operatedat Aer Rianta contained explicit directions thatunions and management would ‘do all possibleto improve company performance and livingstandards for employees’ (cited in Roche andGeary, 2002, p. 668). The main benefit for theorganisation from this new agreement was that

‘workers were believed to have become morewilling to contribute voluntarily to the successof the company in ways that had been absent inthe past’ (Roche and Geary, 2002, p. 673),indicating at least a causal link between theadvent of partnership and employee attitudechanges. This partially supports the claims forimprovements to the psychological contract, butRoche and Geary’s work contains no explicitreference to organisational performanceimprovements (this may have been assumedthrough employee attitude changes). However,there was also significant opposition to the newways of decision making, from both workerdirectors and middle management. Yet, for theemployees, a ‘better quality of working life’(Roche and Geary: 2002, p. 673) was seen as aprincipal outcome. A key element of thepartnership agreement within this organisationwas the protection of established collectivebargaining procedures and spheres of influence,overlaid by the new partnership structures andprocedures. These newer partnershiparrangements consisted of both established andnew forms of collective representation indecision making and individualisedparticipation – including employee shareownership. In this respect, it was a combinationof collective and individualised participation(both a pluralist and unitarist approach) thatachieved the outcomes of partnership for theorganisation and its employees. Nevertheless,the partnership arrangements were put in placeas a direct response to an increasinglycompetitive environment, includingcompetition from Ryanair, the abolition of duty-free sales in 1999, the threat of privatisation anda near full-employment labour market. Thus,Streeck (1992, 1994, 1995, cited in Roche and

Page 37: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

31

Outcomes of participation

Geary, 2002) and Ramsay’s (1977) doubtsconcerning the durability and longevity of theseparticipation arrangements may well berelevant in these cases.

Guest and Peccei’s (2001) work is alsosomewhat qualified in its support forpartnership. This research also found supportfor the combination of direct and representativeforms of participation (alongside forms offlexible working) in achieving attitude andbehaviour changes in favour of the organisation.This attitude change was also associated withimproved labour retention and absence levels,and with improvements to organisationalperformance, sales and profits. In principle, theauthors conclude that, while they foundevidence of mutual benefits, these werehowever skewed in favour of management inmost of their sample – and this was particularlysharp in those organisations that ‘reported onlylow progress towards partnership’ (Guest andPeccei, 2001, p. 220). In this respect,organisational performance outcomes heldprecedence over employee welfare outcomesand so, while performance was enhanced, atwhat cost to employees? And for how long? Yet,where ‘high-trust’ relations existed withinorganisations, both employee welfare andorganisation performance outcomes wereobserved, which led Guest and Peccei toconclude that:

It is only when employees are engaged, in termsof attitudes and behaviour, that performancegains are apparent, implying that too great adistortion in the balance of advantage would failto lead to positive performance outcomes.(Guest and Peccei, 2001, p. 232)

Other potential sources of conflict

A further major and contentious assumptionconcerning attitude changes is that disharmonyat work adversely affects performance onlywhen it occurs between management andworkers. However, a significant oversight is thedegree and level of conflict between managers.For instance, the lack of success in producingattitude and behavioural changes in middlemanagement is often overlooked, as is theresulting obstacle that middle management canpose to participation programmes (Fenton-O’Creevy and Nicholson, 1994; Cunningham et

al., 1996; Hyman and Cunningham, 1998).Conflict between employees and betweenemployee groups is also often overlooked. Partof the reason for this unquestioned assumptionis that employees are by and large treated as ahomogeneous group with similar interests,responses and behaviours (see McNabb andWhitfield, 1998; Ramsay et al., 1998). Based onthe misconception that employees are ahomogeneous group, a common oversight is toassume that employees will respond toparticipation initiatives in the same way, but, asTynan and Thomas (1981, p. 10) state ‘class,power and skills … to a great extent determinethe response of workers to the workplace’.Oliver (1990) has also pointed out thatemployees can have different motivations; somemay respond to the social or control rewards ofparticipation, while others may respond more tofinancial rewards. Pencavel (2001) hascontended, for example, that worker co-ops canattract financially risk-tolerant participantswhile more risk-sensitive employees areattracted to more traditional workingenvironments. As a result of employee

Page 38: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

32

Employee participation and company performance

differences, various forms of participation arelikely to affect individual employees differently.

Further, scarce attention has been given tothe problems encountered by teams or groupsworking together, particularly the problems thatparticipation schemes can introduce for teamworking. Jackson et al. (2000) identify employeeproblems in team working in terms of employeestrain and reduced well-being. Also, where ateam has been informally established andefficient, a participation scheme may alter theteam composition or its internal dynamics bydictating team membership and roles within it(Ramsay et al., 1998). Therefore ‘employeeempowerment’ measures can potentially reduceemployee autonomy and efficiency and increasediscontent, thereby decreasing workers’propensity to co-operate with management andtheir projects.

The combination effect

Financial and work-related participation

McNabb and Whitfield (1998, p. 171) found thatemployee involvement schemes could have anegative effect on company economicperformance ‘when introduced in isolation’from financial participation measures. They goon to add that the benefits claimed for financialparticipation alone are, however, often‘reflecting the effects of other participationfactors’ (McNabb and Whitfield,1998, p. 172).The combination effect of participationmeasures is replicated in a number of otherrecent studies (Tyson and Levine, 1990;Ichniowski et al., 1994; Kochan and Osterman,1994; Fitzroy and Kraft, 1995; Logue and Yates,2001). Combinations of financial and work-related participation have been noted. Indeed,Pendleton (2001) goes further:

The suggestion that participation in decision-making is an essential accompaniment if shareownership is to bring about attitudinal change hasbeen supported in study after study.(Pendleton, 2001, p. 158)

Bryson and Millward’s (1997) study ofemployee involvement in small firms found thata combination of profit sharing and directemployee involvement produced the greatestimprovements in company performance.Ben-Ner and Jones (1995), on the other hand,provide conflicting evidence of the productivityeffects of combination schemes, indicating that aprecise and tailored programme is probablyrequired. However, much of the research onemployee participation has focused on just oneform of participation, namely financial or work-related participation, and the results presentedabove must therefore question the findings ofmuch of this literature. Furthermore, withoutacknowledging employee heterogeneity, theliterature can provide only ‘sweepinggeneralisations, unalloyed conclusions, andvacuously stirring prescriptions’ (Ramsay et al.1998, p. 2) about the effects of participation.

Representative and direct participationEvidence presented above strongly suggeststhat combinations of representative and directforms of participation have the greatest successin securing positive attitude and behaviouralchanges in employees. Guest and Peccei (2001)concluded that to apply some forms ofpartnership in isolation would not have apositive attitudinal effect. They found thatrepresentative participation alone had nosignificant effect on attitudes and thus onperformance, and suggested that this could bebecause ‘representative participation on its own

Page 39: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

33

Outcomes of participation

will fail to overcome low levels of trust’ (Guestand Peccei, 2001, p. 232). This indicates that aprincipal element of the combination effect isthe engendering of high trust relations betweenthe parties. From a slightly different angle, theTUC (1999a) also endorses trust as ‘an integralelement of the [partnership] process’ (TUC,2001, p. 5) and supports a combination effect,where a ‘high level of trade union involvementmust be matched by an equally high degree ofindividual employee involvement’ (TUC, 2001,p. 6). However, it maintains that a purelyunitarist approach to partnership is unlikely tobe effective and that the inclusion ofrepresentative participation using a trade union‘is essential in delivering commitment andmotivation’ (TUC, 1999a, p. 17). In spite of this,results from WERS98 (Addison and Belfield,2001), while supporting the association betweenunion presence and performanceimprovements, indicate that this association isstrongest where union presence is found in itsweakest forms.

Nevertheless, this emphasis on trust doesnot indicate solely either a pluralist or aunitarist perspective. From a pluralistperspective, where conflicts of interest betweenthe parties are assumed, ‘trust’ could be beingmisread for relative equality of power relationsbetween the parties. As Roche and Geary (2002,p. 661) state, from this perspective ‘the successof partnership arrangements is criticallydependent on the presence of strongindependent unions’. However, where unionstrength and influence are dependent onexternal economic conditions, this equality ofpower relations, or trust, could exist for only aslong as the external economic environmentremains unchanged, and the nature of moderncapitalism is such that change is inherent.

Generalisability of participation effects

A further mediating factor in the applicationand effects of participation is the size of theworkplace. Relatively little is known aboutparticipation in the SME sector beyond whathas been published on co-operatives. Many ofthe more recent surveys and studies fail todifferentiate between large and smallorganisations. However, Bryson and Millward(1997, p. 8) discovered that participation is ‘lessprevalent in small firms ... than in larger firms’.A major survey that has looked into the state ofparticipation in small and large firms is theWorkplace Employee Relations Survey (WERS).The results for WERS98 show that, while only8 per cent of small firms had not introduced anynew management or employee involvementmeasures, less than 30 per cent are using five ormore of these schemes (see Table 2 in Chapter 1of this report) compared with well over half ofthe larger firms. These findings have particularresonance given the Government’s continuingemphasis on expanding and encouraging thesmall firms sector (DfEE, 1998) and onpromoting share ownership in small enterprisesthrough programmes such as the EnterpriseManagement Initiative.

Beyond arguments about enterprise size areconcerns about the industrial sector withinwhich participatory firms are located. Questionsremain concerning whether successfulparticipation schemes are transferable betweenindustry types. Lucas (1996) found that, in thehotel and catering sectors, participation wasextremely low and much poorer that in othersectors. In addition, participatory measures inthis sector were unlikely to induce betterperformance (Lucas, 1995). The hotel and

Page 40: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

34

Employee participation and company performance

catering sector, like other low-skill sectors,e.g. clothing, has a relatively high staff turnover.Management rationales for introducingparticipation schemes in such a sector can bequestioned because participation cannot be usedas a panacea for an industry’s problems. In theabsence of a sustained policy to alter theunderlying structural conditions and clearerunderstanding of the high labour turnover inthese sectors, participation schemes are unlikelyto have significant positive impacts.

Different national conditions

Numerous studies have been conducted in theUSA into the effects of ownership, particularlyownership via the ESOP system. The experienceof the UK ESOP movement, with a top estimateof 100 approved schemes (Pendleton et al.,1995a), is in marked contrast to the USA, whereupwards of 10,000 schemes are estimated to bein operation, covering more than ten millionemployees (Allen et al. 1991; Hyman andMason, 1995, pp. 109–12; Logue and Yates,2001). However, inadequate understanding ofthe different environments and processesinvolved has led to the reification of theAmerican ESOP system. The pitfalls ofemulating the USA are found in many studies ofUS ESOPs, which have demonstrated that thereis little effective participation in these firms(D’Art, 1992) and little evidence for ‘strong andstatistically significant effects of employeeownership on performance’ (Blasi et al., 1996,p. 63). This is because American ESOPs serve adifferent purpose to UK ESOPs. The mostnotable USA purpose for ESOPs is to makeprovision for employee retirement plans ratherthan as a means to involve employees inorganisational decision making (Hanford and

Grasso, 1991; Stevens, 1991/92; Logue andYates, 2001, p. 28).

Different national cultures also account fordifferent participation results when schemes aretransplanted. Profit-sharing plans in Japan areoften held up as crucial factors of Japaneseeconomic success (Freeman and Weitzman,1988). However, doubts persist about thevalidity of these assumptions: in Japan bothprofit-sharing and employee-share schemes areembedded within a complex and possiblyunique ideological network, which emphasisesmutual obligations by both employee andemployer. From the employer, a stake in thecompany and its performance is linked withconcepts of lifetime employment, individualdevelopment and formal consultation; from theemployee, dedication, hard work and companyloyalty are anticipated. It would be difficult tospecifically identify motivational effectsattributable to any one strand of theseideologically informed practices. For thisreason, perhaps, it is difficult to arrive atdefinitive conclusions over the motivationalimpact of these schemes in Japan. The success ofparticipation measures has also been related toworkplace cultures (Gallie and White, 1993;Geary, 1993). Workplace cultures can eithercounteract participation measures (Chelte et al.,1989) or support them; for example, Ramsayet al. (1998) found that management style andpersonality were important determinants ofparticipation success. Commitment to andadministration of participation schemes (Cooke,1992) are crucial elements and can differbetween enterprise, between workplaces withinan enterprise and between departments withina workplace.

Page 41: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

35

Outcomes of participation

Participation and workplace equality

Another misleading assumption on which muchcurrent policy is based is that participation willnecessarily improve working conditions,especially equality in the workplace (betweenemployees and between employees andmanagement), at the same time as improvingcompany economic performance. Much ofcurrent government policy on participationmatters is based on this assumption, i.e. byoffering ‘flexibility with security’.

Social disadvantage

Unlike financial participation, in schemes whereparticipation involves social exchanges betweenemployees and between employees andmanagement, socially derived abilities such aspersuasive powers, ability to communicate,education, and the ability to commit relativelymore time to participation are important sourcesof influence. In addition, this system of decisionmaking does not necessarily allow employeecompetence and confidence to grow and, as apremium is put on oratory, social skills andcommand of information, ‘managers almostalways “win the argument”’ (Paton, 1978, p. 28).As such, the impact of social advantage anddisadvantage may be magnified in participatoryfirms. Within work groups social disadvantagescan alone, or in combination, conspire toexclude certain individuals or groups fromeffective participation. Women, for example,may feel intimidated by a male manager andunable to speak out or express an alternativeopinion, especially in front of other colleagues.Furthermore, caring responsibilities may meanthat certain employees have relatively less timeto commit to preparing for and taking part in

meetings. If gender disadvantages arecompounded by educational differences thenthe individual is put at an even greaterdisadvantage. This is illustrated in Tynan’s 1980study of a printing co-operative, where a femalemachine operator claimed that her feelingsabout her lack of education and working-classbackground made her unable to participate indiscussions. This feeling was mirrored by otherworkers in the meetings, as the better educationand middle-class background of the co-operative founders ‘reinforced the workers’feelings of inadequacy and did so publicly’(Tynan, 1980a, p. 21). Tynan (1980c, p. 33) alsofound in another co-operative, Sunderlandia,that hostility and class attitudes ‘pervaded thefirm’.

These early findings on exclusion aremirrored in Wichman’s (1994) research onparticipation and employee status in the airlineindustry. She found that positive feelings aboutparticipation and ownership programmesvaried by occupation, with lower-levelemployees ‘either uninvolved or cynical aboutthe programme’ (Wichman, 1994, p. 829). Thestudy proposes that ‘higher-level employeeshave the interest and skills necessary to expandtheir areas of control’ (Wichman, 1994, p. 830),and concludes that employee ownership mayproduce increased inequality in the workplace.Miller and Prichard’s (1992) study supports thisproposition, finding that employee propensityto participate was higher in younger, bettereducated and more ambitious employees. Dragoand Wooden (1991) also found that desire andability to participate are influenced bypromotion opportunities, job tenure, jobsecurity and labour market conditions. With all-

Page 42: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

36

Employee participation and company performance

employee share schemes, manual employees aremost likely to sell their shares and to do soquickly (Baddon et al., 1989, pp. 206–15).Baddon et al. point out that, at the time offlotation, BT employees owned 4.6 per cent ofshares, but, by 1989, employee shareholding atBT had diminished to a minuscule 1 per cent ofissued equity.

The wider social context

Social advantage and disadvantage are alsolinked to social groups outwith the workplace.Tynan and Thomas (1981, p. 8) claim that the‘power of an individual within the organisationis linked to the wide social context in which heoperates’. The inclusion of an understanding ofthe different relations between individuals andbetween employee groups, and the limits andextents of these relationships, would allow ananalysis to go ‘beyond the factory gates’ andextend into the realm of family and communityrelations. This would allow the examination ofparticipation effects on the wider socialnetwork, for example, the pub, club or livingroom. Few studies, however, have explored theeffects of the wider social context onparticipation. One that has addressed this issueis Brown and Quarter’s (1994) study of thepropensity to participate in a conversion co-operative. Their study found that the socialcontext was an important component ofindividual participation choices, one that‘influenced employees to become owners oftheir workplace’ (Brown and Quarter, 1994,p. 262). One of the prime determinants here wasco-worker overlapping interests outside theworkplace. When overlap occurred within themanagement group it increased their propensityto participate in the buyout. When overlapping

outside interests coincided with shop-floorunion membership ‘despite a belief thatparticipation in the worker co-operative couldyield capital gains and job security, non-ownerunion members were unwilling to risk thenegative effects of ownership on their socialnetworks’ (Brown and Quarter, 1994, p. 277); infact those who had joined had subsequentlyfound it ‘a major source of friction’ (Brown andQuarter, 1994, p. 278) with their colleagues. Alsoof important consequence were familysituations and pressures. One office worker, inaccounting for her decision not to join the co-operative, explained, ‘my husband is very muchagainst it’ (Brown and Quarter, 1994, p. 278).

Other studies have also highlighted the roleof family opinion in participation choices. Inone co-operative (Tynan, 1980a), the influence offamilial networks on participation was keenlyfelt by some workers; for instance Mary Bewick‘resented helping out in the factory and herhusband preferred her not to’ (Tynan, 1980a,p. 6), which in turn caused resentment amongthe other workers. Another worker found thather friends working in conventionally organisedfirms ‘ridiculed her for doing unpaid overtime’(Tynan, 1980a, p. 14). Perhaps as a result of thesepressures she was one of the first to leave theco-operative. Yet another co-operative casestudy, Little Women (Tynan, 1980b), also foundthat the ‘costs of reconciling the demands ofhome and work proved too great for somewomen’ (Tynan, 1980b, p. 5). Further studies,(Paton and Lockett, 1978) found that socialcontacts outside of work between workers in aco-operative meant that ‘even when theirrespective roles put them at loggerheads, theymaintained cordial relationships, and theirwives were close friends’ (Paton and Lockett,

Page 43: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

37

Outcomes of participation

1978, p. 158). Studies of the Mondragoncomplex of employee-owned firms in Spainhave also suggested that their success is partly aresult of their geographical and social isolationfrom the rest of Spain (Campbell et al., 1977),and the persecution of the Basque people underthe Franco regime, forging a strong regionalidentity and cohesion. Cultural homogeneityand social capital (e.g. mutual trust, communitynetworks) were cited as main factors in thelongevity of worker co-ops in the Pacific NorthWest region of the USA (Pencavel, 2001, p. 76).

Participation and discrimination

On an individual basis, hierarchical status,tenure and advantaged position in the labourmarket through skill or shortage can promoteemployee influence over task and workingconditions and, arguably, enhance employeeperformance (Heller et al., 1998, p. 8).Conversely, less advantaged groups andindividuals may have restricted ‘voice’, whichcan permeate to performance throughfrustration and impotence (Barnes et al., 2002;Arthur, 2003). Broader categories of workersmay also be adversely affected in terms ofinfluence. These could include women, racialminorities, disabled workers and otherpotentially vulnerable individuals such as olderworkers and ex-offenders (Hirsch, 2003). Manyof these groups also suffer from lack ofemployment security, which limits theircapacity to participate in organisational affairsand, partly through this, affects the quality oftheir working lives (see, for example, Burchellet al. 1999). Ex-offenders can be especiallyvulnerable: as individuals, they are clearly at adisadvantage in the labour market and, unlikeother groups, such as women or older workers,

are largely invisible and unlikely to be able togarner collective support from trade unions orpopular support from colleagues (see, forexample, Fletcher et al., 2001 for more details ofthe employment situation of offenders). Theremay be similar problems for gay, lesbian andbisexual workers, who can also facediscrimination at work. The role of sympatheticunions can be crucial in these circumstances. Arecent study reported that over a quarter ofunion representatives surveyed had dealt withcomplaints of harassment or discriminationlinked to sexual orientation (Labour ResearchDepartment, 2003). While it is difficult toquantify the effects of discriminatory behaviouron organisational performance, there is evidencethat good employment practice is related to aharmonious and efficient workplace and that,through their representative actions, unions cancontribute to these beneficial effects (see, forexample, Patterson et al., 1998; Hodson, 2001,Ch. 7). Empirical evidence with regard togender and participation is most readilyavailable.

Gendered inequality

As Ramsay et al. (1998) highlight, genderinequalities can affect both opportunity andwillingness to participate. But, on top of this,false assumptions about gendered differences inattitudes to work and participation instructmany management schemes, with the result thatactivity is focused on men as the ‘core’employees committed to work andorganisation’ (Ramsay et al., 1998, p. 2). Womentend to be seen as less committed to work, withless willingness or time to participate because ofout-of-work associations and commitments.However, as Hakim (1996) has illustrated, it

Page 44: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

38

Employee participation and company performance

would be equally false to assume that allwomen (and all men therefore) behave in thesame way. The conundrum is, however, thatwomen are also thought to be ‘more compliantand therefore better targets for managerialtechniques’ (Ramsay et al., 1998, p. 2). They arealso less likely to be union members and areconcentrated in the less regulated sectors ofindustry and therefore are less likely to becovered by collective bargaining agreements.Trade unions are often seen as patriarchalinstitutions, bypassing women, especially aswomen are less likely to be union members. Butunion presence in a firm can result in collectiverepresentation and may be able to raise theprofile of issues specific to marginalised groups.

In addition, women are disproportionatelyrepresented in part-time work, which isgenerally taken to suggest less time forparticipation in decision making, although theproportion of men engaged in part-time work issteadily growing. In 1996, around a quarter ofall employees were working part time. Whilewomen continue to make up the majority ofpart-time employees, outnumbering men four toone, a significant aspect is the increase in theproportion of men entering part-timeemployment, up to 8.1 per cent of totalemployment. However, Ramsay et al.’s (1998)study of supermarkets found that, while womenwere concentrated in part-time work, thesewomen had been with the companies for longerthan the full-time male employees and weremore positive about the participationprogrammes. Gendered work patterns were alsoimportant; shift working also affected ability toparticipate, with male part-timers more likely tobe working nights and therefore not to be atwork when meetings were taking place.

There is therefore evidence that gender andgendered work experiences do make adifference to experiences of participation (but itis important not to make assumptions abouthow ‘all’ women, for example, will react). Otherpotentially excluded and marginalised groupsalso have different experiences of work, becauseof, for instance language barriers and unequalaccess to information. There is evidence thatethnicity affects experiences of work, from thetype of work to the ability to get work, and agediscrimination policies also suggest that ageinfluences experiences of employment.Ignorance of these differences in workexperiences within a workforce could lead toparticipation schemes magnifying inequalitiesat work. As Perotin and Robinson (2000) pointout, where equal opportunities policies arecombined with employee participation, theproductivity effects for both types of policy areenhanced, and this combination ‘is generallyassociated with a productivity advantage overand above the separate effects of the two typesof policy’ (Perotin and Robinson, 2000, p. 577).

The mechanisms by which this particularcombination works are such that equalopportunities policies may allow greaterproportions of the workforce to participate inparticipation schemes, thus making them moreeffective, and that employee participation indecision making may allow more effective equalopportunities policies to be designed. Whereeither scheme operates more effectively,motivation, morale, effort, loyalty, creativity andco-operation are assumed to increase, impactingpositively on performance. Yet, where adiscriminatory environment exists within afirm, participation may be ‘considerablyrestricted’ and ‘perceptions of unfairness may

Page 45: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

39

Outcomes of participation

worsen if participation schemes are introducedwithout fully involving discriminated groups’(Perotin and Robinson, 2000, p. 562). Where‘high-trust’ relations are a crucial element of theparticipation-perception-performance causalpath, this perception of unfairness may result inthe breaking of this causal mechanism and theloss of productivity for the organisation.However, one significant problem in Perotinand Robinson’s methodology is the narrowfocus on equal opportunities as a determiningvariable. Other, disguised variables mayaccount for some of the results obtained, such asthe existence of complementary bullying orpensions scheme policies, and the omission oftrade unions as a possible variable is significantsince unionism can affect productivity and mayalso influence the quality and scope of equalopportunities polices. For example, as shownbelow, research by Bond et al. (2002) indicatesthat union recognition positively influencesboth the quality and the quantity of family-friendly provisions in organisations.

There is therefore a potential combinationeffect at work beyond combinations of differenttypes of participation – extending to otherpolicies that also seek to alter employeeattitudes, enhance commitment and loyalty, andrelease worker potential and co-operation atwork. While Perotin and Robinson (2000), forinstance, concentrate on equal opportunitiespolices, this potential combination effect couldalso extend to bullying and harassment policies,dignity at work, pensions provisions, etc.

In addition, inequalities at work can beexperienced by employees with differentcontract status. Agency workers, for example,are often less protected and have access to fewerbonuses than permanent staff. Other possibly

disadvantaged workers are those on temporaryor fixed-term contracts, home workers, andsubcontracted employees. Recent years haveseen a tendency toward continuousorganisational restructuring resulting in theincreased use of atypical contracts, and growinglevels of contracting-out of activities andservices (Cully et al., 1999). However, Ramsayet al. (1998) demonstrate that part-time workalone does not necessarily reduce a worker’sability to participate; in contrast, neither isfull-time work a good measure of ability orpropensity to participate. Additional factorsmust be taken into account; for example Ramsayet al. (1998) found that length of serviceincreased propensity to participate, while someshift patterns and job types reduced a worker’sability to participate.

Participation and ageism

The population of the UK is ageing and, at thesame time, organisational restructuring haslargely targeted older workers. As identified inthe JRF series on the experiences of olderworkers, ‘Transitions after 50’, thesedemographic trends lead to a number of policyand practical dilemmas. First, there arepressures on occupational pensions as, withlater starting age in employment and earliertermination, workers may not be employed longenough to accumulate adequate pensionprovision. Second, as the recent Jack Nicholsonfilm About Schmidt demonstrated, there isconsiderable potential wastage of humancapabilities and experience as older workersfind it more difficult to be trained and retainedor recruited by new employers when releasedprematurely into the labour market. Moreover,there is evidence that many over-50 workers

Page 46: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

40

Employee participation and company performance

positively wish to remain in paid employment(Mooney and Statham, 2002). Third, earlyretired people may have years of active lifeahead of them but face social exclusion andisolation through the lack of job opportunitiesimposed on them by age-discriminatoryemployers. Though the UK Government iscommitted to legislating against agediscrimination, experience from other Europeancountries suggests that the impact of suchlegislation, though positive, has not been strong(Hornstein, 2001).

Individual employees are clearly in a weakposition to combat age-discriminatory practices– first because individuals are in a far weakernegotiating position than their employers;second because, in common with otherexclusionary practices, age discrimination canbe disguised and implicit; and third because, inthe UK, there are no sanctions imposed onemployers who practise age discrimination. Aswith other areas of discrimination, unions cantherefore potentially be important sources ofaction, both in the political arena, for example tocampaign for effective legislation, and as part oftheir bargaining and consultative activitieswithin organisations. However, there is littleevidence at present that unions have beenproactive in this dimension of protecting theirmembers. With an increasingly youthful labourforce, mobilising support for older workercampaigns can be difficult. As older employeesare also more likely to be in trade unions (Cullyet al. 1999, p. 26), where these are recognised it istherefore in the interests of unions to ensure thatemployers adopt and exercise fair policies andpractices. Arguably, it is also in the economicinterests of employers to recruit and retain olderstaff, who tend to be loyal to their employers

and have considerable experience to share withcolleagues, thereby stimulating and reinforcingorganisational learning.

Participation and family life

This report has demonstrated that employeevoice can potentially take a variety of forms,often expressed either as direct individualemployee involvement ‘on matters which affectthem’ (CBI News, 1990) or as more indirectrepresentative participation through processesof collective bargaining or joint consultation(Cully et al., 1999). Two justifications aregenerally made for the articulation of employeevoice. First, it is presented as a democratic right,increasingly anticipated by an educated,experienced and knowledgeable workforce(Bean, 1994). Second, it is contended, supportedby empirical evidence, that expression ofemployee voice can be associated with positiveperformance outcomes (Heller et al., 1998, pp. 9,62) There are three principal arguments tosupport this. The first is that managerialdecisions informed by employee contributionsare of higher quality. Following on from this,employees may respond more positively todecisions that they feel they have been able toinfluence. Third, the availability ofopportunities to participate in decisions isbelieved to exert direct behavioural effects onemployee commitment, motivation andperformance (see, for example, Wilkinson, 2001).

As part of a wider JRF ‘Work and FamilyLife’ research programme, a recent study byBond et al. (2002) was concerned with two mainquestions: whether employees have a voice overwork–life issues and, if so, how instrumentalwas this voice in helping to establish family-friendly employment policies within

Page 47: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

41

Outcomes of participation

organisations. Other studies have examined thebusiness consequences of implementing suchpolicies and found that benefits could beassociated with them (Dex and Scheibl, 2001).With regard to the first question, and echoingWERS analysis, it does appear that employeesdo have a voice of some kind in organisationssuch as large financial institutions (Gall, 2001).In these larger organisations, the dominantvoice tends to be a collective one, expressedeither through independent trade unions or byemployer-supported staff associations.Typically, smaller enterprises lack collectivemeans of expression, though other studies in thesame programme show evidence of directcommunication between individual employeesand their employers over flexible working (Dexand Scheibl, 2002). Nevertheless, family-friendlypolicies appeared to be more widespread andmore deeply embedded in those enterprises thatrecognise unions. This association of coursedoes not a priori infer that unions have a moreeffective voice. As part of their research, Bondet al. (2002) studied four finance-sectorcompanies in order to examine the influence ofdifferent arrangements for articulatingemployee voice in greater detail. From bothmanagement accounts and evidence of thefamily-friendly arrangements in place, thesestudies show little evidence of significantoperational impact whether by trade unions,staff association or individual employees.

A number of factors help to explain thisapparent poverty of influence. First, in all fourcompanies, line managers were offered thediscretion or prerogative to apply policiesaccording to their organisational or evendepartmental needs. The evidence indicates thatthis discretion was applied in all four

companies. Employees and their representativesaccepted this situation without challenge. In thecompany where the union was recognised, thisacceptance was compounded by a generalaccommodative stance by the union towards theemployer and also by the absence of negotiationover family or domestic issues. Invariably, theunion would be involved through consultativeor informative discussions, rather than bycollective bargaining. Even if unionrepresentatives had been willing to confrontmanagers in a more assertive way, for exampleover the lack of uniformity of provisionassociated with the differential exercise ofmanagerial discretionary powers, they werewell aware (as were managers) of the overallapathy or passivity of their members. Withoutstrong member support, representatives wouldhave limited opportunities and few resourceswith which to pressure managers to codify or toenhance company family-friendlyarrangements. A final component emergingfrom the case studies is that many managers(and some trade unions, judging frominterviews carried out in the head offices ofunions active in the finance services sector, seeBond et al., 2002) continue to adopt a genderedand possibly marginalised perspective of work–life issues.

An analysis of nearly 100 line managers in arange of public and private sector settingsdrawn from different studies in the JRF ‘Workand Family Life’ programme confirmed the low-key role of trade unions whose ‘involvementfeatured very little in the managerial interviews’(Yeandle et al., 2003, p. 46). Consultation, evenwith and among line managers, also appearedto be rather restricted with the possibleexception of health services where significant

Page 48: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

42

Employee participation and company performance

consultation was pointed to by the linemanagers as part of NHS organisational culturaltraditions (Yeandle et al. 2003, p. 26).

Though the union role was not palpablydeveloped in either the finance sector or widelyreported in the broader study, levels of staffaccommodation to management were higherand overall provision of family-friendly policieswas lower in finance sector companies wherestaff associations formed the main instrumentfor employee voice. There were, however,instances at the small fund managementcompany of individual employees negotiatinginformal arrangements with their managers tosuit their individual circumstances. Similarinformal arrangements were reported by Dexand Scheibl (2002) in their specific studies ofSMEs and by Hyman et al. (2004) in their studyof software engineers. It should be borne inmind, though, that labour at the ‘professional’end of the financial services sector has been inshort supply, and that high proportions of thesestaff were highly educated, independent andassertive professionals operating in a tightlabour market. In all cases, indeed, the majorfactor influencing employers to implement orextend family-friendly policies has not beencollective or individual employee pressures butlabour-market conditions backed by minimalstatutory requirements.

The management of time is an essentialworkplace process over which employees,especially those with domestic responsibilities,need a measure of control in order to combattensions between the demands of work andhome. Evidence from the finance sectorindicates that, despite some softening of thepolitical climate towards trade unions and asectoral environment typified by scarcity of

labour, there is little evidence that employees,whether individually or acting collectively, havebeen able to make any significant impressionson the work–life agendas of companies, despiteevidence from Dex and Scheibl (2001, 2002) thatthere can be a business case for such policies.Earlier research has indicated that long workinghours, another major dimension of potentialwork–life conflict, have scarcely been touchedeither by the Working Time Regulations or byhigh-profile concerns expressed in the mediaand elsewhere. In terms of work–life balanceand family-friendly working, the evidencesuggests that the voices of employees remainfirmly muted.

Human rights, equality and participation

The evidence indicates that vulnerableindividuals and groups can be subject todiscrimination at work. Discriminationundoubtedly causes damage to individuals andindirectly to company performance. Variousinstitutions, both voluntary and statutory, havebeen established to combat discrimination.Among the most effective of these have beentrade unions who:

… have played a leading role in helping workersresist abuse … Along with higher wages andbetter benefits, protection from arbitrarymanagement actions has been a central concernfor trade unions. Unions protect workers fromabuse through providing grievance proceduresand through acting as ombudsmen foremployees.(Hodson, 2001, p. 102)

A recent example concerns an initiative ofthe Amicus finance and technical union to trainand support union representatives as ‘disability

Page 49: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

43

Outcomes of participation

champions’ to provide equality of opportunityfor disabled employees and to encouragedisability-friendly workplaces (Labour Research,2003b, pp. 15–16).

Statutory bodies include the Commission forRacial Equality (CRE) and the EqualOpportunities Commission (EOC), whichconcerns itself with gender equality, and therecently established Disability RightsCommission (DRC). Together with trade unionsand other campaigning bodies, theseCommissions have lobbied for reforms to extendemployment protection to cover age, disabilityand sexual orientation, all of which are currentlysubject to revised or forthcoming legislation.Another proposed reform is to merge theseCommissions to create a single body to deal withequality and human rights and to modernise thelaw on discrimination. Under governmentproposals, the new Commission for Equality andHuman Rights will eventually replace the threeexisting Commissions to provide, in theGovernment’s words, for a ‘fairer, more inclusiveand prosperous Britain’.

While most parties have welcomed theprospect of an integrated equality and rightscommission, there is no doubt that it faces amonumental task. While there is no question thatthe EOC and CRE have helped to progressgender and racial equality at work, after morethan 25 years, employment inequality,discrimination and abuse of individuals are stillpresent (see, for example, EOC, 2004) and therole of protecting employees’ rights at theworkplace will still largely be the responsibilityof trade unions and other supportive bodies. Thisrole will be enhanced and potentially made moredifficult if the proposed legislation for the newequality and rights body inclines to ‘the lighttouch’ favoured by employers and others

opposed to greater regulation of the labourmarket.

Summary

From the literature reviewed above, it would behard to conclude whether stand-alone employeeparticipation schemes have any predictableeffects, positive or negative, on companyperformance. A significant part of the problem isthe extreme difficulty in isolating the effects ofparticipation schemes because of the broad rangeof mediating factors. Without adequateknowledge of how and why participationschemes are achieving results, studies willcontinue to produce contradictory findings.

However, it seems clear that combinations offinancial and work-related participation schemesand collective and individualised participationschemes can exert positively synergistic effects.Of particular importance are the social andeconomic contexts into which a participationscheme is introduced. Changes in legislationconcerning participation and union recognitionare important considerations given the evidencelinking unionism to improved performance. Inaddition, the role of other, complementarylegislative and policy changes must be taken intoaccount since the combination effect appears toextend beyond bundles of participatory practices.

A major social obstacle to participatory formsof work organisation is that they can result inincreased work effort and responsibilities, whichcan be incompatible with family situations orcaring responsibilities (see White et al., 2003).Other significant implications are thatparticipatory schemes may amplify existingsocial inequalities in the workplace. First, theymay further exclude certain individuals or

Page 50: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

44

Employee participation and company performance

groups by making it difficult for them to takepart in these schemes. Second, compounddisadvantage may accrue through excludingthese employees from input into decisionmaking, thereby possibly distancing them furtherthrough consequent actions. Taking the economiccontext, a number of studies reported hereindicate that economic or business needs andnecessity are a principal driving force behindorganisational support for participation schemes,based on the assumption (supported by someempirical evidence and survey data) thatparticipation will engender employee attitudechanges in favour of management goals and thusachieve improved performance levels.

One issue that could unite advocates for bothorganisational performance and human rightswould be whether enhancing the latter throughreducing discrimination could positivelyinfluence employee orientations and behaviourtowards the company. Certainly there areindications that possessing and expressing a‘voice’ in organisational affairs can be associatedwith positive performance effects, and that acollective voice may be most effective. There arepractical problems, though: the evidence showsthat, even where unions are recognised, theirimpact on human rights issues, such as work–lifebalance or promoting gender equality, may bemuted. Second, union membership and influencehas declined spectacularly over the past 20 yearsand shows few signs of revival, especially amongyoung people and in newer sectors of theeconomy (Labour Research, 2004, pp. 10–13).Third, employers do not necessarily associateunion presence with effective employee ororganisational performance, notwithstandingevidence that the most highly performing

organisations in the UK recognise trade unions(Labour Research, 2002, p. 10). Some commentatorshave argued that union revitalisation will occuras a result of the ‘representation gap’ foremployees, which has been generated throughthe decline of union presence, but evidence forsuch a revitalisation process is questionable(Hyman et al., forthcoming). This suggests thatgovernment policy consideration should begiven to greater support for union recognitionand activity, and for a stronger human rightsframework for the protection of vulnerableindividuals and groups of employees. Unionsthemselves, as the prime ‘champions’ for humanrights at work, also need to look at the mosteffective ways in which they could attract,represent and retain a more diverse membership.

However, WERS98 demonstrates that manyparticipation schemes are currently in operationand, as a result of current government policy aswell as shifts to ‘knowledge’ work requiringcommitted employees, many more are likely tobe introduced. While the literature does inclinetowards confirming the efficacy of combinationsof financial and control rewards and collectiveand direct participation schemes, without anadequate understanding of the contexts andchain of processes that the introduction ofparticipation programmes sets in motion, theconsequences for workers and management arelikely to cause unilateral or even bilateraldisappointment.

Note

1 WERS98 results show that union recognitionis associated with higher rates of absenteeism(Addison and Belfield, 2001).

Page 51: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

45

Implications of government policy and

proposals

The extent of current support for employeeparticipation in the UK is fairly limited and attimes unco-ordinated. For example, work-related participation policies are focused onefforts to promote collective participation, e.g.through social partnership, while, on the otherhand, financial participation legislation leanstowards individualised participationprogrammes, such as sharesave programmes.The combination of the two forms ofparticipation is left to voluntary application,notwithstanding results suggested in theliterature that a combination of participationpolicies is likely to be the most, if not the only,effective means of influencing companyperformance. While government policysupports both financial and work-relatedparticipation, there is no legislation that wouldpromote the implementation of both forms.

Furthermore, there appears to have beenlittle attention paid to the changing nature ofwork. Increases in contracting-out of activitiesand services and the rise in the use of atypicalforms of work, such as agency workers, areassociated with a drop in the numbers ofdirectly employed people (Cully et al., 1999).This obviously has implications for the numberof workers covered by company participationschemes. The importance of these changescannot be overstated, as many occupations vitalto the health of the economy or to social well-being are not necessarily in direct employment.For example, software is now thought to be thelargest global knowledge-based industry. In theUK, numbers of software occupations rose by 39per cent between 1996 and 2000, compared with

an increase of just 2 per cent in the economicallyactive population. Large proportions of theseworkers are found in indigenous software SMEsand increasing numbers work in agency, sub-contracted and temporary positions, rather thanas established employees. Similar forms ofatypical work are common in key areas of thepublic services, such as the NHS, again raisingthe possibility of exclusion of these staff fromparticipative initiatives such as partnership,which otherwise are making considerableheadway in the public sector (Workplace Report,2003, p. 4).

Financial participation policies

As the literature demonstrates, someparticipation schemes may engender low-trustrelations (McNabb and Whitfield, 1998), a resultthat runs counter to the intentions in, and theassumptions behind, much of the policy in thisarea. Promotion of individual stakeholding foremployees could prejudice the ‘new enterpriseculture of team-work’ (Gordon Brown, Financial

Times, 4 November 1998) that the Governmentenvisages. As Kruse (1984) found, ownershipalone is unlikely to be enough to produce ormaintain attitude changes; participation indecision making is instrumental, a view alsosupported by Klein and Hall (1988). They foundthat ESOP employees were more satisfied themore the ESOP was committed to industrialdemocracy. This is not a recent revelation. TheUSA’s General Accounting Office’s extensive1985 federal survey of employee shareownership ‘found no relationship betweenESOPs and improved performance – except when

employee ownership was coupled with employee

participation in management decision-making’(Logue and Yates, 2001, p. 78, emphasis in

4 Policy implications and conclusions

Page 52: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

46

Employee participation and company performance

original). Therefore ownership per se is notenough to capture the organisational changesthat the Government is seeking andpsychological ownership appears to be a keyfactor. There should therefore be concern ifindividual stakeholding is promoted withoutequal weight being given to the introduction ofother participation measures in order to avoidthe development of a disillusioned and unco-operative workforce.

Work-related participation policies

The majority of work-related participationproposals have been left to voluntaryapplication, which provides a good deal ofscope for interpretation (or misinterpretation) ofgovernment intent at firm level (Summers andWinterton, 1998; Bond et al., 2002). Roughassumptions and inadequate definition of termsfrequently obscure the policy implications ofmuch of the research into the area of employeeparticipation and company performance. Forexample, the use of the word ‘flexibility’ ismired in controversy and has very differentmeanings for different interest groups such asthe CBI and TUC. The same can be said of theuse of the linked term, ‘participation’, andpotentially ‘partnership’, the flagship of currentUK policy initatives. This confusion ofmeanings results in ambiguous and obscurepolicy implications, allowing for vastly differinginterpretations of policy intent.

A central problem with policy in this areatherefore is that there are often discrepanciesbetween how a policy is conceived at national orenterprise level and how it is interpreted atestablishment or workplace level. As Ramsay et

al. (1998, p. 4) found in their superstores casestudies, ‘management style and personality’

play at least as important a part in the success ofparticipatory programmes as does companypolicy. The propensity for employees toparticipate is partly a result of management’scommitment to the programme and their abilityto make employees think that they are takingthe scheme seriously. Questions remaintherefore about where these policies are likely tolead, for both workers and employers. Ofparticular significance are the policyimplications and assumptions that underlie theEmployment Relations Act 1999 (ERA 1999) andthe Chancellor’s Pre-Budget Statement (HMTreasury, 1998a), which seem to ignore, oractively work against, the combination effect.For instance, the ERA 1999 actively excludesworkers in firms with less than 20 employeesfrom the union recognition rights enjoyed by allother workers.

Partnership

The term ‘partnership’ is used extensivelythroughout government policy and practice,relating not just to employee participation in theworkplace. In this way, partnership can be seenas ‘a central element in the policy of the Labourgovernment’ (Guest and Peccei, 2001, p. 208).The rhetoric of partnership is a key element ofthe Government’s policy thrust on employmentrelations, and has received considerable supportfrom the TUC in this approach. In support ofthis, the TUC has established its ownpartnership advisory body (the TUCPartnership Institute) for its member unions. Inaddition, the TUC’s own documents indicatethat partnership should benefit both employeesand organisations by improving the experienceof working life and by adding value to the firm.

Page 53: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

47

Policy implications and conclusions

Implications for equal opportunity

Policy implications for workers in small firms

The general lack of co-ordination of policyefforts concerning employee participationbecomes even more pronounced in small firms.As the WERS98 data show, small firms are lesslikely to introduce direct, individual forms ofparticipation, therefore there are fewopportunities for accessing the positive sumeffects of introducing financial and work-relatedparticipation. On top of this trend, governmentpolicy proposals work against the developmentof collective participation possibilities in smallfirms through the exclusion of these firms fromunion recognition rights. This has implicationsfor the participation opportunities offered toemployees of small firms, relative to theopportunities available to their counterparts inlarger enterprises. Furthermore, firms withoutindependent recognised unions are less likely toprovide their employees with a high quality andextensive quantity of other complementarypolicies, such as work–life balance provisions(Bond et al., 2002; Dex and Scheibl, 2002). Sincesmall firms employ a disproportionately highproportion of women and ethnic minorities, thepositive sum effects of participation schemesand other employee welfare polices are lesslikely to be found, and the negative sum effectsof a lack of complementariness could beproblematic for this sector on which theGovernment places such productivity hopes.

Employment Relations Act 1999

While the trade unions had overall positivelyreceived the Fairness at Work White Paper (DTI,1998) and the Employment Relations Act 1999that followed, they have voiced deep concerns

over the exclusion of around five millionworkers (many of whom will be trade unionmembers) from trade union recognition simplybecause their workplaces have fewer than 20employees. This has many contradictoryimplications for social partnership in smallfirms. From a perspective of sustainableemployment, firms that recognise trade unionshave a better training record than their non-union counterparts. Trade union recognition istherefore an important element in preventingmultiskilling from becoming synonymous withjob losses (Summers and Winterton, 1998). Forinstance, it could endanger the development oftrust relations by increasing the risk that ‘theonly way a union can pursue its recognitionclaim is by taking industrial action. That wouldbe entirely contrary to the spirit and aims of theWhite Paper’ (TUC, 1998, p. 4). Furthermore,given the prevalence of informal employeerelations in SMEs, the exclusion of many smallfirms from the recognition legislation couldopen up employees to ‘numerous workplaceinfluences, insecurities and other pressures’(TUC, 1997), as well as barring any form oflocal-level social partnership. As Table 2 inChapter 1 of this report demonstrates, smallfirms are also unlikely to introduce other ‘new’forms of direct participation. The exclusion ofsmall firms also sends the message to employersthat partnership with unions is a hindrance togrowth and flexibility, and that employees donot need formal procedures to be involved indecision making. The message in theEmployment Relations Act 1999 is therefore thatcollective participation through trade unions isincompatible with small-firm performance,while the message emanating from recent

Page 54: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

48

Employee participation and company performance

Budget statements is that individual financialparticipation is necessary for improvedproductivity.

For larger firms, there is also a policyambiguity between collective and individualemployee relations. The implementation of theWorking Time Directive sanctioned thepossibility that individual-type agreementscould be introduced into new starters’ contracts,thus forcing the choice between a job and acollective right. This is of particular concern forthe most vulnerable workers, in areas of highunemployment where there is a high degree ofcompetition for jobs.

There is therefore both a collective socialpartnership and an individualised financialparticipation approach to current employeeparticipation policy for large and small firms.However, the success of many employeeparticipation policies depends on how they areadministered within the firm, but the fewsignificant omissions and contradictions withinthe policies and proposals leave an ambiguity inhow the policies would be interpreted atenterprise level.

Implications for equal opportunities between

employees

As this review has demonstrated, a simpleassumed association between the introductionof participation, and attitude and behaviourchange can itself obscure many essential factors.Most of the literature on employee participationtakes the economic outcome as its main focus;little attention is paid, and many assumptionsare made, about the social outcomes foremployees. If, as seems clear, employeeparticipation cannot guarantee the resultsexpected by policy makers, what effects are

policies designed to promote participation likelyto have on the worker, and on companyperformance? For example, from an economicperspective, it is probable that firms makedecisions on which employee groups gain theopportunity to participate ‘because returns oninvestment in individual human capital aremost likely to differ significantly’ (Keller, 1995,p. 324), therefore excluding some employeesfrom opportunities to voice their concerns.

Given the results from the literature, policymakers should be especially concerned aboutthe implications for potentially excludedgroups. Ignorance of gender differences withinthe workforce could lead to participatoryschemes undermining equality in theworkplace, by realigning and reinforcing thepower distribution towards groups more ableand willing to participate. It is possible that, insome schemes, there are core groups who willreap the benefits of participation, andmarginalised workers whose desire and abilityto participate are depressed. This could havenegative consequences not just for growingnumbers of women at work but also for otherexcluded or marginal groups, such as minorityethnic workers or employees on temporary,casual, part-time or agency contracts. Alsodisadvantaged are workers whose job designdoes not enable them to easily participate, forexample shift workers, transport workers, salesrepresentatives, home workers and part-time,temporary or agency workers.

At the operational level, as this review hasshown, management methods are all too oftenbased on false assumptions about the nature ofthe workforce, resulting in probablediscrepancies between the objectives and resultsof participatory programmes. As Ramsay et al.

Page 55: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

49

Policy implications and conclusions

(1998) demonstrated, participation schemeshave to be far more sophisticated than manycurrently in operation in order to capture thehuman resources of the entire workforce.Important considerations for management indesigning a participation programme include:length of service of employees (especially if, asRamsay et al. discovered, some long-termfemale employees do not respond well tofinancial incentives); their types of work; andthe gender mix of the workforce. Theconsequences of unsophisticated schemes arepotentially even more alarming for equalopportunities at work.

Implications of European policy

Information and consultation procedures forman important element of the EU’s socialprogramme, expressed through Europeanworks councils (EWCs), the forthcomingInformation and Consultation directive andemployee participation aspects of the EuropeanCompany Statute adopted in October 2001.EWC legislation was introduced in the EU(excluding UK) in September 1996 and has beenin force in the UK since January 2000. EWCsapply to European companies employing morethan 1,000 employees with at least 150 in two ormore EU states. Areas of information andconsultation are required to be of a European(i.e. transnational) nature, with the forthcomingInformation and Consultation Directive (cominginto force March 2005) intended to deal withcompany issues at national level (see Labour

Research, 2003a).Under the previous Government, the UK

had opted out of the Social Chapter, whichprovided the basis for EWCs; however, many

UK-based companies and UK workforces,totalling around three million employees, werestill bound by the Social Chapter through theiroperations in other EU states (Labour ResearchDepartment, 1997). By 1999, there were morethan 550 EWCs throughout Europe (Gill andKrieger, 2000). It is estimated that, currently,there are about 650 EWCs of which almost 100are UK-based companies (Workplace Report,2003, p. 8). Nearly one in five managers inrelevant organisations surveyed by WERS98stated that their company operated an EWC(Cully et al., 1999, p. 100). Potentially, therefore,the representative scope for EWCs in the UK isconsiderable.

Initially, both positive and negativeoutcomes were predicted for UK companies. Onthe negative side, the costs of establishing andundertaking the information and consultationexercises were criticised by management.Another view, associated especially with NorthAmerican transplants concerned aboutcommercial confidentialty (see, for example,Royle, 1999), was that enforced adoption ofcommunication practices should not be part ofgovernment policy. Kersley and Martin’s (1997)study concluded that formal communicationsbetween employees and employers have littleeffect on productivity and that enforcedadoption of participation programmes actuallyadversely affects company performance.Keller’s (1995) work also supports this thesisand suggests that the more statutory provisionsa government places on the introduction ofparticipation ‘the probability for theintroduction of new forms of representation islower than in the opposite case’ (Keller, 1995,p. 324). From a decision-making perspective, theEWC directive has not specified tightly enough

Page 56: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

50

Employee participation and company performance

what is meant by ‘information andconsultation’, leaving the working definition tothe players at company level (Royle, 1999; Wills,2000). As a result, the interpretation of thedirective differs greatly between EWCs (Sloan,1998).

For some companies, this flexibility ininterpretation has had a positive outcome forcommunications and management–employeerelations; for others, the picture is more bleakwith management taking a very minimalistview of consultation. Further barriers toparticipation have been identified by theInvolvement and Participation Association (IPA)as ‘problems with resentful middlemanagement’ (Sloan, 1998, p. 8) blockingcommunication. In addition, delegates who ‘donot feed back at all to their constituents’ (Sloan,1998, p. 9) prevent effective participation of thewhole workforce. There has also beenscepticism expressed by the trade unions who‘are concerned that EWCs may be used tobypass existing bargaining arrangements andundermine trade unions’ (Labour ResearchDepartment, 1997, p. 4). However, the TUCsupports union involvement in EWCs in orderto prevent them becoming, in the words of JohnMonks, ‘tame bodies whose agenda andfunctioning is determined by the employer’.

From a more positive angle, the directive canwork in favour of promoting equality betweenmanagers and workers. Both the IPA and theLabour Research Department (LRD) studiesfound that the negative implications of EWCswere largely unrealised once companies hadestablished their new consultation procedures.Policy recommendations to facilitate successwould be the training of EWC delegates. Guestet al. (1993) focus on training as the failing area

in employee participation schemes and suggestthat the training for employee involvement ‘hasnot been successful in altering attitudes’ (Guestet al., 1993, p. 198). A European Foundationcomparative study of EWCs concluded that,while the influence of EWCs on systems ofindustrial relations is generally negligible, thereare signs that employee bodies are gaining abetter ‘Europeanised’ awareness of internationalstrategies; that greater co-ordination betweenEuropean representatives is feasible; and thatformation of group-level representative bodiesmay allow employee representatives to gainbetter comprehension of company strategies(www.eiro.eurofound.ie/1998/07/study).Whether employers would welcome thesetrends is of course another question.

These uncertainties surrounding theperformance or other outcomes of EWCs arereflected in the DTI Consultation Paper onEWCs (July 2003) triggered by the CommissionReview. The Paper suggests that, while EWCs inthe UK are comparatively new, researchindicates that, from a positive point of view,EWCs can contribute to ‘better cross-businessco-ordination among management teams and abetter thought out corporate strategy’. Againstthis there have been claims of increasedbureaucracy and ‘unfulfilled employeeexpectations about what an EWC might achieve’(www.dti.gov.uk/er/europe/ewcdoc.pdf).Anecdotal evidence submitted to the DTIsuggests that costs of running an EWC canescalate to £250,000 annually.

The European Trade Union Confederation(ETUC) and the European Parliament wouldlike to see further refinement of EWCs,suggesting that information and consultationneed to be defined more clearly, to ensure that

Page 57: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

51

Policy implications and conclusions

these take place prior to decisions taken bymanagement. ETUC is also of the view thatEWC members need time to communicate witheach other and, in affirmation of other studies,that more resources need to be allocated totraining of employee representatives. Mergersand restructuring are also areas where EWCsmay need additional time in order to respond tomanagement proposals and decisions(http://www.etuc.org/EN/(ETUC).

In his summary review of EWC experience,R. Hyman (2000) stresses three points. First,there appears to be no standard model, with

each EWC influenced by national, sector andcompany factors interacting with individualdynamics. Second, EWCs evolve throughexperiences, circumstances and personalities.Third, an EWC with ‘internal cohesion andstrategic vision can achieve an impact’ (Hyman,R., 2000, p. 7). It seems that, in an eracharacterised by globalisation, partnership andforms of co-determination, a significant elementof the future of participation may well rest withcross-national bodies like EWCs, though there isas yet little hard evidence that these impactsignificantly on trans-European corporations.

Page 58: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

52

As demonstrated in the body of this report,there is now a massive and expanding volumeof literature on all manifestations of employeeparticipation. From this body of work, someuncomfortable conclusions emerge.

First, the relevance of the topic isundiminished as employee needs (and unionrequests) for information and influence persistin an uncertain and insecure world in whichdistance between governors and governedappears to be growing in the globalisedeconomy. At the same time, employers facecontinual pressures to be competitive byreducing costs and optimising outputs whileattracting, deploying and retaining highlyskilled labour. ‘Best ways’ of managinginevitably confront issues of reconciling levelsand embeddedness of communication andinfluence for employees and for managers. Thedifferent participative rationales identified inChapter 2 confirm the ambiguities andcomplexities facing all the social partners. Afurther participation problem for bothemployers and for workers derives from thechanging nature of the workforce, as flexibleregimes involving part-time, home-working,agency and contracted staff introduceincreasingly heterogeneous labour resourcesinto organisations (see Felstead and Jewson,1999).

Unfortunately, considerable uncertainty stillsurrounds the outcomes of participation,especially in terms of contribution toorganisational performance. In Appendix 1, thereport points to methodological issues,especially in terms of identifying direction ofcausality, as a major weakness to understandinglinks between employee attitudes, levels ofcommitment, behaviour and company

performance. The role of unions in contributingto these variables is still debated. Outcomesthemselves have tended, especially in thedominant American literature, to be assessedaccording to finance indicators. One weaknessinherent in this approach is the potential neglectof other perhaps more qualitative measures ofperformance. Second, and related to this, is therisk of neglecting research in non-profit-seekingorganisations such as critical areas of the publicsector (health service, education, social services,etc.) and voluntary organisations.

Nevertheless, there are positive indications.For example, financial participation appears toexert an effect on employee orientations andpossibly behaviour if a genuine ‘ownershipeffect’ can be established. Whether, thisrelationship would hold at a time of stockmarket fluctuation and decline in share valuesis, of course, a question that has not beenconfronted empirically. Second, there is someevidence that combinations of participativeapproaches may be associated with indicators ofenhanced performance, though there is moredoubt about management-initiated high-performance regimes predicated largely onindividualistic assumptions about theemployment relationship. This introduces thepoint that the assumed shift to individualisticvalues – and hence employees’ willingacceptance of management policies designed toengage with these values – has yet to beestablished. Third, the evidence on Europeanworks councils is mixed, though there is littleevidence of any significant negative effectseither for the employer or for employees.Nevertheless, training for the latter has beenidentified as a major requirement for the futureif employee representatives are to make a

5 Conclusions

Page 59: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

53

Conclusions

significant impression on these institutions. Nodoubt, our understanding of the processes andoutcomes of these cross-national bodies willgrow as further research over their activities andexperiences is commissioned. Fourth, while thejury is still out on the effects of partnershipschemes, there are at least short-termindications that, where unions are fullyinvolved and the parameters of partnership arefounded on agreed commitments andcontributions by both parties, employmentrelationships can benefit. Fifth, the potentiallymarginalised status of workers vulnerable todiscrimination is being recognised by theGovernment and European bodies as well asbodies committed to addressing equality andperformance (e.g. the Chartered Institute for

Personnel and Development’s campaign againstageism at work) and this recognition is beingreflected in new anti-discrimination legislation.Finally, after 20 years of decline, there are smallsigns of union revival as the unions come toterms with the need to attract a more diversemembership in a less oppressive politicalclimate. Participation through trade unions, asrecognised institutional protectors ofmarginalised and disadvantaged employees,supported by appropriate legislation, may bethe most visible and effective means of ensuringthat all employees have access to full equalityand human rights at the workplace and,alongside this, the potential to contribute toorganisational effectiveness.

Page 60: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

54

Ackers, P. and Payne, J. (1998) ‘British tradeunions and social partnership: rhetoric, realityand strategy’, International Journal of Human

Resource Management, Vol. 9, No. 3, pp. 529–50

Ackers, P., Marchington, M., Wilkinson, A. andGoodman, P. (1992) ‘The use of cycles?Explaining employee involvement in the 1990s’,Industrial Relations Journal, Vol. 23, No. 4,pp. 268–83

Ackroyd, S. and Procter, S. (1998) ‘Britishmanufacturing organization and workplace-industrial relations: some attributes of the newflexible firm’, British Journal of Industrial

Relations, Vol. 36, No. 2, pp. 163–84

Adam, E. (1991) ‘Quality circle performance’,Journal of Management, Vol. 17, No. 1, pp. 25–39

Addison, J. and Belfield, C. (2001) ‘Updating thedeterminants of firm performance: estimationusing the 1998 UK Workplace EmployeeRelations Survey’, British Journal of Industrial

Relations, Vol. 39, No. 3, pp. 341–66

Alchian, A.A. and Demsetz, H. (1972)‘Production, information costs, and economicorganization’, American Economic Review, Vol. 62,No. 5, pp. 777–95

Allen, D.G. and Griffeth, R.W. (1997) ‘Verticaland lateral information processing: the effects ofgender, employee classification level, and mediarichness on communication and workoutcomes’, Human Relations, Vol. 50, No. 10,pp. 1261–73

Allen, C., Cunningham, I. and McArdle,L. (1991) Employee Participation and Involvement

in the 1990s. Stockton: Jim Conway Foundation

Arthur, S. (2003) Money, Choice and Control: The

Financial Circumstances of Early Retirement.Bristol: Policy Press

Bacon, N. and Blyton, P. (2000) ‘The diffusion ofteamworking and new working practices: whatrole do industrial relations factors play?’, inS. Procter and F. Mueller Teamworking.Basingstoke: Macmillan

Baddon, L., Hunter, L., Hyman, J., Leopold, J.and Ramsay, H. (1989) People’s Capitalism? A

Critical Analysis of Profit-sharing and Employee

Share Ownership. London: Routledge

Barker, J.R. (1993) ‘Tightening the iron cage:concertive control in self-managing teams’,Administrative Science Quarterly, Vol. 38, No. 3,pp. 408–37

Barnes, H., Parry, J. and Lakey, J. (2002) Forging a

New Future: The Experiences and Expectations of

People Leaving Paid Work over 50. Bristol: PolicyPress

Bartlett, W. (1994) ‘Property and contract ineconomics: the case for economic democracy’,Economic and Industrial Democracy, Vol. 15, No. 2,pp. 296–8

Batstone, E. (1983) ‘Organisation andorientation: a life cycle model of French co-operatives, Economic and Industrial Democracy,Vol. 4, No. 2, pp. 139–61

Batt, R. and Appelbaum, E. (1995) ‘Workerparticipation in diverse settings: does formaffect the outcome, and, if so, who benefits?’,British Journal of Industrial Relations, Vol. 33,No. 3

Bibliography

Page 61: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

55

Bibliography

Bean, R. (1994) Comparative Industrial Relations.London: Routledge

Bell, D.W. (1979) Industrial Participation. London:Pitman

Bell, D.W. and Hanson, C.G. (1987) Profit-sharing

and Profitability. London: Kogan Page

Ben-Ner, A. (1988) ‘Comparative empiricalobservations on worker owned and capitalistfirms’, International Journal of Industrial

Re-organisation, Vol. 6

Ben-Ner, A. and Jones, D.C. (1995) ‘Employeeparticipation, ownership and productivity: atheoretical framework’, Industrial Relations,Vol. 34, No. 4, pp. 532–54

Benschop, Y. and Doorewaard, H. (1998) ‘Six ofone and half a dozen of the other: the gendersubtext of Taylorism and team-based work’,Gender, Work and Organisation, Vol. 5, No. 1,pp. 5–18

Blasi, J. and Kruse, D. (1991) The New Owners.New York: Harper Business

Blasi, J., Conte, M. and Kruse, D. (1996)‘Employee stock ownership and corporateperformance among public companies’,Industrial and Labor Relations Review, Vol. 50,No. 1, pp. 60–80

Bond, S., Hyman, J., Summers, J. and Wise, S.(2002) Family-friendly Working? Putting Policy

into Practice. York: York Publishing Services

Bonin, J.P., Jones, D.C. and Putterman, L. (1993)‘Theoretical and empirical studies of producerco-operatives: will ever the twain meet?’, Journal

of Economic Literature, Vol. 31, No. 3, pp. 1290–1320

Bradley, H., Erickson, M., Stephenson, C. andWilliams, S. (2000) Myths at Work. Bristol: PolityPress

Bradley, K. and Gelb, A. (1983) Co-operation at

Work: The Mondragon Experience. London:Heinemann

Bradley, K. and Gelb, A. (1986) Share Ownership

for Employees. London: Public Policy Centre

Bradley, K. and Nejad, A. (1989) Managing

Owners: The National Freight Company Buy-out in

Perspective. Cambridge: Cambridge UniversityPress

Brewster, C., Gill, C. and Richbell, S. (1981)‘Developing an analytical approach to industrialrelations policy’, Personnel Review, Vol. 10, No. 2,pp. 3–10

Brown, C., Reich, M. and Stern, D. (1993)‘Becoming a high performance workorganisation: the role of security, employeeinvolvement and training’, International Journal

of Human Resource Management, Vol. 4, No. 2,pp. 247–75

Brown, J. and Quarter, J. (1994) ‘Resistance tochange: the influence of social networks on theconversion of a privately-owned unionizedbusiness to a worker co-operative’, Economic and

Industrial Democracy, Vol. 15, No. 2, pp. 259–82

Bryson, A. and Millward, N. (1997) Employee

Involvement in Small Firms. London: PolicyStudies Institute

Bullock, Lord Alan (1977) Report on the

Committee of Inquiry on Industrial Democracy.London: HMSO

Page 62: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

56

Employee participation and company performance

Burchell, B.J., Day, D., Hudson, M., Lapido, D.,Mankelow, R., Norton, J.P., Reed, H., Wichert, C.and Wilkinson, F. (1999) Job Insecurity and Work

Intensification. York: York Publishing Services

Cable, J. and FitzRoy, F.R. (1980) ‘Co-operationand productivity: some evidence from WestGerman experience’, Economic Analysis and

Workers’ Management, Vol. 14, No. 2, pp. 163–80

Campbell, A., Keen, C., Norman, G. andOakshott, R. (1977) Worker Owners: The

Mondragon Achievement. London: Anglo-GermanFoundation for the Study of Industrial Society

Castells, M. (2000) The Rise of the Network Society.Oxford: Blackwell

CBI News (1990) ‘A nation of shareholders’,November, pp. 8–10

Chelte, A.F., Hess, P., Fanelli, R. and Ferris, W.P.(1989) ‘Corporate culture as an impediment toemployee involvement: when you can’t getthere from here’, Work and Occupations, Vol. 16,No. 2, pp. 153–64

Coates, G. (1997) ‘Organisation man – womenand organisational culture’, Sociological Research

Online, Vol. 2, No. 3, www.socresonline.org.uk

Cohen, A. and Quarrey, M. (1986) ‘Performanceof employee owned small companies: apreliminary study’, Journal of Small Business

Management, April

Conte, M. and Svejnar, J. (1988) ‘Productivityeffects of worker participation in management,profit-sharing, worker ownership of assets andunionization in US firms’, International Journal of

Industrial Organisation, Vol. 6, March

Cooke, W. (1992) ‘Product quality improvementthrough employee participation: the effects ofunionisation and joint union–managementadministration’, Industrial and Labour Relations

Review, Vol. 46, No. 1, pp. 119–34

Cooke, W. (1994) ‘Employee participationprogrammes, group based incentives andcompany performance: a union–non unioncomparison’, Industrial and Labour Relations

Review, Vol. 47, No. 4, pp. 594–609

Cornforth, C. (1983) ‘Some factors affecting thesuccess or failure of worker co-operatives: areview of empirical research in the UnitedKingdom, Economic and Industrial Democracy,Vol. 4, No. 2, pp. 163–90

Cornforth, C. (1995) ‘Patterns of co-operativemanagement: beyond the degeneration thesis’,Economic and Industrial Democracy, Vol. 16

Cornforth, C., Thomas, A., Lewis, J. and Spear,R. (1988) Developing Successful Workers’

Co-operatives. London: Sage

Cotton, J.L. (1993) Employee Involvement: Methods

for Improving Performance and Work Attitudes.Newbury Park, CA: Sage

Creigh, S., Donaldson, N. and Hawthorn, E.(1981) ‘ A stake in the firm’, Employment Gazette,May, pp. 229–36

Cressey, P. and Williams, R. (1990) Participation

in Change: New Technology and the Role of

Employee Involvement. Dublin: EuropeanFoundation for Improvements in Living andWorking Conditions

Page 63: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

57

Bibliography

Cressey, P., Eldridge, J., MacInnes, J. and Norris,G. (1981) Industrial Democracy and Participation:

A Scottish Survey. Research Paper No. 28.London: Department of Employment

Cully, M., Woodland, S., O’Reilly, A. and Dix, G.(1999) Britain at Work. London: Routledge

Cunningham, I., Hyman, J. and Baldry, C. (1996)‘Empowerment: the power to do what?’,Industrial Relations Journal, Vol. 27, No. 2,pp. 143–55

D’Art, D. (1992) Economic Democracy and

Financial Participation. London: Routledge

Defourney, J., Estrin, S. and Jones, D.C. (1985)‘The effects of workers’ participation onenterprise performance: empirical evidencefrom French co-operatives’, International Journal

of Industrial Organisation, Vol. 3

Delaney, J. and Huselid, M. (1996) ‘The impactof human resource management practices onperceptions of organizational performance’,Academy of Management Journal, Vol. 39, No. 4,pp. 949–69

Department of Employment (1986) Building

Businesses … Not Barriers. London: HMSO

Dex, S. and Scheibl, F. (2001) ‘Flexible andfamily-friendly working arrangements in UK-based SMEs: business cases’, British Journal of

Industrial Relations, Vol. 39, No. 3, pp. 411–32

Dex, S. and Scheibl, F. (2002) SMEs and Flexible

Working Arrangements. Bristol: Policy Press

DfEE (1998) UK Employment Action Plan.London: DfEE

Doucouliagos, C. (1995) ‘Worker participationand productivity in labour-managed andparticipatory capitalist firms: a meta-analysis’,Industrial and Labor Relations Review, Vol. 49,No. 1, pp. 58–77

Doyle, J. and Nathan, M. (2001) Wherever Next?

Work in a Mobile World. London: WorkFoundation

Drago, R. and Wooden, M. (1991) ‘Thedeterminants of participatory management’,British Journal of Industrial Relations, Vol. 29,No. 2, pp. 177–204

DTI/DfEE (1997) Partnerships with People.London: DTI/DfEE

DTI (1985) Burdens on Business. London: HMSO

DTI (1985) Lifting the Burden. London: HMSO

DTI (1998) Fairness at Work. White Paper.London: DTI

Dunphy, D. and Brynat, B. (1996) ‘Teams:panaceas or prescriptions for improvedperformance?’, Human Relations, Vol. 49, No. 5

EFILWC (European Foundation for theImprovement of Living and WorkingConditions) (1992) Report on European-level

Information and Consultation in Multinational

Companies – An Evaluation of Practice. Dublin:EFILWC

Emerson, T. (1982) The Story of Neighbourhood

Textiles. Cooperatives Research Unit, Case StudyNo. 6. Milton Keynes: Open University

Employee Participation in Company Structure

(1975) COM (75) 150. Brussels: European Union

Page 64: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

58

Employee participation and company performance

EOC (Equal Opportunities Commission) (2004)Sex and Power: Who Runs Britain? Manchester:EOC

Estrin, S., Jones, D.C. and Svejnar, J. (1987) ‘Theproductivity effects of worker participation:producer co-operatives in Western economies’,Journal of Comparative Economics, Vol. 11, No. 1,pp. 40–61

Felstead, A. and Jewson, N. (1999) Global Trends

in Flexible Labour. Basingstoke: Macmillan

Felstead, A., Jewson, N. and Walters, S. (2003)‘Managerial control of employees working athome’, British Journal of Industrial Relations,Vol. 41, No. 2, pp. 241–64

Fenton-O’Creevy, M. and Nicholson, N. (1994)Middle Managers: Their Contribution to Employee

Involvement. Employment Department ResearchSeries No. 28. London: EmploymentDepartment

Fernie, S. and Metcalf, D. (1995) ‘Participation,contingent pay, representation and workplaceperformance: evidence from Great Britain’,British Journal of Industrial Relations, Vol. 33,No. 3, pp. 379–431

Findlay, P., McKinlay, A., Marks, A. andThompson, P. (2000) ‘“Flexible when it suitsthem”: the use and abuse of teamwork skills’, inS. Procter and F. Mueller (eds) Teamworking.Basingstoke: Macmillan

Fitzroy, F.R. and Kraft, K. (1995) ‘On the choiceof incentives in firms’, Journal of Economic

Behavior and Organization, Vol. 26, pp. 145–60

Fletcher, D., Taylor, A., Hughes, S. and Breeze, J.(2001) Recruiting and Employing Offenders. York:York Publishing Services

Forsyth, D.R. (1990) Group Dynamics. PacificGrove, CA: Brooks/Cole Publishing Co.

Freeman, R. and Medoff, J. (1984) What do

Unions do? New York: Basic Books

Freeman, R. and Weitzman, M. (1986) Bonuses

and Employment in Japan. National Bureau ofEconomic Research, Working Paper No. 1878

Freeman, R. and Weitzman, M. (1988) ‘Bonusesand employment in Japan’, Journal of the Japanese

and International Economies, Vol. 1, pp. 168–94

French, J.L. and Rosenstein, J. (1984) ‘Employeeownership, work attitudes, and powerrelationships’, Academy of Management Journal,Vol. 27, No. 4, pp. 861–9

Frenkel, S., Korczynski, M., Shire, K. and Tam,M. (1999) On the Front Line. Ithaca, NY: ILRPress

Frick, B. (1996) ‘Co-determination andpersonnel turnover: the German experience’,Labour, Vol. 10, No. 2

Gall, G. (2001) ‘From adversarialism topartnership? Trade unions and industrialrelations in the banking sector in the UK’,Employee Relations, Vol. 23, No. 4, pp. 353–75

Gallie, D. and White, M. (1993) Employee

Commitment and Skills Revolution. London: PolicyStudies Institute

Gamson, Z. and Levine, H. (1984) ‘Obstacles tothe survival of democratic workplaces’, in M.Mellor, J. Hannah and J. Stirling (eds) Worker

Cooperatives in Theory and Practice. MiltonKeynes: Open University Press

Page 65: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

59

Bibliography

Garavan, T. and Morley, M. (1992)‘Organisational change and development:introducing flexible working groups in a hightechnology environment’, in D. Winstanley andJ. Woodhall (eds) Case Studies in Personnel.London: IPM

Geary, J.F. (1993) ‘New forms of workorganisation and employee involvement in twocase study sites: plural, mixed and protean’,Economic and Industrial Democracy, Vol. 14, No. 4,pp. 511–34

Gill, C. and Krieger, H. (2000) ‘Recent surveyevidence on participation in Europe: towards aEuropean model?’ European Journal of Industrial

Relations, Vol. 6, No. 1, pp. 109–32

Guardian Online (1998), 19 November

Guest, D. (1989) ‘Personnel and HRM: can youtell the difference?’, Personnel Management,January, pp 48–51

Guest, D. and Peccei, R. (2001) ‘Partnership atwork: mutuality and the balance of advantage’,British Journal of Industrial Relations, Vol. 39,No. 2 pp. 207–36

Guest, D., Peccei, R. and Thomas, A. (1993) ‘Theimpact of employee involvement onorganisational commitment and “them and us”attitudes’, Industrial Relations Journal, Vol. 24,No. 3, pp. 191–200

Guest, D., Michie, J., Conway, N. and Sheehan,M. (2003) ‘Human resource management andcorporate performance in the UK’, British Journal

of Industrial Relations, Vol. 41, No. 2, pp. 291–314

Hakim, C. (1996) Key Issues in Women’s Work:

Female Heterogeneity and the Polarisation of

Women’s Employment. London: Athlone

Hanford, T.J. and Grasso, P.G. (1991)‘Participation and corporate performance inESOP firms’, in R. Russell and V. Rus (eds)International Handbook of Participation in

Organizations, Vol II. Oxford: Oxford UniversityPress

Hanson, C. and Watson, R. (1990) ‘Profit-sharingand company performance: some empiricalevidence for the UK’, in G .Jenkins and M. Poole(eds) New Forms of Ownership. London:Routledge

Harley, B. (2001) ‘Team membership and theexperience of work in Britain: an analysis of theWERS data’, Work, Employment and Society,Vol. 15, No. 4, pp. 721–42

Hartley, J.F. (ed.) (1992) Employment Relations.London: Blackwell

Hartley, J. and Barling, J. (1998) ‘Employeeattitude surveys’, in K. Whitfield and G. Strauss(eds) Restructuring the World of Work. Ithaca, NY:Cornell University Press

Heery, E., Keely, J. and Waddington, J. (2003)‘Union revitalization in Britain’, European Journal

of Industrial Relations, Vol. 9, No. 1, pp. 79–97

Heller, F., Pusic, E., Strauus, G. and Wilpert, B.(1998) Organizational Participation: Myth and

Reality. Oxford: OUP

Heyes, J. (1996) ‘A formula for success?Training, reward and commitment in achemicals plant’, British Journal of Industrial

Relations, Vol. 34, No. 3, pp. 351–70

Hirsch, D. (2003) Crossroads after 50: Improving

Choices in Work and Retirement. York: JosephRowntree Foundation

Page 66: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

60

Employee participation and company performance

HM Treasury (1998a) Pre-Budget Statement.London: HM Treasury

HM Treasury (1998b) Pre-Budget Report:

November. London: HM Treasury

HM Treasury (1998c) Consultation on Employee

Share Ownership. London: HM Treasury

Hodson, R. (2001) Dignity at Work. Cambridge:Cambridge University Press

Hornstein, Z. (ed.) (2001) Outlawing Age

Discrimination: Foreign Lessons, UK Choices.Bristol: Policy Press

Huczynski, A. and Buchanan, D. (2001)Organizational Behaviour. London: Prentice Hall

Huselid, M. (1995) ‘ The impact of humanresource management practices on turnover,productivity and corporate financialperformance’, Academy of Management Journal,Vol. 38, No. 3, pp. 635–72

Hyman, J. (2000) ‘Financial participationschemes’, in G. White and J. Druker (eds)Reward Management: A Critical Text. London:Routledge

Hyman, J. and Cunningham, I. (1998) ‘Managersas developers: some reflections on thecontribution of empowerment in Britain’,International Journal of Training and Development,Vol. 2, No. 2, pp. 91–107

Hyman, J. and Mason, B. (1995) Managing

Employee Involvement and Participation. London:Sage

Hyman, J., Scholarios, D. and Baldry, C. (2004)‘Getting by or getting on? Employee copingstrategies for home and work’, Work,

Employment and Society Conference, Manchester,September

Hyman, J., Lockyer, C., Marks, A. andScholarios, D. (forthcoming) ‘Needing a newprogram? Why is union membership so lowamong software workers?’, in W. Brown,G. Healy, E. Heery and P. Taylor (eds) The Future

of Worker Representation. Basingstoke: Palgrave

Hyman, R. (1997) ‘The future of employeerepresentation, British Journal of Industrial

Relations, Vol. 35, No. 3, pp. 309–31

Hyman, R. (2000) ‘Editorial’, European Journal of

Industrial Relations, Vol. 6, No. 1, pp. 5–7

Ichniowski, C., Shaw, K. and Prennushi, G.(1994) ‘The effects of human resourcemanagement practices on productivity’, mimeo,Columbia University

IDS (Income Data Services) (1989) Employee

Share Ownership Plans. Study No. 438. London:IDS

IDS (1990) Profit Sharing and Share Options.Study No. 468. London: IDS

IDS (1996) IDS Study. European Works Councils.Study No. 600. London: IDS

IDS (1998) Profit-sharing and Share Options.Study. No. 641. London: IDS

IRS/IRRU (1996) European Works Councils

Bulletin, No. 2, March/April

Page 67: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

61

Bibliography

Jackson, P., Sprigg, C. and Parker, S. (2000)‘Interdependence as a key requirement for thesuccessful introduction of teamworking: a casestudy’, in S. Procter and F. Mueller (eds)Teamworking. Basingstoke: Macmillan

Japan Productivity Centre (1989) Survey of

Institutions Concerning Leisure, Job Satisfaction and

Productivity. Japan Productivity Centre

Jensen, M.C. and Meckling, W.H. (1979) ‘Rightsand production functions: an application tolabour-managed firms and co-determination’,Journal of Business, Vol. 4

Jones, D.C. (1987) ‘The productivity effects ofworker directors and financial participation byemployees in the firm: the case of British retailco-operatives’, Industrial and Labor Relations

Review, Vol. 41, No. 1, pp. 79–92

Jones, D.C. and Kato, T. (1993) ‘On the scope,nature and effects of Japanese ESOPs’, Industrial

and Labour Relations Review, Vol. 46, No. 2,pp. 352–67

Jones, D. and Kato, T. (1995a) ‘Japan’, in D.Vaughan-Whitehead (ed.) Workers’ Financial

Participation. Geneva: International LabourOffice

Jones, D.C. and Kato, T. (1995b) ‘Theproductivity effects of employee stock-ownership plans and bonuses: evidence fromJapanese panel data’, American Economic Review,Vol. 85, No. 3, pp. 391–414

Jones, D.C. and Svejnar, J. (1982) Participatory

and Self-managed Firms: Evaluating Economic

Performance. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books

Juravich, H., Harris, H. and Brooks, A. (1993)‘Mutual gains? Labor and management evaluatetheir employee involvement programs’, Journal

of Labor Research, Vol. 14, No. 2, pp. 165–85

Kay, J. (1997) ‘A stakeholding society – whatdoes it mean for business?’, Scottish Journal of

Political Economy, Vol. 44, No. 4, pp. 425–36

Keef, S.P. (1998) ‘The causal association betweenemployee share ownership and attitudes: astudy based on the Long framework’, British

Journal of Industrial Relations, Vol. 36, No. 1,pp. 73–82

Keenoy, T. (1992) ‘Constructing control’, inJ.F. Hartley and G.M. Stevenson (eds)Employment Relations: The Psychology of Influence

and Control at Work. Oxford: Blackwell

Keep, E. and Rainbird, H. (2003) ‘Training’, inP. Edwards (ed.) Industrial Relations: Theory and

Practice. Oxford: Blackwell

Keller, B.K. (1995) ‘Rapporteur’s report:emerging models of worker participation andrepresentation, British Journal of Industrial

Relations, Vol. 33, No. 3, pp. 317–27

Kelly, J. and Kelly, C. (1991) ‘“Them and us”:social psychology and “the new industrialrelations”’, British Journal of Industrial Relations,Vol. 29, No. 1, pp. 25–48

Kersley, B. and Martin, C. (1997) ‘Productivitygrowth, participation and communication’,Scottish Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 44,No. 5, pp. 485–501

Page 68: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

62

Employee participation and company performance

Kessler, I. and Purcell, J. (1992) ‘Performance-related pay: objectives and application’, Human

Resource Management Journal, Vol. 2, No. 3,pp. 16–33

Kessler, I. and Purcell, J. (2003) ‘Individualismand collectivism in industrial relations’, inP. Edwards (ed.) Industrial Relations: Theory and

Practice. Oxford: Blackwell

Klein, K.J. (1987) ‘Employee stock ownershipand employee attitudes: A test of three models’,Journal of Applied Psychology, Vol. 72, pp. 319–32

Klein, K.J. and Hall, R. (1988) ‘Correlates ofemployee satisfaction with stock ownership:who likes an ESOP most?’, Journal of Applied

Psychology, Vol. 73, No. 4, pp. 630–8

Klein, K.J. and Rosen, C. (1986) ‘Employee stockownership in the United States’, in R.N. Stemand S. McCarthy (eds) International Yearbook of

Organizational Democracy, Vol. III. New York:Wiley

Knell, J. (1999) Partnership at Work. London: DTI

Knights, D. and McCabe, D. (2000) ‘Bewitched,bothered and bewildered: the meaning andexperience of teamworking for employees in anautomobile company’, Human Relations, Vol. 53,No. 11, pp. 1481–1517

Kochan, T. and Osterman, P. (1994) The Mutual

Gains Enterprise. Cambridge, MA: HarvardBusiness School Press

Korvajarvi, P. (1998) ‘Reproducing genderedhierarchies in everyday work: contradictions inan employment office’, Gender, Work and

Organisation, Vol. 5, No. 1

Krieger, H. and O’Kelly, K.P. (1998) ‘The extentof participation in Europe’, Transfer – Quarterly

Journal of the European Trade Union Institute,Vol. 4, No. 2

Kruse, D. (1984) Employee Ownership and

Employee Attitudes: Two Case Studies. Norwood,PA: Norwood Editions

Kruse, D.L. (1993) Profit-sharing: Does it Make a

Difference? Kalamazoo, MI: W.E. UpjohnInstitute

Kruse, D.L. (1996) ‘Why do firms adopt profit-sharing and employee ownership plans?’,British Journal of Industrial Relations, Vol. 34,No. 4, pp. 515–38

Kruse, D.L. and Blasi, J. (1997) ‘Employeeownership, employee attitudes, and firmperformance: a review of the evidence’, inD. Lewin, D. Mitchell and M. Zaidi (eds) The

Human Resource Management Handbook. London:JAI Press

Labour Research (1995) ‘Works councils: spot thewomen’, March

Labour Research (1997) ‘Thank you Sid, andgoodbye!’, March, pp. 23–4

Labour Research (2002) ‘Union recruiters goshopping’, September, pp. 9–11

Labour Research (2003a) ‘Staff get closer toconsultation’, August, pp. 17–18

Labour Research (2003b) ‘Making workplacesdisability friendly’, December, pp. 15–16

Labour Research (2004) ‘Union recruiters facenew employer hostility’, January, pp. 10–14

Page 69: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

63

Bibliography

Labour Research Department (1995) European

Works Councils. London: Labour ResearchDepartment Booklets

Labour Research Department (1997) European

Works Councils – Negotiating the Way Forward.London: Labour Research Department Booklets

Labour Research Department (2003) Lesbian and

Gay Workers’ Rights – an LRD Guide. London:Labour Research Department Booklets

Lawler, E.E. (1986) High Involvement

Management. San Francisico, CA: Jossey-Bass

Legge, K. (2001) ‘Silver bullet or spent round?Assessing the meaning of the “highcommitment management”/performancerelationship’, in J. Storey (ed.) Human Resource

Management: A Critical Text. London: Thomson

Levine, D.I. (1995) Reinventing the Workplace:

How Business and Employees Can Both Win.Washington, DC: Brooking Institution

Lewis, S. (1997) ‘“Family-friendly” employmentpolicies: a route to changing organisationalculture or playing about at the margins?’,Gender, Work: and Organisation, Vol. 4, No. 1

Little, S., Quintas, P. and Ray, T. (eds) (2002)Managing Knowledge. London: Sage

Logue, J. and Yates, J. (2001) The Real World of

Employee Ownership. Ithaca, NY: ILR Press

Lucas, R. (1995) Managing Employee Relations in

the Hotel and Catering Industry. London: Cassell

Lucas, R. (1996) ‘Industrial relations in hotelsand catering: neglect and paradox?’, British

Journal of Industrial Relations. Vol. 34, pp. 267–86

MacInnes, J. (1987) Thatcherism at Work. MiltonKeynes: Open University Press

Mackie, G. (1994) ‘Success and failure in anAmerican workers’ co-operative movement’,Politics and Society, Vol. 22, No. 2, pp. 215–35

McNabb, R. and Whitfield, K. (1998) ‘Theimpact of financial participation and employeeinvolvement on financial performance’, Scottish

Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 45, No. 2,pp. 171–87

McNabb, R. and Whitfield, K. (2000) ‘Worth soappallingly little: a workplace-level analysis oflow pay’, British Journal of Industrial Relations,Vol. 38, No. 4, pp. 585–610

Mahoney, T. and Watson, M. (1993) ‘Evolvingmodes of workforce governance: an evaluation’,in B. Kaufman and M. Kleiner (eds) Employee

Representation: Alternatives and Future Directions.Ithaca, NY: ILR Press

Marchington, M. (2000) ‘Teamworking andemployee involvement: terminology, evaluationand context’, in S. Procter and F. Mueller (eds)Teamworking. Basingstoke: Macmillan

Marchington, M., Parker, P. and Prestwich, A.(1989) ‘Problems with team briefing in practice’,Employee Relations, Vol. 11, No. 4

Marchington, M., Goodman, J., Wilkinson, A.and Ackers, P. (1992) New Developments in

Employee Involvement. London: EmploymentDepartment

Marchington, M., Wilkinson, A., Ackers, P. andGoodman, J. (1993) ‘The influence of managerialrelations on waves of employee involvement’,British Journal of Industrial Relations, Vol. 31,No. 4, pp. 553–76

Page 70: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

64

Employee participation and company performance

Markey, R. and Monat, J. (1997) Innovation and

Employee Participation through Works Councils:

International Case Studies. Aldershot: Avebury

Marks, A., Findlay, P., Hine, J., McKinlay, A. andThompson, P. (1998) ‘The politics ofpartnership? Innovation in employmentrelations in the Scottish spirits industry’, British

Journal of Industrial Relations, Vol. 36, No. 2

Martin, R. (1998) ‘The British tradition ofindustrial relations research: the contribution ofW.E.J. (Lord) McCarthy’, British Journal of

Industrial Relations, Vol. 36, No. 1, pp. 83–97

Martin, T.N. (1981) ‘A path analytic model ofhuman capital and organisational jobcharacteristics on female job satisfaction’,Human Relations, Vol. 34, No. 1, pp. 975–88

Mayoux, L. (1992) ‘From idealism to realism:women, feminism and empowerment inNicaraguan tailoring co-operatives’,Development and Change, Vol. 23, No. 2,pp. 91–114

Mellor, M., Hannah, J. and Stirling, J. (1988)Worker Co-operatives in Theory and Practice.Milton Keynes: Open University Press

Miller, R.W. and Prichard, F.N. (1992) ‘Factorsassociated with workers’ inclination toparticipate in an employee involvementprogram’, Group and Organisation Management,Vol. 17, No. 4, pp. 414–30

Mitchell, D. (1995) ‘The United States: flexibilityfirst?’, in D. Vaughan-Whitehead (ed.) Workers’

Financial Participation. Geneva: InternationalLabour Office

Monks, J. (1998) ‘Government and trade unions’,British Journal of Industrial Relations, Vol. 36,No. 1, pp. 125–36

Mooney, A. and Statham, J., with Simon, A.(2002) The Pivot Generation: Informal Care and

Work after Fifty. Bristol: Policy Press

Newell, S., Robertson, M., Scarbrough, H. andSwan, J. (2002) Managing Knowledge Work.Basingstoke: Palgrave

Nichols, T. and O’Connell Davidson, J. (1992)‘Employee shareholders in two privatisedutilities’, Industrial Relations Journal, Vol. 23,No. 2, pp 107–19

Nolan, P. and O’Donnell, K. (2003) ‘Industrialrelations, HRM and performance’, in P. Edwards(ed.) Industrial Relations: Theory and Practice.Oxford: Blackwell

Noon, M. and Blyton, P. (1997) The Realities of

Work. Basingstoke: Macmillan

Ohashi, I. (1989) ‘On the determinants ofbonuses and basic wages in large Japanesefirms’, Journal of the Japanese and International

Economies, Vol. 3, pp. 451–79

Ohkusa, Y. and Ohtake, F. (1997) ‘Theproductivity effects of information sharing,profit sharing, and ESOPs’, Journal of the Japanese

and International Economies, Vol. 11, pp. 385–402

Oliver, N. (1990) ‘Work rewards, work valuesand organisational commitment in anemployee-owned firm: evidence from the UK’,Human Relations, Vol. 43, No. 6, pp. 513–26

Osawa, M. (1989) ‘The service economy andindustrial relations in small and medium sizesfirms in Japan’, Japan Labor Bulletin, 1 July

Page 71: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

65

Bibliography

Osterman, P. (1994) ‘How common is workplacetransformation and who adopts it?’, Industrial

Relations and Labor Relations Review, Vol. 47,pp. 173–88

Patterson, M., West, M., Hawthorn, R. andNickell, S. (1997) The Impact of People

Management Practices on Business Performance.London: Institute of Personnel andDevelopment

Patterson, M., West, M., Hawthorn, R. andNickell, S. (1998) ‘ Impact of peoplemanagement practices on business performanceissues’, People Management, Vol. 22

Paton, R. (1978) Some Problems of Co-operative

Organisation. Milton Keynes: Co-operativeResearch Unit, Open University

Paton, R. and Lockett, M. (1978) Fairblow

Dynamics. Co-operative Research Unit, ResearchMonograph No. 2. Milton Keynes: OpenUniversity

Pencavel, J. (2001) Worker Participation. NewYork: Russell Sage Foundation

Pendleton, A. (2001) Employee Ownership,

Participation and Governance. London: Routledge

Pendleton, A., McDonald, J., Robinson, A. andWilson, N. (1995a) ‘The impact of employeeshare ownership plans on employeeparticipation and industrial democracy’, Human

Resource Management Journal, Vol. 5, No. 4,pp. 44–60

Pendleton, A., Robinson, A. and Wilson, N.(1995b) ‘Does employee ownership weakentrade unions? Recent evidence from the UK busindustry’, Economic and Industrial Democracy,Vol. 16, pp. 577–605

Pendleton, A., McDonald, J., Robinson, A. andWilson, N. (1996) ‘Employee participation andcorporate governance in employee-ownedfirms’, Work, Employment and Society, Vol. 10,No. 2, pp. 205–26

Pendleton, A., Wilson, N. and Wright, M. (1998)‘The perception and effects of share ownership:empirical evidence from employee buy-outs’,British Journal of Industrial Relations, Vol. 36No. 1, pp. 99–124

Perotin, V. and Robinson, A. (2000) ‘Employeeparticipation and equal opportunities practice:productivity effect and potentialcomplementarities’, British Journal of Industrial

Relations, Vol. 38, No. 4, pp. 557–84

Peters, T. and Waterman, R. (1982) In Search of

Excellence. New York: Harper and Row

Pfeffer, J. (1998) The Human Equation.Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business School Press

Pierce, J.L., Rubenfeld, S.A. and Morgan, S.(1991) ‘Employee ownership: a conceptualmodel of process and effects’, Academy of

Management Review, Vol. 16, No. 1, pp. 121–44

Poole, M. (1986) Towards a New Industrial

Democracy. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul

Poole, M. and Jenkins, G. (1990) The Impact of

Economic Democracy. London: Routledge

Poutsma, E. (2001) Recent Trends in Employee

Financial Participation in the European Union.Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications ofthe European Communities

Prattis, J. (1987) ‘Organisational change andadaptation: community co-operatives andcapital control in the Western Isles of Scotland’,American Anthropologist, Vol. 87

Page 72: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

66

Employee participation and company performance

Ramsay, H. (1977) ‘Cycles of control’, Sociology,Vol. 11, No. 3, pp. 481–506

Ramsay, H. (1993) ‘Recycled waste: response toAckers et al.’, Industrial Relations Journal, Vol. 24,No. 1, pp. 76–80

Ramsay, H. (1995) ‘Euro-unionism and the greatauction: an assessment of the prospects for theEuropean labour movement post-Maastricht’,Labour and Industry, Vol. 6, No. 2, pp. 13–44

Ramsay, H., Hyman, J., Baddon, L., Hunter, L.and Leopold, J. (1990) ‘Options for workers:owner or employee?’, in G. Jenkins andM. Poole (eds) New Forms of Ownership. London:Routledge

Ramsay, H., Parry, S., Paton, A. and Hyman, J.(1998) ‘The big sell: employee participation andgender in retail’, paper for 14th World Congressof Sociology, 26 July–1 August

Ramsay, H., Scholarios, D. and Harley, B. (2000)‘Employees and high-performance worksystems: testing inside the black box’, British

Journal of Industrial Relations, Vol. 38, No. 4,pp. 501–31

Rhoades, R. (1984) Milkwood Cooperative Ltd.Cooperatives Research Unit, Research StudyNo. 4. Milton Keynes: Open University

Rivest, C. (1996) ‘Voluntary European workscouncils’, European Journal of Industrial Relations,Vol. 2, No. 2

Roche, W. (2001) ‘The individualization of Irishindustrial relations’, British Journal of Industrial

Relations, Vol. 39, No. 2, pp. 183–206

Roche, W. and Geary, J. (2002) ‘Advocates,critics, and union involvement in workplacepartnership: Irish airports’, British Journal of

Industrial Relations, Vol. 4, No. 4, pp. 659–88

Rosner, M. (1984) ‘A search for “copingstrategies” or forecasts of co-operative“degeneration”’?, Economic and Industrial

Democracy, Vol. 5, pp. 391–9

Royle, T. (1999) ‘Where’s the beef? McDonald’sand its European Works Council’, European

Journal of Industrial Relations, Vol. 5, No. 3,pp. 327–47

Rubery, J. (1995) ‘Performance-related pay andthe prospects for gender pay equality’, Journal of

Management Studies, Vol. 32, No. 5, pp. 637–54

Rubery, J. and Edwards, P. (2003) ‘Low pay andthe national minimum wage’, in P. Edwards(ed.) Industrial Relations: Theory and Practice.Oxford: Blackwell

Scarborough, H. (ed.) (1996) The Management of

Expertise. Basingstoke: Macmillan

Schulten, T. (1996) ‘European works councils:prospects for a new system of Europeanindustrial relations’, European Journal of

Industrial Relations, Vol. 2, No. 3, pp. 303–24

Schultz, T.P. (ed.) (1995) Investment in Women’s

Human Capital. Chicago: University of ChicagoPress

Scott, A. (1994) Willing Slaves? British Workers

under HRM. Cambridge: Cambridge UniversityPress

Page 73: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

67

Bibliography

Sesil, J., Kroumova, K., Blasi, J. and Kruse, D.(2002) ‘Broad based employee stock options inUS “New Economy” firms’, British Journal of

Industrial Relations, Vol. 40, No. 2, pp. 273–94

Sewell, G. (1998) ‘The discipline of teams: thecontrol of team-based industrial work throughelectronic and peer surveillance’, Administrative

Science Quarterly, Vol. 43, No. 2, pp. 397–428

Shepard, E.M. (1994) ‘Profit-sharing andproductivity: further evidence from thechemicals industry’, Industrial Relations, Vol. 33,No. 4, pp. 452–66

Sinclair, A. (1992) ‘The tyranny of a teamideology’, Organization Studies, Vol. 13, No. 4,pp. 611–26

Sinclair, D.M. (1996) ‘The importance of genderfor participation in and attitudes to tradeunionism’, Industrial Relations Journal, Vol. 27,No. 3, pp. 239–52

Sisson, K. and Frohlich, D. (1998) ‘Thesignificance of consultation and delegation inthe forms of work organisation: the need for are-appraisal?’, Transfer: Quarterly Journal of the

European Trade Union Institute, Vol. 4, No. 2

Sloan, R. (1998) European Works Councils: Moving

Forward with Employee Consultation, A Guide to

Good Practice. London: Involvement andParticipation Association (IPA)

Steers, R.M. and Porter, L.W. (1979) Motivation

and Work Behaviour. New York: McGraw-Hill

Stevens, B. (1991/92) ‘Employee ownership andparticipation in the USA’, Industrial Participation,Winter, pp. 16–19

Summers, J. (2004) ‘A lexicon of conflict underconcertive control conditions’, Economic and

Industrial Democracy, Vol. 25, No. 3, pp. 447–73

Summers, J. and Winterton, J. (1998) UK

Employment Action Plan: An Analysis of the

Entrepreneurship Pillar. Brussels: European TradeUnion Institute

Taylor, P. and Ramsay, H. (1998) ‘Unions,partnership and HRM: sleeping with theenemy?’, International Journal of Employment

Studies, Vol. 6, No. 2, pp. 115–43

Taylor, R. (2002) Managing Workplace Change.Swindon: ESRC

Thelen, H.A. (1970) Dynamics of Groups at Work.Chicago and London: University of ChicagoPress

Thompson, M. (1993) Pay and Performance: The

Employee Experience. Report No. 258. Brighton:Institute of Manpower Studies

Thompson, P. and Wallace, T. (1996)‘Redesigning production throughteamworking’, International Journal of Operations

and Production Management, Vol. 16, No. 2,pp. 103–18

Thompson, P. and Warhurst, C. (eds) (1998)Workplaces of the Future. Basingstoke: MacmillanPress Ltd

Thornley, J. (1981) Workers Co-operatives: Jobs and

Dreams. London: Heinemann

TUC (1997) The Small Firms Myths: A TUC

Analysis of the Small Firm Sector within the UK

Economy. London: TUC

Page 74: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

68

Employee participation and company performance

TUC (1998) Response to Fairness at Work White

Paper. www.tuc.org.uk

TUC (1999a) Response to McKinsey, Productivity

and Partnership. London: TUC

TUC (1999b) Partners for Progress. New Unionism

in the Workplace. London: TUC

TUC (2001) Partners for Progress. Winning at

Work. London: TUC Partnership Institute

TUC (2002) Partnership Works. London: TUC

Tucker, J., Nock, S.L. and Toscano, D.J. (1989)‘Employee ownership and perceptions of work:the effect of an employee stock ownership plan’,Work and Occupations, Vol. 16, No. 1

Tynan, E. (1980a) Unit 58. Co-operative ResearchUnit, Case Study No. 1. Milton Keynes: OpenUniversity

Tynan, E. (1980b) Little Women. Co-operativeResearch Unit, Case Study No. 2. MiltonKeynes: Open University

Tynan, E. (1980c) Sunderlandia. Co-operativeResearch Unit, Case Study No. 3. MiltonKeynes: Open University

Tynan, E. and Thomas, A. (1981) Careers of

Activists in Workers’ Co-operatives. MiltonKeynes: Co-operative Research Unit, OpenUniversity

Tyson, L. and Levine, D. (1990) ‘Participation,productivity and the firm’s environment’, inA.S. Blinder (ed.) Paying for Productivity.

Washington DC: Brookings Institute

Vanek, J. (1977) The Labour-managed Economy.Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press

Vaughan-Whitehead, D. (ed.) (1995) Workers’

Financial Participation. Geneva: InternationalLabour Office

Waddington, J. (2003) ‘Trade unionorganization’, in P. Edwards Industrial Relations:

Theory and Practice. Oxford: Blackwell

Wadhwani, S. (1985) The Macro-economic

Implications of Profit-sharing: Some Empirical

Evidence. Discussion Paper No. 220. London:Centre for Labour Economics, London School ofEconomics

Walton, R.E. (1985) ‘From control tocommitment in the workplace’, in Manage People

not Personnel (1990). Cambridge, MA: HarvardBusiness Review Books

Weitzman, M. (1983) ‘Some macro-economicimplications of alternative compensationschemes’, Economic Journal, Vol. 93, No. 4,pp. 763–83

Weitzman, M. (1984) The Share Economy.Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press

Weitzman, M. (1985) ‘The simple macro-economics of profit-sharing’, American Economic

Review, Vol. 75, No. 5, pp. 937–53

Weitzman, M. and Kruse, D.L. (1990) ‘Profit-sharing and productivity’, in A. Blinder (ed.)Paying for Productivity: A Look at the Evidence.Washington DC: Brookings Institute

White, M., Hill, S., McGovern, P., Mills, C. andSmeaton, D. (2003) ‘“High performance”management practices, working hours andwork–life balance’, British Journal of Industrial

Relations, Vol. 41, No. 2, pp. 175–95

Page 75: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

69

Bibliography

Whyte, W.F. and Whyte, K. (1991) Making

Mondragon. Ithaca, NY: Participation andEmployee Attitudes

Wichman, A. (1994) ‘Occupational differences ininvolvement with ownership in an airlineemployee ownership programme’, Human

Relations, Vol. 47, No. 7, pp. 829–45

Wickham, J. (1998) ‘Squaring the circle?Participation, innovation and employment –some results from the EPOC survey’, Transfer:

Quarterly Journal of the European Trade Union

Institute, Vol. 4, No .2

Wilkinson, A. (2001) ‘Empowerment’, inT. Redman and A. Wilkinson (eds) Contemporary

Human Resource Management. Harlow: Pearson

Wills, J. (2000) ‘Great expectations: three years inthe life of a European Works Council’, European

Journal of Industrial Relations, Vol. 6, No. 1,pp. 85–107

Wills, J. and Myhill, T. (1997) ‘Stakeholding: canemployee ownership play a part?’, in Official

Proceedings, Fifth International Industrial Relations

Association Conference. Dublin: Oak Tree Press

Wilson, N. and Peel, M. (1990) ‘The impact ofprofit-sharing, worker participation, and shareownership on absenteeism and quits: some UKevidence’, in G. Jenkins and M. Poole (eds) New

Forms of Ownership. London: Routledge

Winterton, J. and Winterton, R. (1993) ‘Coal’, inA. Pendleton and J. Winterton (eds) Public

Enterprise in Transition: Industrial Relations in

State and Privatized Corporations. London:Routledge

Wolf, A. (2002) Does Education Matter? London:Penguin

Wood, A. (1993) Buzz Co-operative. MiltonKeynes: Co-operative Research Unit, OpenUniversity

Woodall, J., Edwards, C. and Welchman, R.(1997) ‘Organisational restructuring and theachievement of an equal opportunities culture’,Gender, Work and Organisation, Vol. 4, No. 1,pp. 2–12

Workplace Report (2003) ‘Employers are failing torise to childcare challenge’, No. 4, June,pp. 18–19

Yeandle, S., Phillips, J., Scheibl, F., Wingfield, A.and Wise, S. (2003) Line Managers and Family-

friendly Employment. Bristol: Policy Press

Page 76: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

70

We have seen that many uncertainties inidentifying participation outcomes arise fromdifferent types of study. Extreme care must betaken in analysing and interpreting studies ofemployee participation, not least because of thevarious definitions and meanings attached to‘participation’, which cloud the results. Furtherproblems arise from the methodologicalassumptions used in the literature.

Comparability of qualitative and

quantitative methods

There are profound problems within theliterature because of the mix of qualitative andquantitative methods, making comparisonstricky at best. Both methods provide differentpictures of participation processes andoutcomes within enterprises (see, for example,the debate between Ackers et al., 1992 andRamsay, 1993). Quantitative studies tend tofocus on the existence of participation methods,while qualitative works can also indicate thedepth or scope of use of participation methods.Quantitative studies may also over- orunderstate satisfaction levels, as satisfaction isknown to involve a comparison with what isthought feasible (Ramsay et al., 1998, p. 8).Obviously, different employees and employeegroups will have different perceptions of whatis feasible. A female worker, for example, maynot think that a male manager will take hersuggestions seriously and therefore she may notattempt to make any; however, her assessmentof satisfaction with a participation programmewill be based on what she considers feasible.The subjectivity of many measures ofparticipation also means that comparisonsbetween firms are problematic, as feasibility will

differ between enterprises and their differentstructures and cultures. Furthermore, errorsoccur through subjective judgements of thesuccess of participation schemes, particularlythrough respondent bias when self-reporting.Problems are also encountered throughsubjective judgements of what actuallyconstitutes ‘participation’ (Kochan andOsterman, 1994). Juravich et al. (1993) have alsoquestioned the reliability of surveys based ononly one party in the employment relationship.Other measurement problems are associatedwith the use of proxy variables (Kelly and Kelly,1991), which may be poor representations of, forexample, real levels of employee control.

Obscured causality

The conceptual problems within the literatureoutlined above have severe implications formethodological accuracy. Of particular concernare incidences of obscured causality and caremust be taken in accepting findings that arebased on untested assumptions about the firmor the nature of the workforce (Ben-Ner andJones, 1995; Fernie and Metcalf, 1995, p. 392).Without care, the reasons a firm has forestablishing a participation scheme can beincorrectly assumed, along with the direction ofcausation. This occurs in many studies becausemuch of the empirical research in this area isbased on cross-sectional data, which ‘makescausal inferences hazardous’ (Bryson andMillward, 1997, p. 9). For instance, aparticipation programme may have beenintroduced as an incentive towards improvedperformance or as a reward for exceptionalperformance. On the other hand, the schemecould have been adopted to prevent a hostile

Appendix 1

Methodological problems

Page 77: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

71

Appendix 1

buyer, e.g. the UK bus ESOPs, or to prevent thefirm from closing, e.g. Fakenham Enterprises orthe Benn Co-ops. A means of avoiding thisproblem would be the longitudinal, before-and-after study (Guest et al., 1993); however,surprisingly few studies in employeeparticipation use this methodology.

Multiple variables

In addition, many studies test for only onemeasure or form of participation and a numberof studies have shown that it is the cumulativeeffects of a number of forms of participation thathave the greatest effects on productivity.Ramsay et al.’s (1998) study found that femaleworkers were more likely to emphasise‘opportunity to improve decision-making’(Ramsay et al., 1998, p. 7), while male employeeswere more instrumental and stressed thefinancial rewards of participation. Therefore it isnot surprising that a mix of participatorymeasures will capture the needs of both maleand female employees.

Therefore, there is a methodological problemof omitted variables (Ben-Ner and Jones, 1995;Bryson and Millward, 1997), with the result that‘the estimates on employee ownership variablesthat arise from such studies may have thewrong sign’ (Ben-Ner and Jones, 1995, p. 551).Furthermore, the interaction effects ofcombination packages are still obscure, withvery little actual research into the processes atwork (Cable and FitzRoy, 1980; Kruse, 1993;Perotin and Robinson, 2000). For example, theprocesses within combination participationmeasures that result in the sum appearing to be

greater than its parts need to be identified(Kochan and Osterman, 1994). Therefore,without a full appreciation of how combinationsof organisational polices interact withparticipation schemes, conclusions concerningthe relationship between participation andproductivity are likely to be inaccurate to someextent and may account for the contrastingevidence provided by different empiricalstudies and between surveys undertaken atdifferent times under different legislative,economic and social conditions.

Generalisation

Finally, the generalisability of research findingsin this area can be called into question. Becauseof the mediating effects of variables such asemployee heterogeneity, different organisationalcultures and situations, and firm size, thelikelihood of a particular form of participationproducing the same results in more than oneorganisation is doubtful. Therefore success maybe claimed for participation in a particularworkplace, but this cannot then suggest that thisform of participation will be a successelsewhere. Plus, questions remain about theunderlying processes at work linkingparticipation with performance, as these may besituationally specific and therefore generalisingfrom these results may be misleading. Thisproblem could be exacerbated especially whendrawing comparisons across sectoral andnational boundaries where a host of culturalfactors intersect with different political andsocio-economic contexts.

Page 78: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

72

1 The Employment Relations Act 1999introduced a number of extensions toemployee rights. These can be summarised aschanges to individual workers’ rights,particularly in the area of family-friendlyprovision, and as alterations to collective,trade union rights. The introduction of theEmployment Relations Act has therefore beena significant piece of policy, which providesthe opportunity to research many differentaspects. These include the extent to which theAct has had a differential impact on forms ofparticipation in small firms compared tolarge firms – are smaller enterprises lesslikely to adopt representative participationmeasures? In addition, an analysis of theextent and impact of social partnership indifferent contexts is needed.

2 Concerning the question of sustainableemployment, research is needed into theassociations between forms of participationand training and personal development. Forexample, to what extent will the promotion ofsocial partnership improve job retentionthrough multiskilling?

3 A significant omission from the publishedresearch is analyses of different employeetypes and their differential access to thevarious participation schemes. Of particularinterest in the current policy climate is theinvolvement of marginalised groups inparticipation schemes. Who is likely to beexcluded, or included, and under whatconditions and forms of participation doesthis occur and what are the effects, especiallyin key growth areas such as software or instrategically vital areas such as the NHS?

4 Given continuing political emphasis on socialinclusion, research is needed to identify thenature of links between forms ofparticipation and the quality of workers’lives, and any benefits to the widercommunity.

5 Patterns and distribution of participation insmall firms and the reasons why small firmsare less likely to have participation schemesis an under-researched area. Are the lowlevels of reported participation because oftheir size or are there other factors (Brysonand Millward, 1997)?

6 Further research would also be beneficial intothe underlying meanings behind workers’orientations, responses and attitudes – towhat extent, why and how do they change?This could be linked with an exploration intothe meanings and expressions of employeecommitment. This research direction wouldessentially question the widespread relianceon attitude surveys in the literature, whichare often based on false assumptions aboutemployee responses. Research into employeeorientations could also examine in greaterdepth links between individualism,collectivism and participation and its effects.

7 A study into the combination effects ofdifferent forms of participation and theprocesses by which the sum is greater than itscomponent parts – the additional effects – isrequired. Is a new model of participationemerging? Recent research is suggestive of acomplementary effect between bundles ofhigh-influence policies in the workplace.Further research into combinations ofparticipation types with, for example, policies

Appendix 2

Further research

Page 79: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

73

Appendix 2

aimed at equal opportunities, unionism,work–life balance, dignity at work, bullyingand harassment, peer reviews, and employeedevelopment and training are called for,especially from a longitudinal perspective.

8 To examine these research questions, case-study approaches would complementexisting survey and quantitative data. Inaddition, to move away from mereassociation and to illuminate the question ofcausality between participation, attitude andbehaviour change, and increasedproductivity, more longitudinal studies of thechanges brought about by employeeparticipation and ownership schemes areneeded. In particular, qualitative studiescould be promoted in order to gain insightinto the processes at work once aparticipation programme has beenintroduced to an organisation.

9 Research into EWCs will need to continue,especially with the recent expansion of theEU to include new entrants in 2004. Again,longitudinal case studies could be anappropriate means to examine theimplementation and effects of EWCs andother emergent information and consultationprocedures.

10 Significant research on participation has beenconducted in the private sector, with ratherless emphasis on developments and effects inthe public sector. Research in this sector (andthe voluntary sector) to establish means,measures and effects would be of vitalinterest, bearing in mind interest attached torecruitment and labour turnover, for examplein the NHS.

Page 80: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

74

Approved deferred share trust (ADST)

Under this scheme, a company can give sharesto all its employees with a minimum of fiveyears’ service. Distribution is from a share pooland shares are kept in trust for three years toattract tax relief.

Attitude surveys

A survey involves the collection of information,usually by interviews or questionnaires, from asample of the target population. Attitudesurveys examine a variety of attitudes andbehaviours, such as beliefs, opinions, values,expectations and satisfaction (Hartley andBarling, 1998).

Autonomous work groups

Also known as ‘self-regulating work groups’.This method enhances participation at the shop-floor level, giving groups of workersresponsibility for the regulation, organisationand control of their jobs, and an influence ontheir immediate environment. The groups makedecisions on the following issues: thescheduling of work, allocation and rotation ofjobs, quality acceptability, organising breaks,selecting and training new members, providingmaintenance, and evaluating performance forpay purposes.

Co-determination

Germany offers the best known version of co-determination. Employee representatives,known as worker directors, sit on supervisoryboards, which act as an intermediary between

the shareholders’ annual meeting and themanagement. The make-up of these boards isknown as 2x + y, meaning one each of workerand shareholder representatives (2x) plus one ormore neutral members on the board (y), drawnfrom such bodies as ACAS. Supervisory boardstend to have the following powers:

• appointment and dismissal of themanagement board

• overseeing the work of the managementboard

• veto power over strategic issues.

Collective bargaining

In the British context, collective bargaining takesplace between management and trade unions atboth national and local (plant) level. However,the issues covered by collective bargaining tendto be narrow, concerning wages and other basicissues such as hours of work and holidays.

Company share option plans

Shares are distributed at the company’sdiscretion, usually to senior management.Shareholders have the option to buy shares atthe current market price at a future datebetween three and ten years later.

Employee buyouts

An employee buyout occurs when the whole ofthe workforce is invited to take part in thepurchase of a company or part of a companyfrom its current owners or from a receiver.

Appendix 3

Glossary of terms

Page 81: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

75

Appendix 3

Employee empowerment

Empowerment is seen as providing an extensionto employee authority by allowing workers totake decisions that were previously the preserveof their line managers and to assumeresponsibility for the consequences. This occurswithin an organisational culture of initiative,team work and flexibility (Hyman andCunningham, 1998).

Employee involvement

Employee involvement is a term associated withschemes that involve low-level, individualisedparticipation, with little or no input intocorporate or high-level decision making.

Employee share ownership plans (ESOPs)

An ESOP is a scheme designed to allow allemployees to become shareholders in theircompany. ESOPs can offer majorityshareholdings to employees. Exemption fromincome tax is available if shares are retained fora minimum of five years in trust.

Human resource management (HRM)

HRM describes a bundle of managementstrategies, with a common emphasis on theshared goals of employees and managers inorganisations. HRM treats employees as a keystrategic resource, turning employees frompassive recipients of decisions into activeinitiators within the organisation. As such, HRMdisregards any plurality of interests and appealsto the ideas of commitment and co-operation.

Industrial democracy

Industrial democracy is a phrase designed toencompass those measures that result in theequitable distribution of power withinenterprises. However, it can also be used todescribe entire social and economic systems,which have significantly different structures toconventional systems within which ademocratic firm may operate. Possibly the mostobvious example of a formally industriallydemocratic firm is the co-operative, whereownership and control are distributed evenlyamong the members.

Joint consultation committees (JCCs)

A process whereby management seeks theviews of employees before making a firmdecision. In practice, it is rare for a JCC to haveveto power over managerial decisions. Twospecific types of JCCs are works councils andjoint working parties.

Joint working parties (JWPs)

A typical JWP will consist of between six andten members, drawn from management andemployee representatives. In contrast tocollective bargaining, JWPs will often involvejoint problem-solving techniques, such as‘brainstorming’ sessions.

Management buyouts

Management buyouts occur when members ofthe management of a company negotiate topurchase the company from its current ownersor from a receiver, having organised the financeto support the purchase.

Page 82: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

76

Employee participation and company performance

Partnership

One of the themes of the Employment RelationsAct 1999 and its precedent, the Fairness at Work

White Paper, is partnership (or socialpartnership). The term implies a new approachto industrial relations, replacing adversarialrelations with a joint approach, betweenemployers, employees and their representatives,to solving workplace problems. Socialpartnership can also operate at the nationallevel, and is demonstrated by the jointconsultation document drawn up by the TUCand CBI, which fed into the 1998 UK

Employment Action Plan.

Performance appraisal

Performance appraisal schemes consist of theappraisee and their appraiser, usually animmediate superior. Together they will assessthe employee’s past performance, set goals forfuture performance and monitor how effectivelythese goals are achieved.

Performance-related pay

Performance-related pay is usually linked toindividual effort and is sometimes connected toappraisal schemes. Pay acts as an incentive andreward for performance.

Profit-related pay

Profit-related pay describes a portion ofemployee pay that is linked formally to theprofits of the company. Companies offer cash-based profit sharing to their employees forwhich bonuses are triggered by attainment ofstipulated profit levels.

Quality circles

The idea behind quality circles is to enableworkgroup teams to assess and implementimproved methods of production and deliveryof services. Quality circles consist of a group ofpeople coming together from the same workarea, performing similar work, who voluntarilymeet on a regular basis to identify, analyse andsolve their own work- related problems.

Save as you earn (SAYE)

Employees contract to save regularly with arecognised savings institution. At the end of thesavings period, employees can opt to takesavings with accumulated interest or use theamount saved to purchase company shares at aprice fixed at the commencement of the savingsperiod.

Savings-related share options

Savings schemes are open to all employees witha minimum of five years’ service. Shares can bebought at no less than 80 per cent of the currentmarket price in three, five or seven years’ time,based on accumulated monthly savings.

Suggestion schemes

Suggestion schemes are a procedure forsubmitting and evaluating ideas. Suggestionboxes, suggestion committees, or individualmanagement can all be used as the transmissionagency for ideas.

Page 83: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

77

Appendix 3

Team briefing

Also known as briefing groups, team briefingswork on the principle of cascading informationdown the line from executive managementthrough line management/supervisors to theshop floor.

Team building and team work

This involves the organisation of employees intowork groups, which take responsibility for aprocess. Demarcation is eliminated, directsupervision reduced and a goal-oriented cultureencouraged.

Total quality management (TQM)

TQM is concerned primarily with meeting theneeds of customers. Through increasing workerinput into problem solving and enlargingemployees’ areas of responsibility, the‘continuous improvement’ of product qualityand work organisation is promised (Thompsonand Warhurst, 1998).

Worker co-operatives

Co-operatives are businesses owned andcontrolled by the people working in them. Co-operatives are democratic organisationsadministered by people elected or appointed ina manner agreed by the members andaccountable to them. Members enjoy equalvoting rights (one member, one vote) andparticipation in decisions affecting theirenterprises.

Worker directors

Worker directors are pulled from the employeebody to represent workers’ views on the Boardof Directors. Worker directors may be elected orselected, and many are drawn from the tradeunion body.

Works councils

Works councils potentially involve employeerepresentatives in strategic decision making.They may also serve as a channel forinformation disclosure and consultation, e.g.European works councils.

Page 84: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the
Page 85: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

Titles available in the Work and Opportunity series:

Published in 1998

Local responses to long-term unemployment

Mike Campbell with Ian Sanderson and Fiona Walton

A review of research to date on how to reconnect the long-term unemployed to the labour market.£12.95

Published in 1999

Company recruitment policies: Implications for production workers

Stanley Siebert

This study explores whether increased regulation of the labour market has an impact on hiringstandards, screening out less qualified workers and so reducing their job opportunities.£12.95

Young men, the job market and gendered work

Trefor Lloyd

A study of whether young men are being adequately prepared for the contemporary workplace, andwhether their, or others’, gender assumptions are affecting their opportunities.£10.95

Back to work: Local action on unemployment

Ian Sanderson with Fiona Walton and Mike Campbell

This report complements Local responses to long-term unemployment (above), presenting detailed case-study research into what local action is effective in getting people into work.£13.95

Ending exclusion: Employment and training schemes for homeless young people

Geoffrey Randall and Susan Brown

An evaluation of the particular difficulties in finding work faced by this group, and an assessment ofthe impact of a range of projects designed to assist them.£13.95

Job insecurity and work intensification: Flexibility and the changing boundaries of work

Brendan J. Burchell, Diana Day, Maria Hudson, David Ladipo, Roy Mankelow, Jane P. Nolan, Hannah Reed,

Ines C. Wichert and Frank Wilkinson

An exploration into the effect of job insecurity on the social, physical and psychological well-being ofemployees.£13.95

Page 86: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

Finding work in rural areas: Barriers and bridges

Sarah Monk, Jessica Dunn, Maureen Fitzgerald and Ian Hodge

A timely analysis of disadvantage in rural areas, and the role employment plays in this. The reportfocuses on the particular problems people in rural areas face and what strategies work in attemptingto find work.£12.95

Work and young men

Bruce Stafford, Claire Heaver, Karl Ashworth, Charlotte Bates, Robert Walker, Steve McKay and

Heather Trickey

A study which analyses whether certain young men are underachieving, and what the long-termconsequences of this are. The authors also review the social, personal and economic factors that affecthow young men are integrated into the labour market.£13.95

Making the grade: Education, the labour market and young people

Peter Dolton, Gerry Makepeace, Sandra Hutton and Rick Audas

The decisions young people make when they first become eligible to leave school are crucial to theirlong-term prospects. This wide-ranging study investigates what influences a child’s performanceand choices during this important time.£14.95

Young Caribbean men and the labour market: A comparison with other ethnic groups

Richard Berthoud

An exploration of the challenges faced by a group of young people with an exceptionally high risk ofunemployment. The study relates young Caribbean men’s experiences in the labour market to otherethnic groups, whose employment prospects vary substantially.£14.95

Published in 2000

Young people in rural Scotland: Pathways to social inclusion and exclusion

Stephen Pavis, Stephen Platt and Gill Hubbard

This report provides substantial first-hand evidence of what life is like for rural young people today.It explores the impact of education on their work opportunities, and how rural wages, availableaccommodation and isolation affect their lifestyle and their transitions to adulthood.£12.95

Youth unemployment in rural areas

Fred Cartmel and Andy Furlong

A review of the distinctive features of rural youth unemployment, including seasonal work,transport issues and the importance of local networks in obtaining work.£12.95

Page 87: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

Successful futures? Community views on adult education and training

Helen Bowman, Tom Burden and John Konrad

This study focuses on the perceptions and experiences of people who have taken part in the newGovernment schemes designed to enable them to find work and increase their skills.£12.95

The intermediate labour market: A tool for tackling long-term unemployment

Bob Marshall and Richard Macfarlane

An examination of ILM programmes, designed to move people back into work. It looks at theirstructure, and what factors lie behind achieving successful implementation and results.£13.95

Enduring economic exclusion: Disabled people, income and work

Tania Burchardt

This report offers detailed analysis of the position of disabled people in the labour market and in theincome distribution, and how the situation has changed since the 1980s.£14.95

Published in 2001

Everything under a fiver: Recruitment and retention in lower paying labour markets

Donna Brown, Richard Dickens, Paul Gregg, Stephen Machin and Alan Manning

A study of firms offering ‘entry-level’ jobs, whose wages are in the bottom fifth of the nationalearnings distribution. The report not only throws light on how these firms and their workers behave,but also explores how their behaviour relates to economic theory.£13.95

Young men on the margins of work: An overview report

Pamela Meadows

An overview of a series of JRF-funded research projects, which looked at young men’s experience inthe labour market during the 1990s, against a background of social and technological change. Theauthor draws out the key findings and conclusions from this large body of research.£10.95

What works locally? Key lessons on local employment policies

Mike Campbell and Pamela Meadows

This overview study examines current evidence on what can be done at the local level to getpeople into work. It reviews research on local employment and training initiatives, and considersimplications for future policy development.£10.95

Page 88: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

Who calls the tune at work? The impact of trade unions on jobs and pay

Neil Millward, John Forth and Alex Bryson

This report examines the effect of trade unions upon workplaces and their employees. It contains up-to-date information on the effect of unions on employment growth, workplace closures, bargainingscope and pay levels.£12.95

Training and support for lone parents: An evaluation of a targeted study programme

Karen John, Sarah Payne and Hilary Land

This report evaluates a programme set up to assess the training and support needs of unemployedlone parents, in the context of other local and national services. It highlights good practice for futuresimilar schemes.£12.95

Recruiting and employing offenders

Del Roy Fletcher, Alan Taylor, Stephen Hughes and Jonathan Breeze

This report identifies how employers currently respond to job applications from offenders andexamines the likely impact of the Police Act (1997) on both recruitment and existing employees. Itculminates in a series of key recommendations for policy makers.£13.95

Getting a chance: Employment support for young people with multiple disadvantages

Jane Lakey, Helen Barnes and Jane Parry

Many young people who have been long-term unemployed and taken part in the New Dealprogramme experience multiple disadvantages in their lives. This report examines the types ofsupport offered by government and non-government organisations currently working withdisadvantaged young people.£13.95

Published in 2002

Employing drug users: Individual and systemic barriers to rehabilitation

Hilary Klee, Iain McLean and Christian Yavorsky

The provision of enlightened and informed employment services for drug users is vital, to workalongside improvements in drug treatment currently being considered. This report looks critically atthose services in the context of their clients’ difficulties and needs.£13.95

Underachieving young men preparing for work: A report for practitioners

Trefor Lloyd

Underachieving boys have been particularly badly affected by recent changes in the labour market.This report details and evaluates a programme developed for 14- to 15-year-old young menidentified by their school as ‘at risk’ and under-achieving. It draws out components that worked andsuggests policy implications arising from the project.£17.95

Page 89: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the

Published in 2003

Young people, employability and the induction process

Steve Johnson and Tom Burden

A review of the experiences of young people entering the job market and how these affect their long-term employability.£14.95

Multiple disadvantage in employment: A quantitative analysis

Richard Berthoud

A detailed analysis of the job-chances of more than half a million people collected from a nine-yearsequence of Labour Force Surveys.£13.95

Page 90: Employee participation and company performance: A review of the