218
Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies A NORDEM SPECIAL REPORT 2011 Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch and Tonje Merete Viken Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies A NORDEM SPECIAL REPORT 2011 The Norwegian Centre for Human Rights

Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    2

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies

A NORDEM SPECIAL REPORT 2011

Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan

With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch and Tonje Merete Viken

Electoral Quotas and the C

hallenges of Dem

ocratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies A

NO

RDEM

SPECIA

L REPORT 2011

The Norwegian Centre for Human Rights

Page 2: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan:Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies A NORDEM Special ReportEditor: Siri Skåre

Copyright: Norwegian Centre for Human Rights, (NCHR)The Norwegian Resource Bank for Democracy and Human Rights (NORDEM)Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan

Quotations and extracts from this report may be reprinted by permission and if accompanied by source information. This report is published electronically in a pdf version on the NCHR web pages: http://www.jus.uio.no/smr/english/about/programmes/nordem/

NORDEM is a programme at

The Norwegian Centre for Human RightsThe Faculty of LawUniversity of OsloP.O. Box 6706 St. Olavs plassNO-0130 OsloNORWAY

[email protected]

Front page photo: Kåre Vollan. Printed by permission

ISBN 978-82-8158-071-8

Technical consultant: Christian Boe Astrup/NCHRPrinted by: 07 Gruppen AS

Page 3: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of

Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden

Societies

Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan

With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch and Tonje Merete Viken

September 2011

Page 4: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

2

Page 5: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

3

Contents 1: Introduction ............................................................................................................................ 6

1.1 The Purpose of the Study ............................................................................................ 6

1.2 The Case Studies ......................................................................................................... 9

1.3 Scope and Limitations ............................................................................................... 10

2: Power-Sharing Arrangements: Representation and Decision-Making Rules ...................... 14

2.1 Democratic Institutions in Deeply Divided Societies ............................................... 14

2.2 Power-Sharing through Representation and Decision Rules .................................... 17

2.3 The Systems of Representation ................................................................................. 19

2.4 Methods for Securing Group Representation ............................................................ 25

2.5 Power-Sharing – Decision-Making Procedures ........................................................ 34

3: Broad Overview of Systems ................................................................................................. 37

3.1 The Americas ............................................................................................................ 37

3.2 Asia-Pacific ............................................................................................................... 40

3.3 Central Eastern Europe .............................................................................................. 52

3.4 Middle East and North Africa ................................................................................... 59

3.5 Sub-Saharan Africa ................................................................................................... 63

3.6 Western Europe ......................................................................................................... 79

4: Case Study Lebanon ............................................................................................................. 86

4.1 Introduction ............................................................................................................... 86

4.2 Historical and Political Background ......................................................................... 86

4.3 Building Democracy in Lebanon. ............................................................................. 94

4.4 The Quota Arrangements and Other Power-Sharing Elements ................................ 99

4.5 The Field Study ....................................................................................................... 106

4.6 Main Conclusions and Thoughts for the Future ...................................................... 108

5: Case Study Nepal ............................................................................................................... 110

Page 6: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

4

5.1 Historical and Political Background ....................................................................... 110

5.2 The Quota Arrangements and Other Power-Sharing Elements .............................. 133

5.3 The Intended Effects – a Discussion ....................................................................... 139

5.4 Some Side Effects of the 2008 System ................................................................... 144

5.5 The Field Study ....................................................................................................... 144

5.6 Conclusions and Thoughts for the Future ............................................................... 148

6. Case Study Bosnia and Herzegovina ................................................................................. 152

6.1 Historical and Political Background ....................................................................... 152

6.2 The Quota Arrangements and Other Power-sharing Elements ............................... 159

6.3 The Field Study ....................................................................................................... 169

6.4 Main Conclusions and Thoughts for the Future ...................................................... 171

7: Conclusions and Recommendations .................................................................................. 175

7.1 Conflicts and Tools ................................................................................................. 175

7.2 Quotas and Veto Powers in Conflict-Ridden Societies. Main Findings ................. 175

7.3 Methods for Group Representation ........................................................................ 179

7.4. What May Work in Conflict Situations? ................................................................ 192

7.5 The Quota Tool Box ............................................................................................... 197

7.6 A Feature of Representative Systems ...................................................................... 201

Appendices ............................................................................................................................. 202

A: A Method for Quotas on the Total Result in a List PR System ............................... 202

B: Abbreviations of Names of Electoral Systems ......................................................... 207

References .............................................................................................................................. 208

Page 7: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

5

Preface

Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies is

a project organised under NORDEM, the Norwegian Resource Bank for Democracy and

Human Rights at the Norwegian Centre for Human Rights, University of Oslo. The basic

purpose is to contribute to the filling in of what we consider to be a gap in our understanding

of the significance of the type and design chosen for electoral laws and systems in critical

stages of political transition from open conflict to democratic stability in conflict-ridden

societies. We look particularly into cases of conflicts between socio-cultural groups mobilised

along ethnic, religious, and linguistic cleavages.

This report addresses an aspect of a classical theme in political analysis: How can designing a

political system contribute to overcoming deep-seated conflicts in society? Peace agreements

after civil wars should seek to overcome the mistrust and enmity between the groups, possibly

overcoming the conflict-producing cleavage structure itself. The assumption is that

democracy and stability are strengthened if citizens see their interests in terms of socio-

economic factors across cultural divides rather than in terms of socio-cultural identities. The

recommendation would therefore be to encourage types of political representation that criss-

cross cultural divides in society. On the other hand, a democratic system should also reflect

real opinions and interests in society as the voters themselves define them. We observe that in

most post-conflict societies, the political system tends to be organised along the ethnic divides

that defined the previous conflict. The dilemma then is how a democratic principle of

representation that tends to reflect group-based identities can contribute to overcoming group-

based conflict dynamics. This is where electoral quotas come into the picture: What are the

effects of introducing quotas? Will they contribute to democratic stability or rather preserve

and strengthen the cleavages that led to open conflict in the first place?

In addition to the three cases of Lebanon, Bosnia and Herzegovina and Nepal, the report

includes a broad overview of all relevant systems in the world where such quotas are applied

(Chapter 3). We believe that this has a value in its own right as a catalogue of applied quota

systems. It furthermore gives a valuable empirical context for the comparative discussion and

the “tool box” developed in the concluding chapter. Researcher Tonje Merete Viken wrote a

draft version of Chapter 3 and collected the data for that chapter. She also drafted part of the

chapter on Bosnia and Herzegovina. Professor Bjørn Erik Rasch, Department of Political

Science, University of Oslo, has commented throughout the process on all parts of the report

and contributed particularly to Chapter 2. Siri Skåre, Director of International Programmes at

the Norwegian Centre for Human Rights, has had the administrative responsibility.

We would like to thank the Norwegian Ministry of Foreign Affairs for their generous support

making this study possible and for their patience regarding the completion of the final

product. We are also grateful for the invaluable support we received by Norwegian embassy

personnel in conducting our fieldwork for the case studies.

Oslo, September 2011,

Nils Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan

Page 8: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

6

1: Introduction

1.1 The Purpose of the Study

Within the tradition of democratic theory, models of power-sharing can be considered as

modifications of the classical liberal principle of 'one person-one vote'. For a variety of

reasons, this principle of organising a political order – when strictly applied in national

elections – does not always produce institutional outcomes that give every group of citizens

adequate protection of their core rights and interests or a fair say in the running of their

country. This is because political institutions composed on the basis of aggregate individual

votes do not always meet the requirements for reconciling or managing conflicts in societies

that are collective in nature. The democratic dilemma that this situation creates is particularly

typical of deeply divided societies. Minorities who are constantly and systematically outvoted

or otherwise marginalised in the political process might easily feel trapped in a position of

democratic deficiency, lose confidence in the political system, and seek non-democratic ways

in the struggle for their interests. This is why models of group-based power-sharing are

frequently being discussed as ways in which new democratic institutions can replace or be

introduced as complementary to existing ones in conflict-ridden societies.

In this way, electoral laws and decision- making procedures can be critical factors in peace

processes and mechanisms of transitional justice from open conflict to democratic stability.

This study focuses on the significance and application of such factors and mechanisms as they

can be observed both in the form of an overview of global trends and in three countries

chosen as cases for more detailed analysis: Nepal, Bosnia and Herzegovina, and Lebanon.

On the global scale, we find that countries apply a whole range of constitutional provisions

and other formal or informal arrangements and rules meant to secure or facilitate the politics

of compromise between groups. Strengthening political stability within the existing

constitutional order is normally the aim of such arrangements. They can be found at different

institutional levels in a state, and they vary in nature according to the underlying tensions that

they seek to address. States with deep-seated geographical divisions will, for example, tend to

be organised as federations where the constitutive parts are equally represented in a national

decision-making body (i.e., a senate) with qualified veto powers, irrespective of the relative

demographic strength of each part. In other situations, the purpose of power-sharing

mechanisms can be to accommodate demands for minority rights or to define modes of power

distribution between multiple groups of varying sizes within a unitary state. Arendt Lijphart,

in one of his well-known studies of power-sharing, explains:

Especially in plural societies – societies that are sharply divided along religious,

ideological, linguistic, cultural, ethnic, or racial lines into virtually separate sub-

societies with their own political parties, interest groups, and media or communication

– the flexibility necessary for majoritarian democracy is absent. Under these

conditions, majority rule is not only undemocratic but also dangerous, because

Page 9: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

7

minorities that are continually denied access to power will feel excluded and

discriminated against and will lose their allegiance to the regime.1

The use of quota systems, reserved seats and other deviations from the 'one person-one vote'

principle might be to secure a proportional representation of votes that would otherwise not

be realised. But it might also be used to create disproportional representation (positive

discrimination) if that is considered conducive to stability in the society at large. Such

arrangements are typically introduced as negotiated outcomes of protracted conflicts between

communal groups where the dominating dividing cleavage is ethnic, religious or linguistic, or

a combination of the three. Power-sharing along such lines is often described as

‘consociational’ and the corresponding political system as ‘consociational democracy’, a term

coined by Arend Lijphart. Lijpart’s work has had a significant impact on contemporary

discussions among academics and electoral experts on the questions of power-sharing as a

solution to democratic dilemmas in deeply divided societies.

While there might be many good reasons to consider the use of consociational principles in

transitions from civil war or authoritarian rule to more democratic governance, the

effectiveness of such an arrangement will be contingent on the specific conditions in each

case. The most salient factor is naturally whether or not the dominant parties are ready to

accept power-sharing and respect agreements to that regard. This, furthermore, reflects the

level of mutual trust and polarisation between the groups. In addition, several structural

factors will influence the outcome, such as number and degree of contending parties, the

balance of power between them, their geographic distribution, the general level of economic

and political development in society and the distribution of such resources.

It is also important to pay critical attention to the risks involved in establishing institutions of

power-sharing for the sustainability of democratic politics. The most obvious of these risks is

that power-sharing arrangements can be very difficult to undo if introduced in the first place,

even if the conditions and political dynamics that underpinned the original agreement have

changed. A political system based on consociational power-sharing has built-in mechanisms

that normally give the parties formal or de facto veto power over constitutional changes or

reforms that would substantially reduce their relative power in the system. What is often

introduced as a transitional arrangement to facilitate a political agreement in a situation of

serious conflict might consequently become a permanent mode for distributing powerful

positions in society. On the one hand, such arrangements give the parties a large margin of

flexibility in inter-group negotiations, since the central government can only exist as long as

the most powerful groups are able to find common ground. This might be conducive for

keeping peace and political stability. However, this modus operandi of the system tends to

empty the formal political institutions of decision-making power, leaving it in the hands of

informal power structures that are controlled by the most important groups. This arrangement

is not only a democratic problem — it makes it almost impossible to reform the political

system in directions that are considered unacceptable to at least one influential group

commanding a veto power.

1 Lijphart 1984:22-23.

Page 10: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

8

An existing system of power-sharing that allows for flexibility and pragmatism in decision-

making processes between the parties in power might be very inflexible in other respects,

particularly when it comes to adapting to or addressing new conditions and challenges to the

established power-sharing arrangement. The arrangement itself will have the probable effect

of “cementing” or “freezing” old cleavages in the society that would otherwise dissolve under

the influence of economic or socio-cultural developments. The obvious risk in the long run is

that inflexible political institutions will stand in the way of dynamic societal developments,

which will create mounting discontent, reproduce old conflicts, and undermine the stability

that these institutions were meant to secure.

An important challenge to policymakers and advisors in conflict-ridden societies seeking a

peaceful and democratic future would therefore be to strike a balance, on the one hand,

between building institutional guarantees within which every group and every individual

within the group can feel secure and have their basic rights protected. On the other hand, such

policymakers and advisors must remain flexible in the face of the unpredictability of

democratic politics based on decision-making procedures that presuppose a certain level of

mutual trust among the citizens.

In the following, we will study the mechanisms that are actually being used for representation

and decision-making in pre- and post-conflict situations, with a particular focus on

arrangements that seem to have favourable effects on democratic stability. First, we will

present the discourse among academics and experts on theoretical questions relevant to this

study (Chapter 2). This will be followed by an overview of mechanisms in use across the

world (Chapter 3). Chapters 4 to 6 contain three case studies with detailed assessments of the

electoral arrangements and their effects, and Chapter 7 concludes the study, giving

recommendations on the basis of what we consider to be the lessons learned so far.

We enter this study with certain expectations that we want to elaborate further. On both

representation and decision-making rules, it is likely that there are methods that vary in their

efficiency from greater to lesser, and that they offer various degrees of conflict resolution in

the short- and long-term perspectives. Not least, the long-term incentives for reconciliation

will be discussed. In particular, the following questions will be studied:

To what extent is representation by a representative group in parliament able (or

sufficient) to reduce conflict?

To what extent are formal power-sharing agreements, including veto powers,

necessary to establish peace?

To what extent must the group elect its own representatives (as opposed to be quotas

on regular party elections) to be able to reduce conflict?

What are the effects of these arrangements (in particular power-sharing) on efficiency

and the ability to govern?

What are the long-term effects of these arrangements? Do they deepen the divide

between groups or do they contribute to normalising them?

Page 11: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

9

1.2 The Case Studies

1.2.1 Introduction

The three case studies include countries that have recently emerged from armed internal

conflicts: Lebanon, Nepal, and Bosnia and Herzegovina. The nature of the conflicts varies, as

does the degree of stability established after the conflict. Both Bosnia and Herzegovina and

Lebanon have introduced a number of arrangements supporting power-sharing between

earlier combatants. In Nepal, the constitution currently being drafted is expected to bring

forward quota rules ensuring that the social and ethnic groups previously excluded from

political life can be properly represented.

The case studies were designed to allow for a more thorough discussion of the effects of

introducing certain electoral mechanisms in countries haunted by ethnic or confessional (i.e.

religious) conflicts. The purpose is to assess whether the arrangements work as intended and

if there are side effects, expected or unexpected, which could have been avoided if they had

been considered at an early stage.

1.2.2 Methodology for the Case Studies

Each case study consists of an overview of the recent history of the country and a detailed

analysis of the electoral system and other power-sharing elements, and the field study that

primarily discusses the current challenges as seen by respondents. The field study is based

upon interviews with a selection of stakeholders in the country. The purpose of the

interviews is partly to get a first-hand view of the intentions behind the relevant power-

sharing arrangements, then to make an assessment of how they have worked out in practice,

both in terms of providing a safe and peaceful environment and in providing a functional

state, and finally to find out whether stakeholders are looking for changes or how they intend

to assess the development ahead.

Respondents were selected according to a number of criteria, the most obvious being

prominent representatives of the previous conflicting parties. In addition, we interviewed

representatives of groups that were being marginalised by the peace agreement (e.g. Romas in

Bosnia and Herzegovina), politicians, NGO representatives, academics, etc. In sum, a

selection among the following — partly overlapping — groups were interviewed:

Leaders of the parties in conflict

Political leaders at large within and outside the parliament

Leaders of religious, ethnic, linguistic, social groups whenever relevant

Representatives of possible marginalised groups

Representatives of the government

Representatives of the international community (and in Bosnia and Herzegovina in

particular the office of the High Representative, OSCE and Embassies)

Representatives of local governments

Opinion leaders

Think tanks and institutes

Page 12: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

10

To work as an aide memoire during the interviews, a checklist was prepared. The intention of

this was not to list a strict questionnaire but to assist in ensuring that we covered the topics

relevant for the person being interviewed. The interviews were recorded according to a

thematic structure defined. In addition to these formal interviews, a number of meetings of a

more informal nature were conducted.

We recorded fourteen interviews in Bosnia and Herzegovina, ten in Lebanon and twelve in

Nepal. It should be noted that the countries were chosen partly based upon two of the

researchers’ prior thorough knowledge of the countries. The interviews could not, in

themselves, provide for a representative selection of respondents from all relevant parts of

society. However, with the researchers' background knowledge, the interviews provided for a

very useful update on the current status in the country and were an invaluable addition to the

facts that were already available to the team.

It should also be noted that ten years ago one of the interviewers2 played an active role as an

advisor in Bosnia and Herzegovina on electoral issues and is currently active in an advisory

role on the same issues in Nepal. In Nepal, it was made very clear to the interviewees that the

purpose of the interview was for the respondents to come up with their own views and not to

discuss various alternatives.

The number of interviewees is too low to be subject to statistical analysis and it is the total

amount of information we have about the countries that forms the basis for our conclusions

and recommendations. Without the researchers' prior knowledge, much of the information

collected might have been misinterpreted and too much emphasis could have been put on

statements of individuals which were not really representative of the views of the group.

1.3 Scope and Limitations

1.3.1 General

The study includes a review of all countries in the world applying quotas to the election of

parliament. When describing a country, other elements of power-sharing, such as devolution

of powers and decision rules, are included, but countries are not included if they do not also

have electoral quotas. The quota arrangements are described regardless of whether their

purpose is to reconcile after a war or if it is merely to include groups that the electoral system

would otherwise exclude. Countries that have only gender quotas are not included, however,

if the country is included in the study for other qualifying reasons, their gender quotas are also

described.

In addition, three countries — Lebanon, Bosnia and Herzegovina and Nepal — have been

selected for case studies. In these three case studies, the relationship between representation,

decision-making rules and devolution of powers is of central concern.

In the end, the purpose of this study is to present a toolbox of electoral quotas that may be

applied in certain situations as well as an analysis of their pros and cons. Quota rules have

2 Kåre Vollan

Page 13: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

11

aspects that are technically complicated and the alternatives may be of interest in a post-

conflict situation, even if they, up to this point, have been applied in a context that differs

from the present examples.

Three kinds of sources have been applied in compiling data for this study: To the extent

possible within the resources available, we have used primary sources as bases for empirical

presentations, including the overview of global patterns. Interviews with representatives of

conflicting parties, as well as country experts, were conducted in order to strengthen the

analysis of the three selected cases. A broad range of academic works were also consulted in

developing the theoretical and analytical perspectives. In addition, the authors have

considerable experiences within this field of study, both as researchers and experts in different

countries for governmental and non-governmental organisations.

1.3.2 The Broad Overview

The broad overview of systems is aimed at giving a comprehensive overview of ethnic,

religious and social quotas in parliaments around the world. The overview will be used as a

source of information on what systems of group representation are actually in use for

whatever purpose, even if they have not originated from a conflict situation. This will be

useful when a toolbox of systems is discussed in the last part of the report. At the end of each

regional presentation, those systems that are being used particularly for the reduction of

conflict will be discussed.

In Chapter 2, power-sharing arrangements are defined as combinations of the following

elements:

1. Grand Coalitions

2. Proportionality or representation of groups

3. Devolution of powers

4. Decision-making rules designed to protect groups.

In the broad overview, those countries that have predefined rules for representation of groups

have been selected. For these countries, decision-making rules, grand coalitions and gender

quotas are also described. Devolution of powers is described for countries selected due to

point 2, above, by classifying them as federal or unitary states. Countries with conflicts that

are considered to be reduced only by devolution of powers or decision-making rules

(including grand coalitions) are not covered in this part unless they also have particular

representation of groups according to point 2, above.

It should be noted that parliamentary quotas are in themselves only one of several possible

measures to ensure representation of selected groups in state affairs. Quota mechanisms can

also apply to the executive, the courts and bureaucracy and they may apply exclusively to the

local level of governments. In several countries, requirements for nominations (such as the list

composition) are covered in parties’ by-laws. Such countries have not been included here.

Countries where group representation is secured solely by appointments are not included even

Page 14: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

12

though appointments are described where they come in addition to elected group

representation.

Types of Groups

We have already pointed to the distinction between small and large minorities. The concept of

‘group’ may be further elaborated. Groups protected in constitutions and election laws are

broadly defined by ethnic, linguistic or religious features. While a rough categorization is

applied here, these distinctions are blurred and overlapping. Are Bosniacs, for instance, a

religious or ethnic group? While Bosniacs are Moslem by definition, members of the Bosniac

group will not necessarily accept that religion is a constituting element of their group identity.

Other types of groups that enjoy quota protection can be professional groups, like workers

and farmers in Egypt. Social factors may also trigger protection. Examples are the quotas for

youth and disabled (Uganda and Kenya). Protection of all these groups will be discussed here.

Gender quotas will be described when other mechanisms of group protection are also present.

Selection of Countries

Countries with quotas have been identified at the outset by use of the Parline database of the

Inter-Parliamentary Union and other secondary sources. The information has been verified by

the countries’ legislation. Further reading and research has added additional countries. It

should be noted that electoral design is an ongoing process all over the world, and a study

such as this will inevitably be outdated. This does not, however, lower the value of such a

thorough compilation of available legal tools to ensure group representation at a given time in

history.

Countries are grouped and presented alphabetically according to the regional breakdown of

Freedom House. Countries that are ranked as ‘not free’ on the 2011 Freedom in the World

index are only summarily described in the country tables but not in the narrative following the

table. Countries that have devolution of powers and relevant decision-making rules in

response to an ethnic, religious or social conflict, in addition to group representation, will be

discussed in some detail.

Sources

To the greatest extent possible, the quota mechanisms themselves are described on the basis

of primary sources, namely, the constitutions and electoral laws of the selected countries. It

should be noted that the quality of legislation and their translation into languages these

authors may command may vary, and electoral laws may be incomplete, inconsistent, or may

even contradict the constitution. Furthermore, the election laws may consist of several pieces

of legislation, and it has not always been possible to obtain all the relevant documents. In

such rare cases, we have consulted secondary sources to answer questions concerning voter

registries, voting rights, etc.

Page 15: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

13

Country profiles

Each country profile contains a thorough presentation of the quota mechanism. In addition,

the countries’ political systems are briefly described, with regard to the federal or unitary

nature of the state, form of government, and decision-making procedures whenever these are

related to the quota rules. Focus is on the technical aspects of the quota. It does not fall within

the scope of this part of the study to measure to what extent the quotas affect informal

politics.

Such a broad comparative study does not allow for extensive studies of each country.

However, each country profile contains a brief background outlining the main conflicts in the

country.3 The purpose is to broaden the understanding of the quota systems and the political

context in which they work (or don’t work).

For the sake of readability, selected countries are presented alphabetically and grouped by

continent or parts of continents. Some of the quota mechanisms represent differing national

solutions to cross-border conflicts, such as Hutus and Tutsis in Rwanda and Burundi, and

some of the former Yugoslav republics. This gives some advantage to the subdivision.

However, this breakdown is primarily for pedagogical reasons, and we do not attempt to draw

a causal line from geographical situation to the quota systems that are applied in each

individual country. Some rough patterns may be distinguished, namely, the relatively

extensive use of linguistic quotas in Europe, and social quotas in Africa. We aim to describe,

not to explain, such patterns wherever they occur in our material.

3 In addition, Chapter 4 contains case studies of three conflict-ridden countries with quota systems.

Page 16: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

14

2: Power-Sharing Arrangements: Representation and Decision-

Making Rules

2.1 Democratic Institutions in Deeply Divided Societies

Every society has divisions between groups of people, reflecting differences in living

conditions, religion, education, culture, and so on. Some divisions are easier to handle than

others, for instance, because they do not concern deep-rooted values and identities. Societies

are often described as deeply divided when cleavages are particularly intense, and they run

along ethnic, religious or nationalistic lines. Ethnicity is a contested concept, but it is usually

defined broadly in terms of shared beliefs of common ancestry, shared customs and cultural

features, common language, and the like.4 The configuration of conflicting groups – whether

divisions rest on ethnicity, culture, religion or other factors – may vary a lot: A majority could

dominate minorities, a minority group could dominate other parts of the society (the

majority), a balanced configuration with a relatively limited number of groups is a possibility

(bipolar or multipolar conflict), as well as a highly fragmented situation with no dominant

group at all.5 Lijphart used the term plural society to describe societies with deep and lasting

segmental cleavages of a “religious, ideological, linguistic, regional, cultural, racial, or ethnic

nature.”6 Rabushka and Shepsle use the term more narrowly: A plural society is culturally

diverse, and the feature that distinguishes it from a pluralistic society is that politics almost

exclusively follow ethnic cleavages.7

Deeply divided multi-ethnic societies may choose different models for their state structure.8

The classical liberal state puts emphasis on the individual and gives equal rights and

opportunities to each individual, regardless of what segment of society the individual belongs

to. The problem with this model in deeply divided societies is that there may be a long

distance from the theoretical equality to the actual possibility for all to exercise their right in

full. A different model is the “consociational state” or a state based on forms of power-

sharing between groups. Power-sharing may be by tradition or by design or both. In deeply

divided societies, power-sharing may be a necessary condition for a democratic system to

work and even for civil peace. Power-sharing may not be written into the constitution but

rather be a strong element of the political tradition (like grand coalitions in Switzerland). In

4 After discussing conceptual issues, Fearon 2003 presents data on ethnic structure in 160 countries in the early

1990s. More than 800 ethnic groups are identified. See also Chirot 2009.

5 Rabushka and Shepsle (1972) thus distinguish between four types of deeply divided societies: Fragmented,

balanced, dominant minority and dominant majority. Each configuration has its own challenges.

6 Lijphart 1977: 3-4. The term “segmental cleavages” was taken from Eckstein’s 1966 study of division and

cohesion in Norway.

7 Rabushka and Shepsle 1972: 20-21

8 For an overview, see Lijphart 1977, 2008, Sisk 2006 and Reynolds 2011.

Page 17: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

15

some cases, power-sharing arrangements are vital elements of formal peace agreements and

are laid out in detail (for example, the Dayton Agreement in Bosnia and Herzegovina).

Power-sharing may take different forms, and four basic characteristics are often accentuated.

Together, they define consociational democracy, and each of them implies some kind of

deviation from (pure) majority rule and the principle of ‘one person-one vote’. Grand

coalition is the primary feature of consociational government, but broad-based coalitions are

complemented by the following three secondary instruments:9

1. Grand Coalition. Power-sharing can take the form of broad-based governmental

coalitions. This implies that all the main political forces are invited into central

decision-making bodies, thereby ensuring that no significant minority is permanently

excluded from exercising political power. In parliamentary systems, grand coalition

may mean that the cabinet includes the political leaders of all significant groups or

segments of the society. In systems without an executive body accountable to the

parliament (e.g. presidential ones), a variety of arrangement are available to serve the

same purpose of inclusive decision-making. Grand coalitions may blur the distinctions

between government and opposition or leave the country without a formal opposition.

In turn, it could also limit political contestation.

2. Decision-making rules: Minority veto or mutual veto. Minority groups may not

only be included and given participation rights, they may also be granted veto power

(formally or informally), in particular with regard to vital interests. For instance, the

veto option guarantees that a group will not be outvoted when its autonomy is at stake.

Alternatively, the decision-making rules may be designed to protect a minority from

changes by the majority by qualified or double majorities. Super-majority

requirements and the like are, of course, a weaker type of minority protection than

veto power. In any case, consensus may be the underlying goal.

3. Proportionality. Power-sharing implies that arrangements for representation are

utilized at every level of political life – nationally, regionally and locally. The purpose

is to give (almost) every group in society access to decision-making bodies according

to their overall size, and to allocate scarce financial resources in the form of state

subsidies in roughly the same way.10

The electoral system is the instrument by which

votes are translated into seats in assemblies, and its design is crucial for how – and to

what extent – segments or (minority) groups are represented. Below, we will have a

lot more to say about electoral systems and methods of securing minority

representation.

4. Segmental group autonomy or federalism. Segments of society (here called groups)

may have rights to a well-defined autonomy. Devolution of powers may take care of

this aspect. In federal states, this may be a fundamental condition. If the states are

9 See Chapter 2 in Lijphart 1977.

10 Lijphart 1977: 38-41.

Page 18: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

16

drawn up along linguistic or ethnic lines, the power-sharing is protected by the

definition of powers of the states versus the centre. Other forms of autonomy for

groups may also be envisaged, such as giving ethnic groups the right to their own

elected bodies with advisory or even decision-making authority (e.g. Norwegian Sámi

parliament).

Some of the principles are interrelated, and in practice, they often occur together. There is no

“one size fits all” solution for power-sharing in deeply divided societies. The tradition for

consensus policy may be very strong in some countries whereas in other countries the

majority will use their powers regardless of strong opposition from minority groups. In this

report, we will assess some elements of power-sharing and the effects of formalising the rules.

In particular, the representation of groups and the decision-making aspects of such

arrangements will be covered (i.e. characteristics 2 and 3, above). Devolution of powers will

be discussed only when necessary for the analysis of the primary aspects of the report. As

Lijphart emphasises, the grand coalition is a superior principle of consociational democracy,

but will only be discussed more indirectly in the sequel.

Several arguments against consociationalism have been voiced over the years. It has been

criticized for relying too much on elite accommodation. It has been argued that there is a

problem of elite initiated conflict, as political leaders of the various segments may increase

their bargaining power vis-à-vis other groups by mobilizing their own group on sectarian

grounds.11

A related critique says that consociationalism is problematic in deeply divided

societies because it rests on constraints and restrictions against immoderate politics via veto

power, instead of incentives for actors to cooperate across segments.12

In short,

consociationalism may provide fertile grounds for conflict entrepreneurs, whose powerbase

rests on continued conflict, rather than actors of reconciliation. Furthermore, the tendency

towards non-democratic decision-making, in the sense of not honouring majority rule and the

principle of ‘one person-one vote’, has been emphasized by many.13

Similarly, inefficiency

and the risk of deadlock has been an important part of the criticism. If a political system is

incapable of producing necessary decisions because of a stalemate, the legitimacy of the

system is potentially threatened. Finally, consociationalism has been criticised for facilitating

policies of discrimination, for example, related to the tendency of powerful minorities to

exploit the system of veto power to protect undemocratic privileges. Such problems are

particularly evident in situations of extreme power asymmetry between the groups because

the power-sharing institutions, set up on the basis of negotiations between the constituent

groups in the society, will tend to reflect the imbalances between them and thus build

discriminatory practices into the emerging political system. Injustices will consequently be

institutionalised, not abolished.14

Lijphart’s suggestions for a system of power-sharing in

11

See, in particular, Tsebelis 1990.

12 Here, work by Horowitz (e.g. 1985, 1990) is relevant.

13 See, for example, Barry 1975.

14 See Butenschøn, 1985 and 2006.

Page 19: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

17

South Africa in the mid-1980’s (i.e., before the end of Apartheid) that would have preserved

the White community as a separate and relatively privileged political community is an

example, and was heavily criticised by anti-Apartheid activists and academics at the time.15

Our main reason for focusing on power-sharing arrangements is their prospect for preventing

or ending violent conflicts. Power-sharing may also be used to secure civil peace even if there

is no immediate danger of conflict. We will concentrate on consociational arrangements

(related to representation and decision-making rules) that have a peace-keeping justification.

There is a growing body of academic literature that studies the relationship between power-

sharing and post-conflict peace, and several have found a positive association.16

Even in a structure based upon power-sharing between groups, the long-term goal may be the

development into a liberal state where group identity is less important. In the following

discussion, we will therefore also study the long-term effects of formal arrangements for

power-sharing and to what extent they are self-magnifying (deepening conflict and the needs

for measures) or if they are giving incentives for more equality.

2.2 Power-Sharing through Representation and Decision Rules

Special representation for groups may be introduced for different reasons. Our focus is on

measures that may reduce conflict at its outset or on arrangements that may reduce the

conflict level after an armed conflict. Representation in elected bodies is clearly only one of

many such measures and a peace agreement will often have elements of power-sharing as an

extension to group representation.

Power-sharing agreements are agreements between groups that regulate the decision-making,

independent of the election result. Therefore, it deviates from pure majority rule. The groups

of the agreement may be represented according to an election result but the power is shared

between the groups according to the agreement, not the balance between parties as a result of

an election.

A power-sharing agreement may regulate the composition of the executive or parliament or it

may regulate the decision-making process. An example of the first is the presidency of

Bosnia and Herzegovina, where each of the three war-faring parties from 1992 to 1995 has

one member in the presidency and an equal number of members in the upper house of

parliament. In Sudan, until the secession of South Sudan in 2011, the president and the first

vice president need to come from different groups (north and south).

The rules for decision-making may vary from a requirement for a qualified majority which

guarantees that one group alone cannot pass a decision without at least some support of the

other group(s) (Burundi), to firm veto powers of a group over all or some decisions (Bosnia

and Herzegovina). In a way, all deviations from a strict majority rule may be seen as a kind

of power-sharing agreement. When a qualified majority is needed to change a constitution, it

15

See Lijphart 1985. For a critical discussion of Lijphart, see Jung and Shapiro 1995.

16 See Hartzell and Hoodie 2003, Hartzell et al. 2001 and Binningsbø 2006 for further references.

Page 20: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

18

is a measure to ensure that a small simple majority cannot change fundamental rights or the

rules of the game.17

The same is the case for requirements for double majorities as required

for changes to the US constitution. A much stronger form is where a minority group can veto

certain decisions. If a decision concerns fundamental group rights or division of powers

between bodies or units, they may not have a very significant effect on the day-to-day

government of the country but if they can be applied to large number of decisions such as in

Bosnia and Herzegovina, they may represent a hurdle to the functioning of the state as such.18

Group representation in the form of electoral quotas may be introduced alone or together with

more extensive power-sharing agreements. They may be introduced only to make a

parliament more representative (or to over-represent a group) along an ethnic, linguistic or

social dimension in addition to the political one. The purpose can be to broaden the

representation and to make sure that the groups have their voices heard before decisions are

made. Section 2.4, below, will provide an overview of electoral quotas regardless of whether

the purpose is to underpin a peace agreement, prevent an armed conflict or simply to provide

broader representation in the elected body.19

Even if an arrangement is used only for

representation, the same method may have a conflict-prevention effect in another country.

In the following, we will cover both direct and indirect elections. Systems of representation

may be the same in the two cases but, in an indirect election, the inequality is often

established in the number of representatives of each group in the upper house of parliament

rather by the electoral system.

It is useful to distinguish between small and large minorities, and how dispersed they are

geographically, although it is not always possible to draw a sharp line between them.20

A small minority will typically have a strength of a few percent of the population (for

example, less than ten), but their characteristics are such that they may need special protection

in such areas as the use of language, the promotion of culture, etc. A group which in the

country as a whole is a large minority or even a majority, may in some respects constitute a

small minority and need corresponding protection. Except when a small minority is

geographically concentrated, it will typically not be involved in civil wars and other major

conflicts, or it will at least not be among the principal parties to such conflicts.

A large minority runs the risk of losing all influence by systematically being voted down by

the majority or a coalition of other large minorities. Protection against this would typically

take the form of balancing the group interest within the organization of the state, or by

introducing an electoral system that secures a balance between competing groups. To use

17

On constitutional amendment procedures, see Rasch and Congleton 2006.

18 A thorough and sophisticated analysis of the properties of relevant decision-making rules can be found in

McGann 2006.

19 A discussion of different types of quotas, see Htun 2004 and Schwindt-Bayer 2009.

20 This and the next paragraph are taken directly from Blanc, Hylland and Vollan, 2006: 3-4.

Page 21: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

19

Bosnia and Herzegovina as an example, the main groups involved in the civil war – Bosniacs,

Croats and Serbs – are large minorities in the country as a whole, and each of them may be a

majority in certain regions. On the other hand, Romas, Slovenians, Montenegrins, etc. are

small minorities.

The purpose of defining small and large groups is to be able to differentiate between groups

that could be parties to a peace agreement and those groups that should be guaranteed

representation for other reasons. This division is obviously not sharp. Even small groups

may use arms in the end to protect their interests if the majority does not respect what they

regard as their fundamental rights. In our context, most of the groups in conflict will be

‘large’ but there may be exceptions that, in such cases, will also be covered.

2.3 The Systems of Representation

Elections are a central ingredient in the system of representation in modern democracies.

They are conducted by a more or less complex set of rules and procedures; electoral systems

can be “defined as those rules which govern the processes by which preferences are

articulated as votes and by which these votes are translated into the election of decision-

makers.”21

Electoral systems are used for many purposes, but what concerns us in this report

are primarily legislative elections at the level of nation-states (and not, for instance,

presidential elections). There is a broad family of such systems ranging from

plurality/majority-based systems, which normally produce an overrepresentation of the largest

party to fully proportional systems. It is also possible to design systems that secure

overrepresentation of small entities, which is particularly relevant in processes of

apportionment (e.g. distribution of seats on constituencies).22

Electoral systems have different

qualities regarding group representation and some may be more suited in post-conflict

situations than others. In this section, we will first list some criteria for good electoral

systems and then give a categorisation of systems that will be used in this report.

2.3.1. Criteria for good systems of representation

Blanc, Hylland and Vollan define the following criteria for good systems of representation:23

Even though a large variety of systems are being used in established democracies,

some general criteria for good electoral systems can be defined. The weight put on

each of them, however, would vary, among experts as well as among political decision

makers.

We list some criteria that electoral systems may meet, and discuss briefly some

aspects of each. Most of the criteria apply to elections generally, not just to elections

in post-conflict situations, but some of them are particularly important in such

situations.

21

Blais 1988: 100.

22 Balinski and Young 2001.

23 Blanc, Hylland and Vollan 2006: section 7.4.

Page 22: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

20

Create representative assemblies. In simple terms, this criterion means that a party

running in an election shall get a number of seats in the assembly that corresponds

approximately to its proportional share of the vote. This is often regarded as the

overriding criterion for a fair electoral system, and it is the most important

justification for proportional elections. An elected assembly should reflect the political

composition of the electorate, as well as other aspects such as geography, gender, etc.

The decisions made by the assembly should be representative of the opinions of the

electorate.

Support accountability of the elected members. Another important aspect of elections

is the relationship between the electorate and the elected member of the assembly.

Elections in single-member constituencies are often justified by the need for strong

accountability, since a comparatively small electorate will elect its own member of

parliament and maintain direct contact with the elected member.

Support stable governments. It has been argued that a fully proportional electoral

system may result in an assembly split into a large number of parties, which in turn

will lead to unstable coalition governments. The empirical data does not necessarily

support this claim, at least not in countries with some kind of threshold for

representation.

Give equal weight to each voter. This requirement can be interpreted in various ways

when applied to different electoral systems. The most general formulation is that

voters shall not be discriminated against on account of ethnicity, geography, gender

and so on, except for what may follow from valid affirmative actions.

Resist tactical voting behavior. A system should support an immediate link between

the voters' primary preferences and the result. Tactical voting means that the voters do

not vote according to their primary preferences. Instead, they vote according to, for

example, their secondary preferences, because they believe they can thereby get an

advantage.

Be simple for the voters. Systems can be designed to meet many requirements, but

could end up being extremely complicated for the voters, both in the sense that it is

difficult to cast a valid and effective vote, and in the sense that it is not easy to

understand how the system works.

Be simple for the election administration. Systems can be very complicated for those

implementing them. However, what may seem difficult to implement, need not be

complicated from a voter's point of view. A possible example is the single transferable

vote.

Be generally accepted by the parties and the public. Degree of acceptance should be

taken into account when choosing a system. This is particularly important in post-

conflict elections, because of the level of mistrust, frequently occurring disorder in

election administrations, and the immaturity of the party system. One should not,

however, refrain from proposing a system one genuinely regards as good, simply

because of fear that it will not be accepted.

Promote conciliation among different groups. In post-conflict situations this is an

Page 23: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

21

important criterion, and it is the main focus of this report.

Promote cross-community parties. This is related to the previous item, but is not

exactly identical as a criterion for electoral systems. Community may refer to ethnic,

linguistic, religious or sectarian groups as well as geographical areas.

Promote dialogue and compromise. The electoral system should in general support

dialogue and conciliation in post-conflict situations. Therefore, whenever reasonable,

the system should promote compromise candidates instead of extremist ones.

However, there are clear limits to what an electoral system can and should do in this

respect. If the voters really support extremist candidates, the system should not

prevent these candidates from being elected.

Be robust against changes. This may be a fairly technical issue, but a system should

be designed in such a way that small changes in some aspect of the system, such as

constituency boundaries, will not have a drastic effect on the outcome of the elections.

In a system based on single-member constituencies, the drawing of boundaries can

significantly affect the outcome, even if it is required that all constituencies be of

equal size. If the boundaries are determined through a political process, there is a

danger that the present majority will try to perpetuate its power by carefully taking

account of how its support is distributed when boundaries are drawn, so-called

"gerrymandering".

Respond logically to changing support. Increased support for a party should normally

lead to increased representation, with as few unforeseen and illogical side effects as

possible.

Be sustainable. This means that even though there may be particular needs in a

transitional period, the electoral system should be adapted to a normalized situation

and should also support the process of normalization. One should keep in mind that

systems which are adopted after a conflict, even if they are tailor-made to the current

situation, will create precedent, that is, they will have a tendency to perpetuate

themselves. This is particularly true if the international community has been

instrumental in establishing the system.

A system should be chosen according to the needs and the historical context of the country.

Some choices are nevertheless political and controversial, as many aspects of electoral

systems have long-lasting political consequences.24

In most countries, there would be people

who strongly believe in proportional systems because of their ability to represent all parties

according to their overall votes, whereas for others the accountability offered by first-past-

the-post systems in single-member constituencies would be much more important.

In our context, it is the system’s ability to represent groups in conflict and to promote

dialogue and reconciliation that would be more important. Again, it is important to stress that

there is no 'one-size-fits-all' solution. In some situations, constituencies may be the best

solution if a minority is geographically concentrated. In such a case, the regular party

24

See e.g. Lijphart 1994 and Taagepera and Shugart 1989.

Page 24: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

22

structure may work across constituencies and promote a long-term goal of 'normalising'

political life across group identities. In other situations, a proportional system with the whole

country as constituency and a low threshold may offer the best solution because every group

with some support in the electorate will have a chance to be represented. That system may,

however, give incentives to forming parties with group identities rather than parties formed

on a political platform across group identities.

2.3.2 The Classification of Systems of Representation

Electoral systems can be classified in various ways, and many classifications are offered in

the literature.25

Two dimensions are central to most typologies: Electoral formula

(majoritarian or proportional type) and district structure (single-member or multi-member

constituencies or some mix thereof). In addition, some also take explicit account of the ballot

structure of the electoral system, i.e. what kind of information voters provide through their

vote. Several electoral formulas can be used both in single- and multi-member districts. The

alternative vote (AV), where voters are allowed to rank candidates, becomes STV when

applied in multi-member districts. First-past-the-post or plurality rule has a straightforward

application in multi-member districts as the SNTV system.26

It could also be implemented as

a block voting system. Proportional electoral formulas are, of course, not designed for single-

member constituencies, but if nevertheless applied, they would simply reduce to first-past-

the-post.

The classification below is relatively close to the ones in Reynolds et al. 2005 and Blanc et al

2006, but it is not exhaustive with respect to electoral formulas. A further description of the

methods can be found in both sources.

Plurality and majority elections in single-member constituencies:

– Plurality elections, ‘first-past-the-post’ (FPTP)

– Majority elections in two rounds (either top-two run-off or second round plurality)

– Majority elections by the alternative vote (AV)

Plurality elections in multi-member constituencies:

– Single, non-transferable vote (SNTV, which may result in semi-proportional

outcomes)

– Elections based on individual candidates, the ‘block vote’27

– Elections based on party lists, the ‘party block vote’

Proportional representation (one nation-wide constituency or several multi-member

constituencies):

25

Examples are Blais 1988, Reynolds, Reilly and Ellis 2005, Norris 2004: 41 and Renwick 2010: 4.

26 Cox 1997 has even shown that, under some conditions, SNTV will give the same outcome as the d’Hondt

(proportional) divisor rule.

27 In the block vote system, the voter may give as many individual votes as there are seats in the constituency. In

SNTV, the voter may only give one vote. The ‘limited vote’ system, where the voter may give more than one

vote but fewer than the total number of seats, is not listed here. In parliamentary elections, the only example of a

limited vote is to the Senate of Spain (Reynolds et al. 2005)

Page 25: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

23

– List-based proportional systems (List PR)

– Formulas based on quotas and largest remainders

– Formulas based on divisors and largest averages

– The single transferable vote (STV)

Mixed systems (combining single-member and multi-member constituencies):

– Dependent (compensatory system): Mixed-member proportional representation

(MMP)

– Independent (parallel system with separate upper tier, which may result in semi-

proportional outcomes)

We will not discuss other methods that are rarely used in parliamentary elections, such as the

de Borda count28

.

Mixed systems have at least two tiers, and one of the tiers consists of single-member

constituencies. Upper tiers also occur in systems with only multi-member districts, but then

typically as a set of adjustment seats to improve on the proportionality of election results. The

Scandinavian countries and South Africa are examples.

Depending on how one counts it, roughly half of today’s countries and territories conduct

legislative elections with systems that belong to the plurality/majority family. Most of the

others use (single-tier) proportional representation, but mixed systems have become more and

more popular over the last couple of decades.29

2.3.3 The Effect of the System of Representation on Group Representation

Each electoral system has its own characteristics when it comes to group or minority

representation. Generally speaking, the List PR system will accommodate such

representation better than majority/plurality-based systems.

Lijphart states that “[f]or divided societies, ensuring the election of a broadly representative

legislature should be the crucial consideration, and PR is undoubtedly the optimal way of

doing so”.30

Andrew Reynolds also argues that List PR gives better minority representation than other

systems do, without any pre-defined arrangement:

Because List PR systems encourage parties to maximize votes won both in areas where they are

strong and areas where they are weak (because every vote is aggregated at a larger level) there

exists an incentive to appeal to ‘other’ voters who may not be part of your core ethnic or

ideological base. Thus, List PR systems might encourage moderation in ethnic chauvinism and

inclusiveness of minorities in campaign appeals. This may be particularly strong if majority

parties need minority votes to make it over a given threshold or to have enough seats to form a

28

The election of two minority representatives of the parliament in Slovenia is a rare exception.

29 Reynolds et al. 2005, Golder 2005 and Shugart and Wattenberg 2001.

30 Lijphart 2008: 78.

Page 26: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

24

government. These incentives would dissipate if the party/majority group did not need extra votes

and appealing for such votes would lose them members of their core constituency who were

opposed to accommodatory overtures to minorities. 31

On the other hand, the majority/plurality systems will normally not accommodate minority

representation since the parties will tend to propose candidates belonging to the majority

group of the constituency. However, if a minority is geographically concentrated, such

systems may still work in a minority’s favour. Reynolds says:

Plurality-majority systems [...] are predisposed to exclude minorities from power, even if the

minority’s concentration allows them to win some single-member seats. There are countless cases

of minorities clustered in a given geographical area who can win a small number of

representatives, but who rarely form part of governing coalitions and cannot mount much of an

opposition to majority rule within the legislature. Plurality-majority systems (without extra

provisions to ensure multi-ethnic parties) are also likely to accentuate majority–minority

polarization and campaigns based on ‘us against them’ and ethnic chauvinism. The most efficient

way of winning more votes than the next candidate (if you are the largest group in a district) is to

make sure all your group members support you, and the easiest mobilization strategy revolves

around appeals to identity and preservation of group interests. If no single group can expect a clear

majority in a district, one group may seek alliances with other groups, but such geographic

intermingling is rare and alliances, while useful for one district, may alienate core voters in

others.32

This means that, everything else remaining the same, a List PR system will be more efficient

in providing minority representation than majority/plurality systems, even without any extra

measures.

Another advantage of List PR is that the groups do not have to be pre-defined.33

Any group

may form a party and take advantage of the system and any group may be included on the

lists by parties that want to appeal to the group in a particular election.

Majority or plurality-based systems may work well in cases where the minority is

concentrated and the constituencies are drawn up in such a way that the minority gets benefit

from the concentration. Under suppressive regimes, the opposite is often the case; the

constituencies are drawn to dilute the minority’s influence. It is therefore a challenge to

implement such systems for the benefit of a minority if there is a conflict; it will need good

will. Changes in the population structure will also not be automatically covered and the

arrangements will have to be pre-defined.

Further, List PR systems are easier to combine with methods to guarantee minorities a certain

representation. Plurality and majority systems may be combined with certain quota rules but

such rules, unless the groups are geographically concentrated, will often have negative side

31

Reynolds 2006: 21.

32 Reynolds 2006: 21-22.

33 Lijphart 2008.

Page 27: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

25

effects in terms of unreasonable restrictions to the passive voting rights or by changing the

political party result of the election (see the discussion of the various systems below).

Some experts advocate the use of the alternative vote (AV) in deeply divided societies (e.g.

Horowitz). It is a preferential system that – they argue – tends to reward political moderation

and compromise. The idea is that the single-member constituencies are drawn up in such a

way that no group has majority (more than fifty percent) and an elected candidate would

therefore need additional votes (second preference, third preference, etc.) from voters of

communities other than his or her own to be elected. This, in particular, has been tried out in

Fiji where one may claim that it has not worked as intended.34

It has been argued that the Fiji

experience has shown to be unsuccessful and that elections in single-member constituencies

will inevitably make minority representation more difficult.

See Chapter 7 for a more comprehensive discussion of the various systems.

2.4 Methods for Securing Group Representation

2.4.1 On the Purpose of Secured Group Representation

There are a large number of methods securing group representation. To a large extent, the

way each of them works is dependent on the overall system of representation, with some

exceptions. The method is also often chosen to support a specific purpose of the quotas. One

example is arrangements defined in power-sharing agreements where groups in conflict have

a fixed share of representatives in decision-making bodies regardless of electoral result.

Another example of a milder rule is the more general need for including groups that are

otherwise underrepresented or not represented at all in political decision-making. The driving

force is then a belief that a more inclusive body may be able to take better decisions; they can

draw on a broader experience, in addition to simply being fair.

This study is motivated by the search for arrangements which may reduce conflict, but it is

not obvious that it is the formal and rigid power-sharing agreements which have the most

positive short and long term effects. We therefore need to study all the quota systems

available to see how they work from a theoretical as well as empirical point of view.

The group representation arrangements that are independent of the system of representation

are those that can be classified as separate elections for a group. Other methods will be

described under the relevant systems of representation.

One important question regarding group representation is who is the electorate? Most gender

rules are, for example, implemented in such a way that all voters vote for all candidates but

the rules secure the gender balance. In other cases, the electorates are singled out, such as the

Maoris in New Zealand, who have a separate voters register for voters electing a fixed

number of members of parliament.

34

See e.g. Frankel 2001 for a thorough discussion.

Page 28: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

26

If the purpose of the quotas is to accommodate a small ethnic group with very special

interests compared to those of the population at large (e.g. in their use of natural resources), it

may be important that the representatives are elected by the group itself. However, where

fairly large groups have been at war, it may be sufficient to guarantee that a parliament has a

certain balance between the groups. This is not a straightforward consideration. Neither in

Bosnia and Herzegovina nor in Lebanon are there direct connections between the elected

group representatives and the groups they represent. Bosniacs may elect the Croat member of

the presidency and the Muslims may decide the Christian representative of a constituency of

the parliament of Lebanon. This may still be the best long-term solution if the goal is to

reduce segmentation and division.

If the groups in question are concentrated geographically, the most obvious solution to power-

sharing arrangement is to draw electoral constituencies in such a way that the groups are

guaranteed representation. This may be further underpinned by federal arrangements that

guarantee the units a degree of autonomy and rights to language, religion, etc. Devolution of

powers and federal systems as a means of power-sharing is, however, outside the scope of this

report.

It should also be mentioned that some schools of thought would try to do exactly the opposite:

draw constituencies in such a way that no group has a majority and that the elected member

(from single-member constituencies) will need support beyond his or her own group. This

may be done under AV or two-round systems.

The broad groups of methods for group representation are the following:

- Earmarked Seats

- Requirements to candidate nominations

- Requirements to the results (outcome)

- Appointments (discussed here even if they do not involve elections)

Within each category, there are a number of variants. For some of the mechanisms, effects are

closely linked to the system of representation with which they are combined.35

2.4.2 Earmarked Seats

Earmarked seats are contested only by candidates of one group, so it is a separate race for that

group. The term is used only for elected seats, even if there may be earmarked seats in

appointments as well. Earmarked seats may be used in any system of representation.

There are two main types of earmarked seats: (i) Systems with a separate tier defined for the

group (e.g. a Serb race for earmarked seats in Croatia) and (ii) systems with earmarked

constituencies (e.g. for scheduled castes and tribes in India). In some cases, the voters are the

general electorate and sometimes there is a separate electorate for that group only.

35

See also Reynolds 2005 for a brief, general overview of reserved seats in national legislatures.

Page 29: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

27

If only those belonging to the groups may elect the group representatives, one needs to

identify those voters, most often by a separate voters register. One fundamental requirement

for a separate race is that nobody should be forced to vote according to ethnicity, religion,

etc.36

If a voter register is used, it should be up to the individual to register there, and if there

is not a register the voter should, if needed, choose in secret which race to participate in.37

Sometimes a separate race is organised within a body for indirect elections. An example is

the election of the Croat and Bosniac members of the upper house (House of Peoples) in

Bosnia and Herzegovina. These elections are held in separate caucuses of the House of

Peoples of the entity known as the Federation Bosnia and Herzegovina.

Earmarked seats may lead to over-representation, both for direct and for indirect elections,

since the system may allow a group to be represented both in a general race and in a race for

earmarked seats. Such overrepresentation may be intentional or, at least, it must be tolerable.

Earmarked seats (separate race) without separate voters register

This can be done either by letting the voters decide in what race they want to participate, or

by adding a race where everybody can vote but where all the candidates need to come from

the group in question. The latter arrangement is often referred to as a second (or multi) tier

election.

Voters choose the race. In this case, the candidates or candidate lists are marked with group

belonging but all voters can choose any candidate or list of candidates in secret. For example,

this is the case in Kosovo where there are lists for Serb parties and for other smaller

minorities.38

Voters cast votes in multiple races. Here, all voters are invited to give a vote both in the

general race and in the race for the seats reserved for the group representation. This is quite

common for female representation (Egypt, Sudan, etc) but could also be used to promote

other excluded groups.

Earmarked constituencies. Constituencies may be earmarked for particular groups. In India,

more than 20 percent of the single-member constituencies (FPTP) are reserved for so-called

36

Some elections are held without voter registers and in such cases the voters would need some kind of

identification to show the group belonging in polling station.

37 See The Council of Europe Framework Convention for the Protection of National Minorities, Article 3:

«1. Every person belonging to a national minority shall have the right freely to choose to be treated or not to be

treated as such and no disadvantage shall result from this choice or from the exercise of the rights which are

connected to that choice.

2. Persons belonging to national minorities may exercise the rights and enjoy the freedoms flowing from the

principles enshrined in the present framework Convention individually as well as in community with others.»

38 In Kosovo, such lists participate both in the general race and in the separate race for reserved for the groups.

Page 30: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

28

scheduled castes and tribes. Those constituencies to be earmarked have a concentration of the

protected groups in their population. That means that all candidates in such constituencies

must come from the reserved groups. Other people living in the constituencies can only run

in another constituency. In a system with single-member constituencies, it is quite common

to run outside where the candidate lives, but the earmarking does limit the right to stand for

elections. In India, this limitation has been regarded as acceptable.

In Lebanon, all seats in the multi-member constituencies (in a block vote system) are

earmarked by confession. The profile of the constituency is the basis but there will be a

number of people who cannot run in their own constituency. With multi-member

constituencies and all seats earmarked, a candidate without the right confession may have to

run quite far from his or her own constituency. In addition, only Christians and Muslims are

able to run and therefore some people (even though they are currently few) cannot run at all.

This represents a rather serious limitation to the right to stand for elections. The Lebanese

system is a combination of earmarked constituencies and best runner-up, since the

constituencies are not earmarked for one single group only.

Another possibility is that the earmarking may rotate from one election to the next. This is

done for women in local elections in India. In one election, all candidates of a constituency

have to be women and then at the next election, that requirement is shifted to another

constituency. In that way, the restriction on running is limited and temporary.

Earmarked Seats (Separate Race) with a Separate Voters Register

Under this arrangement, a separate voters register for the group is established. In some cases,

like for the Maoris in New Zealand, those choosing to register in the separate register are

removed from the general register. Each voter, therefore, has only one vote, either the general

or the separate group one. In Croatia as well, voters from minority groups may choose to

register as a minority voter and then participate in the minority race.

One could have arrangements where the group only had two ballots, one general and one for

the group. This would affect the equality of the vote and may therefore be problematic.

2.4.3 Requirements to Candidate Nominations

In plurality and majority systems, one may require parties to nominate a certain number of

group candidates across the country.39

This was done for women in Nepal in 1999, but it did

not translate into a corresponding number of women elected to parliament. It is easy for

parties to undermine the purpose of such a requirement by putting up the group candidate in

constituencies where they are sure not to win. Further, the requirement would only be applied

to party candidates and not to independent candidates.

Within List PR systems, the simplest form of group representation is to define requirements to

the candidate lists. One may either require a certain percentage of candidates to be of a

39

A special issue of the journal Party Politics (volume 7, issue 3, 2001) gives a general overview of methods for

candidate selection and their consequences.

Page 31: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

29

certain group or, in addition, they could include requirements for a prominent placement of

the group candidates on the list. It has, for example, become common for parties in their by-

laws to require women and men to alternate on the lists (the 'zipper rule') and in some

countries, similar rules are enforced by law.

If the lists are closed (which means that they are published in advance and that the seats won

by a party are filled from the top of the ranked lists), rules of the type described above will, to

a large extent, guarantee group representation. With open lists, the voters may give votes to

individual candidates on the lists and the voters’ choice determines which candidates will fill

the seats. In such cases, the ranking on the list may change and the representation of specific

groups is not guaranteed unless there are quota rules even for the results.

2.4.4 Requirements to the Results

Obviously, the earmarked seats provide requirements to the results. Under this header, we

will, however, consider systems where all or a number of groups may run for the elections,

but the outcome of the election is “adjusted” ex post in such a way that it meets certain pre-

defined requirements of group representation.

In block vote, STV or SNTV in multi-member constituencies, one may have a requirement

where a certain number of those elected need to come from a particular group. If the

requirement is not met automatically, the group candidate(s) with the highest number of votes

replace(s) the general candidates elected with the lowest number of votes — this is known as

the ’best runner-up system‘. The problem with this rule is that a group candidate of one party

may replace the candidate of another party. The political party dimension is therefore

affected. In Palestine in 1996 and 2006, Christians had quotas in the multi-member

constituencies under a block vote system and, in both elections, Christians from one party

replaced Muslims from another party because of the quota system.

In Jordan, there is a women’s quota applied to the whole membership of the parliament, but

not to each multi-member constituency.40

If there are not a sufficient number of women

elected, the runner-up(s) with the highest number of votes replace the weakest elected

candidate of the same constituency. The political distribution is affected in this case as well.

In addition, the choice of which constituency is subject to the quota is quite random. The one

with the highest number of votes is not necessarily the strongest candidate, since the size of

the constituencies varies.

In single-member constituencies, the best runner-up is a less obvious solution, but it could be

done in a way similar to the Jordanian example, with the same negative effects in the political

composition, which, in this case, would always change.

In List PR systems, requirements for the result may be applied within lists or across lists.

Requirements within lists means that a certain share of the candidates elected from a party

need to come from a certain group. If the requirements are not met by filling the seats from

40

The system of representation is SNTV, but the quotas may work in the same way under the block vote system.

Page 32: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

30

the top of the list (as defined by the party or by the voters if the list is open), one may search

down the list for the best runner-up of the needed category.

Requirements across lists are more complicated to implement (for the election management

body, not the voters), but they may be used where one needs to guarantee a certain

representation. If, for example, there are many small parties winning seats, the quotas may

not be filled when adding up the results for all parties.41

The rules are most easily

implemented by the use of division methods for distributing seats (such as d’Hondt or Sainte-

Laguë) where the seats are issued to parties one by one. If there is a minimum quota for a

group of 30 percent, there cannot be more than 70 percent of seats filled by members not

belonging to that group. When the number 70 percent is reached during the distribution, all

non-group members on all lists are simply deleted and the rest of the seats are given to

members of the protected group. Requirements for the composition of the lists would ensure

that all party lists include such candidates and the balance between the parties is therefore not

affected.

Closed lists

With closed lists, requirements for filling seats applied to the lists only will not add to the

representation.42

The exception to that is the system used in Nepal where the lists are not

predefined in a ranked order. The parties may fill the seats by anyone on the lists after the

elections, as long as they observe the quota rules.43

The requirements across lists may add to the group representation by guaranteeing a

minimum representation, regardless of the size of parties winning seats.

Open lists

With open lists, the voters may change the order on the list and thus alter the group

representation. This may be “repaired” or “corrected” by applying the quotas to the result.

This will limit the voters’ choice in their open list vote, but every quota rule has that effect.

The voters will still decide on the candidates to be elected within the boundaries defined by

the quotas.

Requirements across lists would serve the same purpose as for closed lists.

2.4.5 Appointments

In some countries, group representation is secured by indirect elections or appointments. For

the principal chamber of parliament, it is a generally understood principle that all members

41

If one out of four needs to be a minority representative and many parties win from one to three seats, there is a

chance that the group never wins a seat.

42 Rules for filling seats could, however, replace the rules for prominent placement of group candidates on the

list, but that would be less transparent and less predictable for the voters.

43 This is not a system recommended by international bodies since the transparency and predictability is low.

Page 33: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

31

should be directly elected.44

In some countries (for example Pakistan), minority

representatives are distributed to parties according to their share in the parliament and are

selected from predefined lists. In a way, they are therefore elected but the Hindu or Christian

representatives are chosen based upon votes for the majority parties in single-member

constituencies and the distance from the voter to those elected is therefore long.

In other countries, the government or the president appoints a number of representatives that

may be used to compliment the group representation. In these arrangements, one

disadvantage is the distance from those appointed and the people they are supposed to

represent and the lack of accountability. We will not discuss such arrangement any further

except for listing the countries that apply such arrangements.

2.4.6 A Summary Table

We summarise the discussion above with a table. The various types of requirements and the

main types of electoral systems (systems of representation) result in forty combinations or

cells. We illustrate by mentioning one or two countries that currently use a particular

combination. Empty cells mean that a combination as far as we know is not in use today, but

there could nevertheless be historical examples.

44

This is explicitly stated in the CSCE Copenhagen document of 1991, but it also follows from a reasonable

interpretation of the International Covenant on Civil and Political Rights.

Page 34: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

32

Table 2.1: Electoral systems and types of requirements to secure group representation.

System of

representation

(electoral

systems)

Earmarked Seats

(Separate race)

Nomination requirements Results

requirements,

best runner-ups Without

separate

voters

register

With

separate

voters

register

In percent Placement

Single-member

constituencies

with

plurality/majorit

y

India Fiji, New

Zealand

Not efficient,

women in

Nepal before

2008

This is handled

under

earmarked

seats

Block vote Lebanon, in

combination

with best

runner-up

Possible but

not efficient

Possible but

not efficient

The Palestinian

Territory

Party block vote Singapore

List PR closed Kosovo Croatia Does not

guarantee

representatio

n

Bolivia,

women

Municipal

election in the

Palestinian

Territory, Nepal

List PR Open Does not

guarantee

representatio

n

Women in

Bosnia and

Herzegovina

STV

Mixed systems

(MMP and

Parallel)

The

Palestinian

Territory,

women

The Palestinian

Territory,

women

Nepal

SNTV Jordan

Page 35: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

33

2.4.7 A theoretical Assessment of the Methods

When assessing the methods, one should look into how they actually work, including whether

they have unwanted side effects. In this section, we restrict ourselves to a brief overview of

possible effects and other evaluative considerations.

The possible side effects could be:

The quotas may change the composition of the parliament in terms of party

representation. If, for example, in the best runner-up system under the block vote, a

candidate from a protected group of one party replaces a candidate of another party,

the political distribution is affected. In the long-term in particular, the political

dimension should be the most important one to consider.

The equality of the vote could be undermined, and weaken the democratic quality of

the system.

Limitations to the right to vote.

Unreasonable limitations to the right to stand for elections.

Complexity.

The long term incentives for reconciliation and equality.

The following systems seem to be the most effective:

Earmarked Seats

Efficiency in representation: The representation will be as intended. Representation

may be in addition to representation coming out of the regular race.

The party-wise representation: This may be less affected, at least if the system of

representation is the same for all seats.

Equality of the vote: If the group voters have votes in a general race in addition to in

the separate one, the inequality may be strong. This may be an intended effect for a

vulnerable group.

Limitations to the right to vote: Normally not affected.

Limitation to standing for elections: If there are earmarked constituencies where the

candidacy is restricted and the electorate a general one, there will be a limitation to

standing for elections. Normally, the restrictions will be applied only locally and

candidates will be able to run in another constituency.

Long-term effects: Since the earmarked seats are separated out, inequalities are

underlined.

Requirements to nominations in List PR

Efficiency in representation: If there is a requirement to the placement on the lists, the

system is efficient. Even if an open list system may reduce the effect, the system still

works quite well.

The party-wise representation: No effects.

Equality of the vote: All voters are treated the same way.

Limitations to the right to vote: Normally not.

Limitation to standing for elections: Some candidates will have a lower chance of

being nominated, and that is an intended and legitimate effect of the system.

Page 36: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

34

Long-term effects: This is a system which is fully integrated into the general system

of representation and may affect the segmentation of the electorate less compared to

other systems.

Requirements to the results in List PR

Efficiency in representation: The system is efficient.

The party-wise representation: No effects, unless a party list is exhausted of

candidates of the required flavour. The party may prevent this from happening by

securing a broad range of candidates.

Equality of the vote: All voters are treated the same way.

Limitations to the right to vote: Normally not.

Limitation to stand for elections: Some candidates will have a lower chance of being

nominated, and they may be by-passed when filling seats won. That is an intended

and legitimate effect of the system.

Long-term effects: This is a system which is fully integrated into the general system

of representation and may affect the segmentation of the electorate less compared to

other systems.

Best runner-up systems in a plurality of majority-based systems may change the party

political composition of the parliament and should be avoided.

2.5 Power-Sharing – Decision-Making Procedures

Elements of power-sharing agreements will limit majority rule and give the parties to the

arrangement powers in terms of guaranteed representation and decision-making rules

(presumably) favourable to their interests. In the sections above, the main focus has been on

representation. We will now look into some of the formal rules for decision-making, which

may be elements of a power-sharing arrangement. For example, most countries have

conservative rules for changes to the constitution or for the impeachment of a president.

These are not covered here. The rules we deal with are those that can be seen as unusual or

atypical for the type of decision-making in question, and that are motivated out of power-

sharing considerations.

Decision-making rules based on broad consensus have to be balanced against the needs for

efficiency. In all the countries of the in-depth studies, this balance is important. In Part IV,

we will draw some conclusions based upon the experience of different models.

2.5.1 Qualified Majorities

Most decisions in representative bodies are made by a majority of those present and voting;

simple majorities decide. Absolute majority is a slightly more demanding requirement, as at

least a majority of the members (not just those present) of an assembly need to agree.

Qualified majority rule means that more than half of those present or of all members has to

agree to make a decision. The most common types of qualified majority rules are three-fifths,

two-thirds and four-fifths, but any rule between simple or absolute majority and unanimity

Page 37: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

35

belong to this class.45

Unanimity rule grants veto power to each and every participant. It is

common to require a qualified majority to change a constitution and in other situations where

the status quo is a viable alternative. When voting on regular legislation and budgets, the

common practice is to require only a simple majority for a valid decision. A higher threshold

may easily lead to stalemates where the body is unable to make a decision, even in such cases

where everybody agrees that a decision is necessary.

Requiring a qualified majority even in ordinary decisions typically has the need for consensus

as background. In a deeply divided society, the ideal may be that decisions should be

compromises where none of the groups feel left out or overrun by the majority. In Bosnia and

Herzegovina, Lebanon and Nepal, which are the cases we analyse, there are strong elements

of consensus philosophy behind the peace agreements.

In Burundi, all laws need a two-thirds majority to pass in parliament. Each of the groups in

conflict has at least forty percent of the representatives of the parliament so that such a

requirement would prevent the largest group to force through a decision without at least some

support of the other group.

2.5.2 Double Majorities

Repeated majority decisions by the same body and various forms of double majority

requirements have the same stabilizing effects as qualified majority rule. The decision-making

system turns more rigid and deadlocks become more likely.46

In Bosnia and Herzegovina,

certain decisions can only be made by a double majority. In addition to the majority of all

representatives of a house of parliament, there needs to be a majority within the caucus of

each of the two entities as well.

2.5.3 Veto Powers

Another way of protecting a minority from arbitrary decisions by the majority is to give the

minority veto powers within certain areas. In Bosnia and Herzegovina, one of the three

caucuses (Croats, Bosniacs and Serbs) in the parliament may apply a so-called vital national

clause if they feel that their fundamental rights are threatened and veto the decision. It is also

common that changes to a constitution may require consent by various groups and thus offer a

veto against change to defined groups.

2.5.4 The Balancing of State Bodies

In many countries, the composition of the two houses of a bicameral parliament may have a

composition reflecting different principles. The upper house may represent groups of people

(or units of a federation) rather that individual voters and some decisions may have to pass

votes in a chamber where a minority is stronger than in the principal chamber.47

45

See Rasch 1995 and McGann 2006. Rasch also deals with quorum requirements and mechanisms to resolve

ties.

46 Tsebelis 2002 and McGann 2006.

47 Tsebelis and Money 1997 give an overview of institutional features in bicameral systems.

Page 38: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

36

Other mechanisms, such as the relationship between the executive and the parliament, the

powers of the judiciary, etc. also have implications on the power-sharing between groups, but

these are elements which will not have the main focus in this study.

Page 39: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

37

3: Broad Overview of Systems

3.1 The Americas

3.1.1 Introduction

Bolivia, Columbia and Venezuela all have quotas for small indigenous and some other

groups. The indigenous groups live in a traditional manner in the Amazonas region and

should not be confused with Mestizo or other mixed or urbanised groups. The countries have

a colonial history, have mixed populations (indigenous groups and European and African

heritage) and have had conflicts related to the control of land and natural resources like water,

forestry, and oil.

Belize is not included here, since their social representation is based on appointments only.48

Table of systems The Americas

Country and

name of

assembly

Electoral System Basis of Quota Type of quota Democracy Index

BOLIVIA

Plurinational

Legislative

Assembly

(Asamblea

Legislativa

Plurinacional)

Chamber of deputies (Cámara de Diputados)

Parallel

(List PR+FPTP)

Ethnicity Earmarked seats

Partly free Gender Quota on lists

Senate (Cámara de

Senadores) No quota No quota

COLOMBIA

Congress

(Congreso)

House of representatives

(Cámara de

Representantes): FPTP

Ethnicity

and ‘small parties’

Earmarked constituencies,

earmarked seats

Partly free

Senate (Senado de la

República): List PR Ethnicity

Earmarked constituency,

earmarked seats

VENEZUELA

National Assembly

(Asamblea Nacional):

Parallel

Ethnicity Earmarked constituency,

earmarked seats Partly free

48

Half of the senators of Belize are appointed on advice from the prime minister, while three are appointed in

accordance with advice of the leader of the opposition, one in accordance with advice from the Council of

Churches and Evangelical Association of Churches, one from Commerce and Industry and the Business Bureau,

and one in accordance with the National Trade Union Congress (Belize Constitution Act Chapter 4, Revised

Edition 2002, Article 61.4).

Page 40: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

38

3.1.2 Bolivia

The current government party, MAS (Movimiento al Socialismo) was established in 2001 as

an alliance of social movements, representing indigenous groups, small farmers, organized

labour and parts of the Bolivian middle class. MAS forms a reaction to social and economic

cleavages that date back to the colonization by Spain in the 16th

century and the prevailing

dominance of the Spanish elite over political powers, land and natural resources. In 1952, a

Mestizo-led revolution resulted in general voting rights, land reform and the nationalization of

tin mines. The (MNR) Revolutionary Nationalist Movement government was deposed in

1964, and until 1982, Bolivia was under military rule. Comprehensive liberal market reforms

in the 1980s and 1990s culminated in strong protests, strikes, marches, demonstrations and

the loss of faith in traditional political parties. Against this backdrop, the MAS won elections

in 2005 on a platform of socialism, nationalization and land reform. Perhaps the most

important electoral promise was that of a new constitution to ‘re-establish’ the Bolivian state

on a multicultural and multiethnic basis. The new constitution was passed in 2004 in spite of

bitter, and at times violent, protests from the opposition due to disagreements over the

distribution of income from the oil and gas sector, as well as the issue of regional autonomy.

Bolivia defines itself as a unitary social state based on ‘Pluri-National Communitarian Law’

(Constitution49

, Article 1). Article 3 states that the Bolivian nation is formed by all Bolivians,

the native indigenous nations and peoples, and the inter-cultural and Afro-Bolivian

communities that, together, constitute the Bolivian people. Nations and indigenous peoples

are defined as “every human collective that shares a cultural identity, language, historic

tradition, institutions, territory and world view, whose existence predates the Spanish colonial

invasion” (Constitution, Article 30).

The parliament has two chambers: The Chamber of Deputies and the Senate. The Chamber of

Deputies consists of 130 members elected in a Parallel system. 77 are elected from single-

member constituencies and the other 53 are elected in a List PR system in multi-member

constituencies, which constitute the nine ‘departments’50

. Among the 77 single-member

constituencies, there are seven reserved for indigenous peoples and they are apportioned to

non-contiguous, rural areas (Constitution, Article 146-147) based upon population data.

Article 147 of the Constitution also has two other requirements:

I. The equal participation of men and women shall be guaranteed in the election of the

members of the assembly.

II. Proportional participation of the nations and rural native indigenous peoples shall be

guaranteed in the election of members of the assembly.

In order to meet criterion I above, the election law Article 9 prescribes that male and female

candidates need to be 'zipped' on the list in the PR race (which means that there will be close

to half of each gender on the lists) and the parties need to suggest a man and a woman as

candidate and substitute in each of the single-member constituencies. These two rules will

49

As updated per May 2009. 50

The transitional election law of 14 April 2009.

Page 41: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

39

not guarantee that half of the members of chamber are women, since parties winning an odd

number of seats may return one more men than women and all the candidates elected from the

single-members constituencies may be men. However, the requirements for gender balance

are quite far reaching.

The second requirements (II) of proportional participation of the nations and rural native

indigenous peoples do not seem to be regulated further by law. There is no specific rule for

the composition of the candidate lists in the multi-member constituencies. The only guarantee

is the one coming from the seven reserved single-member constituencies.

According to Article 148 of the Constitution, the Senate consists of 36 members with four

elected from each of the nine departments. The election is direct and by List PR.

3.1.3 Colombia

Close to 60 percent of the Colombian population is of mixed European-Native American

descent as a result of the Spanish colonization of the country. Colombia is a unitary republic

with a presidential system. The legislature is bicameral. The House of Representatives

consists of 166 directly elected members, out of which 161 are elected from 33 multi-member

constituencies corresponding to the departments and district of Bogotá51

with at least two

seats in each. The electoral system is List PR with closed lists.

Article 176 of the constitution provides ethnic minority representation in the House of

Representatives. According to the law,52

five special representatives are elected in nationwide

constituencies, two for the black community and one for each of the groups: indigenous

people, political minorities and Colombians abroad. The term political minorities refers to

such parties which have tried to stand for elections nationwide but not won any seats53

, and

the electoral system is FPTP.

Everybody is entitled to vote for the indigenous and black candidates.54

According to Duarte,

only 0.51 percent of those eligible to vote in the black constituency participated in 2006

(51,443 out of 26,593,271 voters).

The Senate consists of 83 directly elected members, also elected by List PR with closed lists.

In addition to the 83, two seats are earmarked for indigenous communities from one

nationwide constituency (Constitution, Article 171.2), and three in an earmarked constituency

for political minorities (Constitution, Article 171.2). Indigenous candidates must have been a

traditional leader figure in their communities or have been leaders of an indigenous

organization.

51

The Constitution as last updated November 2008. 52

Law 649 of 27 March 2001. 53

Article 40 of the Law 649 requires those competing for these seats to have nominated candidates in at least 30

percent of the constituencies, not won any seats and not have more than 70 percent of their votes cast in one

constituency. 54

This is not obvious from the primary sources available but Duarte 2007, for example, gives a good indication.

Page 42: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

40

In addition to the indigenous quota, Article 112 of the Election Law requires that candidate

lists to the Lower House (Cámara de Diputados) must include at least one woman out of

every three candidates in the PR part of the election.

3.1.4 Venezuela

Venezuela’s population is mixed, with Spanish, Italian and Portuguese as the main European

groups, and indigenous peoples. The Venezuelan republic is unitary with a presidential

political system. The legislature is unicameral and has 165 members. Out of these, 110 are

elected by FPTP from 87 constituencies, 52 elected on a party list system (two or three

deputies per state of Venezuela, depending on population), and 3 seats were reserved for

indigenous peoples, with separate rules (Constitution, Article 186). The system is a Parallel

system.

According to the Election Law of 12 August 2009 Chapter XV, the three seats reserved for

the indigenous are elected from geographical constituencies, one from the west, one from the

east and one from the south of the country. Such a constituency may not constitute a

continuous geographical area (Article 179.) The candidate is elected who receives a majority

of the valid votes in his region.

All native organizations or communities have the right to nominate native candidates who

speak their native language, and who have an established social or political position within

the community. The nominating organizations must be legally constituted and must have been

in existence for at least three years.

Candidates eligible for election must fulfil one of the following requirements: 1. Been a

traditional leader, 2. Had a track record of fighting for cultural indigenous identity, 3. Played

an active role in providing benefits for indigenous people, 4. Be a member of a legal

indigenous organisation that has been operating for at least three years.

The Article 178 prescribes that those eligible to vote for the ethnic group race have to be

registered in a separate voters register.

3.1.5 Main Findings

Ethnic quotas are found in Colombia, Bolivia and Venezuela in the form of earmarked seats

for indigenous and other small groups. The violent conflicts in the countries have a political

and ideological background. The conditions for indigenous groups have not been unrelated to

conflicts but the quotas as such cannot be seen as measures to establish power-sharing

between conflicting groups.

3.2 Asia-Pacific

3.2.1 Introduction

In this area, there are conflicts related to religious identity (Moslem versus Christian, Hindu

versus Moslem and Christian), ethnicity and social and economic differences. In some

countries, far left parties with a strong ideological conviction often with broad mass bases

have emerged. Armed conflicts have prevailed.

Page 43: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

41

Nepal is the only country in our selection without a colonial past.

Our selection only includes countries with electoral quotas. That is why Sri Lanka, which has

been through a civil war based on an ethnic conflict, has not been included. Sri Lanka is a

country where devolution of powers combined with quotas could be a response to the conflict.

Prolonged attempts to find a power-sharing arrangement have, however, failed. Kiribati is not

included since their group representation is based upon appointment only.55

Table of systems Asia-Pacific

Electoral System Basis of Quota Type of quota Democracy

Index

AFGHANISTAN

National Assembly

(Jirga)

House of

Representatives (Wolesi Jirga)

SNTV

Social Group

Earmarked seats

Reserved constituency for

nomads

Not free House of Elders (Meshrano Jirga)

Indirect TRS +

presidential

appointment

No quota

FIJI

Parliament

House of

Representatives

AV and FPTP

Ethnicity

Separate race

and voters registers FPTP

and multiethnic delimitation

in AV constituencies

Partly free

INDIA

Parliament (Sansad)

House of the People (Lok Sabha)

FPTP + Executive

Appointment

Social group and

ethnicity

Earmarked constituencies

for scheduled castes and

tribes

Free Ethnicity Earmarked seats, executive

appointment

Council of States (Rajya Sabha)

Indirect, STV +

Executive Appointment

Experts and

particular skills

Earmarked seats, executive

appointment

NEPAL

Parliament (Sansad)

Constituent Assembly

(Sambidhan Sabha)

Parallel (FPTP and List

PR) plus appointments

Social group,

ethnicity and

linguistic groups

Requirements to lists

Nomination percentage

Selection from party lists

composed after elections to

fill quotas

Partly free

Gender

55

One seat is reserved from a representative of the Banaban community, who inhabit the Rabi Island which in

turn belong to Fiji. This member is appointed by the Rabi Council (Constitution, Article 117), the municipal

body that administers the Rabi Island. It may be classified as indirect election but it is not significant in our

context.

Page 44: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

42

NEW

ZEALAND

House of

Representatives

MMP

Ethnicity

Separate race

earmarked constituencies Free

PAKISTAN

Parliament (Majlis-E-

Shoora)

National Assembly:

Direct FPTP election +

indirect List PR

representation

Religion

List PR in one nationwide

constituency from separate,

closed party lists, based on

the distribution of seats in

parliament

Partly free Gender

List PR in reserved

constituencies from

separate, closed party lists

based on the distribution of

seats in parliament

Senate:

STV Indirect

Gender Reserved seats

Social Groups Reserved seats

PHILIPPINES

Congress

(Kongreso)

House of

Representatives (Kapulungan Ng

Kinatawan):

Parallel (Mostly FPTP

but List PR for small

parties)

Small parties with

purpose to

accommodate social

groups

Reserved constituency with

List PR

Partly free

Senate

(Senado): Block vote No quota

SAMOA

Legislative Assembly

(Fono): Parallel

(FPTP+BV)

Ethnicity

Earmarked constituency,

separate race

Free

SINGAPORE

Parliament

Parallel (FPTP+PBV)

+

appointments

Ethnicity

Reserved constituencies

with list requirements and

Party block vote

Partly free

3.2.2 Fiji

Fiji is a unitary republic with a parliamentary political system. The parliament has two

chambers, the House of Representatives and the Senate, with 71 and 32 members

respectively. The Senate consists of 32 members, of whom 14 are appointed by the President

on the advice of the Great Council of Chiefs (Bose Levu Vakaturaga)56

, nine are to be

appointed by the President on the advice of the Prime Minister, eight are appointed by the

56

The Council has, however, been suspended after a conflict with Frank Bainaimarama, leader of the interim

government, which came to power after a military coup in December 2006.

Page 45: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

43

President on the advice of the Leader of the Opposition, and one is appointed by the President

on the advice of the Council of Rotuma (Constitution, Article 64). The Senate has a delay

veto, except for money bills (Constitution, Article 47-48).

From 1874 until 1970, Fiji was a colony under British rule. Under the rule of the British

governor, Indian labourers were imported to work on the European sugar estates. Interaction

between these and the indigenous Fijian population was limited until independence was

achieved. Over time, the Indian population has come to dominate the economic sphere,

whereas the indigenous Fijians have maintained political dominance. Elections were fought

largely along communal lines until the emergence of the Fiji Labour Party in 1985. The 1987

elections brought a coalition of the Labour party and the Indo-Fijian National Federation

Party to power, followed by a military intervention to restore indigenous political hegemony

only two years later57

. Since then, Fijian politics has been marked by instability caused by

friction between the two dominant groups.

An escalating conflict between the groups was tried solved in the 1990s by the adoption of a

new constitution in 1997, changing the electoral system of Fiji from FPTP into the Alternative

Vote. Several electoral rolls were introduced: one Fijian, one Indian, one for the smaller

Rotuman group, one general, and one common for all groups. Electors registered in the two

first rolls choose 23 and 19 representatives respectively to a parliament consisting of 71

members. The two following groups elect a total of four, while all electors registered in the

common roll elect 25 representatives. The ethnically-based elections are done by FPTP,

whereas the common election is held by AV in single-member constituencies.

The system was intended to reduce the polarization between Fijians and Indians by promoting

majority victors and encourage interethnic accommodation through the common roll.58

The

idea was to draw up constituencies where none of the groups had majority and therefore

candidates would have to rely on secondary support from ethnic groups other than their own.

This system should therefore encourage moderate candidates within the groups.

Results from elections held in 1999, 2000 and 2006, however, indicated that “the majority of

transfers of preference votes in Fiji flowed from the more moderate or centrist parties towards

the more extremist organisations”.59

Since then, the country has seen two military coups

(2000 and 2006), and there is a widespread concern that the system has not worked as

intended. The conflict still runs deep. New elections are scheduled for 2011. Electoral reform

has been on the political agenda for years, but the debate has remained inconclusive. One

main criticism of the AV constituencies has been that they are artificial. They have been

drawn up to produce a particular result and have therefore been seen by many as ‘electoral

engineering’.

57

Lal 1997 and Ramesha 2010. 58

Reeves, Vakatora & Lal, 1996 as quoted in Horowitz 2006: 653, and Reilly as quoted in Ramesha 2010: 493 59

Fraenkel, as quoted in Ramesha 2010: 493.

Page 46: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

44

3.2.3 India

India is a federal republic consisting of 28 states, the National Capital Territory of Delhi and 6

centrally administered Union Territories. The federal system has defused some of India’s

tensions, exempting the thorny issue of Kashmir. In spite of a constitutional ban, there is also

widespread discrimination against the Dalits or outcastes by India’s higher castes. A growing

Maoist movement appealing to the Dalits and the landless, and communist guerrillas were

active, as of 2010, in more than one-third of India’s districts. Christians and Muslims have

been subject to attacks by Hindu groups in areas like Gujarat and Orissa. Similarly, Hindus

have been attacked in Jammu and Kashmir, where they themselves constitute the minority.

The political system is parliamentary. The President appoints the Prime Minister who needs

to enjoy the confidence of the House of People (Constitution, Article 75), Ministers are

appointed by the president on advice of the prime minister, and do not require parliamentary

approval (Constitution, Article 75). The President is elected by the legislature (Constitution,

Article 54).

The legislature consists of a lower chamber, the House of the People (Lok Sabha), and an

upper chamber, the Council of States (Rajya Sabha). Laws must be passed in both chambers

(Constitution, Article 108). The exception is money bills, which are not presented to the

Council of States. When a bill has been passed by both Houses, it is presented to the

President, who may either assent or request the Houses to reconsider the bill with proposed

amendments. If the bill is passed again, with or without amendments, the president cannot

withhold his assent (Constitution, Article 111). Laws can be subject to constitutional review

by the Supreme Court (Constitution, Article 132).

The House of the People consists of no more than 530 members elected directly from the

constituencies and not more than 20 members elected to represent the Union territories

(Constitution, Article 81.1). These are elected by plurality vote in single-member

constituencies, FPTP. The Council of States consists of no more than 238 representatives

from the states. Representatives are elected “by the elected members of the Legislative

Assembly of the State in accordance with the system of proportional representation by means

of the single transferable vote”. (Article 80, 4)

There are 84 reserved seats in the Lok Sabha for so-called Scheduled Castes and 46 seats for

Scheduled Tribes.60

Scheduled castes constitute approximately 16 percent of the Indian

population, whereas scheduled tribes constitute 8 percent. Relative to the remaining

population, these groups remain socially and economically disadvantaged.61

In order to

improve the standing of scheduled castes and tribes, the 1950 Constitution sets down a system

for ensuring representation for these groups in the national and state assemblies. According to

Article 332 of the Constitution, the reserved seats are filled from reserved constituencies

where only candidates from these communities can stand for elections. However, the entire

electorate may vote for any qualified candidate.

60

Increased from 79 and 41 respectively in March 2009, see Election Commission of India, No.

ECI/PN/47/2009, Press Note, 31. August 2009. 61

Pande 2003: 1138.

Page 47: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

45

Caste definitions are based on the 1931 census, whereas tribal identification criteria were

decided by Parliament in 1950. The state-wise break-up is given in the 1st schedule to the

Representation of the People Act, 1950. The scheduled caste and scheduled tribe lists have

been twice revised since then. It falls to the Delimitation Commission to ensure that the

selected districts are the ones with a higher population share of the group in whose favour

reservation is being practiced, while ensuring a sufficient dispersal of reserved jurisdictions

within the state.62

In addition, the president may nominate two members to the House of the People to represent

the Anglo-Indian community, “if he is of opinion that the Anglo-Indian community is not

adequately represented” (Constitution, Article 331). Furthermore, the president appoints

twelve members to the Council of States. These members are “persons having special

knowledge or practical experience in [...] Literature, science, art and social service”

(Constitution, Article 80 (3)).

As of May 2011, there is no women’s quota for the Parliament. An attempt was made to pass

legislation to reserve one third of the seats for female candidates, but the process was

interrupted by the dissolution of Lok Sabha before the 1998 elections. However, on March 9th

2010, the Constitution (108th Amendment) Bill that grants 33 percent reservation to women

was passed by the Rajya Sabha. At the time of writing, the legislation is to be introduced to

the Lok Sabha, where it will need a two-thirds majority to pass.

3.2.4 Nepal

Nepal’s current legislature is the Constituent Assembly that was elected in April 2008.

Pending a new constitution due in 2011, the Assembly draws its powers from the Interim

Constitution of January 2007. The following is based on the Interim Constitution as amended

by May 2010.

The Interim Constitution stated that the Constituent Assembly should implement the

transition from a monarchy to a republic at its first meeting (art. 159 (2)), which was held in

May 2008. Nepal is still a unitary republic with a unicameral parliament, but the transitional

article 159 of the interim constitution pre-empts the future constitution by stating that, “Nepal

shall be a federal democratic republican state.”

The constituent assembly is tasked with drafting a new constitution. Article Laws are passed

by a simple majority of the total number of members of the House (Interim Constitution,

Article 85). A bill becomes an Act after being certified by the Speaker (Interim Constitution,

Article 87).

The Constituent Assembly consists of 601 members. Of these, 240 members were elected by

FPTP from single-member constituencies, and 335 were elected by List PR with closed lists63

from one nationwide constituency. 26 distinguished persons and persons from ethnic groups

62

Ibid, p. 1139. 63

The term 'closed lists’ means that voters could not influence the election, but the lists were not ranked and it

was up to the party executives to select which candidates should fill the seats won after the elections.

Page 48: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

46

who fail to be represented through the regular election process (Interim Constitution of 28

December 2007, Article 63) were to be appointed by the government. Elections were held in

two parallel races that were disconnected in terms of distribution of seats under the List PR

race.

The election law required parties to keep ‘in mind’ the principle of inclusiveness in

nominating candidates for the FPTP elections. In composing the lists for the List PR race,

parties were required to “ensure the proportional representation of women, Dalits, oppressed

communities/indigenous groups, backward regions, Madhesis and other groups” (Article 7,

3). Schedule 1 of the Election Law broke this down into specific percentages for Madhesi,

Dalit, Janajatis, backward regions and ‘others’. The distribution between the genders was also

specified in that a minimum of one-third of each party’s candidates for both races had to be

women.

In the List PR race, the party leaders filled the seats won by the party after the elections from

lists defined and published before the election. The party leaders did not have to follow a

ranked sequence of the lists in doing so, but they had to meet the same quota rules as for the

candidate lists. As one of three selected case studies, Nepal is described in more detail in

Chapter 5.

3.2.5 New Zealand

New Zealand is a constitutional monarchy with a parliamentary political system. The

legislative body is unicameral and has 120 members directly elected by the Mixed Member

Proportional system. Each voter can vote for two candidates; one from single-member

constituency lists, and one from nationwide party lists. The number of constituencies is from

time to time adjusted based on census data (Electoral Art, 35). In the 2008 elections, 63

members were elected by FPTP in general electoral districts and 50 members by List PR from

nation-wide party lists. List seats are distributed to parties winning more than the five percent

threshold. If parties win more electorate seats than their share of seats determined by the party

vote, then they can keep the extra seats, called ‘overhang seats’ (Election Law, Article 192).

There are a number of Maori electoral districts to be set from time to time (Electoral Law,

Article 45). These are filled by FPTP in a separate race. Maori voters may choose whether

they want to be registered either as an elector of a Maori electoral district or as an elector of a

General electoral district (Electoral Law, Article 76-79). As of December 2010, there were

seven members elected from Maori constituencies. Maoris may also run in general

constituencies and on party lists in the List PR race.

3.2.6 Pakistan

Pakistan is a federation consisting of four provinces (Baluchistan, Khyber Pakhtunkhwa,

Punjab, and Sindh), a federal capital district and two federally administered areas (the

Northern Area and Tribal Areas). Formally, the political system of Pakistan has been

parliamentary. In 1999, when General Pervez Musharraf took over the country in a bloodless

coup, he declared himself president and suspended parliament and the constitution. In 2002,

the constitution was restored but at the same time a Legal Framework Order with later

Page 49: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

47

amendments was issued by a Chief Executive Order in 2002 and the Constitution was

amended so as to provide for a stronger presidential system (Seventeenth Amendment of

2003). Elections held in the same year resulted in a hybrid military-civilian order, in which

Musharraf simultaneously served as President and Chief of Army Staff. The Seventeenth

Amendment to the Constitution therefore enabled the President to dismiss the National

Assembly.

In 2010, the Eighteenth Constitutional Amendment repealed the Seventeenth Amendment and

the Legal Framework Order and returned powers to the Prime Minister.

The president appoints the prime minister, but the candidate must have support in parliament

(Constitution, Article 91). Individual ministers are not approved by parliament (Constitution,

Article 91). The president is elected by an electoral college constituted by the legislature and

provincial assemblies (Constitution, Article 41).

The Parliament is bicameral, consisting of the National Assembly and the Senate. Bills may

originate in either House and must be passed by both houses without amendment. If a bill is

rejected or is not passed within 90 days of receipt, the House of origin requests that the bill be

referred to a mediation committee for redrafting (Constitution, Article 71). Money bills shall,

however, originate in the National Assembly. The Senate may make recommendations, which

the National Assembly may or may not incorporate upon presentation to the president for

assent (Constitution, Article 73). The president may request amendments, which the

parliament may or may not incorporate. A presidential veto can be overridden by a majority in

both houses (Constitution, Article 75).

There are 342 representatives in the National Assembly. Of these, 272 are so-called ‘general

seats’ filled with representatives elected by FPTP in single-member constituencies. The 70

remaining seats are reserved for non-Moslems and women (Constitution, Article 51), which

are allocated based upon the distribution of seats among the parties after the general FPTP

part of the election (see below). Members of the upper house are indirectly elected by federal

assemblies and from the federally administered territories “in such a manner as the President

may, by Order, prescribe” (Constitution, Article 59).

There are ten seats reserved for non-Muslims and sixty for women in the National Assembly.

There is no separate vote to fill these seats but the allocation is to party lists in accordance

with their strength in parliament after the FPTP election. The ten non-Muslims are elected

from lists regarding the country as one constituency according to List PR (Constitution

Article 51.e). Women are elected from lists defined in separate constituencies in each region:

“...each Province shall be a single constituency for all seats reserved for women who are

allocated to the respective Provinces ...” (Constitution, Article 51.b). Women and non-

Muslims may also run for general seats on the basis of party nomination.64

The distribution of

reserved seats is based “on the total number of general seats won by each political party in the

National Assembly”. Candidates are elected from lists of candidates in prioritized order

64

Mudassir Rivzi, "Women win record seats, but not activists' hearts, "Inter Press Service,

http://ipsnews.net/interna.asp?idnews=12918 <accessed 5 May 2010>.

Page 50: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

48

presented by the political parties prior to the elections (Conduct of General Elections Order,

2002, Chief Executive's Order No.7 of 2002, 4.e., f.; 8F1). Consequently, the distance

between the voters and the elected representative provides for weak accountability.

Only parties achieving at least 5 percent of the general seats may benefit from the reserved

seats (The Conduct of General Elections Order, 2002, Chief Executive's Order No.7 of 2002,

4.g) and no independents can run for such seats.

The Senate consists of 100 members. Of these, fourteen are directly elected from each

provincial assembly. Eight are directly elected from the Federally Administered Tribal areas.

In addition, four women and four technocrats and clerics are elected by each of the Provincial

assemblies respectively (Conduct of General Elections Order, 2002, Article 8b.1). Seats are

allocated by the single transferable vote (Conduct of General Elections Order, 2002, Article

8b.2)

3.2.7 Samoa

Samoa is a unitary republic with a parliamentary political system. The legislative assembly is

unicameral. On advice from the prime minister, the head of state may refuse to give his ascent

to a draft bill, in which it will not become law (Constitution, Article 60). The assembly

consists of 49 members.

35 members are elected by FPTP in single-member constituencies, whereas 14 are elected by

block vote in two-member constituencies.

47 seats are reserved for ethnic Samoans elected from so-called Territorial Constituencies.

Two are elected from the Individual Voter’s Roll, which is open to citizens of foreign and

mixed descent. The Individual Voters roll was formerly reserved for Europeans, but now

includes all citizens of foreign and mixed descent, as well as their spouses.

The right to stand for election is restricted in both the constituencies and the Individual Voters

Roll. Only traditional heads of families (holders of so-called matai titles) can stand for

elections in the territorial constituencies65

. Only those registered in the Individual Voters roll

are eligible as candidates to represent individual voters (Electoral Act, Article 5).

3.2.8 Philippines

The Congress (‘Kongreso’) of the Philippines was established in 1946 upon independence

from the United States. In 1972, President Ferdinand Marcos suspended parliament and

declared martial law. A new constitution in the following year formalized Marcos’s absolute

authority. Marcos relinquished power in 1986 amid demonstrations sparked by allegations of

massive fraud in a presidential election. He subsequently fled the country, and in 1987, the

Philippines adopted its current constitution.

65

A matai title can only be bestowed on someone chosen by the family as their matai. The 2006 official census

of Samoa identified a total of 15,783 matai (8.7 percent) living in the country from a total population of 180,741.

Of the total number of matai, 12,589 (79.8 percent) were male and 3,194 (20.2 percent) were female.

Page 51: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

49

There are two major conflicts in the Philippines: that of the communist guerrillas against the

government, and that of Muslim separatism in Mindanao. From 1993 to 1990, the Philippine

government encouraged a large number of Christians to settle in Mindanao. The proportion of

Muslims in Mindanao subsequently decreased from 77 percent to 19 percent, numbers which

are reflected also in land ownership. Increased political, economic and social polarisation has

adversely affected the Muslim population, leading to widespread dissatisfaction and an

upsurge of armed separatist groups. In an attempt to defuse tensions in Mindanao, an

Autonomous Region in Muslim Mindanao (ARMM) has been established. The establishment

of ARMM, however, has been insufficient to solve the grievances of the Muslim minority. A

further contribution would be an electoral reform in the Philippines as a whole, which would

also address the conflict with the communists.66

The Philippines is a unitary republic with a presidential system. The 1987 Constitution

(Article VI) defines a bicameral legislature with an upper house, the Senate (Senado), and a

lower house, the House of Representatives (Kapulangan Ng Mga Kinatawan). Laws must be

passed by both chambers. However, appropriation, revenue or tariff bills, bills authorizing

increase of the public debt, bills of local application and private bills, may not originate in the

Senate. The president has a delay veto. A bill passed by the houses is presented to the

president, who may return it with amendments to the house where it originated. It takes a two-

thirds majority in both houses to override the presidential veto. In addition, the president has a

line-item veto on appropriations, revenue or tariff bills.

The House of Representatives has up to 250 members unless the number is increased by

law67

, where up to 200 are elected in a first-past-the-post system in single-member

constituencies from the different provinces, cities and the Metropolitan Manila (Constitution

Article VI, 5).68

There are seventeen regions. These consist of provinces following

administrative units. Each of the units has from one to seven seats. Those with more than one

seat are further sub-divided into single-member constituencies. In addition, twenty percent of

the total number is supposed to be elected from nation-wide party lists under a proportional

system, where only the less prominent parties may participate. Each voter has two ballots:

One for the regular constituency election and one for the party list. The top five parties of a

previous election cannot propose lists. The idea is to offer seats to minority groups, which

have difficulties in winning seats under a first-past-the-post system.69

A particular list needs

at least two percent of the votes to get a mandate, and it can only win up to three mandates.

66

For an assessment of ARMM and political participation inside ARMM, see Blanc, Hylland and Vollan 2006:

92-94. 67

The House elected in 2010 has 283 members. 68

69 An Act Providing for the Election of Party-List representatives through the Party-List System, and

Appropriating Funds Therefor. Republic Act No.7941. March 3 1995 states: ”Declaration of Policy – The State

shall promote proportional representation in the election of representatives to the House of Representatives

through a party-list system of registered national, regional and sector parties or organizations or coalitions

thereof, which will enable Filipino citizens belonging to the marginalized and underrepresented sectors,

organizations and parties, and who lack well-defined political constituencies but who could contribute to the

formulation and enactment of appropriate legislation that will benefit the nation as a whole, to become members

Page 52: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

50

When the system was first used, it was not possible by this rule to fill all the seats dedicated

for the groups, but the rule was later changed so that one allocates one seat to each of the

largest party lists with less than two percent until the twenty percent quota is filled.70

In the Senate, there are 24 senators serving in staggered terms, so that twelve are elected at

one Election Day, and the other twelve are elected three years later. The electoral system [for

the Senate] is first-past-the-post, with the whole country as one constituency. The voters vote

for individual candidates and can cast more than one vote (probably up to twelve). The twelve

candidates with the highest number of votes are elected. The system is often referred to as the

block vote system.

3.2.9 Singapore

Singapore is a unitary republic with a semi-presidential system. The president may not veto

legislation passed by parliament (Constitution, Article 58). The legislature may, however, not

introduce legislation related to taxation, government expenditures, government debt, and

other financial issues (Constitution, Article 59). Legislation is subject to judicial review

(Constitution, Article 4; 100).

The electoral system combines FPTP in single-member constituencies and party block vote

multi-member constituencies with reserved group representation (Constitution, Article

39A.1a). There are not a fixed number of seats in the parliament but there needs to be at least

eight single-member constituencies and at least one-quarter are to be elected from multi-

member constituencies with a magnitude from three to six. Constituencies are drawn by the

president and may be changed from time to time. There are, however, at least eight single-

member constituencies at any time. The group representation constituencies are reserved for

the Malay, Indian or other minority groups, who are to constitute at least a quarter of the

members in the principal chamber (Parliamentary Elections Act, Article 8A.2). In a group

representation constituency, elections are “held on a basis of a group of not less than 3 but not

more than 6 candidates” (Constitution Article 39A.1a). Article 39A.2a further stipulates that:

[… ] at least one of the candidates in every group shall be a person belonging to the Malay

community; or

[…] at least one of the candidates in every group shall be a person belonging to the Indian or other

minority communities;

Article 8A.3 states that Group constituencies designated under subsection b (i) are to

constitute three-fifths of the total number of group representation constituencies. Article

of the House of Representatives. Towards this end, the State shall develop and guarantee a full, free and open

party system in order to attain the broadest possible representation of party, sector or group interests in the

House of Representatives by enhancing their chances to compete for and win seats in the legislature, and shall

provide the simplest scheme possible.” The ‘sectors’ are defined as: “sectors shall include labour, peasant, fisher

folk, urban poor, indigenous cultural communities, elderly, handicapped, women, youth, veterans, overseas

workers, and professionals.”

70 See results of the 2010 elections at the election commission’s (COMELEC) web site,

http://www.comelec.gov.ph.

Page 53: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

51

9A.2c states that each group must consist of members from the same political party or a

cluster of independent candidates standing as a group.

In the 2006 election, nine members were elected from single-member constituencies, and

seventy were elected from fourteen multi-member constituencies. The ruling party (PAP)

won all multi-member constituencies plus seven single-member constituencies and two

opposition parties won one of the single-member constituencies each (SDP and WP). In

contested multi-member constituencies PAP got from 56 to 77 percent of the votes (and 100

percent of the seats).

In addition to constituency members, as many as six members can be appointed by the

legislature in order to “to ensure the representation in Parliament of a minimum number of

Members from a political party or parties not forming the Government”. Furthermore, the

president may appoint as many as nine members. These appointees are to be

… persons who have rendered distinguished public service, or who have brought honour to the

Republic, or who have distinguished themselves in the field of arts and letters, culture, the sciences,

business, industry, the professions, social or community service or the labour movement; and in

making any nomination, the Special Select Committee shall have regard to the need for nominated

Members to reflect as wide a range of independent and non-partisan views as possible (Constitution,

Article 39.b; Fourth Schedule). 71

3.2.10 Main Findings

Afghanistan, India, Nepal, Philippines and Pakistan have quotas for social groups. Fiji, India,

Kiribati, Nepal, New Zealand, Samoa and Singapore have ethnic quotas. Pakistan has a quota

reserved for religious minorities. Only in Fiji one may say that the quotas are intending to

directly represent groups in conflict. However, in Nepal the quotas are meant to address the

underlying social and ethnic problems that caused the armed conflicts of the 1990s and 2000s.

In other countries, the quotas have been introduced based upon a view of ‘fairness’ but clearly

they may also contribute to lower group-based conflicts.

Some of the quota rules intended to provide minority representation represents arrangements

where one has made an effort to repair a FPTP system that does not automatically give the

desired diversity. In particular, in Pakistan and in the Philippines, the minority representation

comes as add-ons to the general system which introduces side effects that could have been

avoided by a more fundamental overhaul of the system.

In Pakistan72

, religious minorities are elected on lists of the main-stream parties in accordance

with their parliamentary representation. For example, the Hindu candidates are elected from

the Muslim League party based upon the general political contest where the voters primarily

select the parties’ candidates in single-member constituencies. The accountability is therefore

very weak and the distance from the voters to those elected representing minorities is

unnecessarily large.

71

Non-Constituency members have restricted voting rights, see Constitution Article 39.2. 72

A similar system is now introduced for group representation in Kenya.

Page 54: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

52

In the Philippines, one needs to define parties representing the selected sectors and which

have not done well in previous elections. Exclusion of the biggest parties from contesting in

the proportional part of the election is extraordinary and can give very random results. The

link to previous elections means that the result does not necessarily reflect the voters' will on

Election Day and the system is unnecessarily intricate.

Both in Pakistan and in the Philippines, the purpose seems to have been to compensate for the

defects of the plural system, which favour the big parties and groups, by repairing it in such a

way that new unreasonable features are introduced. In both countries, a mixed system

combining first-past-the-post (FPTP) in single-member constituencies with list proportional

(List PR) systems could have been used and the voters would have direct influence on who is

elected and even small parties would be represented without introducing a ’small party race’.

If there would be an additional need to protect some groups, quota systems for ethnic or

religious minorities could be considered.

The system in Singapore is part of a party block vote system, which will inevitably give the

biggest party of a multi-member constituency all seats of that constituency and, most likely,

all seats contested under that system. In general, party block vote systems should be avoided

in multi-party national elections.

3.3 Central Eastern Europe

3.3.1 Introduction

Parliamentary quotas based on ethnicity or languages are found in all the former Yugoslav

republics, except Macedonia.73

Minority quotas in Poland and Romania are not related to violent conflicts, but to the

presence of linguistic minorities within their territorial borders.

73

The 2002 Ohrid Agreement, which contains a broad range of measures to ensure minority rights, but does not

include guaranteed minority representation in parliament.

Page 55: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

53

Table of systems Central Eastern Europe

Country Electoral System Basis of

Quota Type of quota

Democracy

Index

BOSNIA AND

HERZEGOVINA

Parliamentary assembly

(Parlamentarna

Skupština)

House of

Representatives

(Predstavnički Dom )

List PR with

compensation

Gender

Nomination percentage and

rank order

Partly free

House of Peoples

(Dom Narodna)

Indirect List PR

Ethnicity Earmarked seats

CROATIA

Croatian parliament

(Hrvatski Sabor)

List PR

Ethnicity

Earmarked seats, separate

race, separate voters

registers

Free

KOSOVO

Kosovo Assembly

(Kuvendi i Kosovës)

List PR

Ethnicity Reserved seats

Separate race

Partly free

Gender

Nomination percentage and

rank order

Requirements to result

BRU to fill quota

MONTENEGRO List PR Ethnicity Reserved constituency Free

POLAND

Parliament

(Parlament)

Principal chamber

(Sejm)

List PR

Ethnicity and

language Threshold exemption

Free Senate

(Senat)

Block Vote

No quota No quota

ROMANIA

Parliament

(Parlamentul)

Chamber of Deputies

(Camera Deputatilor)

List PR

Ethnicity and

language

Earmarked seats, best

runner-up

Free Senate

(Senat)

List PR

No quota No quota

SERBIA

National Assembly

(Narodna skupshtina)

List PR

Ethnicity Lower threshold for

minority parties

Free

Gender

Requirements to

nomination percentage and

rank order

SLOVENIA

Parliament

(Parlament)

National Assembly

(Državni zbor)

List PR

Ethnicity Separate race

earmarked constituencies

Free National Council

(Državni svet)

Indirect elections by

electoral colleges

Interest groups Reserved seats

Page 56: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

54

3.3.2 Bosnia and Herzegovina

Bosnia and Herzegovina is a federation consisting of a Croat-Bosniac entity, the Federation of

Bosnia and Herzegovina, covering 51 percent of the territory of the federal state, and the

Serb-led entity Republika Srpska, covering 49 percent.

The legislative framework for elections in Bosnia and Herzegovina is constituted by the 2001

Election Law, and Annex 4 of the Dayton Agreement, which is Bosnia and Herzegovina’s

constitution. The parliament is bicameral and consists of the House of Representatives and the

House of Peoples.

The form of government is a hybrid with a presidency of three directly-elected members with

rotating chairs and a Council of Ministers led by a prime minister who needs the confidence

of the House of Representatives.

There are 42 members of the House of Representatives. Of these, one-third is elected from

Republika Srpska, and two-thirds from the Federation of Bosnia and Herzegovina. The

electoral system is List PR in multi-member constituencies with entity-wide compensation.

House of Peoples consists of 15 members: five Bosniacs, five Croats and five Serbs. They are

elected by List PR. Individuals who do not belong to any of the three groups cannot run for

the House of Peoples. In addition, the Bosniacs and Croats are elected by the Federation of

Bosnia and Herzegovina and Serbs by the Republika Srpska, so Serbs living in the Federation

cannot be elected and similarly for Bosniacs and Croats living in Republika Srpska.

The Presidency consists of one Serb, one Croat and one Bosniac and the restrictions to run as

a member is as for the House of Peoples.

Voting in the House of Representatives is based on equal votes of all citizens, whereas the

House of Peoples are elected by a house of the entity parliaments. Legislation needs to be

approved by a majority of those present and voting in both chambers as the main rule. There

is, however, both a rule for double majority (entity voting), a Vital National Interest Clause

that can be invoked to block any legislation which is perceived as detrimental to any of the

three groups.

The Dayton Agreement also defines the role of the International High Representative with

wide authorities that were further expanded during the first years in office (the Bonn Powers).

A thorough discussion of the representation and the power-sharing arrangements in Bosnia

and Herzegovina is found in the case study in Chapter 6.

3.3.3 Croatia

Croatia is a unitary republic with a hybrid system of government with a directly-elected

president with limited powers and most of the executive powers vested in the government

headed by a prime minister The Croatian Parliament is unicameral and consists of no less than

100, and no more than 160 members (Constitution, Article 71). These are elected through List

PR with closed lists. There are 10 constituencies, each electing 14 members. In addition, there

are two separate constituencies for recognized minorities and diaspora voters, respectively.

Page 57: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

55

The number of diaspora representatives can be a maximum of twelve, depending on the

turnout.

Article 15 of the Constitution and Articles 15-16 of the Election Law provides for the right of

national minorities to be represented in parliament by a total of eight members. What

constitutes a national minority is defined in the Minorities Act Article 5 as “a group of

Croatian citizens whose members traditionally inhabit the territory of the Republic of Croatia,

its members having ethnic, linguistic, cultural and/or religious characteristics different from

other citizens and are led by the wish to preserve these characteristics”.

Article 19 of the National Minorities Act further states that the members of national

minorities may elect no less than five and no more than eight of their representatives in

special constituencies. Members of national minorities that “in the total amount of population

of the Republic of Croatia participate with more than 1.5 percent, one seat is guaranteed”,

with a maximum of three seats for this particular minority.

Article 16 of the Election Law stipulates how these seats are to be distributed among the

various minorities.74

The eight minority members are elected through FPTP from eight lists in

a “special constituency being the territory of the Republic of Croatia” (Election Law, Article

15). National minority voters can choose to be registered in the separate voters rolls and thus

vote in the special constituencies or they may stay in the general register and vote in the

general race.75

3.3.4 Kosovo

Kosovo is a unitary republic with a hybrid system of government emerging from a civil war

and war on secession. The President has limited powers and is indirectly elected, whereas the

executive powers rest mainly with the government led by a prime minister who needs to have

the confidence of the parliament. The parliament is unicameral. Members of the Assembly are

elected through List PR in one constituency covering the entirety of Kosovo (Election Law,

Article 110.1). The national threshold is five percent (Election Law, Article 112.2 (a, b)).

Political Party, Coalition, Citizens’ Initiative or Independent candidate may submit candidate

lists (Election Law, Article 110.2). These appear on an ‘open list’ ballot.

Voters shall vote for one (1) certified Entity and may vote for one (1) candidate from the said Political

Entity’s candidate list […] A vote cast for a Political Entity shall be considered as a vote cast for the

candidate ranking first on the Political Entity’s candidate list.

Twenty out of the 120 seats in parliament are reserved for minority communities and are

distributed to lists that have a minority label. The ten Serb seats are, for example, distributed

to the Serb parties only, irrespective of whether the same parties have won some of the 100

seats. Voters cast only one ballot, but the results are calculated for each race: the general one,

the Serb one, etc.

74

“Members of national minorities from the Article 16 of this Act shall elect representatives to the Parliament by

individual elections, in the manner that the candidate is elected who has won the most votes of the voters who

have cast their votes” (Election Law, Article 43). 75

OSCE/ODIHR and the Venice Commission 2007.

Page 58: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

56

There is also a gender quota, (Election Law, Article 27) whereby parties are required to set up

lists where:

at least thirty (30 %) percent shall be male and at least thirty (30 %) percent shall be female, with

one candidate from each gender included at least once in each group of three candidates, counting

from the first candidate in the list..

3.3.5 Montenegro

Montenegro is a unitary republic with a directly-elected president with limited powers and

otherwise mainly with a parliamentary system of government. Parliament consists of 81

members (Constitution, Article 83). These are elected through List PR with open lists from

the whole republic as a single constituency. The electoral threshold is 3 percent (Election

Law, Article 12; 93-96).

Five of the 81 deputies are chosen from designated polling stations defined by the special

resolution passed by the Assembly (Election Law, Article 12.2). These 70 polling stations are

located in areas populated primarily by ethnic Albanians. Election lists can receive seat

allocations in both the general race and in the special race, providing that the electoral

threshold of 3 percent is passed. If a list does not reach the threshold in either race, the votes

from one race are re-allocated to the other.76

It is up to each individual to register in these

polling stations, where all parties can compete for elections – not only Albanians. In this

special race, Albanian coalitions have been able to win seats that they would otherwise not

have won.77

Laws that regulate how acquired minority rights are exercised, require a two-thirds majority

(Constitution, Article 91).

3.3.6 Poland

Poland is a unitary republic with a directly-elected president with limited powers and

otherwise has a parliamentary system. The legislature is bicameral, consisting of the principal

chamber (Sejm) and the Senate (Senat). The Sejm consists of 460 members elected by list PR

with open lists in 41 constituencies. The 100 senators are elected by block vote in 40

constituencies.78

The national threshold for the Sejm is five percent for parties and eight

percent for coalitions. Parties representing national minorities are exempt from this

requirement (Election Law, Articles 133-134). Article 2.2 of the Law on National and Ethnic

Minorities and Regional Languages of 8 January 2005, identifies nine national minorities in

Poland: Armenian, Belarusian, Czech, German, Jewish, Lithuanian, Russian, Slovak and

Ukrainian. However, in the 2007 elections, only the German minority in the Opole

constituency in Silesia took advantage of this option.79

The German minority party Deutsche

Minderheit, established in 1990, gained seven seats in the 1991 elections and four in the 1993

elections. Support for the party has, however, steadily declined, and in 2005, the party

managed to secure only one seat.

76

OSCE/ODIHR 2009a: 4. 77

Blanc, Hylland and Vollan 2006: 75-76. 78

For elections to the Senate, Kraków and Chrzanów form a single constituency. 79

OSCE/ODIHR 2008: 18.

Page 59: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

57

3.3.7 Romania

Romania is a unitary republic with a hybrid system of government. The President is directly

elected and the government needs the confidence of the parliament. The President’s power is

limited but there are frequent conflicts about how the division of powers between the

President and the Council of Ministers. The legislature is bicameral, consisting of a Chamber

of Deputies (Camera Deputatilor) and a Senate (Senat). Both senators and deputies are

elected by List PR with nation-wide compensation. The number of members of each chamber

varies with the population and the number of representatives granted as per the special

arrangements for minority representation. After the 2008 election, the Senate had 137

members, and the Chamber of Deputies had 334 members.

For both chambers, there are 42 multi-member constituencies corresponding to administrative

units plus one that is designated for Romanians living abroad, in total, 4380

. Each multi-

member constituency is further divided into ‘uninominal colleges’, which are kinds of single-

member constituencies where candidates are running, but the representation depends on the

proportional representation of seats not directly related the results of the election in the

uninominal college81

. The number of such uninominal colleges corresponds to the number of

seats of the multi-member constituency, provided that there is at least four for the Chamber of

Deputies and two for the Senate in each multi-member constituency.

In order to win seats, there is a nationwide threshold of five percent for both chambers. For

alliances, the threshold is increased with three percent for the second party and one percent

for subsequent parties, up to a maximum of ten percent. For the Chamber of Deputies, the

threshold may also be met if the list party or alliance’s candidate comes out first in at least six

uninominal colleges and for the Senate three.

Candidates are nominated by parties and alliances in the uninominal colleges, restricted to one

per electoral competitor. The voters vote for one of these candidates. Candidates who win

more than fifty percent of the votes in a uninominal college and belong to a competitor having

passed the threshold are elected. After this, the votes per electoral competitor are added up to

national level and it is determined how many seats each competitor is entitled to per multi-

member constituency. The seats already won in the uninominal colleges are deducted from

the result and the rest of the seats are given to unelected candidates in uninominal colleges

where the seat is not filled according to the candidates’ relative strength.

The system will produce a close to proportional result nationwide and it will secure

geographical representation, but the candidate with the highest number of votes in a

uninominal college is not necessarily elected.

There are special arrangements for the representation of national minorities, defined as groups

represented in the Council of National Minorities (approximately twenty). The rules are

80

Election law (Law No 35) last changed on 13 March 2008. 81

With the exception mentioned below.

Page 60: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

58

aimed at guaranteeing representation to the smaller minorities such as Roma, Bulgarians,

Ukrainians, etc., whereas the largest minority, the Hungarians, is represented without any

affirmative action.

The Constitution Article 62 paragraph 2 states that “Organizations of citizens belonging to

national minorities, which fail to obtain the number of votes for representation in Parliament,

have the right to one Deputy seat each, under the terms of the electoral law. Citizens of a

national minority are entitled to be represented by one organization only”.

The electoral law specifies (Articles 9 (1) and 47 (4)) that a minority group not winning a seat

in Parliament (any house) by the ordinary election will get one deputy, provided that the

organisation has won in the whole country, at least ten percent of the average number of

validly cast votes for a Deputy. In the last elections, eighteen minority parties have won one

seat each under this provision.

3.3.8 Serbia

Serbia is a unitary republic with a parliamentary political system. The President is mainly a

ceremonial head of state. The Parliament is unicameral and has 250 members. These are

elected from the whole territory as one constituency through a closed List PR system

(Election Law, Article 4) with an electoral threshold of five percent (Election Law, Article

81).

Parties “whose basic aim is to represent and stand for the interests of an ethnic minority...

shall be considered political parties”, according to Article 81 of the Election law. Once an

electoral list is proclaimed, the Republic Electoral Commission decides whether the submitter

of the electoral list should be considered an ethnic minority party or coalition. These parties

are exempt from the electoral threshold.

There is also a gender quota enshrined in Article 40a of the Electoral law, imposing a

nomination percentage and rank order to electoral lists:

For every four candidates on the electoral list (first group of four places, second group of four places

and so on until the end of the list) there shall be one candidate of the gender less represented on the

list, and the number of candidates of the gender less represented on the list shall be at least 30 percent

of the total number.

3.3.9 Slovenia

Slovenia is a unitary republic with a parliamentary political system. The President is mainly a

ceremonial head of state. The Slovenian parliament is bicameral and consists of a National

Assembly and a National Council. The National Assembly of Slovenia consists of ninety

deputies. Of these, eighty-eight are elected from eight eleven-member constituencies

(Election Law, Article 20). These are elected by List PR from open lists with an electoral

threshold of four percent (Constitution, Article 80). The 40 members of the National Council

are indirectly elected by interest groups.

One deputy of the Italian and one deputy of the Hungarian national communities shall always

be elected to the National Assembly (Constitution, Article 80). Only members of the Italian

Page 61: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

59

and Hungarian national communities shall have the right to vote for and be elected as deputies

of these national communities (Election Law, Article 8). Special constituencies are to be

formed “in those areas in which these communities reside”. The two candidates are elected by

de Borda Count. Each voter gives a number from one up to the number of candidates to the

candidates, in order of their preference. The Election Law Article 94 describes the counting:

Points shall be assigned to candidates according to orders of preference. For each first place the

candidate shall receive as many points as there were candidates on the ballot paper, and for each

successive place a point less. The points of each candidate shall be totalled.

The 40 members of the National Council are indirectly elected and represent “social,

economic, professional and local interests”:

It is composed of: four representatives of employers; four representatives of employees; four

representatives of farmers, crafts and trades, and independent professions; six representatives of non-

commercial fields; twenty-two representatives of local interests (Constitution, Article 96).

3.3.10 Main Findings

Only in Bosnia and Herzegovina and in Kosovo are the quotas the main elements of a power-

sharing agreement between groups who had been in conflict. In Bosnia and Herzegovina,

they are accompanied by a set of decision-making rules that make up the power-sharing and

their effects are discussed in detail in the in-depth study.

The other quota arrangements in this area are mainly introduced in order to accommodate

small groups that would otherwise not be represented and the technical implementation is

well-integrated into the general system.

3.4 Middle East and North Africa

3.4.1 Introduction

Lebanon is the only country in the region that has introduced quotas as part of a power-

sharing agreement after conflict. The other countries in this region have quotas in order to

increase diversity but not necessarily to prevent conflict.

Page 62: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

60

Table of systems Middle East and North Africa

Country Electoral System

Basis of Quota Type of quota Democracy

Index

EGYPT

Parliament

(Majilis al-Sha’ab)

People’s Assembly

(Majilis al-Sha’ab)

Direct, two-member

majoritarian (TRS) +

presidential

appointment

Social group

Requirements to

result

Best runner-up

Not free

Gender

Earmarked seats

Separate race in

earmarked

constituencies

Advisory Council

(Majilis al-Shura)

Direct, single-

member majoritarian

(TRS) + presidential

appointment

Social group

Requirements to

result

Best runner-up

JORDAN

National Assembly

Chamber of

Deputies

(Majlis al-Nuwaab)

SNTV in multi-

member

constituencies

Religion

Earmarked seats

Earmarked sub

districts

Not free (partly

free in 2009) Gender Best runner-up

House of Notables

(Majlis al-Aayan)

Appointed by the

King

No quota

LEBANON

National Assembly

(Majlis al-Nuwaab)

Block vote in multi-

member

constituencies

Religion

All seats are

earmarked in multi-

member

constituencies

Partly free

PALESTINIAN

AUTHORITY

Palestinian

Legislative Council

Parallel (List PR /

Block vote)

Religion

Requirement to the

result, best runner-

up

Not ranked

SYRIA

People’s Assembly

Block vote

Social Group

(workers and farmers) Not free

3.4.2 Jordan

Jordan is a unitary, hereditary monarchy. The King appoints the Prime Minister and cabinet

ministers. Parliamentary approval is not required (Constitution, Article 35). The Chamber of

Deputies can vote no-confidence in the government (Constitution, Articles 53-54), whereas

the King can dissolve both houses of the legislature and remove individual senators

(Constitution, Articles 34 and 74).

The National Assembly is bicameral. There are 120 seats (after the 2010 reform) in the Lower

House of Parliament or the House of Deputies (Majlis al-Nuwaab), elected by SNTV. The

Senate, the House of Notables (Majlis al-Aayan), has 60 seats, all appointed wholly by the

King. Laws are drafted upon request from the relevant house committee (Constitution, Article

Page 63: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

61

95). A two-thirds majority in both houses is required to pass laws. If either house rejects the

bill, “it shall not be placed again before the House during the same session” (Constitution,

Article 92). Once a draft law is passed, it is submitted to the King for ratification. The King

may choose to refer it back to the house within six months, in which case, a two-thirds

majority in both chambers is required to override a royal veto (Constitution, Article 93).

The Jordanian Parliament was suspended in November 2009, after its members had served

only half of their terms. At the same time, the King ordered that a new election law be

drafted. This was to be part of a broader reform effort. The new election law that was

promulgated in May 2010 retained both a variant of the SNTV system and the quotas for

women and religious minorities from the previous laws, but with some important changes.

The law responded to some key reformist demands, by adding four seats to cities with large

Palestinian populations who have been continuously underrepresented in Parliament.

According to the new election law, the country is divided into 45 multi-member

constituencies out of which three are reserved for Bedouins, which are further subdivided into

so-called virtual 108 single-seat sub-districts. The sub-districts are partly geographical and

partly reserved for Christians (nine), Circassians (three) and Bedouins (nine). Candidates run

in the 108 sub-districts but voters may cast one vote for any candidate of any virtual sub-

district in the constituency. The candidate with the highest number votes per sub-district is

elected. The extra female quota was doubled from six to twelve. The female candidates, not

already elected, with the highest proportion of the votes in their sub-district nationwide are

elected, provided that there is not more than one woman elected of the female quota from any

of the twelve governorates or three Bedouin constituencies.

The most important demand was not met, however, and that was to replace SNTV with a

more proportional system. However, the King called for political and electoral reform in early

2011 to encourage increased participation in the political process. A National Dialogue

Committee was formed by the King in early 2011 to make reform recommendations to the

Government. This national debate regarding political and electoral reform is ongoing as of

August 2011.

3.4.3 Lebanon

Lebanon is a unitary republic with a hybrid form of government. The executive powers are

shared between an indirectly-elected president and a prime minister and they form a cabinet

together. The legislative is unicameral. Laws are passed by regular (not qualified) majority. A

presidential veto may be overridden by a majority vote (Constitution, Article 57).

The legislature is unicameral. 128 representatives are directly elected by the block vote

system from 27 constituencies. The total number of seats is equally distributed between

Christian and Moslem candidates. The Christian seats are further distributed with a fixed

number to Maronite, Greek Catholic, Greek Orthodox, Evangelical, Armenian Catholic,

Armenian Orthodox and Christian Minorities; whereas the Muslim seats are distributed to

Sunni, Shi’a, Druze and Alawi. Every seat is earmarked for a confessional group in every

constituency. The candidates who win the highest number of votes for each religious

community running in a constituency are elected. As one of three selected case studies,

Page 64: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

62

Lebanon is only summarily described here. See Chapter 4 for a more thorough presentation of

the Lebanese election law and the background to it.

3.4.4 The Palestinian Territory

The Palestinian Territory consists of the West Bank and the Gaza Strip. The political system

is stipulated in the Palestinian Basic Law. While a new Election Law was issued by

presidential decree in 2008, the following is based on the Election Law that was adopted by

the Palestinian Legislative Council (PLC) in 2005.

The Palestinian Territory does not constitute a state, but is a partly self-ruled Palestinian

Authority under Israeli occupation. The current status of the political institutions and separate

geographical entities are defined in the so-called Oslo Agreements of 1993 and 1995 and

subsequent agreements. The political system is a hybrid system with a strong president but

with a government that needs the confidence of the PLC. The PLC is unicameral. The

legislature can override a presidential veto with a two-thirds majority (Basic Law, Article 41).

Laws can be subject to constitutional review by the High Court until a Constitutional Court

has been established (Basic Law, Article 103).

The PLC has 132 members elected according to a parallel system. Half of the members are

elected under the block vote system in sixteen constituencies. The other half is elected by List

PR from one territory-wide constituency (Election Law, Article 3). Each constituency gets a

number of seats according to the size of its population, but with a minimum of one from each.

Voters get two ballots – one for the constituency elections, and one for the territory-wide

elections. The two elections are independent of each other in the sense that the distribution of

seats in the proportional election is not dependent on the distribution in the constituencies.

Parties can nominate as many candidates as there are seats in the constituency. The voter can

vote for up to as many candidates on the list as there are seats in the constituency. She or he

may choose candidates across affiliations. The candidates with the highest number of votes

are elected. 82

In a few constituencies, there is a quota for Christians, six seats in total. These are distributed

to the constituencies according to a presidential decree (Article 3.a). In addition, there is a

quota for women applied to the List PR race. Every list must fulfil the following criteria to be

accepted: Among the first three candidates at least one has to be a woman, among the first

seven there must to be two, among the first twelve there must three and then one more for

each step of five (Election Law, Article 4).

In 2007, a new Election Law introducing a fully proportional system was introduced by

presidential decree.83

Due to the political impasse between Fatah and Hamas, the new

Election Law has not been ratified by the Legislative Council.

82

For a thorough introduction of the Palestinian Electoral system, see Butenschøn and Vollan 2006. 83

See information about the presidential decree at the website of the Palestinian General Elections Commission,

http://www.elections.ps:90/template.aspx?id=143&sndx=2 <accessed 12 April 2011>.

Page 65: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

63

3.4.5 Main Findings

The quota systems applied in this area are mainly designed to favour religious minorities who

have existed in the region for centuries, except for the cases of the peasant and worker quotas

in Syria and Egypt. Some quotas also favour ethnic minorities.

It is only in Lebanon that the quotas are a direct answer to a communal conflict and where

they form an important element in a power-sharing arrangement. The system in Lebanon

combines a winner-takes-all system (block vote) with extensive quotas in a way where the

voters' choice is becoming unnecessarily limited and where the voters from minority groups

feel overruled by the majority. For further discussions on Lebanon see Chapter 4.

3.5 Sub-Saharan Africa

3.5.1 Introduction

Here we should first reiterate that the countries included in the study only include those that

have some kind of quota or affirmative action for ethnic, linguistic, etc. groups. This means

that important conflict countries, such as Sudan, Congo and Zimbabwe are left out even if

they have severe ethnic conflicts.

The Burundi and Rwanda conflicts

Only Burundi has quotas that reflect the conflict between Hutus and Tutsis. Rwanda has

chosen a different path by rather understating the ethnic conflict and emphasising that every

person is equal. The way it is implemented in Rwanda is based upon an autocratic leadership

and would fall outside a study of what we consider to be models of democratic reconciliation.

We have, however, chosen to include Rwanda in the study for the comparison with Burundi,

even though the selection criteria otherwise being employed would not have given the country

space.

Page 66: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

64

Table of systems Sub-Saharan Africa

Country and

name of

assembly

Electoral System Basis of

Quota Type of quota

Democracy

Index

BURUNDI

Parliament

(Parlement)

National Assembly

(Inama NshingmateKa)

List proportional + appointments

Ethnicity

Requirements to candidate

nominations of the two major

ethnicities

Requirements to the result:

Supplementing from lists to

top quota

Earmarked seats: Appointment

of representatives of the small

group Twas from predefined

lists

Partly free Gender

Requirements to candidate

nominations Requirements to

result

Senate (Sénat) Indirect, double

member majoritarian (three

round system) + appointments

Ethnicity

Earmarked seats

Indirect elections by electoral

colleges

Separate race for Hutus and

Tutsis Appointment of Twas

from predefined lists

Gender

Requirement to

results Supplementation by

the election commission from

lists to top quota

ETHIOPIA

Parliament (Mekir

Bet)

House of People’s

Representatives

(Yehizbetewekayoch Mekir Bet)

Single-member plurality (FPTP)

+ indirect elections

Ethnicity

Earmarked seats with Indirect

elections to ensure quota

Not free

(partly free in

2011) House of Federation

(Yefedereshn Mekir Bet)

Indirect, single-member plurality

(FPTP) + indirect elections

Ethnicity

Requirements to results

Electoral colleges to ensure

quota for small ethnic groups

KENYA

Parliament

House of Representatives

FPTP + representation based

upon the representation of the

directly elected members

Social

groups

List PR from separate, closed

party lists, based on the

distribution of seats in

parliament

Partly free

Gender Reserved seats FPTP

Senate

FPTP + representation based

upon the representation of the

directly elected members

Social

groups

List PR from separate, closed

party lists, based on the

distribution of seats in

parliament

Gender

List PR from separate, closed

party lists, based on the

distribution of seats in

parliament

Page 67: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

MAURITIUS

National Assembly

Multimember plurality

(block vote)

Ethnicity

Requirements to results for major

groups

Best runner-up

Free

NIGER

National Assembly

(Assamblée National)

Mixed (List PR/FPTP)

Ethnicity

Earmarked seats

Earmarked constituencies with FPTP

for small groups Partly

free

Gender Requirements to candidate

nominations

RWANDA

Parliament

(Inteko Ishinga

Amategeko)

Chamber of Deputies

(Umutwe w’Abadepite)

Direct election with

List PR in one single

constituency

Indirect election

Youth and disabled

Earmarked seats

Indirect elections based on FPTP by

interest groups

Not free

Gender

Earmarked seats

Indirect elections based upon FPTP

by electoral colleges in

administrative units and requirements

to result in the regular race

The Senate

(Umutwe wa Sena)

List PR

Indirect and

appointments

Social groups

(Historically

marginalized groups

and academics)

Requirements to candidate

nominations

Requirements to result

Appointment by president and

indirect elections by interest groups

to fill quota

Gender

Requirements to candidate

nominations

Requirements to result

Indirect elections based by local

councils

UGANDA

National Assembly

National Assembly

Direct, single-member

plurality (FPTP) +

indirect elections +

appointments

Special interest

groups

Earmarked seats

Indirect elections by electoral

colleges

Partly

free

Gender Earmarked seats

Separate race

3.5.2 Burundi

Long-standing tension between Hutus and Tutsis has led to several periods of serious ethnic

violence in Burundi, the last of which was ended by the Arusha Peace and Reconciliation

Agreement of 2000. The agreement set 31 October 2004 as the deadline for the end of a

transitional period, but it would take one more year before Burundi’s current constitution was

approved in a popular referendum in 2005. Parliamentary elections followed under a new

election law, introducing ethnic quotas. This was further amended in 2009, without

significantly altering the quota mechanism.84

Hutus and Tutsis are the two major ethnic

groups in Burundi, constituting 85 and 14 percent of the population respectively. Twas

84

The Election Law was amended in 2009, but alterations to the quota were minor, and the content of this

presentation still applies.

Page 68: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

66

(Pygmies) are estimated to form one percent of the population.85

The constitutional and

electoral framework fixes the relative balance between Hutus and Tutsis in both houses of

parliament, while at the same time guaranteeing a minimum representation for Twas

(Constitution, Articles 164 and 180).

Burundi is a unitary republic. The political system is presidential, but the overall composition

of the cabinet must be proportional to the representation of parties in the National Assembly

(Constitution, Article 129), which derives from an underlying consensus model. Parliament

consists of a principal chamber, the National Assembly (Inama NshingmateKa) and the

Senate (Sénat) (Constitution, Article 147).

Burundi is divided into seventeen provinces, each constituting one constituency. The number

of deputies that each constituency sends to the National Assembly is proportional to the

population (Election law, Articles 126 and 128), and the total number of deputies is to be no

less than 100 (Constitution Article 129). Elections for the National Assembly are list

proportional with closed lists (Constitution, Article 129). The electoral threshold for a party to

be considered elected to the National Assembly is five percent of the national vote

(Constitution, Article 169; Election law, Article 156). Elections for the Senate combine

indirect elections through local electoral colleges and appointments by the Electoral

Commission. In addition, former heads of state are members ex officio.

The legislative framework contains elements of minority protection as well as power-sharing

between the two major groups. Of the 100 deputies in the National Assembly, at least 60

percent must be Hutu, and 40 percent Tutsi.86

Furthermore, at least 30 percent of the deputies

are to be women (2009 Election Law, Article 108).

In order to achieve the quotas, every party must include at least one Hutu and one Tutsi for

every three candidates on their lists. At least one out of four members of the list must be a

woman (Constitution, Article 168 and Election Law, Article 108). If this is not sufficient to

ensure a 60-40 Hutu-Tutsi split and 30 percent female representation in the National

Assembly, the Electoral Commission will allocate additional seats to rectify the imbalance.

These candidates are chosen from lists of political parties or independents who have obtained

at least 5 percent of the vote (Election Law, Article 108)87

. Three additional seats are

allocated to Twas from different regions. These are chosen from lists presented by recognized

Twa organizations, taking geography and gender distribution into account (Election Law,

Article 108).88

85

CIA World Fact Book, https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/geos/by.html, <last

accessed 23 March 2010>. 86

The constitution (Article 129) applies the same principle to the executive. Article 143 of the constitution also

applies the ethnic quota to the Burundian bureaucracy, but not the gender quota. The Twas are only assured

places in the Parliament, and not in the executive branch or the bureaucracy. 87

The constitution does not advise on how the Electoral Commission shall ensure the balance between the

parties in their appointments. 88

The Burundian Election Law was revised in 2009, removing an earlier provision aimed at ensuring broad

political representation: “If, in the first elections, a party gets more than three-fifths of the seats in direct

elections, a total of 18-21 additional representatives are to be appointed by the National Independent Election

Page 69: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

67

The Senate consists of two delegates from each province: one Hutu, and one Tutsi. These two

delegates are elected by a multi-ethnic electoral college in each district in separate races. The

electoral colleges consist of members from the communal councils (Election Law, Article

141). Each member has two votes, one for a Hutu, and one for a Tutsi candidate.89

The two

candidates are elected in a three-round system, whereby each party or group of independent

individuals presents a candidate and a deputy. The candidate is elected who obtains a two-

thirds majority of the votes. If this is not achieved in the first round, a second round is

arranged. If the required majority is still not achieved, a third round is organized between the

two candidates who obtain the largest number of votes. The candidate who gets the highest

number of the votes is elected (Election Law, Article 141).

At least 30 percent of the senators have to be women. If this percentage is not achieved, the

Electoral Commission allocates additional seats to parties having reached the 5 percent

threshold in order to rectify the imbalance. This is done in consultation with the concerned

parties. In addition, three seats are reserved for the Twa (Constitution, Article 161).

A quota is also applied to the Burundian executive. The President of the republic is assisted

by two vice presidents who deal with political and administrative issues and economic and

social issues respectively (Constitution, Article 122). The two vice presidents may neither be

of the same ethnicity, nor from the same party (Constitution, Article 124). Sixty percent of

government ministers and deputies must be Hutu, and 40 percent are to be Tutsi. At least one-

third of the ministers must be women (Constitution, Article 129).

Bills are presented to the Senate and the National Assembly simultaneously (Constitution,

Article 188). Articles 175 and 186 of the Constitution require a two-thirds majority (and at

least half the total membership voting in favour) in both houses in order to adopt laws, e.g.

Article 175 states:

The National Assembly may not deliberate laws unless two thirds of all members are present. Laws

are passed with a two-thirds majority of all members or deputies present.

Organic Laws are passed by two thirds of the members present or their deputies, unless this majority

is less than the absolute majority of all members in the National Assembly.

Resolutions, decisions and important recommendations are passed with a two-thirds majority of

members or deputies present.

These majority requirements also apply to the Senate. The Senate, however, does not vote on

resolutions, decisions and recommendations (Constitution, Article 186). The Senate

comments or suggests amendments to the legislation adopted by the National Assembly

(Constitution, Article 187.7-8). The Senate also approves amendments to the constitution and

organic laws, giving the upper house a stronger role in constitutional matters (Constitution,

Article 187.1). While the Senate has the power to review legislation from the National

Assembly, it does not have a full veto (Constitution, Article 188-190).

Commission in equal numbers from lists who have achieved at least 2% of the vote or two persons from each list

in case more than seven lists have reached the above mentioned threshold.” 89

Reyntjens 2005: 128.

Page 70: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

68

Laws adopted by parliament are promulgated by the president, unless the president decides to

request a second reading, in which case the same text will need a three-fourths majority in

both houses in order to be promulgated (Constitution, Article 197). Laws are subject to

constitutional review by the constitutional court, where the judges must be approved by the

Senate (Constitution, Article 187; 228).

In sum, the Burundian electoral system attempts to guarantee an equitable power balance

between the two major ethnic groups, while also guaranteeing a minimum representation for

one small minority. This is done by imposing requirements on nomination percentage for the

National Assembly, appointment by the electoral commission from predefined lists, by

ensuring bi-ethnic provisional delegations to the Senate, and by imposing requirements on the

final distribution of seats in both houses. Considering the 40 percent quota, the Tutsis are

severely over-represented in parliament and the executive, constituting only 14 percent of the

population. The two-thirds majority requirement provides even further protection, making it

impossible for the Hutu majority to pass laws without some support of the Tutsi minority.

The Arusha Agreement ended a 13 year-long civil war between the Hutu majority and the

Tutsi minority, which had been in power since Burundi achieved in dependence in 1962. The

agreement aimed to devise a power-sharing formula including a quota that would make the

Tutsi minority over-represented in parliament in order to enable them to defend their rights

and interests. While the 2005 elections went calmly, the political situation has since

deteriorated. The former rebel group, Conseil national pour la défense de la démocratie –

Forces de défense de la démocratie (CNDD-FDD), gained complete control of all branches of

government, and the security sector was restructured with CNDD-FDD fighters coming to

constitute 40 percent of the army.90

The government has arrested critics, stifled the press and

tightened control of the economy. It also launched military operations against the last

remaining rebel group, the Palipehutu-FNL. CNDD-FDD still displays some of its

authoritarian character, which is a legacy from its past as a guerrilla movement. 2008 was

marked by political infighting and repeated purges within the party.

The ethnic balance stipulated in the constitution has been maintained, and CNDD-FDD

emerged as the most multi-ethnic party after the elections, with 30 percent of its elected

deputies being Tutsi. While the first post-election cabinet conformed to the ethnic formula, it

did not comply with the requirements of a proportional representation of the political

parties.91

Parliamentary work was seriously hampered as a result of friction between CNDD-

FDD and the opposition over the composition of the government, as well as within the

CNDD-FDD itself over the authoritarian style of the party leadership and lack of transparency

within the party. These combined factors sparked a series of defections from the CNDD-FDD

in parliament, and a boycott by opposition parties. After protracted negotiations, a new

cabinet was appointed that gained the acceptance of the major opposition parties. However,

the underlying causes of the 2007 parliamentary crisis have not been resolved.

90

International Crisis Group 2005. 91

For a breakdown of the cabinet and parliament, see Falch 2009: 10-11.

Page 71: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

69

Prior to the July 2010 parliamentary elections, all opposition groups except one (UPRONA),

boycotted the polls, citing massive electoral fraud in local elections immediately preceding

the parliamentary elections. As a result, the CNDD-FDD party took 81 of the 106 seats in the

lower house of parliament. UPRONA, the only opposition group to take part in the polls, won

17 seats and another smaller party won five. At the time of writing, there have been no

official talks between the opposition parties and the government. There have, however, been

frequent clashes between the security forces and unidentified armed men that are believed to

be linked to some opposition leaders. 92

3.5.3 Rwanda

Rwanda is a unitary republic with a presidential system. Hutus constitute the largest ethnic

group with 84 percent of the population. 15 percent are Tutsi, and 1 percent belongs to the

Twa. The legislature is bicameral and consists of the Chamber of Deputies and the Senate.

Deputies serve for five years, and Senators for eight years (Constitution, Article 82). The

Chamber of Deputies consists of 80 members. Of these, 53 are directly elected by List PR

with a five percent national threshold. The lists must reflect gender equality. In addition, 24

women (two from each Province and the city of Kigali) are indirectly elected by a joint

assembly composed of district municipalities, city councils and the executive committees of

women’s organizations. Furthermore, two members are indirectly elected by the National

Council and one by the Federation of the Associations of the Disabled (Constitution, Article

76-77). The gender quotas on the lists and the separate race for women have led to a clear

majority of women in the Chamber of Deputies (56.3 percent in 2008).

The Senate consists of 26 members who are either indirectly elected or appointed. In addition,

former Heads of State become members of the Senate upon their own request. Organs

responsible for nominating Senators are required to consider national unity and gender

representation. The constitution (Article 82) requires at least 30 percent of Senators to be

women, but does not specify what will happen if the quota is not met. Twelve of the Senators

are indirectly elected by members of the Executive Committees of Sectors and District,

Municipality, Town or City Councils of each Province and the city of Kigali. Four members

are designated by the Forum of Political organizations. Two academics are indirectly elected

by academic and research staff from academic institutions. In addition, the President may

appoint eight members in order to ensure representation of historically marginalized

communities (Constitution, Article 82).

The genocide in Rwanda occurred when the Rwandan Patriotic Front (RPF), which had been

embroiled in a civil war against the government since 1990, seized most of Rwandan territory

and drove the regime into exile in 1994. Until 2003, RPF ruled the country under a consensual

dictatorship in which it shared power with a limited number of political parties.93

A new constitution adopted in 2003 provided for multi-party elections, followed by

presidential and parliamentary elections in the same year. New parliamentary elections were

92

International Crisis Group 2011: i. 93

Freedom House, Countries at the Crossroad 2007, Country Report – Rwanda,

http://www.freedomhouse.org/uploads/ccr/country-7259-8.pdf <accessed 31 May 2011>.

Page 72: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

70

held for the Chamber of Deputies in 2008 and presidential elections were held in August

2010. The 2003 constitution strongly emphasises national unity and pledges to “fight the

ideology of genocide and all its manifestations and to eradicate ethnic, regional and any other

form of division”.

Parties based on ethnicity and religion are not allowed (Constitution, Article 54). While the

constitution provides for strong anti-discrimination measures, democratic structures have not

evolved in post-genocide Rwanda. The 2003 elections were marred by bias and intimidation,

and while elections in 2008 took place in a peaceful environment, the EU observer missions

cite a number of fundamental shortcomings regarding international and regional standards for

democratic elections 94

. There was no real political competition between the parties, and

subsequently, no real opportunity for rotation of power. The strong anti-discriminatory

provisions in the constitution had in fact become a useful tool for silencing critics, citing

divisionism or ’genocidal ideology’.

3.5.4 Ethiopia

Ethiopia is a federal republic, consisting of nine regional states (Constitution, Article 45-47).

“Six of these are dominated by one particular group". Christophe Van der Beken describes

these as “ethnic states, which provide a forum for the nominal ethnic groups to different

aspects of their rights to self-determination” as provided in the constitution. The Tigray ethnic

group is dominant in the Tigray state, the Afar in Afar, the Amhara in Amhara, the Oromo in

Oromia, the Somali in Somalia, and the Harari in Harar. Subsequently, “the large majority of

Ethiopia’s more than 80 ethnic groups does not dominate a particular state, but rather

constitutes a minority in one of the six ethnic states or in the three remaining multi-ethnic

states. 95

The Ethiopian constitution distinguishes between ‘nations, nationalities, and peoples’, who

have the right to form their own states within the federation, and ‘minority nations’

(Constitution, Article 9). The constitution defines a ‘nation, nationality or people’ as “a group

of people who have, or share large measure, of a common culture or similar customs, mutual

intelligibility of language, belief in a common or related identities, a common psychological

make-up, and who inhabit an identifiable, predominantly contiguous territory” (Article 39.5)

Minority nations are defined as “a community determined, by the House of People’s

Representatives or its successor, to be of a comparatively smaller size of population than that

of other nations/nationalities” (Election law, Article 2.5).

The legislature is bicameral and consists of the House of People’s Representatives

(Yehizbetwekayoch Mekir Bet), which is the lower house, and the House of Federation

(Yefedereshm Mekir Bet), which is the upper house (Constitution, Article 53). The House of

Federation does not enact legislation, but interprets the constitution and considers the

constitutionality of legislation (Constitution, Article 62). In addition, it has roles regarding the

rights of nations, nationalities, and peoples.

94

European Union Election Observation Mission, 2008. 95

Van der Beken 2009: 17.

Page 73: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

71

The Ethiopian parliament (Mekir Bet) was established in the 1994 constitution. The electoral

system for both chambers of parliament is based on plurality elections in single-member

constituencies, FPTP (Constitution, Article 54.2; Election law, Article 13, 15).96

The House of

Peoples' Representatives consists of no more than 555 directly-elected members. Of these,

minority nationalities and peoples shall have at least 20 seats (Constitution, Article 54.1-3).

These are elected from earmarked constituencies. In the 2005 elections, there were 22 such

“special constituencies”.97

The electoral law does not specify how the minority

representatives are to be elected. Convention, however, is that they are elected through the

regional councils.

The composition of the House of Federation is designed to provide a balance of power

between the major national groups, as they are defined in the constitution and election law.

The House of Federation is tasked with constitutional interpretation and deciding issues

related to national self-determination. It has no legislative role. Article 61 in the constitution

stipulates that:

1. The House of the Federation is composed of representatives of Nations, Nationalities and Peoples.

2. Each Nation, Nationality and People shall be represented in the House of the Federation by at least

one member. Each Nation or Nationality shall be represented by one additional representative for

each one million of its population.

These delegates are indirectly elected by electoral colleges within the State Councils. The

State Councils may, however, decide to hold elections for their representatives (Constitution

Article 54, 61). For the purpose of electing the delegates, the House of Federation may draw

their own constituencies based on a pre-determined procedure (Election Law, Article 15).

Constitutionally, residual powers lie with the regional states (Article 52). The right to self-

determination for ethnic groups has been a double-edged sword in that culturally repressed

groups have been able to use their own language in education and administration. On the

other hand, the system has sparked new ethnic frictions inspiring groups to separate from

other already-established groups.98

It is also not clear whether the regional states have

sufficient competences.99

In particular, the fiscal powers assigned to the regions, do not

generate sufficient revenue to cover regional expenditure. This undermines a truly

autonomous exercise of the regional powers.

The most important impediment for meaningful power-sharing in Ethiopia, however, does not

lie in the relationship between the state and the regions, but in the dominant role of Ethiopia’s

leading political organization coalition, the Ethiopian People’s Revolutionary Front

(EPRDF).100

96

A 2007 draft for a new election law indicates that the election law may be amended. We have not found any

sources that indicate that this draft has been ratified. In the draft, the definitions of minority nation are abolished.

It does, however, include reference to the constitutional guarantee of at least 20 minority seats in the principal

chamber. http://ethiopolitics.com/pdfiles/ELECTIONLAW_UNVEILED.pdf <accessed 28 may 2010>. 97

European Union Election Observation Mission, 2005: 9. 98

Siegfried Pausewang, “Landprofil 2006-2007: Etiopia”, Fellesrådet for Afrika,

http://www.afrika.no/Detailed/14445.html <last accessed 31 May 2011>. 99

Van der Beken 2010: 91-92. 100

Van der Beken 2010: 14-16.

Page 74: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

72

The EPRDF was established in 1989 by the Tigray People’s Leadership Front (TPLF) as an

umbrella of ethno-national fronts, including the Amhara National Democratic Movement

(ANDM), the Oromo People’s Democratic Organisation (OPDO), and the South Ethiopian

People’s Democratic Movement (SEPDM). TPLF, ANDM and OPDO were established to

represent the Tigrayans, Amhara and Oromo respectively; whereas the SEPDM represents the

diverse ethnic groups of the multi-ethnic Southern region. That makes EPRDF effectively into

a party specifically for Tigray, Oromia and the Southern regional states.

In addition, the EPRPDF has formed satellite parties in all ethnic groups in order to maintain

control of the remaining regions.101

Competing parties have systematically been obstructed.

One example is how obstruction of the Oromo People’s Democratic Organisation (OPDO)'s

attempts to run candidates for elections and compete with EPRDF’s own Oromo party. The

federal power-sharing arrangement is in many instances not reflective of realities. EPRDF's

highly centralized party structure and strong control of public administration, courts and

police counteract the federal structure of the state. Furthermore, the central party apparatus

regularly interferes in decisions made on the regional party level.

Since adopting the 1994 constitution, Ethiopia has held general elections in 1995, 2000, 2005

and 2010. EPRDF has been able to consolidate its power since the country’s first elections

were held in 1995. In the 2010 elections, the party captured 534 out of 536 declared seats.102

In 2005, the party gained 327 seats after initial reports that the CUD had won overwhelmingly

in the capital Addis Ababa and major cities. Both CUD and the government declared

themselves as winners of the elections. More than 40 people were killed in demonstrations,

and the security forces clamped down hard on the opposition, arresting its leaders and

thousands of supporters. This repression has caused widespread resentment. Support for the

federation is also being challenged by a growing pan-Ethiopian nationalism, fuelled by

the1998-2000 war against Eritrea. The tense relationship with Eritrea has in turn reinforced

the government’s brutality towards the opposition in Ethiopia.

While the 2010 elections were relatively calm, observers from both the US and the EU state

that the polls did not meet international standards. This is mainly related to the EPRDF’s use

of state resources for campaigning. A new electoral code adopted in 2009 caused widespread

protests among opposition parties, who claimed that the electoral code is designed to maintain

the leading position of the EPRDF. A new press law and law on the registration of political

parties were also criticized.103

At the time of writing, no observer reports were finalized on

the 2010 elections. The EU election-monitoring report on the 2005 elections, however, cites

abuse of human rights such as freedoms of expression, association and assembly.104

101

Pausewang, ‚”Etiopia”, see note above. 102

Tronvoll 2011. 103

European Parliament resolution of 15 January 2009 on the situation in the Horn of Africa,

http://www.europarl.europa.eu/sides/getDoc.do?pubRef=-//EP//TEXT+TA+P6-TA-2009-

0026+0+DOC+XML+V0//EN <accessed 28 may 2010>. 104

European Union Election Observation Mission, 2005: 19.

Page 75: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

73

3.5.5 Kenya

Kenya is a unitary state with a hybrid form of government. The parliament is bicameral and

the powers of the two chambers are rather similar except for money bills, which are to be

passed by the principle chamber (National Assembly) only.

According to the 2010 constitution, the National Assembly has 290 members elected by FPTP

in single-member constituencies. In addition, 47 women are elected from each county

constituting a single-member constituency. Lastly, twelve members are elected from pre-

prepared party lists according to their proportion of members of the National Assembly.

These twelve represent special interests including the youth, persons with disabilities and

workers. The speaker is an ex officio member (Constitution, Article 97).

For the Senate, 47 members are elected from single-member constituencies corresponding to

Kenya’s counties (Constitution, Article 98). Sixteen female members are elected from pre-

prepared party lists according to their proportion of members of the Senate. Two youth and

two disabled members are elected in the same manner, two men and two women respectively.

The new constitution is part of a compromise reached after riots following a highly

controversial presidential election in December 2007. Incumbent President Mwai Kibaki was

declared winner in spite of opposition leader Raila Odinga’s claims of victory and exit polls

indicating a clear victory for Odinga. Hundreds of people were killed in riots by the

opposition, which claimed that Kibaki had manipulated the elections .

An ongoing debate over the need for constitutional reform gained momentum after the riots,

and the new constitution was adopted in August 2010. The Constitution reaffirmed the hybrid

executive model that had been part of the political deal following the riots and it introduced a

number of improvements in basic rights. Elections according to the new constitution are

expected in 2012.

3.5.6 Mauritius

The Dutch occupied Mauritius in 1598 and the island’s current multi-ethnic population are

mainly descendants of people who were brought in from different parts of the world to work:

Africans came as slaves, Indians as indentured labourers, and in the early 1900s, a small

community of Chinese came as traders. The island became home to a number of ethno-

religious groups, divided at present as follows: Hindus (52 percent); Muslims (16 percent);

Creoles of African ancestry (27 percent); Chinese (3 percent); and Franco Mauritians of

European ancestry (2 percent).105

In 1968, the island gained independence from Great Britain

and became part of the Commonwealth.

Mauritius is a unitary republic with a semi-presidential form of government, with a prime

minister as head of government and an indirectly-elected president as head of state. The

parliament is unicameral (the National Assembly) and has 70 members (Constitution, Article

31.2). The Prime Minister and Deputy Prime Minister are appointed by the President on the

basis of who enjoys the support of the legislature (Constitution, Article 59). Ministers are

105

Bunwaree and Kasenally 2006: 6.

Page 76: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

74

appointed by the President on the recommendation of the Prime Minister. Parliamentary

approval is not required (Constitution, Article 59). The President is elected by the National

Assembly, on a motion by the Prime Minister (Constitution, Article 28).

Elections in Mauritius are governed by the Representation of the People Act of 1968

(amended 1976, 1982, 2005) and the Constitution, First Schedule.106

The electoral system of

Mauritius is a multi-member constituency plurality (block vote) system. The country is

divided into 21 constituencies (Constitution, Article 39). According to the First Schedule,

Section 31 (2), Article 1,

There shall be 62 seats in the Assembly for members representing constituencies and accordingly

each constituency shall return 3 members to the Assembly in such manner as may be prescribed,

except Rodrigues, which shall so return 2 members.

Each voter gets to vote for the number of representatives corresponding to the number of seats

allocated to his or her constituency (Constitution, Schedule 1, Article 1).

The Mauritian population is divided into four constitutionally-recognized communities: a

Hindu community, a Muslim community, a Sino-Mauritian community and the General

population (Constitution, 1 Schedule, Article 3). In order to ensure an adequate representation

of each community, eight seats are allocated to the best runners-up from the communities:

In order to ensure a fair and adequate representation of each community, there shall be 8 seats in the

Assembly, additional to the 62 seats for members representing constituencies, which shall so far as is

possible be allocated to persons belonging to parties who have stood as candidates for election as

members at the general election but have not been returned as members to represent constituencies

(Constitution, Schedule 1, Article 5.1).

The additional seats are allocated by the Electoral Supervisory Commission to the best

runners-up from the appropriate parties and communities. The allocation is based on the

provisions prescribed in sub clauses 3-10 of Article 5, Schedule 1:

(3) The first 4 of the 8 seats shall so far as is possible each be allocated to the most successful

unreturned candidate, if any, who is a member of a party and who belongs to the appropriate

community, regardless of which party he belongs to.

(4) When the first 4 seats (or as many as possible of those seats) have been allocated, the number of

such seats that have been allocated to persons who belong to parties, other than the most successful

party, shall be ascertained and so far as is possible that number of seats out of the second 4 seats shall

one by one be allocated to the most successful unreturned candidates (if any) belonging both to the

most successful party and to the appropriate community or where there is no unreturned candidate of

the appropriate community, to the most successful unreturned candidates belonging to the most

successful party, irrespective of community.

Underrepresentation is determined on the basis of the 1972 population figure.107

The constitution of Mauritius states that the National Assembly may make laws for the

“peace, order and good government of Mauritius”. This phrase is a legacy from Mauritius's

106

The Electoral Commissioner's Office,

http://www.gov.mu/portal/site/eco/menuitem.3c8fbbc803ea270b9459d9a365d521ca/ <accessed 26 March

2010>. 107

Bunwaree and Kasenally 2006: 3.

Page 77: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

75

colonial past108

, and even now, the legislature may not initiate legislation related to taxation,

public expenditures or government debt.109

Legislation adopted by the National Assembly

shall be signed by the president or returned to the National Assembly within 21 days,

requesting a reconsideration of the bill and any possible amendments. If the legislation is

passed again, with or without amendment, “the president shall signify his assent”

(Constitution, Article 46.2-3).

In spite of sporadic tensions, Mauritius has a reputation for stability and racial harmony. Post-

independence in Mauritius has been dominated by three political parties: the Labour Party

(LP), Mauritian Militant Movement (MMM) and Mouvement Socialiste Mauricien (MSM).

While the support bases of the main political parties are to a large extent ethnically

homogenous, "explicit appeals by politicians to ethnic interests and ethnic fears have become

uncommon, and are viewed as illegitimate and dangerous. Each of the main political parties

includes at least a few prominent politicians from communities other than those from which

they draw their main support."110

The majoritarian nature of the block vote system has, however, been blamed for “the

proliferation, creation and ultimately the disbanding of political party alliances”. It has also

been criticized for triggering “the crude ethnicisation of political parties”.111

There is a broad

agreement on the need for electoral reform to correct the lacking proportionality of the

electoral system, and Mauritius’ main parties have had electoral reform as part of their

political pledges.

Furthermore, the best runner-up system has required party candidates to disclose their ethnic

affiliation. In 2005, this clause was challenged by the Rezistans Ek Alternative party on the

grounds that it is discriminatory. Candidates from this party refused to specify their ethnic

affiliation and took the Electoral Commissioner, Electoral Supervisory Commission and

electoral staff in their respective constituencies to court. The Supreme Court ruled in favour

of the party, and their candidates were incorporated as qualified candidates for the 2005

elections.112

As early as 2001, a commission on constitutional and electoral reform, the so-called Sachs

Commission, was established to review the electoral system.113

The commission produced

two reports ahead of the 2005 National Assembly elections. Among their proposals was an

enlarged National Assembly (from 70-80) elected by a semi-proportional system. The

constitution was amended in 2005 to provide for international election observers, but due to

recurrent disagreements among the stakeholders, no steps were taken towards a more

proportional system. The parliamentary elections of 2010 were held under an un-amended

electoral framework.

108

Bridge 1997: 789. 109

Fish and Kroenig 2009: 441-447. 110

Carroll and Carroll 1997: 482. 111

Bunwaree and Kasenally 2006: 16. 112

Judgement Supreme Court of Mauritius, Record No 89540 as explained in Bunwaree and Kasenally 2006: 16- 113

Bunwaree and Kasenally 2006: 6.

Page 78: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

76

3.5.7 Niger

By March 2010, Niger has had five constitutions since independence was achieved in 1960.

The following is based on the 1999 constitution and election law. Niger is a unitary republic

with a semi-presidential political system. The National Assembly is unicameral. The number

of deputies is determined by law (Constitution, Article 66), as is the number and size of

constituencies (Constitution, Article 127)114

: In the 2011 elections, 105 deputies were elected

from eight multi-member constituencies and eight from special constituencies, see below.115

Laws passed by the National Assembly are transmitted to the president for promulgation

within fifteen days. The president may request a second hearing, which cannot be denied. If

the bill is passed a second time with an absolute majority, the president shall sign the law

(Constitution, Article 47). The Constitutional Court is formally authorised to review the

constitutionality of Laws (Constitution, Articles 84, 92, 103 and 115), but is in reality unable

to exercise this power116

.

Niger is constituted of the former peripheries of larger states. The population is ethnically

diverse, consisting of the following groups according to the 2001 census: Haoussa 55.4

percent, Djerma Sonrai 21 percent, Tuareg 9.3 percent, Peuhl 8.5 percent, Kanouri Manga 4.7

percent, and other 1.2 percent. About 20 percent of the population are semi-nomadic

livestock-raising peoples, whereas 80 percent of the population are farmers. Niger is one of

the world’s poorest countries, and competition for natural resources has led to an increasing

conflict between the agricultural and nomadic ways of life.

The electoral system for the eight multi-member constituencies is List PR with closed lists

(Election Law, Article 113). In order to ensure minority representation, eight special

constituencies were established in a separate law. The Election Law refers to these

constituencies, but does not specify further details: “For the legislative elections, a law

determines the number of seats to be allotted to each region and the special constituencies”,

the so-called circonscriptions spéciales (Election Law, Article 41). Each of the special

constituencies elects one deputy to parliament, based on the FTPT system of representation.

The law specifies that these seats should go to the smallest minorities, primarily the Arab,

Tobou and Gourmantche communities, who combined constitute 1.2 percent of the

population.117

There is also a gender quota, enshrined in a separate Quota Act signed by the president in

2001:

(a) A minimum of 10 percent of candidates of one and the other sex in all electoral positions; and

(b) A minimum of 25 percent of appointees of one and the other sex in executive government and

state positions and promotions.

114

The Nigerian parliament, http://www.assemblee.ne/texteslegaux/codelec.htm <accessed 30 March 2010>.

115. African Elections Database http://africanelections.tripod.com/ne.html <accessed 9 August 2011>

116 Fish and Kroenig 2009: 493.

117 According to the CIA Fact book, the ethnic breakdown is as follows: Haoussa 55.4%, Djerma Sonrai 21%,

Tuareg 9.3%, Peuhl 8.5%, Kanouri Manga 4.7%, other 1.2% (2001 census),

https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/geos/ug.html <last accessed 1 June 2011>.

Page 79: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

77

The purpose of the quota in Niger was to ensure representation of the smallest minorities and

has not been relevant to the actual lines of conflict in Niger. A Tuareg insurgence between

1990 and 1995 ended with a peace agreement, which has been only partially implemented. In

2007, a previously unknown rebel group, the Movement of Nigeriens for Justice (MNJ),

instigated a major uprising. The group is primarily, but not exclusively, Tuareg, and has

issued a number of demands related to development in the north, which holds significant

uranium resources. Several rounds of peace talks have resulted in a de facto ceasefire.118

Niger introduced a multi-party system in 1991. In 2009, Niger was embroiled in a

constitutional crisis due to President Mamadou Tandja’s decision to put changes to the

constitution out for a referendum to allow him to serve for a third term and to change the form

of government from a semi-presidential to a presidential system. A referendum was held on 4

August 2009 despite an earlier ruling by the Constitution Court that the changes were

unconstitutional. The opposition boycotted the referendum, which, with low participation, did

win a majority. Legislative elections held on 20 October 2009 were boycotted by the main

opposition parties. However, the amended constitution was subsequently suspended after a

military coup on 18 February 2010. The coup leaders immediately created the Supreme

Council for the Restoration of Democracy to be in charge of the country, and in March 2010

they put in place a transitional government with three major objectives on its agenda: 1)

Restoring democracy in Niger; 2) Improving the economic and political situation of the

country; 3) Proceeding with the national reconciliation of Nigeriens,119

and the overarching

goal of equipping the country with legal texts and institutions which will ensure political

stability while honouring major international engagements taken by Niger.

A referendum on constitutional reform was held on 31 October 2010 and it gave a 90.2

percent majority for a semi-presidential system and for limiting the number of presidential

terms to two. Parliamentary elections and the first round of presidential elections were held

on 31 January 2011 with a presidential runoff on 12 March 2011.120

3.5.8 Uganda

The following is based on the Constitution of 2000 and subsequent 2005 amendments.

Uganda is a unitary republic with a presidential system and a unicameral National Assembly.

The electoral framework is extremely fragmented, and the electoral commission of Uganda

cites 35 laws and regulations governing the Ugandan electoral process. Article 78 of the

constitution states that:

(1) Parliament shall consist of –

(a) Members directly elected to represent constituencies;

(b) One woman representative for each district

118

US Department of State, “Background Note: Niger”, Bureau of African Affairs, 12 October 2010,

http://www.state.gov/r/pa/ei/bgn/5474.htm <last accessed 9 March 2011>. 119

IFES 2010.

120 African Elections database, http://africanelections.tripod.com/ne.html#2011_Presidential_Election <accessed

9 August 2011>

Page 80: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

78

(c) Such members of representatives of the army, youth, workers, persons with disabilities and other

groups as Parliament may determine; and

(d) The Vice President and Ministers, who, if not already elected members of Parliament, shall be ex

officio members of Parliament without the right to vote on any issue requiring a vote in parliament.

Whereas the constituency members are directly elected, members under clauses (b) and (c)

are elected on procedures prescribed “by law” (Constitution, Article 78.4). In addition, the

ministers who are not members of parliament are ex officio members without voting rights.

The constitution does not specify the number of deputies, but the number of constituencies are

prescribed by parliament and demarked by the Electoral Commission (Constitution, Article

63).

While the Ugandan Constitution Third Schedule, Article 10 (a) lists about 60 indigenous

communities in Uganda, there are no ethnic quotas for the Ugandan legislature. Ethnic parties

are not allowed (Constitution, Article 71 clauses a) and b); rather, parties are to be “national”

in character. There is, however, a quota system to provide representation for district women

and so-called ‘Special Interest Groups’ representatives (SIGs) (Constitution, Article 78, 1).

Since 2006, district women representatives have been elected by all voters on a special ballot

in each district for women candidates only. These elections may be held on a different day

from the general elections (Election Law, Article 8.4.iii). The modalities for female

representation are further elaborated in The Parliamentary Elections (District Women

Representatives) Regulations, 2001 and the National Women’s Council Act and Regulations.

The election of youth, workers and army representatives is covered in Parliamentary Elections

(Special Interest Groups) Regulation 2001 (SIG).121

Representation of Youth is also regulated

by the National Youth Council Act and Regulations.

In the parliamentary elections in 2011, 238 MPs were directly elected to represent each

electoral constituency; 112 women MPs were directly elected to represent each administrative

district; and 25 MPs were elected by four different kinds of electoral colleges (SIGs), namely

youth, workers and persons with disabilities, each of whom elected five MPs, and the

Ugandan People’s Defence Force elected 10 MPs. The parliament thus composed of 375

MPs.122

Both in the constituencies and within the colleges, elections are conducted by FTPT. Whereas

district women representatives are directly elected, SIG representatives are elected by

electoral colleges comprising leaders in those groups «from grass root level».123

One example

of how the system works is the election of youth to parliament. For the purpose of youth

elections, Uganda is divided into four regions. Of the five youth representatives, at least one

has to be a woman. The female representative is elected by a national youth conference,

consisting of the National Youth Executive Committee, the Chairperson of every District

Youths Council, the Secretary for Female Youths at the District Level, a representative of

121

The Electoral Commission, “Politics and Elections in Uganda” May 2006. 122

European Union Election Observation Mission 2011.

123 Ibid, p. 4.

Page 81: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

79

Youth Persons with Disabilities, and four student representatives elected by the Uganda

National Students’ Association – two of whom shall be female and one from a secondary

school. The remaining four candidates are elected by district youth councils in the four

districts.124

Parliament has the “power to make laws on any matter for the peace, order, development and

good governance of Uganda” (Article 79.1). It may not, however, introduce legislation related

to taxation, public expenditure or government debt (Constitution, Article 93). The president

may return a bill to parliament. If the law is passed again, the president may return it a second

time, in which case it takes a two-thirds majority to override the veto (Constitution, Article

91). The Constitutional Court may review the constitutionality of laws (Constitution, Article

137).

Uganda’s elaborate quota system has no relevance to the main violent conflict in the country,

which is the rebellion by the Lord’s Resistance Army in the north of the country.

During the 2006 elections, Uganda experienced relatively little political violence. This has

been primarily ascribed to improved management of the elections, compared to the 2001

elections.125

After the 2011 election, the EU Election Observation Mission concluded that

“Notwithstanding a number of incidents of violence and intimidation, especially on Election

Day, the electoral campaign and polling day were generally conducted in a peaceful manner”.

3.5.9 Main findings

In Africa south of the Sahara, most quotas are for small minorities or for social groups not

related to power-sharing after conflict. The exception is Burundi, which has both quotas for

the earlier combating groups and decision-making rules in parliament giving a group veto

powers. Rwanda has chosen the opposite approach in understating the ethnic conflict in their

representative systems.

Ethiopia has power-sharing arrangements involving groups large enough to form states of the

federation with ethnic identity. However, the quotas relate to the small groups which has

more to do with inclusion of otherwise excluded groups than with power-sharing

3.6 Western Europe

3.6.1 Introduction

With the exception of Turkey, Western European quotas are intended to ensure representation

for linguistic minorities. Four Western European countries have these kinds of quota: Italy,

Belgium, Germany and Cyprus. Belgium and Germany are federations, while Italy and

Cyprus are unitary states. The two countries of interest in a power-sharing perspective are

Belgium and Cyprus. While there is no armed conflict in Belgium, intra-linguistic tensions

have caused repeated political stalemates. The unresolved conflict between Greeks and Turks

in Cyprus has at times been violent and culminated with the Turkish invasion in 1974.

124

Uganda Electoral Commission, “Guidelines Covering Elections of Youth Representatives to Parliament,” 18

April, 2006. 125

Stremlau and Price 2009: 9.

Page 82: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

80

Switzerland clearly has a structure with power-sharing between the three linguistic groups of

the country. The constitutional arrangements are based upon the twenty-six cantons rather

than the linguistic groups but unwritten rules secure the even balance between the four

groups. One of the unwritten rules, the requirement to rotate the membership in the seven-

person cabinet (Bundesrat) among districts and language areas was written into the

Constitution after a referendum in February 1999, thus formalising that part of the power-

sharing. However, the lack of more explicit quotas excludes Switzerland from this broad

overview.

In Norway, the Sámi people enjoy rights as an indigenous people and elect their own council,

the Sámi Parliament with advisory and decision-making powers within certain subject areas.

This is an element in the devolution of powers and does not affect representation in central

political bodies. Norway is therefore not part of the overview.

Finland has not been included even if the island of Åland has a special status. The island,

which is inhabited by a Swedish-speaking minority, has an exemption to the multi-member

constituencies formed on the basis of population as it is elsewhere in Finland by electing one

member of parliament. Even if this is guaranteed regardless of the population, it corresponds

quite closely to their share of the population.

Page 83: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

81

Table of systems Western Europe

Country Electoral System Basis of

Quota Type of quota

Democracy

Index BELGIUM

Federal

parliament

(Parlement

fédéral

Federaal

Parlement

Föderales

Parlament)

House of Representatives: List PR

(Kamer van

Volksvertegenwoordigers / Chambre

des Représentants)

No quota

Free

Senate: List PR

(Sénat / Senaat) Language

Earmarked seats,

separate races

CYPRUS

House of representatives: List PR

(Vouli Antiprosopon) Ethnicity

Separate race with

separate voters registers Free

GERMANY

Parliament

(Bundestag)

Parliamentary Assembly: MMP

(Bundestag)

Ethnicity and

language

Threshold and support

signature exemptions

Free

Federal Council: Indirect

(Bundesrat)

No quota

ITALY

Parliament

(Parlamento)

Chamber of Deputies

(Camara dei deputati)

List PR + FPTP in Valle d’Aousta

Language Threshold exemptions

Free Senate

(Senato)

List PR + FPTP in 7 constituencies

in autonomous regions

Language

Constituencies drawn in

support of minorities

Best runner-up for

earmarked seats

3.6.2 Belgium

Belgium is a federal monarchy with a parliamentarian system. According to the Constitution

Article 2-4, the federation consists of three communities, three geographical regions and four

linguistic regions. The three communities are the Dutch-, the French-, and the German-

speaking communities. The regions are the Flanders, the Wallonia and the Brussels regions.

The communities and the regions have their own representative bodies. The linguistic regions

are the Dutch-, the French- and the German-speaking regions in addition to the bilingual

region of Brussels, but they do not have representative bodies. Each municipality is part of

one of these linguistic regions (Constitution Article 1-4). The federation may be called

‘double-layered’ since it has two types of entities below the national level, the communities,

and the regions (Constitution Article 7). Residual power lies with the regions and the

communities (Constitution, Article 35).

The legislature is bicameral and consists of the House of Representatives (Kamer van

Volksvertegenwoordigers / Chambre des Représentants) and the Senate (Sénat / Senaat).

Members of the House of Representatives are elected by List PR from ten constituencies. The

national threshold is five percent. Five constituencies in the Walloon region, five in the

Page 84: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

82

Flemish region, and the constituency of Brussels send a total of 150 representatives to the

House of Representatives.

There are 71 Senators, of which 40 are directly elected by List PR with a national threshold of

5 percent. Of these, 25 are elected from the Dutch-speaking lists and 14 from French lists. In

addition, 21 Senators are elected by the Community Parliaments, and 10 senators are

appointed by other senators. The King’s children are also Senators, but do not play a political

role. Voters in the Walloon Region belong to the French-speaking Electoral College and can

only vote for the French-speaking lists.

Voters in Brussels have the choice to vote either for the Flemish-speaking or for the French-

speaking lists, whereas voters in the Flemish Region (with the exception of Halle/Hal and

Volvorde/Vilvoorde areas) belong to the Dutch-speaking Electoral College and can only vote

for the Flemish-speaking lists. According to Blanc, Hylland and Vollan, the linguistic groups

as such play an important role in decision-making:126

Each chamber is divided into a French linguistic group and a Dutch linguistic group. This division

is important, since certain so-called special majority laws require a majority within each linguistic

group, in addition to two-thirds overall majority.

There exists an "alarm procedure", which does not give anybody veto power, but provides for

particularly thorough consideration and debate when there is a danger that a measure might "gravely

damage the relations between the communities". If at least three-quarters of the members of one of

the linguistic groups sign a motivated statement declaring that a proposal is of such a nature,

parliamentary procedure is suspended and the matter is referred to the Council of Ministers. Within

thirty days, the Council of Ministers gives its recommendations and invites the chamber involved to

express its opinion on these recommendations or on the original proposal, possibly in revised form.

This procedure can only be applied once by the members of a linguistic group to the same issue. It

does not apply at all to the budget or to laws requiring a special majority.

For regular legislation the Senate has reviewing powers only and the Chamber of Representatives

has the decisive powers. For a number of specified types of legislation, including the Constitution,

election laws and laws involving vital interests of the communities or regions, approval by both

chambers is required. …

In some cases, there is even a requirement of two-thirds majority in each chamber and majority

within each linguistic group of each chamber.

Some parties advocate a split of the country and there have been long-lasting stalemates in

forming the government. Despite the strong elements of power-sharing, these have not been

sufficient to reduce the discontent within some groups with the current state of Belgium.

3.6.3 Cyprus

According to the 1960 Constitution, Cyprus is a unitary republic. In reality, the island is split

between the Greek Cypriot part and a Turkish Cypriot part, which is only recognized by

Turkey. A UN power-sharing plan was rejected by the Greek part in a referendum in 2004.

The political system is presidential. The legislature is unicameral and consists of 80 members.

According to the 1960 Constitution, 70 percent (56 seats) of these are to be elected by the

126

Blanc, Hylland and Vollan 2006: 23-24.

Page 85: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

83

Greek community, and 30 percent (24 seats) by the Turkish community, “separately from

amongst their members respectively”. The members of the Greek community shall only be

registered in the Greek electoral list, and the members of the Turkish community shall only be

registered in the Turkish electoral list (Constitution, Article 62-63). Candidates are elected by

List PR with open lists.

After the conflict between Greek and Turkish Cypriots broke out in 1963, the Turkish

Cypriots withdrew from parliament. In 1974, Turkey invaded part of Cyprus, and the conflict

between the two groups remains unsolved. The 24 Turkish Cypriot seats have remained

vacant.

After a decision by the European Court of Human Rights in 2004, a new law was passed

providing Turkish Cypriots living in the Greek Cypriot controlled south the right to vote and

be elected in parliamentary and municipal elections. They also have the right to vote in

presidential elections, but may not stand for elections. As this law only applies to Turkish

Cypriots living in the south, the vast majority of Turkish Cypriots still lack the right to vote

and to be elected.

The religious groups of the Maronites, the Armenians and members of the Latin community

are also represented as observers in the House by one Representative for each group, elected

by their respective group for a five-year term. As observers, they have only limited speaking

rights and no voting rights.

3.6.4 Italy

Italy is a parliamentary republic with a figure-head indirectly-elected president and a

government which requires the confidence of the principal chamber of parliament. The

Italian parliament is a bicameral body comprising the Chamber of Deputies (principal house)

with 630 members and the Senate (upper house) with 315 senators. For the elections to the

Chamber of Deputies, the country is divided into 27 constituencies, roughly corresponding to

the administrative districts. All constituencies, except Valle d’Aosta are multi-member

constituencies using closed lists. Twelve seats represent Italians abroad.

Italy is home to fourteen defined linguistic minorities who constitute a total of seven percent

of the population. While Italy is a unitary state, Article 116 of the constitution grants special

autonomy to five regions which host ethno-linguistic minorities The five autonomous regions

are: Friuli-Venezia Giulia, Trentino-Alto Adige (Südtirol) and Valle d’Aosta in the north, and

Sardinia and Sicily in the south.

The electoral system is closed list proportional at the national level, except that the largest

party or coalition is guaranteed at least 340 seats. In order to ensure representation for

linguistic nationalities in the Chamber of Deputies, a variety of thresholds are applied. The

national electoral threshold for seats in the chamber is ten percent for coalitions, four percent

for single parties, and two percent for any party in a coalition. Parties representing linguistic

minorities in regions with special status win seats if they achieve at least 20 percent of the

Page 86: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

84

votes in their constituency. After having assigned the seats at the national level, the seats won

by each party or coalition are distributed to the constituencies according the votes.127

315 of the senators are directly elected. Four members are appointed by the President. In

addition, former presidents of the Republic may serve ex officio. Elections for senate are

conducted by List PR, except for the autonomous regions that send one senator each from

single-member constituencies. Six seats represent citizens abroad.

The legislative procedure gives the Senate the same powers as the Chamber of Deputies

except for money bills.

3.6.5 Germany

Germany is a federal republic, consisting of 16 states (Länder). The political system is

parliamentary, and the legislature is bicameral. Parliament consists of the principal chamber,

the Parliamentary Assembly (Bundestag) and the Federal Council (Bundesrat), which

represents the sixteen states.

The Bundestag has at least 598 members elected by a Mixed Member Proportional (MMP)

system. 299 of the members are elected by FPTP from as many constituencies, while the rest

are distributed based upon the nationwide result by a proportional distribution of all the 656

members. These ‘top-up’ or compensatory seats are filled from closed lists registered at state

level. The electoral threshold for parties winning compensatory seats is five percent, or a

minimum of one seat in at least three constituencies. This requirement does not apply to lists

submitted by parties representing national minorities (Article 6). National minority parties are

also exempt from the collection of support signatures (Federal Election Law, Articles 6, 20,

27). The seats won at national level are then distributed to party lists suggested at state level

according to the votes.

Germany’s recognized national minorities are Danish, Sorbian, Frisian and Roma/Sinti. The

first three groups have traditionally been concentrated to Schleswig-Holstein, Brandenburg

and Saxony. The Roma/Sinti population is spread all across Germany, many living in larger

cities.128

The waving of threshold for minority lists has no practical implication at the federal

level but it has given representation to parties representing the minorities in state legislatures.

The Bundesrat consists of members from the states and its representatives vote en bloc on a

mandate given by the state governments. The number of votes per state varies between three

and six, depending on the size of the state.

The Bundesrat is subordinate to the Bundestag but legislation that is of special interest to the

federal structure or the states, as defined in the constitution, must be passed there as well.

Such laws are called ‘agreement laws’ (Zustimmungsgesetze)129

, and they include changes to

127

Article 83 of Presidential Decree No. 361 of 1957 as modified by Law of 21 December 2005 No. 270.

128 OSCE/ODIHR 2009b.

129 Laws where the Bundestag may override the Bundesrat are called ’Einspruchsgesetze‘.

Page 87: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

85

the constitution (which require a two-thirds majority in both houses), laws with effect on the

state’s finances, and laws that would affect the organisation or authorities of the states.

3.6.6 Main Findings

There are few quota arrangements in Western Europe. One reason may be that List PR

systems are widespread and such systems tend to represent minorities more efficiently than

first-past-the post systems. Wavering threshold values are used in some countries to make it

easier for parties representing minorities to be represented.

Only Belgium and Cyprus have quota systems that are clearly elements of larger power-

sharing agreements. In Cyprus, the rules are not in force because of the split of the country,

and in Belgium, they have not proven to defer the tension between the French and Dutch

speaking parts of the population, in particular.

Page 88: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

86

4: Case Study Lebanon

4.1 Introduction

Lebanon is a small country, the smallest in the Levant, covering an area of 10 500 sq km and

with a population of about 4.2 million (UN, 2009). Lebanon harbours many characteristics

that are often attributed to Middle Eastern societies in terms of social, cultural and political

patterns. But the ways in which it deviates from these patterns are just as obvious. It is the

most fragmented country in the region with seventeen officially recognised sects sharing

political power in a carefully designed political system on the local, regional and national

levels, but living to a large extent in parallel communities. Throughout its short history as a

sovereign state since World War II, the Republic of Lebanon has experienced periods of

political stability and economic prosperity, but also bitter internal conflicts (including a civil

war) and external interventions and occupation.

The civil war of 1975-1990 was the most devastating, challenging the integrity of the state as

such. It was ended by the National Reconciliation Accord (the Taif Agreement) in October

1989. The question is if this new national agreement sufficiently addresses the critical issues

dividing the Lebanese communities and parties and if the Agreement and the political reform

process as foreseen have been followed up as intended.

A proper analysis of the dynamics of contemporary Lebanese politics and the challenges that

the country faces in building a stable and democratic future requires a deeper look into some

of the contextual aspects defining the Lebanese political discourse, particularly the forces of

regional Middle Eastern politics as well as the unique characteristics of Lebanese inter-

confessional relations. The roots of Lebanon’s predicament are not only to be found in the

conflictual relations within its borders, but as much in the dynamic and often confusing

interplay and changing alliances between local, regional and international actors. If anything

is constant in Lebanese politics, it must be the complexities of its explanatory variables.

4.2 Historical and Political Background

4.2.1 Origins of the Republic of Lebanon

Historically, the overriding challenge of the Lebanese society as a polity in its own right has

been to arrive at a common purpose for the State of Lebanon, a state idea that binds the

communities together and that can serve as the basis on which a national solidarity and thus

stable political institutions can be built. More specifically, in terms of conflict regulation, it is

a question of finding a balance between respecting the quest for group autonomy on the one

hand and national integration on the other, arrangements that can support a sustainable system

of trustful coexistence and power-sharing. Had it been up to the Lebanese themselves, lasting

solutions might have been found long ago. But the challenges are made all the more difficult

and unpredictable because of direct or indirect external intervention – made possible by a

weak central government and weak national defence – that seems to be an inseparable aspect

Page 89: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

87

of Lebanese history. As Malcolm Kerr has noted, “confessional democracy will collapse if

outside pressures make it impossible for politicians to compromise”.130

The balance of centripetal and centrifugal forces is, among other things, linked to the

country’s geographic location and topographic nature as summarised by Pierre Rondot in the

late 1940’s:

A rugged country difficult to access, Lebanon has given refuge to dissidents of all sorts. The

isolation of its peaks and valleys has enabled tribes and religious groups to survive with their

character intact. But the small size of the territory and the need to defend it has compelled these

varied groups to practise solidarity and cooperation […] The opening of the sea has invited

frequent foreign intervention, both for better and worse. On account of its proximity, the Occident

has had a strong influence, […] encourag[ing] the development of education and [the] emergence

of new ideas. Notwithstanding this, tradition has a strong hold on this country. It remains

essentially an alliance of families.131

In his well-known book, Lebanon’s Predicament, on the origins of Lebanon’s civil war,

Samir Khalaf adds to this profile of the country with reference to peasant uprisings in the

nineteenth century and the devastating conflict between Maronites and Druzes in 1860:

This persisting feature of Lebanon’s pluralism reflects, among other things, the deficiency of

secular loyalties, class ties and other civic attachments and the survival of sectarian, communal and

primordial sentiments. One might perhaps argue that had the earlier class conflicts succeeded in

eroding or containing these feudal and communal loyalties, Lebanon might have been spared much

of its subsequent turmoil. It would at least have become more of a nation-state and less of a

precarious mosaic of pluralistic and fragmented communities.132

Until the end of World War I, Lebanon of today was part of the greater Syria region of the

Ottoman Empire (as was Israel, Palestine and Jordan). With the disintegration of the Ottoman

Empire, the Levant became subject to intense rivalries between Great Britain, France, and the

Arabs. The European powers wanted control of these Arab territories of the former Ottoman

Empire for obvious geopolitical reasons, whereas the Arabs demanded independence. In

addition, the Europe-based World Zionist Organisation presented their claim to Palestine

where they wanted to build a state for the Jews through settler colonisation. Great Britain, as

the dominant victor by the end of the war, negotiated separate and inconsistent agreements

with the French, the Arabs and the Zionists, drawing borders, defining spheres of influence

and installing ruling elites. The partition of the region into British- and French-controlled

zones concluded in a secret agreement (the Sykes-Picot Agreement, 1916), and the declared

support of Zionist aspiration in Palestine by the British government in 1917 (the Balfour

Declaration) were not consistent with promises made to the Arabs (Husayn-McMahon

Correspondence 1915-1916) with regards to Arab independence in these territories after the

130

Kerr 1966 in Binder1966, cited in El Khazen 2000:14.

131 Quoted in Hanf 1993:47.

132 Khalaf 1987:23.

Page 90: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

88

war in return for Arab support in the war efforts against the Ottomans in the Arab Middle

East.

Already in the negotiations with the Arabs in 1915-1916, Britain (not wanting to provoke its

French ally) made it clear that territories that more or less comprise today’s Lebanon should

not be included in the future independent Arab territory since France had a special historic

relationship to and interests in this particular area. This provision refers to France’s

longstanding connections with and protection of the Maronites (Christians affiliated with, but

not part of the Roman Catholic Church), which also gave the French a secure bridge-head in

the region. After the war, France accepted Maronite demands for a Maronite-dominated state

and got recognition for a separate mandate for "Greater Lebanon” at San Remo: In order to

have a sufficient territorial basis for an independent and viable state, the borders of the new

state were extended from the original Maronite area in Mount Lebanon – which had enjoyed a

semi-autonomous status within the Ottoman Empire since 1861 – to include new regions in

the south, east and north, thereby including groups with other religious and cultural identities.

Most of these groups did not want to be ruled by a Maronite-dominated state and did not

accept a separate non-Arab Lebanese identity for their country separated from Syria. In this

way, the foundations of some of the most intractable problems of contemporary Lebanese

politics were laid.

The complex issues that surrounded these contentious wartime agreements were dealt with by

the victorious powers first at the Paris Peace Conference in 1919 (which established the

League of Nations) and then at the San Remo Conference in 1920. At San Remo, the League

of Nations established the principle of mandatory government for territories previously under

the rule of the losing powers (the Habsburg and Ottoman Empires), allowing Britain and

France to take over these territories within the framework of international legitimacy. Taking

new colonies by conquest was no longer tenable, as ideas of national self-determination were

gaining international legitimacy after the war. The Arab territories were categorised as ”A”

mandates with reference to article 22 of the Covenant of the League of Nations that provided

the legal source for the mandate system. Under this system, A mandates could provisionally

be recognised as independent nations. But since they, in the language of Article 22, were not

yet able to “stand alone”... “under the strenuous conditions of the modern world”, they needed

the “tutelage” from a Mandatory power in order to achieve independence.133

Mandatory

power was obliged to facilitate transition to independence as soon as circumstances would

allow. Syria (including today’s Lebanon) was allocated to France, whereas Palestine

(including today’s Israel, Palestine and Jordan) and Mesopotamia (Iraq) were allocated to

133

The relevant section of article 22 reads: “Certain communities formerly belonging to the Turkish empire have

reached a stage of development where their existence as independent nations can be provisionally recognized

subject to the rendering of administrative advice and assistance by a Mandatory until such time as they are able

to stand alone.” (Covenant of the League of Nations, 28 June 1919).

Page 91: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

89

Britain. The mandate went into force as a valid arrangement under international law in

September 1923.134

In effect, the mandatory powers Britain and France that, in the inter-war period, ruled these

Middle Eastern countries (today’s Israel/Palestine, Jordan Syria and Iraq, in addition to

Lebanon) had wide powers to establish not only the borders of the new states but also to pick

their leaders and form their systems of government.135

This period thus constitutes the

formative years of these contemporary Middle Eastern states and laid the foundations of many

of the intractable problems and conflicts they still have to cope with.

4.2.2 Constitutional Developments 1926 to Present

In 1926, the French High Commissioner promulgated a constitution for Greater Lebanon

(now renamed “The Republic of Lebanon”) which to a large extent reflected the French

republican and secular state model: A presidential system empowered by a parliament (House

of Deputies) and with an independent judiciary based on the rule of law. This constitution is

still in force today, however with changes and amendments, with the latest enacted in 1990

after the 1975-1989 civil war.

Whereas the constitution since its original adoption has prescribed a clear distinction between

religion and state as its constitutional norm, the mandatory power also had to take the reality

of the Lebanese political landscape into consideration, which for centuries had been deeply

divided along sectarian lines. The constitution consequently also included provisions that in

effect opened for what has become known as the Lebanese confessional system whereby

political rights and duties are ascribed according to religious affiliation. The autonomous

nature of Lebanon’s religious communities – also strongly rooted in the territory’s history –

were recognised in the original constitution, and over the years provisions have been included

whereby leading offices of state and parliamentary seats are distributed according to religious

quotas. The most important amendments were adopted in 1943 when Maronite Christians and

Muslims joined efforts to liberate Lebanon from French mandatory rule, and in 1990, that

ended the devastating civil war which erupted in 1975.

The 1943 amendments came as part of dramatic political events in the autumn leading to the

abolishment of the French mandate, including an unwritten agreement (later known as the

134

Three steps were required to establish a Mandate under international law: (1) The Principal Allied and

Associated Powers confer a mandate on one of their number or on a third power; (2) the principal powers

officially notify the council of the League of Nations that a certain power has been appointed mandatory for such

a certain defined territory; and (3) the council of the League of Nations takes official cognisance of the

appointment of the mandatory power and informs the latter that it [the council] considers it as invested with the

mandate, and at the same time notifies it of the terms of the mandate, after ascertaining whether they are in

conformance with the provisions of the covenant. See http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/League_of_Nations_mandate.

135 Article 90 of the Lebanese constitution stipulated that the mandatory power must preserve its rights and duties

under article 22 of the Charter of the League of Nations and the terms of the mandate. France interpreted such

rights to include the power to suspend the constitution, shut down the House of Deputies, and to dismiss the

Cabinet and the duly elected President. See US Library of Congress, http://www.loc.gov/law/help/lebanon-

constitutional-law.php#f3 accessed 04.03 2011.

Page 92: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

90

‘National Pact’) between the leaders of the two dominant streams of Lebanese politics that

had emerged from the parliamentary elections in August. Beshara al-Khouri represented the

Maronite-dominated Constitutionalists, Riad El-Sohl the Arab nationalists. According to

Raghid El-Sohl’s important study of these events,

...the primary significance of the National Pact was its contribution to the emergence of a

‘democracy by conciliation’ in Lebanon. This system provided both the Muslims and the Maronite

communities, irrespective of their numbers, with a veto power against any major decisions that

either party deemed threatening to its existence or to its basic interests [...] The al-Khouri-Sohl

agreement thus set a precedent and lead to an ad hoc mechanism that was adopted in order to

smooth out the differences among the Lebanese.136

The agreement found overwhelming support in the newly elected parliament, which elected

al-Khoury as President on 21 September. He consequently asked al-Sohl to form a

government. This was followed by a parliamentary decision to amend the constitution, most

significantly by removing all references to the French mandate and the rights and obligations

of the mandatory government. This move was considered by the Free French government to

be illegal and tantamount to a revolution. The French authorities decided to dissolve the

Parliament and ordered the arrest of the President, Prime Minister and other leaders. An acute

constitutional crisis was a fact. Weeks of wide-spread protests in Lebanon, regionally and

internationally (including finally a British ultimatum on 17 November) forced de Gaulle and

his commander-in-chief in the Levant Georges Catroux to reinstate the Lebanese leaders on

22 November, the date consequently to be celebrated as Lebanon’s Independence Day.

This moment of relative national solidarity forged political alliances and set ground rules for

political bargaining, power-sharing and decision-making both within and outside the formal

constitution which has lasted, however modified, to this day. The principles agreed upon,

according to Righis El-Sohl, “...were Lebanon’s independence from France, a close albeit

independent relationship with Syria, and cooperation with the Arab world.”137

Furthermore, the agreement also included a key for distributing senior political and executive

positions in the state was to be based on the 1932 census indicating a Christian majority.

Consequently, the general rule was a 6:5 ratio in the favour of Christians (i.e., in Parliament).

The President of the Republic should be a Maronite Christian, the Prime Minister a Sunni

Muslim and the Speaker of Parliament a Shiite Muslim.

Taken together, these principles and rules define the political framework of modern Lebanon.

But Righid El-Sohl adds an important modification: “... outside the framework provided by

these principles, each side continued to adhere to its own convictions and objections.”138

We

can clearly say, not least with the hindsight of today, that the Republic of Lebanon emerged

more as a de facto federation of religious sects, with separate and deeply divided communities

136

El-Sohl 2004: 208-209.

137 Ibid., p. 208.

138 Ibid.

Page 93: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

91

finding themselves together in a union of convenience and historical necessity, far from the

ideal prescribed by the French republican model.

The principles of the unwritten National Pact of 1943 were in force until the civil war that

broke out in 1975. The civil war had many reasons, one of which was the impact on the

Lebanese society of regional conflicts, first and foremost the Palestine conflict. But it also

brought up to the surface the old identity conflicts among the religious communities in this

fragmented country. The mutual trust symbolised by the National Pact had lost much of its

cohesive power, and all major communities organised their own militias. One underlying

structural problem was the inability of the political system, due to the veto-power of the most

powerful groups, to adjust to changes in the society, including demographic changes. Since

the census in 1932, the Muslims had strengthened their position in the society, both in

numbers and in the economy. But the Christians were blocking all attempts to organise a new

census that could document the relative demographic strength between the communities. And

a change in the 6:5 ratio could not be implemented without the Christians agreeing to it.

Muslims demanded a redistribution of power in the society. The civil war did not in itself

change the political system or the composition of the political elite, but prepared the ground

for modifications of the system in favour of the Muslims.

This change is reflected in the Taif Agreement (the Document of National Accord, 1989) that

ended the civil war, and then in the constitutional law of 1990 that implemented the

constitutional aspects of the Agreement. The 6:5 ratio was changed to 50:50 and the

constitutional prerogatives of the (Christian) President were reduced, strengthening the (Sunni

Muslim) Prime Minister. The total number of seats in Parliament was increased from 99 to

128, 64 seats allocated to Christians (up from 54) and Muslims (up from 45) alike. The most

important constitutional changes can be summarised as follows:

The vesting of the executive power of the State in the Council of Ministers rather than

in the President (Article 17);

The necessity of a two-thirds vote by the Cabinet on all major decisions (Article 65);

The creation of a Constitutional Court (Article 19);

The distribution of the seats of the Parliament (House of Deputies) equally between

Christians and Muslims and proportionally among each of them until such time as the

House of Deputies has enacted an electoral law not on the basis of religious

representation (Article 24);

A provision for the creation of a Senate where all religious communities are to be

represented when the members of House of Deputies are no longer elected on a

confessional basis (not implemented).139

A few other elements of power-sharing were also written into the constitution and will be

discussed later in this chapter.

139

Based on El-Sohl, op.cit., 208-209.

Page 94: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

92

It is noteworthy that the constitution in its present form retains the aim of abolishing the

confession-based system on the one hand, whereas on the other hand, it strengthens and

further institutionalises the autonomy of the religious communities as stakeholders in the

political system. What is presented in the Lebanese constitution as transitional provisions,

seem in effect to have become its core characteristics. More than anything, this reflects the

necessity felt by the Lebanese parties – if the state of Lebanon is not to collapse – of finding a

way of co-existing until the underlying conditions preventing the formation of a unified

nation-state have been solved. The problem of escaping this omnipresent dilemma in a

practical sense is reflected in the fact that the Taif Agreement included a decision to set up a

high-level commission to work out a roadmap for abolishing the confessional system, but that

twenty years have since elapsed without any significant effects of that decision.140

4.2.3 Changing Political Alliances in Contemporary Lebanon

The Lebanese society today is as fragmented as ever, and tensions over the relationship with

Syria continues to be a major dimension in this larger picture. However, since Taif, there has

been an important shift in the internal balance of power with the Shi’a community,

traditionally the underdog in Lebanese politics, ascending as more and more influential. This

is arguably not only because of its relative demographic growth, but more importantly

because of the organisational and military strength of the Hizbollah and (to lesser extent)

Amal movements. Hizbollah has taken over the ‘state-in-the-state’ position that the PLO had

established in the 1970’s until the Israeli invasion in 1982. Whereas the PLO was basically an

alien element operating on behalf of refugees struggling for the return to their neighbouring

native Palestine, Hizbollah is a militant Lebanese movement not only struggling against the

Israelis (which has won them enormous popularity both in Lebanon and in the wider Arab and

Muslim world), but also for what they consider to be a fair share of influence for the Shi’as in

Lebanese politics. In both these endeavours, Hizbollah has been greatly helped by a close

alliance with and material support from Syria and Iran. Hizbollah is today considered to be

the single most powerful force in Lebanon, stronger even than the Lebanese army.

The rise of Hizbollah over the last twenty years has changed the dynamics of Lebanese

politics, particularly since 1990 when Sayyad Hassan Nasrallah became the leader and the

140

The relevant Section G under Political Reforms reads: “Abolishing political sectarianism is a fundamental

national objective. To achieve it, it is required that efforts be made in accordance with a phased plan. The

Chamber [House] of Deputies elected on the basis of equal sharing by Christians and Muslims shall adopt the

proper measures to achieve this objective and to form a national council which is headed by the president of the

republic and which includes, in addition to the prime minister and the Chamber [House] of Deputies speaker,

political, intellectual, and social notables. The council's task will be to examine and propose the means capable

of abolishing sectarianism, to present them to the Chamber of Deputies and the cabinet, and to observe

implementation of the phased plan. The following shall be done in the interim period:

a. Abolish the sectarian representation base and rely on capability and specialization in public jobs, the judiciary,

the military, security, public, and joint institutions, and in the independent agencies in accordance with the

dictates of national accord, excluding the top-level jobs and equivalent jobs which shall be shared equally by

Christians and Muslims without allocating any particular job to any sect.

b. Abolish the mention of sect and denomination on the identity card.” English translation from Council of

Lebanese-American Organizations, Policy Statement and Analysis of the Lebanese Situation, July 1991

Page 95: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

93

movement decided to participate in Lebanese politics as a regular political party. Until then,

Amal had been the most influential political movement representing the Shi’as. The focus has

gradually changed from the Christian/Muslim divide to the Sunni/Shi’a divide, also reflecting

developments in the wider region after the Shi’a revolution in Iran in 1979 and the Gulf wars,

which started with the Iraq-Iran War in 1980. A defining moment in this development was the

assassination of Rafik al-Hariri, Lebanon’s Sunni Muslim Prime Minister 14 February 2005

in a spectacular bomb attack in the city centre of Beirut, an attack that also killed twenty

others. Syria, possibly with the help of Hizbollah (or the other way around) was widely

believed to be responsible for the attack, also among the Sunnis.141

The assassination

unleashed a massive mobilisation of Lebanese for and against Hariri’s anti-Syrian/pro-

Western agenda (focusing on the demand for Syrian withdrawal from Lebanon), culminating

with two huge demonstrations in Beirut; a pro-Syrian demonstration lead by Hizbollah on 8th

March and an anti-Syrian demonstration with Saad Hariri (the son of Rafik) in the front on

14th

March (often referred to as the ‘Cedar Revolution’), exactly one month to the day after

the assassination.

The parties and groups that participated in the two sides have consequently formed the two

main contemporary party blocks in Lebanese politics, known as the March 8 Alliance and the

March 14 Alliance. Interestingly, this divide does not seem to follow basically sectarian

lines, but rather, it resembles the old cleavage between the 'Western-oriented’ and ‘Eastern-

oriented’ Lebanese. Historically, this cleavage roughly overlapped with the Muslim/Christian

divide; today this is mostly a Muslim/Muslim divide that follows a regional geopolitical

pattern (Egypt-Saudi-Arabia vs. Iran-Syria as the two poles). The geo-political divide seems

to dominate the sectarian divide. At the same time, there are overlaps that complicate the

picture: The general pattern in Lebanon is that almost all Shi’as support the March 8 Alliance,

most Sunnis support the March 14 Alliance, whereas Maronites and other Christians are

distributed on both sides of the divide.142

The tensions between the two main blocks escalated in the following years with a peak

between December 2006 and May 2008. The immediate background was the 34-day war

between Israel and Hizbollah paramilitary forces in June-July 2006 after Hizbollah had killed

three and captured two Israeli soldiers. More than 1100 Lebanese, the majority of whom were

civilians, were killed in the Israeli war of retaliation, which also caused massive destructions

141

A UN Tribunal was set up to investigate the assassination, but at the time of writing its final conclusion has

not yet been revealed. This is an extremely contentious issue in contemporary Lebanese politics. Many fear that

it might trigger renewed violence.

142 The three most important parties of the March 8 Alliance (57 seats in the 2009 elections) is the Hizbollah (12

seats), Amal (also a Shi’a Muslim party lead by Nabih Berri, Speaker of Parliament, 13 seats), and the Free

Patriotic Movement lead by Michel Aoun, a former general who presently leads the largest faction of Christian

deputies (18 seats) in the Parliament. Aoun joined the Alliance in 2006. The main parties of the 14 March

Alliance is the Future Movement (Sunni-dominated, 26 seats) and 14th

March Independents (Christians, 13

seats). The Druz-dominated Progressive Socialist Party lead by Walid Jumblat (11 seats) was originally part of

this Alliance, but change side in January 2011, tipping the parliamentary majority in favour of the March 8

Alliance.

Page 96: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

94

of Lebanese infrastructure. Israel did not, however, reach its major war aims and was heavily

criticised internationally for disproportional use of force. Hizbollah claimed victory, increased

its popularity immensely and emerged as a more dominant political force in Lebanon. Its

principle demand was that the 8 March Alliance should have at least one third of the members

in a national unity government, securing an effective veto power for the opposition. In

November, all Shi’a and one Orthodox Christian member of the government resigned in

support of this demand, followed by huge demonstrations and large sit-ins in downtown

Beirut that lasted for weeks.

This standoff lasted for about 17 months until the government on 7 May 2008 decided to shut

down Hizbollah’s internal communication network. Hizbollah’s answer was to occupy large

parts of Beirut, including areas controlled by pro-government groups. They met little

resistance and handed the area over to the Lebanese Army on 14 May when the government

had revoked its decision. The crisis was brought to an end on 21 May with the Doha

Agreement, a document that concluded the Lebanese National Dialogue Conference arranged

by the Emir of Qatar. The Doha Agreement gave the opposition one-third plus one minister

(11 of 30) in the government of national unity and the parties pledged to elect Michel

Suleiman, the respected head of the armed forces, to the vacant post as President – a pledge

that was confirmed by the Parliament shortly afterwards.143

The opposition ended its months

of sit-in; Lebanon returned to relative normalcy, which allowed them to start preparing for the

2009 elections.

4.3 Building Democracy in Lebanon.

4.3.1 Introduction

The building of trust and national solidarity in Lebanon is immensely complicated by

underlying suspicions of foreign agency that are always present, particularly in times of

political tension. A certain pattern of political dynamics seems to result from this basic

condition: If actor A has reason to believe that actor B to some degree is influenced or even

controlled by external power X, actor A will be motivated to seek guarantees from external

power Y or any other available external power in order to counter the advantages acquired by

actor B – a move that will further motivate actor B to strengthen its relation with X in order

not to lose relative power or to be dominated by actor A. And so on.

In this way, parties easily get trapped in what is known as the 'Prisoner’s Dilemma’,

preventing rational parties that follow their preferences to choose a cooperative strategy. The

mistrust prevents the parties from coordinating their positions in a way that could produce a

win-win outcome. This pattern of self-sustained or reinforced suspicion and fragmentation has

the potential to tear the country apart politically, but is at the same time counterbalanced by

such factors as shared economic interests, changing bases of tactical or strategic alliances, and

the sheer necessity of finding practical solutions to common challenges (i.e., building the

143

General Suleiman was the only candidate acceptable to all factions. However, the election of Suleiman was,

strictly speaking, unconstitutional. According to Article 49, a high-ranking person must be out of office for two

years before he or she can be elected president.

Page 97: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

95

physical infrastructure in the country). The question is whether the political institutions,

notably the electoral system, can contribute to making it easier for the parties to overcome

mutual suspicion and mistrust.

4.3.2 The Challenge of Confessionalism

The general question that will be discussed in this section relates to basic challenges of

building a stable and democratic future in Lebanon. We can distinguish between two

approaches: Should the socio-cultural fragmentation of the country’s political institutions

(organised along sectarian cleavages and known as ‘confessionalism’) be considered as a

given – and consequently an organising principle for any future political system in Lebanon,

or should it be considered as an transitional stage on the road to a more integrated system

whereby the sects no longer constitute a dominating cornerstone of the system, in line with

the visions of the Lebanese constitution with the aim of overcoming confessionalism?

The choice between these two approaches reflects alternative normative conceptions of

democratic development in divided societies; one which holds that a democratic approach

requires a system that respects established socio-cultural identities and that provides

institutional mechanisms for preserving these identities as building blocks of the political

system, as opposed to the ‘nation-building’ (or ‘modernisation’) approach, seeking

mechanisms that facilitate the gradual assimilation of fragmented socio-cultural identities in

the formation of a new, overriding national political culture. More specifically, in the context

of the present study, we can ask: How should the electoral system be designed on the basis of

such different conceptions of Lebanon as a polity in order to meet universal requirements of a

democratic political process?

These questions are not new, but have been central to the political and academic discourses on

the future of Lebanon at least since the outbreak of the civil war in 1975. Recent

developments in the period 2005-2011 have also been dramatic, including the assassination of

Prime Minister Rafiq Hariri and the Syrian withdrawal of troops (2005), the war with Israel

(2006), the United Nations Security Council Resolution 1757 (2007) establishing the Special

Tribunal investigating the Hariri assassination, the high tensions and clashes between

opposing internal political coalitions (particularly in 2007-2008), elections in 2009, and the

collapse of the Saad Hariri government in January 2011. To what extent have these events

influenced the underlying political discourse on the Lebanon of tomorrow?

According to the first approach mentioned above, the political system and the elected bodies

should reflect as accurately as possible existing political loyalties and interests, often deeply

rooted in local history – not a utopian vision of a society that does not reflect the real nature

of inter-group relations in contemporary Lebanon – and thus contribute to making identifiable

and distinct political entities and parliamentary groups as a sound basis for negotiations on

power-sharing arrangements between the country’s constituent groups. This will be the best

guarantee for strengthening the democratic powers of the Parliament and thus for building a

system of democratic co-existence in Lebanon. The other view would be that elections

should contribute to create cross-sectarian alliances that could contribute to undermining

sectarian political identities and building a unified democratic citizenship. This would provide

Page 98: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

96

the foundations for political loyalties based more on political-ideological cleavages (i.e.,

left/right) and thus, create a political culture suited for a real competition between alternative

policies.

Both of these views on Lebanon’s way forward find support in well-established trends in

academic and ideological (or a combination of both) schools. The most common approach (in

line with the second view above) is a variation of the ‘modernisation theories’ that analyse the

path of societies from a ‘traditional’ to a ‘modern’ level of political development.

‘Modernisation’ involves a dynamic process of social, cultural and political integration,

creating a modern nation-state of the Western European type. It finds its most articulated and

ideological expression in the Jacobinism or republican patriotism of the French model.

Cultural distinctions and cleavages should not be of any significance in political mobilisation

and organisation of the state. The republic should stay ’une et indivisible’.144

Michael Hudson has contributed some of the most influential analyses of political

development in Lebanon from the theoretical perspective of modernisation and social

mobilisation, particularly in his early book The Precarious Republic.145

Hudson is fascinated

by the observation that Lebanon seems to present a ‘deviant’ case defying categorisation

within the modernisation paradigm: On the one hand, it displays some characteristics of

modernisation, particularly in the economic sphere and in its exposure to cultural modernity,

whereas progressive changes in the spheres of socio-cultural (family-based communities) and

political (confessionalism) relations, as would be expected, lag behind: “The Lebanese

experience illustrates both the surprising possibilities for modernisation in a deeply divided

political culture and the strains that such a process imposes on the political system.”146

In

Hudson’s view, this creates a political dilemma and a dysfunctional political system

accentuated by the lack of adequate institutions able to deal effectively with internal and

external problems.

Farid El Khazen, Theodor Hanf and others represent an alternative approach to Lebanese

politics. El Khazen accepts that the modernisation approach of Hudson and others helps to

detect the flaws in the Lebanese system, but not to explain the causes:

Missing in Hudson’s assessment of the performance of Lebanon’s political system is the historical

dimension that has shaped the particular socio-political features of Lebanese society. In fact, of all

modern states in the Middle East, Lebanon is the most rooted in history both in its communal and

regional dimensions. The historical nucleus of the modern Lebanese state, namely, the Imarah of

Mount Lebanon and, after 1861, the mutasarrifiyya arrangement, emerged as a result of a complex

144

Hanf 1993:28.

145 Hudson 1968. The modernisation approach to Lebanese politics was introduced by Daniel Lerner in his The

Passing of Traditional Society. Modernizing in the Middle East (1958), another important work was Politics in

Lebanon, edited by Leonard Binder (1966). In his …Arab Politics. The Search for Legitimacy ….. Hudson

presents a systematic analysis of political development in the Arab world, which has survived as a much-used

textbook in spite its many critics.

146 Hudson 1968:4, quoted in El Khazen 2000:16.

Page 99: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

97

interplay between internal and external change. In this way, confessionalism could not be regarded

simply as an irresponsible act on the part of the Lebanese elite. Nor was parochialism something

that could be reversed by state decrees or by the forces of modernisation.147

In line with authors like Arend Lijphart and David and Audrey Smock, El Khazen argues that

one should consider the positive and constructive potentialities of the confessional nature of

Lebanese politics as a point of departure for democratic developments: “A closer look at

Lebanon’s history and political system reveals that the abolition of the confessional system

would have undermined the very basis of democracy in the country. For confessionalism is in

effect a de facto recognition of diversity and dissent, the two conditions necessary for the

establishment of democratic order, particularly in a divided society.”148

Antoine Messara –

another Lebanese academic and presently member of Lebanon’s newly appointed

Constitutional Council – supports this point in an earlier article by observing that the

unicameral Lebanese Parliament does not seem to be the appropriate place for negotiating

policies of accommodation between Lebanon’s communities. “The power of compromise”, as

he calls it, is held by elites that are the leading representatives of these communities and that

meet in arenas outside the parliament where the real bargaining takes place: “Hence, they

leave it to Parliament to ratify what they decide.”149

The point here with relevance to the electoral system is that the Parliament is not regarded as

truly representing the immediate and conflicting political cleavages in the society because the

candidates are voted in on lists composed of persons from different confessional groups.

Voters will therefore have to give their votes not only to members of their own confessional

group, but also to representatives of other groups from the electoral district. For example, a

Christian member of Parliament who was voted in with Moslem votes will in certain

situations not be considered by the Christian electorate as genuinely representing them and

could therefore not be trusted with “the power of compromise”. Another intended effect of

the system is that it strengthens the chances of moderate candidates because they will be more

likely to get votes from the other communities. However, this is only in such cases where a

confessional group represents a minority. If one group is dominant, extremist candidates may

fare well. The fact that the system promotes multi confessional alliances may, in itself,

promote moderation. Messara comments:

147

El Kazen 2000:21. Faris 1982:7-8 explains that the Lebanese political system originates in the Imarah of

Mount Lebanon, an arrangement whereby the conquering Ottomans in the early sixteenth century conferred the

title of ”Sultan of the Mountain” on the Ma’ni Amir, Fakhr al-Din I, and allowed him to become the first among

equals in relation to other feudal Maronite and Druze feudal lords in the southern region of Mount Lebanon. This

system, which was basically secular in nature, survived for more than three centuries, was replaced in 1861 by

the Mutasarriffiyya following violent conflicts between Maronites and Druzes. This system, agreed upon

between five European powers and the Ottomans, introduced confessionalism as a system of political

representation, later inherited by the Republic of Lebanon.

148 El Khazen 2000:24. Cfr. Lijphart 1977; Smock and Smopck 1975.

149 Messara 1988:625-626.

Page 100: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

98

However, this moderation, within the framework of the single electoral college, is purely tactical

and is often exploited by candidates to get the votes of other communities. The fact that the

representatives of communities, and even the most extremist ones, are excluded from

representation may impede conflict regulation.150

Messara’s solution to this dilemma is that the unicameral parliamentary system should be

reformed with the introduction of “a communal senate or a communal council where

communities are represented as such. Hence, in crisis periods or when dealing with basic

issues, the debate would not be transferred from the Parliament to the ‘street’”.151

Many Lebanese who share this basic approach of ‘unity in diversity’ to the country’s need for

conflict regulation and stability point to Switzerland and its ’Konkordanzdemokratie’ as a

model for Lebanon: A federation of communities that constitute a transcending, multifarious

nation.152

The core idea of this approach is that existing communities are legitimate building

bricks of a transcending nation.153

Existing communities will not disappear; making them

disappear is morally unacceptable and will create resistance that undermines peace and

stability. The Lebanese nation, which is not pre-determined, but is organically transcendent as

the different groups, parties and actors that comprise the Lebanese society interact in the day-

to-day life.

It is worth pointing out, however, that the Lebanese Constitution, first issued in 1926, as well

as the National Reconciliation Accord of 1989 (the Taif Agreement) state that the goal and

vision for Lebanon is a political system not based on confessionalism. Consequently, there is

an ongoing discourse in Lebanon on the relationship between the vision of Lebanon as a

secular nation-state and the reality of contemporary Lebanon as a fragmented republic.

Two related aspects that contribute to keep a country like Lebanon fragmented and

undermining efforts of national integration should be kept in mind. One is a weak central

government, a direct effect of a fragmented political system where important decisions have

to be made on the basis of consensus. The state as such is (in principle) neutral in relation to

inter-group rivalries and does not interfere much in the daily life of the semi-autonomous

communities of Lebanon. Indeed, "the secret of the [Lebanese political] system’s precarious

survival is its very institutional weakness".154

But, at the same time, the state does not have

sufficient monopoly of power to impose incorporation of different groups under a common

institutional framework or to set up powerful mechanisms for inter-group arbitration. This

weakness is difficult to get around as long as the President, the Prime Minister and the

Speaker of Parliament are carefully chosen from and thus considered as representatives of

particular groups, not primarily as authoritative representatives of the Lebanese state.

150

Messara 1988:629.

151 Ibid.

152 See Hanf 1993:29.

153 However, since the communities in Lebanon are so geographically mixed, this cannot be applied in the simple

geographical manner as in Switzerland. 154

El Khazen 2000:16 with reference to Hudson 1968:211.

Page 101: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

99

The other aspect is ‘the politics of fear’, characteristic of ‘anarchical’ societies lacking or

saddled with a weak central government or regime (i.e., the international society and failed

states). According to Hanf, the behaviour of most groups and states in the Levant is basically

motivated by fear: “For, in reality, the loss of [one’s position] means subjugation, expulsion,

life in refugee camps or emigration – if not physical annihilation. The fear of being the

ultimate loser is the supreme force in politics in the countries along the road to Jerusalem.”155

In Lebanon, nobody in a situation of violent conflict can trust the state to come to the rescue

or guarantee basic rights. The individual citizen depends totally on the family, the clan, the

sect, whereas the larger groups depend on relations and alliances with other groups or external

powers. Hanf also points to the fact that existence in such an environment might not only

breed extremism, hate and irrationality, but might as easily induce parties to behave extremely

rationally and responsible, considering all available alternatives, including compromise with

arch-enemies, in order to secure their own interests of a more or less existential nature. This

might be the logic behind the drastic changes in political orientation or alliances that can be

observed from time to time in Lebanese politics. As Hanf puts it: ”…fear can indeed produce

a vicious circle of hate and violence, but also reason and compromise – that conflict can bring

forth coexistence.”156

4.4 The Quota Arrangements and Other Power-Sharing Elements

4.4.1 Introduction

As already discussed, the current Constitution of Lebanon adopted in 1926 has undergone

important amendments. Up till 1947, the Parliament had two chambers, the Chamber of

Deputies and the Senate. Since then the parliament has been unicameral. The Taif Agreement

of 1989, which ended the civil war, represents a starting point for the current discourse on

constitutional reforms and changes in the electoral system.

The Taif Agreement stated that “Parliamentary elections shall be conducted in accordance

with a new election law based on the Governorate (Mohafazah) and which considers the

principles that guarantee cohabitation among Lebanese and which insures the accuracy of

political representation of the various categories of people and their generations and the

effectiveness of such representation, after the reconsideration of administrative divisions

within the framework of the unity of land, people and institutions”.

The new formula for representing confessions in the transition period was implemented, but

the main intentions of the Taif Agreement were never pursued.

A National Committee for Drafting the Electoral Law, headed by former Minister Fouad

Boutros, proposed a draft election law in 2006 which took some steps in the direction of

promoting multi-confessional parties and normalising political institutions, even though it

kept a detailed confessional formula in its proposals. The committee introduced an element

of proportional elections in parallel with a plurality-based system in multi-member

155

Hanf 1993:2.

156 Hanf 1993:5.

Page 102: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

100

constituencies (block vote) with constituencies based on the Qadas. The draft was never put

on the Parliamentary table before the Israeli attack in 2006 and the following crisis in

Lebanon in 2008.

After the events of the spring of 2008, the Lebanese National Dialogue Conference was held

in Doha from 16 to 21 May 2008 with strong coordination by the Arab League and with

participation of Lebanese political leaders. The Conference resulted in an agreement (the

Doha Agreement) where all parties voiced their commitment to the principles of the Lebanese

Constitution and the Taif Accord.

The Doha Agreement did not shift to a system based on governorates, but made some

adjustments to the Qada based-constituencies of the Boutros Commission proposal, which

would give more confessional homogeneous constituencies. It was implied that the block

vote system would remain the only system, even though the agreement stated that “The

parties also agree on forwarding to the Lebanese Parliament the electoral reforms that were

proposed by the National Committee for Drafting the Electoral Law, headed by former

Minister Fouad Boutros.”

The Administration and Justice Committee of the Parliament (AJC) drafted a new election

law based upon the Boutros draft but without the proportional element and without an

independent election commission (except for a Supervisory Commission on campaign and

finance issues). The law was adopted in Parliament on 29 September 2008, and the

Parliament had then also removed some of the other reform elements of the AJC draft such as

pre-printed ballot papers.

In 2011, the Ministry of Internal Affairs has taken an initiative for election reform. The most

likely change is that the block vote is replaced by a List PR system in multimember

constituencies.

4.4.2 The Administrative and Confessional Division of Lebanon

Lebanon is divided in 6 governorates (Mohafazah) and 26 Qadas (counting Beirut as one). In

addition there are more than 900 municipalities.

The six Muhafazah are: 1. Beirut, 2. Mount Lebanon (Jabal Lubnan), 3. North Lebanon (El

Shmal), 4. Bekaa, 5. South Lebanon (El Jnoub), and 6. Nabatiyyeh.

The Qadas are:

Beirut: No subdivision.

The North (7): Batroun , Minnieh-Dinneih, Koura , Bcharreh, Zgharta, Tripoli, and Akkar.

Mount Lebanon (6): Maten, Jbeil, Kesrwan, Aley, Baabda, and Chouf.

The Bekaa (5): Baalbeck, Hermel, Zahle, West Bekaa, Rachaya.

The South (3): Tyre , Saida, and Jezzine.

Page 103: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

101

Nabatiyyeh (4): Nabtieh, Bint Jbeil, Hasbaya, and Marjeyoun.

In electoral terms the following groups are currently given specific seats in the parliament:

Muslims: Sunni, Shi’a, Druze and Alawi.

Christians: Maronite, Greek Catholic, Greek Orthodox, Evangelical, Armenian Catholic,

Armenian Orthodox and Christian Minorities.

4.4.3 Summary of the Systems From 2000 to 2008

The following presents a comparison between the systems from 2000 onwards, including the

proposal of the 2006 Boutros Commission. Before 2000, the block vote system was used but

the constituencies were changed for almost every election. The 2000 and the 2008 laws are

also based upon the block vote combined with an extensive use of confessional quotas. It is

predefined exactly how many members of the Parliament should belong to which confession

for each district, leaving no room for deviation. That means that a person may only run in

constituencies with seats marked for his or her confession.

The Boutros Commission proposed a parallel system where two races were to be conducted

simultaneously. Still, the confessions were given detailed quotas, and for the PR system, the

six constituencies were broken further down into Qadas, where the confessional quotas were

applied.

Such extensive and detailed applications of quotas may satisfy the parties in their negotiation

over powers, but they do reduce the influence of the voters considerably. We will discuss that

later.

Even though the Christians are guaranteed 50 percent in the Parliament, the system where

everybody votes for all groups makes it possible for a Muslim majority to decide who is going

to represent the Christians from a constituency. This was the background for the redrafting of

constituencies for the 2009 elections.

Page 104: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

102

The table shows the main features of the three systems discussed.

The law 2000 The 2006 Boutros

Commission

2008

Block vote element

Number of elected

members

128 77 128

Number of

constituencies

14 27 27

Magnitude of

constituencies

6 - 17 1 - 6 1 - 10

PR element

Number of elected

members

- 51 -

Number of

constituencies

- 6 -

Magnitude of

constituencies

- 6 - 11 -

4.4.4 The System of 2000

In the 2000 law, as in previous election laws, the block vote system was applied. In general

terms, this is to a large extent a winner-takes-all system. The number of constituencies was

fourteen and each constituency had from six to seventeen seats.

The quotas for the sects were broken down by Qadas in such a way that for each Qada there

was a predefined number of seats to be filled and they were allocated to sects. This system

had the effect that alliances across confessional lines were established, at least for tactical

purposes.

The alliances printed their lists and handed them out to voters who were allowed to use them

as ballots. There were no pre-printed ballots. One of the general justifications of the block

vote system is that it provides a lot of choice for the voters. The voters elect the candidates

across party lines directly, as opposed to leaving it to the parties to select the candidates.

With the lists printed by the coalitions, the largest coalition has an even bigger advantage than

normally with the system. A side effect is that the largest group in a fairly big constituency

would also decide who should represent a minority confessional group in the Qada (which is a

smaller unit), regardless of the votes in that particular Qada. If, for example, there was a

Page 105: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

103

Muslim majority in a constituency, they would link up with Christian groups to be able to fill

all the seats of the constituency. However, those candidates might not be persons whom the

groups themselves would feel best represented by, but the coalition of the largest group would

still be likely to fill also such minority seats.

4.4.5 The Boutros Proposal

The draft law of the Boutros Commission tried to meet requirements for creating a

representative composition of the Parliament along three dimensions: the political, the

confessional and the geographical. In the proposal, the political dimension was the weakest

of the three.

Out of the two common types of ‘mixed systems’ commonly used, the commission proposed

a parallel system. The two elements were a List PR system and a plurality system in multi-

member consistencies (block vote). The parallel system 157

is well accepted to be within

international standards. However, the plurality segment of the parallel system would

normally be in single-member constituency, not the block vote system.

In the draft, 77 seats were to be filled from 27 districts by the block vote system and 51 seats

were elected from six districts within a List PR system.

The List PR element would not make the Parliament proportional, but it would help organise

groups of a moderate size to win seats in the Parliament. In the six districts, the magnitude

varied from six to eleven seats with an average of 8.5, which would allow lists with down to 8

to 15 percent support to win seats. Most countries with a parallel system would run the List

PR part in the whole country as one district and applied to Lebanese parties with down to 2

percent support would win seats.

The proposal included confessional quotas applied to each district, and the quotas were

broken down by the smaller Qadas.

The way the proportional part was described there would have been a bias in favour of the

biggest parties when it comes to which parties will have the best chance to get their most

important candidates elected. This could easily have been corrected by the method described

in Appendix A.

4.4.6 The Adopted 2008 system

The system adopted on 29 September 2008 for the 2009 parliamentary elections is closer to

the 2000 law than to the Boutros suggestion. The Doha Agreement gave a direction and also

specified that the constituencies should build on (but not be exactly the same as) the Qadas.

That means that there are 27 constituencies and each seat is again allocated to a confessional

group. By reducing the size of the constituencies, the winner-takes-all effect of the block vote

system is reduced. It is also not the majority of a large constituency who decides the result in

157

The parallel system is often a compromise between those favouring a plurality system and those favouring a

proportional system whereas the other mixed system, the multi-member proportional system, combines the

qualities of single-member constituencies and proportional representation.

Page 106: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

104

a Qada, but the majority of that Qada. However, within the Qada, the majority will decide

over the minority, but the scale of the problem is reduced.

The coalitions are still allowed to print their own ballot papers and this limits the influence of

the voters and strengthens the winner-takes-all of the system.

4.4.7 An Attempt for Reform of the Municipal Electoral System in 2010

When the reform of the system of representation for parliamentary elections fell in 2007,

some groups of the civil society (LADE) took the initiative to reform the system for the

municipal council. The next elections were scheduled for May 2010 and the main idea was to

introduce some elements of proportional elections in addition to other reforms, such as an

independent electoral commission, quotas for women, pre-printed ballot papers, etc. One

purpose was to make the parties and voters familiar with a List PR system and to bring the

administrative parts of the municipal elections in line with the new parliamentary election

law.

A draft law was proposed by the Minister of Interior that included a system based upon List

PR but with a provision that municipal councils would always have a one-party majority. The

mayor and deputy mayor would be the first two candidate names of the list with the highest

number of votes.

The Cabinet approved the proposal but it never came to a vote in Parliament. The elections in

May 2010 were therefore held according to the old election law under a block vote system.

4.4.8 The Executive and the Decision-Making Procedures

In addition to constitutional changes already mentioned, the Taif Agreement introduced a

number of other elements of power-sharing in the agreement. These are in turn written into

the Constitution. The following is a summary of those agreements.

The President of the Republic, the Prime Minister and the Speaker of the Parliament are the

three key positions in the country’s political system (the three presidents). There are unwritten

rules on their election and appointment, but there are also formal rules underlining the need

for consensus in their appointments.

The President is to nominate the Prime Minister in consultation with the speaker “based on

binding parliamentary consultations which he officially communicates to the Speaker”. The

Council of Ministers (government) “takes its decisions by consensus, and in the absence of

consensus, they are taken by voting”. Decisions are taken by simple majority of the

attendants, except Major Issues that require the consent of two-thirds of the Council's

members. The following subjects are considered Major Issues: The state of emergency and

lifting it; war and peace; general mobilisation; international treaties and agreements; the

national budget of the State; comprehensive development and long range plans; appointment

of the employees of the first category and its equivalent; reconsideration of administrative

divisions; the dissolution of Parliament; elections law; naturalization law; personal statute

laws; the dismissal of ministers. The type of issues needing a two-thirds majority in the

government is, in other words, fairly wide.

Page 107: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

105

The President is elected by a two-thirds majority in the Parliament but, should the first

attempt fail, the next only requires an absolute majority.

In Parliament, most decisions may be taken by regular (not qualified) majority and the

government needs only a regular majority for the confidence vote.

Despite these formal rules, electing the President and forming the government have proven

problematic. The unwritten rules have been to require broad consensus on the election of

President and the government has been a national unity government where both the majority

block as well as the opposition are represented.

After the events of 2008 the Doha Agreement of 21 May 2008 stated:

First: The parties have agreed on having the Lebanese parliament speaker, based on the rules in effect,

invite the parliament to convene within 24 hours to elect consensus candidate General Michel

Suleiman, knowing that this is the best constitutional method to elect the president under these

exceptional circumstances.

Second: forming a national unity government composed of 30 ministers distributed among the

majority (16 ministers), the opposition (11 ministers) and the president (3 ministers), and by virtue of

this agreement, all parties commit not to resign or obstruct the government’s actions.

The appointments were part of a broad agreement and this was also carried forward to the

time after the 2009 election.

In addition to these rules, it is also understood that the three ‘presidents’ should come from

different confessional groups. The President is a Christian, the Prime Minister is a Sunni and

the Speaker is a Shi’a.

4.4.9 The Intentions and Possible Effects

The Taif Agreement has a short-term and a long-term perspective. The short-term need was

to stop the civil war. Even though there have been armed conflicts in Lebanon after the civil

war, they have been of a different nature and they were contained after a short time. One of

the element of the short-term arrangement was the 50 – 50 percent balance between Muslims

and Christians in the Parliament and there are unwritten rules which prescribe a broad

national government based upon consensus or near-consensus decisions. All these

arrangements are intended to ensure that no group is left out of the decision-making and that

the balance between the Christians, the Sunnis and the Shi’as is maintained.

The system has two types of side effects. Firstly, the system restricts the right to stand for

elections to Muslims and Christians. Traditionally, all people of Lebanon belong to a sect by

birth and it is not a belonging which can be changed. However, naturalised citizens may

belong to other groups and one may also see a future development where the sects would play

a less prominent role. The numbers of people disenfranchised by the rule is low at the

moment but nevertheless, the rule is in violation of the International Covenant on Civil and

Political Rights Article 25 b (the right to vote and be elected), which was ratified by Lebanon

Page 108: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

106

in 1972. It should be noted that the limitation is extended to the government members as

well.

The other types of side effects are the ones concerning the efficiency and the functioning of

the state. The requirements for national unity governments have made the forming of

government very complicated. After the June 2009 elections, it took five months.

Appointments to key civil servant positions (of the first category) have proven to be very

difficult because the sectarian formula has been seen as an overriding principle. In regular

policy matters, it is also difficult to reach consensus or a sufficient majority to pass decisions

in government.

4.5 The Field Study

4.5.1 The Conflict

There was a general agreement among the respondents that the conflict in Lebanon can only

be understood if seen in a larger regional context. But there were different and partly

opposing views on how regional powers interacted with and influenced Lebanese politics.

One of the respondents gave this answer: “There are two basic dimensions to the Lebanese

conflict: Internal confessionalism and external interference. The two dimensions are closely

interlinked because the confessional groups are dependent on external supporters and

sponsors and external players struggle for regional dominance through internal confessional

groups.”

As expected, the view on Syria’s role in Lebanon is highly contentious, dividing the two main

electoral alliances, 8 March and 14 March, as well as our respondents. In one answer, Syria’s

role was described as overriding any internal Lebanese agreement: “In Taif the power sharing

was important, but that was not what ended the war. Many Lebanese opposed the Taif

Agreement because of the reduced sovereignty under Syrian pressure. The Syrian army

controlled the whole territory. That is what ended the civil war, and Syrians ruled til 2005.”

Some respondents emphasised the significance of the Palestine conflict, both historically

(Palestinian refugees since 1948 and the “watershed events” of the 1967 war), and more

recently with Hizbollah as a major opponent of Israel in the regional power struggle that also

brings in Iran. One respondent gave this explanation: “As a consequence of the 1967 war,

Lebanon became weakened, the weakest of the states in the region. With the emergence of

PLO came an armed non-state actor which was in war with Israel. There was no empty space

left for the Palestinians. PLO was bound to clash with the Lebanese state as it had done in

Jordan in the 1970s. The Lebanese army was paralysed and the PLO created an autonomous

space for itself. PLO got into fights with the Christians, then the Shi’as and in 1982 the

Israelis.”

An important change over time was emphasised as the traditional Christian-Muslim cleavage

that used to be the dominant dimension of the conflict is, to a large extent, replaced by the

Sunni-Shi’a dimension – partly because of the gradual demographic strengthening of the

Shi’a population and partly because of regional dynamics since the 1979 revolution in Iran.

Page 109: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

107

4.5.2 The Purpose of the Power-Sharing Arrangements and their Effects

The purpose was clearly to stop the war. Everybody seems to agree that the rigid quotas and

the extensive requirements for consensus (written and unwritten) have been necessary to

reduce conflict. The opinions on to what extent the arrangements are still necessary and

whether they lead to an unnecessarily inefficient government are more diverse. Some

interlocutors, from the Sunni community in particular, thought that the intentions of the Taif

agreement could be implemented now, at least in parts. Others thought that the time was not

ready and that external pressure and aggression had to be reduced first.

4.5.3 Participation in Decision-Making

Representatives of the Christian communities raised the issue of how the Christian

representatives to the Parliament are elected. In constituencies with a Muslim majority, the

Christian representatives would be chosen by the Muslim majority. Many interlocutors

acknowledged this fact and it was one of the reasons why electoral reform towards more

proportionality had widespread support.

The Christians are now split in several groups. They are not all represented by a single leader

and they participate in both the major alliances (8 March and 14 March). Some would see

this as a sign of normalisation of politics rather than a weakness of the Christian community.

Both Sunni and Shi’a representatives felt quite content in their representation. Shi’as are less

willing to make changes to the consensus rules than the Sunnis.

4.5.4 Development over Time

All groups would like see the development of the state structure in relation to the general

development of the region. As long as the Palestinian problem remains unsolved, the regional

conflicts will play a central role in Lebanon. Hizbollah see themselves as a resistance

movement which will be important as long as Israeli aggression is a threat. All seemed to

share the long-term vision articulated by Taif of reducing the confessional element and

moving towards a civil society based upon citizenship and equal rights. The differences are in

the view of how fast steps could be taken in such a direction. Some, in particular from the

Sunni community, thought that a Senate could be established with confessional representation

and then offload the House of Representatives for the same.

It was also seen to be important that efficiency in certain issues, like taxation, electricity

supply, etc. should improve, even though the slow pace in decision-making for many was

considered the price to pay for peace.

An introduction of a proportional element in the electoral system for the Parliament seemed to

have general support. One of the problems earlier might have been that all initiatives of

reform have come from the civil society outside of the Parliament and when presented to the

politicians, the proposals have not been sufficiently founded.

Page 110: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

108

A list proportional system may easily be combined with quotas, either with requirements to

each list or to the total result (or both). Groups feeling they are not represented by the ‘right’

representatives would always have the possibility of proposing their own lists and, at the same

time, big parties would have strong incentives for proposing candidates that would gain

genuine support in each confession.

4.5.5 Development of Political Parties

Most interviewees seemed to see the development of multi-confessional political parties with

political programmes as an ideal. Within the alliances, there are efforts to politicise them and

move from person-oriented to a more political platform. The Christian caucus within the 14

March alliance put emphasis on that. It is generally not obvious that the current alliances are

starting points for regular political parties.

4.5.6 Other Possible Side Effects

The limitation to the right to stand for election seems to worry very few. As long as there are

very few citizens of Lebanon who are excluded by the arrangements, it was not seen to be a

problem compared to much more urgent needs.

4.6 Main Conclusions and Thoughts for the Future

The Taif Agreement points in the direction of moving away from a confessional

representation. However, a number of conditions need to be in place before that can happen.

The discussion here is therefore still based upon the following conditions of the Taif

Agreement:

4. The electoral unit is the Mohafazah [governorates].

5. Until Parliament enacts an election law which is not based on religious affiliation records; seats in

Parliament shall be allocated according to the following rules:

a) Equally between Christians and Moslems.

b) Proportionally among the sects of each of the two categories.

c) Proportionally among the region.

The Boutros Commission declared as a goal that the system should strengthen the parties.

This was one of the reasons for introducing an element of proportional representation (PR).

With PR, every vote counts and it would be worthwhile fighting for votes based upon clearer

alternatives than just tactical coalitions. There are many other reasons for such a proposal and

one is that quotas for confessions and genders can easily be combined with a list PR system

without changing the political distribution between the party lists.

One of the most obvious suggestions for a system which would meet the Taif requirements

would be to introduce List PR as the only system in the six governorates. The quotas for each

of the eleven confessions will be distributed to the governorates, but not further down to

Qadas. People would have to accept that a Qada is not always represented by

parliamentarians of a certain faith. On the other hand, the system would ensure:

Page 111: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

109

More choice and influence by the voters since every vote counts in the distribution

between lists. There will be fewer wasted votes.

The parties or coalitions will have to include prominent candidates of all Qadas and of

minority confessions on their list in order to appeal to such voters. Since every vote

can contribute to more seats, it is not recommendable to parties to include token

representatives of groups on their lists. In a majority system, it is not important how

many votes a coalition gets as long as it is biggest. They may therefore ignore the

support of their minority candidates, which they cannot afford to do in a PR system.

The quotas can be applied in such a way that even smaller parties have a fair chance to

get their main candidates elected.

The quotas would not alter the distribution between parties and the parties would have

incentives to run under programmes with appeal across confessions.

The system may be combined with open lists, which would give the voters direct

influence on the candidates filling the seats won by a party.

The system is easy to combine with gender quotas.

The system is easy for voters and for the public at large to understand.

Page 112: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

110

5: Case Study Nepal

5.1 Historical and Political Background

5.1.1 The Diversity of Nepal

Nepal is a landlocked country situated between the Asian giants, India and China. A common

perception in Nepal is that it is a small country. However, by any other standard than Nepal’s

own, Nepal is a middle-sized country. With its 147,181 square kilometres and a population of

26.6 million158

, it is slightly larger in area than Bangladesh and Greece, and slightly smaller

than Tunisia, and in population smaller than Canada but larger than Romania.

The country is diverse in terms of people, geography, social status, wealth, etc. This is an

important element for the understanding of the country’s history, not least the dramatic recent

history. Sharing borders with the regional superpowers India and China has made it

necessary to balance the internal politics against the neighbours’ interests in the region.

Nepal has been able to keep its independence partly by giving concessions to China and in

particular to British India and to India after independence.

The country consists of the lowlands of the Terai along the Indian border, the Hills which

include areas with deep valleys and high mountains (despite the word ‘hill’), and the

Mountains which are the Nepali part of the Himalayas. People define their identity along

ethnic, linguistic, caste and religious dimensions. Even though there is no universally agreed

classification system of the people, the following is broadly accepted:

Over the past two hundred and fifty years, the elite stratum of society has been made up of the

Nepali speaking Hindu castes of the hills. They belong to the Khas people, believed to be

part of the Arians who migrated to India more than three thousand years ago and who also

entered the hills of Nepal. Nepali is a Sanskrit-based language but is distinct from Indian

languages. Within the Khas people, the elite are the upper castes, mainly Bahuns (Brahmins)

and Chhetris, and the ‘untouchables’, or Dalits, consist of a number of sub-castes and have

been discriminated against as part of Hindu tradition for centuries.

The indigenous people, collectively referred to as the Janajatis, are groups that settled early in

Nepal migrating from Tibet or North Burma and who speak a large variety of

Tibetan/Burmese languages. They may be Buddhists or Hindus with elements of animism

among some groups. Each Janajati group is associated with a district where they traditionally

settled, but they live side-by-side with other groups and the population now is rather mixed.

There are currently fifty-nine such Janajati groups, but the groups are being revised and the

number is likely to pass eighty. Among the Janajati groups, there are significant variations.

The Newars, who live mainly in the Kathmandu valley, are both urban dwellers and villagers

and they have traditionally participated in the economic and political development. Other

158

According to a preliminary report on the 2011 census published by the Central Bureau of Statistics on 27

September 2011.

Page 113: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

111

groups are nomads living as they have done over centuries and they may comprise no more

than a few hundred people. The degree of political participation varies from

overrepresentation to hardly participating. The Janajatis are found in the mountains, the hills

and in the Terai.

In the Terai, there is a relatively dominant community referred to as the Madhesi. The most

common definition of this group is linguistic159

. They speak Indian languages like Hindi,

Bengali, Punjabi, etc. 160

Most of them are Hindus, and adhere to the Indian Hindu caste

systems, except for a group of Muslims and small groups of Jains and Sikhs. Unlike the caste

system of the hills, there are a large number of oppressed castes among the Madhesis. Along

with the Madhesi Dalits, they constitute a large group of people that have been discriminated

against.

The Janajati groups in the Terai are sometimes classified as Madhesi even if they do not speak

an Indian language (like during the 2008 elections) but most members of such groups (the

Tharus being the biggest) seem to oppose this classification.

5.1.2 Unification of the Kingdoms

Until the end of the eighteenth century, present day Nepal consisted of a number of kingdoms.

In the Kathmandu valley, the Newar Malla dynasty ruled and further west there was a

powerful Gorkha kingdom ruled by the Shahs. From his accession in 1743, Prithvi Narayan

Shah of Gorkha fought continuously for control of the Kathmandu Valley and in 1768, he

succeeded. By his death in 1775 he had captured all of Eastern Nepal and most of present day

Sikkim. He is the founder of the Shah dynasty, whose descendants ruled until 2006, when he

transferred all powers to the parliament and the government.161

5.1.3 The Rana Rule

In 1846, Jang Bahadur Kunwar Rana became head of the King’s cabinet.162

From then on,

the prime minister position became a hereditary post within the Rana family under the title

Maharaja. Real power rested with the Maharajas and the kings were reduced to ceremonial

puppets, even though court intrigues were numerous and some kings and queens managed to

manoeuvre with success in the intricate power structures. Both the Ranas and the Shahs were

Chhetris according to the caste system, but Bahuns filled important roles in society and were

included in the ruling elite.

In the 1930s and 1940s, there were attempts to organise opposition against the dynastic and

feudal rules of the Maharajas, but it was only in 1947, when the Nepali Congress party was

159

“The Madhes” is sometimes also used as a geographic term interchangeable with the word “Terai”. This

study will use Madhesi to refer to the linguistically-defined community.

160 Madhesis falling under this definition would also have cultural features similar close to their Indian

neighbours.

161 The monarchy was formally abolished in 2008.

162 The history from here to 2003 is mainly based upon Whelpton 2005, 2010.

Page 114: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

112

formed in Indian exile, that the first strong democratic force surfaced, inspired by the success

of the National Congress of India.163

The first Communist party of Nepal (CPN164

) was

formed in India in 1949. Both NC and CPN were initially forbidden by law.

At the end of the forties, resistance against Rana rule grew stronger. The Maharaja was now

Mohan Shamsher Rana who tried to gain the support of India in curbing the opposition, but

his actions had the opposite effect. The Nepali Congress leader B.P Koirala, his half-brother

Matrika Prasad Koirala and other personalities formed a strong force and they took the lead in

the revolt of 1950 and 1951. King Tribhuvan decided to escape from Mohan’s custody and

on 6 November 1950, the King left the palace with most of his family and arrived safely in

India. With silent support of India, the Nepali Congress increased their attacks on the Rana

regime. On 8 January 1951, Mohan Shamsher Rana finally agreed to Tribhuvan’s return to the

throne and a new government made up of Ranas and ‘representatives of the people’ was

formed. Even if Mohan Shamsher Rana still headed the government, this now included B.P.

Koirala, and it was the King who had the formal and real powers. The special arrangements

for the Maharajas were removed.

5.1.4 The King’s Rule with Parties Contribution

The Rana – Congress coalitions faced many problems and new opposition parties emerged.

The CPN joined with other groups to form the United Front to fight Indian influence. The

thirty-five member strong advisory board appointed by the King also created controversy by

not including Ranas or opposition representatives, only members of Congress and

independents. In the following years, the relationship between the government and the

Congress was marred by rivalries. M.P. Koirala became prime minister and B.P. Koirala had

control of the party.

As regent for his ailing father King Tribhuvan, Crown Prince Mahendra started out being

sympathetic to the Nepali Congress’ demand for an election of a constituent assembly, which

his father had promised in 1951, but he soon proved eager to keep control in his own hands.

In January 1956, he appointed Tanka Prasad Acharya of the Praja Parishad party as Prime

Minister, along with other members from his party and favourites of the king as ministers.

The other parties had refused to participate in the government when he wanted to handpick

the members from their ranks. After succeeding to the throne in 1955, King Mahendra (king

from 1955) agreed to hold an election in 1957 for parliament but not for a constituent

assembly. In his view, the constitution should be gifted to the people by the King rather than

be created by the people, in which case, the King’s ultimate powers would be undermined. In

December 1957, the newly-formed alliance United Democratic Front (consisting of the Nepali

Congress, Praja Parishad and Nepali National Congress, a splinter group from the Nepali

Congress) started a satyagraha, a civil disobedience campaign, to force the holding of

163

Hachhethu 2006

164 Until today, the communist parties have split and merged frequently, often on disagreements between

revolutionary wings and factions who were in favour of (at least tactically) accepting a multi-party democracy

based on free elections.

Page 115: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

113

elections within six months. In a compromise, the King suggested 18 February 1959 as the

election date, which all groups accepted. With the exception of the communists, the parties

also accepted that the election was for parliament only and that election of a constituent

assembly was put on hold for a generation. A Council of Ministers with representatives of the

main parties and the King was established in May 1958 and remained in place until after the

elections.

5.1.5 The First Elections and Democratic Experience

A new constitution was drafted nominally by a Drafting Committee consisting of party

representatives but in reality it was drafted by a British advisor, Sir Ivor Jennings, on the

King’s instructions. The draft was promulgated on 12 February 1959, only six days before the

first parliamentary elections.

The constitution provided for a bicameral parliament with a directly elected Lower House

(House of Representatives) of one hundred and nine members and an Upper House (Senate)

of thirty-six members, half elected by the House of Representatives and half appointed by the

King. The King remained head of the executive branch. There were provisions giving the

King strong powers over other state bodies and control of the army.

The results of the elections declared in May 1959 gave Nepali Congress thirty-seven percent

of the votes and seventy-five out of the one hundred and eight seats in the House of

Representatives. B.P. Koirala was asked to form government on 27 May. At the beginning,

his relationship with King Mahendra seemed to be good. The government was able to initiate

three major reforms. They abolished the birta system of tax-free long-holdings of which the

Ranas and their closest allies had been the main beneficiaries.165

They also abolished the

rajyauta system under which some of the former independent rajas had kept control of their

territories in return for a fixed annual tribute to the central government. Finally, the Nepali

Congress extended measures that had already begun for nationalisation of the country’s

forests which had so far been the personal property of the King’s brothers.

King Mahendra had probably agreed to hold elections in the belief that it would lead to a

hung parliament he could easily control, but instead he got a Nepali Congress-controlled

parliament with the strong-willed leader and Prime Minister B.P. Koirala. After a period of

protests and unrest in parts of the country, the King used the concern for public order as a

pretext for using his emergency powers to dismiss the government and arrest B.P. Koirala and

his colleagues on 15 December 1960.

5.1.6 The King’s Rule and the Panchayat System

Initially there were few protests against the King’s takeover. Even fifty-five out of the Nepali

Congress’ seventy-four MPs swung in favour of Mahendra. But the resistance gradually rose

and the Congress party organised serious military efforts from the autumn of 1961 into a

3000-strong guerrilla force operating from India. However, they called off the campaign when

165

This did not have a lot of effect on who actually cultivated the land because an intermediate class of landlords

had already developed, but it showed the Nepali Congress’ willingness toward land reform.

Page 116: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

114

war broke out between India and China in October 1962. After this, Mahendra was free to

build his party-less ‘Panchayat democracy’ as enshrined in his new 1962 constitution. It

provided for directly-elected village and town councils (panchayats). These formed electoral

colleges that elected district councils which again in turn elected the majority of the national

legislature, the Rastria Panchayat, the remaining either being representatives of government

sponsored ‘class organisations’ (peasants, youth, workers) or royal appointees. Parties were

banned from 1961166

and could not nominate candidates. The Rastria Panchayat had limited

powers and the system allowed the King to rule unhindered. Following unrest after King

Birendra’s accession to the throne in 1972, a constitutional change in 1975 increased the

number of district council members who could vote for the Rastria Panchayat and lifted the

ban on reporting from its procedures. However, perhaps inspired by Indira Gandhi’s

suspension of democratic liberties in India, Birendra gave a government-appointed committee

powers to vet candidates to councils and gave it powers to appoint members. He also

cancelled the class organisations’ right to elect members of the Rastria Panchayat and thus

removed the embarrassment of having some critical voices in the legislature.

There were small scale resistance efforts to the regime before 1979. Mahendra implemented

some of B.P. Koirala’s reforms, and the 1964 land reform act was similar to his proposals.

There was, however, growing opposition to the system and prominent figures were arrested

for voicing criticism. B.P. Koirala had been released in 1968 but in 1969 he moved into exile

in India upon information that he would be re-arrested. When he returned in 1976, he actually

was re-arrested. He was acquitted of all charges in the autumn of 1978. That could have been

a sign of Birendra actually wanted to reconcile with B. P. Koirala, but it could also have been

a realisation that the new Janata Party government in India would be less tolerant of

repression in Nepal.

By the end of 1970s, the Congress party had become two parties, while the communists had

split in at least seven factions, divided on tactics towards the palace and the Nepali Congress

and their stance on the Sino-Russian split. In retrospect, the most important group was the

CPN (Marxist-Leninist)167

formed by former members of the extremist Jhapeli group and the

Fourth Convention. Both were Maoists in ideology inspired by the Cultural Revolution in

China. The latter put particular emphasis on the demand for a constituent assembly. The

Marxist-Leninists had taken inspiration from the Naxalites of India and led a campaign of

assassinations of class enemies in villages of the Jhapa districts. After a prompt reaction of the

security forces, they turned to clandestine but non-violent agitation.

Even with the underground communist activities, the regime saw the Nepali Congress as the

main threat and at times the regime tried to use communists as foils against B.P. Koirala and

his supporters. Party politics were banned but in a few areas like the student union it still

166

The ban was brought into the constitution in 1967.

167 In the fragmentation of Nepali political parties, factions have often retained the name of the original party,

along with a distinguishing identifier. It has become common usage to refer to such parties with the name of the

party followed immediately by the identifier in parentheses.

Page 117: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

115

thrived. How hard the palace cracked down on protests and political activities varied from

time to time, but despite the suppression, there does not seem to have been a general fear of

expressing political opinions among citizens at large.

The protests against the regime in 1979 were sparked by the hanging of two Nepali Congress

activists sentenced for an attempt on Birendra’s life in 1974. The security situation never went

out of control but the palace took the student revolts and demonstrations by parties seriously.

Birendra announced a referendum presenting voters with the choice of either a reformed

Panchayat system or a multi-party democracy. The proposed reforms of the Panchayat

system would include direct election of the Rastria Panchayat.

Apart from the Marxists-Leninists and the Forth Convention who boycotted the referendum,

the opposition parties campaigned for the multi-party alternative. The Panchayat alternative

won with 2.4 against 2 million votes after a campaign in which the opposition was free to

organise meetings but in which the radio was totally on the side of the Panchayats and the

government used all their resources in support of that alternative. The multi-party alternative

won more support in the big cities and the overall result did indicate a growing opposition

against the Panchayat system.

In the 1980 amendment to the constitution, the Rastriya Panchayat was expanded to 140

members, of whom 112 were elected and the rest appointed by the King. Candidates had to

take an oath of loyalty to the Panchayat system and had to be members of one of the ‘class

organisations’. The government was responsible to the Rastria Panchayat, which henceforth

elected the prime minister with a 60 percent majority. If such a majority could not be

reached, they would suggest three candidates out of which the King could choose one. The

whole system was supervised by a Panchayat Policy and Evaluation Committee which

seemed similar to the previous committee for vetting and appointing candidates.

The large leftist groups and the Nepali Congress stayed out of the first elections after the

constitutional amendments, but two candidates backed by the moderate Congress faction and

three by leftist parties were elected, nominally as independent candidates. In later elections, a

few more party representatives were elected and the critics of the Panchayat system grew

stronger.

At the same time, the relationship with India was difficult. At the end of 1989, the

government failed to reach an agreement with the otherwise sympathetic new Indian Prime

Minister V. P. Singh on a trade and transit agreement and India curbed the delivery of

kerosene and other vital goods which resulted in hardship for the people at large. The events

in Eastern Europe also encouraged hopes of the opposition and the Marxists-Leninists left the

Maoist line and started to cooperate with the Nepali Congress in favour of a parliamentary

democracy as a short-term goal. Against that background, the Movement for Restoration of

Democracy was launched on 18 February 1990 by the Nepali Congress joined by United Left

Front (ULF), an alliance of seven communist parties including both the Marxist-Leninists and

the Fourth Convention. The Marxist-Leninists had replaced the Fourth Convention as the

strongest party of the left after the latter had split several times. Two of the splinter groups,

the Masal and the Mashal (Mashal included Pushpa Kumar Dahal [alias Prachanda], the later

Page 118: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

116

Maoist leader), refused to join the ULF, but together with other groups, they formed the

United National People’s Movement (UNPM) and announced they would carry out protests of

their own.

5.1.7 The First Jana Andolan (People's Movement) in 1990

The Movement began demonstrations and their well-known leaders were arrested. The

middle-level leaders managed to continue a coordinated effort of protests and on 6 April

1990, King Birendra announced in a radio speech that he had appointed a new prime minister

and would start talks with the parties. This was not enough for the political leaders and the

protests intensified. Only after direct negotiations and another round of protests, the King

agreed to full abolishment of the Panchayat system and the parties were allowed to operate

again. On 19 April, K.P. Bhattarai of the Nepali Congress was appointed prime minister in an

NC - ULF government which also included two independents and two royalists. After a

commission appointed by the King had failed to draft a new constitution, a commission with

the Nepali Congress and ULF representatives and representatives of the King drafted a new

constitution, which was promulgated in November 1990. The constitution prescribed a

bicameral parliament with a 205 member House of Representatives directly-elected through a

first-past-the-post system. The King was obliged to appoint a prime minister who controlled

the majority of the House. In addition, an indirectly elected Senate with few powers was

created.

The leftist parties, in particular the Masal and Mashal, argued for an elected constituent

assembly which the Nepali Congress had demanded in the 1950s and the Fourth Convention

had agitated for in the 1970s, but moderate Nepali Congress leaders felt it was important to

get a constitution in place fast.

The constitution prescribed a constitutional monarchy where the King had to act on the advice

of the government but he was left with some discretion168

on the declaration of state

emergencies. The left wanted to have the possibility to abolish monarchy later and also to

replace the bourgeois multi-party democracy. They lost on those issues and, in addition,

Nepal was declared a Hindu state and not a secular one. However, the constitution went some

way in recognising the diversity of the country by declaring it to be multi-ethnic and multi-

lingual but with Nepali being the language of the nation.

Prior to the 1991 election, the NC and ULF discussed cooperation, but it was rejected by the

NC’s national congress. The Marxist-Leninists and the Marxists managed to unite under the

name CPN (UML) – Unified Marxist Leninist, but cooperation with other groups turned

difficult.

The UML was still ambivalent about multi-party democracy and the monarchy, whereas the

United People’s Front (UPF) participated to ‘expose the system’. The UPF was a front

organisation of the underground party Unity Centre, a merger between Mashal (Prachanda)

and the Fourth Convention (Nirmal Lama). Masal called for a boycott of the elections.

168

Which the King used quite vigorously when he resumed powers in 2002.

Page 119: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

117

The Nepali Congress won 110 out of the 205 seats with UML establishing themselves as the

main opposition party with 69 seats. The two National Democratic Parties (Rastriya

Prajatantra Party, RPP) combined, winning 12 percent of the votes but only four seats. UPF

won nine seats and Nepal Sadbhavana party (Terai regionalist party) won six.

5.1.8 The Second Period of Democracy

The Nepali Congress leader K.P. Bhattarai was defeated in his constituency by the UML

leader Madan Bhandari, so it was Girija Prasad (G.P.) Koirala, youngest brother of B.P.

Koirala, who became prime minister following the election victory. The first period was

characterised by street protests organised partly by UML and partly by UPF, to which the

government responded firmly. The death of two senior leaders of the UML (Bhandari and

Jivraj Ashrit) in May 1993 in a car accident gave rise to suspicions of foul play and demands

for investigations. Within the Nepali Congress, there was a growing opposition against

Koirala’s leadership and when thirty-six Nepali Congress MPs stayed away from the vote on

the King’s speech in May 1994, Koirala asked the King to dissolve parliament and call for

new elections.

Street protests continued, organised both by UML and followers of the two Nepali Congress

leaders in opposition to Koirala: Bhattarai and Ganesh Man Singh. In the early election of

November 1994, UML won most seats, 88 out of 205, even if they had a lower share of the

vote than the Nepali Congress, which won 83. The now-merged RPP (National Democratic

Party) won twenty seats with almost twenty percent of the votes, and were therefore the ‘king-

makers’ of a hung parliament. UPF won no seats after the more radical wing had broken away

and abandoned parliamentary politics (and would declare the ‘People’s War’ two years later).

Coalition negotiations were inconclusive and UML’s Man Mohan Adhikari formed a minority

government. The government fell in a non-confidence vote in Parliament in September 1995

when the Nepali Congress got support from RPP and Sadbhavana and the NC formed a

coalition government. Sher Bahadur Deuba, who had replaced Koirala as head of the

parliamentary group after the election, was elected prime minister.

From February 1996, the government faced increased challenges with the People’s War

declared by the CPN (Maoists), the splinter group from the UPF. Initially this seemed to be a

minor problem, and the government concentrated on finalising a controversial treaty with

India on hydroelectric power and water from the Mahakali River, in which it managed to get

more benefits in return than earlier governments. The RPP was split in their commitment to

the coalition and the Chand faction was tempted by UML’s offer for a coalition government

under Chand’s leadership. The government survived a non-confidence vote in March 1996

and again in December when the vote against the government was higher than the one in

favour, but higher than the required majority of the 205 members of parliament. However,

Deuba resigned after he did not get sufficient support in a confidence vote in March 1997 and

Koirala again became head of the Nepali Congress parliamentary group.

Page 120: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

118

The new government was a coalition between UML169

, RPP and Sadbhavana with Chand as

prime minister but with UML’s deputy prime minister Bamdev Gautam as a strongman of the

government. The RPP was split on the government issue and in September 1997 the

government lost a non-confidence vote and RPP’s Surya Bahadur Thapa became prime

minister in an RPP, NC, and Sadbhavana coalition. In April 1998, Thapa handed over the

leadership to the Nepali Congress according to an earlier agreement, but Koirala now formed

a Nepali Congress minority government without Thapa. He managed to secure a confidence

vote in parliament by the help of UML and the rivalling Chand RPP.

At the end of May 1998, Koirala launched a large-scale police operation against the Maoists

insurgency in the mid-western hills. Although the offensive brought casualties on the Maoists,

the government was criticised for the loss of civilian lives.

The NC and UML now agreed to new elections and formed a coalition that also included the

Sadbhavana to oversee elections, and they won a confidence vote in January 1999. The

elections were set for 3 and 17 May 1999, and the NC won an outright victory with 36.7

percent of the votes and 111 seats against UML’s 30.7 percent and 71 seats. The UML had

split in March 1998 and the splinter group CPN (ML) secured 6.4 percent but no seats. Had

they not split, UML would probably have won a comfortable majority. K. P. Bhattarai then

formed an NC government. Koirala had agreed to have him become prime minister in an

attempt to keep the party together for the elections, but the rivalry within the party sparked off

almost immediately after the elections

5.1.9 The Peoples War – the Maoist Insurgency

At the beginning of February 1992, Dr. Baburam Bhattarai issued a manifesto with 40

demands to the government. Among those were a halt to the police excesses against them,

retraction of major agreements with India, election of a constituent assembly and declaration

of a secular state. The manifesto was an ultimatum and unless the government responded

positively by 17 February, they would start the People’s War. The first attacks on police

stations and government offices were already launched on 13 February. The Maoists were

driven by their ideology and they managed to get support from poor farmers, excluded ethnic

groups and castes and Dalits who had been discriminated against for centuries. Even though

leaders like Prachanda and Dr. Bhattarai were from the Hill elite castes, they were able to win

support of cadres from underprivileged groups. Among the nine seats the UPF won in 1991,

winning candidates included Magars, Tamangs and Thakalis, making them more inclusive

than other parties’ groups. There had also been a history of communist parties being active in

the districts from the fifties and the Maoists were seen to continue their work.

From the beginning of the war, the Maoists were successful in the western areas of Rolpa and

Rukum, Jajarkot and Salyan. These had little economic interest and the communication lines

were very poor. The Maoists managed to take over land from the landowners and the workers

would then work for the party instead. They also got support from radical groups in India and

in the UK where the leaders had good contacts. Weapons were obtained through raids at

169

UML had in its conference in 1993, officially adopted the policy of multi-party democracy.

Page 121: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

119

police stations. They played the ethnic card skilfully and they worked at the village level to

get rid of caste discrimination and to raise the position of women.

To what extent their support was genuine or out of fear is a matter for discussion, although it

was probably both. There is no doubt that the insurgency eventually gained broad support in

many districts.

The government’s response was not strong: the police force was not well trained, and low

salaries made it vulnerable to corruption. The King, to whom the army was loyal, did not

want to use the army against the people. The leftist parties had sympathy for the Maoists’

cause, and recognised that Maoists cadres were a protection against police brutality at a local

level, even though UML workers were often targets for Maoists tactics. They still called for

negotiations rather than the heavy-handed use of security forces. Early in 1998, the Maoists

set up their own People’s Committees as alternatives to the VDCs (Village Development

Committee, the lowest level of local administration). These included Maoists members as

well as parties acceptable to them.

Following G.P. Koirala’s crackdown on the Maoist army in May 1998, it was generally

accepted that the insurgency had cost around eight hundred lives on both sides by the end of

the year. It was estimated that the Maoists had 5,000 – 6,000 full-time cadres. Three-quarters

of the seventy-five districts were ultimately affected by the insurgency.

In 1999, there were some attacks on police stations, leaving a number of casualties which

made Prime Minister Bhattarai consider using the army. The King and Koirala, however,

were sceptical and the army itself said a political consensus would be needed for such an

action. Instead, the government announced the establishment of a special Armed Police Force

to combat the Maoists. Negotiations were discussed but they did not happen.

Koirala worked for taking over the government again and, in March 2000, he became prime

minister using the security situation as the main reason for his election.

In December 1999, the Maoists established District People’s Governments in Rukum and

Rolpa. In September 2000, they attacked the Dunai headquarters of the Himalayan district of

Dolpa, killing fourteen police officers and seizing fifty million rupees from a bank. The

attacks continued and, in April 2001, the government initiated the Integrated Security and

Development Programme with the army in control. The King was reluctant and the

opposition against the move of the government, while the army chief was demanding political

consensus for it to work. Koirala was under pressure from the Deuba faction and was

weakened by being investigated over a claim of corruption.

5.1.10 The Massacre at the Palace

That was when a bizarre tragedy happened on 1 June 2001. Crown Prince Dipendra, after

having drunk a lot and possibly taken drugs, drew a number of weapons during a family

gathering and killed his father King Birendra, his mother, his sister and brother, uncle, two

aunts and one aunt’s husband and a cousin, and injuring a number more. At the end of his

attack, he pointed the gun on himself and was fatally injured. While in a coma, Dipendra was

Page 122: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

120

declared King, but he died on 4 June. After that, King Birendra’s brother Gyanendra was

pronounced King. He had not been in the palace at the day of the shooting.

There have been a number of conspiracy theories about the events and some claimed that

Gyanendra was behind the shooting. Even though the official inquiry left questions

unanswered and it is natural for suspicions to flourish in situations like this, there is little

evidence in support of any other theory than Dipendra killed his family as a reaction to their

refusal to grant him permission to marry his girlfriend Devyani Rana.

5.1.11 King Gyanendra and the Intensified War

Gyanendra was a far less popular person than King Birendra. Part of the reason may have

been that he had been crowned king as a boy by the Ranas in 1950 at Tribhuvan’s absence in

India, but more importantly he did not have a fortunate hand in politics.

After the Maoists killed forty policemen on the King’s birthday in July 2001 and abducted

another sixty-nine five days later in Rolpa, prime minister Koirala wanted the army to

intervene and thought he had Gyanendra’s and the army commander in chief’s agreement.

The army was deployed but decided the risk of casualties was too high. The Maoists released

the captured policemen in batches. However, Koirala at this time resigned and left the

leadership to his NC rival Deuba.

A ceasefire was now agreed upon and there were three rounds of talks from August to

November 2001. The government did not agree to a constituent assembly and Prachanda

backed out of the talks. On 23 November, the Maoists launched a successful attack on army

units and seized large quantities of weapons. The Maoists formed a United Revolutionary

People’s Council of Nepal under Dr. Bhattarai’s leadership. The government declared a state

of emergency which was ratified by parliament in February 2002 with the support of all major

parties. Now the army was fully deployed in conflicted areas. During the next fourteen

months, the military situation was indecisive, even though 100,000 security personnel were

facing approximately 5,000 – 10,000 trained guerrillas.

When the state of emergency came up for renewal in May 2002, UML and a faction of the

NC were against it. They felt the army had taken over control, and the army felt there was

little political control. Deuba insisted and asked for dissolution of parliament and new

elections. The parliament was dissolved on 22 May and new elections were set for November

2002. Thereafter, the state of emergency was confirmed by executive ordinance. As a result

of the split, the Deuba faction broke out and formed a new party, the Nepali Democratic

Congress. Because of the security situation, Deuba asked the King for an ordinance to

postpone the election a year until November 2003 and for him to lead a caretaker government

in the meanwhile. The King instead dismissed him in October 2002 and announced he would

take over full executive power himself. The main parties did not want to nominate members

of his caretaker government and the King turned to Chand of the RPP instead. Even if the

King maintained that he had acted according to the power given to him by the emergency

Page 123: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

121

rules of the Constitution170

he had, in fact, taken over the powers the King had had before

1990.

The government entered into a ceasefire with the Maoists in January 2003. It was broken by

some incidents and in August the Maoist renounced it, insisting on a constituent assembly

which the government did not agree to, arguing it was outside their mandate. By the end of

2003, 10,000 people had died and 100,000 had been displaced because of the insurgency.

During 2002, there were some political developments. The Gautam faction returned to UML

and the UPF merged with the National People’s Front to form the People’s Front. These and

the Nepali Workers and Peasants Party joined the NC and UML in May 2003 in a campaign

against the royal takeover, and a demand for multi-party government and the restoration of

the 1999 parliament. Chand tried to get the parties involved in his government but they

rejected his proposal and suggested Madhav Kumar Nepal of UML as leader of a new

government. Chand resigned and the King appointed the other RPP leader Thapa in June

2003, thus rejecting Madhav Nepal.

The idea of a constitutional assembly won more support after the royal takeover, but the main

parties still thought the 1990 constitution could be the basis for reform. The King would not

accept a constituent assembly without his role being guaranteed in advance and the Maoists

had a republic as their one goal for a constituent assembly.

In June 2004, the King restored Deuba as prime minister and he stayed until the King’s

takeover on 1 February 2005.

5.1.12 King’s Takeover on 1 Feb 2005

The famous 1 February proclamation started with King Gyanendra's characteristically

pompous glorification of the Shah Dynasty's proud tradition of respecting and going by the

people's desires. 171

Then he came down heavily upon the Nepali political parties for ignoring

the people, bickering for power, misusing the state apparatus, and competing for individual or

partisan interests at the cost of the nation and the people. Then he proclaimed his actual

intentions: 'Due to the responsibility vested in me to save nationalism, national unity,

sovereignty, and to establish peace and security, and to save the country from any kind of

further deterioration, according to the spirit of The Constitution of the Kingdom of Nepal

1990, using clause 27, sub-clause (3)172

, I hereby dismiss the Council of Ministers. The new

Council of Ministers will be formed under my Chairmanship. This Council of Minister's

170

Article 127. Power to Remove Difficulties: If any difficulty arises in connection with the implementation of

this Constitution, His Majesty may issue necessary Orders to remove such difficulty and such Orders shall be

laid before Parliament. 171

Pokharel and Rana 2012.

172 “His Majesty is to preserve and protect this Constitution by keeping in view the best interests and welfare of

the people of Nepal.”

Page 124: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

122

priority will be directed towards managing peace, better governance, and reactivating

democracy in the coming three years.'173

An aid to the King later revealed that the reason the King had given for the takeover was to

weaken the Maoists’ military strength and then enter negotiations, taking advantage of a

weakened counterpart.174

The soldiers of the Royal Nepal Army marched into leading media houses to stop all

operations and to control independent radio and FM stations. Security forces also moved into

the houses of senior leaders to put them under house arrest. Around a thousand political

activists, journalists, and human rights workers were rounded up and jailed, refreshing

memories in many people of his authoritarian father King Mahendra's action in 1960.

5.1.13 Informal Talks with the Maoists175

In May 2002, G.P. Koirala went to Delhi to meet with the Maoists’ leaders. This was after the

central committee meeting of the Nepali Congress mandated him to initiate a dialogue for

peace with the Maoists. NC leaders were concerned about the indiscriminate murder of their

party workers. The widows of the murdered were pressuring these leaders to do something

decisive about it as soon as possible. A huge number of displaced NC workers in the villages

equally pressured them. In this context, Koirala went to Delhi with his family members (Nona

and Sujata) and another central committee member Chakra Prasad Bastola to meet with

Prachanda.

This was the first time Koirala ever met Prachanda. Baburam Bhattarai was also there. The

meeting lasted for 45 minutes, in which they discussed how to move forward. Following the

meeting, Prachanda agreed to hold talks through the then-existing parliament. The bottom line

for the talks from Koirala's side was that five principles of the 1990 Constitution ─ multi-

party democracy, the parliamentary system, an independent judiciary, human and civil rights,

and a constitutional monarchy ─ were not negotiable and that the Maoists needed to clarify

the objectives of the constituent assembly.

After reaching this understanding, G.P. Koirala informed King Gyanendra about the meeting.

King Gyanendra agreed that the parliament should hold talks with Maoists, but he asked what

the King's role would be. Koirala explained to him that the parliament was none other than the

King-in-Parliament. But the old politician immediately sensed a dangerous personal ambition

shaping up in the King's mind.

With the King's green signal to go ahead with the talks with the Maoists, Koirala organised a

mass rally with the political parties represented in the parliament on May 10, 2002. In the

public rally, he appealed to the Maoists to correspond to the parties in the parliament within a

week if they were really serious about peace-related talks. The Maoists responded within

173

Pokharel and Rana 2012.

174 Ibid

175 This section is built on Pokharel and Rana 2012.

Page 125: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

123

three days. Serious planning was done to move the dialogue forward and to hold formal talks

thereafter. The central committee meeting of the NC directed its party's Prime Minister Sher

Bahadur Deuba not to extend the ongoing emergency. Curiously, going against the party's

decision, the prime minister instead tabled a bill in parliament to extend the emergency.

After Deuba was threatened with a non-confidence vote from his own party, the King

dissolved the Parliament on 22 May 2002. Some would speculate that if the parliament had

not been dissolved at that time then peace may have prevailed after proper negotiations and a

peace accord, and Nepal's history would have been different.

Up towards the King’s takeover on 1 February 2005, Prachanda led a faction who felt that the

Maoists should deal with the King, not with democratic parties in that particular political

context. This was opposed by the faction led by Baburam Bhattarai and Prachanda had taken

action against Bhattarai so that there was no obstruction to talk with King Gyanendra directly.

The King’s takeover spoiled any such chance.

After the royal takeover, many political leaders were detained and others fled to India. An

alliance covering more than ninety percent of the seats in the old parliament was organised,

called the Seven Party Alliance (SPA)176

. In a private flat in Delhi, representatives of the

Seven Party Alliance (SPA) met Maoist leaders to finalise what was to become the 12-point

agreement. Despite discouragement from the international community including the

Americans, G.P. Koirala agreed on the document on 22 November 2005, arguing that they

had the responsibility to bring the undemocratic forces into the democratic, constitutional

fold. The agreement included a common front against the King’s rule, the holding of election

of a constituent assembly, the Maoists to return land to their owners and a common

commitment to multi-party democracy. They also agreed to put both the Peoples Liberation

Army (PLA) and the Royal Nepal Army under UN supervision.

Five months after the signing of the 12-Point Understanding, the SPA and the Maoists

decided to launch an agitation against the royal government. The second point in the 12-Point

Understanding called for ending the autocratic King’s rule through the force of the people’s

movement. Accordingly, in the first week of April 2006, the SPA called a three-day general

strike demanding restoration of peace and full democracy. The beginning of this general

strike, on 6 April 2006, saw huge demonstrations in the capital defying the Government’s ban

on public gatherings.

Many western donors had cut down foreign aid prior to this second Jana Andolan177

(People's

Movement II) to pressure the King to respect human rights and democratic freedom. At the

end of the third day of the general strike, the SPA announced the continuation of the agitation

until their demand for the restoration of Parliament was met. The demonstrations gained

176

The parties were Nepali Congress, Nepali Congress (Democratic) CPN (UML), Nepal Workers and Peasants

Party, Nepal Sadbhavana Party (Anandi Devi), United Left Front (an alliance of three parties), People’s Front

and they made up 194 of the 205 seats of the parliament elected in 1999.

177 Or ’Loktantra Andolan’ (Democracy movement)

Page 126: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

124

general support from all groups of the population, where the Maoists also played a crucial role

in mobilising people in favour of democracy and peace. A senior Maoist leader Khim Lal

Devkota has said: “The Maoist leaders could not come out openly so we asked the ordinary

people in the villages to join the agitation assuring them we would look after their work.”178

On 14 April 2006 (Nepali New Year’s Day), King Gyanendra invited the agitating political

parties for a dialogue, but the offer was rejected by the SPA stating that it did not address the

burning problems of the country. The agitation continued with aggressive demonstrations

throughout the country. People were killed and thousands of others were injured across the

country.

The mounting international and national pressure forced King Gyanendra on 21 April 2006 to

finally give up his power and called for the SPA to form a government. Even if many

international governments recommended that the SPA to take up this offer, they rejected it

thinking they knew the King’s logic too well. Then after direct talks between the SPA and the

palace on 24 April, the King made a new speech where he reinstated the dissolved parliament

which were to be summoned on 28 April and a new government was to be formed by the

SPA. The Maoists did not accept the deal at first because it did not explicitly state that a

constituent assembly would be formed as agreed in the 12-point Agreement, but Prachanda

became convinced by G.P. Koirala that it would happen anyway, but on a path of continuity.

The SPA appointed Koirala as prime minister on 27 April and two days later the parliament

unanimously agreed to Koirala’s proposal for elections of a constituent assembly. On 18

May, the parliament passed a proclamation reducing the monarchy to a ceremonial position,

declared the centuries-old Hindu kingdom a secular state, guaranteed women a full third of

government positions and placed the armed forces under the control of parliament.

5.1.14 Formation of a Democratic Government and the Constituent Assembly Elections

On 19 May 2006, the parliament assumed total legislative power and gave executive power to

the Government of Nepal (previously known as His Majesty's Government).179

Names of

many institutions (including the army) were stripped of the ‘royal’ adjective and the Raj

Parishad (a council of the King's advisers) was abolished.

The negotiations between the SPA, now in government, and the Maoists continued. A twenty-

five-point ceasefire code of conduct was signed on 26 May 2006. It included the ceasefire,

commitment not to use force, not to show combat dress or weapons in public, to release

prisoners of war and to allow for international monitoring of the truce.

On 16 June, the parties entered the eight-point agreement committing to free and fair

Constituent Assembly elections and to send a request to the UN to monitor arms and the

elections. It reiterated the commitment to multi-party democracy and to negotiate on

disagreements. It also stated that they should ‘bring about a forward-looking restructuring of

178

Pokharel and Rana.

179 Pant 2011: 18

Page 127: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

125

the state so as to resolve the class-based, racial, regional and gender-based problems through

Constituent Assembly elections’. The ceasefire was to be transferred into peace.

In August, the government sent a letter to the UN requesting monitoring of the arms and the

elections.180

On 8 November 2006, a comprehensive six-point agreement with a number of sub-paragraphs

was signed. This introduced the mixed electoral system and the specific formula of

inclusiveness for elections was defined. The Constituent Assembly should have 409 elected

members: 205 elected from single-member constituencies by FPTP181

and 204 by List PR

with the whole country as one constituency. In addition, there was to be sixteen members

appointed by the interim Council of Ministers from “among distinguished persons” so the

total came to 425 members. The formula of inclusiveness in the List PR part of the election

which later was included in the Interim Constitution stated: “While appointing the

candidates, the political parties should ensure proportional representation of oppressed

Janajati groups, backward regions, Madhesi, women, Dalit and other groups.”

It also regulated the interim period up to when the Constituent Assembly would take over as

parliament in addition to its duties as constituent assembly. The interim legislature should be

unicameral with 330 members and be given the following composition:

i. 209 members of the seven parties and others who were members of the lower and

upper house (excluding those who opposed the people’s movement). Since the Left

Front did not have its representation in the parliament, its representation in the interim

parliament was be determined based on an agreement

ii. 73 members from the Maoists

iii. 48 members from sister organisations and professional bodies, oppressed ethnic

communities and regions and political personalities appointed based on understanding.

The elections were set to mid-June 2007. The United Nations should be asked to monitor the

elections.

On 21 November 2006, the Comprehensive Peace Agreement (CPA) was signed by the

Government of Nepal and Communist Party of Nepal (Maoist). The CPA called up the six-

point agreement regarding elections after stating that an interim legislature parliament should

be appointed on the basis of an interim constitution and including a commitment to hold free

and fair elections to a constituent assembly by June 2007. The agreement also reiterated two

pillars of the agreements between the Maoists and the SPA: The commitment to a drastic

restructuring of the state and the commitment to multi-party democracy. Main elements were:

180

From July 2006 to present the author has been travelling frequently to Nepal and been able to monitor the

political development first hand. The narrative from here onwards is based on his observations and on primary

document sources.

181 The number was kept as for the parliaments of the 1990s and the constituencies were planned to be kept as

per the existing law as used in 1999.

Page 128: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

126

Expressing determination to carry out a progressive restructuring of the state to resolve

existing class-based, ethnic, regional and gender problems.

To adopt an interim constitution

To decide whether or not to retain the monarchy by a simple majority in the first

meeting of the constituent assembly.

To adopt a political system that fully abides by the universally accepted principles of

fundamental human rights, multiparty competitive democratic system, sovereignty of

the people and supremacy of the people, constitutional balance and control, rule of

law, social justice, equality, independent judiciary, periodic elections, monitoring by

civil society, complete press freedom, people's right to information, transparency and

accountability in the activities of political parties, people's participation, impartial,

competent, and clean bureaucracy.

To hold the constituent assembly elections in a peaceful, fair and fear-less

environment and to carry out democratisation and restructuring of the army.

The agreement also defined the system of UN-monitored cantonments of the Maoist army as

well as the UN-monitoring of the Nepal Army and it mandated the “Interim Council of

Ministers to work by forming a special committee to supervise, integrate and rehabilitate the

Maoist combatants”.

On 8 December 2006, an Agreement on the monitoring of the management of arms and

armies (AMMAA) was signed detailing the immediate steps in monitoring the cantonments

and, in addition, contained the following sentence, which later caused a lot of conflict: “Only

those Maoist army combatants who have been properly registered at cantonment sites will be

eligible for possible integration into the security forces fulfilling the standard norms.” In

particular, the NC interpreted the standard norms to be taken literally, so that those being

integrated had to meet all current recruitment criteria of the Nepal Army and, at the same

time, the number of combatants to be integrated was negotiated.

On 14 January 2007, the new 330-seat interim parliament was sworn in, including 83

Maoists182

. They immediately approved the Interim Constitution which came into force on 15

January 2007. The Interim Constitution had been prepared by a drafting committee formed in

June 2006 headed by retired Supreme Court Justice Laxman Aryal and with six other

prominent lawyers as members. Later, the committee was expanded to include a few women,

and members put forward by the various parties including the Maoists. 183

The Interim Constitution reflected the CPA, which was also included as a Schedule. It was

frequently amended partly to reflect new political agreements and partly to make it more

practical. It was drafted using the 1990 constitution as a basis and included fundamental

rights, the structure of government, the rules for drafting a new constitution and political

statements on the restructuring of the state.

182

The party quota plus part of the civil society quota.

183 UNDP: A bilingual commentary issue of the Interim Constitution of Nepal, January 2008.

Page 129: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

127

The interim period defined in the constitution was the time from the promulgation of the

Interim Constitution until a new constitution had been passed and a parliament had been

elected. In this period, there would be a unicameral interim legislature parliament. The

government should, as the main rule, be established by consensus, which meant in agreement

among the parties to the SPA. In case such consensus could not be reached, a majority

government should be established.184

The expanded parliament as prescribed in the SPA

would be the legislature parliament up to the time when the elected Constituent Assembly had

been inaugurated and, after that, the Constituent Assembly would take the dual role of a

constituent assembly and a legislature-parliament.

The constitution included provisions for proportional participation in the restructuring of the

state 185

, pursuing the policy of adopting scientific land reform programs by gradually ending

capitalistic land ownership practices186

, abolishing the monarchy in the first meeting of the

Constituent Assembly, etc.

The new constitution was to be drafted and promulgated within two years of the Constituent

Assembly’s first meeting.187

The constitution should ideally be passed by a two-thirds

majority of the full membership of the Constituent Assembly with a fall back possibility of a

two-thirds majority of those voting when at least two-thirds of the members are present.

On 22 October 2006, Bhojraj Pokharel was appointed Chief Election Commissioner and four

new commissioners were appointed in the following two months. They started immediately

drafting a new election law based upon the mixed system. To start with, it was unclear if a

mixed system meant a parallel system or a so-called mixed-member proportional system

(MMP)188

but a compromise was struck among the parties in February 2007, specifying a

parallel system. A draft law was sent by the Election Commission to the Cabinet on 7 March

2007 and the Cabinet sent it to the parliament on 20 March. The expectation had been high

184

At the outset, the requirement for electing a prime minister if consensus was not reached was a two-thirds

majority of the members of the Legislature-Parliament but a constitutional amendment changed that in July 2008

to the majority of the members. The rule was tested in the period from July to November 2010 when sixteen

unsuccessful votes were held in the parliament to elect a prime minister after negotiations on a consensus

candidate had failed. The vote succeeded on 3 February 2011 after having modified the procedure by an

agreement between UML and the Maoists not to allow blank votes or votes against a candidate. After that, the

members of parliament had to make a choice among the candidates running.

185 Article 21. Right to Social Justice: (1) Economically, socially or educationally backward women, Dalit,

Ethnic Tribes, Madhesi community, oppressed class, poor farmers and labourers shall have the right to

participate in the state restructuring on the basis of proportional inclusive principles. 186

Article 33 (f)

187 However, there was a provision that if the constitution formulation could not be completed due to the

declaration of an emergency situation in the country, the Constituent Assembly could be extended by another six

months.

188 The Parallel system is a half-proportional system where the two races are run independently of each other,

whereas in the MMP, the List PR race provides a compensatory system which provides for a fully proportional

result (New Zealand and Germany offering prominent examples).

Page 130: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

128

that the political parties would remain loyal to the deadline of the Interim Constitution189

, but

on 13 April, the Election Commission proclaimed that it was now impossible to hold elections

in June and that they would need at least 110 days from the day the law was passed until

Election Day to prepare for the election. The election was then eventually postponed to

November 2007.

In 2007, the Madhesi parties became more active in their demands, and the first election issue

they raised was a demand for more seats in the Terai in the FPTP race. The Constitutional

Amendment No. 1, passed on 13 April, changed the number of constituencies from 205 to 240

in order to accommodate that around 48 percent of the constituencies should be located in

Terai. The same number, 240, were to be elected by List PR. A federal system of governance

was also added.190

On 1 April, a new government was sworn in with five Maoist ministers and one State

secretary. In September, the Maoists resigned on the issue of a fully proportional system and

the demand for the declaration of the republic before the election. The Maoists had accepted

the parallel system earlier, but in their plenary meeting in August, they decided to go for a

fully proportional system. On 23 December 2007, a compromise was reached in a twenty-

three point agreement which moved the system further towards more proportional

representation (335 elected by List PR against 240 in FPTP) and the parties committed to

abolish the monarchy in the first meeting of the Constituent Assembly. In a transitional

article, it was stated that Nepal shall be a federal republic and the King should have no state

functions. After this, the Maoists entered the government again.

The Madhesis again started agitation, including violent actions. The demands included that a

promise by the government that the future federal republic should include one single Madhes

state (one Madhes Pradesh). In addition, they wanted more possibilities for Madhes parties to

have an exception from the quota rules: They did not want to be forced to have Hill

candidates on their lists. The uprising ended in an eight-point agreement on 28 February 2008

between the government and the Sadbhavana Party, the Madhesi People’s Rights Forum,

Nepal and the Tarai Madhes Democratic Party. The agreement included the following:

“By accepting the Madhesi people’s call for an autonomous Madhes and other people’s desire

for a federal structure with autonomous regions, Nepal shall become a federal democratic

republic.”

“The existing legal provision for 20 percent, in Sub-section 14 of Section 7 of the Election of

Members to the Constituent Assembly Act 2064, shall be changed to 30 percent.”

“We appeal to everyone to help conduct the Constituent Assembly election on 10 April in a

peaceful, violence-free, impartial, fair and fear-free environment.”

189

In hindsight, the process of passing the law was quite fast and the deadline was rather unrealistic.

190 Article 138.

Page 131: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

129

The government did not promise one Madhes state even if the language went far in that

direction. The increase from 20 to 30 percent was about candidate lists. Short lists had

exceptions from the quota rules for groups (but had to meet the gender rules) and the

definition of ‘short’ was raised to 30 percent or a list with up to hundred candidates. In that

way, the Madhesi parties could avoid Hill people and, at the same time, propose quite

substantial lists.

On 1 March 2008, an agreement was also entered between the government and the Federal

Republican National Front regarding the rights of some indigenous groups, Dalits and

women. The agreement included point 3 which stated i. a: “By keeping Nepal's sovereignty,

national unity and integrity intact, provision of scientific autonomous federal republican

provinces such as Limbuwan, Khurnbuwan, Tamangsaling, Tharuhat, etc. based on historical

background, language, geographical region, economic source and possibility will be made

through Constituent Assembly by ending 239 year-old centralized governance system. To

ensure this, it will be approved by the cabinet. [...] This agreement will be sent to the

Restructuring Commission, which is going to be formed for the new structure of the nation,

for its implementation.”

The agreement committed the Front to withdraw all Bandhas and fully cooperate with the

elections. The document, together with later concept papers of the Constituent Assembly

(2009), also contributed to raising high expectations of a future federation with states drawn

up based on ethnic identity.

The Constituent Assembly elections were held on 10 April 2008. There were incidents prior

to the elections which included both threats and intimidation, but the vote itself received good

international reviews. The Carter Center stated in their final report: ”In contrast to

expectations, the election itself was remarkably peaceful. In addition, the election process for

the most part was orderly and in accordance with the established procedures”191

. There is no

reason to believe that the results did not reflect the will of the voters on Election Day. The

results broke with a tradition of elitism and produced an assembly with a variation of

backgrounds never seen before. This was partly due to the Maoists’ willingness to nominate

candidates for FPTP from Dalit and Janajati communities but, first of all, it was due to the

extensive quota rules enforced for the List PR part of the elections (see next section).

Politically, the Maoists came out as the clear winner and the biggest party. With 30.0

percent192

of the votes, they won 220 seats in the Constituent Assembly. The NC won 21.7

percent and 110 seats and UML 20.9 percent and 103 seats. The largest Madhesi parties also

fared well. Since the List PR election was conducted without a threshold193

, many small

191

The Carter Center May 2009: ’Observing the 2008 Nepal Constituent Assembly Election

April 2008’. 192

In the List PR race.

193 The Sainte-Laguë formula was modified by changing the first divisor from 1 to 1.4. Otherwise another five

parties would have won seats. With the Modified Sainte-Laguë, the lowest vote share to win a seat was 0.22 %.

Page 132: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

130

parties won seats; fifteen parties won from one to four seats, and there were twenty-six parties

winning seats all together194

.

After negotiations over almost three months from the Constituent Assembly inauguration on

28 May 2008, the Maoist chairman Prachanda formed a government without NC

participation. Prior to his appointment, the parties had signed an “Agreement between the

Political Parties to Amend the Constitution and to Further the Peace Process” on 25 June,

which made the election of the Prime Minister simpler in the case consensus was not

reached195

. In addition, it stipulated a six-month deadline for the army’s integration and a

request to UNMIN to extend its mandate by half a year.

In a dispute over his authority to dismiss the army chief which had been rejected by the

President of the Republic, Prachanda resigned on 4 May 2009. A new government under the

UML leader Madhav Nepal was formed on 25 May 2009 with NC but without Maoist

participation.

The progress on the peace process was meagre. The Maoist combatants had successfully

been placed in cantonments at the end of 2006, but after that, the army integration had

stopped. The parties were not able to agree on the modalities. The drafting of the constitution

had a slow start but concept papers were produced by the various committees in 2009 and

early 2010. At that time, it became clear that the two-year deadline for the Constituent

Assembly could not be met. The Maoists agitated for a consensus government and all issues

seemed to be made dependent on each other.

One and a half hours past midnight on 28 May 2010, the parties finally agreed to change the

Interim Constitution and extend the term for the Constituent Assembly by an extra year. They

also agreed in principle on a consensus government. Madhav Nepal resigned on 30 June 2010

and negotiations started on a new consensus government. When the negotiations had been

unsuccessful and a number of deadlines set by the president had passed, the parliament started

the fallback process: The voting started on 21 July for a majority government. The rules were

interpreted in a strict manner. A candidate would need not only a majority of those present

and voting but a majority of the total membership of the Legislature-Parliament to be elected.

The candidates in the first vote on 21 July were Prachanda from the Maoists, Ram Chandra

Poudel from the NC and party chairman Jhalanath Khanal of the UML. UML withdrew their

candidate at the last minute in a move which caused a lot of internal agony within the party.

The vote was organised separately for each candidate where members of parliament could

vote in favour, against or abstain. Both candidates fell short of reaching the necessary

majority; Prachanda drew at the maximum 259 votes and Poudel 124 against the requirement

of 299. UML’s Khanal maintained that they should still seek a consensus government rather

than carrying out majority votes and abstained. The voting pattern was repeated for another

six votes until Prachanda withdrew his candidacy. Poudel stayed as the only candidate, but

194

Plus two independents.

195 The change was from a two-thirds to a simple majority of the members of the Legislature-Parliament.

Page 133: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

131

his support dropped over time and in the 16th vote on 4 November, only 101 MPs participated

in the vote and 82 voted in his favour.

In the new session of parliament, the parties agreed to change the parliamentary regulations so

that it would not be possible to be neutral in the vote any more. They further agreed that new

candidates could be put forward. On 3 February 2011, the 17th

attempt to elect a prime

minister was held. Prior to the vote, intense discussions were held between parties and, at last

minute, the UML chairman Khanal entered an agreement with Prachanda, which meant that

the Maoists would not run but vote for Khanal against benefits in ministerial posts and an

agreement on some principles of the army integration. In the vote, Khanal secured 368 out of

the 557 votes cast, Poudel won 122 and the Madhesi Janadhikar Forum Loktantrik candidate

Bijaya Kumar Gachhadar won 67.

Khanal had entered a seven-point agreement with Prachanda before the elections without

informing prominent UML or NC leaders. The NC in particular criticised that the agreement

opened for a separate army division for the PLA combatants. Key ministries would be given

to the Maoists who claimed the Home Ministry. Khanal was not allowed by his own party to

give them any security-related ministry.

Filling the minister posts caused controversies internally, both with the Maoists and UML.

The Madhesi Janadhikar Forum-Nepal decided in March to join the government, but it did not

happen due to endless negotiations within both the UML and the Maoist party. Only on 5

May did Khanal manage to expand the Cabinet to its full membership. The Home Ministry

was given to the Maoists and three other parties joined: Madhesi Janadhikar Forum-Nepal

(MJF-N), CPN (ML) and CPN (Samyukta). At the same time, Khanal became weaker,

particularly with the lack of support from his own party and approaching the of 28 May

deadline for the Constituent Assembly term, the NC became firmer in their demand for

Khanal to resign and make room for a consensus government.

Some progress had been made by a high-level panel chaired by Prachanda from October 2010

to reduce the list of 250 disputed issues with regard to the constitution. By 28 May 2011, the

list was down to 22, but the three main issues — the federal structure, form of government

and the electoral systems — were still unresolved. Prior to the 28 May deadline, the

integration modality, numbers and standards came to the forefront, in addition to the

government issue. The NC put forward ten demands, and the two most prominent were for

Khanal to resign and the handover of the weapons from the Maoists. The Maoists were firm

that they did not want a process which could look like their surrender. The modality had been

close to being agreed upon, with a new Directorate to be formed within the Nepal Army with

duties within rescue operations, engineering, forestry, etc., consisting of a mix of Maoists

combatants and army personnel. Early in the morning on the 29th

of May, the Parliament-

Legislature decided: The fundamentals of the peace process (e.g. integration) to be completed

within three months; preparation of the first draft of the constitution within three months;

implementation of past agreements with Madhesis to making the Nepal Army an inclusive

organisation; extension of the Constituent Assembly by three months and Khanal’s

resignation to pave way for a consensus government.

Page 134: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

132

On 14 August, Khanal resigned. Negotiations on a consensus government failed and on 28

August, Dr. Bhattarai was elected prime minister with support of mainly the Madhesi parties

in addition to his own Maoist party, and on 29 August, the Constituent Assembly was

extended by another three months.

5.1.15 Conflicts and Power-Sharing

The armed conflict was clearly ideological, but it was rooted in centuries of injustice and

discrimination based upon caste, language and ethnicity. The Maoists gained support from

the groups that had been excluded from economic development and social and political

influence. The peace deals were struck between the combating parties, which in the end were

the mainstream democratic parties representing the elite and the Maoists whose leadership

also, to a large extent, came from the elite. In the agreements to end the discrimination,

inclusion and representation were necessary elements. However, organisations representing

Janajati groups, Madhesis, Dalits and women became more vocal as the peace process

progressed. The Madhesi uprising in 2008 was one indication and Tharus, Limbus, etc., also

became violent in their struggle for their rights.

The power-sharing agreement entered as part of the peace agreements mainly covered the

political dimension. These agreements regulated integration of the armies and they put a lot

of emphasis on negotiating consensus with regard to the future state structure and on forming

consensus governments across the parties signing the agreements.

Along the ethnic, caste and linguistic dimensions, the main instrument was to secure

representation in the Constituent Assembly and in the government structure. In the

Constituent Assembly elections, extensive use of quotas had given the Janajati group and

Madhesis fair representation196

. Women and Dalits had improved their representation from

almost nothing to around two-thirds of their share of the population. Madhesis had formed

strong Madhesi parties which could speak on behalf of the group, but women, Dalits and

Janajatis worked within the parties.

In the Constituent Assembly, the Janajatis formed their own caucus (the Indigenous Peoples’

caucus or the IP caucus) across party lines, as did the women. Within the Janajati groups,

there was a frustration that the parties did not represent their interests. Some had hoped that

they could work independently of the party whips when drafting the constitution and they

were afraid that the main issues would be taken by party leaders ignoring the common

Constituent Assembly members as well as the drafting committees and the IP caucus. In the

issues related to the federal structure, this view, in particular, was prominent. The drafting

committee responsible for restructuring of the state suggested fourteen provinces based, to a

large extent, on ethnic identity. The demand was also that identifying ethnic groups should

enjoy some political privileges within their province197

, demands which were unrealistic but

196

As a whole, but not necessarily within the groups. In particular, within the Janajati groups and Madhesi

castes, the differences were huge.

197 Like being guaranteed the position as head of the province.

Page 135: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

133

widespread. In particular, the Limbus in the far east fought hard for a Limbuwan state with

exclusive rights for Limbus as indigenous to the province. This would be at the cost of Hill

caste groups in particular, which would still be the largest group in the province, since the

Limbus only represented 27 percent of the population. The reasons given for such privileges

varied from ‘after more than two hundred years of discrimination it is now our turn to

dominate’ and ‘the hill caste people are indigenous to western hills and they can go back there

to enjoy indigenous rights’, to more sophisticated arguments deriving from the commitments

to the ILO 169 Convention (ratified by Nepal). The discussion at large would include

supporters of extreme group rights and supporters of individual rights only.

The mainstream parties eventually came to the decision that the ethnically-based model for

the federation would not create economically viable federal units. They also dismissed the

most extreme suggestions for group representation. In this process, the dialogue between

parties worked well, but the dialogue with organisations representing Janajati groups did not.

The parties felt that they, as parties to the peace agreements, were entitled to enter agreements

on the future structure and they had the mandate directly from the voters to do so. They also

thought that the Janajati groups often held unrealistic views and the dialogue was never

efficient, and they were of the opinion that they would be able to convince the Janajati groups

once the parties had agreed.

How the state structure will be crafted is still not clear, but the parties would gain from

putting more effort into a close dialogue — even with those representing extreme views on

group representation — to strike an acceptable balance between individual and group rights.

That would be the only hope for putting deep conflicts at rest with the adoption of a new

constitution.

5.2 The Quota Arrangements and Other Power-Sharing Elements

5.2.1 The electoral history

Nepal had elections to parliament in 1991, 1994 and 1999. In all these elections, 205 members

of parliament were elected from single-member constituencies according to a plurality system

(first-past-the-post, FPTP). The parliaments elected reflected the traditional division between

privileged castes and ethnic groups and groups that had been excluded from political

influence for centuries (see Section 3.1.3). During the 1990s and early 2000s, two conflicts

developed in parallel: the conflict with Maoist insurgents and the conflict between the King

and a group of political parties. Both conflicts made it clear that Nepal needed fundamental

reforms of her political structure.

The discussion of a new Nepal intensified and the conflict between the main parties and the

King reached its peak in 2002. The first agreement between the Seven Party Alliance (SPA)

and the Maoists on 22 November 2005 created a broad foundation for the discussions, and

after the King resigned and the House of Assembly was reinstated on 24 April 2006, there

was a clear direction towards a multi-party election of a Constituent Assembly (CA). The

framework for the elections was defined in the six-point agreement between the government

(now consisting of the SPA) and the Maoists on 8 November 2006. This agreement stated:

Page 136: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

134

“The election of the constituent assembly will be based on a mixed electoral system. 205

members will be elected through a first-past-the-post system. 204 members will be elected as

per the proportional representation system on the basis of votes won by the political parties.”

In addition “16 members will be nominated by the interim Council of Ministers from among

distinguished persons”.

As for inclusiveness, the agreement said that “[w]hile appointing the candidates, the political

parties should ensure proportional representation of oppressed groups, regions, Madhesi,

women, Dalit and other groups.”

The Interim Constitution of 15 January 2007 added a few features to the system, but the

principles were kept.

The term ‘mixed system’ was not defined, and it could therefore mean either a parallel system

which is a semi-proportional system or a mixed member proportional system (MMP), which

is a fully proportional system. In a compromise deal between the government and the Maoists

on 21 February 2007, it was concluded that the term was to mean a parallel system conducted

with two ballots198

.

Before 8 November 2006 when the mixed system was defined in the six-point agreement, a

number of systems were discussed among parties and in the civil society. It was clear that an

element of proportionality would be built into the system of representation, moving Nepal

away from the Westminster model with single-member constituencies which had been used

during the 1991, 1994 and 1999 elections. There was, however, widespread confusion about

the term ‘proportional system’. Some understood it in the regular way as a list-based system

where parties would win seats according to their number of votes, but many, in particular

among the NGOs, took it to mean a system where all groups of the society should be

represented in proportion to their demographic strength. The strong call for proportional

representation often referred to the latter interpretation rather than the former.

In the public discussions in 2006, a number of systems were discussed where representation

of groups could be combined with various forms of systems of political representation. Some

interest groups went far in demanding very detailed representation from each of the 100

groups represented in the 2001 census as well as parity between men and women within each

group, whereas others were satisfied with quotas for previously politically marginalised

groups within a broader definition of groups.

When the six-point agreement defined a mixed system of representation, the discussion

concentrated on the choice between a parallel system and the MMP system. The Communist

Party of Nepal–Unified Marxist-Leninist (UML) was particularly in favour of MMP, and the

Nepali Congress (NC) was in favour of the parallel system, whereas the Communist Party of

Nepal–Maoist (CPN-M) were rather ambivalent but very clear on the demand for two ballots

with the possibility for voters to cast a split vote. A compromise was struck on 21 February

2007, after an intensive public debate, whereby an agreement was reached on the parallel

198

Having only one ballot counting for the two races and thus not allowing for a split vote had been discussed.

Page 137: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

135

system with two ballots. When the elections were postponed from June to December 2007,

the Maoists strengthened their support for a proportional system and made a fully

proportional system a condition for moving on with the election. This was also supported by

Madhesi199

groups, which became increasingly visible and militant in 2007 and 2008. The

compromise made in December 2007 raised the number of seats elected by a proportional

system from 240 to 335, and the elections were set to April 2008.

The six-point agreement of November 2006 also stated that “while appointing the candidates,

the political parties should ensure proportional representation of oppressed groups, regions,

Madhesi, women, Dalit200

and other groups”. The term ‘proportional’ here meant in

accordance with their share of the population, which, for example, would mean that there

should be 50 percent female candidates. At this point in time, it was unclear if the term ‘other

groups’ meant all others or only other marginalised groups201

. When the interim constitution

also defined that the List PR part should maintain proportional representation among the

candidates from women, Madhesis, Dalits, Oppressed communities/indigenous groups

(Janajatis), Backward regions and other groups, it was still not clear if the requirements were

on a minimum representation of marginalised groups or if it meant a segmentation of all

people into groups with proportional representation. The latter would imply that even

privileged groups had a quota and that, in turn, would mean that the quotas for the

marginalised groups would not only be minimum quotas, but also maximum quotas.

In the early discussions, many politicians were of the opinion that the FPTP race would be

won primarily by the traditionally privileged groups (such as Bahun and Chhetri202

and

privileged ethnic groups) and therefore the list PR race could be used to offer affirmative

action to marginalised groups. Within that logic, one would believe that the proportional

representation of marginalised groups on the list race would translate into minimum

requirements for such groups only, and not to exact quotas for all groups, including the

Bahuns and Chhetris.

However, after the draft law was submitted to the Cabinet by the Election Commission, and

from the Cabinet to the Parliament, the parties changed it203

from a minimum protection of

marginalised groups to a system of exact quotas for all groups, and with a 50 percent

requirement for both men and women on the lists. One effect of this system was that even

199

A term for groups in the lower planes of Terai with linguistic connections to India (see below).

200 Dalits is the term for the lowest group of the caste system, the ‘untouchables’, see below.

201 In a meeting with the author in 2010, one of the senior political leaders participating in the negotiations of the

six-point agreement and the interim constitution said that it had been clear to them that ’other groups’ meant all

others. Nevertheless, the draft election laws used the term ’at least’ up to June 2007 when the election law was

passed with a quota even for the high castes.

202 The two highest castes in Hindu tradition, these terms correspond to Brahmin and Ksatriya in India.

203 The drafts had been somewhat ambiguous but they had language like ’at least’ connected to the placement of

groups on the candidate lists.

Page 138: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

136

women’s parties would be obliged to have men on the list. Parties representing marginalised

groups such as Dalits or Janajatis could, according to an exception rule, have candidates of

their groups only, provided their lists did not have more than 100 candidates204

.

5.2.2 The system applied in the 2008 Constituent Assembly Elections

The system described here is the one used for the 10 April 2008 elections. Had the elections

happened as planned in 2007, some details would have been different.

The system of representation was defined at three levels.

I. The Interim Constitution

The According to the Interim Constitution (as amended on 28 December 2007) Article 63, the

Constituent Assembly shall have the following composition:

a) 240 members elected on the basis of First Past the Post( FPTP) from single-

member constituencies;

b) 335 members elected on the basis of a party list based proportional electoral

system (List PR) considering the whole country as one single constituency.

c) 26 members nominated by the Interim Council of Ministers on the basis of

consensus from among the distinguished persons and persons from ethnic and

indigenous groups who fail to be represented under a) and b) and who have made

significant contribution to national life.

The mixed system composed of the two races a) and b) above is a parallel system, which

means that there is no connection between the two races in terms of distribution of seats under

the List PR race.

For the FPTP election, the principle of inclusiveness should be ‘kept in mind’. For the List

PR race the requirement is more specific: “[T]he political parties shall ensure the

proportional representation of women, Dalits, oppressed communities/indigenous groups,

backward regions, Madhesis and other groups”. In addition a minimum of one-third of each

party’s candidates for both races has to be women.

II. The Election Law

The law defined the List Proportional system to be a closed list system. This meant that the

voters would only cast a vote for the party, and would not be able to influence the choice of

candidates within the list.

The law also translated the term “proportional representation of women, Dalits”, etc. into

numbers. Each list had to have the following representation according to Schedule 1 of the

law (in the following we will use the term Janajatis for “oppressed communities/indigenous

groups”, which in the law includes all Janajatis, not only the marginalised ones):

204

This rule was designed to accommodate Madhesi parties.

Page 139: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

137

Group to be represented Share of

candidates

Women 50 percent

Madhesi Women 15.6 percent

Men 15.6 percent

Dalit Women 6.5 percent

Men 6.5 percent

Janajatis Women 18.9 percent

Men 18.9 percent

Backward region Women 2 percent

Men 2 percent

Others Women 15.1 percent

Men 15.1 percent

The law further stated (Article 7, 3) that “[w]hile nominating candidates from Madhesi, the

closed list of candidates must be prepared in such a way that it ensures proportional

representation of Dalits, Janajatis and other groups on the basis of the percent of population.”

No percentages were given, and the interpretation by key parliamentarians was that the

Election Commission should not enforce this rule. The same paragraph also said: “While

enlisting the candidates pursuant to this Section, the Political Parties must pay proper

attention to the representation of the oppressed groups, poor farmers, and labourers including

disabled.” This paragraph was also not enforced.

The quota rules – except for the one on women - were waived (Article 7 (14)) for lists shorter

than thirty percent of the total number to be elected by the List PR system, which meant that

lists with up to and including one hundred candidates, did not have to comply with the quotas.

The law introduced a so-called ‘selection’ process regulating the way the seats won in the List

PR system should be filled. Instead of filling the seats from the top of the candidate list

which is the common procedure in closed list systems, the parties were allowed to fill the

seats after the election from anywhere on the list. However, when doing so they had to

comply with the same quota rules as when setting up the list, with ten percent flexibility in

both directions205

. The earlier drafts of the law had defined ranked lists with conditions for

prominent placement on the lists to the groups to ensure that they were also elected. The

205

This meant for example that a party winning 100 seats could select between 45 and 55 women to fill the seats.

Page 140: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

138

Interim Constitution had not explicitly given requirements to the results, only to the

composition of the lists, but it was clearly in its spirit and its general intention of

inclusiveness that the regulation should also ensure representation of excluded groups. When

the parliament decided to remove the ranked lists, they still kept the very important

requirement of proportional representation of groups, and they included actual figures, which

had not been included in the draft which had been sent from the Cabinet.206

The exception for short lists was also applied for the selection process.

III. The Procedures for the Nomination and Selection of Candidates in Proportional

Election Procedures for the, 2064 (2008)

Schedule 2 of the procedures repeats the law’s figures with a slightly more precise definition

of ‘Others’:

Group to be represented Share of

candidates

Madhesi 31.2 percent

Dalit 13.0 percent

Janajatis 37.8 percent

Backward regions 4.0 percent

Others 30.2 percent

Note:

1. ‘Backward Regions’ means Achaham, Kalikot, Jajarkot, Jumla, Dolpa, Bajhang,

Bajura, Mugu and Humla districts.

2. ‘Others’ means communities or groups which are not included in this Schedule as

Madhesi, Dalit and Janajatis.

3. Percentage of women candidates should be fifty.

The procedures also stated that for the short lists (up to one hundred candidates), the selection

of winning candidates should as much as possible follow the profile of the candidate list, that

is, the relative proportion of winning candidates from each group should mirror that in the

nomination list. The intention was to make the inclusiveness predictable for the voters. Since

this rule was not included in the law, it could not be strictly enforced.

206

The drafts of the Election Commission had included an empty table for the quotas but without actual figures

filled in. Such figures had been presented informally to parliamentarians and, in the end, the member of

parliament, Dr. Minendra Rijal, made his own calculation of quotas based on the 2001 census which was close to

the figures of the Election Commission and his figures were included in the schedule.

Page 141: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

139

The requirement of the Interim Constitution and the law that at least one-third of a party’s

candidates had to be female was implemented by the procedures which allowed parties to add

women to their PR lists in order to fulfil this requirement.

5.3 The Intended Effects – a Discussion

5.3.1 The Intentions

The intention of the extensive quota system was to include otherwise excluded groups in the

political decision-making. The words ‘inclusion’ and ‘proportional representation’ were used

extensively in the discussions leading up to defining the rules, and ‘proportional

representation’ meant representation of groups according to the strength in the population, not

the distribution of seats in accordance with an election result.

Inclusion and proportional representation (in the meaning used here) do not necessarily point

in the same direction. The strict quota rules were only applied to the List PR race which in

the end accounted for 335 out of 575 elected members of parliament. Therefore ‘inclusion’

could mean that there would be a minimum representation of excluded groups in the List PR

election, keeping in mind that the FPTP race would have a bias in favour of privileged groups.

‘Proportion representation’ meant that all groups should be reflected proportionally in the List

PR race. Excluded groups would not only have a minimum, but even a maximum

representation in that race, which would have as a consequence that they would still be

underrepresented in the full membership of the CA. Representatives of the ethnic groups had

used the term ‘proportional’ and they did not protest when it, in practice, also put a cap on

their representation. When all groups got a quota, the effect was that that the groups in power

protected their representation as well.

Despite this difference in terms, the overall intention of quotas was to include otherwise

excluded groups. The system should be assessed against its ability to achieve this goal.

Page 142: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

140

5.3.2 How the Group Representation Worked

The following shows the composition of the elected part of the CA:

FPTP List PR Total PR Quota

Identities Percent Identities Percent Identities Percent Percent

Women 30 12.5 161 48.1 191 33.2 50.0

Madhesi 74 30.8 121 36.1 195 33.9 31.2

Dalit 7 2.9 44 13.1 51 8.9 13.0

Janajatis 77 32.1 118 35.2 195 33.9 37.8

Backward

regions

12 5.0

10

3.0

22

3.8

4.0

Others 100 41.7 94 28.1 194 33.4 30.2

The identities add up to more than the number of seats since a person may have more than one

identity, just as the quotas add up to more than 100 percent.

Madhesis and Janajatis got a fairly good representation in the FPTP race. The Madhesis were

over-represented in the List PR race, mainly due to the waiver of quotas for short lists.

Women and Dalits came out with a low representation (even if it was better than in any

previous elections) in FPTP, but their shares were considerably improved by the quotas in the

List PR race.

The Nepal Federation of Indigenous Nationalities (NEFIN) claimed that there were 29 out of

the 59 Janajati groups that did not receive a seat in the election, and they referred to the

agreement with the governing parties to request that the 26 members that were appointed by

the government should be used to compensate for this. This happened to a small degree.

Only four of the appointees, one from each of the groups Meche, Tajpururiya, Bramu/Baramu

and Pahari represented groups without representation among the elected CA members.

It has often been said that within the broad groups defined in the quota rules, some castes or

ethnic groups represented a ‘creamy layer’, picking up the seats on behalf of the whole group.

This is particularly the case within the Madhesi castes and Hill and Mountain Janajatis. Many

groups within these broader categories were already adequately represented or even over-

represented earlier and the wide definition of groups did not help the genuinely

underprivileged to win seats. The two groups which have traditionally been excluded are

women and Dalits. The excluded castes within the Madhesi group and the marginalised

Page 143: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

141

Janajatis were helped only to a limited degree. This is discussed in detail by Vollan207

. By

checking which groups got adequately represented in the 1991, 1994, 1999 and the FPTP part

of the 2008 elections, he suggests which of the one hundred groups of the 2001 census could

be defined as excluded and which could be defined as included. His definition of excluded is

that the group in the elections studied won less than ninety percent of their share of the

population. This threshold is fairly high and led to groups representing 49.6 percent of the

population being excluded. By decreasing the threshold to sixty percent, Magars, Tamangs,

Tharus and Marwadis could be classified as ‘included’ and the total excluded comes down to

29.8 percent208

. Thus the excluded Janajati Hill and Mountain groups become:

Chepang(Praja), Bramu/Baramu, Pahari, Thami, Sunuwar, Dura, Lepcha, Jirel, Raji, Hayu,

Bote, Raute, Walung, Yakkha, Darai, Chhantel, Hyalmo (Yehylmo), Byangsi, Kusunda, Bhote,

Gharti /Bhujel, Sherpa, Majhi, Danuwar and Kumal.

The groups which were adequately represented (or over-represented) were: Newar, Gurung,

Limbu, Tamang, Magar, Rai and Thakali.

For the Madhesi castes the excluded groups are: Hajam/Thakur, Kurmi, Sonar, Lodha, Kahar,

Rajbhar, Lohar, Kamar, Bing/Binda, Mallah, Nuniya, Dhunia, Kewat, Mali,

Bhediyar/Gaderi, Badhae, Nurang, Haluwai, Kalwar, Bangali, Kumhar, Barae, Teli, Kanu

and Sudhi.

The over-represented or adequately represented Madhesi caste groups are: Brahman-Tarai,

Yadav, Kayastha, Baniya, Rajput, Marwadi and Koiri.

The largest Madhesi/Terai Janajati group is the Tharu, which are 6.8 percent of the

population. There are another twelve groups, which are very small (0.0 to 0.8 percent).

Tharus are classified as ‘included’, whereas the following groups are ‘excluded’:

Patharkata/Kuswadiya, Munda, Kisan, Jhangad, (Dhagar/Jhagar), Santhal/Satar, Dhanuk,

Koche, Meche, Rajbansi, Gangai, Tajpuriya and Dhimal.

Muslims won 2.5 percent of the seats in the 2008 FPTP race and had 4.3 percent of the

population. One may either define them as a separate group or include them in the Madhesi

caste (or Madhesi ‘other’) group, together with the Jains and Punjabis/Sikhs.

5.3.3 Summary

The following table shows a summary of the included and excluded groups based upon the

sixty percent threshold.

207

Vollan 2011.

208 Magars and Tamangs are border-line cases if the threshold is set to sixty percent.

Page 144: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

142

The excluded groups’ share of the population209

could form a basis for future minimum

quotas if one should decide to move towards a system of inclusiveness rather than

proportional representation of groups.

5.3.4 The Gender Rule

The one-third requirement for women running in the two races combined was implemented

by allowing parties to add women to the lists beyond the 50 percent required. This was a

209

These criteria are based upon parliamentary election results only and other socio-economic indicators may

also be added in the future. Broadly, the groups seem to be intuitively accepted by stakeholders but with some

comments to the details. The groups defined in the 2001 census are not generally accepted in all details and new

classifications may affect the numbers but not the general principles.

Group 1991 1994 1999 2008 FPTP Share of the population

according to the census

2001 in percent

Excluded groups:

Madhesi Dalits 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.4 3.9

Madhesi/Terai Janajatis,

excluded only

0.5 0.0 0.5 1.7 2.0

Madhesi castes, excluded

only

3.4 2.4 5.4 6.7 12.4

Hill Dalits 0.5 0.0 0.0 2.5 8.0

Hill and Mountain

Janajatis, excluded only

1.0 1.0 1.0 0.4 3.5

Total excluded groups 5.4 3.4 6.8 11.7 29.8

Included groups:

Madhesi/Terai Janajatis,

included only

8.3 6.8 3.9 5.4 6.8

Madhesi castes, included

only

8.3 10.2 10.7 16.4 6.9

Hill caste 53.7 62.4 58.0 41.7 31.2

Hill and Mountain

Janajatis, included only

24.4 17.1 20.5 24.6 25.3

Total included groups 94.6 96.6 93.2 88.3 70.2

Page 145: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

143

practical solution that did not really add to the women’s possibility of being elected. If, in the

future, one would retain FPTP elections, requirements for that part of the elections could be

implemented in the constituency race only (rather than by allowing women candidates to be

added in the other race). This would mean that the returning officers would not be able to

approve candidates before the Election Commission has made an overall review of the

parties’ nation-wide compliance with quota requirements.

5.3.5 Some Practical Issues

The system described above was successfully implemented for the 2008 election. The biggest

challenge to the voters compared to previous elections was to understand the significance of

two ballots and two races. The number of invalid votes reached 5.2 percent in the FPTP race.

One reason for invalid votes was that voters put more than one mark on the same ballot,

which in turn might have been because they knew they were to give two votes and were

unaware that they would be given a second ballot for the other race. The FPTP ballot was

given before the List PR ballot, and the rate of invalid votes dropped to 3.7 percent for the

List PR ballot.

The challenge for the parties was clearly to understand and to adhere to the complex quota

rules for the candidate lists. In particular, the nomination was demanding for the parties that

decided to file long lists. However, with assistance from the Election Commission

administration and software made for helping the parties, those wanting to file lists managed

to meet the quotas in the end.

The most complicated part of the rules came from the fact that the quotas did not add up to

one hundred percent, but to 116.2 percent. Four percent of the difference was due to the

overlap between the backward regions and the rest; 12.2 percent was because of an overlap

between the Madhesi group and the two groups known as the Dalits and Janajatis. The latter

overlap came directly from the regulations in the law, but it represented a challenge for the

parties to understand the rule. However, the parties did their utmost to implement the rules in

good faith and they were able to meet the criteria both for the candidate lists and for the

results.

In the end, eleven parties filed long lists (101 candidates or more) and therefore had to meet

all quota requirements. These parties won 277 seats out of the total of 335.

One complication with any ethnically- or caste-based quota system is to get an accurate

identification of the candidates. A person’s own feeling of identity need not coincide with the

anthropological classification and, because of intermarriages, the identity may not be unique.

In such cases, it is generally accepted that the person’s subjective identity (within reason)

counts. Another problem is that some subgroups do not have a unique classification within

the broader groups used in the law. For example, the Tharus were classified as Madhesi

Janajatis when the quotas were made, but it is far from agreed whether this Janajati group

should belong to the Madhesis or not. The last problem is that mistakes can easily be made.

It is practically impossible to review in detail the classification made by the parties of the

6,000 candidates on the lists.

Page 146: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

144

5.4 Some Side Effects of the 2008 System

5.4.1 The complexity and the good will

The complex quota system did clearly produce a more inclusive Constituent Assembly than

what would have been the case without it. On the other hand, the system made the

nomination and selection process very complicated for the parties, and by allocating quotas to

all groups, it produced restrictions not really needed to create inclusiveness.

5.4.2 The lack of transparency – the ‘selection’ process

In most countries with closed lists in a proportional system, the parties will have to nominate

a ranked candidate list. When a list wins a number of seats, the seats are filled from the top of

the list. The voters will therefore know in advance who will fill the seats a party may win. In

Nepal, this was rejected. The parties could nominate a list of up to 340 candidates, unranked

and they could fill the seats won from any position on the list. Two reasons were used for

this: Firstly, the complexity of the quota system made the ranking complicated. Secondly,

parties would have a problem filling the lower parts of the lists if the candidates knew in

advance that they would not be elected regardless of the result. The first argument is valid but

it could have been overcome. The second is more a principal one. In many countries, the

lower positions are either filled by persons who have a long-term goal of become national

politicians but accept that they will not yet become MPs, or by prominent supporters who

have a good name in the general public but have no ambitions of being MPs (such as

prominent local politicians, people from academia, business, culture, etc.).

The main issue is the transparency of the elections. The elections are held for the voters to

decide on the representation and the international observers criticised the arrangement for

being less transparent and predictable and for giving too much power to parties at the cost of

voters.

5.4.3 The Exceptions for Short Lists

There were also rules which worked against inclusiveness. The short lists (which did not

have to meet quota rules) winning 58 of the 335 List PR seats contributed to a less diverse

overall result than the long lists. Many of the short lists represented Madhesis and therefore

out of the 58 seats won by short lists, the Madhesis won as much as 72.4 percent, while the

Dalits got only 8.6 percent, the Janajatis 22.4 percent and ‘Others’ had 12.1 percent. Smaller

parties with roots in the Hill caste population did not take advantage of the possibility to the

same extent but if the rule prevails there is no guarantee that this will not happen in the future

and the concept of inclusiveness may be undermined.

5.5 The Field Study

5.5.1 The Conflict

There seems to be a common view that even though the conflict was ideological, the Maoist

movement was supported by a number of underlying social conflicts. The Maoists could not

Page 147: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

145

use the traditional Marxist-Leninist strategy relying on an industrial proletariat which hardly

existed210

.

The social conflicts had at least two dimensions: The exclusion based upon caste and on

ethnicity. The Dalits had been untouchables and had met discrimination based upon caste

regardless of their individual wealth and position otherwise. For Janajatis, the exclusion

meant that a number of groups were kept out of economic, social and political development

and influence without facing the kind of discrimination that Dalits and excluded castes would

experience.

Even if the leaders at large came from privileged castes, the Maoists were able to gain the

support of excluded groups. The Dalits were promised freedom from discrimination and

Janajati groups were promised inclusion and possibilities of self-rule within a federal system.

5.5.2 The Purpose of the Quotas

The inclusiveness statements of the Comprehensive Peace Agreement (CPA) and the interim

constitution are seen as vital parts of the peace agreement. A democratic Nepal could not

continue without giving excluded and discriminated groups representation in the Constituent

Assembly. In general, informants thought that the quotas worked as intended.

However, many interviewees pointed out that the quotas often were filled by representatives

of the ‘creamy layer’ within the group. Newaris, for example, would pick up representation

on behalf of the Janajatis, even if Newaris have not traditionally been excluded from political

life. The same is the case within the Madhesi caste group. In addition, there are poor

Brahmins and Chhetris, in particular in the far west, which are excluded, and Muslims are

often left out. These segments, excluded Madhesi castes, Muslims, excluded Janajatis, poor

Brahmins and Chhetris do not represent strong organised groups that would instigate conflict

in the short run, but their interests need to be covered to avoid conflict in the future.

Another point which was mentioned by many interlocutors was the difference between the

status of those elected in FPTP and those elected by List PR in the CA. The FPTP had met

the electorate and had their mandate directly from the voters. Those elected from lists had, on

the other hand, been selected by the party leaders after the election211

and their accountability

towards the electorate was weak. Examples were made where an active candidate managed to

campaign effectively and possibly managed to bring in few thousand voters for the party but,

despite that, he was not elected and it was claimed that the voters were disappointed. The

selection process had led to separate status of the CA members. Many advocated ranked lists

and the Maoists in particular drew the consequence that they did not want two systems for

elections to the same body any more.

210

As opposed to the 1970 Jhapa movement, which one interlocutor said failed because of a more traditional

approach.

211 The candidate lists were not ranked and the party leadership could fill the seats the party had won from

anywhere on the list as long as they met the quota requirements.

Page 148: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

146

The interim constitution has a consensus government as its ideal212

, but at the time of the

interviews (early 2010), there was a majority coalition government without Maoist

participation. In particular, the Maoists stressed the need for a new consensus government in

order to complete the peace process. Main decisions are made by the top leaders of the main

parties even if they do not form the government together.

5.5.3 The Ability to Reduce Conflict

The CPA has worked in the sense that there has not been an armed conflict between the

Maoists and the rest recently. Youth groups still create unrest locally and there was

intimidation and threats in some areas at the time leading up to the elections. YCL (the

Maoist youth groups) members are still in their barracks and UML is organising militant

youth groups. Others may feel forced to do the same.

In 2007, there was a Madhesi revolt which led in the end to an agreement with the

government after having given more FPTP seats to the Terai and having raised the threshold

for the short list which were allowed not to adhere to the quota rules.213

The government also

agreed to a language on Madhesi province in the future federation which was open to

interpretation.

This does not mean that all groups are satisfied with what has been agreed so far. The

organised Janajati groups within the umbrella organisation NEFIN are frustrated partly

because they feel that the rights of the indigenous people are not sufficiently covered and

partly because the dialogue with the parties has not worked well. Some interviewees from

Janajati groups suggested representation in parliament based upon elections within the

different groups and, in their federal models, some suggest giving one indigenous group a

special status within a province. Since such arrangements would create new minorities of

other indigenous groups, a system of autonomous areas within the provinces has been

proposed.

Many of the proposals from the Janajati groups would lead to a very complex state and others

would go at the cost of equal individual rights of the population at large. On the other hand,

for a country having ratified the ILO convention 169 on Indigenous and Tribal Peoples, it is

important that the process of defining their constitutional rights is inclusive and an efficient

dialogue is crucial to a peaceful transition to a stable democracy.

5.5.4 The Effects of Participation

The elections in 2008 produced a constituent assembly far more inclusive than any parliament

before. The Madhesis are generally very pleased with their representation and so are Dalits

and women. Within the Dalit community there are discussions on forming a Dalit party.

(Such a party exists, but does not have a lot of support). Some of their representatives

expressed a fear that such parties would be marginalised by the main-stream parties and they

212

The interim constitution anticipates that the parties to the peace agreement should form a government but it

has a parliamentary system as a fall-back arrangement.

213 A rule which was specially designed for Madhesi parties.

Page 149: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

147

would therefore prefer to work within the main parties. This would, however, only be

possible if the parties were fundamentally reformed and would genuinely include Dalits and

excluded castes in their management, policy making, etc.

Excluded castes and Janajati groups are more silent but there are voices speaking on their

behalf and they are not content with their representation. However, these groups are not well

organised and those speaking on their behalf often belong to other groups.

The most frustrated group is possibly the Janajatis. They are well represented in the CA but

the fact that they are all elected on party tickets makes their loyalty split. They have been

permitted by the parties to form an informal caucus in the CA but they are still bound by the

party programme and views. Many feel that they are not able to influence their parties to the

extent they want.

After the CA elections, there are some visible changes: There is a Madhesi President and a

Dalit minister. However, the same change needs to penetrate the civil administration in

general. People of Terai are also disillusioned on the ground since they do not see changes

even with strong Madhesi representation.

There is also a fear that many decisions in the CA will be made by the leadership of the three

main parties (NC, UML and Maoists) and that the elected representatives of the CA with its

broad representation will not be heard. The representation is necessary but not sufficient.

The political influence must be real.

5.5.5 Development over Time

The quotas will be needed in the future. One may look into possibilities for including groups

that are still excluded and the lack of accountability within the List PR system should be

removed. Since quotas may divide the society, they should be used properly.

The Maoists want to bring the concept of a consensus government into the new

constitution214

. They suggest a strong, directly-elected president and a government that

proportionally reflects the composition of the parliament. At the same time, they suggest a

block vote system of election to the parliament (FPTP in multi-member constituencies),

which would give a huge benefit to the largest party and reduce the number of parties in the

parliament to a handful. However, they have as an alternative proposal List PR in multi-

member constituencies.

Most other parties support a mixed electoral system, the main ones with a change to mixed

member proportional (a fully proportional system) as opposed to the parallel system (semi-

proportional) being used in 2008. Most parties seem to be willing to discuss a more targeted

and simplified quota system but the proposal currently defined is similar to the 2008 system.

214

Their suggestion is that the parties should be represented in government in proportion to their representation

in the parliament.

Page 150: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

148

5.5.6 Side Effects

The main side effect of the system used in 2008 is that marginalised groups had their

representation capped. It was not permitted to have more than 13 percent Dalits or fifty

percent women on the lists, even if it was clear that those groups would still be under-

represented. The complexity of the system was also recognised.

5.6 Conclusions and Thoughts for the Future

5.6.1 The System of Representation

It has not been decided at the time of this writing which system of representation will be

chosen for the future principal chamber of parliament. The most likely outcome seems to be

to carry forward a mixed system in some shape or form. Other systems are also being

discussed, but it is most likely that the system will have a strong element of List PR. The

following is built on that assumption.

5.6.2 Representation of Groups

After centuries of suppression, the Constituent Assembly election in 2008 provided an

assembly with a much more diverse composition than the previous parliaments. Out of the

groups that had earlier been excluded, Dalits and women in particular improved their

representation considerably. Within the broader groups of Madhesi castes and the Janajatis,

the picture is more complex. These groups received good representation but often the seats

were filled by representatives of castes or Janajati groups who would be well represented

anyway. However, the system worked as designed and intended with the complex quota

system applied to the List PR election.

The quotas were introduced in response to deep social divides and discrimination, which was

the underlying reason for the success of the Maoist uprising.

The quotas system had disadvantages in two areas: With the broad categories defined, the

quotas were filled by subgroups that would be represented anyway. Within the broad groups,

there were still groups not represented. In addition, the system where all groups had a quota

made, the quotas not only guaranteed excluded groups a minimum representation from the

List PR system but it also provided a maximum for their representation. The exact quotas

with overlapping groups also became extremely complex both for parties and the Election

Commission to administer.

One may consider three alternatives for minimum quotas for excluded groups in the List PR

race to replace the system used in the CA elections.

By combining Madhesi and Hill Dalits into one group and putting all excluded Janajatis into

one group, the quotas could be the following:

Page 151: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

149

Group Quota

Dalits 11.9

Janajatis, excluded only 5.5

Madhesi castes, excluded only 12.4

Total 29.8

In addition, there would need to be at least 50 percent women.

One advantage of not differentiating between Madhesi groups and the corresponding Hill and

Mountain groups is that regional parties would be free to choose regional members only on

their lists. More specifically, Madhesi parties would not be required to nominate Hill and

Mountain candidates. Including the excluded Madhesi castes as a group would still retain an

element of asymmetry since the Hill and Mountain based parties would need to include such

candidates on the lists. However, this asymmetry was there in 2008 as well by exempting

lists of not more than one hundred candidates from the quota requirements, a rule designed in

particular for Madhesi parties.

One could also name the third group Caste Excluded and then include the Churaute, which is

a very small, excluded Hill Muslim group. It would not change the figures above. The reality

would still be that the caste quota would remain asymmetric between Tarai and the hills and

mountains, but that would be due to the actual structure of the society, not the rule formally

speaking.

In order to make the quotas fully neutral and very simple, one could combine all groups and

simply state that at least 29.8 percent need to come from excluded groups and such groups

must include Dalits, excluded castes and excluded Janajatis. The parties could choose the

balance within the excluded groups as long as they would have at least 29.8 from any of the

groups. This would allow parties representing an excluded group to have candidates from

their own group(s) only.

To what extent the quotas should apply to the List PR part of a mixed system or to the whole

result is a political issue that is being discussed as the time of this writing. Some parties want

to apply the quotas on the List PR election but still guarantee women 33 percent, possibly by

a compensation mechanism. Similar arrangements may be applied for the other excluded

groups that would offer an incentive for parties to nominate candidates from excluded groups

also at electable places in the single-member constituencies.

5.6.3 Accountability

The System of Representation is likely even in the future to include a strong element of List

PR.215

The selection arrangement where the party leadership could choose which candidate on

215

The concept papers presented by the committees of CA by mid 2010 include two main alternatives: NC and

UML with support of a number of other parties propose MMP and the Maoists block vote in multi-member

Page 152: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

150

the list was to fill a seat regardless of the placement on list weakened the accountability of the

members elected from the List PR considerably. In the CA, it developed two kinds of

candidates: those accountable to the voters (elected by FPTP) and those accountable to the

party leaders (elected from List PR). The Maoists went as far as stating that a primary

requirement to a new electoral system is that there is only one system to the same body. They

wanted to avoid the division of status of the future MPs.

The obvious way to improve the accountability of those elected from the List PR race would

be to introduce ranked lists. The complexity in designing the lists with requirements to both

quotas in percent and to the position on the list would increase but not beyond what would be

manageable. Under a mixed system, the List PR seats could be filled from province lists

instead of national lists. That would improve the accountability even more since the voters

would have a better chance to know the candidates and their performance as MPs. Similarly,

if the future system would be a province based List PR system only the affect on

accountability would be similar.

5.6.4 Decision-Making

Nepal has not introduced particular rules for decision-making which should provide particular

veto powers or advantages above their regular voting force. The new constitution should, as a

main rule, be passed by consensus but after having followed a defined procedure a two-thirds

majority suffices.216

The Council of Ministers is currently supposed to be formed on the basis of consensus which

is defined upon agreement of the parties to the peace agreement.217

If that cannot be

achieved, the prime minister is elected by the CA with a qualified majority of two-thirds

according to the original provisions of the Interim Constitution. The fallback was changed by

Amendment No 5 on 12 July 2008 to a majority vote only, not a qualified majority.

The main issue in Nepal is representation. However, the Maoists have proposed a consensus

principle for forming government written into the new constitution.218

The other main parties

favour variants of a parliamentary system. Nobody has proposed particular voting rules to

protect defined groups. However, a second chamber of parliament with representation from

the provinces making up the future federation has been proposed by NC and UML with

support of some other parties. This would possibly be used as a mechanism to protect the

rights of the provinces, but these issues have not been worked out in detail.

With the complex situation of Nepal, it is likely that representation will be the main issue

even in the future. Special rights of indigenous people and protection of minority groups

constituencies. The Maoists do, however, consider List PR in multi-member constituencies as an alternative

which they think is more likely to be adopted and with would be much simpler for the voters.

216 Article 70 of the Interim Constitution.

217 Articles 38 and 44 of the Interim Constitution.

218 Members appointed in proportion to their parties strength in the parliament.

Page 153: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

151

could in addition to guaranteed representation at various level of government be implemented

by councils or bodies which will have to be consulted on certain issues of particular interest to

the groups.

Page 154: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

152

6. Case Study Bosnia and Herzegovina

6.1 Historical and Political Background

6.1.1 Constitutional Development under Tito

In 1945, the Yugoslav communists came to power. A new constitution of 1946 established a

federation consisting of six republics: Serbia, Croatia, Slovenia, Bosnia and Herzegovina,

Macedonia and Montenegro219

(1946 Constitution, Art 2). The federation was based on “a

community of peoples equal in rights” and the “principle of self-determination, including the

right to separation” (1946 Constitution, Art 1). All citizens were given equal rights,

“regardless of nationality, race and creed” (1946 Constitution, Art 21). In addition, “national

minorities” were given cultural rights, such as the free use of their own language (Art 13).

In Yugoslav constitutional terminology, there was a distinction between narod (nation) and

narodnosti (nationality). The terms first appeared in the Yugoslav constitution in 1974.220

While nations were considered to be the so-called ‘constituent nations’ of Yugoslavia,

nationalities were groups that did not have their national origin in any of the six republics,

such as Hungarians, Albanians, Slovak, Ruthenians, Vlachs, Turks and others.221

The

Muslims had been introduced as a nation in 1971 in order to defuse increasing nationalist

tensions between Serbs and Croats in Bosnia and Herzegovina. The republics were drawn up

according to the nationalities but they were not given any additional rights as ‘constituent

people’. Article 245 of the Constitution guaranteed equal rights for the nations and the

nationalities.

In the late 1960s and early 1970s, the Yugoslav constitution was subject to consecutive

amendments where the Chamber of Nationalities with representation was from the republics

became more powerful and therefore strengthened the emphasis on ‘nations’ and

subsequently also the ‘nationalities’.222

The constitution of 1974 aimed to consolidate the role of the League of Communists of

Yugoslavia as “an essential factor of stability and cohesion”.223

With this move, Tito aimed to

219

Vojvodina was granted status as an autonomous province, whereas Kosovo and Metohija were labelled as

Autonomous Districts within Serbia.

220 Nystuen 2005: 138-139.

221 Nystuen 2005: 139.

222 Article 57 of the 1946 constitution had granted both chambers “equal rights”, the 1967 amendments 1-6

broadened the Chamber of Nationalities and made it the most powerful component in the Federal Chambers.

Ref: Haug 2007: 186.

223 Haug 2007: 267.

Page 155: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

153

run the federation through a centralised communist party, in the face of mounting nationalistic

aspirations from the republican governments.224

6.1.2 The War 1991 to 1995

While Tito passed away in 1980, his legacy lasted until a series of events towards the end of

the decade offset the gradual break-up of the federation. Against the backdrop of the fall of

the Soviet Union and the demise of the Yugoslav Communist Party, a plethora of independent

parties emerged. In 1990, multi party elections were held in Croatia and Slovenia, bringing a

liberal-nationalist coalition to power in Slovenia, and the nationalist Croatian Democratic

Union (HDZ) to power in Croatia under the leadership of Franjo Tudjman. In Serbia,

President Slobodan Milosevic abandoned his strategy to gain control over Yugoslavia through

the existing structures of the Communist party in favour of carving out an extended Serbian

territory and proceeded to encourage pan-Serb initiatives and radicalisation of the Serb

population in Croatia and Bosnia and Herzegovina. Croatia and Slovenia, meanwhile

advocated a looser federal arrangement with the existing republics.

A full account of the various events that led to the breakout of a full scale war in 1991 is not

possible within the scope of this presentation.225

Suffice it to say, that the declarations of

independence by Slovenia and Croatia on 25 June 1991 were countered by an invasion of

Slovenia by the Serb-dominated federal army. Surprisingly, the Slovene army defended their

republic successfully, and Milosevic had to abandon his plan to make an example of Slovenia.

By late August, the war scene had moved to Croatia. Bosnia and Herzegovina initially

declared itself neutral. In January 1992, a peace settlement was negotiated for Croatia by the

UN representative Cyrus Vance, and on the 15th that month, international recognition of

Croatian and Slovenian independence came into effect.

The leaders of Bosnia and Herzegovina felt they now were left with no choice but to declare

independence, as the alternative would have been to remain in a much reduced Yugoslavia

under Serbian control. A referendum was held on 29 February and 1 March 1992 over

independence for Bosnia and Herzegovina. About 64 percent of the electorate voted,

including thousands of Serbs in major cities, even though Serb leaders had called for a

boycott. Of these, 99.7 percent voted for independence. The following month, Bosnia and

Herzegovina was recognised as an independent state by the European Community. War

ensued as Serbian Republic of Bosnia and Herzegovina and the Croatian Community of

Herzeg-Bosnia were proclaimed and the fight for territorial control started226

. In 1994, an

agreement was negotiated between Bosniacs and Croats, creating the Federation of Bosnia

and Herzegovina, consisting of a cantonal system covering the areas controlled by the two

parties. This put an end to the war in Central Bosnia and brought Muslims and Croats together

224

Burg 1982: 131.

225 The presentation of the historical context is mostly based on Malcolm 1996 and Nystuen 2005.

226 Meetings had been held already in March 1991 between Tudjman and Milosevic known as the Karadjordjevo

meetings on dividing Bosnia and Herzegovina between their two republics but the existence of an agreement

were later denied by the two.

Page 156: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

154

in a united front against the Serbs. Various territorial options were discussed among the

groups respectively, as among the international community. A year later, the Dayton

Agreement put a final end to the hostilities.

6.1.3 Dayton: Institutions Based on Ethnicity

The Vance-Owen plan 227

had outlined a constitutional framework for Bosnia and

Herzegovina based on a decentralised state with three recognised ‘constituent peoples’

(Paragraph 1). There was a clear understanding that only Bosniacs, Croats and Serbs fell

under this category. The drafters in the Dayton Contact Group tried to keep this term out of

the text, but this was not politically possible, and it was agreed to place the reference to

constituent peoples in the preamble.

The Dayton Agreement, concluded in November 1995, represented a compromise between

the three main groups’ institutional options.228

Annex 4 of Dayton serves as Bosnia and

Herzegovina’s constitution. Bosnia and Herzegovina was set up as a weak federation

consisting of a Croat-Bosniac entity, the Federation of Bosnia and Herzegovina covering 51

percent of the territory of the state, and the Serb-dominated entity Republika Srpska covering

49 percent. The Federation Bosnia and Herzegovina was divided into ten cantons, each with a

separate constitution, a directly elected assembly, prime minister and ministries. The entities

with their own parliaments and governments were allowed to establish special relations with

“neighbouring states” (the Republic of Croatia and the Federal Republic of Yugoslavia229

).

The Dayton Agreement was designed to maintain a balance of powers between the three

constituent peoples, Croats, Serbs and Bosniacs. Core elements in the power-sharing formula

were a tripartite presidency with rotating chair, equal representation of the constituent people

in the upper chamber of the state parliament, entity voting in the parliament (a double

majority requirement) and the so-called vital national interest clause which may be invoked to

stop certain types of legislation. These institutions and mechanisms will be discussed in detail

later in this chapter.

The Dayton Agreement sets up an institutional system based on ethnicity, recognising the

three main ethnic groups as ‘constituent peoples’, along with ‘others’ (including e.g. Romas

and Jews). In making political representation based on ethnicity, the agreement discriminates

against groups who either do not belong to or do not identify themselves as belonging to one

of the three main groups. Furthermore, individuals “might not be able to exercise a variety of

rights because they reside in an area where they constitute a minority.”230

An international

High Representative was established to monitor the implementation of the civilian aspects of

227

The Vance-Owen plan was one of several proposals put forward by the European Community and UN to

solve the conflict. Negotiations over the proposal were initiated by UN Special Envoy Cyrus Vance and EC

representative Lord Owen in January 1993. In May, the plan was rejected by the Bosnian-Serb assembly. 228

Belloni 2009: 350-360

229 Which at the time consisted of Serbia including Kosovo, and Montenegro.

230 Belloni, 2009: 360

Page 157: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

155

the Agreement. Over time, the High Representative acquired increasing legislative and

political powers, including the authority to remove local elected officials.

6.1.4 Political Deadlock

The institutions of the Dayton Agreement are set up as to allow each of the constituent

peoples to veto legislation that is perceived to go against their ‘vital interests’. There is,

however, no exact definition of what these ‘vital interests’ consist of but the Constitutional

Court has made interpretations based on a number of cases. In addition, the three constituent

peoples have divergent attitudes towards the Dayton Agreement. While the Bosnian Serbs

tend to be in favour of maintaining the status quo, which grants them the right to govern their

entity without external interference on a number of issues, Bosniacs favour a stronger unified

government in Sarajevo. The Croats, on the other hand, are outnumbered within the Bosniac-

Croat entity and are often outvoted by the majority. The nationalistic parties favour more

independence of the Croats, some even a separate entity. Fourteen years after Dayton, Bosnia

and Herzegovina is ridden by political deadlock. Political debates mainly centre on the

intertwined issues the phasing out of the High Representative, the possibility of EU

membership and constitutional reform.231

The debate over constitutional reform will be

thoroughly discussed later in this study.

6.1.5 Role of the International High Representative

The mandate of the High Representative is laid out in the Dayton Agreement’s Annex 10,

Article 2. Its function was to monitor the implementation of the peace settlement and to co-

ordinate the activities of civilian organisations and agencies in Bosnia and Herzegovina. The

role of the High Representative has developed over time; a key task for the High

Representative has become to ensure that the state and entity institutions of Bosnia and

Herzegovina are operating efficiently. In 1997, the requirements of Annex 10 was elaborated

to include the removal of elected officials who are seen to violate legal commitments and the

Dayton Peace Agreement, and impose laws on own discretion, if the legislative bodies of

Bosnia and Herzegovina fail to do so, the so-called Bonn powers. As of mid 2010, the High

Representative has issued close to 900 decisions in constitutional, economic and judicial

matters.232

These decisions have provided controversies and are particularly detested by

representatives of Republika Srpska, who see decisions by the High Representative as

untimely interventions in Republika Srpska internal affairs. There are also questions raised by

the public at large as to the long term affect of the Bonn powers decisions on empowerment

and responsibility of elected authorities. The High Representative has been dealt several

blows to his credibility, as is well illustrated by the flawed police reform process and his

attempt to force the reform by resorting to using the Bonn powers.

231

See International Crisis Group 2009a: 4-5 for further details on the main points of contention. Other vital

issues are a dispute over the ownership of state property, the status over the Brčko District, whether or not the

2011 census should include national or confessional identity, but these issues are not touched upon in this study.

232 All High Representative’s Decisions, http://www.ohr.int/decisions/archive.asp?so=d&sa=on.

Page 158: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

156

6.1.6 Police Reform

In 2005, the European Commission required Bosnia and Herzegovina to reform its police

force in order to conclude a Stabilization and Association Agreement (SAA) with the EU.233

The reforms were an attempt to consolidate the entities’ police forces into one national force

and were blocked by Republika Srpska prime minister. Key demands were related budgetary

and legislative decisions, distribution of competencies between state and entity level on police

related legislation and drawing of police districts. The demands seemed unreasonable to many

Bosnians because they went beyond the practice of many EU member states, whereas the

reforms would also erode the autonomy of Republika Srpska. After two years of unsuccessful

attempts to coax Republika Srpska into compliance, the High Representative, Miroslav

Lajčák, went for a full confrontation.

On 19 October 2007, Lajčák issued a decision instructing the legislative chambers to amend

their rules of procedure by 1 December or face further Bonn powers impositions. The intent

was to make it more difficult for one party or entity to block the operation of the Council of

Minister and the Parliamentary Assembly. The decision was intended to be the first in a series

of edicts to soften Republika Srpska. Instead, a crisis erupted when the Republika Srpska’s

Prime Minister, Milorad Dodik, withdrew his ministers from the Council of Ministers and

threatened to resign. As international efforts were directed at settling the final status of

Kosovo, Lajčák backed down and settled for a compromise whereby no cross-entity police

regions were established. In June 2008, the SAA was concluded, even though reforms had in

fact not been implemented.

It is a stated goal that the Office of the High Representative (OHR) should eventually close

down, but there are disagreements as to when. The High Representative is subsequently to be

replaced by a “reinforced” EU Special Representative (EUSR), without the legal powers of

the High Representative.234

Constitutional reform is one of the prerequisites for closing down

the OHR and in particular a reform which would make the constitution comply with the

ECHR decision of December 2009 (see below). There was a hope that this could happen

before the 2010 elections but it showed impossible.

6.1.7 The April Package

In 2005-2006, the first comprehensive attempts at reforming The Dayton Agreement came

about in response to a report by the Venice Commission, recommending that the government

pursue a process of constitutional reforms in order to enable Bosnia and Herzegovina to make

substantial progress towards European integration. As part of a private initiative by Bruce

Hitchner, Chairman of the Dayton Peace Accords Project at Tufts University, Executive

Director Paul Williams of the Public International Law and Policy Group and former

Principal Deputy High Representative Donald Hays, Bosnian officials were presented with a

series of proposals aimed at helping Bosnia and Herzegovina improve its EU candidacy and

233

Belloni, 2009: 364-365. See also International Crisis Group 2005a for a more thorough presentation of the

police reform efforts.

234 International Crisis Group 2009a: 14.

Page 159: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

157

enhance governmental efficiency on the state level.235

The leaders of all major political parties

agreed to form a constitutional working group, with Hitchner, Hays and Williams as a

secretariat to serve as an “honest broker”.

Negotiations took place in three phases, and among the vital issues were:

A new format for the election of the presidency along with a reduction of its powers;

Powers required for European integration to be provided to the state the creation of

two new ministries (agriculture and technology);

Guaranteed representation of national minorities in the House of Representatives;

A definition, and a mechanism to review of the use, of a vital national interests veto by

parliamentary representatives;

The strengthening of the Council of Ministers by transfer of key powers from the

presidency;

An increase in the number of members in both parliamentary chambers.

While the international community played an active part in facilitating the talks, the April

process was chaired for and led by domestic actors.236

All major Serb parties, the Bosniac

Parties SDA, the Croat HDZ BH as well as and SDP agreed on the reforms. However, it fell

two votes short of the two-thirds majority needed for it to be passed in the House of

Representatives. SBiH237

and the Croat HDZ 1990 (splinter party from HDZ BH) and

independent MPs voted against the package in the House of Representative.238

6.1.8 The Butmir Process

Antagonism peaked in June 2009, when the High Representative forced the Republika Srpska

to retract a set of largely symbolic declarations critical of allegedly improper transfers of

competencies from the entities to the state. Dodik complied, but later threatened a long-term

withdrawal from state institutions.239

A similar stand-off took place in September 2009, when

High Representative Valentin Inzko used the Bonn powers to impose eight laws, followed by

a further law the next day by the Principal Deputy High Representative. It was a matter of

days before Dodik rejected all nine laws and threatened to pull all Serb representatives from

the national government if Inzko tried to impose any further measures. In response to the

looming crisis, the US and EU attempted to broker a package deal including constitutional

235

Hitchner 2006: 127.

236 Sebastián 2007: 5.

237 SBiH was the only Bosniac party who withdrew from the latter stage of the talks. They rejected the package

on formalistic grounds, arguing that the reforms would be “cosmetic” only, in that it did not aim to eliminate the

Republika Srpska and entity voting. Secondly, they argued that the adoption of the April Package would

implicitly amount to a ratification of the Dayton Constitution, which was never voted on by the Bosnian

parliament. Sebastian, Leaving Dayton behind, p. 6.

238 Sebastián 2007: 6.

239 International Crisis Group 2009b: 3

Page 160: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

158

reforms that would allow the OHR to close and push Bosnia and Herzegovina towards

membership in the EU and NATO.

Negotiations were held at Camp Butmir on 8 and 9 October 2009, with a follow-up session on

20 and 21 the same month.240

The conference was hosted by Deputy Secretary of State James

Steinberg and Swedish Foreign Minister Carl Bildt, (representing the Presidency of the EU),

later joined by the European Commission commissioner for enlargement, Olli Rehn. The

proposed amendment explicitly assigned defence and intelligence to the state level. While

The Dayton Agreement had defined the responsibilities of the entities (Clause 2), the Butmir

proposals defined an additional set of “Shared Responsibilities”, including internal security,

taxation, the judiciary and local self-governance. The proposals would also explicitly

empower the state level “to undertake legal and political commitments required for the

process of accession to the European Union including on matters that in accordance with

other provisions of this Constitution are the responsibility of the entities”.

The proposed amendments241

would strengthen the Parliamentary Assembly and modify its

structure: the House of Representatives would have 87 members (instead of the current 42)

and be responsible for legislative activity. The House of Peoples would have 21 (instead of

the current 15) members appointed from among the members of the House of Representatives

and would see its role limited exclusively to deciding on issues of ‘vital national interests’.

Out of 87 seats in the House of Representatives, three seats would be reserved for

representatives who do not define themselves as members of the Constituent peoples (i.e.

those belonging to the group of ‘Others’)242

. In the House of Peoples six seats would be

earmarked for each of the three constituent peoples respectively, leaving three seats open for

members who did not necessarily belong to a constituent people. Candidates were to be able

to run for all seats of the House of Peoples and the presidency from anywhere in the country.

The proposed amendments would also change the structure of the Presidency, which would be

composed of one President and two Vice-Presidents and be elected by the House of

Representatives. The President and the Vice-Presidents may not be members of the same

Constituent peoples. The candidates for the Presidency would be nominated by the House of

Peoples. The President’s and the Presidency’s powers would be decreased in favour of the

Council of Ministers, which, according to the proposed amendments, would be presided over

by a real Prime Minister.

240

International Crisis Group 2009b: 4

241 See for example the Report of the Committee on the Honouring of Obligations and Commitments by Member

States of the Council of Europe (Monitoring Committee) of 17 December 2009 “The functioning of democratic

institutions in Bosnia and Herzegovina”

242 It is not easy to see the justification for this particular element since there is no discrimination built into the

election of the House of Representatives.

Page 161: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

159

While so-called ‘entity voting’243

would continue, the overall effect of the amendments would

be to concentrate state power within the House of Representatives. Furthermore, the state

would be given authority to assume responsibilities and make commitments in the EU

accession process.

The package was eventually rejected by all parties except the Bosniac Party of Democratic

Action (SDA).

6.1.9 The European Court of Human Rights decision

A salient issue is the status of ‘others’ (non-constituent peoples), which are constitutionally

barred from running for the presidency. The debate has gained momentum after a court case

in June 2009. Jakob Finci, head of the Jewish community and Bosnia and Herzegovina’s

ambassador to Switzerland, and Dervo Sejdić, a member of the Roma Council, appealed to

the European Court of Human Rights to overturn laws that prevent them from running for

president. They argued that Bosnia and Herzegovina’s constitution violates the European

Convention on Human Rights and United Nations conventions and international treaties. In

December, the Court ruled in favour of the plaintiffs. This has caused a debate on whether

Bosnia and Herzegovina should one, three, or even four presidents on state level. At the time

of writing, the court decision has not been implemented.

6.2 The Quota Arrangements and Other Power-sharing Elements

6.2.1 The Dayton Agreement and the Role of the International Community

The General Framework Agreement for Peace in Bosnia and Herzegovina (the Dayton

Agreement) was signed in Paris on 14 December 1995 by the presidents of Bosnia and

Herzegovina, the Republic of Croatia and the Federal Republic of Yugoslavia. The agreement

was witnessed and co-signed by representatives of EU, France, Germany, Russia, UK and US,

and in particular the US played a vital role during the negotiations at Dayton leading up to the

signing.

The agreement contains eleven articles and 11 Annexes, whereas Annex 4 is the Constitution

of Bosnia and Herzegovina. The constitution is in other words a negotiated document and part

of an international agreement. It does, however, contain articles allowing it to be amended by

a procedure of parliament.

The agreement defined a special role for the international community. An international High

Representative was to be appointed in accordance with Annex 10 to the agreement. Article I

of the annex states in its second paragraph:

In view of the complexities facing them, the Parties request the designation of a High Representative,

to be appointed consistent with relevant United Nations Security Council resolutions, to facilitate the

Parties' own efforts and to mobilize and, as appropriate, coordinate the activities of the organizations

and agencies involved in the civilian aspects of the peace settlement by carrying out, as entrusted by a

U.N. Security Council resolution, the tasks set out below.

243

A provision which requires a certain number of votes from each entity to be cast to approve for all legislative

acts.

Page 162: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

160

The list of authorities includes (Article II):

1. The High Representative shall:

Monitor the implementation of the peace settlement;

Maintain close contact with the Parties to promote their full compliance with all civilian aspects of the

peace settlement and a high level of cooperation between them and the organizations and agencies

participating in those aspects.

Coordinate the activities of the civilian organizations and agencies in Bosnia and Herzegovina to

ensure the efficient implementation of the civilian aspects of the peace settlement. The High

Representative shall respect their autonomy within their spheres of operation while as necessary

giving general guidance to them about the impact of their activities on the implementation of the

peace settlement. The civilian organizations and agencies are requested to assist the High

Representative in the execution of his or her responsibilities by providing all information relevant to

their operations in Bosnia- Herzegovina.

Facilitate, as the High Representative judges necessary, the resolution of any difficulties arising in

connection with civilian implementation.

Participate in meetings of donor organizations, particularly on issues of rehabilitation and

reconstruction.

Report periodically on progress in implementation of the peace agreement concerning the tasks set

forth in this Agreement to the United Nations, European Union, United States, Russian Federation,

and other interested governments, parties, and organizations.

Provide guidance to, and receive reports from, the Commissioner of the International Police Task

Force established in Annex 11 to the General Framework Agreement.

The High Representative’s authority got expanded by the so-called Bonn powers. The High

Representative describes it as follows: “Among the most important milestones in the peace

implementation process was the PIC Conference in Bonn in December 1997. Elaborating on

Annex 10 of the Dayton Peace Agreement, the PIC requested the High Representative to

remove from office public officials who violate legal commitments and the Dayton Peace

Agreement, and to impose laws as he sees fit if Bosnia and Herzegovina’s legislative bodies

fail to do so.” 244

The actual decision by the PIC states:

2.The Council welcomes the High Representative's intention to use his final authority in theatre

regarding interpretation of the Agreement on the Civilian Implementation of the Peace Settlement in

order to facilitate the resolution of difficulties by making binding decisions, as he judges necessary,

on the following issues:

timing, location and chairmanship of meetings of the common institutions;

interim measures to take effect when parties are unable to reach agreement, which will remain in force

until the Presidency or Council of Ministers has adopted a decision consistent with the Peace

Agreement on the issue concerned;

244

From OHR home page: “Following the successful negotiation of the Dayton Peace Agreement in November

1995, a Peace Implementation Conference was held in London on December 8-9, 1995, to mobilise international

support for the Agreement. The meeting resulted in the establishment of the Peace Implementation Council

(PIC).

The PIC comprises 55 countries and agencies that support the peace process in many different ways - by

assisting it financially, providing troops for SFOR, or directly running operations in Bosnia and Herzegovina.

There is also a fluctuating number of observers.”

Page 163: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

161

other measures to ensure implementation of the Peace Agreement throughout Bosnia and Herzegovina

and its Entities, as well as the smooth running of the common institutions. Such measures may include

actions against persons holding public office or officials who are absent from meetings without good

cause or who are found by the High Representative to be in violation of legal commitments made

under the Peace Agreement or the terms for its implementation.

Annex 3 contained a separate agreement on elections. It stipulated that elections to national

and entity bodies were to be held within six to nine months following the entry into force of

the agreement245

. The OSCE was tasked with supervising the elections (Article II) and to

establish a Provisional Election Commission which in turn should pass rules and regulations

for the elections, since an election law would not be in place. The commission was headed by

the OSCE Head of Mission whose vote in case of disagreement would be decisive. That

meant that the OSCE had all powers regarding elections. In addition it was stated (Article V)

that the parties agreed to create a permanent election commission to ‘conduct future

elections’. This happened only after passing an election law in 2001.

In addition, other international agencies, in particular within the UN, were given specified

roles in the agreement.

The refugees and displaced persons right to return and reclaim property was also defined

(Annex 7) and a special Annex 6 defined provisions regarding Human Rights.

6.2.2 The Priority Tasks after the War

After the devastating war there were a number of tasks which had to be dealt with, including:

- Cease fire;

- Disarmament;

- Establishing a legal, democratic and functional government;

- Establish a functioning judiciary;

- Return of displaced persons and refugees and return of property.

Elections to state level, entity level governments and municipal councils were held as

specified in the Dayton Agreement and the arms fell silent as committed but almost every

other task got postponed and some are still not completed after fifteen years.

6.2.3 The Power-Sharing Elements

The power-sharing agreement between the three groups, Bosniacs, Serbs and Croats is

defined in the Dayton Constitution. It contains the following elements:

- Definition of Serbs, Bosniacs and Croats (and ‘others’ mentioned in brackets) as

constituent people of Bosnia and Herzegovina.

- The division of the country into two entities with their own parliaments and

governments;

- Two chambers of the state parliament with a House of Peoples having equal

representation of the three constituent people only.

- A presidency consisting of three members reserved for the constituent people only,

and with restricted election rules.

245

They were held on 13 and 14 September 1996 exactly on the deadline.

Page 164: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

162

- Decision-making rules with important restrictions allowing an entity to apply a veto;

- Allowing each of the three caucuses to apply a vital national interest clause to stop

legislation in the House of People.

The rules for representation in the House of People and in the Presidency limit the citizens’

right to stand for elections and for the House of People even to vote. These rules are found by

the European Court of Human Rights to violate the European Convention for Human Rights

(ECHR). According to Nystuen246

it was recognised at Dayton that the discriminatory election

rules would violate international convention and she states that the expectation was that the

Constitution would undergo a ‘dynamic interpretation’ over time. This will be discussed later.

6.2.3 Constituent Peoples

The concept of nationalities was also imbedded in the Yugoslav constitution, but without

giving such people any particular rights regarding decision-making. The reason for

identifying the Bosniacs, Croats and Serbs247

as constituent people of Bosnia and

Herzegovina was to give the groups of the conflict equal rights in the state and to balance the

powers between them. At the same time other citizens were identified as ‘others’. The

dilemma for the constitutional drafters was on one hand to provide sufficient protection for

each of the combating groups and on the other hand not to deprive other citizens with

fundamental human rights.

In the specific rules of the constitution the constituent people are given certain rights of

representation (as discussed in detail below) and those rules limited the fundamental rights of

other groups to stand for elections to parliament and the presidency. It is not obvious how this

limitation of human rights could most easily be lifted. One way could be to reduce the

emphasis of the term constituent people. The Constitutional Court decided to in a judgement

of 2000 to move in the opposite direction and require the entity constitutions to reflect the

same list of constituent people. A practical consequence was that even Republika Srpska had

to establish a second house of parliament, the Council of People. It also led to more

representation of the different groups at all level of government and legislation (if not its

implementation) secured more representation in civil service, public companies, etc. There

was a shift away from emphasis on individual rights to securing more group rights in

Republika Srpska.

6.2.4 The Entities

The Dayton Constitution gives substantial powers to the entities. Article III, 1 of the

constitution states defines the powers at national level:

The following matters are the responsibility of the institutions of Bosnia and Herzegovina:

(a) Foreign policy.

246

Nystuen 2005.

247 In the preamble to the constitution it is stated: “Bosniacs, Croats, and Serbs, as constituent peoples (along

with Others), and citizens of Bosnia and Herzegovina hereby determine that the Constitution of Bosnia and

Herzegovina is as follows: “

Page 165: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

163

(b) Foreign trade policy.

(c) Customs policy.

(d) Monetary policy as provided in Article VII.

(e) Finances of the institutions and for the international obligations of Bosnia and Herzegovina.

(f) Immigration, refugee, and asylum policy and regulation.

(g) International and inter-Entity criminal law enforcement, including relations with Interpol.

(h) Establishment and operation of common and international communications facilities.

(i) Regulation of inter-Entity transportation.

(j) Air traffic control.

Paragraph 2 defines the powers of the entities:

2. Responsibilities of the Entities.

(a) The Entities shall have the right to establish special parallel relationships with neighbouring states

consistent with the sovereignty and territorial integrity of Bosnia and Herzegovina.

(b) Each Entity shall provide all necessary assistance to the government of Bosnia and Herzegovina in

order to enable it to honour the international obligations of Bosnia and Herzegovina, provided that

financial obligations incurred by one Entity without the consent of the other prior to the election of

the Parliamentary Assembly and Presidency of Bosnia and Herzegovina shall be the responsibility of

that Entity, except insofar as the obligation is necessary for continuing the membership of Bosnia and

Herzegovina in an international organization.

(c) The Entities shall provide a safe and secure environment for all persons in their respective

jurisdictions, by maintaining civilian law enforcement agencies operating in accordance with

internationally recognized standards and with respect for the internationally recognized human rights

and fundamental freedoms referred to in Article II above, and by taking such other measures as

appropriate.

(d) Each Entity may also enter into agreements with states and international organizations with the

consent of the Parliamentary Assembly. The Parliamentary Assembly may provide by law that certain

types of agreements do not require such consent.

Paragraph 3 defines the residual powers and the precedence of laws:

3. Law and Responsibilities of the Entities and the Institutions.

(a) All governmental functions and powers not expressly assigned in this Constitution to the

institutions of Bosnia and Herzegovina shall be those of the Entities.

(b) The Entities and any subdivisions thereof shall comply fully with this Constitution, which

supersedes inconsistent provisions of the law of Bosnia and Herzegovina and of the constitutions and

law of the Entities, and with the decisions of the institutions of Bosnia and Herzegovina. The general

principles of international law shall be an integral part of the law of Bosnia and Herzegovina and the

Entities.

This means that except for the rather lean list of responsibilities given to the state level in

paragraph 1, the residual power is left with the entities. This is one of the issues which is most

controversial today and which have represented hurdles for a well functional state. Some

adjustments strengthening the central powers have been made but such efforts have failed

from 2006 onwards.

Page 166: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

164

6.2.5 The Two Chambers of Parliament

The Parliamentary Assembly consists of two chambers. The House of Representatives with

forty-two members is the principal chamber based upon equal votes of all citizens and the

fifteen members House of Peoples which is a house with equal representation of the three

constituent people. Legislation needs to be approved by a majority of those present and voting

in both chambers as the main rule, with the exceptions described under entity voting and vital

national interest clauses below.

Out of the forty-two members of the House of Representatives, two-thirds (twenty-eight

members) are elected from the Federation and one-third (fourteen members) from Republika

Srpska. The electoral system is List PR in multi-member constituencies with entity-wide

compensation.

Out of the fifteen members of the House of Peoples five Bosniacs and five Croats are elected

by the Federation House of Peoples and the five Serbs are elected by the Republika Srpska

National Assembly. The electoral system is List PR. In the Federation there are two separate

elections, the one electing the Bosniac members where only the Bosniac members of the

Federation House of Peoples can vote and similarly one electing the Croat members where

only the Croats can vote. This has two effects: The Serb or other members of the Federation

House of Peoples do no neither vote for nor stand for election to members of the House of

Peoples at all and multi-ethnic parties will have to split their vote force in the election and

may risk not winning seats even if their total strength in Federation House of Peoples would

suffice for a seat.

The Federation House of Peoples is elected under a similar system by the Canton Assemblies.

This election is not ruled by the Dayton Constitution and the national election law could

define rules more freely. In 1999 there was a proposal to change the rules for electing the

Federation House of Peoples to a single List PR election in each cantonal assembly with

ethnic quotas instead of separate elections in each ethnic caucus. This would have removed

the disadvantage for multi-ethnic parties in those elections, but the election law adopted in

2001 did not include this reform. The List PR system was, however, introduced for the House

of Peoples elections replacing the previously used block vote system.

6.2.6 The Presidency and the Council of Ministers

Bosnia and Herzegovina has a hybrid executive system consisting of a three member

presidency with limited powers and a Council of Ministers led by a Chair. The Council of

Ministers need to have the confidence of the House of Representatives.

According to the constitution the three-member presidency of Bosnia and Herzegovina has

the following competencies, according to article V, 3:

(a) Conducting the foreign policy of Bosnia and Herzegovina.

(b) Appointing ambassadors and other international representatives of Bosnia and Herzegovina, no

more than two-thirds of whom may be selected from the territory of the Federation.

Page 167: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

165

(c) Representing Bosnia and Herzegovina in international and European organizations and institutions

and seeking membership in such organizations and institutions of which Bosnia and Herzegovina is

not a member.

(d) Negotiating, denouncing, and, with the consent of the Parliamentary Assembly, ratifying treaties

of Bosnia and Herzegovina.

(e) Executing decisions of the Parliamentary Assembly.

(f) Proposing, upon the recommendation of the Council of Ministers, an annual budget to the

Parliamentary Assembly.

(g) Reporting as requested, but not less than annually, to the Parliamentary Assembly on expenditures

by the Presidency.

(h) Coordinating as necessary with international and nongovernmental organizations in Bosnia and

Herzegovina.

(i) Performing such other functions as may be necessary to carry out its duties, as may be assigned to

it by the Parliamentary Assembly, or as may be agreed by the Entities.

In addition each member of the presidency had civilian command over armed forces, until the

armies were merged. Now that is a joint responsibility.

The Council of Ministers conduct the other executive functions within the authorities of the

state level.

Similar to the composition of the House of Peoples the presidency has one Croat, one Bosniac

and one Serb member. They are elected by a direct vote where the Croat and the Bosniac

members are elected from (by and amongst voters of) the Federation and the Serb is elected

from Republika Srpska. This means that all other than Croats and Bosniacs of the federation

and Serbs of Republika Srpska are deprived of the right to stand for the presidential elections.

The elections are held under a first pass the post system where the voters can cast one vote

each. In the Federation all voters may choose which race they want to participate in. The

Croats have been complaining that Bosniacs vote in ‘their’ race and thus decides who is

representing them in the presidency. Even if this may not be confirmed Serbs and other

smaller groups of the Federation clearly vote in the Croat or the Bosniac race since they do

not have a race there.

In the Council of Ministers no more than two-thirds of all Ministers may be appointed from

the territory of the Federation. A minister and his or her deputy ministers may not be of the

same constituent people.

6.2.7 Entity voting

In each house, two-thirds of the representatives from an entity may veto a decision. The rule

is being used quite frequently and not only on decisions on legislation. There are no

qualifications to the rule in the constitution (Article IV, 3 d)) so even if the intention probably

was that the decision had to be prominent for the rule to be used this is not how it has worked

out.

Page 168: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

166

6.2.8 The Vital National Interest Clause

Article IV, 3 e) and f) of the constitution define another rule which is intended to promote

consensus decisions and to protect the groups from being overruled by the other two. It

applies to the House of Peoples only and for decisions which may be ‘destructive of vital

interests of’ each of the constituent peoples. In such case a majority within the caucus in the

House of Peoples may stop a law which may otherwise have an overall majority. It means in

practise that three members of a caucus may veto such legislation. Paragraph e) states:

A proposed decision of the Parliamentary Assembly may be declared to be destructive of a vital

interest of the Bosniac, Croat, or Serb people by a majority of, as appropriate, the Bosniac, Croat, or

Serb Delegates selected in accordance with paragraph l(a) above. Such a proposed decision shall

require for approval in the House of Peoples a majority of the Bosniac, of the Croat, and of the Serb

Delegates present and voting.

There is no further advice on what constitutes a decision which may be ‘destructive of vital

interests’ but there is a procedure in place for the Constitutional Court to make a final

decision to whether the clause may be invoked or not. Paragraph (f) states:

When a majority of the Bosniac, of the Croat, or of the Serb Delegates objects to the invocation of

paragraph (e), the Chair of the House of Peoples shall immediately convene a Joint Commission

comprising three Delegates, one each selected by the Bosniac, by the Croat, and by the Serb

Delegates, to resolve the issue. If the Commission fails to do so within five days, the matter will be

referred to the Constitutional Court, which shall in an expedited process review it for procedural

regularity.

The Constitutional Court (with three international members) has ruled in a number of such

cases and has often decided that the rule cannot be used in cases when a caucus has invoked

it.

6.2.9 Later developments

The weak powers at the state level, the entity voting rule and to some extent the vital national

interest clause (even though the overruling of the Constitutional Court) have made the

decision-making at state level inefficient. A large number of important issues have simply not

been dealt with by the state bodies. In its Bonn meeting in December 1997 PIC concluded that

there was little progress on a number of vital issues and their response was to give the High

Representative legislative powers and the powers to remove elected and appointed officials at

all levels. This did not lead to a more responsible parliament and government and the number

of decrees issued by the High Representative came to twenty per year at its peak (only

counting issuing or changing laws at national level, not other decisions or laws at entity

level)248

.

The number of laws passed by the parliament at national level was very low from 1997 to

2000 when ten laws or changes to laws were passed per year249

. This later increased to 87 in

2004 and it has later dropped again to 30 to 60 per year. The number of laws rejected because

248

Office of High Representative

249 The parliament publication on http://www.parlament.ba/uzakoni/. Retrieved on 7 August 2010

Page 169: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

167

of entity voting was seven in 2007 (when the parliament passed 30 laws), eleven in 2008

(when 40 were passed) and 34 in 2009 (when 60 were passed).

The 2000 Constitutional Court decision mentioned earlier led to the introduction of a Council

of People in Republika Srpska with rights of each of the three peoples to challenge decisions

made in the National Assembly of Republika Srpska.

In April 2006, the leaders of the major parties agreed to a reform package which would have

strengthened the state level of the country and removed the discrimination in the electoral

system to the presidency. The role of the presidency was reduced and the importance of the

Council of Ministers strengthened and the number of seats in both chambers was to be

increased. The initiative failed as it had not been sufficiently based within the parties.

In June 2009, the Butmir process also offered a proposal for a number of reform elements.

The discrimination in the electoral systems to the House of People and the Presidency was

removed, the number of members of both houses increased and in the responsibility for

decisions regarding EU membership and changes needed to meet EU requirements were

placed at state level. Both the entity voting and the vital national interest clause were kept.

This initiative also failed in the end.

By entering the Council of Europe in 2002 Bosnia and Herzegovina came under the regime of

the European Court of Human Rights. The decision following the complaint by Jakob Finci,

and Dervo Sejdić has obliged the country to change the constitution to allow all people the

right to vote and be elected in both these bodies.

6.2.10 The Intentions and Possible Effects

The main intention of the Dayton Agreement was to end the war. The state emerging from the

Dayton Constitution had clear flaws in terms of power distribution, representation and

efficiency. With a very limited list of functions given to state level and with the residual

powers given to the entities Bosnia and Herzegovina became a weak state.

The representation was clearly discriminatory: Large groups were prevented from standing

for elections to the presidency and even more important to the House of Peoples. The

constitution stated that (Article II, 2) ‘[t]he rights and freedoms set forth in the European

Convention for the Protection of Human Rights and Fundamental Freedoms and its Protocols

shall apply directly in Bosnia and Herzegovina. These shall have priority over all other law.’

Nystuen has argued that ‘all other law’ includes the Constitution itself and that the

Constitutional Court could have addressed the issue of the inconsistency between the ECHR

and the discriminatory election rules250

. However, the view in Bosnia and Herzegovina

including the High Representative251

was that the specific rules of the constitution cannot in

themselves be unconstitutional. There was also a common understanding (including Nystuen)

250

Nystuen 2005: 99 and 243

251 This was for example the view of the international expert engaged by the High Representative to head the

group drafting the election law in 1999. (The author of this section participated in the drafting.)

Page 170: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

168

that the Bonn powers of the High Representative did not extend to constitutional changes. The

changes would ideally have to come by decision in the parliament applying the change rules

of the constitution itself, even if a Dayton II conference with the same parties as that of the

Dayton Agreement was discussed at times.

Nystuen, who was at Dayton as legal expert in the Contact Group, writes that it was a

common understanding that the constitution would undergo a dynamic interpretation over

time. The experts were fully aware that the ethnic formulas violated international human

rights conventions and the first drafts of the constitution had not included such provisions.

According to Nystuen, even if permissible in an emergency situation in order to stop the war

such rules should not be part of a permanent constitution. One may counter-argue that if such

rules had not been entered into the constitution the parties would not have accepted the peace

agreement. It might therefore only have been possible to solve the emergency situation by

committing to such discriminatory rules on a permanent basis.

With the decision of the European Court of Human Rights Bosnia and Herzegovina is obliged

to change the rules of representation. This will not be sufficient to create a well functioning

state. The double majorities and to some extent the vital national interest clause have led to a

number of stalemates and laws have only been passed with great difficulties.

From the Serb point of view, the Dayton Constitution works as intended. The powers were

supposed to rest with the entities and there is no need for a stronger state level. The Bosniacs

are of the opposite view and the Croats do feel that their interests are still threatened since

they constitute a minority within one entity. The requirement for the double majority (entity

voting) in the houses of the Parliamentary Assembly was important to the Serbs at Dayton.

The international negotiators had probably envisaged the rule to be used much more

restrictively than what has been the case.

The result is that there is peace in the country but reform and progress have been less than

hoped and expected. Even if some of the difficult arrangements were inevitable at the time,

the following could possibly have been included at Dayton252

:

- A limited period with a three member presidency;

- A specified list of decisions where the entity vote might be invoked;

- Clearer rules for the use of the vital national interest clause;

- A voting arrangement for the Federation representatives of the House of Peoples

where everybody votes for everybody but with ethnic quotas;

- Introduction of an ‘other’ group wherever representation is defined so that nobody is

deprived their fundamental right to stand for election.

The list above does not necessarily include changes that would have been possible to get

agreement on at Dayton, but they would have had an enormous effect on the functioning of

the state if they had been adopted and may be seen as an advice for the future.

252

To what extent the list is realistic remains speculative.

Page 171: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

169

The other highly controversial element of the peace agreement and its implementation is the

willingness of the international community, in particular the High Representative but also the

OSCE, to take up the responsibility for change and progress when the elected bodies failed.

Some decisions regarding return of displaced persons, return of property and strengthening of

the judiciary system represent areas which probably could not have been implemented

without the international community overruling the representative bodies. On the other hand

there can hardly be any doubt that when the High Representative took so much responsibility

the authorities were allowed to act with less responsibility and the long term effect was not

only positive. In addition, the process of dismissing a large number of elected representatives

because of their alleged acts against Dayton did not always represent an example of due legal

process.

6.3 The Field Study

6.3.1 The Conflict

Bosniacs tend to see the war as an act of aggression from the Federal Republic of Yugoslavia

and the Republic of Croatia, rather than a civil war. The war is interpreted as a battle for

territory, which would not have taken place without aggression from Belgrade. Among Serbs,

on the other hand, the conflict is seen as an inter-ethnic or religiously motivated civil war

where all parties participated equally. The Croats express somewhat more ambivalent

attitudes, but tend towards seeing the war as a ‘conflict which turned territorial’. In the words

of a Croat politician,

Views on the war are as numerous as there are people [...] Was it a turning point or a trigger for

already prepared fireworks? [...] Some will tell you it was an act of aggression towards BiH, others

that it was not. I am prone to support the former.

The purpose of the power-sharing arrangements and their effects

The rights of minorities are clearly seen as having been “sacrificed” in order to end the war.

On the other hand, Dayton is perceived as absolutely necessary to stop the war. The ethnic

solution is perceived as a “logical conclusion” and “the right choice at the time”. In the words

of a Bosniac politician: “It created peace, even if it was not just. It stopped the war”.

To some degree, however, Dayton is also seen as an imposed solution, over which the local

population had little influence. This criticism also applies to the discriminatory nature of the

agreement. In the words of a Serb politician,

Many would hold it against Bosnia and Herzegovina that the constitution is not in line with European

Human Rights conventions. Many forget that Annex 4 was not a domestic product, but drafted by

internationals and required to be accepted as such. Citizens of BiH did not influence it.

Many others did, however, see that the local negotiators did not only accept but certainly

contributed to the solution, which is also confirmed by representatives of the international

community and as stated earlier the ethnic formulas came from the local negotiators.

6.3.2 Participation in Decision-Making

On this point, opinions diverge strongly among the groups. Bosniacs seek reforms that will

strengthen the state level at the cost of the entity level. This has implications for how they

Page 172: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

170

view the elements of power-sharing in the decision-making process. In the view of Bosniacs,

the vital national interest clause is often abused as a political tool to impose certain policies,

rather than protecting the national interests.

Croats, on the other hand, focus on their role as a group that constitutes a minority both within

the Federation and in Republika Srpska which tend to be outvoted by the larger groups in the

House of Representatives. When the Croats invoke the vital national interest clause in the

House of Peoples, it may be overturned by the Constitutional Court where the Croat judges

may be outvoted. In the words of a Croat politician:

The electoral system established a structure of three ethnic groups. It becomes obvious that the group

who has 200 000 votes cannot compete with someone who has ten times as much. Due to the very few

Croat votes, Croat parties are always sidelined in all elected organs. Every decision made in the

parliamentary assembly can be passed without any Croat vote in the BiH parliament, the parliaments

of the entities and in most cantons. Out of 140 municipalities, in more than 100 no Croat vote is

needed for decisions.

While representatives of the other groups seemed sensitive to this problem, it seems hard to

find practical solutions that will be accepted by the Croats. Some Croat parties have proposed

a third entity for Croats, but this seems unsatisfactory to Bosniacs, who favour a more

centralised federation. Furthermore, it would not address the predicament of ‘others’, who are

not represented in the House of People, and who are constitutionally barred from running for

the presidency. For ‘others’, the House of Peoples is not seen as a constructive institution, but

rather as an instrument of obstruction. Serbs and Croats, on the other hand, will not support

any move to abolish the vital national interest clause or change the relative balance between

the groups. Entity voting is seen as a tool that protects the peoples from being outvoted. Aptly

put by one Serb politician: “Without entity voting, it would be majority voting, but that would

destroy the structure of BiH as we know it.”

6.3.3 Development over Time

The three constituent peoples seem to lack a common vision for where their country should be

within the next five years. Important issues, such as constitutional reform, the future of the

House of Peoples and the national state as such, remain unsolved. In the words of a Serb

politician:

It is like a minefield. The constitution is based upon distrust and full of protection mechanisms. It is

absolutely dysfunctional. Some also say that it is too centralized, and that it should not even have the

power it has now.

While the European Court of Human Rights in December 2009 ruled that the constitution

must be changed, so as not to discriminate Jews and Serbs, there is no agreement on how to

implement this reform.

Another divisive issue is how to move towards EU integration. While there is a broad

agreement that EU membership is a goal, Republika Srpska has for the time being remained

unwilling to implement reforms that will further additional centralisation.

Page 173: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

171

6.3.4 Development of Political Parties

Most parties in Bosnia and Herzegovina are ethnic parties. The social democratic party SPD

has gone furthest in developing a multi-ethnic appeal and maintaining a fairly inclusive party

apparatus. There have been other attempts, for example Nasa Stranka, formed in April 2008,

but it remains to be seen whether this party will be able to establish itself as a main political

actor.

Among ‘others’, there are no concerted efforts to initiate multi-ethnic parties. There was an

unsuccessful attempt by the Roma to create a political party, but the aim in that case was to

enhance Roma participation specifically.

6.3.5 Other Possible Side Effects of the Power-Sharing Agreement

Dayton places all residual powers with the entities, making it extremely hard to change the

structures that are in place. In the words of one Croat politician:

If the citizens want to protest, they go to the federal entity because they know where the power is. We

have too much government authority per capita. When the time comes to solve the problem,

everybody says “that does not fall within my jurisdiction”. When it comes to exercising power,

everybody says the power belongs to them.

Frequent stalemates have led to a sense of pessimism among our informants. Fear of future

conflicts was a reoccurring topic, and it seems that this partially explains the perceived

importance of holding on to the existing protection mechanisms. Instead of healing the

division, Dayton is seen as having made them permanent.

6.4 Main Conclusions and Thoughts for the Future

6.4.1 Learning Points

The Dayton Agreement was successful in ending the war but less successful in creating a

functional, democratic state. The weaknesses fall into two areas: The discrimination in the

representation of people to House of People and the Presidency on one hand and the division

of powers and the decision-making rules on the other. By the European Court decision the

first issue needs to find a solution and all parties express their willingness to change the rules.

The power-issues are much more difficult. They are related to how the other parts of the

Dayton Agreement were followed up and the success of the institution building in general.

The international community may take similar responsibilities after conflicts in other parts of

the world and some questions might then be considered:

Should a direct international rule be more explicit for some period of time after the peace

agreement is signed, without electing national bodies? This would enable the international

‘governor’ to deal with fundamental problems without being in constant conflicts with

democratically elected authorities.

Should the return of displaced persons and properties be given a higher priority? It took at

least four to five years to establish and enforce a framework for return in Bosnia and

Herzegovina.

Page 174: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

172

Should the reform of the judiciary be in place before election of state bodies? A well working

judiciary is a corner stone for a civil state and it is needed to provide return of property and

the general trust in the authorities. The elected authorities have shown little capability for

such reforms which have been carried out by the international community instead.

When the elected bodies are in place should the governor hand over all responsibilities and

permit such bodies to make its own ‘wrong’ decisions?

In Bosnia and Herzegovina there were almost immediate elections and a long period were the

powers in reality rested with the High Representative and the OSCE (regarding elections in

particular but also regarding return of property and in suggesting that elected people be

removed from office). The politicians hesitated to risk losing credibility as protectors of their

people by taking decision necessary to bring the country forward when they instead could

trust that the High Representative would take such decisions for them. In addition the High

Representative dismissed a number of elected representatives and invalidated candidatures in

response to parties’ actions against Dayton. Even if these actions might have been justified

they did not offer good examples of how a civil state functions and of due legal processes. All

this could possibly have been avoided if the elections had come much later following a period

of rule by an international High Representative without pretending to empower elected

bodies.

The devolution of powers was partly in favour of the two geographical entities, and partly of

the constituent peoples with their veto powers. The Croats demanded at times a third Croat

entity because they did not feel sufficiently protected as a minority within the Federation. The

international community253

rejected such thoughts. They also tried to reduce the importance

of the geographical divide, possibly because they did not want the ethnic cleansing to have

succeeded and the entity voting already made decisions very cumbersome. Keeping in mind

that voters - as the main rule - were to vote for the bodies and constituencies where they had

lived before the war, there were a good number of Bosniacs and Croats elected from

Republika Srpska and Serbs from the Federation. Multi-ethnic entities were part of the ideal

and creating a new Croat entity was not seen to be a step forward.

The Serbs were the group most concerned with protecting the independence of their entity

Republika Srpska. At a time many Serb politicians would interpret the constitution in such a

way that any voter registered in Republika Srpska could run for the Serb seats in the House of

People and the Presidency. The entity constitution stated that Republika Srpska was a State of

the Serb people, but otherwise it was quite neutral in terms of ethnicity. By the Constitutional

Court decision in 2000 (U-5/98) mandating Republika Srpska and the Federation to define

constituent people, this neutral position became impossible and the Serb representatives did

not only have to come from Republika Srpska but they had to be ethnic Serbs254

. After this

253

The High Representative, the OSCE and the US State Department.

254 A ruling of the Constitutional Court in 2006 (AP 2678/06) confirmed this.

Page 175: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

173

Republika Srpska established a Council of People with representatives of constituent people

but particularly the Croats are so few that their representatives are elected from Serb parties.

Croats sometimes advocated cantonising the whole country replacing the entity level. This

would have given them a couple of Cantons where they had majority and one where they

would be the largest group and any veto rules could be resting with geographical units rather

than ethnic groups. Serbs clearly would not have accepted such a solution but even the

international community was quite unwilling to discuss models based upon geography alone.

This might have been a mistake even though it is easy to understand that stakeholders were

reluctant to support such a drastic change.

In sum the following adjustments to the Dayton Constitution could make a big difference:

- A more extensive list of powers at state level, in particular if the residual powers were

given to the entities.

- Limitations to the kind of decisions where entity voting could be applied;

A clearer definition of what ‘vital interests’ of a constituent people could be;

- Representation in House of People and the Presidency where the right to stand for

election would not be limited, even if the balance between the three ‘constituent

people’ was secured.

- An electoral system to the House of People which would not prescribe elections in

separate caucuses but where all members of the Federation House of People could

vote for all Federation representatives, even if the rules had ensure the representation

of the constituent people. If that had been done multi-ethnic parties would not face the

disadvantages they do under the current system.

- Consideration of shifting from group rights to geographical rights only combined with

strengthening the national authorities.

Bosnia and Herzegovina was admitted to the Council of Europe in 2002. At this time it was

clear that the representation rules were highly discriminatory and state did not function

without the powers of the High Representative. One could raise the question whether the

pressure had been stronger if the admittance had been delayed until such time when more

criteria had been met.

6.4.2 The Way Ahead

Among the ethnic groups, there are serious disagreements as to how the issues discussed here

can be solved. The disagreements stem from a blend of genuine fears, actual political

disagreements as to the best solution, and power seeking among political actors. While

Bosniac and Croat leaders perceive of the situation as “worse than ever”, they still express

faith in the future. Republika Srpska politicians mainly seek to maintain status quo with its

authorities as is today.

Electoral discrimination will possibly be removed from the constitution as a result of the

European court decision, but the rules limiting the state powers are more difficult to reach an

agreement on.

The High Representative has clearly expressed that he will use the Bonn powers much less in

the future. The international community seems to agree that the way ahead would give elected

Page 176: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

174

authorities more responsibility which in turn would mean that they are permitted to make their

own mistakes. Some would therefore claim that the only pressure left is the conditions for

entering the EU. Others seem to be more pessimistic stating that EU is giving too mixed

signals and have problems in showing a consistent line which would constitute an efficient

pressure255

. The Serb position is that most of the negotiations with the EU on membership

conditions could be done on entity level and some even states that if that is not acceptable

they would rather stay outside the EU. The voters might, however, not agree to this line, in

particular if Serbia is admitted membership.

A precondition for progress seems to be more coordination and consistency within the

international community if they at all shall have a say on the progress. But it is the voters

who, after having seen the progress in the region at large, can give the clear message if they

want change.

255

The police reform is often used as an example where wrong information was given what was international

precedence for organising police districts, and the international community had back down on their position.

Page 177: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

175

7: Conclusions and Recommendations

7.1 Conflicts and Tools

7.1.1 The Type of Conflicts Studied

As mentioned in the introduction the countries included in this study are limited to those with

quotas for ethnic, confessional, linguistic or social groups as an imbedded part of the system

of representation of national parliaments. The conflicts included are therefore such conflicts

which ended with a power-sharing agreement where quotas are one of the elements. These

are of different kinds: In some countries the quotas directly reflect the combating groups. In

Bosnia and Herzegovina, Lebanon and Burundi that is the case and the quotas work along

with decision-making rules (written or unwritten) to create a balance between the groups

earlier in conflict or at war. In other countries, such as Nepal and the Philippines, the conflict

was fought between political groups but the underlying causes where social or ethnic

discrimination. The quotas in Nepal intend to address that conflict but in the Philippines there

is no such agreement which is relevant to the conflict.

In Latin America there have also been a number of civil wars or insurgencies with an

ideological identity but where the basis is deep social or ethnical divisions. None of these

conflicts have resulted in power-sharing agreements which are covered in this study. All

those countries have, however, introduced electoral systems with a strong element of

proportional representation which in itself provides for inclusiveness.

7.1.2 The Tools

In the following we will summarise the quotas used by (or discussed in) the countries of the

study regardless of their purpose. After that we will discuss the effect of such arrangements

in countries in conflict and then in the end we provide a list of possible quotas – the tool box.

7.2 Quotas and Veto Powers in Conflict-Ridden Societies. Main Findings

In the beginning of this study we asked a number of research questions that has guided the

work. The aim has not been to give conclusive answers but rather to demonstrate the

academic and policy-related relevance of the themes raised, and to arrive at tentative

recommendations that we think should be taken into account by policymakers and experts

involved in democratic transitions in conflict-ridden states.

- To what extent is (minority) group representation in parliament able (sufficient) to

reduce conflict?

The main consideration here is if it is possible to see significant effects of the way in which

electoral systems are designed relevant to group representation in processes of democratic

transition. One conclusion based on our data is that we cannot identify any case where special

provisions for group representation, with a particular focus on quota arrangements, has had a

negative effect, i.e. that such provisions in itself has strengthened inter-communal conflict. It

is however possible to demonstrate that choice of electoral system in such situations can have

a direct effect on the distribution of political power in a country, including government

Page 178: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

176

formation. Representation of groups that have been involved in open conflict is, however, no

guarantee for more permanent peaceful relations. Some groups might boycott participation

because their share of power turned out to be lesser than they had expected or were promised.

Another decisive factor is the actual power of political institutions, particularly the

parliament. In many countries, the parliament plays a secondary role in distributing real

power in society and as the main arena for brokering power-sharing deals. In such cases

design of the electoral system will have a reduced significance. In some countries, e.g.,

Lebanon and Bosnia and Herzegovina, the picture is further complicated by the fact that

external actors and powers have a direct influence on the internal balance of power between

contending groups. In these countries representation in parliament did not prevent the war to

break out but a peace agreement would have been impossible without guaranteed group

representation.

In the Philippines, the plurality system does not offer smaller parties a realistic possibility of

representation in parliament beyond the rather artificial arrangements for ‘sectors’ of society.

The Communist Party of the Philippines was re-established at the beginning of the Ferdinand

Marcos dictatorship and it is impossible to assess if the insurgency still prevailing could have

been prevented by a fair representation in a democratic parliament. However, a lasting peace

deal should include electoral reform as an important component giving the parties to the

conflict a real possibility of being represented according to their support.

In Nepal, the representation of earlier excluded groups is the new and essential element of the

representative democracy. The electoral system includes a strong element of proportional

representation which would secure the Maoists a fair share of the seats in the first parliament

even if they should not have done very well. In the 2008 elections, the Maoists became the

biggest party and took advantage of the plurality part of the mixed system but the political and

group diversity would not have been secured without the electoral reform prior to that

election.

In Burundi guaranteed representation of the groups in conflict has been essential to the peace

deal whereas in Rwanda toning down the ethnic conflict has been imposed. With the

autocratic regimes the actual effects of the opposite models are difficult to monitor.

In Iraq the Saddam Hussein regime had the Sunni minority as its power base. The List PR

system introduced in 2005 secured all parties fair representation and the Shi’as became

dominant in the parliament. Suppression of the largest confessional group was brought to an

end and the Kurdish minority did also get a substantial share in the parliament. Iraq is still not

at peace and to what extent this will be sufficient to establish a lasting peace is too early to

assess.

- To what extent are formal power-sharing agreements including veto powers

necessary to establish peace?

There is no doubt that a peace agreement in Bosnia and Herzegovina had to include rather

strong decision-making rules to establish a power balance between the groups. The question

is if the elements that have produced a dysfunctional state could have been avoided by being

clearer on the definition of vital interests, limiting the use of entity voting to certain decisions

Page 179: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

177

and limiting the powers of the House of Peoples. If such rules could not be avoided, one

might have been able to institutionalise a review conference with powers to reform the system

in a more dynamic manner than a constitutional reform which is almost impossible to carry

through because of the veto powers.

In Burundi, the requirement for qualified majorities encourage consensus but will sooner or

later lead to stalemates which will weaken the parliament as an institution.

The main features of the Taif Agreement of 1989 that ended the civil war in Lebanon spelled

out a formal power-sharing arrangement including a grand coalition government. This

arrangement was essential to convincing the conflicting parties to lay down arms and

reengage in parliamentary politics. A critical aspect of the arrangement is the institution of

veto power that gives the groups certain guarantees for protecting vital interests also in the

absence of mutual trust. A side effect of this arrangement is a weak executive and

governmental inefficiency. Most stakeholders expressed however that such inefficiency is a

prize worth paying for peaceful relations. The Taif Agreement foresees a reform of the

institutions and gives the direction towards a more efficient and less confession-based system

but this process of reform has not yet started.

- To what extent must the group elect its own representatives (as opposed to be

quotas on regular party elections) to be able to reduce conflict?

In Bosnia and Herzegovina and in Lebanon this issue has led to controversies. The Croats

claim that their representative in the presidency is elected by the other groups and they have

insisted on a maintaining the system where only the Croat caucus of the entity House of

Peoples elect the Croat members of the country level House of Peoples. In Lebanon, the

Christians complain that the Muslim majority in many constituencies decide the Christian

representation.

There is no simple answer to this. By splitting the electorate one introduces a static element

institutionalising the division as a permanent feature. If people’s priorities should change

towards more political than ethnic divisions, the system would still lock parties and actors at

large into an ethnic formula. In other cases, the distance from those electing and the elected

may be too large. An obvious example is the religious minority representation in Pakistan

where the accountability towards the minority constituency is weak. Instead, imbedding

quotas into a List PR system where everybody vote in the same race may offer a good

compromise and above all secure the dynamics needed to reflect changes to the priorities over

time. A reform in Lebanon replacing the block vote with quotas, with a List PR system with

quotas would accommodate the Christians’ concern there. In Pakistan, a direct election of the

minorities’ representatives replacing the add-on system used today could strengthen the

accountability. Further divisions of the electorate in Bosnia and Herzegovina would probably

work in favour of more unwanted division. A more progressive reform working in the

opposite direction would be to establish an electoral system to the House of Peoples which

would not hamper the success of multi-ethnic parties.

In Nepal, a splitting of the electorate has not been seriously discussed among the main parties

but it has been floated by group representatives from time to time. Such a move would

Page 180: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

178

clearly accelerate the group division rather than reducing it. The main challenge is to

maintain a direct election of all representatives of the excluded groups (with everybody

voting) and not to introduce indirect elections or appointments of such representatives,

suggestions that has been on the table from time to time.

- What are effects of the arrangements (in particular power-sharing) on efficiency,

ability to govern?

In Bosnia and Herzegovina, it is obvious that the power-sharing arrangements have led to

weak central powers. The real powers rest with the entities and the international High

Representative. In particular the Bosniacs advocate a stronger and more efficient central

government. In Lebanon the powers are concentrated with leaders of the groups once in

conflict, but they are not necessarily members of the elected bodies. Many stakeholders seem

to accept that the lack of efficiency of elected bodies is an acceptable price to pay for peace.

In Nepal, the ideal of consensus governments to be established in the transition period until a

new constitution had been adopted, proved very difficult to implement in practise. The

procedures for electing a majority government (which was the fall-back system already

described in the interim constitution) also failed and had to be changed both in the

constitution and in the standing procedures of parliament before they could produce a

government efficiently. Such changes were consequently made. In Bosnia and Herzegovina,

some moderate reforms were implemented at an early stage but from 2005 it has not been

possible to agree on reforms of the power-sharing.

A general lesson is that peace agreements should to a larger degree take a realistic view on the

requirements of an efficient state, either by limiting cumbersome decision rules or by

including a subsequent reform process. The latter is the case in Nepal since the consensus

rules are limited to an interim period and in Lebanon where the Taif Agreement describes a

more dynamic permanent solution. In Lebanon, the commitment of the parties to implement

the reform process has, however, not been strong enough.

- What are the long-term effects of the arrangements? Do they deepen the divide

between groups or do they contribute to normalise them?

In Nepal, people are more conscious on ethnicity and caste than before the war. Unless the

system of representation is being changed in the constitution now being drafted at the time of

writing the direction may be towards more division rather than more equality. A shift from

quotas affecting everybody to targeted quotas for excluded groups only may change this

trend.

In Bosnia and Herzegovina, the identity of many people before the war was ’Yugoslav’ not

Bosniac, Croat or Serb. The war created a division256

with a basic lack of trust between the

groups and fear of suppression. Even with a large number of mixed marriages the feeling of

group identity prevails. Clearly, the confessional divide in Lebanon became much stronger

by the war. The question is if arrangements can be found that would reduce the conflicts and

256

It is not obvious that the war was a result of the division but the end result was certainly strengthened group

identity.

Page 181: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

179

fears over time rather than deepening them. The ethnic cleansing in Bosnia and Herzegovina

has proven difficult to reverse. There are fewer areas than before the war where the people

live in mixed communities.

Any peace agreement will need to take the actual situation into account, identify the groups in

conflict, and issue them with rights. However, by use of representative models which would

also be able to absorb changes to people’s priorities and to review the systems over time one

may create a dynamic which may reduce rather than accentuate differences over time

7.3 Methods for Group Representation

7.3.1 What Did the Study Show?

Representation of special groups is quite common. We have found 36 countries with electoral

arrangements for ethnic, linguistic, social and religious groups. In addition there are countries

which have gender quotas and quotas for particular professions, youth, etc. The purpose of

the quotas is in a few cases related directly to conflict between groups, but in most cases it is

to ensure that groups which are otherwise excluded are included in parliament. This could

have a conflict-prevention effect even though there have not been violent conflicts in the

country.

In some cases, the arrangements are made for small groups whose voting power would

otherwise not be strong enough to secure representation. When they are given quotas it could

be to secure at least one or few representatives, which might still leave them underrepresented

or, in some cases, actually by intention provide them with overrepresentation. In other cases it

might be larger shares of the population which are provided for a quota in parliament, because

they are traditionally excluded. This could be socially underprivileged groups (Dalits or

ethnic groups in India and Nepal, Maoris in New Zealand) and they are provided for by

special arrangements which may secure a certain representation which may or may not be in

proportion to their share of the population. For example, Christians in Palestine are secured

over-representation based upon their previous strong position in the territory, whereas

women’s quotas in general almost never secure their full share of the population.

The main groups in a post-conflict situation may, as part of a power-sharing agreement, be

secured a fixed representation in the parliament. The share may be negotiated and not

necessarily represent a proportional share of the population. In Lebanon the share is set to

fifty percent for both Christians and Muslims, even though the latter group is now the bigger,

and in Bosnia and Herzegovina the three groups in conflict are each given one-third of the

members of the upper chamber of the parliament, which gives the Croats strong

overrepresentation.

The arrangements for achieving the desired representation vary a lot. Some fall into the

categories we already introduced in Chapter 2, but some are quite different from that. In a

number of cases, the rules for group representation are designed to ‘repair’ an electoral

system which has not had the ability to produce the desired representation. One has decided

on a general system of representation based on political considerations and notes that the

result is not coming out as representative as desired. Instead of looking for a total overhaul of

Page 182: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

180

the system amendments are made that may directly benefit specific groups without taking into

careful considerations what possible side effects the rules might have. The most obvious

example of such rules is where the parliament or the executive appoints members of

parliament to represent certain groups257

. If this is done to the principal chamber of

parliament it violates the commonly accepted principle that one house of parliament shall be

directly elected. The other common manner in which the side effects are not paid attention to

is where the electoral system for the groups are based upon other principles than the general

and possibly preferred one.258

A third category includes systems where the political (party-

wise) composition of the parliament is affected by the group representation rules.259

The study brought up a number of arrangements, which partly did not involve elections and

partly were based upon indirect elections where the electorate would not necessarily be

representative. These repair-rules made to mend a flawed system could always be replaced

by systems which would form more integral parts of the electoral system rather than add-ons

which break with the over-all system of representation. In the next section we will look into

some systems which may work well, and in the section after that we shall go through some

unfortunate systems in use and suggest how the underlying intentions could be covered by a

more regular and integrated system.

7.3.2 Workable Quota Arrangements

As stated earlier the arrangements should fit with the general system of representation used in

the country. With List PR it is easier to include quota arrangements than with FPTP in single-

member constituencies. The choice of general electoral system is often based upon long

traditions and is not only a result of a conscious political choice. The choice of special

representation for groups is often not that conscious and has therefore sometimes been given

strange shapes. In the following we will mainly consider the two main systems: List PR and

FPTP in single-member constituencies. These would also cover mixed systems where quota

arrangements may be combined with either of the two races.

Block vote (FPTP in multi-member constituencies) is not a system recommended for multi-

party elections to parliament because of its winner-takes-all qualities, but the system is

discussed only because it is used in a few countries together with quotas. SNTV and STV

will be covered to some extent, even though few countries use them.

In the following we will advice on some systems which may be a good response to specific

needs for group representation.

257

For example in Nepal in 2008.

258 Philippines.

259 The Palestinian Territory.

Page 183: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

181

Guaranteeing a minority which otherwise is unrepresented a minimum representation in

parliament – affirmative action

The group may represent interests which are often different from those of the majority and

should therefore be guaranteed a voice in parliament. They may be a discriminated social

group (e.g. Dalits and under-privileged castes in India and Nepal), an ethnic group with

interests which may be in conflict to the main stream politics or religious or linguistic

minorities.

Constituency delimitation

If the group is geographically concentrated the simplest is to draw the constituencies in such a

way that the group is guaranteed representation even if the constituency may be smaller than

the norm (e.g. Åland in Finland). This secures the representation, the group elects their own

representation and it has few negative side effects. The only problem with the constituency

solution may be that such constituency may have an unusual small magnitude and thus affect

the equality of the vote. This could be, however, an intended effect. Even if it does have an

effect on the overall political party composition of the parliament it is internationally

acceptable. Under a List PR system (and STV and SNTV) a side effect of small

constituencies is that the degree of proportionality may be reduced. If the constituency is

given more seats than its population should account for the equality of the vote is affected as

well. However, under a List PR system these two side effects can be amended by nation-wide

compensatory seats. With a sufficient number of such seats to be distributed among parties

based upon the nation-wide results the political composition of the parliament is not affected

by over-representing a geographical area or by making an unusual small constituency.260

Separate race

In many cases the small group which needs affirmative action is not geographically

concentrated. One solution which may be used independently of the electoral system is a

separate race for that group. This may be done either with a separate voters register for the

group allowing only members of the group to vote for the reserved seats or without such

register. In the latter case one may either let every voter vote both in the general election and

in the separate race or one may allow the voter to make a choice in secrecy for which race he

or she wants to participate, without checking the group belonging. All these arrangements

have their own qualities.

In Croatia, there has since independence been quotas for Serbs and other minorities, organised

as a separate race. Initially it was up to the voter on election day to decide which race to

participate in. It was then reported that polling station staff would intimidate Serbs to take the

Serb ballot and not the ballot of the general race. Seen from a Serb point of view it might,

however, be more rational to participate in the general race, since they were guaranteed the

reserved seats anyway. It is doubtful if the opposite happened to any extent; that Croats

wanted to influence the choice of Serbs. It could therefore not be claimed that the Serb

260

Finland has not introduced compensatory seats to make up for disproportional results which the small Åland

constituency may contribute to.

Page 184: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

182

representatives were elected by the Croat majority. This arrangement was later changed and

now minority group members may choose to register in a separate civil and voters register.

The principle of individual choice is maintained, the voters vote for their representatives. The

drawback seen from a minority point of view is that the choice is made well in advance of the

elections and it takes some effort to change the registration.

With a limited number of minorities and a well functional registration system a separate

registry may work well. In other situations, such as in Nepal with more than one hundred

groups, such arrangements would not be practical. There a separate race would only work if

one allowed people to make the choice on election day.

Allowing everybody to vote in both (or all) races is an option. This would guarantee minority

representation but a minority may feel that their representatives have been chosen by the

majority and not by them. This system is used in some countries to secure women’s

representation where the purpose is to achieve gender balance, not to have women

representing women in parliament.

If the voter has to choose the race there is always a tactical element. By voting in the general

race a minority voter may get it in two ways: having a representation independent on the vote

and still being able to influence the political composition in the main race. This may,

however, be a possibility which is intended and accepted by the majority.

Nomination requirements

The implementation of nomination requirements will depend a lot on the electoral system and

so will the effects on actual representation. In systems based upon single-member

constituencies (and block vote for that matter) there have been attempts to require a certain

number of the candidates of a party to belong to a group. However, this will not necessarily

translate into representation since the parties may choose to put forward group candidates in

constituencies where they are not likely to win the seats. The only efficient quota

arrangement under single-member constituencies would be if all candidates of a constituency

have to come from a group, which is covered under the next section.

In List PR systems, it is more common to have requirements on candidacy and the effects are

more significant. If the requirements are simply to nominate a certain percentage of

candidates on a list the effect may be small since the party may choose to put the minority

candidates on losing positions, even though the incentives are strong for giving them a more

prominent position if the party wants to attract the group’s votes. However, it is common to

combine this quota system with requirements to prominent placement on the lists and the

actual effects on representation become more predictable. In the case of open lists the effects

still tend to be more representation of the group even though the voters may change the

sequence on the lists.

Requirements on the result

In single-member constituencies this is either done by defining extra super-constituencies

where all candidates have to be from a certain group or by earmarking some of the

constituencies for a group only. The first is for example used for female representation in

Page 185: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

183

Egypt, Uganda, Kenya and some other countries. In Egypt area of three regular

constituencies make out one women’s super-constituency and in Kenya each county

represents a women only constituency. This arrangement could also be used for minorities

but there are no such examples. This is very similar to a separate race open to all voters.

In India certain geographical constituencies may only be contested by scheduled castes and

tribes. This restricts the right to stand for elections for those not belonging to the group in the

sense that they will have to stand in some other constituency, not the one they might have

preferred. The system is accepted in India and may work in other places as well.

In Kenya there has been discussion on another alternative system to secure women’s

representation in the single-member constituencies.261

In each single-member constituency

the parties should suggest a ticket of two ranked candidates, one man and one woman. In

case that there will not be a sufficient number of women (or in principle even men) elected

some tickets will have a number-two ranked women elected instead of the number-one man.

Only so many tickets are changed which are needed for meeting the one-third requirement

and it is the ticket with the relatively weakest electoral support that are changed.

In multi-member constituencies, one may use variants of best runner-up systems to guarantee

representation. In a List PR system the shift up would be within a list and would therefore not

affect party distribution of seats. In block vote and SNTV the best runner-up system has been

used to elect group candidates regardless of party affiliation and a candidate of a minority of

one party may therefore push out a candidate from another party262

. This is a regrettable side

effect which should be avoided.

It is possible to define a system whereby the shift takes place only within a party also in the

case of block vote and SNTV (and STV) but that would create strong incentives for running

as independent candidates instead of under party affiliation and would probably not work.

Block vote systems should in general be avoided in multi-party national elections because of

its winner-takes-all nature. SNTV has some serious drawbacks on promoting tactical voting

behaviour. STV is a robust electoral system but there is no straight-forward way of

implementing quotas without altering the party representation. It is possible, though, but one

will have to accept that candidates with very little individual support may be elected in such

case.

Representing groups according to a preset exact or close to exact formula

This is mainly a requirement after conflict when the groups want to secure a fixed balance

between the conflicting groups (Bosnia and Herzegovina and Lebanon). There is also an

example where the need for representing underprivileged groups has resulted in a demand for

261

The new constitution of 2010 requires that at least one-third of the members of parliament are women but the

system laid out in detail in the constitution does not guarantee this. Some systems have been presented publicly

in order to give such guarantees without making big changes to the prescribed system.

262 In principle this could also be done under STV but we know of no such example.

Page 186: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

184

all groups, even the privileged, being represented according to their proportional share of the

population. In Nepal this demand has strong but the implementation has only been on the List

PR side of a mixed system, which means that some excluded groups have got their share in

the List PR part of elections but have remained excluded in the single-member constituency

part of the election. It remains to be seen what principle will win in the constitution still

being drafted in 2011 – inclusiveness or proportionality. In the following it is the conflict

situation which is the scenario but the discussion is valid to a large extent even for situations

like Nepal.

The vision

In deeply divided societies, one will need to strike the balance between granting political

group rights, which may even go beyond the group’s strength in the population, and

maintaining individual rights. Group rights in terms of cultural protection, development of

language, etc are not problematic in this context. Political rights which come out of an

agreement with the aim of keeping a balance between the groups over time may, however,

rather deepen than reduce differences. A peace treaty will first of all state that the groups in

conflict shall stop the hostilities and it will deal with disarmament, return of displaced

persons, property, etc. The vision for the country may include:

Maintaining mutual respect for the groups identity, religion, language, and way of life;

Establishing forms of self rule within reasonable areas, such as religion and culture,

and sometimes beyond that;

Establishing a regular political scene where the group belonging is less important.

That would include encouragement of political parties across groups and where

regular political issues and ideologies would be the focus of their platforms rather

than group identity;

Establishing a society where cultural differences are an integral common value but

where the belonging to a group is not predefining a person in all respects;

Developing a society where it is up to the individual’s free choice to invoke group

rights or to individual rights only;

Creating a society which protects the individual’s rights and where any group rights

employed does not limit any person’s basic human rights.

Some of these principles are blueprints of international conventions but others are less

obvious: In particular the ideal of creating a political system where political parties reach

beyond group interests and develops into organisations based on a political action plans for

the country. In a number of divided societies this is a main challenge, such as in Bosnia and

Herzegovina, Lebanon, Iraq, etc.

If a society based upon equality is the ideal it means that the quota arrangements should be

structured in such a way that they have inbuilt incentives for cross group politics,

reconciliation, and dialogue. To achieve that one may look for arrangements which are less

divisive and constitute a more integral part of a general electoral system rather than for

systems which may strengthen the separation.

Page 187: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

185

Who votes?

One fundamental question is who elect the group representatives. This has been an issue in

Bosnia and Herzegovina where in particular Croats claim that their representative in the

national presidency is elected by votes from other groups than the Croats and in Lebanon

where the Christians claim that in some constituencies the Muslims decide who to represent

them.

After a conflict between ethnic or confessional groups it is important that people feel that

those elected to represent them is actually representing them. That does not mean that there

should be exclusive electorates in separate races for all groups. Electoral systems based upon

lists would encourage diversity while separate electorate may encourage division. When the

population is mixed the only way of securing that for example the Croats votes for the Croats

is to keep a separate voter register for the group and have a separate race for the group. This

raises a number of other issues: The definition of who belongs to the group, the complexity if

there are a number of groups, the pressure that may be in place for registration as a group

member, and thus violate the principle of free choice, etc. Most important is, however, that

people from the same neighbourhood and area, vote for totally different candidates even if

they may have similar political programmes. Because of the group belonging a person may

be deprived the right to vote for the party and the candidates which may cover the person’s

views best, only because of the group belonging. It is therefore often agreed that in most

cases everybody should be able to vote for everybody in a constituency. In addition if

diversity is promoted rather than division the system may by more dynamic and reflect

changes to the electorate’s priorities in a better way that a static division resulting from a

power-sharing agreement263

.

That does not mean, however, that constituencies should not be drawn up in such a way that

people feel represented along several dimensions, also group-wise. This may be combined

with a system of federalism or devolution of powers to keep the balance of powers without

the use of special group representation.

Constituencies

Constituencies may be drawn in such a way that minorities or groups at large are guaranteed

representation. Federal states also serve as the basis for representation at national level and

some federal states are drawn up so that the group identity of the states is strong (Switzerland,

Ethiopia). With devolution of powers and protection against the majority’s possibility to

change the rules of the game, this may be sufficient to diffuse conflict.

There is, however, another school of thought: After conflict one might design an electoral

system which would promote reconciliation and dialogue between groups and where the

moderate leaders within groups previously in conflict should have a good chance of being

elected. Some experts have on strongly promoted the alternative vote system (AV) combined

with design of constituencies where the groups are as mixed as possible in order to achieve

263

Lijphard 2008.

Page 188: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

186

that. Fiji is the most prominent example of this done in practice264

. The constituencies are

drawn up with the aim to make the Indians and the indigenous Fijians as equal in number as

possible. The constituencies are single-member and the candidates are individuals which may

belong to parties or be independents. The voter will rank the candidates by preference and a

candidate needs support of at least half of the electorate to be elected. The ballots will first be

sorted by first preference. If a candidate has won more than fifty percent of the votes he or she

is elected straight. If no candidate has won such a majority one will continue with rounds of

counting where the second and further preferences are coming into the count.

The theory is that even if a voter would prefer a candidate who is standing firm on his own

identity he would vote for a more moderate candidate of the opposite identity with lower

preference before voting for a radical candidate of that identity. A candidate would therefore

need to appeal not only his or her own group but would seek support of other groups as well.

The reason for trying to balance the groups within a constituency is to avoid that a radical

candidate running on groups identity programme is elected straight based upon first

preferences.

The system in Fiji has not been a great success with two coup d’états since the election

reform in 1999265

. The criticism in Fiji is that the constituencies are seen to be drawn up in

artificial way and that the system represents electoral engineering to achieve a particular

result rather than providing a representative parliament. A similar system was suggested in

Bosnia and Herzegovina in 1999 but rejected by both political leaders and prominent leaders

of the civil society. They did not want a system based upon single-member constituencies

because they were convinced that the voters would vote ethnically in such case. With List PR

in multimember constituencies (which they had from before) it would be easier to convince

people to vote for multi-ethnic lists since their group would be properly represented anyway.

AV may be a system which works well in some situations. In particular, when a president is

to be elected in a country of conflict it can be a very good alternative to a two-round system

(which basically tries to achieve the same). However, the combination with drawing

constituencies which the general public find artificial may work against its purpose and the

ability to represent minorities is just as weak as any other majoritarian system.

Separate race

A separate race is possible to combine with any systems of representation. It may be done

with or without a separate voters register. The elections of the Croat and the Bosniac

members of the presidency of Bosnia and Herzegovina are in principle two separate races.

There is no group identification of the voters and each voter may choose in secrecy whether to

participate in the Croat race or the Bosniac race. Most voters would probably be most

interested in ‘their own’ representative but Serbs and other groups may choose any race.

Croats claim that even Bosniac voters vote in ‘their’ race and thus insure that a moderate

264

Donald Horowitz was a main architect and has written a lot about AV in Fiji and other scholars has written

more critical reviews, such as Lijphart 2008.

265 In 2000 and 2006.

Page 189: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

187

person is elected. One may claim that it is an advantage that everybody can cast their vote in

any of the races. Representatives of the Croat parties argue that the real Croats are only those

running from parties with ‘Croat’ in their names. According to them candidates running on

multi-ethnic parties cannot properly represent the Croats.

The presidency is not the most important body in Bosnia and Herzegovina. However, the

system is open for tactical behaviour which may benefit the parties which are best at

predicting the voters’ vote and to control the voting of their own electorate. A better method

could have been STV with quotas to ensure that one Bosniac and one Croat are elected. This

would have ensured proportionality in the party-wise representation and every voter would in

principle have influence in the election of both members of the presidency, without tactical

planning of the vote.266

Requirement to the result

If one wants to guarantee certain group representation the arrangements will depend on the

general system of representation. Quotas with FPTP will generally have more negative side

effects that List PR and in some cases one may want to change the general system of

representation to be able to include the group representation in a good manner.

Elections in single-member constituencies combined with exact quotas may only be

implemented by reserving constituencies to each group.267

Such system would be equivalent

to separate race(s).

For multi-member constituencies the discussion is as for the minority representation above.

It is quite easy to combine exact quotas with List PR (like in Nepal) but for block vote, SNTV

and STV the party representation may be changed by the quota rules.

Despite that, the block vote system is combined with exact quotas in Lebanon. There the

implementation is done without pre-printed ballots (which would make the risk of many

invalid votes high) and allowing the parties and alliances to print their own ballots instead.

Those ballots are widely used and the system has therefore almost degenerated to a party

block vote system. Only in one constituency the alliances were broken during the 2009

election.

The Dynamics of the Methods of Representation

The electoral system should translate the will of the voters into a representative parliament.

That means that shifts in the electorate’s preferences should be reflected in the result. A

power-sharing agreement may limit the dynamics of the representation. If the agreement sets

the balance between the groups because that is important at the time of the agreement, a shift

in the preferences of the electorate would not change this balance (Lebanon and Bosnia and

Herzegovina) unless the quotas are linked to the share of the population as measured in a

266

Even better would it be if all three (or even four if the discriminatory exclusion of other groups is amended by

adding one member) had been elected by all voters across the entity lines. STV with quotas would then be an

excellent choice.

267 Or with ranked tickets as discussed above.

Page 190: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

188

census (India, Nepal). After conflict ethnicity may mean everything to the voters but after

some time the priorities may shift to political issues. Electoral systems have different ways of

responding to such changes in preferences in the electorate.

The STV system may be one of the most dynamic systems in that respect. The voters rank the

individual candidates according to their preferences. If ideology is dominant the voters would

rank all candidates of their preferred party first and then the candidates closest to their own

party. If ethnicity, gender, geography, age or other priorities are more important the voter

will rank the candidates accordingly. Different voters may have different dimensions of

priorities in the same election and the system would give a proportional representation along a

complex set of dimensions. STV therefore may be said to give an immediate response to the

shifts of the priorities in the electorate.

List PR systems would basically respond to the party priority of the electorate. Parties may

be formed on the basis of ethnicity (Bosnia and Herzegovina), age (the party Fidesz in

Hungary268

) or other dimensions of representation and the system will therefore be able to

reflect shifts in priorities. The response will, however, have to be institutionalised for

example by formation of parties. If the parties are group based the groups will be represented

according to their strengths as long as the voters feel group identity is important. If group

identity is not important any more voters may shift to parties based upon their political

platform instead.

The elections of the members to the Federation of Bosnia and Herzegovina (the entity) House

of Peoples have to be done in separate caucuses for Bosniacs, Croats and Others in each

canton assembly of the entity. That contributes to cementing the group divisions and works

against the incentives to form multi-ethnic parties. A system where all members of the

assemblies vote for all representatives but with quotas would not have that effect.

In FPTP there are few incentives for parties to nominate candidates (of the constituency) of

the minorities since they have less chance to be elected. Small changes in party preferences

may give big changes in the result but group representation will remain conservative.

Two round systems and AV will give a possibility to compromise candidates but in other

ways have the same effects as FPTP and not really reflecting minorities in any systematic

manner.

7.3.3 Alternatives to Systems that Should be Avoided

At least one chamber of parliament should be directly elected. A number of countries, not

least in Africa, have chosen to give special minority (and even gender) representation by

appointments or indirect elections rather than by direct elections by the voters. This is

probably most often done for simplicity but it could also be done to secure representation

which is loyal to the executive powers of the country.

268

The upper limit of 35 years for membership was abolished in 1993.

Page 191: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

189

Further there are election based systems which should be avoided because of their side

effects. The side effects may include:

- The system may change the party-wise representation in the parliament. This happens

for example in best runner-up systems in candidate based multi-member

constituencies269

.

- The system may restrict the voters’ choice to an unacceptable level. The voters’

choice will always be restricted by quotas but not necessarily to an unacceptable level.

- The right to stand for elections may be restricted to an unacceptable level. The

candidates’ rights will always be restricted by quotas but not necessarily to an

unacceptable level.

- The complexity of the system may be too high (e.g. Nepal in 2008).

- The incentives may not be right in that it is more divisive than necessary and therefore

consolidate differences rather than bridge them. With group quotas as least the

candidates need to be identified, but such identification should be kept to a minimum.

- The accountability may be weak because the group representation comes as a by-

product of another vote (Pakistan and Kenya from 2010) or of a winner takes all

system favouring the largest party (Singapore).

It may sometimes not be possible to design a system which combines the general system of

representation and quotas in an integrated manner without negative side effects. The general

system may therefore have to be redesigned in order to accommodate group representation in

a reasonable manner.

One possibility is always to define a separate race for a minority group. This may be done

either by allowing everybody to vote in both the general and the special race or by a separate

voters’ register, but if there are many groups which are to be represented it becomes too

complicated. This is illustrated by the example of the system used in Sudan in 2010 the last

election before South Sudan voted for secession270

. Sudan decided on using a parallel system

for the election of the national legislator, the legislator of Southern Sudan and the provinces

(states). That meant that each of these three elections held simultaneously with three

executive elections would need two ballots each. In addition they decided to have separate

race for women in all three legislatures each with yet another ballot. All together voters in

Southern Sudan had to cast twelve ballots and in the rest of the country eight ballot. The

Carter Center commented in their preliminary statement after the election: “The electoral

system, as established within the National Elections Act, is highly complex and has led to

confusion among the public and significant problems in its implementation.”271

It would not have been difficult to find simpler solutions meeting the possible intentions. The

National Legislative Assembly had 450 members elected according to the following three

269

Block vote, SNTV and STV, but not List PR.

270 Sudan is not described in previous sections since they do not have other quotas than the women’s quota. Here

it is used only to illustrate unnecessary complexities.

271 The Carter Center 2010

Page 192: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

190

races (and the two other legislative bodies had similar structures):

i) 270 (60 percent) elected in single-member constituencies

ii) 112 (25 percent) women elected at province level in closed PR lists. (Average

constituency magnitude 4.5)

iii) 68 (15 percent) elected at province level in closed PR lists. (Average constituency

magnitude 2.7)

With the constituency magnitude of two to five, List PR would not produce an overall

proportional result within the List PR parts of the election. Small parties would have little

chance to be elected272

. The parallel system was chosen as a compromise between the two

dominant parties (NCP in the north and SPLM in the south). The List PR part was

substantially smaller that the FPTP part (40 percent against 60 percent) but the proportionality

was weakened even further by splitting the List PR vote into two races, even with the same

electorate of the provinces. The extra ballot for women was difficult to justify both from a

complexity and representation point of view. It would have been easy to reduce it to two

races and ballots by simply introduce a 65 percent quota on the PR lists in a combined race.

This would have increased the proportionality and allowed more of the smaller parties to win

seats.273

When the general system is FPTP, a separate race may be a more adequate choice for

minority representation. If the group is geographically concentrated delimitation of

constituencies may be sufficient. An alternative would be create a meta-constituency

covering the country or a region and provide an extra ballot voting for the group candidates

(Egypt for women, etc). With many groups this become too complicated and a shift to List

PR may be considered.

If the general system is FPTP, one may introduce a separate race with List PR for minority

representation. It is similar to what is done in the Philippines but there the groups are not

defined274

. In for example Niger where the general system is List PR it would have been

more logical to define one List PR constituency for all the minorities combined and used

quota rules as per Appendix B to ensure representation instead of introducing eight single-

member constituencies. A similar system could have been used in Rwanda and other

countries using systems where the voters have little say in the minority representation.

272

Only five seats were won by other parties that the two dominant ones and four of the five were won in the

province of Southern Sudan by a party with concentrated support there.

273 NCP and SPLM may have intended to keep small parties out but some generosity would probably have had a

positive long term effect in Sudan

274 The seats are reserved for “small parties” not groups, which makes the system quite arbitrarily.

Page 193: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

191

The systems used in Kenya (according to the constitution passed by referendum 4 August

2010) and Pakistan are better than the ones described above but the distance from the voters

to those elected is unnecessarily long. In both countries, the parties will before the election

suggest lists of minority candidates (and in Pakistan also for women) and the parties win such

seats according to their strength in parliament resulting from an FPTP election. The balance

between the parties is therefore maintained but the voter will by casting a vote in a single-

member constituency not necessarily being aware that the vote also counts for the minority

representation. A separate ballot within a direct List PR vote would reduce the distance, and

this could have been combined even with women’s representation so that only two ballots

would be needed.

In Mauritius, the main system is block vote but at the same time they want the four

communities to have shares in the seventy member parliament in accordance with their share

of the population. This is done by adding eight seats to the parliament which are filled by the

best runner-ups from groups which are underrepresented. There is an attempt to look to the

political balance with a rather intricate system where four out of the eight are given to parties

which won the highest share of the votes in the constituencies, and to the underrepresented

communities. However, it is clearly possible that the allocation of the eight seats may change

the political balance of the parliament. With block vote this cannot easily be avoided unless

one goes for something like the Pakistani or Kenyan system. If one wants to maintain the

block vote system as the general system of representation (which is not recommended due to

the winner takes all quality) one good option could be to have a mixed system where at least

the eight seats are filled from a List PR system based upon the same ballots or a separate

ballot. Then the eight seats may still change the political composition but it will be according

to a popular vote and not by random affects of the best runner-up arrangement.

Palestine has quotas for Christian in some of their multimember constituencies with FPTP

(block vote) and Jordan has quotas for women and for Christians and Circassian275

in multi-

member constituencies under SNTV. In both cases the best runner-up method is used across

parties and in both cases a group representative of one party may push out a candidate from

another party. This gave Fatah FPTP seats that would otherwise have gone to Hamas in 2006.

A better way would be to either change to a list based system or to have a separate race

(without separate voter register) for the group representatives.

In Lebanon, every seat is marked for a group representative. Even though the principle is

block vote and best runner-up, the complexity for the voters to cast a valid ballot has in

practise transformed the system into a party block vote system. The party alliances make

deals on a combined list of candidates which for each constituency meets the quota

requirements and they print their own ballots to reflect that. If all voters are using the

privately pre-printed ballots and thus are loyal to the alliances’ deals the biggest alliance in

that constituency will win all seats. In 2009, only one constituency had candidates elected

from more than one alliance. In Nepal, the Maoists had this system as one of their options for

the new constitution.

275

The Bedouin representation is from separate constituencies.

Page 194: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

192

In Singapore, most members of parliament are elected under a party block vote system where

there are some requirements to ethnic representation of the lists. Party block vote is not just

in reality but even formally a winner-takes-all system and the smaller parties will not be

represented. The minority representatives will also always come from the biggest party of the

constituency and the minorities may not feel that their vote is taken into account in a

reasonable manner. In 2006 the ruling party won all seats in all multi-member constituencies.

The only reasonable alternative to such extensive use of quotas in multi-member

constituencies is to combine them with a List PR system; such reform is being discussed in

Lebanon (2011) and in Nepal that is the most realistic alternative for the future system, either

with the country as a whole or the provinces as constituencies.

7.4. What May Work in Conflict Situations?

7.4.1 Power-Sharing Elements

Consociational or Majority Democracy, this is a crucial question after conflict. The

alternatives may be reflected in a complex combination of representation, devolution of

powers and decision-making. This study has mainly looked into representation and decision-

making. In countries which are discussed because of the representation of particular groups

even federalism has been assessed (Bosnia and Herzegovina) but we have not included

countries where federalism is the main element of a power-sharing agreement if there are no

quota arrangements.

Should a consociational government be a permanent and inevitable feature or is it a step on

the road to a majority based system where the ethnic, linguistic or confessional belonging has

been made irrelevant? In Germany there is a consociational political culture even though it is

not written into the constitution (except for what derives from the federal structure. The

tendency to prefer broad coalitions to weaker but more political unified coalitions is a sign of

this. Switzerland is also a long lasting example of a consociational system where four

linguistic groups have been able to make common decisions while keeping their identity.

However, the balance between the linguistic groups is mainly covered by unwritten rules

where the formal rules deal with the balance between the cantons regardless of the official

language of the cantons.276

In some countries, like Germany and Switzerland, the federal system with substantive

devolution of powers is key to the consociational philosophy of governance. This also

reduces the number of issues that may cause stale mate situations centrally. Unlike in Bosnia

and Herzegovina and in Lebanon the formal requirements for regular decisions are majority,

not consensus or qualified majorities (more than 50 percent). In Germany and Switzerland

the consociational system is more of a political cultural issue, except for when the rules of

game are to be changed. Constitutional changes and entering international organisations with

supra-national powers in Switzerland need majorities in referenda both in total and a majority

276

However, the rotation of the membership of the cabinet among the linguistic groups was written into the

constitution after a referendum in 1999.

Page 195: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

193

in a majority of cantons277

. The members of the cabinet (Bundesrat) are elected one by one by

the parliament by majority vote according to the law278

but the unwritten rules secures that the

members ‘reflect the people’ which means that the parties are represented according to their

strength in the parliament in addition to the constitutional requirement of reflecting language

groups279

. The constitution also has a number of statements underlining principle of finding

agreements by negotiations and cooperation (e.g. articles 44 and 55). In Germany changes to

the constitution needs a two-thirds majority in both chambers, and laws affecting the

financing or competencies of the states need to pass the upper house in addition to the

principal chamber of the parliament.

7.4.2 Representation and Decision-Making

The ideal principle in a peace agreement is often that state affairs shall be handled in

consensus but such understanding may break down when tough decisions are to be made. In

Nepal the peace agreement of 2006 and the interim constitution of 2007 the ideal is a

consensus government including all the major parties (the seven party alliance and the

Maoists). After the 2008 elections such a government was formed after two and a half

months of negotiations but it resigned after less than nine months. After that a simple

majority government not including the biggest party (the Maoists) was formed but came

under tremendous pressure to resign to make space for a new consensus government. In May

2010 it resigned, but efforts to make a consensus government failed and in July the parliament

started a vote for a majority prime minister following the fall-back procedure of the

constitution. Only in February 2011 in the 17th vote a majority prime minister was elected

and a UML and Maoist government was formed.280

When a majority was reached during the

endless votes in 2010 the underlying reason was the intention of the peace agreement to form

consensus based government and this in turn was linked to the unresolved issues of

integration of the armies. Consensus is clearly not an efficient way of taking decisions but it

is needed immediately after conflict in order to establish a political system acceptable to all

major parties.

In Lebanon and in Bosnia and Herzegovina the consensus requirements are written into the

agreements and the constitution. In Lebanon forming the government is a struggle and key

decisions are only made after endless negotiations. In Bosnia and Herzegovina it is the

decision-making in parliament which suffers from the consensus requirement and decisions

were for twelve to thirteen years after the war only made by the international High

Representative according to his power to enact laws (the Bonn power)281

. Consensus rules

277

The constitution articles 140 and 142.

278 Federal law on the parliament (Bundesgesetz über die Bundesversammlung) Article 132, as per 1 May 2011

279 Article 175,4

280 This government resigned in August the same year and new negotiation on a consensus government failed.

At the end of August a new majority prime minister was voted in by majority vote.

281 Nobody knows what would have happened had the High Representative not enacted that many laws, see the

discussion in the in-depth study.

Page 196: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

194

were key elements of the peace agreements and possibly condition for the peace. However,

the long term vision of reducing the confessional and ethnic basis for decisions could have

been more clearly spelled out with a roadmap for how to reduce the ethnic element. In

Lebanon the Taif agreement does have such a vision but in Bosnia and Herzegovina the Serbs

and to some extent the Croats have at times rather tried to move the country in the opposite

direction.

Bosnia and Herzegovina has a federal structure of two entities with few duties given to

national level and the residual powers given to the entities. In order to make a well

functioning national state the central government is far too weak and a number of attempts

have been done to strengthen the central power. The only consistent supporters of this system

today are the majority of the elected Serb representatives from Republika Srpska. A few

initiatives to strengthen the central powers succeeded but since 2006 they have all failed. A

federal structure was clearly the only possible solution for peace in Bosnia and Herzegovina

and it was part of all peace negotiations also before Dayton. What is more uncertain is if the

actual lists of power-sharing elements between the centre and the entities could have been

made in such a way that the state at the central level could function, or if a roadmap for

reform could have been worked into the agreement (e.g. a Dayton II).

In Lebanon, consensus rules are seen in general as a necessity and the costs of reduced

efficiency are by many stakeholders seen to be worth taken even if they share a vision of a

state where such arrangements are unnecessary.

Burundi is another interesting case, not least with the contrast to Rwanda. Both countries

came out of devastating conflicts between Hutus and Tutsis but they chose very different

models for reconciliation. In Burundi rigorous quotas for the two conflicting groups are

combined with a two-thirds majority requirement for all decisions in parliament. That insures

that no ethnic group can impose decisions without some support from the other group. In

Rwanda, they chose to introduce strong regulations against any divisive laws, rules and

parties. The idea was, instead of defining the groups and securing representation, to regulate

that all people are equal and that the political system should not recognise groups at all.

Parties are not allowed to be based on group identity and they cannot discriminate against any

groups. Decisions in parliament are taken based upon regular majority rules.

Burundi and Rwanda are not rid of their political or ethnical problems. It is too early to make

an assessment of which of the two models (if any) would work since the complexity of the

current issues go beyond the ethnic dimension only. It may be that Rwanda is hiding the real

underlying problems by leaping into a civil society pretending not to see ethnic divide and

base the system on individual rights only while Burundi has introduced rules which cannot

possibly create an efficient parliament. However, none of the two countries are well

functioning democracies and one may therefore not draw conclusions based upon the different

paths chosen as if their models were free and democratic.

Page 197: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

195

The democracies which have practised a consensus model (written or unwritten) over time

have not had restrictions on regular decision-making beyond regular majorities.282

Only

constitutional changes would require special majorities and the constitution would often

define a substantial devolution of powers in particular within federal states. After conflict

rules restricting a larger class of decisions may be inevitable but they can hardly underpin a

functioning state in the long run. The following should be considered when qualified

majorities are introduced beyond constitutional changes:

The scope of decisions where qualified majorities are required should be clearly

defined and restricted to such decisions which may threaten the identity and freedom

of a group.

The rules should either have a time stamp or some other mechanisms for moving into

more regular systems.

As an alternative to qualified majority within bodies devolution of well defined

powers may be more carefully worked out.

7.4.3 Side Effects of Quotas which May not be Avoided

In general power-sharing agreements may have unwanted side effects. We already discussed

those connected to decision-making. Here we will look closer into some side effects of quota

rules which may be regrettable but still inevitable.

First of all quotas will always limit the voters’ and the parties’ choice. Quotas, regardless of

whether it is a separate race, requirements on lists or results, bring in a restriction to the right

to vote and stand for elections. If the parties have to nominate group representatives on

electable position on a list the choice is already limited. This is why quotas are still subject to

political criticism from a principle point of view. However, these are effects which

internationally are held to be acceptable if the long term aim is equality or reconciliation.

When every seat in FPTP elections are assigned to a confession like in Lebanon one may

argue that this restrict the voters’ choice more than what is acceptable. Similar quotas applied

to List PR systems would offer more flexibility and the voters’ choice would be higher.

Systems totally excluding segments of voters are not common283

, but it is common that a

system affects the equality of the vote. If a group of voters have the possibility to cast a vote

in a general election and an additional vote for a group representative such voters will have

extra weight.284

If a group is over-represented in an elected body, their voters’ have a higher

weight than others (e.g. Croats in the House of Peoples of Bosnia and Herzegovina). This is

282

But requirements to pass laws in a second chamber based upon representation of provinces or states rather

than equal vote do exist.

283 But it exists in Bosnia and Herzegovina for the House of Peoples and the Presidency.

284 In the case of indirect elections in a number of African countries, it is the organised members of the groups

which have these extra possibilities, but we do not discuss that further since we do not recommend such

appointments at all.

Page 198: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

196

an intended quality of the system and is mostly seen as acceptable if it is necessary for

promotion of equality of peace.

The limitation to stand for elections which derives from limited quotas on party lists is

generally regarded as acceptable. With a separate race for a group where all can vote but only

group representatives can stand for elections gives this group an advantage provided they can

also run in the general race. The Maoris in New Zealand have these double possibilities,

which are generally seen as serving the overall purpose of providing representation for

otherwise excluded groups, and they have eventually even produced overrepresentation. A

more problematic case is the system in India where more than twenty percent of the single-

member constituencies are reserved for scheduled tribes and castes. That means that persons

not belonging to those groups cannot stand for elections in the earmarked constituencies. If

he or she lives in the constituency and feel that their chance would have been better if the

person were able to run in his or her home constituency. Under the Westminster electoral

model it is on the other hand quite common to run outside the candidate’s own constituency

and this has been regarded as acceptable in India.

We have stated earlier that the quotas should not change the political party composition of the

parliament. The examples of such replacement are mainly where a best runner-up system

makes a person with fewer votes replace one with more votes from another party. One should

make attempts to find alternatives to such systems. When there is a separate race for

minorities this arrangement may clearly give a different political result than if there had been

only one main race. This is generally acceptable since the result reflects the votes in that

special race. However, one may argue that some of the systems where the special race is

conducted under another system of representation than the main race, the effect on the party

representation of the separate race becomes unnecessarily significant. The separate race in

the Philippines (List PR) gives an advantage to some small parties and the separate race in

Niger (FPTP) gives an extra advantage to the largest party. In conclusion, the separate race

should as far as possible follow the same system of representation as the main vote.

The last side effect we want to discuss is the distance between the voter and the person

elected, the accountability. Generally, accountability is used as the main justification for

FPTP in single-member constituencies but also within a List PR system the accountability is

strong if it is known to the voters which candidates are elected if the party wins a certain

number of seats and the constituencies have a reasonable magnitude. With quotas on the

result this may be slightly more complicated since there may be a best runner-up system

within the list to accommodate quota requirements. This is acceptable as long as the rules are

clear and the sequence on the list (or votes collected in an open list system) is followed with

the exceptions deriving from the quotas. These restrictions are not more severe than

restrictions on the nomination before the elections.

Pakistan and Kenya have introduced minority representation which will not change the party-

wise composition of the parliaments elected according to FPTP. The minority (and in

Pakistan also the women) seats are filled from predefined lists in proportion to the parties’

representation in parliament. The voter cast a vote for a candidate in a single-member

Page 199: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

197

constituency and that vote will also influence the choice of minority representatives. The vote

is counted for two tiers of an election; it is the result in form of seats in the parliament which

is decisive. This means that in Pakistan, the Hindus and Christians are represented from the

Muslim League, the PPP, etc, regardless of whether the parties show any interests in minority

rights. The representation seems to be unnecessarily indirect and illustrates the inbuilt

problems with combining quotas with FPTP. If one has only one minority group, it could be

solved by a separate ballot for the minority race but with a number of groups, that will

become too complicated. Alternatively, one could have a separate List PR race combining all

minority representations. Then one would have to accept that the two systems are different

but it would improve the accountability. One more fundamental change could be to introduce

a regular mixed system with half the parliament elected in FPTP and half with List PR and

then build in the quotas in the List PR part of the election. In such case there should be a

political will to actually introduce a strong element of proportional representation even for

other reasons than to accommodate group representation and the group representation would

integrate elegantly into the system. In Sudan, a mixed system was introduced as a

compromise between those supporting a plurality system and those favouring proportional

systems but they unnecessarily introduced a separate race for women instead of integrating

women’s quotas in one single List PR race.

7.5 The Quota Tool Box

In the following we will give some recommendations related to defined situations. We will

not cover such solutions which have unacceptable or unnecessary side effects as described

earlier. Only representation and quotas are presented, not devolution of powers and decision-

making rules.

7.5.1 Representing Large Groups after (or before) Conflict

The groups are assumed to be large in the sense that they are more than minor, marginalised

groups.

The size of the quotas

After conflict the purpose of the system may be to balance the representation of the

conflicting groups. This may be done numerically by the quotas and it may be underpinned

by decision-making rules. Sometimes it may suffice to secure the groups a share in the

parliament according to their share of the population, but overrepresentation of the smallest

group may also be institutionalised (Burundi, Lebanon, The House of Peoples in Bosnia and

Herzegovina).

Who elects the representatives?

It is not obvious that the voters of a group should elect their own representatives. The

dynamics of the system of representation may be weakened by splitting the electorate by

groups. Instead the group representation may come as an add-on to a general system of

representation. However, if the distance between the vote of the smallest group and their

representatives is too large, there may be justified complaints that the majority elects even the

minority’s representatives (Lebanon, Pakistan).

Page 200: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

198

Geographically concentrated groups

If the groups are geographically concentrated delimitation of constituencies (single- or multi-

member) may be sufficient to create the representation needed. In order to balance the groups

some areas may be over-represented relative to their strength in the population. Any system

of representation may work in this case and even though the representation is geographical the

effect is that the group representatives are mainly elected by the group voters. The dynamics

may in this case be quite good since the representation formally is connected to geographical

areas and if the population gets more mixed the system does not need to be adjusted since the

changes probably reflects reconciliation between the groups.

Separate race for scattered group

If the group which needs protection is scattered around the country285

one may introduce a

separate race for the minority. The separate race does not necessarily have to be with a

separate ballot, but the results may be calculated separately for the group representatives. If

only the candidates are identified in terms of groups and not the voters, it means that

everybody is voting for everybody. The problem may then be that the smallest group feel that

the majority elects their representatives. This will effect will be largely dependent on the

system of representation. There are three possibilities:

1. There is one ballot only and the group representation is fixed by counting the ballot

twice, for the general and the separate race (Kosovo).

2. There are two races, one general and one for the group and votes are cast by all voters

(women in Kenya).

3. There are two races and the voters choose in secrecy which race to vote for

(Presidential election in Bosnia and Herzegovina from the Federation entity).

The next option is that the group races are also defined by separate electorates. Voters are

then registering as per their identity and vote in that race only (Fiji, where they vote both in

separate race and in a general vote). The alternative is to make such registration a personal

choice (Croatia and New Zealand). In the first case one may argue that ethnic voting

sharpens the divide rather than reconcile (which is part of the critics in Fiji): The second

option is a milder form but with this alternative the electorate is also segregated. The

advantage by the separate electorate is that groups elect their own representatives but the

segregation may be unnecessarily sharp. A better alternative may be to implement quotas

embedded in the general representation as discussed below.

Quotas imbedded in the electoral system

Quotas integrated into the general electoral system are implemented with fewer side effects

within proportional systems than in majoritarian ones. Proportional systems are also more

capable of automatically giving minorities a fair representation and thus make quotas less

necessary. The choice of the general system of representation therefore becomes important.

Instead of adding group representation on top of the system of representation one should

consider the system of representation as a whole.

285

Or one does not want to introduce constituencies which was the case in Kosovo.

Page 201: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

199

Plurality and majority based systems cannot easily be combined with group representation

without making a separate race. One way is to mark certain constituencies for group

candidates only (India). The disadvantage is that all citizens living in the constituency cannot

run in their home constituency but have to choose another one. Nevertheless it is a possible

solution.

Another way of securing a certain representation of a group under FPTP in single-member

constituencies could be to let candidates run in tickets of two (or in principle more). The

ticket is ranked and if in the country as a whole a pre-set quota for a group (or more groups) is

met the seat of the winning ticket is filled with number one on the list. If the quota is not

filled, a number of such candidates who belong to the group and are ranked as number two on

winning tickets are elected instead. The constituencies where this change is made should be

those where the ticket won with the least convincing margin. This system would not alter the

political composition of the parliament, will not limit the right to stand for election and those

ranking first on tickets with high voters’ support will be elected. Only those with less support

are altered.286

In the block vote system, quotas may change the political composition of the parliament and

party block vote is not recommended because of its winner-takes-all quality (as is block vote

in a slightly milder form). STV and SNTV will also have the possibility to change the

political composition if combined with quotas by first runner-up arrangements.

Within List PR systems it is possible to implement quotas which will only effect the

representation within the party, not across parties. The political distribution of seats will

therefore not be effected by quotas on nomination or results.

After a conflict a good representation of the groups in conflict is crucial. This may be more

important than providing for systems which produce overrepresentation of the largest party

(and therefore produce a parliament where it may be easier to form government) or to have

the direct accountability between voters and single MPs. Lijphard argues that there is a

‘scholarly consensus against majoritarian systems in divided societies”.287

Alternative vote (AV) has been suggested by some (e.g. D. Horowitz) as a mean of promoting

moderation and reconciliation. Fiji has such a system but the country’s political system has

not proven to be very successful, partly because of the ethnic formula in one part of the

election and partly because people feel that the delimitation of AV constituencies of the

general part of the election is artificial and done to achieve a certain political result288

. The

system is furthermore basically a majoritarian system with the benefits for large parties and

ethnic groups which come with it.

286

The system has not been used but has been discussed in Kenya to secure female representation.

287 Lijphart 2008: 78.

288 See Chapter 3 for a more thorough explanation.

Page 202: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

200

7.5.2 Representing small minority groups

If the purpose of representation is to represent minorities which would otherwise be excluded

there are more systems to choose from. Again the general system of representation is decisive

for how easily and elegantly such representation may be incorporated. List PR gives more

automatic representation than majority based systems and minimum quotas for excluded

minorities can be built in with few negative side effects.

Many of the same questions as we rose for the larger groups are relevant here as well, but

some of the side effects may be less significant.

For small groups, it may be important that there is a firm link between the minority voters and

those elected. A separate race with a separate electorate might therefore have an attraction.

However, with many minority groups within the electorate that may become very

complicated. If one instead marks constituencies reserved for minorities (India), the effect

may be that the general electorate elects the minority representatives but that may still work

well if the vision is to reduce the divide rather than deepen it. A general recommendation is

to group minorities together in their representation if they have similar political interests even

if they culturally are different in order to reduce the complexity.

If the minority is geographically concentrated a separate constituency (or constituencies) may

be sufficient (Gagauz in Moldova).

For minorities scattered across the country it might be better to force parties to include the

minority candidates on their lists, provided the system is List PR. The minority may then

either work within the parties to insure good representation and be careful in the vote to

honour such parties which take their representation seriously. In the worst case the minority

may choose to from their own party which in List PR system may have a chance to get

representatives elected. In such cases, one may lower the threshold for lists representing

minorities (Germany and Poland).

If there is a need to represent a number of smaller minorities in the parliament one may

benefit from taking a holistic view on the system of representation. In a number of countries,

one has chosen a rather artificial add-on to the general system and by doing so introduced

weak accountability (Pakistan and Kenya)289

. By shifting from majoritarian systems to

proportional systems the need for special quotas may be reduced and the possibility to

integrate quotas without serious side effects would be much better. In other cases

delimitation of constituencies honouring the minorities’ needs could be the most straight

forward solution, even combined with a certain overrepresentation from minority dominated

areas.

289

Or by appointments which offer no accountability at all (e.g. Nepal in 2008)

Page 203: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

201

7.6 A Feature of Representative Systems

In sum, the most important is that the voters are regarded the masters of a representative

system. No systems should be designed in such a way that representation comes out of a pre-

negotiated deal only. Restrictions of the voters’ choice are acceptable but reducing the

powers of the vote to mere symbols is not. One chamber of parliament should be fully elected

by the voters under a predictable and transparent system with reasonable accountability and

reasonable representation, along political and other relevant dimensions.

Page 204: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

202

Appendices

A: A Method for Quotas on the Total Result in a List PR System

Open and closed lists

In this Appendix we assume that the candidate lists are ranked. If the lists are ‘closed’ the

seats won by a list are filled from the top of the lists. With ‘open lists’ the voters are able to

give some priority vote to individual candidates within the list and the thereby change the pre-

set order. If the voters are not giving such votes the party ranking prevails.

Requirements for meeting quotas when composing a list would normally only have an effect

if it is followed by a requirement to the placement on the list. If there is a Christian Quota of

ten percent in an otherwise predominantly Muslim country it will not help if all the Christian

candidates are put at the end of the list at places where they have no chance to be elected. It is

therefore common to have rules like the following:

Among the first ten candidates at least one should be Christian, among the first twenty

candidates at least two should be Christian, etc.

With open lists the voters may change the ranking on the list and therefore the list may not

return as many from the group with quota as intended. This may be acceptable. In Bosnia

and Herzegovina the female representation is slightly reduced by the voters’ choice but not

drastically. One may, however, still enforce the quotas by prescribing a best runner-up system

for the group candidates within the list in order to meet the requirements. That would mean

that the voters’ choice in the open list system is limited by the quotas.

Quotas within lists

Some quota requirements would apply to the result for each political party list. This is

common for gender quotas and also for other group representation for example in Nepal. Out

of the number of seats won by a list a minimum percentage need come from specified groups.

Now, if it is prescribed that for example 10 percent of the seats won by each party have to be

Dalits, there is no guarantee that the parliament will have at least 10 percent Dalits.

Dependent on the rules for treating fractions the rule may in worst case only kick in for

parties having won ten seats of more. Therefore only big parties will be close to return 10

percent Dalits and even they might be well below if they are required to return only two if

they win 29 seats.

This problem can partly be overcome by requiring more Dalits at the top of the candidate lists

that further down. This is done for women’s representation in Palestine where they need one

Christian among the first three candidates, two among the first seven, three among the first

twelve and then one more for each step of five. The intention was to get approximately

twenty percent women, but even this rule is no guarantee for a minimum representation.

Page 205: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

203

Quotas across lists

If one want to give a full guarantee that a group gets a fixed representation290

, quotas may be

applied to the result across parties. This has been done in the Mostar city council election

(which had fixed quotas for three groups), in local elections in Palestine (with quotas for

Christians in some municipalities), and could be used in Lebanon to secure a fixed group

result for each constituency.

With fixed quotas by-passing candidates on some lists is inevitable. There are simple

methods to achieve this by using a division method for the distribution of seats between lists

combined with quotas. A division method would rank the mandates from the strongest to the

weakest and the seats can be filled in the same sequence. One such division method which

produces a result close to the method of largest remainder is the Sainte-Laguë method. By

this method the votes for each list are divided by the numbers 1,3,5,7, etc. to produce the

‘quotients’. The quotients are ranked from the highest to the lowest, and the seats are

allocated one by one according to this ranking until all seats are distributed.

Let us illustrate by an example: The requirement is that at least 30 percent of the members of

the assembly represent a Christian group. There is, in other words, a maximum quota of 70

percent Muslim in the assembly. Let us consider an election in a constituency with twelve

seats. Out of these at least four should be Christian (and maximum eight may be Muslim). In

the example we will use the Sainte-Laguë division method. The votes for each party list are

divided by 1, 3, 5, etc.

290

The quota may be a minimum requirement for one group or an exact requirement for all groups.

Page 206: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

204

The number after the oblique indicates in descending order the size of the quotient. The first

mandate is given to the party with the first quotient and so forth. The candidates elected are

those ranking highest on the party list. However, if one maximum Muslim quota is filled, one

will simply delete from the list all remaining Muslim candidates. If there is nobody left on

that list, the party loses the mandate, and the mandate goes to the list with the next quotient.

If there in the end are no more candidates to fill the quota, the seat remains empty.

Divisors

Party 1

Party 2

Party 3

Party 4

1

5000/1

3600/3

4000/2

500/13

3

1667/4

1200/6

1333/5

167

5

1000/7

720/9

800/8

7

714/10

514/16

571/11

9

555/12

400/17

444/15

11

455/14

327/20

364/19

13

384/18

277

307/21

15

333/20

17

294/22

Total number of seats

5

3

4

0

Page 207: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

205

In the example, it may go like this:

Candidate number on list

Party 1

Party 2

Party 3

Party 4

1

Muslim/1

Christian/3

Muslim/2

Christian/13

2

Muslim/4

Muslim /6

Muslim/5

Muslim

3

Muslim/7

Muslim/9

Muslim/8

Muslim

4

Muslim/10

Muslim

Muslim/11

Muslim

5

Muslim/12

Christian

Muslim/14

Muslim

6

Muslim/15

Muslim

Christian

Muslim

7

Muslim

Christian

Muslim

Muslim

8

Muslim

Muslim

Muslim

Muslim

9

Muslim

Muslim

Muslim

Muslim

10

Muslim

Christian

Muslim

Muslim

11

Muslim

Muslim

Christian

Muslim

12

Muslim

Muslim

Muslim

Muslim

Total number of seats

3

3

5

1

After having distributed the first nine mandates, eight of them went to men. The maximum

quota for men was reached and the remaining three had to go to women. Party A was entitled

to five seats, but since they did not have women on the list, they lost two of them. Parties B,

C and D were balanced and received either what they were entitled or more. Parties C and D

were the ones which were next to gain seats and they therefore gained one each of the two

seats lost by Party A.

One advantage of this system is that it would allow women’s parties to run without restriction.

A disadvantage is that it will clearly cause agony if a party loses seats. It may also not get the

positive psychological effect before the elections by showing to the electorate that women are

running at prominent places for parliament.

Page 208: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

206

The legal text to regulate this could be as simple as this:

1. The number of votes obtained by a list is divided by 1, 3, 5, 7, 9, etc. up to the number of

candidates on the list. The numbers resulting from these series of divisions are “quotients”. The

quotients shall be ranked in order from the highest quotient to the lowest quotient. Seats shall be

distributed, in order, to the highest quotient remaining until all the seats have been distributed.

2. The seats are filled by candidates one by one in the order they are won according to Section 1 by

filling the seats according to the ranked lists. If during this process all seats of a group is filled all

candidates of that group are deleted from the list of all remaining candidates from all lists. If there

are no more candidates on a list to fill the seat that list will go to the list next to win a mandate

according to Section 1.

In that way, it is the strength of each mandate which counts. The strongest mandate will

always belong to the biggest party and therefore that party will get their first candidate

elected. After that it depends on the strength of subsequent mandates.

Page 209: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

207

B: Abbreviations of Names of Electoral Systems

BV Block vote

FPTP First-past-the-post

List PR List proportional representation

MMP Mixed member proportional system

PBV Party block vote

SNTV Single non-transferrable vote

STV Single transferrable vote

TRS Two round system

Page 210: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

208

References

Antheaume, Benoît and Frédéric Giraut 2002. "Margins at the Heart of Territorial Innovation?

A Comparative Look at Administrative Borderlands (South Africa, France, Morocco, Niger

and Togo)”, Rencontres de l'innovation territorial, Pacte CNRS.

Balinski, Michel L. and H. Peyton Young 2001. Fair Representation. Meeting the Ideal of

One Man, One Vote. Washington, DC: Brookings.

Barry, Brian 1975. “Review Article: Political Accomodation and Consociational Democracy,”

British Journal of Political Science 5: 477-505.

Belloni, Roberto 2009 “Bosnia: Dayton is Dead! Long Live Dayton!'” Nationalism and

Ethnic Politics,15: 3, 355 — 375.

Binder, Leonard (ed) 1966. Politics in Lebanon, New York: John Wiley.

Binningsbø, Helga Malmin 2006. Power-Sharing and Postconflict Peace Periods. Paper

prepared for the workshop Power-Sharing and Democratic Governance in Divided Societies,

Oslo: PRIO.

Blais, Andre 1988. “The classification of electoral systems,” European Journal of Political

Research 16: 99-110.

Blanc, Jarrett, Aanund Hylland and Kåre Vollan 2006. State Structure and Electoral Systems

in Post-Conflict Situations. Washington, DC: IFES/Quality AS.

Bogaards, Matthijs 1998. “The favourable factors for consociational democracy: A review,”

European Journal of Political Research 33: 475-496.

Bridge, John W. 1997 “Judicial Review in Mauritius and the Continuing Influence of English

Law”, International and Comparative Law Quarterly, Vol 46, No. 4:787-811.

Burg, Steven L. 1982. “Republican and Provincial Constitution Making in Yugoslav Politics”

The Journal of Federalism 12. Center for the Study of Federalism, Philadelphia.

Bunwaree, Sheila and Roukaya Kasenally 2006. "Political Parties and Democracy in

Mauritius,” Eisa Research Report No. 19, Johannesburg.

Butenschøn, Nils 1985. "Conflict Management in Plural Societies: The Consociational

Democracy Formula", Scandinavian Political Studies, Vol. 8, no. 1-2.

Page 211: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

209

Butenschøn, Nils 2006. “Accommodating Conflicting Claims to National Self-determination.

The Intractable Case of Israel/Palestine”, International Journal on Minority and Group

Rights, Vol 13, No. 2-3:285-306.

Butenschøn, Nils and Kåre Vollan 2006. Democracy in Conflict: Report on Elections for

Local Councils, President, and Legislative Council in the Occupied Palestinian Territiory

2004-2006. Nordem Special Report, Oslo: Norwegian Centre for Human Rights. University

of Oslo.

Carroll, Barbara Wake and Terrance Carroll 1997 “State and Ethnicity in Botswana and

Mauritius: A Democratic Route to Development”, Journal of Development Studies, Vol. 33,

No. 4, April 1997.

Chirot, Daniel 2009. “Does Democracy Work in Deeply Divided Societies?” In Zoltan

Barany and Robert G. Moser eds. Is Democracy Exportable? Cambridge: Cambridge

University Press.

Cox, Gary W. 1997. Making Votes Count. Strategic Coordination in the World’s Electoral

Systems. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Duarte, Eliana 2007 “Usos políticos de la diferenciación Étnica y racial. Un estudio de la

circunscripción electoral especial,” Institute for Research and Debate on Governance.

EISA Election Update 2005, Mauritius, No 1, 17, Johannesburg.

El Khazen, Farid 2000. The Breakdown of the State in Lebanon, 1967-1976, London: I.B.

Tauris.

El-Sohl, Raghid 2004, Lebanon and Arabism: National Identity and State Formation, London

and New York: I.B. Tauris.

European Union Election Observation Mission 2005 Ethiopia Legislative Elections 2005,

Final Report.

European Union Election Observation Mission 2008 Republic of Rwanda Final Report

Legislative Elections to the Chamber of Deputies 15-18 September 2008.

European Union Election Observation Mission 2011 Uganda, Final Report, General

Elections 18 February 2011.

Falch , Åshild 2009, Towards Durable Democracy in Burundi? Assessment of the Promise

and Pitfalls of Democratization in Burundi" Oslo: Peace Research Institute Oslo.

Faris, Hani 1982, Beyond the Lebanese Civil War: Historical issues and the challenges of

reconstruction, Washington D.C.: Center for Contemporary Arab Studies, Georgetown

University.

Fearon, James D. 2003. “Ethnic and Cultural Diversity by Country,” Journal of Economic

Growth 8: 195-222.

Page 212: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

210

Fish, Steven M. and Matthew Kroenig 2009. The Handbook of National Legislatures: A

Global Survey, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Fraenkel, Jon 2001. “The Alternative Vote System in Fiji: Electoral Engineering or Ballot-

Rigging?” Commonwealth and Comparative Politics 39: 1-31.

Golder, Matt 2005. “Democratic electoral systems around the world, 1946-2000”, Electoral

Studies 24: 103-121.

Hachhethu, Krishna 2006. Political Parties of Nepal. Lalitpur: Social Science Baha.

Hanf, Theodor 1993. Coexistence in Wartime Lebanon: Decline of a State and Rise of a

Nation. London: I.B. Tauris.

Hartzell, Caroline, Matthew Hoodie and Donald Rothchild 2001. “Stabilizing the Peace After

Civil War: An Investigation of Some Key Variables,” International Organization 55: 183-

208.

Hartzell, Caroline and Matthew Hoodie 2003. “Institutionalizing Peace: Power-Sharing and

Post-Civil War Conflict Management,” American Journal of Political Science 47: 318-332.

Haug, Hilde Katrine 2007. Comrades between Brotherhood and (dis)Unity, The Yugoslav

Communists' search for a Socialist Solution to the National Question 1935-1980, Dissertation

for the Degree of Ph.D. Oslo: Faculty of Humanities, University of Oslo.

Hitchner, R. Bruce 2006. ”From Dayton to Brussels: The Story Behind the Constitutional and

Governmental Reform Process in Bosnia and Herzegovina,” The Fletcher Forum of World

Affairs, Vol. 30:1 Winter 2006.

Horowitz, Donald 1985. Ethnic Groups in Conflict. Berkely: University of California Press.

Horowitz, Donald 1990. “Making Moderation Pay,” in Joseph Montville, ed. Conflict and

Peacemaking in Multiethnic Societies. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books.

Horowitz, Donald L 2006. “Strategy Takes a Holiday: Fraenkel and Grofman on the

Alternative Vote", Comparative Political Studies, Volume 39, No 5.

Htun, Mala 2004. “Is Gender like Ethnicity? The Political Representation of Identity Groups,”

Perspectives on Politics 2: 439-458.

Hudson, Michael C. 1968, 1985. The Precarious Republic: Political Modernization in

Lebanon. New York: Random House.

Hudson, Michael C. 1979. Arab Politics. The Search for Legitimacy. New Haven: Yale

University Press.

Page 213: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

211

IFES 2010. Niger: A Potential Role Model for Democracy in Sub-Saharan Africa.

Washington DC.

International Crisis Group 2005a. Bosnia's Stalled Police Reform: No Progress, No EU,

Europe Report N°164.

International Crisis Group 2005b. Elections in Burundi: A Radical Shake-up of the Political

Landscape, Africa Briefing No. 31.

International Crisis Group 2009a. Bosnia’s Incomplete Transition: Between Dayton and

Europe. Europe Report N°198.

International Crisis Group 2009b. Bosnia’s Dual Crisis. Europe Briefing N°57.

Sarajevo/Brussels.

International Crisis Group 2011, Burundi: From Electoral Boycott to Political Impasse,

Africa Report No. 169.

Jung, Courtney and Ian Shapiro 1995. “South Africa’s Negotiated Transition: Democracy,

Opposition, and the New Constitutional Order”, 23:3, Politics & Society 23: 269-308.

Kaplan, David 2000, “Conflict and compromise among borderland identities in northern

Italy,” Tijdschrift voor economische en sociale geografie, Vol 91, No 1: 44–60.

Kerr, Malcolm H. 1966, ”Political Decision-making in a Confessional Democracy” in Binder,

Leonard (ed.), Politics in Lebanon, New York: John Wiley.

Khalaf, Samir 1987. Lebanon’s Predicament. New York: Columbia University Press.

Khodish, Shpethanie 2006. “ Balancing Representation: Special Representation Mechanisms

Addressing the Imbalance of Marginalized Voices in African Legislatures", Suffolk

Transnational Law Review, Vol 30, No. 1: 1-100.

Lal, Brij V. 1997 "Towards a United Future: Report of the Fiji Constitution Review

Commission," The Journal of Pacific History, Vol. 32, No 1: 71-84.

Lerner, Daniel 1958. The Passing of Traditional Society. Modernizing in the Middle East.

Lijphart, Arend 1977. Democracy in Plural Societies. A Comparative Exploration. New

Haven: Yale University Press.

Lijphart , Arend 1985, Power-Sharing in South Africa (University of California Institute of

International Studies, Berkeley,

Lijphart, Arend 1994. Electoral Systems and Party Systems. A Study of Twenty-Seven

Democracies, 1945-1990. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Page 214: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

212

Lijphart, Arend 2008. Thinking about democracy. Power-sharing and majority rule in theory

and practice. Milton Park: Routledge.

McGann, Anthony 2006. The Logic of Democracy. Reconciling Equality, Deliberation, and

Minority Protection. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

Messara, A. 1988. Prospects for Lebanon: The Challenge to Co-existence, Oxford, Centre for

Lebanese Studies.

Noel Malcolm, Noel 1996. Bosnia: A Short History, new and updated edition New York

University Press.

Norris, Pippa 2005. Electoral Engineering. Voting Rules and Political Behavior. Cambridge:

Cambridge University Press.

Nystuen, Gro 2005. Achieving Peace or Protecting Human Rights? Leiden/Boston: Martinus

Nijhoff Publishers.

O’Leary, Brendan, Bernard Grofman and Jørgen Elklit 2005. “Divisor Methods for Sequential

Portfolio Allocation in Multi-Party Executive Bodies: Evidence from Northern Ireland and

Denmark,” American Journal of Political Science 49: 198-211.

OSCE/ODIHR and the Venice Commission 2007. Joint opinion on the Draft Law on Voters

Lists of Croatia, adopted by the Venice Commission and the at its 71st Plenary Session.

OSCE/ODIHR 2008. Republic of Poland, Pre-term Parliamentary Elections, 21 October

2007, OSCE/ODIHR Election Assessment Mission Final Report Warsaw: Office for

Democratic Institutions and Human Rights.

OSCE/ODIHR 2009a. Montenegro, Early Parliamentary Elections, 29 March 2009,

OSCE/ODIHR Election Observation Mission Final Report, Warsaw: Office for Democratic

Institutions and Human Rights.

OSCE/ODIHR 2009b. Elections to the Federal Parliament (Bundestag), OSCE/ODIHR

Election Assessment Mission Report, Warsaw: Office for Democratic Institutions and Human

Rights.

Pande, Rohini 2003 "Can Mandated Political Representation Increase Policy Influence for

Disadvantaged Minorities? Theory and Evidence from India", The American Economic

Review, Vol 93, No. 4: 1132-1151.

Pant, P.K 2011. A Half Decade of Peace Process (2005-2010) It’s Challenges and Prospects

Kathmandu: Weekly Mirror Publication Pvt. Ltd.

Pokharel, Bhojraj and Shrishti Rana 2012. Manuscript to be published in 2012.

Page 215: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

213

Ramesha, Sanjay 2010. “Constitutionalism and Governance in Fiji”, The Round Table: The

Commonwealth Journal of International Affairs, Vol 99, No 410: 491 – 502.

Rabushka, Alvin and Kenneth A. Shepsle 1972. Politics in Plural Societies. A Theory of

Democratic Instability. [2009 edition.] New York: Pearsons.

Rasch, Bjørn Erik 1995. “Parliamentary Voting Procedures,” in Herbert Döring, ed.

Parliaments and Majority Rule in Western Europe. New York: St. Martin’s Press.

Rasch, Bjørn Erik and Roger Congleton 2006. “Amendment Procedures and Constitutional

Stability.” In Roger Congleton and Birgitta Swedenborg, eds. Democratic Constitutional

Design and Public Policy. Cambridge, MA.: MIT Press.

Regassa, Tsaye 2010 ”Learning to live with Conflicts: Federalism as a Tool of Conflict

Management in Ethiopia: An Overview”, Mizan Law Review, Vol 4, No 1: 52-101.

Renwick, Alan 2010. The Politics of Electoral Reform. Changing the Rules of Democracy.

Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Reynolds, Andrew 2005. “Reserved Seats in National Legislatures: A Research Note,”

Legislative Studies Quarterly 30: 301-310.

Reynolds, Andrew 2006. Electoral systems and the protection and participation of minorities.

MRG Report. London: Minority Rights Group International.

Reynolds, Andrew 2011. Designing Democracy in a Dangerous World. Oxford: Oxford

University Press.

Reynolds, Andrew, Ben Reilly and Andrew Ellis (eds) 2005. Electoral Systems Design: The

New International IDEA Handbook. Stockholm: International Institute for Democracy and

Electoral Assistance.

Reyntjens, Filip 2005, “Briefing: Burundi: A Peaceful Transition After a Decade of War?”,

African Affairs, Vol. 105, No. 418: 117-135.

Schwindt-Bayer, Leslie A. 2009. “Making Quotas Work: The Effect of Gender Quota Laws

on the Election of Women,” Legislative Studies Quarterly 34: 5-28.

Sebastián, Sofía 2007. Leaving Dayton behind: constitutional reform in Bosnia and

Herzegovina, FRIDE Working Paper, FRIDE, 16 November 2007.

Shugart, Matthew S. and Martin P. Wattenberg eds., 2001. Mixed-Member Electoral Systems.

The Best of Both Worlds? Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Sisk, Timothy D. 1996. Power Sharing and International Mediation in Ethnic Conflicts.

Washington DC: United States Institute of Peace Press.

Page 216: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

214

Stremlau , Nicole and Monroe E. Price 2009. Media, Elections and Political Violence in

Eastern Africa: Towards a Comparative Framework, An Annenberg-Oxford Occasional

Paper in Communications Policy Research, London

Taagepera, Rein and Matthew S. Shugart 1989. Seats and Votes. The Effects and

Determinants of Electoral Systems. New Haven: Yale University Press.

The Carter Center 2010. Election Observation Mission in Sudan Presidential, Gubernatorial,

and Legislative Elections April, 2010, Preliminary Statement.

Tronvoll, Kjetil 2011 ”The Ethiopian 2010 federal and regional elections: Re-establishing the

one-party state” African Affairs Volume110, Issue 438: 121-136.

Tsebelis, George 1990. “Elite Interaction and Constitution Building in Consociational

Democracies,” Journal of Theoretical Politics 2: 5-29.

Tsebelis, George and Jeannette Money 1997. Bicameralism. Cambridge: Cambridge

University Press.

Tsebelis, George 2002. Veto players. How Political Institutions Work. Princeton: Princeton

University Press.

Van der Beken, Christophe 2009 ”Federalism and the Accommodation of Ethnic Diversity:

The Case of Ethiopia”, Proceedings of the 3rd European Conference on African Studies,

Leipzig.

Vollan, Kåre 2011. ”Group Representation and the System of Representation in the

Constituent Assembly and Future Parliaments of Nepal.” International Journal of Minority

and Group Rights 18: 343–368.

Whelpton, John 2005, 2010: A History of Nepal. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Wolff, Stefan 2008. "Complex Power Sharing as Conflict Resolution: South Tyrol in

Comparative Perspective”, in Woelk, Jens, Palermo, Francesco and Marko, Joseph, Tolerance

through Law: Self-governance and Group Rights in South Tyrol edited by Jens Woelk,

Francesco Palermo, and Joseph Marko, Nijhoff.

Page 217: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch
Page 218: Electoral Quotas and the Challenges of Democratic …...Democratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies Nils A. Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan With contributions by Bjørn Erik Rasch

The Authors: Nils A. Butenschøn is professor of International Relations and Director of the Norwegian Centre for Human Rights, Faculty of Law, University of Oslo. His publications are mostly within the academic field of nationality conflicts and state formations. The theoretical focus is on questions of citizenship in deeply divided societies, the empirical focus is on the Middle East. Examples include: Butenschøn, N., Davis, U., and Hassassian, M. (eds.): Citizenship and the State in the Middle East. Approaches and Applications, Syracuse, N.Y. (2000); Butenschøn, N. and Vollan, K., Democracy in Conflict, NORDEM Special Report, NCHR, University of Oslo (2006); Butenschøn, N., Midtøsten. Imperiefall, statsutvikling, kriger, Universitetsforlaget (2008) [The Middle East. The Fall of Empires, State Formations, Wars, Oslo University Press, in Norwegian].

Kåre Vollan is Director and owner of the company Quality AS. He has been working on elections in thirty countries and territories including Nepal, Kenya, Iraq, Palestine, Sudan, Egypt and Bosnia and Herzegovina. He has since 2006 been advising the Election Commission and politicians in Nepal, in particular the group representation system. From 1999 to 2000 Vollan was Deputy Head of the OSCE Mission to Bosnia and Herzegovina organising two elections. In the period 1996 to 2009 he headed twelve OSCE/ODIHR and NORDEM international election observation missions or teams. From 2003 he has issued opinions on election laws for the Council of Europe Venice Commission. Vollan, who is an applied mathematician by profession, has published a number of articles and reports on electoral and decision making issues.

Also by the same Authors:Nils Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan (eds.): Interim Democracy. Report on the Palestinian Elections January 1996, Human Rights Report No 7 1996, Norwegian Institute of Human Rights, University of Oslo.

Nils Butenschøn and Kåre Vollan: Democracy in Conflict. Report on the Elections for Local Councils, President, and Legislative Council in the Occupied Palestinian Territory 2004-2006, NORDEM Special Report 2006, NCHR, University of Oslo.

The Front Page Photo:A handshake between two senior officials on the Palestinian presidential Election Day in January 2005 following President Yasser Arafat´s death. Both thumbs carry indelible ink showing that they have voted and the handshake may symbolise the overall political agreement to carry out an election, even under occupation. (Photo: Kåre Vollan)

Electoral Quotas and the C

hallenges of Dem

ocratic Transition in Conflict-Ridden Societies A

NO

RDEM

SPECIA

L REPORT 2011

ISBN 978-82-8158-071-8