28
Does Wage Volatility Matter in Labor Markets? Theory and Evidence on Labor Mobility Tackseung Jun 1 , Lalith Munasinghe 2 1 Kyung Hee University e-mail: [email protected] 2 Columbia University e-mail: [email protected] Abstract We present theory and evidence on the eects of wage volatility on labor mobility. Our model of job turnover explicitly incorporates vari- ance of within-job wages by assuming that wages evolve as random walk processes. With the additional assumption that job changes entail “switch- ing” costs, the key theoretical result is that the optimal threshold of turnover — the minimum wage dierence between outside and inside jobs necessary for a job change — is positively related to wage volatility. Data from the National Longitudinal Surveys of Youth show that workers who hold more volatile jobs get bigger wage gains when they quit and move to a new job and that they quit less frequently especially if their jobs are also charac- terized by high within-job wage growth rates. These ndings are consistent with the implications of our theoretical model. Key words Labor mobility, Within-job wage volatility, Random walk, Multi-armed bandit problem JEL Classication: J30, J60 1 Introduction The shift in focus from labor mobility as a mere means of allocative e- ciency in the labor market to labor mobility as an outcome of individual investment decisions has provided important insights into the structure of inter-rm mobility. Since the prospect of higher wages is a major impetus for voluntary job changes, the analysis of inter-rm labor mobility and its associated (mobility) wage gains is a central topic in modern labor eco- nomics. However, it is somewhat surprising that the role of wage volatility has been largely unexplored in the voluminous literature on labor mobility

Does Wage Volatility Matter in Labor Markets? Theory and ... · volatility and mean within-job wage growth in a quit regression. The effect of volatility on mobility wage gains is

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    1

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Does Wage Volatility Matter in Labor Markets? Theory and ... · volatility and mean within-job wage growth in a quit regression. The effect of volatility on mobility wage gains is

Does Wage Volatility Matter in LaborMarkets? Theory and Evidence on LaborMobility

Tackseung Jun1, Lalith Munasinghe2

1 Kyung Hee University e-mail: [email protected] Columbia University e-mail: [email protected]

Abstract We present theory and evidence on the effects of wage volatilityon labor mobility. Our model of job turnover explicitly incorporates vari-ance of within-job wages by assuming that wages evolve as random walkprocesses. With the additional assumption that job changes entail “switch-ing” costs, the key theoretical result is that the optimal threshold of turnover— the minimum wage difference between outside and inside jobs necessaryfor a job change — is positively related to wage volatility. Data from theNational Longitudinal Surveys of Youth show that workers who hold morevolatile jobs get bigger wage gains when they quit and move to a new joband that they quit less frequently especially if their jobs are also charac-terized by high within-job wage growth rates. These findings are consistentwith the implications of our theoretical model.

Key words Labor mobility, Within-job wage volatility, Random walk,Multi-armed bandit problemJEL Classification: J30, J60

1 Introduction

The shift in focus from labor mobility as a mere means of allocative effi-ciency in the labor market to labor mobility as an outcome of individualinvestment decisions has provided important insights into the structure ofinter-firm mobility. Since the prospect of higher wages is a major impetusfor voluntary job changes, the analysis of inter-firm labor mobility and itsassociated (mobility) wage gains is a central topic in modern labor eco-nomics. However, it is somewhat surprising that the role of wage volatilityhas been largely unexplored in the voluminous literature on labor mobility

Page 2: Does Wage Volatility Matter in Labor Markets? Theory and ... · volatility and mean within-job wage growth in a quit regression. The effect of volatility on mobility wage gains is

2 Tackseung Jun, Lalith Munasinghe

and wages, especially since within-job wage evolution is often modeled as astochastic process. In this paper we attempt to fill this gap by presenting atheoretical and empirical analysis of wage volatility and its effects on labormobility. First, we present a theory of job turnover that explicitly modelsthe role of wage volatility in predicting labor mobility. Second, using datafrom the National Longitudinal Surveys of Youth, we analyze the effects ofwage volatility on quit rates and mobility wage gains. Our empirical findingsare consistent with the implications of the theory.The modern literature on earnings dynamics views evolution of labor

productivity and wages as stochastic processes. For example, in their clas-sic 1982 article “A Theory of Wages,” Harris and Holmstrom assume that aworker’s productivity on a job is subject to random shocks. Since firms arerisk neutral and workers are risk averse, they derive an equilibrium wagecontract that provides partial insurance against productivity shocks to theworker. Although this wage contract (which is non-decreasing) is stochastic,it is clearly designed to attenuate the presumed volatility in worker pro-ductivity. In another theoretical article on wages and turnover, Mortensen(1988) explicitly models wage evolution as a stochastic process. Topel andWard (1992) present evidence that within-job wages do in fact evolve asa random walk process with drift. Although the stochastic nature of pro-ductivity and wage evolution is central in these studies, the literature hasyet to address volatility effects in labor markets. This omission is particu-larly striking given the enormous theoretical and empirical significance ofvolatility effects in financial markets.Our model of job turnover is based on a two-job framework where an

employed worker in every period has the option of either staying with thecurrent (inside) job or switching to an outside (future) job.1 The importantfeature of the model is that the within-job wage evolves as a random walkprocess. This random walk assumption is of course the source of variance ofwithin-job wages — i.e. of wage volatility. With the additional assumptionthat job changes entail irrecoverable switching costs, the key theoreticalresult is that the optimal threshold of turnover — i.e. the minimum wagedifference between the outside job and current job necessary for a worker toswitch jobs — is positively related to wage volatility.2 The intuition follows

1 We consider embedding this two-job framework within a more realistic searchframework where the outside job is interpreted as arising periodically from astationary distribution of outside jobs. In Section 2 we discuss how our model isrelated to job search theory.2 The model here is an adaptation of modern investment theory — which is inturn a generalization of financial option pricing theory — into the labor mobilityframework. The options pricing approach to investment is based on the insightthat “irreversibility and the possibility of delay are very important characteris-tics of most investments in reality” (p. 6 in Dixit and Pindyck 1994). These twofeatures are well-known in the labor mobility literature: first, job changes entailirrecoverable moving costs; and second, workers typically have the option of delay-ing a switch from one job to another. What is absent in the labor literature, unlike

Page 3: Does Wage Volatility Matter in Labor Markets? Theory and ... · volatility and mean within-job wage growth in a quit regression. The effect of volatility on mobility wage gains is

3

from the fact that volatility increases the value of delaying the decision toswitch jobs. At the optimum threshold the worker is indifferent betweenswitching jobs now versus later. However, if volatility increases the workercan avoid the increased downside risk by waiting. This delay is achieved bysetting a higher optimal threshold of turnover. Although a few earlier studies(Kiefer and Neumann 1989; Macdonald 1988; Sargent 1987) refer to thepossible link between “labor market volatility” and the relative valuationof outside versus inside jobs, no previous theoretical study has derived alink between volatility and labor mobility. To our knowledge this is the firstmodel of inter-firm labor mobility to explicitly derive a relationship betweenwithin-job wage volatility and the optimal threshold of turnover.3

The theoretical result that volatility is positively related to the optimalthreshold of turnover of course cannot be directly tested because we do notobserve this threshold of turnover. By considering the threshold effects onquit rates and mobility wage gains, we can discern some testable implica-tions of volatility on these observed mobility outcomes. Our model identifieswithin-job wage growth as a factor that influences the effect of volatility onquit rates, a non-intuitive model prediction that we can explicitly test.The effects of volatility on quit rates and mobility wage gains are com-

plicated because volatility not only affects the threshold of turnover but alsothe distribution of the wage difference between the outside and inside jobs.For example, if volatility only increased the threshold, then volatility willbe negatively correlated with quit rates because a higher threshold simplyreduces the likelihood of a job switch. However, this negative effect is coun-teracted by the fact that any positive wage difference between the outsideand inside jobs increases if wage volatility increases; making job switchesmore likely for any given threshold. Hence the net effect of volatility on quitrates will depend on which of these two effects dominate. In the model sec-tion we explicitly characterize this condition and identify an implication totest the theory. Since the model shows that volatility is more likely to havea negative effect on turnover if the within-job wage growth rate is larger, wecan explicitly test this implication by including an interaction term betweenvolatility and mean within-job wage growth in a quit regression.The effect of volatility on mobility wage gains is far less ambiguous.

For instance, if volatility does not lead to a higher quit rate — which is

in the investment literature, is an analysis of the ramifications of wage evolutionas a random walk process on other related outcomes. As a consequence when therandom walk assumption is explicitly introduced into the mobility framework, thestandard result from modern investment theory, which says that higher volatilityincreases the value of delaying costly investments because the increased downsiderisk can be avoided by waiting, also holds in the context of labor mobility.3 Search and mobility costs are of course key features of a variety of models thatunderpin empirical analyses of the joint determination of wages and mobility (e.g.Black and Loewenstein 1991; Barron et al 1993; Kuhn 1993). Given this extensiveliterature on mobility costs we do not focus on the ramifications of switching costsper se on mobility outcomes.

Page 4: Does Wage Volatility Matter in Labor Markets? Theory and ... · volatility and mean within-job wage growth in a quit regression. The effect of volatility on mobility wage gains is

4 Tackseung Jun, Lalith Munasinghe

indeed possible if the positive effect of volatility on the optimal thresholdis sufficiently large — then volatility will necessarily increase mobility wagegains. Of course, this positive relationship can hold even if the quit rateincreases, although not necessarily. Hence a positive coefficient on volatilityin a mobility wage gain equation and a negative coefficient on the interactionbetween volatility and mean wage growth in a quit equation are empiricalresults that would support the theory.The major challenge of testing these implications is the construction of

an appropriate empirical counterpart of within-job wage volatility. The dif-ficulties are both conceptual and practical. The first question is the employ-ment context over which volatility is likely to significantly vary. In econo-metric parlance, is wage volatility a job-, person-, industry- or occupation-specific effect? If we follow the theoretical model then the most disaggregatemeasure of volatility would be based on job-specific wage data. Panel datasources notwithstanding, the practical difficulty of obtaining such a job-specific measure is the loss of a huge fraction of the job sample due tounder-selection of short duration jobs.4

An alternative measure — adopted in this paper — is to compute a person-specific wage volatility measure based on within-job wage changes over theentire observed individual life cycle of employment. The obvious advan-tage of a person-specific volatility measure is that we avoid sample selectionproblems that plague the construction of a job-specific measure. The disad-vantage is that if a significant component of the variation in wage volatilityis job-specific and workers randomly move across jobs characterized by dif-ferent volatilities, then our person-specific measure could obscure this vari-ation in volatility. As a result, any lack of evidence of volatility effects usingperson-specific measures, would not necessarily rule out the existence ofjob-specific volatility effects. On the other hand, evidence of person-specificvolatility effects would not also necessarily suggest that volatility is a personeffect. For example, if workers move among similar volatility jobs or indus-tries or occupations then our person-specific measure would simply proxyvolatility variations across these different employment dimensions. Evidenceof person-specific volatility effects, however, would provide support for ourtheory and highlight the role of wage volatility in predicting labor marketoutcomes even though we might not be able to pinpoint the exact sourceof volatility variation. A decomposition analysis of wage volatility is a topicfor a future research agenda.In the empirical section we compute person-specific within-job wage

growth and within-job wage volatility measures, and estimate the effects

4 Note that most micro survey data provide only annual wage data and jobdurations are relatively short especially among workers in the early part of theircareers. Since a minimum of four within-job wage observations are required tocompute a sample variance of (de-trended) job-specific wages, many jobs willhave missing volatility information. Of course, even in principle, time series of job-specific wage data will be limited because (nominal) wage adjustments, unlike saystock price data, occur infrequently for a variety institutional and other reasons.

Page 5: Does Wage Volatility Matter in Labor Markets? Theory and ... · volatility and mean within-job wage growth in a quit regression. The effect of volatility on mobility wage gains is

5

of these measures on the likelihood of quit rates and on mobility wage gainsdue to voluntary job changes. To preview our findings: workers who holdmore volatile jobs get bigger wage gains when they quit and move to a newjob and they quit less frequently especially if their jobs are also characterizedby high within-job wage growth rates. These findings are highly significantand robust to various model specifications, sample selection corrections, andinclusion of an extensive array of control variables related to individual, joband other relevant characteristics.Our empirical analysis of volatility effects is a significant departure from

the existing literature because no previous study has analyzed the effectsof wage volatility on labor mobility. The empirical literature on turnoverand mobility wage gains is largely motivated by testing implications of spe-cific human capital and job search theories. For example, Antel (1986) ar-gues that the comparison of wages between movers and stayers underesti-mates mobility wage gains (due to search) because stayers experience higherwithin-job wage growth. Topel (1991) makes the converse case that the com-parison of wages of stayers and movers underestimates the true returns tospecific skills because movers move to more lucrative jobs. Mincer (1993)analyses differential wage gains conditional on quits and layoffs across olderand younger workers. He finds wage gains are typically positive, higher forquits than for layoffs, and higher for younger than older movers. Bartel andBorjas (1981) find that workers who quit due to finding a better job expe-rience significant wage gains compared to their counterparts who move forother reasons.One final issue of interpretation is whether our empirical findings might

be compatible with risk aversion on the part of workers. For example, thefact that volatility reduces quit rates and increases mobility wage gains couldbe consistent with risk aversion if volatility pertains to wages of future jobs.Clearly, risk averse workers would be less likely to switch to more volatilejobs, and if they did switch to such jobs, they would need a compensatingwage differential to offset the risk. A direct test of this hypothesis wouldcorrelate wage volatilities of past versus future jobs with quit rates andmobility wage gains and evaluate whether the effects of future job volatilitieson these mobility outcomes are stronger. However, as mentioned earlier, datalimitations prohibit the computation of job-specific volatility measures. Wedo however present an indirect test of sorts by exploiting the exact timing ofthe incidence of quits and observed mobility wage gains. For example, ourperson-specific measure will largely reflect wage volatility of future/pastjobs if the incidence of quits and mobility wage gains occur early/late in aworker’s career.5 We can empirically address whether our estimated effects

5 This interpretation of risk aversion of course hinges on the assumption thatvolatility is job specific. Under this presumption the proposed test is somewhatimprecise because our person-specific measure of volatility represents an aggregateover several jobs, even though we can determine at every point in time whetherour person-specific volatility measure is based on (largely) past or future wageobservations.

Page 6: Does Wage Volatility Matter in Labor Markets? Theory and ... · volatility and mean within-job wage growth in a quit regression. The effect of volatility on mobility wage gains is

6 Tackseung Jun, Lalith Munasinghe

of volatility are stronger in the early part of a worker’s career since ourmeasure would then reflect wage volatility of future jobs. The evidence doesnot support the risk aversion hypothesis.The remainder of the paper is arranged as follows. The next section

presents the theoretical analysis. In the first part we present a simpler ver-sion of our theory to clarify the intuition behind the main theoretical result— i.e. the positive relation between volatility and the optimal threshold ofturnover — and to highlight the effects of volatility on mobility wage gainsand quit rates and to derive the various implications that we can test. Nextwe present the general model of turnover, and derive the optimal switchingrule and various comparative static results. We conclude the theory sectionwith a detailed discussion of the relation of our model to job search theory.Section 3 presents empirical analysis. First, we describe the NLSY data andthe construction of our volatility measure. Second, we detail the estimationframework. Third, we present and discuss our empirical findings. Section 4concludes with a brief summary.

2 Theoretical Analysis

2.1 A Motivating Example

In this section we present a simple example of our model of turnover tomotivate the key theoretical result of the paper and to illustrate the linksbetween wage volatility and labor mobility. Here we consider a simple modelin which wages are permanently shocked only once at the beginning ofthe second period. As a consequence the worker simply decides whether toswitch jobs in the current period or to postpone this decision to the nextperiod. Despite this restriction, our example helps to clarify the intuition forwhy volatility increases the optimal threshold of turnover and to illustratewhy wage volatility leads to higher mobility wage gains and its effects on jobturnover. In the next subsection we present the full model where within-jobwages evolve as a random walk process.Denote zl for l = d> e as wage of job l in period 1. Assume that job

e is the currently-holding job. Suppose that for all l = d> e, zl can eitherincrease by k with probability s, or decrease by k with probability 1− s atthe beginning of the second period. Hence the only decision for the workeris whether to switch now or to delay this decision to the second period.The present value of expected net income Yvzlwfk if the worker switches

jobs in period 1 is given by:

Yvzlwfk = zd − F +�

1− �(zd + sk− (1− s)k) > (1)

where F is the switching cost, and � is the discount factor. If the workerdecides to delay the switching decision to the second period then the present

Page 7: Does Wage Volatility Matter in Labor Markets? Theory and ... · volatility and mean within-job wage growth in a quit regression. The effect of volatility on mobility wage gains is

7

value of net income Yzdlw is given by:

Yzdlw = ze +�

1− �

⎜⎜⎝

s2max¡zd + k>ze + k

¢

+s (1− s)max¡zd − k>ze + k

¢

+s (1− s)max¡zd + k>ze − k

¢

+(1− s)2max¡zd − k>ze − k

¢

⎟⎟⎠

= ze +�

1− �

µ¡zd − ze − F

¢(1− s (1− s))

+ze − k¡1 + 2s2 − 4s

¢¶

(2)

Equating (1) and (2) at the threshold wage differential v = zd − ze, andrearranging terms, we get

v = �1F + �2 (3)

where �1 =1−�(2−s(1−s))1−�(1−s(1−s)) and �2 =

2�s(1−s)k1−�(1−s(1−s)) . Note that mean within-

job wage growth, zmzj, is given by:

zmzj ≡ sk− (1− s)k = k (2s− 1) = (4)

Assume that s A 1@2 to make zmzj postive. Now consider the case wherezmzj is held constant. Clearly v increases as switching costs F increase. Themore interesting comparative static result is the effect of wage volatility onv. Note that from (4), s can be expressed as follows:

s =k+ n

2k, (5)

where n = zmzj. Substituting (5) into equation (3), and taking the deriv-ative with respect to k, we get

Cv

CkA 0,

which follows from the fact that both �1 and �2 are increasing in k. There-fore the change in the optimal threshold of turnover due to a change involatility is positive. Clearly an increase in wage volatility leads to a higheroptimal threshold of turnover.Since we do not observe v we cannot of course directly test this theoret-

ical result of the model. However, in the context of this simple example wecan inquire about the likely ramifications of an increase in wage volatilityon the quit rate and mobility wage gains. Note, the quit rate is determinedby the frequency with which a given wage difference between the outsidejob and current job reaches v. Starting from a given v, this frequency isclearly a positive function of k and a negative function of v. So whether anincrease in k implies a higher or lower quit rate depends precisely on howvolatility k affects the optimal threshold v. If v increases substantially dueto an increase in k — i.e. where the derivative gv@gk is sufficiently large —then the likelihood that volatility will have a negative effect on the quit ratewill also increase. So the question is under what conditions will this deriv-ative of v with respect to k will be relatively large. Note that g2

gkgn�1 A 0

Page 8: Does Wage Volatility Matter in Labor Markets? Theory and ... · volatility and mean within-job wage growth in a quit regression. The effect of volatility on mobility wage gains is

8 Tackseung Jun, Lalith Munasinghe

and g2

gkgn�2 A 0. So, from equation (3), the cross derivative with respect tok and n — mean within-job wage growth — turns out to be positive:

C2v

CkCnA 0=

This condition implies that the positive volatility effect on the thresholdof turnover is increasing with the within-job wage growth rate.6 Hence itis more likely that volatility will have a negative effect on the quit rate ifwithin-job wage growth is higher. This model implication can be tested byincluding an interaction between volatility and within-job wage growth ina quit regression. The model predicts that the estimated coefficient on thisinteraction term should be negative.The effect of an increase in k on mobility wage gains is much less ambigu-

ous. If an increase in volatility does not lead to an increase in the quit ratethen mobility wage gains will necessarily increase with volatility. Note thatevery observation v that implies a job change will have a correspondinglyhigher wage difference because of the volatility increase. But even if the quitrate increases with volatility, mobility wage gains are still likely to increasewith volatility. If the quit rate increases then some positive wage differencesthat were smaller than the threshold prior to the volatility increase wouldhave to increase sufficiently to cross the new threshold (even though thisnew threshold is now higher than it was before the volatility increase). Suchobservations could in principle have a negative effect on the expected valueof mobility wage gains. However, for volatility to have a net negative effecton mobility wage gains, this possible negative effect must dominate the twopositive effects — via the increases in the threshold and in the positive wagedifferences — that result from the increase in volatility.Before we take these predictions to our empirical analysis we present the

full model where wages evolve as a random walk process in every period.

2.2 Model of Inter-Firm Mobility

As mentioned earlier our two-job model of inter-firm mobility is based on ir-recoverable switching costs and the stochastic evolution of within-job wages.First, assume that a worker is currently employed at say job e. The wageat this “inside” job evolves over time as a random walk process with drift.Suppose at the beginning of each time period the worker has the option toswitch to an outside job d. If the worker switches to job d then the wagein job d also evolves as a random walk process with drift.7 For analytical

6 See the discussion following Theorem 2 below for a more formal explanationof this result.7 The modeling details below assume that both jobs d and e evolve simultane-ously as independent and identical random walk processes. The main conclusionsof the model are robust to the alternative assumption that either the inside orthe outside job is frozen (Jun 2004). As it turns out the only relevant statistic for

Page 9: Does Wage Volatility Matter in Labor Markets? Theory and ... · volatility and mean within-job wage growth in a quit regression. The effect of volatility on mobility wage gains is

9

simplicity, assume that all jobs evolve as symmetric random walk processeswith drift. We begin with the definition of wage dynamics:

Definition 1 (Wage Dynamics) For job l ∈ {d> e}, the incremental process{{w} is an i.i.d. sequence with

Pr ({w = k) = s, Pr ({w = −k) = 1− s,

where s ∈ [0> 1] is the drift parameter and 0 ? k ?∞ is the scale parameter.Then the wage of job l at time w is simply zl

w =Pw

q=0 {q.

At the beginning of every time period w the worker decides whetherto switch to the outside job or to remain in the current job till the nextperiod. If the worker decides to switch jobs then she must incur a fixed andirrecoverable cost F.8 In addition assume that the worker is risk neutral— i.e. utility is a linear function of wages — and infinitely lived. Hence theworker’s problem is to maximize the expected discounted stream of life-time net income, where net income at any given time is the wage minus theswitching cost F, conditional on a job switch.Since all jobs evolve as symmetric random walk processes the worker’s

decision to switch jobs depend only on the wage difference between theoutside job option and the current job. Therefore, given switching cost F,the worker only needs to evaluate the wage difference between the outsidejob option and the current job to decide whether to switch or not. Thisimplies that there is a reservation value such that whenever the potentialmobility wage gain exceeds this value the worker will switch jobs. Thisreservation value will depend on switching costs F, and more importantly,on the properties of the random walk process of wages — i.e. within-job wagevolatility. The point, however, is that the switching rule depends on neitherthe level of wages nor the identity of jobs.The Bellman representation of the decision problem faced by a worker

can be stated as follows:

ye¡zd> ze

¢= max

£zd − F + �Y d> ze + �Y e

¤, (6)

where yl¡zd> ze

¢denote the value function for a worker who is currently

employed at job l, given zd and ze. The continuation value of job l toworker is:

Y l = s2yl¡zd + k>ze + k

¢+ (1− s)

2yl¡zd − k>ze − k

¢+

s (1− s) yl¡zd + k>ze − k

¢+ s (1− s) yl

¡zd − k>ze + k

¢=

The solution to this problem is to find the optimal switching rule — theminimum wage difference between the outside job and current job for aworker to switch jobs — given the fixed cost F of switching jobs.

labor mobility in this framework is the wage difference between the outside andinside jobs as long as jobs are symmetric.8 Although we do not explicitly model the source of switching costs, the obviousreasons are direct monetary and psychological costs of moving, and possible costsassociated with relocation of family.

Page 10: Does Wage Volatility Matter in Labor Markets? Theory and ... · volatility and mean within-job wage growth in a quit regression. The effect of volatility on mobility wage gains is

10 Tackseung Jun, Lalith Munasinghe

2.3 Optimal Threshold and Some Comparative Statics

We now derive the minimum wage difference between the outside job optionand the current job that is necessary for a worker to switch jobs. Let v denotethis threshold for job turnover. Theorem 1 below details the solution to theoptimal job switching rule.

Theorem 1 (Optimal Job Switching Rule) The worker will switch jobsif the wage difference between the outside and inside jobs is greater than orequal to the optimal threshold of turnover v, which is given by:(1=1) v = F (1− �) + 2�s (1− s) if v ? k,

(1=2) v = F (1− �) + 2k� 1−�v@k

(1−�)(1+�v@k+1)if v ≥ k and v@k is an integer,

(1=3) v (1− �) = F (1− �) (1 + �) + 2k1+�2o+1

³�1−�

2o

(1−�) − (�+ 1) n�o´,

if v ≥ k, v@k is not an integer, and where v@k ? o ? v@k+ 1, where

� = 2s(1−s)�1−2�s2−�+2�s+

√(1−4�s2−�+4�s)(1−�)

and � = �o(1+�)1+�2o+1

.

We present the details of the derivation in the Appendix. Here we outlinea sketch of our proof strategy. First, consider a worker who always switchesjobs whenever the current wage gain is at least as large as some minimumwage gain. Second, we compute the sum of present discounted expected netincomes from this threshold rule of mobility. This enables us to calculatethe sequences of switching times, and the sum of present discounted netincome for each completed job spell. Third, for any arbitrary thresholdwage differential we can compute: (1) the expected wages from switchingand then following some threshold rule, and (2) the expected wages fromstaying and then also following the same threshold rule. Finally, the optimalthreshold wage differential, v, is defined and solved for where (1) and (2)are equal.Theorem 2 summarizes the main comparative static results.

Theorem 2 (Comparative Statics) Fix zmzj = k (2s− 1) and s A [email protected] the minimum mobility wage gain v: (1) increases in F, and (2) in-creases in k and this increase in v with respect to k is larger when zmzj ishigh.

Using the Implicit Function Theorem, it is easy to show that the mini-mum mobility wage gain v increases in F, increases in k, and decreases in sfor s ∈ (1@2> 1) (See Jun 2001 for details). Now, fix zmzj = sk−(1− s)k =k (2s− 1). Even if we fix within-job wage growth the minimum mobilitywage gain still increases in switching costs F. Assume that mean within-jobwage growth is positive, s A 1@2. Note, for within-job wage growth to remainconstant, s and k must trade-off each other. For example, an increase in kmust be accompanied by a decrease in s. Therefore if k increases, then theminimum mobility wage gain v increases more when zmzj is fixed beause anincrease in k is accompanied by a decrease in s, which further increases theminimum mobility wage gain. This simply says that an increase in k induces

Page 11: Does Wage Volatility Matter in Labor Markets? Theory and ... · volatility and mean within-job wage growth in a quit regression. The effect of volatility on mobility wage gains is

11

a higher minimum mobility wage gain when zmzj is fixed. Moreover sincea high s is equivalent to a high within-job wage growth rate, the increase inthe minimum mobility wage gains due to an increase in volatility k, is largerwhen within-job wage growth rate is at a higher level. The corollary of thisresult is that the negative effect of volatility on turnover is more likely whenwithin-job wage growth is high.Some of the specifics of this model can be extended in several ways.

First, it can be generalized to allow the evolution of outside and insidewages to be correlated. The implications are discerned as follows: if thecorrelation is positive then the threshold wage differential decreases, andif the correlation is negative then the threshold wage differential increases.These results raise an empirical challenge because we do not observe thesimultaneous evolution of wages in the current and outside jobs. Second, wecan model optimal switching in an environment where either the inside oroutside wage is frozen. The same results hold since only the wage differencebetween the outside and inside job matters for switching decisions.In the next subsection we briefly discuss some related theory and espe-

cially how our model might be related to search theory.

2.4 Job Search and Other Related Theory

The obvious shortcoming of our model is the unrealism of the two-job frame-work since workers typically do not switch between the same two jobs overthe life cycle of employment. Of course, the outside wage option can arisefrom a distribution of outside job offers. But the question is whether oursimple two-job model and its theoretical implications can be interpretedwithin a proper job search framework.Although job search theory has various renditions, a non-degenerate dis-

tribution of outside job offers and imperfect information about the qualityand location of job matches are some of the salient characteristics of searchmodels. In Jovanovic’s (1979) well-known mismatch theory of turnover work-ers search from a non-degenerate distribution of outside job offers. Althoughin equilibrium this distribution of outside offers is supported by the assump-tion of heterogeneity of match quality, ex ante all outside jobs are identicalbecause jobs are treated as experience goods. Hence all jobs offer the sameinitial wage. Worker-firm separations result because of the arrival of signalsabout match quality over the course of an employment relationship. Sincepriors about match quality are presumed to be identically non-informativeacross all jobs and Bayesian learning implies that within-job wage volatilitydecreases with job tenure, the mismatch theory is not well suited to studythe effects of wage volatility on labor mobility.Both the mismatch theory and our model of turnover are also related

to a larger theoretical literature on multi-armed bandit problems. The well-known Gittins index rule, from the classical formulation of the multi-armedbandit framework (Gittins 1979), shows that the optimal strategy is to pick

Page 12: Does Wage Volatility Matter in Labor Markets? Theory and ... · volatility and mean within-job wage growth in a quit regression. The effect of volatility on mobility wage gains is

12 Tackseung Jun, Lalith Munasinghe

the arm with the highest Gittins index, where the computation of the indexof an arm is based only on the properties of that arm. Banks and Sundaram(1994) argued that in the presence of switching costs any index rule willnot be optimal. The theoretical contribution of our model is that we derivean optimal rule in the presence of switching costs. However, we do so byrestricting our model to the two-armed bandit framework. Bergemann andVälimäki (2001) have shown that if the distribution of arms is stationarythen a modified index rule is optimal even in the presence of switching costs.Note that Jovanovic’s mismatch theory of turnover is structurally identicalto this multi-armed bandit framework since the stochastic element of eacharm arises from the learning process about underlying productivity of thearm. Hence, this framework, like Jovanovic’s, is not ideally suited to studythe effects of volatility on switching behavior. By contrast, our model —because it allows volatility to play an exogenous role in predicting labormobility — is better suited to illustrate the links between wage volatilityand the optimal threshold of turnover.To return to the question posed earlier, can our two-job model of turnover

be interpreted within a job search framework? For example, suppose thatthe outside wage option arises from a stationary distribution and that nei-ther the worker nor the firm knows the match quality at the time of jobstart. Hence ex ante all jobs must offer the same initial wage. However,once a job commences, the evolution of within-job wages are determinedby two distinct stochastic processes — i.e. by a random walk component(which is exogenously given) and a match quality component (which arisesfrom Bayesian updating). With the further assumption that job changesentail an irrecoverable switching cost, this framework clearly maintains allthe elements of the mismatch theory and our model of job turnover. Thekey prediction of the mismatch model is that worker-firm separations areless likely to occur as the employment relationship ages. Hence holding jobtenure constant, wage volatility (due to the random walk assumption) isstill likely to be positively related to the optimal threshold of turnover — thekey theoretical result of our model. The formalization of this conjecture isa part of an ongoing research project.

3 Empirical Analysis

3.1 NLSY Data and Wage Volatility

We use the National Longitudinal Surveys of Youth (NLSY) data from1979 to 1994 for our empirical analyses. The NLSY tracks a panel of 12,686young women and men, first interviewed in 1979. The availability of workhistories of early careers, including detailed information on job durationand separation, labor market experience, wage rates, and other individualand job characteristics, make this data ideal for our analyses of volatilityeffects on labor mobility outcomes. We only track CPS (Current PopulationSurvey) designated jobs, although the NLSY tracks additional jobs. The

Page 13: Does Wage Volatility Matter in Labor Markets? Theory and ... · volatility and mean within-job wage growth in a quit regression. The effect of volatility on mobility wage gains is

13

CPS job is typically the main or most recent job, and more information isavailable about CPS jobs. Wage rates are deflated by the consumer priceindex from the Report of the President, where the base year is 1987.One of our dependent variables is mobility wage gains. It is defined as

the percentage difference between the first wage in the future job and thelast wage in the current job, conditional on a voluntary job change. Weensure that the two wage observations occur in contiguous years. The otherdependent variable is the quit rate, where a quit is defined as a voluntaryjob change between two contiguous survey years. Since these surveys areconducted each year our quit models estimate an annual turnover rate.The more contentious issue is the construction of our wage volatility

measure. Since we assume that wages evolve as a random walk with drift,our empirical analyses focus on volatility of within-job wage changes. Foreach individual in our sample we estimate a simple OLS within-job wagedifference equation based on wage observations over the entire life cycle.Obviously, we do not include wage changes due to job changes in this sample.In these individual regressions, job tenure and experience are included asright hand side variables to account for the concavity of the wage-experienceand wage-tenure profiles. We then take the sample variance of the error termfrom each of these individual regressions as our sample measure of person-specific wage volatility. More explicitly, we can write the estimation equationfor measuring volatility of worker l (volatilityl) as follows:

zmzflw¡= zf

lw − zflw−1

¢= �1 + �2experiencelw + �3tenurelw + �lw>

where zflw is the log wage of current job of worker l at time w. Then volatilityl

is simply the variance of the error term of above regression:

yrodwlolw|l =X³

zmzflw −\zmzflw´2

@ (ql − 3) >

where ql is the number of zmzf observations for individual l.This wage volatility measure is of course the key predictor in our sub-

sequent analyses of quit rates and mobility wage gains. In our empiricalanalyses we also include the mean of within-job wage growth among our in-dependent variables.9 Also note that a key prediction of the model is that itis more likely for volatility to have a negative effect on turnover if within-jobwage growth is higher.We impose various sample restrictions on our data by excluding: (1)

any observation where the real wage (in 1987 dollars) is less than $1.50 orgreater than $200.00, (2) if mobility wage changes fall by more than 50%

9 Here we depart from Topel and Ward (1992). Their evidence shows that “het-erogeneity among jobs in predictable wage growth is not an important feature ofthe data” (p. 459). As a consequence, their evidence is consistent with the samedrift parameter across all jobs. Since our framework is based on person-specificeffects, we proceed on the assumption that individuals are likely to differ in termsof this drift parameter. Hence we include mean wage growth over the life cycle asa control variable in both our mobility wage gains and quit equations.

Page 14: Does Wage Volatility Matter in Labor Markets? Theory and ... · volatility and mean within-job wage growth in a quit regression. The effect of volatility on mobility wage gains is

14 Tackseung Jun, Lalith Munasinghe

or exceed 300%, and (3) if within-job wage changes fall by 50% or exceedby 300%. The primary purpose of these restrictions is to exclude obviousoutliers and data errors. Although these criteria are arbitrary, we check forrobustness of our results by experimenting with various alternative cutoffswith no qualitative changes and only minor quantitative changes in ourresults.

3.2 Estimation Framework

In this section we outline the estimation framework to test volatility effectson mobility wage gains and quit rates. We first derive our mobility wage gainequation as a reduced form version of a standard human capital earningsfunction. Hence, consider wages in the last period of the current job andthe first period of the future job as

zflw = ]lw� + �1l + �2l w+ %lw and zi

lw+1 = ]lw+1� + �1l + �2l w+ %lw+1,

respectively.10 Note that z is the log wage and ] is a vector of worker char-acteristics such as age, education, race, gender, and other determinants ofwages subscripted by time w; superscripts f and i on z designate wages inthe “current” and “future” job, respectively. We also allow for individualfixed effects as well as individual time trends, denoted by �1l and �2l w, re-spectively. Since our focus is on mobility wage gains, we take the differencein wages across the future job and current job. This yields an equation thatis one step closer to our estimating equation:

�zlw ≡ zilw+1 − zf

lw = �]lw� + �2l +�%lw= (7)

An individual’s mobility wage gain is now a function of the changes inexplanatory variables such as changes in marital status. The individual fixedeffects in the error structure of course drop out with the exception of thetime trend terms which generate individual fixed-effects in the mobility wagegain specification. We assume, however, that mobility wage gains continueto be a function of time invariant factors such as education, gender, andrace. Our framework up to this point closely parallels Goldberg and Tracy(2001).Our theoretical analysis of course implies that mobility wage gains will

also be a function of wage volatility. As a consequence we augment equation(7) to generate our estimating equation:

�zlw = [lw� + �1volatilityl + �2growthl + �2l +�%lw,

10 We assume the same � for both equations only for notational convenience.In our empirical specifications we include current and lagged time dependentvariables separately and thus estimate a different � for the current and futurewage equations.

Page 15: Does Wage Volatility Matter in Labor Markets? Theory and ... · volatility and mean within-job wage growth in a quit regression. The effect of volatility on mobility wage gains is

15

where volatilityl is wage volatility and growthl is mean of within-job wagegrowth rate for worker l. The vector [ includes not only worker charac-teristics such as age, education, gender and race, but also changes in timedependent covariates.Since we observe mobility wage gains only if a worker voluntarily changes

jobs, our subsample of mobility wage gain observations is not a random sam-ple of individuals with a current job and a potential outside job option. Asa result we need to explicitly introduce a quit model in order to correct forpotential sample selection bias in our estimation. Of course this first stagequit model is of direct interest to us since our theoretical considerationssuggest that volatility is a likely determinant of the quit rate also. In par-ticular, the model implies that the volatility effect on turnover is more likelyto be negative if within-job wage growth is higher.We implement various Heckman-type sample selection corrections. Our

selection equation is based on whether or not an individual quits her currentjob voluntarily. The basic framework can be outlined by first considering alatent quit equation, and the corresponding quit outcome.

t∗lw = }lw�1 + volatilityl�2 + growthl�3 + volatilityl ∗ growthl�4 + �lw>

tlw = 1 if t∗lw A 0, and tlw = 0, otherwise.

The tlw variable indicates whether worker l quits her current job at time w.Note that our model predicts that �4 ? 0. Of course sample selection arisesbecause mobility wage gains are observed only if a worker quits her currentjob and moves to a new job. Hence:

�zlw = [lw�1 + volatilityl�2 + growthl�3 +�%lw if tlw = 1.

This model can be estimated either via maximum likelihood (Greene 1981)or by using Heckman’s “two-step” procedure (Heckman 1976, 1979). In ourempirical results section we present estimates from both techniques.Since in the presence of individual fixed effects this sample correction

does not yield consistent estimates, Woodbridge (1995) suggests an alter-native procedure that yields consistent estimates with fixed effects. Theprocedure exploits the panel nature of our data. The basic idea is to gen-erate Inverse Mills Ratios for each year and then to include not only thisratio in our mobility wage gain regression (the standard two-step Heckmanprocedure), but also interactions of this ratio with time dummies.11 Henceour final estimating equation is:

�zlw = [lw�1 + volatilityl�2 + growthl�3 + �4�lw + W�lw�5 +�%lw,

where � is the Inverse Mills Ratio and W is a vector of time dummies. Thisprocedure provides consistent estimates in the presence of fixed effects.12

11 See Chapter 17 of Woodbridge (2002) for details.12 See Woodbridge (1995) for details.

Page 16: Does Wage Volatility Matter in Labor Markets? Theory and ... · volatility and mean within-job wage growth in a quit regression. The effect of volatility on mobility wage gains is

16 Tackseung Jun, Lalith Munasinghe

3.3 Empirical Results

3.3.1 Summary Statistics Table 1 lists the labels and descriptions of thekey variables. Tables 2 through 4 present various summary statistics. Table2 pertains to person-specific variables. Tables 3 and 4 are based on samplesspecific to the mobility wage gains and quit models, respectively. Table 2 isrestricted to a sample of 6,099 individuals that have information on wagevolatility. To compute a volatility measure, an individual needs to have atleast four valid within-job wage observations. The average individual hasabout 7 such within-job wage observations, where the range goes from theminimum of 4 to a maximum of 15 observations. In our sample the averagenumber of mobility wage gain observations per individual is about 1.7. Thekey variable is the sample variance based on individual within-job wageregressions — our measure of within-job wage volatility. The mean volatilityis .075 and the standard deviation is .16. This substantially high standarddeviation bodes well for our efforts to study the effects of volatility variationsacross individuals on their labor mobility outcomes. The within-job wagegrowth is .08. Our sample is composed of slightly more than 50% male andabout 60% white. The average completed years of schooling in the sampleis a little over 13 years.The sample in Table 3 is based on observations from our mobility wage

gain equations. Since each individual can have multiple wage gain observa-tions, individuals are repeated in this sample. We include summary statis-tics for experience, tenure, on-the-job training, and whether the job changeentailed a change in the 2-digit industry classification. Table 4 repeats thesame for the sample of observations on which our quit regressions are based.Clearly this sample includes not only observations with valid mobility wagegains — i.e. when a person quits — but also all the within-job observationswhen individuals do not quit their jobs. Hence this sample size is consider-ably larger.

3.3.2 Volatility Effects on Mobility Wage Gains Table 5 presents coeffi-cients estimates from various mobility wage gains models. The first and sec-ond columns show estimates from OLS and random effects specifications,respectively. Here we do not explicitly take into account the first stage quitequation. The remaining three columns are estimates from models that ex-plicitly take into account the first stage selection equation. Column 3 isbased on the maximum likelihood specification that jointly estimates boththe mobility wage gain equation and the quit equation. (We show the coef-ficients of the quit equation in column 4 of Table 6.) Column 4 includes theInverse Mills Ratio from the first stage selection equation that is based onHeckman’s two-step correction — i.e. the quit equation. Column 5 includesin addition the interaction of this Inverse Mills Ratio with time dummies toaccount for individual fixed effects, as discussed in the earlier section. Allthe standard errors (except column 2) are corrected for multiple individualobservations and all are weighted regressions by the number of observations

Page 17: Does Wage Volatility Matter in Labor Markets? Theory and ... · volatility and mean within-job wage growth in a quit regression. The effect of volatility on mobility wage gains is

17

used to compute the volatility measure. A host of control variables are in-cluded in all the models. Variables with a w subscript pertain to the timeperiod coinciding with the first period on the future job.The key finding is a positive and highly significant coefficient on volatil-

ity. This positive effect of volatility on mobility wage gains holds acrossall the different model specifications. In particular, the effect of volatilityon mobility wage gains appears to be even stronger when we account forsample selection. This positive correlation between volatility and mobilitywage gains is of course consistent with our model of job turnover. Also notethat within-job wage growth is negatively correlated with mobility wagegains. The variable Career is the ratio of the number of prior within-jobwage change observations at a given point in time to the total number ofwithin-job wage change observations over the entire observed life cycle ofan individual.13 The negative coefficient on Career simply says that mobil-ity wage gains decrease as individuals progress along their careers. Amongother noteworthy findings are: men experience high mobility wage gains,entering a union covered job leads to high gains, and conversely, leaving anunion covered job leads to lower gains.

3.3.3 Volatility Effects on Quit Rates Table 6 presents coefficients fromfour quit models: a linear probability model, a probit model, a randomeffects probit model, and the first stage of the maximum likelihood jointestimation of mobility wage gains equation, respectively. (The last columnhere corresponds to the third column of Table 5.) We include a similarset of independent variables in these models as in the mobility wage gainmodels except that we do not use information about future jobs to predictthe likelihood of a quit probability. In addition we also include the currentwage as a control for job value. The key difference however is that in thesequit models we include an interaction between volatility and within-jobwage growth. Across all these different model specifications we find thatthe estimated effect of this interaction term is negative as predicted byour model. The coefficient on volatility is positive (and significant) and thecoefficient on within-job wage growth is negative (and not significant). Butthe key model prediction is of course that volatility is more likely to have anegative effect on turnover as within-job wage growth increases, which findssupport in the negative coefficient estimate on the interaction term. Previousstudies have shown that past wage growth on a job reduces the likelihoodof turnover (Topel and Ward, 1992). Our negative but insignificant effect ofwithin-job wage growth on turnover should not be interpreted as past wagegrowth on the job since our measure of within-job wage growth is a person-and not a job-specific measure.

3.3.4 What about Risk Aversion? If our measure volatility pertained towages of future jobs then these joint findings — namely, that volatility re-13 Note that our volatility measure of within-job wage changes is based on thelatter number of observations.

Page 18: Does Wage Volatility Matter in Labor Markets? Theory and ... · volatility and mean within-job wage growth in a quit regression. The effect of volatility on mobility wage gains is

18 Tackseung Jun, Lalith Munasinghe

duces quit rates and increases mobility wage gains — would be consistentwith risk aversion on the part of workers. However, since our measure ofvolatility is person-specific and based on the entire life cycle of wage ob-servations these findings cannot be interpreted as evidence of risk aversion.Although we are unable to directly test this risk aversion hypothesis be-cause job-specific volatility measures are infeasible, we attempt to providea discriminating test of sorts by exploiting the exact timing of when a quitoccurs in the course of an individual’s life cycle.Note that a low Career value (close to zero) indicates not only an early

point in an individual’s observed career, but more precisely the fact thatour person-specific volatility measure is based more on wage observationsof future jobs. Conversely, a high value (close to one) would indicate thatour volatility measure is based more on wage observations of past jobs.With this variable we can address whether the negative effect of volatilityon quits and the positive effect of volatility on mobility wage gains arestronger when our volatility measure is based more on future than on pastjob wage observations by including Career and its interaction with volatilityas independent variables in our mobility wage gains and quit regressionmodels. Such evidence would provide some support for the risk aversionhypothesis.In Tables 5 and 6 we also include coefficient estimates of Career inter-

acted with volatility. In the wage gain models (Table 5) the sign of theinteraction term is positive across all model specifications, although theestimates are insignificant. A Negative coefficient would indicate that pastwage volatility has a negative impact on mobility wage gains and would lendsupport to the risk aversion explanation. However given that these estimatesare positive (although insignificant) implies that we find no evidence of riskaversion. We also include this interaction term in all of our quit models(Table 6). As we argued earlier, risk aversion would predict a positive signon the interaction term in the quit model. However, all the coefficients ofthe interaction term are negative (and significant). Hence if anything thisset of results contradict the risk aversion explanation. In conclusion, we failto find any supporting evidence for the risk aversion hypothesis.

4 Conclusion

In this paper we present a theory about the role of wage volatility in pre-dicting labor mobility. The model is structurally equivalent to the optionspricing approach to investments where switching costs associated with mov-ing from one job to another are explicitly incorporated and within-job wagesare assumed to evolve as a random walk process. The key theoretical re-sult is that an increase in wage volatility implies a higher optimal thresh-old of turnover. As a consequence volatility can reduce quit rates and in-crease mobility wage gains conditional on workers voluntarily switching jobs.We present supporting evidence from the National Longitudinal Surveys

Page 19: Does Wage Volatility Matter in Labor Markets? Theory and ... · volatility and mean within-job wage growth in a quit regression. The effect of volatility on mobility wage gains is

19

of Youth. The data show, under various specifications, that volatility ofwithin-job wage changes is negatively correlated with quits and positivelycorrelated with wage gains controlling for a variety of individual and othercharacteristics.

Acknowledgements.We thank Richard Ericson, Cynthia Howells, BoyanJovanovic, Myonghyun Lee, Brian Levine, Brendan O’Flaherty, Randall Re-back, Rajiv Sethi, Paolo Siconolfi, Nachum Sicherman, Michael Waldman,and Heesuk Yun for helpful comments. The first author acknowledges thefinancial support from Kyung Hee University under 20070668.

A Appendix: Proof of Theorem 1

We begin the proof of Theorem 1 by considering the difference:

yd¡zd + k>ze + k

¢− ye

¡zd + k>ze + k

¢=

Let zd − ze equal the threshold v. Note that it is optimal to stay injob d at yd

¡zd + k>ze + k

¢. The worker is indifferent between switch-

ing now and delaying at ye¡zd + k>ze + k

¢since mobility wage gain is

equal to the threshold. Hence ye¡zd + k>ze + k

¢has the same value as

yd¡zd + k>ze + k

¢− F if a switch is made to job d now. Therefore it fol-

lows:yd¡zd + k>ze + k

¢− ye

¡zd + k>ze + k

¢= F= (8)

The same argument leads to:

yd¡zd − k>ze − k

¢− ye

¡zd − k>ze − k

¢= F= (9)

Now consider the difference yd¡zd + k>ze − k

¢− ye

¡zd + k>ze − k

¢. By

the threshold definition, it is optimal to choose job d in yd¡zd + k>ze − k

¢

and ye¡zd + k>ze − k

¢. Hence ye

¡zd + k>ze − k

¢and yd

¡zd + k>ze − k

¢−

F has the same value if a switch is made to the job d. This implies:

yd¡zd + k>ze − k

¢− ye

¡zd + k>ze − k

¢= F= (10)

Hence only the following difference remains to be derived:

yd¡zd − k>ze + k

¢− ye

¡zd − k>ze + k

¢.

We first derive this difference if the threshold v is less than the jump k,which is the case of Theorem 1.1. Notice that the wage differential in¡zd − k>ze + k

¢is less than −v. Hence a worker will switch to job e in

yd¡zd − k>ze + k

¢and a worker with ye

¡zd − k>ze + k

¢will remain in

job e. As a result, the value of yd (v− k> k) + F is identical to the valueye (v− k> k) if a switch is made to job e now. This implies yd (v− k> k) −ye (v− k> k) = −F. Substituting this and (8)−(10) into (6) and rearrangingterms, we prove Theorem 1.1.

Page 20: Does Wage Volatility Matter in Labor Markets? Theory and ... · volatility and mean within-job wage growth in a quit regression. The effect of volatility on mobility wage gains is

20 Tackseung Jun, Lalith Munasinghe

Theorem 1.2 and 1.3 use identical arguments, and we only present theproof of Theorem 1.2. With the initial wage differential �0(= zd − ze) attime zero, suppose that a worker is currently in job e and remains thereuntil the wage differential becomes �� = �0 + 2k for the first time, where

� ∈ {W A 0|�m ? �0 + 2k for all 0 ? m ? W and �W = �0 + 2k} = (11)

We assume that �0 ? v and thus it is optimal to stay in job e until thetime � .

We derive the sum of present discounted value of wages between time0 and � . This sum can be separated into two components: a “constantterm” J and a fluctuation term. The constant term denotes the sum ofpresent discounted value of starting wage ze, and the fluctuation term isthe remainder. By definition, the fluctuation term does not depend on thestarting wage. We focus on the constant term. For each � ≥ 1, there aremultiple sample paths that lead to the target wage difference �0 + 2k atrandom time � . Let Qm denote the set of such sample paths where the firsthitting time to the target wage difference �0 + 2k is a random time m, andqm is the cardinality of the set. Fixing m, the constant term on a particularsample path is given by ze

Pml=1 �

l (there are qm of such sums). Denote !mas the probability associated with the random time m. Then the constantterm with starting wage ze is:14

J¡ze¢= ze +

∞X

m=1

!mqmze

mX

l=1

�l = ze

⎣1 +∞X

m=1

!mqm

mX

l=1

�l

where !m ≡ Pr[m A 0|�o ? �0 + 2k for all 0 ? o ? m and �m = �0 + 2k]=

We now proceed to derive the value function at the end of the “travel”to the target difference �0 + 2k from �0. Consider the value functionye¡zd> ze

¢. For each random time m defined above, this value function at

the end of the travel will be �mye (�0 + 2k).15 This occurs on qm differentpaths, each with the probability !m of occurring. Since the stochastic processof the wage differential �w does not keep track of wage at each job, the wagelevel of each job can be anything at a random time m. However, all the wagepairs are equivalent as long as they have the identical difference since theoptimal switching rule only depends on the wage differential (as we showed

14 Note that the first period wage ze is earned regardless of sample paths.15 For this notation only, we put the wage differential in the value function.

Page 21: Does Wage Volatility Matter in Labor Markets? Theory and ... · volatility and mean within-job wage growth in a quit regression. The effect of volatility on mobility wage gains is

21

earlier). Therefore we can show:16

ye¡zd + k>ze + k

¢−ye

¡zd> ze

¢= J

¡ze + k

¢−J

¡ze¢+

k

1− �

∞X

m=1

!mqm�m ,

(12)which reduces to

1 +∞X

m=1

!mqm

mX

l=1

�l =1−

P∞m=1 !mqm�

m

1− �= (13)

Note thatP∞

m=1 !mqm�m is simply the moment generating function of the

“�-discounted” first hitting time probability that the wage differential isreduced by 2k. Denote � as this m.g.f. A standard exercise17 shows that �can be expressed as in Theorem 1. Rewrite (13) such that:

1 +∞X

m=1

!mqm

mX

l=1

�l =1− �

1− �= (14)

The equality in (14) is critical in deriving the optimal switching policy. InLemma 1 below, we derive yd (v− k> k)− ye (v− k> k).Lemma 1. Let n = v@k.

yd (v− k> k)− ye (v− k> k) = −2k(1− �)

¡1− �n

¢

(1− �) (1 + �n+1)+ F=

We prove the lemma from the two following claims.

Claim 1.

yd (v> 0)− yd (v− k> k) = k1− �2n+2 − 2�n + 2�2n+1

(1− �) (1− �2n+2).

Proof of Claim 1: The proof is done by constructing optimal paths. Foryd (v> 0), we construct the following optimal rule. First define switching rule�11 as:

�w = D for 0 ≤ w ? �1, where {�1 A 0|�w A −v ∀w ? �1>��1 = −v} .16 The argument is as follows. For the value functions ye

�zd> ze

�and

ye�zd + k>ze + k

�, note that for every sample path arriving at the wage dif-

ferential �0 + 2k from the pair�zd> ze

�, there exists an identical sample path

from the pair�zd + k>ze + k

�except that it is always k higher until the first hit-

ting time � , since the wage differential between the wage pairs remains identicalon every “matched” path, and the optimal rule only depends on wage differential.Hence the sum of present discounted value of the difference between ye

�zd> ze

and ye�zd + k>ze + k

�over all sample paths until the time � can be expressed

as the difference between two constant terms: J�ze�and J

�ze + k

�. The exis-

tence of the identical sample paths makes computation of the fluctuation termredundant since it will be canceled out in the difference between the two valuefunctions.17 Interested readers can find a derivation of � in Cox and Miller (1965).

Page 22: Does Wage Volatility Matter in Labor Markets? Theory and ... · volatility and mean within-job wage growth in a quit regression. The effect of volatility on mobility wage gains is

22 Tackseung Jun, Lalith Munasinghe

and next define �12 as:

�w = E for �1 ≤ w ? � 01>

where©� 01 A �1|�w ? v+ 2k ∀�1 ≤ w ? � 01>�� 01

= v+ 2kª>

�w = D for � 01 ≤ w ? � 001where

©� 001 A � 01|�w A −v ∀� 01 ≤ w ? � 001 >�� 001

= −vª=

We first apply �11 and then apply �12 at random time �1. Clearly, the con-structed policy �11 and the subsequent application of �12 satisfy optimality.For yd (v− k> k), we start by defining switching rule �21 as follows:

�w = D for 0 ≤ w ≤ �2 where {�2 A 0|�w A −v− 2k ∀w ? �2>��2 = −v− 2k} .

Next define �22 as follows:

�w = E for �2 ≤ w ? � 02>where

©� 02 A �2|�w ? v ∀�2 ≤ w ? � 02>�� 02

= vª

�w = D for � 02 ≤ w ? � 002 >where

©� 002 A � 02|�w A −v− 2k ∀� 02 ≤ w ? � 002 >�� 002

= −v− 2kª=

We first apply �21 and then apply �12 at random time �2. As in theprevious case, it is easy to check that the policy �21 and the subsequentapplication of �22 are optimal. At the end of applying policy �12 and �22, thewage differential is−v and−v−2k for yd (v> 0) and yd (v− k> k), respectively,which is identical to the wage differential at time w = �1 and w = �2 for eachrespective value function. This implies that starting with �11 and repeating�12 over and over again is an optimal rule. Denote this optimal rule as �∗1.The optimal rule �∗2 can be constructed in a similar fashion. Let {�∗1} be thesequence of switching times under �∗1 and {�∗2} be the sequence of switchingtime under �∗2.Note that each {�∗l } can be decomposed into the sequence of independent

hitting times when the wage differential widens or shrinks by 2k for the firsttime from the previous wage differential. Notice further that random timesin {�∗1} and {�∗2} can be matched by matching paths under the optimalrule. This implies that �1 = �2, � 01 = � 02, and � 001 = � 002 . This means thatswitching costs will disappear in the difference yd (v> 0)− yd (v− k> k).We are now ready to derive the difference yd (v> 0)− yd (v− k> k). Note

that the optimal path before the first job switch to job e under �∗1 (and also�∗2) can be decomposed into n (= v@k) independent “steps” where the wagedifferential shrinks by 2k in each step. (12)− (14) imply that the differenceyd (v> 0) − yd (v− k> k) between any two adjacent steps until the first jobswitch is exactly k (1− �) @ (1− �). This is because, for each sample pathfrom yd (v> 0) under the optimal rule �∗1, there exists an identical samplepath from yd (v− k> 0) under the optimal rule �∗2 except that it is alwaysk below. After n steps of 2k decreases in each step, the wage differentialwill be −v and −v − 2k for yd (v> 0) and yd (v− k> k), respectively. At thispoint in time, it is optimal to switch to job e for both value functions.

Page 23: Does Wage Volatility Matter in Labor Markets? Theory and ... · volatility and mean within-job wage growth in a quit regression. The effect of volatility on mobility wage gains is

23

Similar arguments as above show that the difference between the two valuefunctions from the time of the first switch and up until the second switchis: −k (1− �) @ (1− �). Since {�∗l } is constructed as a repetition of optimalrules applied until the second (random) switch defined in �12 and �22, thedifference between the two value functions will also alternate accordingly asthe optimal rules.18 Using this argument, we get:

yd (v> 0)− yd (v− k> k)

= k1− �n

1− �− �nk

1− �n+1

1− �

⎣∞X

m=0

�2m(n+1) −∞X

m=0

�(2m+1)(n+1)

⎦ =

Rearrangement completes the proof. k

Claim 2. With n = v@k

ye (v> 0)− ye (v− k> k) = k2�−

¡1 + �n+1

¢

(1− �) (1 + �n+1)=

Proof of Claim 2 is based on the same argument as the proof of Claim1, and it is omitted here. Lemma 1 is then a straightforward implication ofClaim 1 and Claim 2. k

Proof of Theorem 1: Since worker is indifferent between switching nowand delaying at the threshold v, plugging the result from Lemma 1 into (6)and using (8)− (10), we get:

v−F + �³s2 + (1− s)2 + s (1− s)

´F − �s (1− s)

2k(1−�)(1−�n)(1−�)(1+�n+1) +F = 0.

Rearrangement completes the proof. k

18 In other words, whenever job d is chosen, for each sample path under �∗1, thereexists an identical sample path of �∗2 except that it is k below, and whenever job eis chosen, for each sample path of �∗1, there exists an identical sample path under�∗2 except that it is k above.

Page 24: Does Wage Volatility Matter in Labor Markets? Theory and ... · volatility and mean within-job wage growth in a quit regression. The effect of volatility on mobility wage gains is

24 Tackseung Jun, Lalith Munasinghe

References

Antel J (1986) Human Capital Investment Specialization and the WageEffects of Voluntary Labor Mobility. Rev Econ Stat 68: 477-483.

Barron JM, Black DA, Loewenstein MA (1993) Gender Difference in Train-ing, Capital, and Wages. J Hum Resour 28: 343-364.

Banks JS, Sundaram RK (1994) Switching Costs and the Gittins Index.Econometrica 62: 687-694.

Bartel A, Borjas G (1981) Wage Growth and Job Turnover: An Empiri-cal Analysis. In: Studies in Labor Markets. University of Chicago Press,Chicago.

Bergemann D, Välimäki J (2001) Stationary Multi Choice Bandit Problems.J Econ Dyn Controls 25: 1585-1594.

Black DA, Loewenstein MA (1991) Self-enforcing Labor Contracts withCostly Mobility. Rev Labor Econ 12: 63-83.

Cox DR, Miller HD (1965) The Theory of Stochastic Processes. Chapman& Hall, New York.

Dixit AK, Pindyck RS (1994) Investment Under Uncertainty. PrincetonUniversity Press, Princeton.

Gittins JC (1979) Bandit Processes and Dynamic Allocation Indices. JRoyal Stat Soc Serial B 14: 148-177.

Goldberg L, Tracy J (2001) Gender Difference in the Labor Market Effectsof the Dollar. Am Econ Rev 91: 400-405.

Greene WH (1981) Sample Selection Bias as a Specification Error: Com-ment. Econometrica 49: 795-798.

Harris M, Holmstrom B (1982) A Theory of Wage Dynamics. Rev EconStat 49: 315-333.

Heckman J (1976) The Common Structure of Statistical Models of Trunca-tion, Sample Selection, and Limited Dependent Variables and a SimpleEstimator for Such Models. Ann Econ Soc Meas 5: 475-492.

Heckman J (1979) Sample Selection Bias as a Specification Error. Econo-metrica 47: 153-162.

Jovanovic B (1979) Job Matching and the Theory of Turnover. J Polit Econ87: 972-990.

Jun T (2001) Essays on Decision Theory: Effects of Changes in Environmenton Decisions. Ph. D. Thesis. Columbia University, New York.

Jun T (2005) Costly Switching and Investment Volatility. Econ Theory 25:317-332.

Kiefer NM, Neumann GR (1989) InterfirmMobility and Earnings. In: SearchModels and Applied Labor Economics, Part IV, Chapter 13, pp.247-283.Cambridge University Press, New York.

Kuhn P (1993) Demographic Groups and Personnel Policy. Labour Econ 1:49-70.

MacDonald GM (1988) Job Mobility in Market Equilibrium. Rev Econ Stat55: 153-168.

Page 25: Does Wage Volatility Matter in Labor Markets? Theory and ... · volatility and mean within-job wage growth in a quit regression. The effect of volatility on mobility wage gains is

25

Mincer J (1993) Wage Changes and Job Changes. In: Studies in HumanCapital: Collective Essays of Jacob Mincer Volume 1, Part II, pp.184-211. Edward Elgar Publishing Company, Brookfield.

Mortensen D (1988) Wages, Separations and Job Tenure: On-the-job Spe-cific Training or Matching. J Labor Econ 6: 445-471.

Sargent TJ (1987) Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory. Harvard UniversityPress, Cambridge.

Topel RH (1991) Specific Capital, Mobility, and Wages: Wages Rise withJob Seniority. J Polit Econ 9: 145-176.

Topel RH, Ward MP (1992) Job Mobility and the Careers of Young Men.Q J Econ 107: 439-479.

Woodbridge JM (1995) Selection Corrections for Panel Data Models underConditional Mean Independence Assumptions. J Econometrics 68: 115-132.

Woodbridge JM (2002) Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and PanelData. MIT Press, Cambridge.

Table 1. Variable Descriptions

Variable Description # Obs Meanmwg Mobility wage gain 19> 220 =1658volatility Sample variance from wage change OLS 55> 709 =0722growth Mean within-job wage changes over career 69> 707 =0849gender If male 160> 502 =5181nonwhite If non-white 160> 502 =4019grad Highest grade completed 159> 716 12=6670wage Hourly pay rate deflated (in 1987 dollars) 113> 659 7=6538afqt Armed Forces Qualifying Test Scores 151> 344 40=9813tenure Job tenure, years 103> 568 2=6983union If wages set by collective bargaining 95> 044 =1803quit If quit job since last interview 91> 808 =2437training Required years of occupational training 115> 689 1=0693married If married and living with spouse 137> 340 =4134change_ind If changed industry at job change 92> 104 =3224career Ratio of current to total completed exp. 55> 353 =5328

Page 26: Does Wage Volatility Matter in Labor Markets? Theory and ... · volatility and mean within-job wage growth in a quit regression. The effect of volatility on mobility wage gains is

26 Tackseung Jun, Lalith Munasinghe

Table 2. Summary Stastistics for Person-Specific Variables(# Observations = 6,099)

Variable Mean Std. Minimum Maximumn_mwg 1=6980 1=4960 0 9volatility =0754 =1630 0 2=4303growth =0797 =1032 −=1926 1=3407n_vol 7=3777 2=7734 4 15nonwhite =4030 =4905 0 1gender =5302 =4991 0 1afqt 45=0340 28=4611 1 99grad 13=1623 2=3801 0 18

Note: q_pzj is the number of mobility wage gain observations fora worker, and q_yro is the number of residual observations from whichvolatility is computed.

Table 3. Summary Statistics: Moblity Wage Gain Variables(# Observations = 10,355)

Variable Obs Mean Std. Minimum Maximummwg 10> 355 =1682 =4455 −=4997 2=9506

volatility 10> 355 =0763 =1654 0 2=3028growth 10> 355 =0829 =1082 −=1926 1=3407grad 10> 355 13=2673 2=3516 0 18

unionw−1 9> 949 =1302 =3366 0 1tenurew−1 10> 277 1=9861 2=2244 =0192 19=6731trainingw−1 10> 295 1=0415 =7350 =1667 5change_ind 9> 584 =5581 =4966 0 1

Table 4. Summary Statistics: Quit Variables(# Observations = 55,705)

Variable Obs Mean Std. Minimum Maximumquit 55> 705 =1859 =3890 0 1

volatility 55> 705 =0721 =1516 0 2=4303growth 55> 705 =0768 =0957 −=1926 1=3407grad 55> 705 13=1525 2=3185 0 18

unionw−1 53> 457 =2094 =4069 0 1tenurew−1 55> 332 3=2957 3=0873 =0192 19=6731trainingw−1 55> 490 1=1127 =7508 =1667 5change_ind 49> 538 =1956 =3966 0 1

Page 27: Does Wage Volatility Matter in Labor Markets? Theory and ... · volatility and mean within-job wage growth in a quit regression. The effect of volatility on mobility wage gains is

27

Table 5. Mobility Wage Gain Regressions(# Observations = 10,268)

Dependent Variable OLS OLS Sample Selection: mwgw (RE) MLE 2Step Modified

Two-Step

Intercept=0287(=0385)

=0281(=0397)

=1255(=0395)

=0310(=0400)

=0239(=0406)

volatility=1210(=0362)

=1197(=0382)

=1070(=0374)

=1050(=0370)

=1054(=0370)

growth−=4548(=0544)

−=4596(=0476)

−=4263(=0555)

−=4496(=0564)

−=4498(=0563)

Career−=0622(=0151)

−=0619(=0168)

=0845(=0173)

−=0512(=0194)

−=0454(=0224)

DCareer w=0042(=0019)

=0044(=0021)

=0194(=0021)

=0059(=0021)

=0056(=0021)

volatility*Career w=0350(=0816)

=0445(=0825)

=0909(=0887)

=1348(=0898)

=1358(=0894)

Inverse Mills Ratio−=0294(=0115)

−=0387(=0206)

IMR*TimeDummies Lqfoxghg

gender=0490(=0085)

=0495(=0093)

=0638(=0089)

=0508(=0089)

=0509(=0089)

grad w=0061(=0025)

=0063(=0025)

=0052(=0025)

=0066(=0025)

=0067(=0025)

tenurew−1−=0269(=0049)

−=0274(=0049)

−=0252(=0051)

−=0244(=0054)

−=0257(=0054)

tenure2w−1=0015(=0005)

=0015(=0005)

=0013(=0005)

=0012(=0005)

=0014(=0005)

trainingw=0369(=0067)

=0366(=0063)

=0391(=0068)

=0373(=0069)

=0368(=0069)

trainingw−1−=0241(=0072)

−=0241(=0066)

−=0216(=0072)

−=0215(=0074)

−=0217(=0074)

unionw=1412(=0164)

=1406(=0139)

=1455(=0167)

=1447(=0165)

=1445(=0165)

unionw−1−=0701(=0119)

−=0695(=0132)

−=0425(=0122)

−=0697(=0123)

−=0711(=0123)

�ind w=0582(=0091)

=0585(=0093)

−=0941(=0111)

=0369(=0127)

=0395(=0128)

R2 =0641 =0641 =0665 =0688"2 (1) 284=24

Note: Robust standard errors in parenthesis. In addition to the reportedcoefficients, we also include the following independent variables: square ofgrowth, race, AFQT scores, local unemployment rate, if reside in SMSA,net experience, and marital status. DCareerw is denominator of careerw.

Page 28: Does Wage Volatility Matter in Labor Markets? Theory and ... · volatility and mean within-job wage growth in a quit regression. The effect of volatility on mobility wage gains is

28 Tackseung Jun, Lalith Munasinghe

Table 6. Quit Regressions(# Obs = 55,153)

Dep. Variable OLS Probit Probit MLE: quit w (RE) (Selection)

Intercept=5029(=0140)

=4949(=0698)

=4949(=0660)

=4789(=0701)

volatility=0723(=0264)

=3248(=1266)

=3249(=1285)

=3577(=1215)

growth−=0366(=0306)

−=0673(=1394)

−=0673(=1319)

−=1953(=1409)

volatility*growth−=1120(=0618)

−=5721(=3058)

−=5721(=2859)

−=6771(=2939)

Career−=3030(=0088)

−1=2812(=0448)

−1=2812(=0334)

−1=2478(=0448)

DCareerw−=0263(=0006)

−=1340(=0035)

−=1340(=0033)

−=1319(=0035)

volatility*Career−=1055(=0373)

−=5104(=2097)

−=5104(=1583)

−=5131(=2079)

wagew−1−=0054(=0005)

−=0310(=0031)

−=0310(=0025)

−=0442(=0037)

gender−=0244(=0031)

−=1130(=0166)

−=1130(=0156)

−=0974(=0167)

grad w=0029(=0008)

=0141(=0044)

=0141(=0041)

=0174(=0044)

unionw=0097(=0049)

−=0416(=0252)

−=0416(=0243)

−=0336(=0252)

unionw−1−=0461(=0047)

−=2345(=0247)

−=2345(=0233)

−=2266(=0246)

tenurew−1−=0031(=0015)

−=0194(=0089)

−=0194(=0079)

−=0172(=0089)

tenure2w−1=0010(=0001)

=0035(=0007)

=0035(=0007)

=0034(=0007)

trainingw−1−=0025(=0021)

=0043(=0111)

=0043(=0107)

=0149(=0112)

�ind w=3838(=0060)

1=3368(=0193)

1=3368(=0170)

1=3305(=0193)

R2 =3104 =3118"̄2 (1) 0=00 284=24

Note: Robust standard errors in parenthesis. In addition to the reportedcoefficients, we also include the following independent variables: square ofgrowth, race, AFQT scores, local unemployment rate, if reside in SMSA,and martial status. DCareerw is denominator of careerw.