DEV_2001

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/7/2019 DEV_2001

    1/18

    PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE

    This article was downloaded by: [INFLIBNET India Order]

    On: 20 April 2011

    Access details: Access Details: [subscription number 934171966]

    Publisher Routledge

    Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: Mortimer House, 37-

    41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK

    Oxford Development StudiesPublication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information:http://www.informaworld.com/smpp/title~content=t713439972

    R&D and Technological Learning in Indian Industry: EconometricEstimation of the Research Production FunctionAmit S. Ray; Saradindu Bhaduri

    Online publication date: 19 August 2010

    To cite this Article Ray, Amit S. and Bhaduri, Saradindu(2001) 'R&D and Technological Learning in Indian Industry:Econometric Estimation of the Research Production Function', Oxford Development Studies, 29: 2, 155 171

    To link to this Article: DOI: 10.1080/13600810120059306URL: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/13600810120059306

    Full terms and conditions of use: http://www.informaworld.com/terms-and-conditions-of-access.pdf

    This article may be used for research, teaching and private study purposes. Any substantial orsystematic reproduction, re-distribution, re-selling, loan or sub-licensing, systematic supply ordistribution in any form to anyone is expressly forbidden.

    The publisher does not give any warranty express or implied or make any representation that the contentswill be complete or accurate or up to date. The accuracy of any instructions, formulae and drug dosesshould be independently verified with primary sources. The publisher shall not be liable for any loss,actions, claims, proceedings, demand or costs or damages whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directlyor indirectly in connection with or arising out of the use of this material.

    http://www.informaworld.com/smpp/title~content=t713439972http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/13600810120059306http://www.informaworld.com/terms-and-conditions-of-access.pdfhttp://www.informaworld.com/terms-and-conditions-of-access.pdfhttp://dx.doi.org/10.1080/13600810120059306http://www.informaworld.com/smpp/title~content=t713439972
  • 8/7/2019 DEV_2001

    2/18

    Oxford Development Studies, Vol. 29, No. 2, 2001

    R&D and Technological Learning in Indian Industry:

    Econometric Estimation of the Research Production

    Function

    AMIT S. RAY & SARADINDU BHADURI

    ABSTRACT Estimation of research production functions has produced rich and useful results

    for developed countries in the past. This paper makes a pioneering attempt to estimate the same

    in the context of a less-developed country (LDC) (India). The objective is to examine the

    process of technology generation and learning in Indian industry. The existing literature

    recognizes two principal characteristics of technological activities in LDCs. First, their R&D

    effort is geared towards minor as opposed to major innovations. Second, technological

    learning constitutes an integral part of their research thrust. This paper attempts to capture

    these characteristics in a rigorous econometric framework by estimating a comprehensive

    research production function incorporating the role of learning. We use Indian rm-level

    in-house R&D data for two sectors: pharmaceuticals and electronics. Our study not onlycaptures the role of learning in determining research effort and research output, but also

    re-examines some of the existing hypotheses relating to the effects of rm size, technology import

    and ownership. We nd that the two sectors display two distinct learning trajectories, but in

    both cases learning proves to be crucially important in technology generation.

    1. Introduction

    Much of the theoretical literature on technology and R&D evolved against the back-

    drop of capital-rich developed economies. In this literature less-developed countries(LDCs) are portrayed as mere recipients of old technologies from the industrialized

    countries in the mature phase of the product cycle. Challenging this paradigm, the

    importance of technological activities in LDCs started gaining ground in the 1960s and

    1970s, particularly after the emergence of Japan as a major technological power.

    Economists recognized that LDCs may carry out independent research activities,

    according to their economic environment and priorities. These ideas crystallized in the

    conceptual framework offered by development economists such as Nelson, Katz, Lall,

    Bell and others. All of them recognized two principal characteristics of technological

    activities in LDCs. First, their R&D effort is geared towards minor as opposed tomajor innovations. Second, technological learning, in some form or other, constitutes

    an integral part of their research thrust. Unfortunately, however, the existing empirical

    literature in this area has not captured these LDC characteristics in a rigorous

    Amit S. Ray and Saradindu Bhaduri, School of International St udies, Jawaharlal Nehru University, New Delhi

    110067, India.

    We are grateful to the Department of Science and Technology, Government of India, for a research grant.

    ISSN 1360-0818 print/ISSN 1469-9966 online/01/020155-17 2001 Internationa l Development Centre, OxfordDOI: 10.1080/13600810120059306

    DownloadedBy:[INFLIBNETIndia

    Order]At:10:0120April2011

  • 8/7/2019 DEV_2001

    3/18

    156 A. S. Ray & S. Bhaduri

    econometric framework. None of the studies, for instance, estimated a research pro-

    duction function for LDCs, let alone a comprehensive one incorporating the role of

    learning.1

    This paper attempts to ll this gap in the literature and focuses on in-house R&D

    of Indian enterprises in order to understand the process of technology generation and

    learning in Indian industry. Section 2 presents an analytical framework and arrives at

    a research production function incorporating the role of learning. Section 3 outlines the

    econometric model and Section 4 presents the results of the econometric estimation.

    Section 5 synthesizes and concludes.

    2. Analytical Framework

    Industrial R&D is often viewed as a production process where research inputs such as

    R&D spending (equipment, manpower, etc.) are transformed into research outputs

    such as invention, innovation and diffusion. The R&D production function, however,

    is not a simple mapping of research inputs into research outputs. Rather, it encom-passes a complex set of factors evolving from the large body of theoretical literature on

    technology. The Schumpeterian hypothesis as well as the later neo-classical models

    (Arrow, 1962a; DasguptaStiglitz, 1980, etc.) considered a wide array of theoretical

    determinants of the nature and direction of R&D activity, much of it revolving around

    market structure variables. In this theoretical tradition, however, technological progress

    is identied with major breakthroughs in science and technology resulting in a shift of

    the frontier.2 As a result, the important contribution to technical progress made in

    diffusion, adaptation and application of new technologies, which are particularly

    important in the context of LDCs, has remained under-emphasized. However, theevolutionary models of technological progress (Nelson & Winter, 1982; Mowery &

    Rosenberg, 1989) are perhaps the only theoretical constructs that consider minor, as

    opposed to major, innovations to be the more likely and more conventional research

    output of any R&D programme. These models have a broader perspective on technol-

    ogy dened as a set of linked capabilities based on different types of knowledge: formal

    and informal (i.e. tacit or experimental). Indeed, the evolutionary models characteriza-

    tion of technical change as a tacit, path-dependent and non-linear movement

    makes technological progress similar to the process of technological catch-up com-

    monly observed in many LDCs.

    Lall (1987) observed that considering technological progress only as a movement

    of the frontier is a highly simplied neo-classical view because major technological

    innovations are not the only, perhaps not even the main, source of productivity

    improvement in the history of industrial development and minor changes to given

    technologiesto equipment, materials, processes and designsare vital and continu-

    ous source of productivity gain in practically every industry. Therefore, one can argue

    in line with Bell (1984) that technological effort should ideally be viewed as conscious

    use of technological information and the accumulation of technological knowledge,

    together with other resources, to choose, assimilate and adapt existing technology

    and/or to create new technology. This is what reects technological capability of anLDC, dened as the capacity to select, absorb, assimilate, adapt, imitate and perhaps

    improve given (imported) technologies.3 Several case studies (country level, industry

    level and rm level) conrm that the creation of such indigenous technological

    capabilities requires conscious technological effort and risky investments in R&D.4

    Accordingly, one must broaden the denition of technological output in the context

    of a research production function of an LDC. R&D units in LDCs need not come up

    DownloadedBy:[INFLIBNETIndia

    Order]At:10:0120April2011

  • 8/7/2019 DEV_2001

    4/18

    R&D and Technological Learning 157

    Figure 1. The R&D production function: a schematic framework.

    with very different products or processes but may still be acknowledged as an innovator,

    albeit of minor rather than major innovations. Katz (1984) further extended the

    coverage of technological output by including not only adaptation and assimilation to

    be a part of innovative process but also changes in market structure and organizational

    planning as an outcome of their technological effort.

    Another departure point for LDCs with respect to their technological activities is,

    perhaps, the absence of the so-called technology shelf5 which generally implies higher

    search cost for LDC entrepreneurs. They are engaged in two kinds of researchactivities: to nd the best (most suitable) technology among an existing set and to

    achieve new technologies. Learning, thus, becomes a most essential component of

    technological activities in developing countries. As Nelson (1987) puts it: To the

    extent that technology is not well understood, sharply dened invention possibility sets

    are misleading concepts and interaction between learning through R&D and learning

    through experience is an essential part of the invention process.

    2.1 The Research Production Function

    Given the idiosyncrasies of technological activities of developing countries, we posit a

    research production function for our analysis in the form of a schematic framework

    (Figure 1). R&D inputs and outputs are both endogenously determined in this

    framework in a recursive structure. Apart from the conventional rm-size effects of

    R&D, which has been extensively researched in the context of developed as well as

    developing countries, our framework considers further determinants like technology

    imports, ownership and, above all, learning of different kinds.

    2.2 Firm sizeIn order to test the Schumpeterian hypothesis, most of the studies have focused on

    the likely impact of the size of a rm on its research effort, assuming market structure

    to be exogenous and independent of a rms R&D decision. It is argued that large rms

    are better qualied or perhaps more eager to undertake R&D than smaller rms for the

    following reasons. First, R&D is characterized by increasing returns to scale which a

    large rm can exploit better. Second, since R&D activity involves a high level of risk

    DownloadedBy:[INFLIBNETIndia

    Order]At:10:0120April2011

  • 8/7/2019 DEV_2001

    5/18

    158 A. S. Ray & S. Bhaduri

    that is difcult to eliminate with insurance (for reasons of moral hazard), large rms

    may be more willing to take these risks as they can be diversied over a wider range of

    product lines. Third, the production pattern in a large rm is more systematic and

    routinized, which makes it easier for them to implement a new innovation.

    The results obtained are diverse and the sizeR&D relationship remains inconclus-

    ive. Among the Indian studies, while Goldar & Ranganathan (1997) obtained a linearly

    positive effect of rm size on research effort of a rm, Katrak (1985, 1990) concluded

    that R&D effort increases with rm size, but less than proportionately. We will examine

    this relationship (linear or non-linear) and explore the existence of an optimum rm

    size, if any, with respect to research effort.6

    2.3 Imported Technology and R&D Effort: Complement or Substitute?

    This is an issue specic to a typical LDC rm. Import of technology is likely to enhance

    in-house R&D if it is adaptive and absorptive in nature.7 Along this line, Kumar (1987)

    argues that technology import through FDI may be followed by less in-house R&Dcompared with technology import through licensing by non-afliate rms, as the latter

    may be more willing to absorb, assimilate and adapt the imported technology.

    On the other hand, if the rms R&D activity is geared towards import substitution

    (essentially substituting for the imported technical know-how as well as intermediate

    inputs as argued by Dore (1984), Lall (1984, 1987) and Desai (1984) for Indian rms),

    we may expect a negative relationship between technology import and R&D.

    In fact the latter argument will hold particularly for disembodied technology

    imports, while the former may be relevant for import of embodied technology. Accord-

    ingly, we examine the effect of both imported capital goods (embodied technology) andimported disembodied technology on research effort. The latter represents the direct

    import of technical know-how, which reduces the necessity of rms research activity.

    Import of capital goods, on the other hand, promotes R&D as purchased machines are

    to be adapted in domestic environment for protable functioning. We thus hypothesize

    a negative relationship of R&D with import of disembodied technology but a positive

    one with imported capital goods.

    Implicit in the hypothesis posited above is the presumption that technology import

    decisions are exogenous to R&D decisions of rms. This could appear to be suspect.8

    We justify this presumption on the grounds that ours is a cross-sectional study for a

    given point in time. Any technology import/collaboration agreement is made for a

    period of at least 34 years (if not longer), while the bulk of R&D projects are of much

    shorter duration in India. Therefore, we can reasonably argue that while deciding about

    R&D at a given point in time, the rm considers its technology imports as fait accompli.

    2.4 Ownership

    In the standard neo-classical production theory, ownership per se is not expected to play

    any role in the day-to-day operation of a rm, because every rm is hypothesized to be

    a prot maximizer. But unlike developed economies, LDCs are characterized by thepresence of rms with different ownership categories, with diverse levels of technologi-

    cal as well as nancial capabilities. Accordingly, we hypothesize that research thrust

    would also vary among rms belonging to different ownership groups and the differen-

    tial effects of ownership are expected to play an important role in the process of

    technology generation in LDCs.

    In our study, we have distinguished between three types of ownership structures:

    DownloadedBy:[INFLIBNETIndia

    Order]At:10:0120April2011

  • 8/7/2019 DEV_2001

    6/18

    R&D and Technological Learning 159

    public enterprises, private Indian enterprises and foreign multinationals. It has been

    suggested that since technology is readily available to a multi-national corporation

    (MNC) (from their parent bodies), their research thrust would be simpler and less than

    that of a domestic private enterprise. In the Indian context, Goldar & Ranganathan

    (1997) found a signicant positive impact of foreign ownership on R&D intensity.

    Rays (1998) results show that though MNCs employ fewer research personnel, they

    are more productive in converting the inputs into R&D outputs.

    The theoretical literature is less precise about the effect of government ownership on

    R&D activity. It is difcult to address this issue because the prot maximization

    principle may not play a decisive role in determining R&D behaviour of public sector

    rms. Indeed, public sector rms can afford to stay out of equilibrium longer compared

    with a private rm and therefore can undertake activities that are erratic (non prot

    maximizing).9 Goldar & Ranganathan (1997) found a positive impact of a public sector

    dummy on R&D intensity of Indian rms. Our study covers the pharmaceutical and

    electronics sectors. Both are among the more R&D-aggressive industries receiving

    special attention from the government from time to time for the development of thesesectors. It is, therefore, difcult to predict an exact a priori impact of ownership on

    R&D.

    2.5 Learning

    There has been little explicit theorization of the role of learning in the research

    production process. Arrow (1962b) is perhaps the only theoretical construct introduc-

    ing the concept of learning by doing in the neo-classical theoretical literature, butthere is little discussion even in that article regarding the nature of the process

    involved.10 In the context of developing countries, Bell (1984) distinguished between

    two dimensions of the learning process: (1) doing based learning; and (2) learning

    by training or learning by hiring or learning by searching or spillover.

    Both types of learning are equally important in the research production process in

    an LDC. Learning by doing, for instance, may not result in a research outcome which

    is altogether new (major innovation), but it certainly contributes to acquisition of

    technological capability (absorptive, adaptive) and the consequent minor changes or

    inventing around, which is crucially important in LDCs. We also expect that rms

    with longer experience will spend more on R&D. The justication comes from an

    evolutionary framework, where rms that are successful in research continue with

    their research activity and enlarge their R&D outt. Learning through experience also

    raises the efciency with which R&D inputs are converted into outputs. It thus

    has a positive impact on the amount of technological output by raising the marginal

    productivity of R&D inputs.11 We therefore expect that ceteris paribus rms with longer

    history of learning (or with more experience) would produce more research output.

    With regard to the role of learning through spillover, the neo-classical literature is

    less precise as it assumes instantaneous diffusion.12 However, later developments

    recognized diffusion as a complex process requiring explicit effort and investment.13

    This is true even for acquiring knowledge freely available in the public domain.

    Spillovers would then enter the research production process in a signicant way. It

    would augment technological output in the same manner as learning by doing, but its

    impact on research effort is less obvious. We dene two distinct sources of spillover:

    national and international, both of which could act as important inputs into the

    research production function.14

    DownloadedBy:[INFLIBNETIndia

    Order]At:10:0120April2011

  • 8/7/2019 DEV_2001

    7/18

    160 A. S. Ray & S. Bhaduri

    3. Econometric Specication

    We specify the following econometric models for estimation.

    RS5Xb1 u, (1)

    where RS is an n3 1 vector denoting R&D effort for n number of rms, X is an n3 k

    matrix consisting of k explanatory variables, b is the coefcient matrix of order k3 1and u is the matrix of error terms of the order n3 1.

    TQ5Zg1 v, (2)

    where TQ is the n3 1 vector denoting R&D output for n number of rms, Z is an n3 k

    matrix consisting of k explanatory variables, g is the coefcient matrix of order k3 1

    and v is the matrix of error terms of the order n3 1.The variables RS, X, TQ and Z are

    described below.

    3.1 The Data and Variables

    For this cross-sectional econometric analysis, we select two industry categories: phar-

    maceutical and electronics rms with 71 and 52 observations, respectively. The sample

    is constructed by merging a corporate database (PROWESS) supplied by the Centre for

    the Monitoring of the Indian Economy (CMIE) with the rm-level R&D data from

    NSTMIS division of the Department of Science & Technology (DST), Government of

    India. Although DST maintains a time series, we could obtain the data only for

    199495, which included information on R&D expenditure for the latest 3 years. In the

    pharmaceutical sample we have 13 foreign rms and the others are domestic rms. In

    the electronics and electrical sample, there are eight foreign rms, nine public sector

    rms and 35 private (Indian) rms.

    R&D input (RS). We have used R&D stock as the measure of research input.15 Stock

    is constructed assuming a 15% depreciation rate for both industries.16 We had the

    gures for R&D expenditure only for a period of 3 years. Our R&D stock measure thus

    covers the period 1992/93 to 1994/95.

    R&D output (TQ). TQ is a summation of various technological outputs produced andreported by Indian enterprises. The variable includes the number of product, process,

    import substitutes and design prototypes developed by a rm. It also includes the

    number of publications of papers, books and technical reports and consultancy services

    provided by the enterprise. Data for two consecutive years 1993/94 and 1994/95 have

    been aggregated to rule out the possibility of systematic errors or year-to-year

    uctuations.

    Learning. Learning is believed to operate in two ways: (a) learning through experience;

    and (b) learning through interaction (spillover). Learning through experience (LE) hasbeen measured by the age of the R&D unit of a rm.17 To measure the effect of learning

    on the efciency of the research production process, one can look at the interaction

    effect of R&D stock and experience (age of R&D unit) by constructing a variable

    (RSAGE).

    Spillover has been identied in the empirical literature as the stock of knowledge

    transmitted to a rm from sources extraneous to its R&D outt. Accordingly measures

    DownloadedBy:[INFLIBNETIndia

    Order]At:10:0120April2011

  • 8/7/2019 DEV_2001

    8/18

    R&D and Technological Learning 161

    of spillover pool have been incorporated as input into a rms research production

    function.18 Such measures have been conceptualized either on the basis of the total

    stock of knowledge pool (created by R&D of all other rms) or on the basis of

    specic sources of spillovers like patent applications. These measures also implicitly

    assume that spillover is available to a rm automatically.

    Our measure of learning through interaction captures spillover in a more general

    sense. We look at the participation (attendance) of rms in R&D-related national and

    international seminars and training programmes to capture the extent of benets

    received by a rm from the common stock of knowledge pool. This knowledge pool

    contains broad and overall developments in the relevant elds of research rather than

    specic information about particular innovations and patents. Patent data exclude all

    research that is either unsuccessful or not patented, but may generate considerable

    knowledge base. It is in this sense that we call our measure a more general index of

    spillover. Access to this generalized spillover pool will vary from rm to rm depending

    on their attendance. Our measure, therefore, captures this inter-rm variation better

    and more directly than commonly used measures (e.g. Basant & Fikkert, 1993) ofspillover pools, which capture industry-level variations better than rm-level variations.

    We have two different indices of spillover: national or domestic spillover (NSP) and

    international spillover (ISP). The former contains the number of various national-level

    training programmes and seminars attended by a rm. The latter counts the number of

    international training programmes and seminars that a rm has attended during the

    years 1993/94 and 1994/95. The square of these two variables (NSP2 and ISP2) would

    take care of possible non-linear effects and would enable us to determine an optimum

    spillover level, if it exists.19

    Ownership. The effect of ownership has been captured through two dummy variables.

    The dummy showing the effect of foreign ownership (FD) takes the value one for

    multinational rms and zero for Indian (both public and private) rms. Likewise, the

    dummy capturing the impact of private versus public ownership (PD) takes the value

    one for private rms (both domestic and MNCs) and zero for Indian public sector

    enterprises.

    Size. The effect of size is measured by the annual sales turnover of rms (S) for the year1994/95. The square of the sales gures (S2) will be used to represent the non-linear

    effect of size on R&D effort.

    Technology import. The import of embodied technology is captured by the value of

    imported capital goods (ME). Disembodied technology import is measured by royalty

    payments (MD).

    3.2 The Models

    From the foregoing discussion we now list the models which we attempt to estimate

    using tools of applied econometrics:

    (1) RSi5 a01 a1 Si1 a2S2i1 a3LEi1 a4MEi1 a5MDi1 a6FDi1 a7PDi1 u1i.

    (2) TQi5b01 b1RSi1 b2LEi1 b3NSPi1 b4NSP2i1 b5ISPi1 b6ISP

    2i1 b7FDi1 b8PDi

    1 u2i.

    DownloadedBy:[INFLIBNETIndia

    Order]At:10:0120April2011

  • 8/7/2019 DEV_2001

    9/18

    162 A. S. Ray & S. Bhaduri

    Table 1. Pharmaceutical: correlation matrix of

    the independent variables of model 1

    Variables S FD ME MD

    S 1

    FD 0.25 1ME 0.52 20.1 1

    MD 0.47 0.03 0.28 1

    3.3 Estimation Method

    The above models represent a set of recursive simultaneous equations, and therefore

    can be estimated individually, using classical least squares.20 Model 1 is estimated by

    ordinary least squares. To test for the presence of heteroscedasticity we use the

    CookWeisberg (1983) test.

    21

    In case of heteroscedastic error structure we use robustestimation correcting for the standard errors and signicance levels of the coefcients.

    We also check for the presence of multicollinearity by looking at the pairwise corre-

    lation coefcient matrix of the independent variables.

    In our attempt to estimate the research production function (model 2) we notice

    that the research output TQ can only take non-negative values with a signicant

    proportion of zeros. The dependent variable in this model is therefore (left)- censoredat

    zero. We therefore use the Tobit estimation procedure to estimate the model.

    4. Results and Analysis

    4.1 The Pharmaceutical Industry

    Model 1 (Tables 1 and 2). There is clear evidence that initially R&D effort increases with

    rm size but at a decreasing rate and then falls after attaining an optimum rm size

    (calculated to be sales level of rupees 550.55 crores (crore5 ten millions)).22 Foreign

    rms R&D effort appears to be signicantly less than that of Indian rms. It is further

    observed that import of embodied technology promotes R&D while import of disem-

    bodied technology reduces R&D effort.

    Model 2 (Tables 3 and 4). We included the national and international spillover variables

    separately to avoid possible multicollinearity problems. The principal factors that

    appear as statistically signicant determinants of research output are the learning

    variables.

    Learning through experience does not appear to have any signicant impact on the

    research production function (RPF) on its own. For that matter, we nd that even the

    key input of R&D effort (RS) does not always explain variations in research output. But

    interestingly, the interaction term (RSAGE) appears positive and signicant. An older

    rm uses one unit of R&D input much more efciently than a newer rm, which is lessexperienced in R&D.

    There is clear evidence of an inverse U-shaped impact of spillover on total output,

    although the quadratic effect of national spillover is weak. The optimum (satiation)

    point is reached earlier for ISP compared with NSP. This may be explained as follows.

    International spillover exposes a rm to the state of the art on the global frontier. This

    is important for LDC manufacturers but in a limited manner as they are not engaged

    DownloadedBy:[INFLIBNETIndia

    Order]At:10:0120April2011

  • 8/7/2019 DEV_2001

    10/18

    R&D and Technological Learning 163

    Table 2. Pharmaceutical: estimation of model 1 (dependent

    variable is RS

    Independent

    variables Equation (1)a Equation 1(a)(robust)

    Constant2

    21434.65**2

    21434.65**(2 2.357) (2 2.43)

    S 722.03*** 722.0281***

    (7.598) (5.118)

    S2 2 0.656*** 2 0.656***

    (2 5.117) (2 3.948)

    LE 175.614 175.6135

    (0.483) (0.469)

    FD 2 32213.2** 2 32213.2**

    (2 2.494) (2 2.145)

    ME 13686.11*** 13686.11***

    (3.489) (2.889)

    MD 2 22568.85*** 2 22568.85***

    (2 3.577) (2 3.115)

    Adj R2 0.68 0.7

    F-statistic 25.77*** 10.31***

    No. of 71 71

    observations

    aCookWeisberg test for homoscedasticity was rejected at the 1% level of

    signicance.

    *Signicant at the 10% level, **5% level and ***1% level.

    in R&D to push the frontiers of global technology. Rather, most of their R&D activities

    are adaptive in nature and outputs are often in the form of minor changes. Therefore,

    their exposure to international spillover will have a steeper slope, but reach an optimum

    early. National spillover, on the other hand, exposes them to research of similar

    adaptive nature. Therefore, although the marginal gains from NSP may be lower than

    ISP initially, it continues to remain positive for a larger amount of spillover compared

    with ISP.

    4.2 The Electronics Industry

    Model 1 (Tables 5 and 6). When we estimated the model with the complete sample, the

    coefcient for the private ownership dummy (PD) appeared signicantly negative,

    indicating that private sector rms spend less than the public sector rms on R&D.

    Does this mean that public sector rms are more research-oriented than private rms?

    Table 3. Pharmaceutical: correlation matrix of the inde-

    pendent variables of model 2

    RDS FD LE NSP ISP

    RS 1

    FD 0.019 1

    LE 0.17 0.193 1

    NSP 0.293 0.049 20.043 1

    ISP 0.257 0.093 0.178 0.431 1

    DownloadedBy:[INFLIBNETIndia

    Order]At:10:0120April2011

  • 8/7/2019 DEV_2001

    11/18

    164 A. S. Ray & S. Bhaduri

    Table 4. Pharmaceutical: Tobit estimation of model 2 (dependent variable is TQ)

    Independent

    variables Equation (2) Equation (3) Equation (4) Equation (5)

    Constant 2 4.618 2 2.774 2.307 2.12

    (2 0.996) (2 0.871) (0.544) (0.686)

    RS 4.23 102 5 6.753 102 5*

    (1.193) (1.943)

    LE 0.148 20.547

    (0.822) (20.309)

    RSAGE 3.033 102 6*** 2.173 102 6*

    (3.099) (1.713)

    FD 2 5.302 2 3.814 25.563 25.76

    (2 0.827) (2 0.678) (20.914) (20.951)

    NSP 1.903*** 1.952***

    (3.2) (3.579)

    NSP2 2 0.193 2 0.021*

    (2 1.422) (2 1.667)

    ISP 6.515*** 7.148***

    (3.202) (3.527)

    ISP2 20.293* 20.366**

    (21.867) (2.291)

    c2 statistic 27.12*** 32.99*** 27.53*** 26.78***

    No. of observations 57 57 71 71

    *Signicant at the 10% level, **5% level and ***1% level.

    This sounds unrealistic, especially in the face of the alleged inefciencies of the public

    sector rms. Of course, this could be due to the fact that their decision-making process

    is often guided by considerations other than prot maximization. Overall policy thrust

    can prompt them to spend more on R&D, although this is not a viable and sustainable

    proposition in the long run. We therefore repeated the same regression taking private

    rms only as reported in Table 6. The pair-wise correlation matrix reported in Table

    51 displays signicant mutual correlation among S, FD, ME and MD.23

    We correct for this multicollinearity by constructing a principal component for the

    four variables, S, FD, ME and MD (PCP). Our principal component is the weighted

    average of all (four) individual components with weights equal to the percentage ofvariations explained by them.

    PCP and LE appear with signicant coefcients. The positive coefcient of PCP

    implies that the combined effect of large size, foreign ownership and higher imported

    technology (embodied and disembodied) raises R&D effort. LE displays signicantly

    Table 5. Electronics: correlation matrix of the independent

    variables of model 1 (private rms)

    S LE FD ID ME MD

    S 1

    LE 0.45 1

    FD 0.43 0.074 1

    ID 0.035 2 0.303 0.192 1

    ME 0.66 0.158 0.507 0.148 1

    MD 0.35 0.083 0.228 0.23 0.273 1

    DownloadedBy:[INFLIBNETIndia

    Order]At:10:0120April2011

  • 8/7/2019 DEV_2001

    12/18

    R&D and Technological Learning 165

    Table 6. Electronics: estimation of model 1 with principal

    components (private rms only)

    Equation (1a)

    Independent (robust

    variable Equation(1)a estimation)

    Constant 6058.75 6058.75

    (0.409) (0.588)

    LE 1173.459* 1173.459***

    (1.882) (3.588)

    PD

    ID 2318 2 318

    (2 0.028) (0.976)

    PCP 25480.93*** 25480.93***

    (3.986) (3.669)

    Adjusted R2 0.37 0.42

    F-statistic 9.00*** 14.95***

    No. of

    observations 42 42

    aCookWeisberg test for h omoscedasticity was rejected at the 1% level of

    signicance.

    *signicant at the 10% level, **5% level and ***1% level.

    positive impact on the RS, signifying that rms with more experience of research spend

    more on R&D.

    Model 2 (Tables 79). The primary input to R&D production function, research effort

    (RS) has a negative and signicant impact on the research output. PD is shown to have

    a positive impact on the amount of research output produced, suggesting that private

    rms produce more output relative to public sector rms. These two results demand

    further explanation.

    Positive PD in this model together with the negative sign of PD in the earlier model

    should imply that private sector rms spend less on R&D but spend it more efciently

    than public sector rms. Therefore, one may reasonably suggest that the negative effect

    of RSon TQ is due to the large and unproductive R&D expenditure of the public sector

    rms. In fact, when we carry out a separate regression taking only private rms, RS

    becomes insignicant (equation (3) in Table 9).24

    LE is positive and signicant in both the samples. With regard to spillover, both

    NSP and ISP and their square terms appear statistically signicant with the expected

    Table 7. Electronics: correlation matrix (all rms) of the independent variables of

    model 2

    RS LE FD PD ID NSP ISP

    RS 1

    LE 0.352 1

    FD 0.181 0.081 1

    PD 2 0.289 0.07 0.195 1

    ID 0.179 20.268 0.133 2 0.213 1

    NSP 0.258 20.043 0.016 2 0.474 20.085 1

    ISP 0.123 0.131 2 0.107 2 0.13 20.263 0.092 1

    DownloadedBy:[INFLIBNETIndia

    Order]At:10:0120April2011

  • 8/7/2019 DEV_2001

    13/18

    166 A. S. Ray & S. Bhaduri

    Table 8. Electronics: correlation matrix of the indepen-

    dent variables of model 2 (for private rms)

    RS LE FD NSP ISP

    RS 1

    LE 0.372 1FD 0.39 0.074 1

    NSP 0.555 0.305 0.394 1

    ISP 0.021 0.11 2 0.085 0.045 1

    signs. When we carry out the same regression with only private rms, the results are

    slightly different (see equation (3) in Table 9). NSP variables become insignicant. The

    coefcient of FD is seen to display a statistically signicant negative impact on amount

    of output. However, there is a possible multicollinearity problem in our estimation of

    model 2 for private rms. The relevant correlation matrix (see Table 8) of the

    explanatory variables this time shows strong positive correlation between RS and NSP.

    We therefore construct a principal component for these two variables ( PCSP).25

    Revised estimates of equation (3a) show that the coefcient of PCSP is positive and

    signicant. FD remains negative and signicant showing that foreign MNCs produce

    less research output than the private Indian rms. ISP and ISP2 are signicant with

    positive and negative signs respectively, conrming the existence of an optimum level

    of international spillover.

    Table 9. Electronics: Tobit estimation of model 2 (dependent variable is TQ)

    Independen t vari ables Eq uation (2 for Eq uat ion (3) (for Equati on (3a)(for

    all rms) private rms) private rms)

    Constant 2 78.795** 2 18.544 0.731**

    (2 2.666) (2 1.314) (0.048)

    PCSP 29.23***

    (4.714)

    RS 2 0.00049*** 2 1.413 1025

    (2 3.175) (2 0.067)

    LE 2.022*** 1.18* 1.062 (1.393)

    (3.094) (1.66)

    FD 2 10.144 2 32.402* 2 46.08**

    (2 0.64) (2 1.739) (22.245)

    PD 48.764*

    (1.818)

    NSP 1.312*** 0.797

    (4.269) (1.202)

    NSP2 2 0.002*** 0.002

    (2 4.065) (0.387)

    ISP 8.435** 8.341** 7.834*

    (2.524) (2.15) (1.978)

    ISP2 2 0.164** 2 0.166* 20.156*

    (2 2.234) (2 1.95) (21.798)

    c2 statistic 34.98*** 28.09*** 21.19***

    No. of observation 51 42 33

    *Signicant at the 10% level, **5% level and ***1% level.

    DownloadedBy:[INFLIBNETIndia

    Order]At:10:0120April2011

  • 8/7/2019 DEV_2001

    14/18

    R&D and Technological Learning 167

    5. Synthesis and Conclusion

    Our econometric analysis presents new and interesting insights into the process of

    technology generation in Indian industry by estimating a comprehensive research

    production function for two industries: pharmaceuticals and electronics. We have

    analysed four specic determinants of technology generation, namely, rm size, tech-

    nology import, ownership and learning.With regard to rm size, we nd that for both sectors larger rms, in general, spend

    more on R&D, perhaps due to their liquidity and scale economy advantages.26 In the

    pharmaceutical sector, however, R&D effort increases less than proportionately with

    rm size, and tapers off beyond an optimum level. If R&D in this sector is primarily

    business-driven reverse engineering to come up with non-infringing processes to cap-

    ture newer markets, then very large rms already enjoying large market share and

    diversied product portfolios may have less incentive to spend on R&D.

    In the pharmaceutical industry, import of embodied technology promotes domestic

    R&D effort. In this sector import of capital equipment for production often demandsgreater adaptive R&D to meet the requirements of changing process parameters.

    Import of quality control equipment could also promote greater R&D in order to

    conform to better quality precision. However, the import of disembodied technology

    (licensing) substitutes for in-house R&D as it reduces the need for reverse engineering.

    On the issue of ownership effect on R&D, we nd inter-industry differences. In the

    pharmaceutical industry MNCs are found to spend less on R&D than Indian rms.

    However, no signicant difference exists in terms of the R&D output they produce.

    This in a sense may imply that pharmaceutical MNCs are more efcient than the

    domestic rms in R&D activities.

    For the electronics industry, domestic private rms are seen to spend less on R&D

    but produce more research output than public sector rms. The impact of foreign

    ownership per se on R&D effort could not be detected due to problems of multi-

    collinearity, but MNCs appear to produce less research output than Indian rms. It is

    thus evident that the Indian private rms are more active and productive in R&D in the

    electronics sector.

    Perhaps the most important nding of our study relates to the role of learning,

    which has been conceptualized in the literature as a key driving force behind technology

    generation in LDCs. Our results reveal learning to be the most important determinant

    of research production process. In fact, for both industries, research effort on its ownfails to explain variations in research output. Only the learning variables come up as

    signicant determinants of the research production function.

    Learning through experience enters the research production function for both

    sectors, although the way in which it augments research output differs across the two

    industries. In the pharmaceutical sector, it enters interactively with research effort,

    implying that rms with older R&D outts spend on R&D more efciently. In other

    words, experience-based learning augments the efciency of R&D effort in the pharma-

    ceutical sector, which is mainly reverse engineering (through trial and error). Research

    experience helps the rm to decode the technology faster, reducing its cost of trial anderror and thereby making its R&D effort more efcient.

    In the electronics sector, on the other hand, learning through experience enters the

    production function as an independent input. Given that the electronics industry in

    India is driven by the so-called screw-driver technology, simple experience-based

    knowledge (of assembling) proves to be important in the R&D process.

    Equally important in the research production process is the learning through

    DownloadedBy:[INFLIBNETIndia

    Order]At:10:0120April2011

  • 8/7/2019 DEV_2001

    15/18

    168 A. S. Ray & S. Bhaduri

    interaction or spillover. The effect of spillover on research output appears to be

    non-linear. In both industries there is evidence of an optimum level of spillover

    (national as well as international).

    To summarize, in this paper we have made a clear distinction between R&D inputs

    and R&D outputs in a research production function framework to understand the

    process of technology generation in Indian industry. We nd that the conventional

    determinants of R&D, like rm size, technology import or ownership, appear signicant

    only in explaining R&D effort in line with existing empirical studies. However, when we

    seek to explain the variations in research output, none of these factors, not even

    research effort on its own, appear to be statistically signicant. Here, in fact, learning,

    both experience based as well as interaction (or spillover) based, proves to be the only

    important determinant of the research production process. In some cases, learning also

    augments the efciency of research effort in producing research output. We therefore

    conclude that technological learning proves to be the most important determinant of

    technology generation in Indian industry.

    Notes

    1. Such exercises have produced rich and useful results for developed industrialized nations.

    See Kamien & Schwartz (1975) and Cohen & Levin (1989) for comprehensive surveys of

    this empirical literature.

    2. See, for instance Schumpeter (1934, 1939). Note that Rosenberg (1976) has strongly

    criticized the Schumpeterian usage of the term innovation on four grounds: (1) We

    conne our thinking about innovations to characteristics which are likely to be true only of

    major innovations, (2) we focus disproportionately upon discontinuities and neglect continu-

    ities in the innovative process, (3) we attach excessive importance to the role of scienticknowledge and insufcient importance to engineering and other lower forms of knowledge,

    and (4) we attach excessive signicance to early stages in the process of invention and neglect

    the crucial later stages.

    3. According to Enos (1991) there are three fundamental components of technological capa-

    bility: individuals with inclination and skills, institutions (rms) assembling these skills and

    know-how and a common purpose/objective driving the rst two.

    4. See Lall (1984) for India, Westphal et al. (1984) for Korea, Dahlman (1984) for Brazil, for

    instance.

    5. See Ranis (1990) and Nelson (1987).

    6. Although there are empirical studies relating rm size with R&D output, we hypothesize that

    the size effect is limited to research effort only since it is not theoretically well established whyresearch output should vary with rm size, ceteris paribus.

    7. This is shown by Odagiri (1983) for non-innovating Japanese rms and Braga & Wilmore

    (1991) for Brazilian rms.

    8. Indeed, Basant (1993, 1998) considered technology purchase and i ndigenous R&D as two

    simultaneously determined decisions to examine the mutual relationship between the two

    decisions but fails to nd any complementarity.

    9. See Katz (1987).

    10. Nelson (1987, p. 81).

    11. This is in line with the timecost trade-off analysis by Scherer (1967) showing that

    curtailment of learning period makes the research production process less efcient by

    reducing the scope of trial and error.

    12. If at all, spillover was believed to have an adverse effect on the incentive to innovate. See

    Spence (1984).

    13. See, for instance, Cohen & Levinthal (1989).

    14. The theoretical literature is less precise about the pattern of learning of both types (through

    experience or through spillovers). It is evident from several empirical studies (Katz (1987) for

    Latin American rms, Lall (1984) for Indian rms, Jomo et al. (1999) for Malaysian rms)

    that the learning pattern as well as its importance varies from industry to industry and

    according to ownership structure.

    DownloadedBy:[INFLIBNETIndia

    Order]At:10:0120April2011

  • 8/7/2019 DEV_2001

    16/18

    R&D and Technological Learning 169

    15. The use of current R&D spending has been criticized on the grounds that it shows capital

    expensed, not the capital capitalized in current accounting rule.

    16. Griliches (1979) and Basant (1993) also assumed the same rate of depreciation.

    17. Lall (1983) and Goldar & Ranganathan (1997) used age of rm for supposedly a similar

    purpose.

    18. See, for instance, Griliches (1979) and Jaffe (1986). It may be noted that the Indian studies

    on spillover do not look at this aspect. Their focus has been on the relationship (or trade-off)

    between spillover and own R&D.19. One can argue that seminars and training programmes attended by a rm may not be

    exogenous as it might depend on the kind of research a rm wants to carry out and the extent

    of R&D expenditure it intends to incur. But after all the seminars and training programmes

    are organized by others, not by the rms themselves. Moreover, due to problems of

    asymmetric information and associated moral hazard, organizers are unlikely to provide full

    information regarding the scope and benets of the programmes. It is therefore unrealistic to

    assume that rms will be able to exercise an effective choice regarding their participation in

    a particular seminar or training programme. Therefore, it may be reasonably assumed to be

    exogenously determined depending on availability.

    20. If R&D teams which are more successful in terms of their research outputs are allowed larger

    R&D budgets, we may have a causality problem of TQ determining RS, resulting in acollapse of the recursive structure of our model. But in reality, TQ may determine RS at best

    with a lag, i.e. RSt,5f (TQt2 1). Therefore, in a cross-sectional model, RSt, becomes

    exogenously determined, given the realized value of TQt21.

    21. The test statistic is dened as Var(u)5 s2 * eXt , c2, where C is the set of explanatory

    variables. It tests the null hypothesis H0: t50 against the alternative hypotheses H1: t10. If

    H0 (homoscedasticity) is rejected for the given sample and at the appropriate level of

    signicance.

    22. A look at the data set reveals that 95% of the rms lie to the left of the above-mentioned

    optimum level. Therefore, most of the rms have not yet attained the optimum size.

    23. We also notice that LE is correlated with S, but not with any of the other variables, and

    therefore not included in the principal component.24. The negative impact (though sometime insignicant) of the key input RS in the production

    process may evoke many questions, as economic theory does not permit negative marginal

    impact of inputs in any production process. But since this is a research production function,

    where output may be realized with a lag (if it is of a complex nature), it may be possible that

    our cross-section study does not capture the complete research process. Moreover, one may

    also note that public sector rms are not always guided by the prot maximization principle

    and therefore some erratic behaviour may be sustained for a longer period. Bureaucratic

    control over the public sector rms often leads to delays in the decision-making process.

    Often a necessary decision to purchase a technology is taken only when a substantial amount

    is already spent on developing the product indigenously. All these may lead to over-spending

    with no commensurate output. These are mere conjectures, which can be conrmed onlythrough extensive case studies of public sector rms.

    25. This limits the scope of our study as the marginal impact of a prime input RS cannot be

    detected.

    26. In the electronics sector, since size correlates with foreign ownership and technology imports,

    we have a combined effect of all these on R&D effort through a principal component.

    References

    Arrow K.J. (1962a) Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for innovation, in: R.

    Nelson (Ed.) The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity (Princeton, NJ, Princeton University

    Press) pp. 609626.

    Arrow, K.J. (1962b) The economic implications of learning by doing, Review of Economic Studies,

    29, pp. 155173.

    Basant, R. (1993) R&D, foreign technology purchase and technology spillovers in Indian

    industrial productivity: some explorations, Working Paper No. 8, United Nations University,

    Institute of New Technologies, Maastricht.

    Basant, R. (1998) R&D, foreign technology purchase and technology Spillovers in Indian

    DownloadedBy:[INFLIBNETIndia

    Order]At:10:0120April2011

  • 8/7/2019 DEV_2001

    17/18

    170 A. S. Ray & S. Bhaduri

    industry: some explorations, paper presented at the NIPFP-Ford Foundation PostDoctoral

    Research Fellows Seminar, New Delhi, 67 November.

    Basant, R. & Fikkert, B. (1993) The impact of R&D, technology purchase, and technology

    spillovers on Indian industrial productivity: some tentative estimates, Working Paper No. 12,

    United Nations University, Institute of New Technologies, Maastricht.

    Bell, M. (1984) Learning and the accumulation of industrial technological capacity in developing

    countries, in: M. Fransman & K. King (Eds) Technological Capability in the Third World

    London, Macmillan, pp. 187209.

    Braga, H. & Wilmore, L. (1991) Technological imports and technological effort: an analysis of

    their determinants in Brazilian rms, Journal of Industrial Economics, 39, pp. 421432.

    Cohen, W.M. & Levin, R.C. (1989) Empirical studies of innovation and market structure, in:

    R.C. Schmalensee & R. Willig (Eds) Handbook of Industrial Organization Vol. II. (Amsterdam,

    Elsevier Science).

    Cohen, W.M. & Levinthal, D.A. (1989) Innovation and learning: The two faces of R&D,

    Economic Journal, 99, pp. 569596.

    Cook, R.D. & Weisberg, S. (1983) Diagnostics for heteroscedasticity in regression, Biometrica, 70,

    pp. 183184.

    Dahlman, C. (1984) Foreign technology and indigenous technological capability in Brazil, in: M.

    Fransman & K. King (Eds) Technological Capability in the Third World (London, Macmillan).

    Dasgupta, P. & Stiglitz, J.E. (1980) Industrial structure and the nature of innovative activity,

    Economic Journal, 90, pp. 266293.

    Desai, A.V. (1984) Indias technological capability: an analysis of its achievements and limits,

    Research Policy, 13, pp. 303310.

    Dore, R. (1984) Technological self reliance: sturdy ideal or self serving rhetoric, in: M. Fransman

    & K. King (Eds) Technological Capability in the Third World (London, Macmillan).

    Enos, J. (1991) The Creation of Technological Capability in Developing Countries, (London, Pinter).

    Goldar, B.N. Ranganathan, V.S. (1997) Economic reforms and R&D expenditure in industrial

    rms in India, NIPFP Working Paper No. 1, January, New Delhi.

    Griliches, Z. (1979) Issues in assessing the contribution of research and development to produc-

    tivity growth, Bell Journal of Economics, 10, pp. 92116.

    Jaffe, A.B. (1986) Technological opportunity and spillovers of R&D, American Economic Review,

    76, pp. 9841001.

    Jomo, K.S., Felker, G. & Rasiah, R. (Eds) (1999) Industrial Technology Development in Malaysia:

    Industry and Firm Studies (London, Routledge).

    Kamien, M.I. & Schwartz, N.L. (1975) Market structure and innovation: a survey, Journal of

    Economic Literature, 13, pp. 137.

    Katrak, H. (1985) Imported technology, enterprise size and R&D in a newly industrializing

    country: the Indian experience, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 47, pp. 213229.

    Katrak, H. (1990) Imports of technology and the technological effort of Indian enterprises, World

    Development, 18, pp. 371381.

    Katz, J.M. (1984) Domestic technological innovations and dynamic comparative advantage, Journal of Development Economics, 16, pp. 1337.

    Katz, J.M. (1987) Domestic technology generation in LDCs: a review of research ndings, in:

    J.M. Katz (Ed.) Technology Generation in Latin American Manufacturing Industries (London,

    Macmillan).

    Kumar, N. (1987) Technology imports and local research and development in Indian manufac-

    turing, The Developing Economies, 25, pp. 220233.

    Lall, S. (1983) Determinants of R&D in a LDC: the Indian engineering industry, Economic

    Letters, 13, pp. 379383.

    Lall, S. (1984) Indias technological capacity: effects of trade, industrial, science & technology

    policies, in: M. Fransman & K. King (Eds) Technological Capability in the Third World (London,

    Macmillan).Lall, S. (1987) Learning to Industrialize: The Acquisition of Technological Capability by India

    (London, Macmillan).

    Mowery, D.C. & Rosenberg, N. (1989) Technology and the Pursuit of Economic Growth (Cam-

    bridge, Cambridge University Press).

    Nelson, R.R. & Winter, S.G. (1982) An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change (Cambridge,

    MA, Belknap Press).

    Nelson, R.R. (1987) Innovation and economic development: theoretical retrospect and prospect,

    DownloadedBy:[INFLIBNETIndia

    Order]At:10:0120April2011

  • 8/7/2019 DEV_2001

    18/18

    R&D and Technological Learning 171

    in: J.M. Katz (ED.) Technology Generation in Latin American Manufacturing Industries (London,

    Macmillan).

    Odagiri, H. (1983) R&D expenditure, royalty payments and sales growth in Japanese manufactur-

    ing corporations, Journal of Industrial Economics, 32, pp. 6167.

    Ranis, G. (1990) Science and technology policy: lessons from Japan and the East Asian NICs, in:

    R.E. Evenson & G. Ranis (Eds) Science and Technology: Lessons for Development Policy (London,

    Intermediate Technology Publications), pp. 157178.

    Ray, A.S. (1998), Are foreign rms technologically more active and progressive in less developedcountries?, ACAES Conference on Macroeconomic Core of an Open Economy, Bangkok, 1618

    December.

    Rosenberg, N. (1976) Perspective on Technology (New York, Cambridge University Press).

    Scherer, F.M. (1967) Market structure and the employment of scientists and engineers, American

    Economic Review, 57, pp. 524531.

    Schumpeter, J.A. (1980 (1934) The Theory of Economic Development (London, Oxford University

    Press).

    Schumpeter, J.A. (1939) Business Cycles (New York, McGraw-Hill).

    Spence, A. (1984) Cost reduction, competition and industry performance Econometrica, 52, pp.

    101121.

    Westphal, L., Rhee, Y. & Pursell, G. (1984) Sources of technological capability in South Korea,in: M. Fransman & K. King (Eds) Technological Capability in the Third World (London,

    Macmillan).

    DownloadedBy:[INFLIBNETIndia

    Order]At:10:0120April2011