Decomposisi Tfp, China

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/16/2019 Decomposisi Tfp, China

    1/13

    Journal of Productivity Analysis, 16, 269–281, 2001.

    C   2001 Kluwer Academic Publishers. Manufactured in The Netherlands.

    A Decomposition of Total Factor ProductivityGrowth in Korean Manufacturing Industries:A Stochastic Frontier Approach

    SANGHO KIM [email protected]

     Department of International Trade, College of Business, Honam University, Kwang ju, 506-714 South Korea

    GWANGHO HAN [email protected] Department of Economics, Sunchon National University, Sunchon, Chonnam, 540-7 42 South Korea

     Abstract 

    This paper applies a stochastic frontier production model to Korean manufacturing indus-

    tries, to decompose the sources of total factor productivity (TFP) growth into technical

    progress, changes in technical efficiency, changes in allocative efficiency, and scale effects.

    Empirical results based on data from 1980–1994 show that productivity growth was driven

    mainly by technical progress, that changes in technical efficiency had a significant positive

    effect, and that allocative efficiency had a negative effect. This study suggests that specific

    guidelines are required to promote productivity in each industry, and provides additional

    insight into understanding the recent debate on TFP growth in Korean manufacturing.JEL classification:  D24, C23, O47

    Keywords:  Korean manufacturing, total factor productivity, technical progress, technical efficiency, scale com-

    ponents, allocative efficiency

    1. Introduction

    Following recent developments in the measurement of productivity growth, a stochastic

    frontier production function is applied to decompose total factor productivity (TFP) growth

    in Korean manufacturing into technical progress and changes in technical efficiency. In the

    “Solow” residual approach, technical progress is usually considered to be the unique source

    of TFP growth. Recent developments acknowledge that along with technical progress,changes in technical efficiency—the gap between frontier technology and a firm’s actual

    production—can also contribute to productivity growth. Stochastic frontier models assume

    that firms do not fully utilize existing technology because of various non-price and orga-

    nizational factors that lead to inevitable technical inefficiencies in production. Under these

    circumstances, TFP growth may arise from improvements in technical efficiency (TE),

    without technical progress (TP).

    From a policy perspective, researchers acknowledge that the decomposition of TFP

    into efficiency changes and technical changes provides useful information in productivity

  • 8/16/2019 Decomposisi Tfp, China

    2/13

    270   KIM AND HAN

    analysis. Policy makers can recommend policies that are more effective in improving the

    productivity of  firms if they understand the sources of variation in productivity growth. For

    example, if low productivity growth results from slow TP, then a policy to induce techno-

    logical innovation should be recommended to shift up the production frontier. If high rates

    of TP coexist with deteriorating TE, resulting in slow productivity growth, then a policy to

    increase the ef ficiency with which a known technology is applied is required, which might

    include improvements in learning-by-doing processes and in managerial practices.

    Since Nishimizu and Page (1982) first proposed the decomposition of TFP into ef ficiency

    changes and technical changes, researchers have applied their approach to various datasets

    in order to investigate productivity growth. Bauer (1990) estimated a translog cost frontier

    using data on the U.S. airline industry to decompose TFP growth into ef ficiency, technical

    progress, and scale components. Fecher and Perelman (1992) applied this method to themanufacturing industries of OECD countries. Recently, Granderson (1997) analyzed regu-

    lated firms in the U.S.; Kalirajan, Obwona and Zhao (1996) analyzed Chinese provincial-

    level agricultural data; and Bayarsaihan, Battese and Coelli (1997) studied Mongolian grain

    farms.

    This paper applies a stochastic frontier production model to decompose TFP growth in

    Korean manufacturing industries from 1980–1994. This paper decomposes TFP growth into

    four components according to Kumbhakar (2000): technical progress, changes in technical

    ef ficiency, changes in allocative ef ficiency, and scale effects.

    Despite an extensive literature on TFP growth in Korean manufacturing, no other studies

    have used a stochastic frontier production model to measure and decompose TFP growth.

    This research vacuum is rather surprising, considering the strong interest and prolonged

    debate on TFP growth in the Korean manufacturing sector. This paper is the  first attempt

    to decompose TFP growth in Korean manufacturing using a stochastic frontier production

    model,and provides additional insights into understanding the recent debateon TFP growth.

    Previous studies on TFP growth in Korean manufacturing measured TFP as a residual

    of  “Solow” growth accounting using aggregate data. Thus, these studies were not able to

    consider changes in technical inef ficiency, which this study estimates to have considerable

    effects on TFP growth. This study also enables us to examine firms’ individual TFP perfor-

    mance by using micro-level firm data that was largely ignored by previous studies, which

    used aggregated data.

    This paper is organizedas follows.Section 2 presents a decomposition of TFP andpresents

    the functional form of the estimation model. Section 3 discusses the data and estimation

    results. Section 4 contains the conclusions.

    2. Decomposition and Functional Form

     2.1. Decomposition of TFP

    A stochastic frontier production function is defined by

     yit  =   f  ( x it , t ) exp(−uit ),   (1)

    where  yit  is the output of the i th firm (i = 1, . . . , N ) in the t th time period (t = 1, . . . , T );

     f  (·) is the production frontier;  x  is an input vector;  t  is a time trend index that serves as a

  • 8/16/2019 Decomposisi Tfp, China

    3/13

    DECOMPOSITION OF TOTAL FACTOR PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH   271

    proxy for technical change; and  u  ≥  0 is the output-oriented technical inef ficiency. Notice

    that technical inef ficiency in equation (1) varies over time.

    The production frontier,   f  (·), is totally differentiated with respect to time to get1

    d  ln   f  ( x , t )

    dt =

    ∂ ln   f  ( x , t )

    ∂t +

     j

    ∂ ln   f  ( x , t )

    ∂ x  j

    d x  j

    dt .   (2)

    The  first and second terms on the right-hand side of equation (2) measure the change in

    frontier output caused by TP and by change in input use, respectively. From the output

    elasticity of input   j, ε j   =   ∂ ln   f /∂ ln x  j ,  the second term can be expressed as

     j  ε j•

     x  j ,

    where a dot over a variable indicates its rate of change. Thus, equation (2) is rewritten as

    d  ln   f  ( x , t )dt 

    = TP +

     j

    ε j• x  j  .   (3)

    Totally differentiating the logarithm of y in equation (1) with respect to time and using

    equation (3), the change in production can be represented as

    • y  =

    d  ln   f  ( x , t )

    dt −

    du

    dt = TP +

     j

    ε j•

     x  j  −du

    dt .   (4)

    The overall productivity change is not only affected by TP and changes in input use, but

    also by the change in technical inef ficiency. TP is positive (negative) if exogenous technical

    change shifts the production frontier upward (downward), for a given level of inputs. If 

    du/dt  is negative (positive), TE improves (deteriorates) over time, and  −du /dt   can be

    interpreted as the rate at which an inef ficient producer catches up to the production frontier.To examine the effect of TP and a change in ef ficiency on TFP growth,

    TFP is defined as

    output growth unexplained by input growth:

    TFP  =•

     y −

     j

    S  j•

     x  j ,   (5)

    where S  j   is input   j ’s share in production costs.

    By substituting equation (4) into equation (5), equation (5) is rewritten as

    TFP  =  TP −du

    dt +

     j

    (ε j  −  S  j )  • x  j

    =  TP −du

    dt 

    + ( RTS − 1)

     j

    λ j•

     x  j  +

     j

    (λ j  − S  j )  • x  j ,   (6)

    where   RTS   (=

     j ε  j ) denotes the measurement of returns to scale, and   λ j =   f  j x  j /l   f l x l = ε j /

    l εl = ε j / RTS . The last component in equation (6) measures inef ficiency in

    resource allocation resulting from deviations of input prices from the value of their marginal

    product. Thus, in equation (6), TFP growth can be decomposed into TP, the technical ef fi-

    ciency change (−du /dt ), scale components (SC= ( RTS −1)

     j  λ j•

     x  j ), and the allocative

    ef ficiency change (AE  =

     j (λ j  − S  j )  • x  j ).  The decomposition formula in equation (6) is

    drawn from Kumbhakar (2000).2

  • 8/16/2019 Decomposisi Tfp, China

    4/13

    272   KIM AND HAN

    If technical inef ficiency does not exist or is time-invariant, the above decomposition

    implies that technical inef ficiency does not affect TFP growth, as in the Solow residual

    approach. If technology exhibits constant returns to scale, the TFP growth formula in

    equation (6) is identical to the one derived in Nishimizu and Page (1982).

     2.2. Functional Form

    The components of productivity change can be estimated within a stochastic production

    frontier framework, and the time-varying production frontier can be specified in translog

    form as

    ln yit   = α0 +

     j

    α j ln x  ji t  + αT t  +1

    2

     j

    l

    β jl  ln x li t  ln x  ji t 

    +1

    2βT T t 

    2 +

     j

    βT j t  ln x  ji t  + vit  − uit ,   j, l  =  L , K ,   (7)

    where yit  is the observed output; t  is the time variable; and the x  variables are inputs. Sub-

    scripts   j  and l  indicate inputs ( j, l  =  L , K ). The ef ficiency error, u , represents production

    loss due to firm-specific technical inef ficiency; thus, it is always greater than or equal to zero

    (u  ≥  0), and it is assumed to be independent of the statistical error, v, which is assumed to

    be independently and identically distributed as  N (0, σ 2v ).

    The stochastic frontier model, as specified in equation (7), allows for non-neutral TP.

    TP is input   j -using (saving) if   βT j   is positive (negative); and TP is neutral if all   βT j s

    ( j  =   L , K )  are equal to zero. If all  β s are equal to zero  (β L L  =   βK K   =  β L K   =   βT T   =βT L   =   βT K    =   0),  the production function reduces to the Cobb-Douglas function with

    neutral TP.

    Following Battese and Coelli (1992), technical inef ficiency is assumed to be defined by

    uit  = u i exp(−η[t  − T ]),   (8)

    where the distribution of  u i  is taken to be the non-negative truncation of the normal dis-

    tribution,   N (µ,σ 2u ),  and  η   is a parameter that represents the rate of change in technical

    inef ficiency. A positive value (η > 0) is associated with the improvement of  firms’ techni-

    cal ef ficiency over time.3

    The maximum-likelihood estimates for the parameters of the stochastic frontier model,

    defined by equations (7) and (8), can be obtained by using the program, FRONTIER 4.1,

    in which the variance parameters are expressed in terms of  γ  = σ 2u /σ 2

    s   and σ 2

    s   = σ 2

    u  + σ 2

    v

    (see Coelli, 1996).

    The technical ef ficiency level of  firm i  at time t  (TE it ) is defined as the ratio of the actual

    output to the potential output as

    TE it  = exp(−uit ).   (9)

    The elasticity of output with respect to the   j th input is defined by

    ε j  = ∂  ln   f  ( x , t )/∂ ln x  j  = α j  +

    l= j

    β jl  ln x l  + β j j ln x  j  + βT j t ,   j, l  =  L , K .   (10)

  • 8/16/2019 Decomposisi Tfp, China

    5/13

    DECOMPOSITION OF TOTAL FACTOR PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH   273

    The elasticity of scale (=RTS) is defined as RTS  =

     j  ε j , and RTS decreases, is constant

    and increases if  RTS  <  1, RTS  =  1 and RTS  >  1, respectively.

    The rate of TP is defined by

    TP =  ∂  ln   f  ( x , t )/∂t  = αT  + βT T t  +

     j

    βT j  ln x  j ,   j  =  L , K .   (11)

    In the estimation of equations (10) and (11), output elasticity and TP are functions of 

    input levels and are estimated at the sample means of input levels.

    3. Data and Empirical Results

     3.1. Data

    The data used in this paper are an unbalanced panel consisting of annual time-series for

    508 Korean manufacturing   firms during 1980–1994, with a total of 6,203 observations.

    The sample covers all manufacturing  firms whose stocks are listed on the Korean Stock 

    Exchange. The enlisted firms are required to report their financial status. All firms’ data are

    taken from their financial reports.

    The capital stock (K ) is the real amount of tangible fixed assets, labor input ( L) is proxied

    by the number of workers, and real value-added  (VA) is used for output. Labor costs (C  L )

    consist of employee remuneration, including wages, bonuses, retirement compensation,

    and other welfare costs, and capital costs (C K ) are calculated as the sum of the interest

    payments, rents, and depreciation costs. Total costs (C ) are calculated as the total sum of these factor costs (C  = C  L  + C K ), and the factor share in total costs ( S  L , S K ) is calculated

    as the factor’s share out of the total costs (S  j  = C  j /C ,  j  =  L , K ). Table 1 presents sample

    means and standard deviations.

    Table 1.   Summary statistics for variables in the stochastic frontier production functions for Korean manufacturing

    industries.

    Total

    Sample Food Textiles Paper Chemical Non-metal Basic-metal Fabrication

    No. of Firms 508 49 82 28 107 26 38 163

    No. of Obs. 6,203 665 981 321 1,367 341 465 1,888

    Labor 6.711 7.007 7.067 5.943 6.386 6.832 6.657 6.744

    (1.411) (1.037) (1.171) (0.713) (0.977) (0.843) (1.243) (1.243)

    Capital 16.154 16.992 16.520 16.292 16.303 17.279 17.104 16.263

    (1.530) (1.103) (1.650) (1.324) (1.468) (1.374) (1.702) (1.571)

    Value Added 16.353 16.683 16.399 15.876 16.264 16.820 16.679 16.197

    (1.343) (1.104) (1.362) (1.126) (1.198) (1.131) (1.509) (1.484)

    Labor Share 0.583 0.538 0.591 0.488 0.583 0.536 0.514 0.627

    (0.165) (0.143) (0.171) (0.148) (0.161) (0.173) (0.182) (0.149)

     Notes:   Standard deviations are in parentheses. Capital and Value Added are logarithmic values as used in actual

    estimation.

  • 8/16/2019 Decomposisi Tfp, China

    6/13

    274   KIM AND HAN

    For individual industry estimation, this study classifies sample  firms into double-digit

    industries according to the International Standard Industry Classification (SIC). The food

    industry is represented by SIC 31 (food, beverages, and tobacco); the textiles industry by

    SIC 32 (textiles, wearing apparel, and leather products); the paper industry by SIC 34

    (paper and paper products); the chemical industry by SIC 35 (chemicals, petroleum, and

    coal products); the non-metal industry by SIC 36 (nonmetallic mineral products); the basic-

    metal industry by SIC 37 (basic-metal products); and the fabrication industry by SIC 38

    (fabricated metal products, machinery and equipment).4

     3.2. Empirical Results

     Hypotheses Tests   The maximum-likelihood estimates of the parameters in the translog

    stochastic frontier production function, defined by equations (7) and (8), are obtained for

    the total sample and each of the seven industries.5 All the estimates of  γ   are statistically

    significant at least at the 5% significance level, except for the non-metal and basic-metal

    industries. All the estimates of  η   are positive, except for the textiles industry, and all are

    statistically significant, except for the food and non-metal industries. A significant γ   along

    with a positive and significant η implies the existence of technical inef ficiency that declines

    over theyears, as is thecasefor thepaper, chemical,and fabrication industries. Theparameter

    η is estimated to be negative only in the textiles industry, which implies increasing technical

    inef ficiency.

    Table 2 presents the test results of various null hypotheses on the total sample. The null

    hypotheses are tested using likelihood ratio tests. The likelihood-ratio test statistic is  λ =

    −2[ L( H 0)− L( H 1)], where L ( H 0) and L ( H 1) are the values of the log-likelihood functionunder the specifications of the null and alternative hypotheses,  H 0  and  H 1, respectively. If 

    the null hypothesis is true, then λ  has approximately a Chi-square (or a mixed Chi-square)

    distribution with degreesof freedom equal to thenumber of restrictions. If thenull hypothesis

    includes γ  = 0, then the asymptotic distribution is a mixed Chi-square distribution (Coelli

    and Battese, 1996).

    The first null hypothesis, that there are no technical inef ficiency effects ( H 0   :  γ   =  µ  =

    η  =  0), is rejected at the 1% significance level for the total sample.6 If the null hypothesis is

    true, there are no frontier parameters in the regression equation, and the estimation becomes

    Table 2. Statistics for tests of hypothesesinvolving some coef ficients of the stochasticfrontier production function

    for Korean manufacturing industry.

    Log-Likelihood Test Critical

    Null Hypothesis Function Statistics (λ) Value Decision

    1. H0  :  γ  = µ  =  η  =  0   −4393.06 1461.84 10.50∗ Reject H0

    2. H0  :  η  =  0   −3721.33 118.38 6.63 Reject H03. H0  :  αT  = βTT  = βTL  =  βTK  = 0   −3752.18 180.08 13.28 Reject H04. H0  :  βTL  =  βTK  = 0   −3677.04 29.80 9.21 Reject H05. H0  :  β LL  =  βKK  = β LK  = βTT  = 0   −3682.33 40.39 13.28 Reject H0

    *The critical value for this test involving  γ    =  0 is obtained from Table 1 of Kodde and Palm (1986, p. 1246).

    Every null hypothesis is rejected at the 1% level of significance.

  • 8/16/2019 Decomposisi Tfp, China

    7/13

    DECOMPOSITION OF TOTAL FACTOR PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH   275

    an ordinary least square estimation. The results suggest that the average production function

    is an inadequate representation of the Korean manufacturing sector and underestimates the

    actual frontier because of technical inef ficiency effects.

    The second null hypothesis, that technical inef ficiency is time-invariant ( H 0   :   η  =   0),

    is also rejected at the 1% significance level for the total sample.7 This implies that tech-

    nical inef ficiency in Korean manufacturing is not time-invariant, given the time-varying

    specification of the stochastic frontier defined by equation (8).

    The third null hypothesis, that there is no technical change ( H 0   :  αT   =   βT T   =  βT L   =

    βT K   =  0), and the fourth null hypothesis, that technical progress is neutral ( H 0   :  βT L  =

    βT K  = 0), are both rejected at the 1% significance level for the total sample.8 This implies

    the existence of non-neutral technical progress in Korean manufacturing as a whole, given

    the specified production model.The last null hypothesis, that the technology in Korean manufacturing is a Cobb-Douglas

    ( H 0   :  β L L  =  βK K  =  β L K   =  βT T   =  0), is rejected for the total sample.9 Thus, the Cobb-

    Douglas production function is not an adequate specification for the Korean manufactur-

    ing sector, given the assumptions of the translog stochastic frontier production function

    model.

    Technical Efficiency and Returns to Scale   Table 3 represents the average technical ef-

    ficiency (TE) and returns to scale (RTS) for some selected time periods. Estimates of TE

    Table 3 .  Average technical ef ficiency (TE), and return to scale (RTS) for Korean manufacturing industries.

    Total Non- Basic-

    Sample Food Textiles Paper Chemical m etal metal Fabrication

    TE 1980–82 0.448 0.790 0.652 0.605 0.439 0.843 0.619 0.480

    (0.028) (−0.00 7) (−0.03 6) (0.046 ) (0.076 ) (0.01 3) (0.031 ) (0.023 )

    1983–85 0.485 0.770 0.602 0.683 0.497 0.795 0.666 0.524

    (0.027) (−0.00 6) (−0.02 3) (0.020 ) (0.029 ) (−0.023) (0.025) (0.039)

    1986–88 0.533 0.758 0.554 0.747 0.550 0.815 0.702 0.602

    (0.037) (−0.00 5) (−0.02 6) (0.057 ) (0.033 ) (0.01 2) (0.018 ) (0.051 )

    1989–91 0.597 0.768 0.517 0.829 0.611 0.842 0.767 0.686

    (0.039) (0.009) (−0.02 2) (0.030 ) (0.035 ) (0.01 0) (0.027 ) (0.042 )

    1992–94 0.662 0.786 0.486 0.893 0.677 0.869 0.810 0.761

    (0.032) (0.005) (−0.01 8) (0.022 ) (0.034 ) (0.01 1) (0.018 ) (0.031 )

    1980–94 0.545 0.775 0.562 0.751 0.555 0.833 0.713 0.611

    (0.033) (0.000) (−0.024) (0.034) (0.039) (0.004) (0.023) (0.038)

    RTS 1980–82 0.890 0.886 0.944 0.633 0.872 0.960 0.967 0.978

    1983–85 0.900 0.863 0.940 0.900 0.865 0.965 0.985 0.980

    1986–88 0.918 0.862 0.944 0.915 0.878 1.006 0.961 0.984

    1989–91 0.942 0.872 0.945 1.093 0.893 1.044 0.989 0.990

    1992–94 0.962 0.871 0.945 1.216 0.902 1.113 1.004 0.996

    1980–94 0.917 0.876 0.935 1.018 0.877 1.021 0.986 0.986  

    (0.01 1) (0.03 1) (0.02 3) (0.090 ) (0.027 ) (0.03 4) (0.041 ) (0.017 )

     Notes:   Average annual growth rates and asymptotic standard errors are in parentheses below TE and RTS,

    respectively.

  • 8/16/2019 Decomposisi Tfp, China

    8/13

    276   KIM AND HAN

    vary considerably, both across manufacturing industries and across time periods. The av-

    erage TE is 0.545 for the total sample. The non-metal and food industries have the highest

    and second highest estimates, 0.833 and 0.775, respectively, and the chemical and textiles

    industries have the lowest and second lowest estimates, 0.555 and 0.562, respectively. The

    other industries—paper, basic metal, and fabrication—have estimates that range from 0.611

    to 0.751.

    The average TE for all industries improves throughout the sample period, and this trend

    of steady improvement is also observed in the paper, chemical, basic-metal, and fabrication

    industries. The average TE deteriorates through the years in the textiles industry. The annual

    growth rate of TE is estimated to be almost zero in the food industry and positive, but small,

    in the non-metal industry. The average TE decreases in the early sample period(s), but

    improves later in the food and non-metal industries.10

    For the total sample, the average estimate of RTS is 0.917. RTS continuously increases

    and approaches one during the sample period. The null hypothesis that RTS is one is

    tested using the  T -test and is rejected at the 1% significance level. Thus, the alternative

    hypothesis, that production technology is not subject to constant returns to scale (CRS),

    is accepted for the Korean manufacturing dataset, given the specified translog production

    model.

    For themanufacturing sector, estimatesrangefrom 0.876 to 1.021.The null hypothesis that

    an industry has CRS technology is tested using the  T -test against the alternative hypothesis

    that technology is notCRS.The null hypothesis is rejected forthe food, textiles, andchemical

    industries, butcan’t be rejected for the otherindustries. Thus,production technologyexhibits

    decreasing returns to scale in the food, textiles, and chemical industries, and exhibits CRS

    for all other industries.

    Technical Progress, Scale Components, Allocative Ef   fi ciency, and Total Factor Produc-

     tivity   Table 4 presents the averages of the rates of technical progress (TP), the scale com-

    ponents (SC), the changes in allocative ef ficiency (AE), and the total factor productivity

    growth (•

    TFP) for selected time periods.11

    The average rate of TP was estimated at 0.047 and declined continuously in the total

    sample during the sampling period. For industry-level estimation, TP was highest in the

    basic-metal and textiles industries with estimates greater than 0.1, and it was lowest in

    the paper and chemical industries with estimates of about 0.04. The rate of TP declined

    continuously over time in the chemical, non-metal, basic-metal, and fabrication industries.

    This decline was most apparent in the basic-metal and non-metal industries, where initially

    the TP was the fastest growing, then slowed continuously, and finally lagged behind other

    industries. Meanwhile, in the textiles and paper industries, the rate of TP increased untilthe first half of the 1980s then decreased thereafter. TP was confined within a small range

    in the food and textiles industries, contrasting with the wide changes in the non-metal and

    basic-metal industries.

    Scale components, which measure the effects of input changes on output growth, are zero

    if RTS is constant, or are greater (less) than zero if RTS is increasing (decreasing), assuming

    positive input growth. Average scale components are −0.002 for the whole manufacturing

    sector, negative but small in the food and chemical industries, and close to zero in the other

    five industries.

  • 8/16/2019 Decomposisi Tfp, China

    9/13

    DECOMPOSITION OF TOTAL FACTOR PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH   277

    Table 4.  Technical progress (TP), scale components (SC), allocative ef ficiency change (AE) and total factor

    productivity growth (•

    TFP) of Korean manufacturing industries.

    Total Non- Basic-

    Sample Food Textiles Paper Chemical metal metal Fabrication

    TP 1980–82 0.066 0.078 0.110 0.068 0.067 0.115 0.141 0.089

    1983–85 0.056 0.079 0.111 0.069 0.057 0.089 0.120 0.071

    1986–88 0.047 0.082 0.112 0.080 0.048 0.068 0.076 0.056

    1989–91 0.035 0.080 0.107 0.055 0.038 0.047 0.060 0.047

    1992–94 0.024 0.081 0.104 0.042 0.028 0.029 0.039 0.038

    1980 – 94 0.047 0.075 0.107 0.047 0.049 0.078 0.112 0.069

    SC 1980–82 0.009 0.002 0.004   −0.005 0.018 0.001 0.005 0.004

    1983–85 0.005 0.003 0.009 0.009   −0.010 0.002 0.005 0.0021986–88   −0.007   −0.012   −0.003   −0.007   −0.010 0.001   −0.001   −0.002

    1989–91   −0.005   −0.009   −0.004 0.002   −0.010 0.002   −0.001   −0.001

    1992–94   −0.001   −0.003 0.001 0.001   −0.006 0.004 0.000 0.000

    1980 – 94   −0.002   −0.004 0.001 0.000   −0.006 0.000 0.000 0.000

    AE 1980–82   −0.008   −0.003   −0.016 0.018   −0.040   −0.055   −0.077    −0.011

    1983–85   −0.002 0.000   −0.001   −0.004   −0.025   −0.006   −0.076    −0.004

    1986–88   −0.002   −0.006   −0.003   −0.038   −0.019   −0.009   −0.008 0.005

    1989–91 0.000   −0.009   −0.009   −0.081   −0.010   −0.007   −0.051 0.003

    1992–94   −0.007   −0.006   −0.019   −0.091   −0.010   −0.038   −0.044   −0.008

    1980 – 94   −0.001 0.000   −0.005   −0.021   −0.015   −0.019   −0.061   −0.007 

    TFP   1980–82 0.094 0.072 0.062 0.128 0.120 0.070 0.097 0.102

    1983–85 0.087 0.077 0.096 0.094 0.052 0.062 0.074 0.108

    1986–88 0.075 0.059 0.081 0.092 0.052 0.072 0.086 0.111

    1989–91 0.069 0.071 0.072 0.006 0.053 0.052 0.035 0.0911992–94 0.048 0.077 0.068   −0.026 0.046 0.006 0.013 0.060

    1980 – 94 0.073 0.071 0.077 0.054 0.061 0.051 0.058 0.094

    The Korean government pursued an industrial policy to promote the heavy and chem-

    ical manufacturing sectors during the 1970s. This policy tried to direct limited national

    resources into strategically chosen industries (mostly in chemical, basic-metal, and fabri-

    cation). One of the policy objectives was to enable  firms to grow large enough to utilize

    scale economies and to compete in foreign markets. Estimated scale components in TFP

    growth for the heavy industries (chemical, non-metal, basic-metal, and fabrication) are very

    small or negative, implying that firms in these industries had already reached a certain size

    where scale economies no longer existed. For example, scale economies in the chemicalindustry vanished in the early 1980s, as we can see from the change in SC from 0.018 in

    the first period to −0.010 in the second period, and those in the basic-metal and fabrication

    industries disappeared by the third period (1986–1988). Thus, this study suggests that the

    prior industrial policy of exploiting economies of scale is no longer effective in promoting

    productivity in the heavy manufacturing sector.

    Allocative inef ficiency results when factor prices are not equal to their marginal prod-

    uct. Almost every estimate of AE has a negative value, implying the existence of alloca-

    tive inef ficiency. For the total sample, AE was a modest  −0.001, implying the existence

  • 8/16/2019 Decomposisi Tfp, China

    10/13

    278   KIM AND HAN

    of a slightly inef ficient allocation of inputs in production with a resulting decline of 

    TFP. For specific manufacturing industries, AE was lowest in the basic-metal industry,

    with an average value of  −0.061, followed by the paper, non-metal, and chemical in-

    dustries. In the other three industries, AE was estimated to be much larger, with esti-

    mates of 0.000,  −0.005, and  −0.007, respectively, for the food, textiles, and fabrication

    industries.

    This discrepancy in AE among industries indicates that the degree of market distortion

    varied across these industries. The resulting inef ficiency costs were generally greater in

    the heavy and chemical manufacturing industries (chemical, non-metal, and basic-metal),

    which the Korean government developed on a massive scale, than in other light manufac-

    turing industries (food, and textiles). The level of government intervention was especially

    high throughout the 1970s. Allocative inef ficiencies in the chemical, non-metal, and basic-metal industries—the heavy and chemical industries promoted by the government—were

    estimated to be much larger during the early 1980s (italics in Table 4) as compared to other

    periods and to other industries. This implies that government intervention led to severe

    market distortions in these industries.

    TFP growth is calculated as the sum of technical progress, as measured by a shift in

    the production frontier, changes in technical ef ficiency, changes in allocative ef ficiency,

    and changes in scale components. In Korean manufacturing industries, TP has been a key

    contributorto TFPgrowth,and improvementsin TE made a considerablecontribution to TFP

    growth, except in the textiles, food, and non-metal industries. AE exerted a negative effect

    on TFP growth, although its magnitude wassmaller than that of TE. In some industries, such

    as the non-metal and basic-metal industries, allocative ef ficiency losses even outweighed

    technical ef ficiency gains.

    Total TFP in the manufacturing sector has grown at an annual rate of 0.073, although

    the rate of growth decreased continuously during the sample period. For industry estimates

    during the sample period, TFP grew fastest in the fabrication industry, with an annual

    average growth rate of 9.4%, followed by the textiles industry with a rate of 7.7%, and the

    food industry with a rate of 7.1%. The remaining industries have grown by about 5 –6%

    per annum. During the early 1990s (from 1989–1991 to 1992–1994), a large downturn in

    TFP was observed in every industry except the food industry. This downturn coincided

    with an economic slowdown in the Korean economy during the same period, supporting the

    presumption that lagging productivity was a major reason for the depression of the Korean

    economy during the early 1990s.

    There are considerable deviations in TFP estimates for the Korean manufacturing sector.12

    Pyo et al. (1992) reported the growth rate of TFP as 1.1% during 1970 –1990; Moon

    et al. (1991) reported that it was 3.7% during 1971–1989; Dollar and Sokoloff (1990)showed that it was 6.1% during 1963–1979; and Young (1995) reported that it was 3.0%

    during 1966–1990. In these Solow residual studies, there are two key reasons for differ-

    ences in TFP estimates: (1) differing primary data sources and (2) assessment methods

    of factor inputs. Pyo et al. (1992) and Dollar and Sokoloff (1990) used the Mining and

    Manufacturing Survey, and Young (1995) and Moon et al. (1991) used the National In-

    come Accounts. Differing growth rates both for inputs and output in the two datasets

    partially explain the variance in the TFP estimates. The estimates also largely depend on

    the way factors are measured in each study. By including quality changes into inputs,recent

  • 8/16/2019 Decomposisi Tfp, China

    11/13

    DECOMPOSITION OF TOTAL FACTOR PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH   279

    studies explain a greater part of output growth by input growth, and report lower TFP

    estimates.

    Based on thelower TFPestimates of recentstudies,Krugman (1994) argued that economic

    growth in East Asia, including Korea, will not be sustainable in the long run, because it has

    mainly been input-driven and not technology based. Chen (1997) insisted that East Asia’s

    growth was mainly driven by factor embodied technical change, which is included in factor

    input growth as a whole and has been ignored in growth accounting that estimates TFP

    only as disembodied technical change. In this debate, it is clear that TFP estimates can vary

    widely depending on the measurement of inputs because TFP is measured as the portion of 

    output growth that is unexplained by input growth.13

    Compared to the literature, this study suggests the following. First, previous studies used

    aggregate data and measured TFP as a residual of the  “Solow” growth accounting. Thus,they cannot examine changes in technical ef ficiency, which this study estimates to have

    had considerable effects on TFP growth. Second, this study uses micro-level  firm data to

    estimate TFP growth rate at 7.3%, which is much higher than in studies that use aggregate

    data. TheKorean manufacturers in this samplehaveshown faster TFP growththan suggested

    by previous productivity studies. Third, this study implies that part of the increase in TFP

    is due to an improvement in TE. Thus, attributing all changes in TFP to technical progress,

    as in previous growth accounting studies, is misleading, and overestimates actual technical

    progress.

    4. Conclusions

    The empirical results of this study show that although productivity growth was driven

    mainly by technical progress, changes in technical ef ficiency had a significant positive

    effect and allocative ef ficiency had a significant negative effect on productivity growth.

    The after-effects of the government’s industrial policy to promote the heavy and chemical

    industries were identified in prevalent allocative inef ficiency and vanished economies of 

    scale across these industries. Thus, the results suggest that the promotion of a freer market

    will considerably enhance productivity growth in the Korean manufacturing sector.

    Policy implications derivable from this study suggest that specific guidelines are required

    to promote productivity in each industry. Industries with slow TP (paper and chemical)

    require the introduction of new frontier technology. Government policy should encourage

    investments that can introduce newly developed production technology. In the paper, chem-

    ical, non-metal, and basic-metal industries, where allocative inef ficiency is considerable,

    a policy to enhance TFP by improving resource allocation should be pursued, which canbe done by promoting free markets and lessening government intervention. Meanwhile, in

    industries where TE is small (food, textiles, and non-metal), a policy to enhance the ef ficient

    use of existing technology is recommended to catch up to frontier technology.

    This study provides additional insight into the recent debate on TFP growth in Korean

    manufacturing by applying a stochastic frontier production approach to analyzing produc-

    tivity. Thus, this study shows that the stochastic frontier production function model could

    be a complementary and alternative model to growth accounting methods for measuring

    and explaining productivity growth.

  • 8/16/2019 Decomposisi Tfp, China

    12/13

    280   KIM AND HAN

    Acknowledgments

    We thank Subal C. Kumbhakar and two anonymous referees for their valuable suggestions

    and comments. We are responsible for any errors.

    Notes

    1. For simplicity, the ‘it ’ subscripts are omitted from now on.

    2. For a survey of the literature on estimation and decomposition of TFP (see Kumbhakar and Lovell, 2000;

    Kumbhakar, Heshmati and Hjalmarsson, 1999).

    3. Thus, this specification assumes a particularparameterizationof the distribution of technical inef ficiency across

    firms. In this parameterization, the ordering of  firms according to the size of the technical inef ficiency effects

    is the same for all years involved.

    4. SIC 33 (wood and wood products) and SIC 39 (furniture and other manufactured products) don’t have a suf fi-

    cient degree of freedom to produce significant results, as they include only four and eleven  firms, respectively.

    5. The parameter estimates are available from the authors on request.

    6. Despite the fact that some parameters, γ , µ and η, are insignificant for some industries, the null hypothesis of 

    γ  = µ  =  η  =  0 was rejected at the 1% significance level for every industry.

    7. For industry-level estimation, the null hypothesis is rejected for every industry, except the food and non-metal

    industries.

    8. Thethird nullhypothesisof no technicalprogresswas rejected for every industry, except the fabricationindustry,

    and the fourth null hypothesis was rejected for the food, paper, and basic-metal industries, but couldn ’t be

    rejected for the other industries.

    9. This hypothesis was rejected for every industry, except the textiles industry.

    10. The dataset is an unbalanced panel, where some  firms enter and others exit during the sampling period. Thus,

    trends in TE can be different from those implied by the estimated sign of  η. This is the case for the food and

    non-metal industries.

    11. Thedecomposition results by year are omitted here to save space, butare available fromthe authors on request.

    12. For a summary of TFP estimates for Korean manufacturing industry (see Young, 1995).

    13. For a critical assessment of the recent debate on TFP in East Asia (see Chen, 1997; Felipe 1999).

    References

    Battese, G. E. and T. J. Coelli. (1992).   “Frontier Production Functions, Technical Ef ficiency and Panel Data:

    With Application to Paddy Farmers in India.” Journal of Productivity Analysis 3, 153–169.

    Bauer, P. W. (1990).  “Decomposing TFP Growth in the Presence of Cost Inef ficiency, Nonconstant Returns to

    Scale, and Technical Progress.” Journal of Productivity Analysis 1, 287–299.

    Bayarsaihan, T., G. E. Battese and T. J. Coelli. (1997).  “Productivity of Mongolian Grain Farming, 1976–1989.”

    CEPA Working Paper, Centre for Ef ficiency and Productivity Analysis, University of New England, Armidale,

    Australia.

    Chen, E. K. Y. (1997). “The Total Factor Productivity Debate: Determinants of Economic Growth in East Asia.”

     Asian-Paci fic Economic Literature 10, 18–38.

    Coelli, T. J. (1996).  “A Guide to FRONTIER Version 4.1: A Computer Program for Stochastic Frontier Produc-

    tion and Cost Function Estimation.”   CEPA Working Paper, Centre for Ef ficiency and Productivity Analysis,

    University of New England, Armidale, Australia.

    Coelli, T. and G. Battese. (1996).  “Identification of Factors Which Influence the Technical Inef ficiency of Indian

    Farmers.” Australian Journal of Agricultural Economics  40, 103–128.

    Dollar, D. and K. Sokoloff. (1990). “Patterns of Productivity Growth in South Korean Manufacturing Industries,

    1963–1979.” Journal of Development Economics  29, 309–327.

  • 8/16/2019 Decomposisi Tfp, China

    13/13

    DECOMPOSITION OF TOTAL FACTOR PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH   281

    Fecher, F. andS. Perelman.(1992). “Productivity Growth and Technical Ef ficiency in OECD Industrial Activities.”

    In R. Caves (ed.),  Industrial Ef  ficiency in Six Nations.  Cambridge: The MIT Press, 459–488.

    Felipe, J. (1999). “Total Factor Productivity Growth in East Asia: A Critical Survey.”   Journal of Development 

    Studies 35, 1–41.

    Granderson, G. (1997). “Parametric Analysis of Cost Inef ficiency and the Decomposition of Productivity Growth

    for Regulated Firms.” Applied Economics 29, 339–348.

    Kalirajan, K. P., M. B. Obwona and S. Zhao. (1996).  “A Decomposition of Total Factor Productivity Growth: The

    Case of Chinese Agricultural Growth Before and After Reforms.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics

    78, 331–338.

    Kodd, D. A. and F. C. Palm. (1986).  “Wald Criteria for Jointly Testing Equality and Inequality Restrictions.”

     Econometrica 54, 1243–1248.

    Krugman, P. (1994). “The Myth of Asia’s Miracle.” Foreign Affairs 73, 62–78.

    Kumbhakar, S. C. (2000).   “Estimation and Decomposition of Productivity Change when Production is not

    Ef ficient: A Panel Data Approach.” Econometric Reviews 19, 425–460.

    Kumbhakar,S. C., A. Heshmatiand L. Hjalmarsson. (1999).“ParametricApproaches to ProductivityMeasurement:A Comparison among Alternative Models.” Scandinavian Journal of Economics  101, 405–424.

    Kumbhakar, S. C. and C. A. K. Lovell. (2000).  Stochastic Frontier Anaysis. New York: Cambridge University

    Press, 279–309.

    Moon, H.,B. Jo,I. Whangand H.Kim.(1992). Total FactorProductivityin Korea: An Analysis of 27 Manufacturing

     Industries. Seoul: Korea Productivity Center.

    Nishimizu, M. and J. M. Page. (1982).   “Total Factor Productivity Growth, Technical Progress and Technical

    Ef ficiency Change: Dimensions of Productivity Change in Yugoslavia, 1965–78.”   The Economic Journal  92,

    929–936.

    Pyo, H., B. Kong, H. Kwon and E. Kim. (1992). An Analysis of the Causes of Growth and Productivity by Industry

     for the Republic of Korea, 1970 – 1990. Seoul: Korean Economics Research Institute.

    Young, A. (1995). “The Tyranny of Numbers: Confronting the Statistical Realities of the East Asian Growth

    Experience.” Quarterly Journal of Economics  110, 643–680.