43
Corporate Tax Planning and Stock Returns Shane Heitzman Maria Ogneva University of Southern California Marshall School of Business October 30, 2015 Abstract This paper investigates the asset pricing implications of corporate tax planning. Tax planning influences real and reported activities to optimize expected tax liabilities. As a result, it changes the amounts, timing and variance of corporate cash flows. Basic intuition suggests that tax planning can significantly influence firm value by changing expected after-tax cash flows. It is less clear whether it can also affect expected returns. By exposing the firm to higher uncertainty associated with government actions, tax planning may increase the firm’s non-diversifiable risk. Our results suggest that a tax planning-based risk premium exists but depends on firm size, the political party of the President, and the ideology of US Tax Court judges. These results have implications for assessing the importance of tax planning risks in the contexts of both capital markets and corporate governance and control. While the expected cash flows should remain the primary focus of evaluating the net present value of tax strategy, managers, boards and investors should also consider the impact of tax strategy on discount rates. Keywords: Tax Planning; Tax Avoidance; Risk; Asset Pricing We appreciate the comments and suggestions of Michelle Hanlon, Ed Maydew and participants at the 2015 Oxford Tax Symposium and the discussant Robert Ullman. This paper benefited from conversations with Robert Novy-Marx and Cliff Smith. Email: [email protected]; [email protected]

Corporate Tax Planning and Stock Returns - Columbia … · 2017-02-06 · 1 Corporate Tax Planning and Stock Returns 1. Introduction Corporate tax planning investments generate cash

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

0

Corporate Tax Planning and Stock Returns

Shane Heitzman

Maria Ogneva

University of Southern California – Marshall School of Business

October 30, 2015

Abstract

This paper investigates the asset pricing implications of corporate tax planning. Tax planning

influences real and reported activities to optimize expected tax liabilities. As a result, it changes

the amounts, timing and variance of corporate cash flows. Basic intuition suggests that tax

planning can significantly influence firm value by changing expected after-tax cash flows. It is

less clear whether it can also affect expected returns. By exposing the firm to higher uncertainty

associated with government actions, tax planning may increase the firm’s non-diversifiable risk.

Our results suggest that a tax planning-based risk premium exists but depends on firm size, the

political party of the President, and the ideology of US Tax Court judges. These results have

implications for assessing the importance of tax planning risks in the contexts of both capital

markets and corporate governance and control. While the expected cash flows should remain the

primary focus of evaluating the net present value of tax strategy, managers, boards and investors

should also consider the impact of tax strategy on discount rates.

Keywords: Tax Planning; Tax Avoidance; Risk; Asset Pricing

We appreciate the comments and suggestions of Michelle Hanlon, Ed Maydew and participants at the 2015 Oxford Tax

Symposium and the discussant Robert Ullman. This paper benefited from conversations with Robert Novy-Marx and Cliff Smith.

Email: [email protected]; [email protected]

1

Corporate Tax Planning and Stock Returns

1. Introduction

Corporate tax planning investments generate cash flows for shareholders by reducing the

share of asset returns paid to the tax authority. These risky cash flows must then be priced.

Relative to other key corporate finance decisions—capital structure and payout policy, for

example—we know surprisingly little about the capital market implications of tax planning. The

purpose of this paper is twofold: to motivate the conditions under which tax planning

investments affect investors’ risk exposure and to provide empirical evidence on the association

between tax planning and investors’ expected returns, a first-order determinant of share values.

The impact of corporate tax planning on security values depends on how tax planning affects

after-tax cash flows and the discount rate. The numerator in a typical valuation model picks up

the effect of tax planning on expected cash flows (cash tax savings less the costs of defending the

position, accounting and audit costs, restructuring costs and agency costs).1 In the denominator,

the discount rate reflects investors’ exposure to risk, specifically risk that cannot be eliminated

through diversification. Tax planning investment affects risk by increasing the variance of after-

tax cash flows. However, it is not clear a priori how it should affect expected returns, if at all.

Risk driven by randomness in the audit process for example should not require a risk premium.

When tax planning risk is diversifiable, incremental cash flows becomes the only relevant metric

for investor valuation and tax strategy purposes (ignoring agency considerations). But if this

strategy exposes investors to systematic risk, investors should demand a risk premium. To the

extent these premiums are more than negligible, they should be detectable in firms’ stock returns.

1 These net cash flow benefits clearly exist but can be challenging to document since the costs of tax planning

primarily affect earnings before tax while the benefits of tax planning are difficult to infer given the limited

disclosure required by financial reporting rules. See Hanlon and Heitzman (2010) for a review of the recent

literature.

2

To motivate the potential for tax planning to affect investors’ risk exposure, consider the

government’s resemblance to a minority shareholder with a legal claim to a share of the firm’s

economic profits (Desai, Dyck and Zingales 2007). What makes this claim on firm value unique

is that this sharing rule varies, both over time and in the cross-section, depending on how

managers and the government behave. Corporate tax planning by managers typically results in

transactions that reduce the share of corporate profits paid to the tax authority. This alters the

firm’s cost structure by reducing costs that have a relatively strong covariance with performance

(by lowering the effective marginal tax rate) and increasing costs that have a significantly weaker

covariance with performance (the fixed costs of tax planning). Thus, a leverage-like financial

risk arises that increases the volatility of residual cash flows to shareholders and should be

associated with higher betas.2

A more appealing question is whether the firm’s tax planning policies expose investors to

greater risk from future changes in the government’s tax policies. There is growing evidence to

suggest that exposure to government policy risks are important determinants of stock returns

(Boutchkova et al. 2012; Croce et al. 2012; Pastor and Veronesi 2013). Tax legislation,

enforcement and judicial decisions combine to determine the government’s claim on asset

returns. And every taxpayer faces some risk that this claim—the expected cash flows paid to

government—will change in the future. However, for such policy risk to affect expected stock

returns, it must be that the market expects tax policy changes to disproportionately affect high

tax planning firms, thereby creating a co-variation among their returns because of correlated

exposure to the shift in policy. This expectation might depend on business cycles (such as greater

2 In other words, in good times, shareholders benefit from a low marginal tax rate and hence have the equivalent of

levered cash flows, raising returns. In bad times, managers have limited flexibility to unwind the transactions

implemented precisely to reduce the marginal tax rate in good times. If tax planning increases investors’ exposure to

financial risk, it should be priced.

3

enforcement in bad times) or political cycles (such as greater enforcement in Democratic

administrations), and can vary in the cross section if firms differ in their adaptability to changing

tax rules.3

Across all potential sources of risk—and there could be others—the question is the same:

does the intensity of corporate tax planning affect expected stock returns? An empirical answer

to this question requires proxies for expected returns and tax planning intensity. Following prior

asset pricing research, we match historical accounting and tax information from year t – 1 with

monthly realized returns from July of year t through June of year t + 1.

Our primary tax planning proxy is an effective tax rate constructed from accrual-based

measures of tax expense and pretax income over a three year period. We adopt this measure over

the alternatives for several reasons. First, regressions of tax planning proxies on tax planning

determinants indicate that the variation in the effective tax rate is driven by factors with higher

tax uncertainty—international operations and mobile capital (R&D)—and not by variation in

capital intensity which affects the timing of the tax liability but not the uncertainty. Because our

tax planning proxy is accrual-based, it is potentially more informative about long-run tax

planning policies than a cash-based measure. Additionally, Armstrong, Blouin and Larcker

(2012) find that tax director compensation is most highly correlated with accrual-based effective

tax rates, suggesting it is a more informative measure about tax planning performance. Finally,

we show that accrual-based tax rates explain future settlement with the tax authority in the

predicted direction; other measures do not.

3 For example, a tax authority might respond to a negative demand shock with a more aggressive approach to firms

determined to “push the limits”, perhaps due to revenue or public pressure (Bagchi 2015). Similarly, Congress might

respond to a negative demand shock by increasing incentives for investment or loss carryback in a way that

primarily benefits tax-abiding firms. There is some evidence that the government responds to economic shocks both

in writing tax law (Romer and Romer 2010) and interpreting it (Brennan, Epstein and Staudt 2009). If more

intensive tax planning exposes shareholders to policy-based systematic risk, it should be priced.

4

We adopt industry-level measures of tax planning intensity to mitigate measurement error

driven by firm-specific short-run measures (Dyreng, Hanlon and Maydew 2008) and biased

inferences caused by dropping firms with losses (Henry and Sansing 2014).4 This approach

assumes that the potential for exposure to a tax planning risk factor is present for all firms, even

those with current losses, and that opportunities for tax planning are correlated with industry-

specific asset and operating characteristics.

The results in this study provide evidence of a tax planning-induced risk premium. The

average equal-weighted excess stock return for the portfolio of firms in industries with the lowest

accrual-based tax rates is 3.6% higher annually than the return on the portfolio of firms in

industries with the highest tax rates. These results are supported by cross-sectional regressions of

monthly returns on industry effective tax rates. 5

Tests based on tax planning sorts within size quintiles suggest that the tax planning-based

risk premium observed with equal-weighted returns is stronger in smaller firms. The average

value-weighted returns are significantly higher for the lowest effective tax rate portfolios than for

the highest effective tax rate portfolios, but only among the smallest stocks. This is not surprising

4 Problems attributed to firm-specific measures of tax planning include: a) bias caused by dropping or eliminating

firms with negative pretax income, b) the impact of idiosyncratic accounting shocks in the measurement of earnings,

c) the need for a long time series of data to calculate long-run cash tax rate measures, d) the relatively short time

series of data on unrecognized tax benefits, e) lack of observability due to incentives for opaque disclosures, f)

correlations between tax proxies and shocks to economic performance. In robustness tests, we examine the

sensitivity of the results to two firm-specific measures of tax planning: long run cash tax rates and the tax reserve for

uncertain tax benefits. 5 Of course, one can argue that the results are influenced by the mispricing of cash flows from tax planning. Suppose

investors systematically underweight the cash savings from tax planning. This will cause high tax planning firms to

have higher future returns as future cash flow realizations surprise investors. This could happen, for example, if

investors are misled by a manager’s decision to “over-reserve” for expected settlements with the tax authority. If this

mispricing explanation is valid, however, it implies that the returns to an investment strategy that is long in high-tax

planning firms and short in low-tax planning firms will earn excess positive returns in years where tax policy is

more likely to be pro-taxpayer and negative in years where tax policy is more likely to be pro-government. It is also

possible this risk premium will vary over time. If governmental responses to tax planning are expected to be more

severe during Democratic presidencies, the risk premium required to invest in high tax planning firms will increase.

This runs counter to the argument that cash flows are somehow mispriced. Chi, Pincus and Teoh (2013) argue that

firms with low tax liabilities are overpriced and generate low future earnings and returns, suggesting that firms with

low tax rates should also have lower returns. Our results do not support this.

5

if small firms find it costlier to hedge against future shifts in tax policy or protect their interest

through political influence, or if the exposure to policy changes at large firms is lower because

such firms are already under continuous audit by the tax authority.

We also examine whether the tax planning premium is associated with time-varying factors

that capture increased uncertainty in government reactions to corporate tax planning. We find

evidence that a tax planning-based risk premium is stronger during Democratic presidencies, and

holds for both equal- and value-weighted returns suggesting it is less sensitive to size effects.

This is consistent with Bagchi (2015) who finds that IRS enforcement efforts increase when a

Democrat is in office and with Belo, Gala and Li (2013) who find that stock returns are higher

during Democratic presidencies for firms that benefit more from government spending. There is

also some evidence that the ideology of the US Tax Court, measured by the political party of

each judge’s appointing President, affects returns. In periods with more Democrat-appointed

judges on the Tax Court (19 judges each serving 15-year terms), stock returns are higher for high

tax planning firms. The results for both the President and Tax Court are consistent with an ex

ante premium to tax planning in periods of heighted risk of an adverse policy change. In contrast,

we find evidence that high tax planning firms generate higher returns during periods of low IRS

enforcement measured by corporate return audits. One explanation for this is that news about

low realized audit rates causes investors to revalue expected cash flows from prior tax planning.

This study contributes to the growing literature on the economic consequences of tax

planning and the specific properties of firms’ tax policies. An implicit assumption in this

literature is that greater tax planning has an effect on cash flow risk orthogonal to operating and

investing risks. Our paper provides two key innovations. First, we focus on the non-diversifiable

risk of tax planning, which is the only risk that should affects firms’ cost of capital in an efficient

6

market. Second, we consider a direct link between tax planning and firms’ systematic risk that

results from the correlated shocks due to government’s tax policy and tax enforcement changes.

This is motivated by the recent work on the pricing of policy uncertainty and stands in contrast to

existing studies that argue tax planning affects stock returns through corporate transparency.

That approach relies on strong assumptions about the link between tax planning and corporate

transparency as well as the pricing of transparency.

Our research also contributes to a growing body of evidence on the importance of economic

policy risk by focusing on a key element of fiscal policy: taxation and tax enforcement. Remarks

by the IRS, law firms, governance advisors and accounting firms point to the increasing

importance of managing tax risk.6 The evidence presented here on shareholders’ demand for a

premium to invest in firms with more intensive tax planning contributes to our understanding of

the pricing of the firm’s securities, and by extension, the types of company policies that will

maximize firm value. Moreover, understanding the valuation consequences of tax planning

appears crucial for the efficient design of incentives and organizational structures that exploit

value-enhancing opportunities for coordinated tax planning. Thus, our findings are relevant to

studies on the role of agency conflicts in tax planning and the broader discussion of tax risk

management occurring in the boardroom. While managers and boards should continue to focus

on the numerator—expected incremental cash flows—when evaluating tax planning

opportunities, our results suggest that denominator effects can be an important consideration

depending on the attributes of the firm, economic conditions and the political climate.7

6 IRS News Release IR-2009-95; “The Role of Executives, Counsel and Boards of Directors in Tax Risk Oversight”

Skadden, May 18, 2010; “Bridging the divide; Highlights from the 2014 Tax risk and controversy survey” Ernst and

Young 2014. 7 Of course, if the t-statistic cutoffs for statistical significance are increased following the suggestions of Harvey, Liu

and Zhu (2014], the strength of our inferences must be moderated.

7

2. Prior literature

2.1. Valuation consequences of tax planning

Economic intuition tells us that managers, properly incentivized, should adopt tax planning

strategies that maximize firm value.8 As firms have unique optimal investment and financing

choices, the efficient tax strategy will also be unique, leading to variation in tax planning over

time and across firms. If managers implement tax strategies that maximize firm value on

average, there should be no association between measures of tax planning and equity values.

However, if tax planning is associated with unresolved agency problems such predictions can

change. Desai and Dharmapala (2006) link aggressive tax planning to corporate opacity and

argue that the value of tax planning to shareholders is conditional on corporate governance.9 In

support of this, Desai and Dharmapala (2009) provide evidence that market-to-book, their proxy

for value, is increasing in tax avoidance but only among firms with more institutional

ownership.10 This interpretation relies on the argument that tax planning has a directional effect

on firm value and that the direction is conditional on external monitoring. Of course, agency

conflicts can cause managers to choose too much or little tax planning and thus any deviation

from optimal will reduce value. Consistent with this, Armstrong et al. (2014) provide evidence

suggesting that greater monitoring appears to reign in both overly-conservative and overly-

8 Agency conflicts complicate the matter if managerial preferences for tax strategy diverge from shareholder

preferences (Crocker and Slemrod 2005; Desai and Dharmapala 2006; Rego and Wilson 2012). 9 If opacity is required to hide aggressive tax positions from the tax authority, monitoring of managers also becomes

more difficult, reducing the manager’s cost to extract rents from shareholders (Desai and Dharmapala 2006). In this

world, more aggressive tax planning signals an increase in agency costs and self-serving managerial behavior, but

can be mitigated by greater monitoring. Kim, Li and Zhang (2011) provide evidence that firms that avoid more taxes

are also more likely to experience a future stock price crash, but this likelihood apparently falls with stronger

monitoring by analysts and institutions. 10 In related studies, Koester (2011) finds that the liability reserve for uncertain tax benefits is positively associated

with share values, suggesting that investors view aggressive tax planning activity as value-increasing. Koester, Lim

and Vigeland (2014) show that the valuation of this tax reserve falls when the internal controls have a tax-related

material weakness.

8

aggressive tax avoidance. Given incomplete models of optimal tax planning, an inherent

complexity and opacity of corporate tax reporting, and infrequent natural experiments, it has

been difficult to draw concrete inferences about the relation between tax planning and value.

In contrast to price-level studies, event studies offer the potential for more powerful

identification of tax-based effects. Hanlon and Slemrod (2009) examine market reactions to

allegations the firm is involved in a tax shelter. If this very aggressive form of tax planning is

value destroying, and the public allegation informs market participants about this activity (as

well as managers’ preference for it), the reaction should be negative. While they find negative

average market reactions across the entire tax shelter sample, firms that appear to be less

intensive tax planners have less negative market reactions, implying a positive market response

to news of aggressive tax avoidance among firms perceived as not aggressive enough

beforehand. Gallemore, Maydew and Thornock (2014) show that the average price declines at

the announcement of the allegations are only temporary, consistent with tax shelter participation

having minimal negative long-run effects on managerial reputation.11

2.2. Tax planning and risk

The notion of tax planning is broad and is often described with more colorful language

depending on the context: avoidance, aggressiveness, sheltering or evasion, for example. It

11 Examining market reactions to corporate inversion announcements, Desai and Hines (2002) and Cloyd, Mills and

Weaver (2003) find mixed evidence that the market responds systematically to announcements to relocate offshore.

Part of the difficulty in interpreting market reactions in the inversion case arise because of investor level tax effects.

In studies related to changes in accounting rules, Frischmann, Shevlin and Wilson (2008) examine the market’s

response to new uncertain tax benefit disclosure requirements under FIN48. They find little evidence that a firm’s

tax planning activity predicts stock returns around key FASB pronouncement dates related to FIN48, suggesting that

the new accounting rule has little expected effect on the costs or benefits of tax planning. When the event date is

centered on the firm’s initial disclosure of the tax reserve, stock returns are positive and increasing in the reserve,

suggesting that investors are, on average, positively surprised by the level of tax planning. Robinson and Schmidt

(2013) find that the market’s positive reaction to the initial disclosure of uncertain tax benefits is significantly

weaker when the firm’s disclosure quality is high, suggesting the value of aggressive tax planning is mitigated when

firms are more transparent (and thus more likely to have a weaker position when challenged).

9

requires intentional actions that involve structuring the organization, its investments, transactions

and reporting to exploit tax-based opportunities to increase shareholder wealth. These

opportunities can arise from investments that are tax favored, transactions that exploit ambiguity

in the tax law to reduce marginal tax costs, and discretion over the location, timing and

characterization of reported income and deductions in the tax returns. There should be little

disagreement that tax planning increases the riskiness of cash flows to investors: holding pretax

cash flows constant, any reduction in the marginal tax rate will increase the volatility of after-tax

cash flows.12 However, whether tax planning leads to higher expected returns depends on how it

affects the covariance of cash flows with performance and whether it changes the firm’s

exposure to tax policy shocks.

The idea that tax planning has implications for the risk profile of the firm is gaining traction.

Practitioner literature in tax management and corporate governance point to the increasing

prominence of tax risk considerations in corporate decision making and control (Levin et al.

2006; Larsen 2011; Ernst & Young 2014). Neubig and Sangha (2004) describe a number of tax-

based sources of risk that managers and directors should consider, some which apply to all firms

and other that apply only to firms that exploit ambiguity in the tax law. Though the distinction is

imperfect, one can think of tax risk as exposure to things in the manager’s control (tax

compliance activities, the location and type of investment and financial policies) as well as

things out of his control (political ideologies of the President and Congress, IRS budgets and

enforcement priorities, the macroeconomy, etc.). The IRS is becoming more outspoken on the

role of corporate governance structures in addressing tax risk, ostensibly to influence corporate

tax planning by appealing directly to those responsible for tax decision making and control.

12 Even if perfectly legal and certain, a reduction in the government’s claim to firm assets increases the variance of

returns to shareholders.

10

Recently, a number of studies address the basic link between tax planning and risk relying on

an indirect corporate transparency argument. They argue that if aggressive tax planning is

associated with greater asymmetric information a la Desai and Dharmapala (2006), and if

asymmetric information is priced, then greater tax planning will increase the cost of equity

capital. In contrast, one can appeal to the narrative in Gallemore and Labro (2015) who show that

firms engaged in more intensive tax planning actually require high quality information systems

to actually identify and support their tax planning strategies. Henry (2014) proposes a discount

rate explanation for the link between stock returns and tax expense surprises (Hanlon, Laplante

and Shevlin 2005; Thomas and Zhang 2014), and argues that tax surprises proxy for priced

information risk arising from earnings manipulation and tax planning-driven opacity (Francis et

al. 2005; Desai and Dharmapala 2006).13 In debt markets, Shevlin, Urcan and Vasvari (2013)

provide evidence that more aggressive tax avoidance leads to higher bond yields by reducing

transparency.

On the other hand, Goh et al. (2014) follow Gallemore and Labro and predict that greater tax

avoidance should decrease the cost of equity capital by enhancing information quality. Using

implied measures of expected returns and book-tax differences, and effective tax rates to

measure tax planning, they document a negative association between tax avoidance and expected

returns. This results in Shevlin et al. (2013) and Goh et al. (2014) are intriguing as one would

13 Henry (2014) uses variance decomposition techniques to link tax surprises to contemporaneous changes in stock

prices and concludes that changes in tax expense are correlated with changes in priced risk. The results in Henry

(2014) are difficult to interpret. Tax surprises appear negatively related to total news, although the effect is larger for

the portion of news attributed to changes in the discount rate. However, when the regressions are estimated on firms

with positive tax surprises only, the conditional association with discount rate news is only one-quarter the

magnitude of the association with cash flow news. Henry partitions the sample on the sign of tax surprise to obtain a

sort on firms more or less likely to have used tax expense to manage earnings, however, the sort on tax surprise is

also a sort on profitability and growth: firms with increasing tax expense are also the same firms with expanding

taxable profits.

11

expect tax-driven information quality problems to affect debt and equity in similar ways.14

Guenther, Matsunaga and Williams (2013) argue that the volatility of a firm’s cash tax payments

is more indicative of “tax risk” than the level of tax payments used in prior studies, and show

that the variance of a cash tax rate is positively correlated with future stock return volatility while

the level of the effective tax rate is not. Rego and Wilson (2012) argue that tax planning

increases risk and that risk-averse managers must be incentivized to undertake such risk.

Consistent with that, they document that CEOs with stronger wealth sensitivity to risk (portfolio

vega) appear to implement more risky tax strategies. However, they are silent on the link

between tax planning and priced risk.

This paper differs from existing work on several key dimensions. First, we provide a simple

descriptive theoretical framework to motivate the existence and pricing of a tax planning risk

factor. This contrasts with prior studies that either ignore the conditions under which tax

planning should lead to higher expected returns or rely on tenuous links between tax planning,

information quality and the pricing of information risk. Second, we employ standard empirical

asset pricing methodologies to test whether tax planning is associated with expected returns.15

Concurrent studies that measure expected returns using implied cost of capital measures suffer

from bias caused by correlations between tax planning proxies and earnings shocks, exclusion of

firms without analyst coverage and exclusion of firms with losses or negative expected earnings.

Third, we employ industry-level accrual-based proxies for tax planning. We use correlations

between tax planning proxies and firm’s exposure to future conflicts with the tax authority to

14 Hutchens and Rego (2013) also examine the association between a number of firm-specific tax proxies and the

discount rate implied by the relation between prices and analyst earnings forecasts. They find little evidence linking

tax planning proxies to expected returns. 15 See Core, Guay and Verdi (2008) and Barth, Konchitchki and Landsman (2013) for examples from the

accounting literature.

12

identify the proxy most consistent with our research question: accrual-based effective tax rates.

Moreover, we rely on the logical assumption that tax planning incentives and opportunities are

driven primarily by industry-based competition in product markets, organizational structure and

investment opportunities. Because expected returns are based on forward looking assumptions,

this allows us to maximize sample size and reduce bias induced by researchers’ typical selection

on historical profitability.

3. Theoretical development

3.1. Tax planning and financial risk

There are at least two potential channels through which tax planning should affect expected

returns: financial risk and tax policy risk. It is well known that financial leverage from debt

financing should be priced. Investors also appear to demand a risk premium to invest in firms

with higher operating leverage, that is, firms whose operating cost structure is comprised of

relatively greater fixed costs that have a lower covariance with the market (Lev, 1974; Novy-

Marx, 2011). In a similar vein, tax planning can exhibit leverage-like characteristics depending

on how it alters the total tax cost function.

To illustrate, consider the taxable firm. Notwithstanding the asymmetry in the taxation of

profits and losses embedded in the tax code, a firm’s tax costs absent planning will be highly

sensitive to profitability. When the firm engages in tax planning, it incurs new costs that to a first

approximation do not vary with economic performance—they are fixed (Mills, Erickson and

Maydew 1998). These costs include the costs of identifying tax planning transactions, direct

legal and accounting costs to structure the transactions, indirect costs when tax planning

activities affect the distribution of information within the firm, legal costs and opportunity costs

of managerial time if transactions are challenged by tax authorities, and lower pretax returns on

13

tax-favored investment structures. With positive demand shocks, shareholders benefit from the

lower marginal tax rate created by tax planning, generating the equivalent of leveraged cash

flows and raising returns. In bad times, managers have limited flexibility to unwind the

investments, transactions and policies implemented precisely to reduce the marginal tax rate in

good times. By reducing the covariance of tax costs with market performance, tax planning that

induces leverage-like behavior in the firm’s cost structure increases shareholders’ exposure to

financial risk that should affect financial risk.16

3.2. Tax planning and policy risk

A second channel runs through exposure to tax policy risk. Tax policy is a cornerstone of the

government’s economic policies. Uncertainty about the government’s policies can affect stock

returns in the cross-section if a) investors expect tax policies to change, and b) the expected

policy response has a disproportionate effect on firms that engage in more intensive tax planning.

A growing literature in financial economics addresses the link between policy uncertainty

and stock returns. In Pastor and Veronesi (2013), policy uncertainty matters because future

policy choices can affect firm cash flows independent of the broader economic conditions and

because of uncertainty about the impact of current policies on cash flows. Moreover, exposure to

policy risk is magnified in weak economic conditions if policies are more likely to change during

those times. Using the economic policy uncertainty index constructed by Baker, Bloom and

Davis (2012)—an instrument constructed from news coverage of policy uncertainty, expiration

of tax provisions, and macroeconomic forecast disagreement—they find consistent evidence that

periods of greater policy uncertainty are associated with stronger correlations in stock returns,

16 Of course, if tax planning does not affect cost structure in this way, it may not affect investors’ exposure to

systematic risk and thus will not be associated with returns through this channel.

14

higher risk premia, and risk premia that increase in weak economic conditions. In the cross

section, Belo, Gala and Li (2013) show that firms in industries exposed to government

expenditure policy (those in industries where more of the output is purchased by the government)

command risk premiums in periods when a Democrat holds the presidency.

The risks that derive from tax policy uncertainty result from at least three sources: tax

legislation, tax enforcement and judicial ideology. Analyzing several decades of tax legislation,

Romer and Romer (2010) conclude that tax legislation appears motivated by attempts to

encourage and stimulate long-term growth. In some periods, tax policy is countercyclical—

increasing tax burdens to slow down expansions while providing tax breaks to stimulate

investment and hiring in bad times. Only before the 1980s are tax changes spending driven.

Uncertainty about future tax legislation is a key component of the economic policy uncertainty

index of Baker et al. (2012). However, the extent to which uncertainty about tax legislation

matters more for investors in high tax planning firms is not obvious. If investors expect tax

legislation will directly target high tax planning firms (perhaps because the ability of these firms

to effectively manage taxes downward is a response to controversial tax rules or incentives

implemented to favor certain industries), then high tax planning firms should command a

premium. If not, the impact on expected returns is not clear.

Tax enforcement offers a more direct link between tax planning and policy uncertainty. The

government’s enforcement policies affect firms by changing the expected payoffs to tax

planning. These policies are likely a function of political ideologies and macroeconomic

conditions. For example, Bagchi (2015) finds that the political party of the President appears to

influence how IRS enforcement resources are allocated, specifically the number of returns that

get audited during the year. When a Democrat occupies the White House, more corporate returns

15

are audited. The number of corporate returns audited is also increasing in the federal deficit and

decreasing in GDP growth, consistent with revenue pressures driving variation in enforcement

efforts. Of course, the agency charged with enforcing tax laws sets tax policy other ways as well:

evidence from the Treasury Department’s anti-inversion guidance suggests targeted responses to

firms pursuing mergers with low-tax foreign partners (IRS Notice 2014-52), transactions viewed

politically as having primarily a tax avoidance motive.

Finally, an interesting question is whether uncertainty about judicial perceptions of tax

planning, and their impact on tax policy, also matter. This is relevant because controversial tax

strategies with high potential payoffs are those where the wedge between the firm’s and the tax

authority’s interpretations is large. Like enforcement, this offers a direct link between tax

planning choices and policy risk. Before a tax position is adopted, the firm forecasts expected

outcomes if challenged to determine expected cash flows. Ex post, when a dispute with the tax

authority arises, the firm and IRS assess the optimal settlement strategy, both forming

expectations of an uncertain judicial response. In both cases, knowing how the court is likely to

rule will impact the decision to adopt the tax plan or fight the challenge. The potential for a

systematic risk factor enters in if the court’s attitude toward tax planning shifts over time due to

economic or political forces. Brennan, Epstein and Staudt (2009) find that Supreme Court tax

decisions vary predictably, becoming pro-government in periods of depression. Staudt, Epstein,

and Wiedenbeck (2006) find that Supreme Court ideology (liberal vs. conservative) affects the

likelihood of a pro-government ruling. More liberal courts are more likely to rule against

corporate taxpayers, but are no different in their rulings against individual taxpayers. In this

paper, we consider time series variation in the composition of the US Tax Court, the venue

where most challenges to corporate tax planning are decided.

16

The collective evidence above suggests that economic policy uncertainty matters to investors,

and that tax enforcement and judicial ideology are particularly relevant tax policy instruments

that affect the government’s claim to firm cash flows through their targeted impact on firms

engaged in more tax planning (and hence more likely subject to enforcement or to end up in

court). Not only do tax laws, enforcement efforts and judicial beliefs change over time, they can

also be explained by the political ideology of the President and macroeconomic conditions. We

consider a variety of instruments designed to capture time-varying risk that the government’s tax

policies shift against firms that engage in more aggressive tax planning: including the political

party of the President, the intensity of corporate tax enforcement, and the composition of the Tax

Court.

3.3. Caveats

Despite these arguments, the theoretical and empirical progress on understanding tax

planning cost behavior and fiscal policy motivations is still early and incomplete, making room

for a credible (and interesting) null. The basic proposition that more intensive tax planning

increases the variance of after-tax cash flows and hence firm risk is unsurprising, but whether

investors require compensation for such risk is not obvious ex ante. If tax planning risks are

driven by enforcement outcomes that are largely idiosyncratic and diversifiable, there should be

no obvious risk premium. Even if a policy-based risk premium does exist, it may be too small to

detect or may switch signs over time. Moreover, if tax planning does not change the firm’s cost

structure in a way that leads to increased financial risk—for example, if tax planning investments

are reversible in bad times or managers have other ways to hedge the downside risk of these

positions—a risk premium should not exist. We also lack a robust and well-accepted theory on

the definition and measurement of tax planning risk, in part due to its correlation with business

17

risk and the interdependence of tax strategies. Ultimately, we adopt accrual-based effective tax

rates because they perform the best at predicting future settlements with the tax authority. With

that in mind, the growing importance of tax planning risk to regulators and practitioners suggests

a clear demand for evidence on the apparent economic consequences of tax planning.

4. Empirical Methodology

4.1. Sample and variable definitions

The sample consists of all U.S. firms traded on NYSE, AMEX or Nasdaq with at least two

years of Compustat coverage and monthly returns available from CRSP between July of 1988

and December 2013. The sample begins in 1988 to ensure consistency in the definitions of tax

expense. Stock returns from July of year t through June of year t + 1 are matched to accounting

and industry information for the fiscal year ending in year t – 1. Market returns are based on the

value-weighted market portfolio. Industry classifications are obtained from Compustat.

Tax planning measures

Following recent research, we rely on effective tax rates to measure the tax planning

intensity. Our setting requires a measure of exposure to future government actions that affect

payoffs to tax planning policies. Prior research provides little guidance on which proxies for tax

planning capture such risk best. To select the most appropriate measure, we examine correlations

between three commonly used candidate proxies (effective tax rates, cash tax rates and book-tax

differences) and subsequent adverse outcomes associated with the firm’s tax policy (tax

settlements). We measure tax planning proxies over a three-year window ending in year t, and

look for settlements over the following three-year period as reported in mandated accounting

disclosures that begin in 2007. We summarize our findings in Table 1.

18

We find that firms with low effective tax rates (high tax planning) have significantly higher

rates of settlements with the tax authority. Surprisingly, firms with high cash tax rates (low tax

planning) also have the highest rate of settlements even after controlling for size and

profitability, suggesting that cash tax rates do a poor job picking up exposure to the types of tax

planning that are subject to ex post challenges by the tax authority. We also consider book-tax

differences—calculated as the spread between book income and grossed-up current tax expense

divided by assets—and find that it behaves similarly to cash tax rates.

Our primary tax planning measure, the effective tax rate, is defined at the industry level. We

do so to mitigate measurement error in firm-specific measures and to accommodate the inclusion

of firms with negative earnings or unreasonable tax rate proxies—these firms are typically

dropped from studies using effective tax rates proxies. The industry effective tax rate is the

median three-year effective tax rate of firms with positive pretax income before special items in

the firm’s industry. It is measured as the sum of total tax expense over the three year period

ending in year t – 1 divided by the sum of pretax income before special items over the same

period.17 The cash tax rate is defined similarly except that cash taxes paid replaces total tax

expense in the numerator. Industries are defined using the 3-digit SIC codes.

Firm characteristics

In the cross-sectional asset pricing regressions, we control for the common characteristics

associated with firm risk, including market capitalization measured at the end of June in year t,

book-to-market measured as the book value of equity (shareholders’ equity less book value of

preferred stock plus deferred taxes) divided by the market value of equity at the end of the fiscal

year, and leverage measured as total debt divided by the market value of assets (total assets less

17 The results are robust to using pretax income without adjusting for special items.

19

book value of equity plus market value of equity). We also include additional controls associated

with incentives and opportunities for tax planning, including net property plant and equipment

(PPE), balance sheet intangibles, and R&D and advertising expenditures (Dyreng, Hanlon and

Maydew 2008). We control for financial performance with EBT (earnings before taxes and

special items, scaled by assets). We also control for foreign operations, an important driver of tax

planning opportunities, by including an indicator variable equal to one when the firm reports

foreign pretax earnings. Because the existence of NOL carryforwards mitigates the value of tax

planning, we include an indicator equal to one when the firm has positive net operating loss

carryforwards at the end of the year.

4.2. Descriptive statistics and determinants of tax planning

Table 2, Panel A reports average characteristics for portfolios sorted into quintiles each year

based on effective tax rates. Firms are assigned to portfolios at the end of each June based on

their tax planning intensity measured in the prior year. Assets and market value are adjusted for

inflation. Panel A suggests key differences between high and low tax planning firms along

dimensions such as growth opportunities, R&D, fixed assets and foreign operations. To explore

these associations more formally, and to compare the drivers of effective tax rates with those of

cash tax rates, we regress the effective tax rates on firm characteristics and compare these results

to regressions using cash-based tax rates. The regressions are estimated annually using one

observation per firm. The table reports averages of the time-series of coefficient estimates and

their t-statistics.

In the first regression, high tax planning firms (those with low effective tax rates] have higher

book-to-market ratios, lower leverage, greater R&D and less advertising. They are also more

likely to have foreign income or NOL carryforwards and have greater past return volatility.

20

The results paint an intuitive picture: firms with high growth opportunities (low book-to-

market) have yet to generate taxable profits to shield while firms with high leverage have higher

effective tax rates when the tax benefits of debt (and thus marginal tax rates) are higher. Capital

intensity reduces current tax payments under the long-standing accelerated deduction regime and

affects cash tax rates, but not effective tax rates that include an accrual for the timing difference.

Firms with R&D not only benefit from tax credits, the assets created from that investment are

more mobile and generate income streams that can be shifted to lower-taxed jurisdictions. Firms

with foreign income have greater opportunities through income shifting, and a negative

association between loss carryforwards and effective tax rates can be driven by the fact that firms

with loss carryforward have lower marginal tax rates by definition.

Before continuing, we briefly consider the explanatory power of industry membership in

determining firm-level tax planning, a key consideration of our use of industry proxies for firm-

level tax planning risks. Panel C of Table 2 reports incremental adjusted R-squared values from

regressions of firm-level effective tax rates on year dummies, industry dummies and firm

controls. Industry effects increase explanatory power by 120% for effective tax rates (from

4.09% to 9.00%) and 197% for cash tax rates (from 3.55% to 10.54%), both relative to year

effects alone. Once year and industry effects are included, firm-specific controls contribute just

11.2% to effective tax rate variation (from 9% to 10.01%) and 27.6% to cash tax rate variation

(from 10.54% to 13.45%). Industry membership explains tax planning proxies relatively well

and avoids the problems inherent in using firm-specific measures described earlier.

4.3. Cross-sectional regressions of returns on tax planning

To test whether tax planning intensity is able to predict returns, we first estimate Fama-

MacBeth regressions of monthly stock returns on industry effective tax rates and firm

21

characteristics (e.g. Fama and French 1992). Table 3 reports average coefficients from the

monthly cross-sectional regressions and the t-statistics corresponding to the time-series

distribution of these coefficients. Effective tax rates have a statistically significant association

with returns. The coefficients on the effective tax rate reported in the first three columns are

statistically significant at conventional levels. In column (2), reducing the effective tax rate by

ten percentage points (from 35% to 25%) is associated with a 3.74% higher stock return

(annualized) after controlling for book-to-market, size and leverage (0.312 coeff. x 0.1 ETR

change x 12 months), and 2.24% when the full complement of control variables are included

(col. 3).

4.4. Evidence from portfolio returns

The cross-sectional tests suggest that tax planning intensity can explain future stock returns.

In this section, we examine returns on portfolios formed on the basis of effective tax rates.

Stocks are assigned to quintile portfolios at the end of June in year t based on the tax planning

measure from year t – 1. This timing ensures that public information about tax planning activity

is impounded in price prior to the measurement of stock returns. The portfolios are re-balanced

monthly to incorporate stock delistings. When a stock delists, we include the delisting return in

the portfolio return calculation. Missing delisting returns are substituted with average delisting

returns from Shumway (1997) and Shumway and Warther (1999).

Table 4 reports average returns on tax planning portfolios. We estimate returns in excess of

the risk-free rate, as well as alphas—intercepts from the time-series regressions of excess returns

on risk factors. The one-factor model includes excess return on the market, the three-factor

model includes the market, size and book-to-market factors, and the four-factor model includes

the market, size, book-to-market and momentum factors. All factor series are obtained from

22

Kenneth French’s website. The last column contains returns on the hedge portfolio that is long

(short) in the quintile of stocks with low (high) effective tax rates.

The portfolio returns in Table 4 are almost monotonically decreasing along effective tax rate

portfolios. The excess returns, three- and four-factor alphas on hedge portfolios based on

effective tax rates are statistically significant. The average alpha from the three-factor model

amounts to 37 basis points per month (4.4% annually) (t = 2.55), while the average alpha from

the four-factor model amounts to 30 basis points per month (3.6% annually) (t = 2.01).

These results suggest limited evidence of a tax planning-based risk premium. Of course, if

the t-statistic cutoff for statistical significance were closer to 3.0 to account for the long history

of risk factor tests as suggested by Harvey, Liu and Zhu (2014), these results would effectively

disappear, suggesting no link between tax planning intensity and priced risk. In the following

section, we consider the role of firm size, and time-series variation in tax planning premiums.

4.5. Sensitivity tests

Time-series variation in risk premiums.

The tax planning-induced systematic risk may be stronger in some periods than in others. For

example, there is a significant increase in the proportion of IRS resources devoted to criminal

investigations and in the number of corporate tax audits during the Democratic presidential

administrations (Bagchi 2015). If Democratic administrations are perceived by the market as

being more determined to curtail tax planning opportunities (through legislated tax policy,

appointments to the Treasury Department, enforcement budgets and mandates and so on), and

political interest in tax law depends on broader economic conditions (Romer and Romer 2006;

Pastor and Veronesi 2013), then firms with more intensive tax planning should be exposed to

more policy risk during those administrations.

23

Table 5, Panel A reports the average coefficients from monthly cross-sectional regressions of

returns on tax planning proxies and firm controls, where regressions are estimated separately

across months in which either a Democrat or Republican held the presidency. The results suggest

a significant premium on tax planning firms with Democratic presidents. In Column 5 of Panel

B, a reduction in the effective tax rate from 35% to 25% is associated with a 31 basis point per

month (3.72% annually) higher return during Democratic presidencies (p-value < 0.01) and

insignificant returns during Republican presidencies.

Table 6 reports the returns on quintile portfolios, partitioned into periods with Democratic

and Republican presidencies. The results support the cross-sectional evidence. The industry

effective tax rate is significantly associated with future returns during Democratic presidencies,

but not during Republican presidencies. Using equal weighted returns in Panel A, The average

hedge portfolio alpha from the four-factor model amounts to 63 basis points per month (7.56%

annually) (t = 2.87).

We also build on the findings in Staudt, Epstein, and Wiedenbeck (2006) who show that

Supreme Court ideology (liberal vs. conservative) affects the likelihood of a pro-government

ruling in corporate tax cases. Because most tax cases involving federal income tax issues are

heard by the United States Tax Court, we focus on variation in the political ideology of the tax

court judges over time. Because it is more difficult to measure the ideology of specific Tax Court

judges, we look to the appointment date. Tax Court judges are appointed by the President and

confirmed by the Senate. They serve 15-year terms after which they remain on as senior judges.

Each year, we identify the fraction of all active Tax Court judges appointed by Democratic

presidents. We sort the sample into periods of relatively high and low fractions democratic

judges. In Table 5, Panel B we report the results from cross-sectional regressions and find that

24

high tax planning firms have higher returns in periods where Democrat-appointed judges make

up a larger fraction of the Tax Court. This effect, however, disappears when the full set of

controls is included in column 5. We find similar results using hedge portfolio returns, with a

hedge return of 51 basis points per month (t = 1.92) when Democrat-appointed judges dominate

the tax court.

Finally, we turn to the impact of time-series variation in IRS enforcement. If tax enforcement

priorities transmit to the variation in reported audit rates, and if these priorities can be expected

to impact high-tax planning firms disproportionately, we expect to find that expected returns of

high tax planning will increase when tax enforcement ramps up. We measure enforcement as the

likelihood of a tax return audit for all firms above $10 million in assets as reported in the Internal

Revenue Service Data Book, adjusting for time trends. The results from cross-sectional

regressions estimated across periods of high and low enforcement are reported in Table 5, Panel

C, and indicate that high tax planning firms do indeed earn higher returns, but only during

periods when tax enforcement is low. We find similar results using hedge portfolio returns in

Panel C of Table 6.

This apparently anomalous result has a potentially simple explanation. The market learns

from the IRS disclosure that the probability of an audit falls and infers (correctly) that high tax

planning firms will keep more of the tax cash flows than expected. The prices for these firms are

immediately adjusted upward, even if there is no information about penalties for particular firms

yet.

Firm size.

The findings reported are sensitive to portfolio weighting—the equal-weighted returns are

significantly associated with industry effective tax rates. However, with the general exception of

25

time-series cuts on ideology of the President and Tax Court, value-weighted returns generally are

not. Since small firms have a larger relative influence on equal-weighted returns, the results

likely depend on size. In Table 7, we estimate value-weighted returns to tax planning portfolios

within size quintiles. Portfolios are formed by sequentially sorting stocks into quintiles based on

size and then, within each size partition, into quintiles based on tax planning. Size is the

beginning-of-the-month market value of equity. For convenience, only alphas from the one-

factor and three-factor models are reported. Results for other models are similar. The results

suggest a significant premium to high tax planning that is concentrated among smaller firms.

Within the lowest size quintile, the alphas for hedge portfolios that are long (short) in low tax

(high tax) amount to 79 basis points per month using the three-factor model across the entire

time period and are statistically significant at conventional levels (t = 4.09). The hedge returns

drop as firm size increases, with hedge returns positive but insignificant in the largest two

quintiles.

One possibility is that small firms, because they lack scale and complexity, have less

diversified tax strategies than large, complex firms. For a given tax planning intensity, this could

increase exposure to adverse consequences of government actions more for small firms.

Alternatively, there is evidence to suggest small firms are less likely to lobby because of high

fixed costs. To the extent larger firms can better insulate themselves from adverse tax policy

changes through political influence, this could explain the variation across size. Finally, large

firms may have less scope for exposure to tax policy risk due to the fact that that they are often

already under continuous audit.

26

4.6. Caveats

This study sheds light on the economic tradeoffs faced by managers in developing and

implementing tax strategy, but important caveats remain. First, any study in this area suffers

from a lack of detailed information about the firm’s tax planning; empirical examinations of tax

planning are contaminated by complexity and aggregation that can yield only limited inferences.

Thus, it is not clear precisely how tax planning changes the behavior of tax costs. Second, we

lack a well-accepted theory on the political economy of tax legislation, enforcement and

interpretation, how it responds to economic conditions and whether it affects firms as a function

of their stance against the tax authority. Like the large body of research on the organizational

determinants of asset prices, the theoretical predictions behind a tax planning risk factor are

largely ad hoc. Third, to the extent tax planning proxies are correlated with a risk factor we have

not controlled for, or if stocks are inefficiently priced with respect to the tax planning proxy we

measure, the inferences will be biased.

5. Conclusion

This study tackles a question of growing interest in political, practitioner and academic

circles: the capital market implications of tax planning intensity. We focus on the potential for

tax planning to induce risk, specifically risk that increases investors’ expected returns. While tax

planning is likely to increase cash flow volatility—and should do so mechanically—whether it

has any effect on expected returns and managers’ valuation of tax planning investments is an

open question. Tax legislation, tax enforcement efforts and judicial tax decisions vary over time

and appear to depend on political ideology. For tax planning to increase priced risk, it must be

the case that tax planning exposes the firm to greater risk from adverse tax policy changes that

systematically work against high tax planning firms.

27

The results in this paper provide some support for a tax-planning based risk premium in stock

returns. We employ accrual-based effective tax rates to measure tax planning following our

evidence that such tax rates capture the types of tax planning risk we are most interested in.

Using realized stock returns consistent with empirical asset pricing research and industry tax

planning proxies to mitigate measurement error and sample selection issues, we find that tax

planning risk premiums are concentrated in small firms and are largest during Democratic

presidencies. This evidence is broadly consistent with the recent findings that fiscal policy

uncertainty is priced, in particular among firms with more exposure to a change in fiscal policy.

The potential for economically significant tax planning-based risk effects appears to be an item

of growing importance on the agendas of corporate decision makers, monitors and regulators.

The evidence here suggests that boards and managers should primarily focus on the expected

incremental cash flows from tax planning, and under certain circumstances, consider the

potential for an impact on the discount rate.

28

References

Armstrong, C., Blouin, J., Jagolinzer, A., Larcker, D., 2015. Corporate governance, incentives,

and tax avoidance. Journal of Accounting and Economics 60, 1-17.

Armstrong, C., Blouin, J., Larcker, D., 2012. The incentives for tax planning. Journal of

Accounting and Economics 53, 391 - 411.

Bagchi, S., 2015. The political economy of tax enforcement: A look at the IRS from 1978-2010.

Journal of Public Policy, Forthcoming.

Baker, S., Bloom, N., Davis, S., 2012. Measuring economic policy uncertainty. Stanford

University, working paper.

Barth, M., Konchitchki, Y., Landsman, W., 2013. Cost of capital and earnings transparency.

Journal of Accounting and Economics 55, 206-224.

Belo, F., Gala, V., Li, J., 2013. Government spending, political cycles and the cross-section of

stock returns. Journal of Financial Economics 107, 305-324.

Boutchkova, M., Doshi, H., Durnev, A., Molchanaov, A., 2012. Precarious politics and return

volatility. Review of Financial Studies 25, 1111-1154.

Brennan, T., Epstein, L., Staudt, N., 2009. Economic trends and judicial outcomes: a

macrotheory of the court. Duke Law Journal 58, 1191-1230.

Carhart, M., 1997. On persistence in mutual fund performance. Journal of Finance 52, 57-82.

Chi, S., Pincus, M., Teoh, S.H., 2014. Mispricing of book-tax differences and the trading

behavior of short sellers and insiders. The Accounting Review 89, 511-543

Cloyd, B., Mills, L., Weaver, C., 2003. Firm valuation effects of the expatriation of US

corporations to tax-haven countries. Journal of the American Taxation Association 25, 87-

109.

Core, J., Guay, W., Verdi, R., 2008. Is accruals quality a priced risk factor? Journal of

Accounting and Economics 46, 2-22.

Croce, M., Kung, H., Nguyen, T., Schmid, L., 2012. Fiscal policies and asset prices. Review of

Financial Studies

Crocker, K., Slemrod, J., 2005. Corporate tax evasion with agency costs. Journal of Public

Economics 89, 1593-1610.

Daniel, K., Grinblatt, M., Titman, S., Wermers, R., 1997. Measuring mutual fund performance

with characteristic-based benchmarks. Journal of Finance 52, 1035-1058.

29

Desai, M., Dharmapala, D., 2006. Corporate tax avoidance and high powered incentives. Journal

of Financial Economics 79, 145-179.

Desai, M., Dharmapala, D., 2009. Corporate tax avoidance and firm value. Review of Economics

and Statistics 91, 537-546.

Desai, M., Dyck, A., Zingales, L., 2007. Theft and taxes. Journal of Financial Economics 84,

591–623.

Desai, M., Hines, J., 2002. Expectations and expatriations: tracing the causes and consequences

of corporate inversions. National Tax Journal 55, 409–440.

Dyreng, S., Hanlon, M., Maydew, E., 2008. Long-run corporate tax avoidance. The Accounting

Review 83, 61–82.

Ernst and Young, 2014. Bridging the divide: highlights from the 2014 tax risk and controversy

survey.

Fama, E., French, K., 1992. The cross-section of expected stock returns. Journal of Finance 47,

427-465.

Fama, E., French, K., 1993. Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds. Journal of

Financial Economics 33, 3-56.

Fama, E., French, K., 1997. Industry costs of equity. Journal of Financial Economics 43, 153-

193.

Francis, J. LaFond, R., Olsson, P., Schipper, K., 2005. The market pricing of accruals quality.

Journal of Accounting and Economics 39, 295-327.

Frischmann, P., Shevlin, T., Wilson, R., 2008. Economic consequences of increasing the

conformity in accounting for uncertain tax benefits. Journal of Accounting and Economics

46, 261–278.

Gallemore, J., Labro, E., 2014. The Importance of the internal information environment for tax

avoidance. Journal of Accounting and Economics, Forthcoming.

Gallemore, J., Maydew, E., Thornock, J., 2014. The reputational costs of tax avoidance.

Contemporary Accounting Research, Forthcoming.

Goh, B., Lee, J., Lim, C., Shevlin, T., 2014. The effect of corporate tax avoidance on the cost of

equity. Singapore Management University, Working paper.

Guenther, D., Matsunaga, S., Williams, B., 2013. Tax avoidance, tax aggressiveness, tax risk and

firm risk. University of Oregon, Working paper.

Hanlon, M., Heitzman, S., 2010. A review of tax research. Journal of Accounting and Economics

50, 127-178.

30

Hanlon, M., Laplante, S., Shevlin, T., 2005. Evidence for the possible information loss of

conforming book income and taxable income. Journal of Law and Economics 48, 407-442.

Hanlon, M., Slemrod, J., 2009. What does tax aggressiveness signal?: Evidence from stock price

reactions to news about tax shelter involvement. Journal of Public Economics 93, 126–141.

Harvey, C., Liu, Y., Zhu, H., 2014. …And the cross-section of expected returns. Duke

University, Working paper.

Henry, E., 2014. The information content of tax expense: A discount rate explanation. University

of Tennessee, Working paper.

Henry, E., Sansing, R., 2014. Data truncation bias and the mismeasurement of corporate tax

avoidance. Dartmouth College, Working paper.

Hou, K., Robinson, D., 2006. Industry concentration and average stock returns. Journal of

Finance 61, 1927-1956.

Hutchens, M., Rego, S., 2013. Tax risk and the cost of equity capital. Indiana University,

Working Paper.

Jensen, M., 1968. The performance of mutual funds in the period 1945-1964. Journal of Finance

23, 389-416.

Kim, J., Li, Y., Zhang, L., 2011. Corporate tax avoidance and stock price crash risk: Firm-level

analysis. Journal of Financial Economics 100, 639-662.

Koester, A., 2011. Investor valuation of tax avoidance through uncertain tax positions.

Georgetown University, Working Paper.

Koester, A., Lim, S., Vigeland, R., 2014. The effect of tax-related material weaknesses in

internal controls on the market valuation of unrecognized tax benefits. Journal of the

American Taxation Association, Forthcoming.

Larsen, R., 2011. Communicating with the board of directors on taxes. The Tax Executive (July-

August), 241-245.

Lev, B., 1974. On the association between operating leverage and risk. Journal of Financial and

Quantitative Analysis 9, 627–641.

Levin, J., Petrini, K., Smith, L., White, T., 2006. The view from above; reactions of audit

committees to tax risks. Taxes, the Tax Magazine 84, 95-105.

Mills, L., Erickson, M., Maydew, E., 1998. Investments in tax planning. Journal of the American

Taxation Association 20, 1-20.

Neubig, T., Sangha, B., 2004. Tax risk and strong corporate governance. Tax Executive 56, 114-

119.

31

Novy-Marx, R., 2011. Operating leverage. Review of Finance 15, 103-134.

Pastor, L., Veronesi, P., 2013. Political uncertainty and risk premia. Journal of Financial

Economics 110, 520-545.

Rego, S., Wilson, R., 2012. Equity risk incentives and corporate tax aggressiveness. Journal of

Accounting Research 50, 775-810

Robinson, L., Schmidt, A., 2013. Firm and investor responses to uncertain tax benefit

disclosures. Journal of the American Taxation Association 35, 85-120.

Romer, C., Romer, D., 2010. The macroeconomic effects of tax changes: estimates based on a

new measure of fiscal shocks. American Economic Review 100.3, 763-801

Shevlin, T., Urcan, O., Vasvari, F., 2013. Corporate tax avoidance and public debt costs.

London Business School, Working paper.

Shumway, T., 1997. The delisting bias in CRSP data. Journal of Finance 52, 327–340.

Shumway, T., Warther, V. A., 1999. The delisting bias in CRSP’s NASDAQ data and its

implications for the size effect. Journal of Finance 54, 2361–2379.

Staudt, N., Epstein, L., Wiedenbeck, P., 2006. The ideological component of judging in the

taxation context. Washington University Law Review 84, 1797-1821.

Thomas, J., Zhang, F., 2014. Valuation of tax expense. Review of Accounting Studies 19, 1436-

1467.

Wilson, R., 2009. An examination of corporate tax shelter participants. The Accounting Review

84, 969-999.

32

Figure 1

Do tax planning proxies explain future tax settlements?

0.30

0.32

0.34

0.36

0.38

0.40

0.42

0.44

Low Tax Planning High Tax Planning

Pro

bab

ilit

y o

f F

utu

re S

ettl

emen

t

Probability of settlement with tax authority as a function of

prior tax planning

Effective Tax Rate Cash Tax RAte Book-Tax Difference

33

Table 1 – Tax proxies and the probability of settlement This table provides statistics on the frequency of future tax settlements for firms as a function of their effective

tax rates. Every year, we sort firms independently into terciles based on their average ROA and average total

assets over the three year period ending in year t. Within each of the nine resulting groups, firms are further

sorted into terciles based on their effective tax rate, cash tax rate or book-tax difference measured over the same

three year period. For each tercile of the tax proxy over the three year period starting in t + 1, we identify the

fraction of firms with a settlement and with a settlement amount (as a percentage of assets) that exceeds 50% of

the reported settlements over the three years. The results are reported below and include results for a two-way

sort on cash and effective tax rates.

Panel A: Rank Correlations Between Tax Proxies

Cash tax rate -[Book – tax] Current tax rate

Effective tax rate 0.421 0.386 0.487

Cash tax rate 0.601 0.707

-[Book – tax] 0.818

Panel B: Probability of future tax enforcement conditional on tax avoidance proxy

Effective tax rate

Median

Effective tax rate Pr(Settle) Pr(HiSettle)

Low 0.217 0.413 0.326

Medium 0.334 0.442 0.313

High 0.382 0.371 0.251

Low – High [t-stat]

0.042 [2.59] 0.075 [5.05]

Cash tax rate

Median

Cash tax rate Pr(Settle) Pr(HiSettle)

Low 0.111 0.338 0.261

Medium 0.267 0.437 0.311

High 0.375 0.434 0.297

Low – High [t-stat]

-0.096 [-6.11] -0.036 [-2.50]

-[Book – Tax]

Median

-[Book – Tax] Pr(Settle) Pr(HiSettle)

Low -0.055 0.331 0.257

Medium -0.021 0.411 0.295

Low 0.002 0.417 0.282

Low – High [t-stat]

-0.086 [-5.76] -0.025 [-1.82]

Panel C: Pr(Settle) as a function of effective and cash tax rates

Effective tax rate

Low – High

Cash tax rate Low Medium High [t-stat]

Low 0.377 0.372 0.281 0.096 [3.02]

Medium 0.473 0.469 0.361 0.112 [3.84]

High 0.443 0.472 0.414 0.029 [1.00]

Low - High -0.066 -0.100 -0.133

34

Table 2 – Descriptive statistics Panel A reports average values within quartiles of tax planning by effective tax rate. Panel B reports the results of

annual regressions of the tax planning proxy on firm-level characteristics. The time-series average and t-statistic

of that average are reported. Panel C reports the incremental explanatory power of year and industry effects in

explaining firm level effective tax rates. The sample begins with fiscal years ending in 1987 for effective tax

rates and 1990 for cash tax rates. The effective tax rate is the average three-year effective tax rate of profitable

firms in the firm’s 3-digit industry where effective tax rate is the sum of total tax expense over three years divided

by the sum of pretax income before special items. The cash tax rate is defined similarly except that cash taxes

paid is in the numerator. Assets is total book assets, market value of equity is calculated at the end of the fiscal

year; both are adjusted for inflation. Book-to-Market is the book value of equity (shareholders’ equity less book

value of preferred stock plus deferred taxes) divided by the market value of equity at the end of the fiscal year.

Market leverage is total debt divided by the market value of assets (total assets less book value of equity plus

market value of equity). PPE is net property plant and equipment. Intangibles is the total intangibles on the

balance sheet. R&D is research and development expense. Advertising is advertising expense. EBT is earnings

before taxes and special items. Pretax loss is an indicator variable equal to 1 when EBT is less than zero. Foreign

income is an indicator variable equal to one when the firm reports foreign pretax earnings. NOL Carryforward is

an indicator equal to one when the firm has positive net operating loss carryforwards at the end of the year. UTB

Reserve is the reserve for uncertain tax benefits. σ(Ret)t is the standard deviation of stock returns estimated over

the 60 month period ending in December of the calendar year in which the fiscal year ends.

Panel A: Sample averages by effective tax rate: fiscal 1987 – 2012

Quintile of effective tax rate

Q1 – Low

Tax Q2 Q3 Q4

Q5 – High

Tax

Effective tax rate 0.264 0.312 0.336 0.360 0.389

Cash tax rate 0.232 0.261 0.274 0.298 0.314

Assets ($BB) 1.829 1.655 2.022 2.159 2.222

MV Equity ($BB) 2.278 2.086 1.980 1.936 2.300

Book-to-Market 0.617 0.581 0.597 0.685 0.710

Debt / MV Assets 0.285 0.268 0.290 0.356 0.374

PPE / Assets 0.275 0.230 0.234 0.281 0.308

Intangibles / Assets 0.091 0.102 0.117 0.120 0.120

R&D / Assets 0.088 0.092 0.062 0.025 0.009

Advertising / Assets 0.008 0.011 0.014 0.018 0.019

EBT / Assets -0.019 -0.006 0.020 0.046 0.059

Pretax Loss (0,1) 0.339 0.285 0.234 0.190 0.165

Foreign Income (0,1) 0.410 0.389 0.388 0.350 0.255

NOL Carryforward (0,1) 0.397 0.381 0.362 0.312 0.278

UTB Reserve / Assets 0.019 0.016 0.014 0.011 0.007

σ(Ret)t 0.171 0.166 0.161 0.145 0.140

35

Table 2 (cont’d) – Descriptive statistics

Panel B: Determinants of tax planning

Dependent Variable = Effective tax rate (%) Cash tax rate (%)

Coeff. [t-stat] Coeff. [t-stat]

Intercept 33.71 [48.91] 31.30 [41.76]

ln(Assets) 0.04 [1.76] -0.08 [-3.51]

ln(Book-to-Market) -0.32 [-7.03] -0.20 [-3.07]

Debt / MV Assets 2.09 [12.31] 2.99 [10.27]

PPE / Assets -0.35 [-0.56] -7.31 [-12.25]

Intangibles / Assets 1.75 [6.50] -0.30 [-0.68]

R&D / Assets -6.62 [-6.70] -7.41 [-12.86]

Advertising / Assets 7.94 [10.45] 14.78 [9.73]

EBT / Assets 0.37 [1.06] -0.81 [-2.76]

Foreign income (0,1) -1.32 [-13.48] -0.93 [-6.31]

NOL carryforward (0,1) -0.47 [-6.94] -0.61 [-7.79]

σ(Ret)t -5.12 [-9.15] -9.97 [-9.95]

Average R2 11.67% 10.45%

Average firms/year 2,810 2,874

Number of years 26 23

Panel C: Explanatory power of industry membership for firm-level tax planning proxies

Dependent variable = Effective tax rate Cash tax rate

Adj. R2 Increase Adj. R2 Increase

Industry effects alone 5.09% 7.25%

Year effects alone 4.09% 3.55%

+ Industry Effects 9.00% 120.05% 10.54% 196.90%

+ Firm Controls 10.01% 11.22% 13.45% 27.61%

N 51,485 47,165

36

Table 3 – Fama-MacBeth regressions of monthly stock returns on tax planning This table reports the results from monthly cross-sectional regressions of firm stock returns on tax planning

(effective tax rate) for non-financial and non-regulated firms. Effective tax rate is defined at the industry-year level

as the average three-year effective tax rate of profitable firms in the firm’s 3-digit industry where the effective tax

rate is the sum of total tax expense over three years divided by the sum of pretax income before special items.

Market value of equity is calculated at the end of the fiscal year. Book-to-Market is the book value of equity

(shareholders’ equity less book value of preferred stock plus deferred taxes) divided by the market value of equity at

the end of the fiscal year. Debt / MV Assets is total debt divided by the market value of assets (total assets less book

value of equity plus market value of equity). Assets is total book assets. PPE is net property plant and equipment.

Intangibles is the total intangibles on the balance sheet. R&D is research and development expense. Advertising is

advertising expense. EBT is earnings before taxes and special items. Foreign income is an indicator variable equal to

one when the firm reports foreign pretax earnings. Average of monthly coefficients reported; t-statistic of the time-

series average in brackets.

Dependent variable = Ri (%)

(1) (2) (3)

Effective tax rate -3.00

[-2.50]

-3.12

[-3.10]

-1.87

[-2.40]

ln(Book-to-Market) 0.33

[2.91]

0.28

[4.92]

0.32

[6.05]

ln(MVE) -0.01

[-0.17]

-0.03

[-0.64]

-0.03

[-0.79]

Debt / MV Assets -0.00

[-0.00]

0.49

[1.79]

PPE / Assets 0.08

[0.28]

Intangibles / Assets -0.44

[-2.39]

R&D / Assets 3.83

[5.71]

Advertising / Assets 1.55

[2.46]

EBT / Assets 0.52

[1.12]

1.67

[3.96]

Foreign (0,1) 0.10

[1.55]

37

Table 4 – Returns on portfolios sorted on tax planning This table reports average equal-weighted excess returns and alphas (intercepts) from the time-series regressions

of excess returns on risk factors for quintile portfolios of stocks sorted by the effective tax rate. The alphas are

from the single-factor (market), three-factor (market, size, and book-to-market) and four-factor (market, size,

book-to-market, and momentum) models. The portfolio returns are equal-weighted. The last column reports excess

returns and alphas on a hedge portfolio that is long (short) in the Low Tax (High Tax) stocks. Returns are in

monthly percentage points. t-statistics are reported in brackets.

Quintile of effective tax rate

Q1 – Low

Tax Q2 Q3 Q4

Q5 – High

Tax

Low Tax –

High Tax

R – Rf

0.95 1.00 0.82 0.68 0.62 0.32

[2.42] [2.64] [2.09] [2.10] [1.86] [1.83]

α [CAPM]

0.15 0.20 0.01 -0.01 -0.10 0.25

[0.64] [0.93] [0.03] [-0.07] [-0.56] [1.41]

α [Three factor] 0.12 0.14 0.00 -0.18 -0.25 0.37

[0.86] [0.95] [-0.02] [-1.43] [-1.96] [2.55]

α [Four factor] 0.30 0.42 0.27 0.05 0.00 0.30

[2.19] [3.33] [2.07] [0.43] [-0.01] [2.01]

38

Table 5 – Fama-MacBeth results across political ideology and tax enforcement regimes This table reports the results from monthly cross-sectional regressions of firm stock returns on industry tax planning,

in Panel A conditional on the political party of the President in office at the time returns are measured, in Panel B

conditional on the ideology of the US Tax Court judges, and in Panel C based on the relative likelihood of a tax return

audit. Tax planning is measured using an effective tax rate, defined as the average three-year effective tax rates of

profitable firms in the firm’s 3-digit industry where the effective tax rate is the sum of total tax expense over three

years divided by the sum of pretax income before special items. Panel A reports the distribution of tax rates across

administrations. Panels B reports the results for effective tax rates. Market value of equity is calculated at the end of

the fiscal year. Book-to-Market is the book value of equity (shareholders’ equity less book value of preferred stock

plus deferred taxes) divided by the market value of equity at the end of the fiscal year. Debt / MV Assets is total debt

divided by the market value of assets (total assets less book value of equity plus market value of equity). Assets is

total book assets. PPE is net property plant and equipment. Intangibles is the total intangibles on the balance sheet.

R&D is research and development expense. Advertising is advertising expense. EBT is earnings before taxes and

special items. Foreign income is an indicator variable equal to one when the firm reports foreign pretax earnings.

Average of monthly coefficients reported. *,**,*** indicate statistical significance at the 0.10, 0.05, and 0.01 levels

(two-tailed).

Panel A: Stock returns and tax planning across presidential party

Dependent variable = Ri (%)

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Dem. Rep. Dem. Rep. Dem. Rep.

Effective tax rate -5.55*** -0.45 -5.29*** -0.85 -3.13*** -0.56

ln(Book-to-Market) 0.33** 0.27* 0.30*** 0.26*** 0.34*** 0.29***

ln(MVE) 0.02 -0.04 0.03 -0.09 0.01 -0.09

Debt / MV Assets 0.31 -0.33 0.99** -0.03

PPE / Assets 0.11 0.05

Intangibles / Assets -0.72*** -0.15

R&D / Assets 4.81*** 2.81***

Advertising / Assets 1.29 1.86**

EBT / Assets -0.23 1.31** 1.24** 2.13***

Foreign (0,1) 0.19** -0.01

Panel B: Stock returns and tax planning across U.S. Tax Court ideology

Dependent variable = Ri (%)

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

High-Dem Low-Dem High-Dem Low-Dem High-Dem Low-Dem

Effective tax rate -4.26** -1.36 -4.08** -1.81* -1.31 -0.98

ln(Book-to-Market) 0.28** 0.33*** 0.33*** 0.25*** 0.38*** 0.27***

ln(MVE) -0.10 0.07 -0.10 0.03 -0.10 0.02

Debt / MV Assets -0.34 0.27 0.36** 0.55

PPE / Assets -0.07 0.18

Intangibles / Assets -0.82*** -0.13

R&D / Assets 5.14*** 2.77***

Advertising / Assets 2.01** 1.11

EBT / Assets -0.01 1.00** 1.60** 1.75***

Foreign (0,1) 0.16 0.19

39

Table 5 (cont’d) – Fama-MacBeth results across regimes

Panel C: Stock returns and tax planning across tax enforcement regimes

Dependent variable = Ri (%)

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

High-Enf Low-Enf High-Enf Low-Enf High-Enf Low-Enf

Effective tax rate 0.15 -6.45** -0.59 -6.00*** 0.24 -2.61*

ln(Book-to-Market) 0.29** 0.32* 0.23*** 0.34*** 0.25*** 0.39***

ln(MVE) 0.12** -0.14 0.06 -0.12 0.05 -0.13*

Debt / MV Assets 0.02 0.00 0.25 0.71

PPE / Assets 0.22 -0.11

Intangibles / Assets -0.03 -0.89***

R&D / Assets 2.58*** 5.22***

Advertising / Assets 0.49 2.60**

EBT / Assets 1.39*** -0.33 2.12*** 1.24*

Foreign (0,1) 0.02 0.20**

40

Table 6 –Political ideology and tax enforcement This table reports average portfolio excess returns and alphas estimated separately for the years when a

Democratic or a Republican president was in office (Panel A), the proportion of Democratic administration

appointees among the US Tax Court judges was high or low (Panel B), or tax audit rates were low or high (Panel

C). The alphas are from the single-factor (market), three-factor (market, size, and book-to-market) and four-factor

(market, size, book-to-market, and momentum) models. The last column reports excess returns and alphas on a

hedge portfolio that is long (short) in the Low Tax (High Tax) stocks. Returns are in monthly percentage points. t-

statistics are reported in brackets.

Panel A: Portfolio returns across presidential party

Quintile of effective tax rate

Q1 – Low

Tax Q2 Q3 Q4

Q5 – High

Tax

Low Tax –

High Tax

Democratic

R – Rf 1.56 1.51 1.26 1.00 0.95 0.62

[2.82] [2.96] [2.38] [2.27] [2.11] [2.11]

α [CAPM] 0.14 0.07 -0.21 -0.27 -0.37 0.51

[0.37] [0.24] [-0.65] [-1.11] [-1.57] [1.70]

α [3F] 0.33 0.19 -0.03 -0.29 -0.39 0.72

[1.53] [0.92] [-0.14] [-1.52] [-2.12] [3.26]

α [4F] 0.50 0.45 0.16 -0.01 -0.13 0.63

[2.42] [2.57] [0.94] [-0.06] [-0.96] [2.87]

Republican

R – Rf 0.30 0.46 0.37 0.35 0.28 0.02

[0.55] [0.83] [0.63] [0.74] [0.57] [0.10]

α [CAPM] 0.23 0.39 0.29 0.29 0.22 0.01

[0.79] [1.27] [0.87] [1.12] [0.80] [0.06]

α [3F] 0.01 0.12 0.06 -0.06 -0.10 0.11

[0.05] [0.61] [0.27] [-0.36] [-0.60] [0.61]

α [4F] 0.15 0.35 0.35 0.04 0.06 0.09

[0.84] [1.94] [1.85] [0.28] [0.37] [0.49]

Panel B: Portfolio returns across Tax Court ideology

High Percentage Judges Appointed by Democratic Presidents

R – Rf 1.40 1.35 1.26 0.96 0.89 0.51

[2.27] [2.39] [1.99] [2.23] [1.93] [1.56]

α [CAPM] 0.30 0.28 0.10 0.15 0.00 0.30

[0.71] [0.78] [0.23] [0.56] [-0.00] [0.93]

α [3F] 0.25 0.15 0.16 -0.25 -0.35 0.61

[1.01] [0.59] [0.55] [-1.19] [-1.59] [2.35]

α [4F] 0.55 0.59 0.64 0.08 0.04 0.51

[2.34] [2.82] [2.64] [0.45] [0.22] [1.92]

Low Percentage Judges Appointed by Democratic Presidents

R – Rf 0.53 0.66 0.39 0.40 0.39 0.14

[1.13] [1.35] [0.86] [0.86] [0.83] [0.94]

α [CAPM] -0.01 0.10 -0.14 -0.14 -0.15 0.15

[-0.03] [0.44] [-0.68] [-0.69] [-0.74] [0.96]

α [3F] 0.01 0.12 -0.13 -0.14 -0.16 0.17

[0.06] [0.77] [-1.05] [-1.06] [-1.15] [1.13]

α [4F] 0.09 0.25 -0.03 -0.01 -0.03 0.13

[0.64] [1.79] [-0.25] [-0.10] [-0.28] [0.86]

41

Table 6 (cont’d) Panel C: Portfolio returns across tax enforcement regimes

Quintile of effective tax rate

Q1 – Low

Tax Q2 Q3 Q4

Q5 – High

Tax

Low Tax –

High Tax

Low Enforcement

R – Rf 1.06 0.93 0.71 0.43 0.45 0.61

[1.70] [1.56] [1.11] [0.86] [0.88] [2.01]

α [CAPM] 0.50 0.36 0.11 -0.05 -0.05 0.55

[1.26] [1.05] [0.29] [-0.17] [-0.17] [1.82]

α [3F] 0.42 0.25 0.06 -0.27 -0.25 0.67

[1.74] [1.00] [0.23] [-1.29] [-1.14] [2.90]

α [4F] 0.66 0.61 0.43 0.04 0.09 0.57

[2.98] [3.01] [1.93] [0.24] [0.50] [2.46]

High Enforcement

R – Rf 0.83 1.06 0.92 0.94 0.82 0.01

[1.92] [2.46] [2.20] [2.39] [2.09] [0.05]

α [CAPM] -0.24 0.01 -0.11 -0.05 -0.18 -0.06

[-1.05] [0.03] [-0.49] [-0.28] [-0.95] [-0.36]

α [3F] -0.14 0.12 0.01 -0.03 -0.16 0.03

[-1.08] [0.91] [0.07] [-0.32] [-1.66] [0.16]

α [4F] -0.11 0.21 0.06 0.00 -0.11 -0.01

[-0.87] [1.60] [0.56] [0.02] [-1.11] [-0.04]

42

Table 7 – Returns on portfolios sorted by tax planning and size This table reports average value-weighted excess returns and alphas for portfolios of stocks sorted by industry tax

planning and size. The stocks are first sorted into quintiles based on the market value of equity at the beginning of

the month and then, within each size quintile, into quintiles based on the tax planning measure. The alphas are

from the single-factor (market], three-factor (market, size, and book-to-market] and four-factor (market, size,

book-to-market, and momentum] models. The last column reports excess returns and alphas on a hedge portfolio

that is long (short] in the Low Tax (High Tax] stocks. Returns are in monthly percentage points. t-statistics are

reported in brackets.

Quintile of effective tax rate

Size quintile Q1 – Low Tax Q2 Q3 Q4 Q5 – High Tax Low Tax –

High Tax

α [CAPM]

1 - Small 0.38 0.10 0.20 -0.09 -0.32 0.70

[1.10] [0.29] [0.56] [-0.33] [-1.04] [3.46]

2 0.18 0.01 -0.12 0.03 -0.14 0.32

[0.58] [0.05] [-0.41] [0.10] [-0.58] [1.40]

3 0.08 -0.07 -0.11 -0.08 -0.13 0.22

[0.29] [-0.27] [-0.40] [-0.37] [-0.60] [0.93]

4 -0.09 0.26 -0.08 0.11 -0.02 -0.07

[-0.38] [1.32] [-0.40] [0.66] [-0.14] [-0.30]

5 - Large 0.01 0.06 0.00 0.15 -0.12 0.13

[0.11] [0.44] [0.04] [1.28] [-1.13] [0.81]

α [3F]

1 - Small 0.31 0.08 0.14 -0.22 -0.48 0.79

[1.08] [0.25] [0.43] [-0.90] [-1.78] [4.09]

2 0.09 -0.08 -0.20 -0.19 -0.36 0.45

[0.42] [-0.35] [-0.97] [-1.04] [-1.95] [2.19]

3 0.05 -0.10 -0.16 -0.29 -0.34 0.39

[0.33] [-0.69] [-0.99] [-2.14] [-2.26] [1.95]

4 -0.10 0.22 -0.08 -0.05 -0.18 0.07

[-0.76] [1.56] [-0.75] [-0.43] [-1.43] [0.38]

5 - Large 0.08 0.21 0.07 0.09 -0.10 0.18

[0.72] [1.54] [0.65] [0.80] [-0.95] [1.09]