Conducting Monetary Policy with a Large Balance Sheet

  • Upload
    ednyc

  • View
    2

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

Remarks byStanley FischerVice ChairmanBoard of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

Citation preview

  • For release on delivery 1:30 p.m. EST February 27, 2015

    Conducting Monetary Policy with a Large Balance Sheet

    Remarks by

    Stanley Fischer

    Vice Chairman

    Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

    at the

    2015 U.S. Monetary Policy Forum Sponsored by the University of Chicago Booth School of Business

    New York, New York

    February 27, 2015

  • Thank you. It is a great pleasure to be here to discuss some of the important

    issues facing the Federal Reserve and other central banks in conducting monetary policy

    with a large balance sheet. I will focus on two main sets of issues that the Fed has faced

    and will continue to face for some time. The first involves our ongoing assessment of the

    effects of the asset purchases. The second concerns policy normalization in the presence

    of a very large balance sheet.

    To set the stage, consider the size of the Feds balance sheet over the past several

    years. Assets have risen from about $900 billion in 2006 to about $4.5 trillion today, or--

    as seen in figure 1--from 6 percent of nominal gross domestic product (GDP) to about

    26 percent of nominal GDP. The net expansion over this period reflects primarily our

    large-scale asset purchase programs.

    Of course, many other central banks have expanded their balance sheets

    substantially over recent years as well. For example, assets of the Bank of Japan have

    increased from about 20 percent of nominal GDP to more than 60 percent of nominal

    GDP over this period, and assets of the Swiss National Bank have increased from

    20 percent of nominal GDP to more than 80 percent of nominal GDP. The net increase in

    assets of the European Central Bank has so far been more modest, with assets increasing

    from less than 10 percent of nominal GDP to more than 20 percent of nominal GDP--but

    their quantitative easing (QE) program is not yet under way.

    For the remainder of my remarks, I will focus on the Fed, beginning with some

    remarks about the asset purchase programs.

  • - 2 -

    The Federal Reserve Asset Purchase Programs

    The nature of our purchase programs has changed over time. In the early

    programs--that is to say, QE1, QE2, and the program we call the MEP, or the maturity

    extension program, otherwise known as Operation Twist--the Federal Open Market

    Committee (FOMC) specified the expected quantities of assets to be acquired over a

    defined period. Early in the crisis, this strategy seemed to help bolster confidence that

    the Fed was acting aggressively to offset the tightening in credit conditions and the steep

    downturn in economic activity.

    The communication of asset purchases changed with QE3. In September 2012,

    the FOMC launched an open-ended asset purchase program in which it directed the New

    York Feds Open Market Desk to conduct purchases at an announced monthly pace until

    there was significant improvement in the outlook for the labor market. Later, the

    FOMC noted that the monthly pace of purchases was data dependent, allowing the pace

    to be revised up or down based on its assessment of progress toward its long-run

    objectives.

    Both of these types of asset purchase programs were aimed at putting downward

    pressure on long-term yields.1 Table 1 provides a summary of various studies estimated

    effects of these programs on the term premium on 10-year Treasury securities. For

    example, the decline in 10-year Treasury yields associated with the first purchase

    1 The Fed staff analysis has focused mostly on the so-called stock effects of the purchase programs--that is, persistent shifts in asset prices observed as the result of a QE program. While these stock effects are well documented in the literature, there have been relatively fewer studies of flow effects that may occur at the time of QE transactions (for example, see Stefania DAmico and Thomas B. King (2013), Flow and Stock Effects of Large-Scale Treasury Purchases: Evidence on the Importance of Local Supply, Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 108 (May), pp. 425-48, http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2012.11.007; and John Kandrac and Bernd Schlusche (2013), Flow Effects of Large-Scale Asset Purchases, Economics Letters, vol. 121 (November), pp. 330-35, http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2013.09.003).

  • - 3 -

    program is estimated to have been as large as 100 basis points. The documented effects

    associated with subsequent programs are generally smaller. These results raise the

    question of whether the marginal effect of asset purchases has declined over time. While

    that question is a valid one, our conclusion is that asset purchases over more recent years

    have provided meaningful stimulus to the economy, and continue to do so.

    Figure 2 provides a current estimate, based on Fed staff calculations, of the effect

    on the term premium on 10-year Treasury securities from the combination of all asset

    programs.2 The results suggest that the Feds balance sheet programs are currently

    depressing 10-year Treasury yields by about 110 basis points. And, with the Fed

    continuing to hold these securities, they should apply downward pressure on rates for

    some time.

    The declines in long-term yields have led to an associated drop in long-term

    borrowing costs for households and firms and higher equity valuations. Thus, the asset

    purchases have helped make financial conditions overall more accommodative and have

    provided significant stimulus for the broader economy. As shown in figure 3, a recent

    study estimates that the QE programs along with increasingly explicit forward guidance

    have reduced the unemployment rate by 1-1/4 percentage points and increased the

    inflation rate by 1/2 percentage point relative to what would have occurred in the absence

    2 The estimates shown in figure 2 are based on an extension of the work done in Ihrig, Klee, Li, Schulte, and Wei (2012). Because the term premium effect depends on both the Feds current and expected future asset holdings, most of this effect--without further unexpected policy actions--will likely wane over the next few years as the balance sheet begins to normalize. See Jane Ihrig, Elizabeth Klee, Canlin Li, Brett Schulte, and Min Wei (2012), Expectations about the Federal Reserves Balance Sheet and the Term Structure of Interest Rates, Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2012-57 (Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, July), www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/feds/2012/201257/201257pap.pdf.

  • - 4 -

    of these policies.3 Moreover, the estimates imply that these macroeconomic effects are

    only now manifesting themselves in full, reflecting the inherent lags in the monetary

    transmission mechanism. Of course, such estimates have a wide band of uncertainty

    around them.

    As is well known, a number of potential costs might be associated with QE and

    the Feds elevated balance sheet. Among these are the possibility that elevated securities

    holdings and low interest rates could pose risks to financial stability, possible effects on

    the Feds income and remittances to the U.S. Treasury, and possible difficulties in

    conducting policy normalization.4 Such potential difficulties arise because the level of

    reserve balances will be very high when the FOMC begins to raise the federal funds rate,

    and, consequently, the Federal Reserve will employ new tools, which have their own

    benefits and costs, to implement monetary policy.

    Despite these potential costs, we think that asset purchases have had a meaningful

    effect in promoting economic recovery and helping to keep inflation closer to the

    FOMCs 2 percent goal than would otherwise have been the case.

    Policy Normalization

    Turning to policy normalization, the FOMC and market participants anticipate

    that the federal funds rate will be raised sometime this year. We have for some years

    been considering ways to operate monetary policy with an elevated balance sheet.

    3 See Eric Engen, Thomas Laubach, and David Reifschneider (2015), The Macroeconomic Effects of the Federal Reserves Unconventional Monetary Policies, Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2015-005 (Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, January), http://dx.doi.org/10.17016/FEDS.2015.005. 4 Reflecting securities holdings from the asset purchases, the Federal Reserve has remitted about $500 billion to the U.S. Treasury from 2008 to 2014 and is expected to have cumulative net income from 2008 to 2025 that is far higher than would have been the case in the absence of these asset purchases.

  • - 5 -

    Prior to the financial crisis, because reserve balances outstanding averaged only

    around $25 billion, relatively minor variations in the total amount of reserves supplied by

    the Desk could move the equilibrium federal funds rate up or down. With the nearly

    $3 trillion in excess reserves today, the traditional mechanism of adjustments in the

    quantity of reserve balances to achieve the desired level of the effective federal funds rate

    may well not be feasible or sufficiently predictable.

    As discussed in the FOMCs statement on its Policy Normalization Principles and

    Plans, which was published following the September 2014 FOMC meeting, we will use

    the rate of interest paid on excess reserves (IOER) as our primary tool to move the federal

    funds rate into the target range.5 This action should encourage banks not to lend to any

    private counterparty at a rate lower than the rate they can earn on balances maintained at

    the Fed, which should put upward pressure on a range of short-term interest rates.

    Because not all institutions have access to the IOER rate, we will also use an

    overnight reverse repurchase agreement (ON RRP) facility, as needed. In an ON RRP

    operation, eligible counterparties may invest funds with the Fed overnight at a given rate.

    The ON RRP counterparties include 106 money market funds, 22 broker-dealers, 24

    depository institutions, and 12 government-sponsored enterprises, including several

    Federal Home Loan Banks, Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, and Farmer Mac. This facility

    should encourage these institutions to be unwilling to lend to private counterparties in

    money markets at a rate below that offered on overnight reverse repos by the Fed.

    5 See Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (2014), Federal Reserve Issues Statement on Policy Normalization Principles and Plans, press release, September 17, www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/monetary/20140917c.htm.

  • - 6 -

    Indeed, testing to date suggests that ON RRP operations have generally been successful

    in establishing a soft floor for money market interest rates.6

    The Fed could also employ other tools, such as term deposits issued through the

    Term Deposit Facility and term RRPs, to help drain reserves and put additional upward

    pressure on short-term interest rates. We have been testing these tools and believe they

    would help support money market rates, if needed.

    Finally, with regard to balance sheet normalization, the FOMC has indicated that

    it does not anticipate sales of agency mortgage-backed securities, and that it plans to

    normalize the size of the balance sheet primarily by ceasing reinvestment of principal

    payments on its existing securities holdings when the time comes. As illustrated in

    figure 4, cumulative repayments of principal on our existing securities holdings from now

    through the end of 2025 are projected to be about $3.2 trillion. As a result, when the

    FOMC chooses to cease reinvestments, the size of the balance sheet will naturally

    decline, with a corresponding reduction in reserve balances.

    Conclusion

    I will close by highlighting that the Feds asset purchases have been a critical

    means by which the FOMC has provided policy accommodation at the zero lower bound

    on nominal interest rates. In other words, the Fed--and other central banks--can

    implement an expansionary monetary policy even when the policy interest rate is at the

    6 Policymakers have discussed benefits and costs of an ON RRP facility. For further discussion on this topic, see, for example, the FOMC minutes for June 2014, July 2014, and January 2015 available on the Boards webpage Federal Open Market Committee: Meeting Calendars, Statements, and Minutes (2009-2015), www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/fomccalendars.htm; and Josh Frost, Lorie Logan, Antoine Martin, Patrick McCabe, Fabio Natalucci, and Julie Remache (2015), Overnight RRP Operations as a Monetary Policy Tool: Some Design Considerations, Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2015-010 (Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, February), http://dx.doi.org/10.17016/FEDS.2015.010.

  • - 7 -

    zero lower bound. The current high level of securities holdings will present some

    challenges for policy normalization, but we are confident that we have the tools necessary

    to remove accommodation at the appropriate time and at the appropriate pace.

  • Conducting Monetary Policy with a Large Balance Sheet

    Stanley Fischer

    Vice ChairmanBoard of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

    Monetary Policy ForumNew York, New YorkFebruary 27, 2015

    For release on delivery1:30 p.m. ESTFebruary 27, 2015

  • Figure 1. Central Bank Assets

  • Table 1. Empirical Studies of LSAPs

  • Figure 2. Effect of Balance Sheet Operationson the 10Year Treasury Term Premium

  • Figure 3. Estimated Effects of Unconventional Monetary Policies in the FRB/US Model

  • Figure 4. SOMA Maturities

  • ReferencesDAmico, Stefania, William English, David Lopez-Salido, and Edward Nelson (2012). The

    Federal Reserves Large-Scale Asset Purchase Programmes: Rationale and Effects,Economic Journal, vol. 122 (November), pp. F415-46.

    DAmico, Stefania, and Thomas B. King (2013). Flow and Stock Effects of Large-Scale TreasuryPurchases: Evidence on the Importance of Local Supply, Journal of Financial Economics,vol. 108 (May), pp. 425-48, http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2012.11.007.

    Engen, Eric, Thomas Laubach, and David Reifschneider (2015). The Macroeconomic Effects ofthe Federal Reserves Unconventional Monetary Policies, Finance and EconomicsDiscussion Series 2015-005 (Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal ReserveSystem, January), http://dx.doi.org/10.17016/FEDS.2015.005.

    Gagnon, Joseph, Matthew Raskin, Julie Remache, and Brian Sack (2011). The FinancialMarket Effects of the Federal Reserves Large-Scale Asset Purchases, International Journalof Central Banking, vol. 7 (March), pp. 3-43, www.ijcb.org/journal/ijcb11q1a1.pdf.

    Hamilton, James, and Jing (Cynthia) Wu (2012). The Effectiveness of Alternative MonetaryPolicy Tools in a Zero Lower Bound Environment, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking,vol. 44, pp. 3-46.

    Ihrig, Jane, Elizabeth Klee, Canlin Li, Brett Schulte, and Min Wei (2012). Expectations aboutthe Federal Reserves Balance Sheet and the Term Structure of Interest Rates, Finance andEconomics Discussion Series 2012-57 (Washington: Board of Governors of the FederalReserve System, July), www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/feds/2012/201257/201257pap.pdf.

  • References (continued)Krishnamurthy, Arvind, and Annette Vissing-Jorgensen (2011). The Effects of Quantitative

    Easing on Interest Rates: Channels and Implications for Policy, Brookings Papers onEconomic Activity, vol. 43 (Fall), pp. 215-87.

    Li, Canlin, and Min Wei (2013). Term Structure Modeling with Supply Factors and the FederalReserves Large-Scale Asset Purchase Programs, International Journal of Central Banking,vol. 9 (March), pp. 3-39, www.ijcb.org/journal/ijcb13q1a1.pdf.

    Meaning, Jack, and Feng Zhu (2011). The Impact of Recent Central Bank Asset PurchaseProgrammes, BIS Quarterly Review (December), pp. 73-83,www.bis.org/publ/qtrpdf/r_qt1112h.pdf.

    Meaning, Jack, and Feng Zhu (2012), The Impact of Federal Reserve Asset PurchaseProgrammes: Another Twist, BIS Quarterly Review (March), pp. 23-30,www.bis.org/publ/qtrpdf/r_qt1203e.pdf.

    Richard, Scott F., and Richard Roll (1989). Prepayments on Fixed-Rate Mortgage-BackedSecurities, Journal of Portfolio Management, vol. 15 (Spring), pp. 73-82.

    Swanson, Eric T. (2011). Lets Twist Again: A High-Frequency Event-Study Analysis ofOperation Twist and Its Implications for QE2, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity,vol. 42 (Spring), pp. 151-207.

    The Federal Reserve Asset Purchase ProgramsPolicy NormalizationConclusionfischer20150227a1.pdfConducting Monetary Policy with a Large Balance SheetFigure 1. Central Bank AssetsTable 1. Empirical Studies of LSAPsFigure 2. Effect of Balance Sheet Operationson the 10Year Treasury Term PremiumFigure 3. Estimated Effects of Unconventional Monetary Policies in the FRB/US ModelSlide Number 6Slide Number 7Slide Number 8