28
Chapter 7 Efficiency and Exchange

Chapter 7 Efficiency and Exchange. Markets are usually a good way to organize economic activity Markets don’t always provide socially efficient outcomes

  • View
    215

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Chapter 7 Efficiency and Exchange. Markets are usually a good way to organize economic activity Markets don’t always provide socially efficient outcomes

Chapter 7

Efficiency and Exchange

Page 2: Chapter 7 Efficiency and Exchange. Markets are usually a good way to organize economic activity Markets don’t always provide socially efficient outcomes

• Markets are usually a good way to organize economic activity

• Markets don’t always provide socially efficient outcomes

• Government intervention can in some cases improve market efficiency

The Domain of Markets

Page 3: Chapter 7 Efficiency and Exchange. Markets are usually a good way to organize economic activity Markets don’t always provide socially efficient outcomes

• Pareto efficient (or just efficient)– Is a situation where there is no change possible

that will help some people without harming others

– Exists when an economy has reached a point where reallocating resources must harm one in order to help another

– Occurs at equilibrium of perfectly competitive markets

Market Equilibrium and Efficiency

Page 4: Chapter 7 Efficiency and Exchange. Markets are usually a good way to organize economic activity Markets don’t always provide socially efficient outcomes

• Total economic surplus– The sum of all the individual economic

surpluses gained by buyers and sellers participating in the market

– Consumer Surplus– Producer Surplus

Economic Surplus

Page 5: Chapter 7 Efficiency and Exchange. Markets are usually a good way to organize economic activity Markets don’t always provide socially efficient outcomes

• Consumer Surplus– Economic surplus gained by the buyers of a product

– Measured by the difference between their reservation price and and the price they pay

• Producer Surplus– Economic surplus gained by the sellers of a product

– Measured by the difference between the price they receive and their reservation price

Surplus

Page 6: Chapter 7 Efficiency and Exchange. Markets are usually a good way to organize economic activity Markets don’t always provide socially efficient outcomes

Fig. 7.4 A Market with “Digital” Supply and Demand Curves

Page 7: Chapter 7 Efficiency and Exchange. Markets are usually a good way to organize economic activity Markets don’t always provide socially efficient outcomes

Fig. 7.5 Consumer and Producer Surplus

Page 8: Chapter 7 Efficiency and Exchange. Markets are usually a good way to organize economic activity Markets don’t always provide socially efficient outcomes

Fig. 7.6 Supply and Demand in the Market for Milk

Page 9: Chapter 7 Efficiency and Exchange. Markets are usually a good way to organize economic activity Markets don’t always provide socially efficient outcomes

Fig. 7.7 Total Economic Surplus in the Market for Milk

Page 10: Chapter 7 Efficiency and Exchange. Markets are usually a good way to organize economic activity Markets don’t always provide socially efficient outcomes

Economic Surplus in an Unregulated Market for Home Heating Oil

Figure 7.4

Page 11: Chapter 7 Efficiency and Exchange. Markets are usually a good way to organize economic activity Markets don’t always provide socially efficient outcomes

• Equilibrium price and quantity maximize the total economic surplus– Total economic surplus would be lower at any

other price and quantity combination– I.E., waste occurs at any other price and

quantity combination

Economic Surplus and Efficiency

Page 12: Chapter 7 Efficiency and Exchange. Markets are usually a good way to organize economic activity Markets don’t always provide socially efficient outcomes
Page 13: Chapter 7 Efficiency and Exchange. Markets are usually a good way to organize economic activity Markets don’t always provide socially efficient outcomes

The Waste Caused by Price Controls

Figure 7.5

Page 14: Chapter 7 Efficiency and Exchange. Markets are usually a good way to organize economic activity Markets don’t always provide socially efficient outcomes

Other Goals• An equitable (fair) income distribution is a

desirable goal for many• Efficiency should be a very important goal

– Efficiency enables us to achieve all other goals to the fullest possible extent

– Efficiency minimizes waste

• However, if the choice is between an efficient but unfair outcome and an inefficient but fair outcome, what should we do?

Page 15: Chapter 7 Efficiency and Exchange. Markets are usually a good way to organize economic activity Markets don’t always provide socially efficient outcomes

Taxes on Goods

• Reasons:– Raise revenue for government activity– Modify market outcomes

• Kinds– Specific or excise, in dollars per unit (gasoline)– Ad valorem, percent of price (sales tax)– Lump sum, (license fee)

Page 16: Chapter 7 Efficiency and Exchange. Markets are usually a good way to organize economic activity Markets don’t always provide socially efficient outcomes

Three Questions

• How does the imposition of the tax affect equilibrium price and quantity?

• Who pays the tax? Buyers or sellers?

• What is the effect of the tax on the economic surplus?

Page 17: Chapter 7 Efficiency and Exchange. Markets are usually a good way to organize economic activity Markets don’t always provide socially efficient outcomes

Effect of an Excise Tax

• Can be viewed as an addition to cost or a reduction in average revenue. Same result.

• Consider the imposition of a tax of $1 per pound on potatoes. This will increase marginal cost by $1 and raise the supply curve by $1. The supply curve shifts to the left.

Page 18: Chapter 7 Efficiency and Exchange. Markets are usually a good way to organize economic activity Markets don’t always provide socially efficient outcomes

The Effect of a Tax on the Equilibrium Quantity and Price of Potatoes

Figure 7.11

Page 19: Chapter 7 Efficiency and Exchange. Markets are usually a good way to organize economic activity Markets don’t always provide socially efficient outcomes

Effect in the Short Run• The shift in supply causes the equilibrium

price to increase from $3 to $3.5 and output to decline from three million pounds to 2.5 million pounds.

• Note that the equilibrium price did not increase by the amount of the tax. This is a key observation.

Page 20: Chapter 7 Efficiency and Exchange. Markets are usually a good way to organize economic activity Markets don’t always provide socially efficient outcomes

Taxes and Efficiency

• What happens to the price of a good when the government imposes a tax on it?– Most people believe that the price of the item

will rise by the amount of the tax.

• However, this will not happen in the short run unless demand curve is vertical or the supply curve is horizontal. In the long run, the price will increase by the amount of the tax in a perfectly competitive industry.

Page 21: Chapter 7 Efficiency and Exchange. Markets are usually a good way to organize economic activity Markets don’t always provide socially efficient outcomes

The Effect of a Tax on Sellers of a Good with Infinite Price Elasticity of Supply

Figure 7.12

Page 22: Chapter 7 Efficiency and Exchange. Markets are usually a good way to organize economic activity Markets don’t always provide socially efficient outcomes

Who Bears the Burden of the Tax?

• It depends on the slopes of the demand and supply curves. In our example, consumers paid 50 cents more and producers received 50 cents less.

• Ceteris paribus, the steeper the demand curve, the greater will be the burden on the consumer. Likewise in the case of the supplier.

Page 23: Chapter 7 Efficiency and Exchange. Markets are usually a good way to organize economic activity Markets don’t always provide socially efficient outcomes

Taxes and Economic Surplus

• Deadweight loss– The reduction in economic surplus that results

from a policy– A tax distorts the signal that free prices send

Page 24: Chapter 7 Efficiency and Exchange. Markets are usually a good way to organize economic activity Markets don’t always provide socially efficient outcomes

The Market for Potatoes without Taxes

Figure 7.13

Page 25: Chapter 7 Efficiency and Exchange. Markets are usually a good way to organize economic activity Markets don’t always provide socially efficient outcomes

The Effect of a $1/pound Tax on Potatoes

Figure 7.14

Page 26: Chapter 7 Efficiency and Exchange. Markets are usually a good way to organize economic activity Markets don’t always provide socially efficient outcomes

The Deadweight Loss Caused by a Tax

Figure 7.15

Page 27: Chapter 7 Efficiency and Exchange. Markets are usually a good way to organize economic activity Markets don’t always provide socially efficient outcomes

Taxes, Responsiveness, and Efficiency

• Deadweight loss is minimized if taxes are imposed on goods and services that are not very responsive to price.

• Example on the supply side: land

• Example on the demand side: salt ( and cigarettes, gasoline)

Page 28: Chapter 7 Efficiency and Exchange. Markets are usually a good way to organize economic activity Markets don’t always provide socially efficient outcomes

Taxes, External Costs, and Efficiency

• Taxing reduces the equilibrium quantity

• Therefore, taxing activities that people tend to pursue to excess can actually increase total economic surplus (e.g., activities that cause pollution)