CDS and Bond Liquidity

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/3/2019 CDS and Bond Liquidity

    1/38

    Credit and Liquidity Risk in Bond and CDS Markets

    Abstract

    In this paper, we develop a reduced-form credit risk model that incorporates

    illiquidity in the bond and the credit default swap (CDS) market. Due to the

    different nature of the two markets, we model the liquidity consequences in a

    different way. In the bond market, illiquidity results in yield premia. In the

    CDS market, the bid-ask spread constitutes a liquidity signal. This approachallows us to explore the liquidity spill-over between the bond and the CDS

    market as well as the co-movement of credit and liquidity premia.

    Our most important findings are threefold. First, we find that adding a

    CDS-specific liquidity component to the model has the important consequence

    of consistently positive credit risk and liquidity premia in bond markets. The

    size of these premia relative to the yield spread is intuitively plausible. Second,

    our analysis of the time series of the liquidity premia shows that the bond

    markets liquidity dries up as default risk increases. The CDS market, on the

    other hand, becomes more dominated by protection sellers during times of highdefault risk. Third, the liquidity of the bond market has a direct impact on

    the liquidity of the CDS market but not vice versa.

    Keywords: credit spread, credit default swap, illiquidity, reduced-form

    model

    JEL classification: G 13, G 14

    1

  • 8/3/2019 CDS and Bond Liquidity

    2/38

    1 Introduction

    Nowadays, credit derivatives markets provide a standardized alternative to bond markets

    in taking on and selling off credit risk exposures. This development offers a new approach

    to one of the most widely explored problems in fixed income analysis - the separation of

    the corporate bond spread into its credit risk and liquidity component.

    The corporate bond spread is usually defined as the difference between the bonds yield

    to maturity and a given default-free interest rate such as the swap rate or the yield on

    government bonds of the same maturity. Unarguably, credit risk is one of the spreads

    most important determinants, but there is clear empirical evidence that liquidity also has

    a significant impact. First, financial instruments such as AAA-rated bonds which are

    practically default-free often trade at a significant positive spread in excess of the yield

    on treasury bonds. This spread is mostly interpreted as a liquidity premium. Second,

    government bonds and mortgage bonds of the same issuer with identical default risk butdifferent issuing volumes are traded in some markets, and they usually differ with regard to

    their spreads. This spread differential is also attributed to differences in liquidity between

    the two instruments.

    These observations show that the separation of the total bond spread into its credit risk

    and liquidity component constitutes a central question if an issuers credit risk has to be

    quantified. When observed corporate bond spreads are directly used to estimate default

    probabilities, neglecting systematic liquidity premia will lead to biased estimates of the

    true default risk. Therefore, the problem is crucial for the correct pricing of bonds and

    credit derivatives as well as for the calculation of the economic capital a bank has to holdbecause of credit risk. However, the identification of the pure credit risk component is

    difficult since only the sum of the two risk premia can be observed in the market. In

    addition, an interdependence between credit risk and liquidity cannot be ruled out.

    The development of credit default swaps (CDS) markets presents a way to overcome

    these difficulties. Since the credit risk of an issuer for which both bonds and single-name

    CDS are traded is, at least in principle, the same for both instruments, the simultaneous

    observation of two prices facilitates the identification of the pure credit risk premium. But

    while there is broad agreement that bond spreads contain a positive liquidity premium, it

    remains ambiguous whether the CDS premium is a pure measure of credit risk or whether

    it also contains systematic liquidity premia. On the one hand, it can be argued that there

    should be no liquidity-driven distortions in CDS premia as CDS are derivatives and not

    assets. Why should the protection buyer pay a higher premium and the protection seller

    earn more for taking on credit risk by liquidity reasons? This symmetry between the two

    counterparties with regard to liquidity renders a systematic liquidity premium which is

    always borne by one party less plausible. On the other hand, large relative bid-ask spreads

    for single-name CDS can be observed which can at least partly be attributed to liquidity

    2

  • 8/3/2019 CDS and Bond Liquidity

    3/38

    issues in the CDS market.

    An extensive amount of empirical literature is concerned with identifying the components

    of the corporate bond spreads which goes back to Fisher (1959). In a recent empirical

    application, Elton et al. (2001) find that only approximately 25% of the corporate credit

    spread

    1

    can be explained by default risk or expected default loss. They attribute theresiduals to a tax and a systematic risk premium which is also associated with liquidity.

    Collin-Dufresne et al. (2001) analyse the impact of financial variables suggested by

    structural-form models on credit spreads. They find that these factors only explain one

    quarter of the variation and that a large systematic component seems to affect the spreads

    which the authors are unable to determine from a variety of structural-form variables such

    as liquidity, firm value and economic state variables. In contrast to this result, Ericsson and

    Renault (2006) obtain a significant positive correlation between the default and liquidity

    components of bond yield spreads in a cross-sectional regression analysis. This correlation

    increases with credit risk. De Jong and Driessen (2005) explore the effect of liquidity riskon the expected excess returns of corporate bonds in a multi-factor model that accounts for

    equity market liquidity and treasury bond market liquidity simultaneously. The estimated

    liquidity risk premia are around 45 bp for investment-grade bonds and more than double

    that size for subinvestment-grade bonds.

    Aunon-Nerin et al. (2002) were among the first to combine information from the bond and

    the CDS market to analyse the impact of typical factors used in structural-form models on

    CDS premia and bond spreads. The authors find that these factors are significant while

    liquidity measured by market capitalization does not seem to matter. The explanatory

    power of structural-form models for CDS premia and bond credit spreads, however, issmall in their study. Houweling and Vorst (2005) also use information from bond and

    CDS markets to implement a reduced-form model of the Duffie-Singleton type. They

    estimate the model for CDS premia and use it to determine theoretical bond spreads, and

    vice versa. This estimation procedure results in lower errors than assuming that the bond

    spread (CDS premium) is exactly equal to the CDS premium (bond spread).

    Expected liquidity in the CDS market has been investigated by Tang and Yan (2006) who

    perform a panel regression analysis of CDS premia. Liquidity is proxied by the number

    of trades and quotes in each month, the order imbalance and the bid-ask spread. The

    results imply that CDS liquidity affects CDS premia and that there exists a liquidity

    spill-over from the corporate bond, the stock and the equity options market to the CDS

    market. Chen et al. (2005) proxy CDS liquidity by the quote updating frequency and

    find evidence that expected liquidity and liquidity risk appears to be priced more strongly

    for protection buyers. Bongaerts et al. (2007) extend the Acharya and Pedersen (2005)

    model to a zero net supply market setup and calibrate it to a sample of CDS quotes and

    1From now on, we will follow the standard in the literature and use the terms bond spread and credit

    spread interchangeably.

    3

  • 8/3/2019 CDS and Bond Liquidity

    4/38

    prices on US-based reference entities. Separating the expected liquidity and the liquidity

    risk component, they observe that expected liquidity has a higher impact than liquidity

    risk and that the liquidity premium is mainly borne by the protection buyers. Meng and

    Ap Gwilym (2006) document that demand-supply pressure, inventory risk and clientele

    effects have an impact on the size of the CDS bid-ask spread. None of these studies,

    however, determines a time-varying CDS-specific liquidity premium for which the dynamic

    relationship between credit risk premia and CDS liquidity premia can be explored.

    There exists a vast theoretical literature that explicitly models credit risk for bonds and

    credit derivatives. However, to the best of our knowledge, only Longstaff et al. (2005)

    present a theoretical model that describes both credit and liquidity premia in bond spreads

    and uses information from the CDS and the bond market simultaneously. In the empirical

    part of the study, the authors are able to identify significant credit risk and non-default

    components in corporate bond spreads. A delicate consequence of their reduced-form

    model, however, is that they obtain partly negative liquidity premia in the bond market,i.e. the prices of illiquid bonds partly exceed the prices of liquid ones. We attribute this

    puzzling finding to the fact that the CDS market is assumed to be perfectly liquid.

    We contribute to the existing literature on the components of bond spreads and CDS

    premia by exploring the idea that the bid and ask quotes for CDS premia contain

    information on the liquidity of the CDS market. To this purpose, we develop a

    reduced-form credit-risk model that incorporates the identical default risk but possibly

    different liquidity in the CDS and in the bond market. We assume that illiquidity in the

    bond market results in price discounts and yield surcharges. This bond-specific liquidity

    has an effect on CDS premia since the potentially illiquid bond will be delivered underthe CDS contract. Therefore, the CDS premium in our model accounts for bond liquidity

    as a source of bond price variation. In addition to this straightforward liquidity spill-over,

    we include a CDS-specific liquidity which has a more intricate effect. We circumvent the

    question of systematic liquidity premia in CDS mid premia by modelling the ask and

    bid premia instead. From these, we are able to infer a theoretical pure credit risk CDS

    premium which is unaffected by the CDS-specific liquidity. Our measure of liquidity then

    naturally arises as the difference between this liquidity-free CDS premium and the mid

    premium.

    In the empirical part of our analysis, we calibrate the model in order to estimate the credit

    and liquidity components of bond spreads and CDS premia. The data we employ are bond

    prices and CDS premia for companies with ratings between AAA and CCC from a broad

    range of sectors that were observed between June 1st, 2001 and June 30th, 2007. We then

    analyse the relation between credit and liquidity premia in both markets as well as the

    relation between the liquidity premia of the two markets.

    Our most important findings are threefold. First, we find that adding a CDS-specific

    4

  • 8/3/2019 CDS and Bond Liquidity

    5/38

    liquidity component to the model has the important consequence of consistently positive

    credit risk and liquidity premia in bond markets. In particular, we obtain the result

    that neglecting CDS-specific liquidity can result in negative bond liquidity premia. On

    average, we attribute 65% of the total bond spread to credit risk and 35% to liquidity

    while the credit risk component in the CDS market constitutes on average 93% of the

    observed mid premium. In both markets, average liquidity premia increase for reference

    entities with higher credit risk. We believe these percentages to be more plausible than

    results in the literature where the reverse attribution is reported. Second, our model

    sheds light on the strongly discussed relation between liquidity premia in the bond and

    the CDS market if credit risk changes. We illustrate our results in a time-series analysis

    of the credit and liquidity premia which shows that the bond markets liquidity dries up

    as credit risk increases. The CDS market, on the other hand, becomes more dominated

    by the protection sellers during times of high default risk. Third, we find evidence of

    an empirical relation between the liquidity of the bond and the CDS market in excess

    of the liquidity spill-over which is immanent to our model. Specifically, we are able to

    demonstrate that higher liquidity premia in the bond market lead to increasing liquidity

    premia in the CDS market as well but that the reverse effect does not apply.

    The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. In the next section, we discuss the

    characteristics of CDS contracts. We introduce our extended reduced-form model and our

    measures of credit and liquidity risk in section 3. Section 4 presents the empirical results

    of the model calibration and a detailed analysis of the estimated credit risk and liquidity

    premia. A stability analysis is provided in section 5. Section 6 summarizes and concludes.

    2 Credit Default Swaps

    In this section, we repeat certain stylized facts regarding CDS contracts which have a

    bearing on our model.

    A credit default swap constitutes the exchange of a fee, paid by the default protection

    buyer, for a payment by the default protection seller if a credit event on a given reference

    asset occurs. The default protection can be purchased on a variety of different debt

    instruments, including loans, bonds, sovereign and derivative contracts. The default

    payment usually equals the difference between the notional value of the reference asset

    and its recovery value.

    CDS contracts can differ with regard to maturity, notional amount, definition of the credit

    event, the protection buyers and sellers payments, and so forth. Naturally, buyers want

    to interpret the scope of protection as widely as possible, while sellers prefer to interpret

    it narrowly. The International Swaps and Derivatives Association (ISDA) has therefore

    published standard guidelines regarding these properties in its 2002 Master Agreement

    5

  • 8/3/2019 CDS and Bond Liquidity

    6/38

    and in the new 2003 credit derivatives definition. Both this publication and the growth of

    the CDS market have led to a standard structure of the CDS contract. CDS premia are

    paid quarterly on certain reference days (March, June, September and December 20th)

    and are quoted in basis points of the nominal value. When a contract is entered into on a

    non-reference day, the time until the next reference day is added to the specified contract

    time such that all contracts mature on a reference day. If a default event occurs between

    two payment dates, the protection buyer pays the CDS premium accrued since the last

    payment date to the protection seller and physically delivers the reference debt entity.

    The protection seller, in turn, pays the notional value of the debt to the protection buyer.

    This physical settlement with a recovery of face value has been widely established in the

    market2 with a standard specification of 30 days for the notice of physical delivery and

    two to five business days for the termination of the contract upon the delivery notice.3

    Cash settlement is only specified for approximately 15% of CDS contracts, see e. g. British

    Bankers Association (2004). In this case, the post-default price of the defaulted referenceentity is determined through a dealer poll or with regard to a number of simplifying

    valuation techniques specified in the ISDA guidelines. The settlement period is then used

    by the protection buyer and seller to collect the information necessary to the valuation of

    the debt and agree on a fair post-default price. While cash settlement can be beneficial

    when there is a highly illiquid market for defaulted debt, determining the fair price is

    often intricate.

    In the following, we will assume that the CDS contract specifies recovery of face value and

    that physical settlement occurs immediately after the default event.

    3 The Credit Risk and Liquidity Model

    In this section, we develop our approach to measure the size of the default and the liquidity

    component in CDS premia and corporate bond prices.

    3.1 Model Framework

    We assume an arbitrage-free capital market in which default-free zero coupon bonds,default-risky coupon-bearing bonds and CDS are traded. The liquidity of these

    instruments can differ, and we choose the liquidity of the default-free zero coupon bond

    as the reference value of 1. This choice implies that the liquidity of each instrument is

    2Approximately 85% of CDS contracts specify physical settlement.3The settlement period has been added to the ISDA guidelines as a reaction to the default of Adelphia

    Communications in 2002. After the default event, numerous protection buyers who did not hold the

    reference entity were forced to buy the defaulted debt contracts which led to a market squeeze. Eventually,

    an auction was used to satisfy the buyers.

    6

  • 8/3/2019 CDS and Bond Liquidity

    7/38

    measured relative to the default-free zero coupon bond. We can therefore circumvent the

    problem of specifying a perfectly liquid instrument in comparison to which each illiquid

    instrument trades at a discount.

    Following Duffie and Singleton (1997), we let rt denote the instantaneous default-free

    interest rate process that determines the price of the default-free zero coupon bond. trefers to the default-risk hazard rate which is assumed to be equally reflected in CDS and

    corporate bonds. We use bt as the illiquidity process which determines the fraction of

    the coupon-bearing bonds price due to liquidity deviations from the reference liquidity of

    1. We also use the CDS-specific liquidity intensities caskt and cbidt to reflect the liquidity

    which only affects the CDS ask and bid premium, respectively.

    Then

    P(t1, t2) = exp

    t2t1

    (s) ds

    denotes the risk-neutral survival probability from time t1 to t2,

    D (t1, t2) = exp

    t2t1

    r (s) ds

    is the price of a default-free zero-coupon bond at time t1 with maturity in t2 and a notional

    of 1, and Lb (t1, t2) = expt2t1

    b (s) ds

    equals the liquidity discount factor that measures the difference between a reference-liquid

    default-free bond and a less liquid bond. We assume that rt, t and bt are stochastic with

    a specific correlation structure which we introduce in section 3.2. Therefore,P,

    D and Lb

    are also stochastic. Besides, we assume that a bondholder recovers a fixed fraction R of

    the face value F if default occurs.4

    The (dirty) price of a coupon-bearing default-risky bond at time t with a fixed coupon of

    c that is paid at times t1, . . . , tn, notional F and maturity in tn is then given by

    CB (c,R,F,t,t1, . . . , tn) = c n

    i=1

    Et

    P(t, ti) D (t, ti) Lb (t, ti)

    + F Et

    P(t, tn) D (t, tn)

    Lb (t, tn)

    (1)

    + R F n

    i=1

    Et P(t, ti1) P(t, ti) D (t, ti) Lb (t, ti) ,where t0 := t and Et is the expectation operator under the risk-neutral measure. Note

    that P(t, ti1) Pt (ti, ti) denotes the probability of surviving from t until ti1 and thendefaulting between ti1 and ti given that the current date is t. Equation (1) can be

    interpreted as the expected present value of all future bond cash-flows: The first summand

    4We have also explored the effect of recovery of treasury and recovery of market value, but our results

    were not vitally affected.

    7

  • 8/3/2019 CDS and Bond Liquidity

    8/38

    gives the expected present value of the coupon payments at each coupon date. The second

    summand equals the expected present value of the principal payment in the last period.

    The last term is the expected present value of the recovery rate payment. Each future

    payment is therefore discounted with regard to the default risk of the bond and to the

    illiquidity which affects the instrument.

    As discussed above, it is not obvious whether liquidity should be included in a model for

    CDS premia, and if so, in which way this should be done. A common solution to this

    problem both in empirical studies and theoretical models, see e.g. Schueler and Galletto

    (2003) and Longstaff et al. (2005), is to assume that the CDS mid premium reflects a

    price which is entirely free of liquidity risk. This assumption neglects the possibility of a

    liquidity-driven market pressure that causes the pure credit risk CDS premium which is

    unaffected by the liquidity of the CDS market to be closer either to the ask or the bid

    quote. In order to cope with this possibility, we focus directly on the CDS ask and bid

    premia from which we extract the pure credit risk component of the CDS premium. Thisprocedure is equivalent to assuming that the bid and ask quote are affected by liquidity.

    As a consequence, we model two values of the fixed leg of the CDS, one for the ask and

    one for the bid side.

    The value of the fixed leg of a CDS contract at time t with fixed arrear premium payment

    sask at times T1, . . . , T n and maturity in Tn equals

    CDSfix

    sask, t ,T1, . . . , T n

    = sask

    ni=1

    Et

    P(t, Ti1) D (t, Ti) Lcask (t, Ti) , (2)

    where Lcask is defined like Lb with the bond liquidity intensity b replaced by the CDSask liquidity intensity cask. Equation (2) suggests that the payment of all ask premia

    sask from the protection buyer to the protection seller has to be discounted for the default

    probability since the payment at time Ti1 only occurs with a probability P(t, Ti1). The

    CDS-specific liquidity discount factor for the ask premium Lcask (t, Ti) is added since weassume that a part of the CDS ask premium is not due to default risk but to the fact that

    the protection seller demands an additional premium because of illiquidity.

    Analogously, we obtain for the CDS bid premium:

    CDSfix sbid, t ,T 1, . . . , T n = sbid ni=1

    Et P(t, Ti1) D (t, Ti) Lcbid (t, Ti) , (3)where Lcbid results from replacing the CDS ask liquidity intensity cask by the CDS bidliquidity intensity cbid .

    The value of the floating leg, that is the payment of the protection seller contingent upon

    8

  • 8/3/2019 CDS and Bond Liquidity

    9/38

    default, equals

    CDSfloat (R,t,T1, . . . , T n) = F n

    i=1

    Et

    P(t, Ti1) P (t, Ti)

    D (t, Ti)

    R

    F

    n

    i=1 Et P (t, Ti1) P(t, Ti) D (t, Ti) Lb (t, Ti) .(4)

    The first summand in (4) equals the discounted present value of the face value F which

    we assume the protection seller pays out in cash. Since physical delivery of the defaulted

    bond constitutes the CDS market standard, the second summand equals the discounted

    present value of the defaulted bond which the protection seller has to sell in the market

    upon the bonds delivery. Therefore, the second summand contains the discounting factor

    for the bond liquidity in addition to the credit risk discounting factor.5

    Setting equal (2) and (4) and solving for sask, we obtain

    sask =F ni=1Et 1 R Lb (t, Ti) P(t, Ti1) P(t, Ti) D (t, Ti)n

    i=1Et

    P(t, Ti1) D (t, Ti) Lcask (t, Ti) , (5)

    where, as in (1), T0 := t.

    The closed-form solution for the CDS bid premium is identical to that for the ask premium

    only with Lcask replaced by Lcbid:

    sbid =

    F

    ni=1Et 1 R Lb (t, Ti) P (t, Ti1) P(t, Ti) D (t, Ti)n

    i=1EtP (t, Ti1) D (t, Ti) Lcbid (t, Ti) . (6)

    Equations (5) and (6) differ only with regard to the liquidity discount factor. If, as we

    generally observe, the bid quote lies below the ask quote, we expect that Lcbid on averageexceeds Lcask. Since the reference liquidity equals 1, we expect that Lcbid > 1 > Lcask. Forlarge bid-ask-spreads, Lcask will be much smaller than 1 and Lcbid will be larger than 1,moving both the bid and the ask premium away from each other. If, on the other hand,

    the CDS market were perfectly liquid, both

    Lcask and

    Lcbid would be identical to 1 and

    the ask and bid premium coincide.

    5In the above setting, the floating leg is not discounted with regard to the CDS-specific liquidity. We

    believe this to be appropriate since the CDS premium is the variable fixed by the CDS protection seller

    and buyer when they enter into the contract. Therefore, we simply capture the net effect of liquidity in the

    fixed leg where we have directly observable variables. In addition, also discounting the floating leg for CDS

    illiquidity is unnecessary since this would lead to the identical discounting factor eLl (t, Ti), l {cask, cbid},

    only with different weights P(t, Ti1) D (t, Ti) andh

    1 R fLb (t, Ti)i

    h

    P(t, Ti1) P(t, Ti)i

    D (t, Ti),

    in the floating and fixed payment leg. Overall, the effect of illiquidity can be captured in our setting while

    keeping the model parsimonious.

    9

  • 8/3/2019 CDS and Bond Liquidity

    10/38

    3.2 Specification of Intensity Processes

    The second step in the specification of the model consists of choosing the dynamics of the

    default and the liquidity intensities.6 As Longstaff et al. (2005), we assume a square-root

    process for the default intensity (t). The liquidity intensities lt, l {b, cask, cbid}, for theliquidity discount factors of the bond (b), the CDS ask premium (cask) and the CDS bidpremium (cbid) follow an arithmetic Brownian motion.

    7 The joint dynamics of the default

    and the liquidity intensity are given by:d(t)

    dl(t)

    =

    d(t) + fl dl(t)fl d(t) + dl(t)

    =

    (t) + fl

    + fl (t)

    dt +

    (t) fl fl

    (t)

    dW(t)

    dWl(t)

    (7)

    with constants , , , l and l, correlation coefficients fl and fl , independent Brownian

    motions W and Wl and independent processes

    and l

    . We do not specify thecovariance structure for the liquidity intensities l, l {b, cask, cbid}, for two reasons.First, it does not directly enter the model equations and second, it is implicitly defined by

    the covariance matrix of each component with . Economically, a correlation between the

    liquidity intensities that is not directly due to the implicit correlation with will allow us

    to determine the way in which pure liquidity effects are translated from one market into

    the other.

    Given the above relation between the intensities, we deduce an analytical solution for the

    joint expectation of P (t1, t2) and Ll (t1, t2) as well as P(t1, t2) and

    Ll (t1, t3):

    EtP(t1, t2) Ll (t1, t2) = Et expt2

    t1

    (s)ds expt4t3

    l (s) ds=: Pt (f, t1, t2) Lt

    lf, t1, t2

    ,

    Et

    P(t1, t2) Ll (t1, t3) = Et expt2

    t1

    (1 + f) s + (1 + f) s

    ds t3t2

    sds

    =: Pt (f, t1, t2, t3) Lt

    lf, t1, t2, t3

    where the functions Pt (f, t1, t2), Pt (f, t1, t2, t3), Lt

    lf, t1, t2

    , Lt

    lf, t1, t2, t3

    and the

    intensities f and lf are derived in the appendix A.

    6We have also estimated the model for the case where both the default and the liquidity intensity are

    correlated with the default-free short rate. The coefficient estimates, however, proved to be highly sensitive

    to the estimation period, leading to an average coefficient estimate of 0 for 158 out of 171 companies.7This will allow the liquidity process to take on both positive and negative values. This specification of

    the dynamics of the liquidity intensity can be favored over the simple White-Noise process in Longstaff et al.

    (2005) since it additionally allows for liquidity trends which may be more appropriate for the maturing CDS

    markets. In addition, the inclusion of a trend parameter results in a liquidity discount factor Ll (t1, t2)

    that is concave in the time-to-maturity for positive values of l. This suggests that liquidity is over-

    proportionately declining as the time-to-maturity increases which agrees with recent empirical evidence by

    Chen et al. (2005).

    10

  • 8/3/2019 CDS and Bond Liquidity

    11/38

    Substituting these expressions in (1) and (5) yields the analytical solutions for CB and s:

    CB = c n

    i=1

    Pt (f, t , ti) Lbt (f, t , ti) Dt

    + F Pt (f, t , tn) Lt bf, t , tn

    Dt

    + R F n

    i=1

    Pt (f, t , ti1, ti) Lt bf, t , ti1, ti Pt (f, t , ti) Lt bf, t , ti Dt,

    (8)

    sask/bid = F n

    i=1

    1 R Lt

    bf, t ,Ti1, Ti,

    Pt (f, t ,Ti1, Ti) Dtn

    i=1 Pt (f, t ,T i1, Ti) Ltcask/cbidf , t ,Ti1, Ti,

    Dt

    F n

    i=1

    1 R Lt

    bf, t ,T i

    Pt (f, Ti, t) Dt

    ni=1 Pt (f, t ,T i1, Ti)

    Lt

    cask/cbidf , t ,Ti1, Ti, Dt

    ,

    (9)

    where we suppress the arguments of the time-discount factor Dt for ease of presentation.

    These closed-form solutions can then be calibrated to a set of bond prices and CDS ask

    and bid quotes to obtain estimates of the default and liquidity intensities.

    3.3 Measures for Credit Risk and Liquidity Premia

    The model developed in sections 3.1 and 3.2 allows us to disentangle the bond spread

    into a credit risk and a liquidity component. By an analogous procedure based on bidand ask quotes of CDS premia, we will be able to compute a credit risk and a liquidity

    component for CDS. Basically, the credit risk premia are determined by model prices for

    which the liquidity discount factors are set to the reference value of 1, i.e. the liquidity of

    the bond and the CDS market are assumed to be identical to the reference liquidity. This

    is identical to only considering the default intensity as a pricing factor. The liquidity

    premia are computed from model prices with liquidity discount factors different from 1.

    The pure credit risk premium csdef for a straight bond with coupon c and face value F

    results from equation (8) for L b 1 and the definition of a spread as a premium onthe risk-free rate:c

    ni=1

    Pt (f, t , ti) Dt + F Pt (f, t , tn) Dt

    + R F n

    i=1

    [Pt (f, t , ti1) Pt (f, t , ti)] Dt

    =:n

    i=1

    ccsdef+ D (t, ti)

    1

    tit

    (tit) + Fcsdef+ D (t, tn)

    1

    tnt

    (tnt) , (10)11

  • 8/3/2019 CDS and Bond Liquidity

    12/38

    where D (t, ti)

    1

    tit 1 equals the yield to maturity of a default-free zero coupon bondwith reference liquidity and time-to-maturity ti t.This pure credit risk premium csdef is directly comparable to the pure credit risk premium

    of a CDS if the maturity of both instruments is identical and if, in addition, the clean

    price of the bond equals its face value. The second condition is important to avoid thedifficulties discussed by Duffie (1999) and Duffie and Liu (2001) who show that the yield

    spreads on fixed-coupon corporate bonds cannot directly be compared to CDS premia.

    Credit spreads determined from par bonds are, apart from interest rate risk which we do

    not consider, identical to theoretical asset swap spreads. These must coincide with the

    premium of a CDS on this bond in arbitrage-free markets by definition.

    The total bond spread cs is determined analogously to csdefwith the impact of the liquidity

    intensity added:

    c n

    i=1Pt (f, t , ti) Lbt (f, t , ti) Dt + F Pt (f, t , tn) Lt bf, t , tn Dt

    + R F n

    i=1

    Pt (f, t , ti1, ti) Lt

    bf, t , ti1, ti

    Pt (f, t , ti) Lt

    bf, t , ti

    Dt

    =:n

    i=1

    ccs + D (t, ti)

    1

    tit

    (tit) + Fcs + D (t, tn)

    1

    tnt

    (tnt) . (11)The liquidity premium is defined by the difference between the the total bond spread cs,

    and the pure credit risk premium csdef:

    csliq := cs csdef. (12)

    The credit risk and liquidity components of a CDS are subsequently determined in the

    following way. We first compute the pure credit risk premium in the CDS spread sdef by

    assuming that the liquidity discount factors Lcask or Lcbid are equal to 1:

    sdef := F n

    i=1

    1 R Lt

    bf, t ,T i1, Ti,

    Pt (f, t ,T i1) Dtn

    i=1 Pt (f, t ,T i1) Dt

    F ni=1 1 R Lt

    bf, t ,T i Pt (f, Ti, t) Dtn

    i=1Pt (f, t ,Ti1) Dt . (13)

    Equation (13) shows that the pure credit risk CDS premium is exclusively determined by

    the default-free interest rates, the survival and default probability and the bond liquidity.

    Note that the bond liquidity affects the CDS both in the case of physical delivery and

    cash settlement: a less liquid bond will have a lower post-default price compared to an

    otherwise identical bond with higher liquidity. The CDS premium will therefore be higher

    for the less liquid bond in order to compensate the protection seller for the lower value

    12

  • 8/3/2019 CDS and Bond Liquidity

    13/38

    of the bond should default occur. This effect would pertain even if the CDS market were

    perfectly liquid.

    In a CDS market which has a liquidity that differs from the reference liquidity, the ask and

    bid premia will differ from the pure credit risk premium sdef. The size of the bid-ask-spread,

    however, is not necessarily an appropriate measure of illiquidity in our context for tworeasons. First, a comparison of (5) and (6) shows that the bid-ask-spread is clearly affected

    by credit risk as well as liquidity since a higher default probability increases the ask

    premium more strongly than the bid premium. Second, even if the bid-ask-spread were

    taken relative to sdef, the resulting quantity would not be comparable to any liquidity

    measure in the bond market since we only have access to mid prices in this market. We

    therefore use the difference between the theoretical mid premium smid,

    smid :=sask + sbid

    2, (14)

    and the pure credit risk premium sdef

    , as a measure of CDS liquidity:sliq := smid sdef, (15)

    where sask and sbid follow from equation (9). Note that sliq is positively related to the

    asymmetry between the ask and the bid spread with regard to sdef. If there is a high

    market pressure from the protection buyers side, that is if there is a high demand for

    credit protection, protection sellers will be able to move the ask premium at which they

    are willing to trade upwards. Since the pure credit risk premium sdef remains at its initial

    value, sliq will increase. If, on the other hand, the market pressure from the protection

    sellers side is high, protection buyers will set lower bid quotes. This will then result in

    lower values ofsliq. Therefore, our measure of CDS liquidity is consistent with the measure

    of bond liquidity: if a large number of investors seeks to sell bonds - which corresponds

    to buying credit protection - the liquidity premium in the bond market will increase and

    vice versa.

    In the next section, we turn to an empirical application of the theoretical model derived in

    this section. In particular, we estimate default and liquidity intensities from bond prices

    and CDS premia. We then analyse the estimated time series of the credit risk and liquidity

    components in CDS premia and bond credit spreads.

    4 Empirical Analysis

    In section 4.1, we first describe the data set of CDS premia and bond prices, respectively

    credit spreads, to which we subsequently calibrate our model. We then discuss the

    estimation procedure and the resulting credit risk and liquidity premia in credit spreads

    and CDS premia. Eventually, we analyse the the time-series behavior of the estimated

    premia.

    13

  • 8/3/2019 CDS and Bond Liquidity

    14/38

    4.1 Data

    As a dynamic proxy for the default-free interest rate, we choose the Nelson-Siegel-Svensson

    curve whose parameters are estimated by the Deutsche Bundesbank on a daily basis

    because our empirical analysis is focused on Euro-denominated bonds and CDS.8 The

    resulting spot rates are used to compute prices of default-free zero-coupon bonds which

    we assume to have the reference liquidity discount factor of 1. The recovery rate is assumed

    to equal 40%.

    All CDS and bond data is collected from Bloomberg. The daily CDS ask and bid closing

    premia were made available to us by an international investment bank. We compute the

    daily closing mid premia for CDS in order to compare them to the bonds credit spreads

    which are computed from Bloomberg yields using mid prices. In order to avoid exchange

    rate issues, we only collect prices of CDS denominated in Euro. As a starting and end

    point, we use June 1st, 2001 and June 30th, 2007 which yields a total of 1,548 trading

    days during which we observe CDS premia with a time-to-maturity of 5 years. All CDS

    which are not quoted with a reference time-to-maturity of 5 years are excluded in order to

    obtain a sample with a homogenous CDS liquidity. To account for the time conventions

    in the CDS market described in section 2, we compute the distance between the quoting

    day and the next reference date and add this to the quoted time-to-maturity to obtain the

    true CDS maturity.

    Bloomberg records CDS prices for companies from 10 industry sectors. We collect all

    bond mid prices for companies from these industry sectors which had at least 2 bonds

    outstanding at some point-in-time during the observation interval. We drop companieswith fewer than 20 observations on consecutive trading days on which at least two bond

    prices as well as the bid and ask CDS premium were available.

    For each of the remaining companies, we collect a rating history from Bloomberg for the

    period during which we observe bond prices and CDS premia. Both the Standard&Poors

    rating and the Moodys rating are collected and mapped on a numerical scale ranging

    from 1 to 50 where 1 corresponds to a AAA Standard&Poors rating (Aaa Moodys

    rating). 50, on the other hand, corresponds to a CCC+ Standard&Poors rating (Caa1

    Moodys rating) and is the worst rating which we observe during the entire observation

    interval. If the resulting numerical rating differs by 2 or more, we take the average of

    the two ratings. If the rating differs by 1, we choose the Standard&Poors rating and

    ignore the Moodys rating. If no rating for the company could be found for at least 20

    observations on consecutive trading days on which at least two bond prices as well as the

    bid and ask CDS premium were available, we drop the company from our sample.

    8As an alternative, we also used the swap curve which is, on average, 10 basis points higher than the

    NSS curve for a time-to-maturity of 5 years. Since the dynamics are almost identical, we here only present

    the results for the NSS curve.

    14

  • 8/3/2019 CDS and Bond Liquidity

    15/38

    The above procedure leaves us with a set of 171 companies from the sovereign and 9

    corporate sectors and a numerical rating history that consistently lies between 1 and 50.

    A detailed overview is given in table 1. For ease of exposition, we first compute the average

    numerical rating of a company for all days during which there are a sufficient number of

    observations. We then map the numerical value to the Standard&Poors rating and use

    this as the column heading.

    Table 1 shows that the majority of companies has an average investment-grade rating over

    time; only 13 companies lie in the subinvestment-grade range. The largest industry group

    consists of the sector Financials with a total of 54 companies. At the same time, these

    companies are also among the top-rated ones. Overall, table 1 demonstrates that the

    sample with which we work is skewed toward financial companies and investment-grade

    rating. We will therefore conduct the estimation procedure on a single-firm level and

    aggregate the data subsequently only.

    In order to present the time-series of the credit spreads and CDS premia, we compute the

    average credit spread and CDS mid premium for each rating class at every date of our

    observation interval. To do so, we first identify the rating for a particular company on

    each day. We then compute the credit spread for each bond of that particular company

    as the difference between the yield of this bond and the yield of a synthetical default-free

    bond with identical coupon and time-to-maturity. Next, we interpolate the resulting credit

    spreads for each company to obtain a synthetical time to maturity of 5 years. We then take

    averages of the obtained credit spreads and the observed CDS mid premia for all companies

    with an average investment, respectively subinvestment grade rating. The resulting timeseries of the average credit spread and CDS mid premia for the investment-grade and

    subinvestment grade rating classes are depicted in figure 1.

    As we see from figure 1, the time series of the average investment-grade bond credit spreads

    (depicted in the solid blue line) consistently exceeds the mid CDS premia. Overall, the

    mean investment-grade credit spread has an average of 89.42 bp with a standard deviation

    over time of 23.03 bp. The lowest average credit spread of 33.54 bp is attained on August

    22, 2001, the highest one which equals 178.86 bp on February 18, 2002. CDS premia

    fluctuate between 15.86 bp and 143.76 bp with a mean of 45.42 bp and a standard deviationof 27.96 bp.

    Credit spreads for the subinvestment-grade sector are, as expected, clearly higher with an

    average of 369.62 bp and a time-series standard deviation of 188.70 bp. Overall, the credit

    spread fluctuates between 87.60 bp and 1320.33 bp which are attained on March 1, 2005

    and on October 9, 2002. The average subinvestment-grade CDS premium fluctuates above

    and below the credit spread with a standard deviation of 224.53 bp, but the time-series

    average of 341.33 bp lies below that of the credit spread.

    15

  • 8/3/2019 CDS and Bond Liquidity

    16/38

    Figure 1: Average Bond Credit Spreads and Mid CDS Premia Time Series

    The figure shows the average bond credit spreads and mid CDS premia between June 1,

    2001 and June 30, 2007. Average mid CDS premia are denoted in black, credit spreads in

    blue. The solid line is used to depict the investment-grade, the dashed line to depict the

    subinvestment-grade time series.

    0

    200

    400

    600

    800

    1000

    1200

    June-01 June-02 June-03 June-04 June-05 June-06 June-07

    Date

    Premiainbp

    Av. CDS Premia IG

    Av. Bond Spreads IG

    Av. CDS Premia Sub-IG

    Av. Bond Spreads Sub-IG

    4.2 Estimation Procedure

    To ensure that the 9 parameters ,,,b, b, cask, cask , cbid, cbid of the 4 intensityprocesses, the starting values , b, cask, cbid (t), t = 1, . . . , 1583, and the 6 correlation

    coefficients can be identified, we demand that the instantaneous default and liquidity

    intensity are equal for bonds of the same issuer with identical seniority but different time-

    to-maturity and coupon rate.9 This identification assumption will make our parameters

    issuer-specific.

    The procedure consists of three steps. Initially, we set all intensity correlation

    coefficients to zero. This corresponds to the case of independent credit risk and

    liquidity intensities. In the first step, we then choose a value for the process parameters

    ,,,b, b, cask, cask, cbid, cbid and then determine the values , b, cask, cbid (t)which minimize our objective function, the squared sum of the deviation between theobserved and the theoretical prices, on each observation date t.10 We then repeat

    9It seems rather reasonable that bonds of the same seniority have the same default probability during

    the next infinitesimally small time interval. The liquidity discount, on the other hand, may well depend

    on the time to maturity and the coupon of a bond. We hope, however, that the homogeneity of the bonds

    of the same issuer will limit the differences induced by this assumption. In addition, the functional form of

    the stochastic liquidity process results in larger liquidity premia for bonds with a longer time-to-maturity.10CDS premia are matched at the basis point level, bond prices at a level that translates to basis point

    16

  • 8/3/2019 CDS and Bond Liquidity

    17/38

    this procedure of choosing process parameters and determining an optimal associated

    time-series of the intensities until we arrive at a minimum of the objective functions in the

    process parameter set. In the second step, we estimate the correlation of the estimated

    intensity time series for the discretized version of equation (7) which gives us our new

    starting point for the correlation coefficients. We then return to the first step and repeat

    the estimation procedure until our estimate of the correlation coefficients changes by less

    than 0.01 in two steps.11

    Given the estimates of the process parameters, the intensities and the correlation

    coefficients, we then compute the credit risk and liquidity premia for CDS and for bonds

    in the third step as explained in section 3.3.

    4.3 Credit Risk and Liquidity Premia: Cross-Sectional Results

    Our estimates for the correlation coefficients imply that the credit risk intensity increasesboth the bond liquidity intensity and the CDS ask and bid liquidity intensity. affects

    b

    significantly for 136 out of 171 reference entities. 149 of the significant correlation

    coefficients are positive and have a mean of 17.39%. The 7 negative correlation coefficients

    are obtained for sovereign reference entities which had a AAA, respectively a AA, rating.

    The impact of on cask is significant for 148 and positive for 147 reference entities

    with a mean of 26.22%. cbid is, in turn, significantly affected by for only 76 reference

    entities with a coefficient which is negative for 44 reference entities. The mean values for

    the positive and the negative coefficient estimates are very similar at -20.73% and 20.32%,

    respectively. The impact of the liquidity intensities on , on the other hand, is almostnegligible: we obtain only one significant coefficient estimate for b

    , three for cask out

    of which two are positive and two for cbid with a positive and a negative one. These

    results show that credit risk premia increase liquidity premia in the bond market but not

    vice versa. We can also conclude that higher credit risk leads to a higher distance between

    the pure credit risk CDS premium and the ask premium. CDS bid premia, on the other

    hand, are not as symmetrically affected. We display the premium components in table 2.

    Overall, we see that the credit risk and liquidity premia increase as the rating deteriorates.

    For the AAA rating class, the pure credit risk premium in credit spreads csdef hasan average of 6.11 bp which approximately doubles for each rating downgrade in the

    investment grade sector. The subinvestment grade sector exhibits values of csdef which

    are about five times as large as for the investment grade sector. For the liquidity premia

    csliq, the increase is less steep than for the credit risk premia. Nevertheless, we obtain

    strictly positive estimates for the liquidity premia. It is also interesting to note that

    accuracy at the yield spread level.11Convergence in the correlation coefficients is usually achieved in less than 10 iteration steps.

    17

  • 8/3/2019 CDS and Bond Liquidity

    18/38

    the minimum of csliq is not monotonously increasing as credit risk increases. These

    findings indicate that even though more risky bonds also contain higher absolute liquidity

    premia, the interdependence between credit risk and liquidity cannot be fully captured

    cross-sectionally.

    Comparing the CDS credit risk premia CDS sdef

    , we find that they almost consistentlyexceed csdef but that the difference, caused by the bond liquidity premia, is very limited.

    The difference is smallest for the AAA rating class with 0.27 bp and maximal for the BBB

    class with 3.40 bp on the absolute level. This agrees with the increasing average level of

    the bond liquidity premium csliq.

    The most noteworthy results of table 2 concern the CDS-specific liquidity premia. As

    explained in section 3.3, we measure the liquidity of the CDS market by the asymmetry

    between bid and the ask quotes relative to the credit risk premium. On average, the

    liquidity risk premium sliq is positive which suggests that the CDS market is mostly

    dominated by protection sellers. On an absolute level, the asymmetry increases as therating deteriorates. Taken relative to the pure credit risk premia, however, the pure

    liquidity premia are smaller for the subinvestment grade sector, and the difference is

    particularly pronounced for the gap between the investment and the subinvestment grade

    sector where the ratio descends from 7.14% to 3.82%. In addition, we find that 19.24% of

    the liquidity premia in the subinvestment grade sector are negative, suggesting that the

    asymmetry may actually be smaller.

    From an economic point of view, investors who have to maintain a given default risk level

    threshold or face a value-at-risk constraint will demand more credit protection through

    CDS if a reference entity is closer to the subinvestment grade barrier. Since the liquidity of

    the bond market is on average lower than that of the CDS market, selling the bond would

    be associated with a loss which can be avoided by buying the CDS. For the subinvestment

    grade sector, these investors will not increase the demand pressure, but the low liquidity of

    the bond market makes it more attractive to take on credit risk synthetically as a protection

    seller. Therefore, the demand pressure decreases and the supply pressure increases. In the

    next section, we will further explore how credit risk and liquidity premia behave during

    times of high and low credit risk.

    4.4 Credit Risk and Liquidity Premia: Time-Series Results

    In this section, we first present the time series of the premia estimates for the investment

    and the subinvestment grade sector. We then explore the relation between the liquidity

    premia in the bond and the CDS market. The section concludes with an empirical analysis

    of the impact of market-wide credit and liquidity measures on the estimated premia time

    series.

    18

  • 8/3/2019 CDS and Bond Liquidity

    19/38

    The estimated credit risk and liquidity premia are depicted in figure 2. For ease of

    presentation, the investment and subinvestment-grade rating classes are summarized into

    a single time series each.

    Figure 2: Estimated Credit Risk, Liquidity and Correlation Premia Time Series

    The figure shows the estimated credit risk, liquidity and correlation components in CDS

    premia and credit spreads for all rating classes. The estimates are computed with regard to

    a constant time-to-maturity of 5 years and a synthetical par bond.

    Investment Grade Premium Components

    -20

    0

    20

    40

    60

    80

    100

    120

    June-01 June-02 June-03 June-04 June-05 June-06 June-07

    Date

    Premiainbp

    CDS Credit Risk

    CDS Liquidity

    Bond Credit Risk

    Bond Liquidity

    Subinvestment Grade Premium Components

    -200

    0

    200

    400

    600

    800

    1000

    1200

    June-01 June-02 June-03 June-04 June-05 June-06 June-07

    Date

    Premiainbp

    CDS Credit Risk

    CDS Liquidity

    Bond Credit Risk

    Bond Liquidity

    Figure 2 shows that the pure credit risk premia both in credit spreads and CDS premia,

    depicted in the solid black lines, can hardly be distinguished both for the investment grade

    19

  • 8/3/2019 CDS and Bond Liquidity

    20/38

    and the subinvestment grade sector. Particularly for the investment grade sector, there

    are two distinct spikes in late 2001 and late 2002 which can be associated with the defaults

    by Enron and WorldCom. The reaction of the subinvestment grade rating sector to the

    Enron default is almost negligible which may be due to the fact that only two companies

    have a subinvestment grade rating between June 2001 and February 2002. Overall, we

    observe a flattening of the pure credit risk premia curves of csdef and sdef over time with

    much lower average levels at the end of the observation interval. Since the premia are

    computed with regard to par bonds with a constant time-to-maturity of 5 years, we can

    directly attribute the lower premium level to a lower amount of risk.

    We observe that the bond liquidity premia csliq also exhibits a similar behavior across

    the rating classes. During the high credit risk periods, the liquidity premia are high

    and rather volatile and become much lower and rather flat during the latter part of the

    observation interval. Visual inspection of the CDS-specific liquidity premia sliq is more

    difficult since the absolute values are small. Overall, the level of s

    liq

    is closer to 0 nearthe end of the observation interval for both the investment and the subinvestment grade

    sector. During times of high credit risk on the other hand, the liquidity premium exhibits

    a reverse behavior across the two sectors. For the investment grade sector, sliq is higher

    during times of high credit risk. In the subinvestment grade sector, sliq becomes more

    negative when credit risk is high. This finding suggests that the demand pressure which

    characterizes the CDS market for investment grade debt is replaced with a supply pressure

    for the subinvestment grade sector.

    In order to study the dynamic interaction between the liquidity premia in the bond and

    the CDS market, we perform a vector error correction model (VECM) analysis. Theaugmented Dickey-Fuller test cannot reject the hypothesis of a unit root in csliq and sliq for

    162 reference entities. The Johansen procedure cannot reject cointegration of the liquidity

    premia across the two markets for 159 companies. The VECM-specification which we use

    joins the models for credit risk and liquidity premia in credit spreads and CDS premia

    and is of the form

    csliqi = w1 csliqi1 + w2 csliqi1 + w3 sliqi1 + w4 sliqi1,sliqi = z1 csliqi1 + z2 csliqi1 + z3 sliqi1 + z4 sliqi1.

    We demand that the parameters are identical for firms in the same rating class. Time lags

    up to degree 5 are considered in order to capture at least a weekly time interval, and the

    resulting parameter estimates are transformed into a single estimate using the approach

    of Fowler and Rorke (1983). The results of the estimation are displayed in table 3.

    As table 3 shows, the interdependence between the pure liquidity premia in bond and

    CDS markets differs between the investment and the subinvestment grade sector. With

    20

  • 8/3/2019 CDS and Bond Liquidity

    21/38

    regard to their own previous level and change, bond and CDS liquidity premia exhibit a

    consistently negative coefficient, suggesting that the liquidity premia are mean-reverting

    and on average declining. This is particularly pronounced for the CDS market. Regarding

    liquidity spillover effects, we observe that the bond market liquidity is not affected by the

    CDS liquidity premia for the investment grade sector. For the subinvestment grade sector,

    we obtain a positive coefficient estimate for sliq and a negative one for sliq which suggests

    that a higher level of CDS liquidity premia leads to lower levels of bond liquidity premia

    and that changes occur in opposite directions. Even though this observation supports

    our hypothesis that the CDS market constitutes a possible substitute in the taking on of

    credit risk for subinvestment grade debt, both the statistical and the economic significance

    of the effect are limited. The bond liquidity premia, on the other hand, significantly

    affect CDS premia both for the investment and the subinvestment grade sector. For the

    investment-grade segment, the association between the level of csliq and changes in sliq is

    positive which shows that higher liquidity premia in the bond market lead to increasing

    liquidity premia in the CDS market. This suggests that protection sellers increase their

    CDS ask quotes relative to sdef if the bond market becomes less liquid. As expected, the

    sign of the coefficient for csliq becomes negative for the subinvestment grade sample: the

    CDS market becomes a more attractive substitute to the bond market in the taking on

    of credit risk. In addition, changes in csliq coincide with subsequent changes ofsliq in the

    opposite direction, further strengthening this hypothesis.

    To conclude our empirical analysis, we determine the impact of market-wide credit risk and

    liquidity measures on the premia estimates. As a proxy for credit risk, we choose the J.P.

    Morgan Aggregate Index Euro (MAGGIE) for which we obtain daily yield spreads from

    Bloomberg. The MAGGIE index comprises a total of roughly 1,750 Euro-denominated

    bonds and Jumbo Pfandbriefs which are included on the basis of their liquidity. Liquidity

    is proxied by the European Central Bank (ECB) financial market liquidity indicator for

    which daily values were made available to us through the ECB. The indicator is designed

    to mirror dynamic patterns in the overall liquidity of the Euro area financial market and

    combines information from the stock, the bond and the equity options market as well as

    European interest rate data.12 A higher value marks higher aggregate financial market

    liquidity.

    Since the premium estimates are not stationary, we perform a Johansen cointegrationanalysis with the credit risk and liquidity premia as dependent variables, i.e. the premium

    change is regressed on its own previous change and that of the explanatory variable. The

    results of the analysis are displayed in table 4.

    As table 4 shows, the credit risk premia for bonds and CDS show a similar dependency on

    12For a detailed description of the indicator, see European Central Bank Financial Stability Report June

    2007.

    21

  • 8/3/2019 CDS and Bond Liquidity

    22/38

    the aggregate market-wide measures. Both csdef and sdef depend positively on credit risk

    and negatively on the liquidity measures, and the impact is stronger for the investment

    grade sector. This suggests that credit risk premia in the subinvestment grade sector

    mainly depend on the reference entitys idiosyncratic default risk. The liquidity premia,

    on the other hand, exhibit a different sensitivity to the explanatory variables depending

    on the rating. For the investment grade sector, csliq and sliq both react positively to

    increases of credit risk and negatively to increases of liquidity, but the effect on the bond

    liquidity premium is much more pronounced. We partly attribute this to the fact that

    the CDS market is, on average, rather liquid, and partly to the increasing overall liquidity

    in the CDS market throughout the observation interval. In the subinvestment grade

    sector, on the other hand, csliq reacts with strong increases to increases in the credit risk

    and steep decreases to increases in overall market liquidity. For CDS liquidity premia, we

    observe a negative dependency on market-wide credit risk and expected liquidity premium

    decreases if the market-wide liquidity decreases. Comparing these results with our findings

    in figure 2, the signs of the coefficients agree with the hypothesis that the market for CDS

    on subinvestment grade reference entities becomes less dominated by protection sellers if

    credit risk increases, possibly because taking on credit risk synthetically becomes more

    attractive.

    Summarizing the results of this section, we find clear evidence that bond credit spreads

    computed from mid prices contain strictly positive credit and liquidity premia. Both

    decrease over time and are subject to frequent changes. For CDS, the pure liquidity

    premia can either be positive or negative but tend to be positive. Their decrease over

    time documents the maturing of the CDS market as a whole. In addition, our results showthat liquidity in the bond market dries up as the default risk increases. CDS liquidity is

    somewhat more difficult to grasp, but we find that the asymmetry between protection

    buyers and sellers increases with default risk for investment-grade debt. We attribute this

    to a higher pressure on investors to insure against further downgrades. The subinvestment

    grade CDS market partly exhibits the reverse behavior. The size of the liquidity premia

    is also very different in both markets. This result raises the question whether an explicit

    modelling of the CDS liquidity premium is necessary or whether the CDS mid premium

    can consistently be used as a proxy for sdef. Since the difference between the mid CDS

    premium and our estimate of this premium is rather small on average, we further explore

    this issue in section 5.1.

    5 Stability of Credit Risk and Liquidity Premia

    In this section, we perform a stability analysis of the estimated credit risk and liquidity

    premia for bonds and CDS. To this purpose, we first explore how bond premia react if we

    ignore liquidity in the CDS market. We then compare the pure credit risk premia which

    22

  • 8/3/2019 CDS and Bond Liquidity

    23/38

    are obtained if the default and liquidity intensities are estimated from CDS ask or bid

    quotes only to the estimate which uses both observations.

    5.1 The Effect of Excluding CDS Illiquidity

    We first explore whether the positive bond liquidity premia csliq we obtain in our

    estimation are a result of including stochastic liquidity in CDS ask and bid premia or

    simply a property of our data set. To do so, we propose the following modification of our

    model: First, we shift our focus to the CDS mid premia in our estimation procedure since

    there is no theoretically compelling reason why sdef must differ systematically from the

    mid premium. Second, we re-estimate the default and bond liquidity intensity time-series

    under the restriction c = c = c = 0 which is basically the approach by Longstaff et al.

    and which makes the liquidity of the CDS market constant and equal to the reference

    liquidity. We last compute csdef and csliq as explained above and compare them to the

    results from the initial estimation which included liquidity in CDS premia. Since the effect

    only pertains when a companys bonds are liquid relative to the CDS on the company, we

    show the estimated time-series for a representative company, the Dutch communications

    company The Nielsen Company (formerly VNU Group B.V.).13 The results are displayed

    in figure 3.

    As we see from figure 3, the estimated default risk premium in the bond credit spread

    csdef has similar dynamics whether CDS liquidity is included or not, but there are also

    clear differences. Overall, when stochastic CDS liquidity is excluded (blue solid line),csdef is higher, fluctuating between 34.98 bp and 537.71 bp with a mean of 110.02 bp and

    a standard deviation of 97.56 bp. When stochastic CDS liquidity is included, csdef lies

    between 35.74 bp and 429.29 bp, the mean equals 95.94 bp and the standard deviation

    73.36 bp. The differences are especially noteworthy during the beginning of our observation

    interval when the CDS market was still relatively illiquid.

    Conversely, the bond liquidity premium csliq that results from excluding stochastic CDS

    liquidity is consistently lower than when CDS liquidity is modelled with a mean of 3.74

    bp versus 24.69 bp, a minimum of -95.95 bp (5.26 bp), a maximum of 81.82 bp (79.78

    bp) and a standard deviation of 32.55 bp (16.11 bp). This suggests that neglectingstochastic CDS liquidity can yield overestimates of liquidity in the bond market and,

    for above time-series, in bond price surcharges instead of discounts. At the same time, the

    default risk is overestimated when the bond liquidity becomes negative, and this results in

    overestimates of a companys default probability. Since neglecting CDS liquidity attributes

    yield differences between the bond and the CDS market directly to bond liquidity, the effect

    13The Nielsen Company is active in marketing and media information, business publications and trade

    shows in more than 100 countries and has a total of 42,000 employees.

    23

  • 8/3/2019 CDS and Bond Liquidity

    24/38

    Figure 3: The Effect of Excluding Stochastic CDS Liquidity

    The figure shows the bond credit risk and liquidity premia estimated for the communications

    company Nielsen when stochastic CDS illiquidity is ignored (blue line) and included (black

    line).

    -200

    -100

    0

    100

    200

    300

    400

    500

    600

    June-01 June-02 June-03 June-04 June-05 June-06 June-07

    Date

    Premiainbp

    Bond Credit Risk w/ CDS Liquidity

    Bond Liquidity w/ CDS Liquidity

    Bond Credit Risk w/o CDS Liquidity

    Bond Liquidity w/o CDS Liquidity

    will be especially prominent when the bond liquidity is high relative to the CDS liquidity.

    As the CDS market matures, the erroneous results of neglecting CDS liquidity becomes

    less striking as long as the net liquidity premium in the bond market remains positive.

    5.2 Estimation from Ask or Bid CDS Premia

    In section 4, we use the CDS ask and bid premia simultaneously in order to extract the

    pure credit risk and liquidity components from CDS premia and bond credit spreads.

    However, only the sum of these components can be observed in practice and our estimate

    could therefore differ significantly from the true values. As a robustness test, we repeat the

    firm-specific estimation procedure described in section 4.2 once using only CDS ask premia

    and once using only CDS bid premia instead of both. We then compare the resulting

    estimates of csdef, csliq, sdef and sliq with those we obtained for the entire sample. Inparticular, we compute the mean, the standard deviation and the mean absolute difference

    between the estimates which are obtained using only one CDS premium and the estimates

    which use both simultaneously. The results are displayed in table 5.

    Table 5 shows that the estimates of the credit risk and liquidity components are almost

    identical regardless of which CDS premia are used in the estimation. On average, the mean

    24

  • 8/3/2019 CDS and Bond Liquidity

    25/38

    estimate of csdef from the CDS ask premium of 47.75 bp falls below the one using both

    premia by 0.01 bp, but the similar standard deviation and the mean absolute deviation of

    0.48 bp imply that the sign is not indicative of a systematic error. The same is true for

    the estimate which uses only the bid premia with a mean difference between the credit

    risk premia of 0.02 bp and a mean absolute error of 0.45 bp. For the bond liquidity

    premia csliq, we observe the reverse result, the mean estimates which only use ask premia

    are slightly higher and the ones using only bid premia are slightly lower. The difference,

    however, does not appear to be systematic in this case either which is supported by the

    low absolute mean deviation of 0.13 bp and 0.14 bp, respectively. The results for the CDS

    credit risk premia sdef and liquidity premia sliq are similar to those for the bond. Again,

    the use of ask premia leads to a very slight underestimation of the credit risk premia and

    overestimation of the liquidity premia while bid premia yield slightly higher values for sdef

    and lower ones for sliq.

    Overall, we find that the choice of ask or bid premia in the CDS market does notsignificantly affect the size and the dynamics of the estimated credit risk and liquidity

    premia. Since these premia are not directly observable in the market, we take the robust

    behavior of the estimates as a sign that our estimation does not result in a systematic

    deviation from the true premia.

    6 Summary and Conclusion

    The purpose of our paper was to develop a credit risk model that simultaneously accounts

    for stochastic liquidity in CDS and bond markets. While there is broad agreement

    in the literature that modelling liquidity in bond prices is an important issue both in

    structural and reduced-form models, CDS markets are often assumed to be perfectly

    liquid. Therefore, default probabilities or, in the context of reduced-form models, default

    intensities, are often estimated directly from observed CDS mid premia and the results

    are used to measure the size of the default component in corporate bond prices and credit

    spreads.

    In our paper, we develop a model that explicitly allows for stochastic liquidity in CDS

    ask and bid premia. As CDS are derivatives and not assets, it is not clear whether

    illiquidity should consistently increase mid premia or whether it should only result in

    larger bid-ask-spreads. We avoid this issue by directly modelling the CDS ask and bid

    premium. This approach allows for closed-form solutions for bond prices and CDS premia

    which are affected by the same default risk but by a different liquidity risk. Specifically,

    we are able to compute a theoretical, liquidity-free credit spread for par bonds and CDS

    premia which are unaffected by the CDS-specific liquidity. These credit risk premia can

    be compared to the corresponding liquidity premia and the CDS mid premium as well as

    25

  • 8/3/2019 CDS and Bond Liquidity

    26/38

    the credit spread. The latter two can be - and our empirical analysis shows them to be -

    affected by illiquidity.

    Eventually, we estimate the model using bond mid prices and CDS ask and bid premia

    for companies with ratings between AAA and CCC from a broad range of sectors. As

    the default-free reference market which is assumed to be of a constant reference liquidity,we use the market for German government bonds. Our results show that the corporate

    bond and CDS markets as a whole reacted strongly to the WorldCom default in late 2002.

    The estimated credit risk component in CDS premia and bond credit spreads is almost

    identical. We also find that the period of highest credit risk coincides with a period of low

    liquidity in the bond market. Liquidity in the CDS market exhibits a less straightforward

    behavior, but it can be observed that the estimate of the pure credit risk component

    in the CDS market becomes more biased towards the bid in times of high credit risk

    for investment-grade CDS. Economically, this suggests that protection sellers demand an

    additional premium in excess of the fair credit risk premium when setting their askquotes. In the subinvestment-grade sample, the evidence is mixed. On the one hand, the

    CDS market shows a higher average liquidity premium than for the investment-grade CDS

    market. On the other hand, liquidity premia can become negative as credit risk rises for

    badly rated debt. This implies that investors increasingly use the CDS market to take on

    synthetic credit risk as the liquidity of the bond market dries up.

    Overall, we observe declining default risk, a slightly increasing bond market liquidity and

    an increase in liquidity in conjunction with a more symmetrical distribution of liquidity

    premia in the CDS market. From an economic perspective, this agrees with the evolution

    and the standardization of the CDS market. The asymmetrical distribution of the liquiditypremia between protection buyers and sellers in the CDS market indicates that CDS mid

    premia are not an appropriate measure of the pure credit risk component. In a firm-specific

    analysis, we show that restricting stochastic liquidity to the bond market can result in

    price surcharges and yield discounts for corporate bonds. This effect, however, becomes

    less apparent as CDS market liquidity evolves.

    An issue not addressed in this paper is that CDS contracts are usually designed to allow

    for a number of bonds deliverable upon the default of a given reference asset. Before

    default, however, it is not clear which of the admissible bond will be cheapest to deliver.

    The choice option of the protection buyer should also be priced in CDS premia.

    As a second extension of our model, it is also possible to add information from the

    stock market. Blanco et al. (2005) and Norden and Weber (2004) have explored the

    information spillover between stock, CDS and bond markets, and their results suggest

    that incorporating stock market information may facilitate the estimation of the default

    intensity. It may be interesting to explore whether including this information in a

    reduced-form model will render explicit liquidity-modelling in CDS premia unnecessary

    26

  • 8/3/2019 CDS and Bond Liquidity

    27/38

    or whether, as our results suggest, our proposed extension of the existing reduced-form

    models is vital if information from the CDS market is used.

    27

  • 8/3/2019 CDS and Bond Liquidity

    28/38

    References

    V. Acharya and L. Pedersen. Asset pricing with liquidity risk. Journal of Financial

    Economics, 77:375410, 2005.

    D. Aunon-Nerin, D. Cossin, T. Hricko, and Z. Huang. Exploring for the Determinants

    of Credit Risk in Credit Default Swap Transaction Data: Is Fixed Income Markets

    Information Sufficient to Evaluate Credit Risk? Working Paper, HEC-University of

    Lausanne and FAME, 2002.

    R. Blanco, S. Brennan, and I. W. Marsh. An empirical analysis of the dynamic relationship

    between investment-grade bonds and credit default swaps. Journal of Finance, 60(5):

    22552281, 2005.

    D. Bongaerts, F. De Jong, and J. Driessen. Liquidity and liquidity risk premia in the cds

    market. Working Paper, University of Amsterdam, 2007.

    British Bankers Association. 2003/2004 Credit Derivatives Report.

    http://www.bba.org.uk, 2004.

    R. Chen, X. Cheng, and L. Wu. Dynamic interactions between interest rate, credit, and

    liquidity risks: Theory and evicence from the term structure of credit default swap

    spreads. Working Paper, 2005.

    P. Collin-Dufresne, R. S. Goldstein, and J. S. Martin. The determinants of credit spread

    changes. Journal of Finance, 61(6):21772207, 2001.

    F. De Jong and J. Driessen. Liquidity risk premia in corporate bond markets. Working

    Paper, University of Amsterdam, 2005.

    D. Duffie. Credit swap valuation. Financial Analysts Journal, 55:7387, 1999.

    D. Duffie and J. Liu. Recursive valuation of defaultable securities and the timing of

    resolution of uncertainty. Annals of Applied Probability, 6:10751090, 2001.

    D. Duffie and K. J. Singleton. An econometric model of the term structure of interest rate

    swap yields. Journal of Finance, 52(4):12871321, 1997.

    E. J. Elton, M. J. Gruber, D. Agrawal, and C. Mann. Explaining the rate spread on

    corporate bonds. Journal of Finance, 56(1):247277, 2001.

    J. Ericsson and O. Renault. Liquidity and credit risk. Journal of Finance, 61(5):22192250,

    2006.

    European Central Bank Financial Stability Report June 2007. 2007.

    28

  • 8/3/2019 CDS and Bond Liquidity

    29/38

    L. Fisher. Determinants of risk premiums on corporate bonds. Journal of Political

    Economy, 67:217237, 1959.

    D. Fowler and H. Rorke. Risk measurement when shares are subject to infrequent trading:

    Comment. Journal of Financial Economics, 12:27928391, 1983.

    P. Houweling and T. Vorst. Pricing default swaps: Empirical evidence. Journal of

    International Money and Finance, 24:12001225, 2005.

    F.A. Longstaff, S. Mithal, and E. Neis. Corporate yield spreads: Default risk or liquidity?

    new evidence from the creditdefault swap market. Journal of Finance, 60(5):22132254,

    2005.

    L. Meng and O. Ap Gwilym. The determinants of cds bid-ask spreads. Univerity of Wales

    Research Paper 2006-7, 2006.

    L. Norden and M. Weber. The comovement of credit default swap, bond and stock markets:an empirical analysis. Working Paper, University of Mannheim, 2004.

    M. Schueler and R. Galletto. Basis trading. Working Paper, JP Morgan Credit Derivatives

    Marketing, 2003.

    D. Tang and H. Yan. Liquidity, liquidity spillover, and credit default swap spreads.

    Working Paper, 2006.

    29

  • 8/3/2019 CDS and Bond Liquidity

    30/38

    Appendix A. Analytical Solutions for the Discount Factors

    The dynamics of the default and liquidity intensities are defined as follows. First, we

    define the independent intensities and through the following system of stochastic

    differential equations:dt

    dt

    =

    t

    dt +

    t 0

    0

    dW,t

    dW,t

    , (16)

    with constants , , , and and independent Brownian motions W and W. The

    correlated intensities and are then defined asdt

    dt

    =

    dt

    + f dtf dt + dt

    = t + f

    + f t dt +

    t f

    f t dW,t

    dW,t .We can rewrite the sum of the correlated intensities as a weighted sum of the independent

    intensities:

    t + t = 0 + 0 +

    t0

    ds +

    t0

    ds

    = 0 + 0 +

    t0

    s + f

    ds +

    t0

    + f

    t

    ds

    +t

    0

    s + f

    s

    dW,s +

    t0

    (f + )dW,s

    = 0 + 0 +

    t0

    (1 + f) s

    ds +

    t0

    (1 + f) ds

    +

    t0

    (1 + f)

    sdW,s +

    t0

    (1 + f) dW,s

    =

    =:(1+f)0

    0 +=:(1+f)0

    0 + (1 + f) t

    0

    ds

    + (1 + f)

    t

    0

    ds

    = (1 + f) t + (1 + f) t.

    30

  • 8/3/2019 CDS and Bond Liquidity

    31/38

    Since and are independent, the joint expectation for the discount factors P(t1, t2)

    and L (t1, t2) equals:

    Et

    P(t1, t2) L (t1, t2)

    = Et

    exp

    t2t1

    sds

    exp

    t2t1

    sds

    = Et expt2t1

    s + sds= Et

    exp

    t2t1

    (1 + f) s + (1 + f) sds

    = Et

    exp

    t2t1

    (1 + f) sds

    Et

    exp

    t2t1

    (1 + f) sds

    =: P

    (1 + f) , t1, t2

    L

    (1 + f) , t1, t2.

    The dynamics of the scaled intensities f := (1 + f) and f := (1 + f) areidentical to those of the independent intensities with the process parameters adjusted:

    tf = (1 + f) t

    = (1 + f) 0 + (1 + f) t0

    ds

    = (1 + f) 0 =0

    f

    +

    t0

    (1 + f) =:f

    (1 + f) s =s

    f

    ds

    +

    t0

    1 + f =:f

    (1 + f) s

    =

    sf

    dW,s

    = 0f + t0f sf ds + t

    0fsfdW,s

    dtf =f tf

    dt + f

    t

    f dW,t,

    tf = (1 + f) t

    = (1 + f) 0 + (1 + f) t0

    ds

    = (1 + f) 0

    =0f+

    t0

    (1 + f)

    =:fds +

    t0

    (1 + f)

    =:fdW,s

    dtf = f dt + f dW,t ,

    that is the scaled intensities also follow a square root process, respectively an arithmetic

    Brownian motion. Thus, the following well-known analytical solutions arise for

    31

  • 8/3/2019 CDS and Bond Liquidity

    32/38

    Pf, t1, t2

    and L

    f, t1, t2

    :

    Pf, t1, t2

    := a1 (t1, t2) exp

    t1f a2 (t1, t2)

    ,

    Lf, t1, t2 := a3 (t1, t2) exp t1

    f

    a4 (t1, t2) ,

    a1 (t1, t2) =

    1

    1 exp[ (t2 t1)] 2

    2

    exp

    (+ )

    2(t2 t1)

    ,

    a2 (t1, t2) = f2

    +2

    f2 ( exp[ (t2 t1)] 1) ,

    a3 (t1, t2) = exp

    f

    2 (t2 t1)36

    +f (t2 t1)2

    6

    ,

    a4 (t1, t2) = t2 t1,

    =

    2f2 + 2,

    =+

    .

    The bond and CDS pricing equations do not only contain the expectation of the

    simultaneous default risk and liquidity discount factors but also Et

    P(t, ti1) L (t, ti)

    .

    Since and are correlated, we also have to determine the expectation of thisnon-simultaneous discount factor. Wlg, assume that t = t1, ti1 = t2 and ti = t3. Then,

    the definition of P and L implies that

    P(t1, t2) L (t1, t3) = exp

    t2t1

    sds

    exp

    t3t1

    sds

    = exp

    t2t1

    sds t2t1

    sds t3t2

    sds

    = exp

    t2t1

    (1 + f)s + (1 + f) s

    ds t3t2

    sds

    .

    We also know that

    s = 0 +

    s0

    du

    = 0 + f 0 +

    s0

    du + f du

    = s + f s.

    32

  • 8/3/2019 CDS and Bond Liquidity

    33/38

    Therefore, we can rewrite the above exponential function as

    exp

    (1 + f) t2t1

    sds

    =:I (1 + f)

    t2t1

    sds

    =:II f

    t3t2

    sds

    =:II It3t2

    sds

    =:IV

    for which we need to determine expectation at time t1. Applying the law of iterated

    expectations, we obtain

    Et1 [exp(I II III IV)] = Et1 [Et2 [exp(I II III IV)]]= Et1 [exp(I II) Et2 [exp(II I IV)]]

    = Et1

    exp(I II) Et2 [exp(II I)]

    =P(f,t2,t3)

    Et2 [exp (IV)]

    =L(,t2,t3)

    = Et1 exp(I) Pf , t2, t3

    Et1

    exp(III) L, t2, t3

    =: P(f, t1, t2) L

    lf, t1, t2

    ,

    where the first equality follows from the law of iterated expectations, the second from the

    fact that I and II are known at t2 and the third and fourth from the independence of

    and . The last two expectation terms are the moment-generating functions of and

    with the following well-known solutions:

    Et1exp(I) Pf , t2, t3 = a1 (t2, t3) Et1 exp (1 + f) t2

    t1

    sds

    expa2 (t2, t3) f t2

    = a1 (t2, t3) b1 (t2, t3) exp

    t1 b2 (t2, t3)

    ,

    Et1

    exp(II I) L

    , t2, t3

    = a3 (t2, t3) Et1

    exp

    (1 + f)

    t2t1

    sds

    expa4 (t2, t3) t2= a3 (t2, t3) b3 (t2, t3) exp

    t1 b4 (t2, t3)

    ,

    33

  • 8/3/2019 CDS and Bond Liquidity

    34/38

    b1 (t2, t3) =2 exp

    t3t22 ( + )

    2 f a2 (t2, t3)(exp[ (t3 t2)] 1) + + exp [ (t3 t2)] ( + )

    2

    2

    ,

    b2 (t2, t3) =

    f

    a2 (t2, t3) [ + + exp [ (t3

    t2)] (

    )] + 2 (1 + f)(exp[ (t3

    t2)]

    1)

    2 f a2 (t2, t3)(exp[ (t3 t2)] 1) + + exp [ (t3 t2)] ( + ) ,

    b3 (t2, t3) = exp

    1

    62 (1 + f)

    2 (t3 t2)3 + (1 + f)2

    2a4 (t2, t3) +

    (t3 t2)2

    +2a4 (t2, t3) + 2

    2a4 (t2, t3) (t3 t2)

    ,

    b4 (t2, t3) = a4 (t2, t3) + (1 + f) (t3 t2) .

    34

  • 8/3/2019 CDS and Bond Liquidity

    35/38

    Table1:ReferenceEnt

    itiesbyRatingClassandIn

    dustrySector

    Thetableshowsth

    enumberofreferenceentitiesineach

    ratingclassandindustrygroup.

    Rat

    ingsareaveragesforthereferenceent

    ityover

    timewhenbothCD

    Spremiaandatleast2bondyields

    wereobserved.

    Thelastcolumnsand

    rowsshowthenumberofobservedm

    idbond

    yieldsandmidCD

    Spremia.

    ThenumberofsyntheticalbondyieldsmatchedtotheCDSc

    ontractmaturityequalsthenumber

    ofCDS

    observationsandis

    thereforesuppressed.

    AAA

    AA

    A

    BBB

    BB

    B

    All

    #

    Obs.Bonds

    #

    Obs.CDS

    Basi

    cMaterials

    -

    2

    4

    7

    2

    1

    16

    33,3

    93

    13,0

    79

    Com

    munication

    -

    1

    7

    8

    3

    -

    19

    73,2

    11

    20,4

    81

    Cycl.Cons.Goods

    -

    2

    3

    9

    2

    -

    16

    47,4

    97

    15,6

    34

    Diversified

    -

    -

    2

    2

    -

    -

    4

    6,5

    36

    3,0

    96

    Financial

    -

    22

    28

    4

    -

    -

    54

    175,8

    70

    38,0

    46

    Industrial

    -

    -

    4

    5

    -

    -

    9

    40,6

    24

    9,5

    31

    Noncycl.Cons.Goods

    -

    -

    5

    8

    1

    -

    14

    40,5

    19

    12,3

    19

    Sovereign

    5

    1

    3

    3

    2

    2

    16

    55,1

    45

    6,5

    94

    Utility

    1

    5

    13

    4

    -

    -

    23

    79,6

    04

    19,0

    36

    All

    6

    33

    69

    50

    10

    3

    171

    552,3

    99

    137,8

    16

    #O

    bs.Bonds

    40,4

    14

    137,7

    02

    193,1

    95

    161,1

    82

    16,3

    99

    3,5

    07

    552

    ,399

    #

    Obs.CDS

    2,9

    46

    29,1

    29

    55,2

    21

    41,5

    27

    7,9

    62

    1,0

    31

    137

    ,816

    35

  • 8/3/2019 CDS and Bond Liquidity

    36/38

    Table 2: Estimated Credit Risk and Liquidity Premia

    The table shows the mean, standard deviation, minimum and maximum for

    the credit risk and the liquidity premia components for each rating class. All

    values are in basis points.

    AAA AA A BBB BB B CCC All

    csdef 6.11 13.05 28.53 55.33 249.52 349.97 250.83 47.76

    Std. Dev.(csdef) 4.46 10.60 28.35 65.59 242.82 167.45 34.96 83.71

    min(csdef) 2.96 2.96 8.32 11.20 33.08 32.60 111.92 2.96

    max(csdef) 52.91 260.85 260.85 1,201.93 1,948.43 1,175.58 397.29 1,948.43

    csliq 1.55 12.60 18.12 42.81 62.58 83.68 71.23 26.54

    Std. Dev.(csliq) 3.10 30.33 43.56 58.57 64.51 47.13 28.94 48.10

    min(csliq) 0.66 3.09 3.09 4.87 21.07 14.50 1.50 0.66

    max(csliq) 30.78 508.81 495.96 349.34 537.66 296.79 194.23 537.66

    sdef

    6.38 13.72 28.95 56.89 252.92 351.04 252.20 49.38Std. Dev.(sdef) 4.41 18.30 28.36 64.67 2