182
1 Claus Thrane-Jensen CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on new venture creation PhD Thesis Department of Management School of Economics and Management University of Aarhus Denmark 2006

CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    1

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

1

Claus Thrane-Jensen

CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR -

A contingency approach on new venture creation

PhD Thesis

Department of Management

School of Economics and Management

University of Aarhus

Denmark

2006

Page 2: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

2

Acknowledgements

I would like to thank a number of people for their support and assistance with writing

this dissertation. First of all, I would like to thank the reviewers and examiners of my

work, Professor Bengt Johannisson, Professor Torben Eli Bager, and Professor Ole

Øhlenschlæger Madsen. I am very grateful to you for your effort and professional

expertise in commenting on and further developing my dissertation. Moreover, I am

grateful to my supervisor and mentor, Associate Professor Per Blenker, and my

secondary advisor, Professor Jørn Flohr Nielsen, for your enthusiasm, academic

creativity, intellectual inspiration, and personal interest.

I also would like to thank the people at the Department of Management (University of

Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette Andersen for proofreading my

German-English and Bibiana Paluszewska for her support through the years.

Finally, I am greatly indebted to my family – my four parents, my three siblings, and

of course my grandmother Mrs. Jensen for being a constant source of support and

encouragement throughout my life. I am extremely grateful to my wife, Riitta, my

daughter Sarah, and my son Buster for their love and forbearance, which made all my

endeavors worthwhile.

Aarhus, 2006 Claus Thrane-Jensen

Page 3: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

3

CONTENT 1. INTRODUCTION 4 2. STATUS AMONG MANAGEMENT JOURNALS 46 AND THE FORUM FOR ENTREPRENEURSHIP RESEARCH 3. A REVITALIZATION OF PERSONAL TRAITS 76 AS COMPLEMENTARY TO THE COGNITIVE APPROACH IN ASPECTS OF NEW VENTURE CREATION 4. PERSONAL NETWORKS IN DIFFERENT PHASES 109 OF NEW VENTURE CREATION 5. GOVERNANCE MECHANISMS IN THE PECKING ORDER 147 OF NEW VENTURE FINANCE 6. DANISH SUMMARY (DANSK RESUME) 180

Page 4: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

4

Introduction

Recent research on entrepreneurship has paid growing attention to the creation of new

ventures (e.g. Gartner 1985, 1988; Katz 1991; MacMillan 1993; Gartner and Shane

1995; Shane 1997; Low and Abrahamson 1997; Gartner, Starr, and Bhat 1999;

McGrath 1999; Audretsch and Thurik 2001; Davidsson, Low, and Wright 2001;

Chandler and Lyon 2001; Shook, Priem, and Mcgee 2003; Parker and Gartner 2004;

Kuratko 2005; Eckhardt, Shane, and Delmar 2006; Lichtenstein, Dooley, and

Lumpkin 2006). In fact Shook et al. (2000) argue that new venture creation is at the

heart of entrepreneurship. Gartner (1988) even provocatively argues that

entrepreneurship is the creation of new organizations.

The increased attention is primarily based on the widespread assumption that new

venture creation is a vehicle for economic and societal growth (e.g. Reynolds 1987;

Low and MacMillan 1988; Shane 1996; Wennekers and Thurik 1999; Davidsson and

Henrekson 2002; Audretsch and Keilbach 2004; Noorderhaven et al. 2004; Rocha

2004; Arenius and Minniti 2005; Sternberg and Wennekers 2005; van Stel, Carree,

and Thurik 2005; Wong, Ho, and Autio 2005). Moreover a large percentage of the

population is at some point involved in starting a new venture. For example Reynolds

(1997) suggests that about 5% of the adult population each year take actions to start a

new venture. According to the Danish National Agency for Enterprise and

Construction the number is the same in Denmark (Erhvervs- og Boligstyrelsen 2003).

Accordingly, practitioners as well as politicians seek to enhance the efficacy of public

or private assistance programs including financial aid programs and educational

programs on (aspects of) new venture creation, not only to create more start-ups but

also to increase the survival rate and successfulness among new ventures. Hence,

there is an outspoken demand to build theories and carry out effective empirical

research to gain a better understanding of the phenomenon of new venture creation.

This dissertation contributes to the general knowledge of the process of new venture

creation on the level of the individual entrepreneur. This does not imply that other

Page 5: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

5

levels of analysis such as institutional, cultural, or environmental characteristics are

not important or that there is no environmental interaction going on with important

consequences for the rate of entrepreneurship and new venture founding (Gartner

1985; Aldrich 1999; Shane and Venkataraman 2000). Clearly, the rate of new venture

founding is affected by such things as the state of the economy, cultural limitations,

the capital market, competitors, government policies, technological conditions, and

societal factors. However, this dissertation focuses on the influence and characteristics

of the individual entrepreneur rather than environmental antecedents and

consequences (see also Shane and Venkataraman 2000 and Shook, Priem, and Mcgee

2003). Following the work of Burt (1992) it is suggested that every individual brings

human, social, and financial capital to the competitive arena. This dissertation devotes

one article to each type of capital in the domain of entrepreneurship and new venture

creation in particular. A common theme in the three papers is the recognition that the

field has produced what appear to be superficial conflicts of thesis and anti-thesis.

Each paper then seeks reconciliation, not through the introduction of synthesis, but of

contingencies of emergence. Hence, existing research on new venture creation is

reconsidered through the lens of a contingency that considers the different needs for

human, social, and financial capital in different phases of new venture creation.

Even though the practical aspects of this array of research are easily legitimized, this

stream of research in academia is still in its infancy (Gartner, Davidsson, and Zahra

2006). In fact, the field of entrepreneurship is one of the youngest schools of thought

in the management discipline which presents scholars seeking legitimacy in this field

with a series of challenges. As suggested by Whitley (2000) the semi permanent

nature of employment in universities and business schools accentuates the importance

of legitimacy and reputation in the sense that jobs and promotions in academia are

highly dependent upon obtaining legitimacy from the dominant management

discourse. This creates a dilemma for scholars in entrepreneurship to contextualize

research in entrepreneurship to the general field of management while building a

perception that entrepreneurship offers a unique and different stream of research to

make it a legitimate research endeavour (see also Busenitz et al. 2003). This

dissertation deals with this dilemma by focusing on the creation of new ventures,

Page 6: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

6

which is not dealt with specifically in the established management discipline, and at

the same time draws on an extensive body of research in the management domain as

well as research in other well-established domains such as psychology and sociology.

Finally, to legitimize this research even further, the first paper in this dissertation,

entitled: “Status among management journals and the forum for entrepreneurship

research”, shows that the legitimacy of entrepreneurship research have indeed

experienced a notable increase since the mid-eighties among high status journals in

the management discipline. Hence, as suggested by Shook et al. (2000)

entrepreneurship is maturing as a discipline and a legitimate area of research in the

management discipline.

CLASSIFICATIONS AND DEFINITIONS

Following the footsteps of Gartner (1985, 1988) entrepreneurship in this dissertation

is conveniently classified as the behavior and activities involved in the process of new

venture creation. Accordingly, an entrepreneur is in this dissertation the individual

who creates new ventures. While this may seem like a minimalist approach to

entrepreneurship it enables a sense of consistency in the dissertation. Moreover, the

approach is backed by the most agreed upon central features of entrepreneurship as

suggested by Gartner’s empirical analysis from 1990. This analysis suggests that out

of 90 possible attributes the two most agreed upon central features among scholars

and practitioners were: 1) the creation of a new business; 2) new venture

development.

A recent stream of research canonized in Shane and Venkataraman (2000) emphasizes

that entrepreneurship addresses a different set of issues than the creation of new

organizations or more specifically points out that entrepreneurship does not require,

but may include the creation of new ventures as they want to highlight the possibility

of different modes of exploitation as well as a criterion for innovativeness. Clearly,

this dissertation does not wish to exclude aspects of entrepreneurship that are

interesting to other scholars, but argues that new venture creation is a situation where

we should at least agree that entrepreneurship is taking place. Hence, entrepreneurship

Page 7: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

7

and new venture creation are arguably not the same, but aspects of new venture

creation retain a fundamental domain in entrepreneurship (cf. Gartner 1990). In this

respect the dissertation agrees with Venkataraman (1997) and Shane and

Venkataraman (2000) in their definition of entrepreneurship as the scholarly

examination of how, by whom, and with what effects opportunities to create future

goods and services are discovered, evaluated, and exploited. In other words, the field

of entrepreneurship should focus on recognition and exploitation of opportunities, the

individuals involved, and the modes of actions used to exploit the opportunities (see

also Bygrave 1993; Hitt et al. 2001; Zahra and Dess 2001; Eckhardt and Shane 2003;

and Davidsson and Honig 2003).

However, two basic contingencies are added to the definition in this dissertation: 1)

that this scholarly examination is done within the realm of new venture creation; 2)

that new ventures per definition provide a new means-end framework. The first

premise is basically a matter of framing the dissertation inside the domain of new

venture creation. We need this distinction because opportunity discovery and

exploitation can easily be related to different units of interests such as the individual

entrepreneur, the new venture, industries, technologies, institution, government and

also different levels of analysis such as individual, social, financial, institutional,

cultural, and environmental characteristics. So the first premise is basically a matter of

focus.

The second aspect may however be somewhat more controversial. Shane and

Venkataraman (2000) – among others – manifest the limitation that entrepreneurship

is dealing with new means-end frameworks restating the concept of ‘opportunities’ as

‘entrepreneurial opportunities’ (see also Casson 1982; Gaglio and Katz 2001;

Eckhardt and Shane 2003). Entrepreneurial opportunities are defined as a situation in

which an entrepreneur can introduce new goods, services, raw materials, markets

and/or organizational methods through the formation of a new means-end framework

(Shane and Venkataraman 2000). This description is very similar to and very much

inspired by Schumpeter (1934). According to Schumpeter, a change in the ‘circular

flow of economic life’, or what economists would generally consider as an external

Page 8: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

8

shock to equilibrium, appears when the means of production is combined in a new

way. Schumpeter suggested five possible ways to carry out these new combinations,

namely through the introduction of: 1) a new product; 2) a new untested method of

production; 3) a new untested market; 4) new and untested sources of supply; and 5) a

new organization of the industry including the break-up or set-up of a monopoly

position. Moreover, as suggested by Kirzner (1997), it is exactly the creation of new

means-end frameworks through the introduction of one or several new combinations

that is the crucial part of the difference between entrepreneurial opportunities and

‘regular’ optimization or opportunities within existing means-end frameworks. For

example, if you optimize your existing machinery using known techniques to make it

run twice as fast to avoid huge loads of inventory, it would be considered a ‘regular’

optimization and a regular opportunity, not an entrepreneurial opportunity. On the

other hand, if you introduce a new machine with a unique set of new combinations

that run twice as fast as the old one, it would be considered an entrepreneurial

opportunity.

As a natural consequence, in this line of thinking it is only during the period when

people are in the actual process of recognizing and/or exploiting one or several of the

five functions that they are called entrepreneurs, and they continue to be entrepreneurs

only for as long as they perform these functions (Schumpeter 1934). In other words, it

is only in the process of recognizing and exploiting new means-end frameworks that

we may use the term ‘entrepreneur’. Even though this is indeed an alluring distinction

between entrepreneurship and other ‘regular’ areas of study, the fundamental

consequences of this approach to empirical research in entrepreneurship are

demoralizing. If empirical research in entrepreneurship had to take these aspects into

consideration the mere sampling of ‘real’ entrepreneurs or ‘real’ entrepreneurial

situations would be a subhuman exercise filled with arbitrary choices. For example,

when are new combinations and new means-end frameworks no longer considered

new? Does an entrepreneurial new venture need to go public with a new combination

before we stop calling it an entrepreneurial opportunity, how many products should be

sold before we stop calling it a new combination, is it a matter of months or years or

any other timeframe, is the entrepreneurial opportunity not entrepreneurial if it is

Page 9: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

9

imitated by competitors, or how many people should adopt the new means-end

framework before it is no longer considered new? By the same token, it is also

difficult to know exactly whether a person is introducing an entrepreneurial

opportunity or just following a regular opportunity within an existing means-end

framework. For example, is the opening of a new McDonald’s restaurant located five

minutes away from an existing McDonald’s an introduction of a new combination and

an entrepreneurial action or is it just regular optimizing? Now, what if the new

McDonald’s introduced singing waiters, would we then consider it a new combination

and an entrepreneurial opportunity instead of merely a regular opportunity? Thus,

when is a new means-end framework literally new and when do we start referring to it

as an existing means-end framework? Finally, should we use time, diffusion of

means-end framework or other measures to make this distinction? The point is

illustrated in Figure 1.

Figure 1: An illustration of blurring borders between regular and entrepreneurial

opportunities.

In order to cope with the fundamental problem of the innovativeness criterion in the

definition of entrepreneurship, this dissertation joins Bhave (1994) in suggesting that

the introduction of new ventures with complete lack of novelty tends not to appear

empirically. Hence, it is suggested that the focus of new venture creation is

automatically a focus on new means-ends frameworks. Moreover, this fundamental

assumption allows us to draw on a line of empirical evidence on new ventures without

inferring on the innovativeness of each observation.

Entrepreneurial opportunity Regular

opportunity Regular

opportunity

? ?

Time/diffusion of means-end framework/?

Page 10: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

10

IS THERE SOMETHING ROTTEN IN THE STATE OF

ENTREPRENEURSHIP?

The last two decades have witnessed increased attention towards the domain of

entrepreneurship manifested in a vast amount of articles dealing with a wide range of

topics from a wide range of disciplinary backgrounds using a variety of theories and

methodologies (Amit, Glosten, and Muller 1993; MacMillan 1993; Birley and

Westhead 1994; Shane and Venkataraman 2000; Covin, Slevin, and Heeley 2000;

Gartner 2001; Eckhardt and Shane 2003). However, even though scholars have

presented an impressive amount and range of research, Shane and Venkataraman

(2000) recently concluded that the field of entrepreneurship is simply a broad label

under which a hodgepodge of research is housed, and that every piece of research

added to the entrepreneurship puzzle only obscures the overall understanding of

entrepreneurship and new venture creation. Moreover, there appears to be widespread

agreement that entrepreneurship research needs to develop better theory (Shane and

Venkataraman 2000; Davidsson, Low, and Wright 2001; Gartner 2001; Low 2001).

For example, Low (2001) as well as Davidsson, Low, and Wright (2001) claim that

the field is caught in an atheoretical empiricism and a subsequent lack of respect.

In the same vein, several scholars claim that the field of entrepreneurship is too

pluralistic and fragmented without any integrating theories, definitions, and methods

(Low and Abrahamson 1997; Aldrich and Baker 1997; Alvarez and Busenitz 2001).

Aldrich and Baker (1997) directly suggest that entrepreneurship has only made

limited progress toward normal science status in a Kuhnian sense and they push for a

single unifying framework in order to progress towards this paradigmatic ideal. The

underlying premises of this critique is that the field needs some kind of overarching

unifying paradigm to fruitfully progress and legitimize itself as a scientific endeavor

(Bull and Thomas 1993; Bull and Willard 1993). It is expected that the unifying

paradigm will point out what counts as legitimate research methods and research

problems even at a highly detailed level, and thereby facilitate more efficient

communication and collaboration among researchers based on a shared vocabulary

and epistemological as well as ontological consensus (Pfeffer 1993).

Page 11: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

11

This dissertation does not agree with this paradigmatic position. Moreover, as

suggested in chapter 2 of the dissertation entitled: “Status among management

journals and the forum for entrepreneurship research”, the field of entrepreneurship is

increasingly manifesting itself as a highly legitimate field of research that does not

lack respect as suggested by Low (2001). Moreover, it is suggested in the following

that this paradigmatic ideal is put forth without considering the particularities of

entrepreneurship as a research field. An analogy from a fundamental debate in

sociology on the solidarity and differentiation of society seeks to highlight these

aspects.

Organic solidarity due to the division of research areas

The challenge to the field of entrepreneurship resembles the challenge of

differentiation to society in general as discussed by the classical French sociologist,

Emile Durkheim, more than a hundred years ago (Durkheim 1893). Durkheim

developed a typology of societies, a mechanical and an organic society, in terms of

their basis of solidarity. The two types rest on different principles of social

integration, involving different morphologies, different systems of symbols, and

different structures of networks. The typology presents not only a distinction between

traditional and modern societies, but also the changing forms of social integration that

emerge with an increasing differentiation of social structures. In the writings of

Durkheim, the source of the differentiation of the social structure was mainly

associated with the increased division of labor, which was considered an inevitable

challenge to the social structure in society in the late eighteenth century. Hence, the

two types of solidarity were not framed as a matter of choice, but more as (a

description of) an unavoidable change in the basis for solidarity due to the increased

division of labor. In fact, the headline in chapter three of Durkheim (1893) can be

translated into “Organic solidarity due to the division of labor”.

According to Durkheim, the mechanical solidarity was based upon a strong collective

conscience regulating the thoughts and actions of individuals located within similar

Page 12: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

12

structural units. The morphology, or structure, of mechanical societies is kinship units

that share strong commitment to common goals. Accordingly, individual freedom,

choice, and autonomy are low in mechanical societies. In a Kuhnian sense, the

mechanical solidarity resembles the behavioral control that a unifying paradigm may

(or is expected to) exert in an academic discipline. In contrast, organically structured

societies are typified by large populations, which are distributed in specialized roles in

many diverse structural units that are needed to unfold the advantages of the increased

division of labor. Highly general values form the exchange contracts and norms

regulating the interdependencies among specialized social units. As the division of

labor grows, the functional interdependencies between individuals should stimulate

the efficient peer pressure and secure a high and diligent work effort. Thus, instead of

relying on a unified paradigm in a Kuhnian sense, which directly controls the

behavior of individuals, Durkheim expected another type of social structure to emerge

on the basis of interdependencies among specialized social units driven by a need to

secure a high and diligent work effort.

The field of entrepreneurship is equally confronted with a high division of labor in

terms of the numerous (units and levels of) analyses and approaches from diverging

disciplines that are necessary to grasp the complexity of entrepreneurship and new

venture development (see e.g. Thornton 1999; Shane and Venkataraman 2000;

Davidsson, Low, and Wright 2001; Davidsson and Wiklund 2001; Gartner 2001;

Ucbasaran, Westhead, and Wright 2001; Shook, Priem, and Mcgee 2003). As

suggested by Gartner (2001), no single theory will be able to take account of the

complexity of entrepreneurship suggesting that scholars should concentrate on

building up a body of theories. Then, as intriguing as a paradigmatic development

may appear – perhaps due to ‘economics envy’ – the characteristics of the subject of

research in entrepreneurship make this paradigmatic development both unlikely and

unwanted. Hence, according to Gartner, we cannot expect and in fact do not need an

overarching theory of entrepreneurship (Gartner 2001). Moreover as suggested by

(Thornton 1999) intellectual development of the entrepreneurship field is greatly

dependent on learning from other social sciences including for example sociology and

psychology. This dependence on other disciplines is equally manifested in the citation

Page 13: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

13

in and to entrepreneurship from a variety of disciplines in chapter 2 of this

dissertation. Finally, as suggested in chapter 2, it is unwarranted to jump to the

conclusion that the field of entrepreneurship lacks legitimacy and respect. In a recent

review of research in entrepreneurship, Ucbasaran, Westhead, and Wright (2001)

demonstrate the wide range of subjects, levels, and units of analyses the scholars in

entrepreneurship have chosen as the main focus of their research. However, they

actually come to the conclusion that most research projects have a clear focus whereas

the field as a whole does not. The point is that entrepreneurship research offers

multiple and relatively well-defined foci, causing the field to appear unfocused due to

its complexity. Then, because entrepreneurship needs multiple disciplines, ontologies,

and methodologies to emerge in a positive direction, no single overarching framework

or paradigm is able to deal with all aspects of entrepreneurship (Gartner 2001;

Davidsson, Low, and Wright 2001).

As a consequence, Gartner (2001) suggests that scholars in the field of

entrepreneurship need to choose sides in the sense that research should be divided into

homogenous groups studying more specific topics in entrepreneurship such as new

venture creation, firm growth, and venture capital; each subfield with a clearly

defined epistemology, ontology, and methodology. Thus, instead of giving up the

mechanical ideal with a unified structure controlled by an overarching paradigm

because of the complexity and differentiation of the field, Gartner (2001) seeks to

reduce the complexity by narrowing down the field to homogenous mechanical sub-

societies. This approach resembles the approach of the isolationists, which was

originally presented in Burell and Morgan (1979) and later in Jackson and Carter

(1991). According to this approach, scholars may basically choose whatever paradigm

in a discipline as long as they stick to that specific paradigm. However, this approach

forces the researcher to make artificial, stultifying and unnecessary choices among

paradigms that only limit the researcher in his/her endeavor (Reed 1992; Ackroyd

1992; Hassard 1993; Willmott 1993). According to Hassard, the isolationist view: “…

advance[s] a very pure and hermetic form of sociological relativism, one which brings

into question the very basis for scientific communication and progress” (1993: 69).

This is equally suggested by Davidsson, Low, and Wright (2001), who argue that

Page 14: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

14

even if narrowing topics of interest in entrepreneurship makes the field more

manageable, the field is not fundamentally altered. Gartner (2001) uses the analogy of

the “blind men and the elephant” offering a syllogism for thinking about problems of

integrating differing views of a large and complex phenomenon. However, it seems

like Gartner’s solution to this syllogism is telling the blind men where to feel the

elephant. Even so, the elephant does not become a less complex phenomenon.

The premise of this dissertation is that the socket spanner set sold with a car can easily

be used to fix problems on bikes and leaking water pipes as well. In other words, if we

have tools available from other disciplines it would be wasteful and ignorant not to

use and combine them. Moreover, as suggested by Thornton (1999), a secondary but

equally important benefit in using available tools from other disciplines is that it

contributes both to legitimacy and quality of entrepreneurship research. Hence, the

premise of this dissertation is that entrepreneurship researchers should use theory

from management, marketing, psychology, sociology, economics and from various

other disciplines that may shed light on the process of new venture creation. Even if

theories are not directly applicable ‘as is’ they may contain elements that are of great

value for making progress within the research on new venture creation. This approach

is often referred to as a multi-paradigmatic approach.

A multi-paradigmatic answer

As suggested by Davidsson, Low, and Wright, “The challenge is to create a

community of scholars that bring insights from multiple disciplines to investigate a set

of phenomena that are neither too broad as to defy the notion of intellectual

community nor so narrow as to lose sight of our goal” (2001: 7). Thus, multiple

paradigms are required to adequately accommodate the multifaceted nature of the

research phenomenon in entrepreneurship. In this way, the use of multiple paradigms

will further our understanding of the social phenomenon by introducing a more

comprehensive set of explanations. Contrary to Gartner (2001), however, the multi-

paradigmatic approach sees the necessity and possibility for dialogue and bridges

between different paradigms while holding on to the possibility and necessity for

paradigms and intellectual communities embedded in subgroups of social or cognitive

Page 15: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

15

relations instead of a paradigm collapse into a broader disintegrated framework.

Importantly, however, these subgroups, or what we might refer to as ‘small’ research

communities, are not completely isolated from the rest of the network, but in some

sense are functionally dependent on the flow of information between these subgroups

as suggested by Durkheim (1893).

The multi-paradigmatic approach is often associated with the term ‘pluralism’ and a

postmodern position. In a somewhat positive sense, the concept of pluralism refers to

the standpoint that the world may be interpreted in several ways and that the academic

research of complex phenomena is enhanced by competition between and use of

several ontological, epistemological, and methodological positions (Smircich and

Stubbart 1985; Bohman 1991; Little 1991; Thomas and Pruett 1993; Bowman 1995;

VanMaanen 1995). In this sense, the term ‘pluralism’ has a western democratic flavor

with the presence of multiple political parties, freedom of speech, and a free market

system ensuring workable competition and free choice. Its connection with a

postmodern position involves a rejection of any dogmatic overarching proposition

either on the paradigmatic or meta-paradigmatic level; an acceptance of pluralism and

fragmentation, and an emphasis on different techniques, insights, methods, etc. from a

variety of disciplines. Thus, the term challenges the monolithic elitism in its attempt

to bridge discourses and interpretive communities. The critics see this as a nihilistic

enterprise that calls the death of all scientific inquiry and the dissolution of any

research standards. However, as suggested by Clegg, “the fate of our time … would

be such as to encourage a profound pluralism with respect to interpretation. … Yet

pluralism need not mean nihilism; that anything is as good as anything else, that any

interpretation will do” (1990: 16). Thus nihilism is rejected in favor of a view that, as

suggested by Derrida (1988), embraces the world, reality, and history instead of

excluding it1. The question is: how does it relate to this dissertation?

An important characteristic with the multi-paradigmatic approach is the adoption of a

comparative approach that builds on paradigm interplay rather than a focus on

paradigm delineation allowing scholars to contrast and connect existing and emerging

1 This view is very similar to Kilduff and Mehra’s affirmative ideal type of postmodernism (1997).

Page 16: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

16

approaches and insights (Schultz and Hatch 1996). Schultz and Hatch claim that the

multi-paradigmatic approach overcomes the limitations of both incommensurability

and paradigm integration. Basically this aspect is manifested in this dissertation in the

sense that paradigms are combined and contrasted from the behavioral aspects of new

venture creation and not merged into synthesis without acknowledging their contrasts.

Hence, this approach respects paradigm and disciplinary diversity by encouraging the

co-existence of competing interpretations for a richer understanding of issues on new

venture creation. As a natural consequence, progress in developing theory and

practice is considered more likely to happen through inclusiveness than exclusivity.

Hence as suggested by Davidsson, Low, and Wright (2001), the field of

entrepreneurship will benefit from multi-disciplinary research on specific topics or

themes inside the domain of entrepreneurship. This dissertation seeks exactly these

benefits from multi-disciplinary research on the aspect of new venture creation.

A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR NEW VENTURE CREATION

Gartner (1985) introduced a conceptual framework for describing the phenomenon of

new venture creation in order to signify the importance and independence of four

major perspectives in entrepreneurship: the characteristics of the individual(s) starting

the new venture; the kind of new venture – or organization – that the individual(s)

create; the environment surrounding the new venture; and the process by which the

new venture is created in terms of the actions undertaken by the individual(s) to create

a new venture (see figure 2).

Page 17: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

17

However, three years after, in Gartner (1988), the process of new venture creation – or

what he interchangeably discussed as the behavior in this process – was put to the

core of entrepreneurship. In his article, Gartner established two fundamental bases for

entrepreneurship: 1) Entrepreneurship is about the emergent process of new venture

creation; and 2) Entrepreneurship is about behavior and not about characteristics and

dispositions of the individual(s) in the process of new venture creation. In fact, his

emphasis on the behavior in the process of new venture creation was put forth as the

strong alternative to the sole studies on personal traits which he considered a dead

end. This dissertation agrees that the process should be the driver of entrepreneurship

and new venture creation in particular. Moreover, the dissertation outlines this process

of new venture creation in terms of opportunity discovery and exploitation as

suggested by a fairly large stream of research in entrepreneurship (e.g. Bygrave 1993;

Kirzner 1973, 1979; Shane and Venkataraman 2000; Hitt et al. 2001; Zahra and Dess

2001; Eckhardt and Shane 2003; and Davidsson and Honig 2003). Importantly, these

two basic constructs are associated with a certain range of behaviors. This is

consistent with Gartner and Carter (2003), who suggest that the process of startup is

not just one decision or one type of behavior, but a whole array of actions spread

across time and events.

ENVIRONMENT

PROCESS

ORGANIZATION

INDIVIDUAL(S)

Figure 2. A framework for describing new venture creation (Source: Gartner 1885: 698).

Page 18: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

18

However, contrary to Gartner 1988 this dissertation not only seeks to explain the

behavior pertaining to the different processes of new venture creation and its

outcomes, but also its antecedents. Importantly however, the antecedents are

constructed on the basis of the observed behavior in the new venture creation process.

In fact this corresponds to a simple textbook approach of induction and deduction.

Simplifying the argument according to the basic induction/deduction approach, I see

Gartner’s critique as mainly an attempt to refocus the field of entrepreneurship from

the deceiving and alluring focus on the personality traits of the entrepreneur. It

appeared that the field of entrepreneurship had lost touch with reality, which was

evident from the equivocal empirical finding on the constructed antecedents and

‘autopiloted’ into a blind process of deduction. Moreover, the field of

entrepreneurship increasingly defined itself around these misplaced constructed

antecedents with exclusive focus on ‘who is an entrepreneur?’. Gartner provocatively

characterized this tradition by stating: “if-we-can-just-find-out-who-the-entrepreneur-

is-then-we’ll-know-what-entrepreneurship-is” (1988: 23). However, without a

thorough understanding of what the entrepreneur is and does, how should we be able

to answer the ‘who’ question – i.e. how can we know the dancer if we artificially

separate the dancer from the dance? In other words, we cannot build a research field

of entrepreneurship around characteristics of the entrepreneur if we do not know what

entrepreneurship is all about. That would be like trying to invent the football player

and discern the characteristics of football players before the actual game of football is

considered.

As a natural consequence Gartner called for field work and a detailed classification

and systematization of the processes and behaviors of new venture creation.

Importantly, the result of this field work would enable researchers to make new

attempts in answering questions of antecedents of this behavior and consequently

answer the question ‘who is an entrepreneur?’ in terms of the skills and abilities the

entrepreneur needs to know or acquire (Gartner 1988). Now, almost two decades have

passed since this highly influential paper was published. Maybe the behavioral

process of new venture creation was not put to the front of entrepreneurship as an

Page 19: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

19

alternative to the trait approach, but several scholars have considered the behavioral

aspects of the entrepreneurial process since then (Bygrave and Hofer 1991; Reynolds

and Miller 1992; Gartner and Shane 1995; Gatewood, Shaver, and Gartner 1995;

Carter, Gartner, and Reynolds 1996; de Koning and Muzyka 1996; Hills, Lumpkin,

and Singh 1997; Gartner and Carter 2003). Perhaps the time is now ripe for bringing

this ‘field work’ into the important process of discerning antecedents for new venture

creation.

BACK TO ANTECEDENTS

As mentioned, the dissertation focuses on the behavioral process of new venture

creation. As regards antecedents, it emphasizes the characteristics of individuals or

their personal networks as the first order forces and holds that forces of organization

and environment are second order in accordance with Shane and Venkataraman

(2000). In fact, a premise of the dissertation is that environmental and organizational

forces are contingencies that may influence the activities involved in the process of

new venture creation. Hence, the primary focus is on the behavior and activities

involved in new venture creation and how these activities place different demands on

the individual. Of course the demands may change according to different

environmental and organizational circumstances, but changes are first related to the

process of new venture creation – i.e. the behavior in this process – and then finally

translated into specific demands pertaining to the individual. Finally, at the individual

level the dissertation distinguishes between the demands of the individual in terms of

human, financial, and social capital obtained from the entrepreneur’s personal

network. As suggested by Burt (1992), every individual brings three types of capital,

which pertains only to that particular individual, to the competitive arena. First, the

individual has human capital in terms of natural qualities, predispositions and

cognitive skills acquired in formal education, job experience, or in the general course

of living. Second, the individual has social capital in terms of social relationships with

family, friends, colleagues, and more general contacts through whom the individual

receives and obtains human and financial capital. Third, the individual has financial

Page 20: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

20

capital in terms of access to financial means necessary in the process of new venture

creations. The particular approach is summarized and illustrated in figure 3.

Figure 3 suggests that the activities involved in the new venture creation process are

of central importance in discerning demands for different types of capital accruing

from the individual. Moreover, it is suggested that the effect of the environment and

organization is maintained as a contingency to the activities involved in the new

venture creation process. Finally, the ‘double’ arrows indicate that the individual’s

different types of capital are interdependent in the sense that they may compensate for

one another to a certain degree. The dissertation relates to each type of capital in three

different papers. The central argument in each paper is that what appear to be

conflicting approaches in each type of capital may be reconciled by relating the

ENVIRONMENTAL CONTINGENCIES

DEMANDS FOR HUMAN CAPITAL

Chap. 3

ORGANIZATIONAL CONTINGENCIES ACTIVITIES

INVOLVED IN THE NEW VENTURE CREATION PROCESS

DEMANDS FOR SOCIAL CAPITAL

Chap. 4

DEMANDS FOR FINANCIAL CAPITAL

Chap. 5

Figure 3. Theoretical approach for the dissertation

Page 21: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

21

different streams of research to the behavioral process of new venture creation.

Hence, antecedents will be proposed on the basis of the behavioral demands

consistent with the process of new venture creation. The thesis and antithesis in each

domain are illustrated in figure 4.

However, before moving on to the ‘chapters’ on human, social, and financial capital

the dissertation will legitimize both entrepreneurship as a sound area of research and

the use of several disciplinary approaches. In this sense, the first ‘chapter’ is

somewhat different from the rest in the sense that it considers the field of

entrepreneurship as an object of study in its own rights.

PROCESS

‘CHAPTER 4’ SOCIAL

CAPITAL

‘CHAPTER 3’ HUMAN

CAPITAL

‘CHAPTER 5’ FINANCIAL

CAPITAL

COGNITION

CONTRACT RELATION

BRIDGING

TRAITS BONDING

Figure 4. Bringing together thesis and antithesis from a process perspective of new venture creation

Page 22: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

22

Chapter 2: Status among management journals and the forum for entrepreneurship research Many scholars have sought to define where issues on entrepreneurship are published

in scientific journals and how entrepreneurship is related to other journals and topics

in management. This study seeks to refine this research and answer a set of

fundamental questions regarding the status and citation pattern of entrepreneurship-

related articles. First, via a social network approach, a broad citation-based analysis of

the field of management is employed in order to uncover the status and possible

clusters in a large group of management journals. From the status network of

management journals, it is first assessed where issues of entrepreneurship are

typically published, i.e. in what clusters, journals and issues of entrepreneurship they

typically appear and the pattern over time. The legitimacy of entrepreneurship

research over time is then assessed, taking into consideration the status of the journals

that publish issues on entrepreneurship. Looking at entrepreneurship-related journals

among the source journals, the study shows that articles dealing with aspects of

entrepreneurship have experienced an increase since the mid-eighties among the

selected journals. This is even more pronounced if we look at the journals with a

relatively high status in the network. The increasing number of entrepreneurship-

related articles among the high-status journals in management suggests that

entrepreneurship as a field of study has increased in status. In addition, it is shown

that aspects of entrepreneurship are primarily dealt with in the cluster labeled ‘general

management and sociology journals’, and secondary economic and quantitatively

oriented journals. Finally, when discerning the citation pattern from entrepreneurship

articles, it is shown that the general management and sociology-oriented journals are

the primary sources of intellectual ballast or status.

‘Chapter 3’: A revitalization of personal traits as complementary to the cognitive

approach in different phases of new venture creation

The basic claim in this paper is that the introduction of the behavior related to the

process of new venture creation can revitalize the personal trait approach, even though

Gartner gave it the death sentence in Gartner (1988). It is suggested that some of the

central traits in the entrepreneurship literature can be traced back to a certain behavior

Page 23: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

23

– or behavioral requirements – related to a specific phase in the process of new

venture creation. However, current research on personality traits is – with few

exceptions – conducted in the phase of exploitation making an implicit and dubious

assumption that traits do not change in the course of the process of new venture

creation, despite evidence to the contrary. Hence, it is claimed that the equivocal

results on personality traits are basically due to a neglect of the behavioral process of

new venture creation. However, as a result of the disappointing results of the trait

approach, scholars in entrepreneurship have suggested an antithesis in terms of a

cognitive approach to explain – among other things – the same aspects of motivation

and evaluation, which was initially the intention of the personal trait approach. This

paper does not aim to find a synthesis of these two approaches. Instead it is argued

how these two approaches may complement each other in different phases of new

venture creation.

The specific propositions made in this paper are illustrated in figure 5. Evidence on

the behavioral process of new venture creation indicates that entrepreneurial intent is

needed as a fundamental kick-starter. Moreover, it is claimed that personal traits like

need for achievement and entrepreneurial self efficacy are positively related to

entrepreneurial intent (P1A and P1B), i.e. antecedents to entrepreneurial intent. As

regards the complementarities between the trait and cognitive approach it is claimed

that optimism, locus of control, and entrepreneurial self efficacy are negatively

associated with the cognitive aspect of risk perception and importantly that this

central cognitive aspect of new venture creation may be explained by these traits in

this particular phase of new venture creation. Hence, reintroducing the behavioral

demands in each phase of new venture creation may revitalize the trait approach as

well as the cognitive approach in discerning the question: Who is an entrepreneur?

Page 24: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

24

Figure 5. Propositions from chapter 3

Chapter 4: Personal networks in different phases of new venture creation The last twenty years of research on personal networks and new venture creation has

contributed to the investigation of a wide range of characteristics more or less

beneficial to new venture creation. The results of this endeavor are basically a

scattered collection of research with diverging concepts, techniques, and measures.

Despite broad agreement about the general importance of personal networks and

personal relations, there is considerably less agreement and more ambiguity about the

specific characteristics of personal networks that relate to success in creating new

P1B+

P2B- -

P2C-

P2A-

Optimism

Locus of control

Entrepreneurial self efficacy

Risk perception Positive evaluation

+

P1A+

Need for achievement

Entrepreneurial self efficacy

Entrepreneurial intent

Opportunity recognition

Opportunity exploitation

Page 25: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

25

ventures. This paper takes stock of studies on the personal networks of entrepreneurs.

It is suggested that what appears to be empirical inconsistencies in the effect of

personal networks is a disregard of the important contingency of the entrepreneurial

phase or an oversimplified description of the needs in different phases of

entrepreneurial development as a need for either information or resources. Hence,

disregarding the behavior constituting the new venture creation process once again

results in inconsistencies and equivocal results that may appear to represent thesis and

antithesis on the importance of social capital. And again, instead of proposing a

synthesis of these views, the dissertation suggests how needs for resources and

information as well as the legitimacy of the new venture change as the new venture

develops from the phases of entrepreneurial intent to the phase of early growth. These

changes are then related to theoretical as well as empirical evidence on the positive

aspects of the personal network of the entrepreneur in terms of personal network size,

the strength of ties, and the density of the personal network. From this endeavor it is

suggested that bonding and bridging resources, information, and legitimacy are not

thesis and antithesis, but complementary in the sense that they relate to different

behaviors in the process of new venture creation. The propositions made in this paper

are illustrated in figure 6.

Page 26: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

26

Figure 6. Propositions from chapter 4

These propositions indicate that as the needs for certain behaviors change in the

process of new venture creation so does the optimal personal network structure. We

may simplify these changes as personal networks that move from bonding in the

phase of entrepreneurial intent to bridging in the phase of opportunity discovery. The

same changes apply to the different phases of exploitation.

Strength of ties P3a+

P1+

P1+

P1-

Personal network characteristics

Size

Density

Size

Strength of ties

Density

Entrepreneurial intent

Opportunity discovery

Nascent exploitation

Ongoing exploitation

P7+

P5+

P6-

P10-

P9-

P8+

P4-

P3b-

P2+

Page 27: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

27

Chapter 5: Governance mechanisms in the pecking order of new venture finance

The final paper seeks to develop taxonomy of governance mechanisms in new venture

finance by introducing elements of transaction cost economics as well as elements of

the relational contracting literature. Instead of focusing exclusively on the formal

contractual options of investors, the paper introduces the transactional relationship

between entrepreneur and investor as the primary unit of analysis. The transaction not

only encompasses the exchange of financial resources, but any kind of information

and social action establishing a linkage between the parties. Focusing on the

transaction, the primary research question is where and how transactions should be

governed under different transactional circumstances in the context of new venture

finance. The paper seeks to answer this question by developing taxonomy of

governance forms and a general framework for understanding new venture finance in

relation to different transactional characteristics. Finally, the different forms and

mechanisms of governance are related to the typical pecking order of new ventures

and four fundamental financial sources, including two types of bank finance, private

equity finance, and finance obtained from strong ties such as friends and relatives. It

is suggested how networking and embedded ties are central to financing new ventures

and how network effects change in the course of new venture creation.

Page 28: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

28

Postlude and appetizer to the dissertation: A short story – exploring a stereotypical individual

“The study of firm founding without a role for the founders is like the study of

Shakespeare in which the prince of Denmark has been expunged from the discussion

of Hamlet” (Baumol 1968: 66).

This scenic description highlights the importance of the individual entrepreneur and

the individual’s opportunity nexus in entrepreneurship research and in the study of

new venture founding. It equally underlines the true uniqueness of new combinations,

new venture founding, and each individual entrepreneur. However, this sense of

uniqueness in entrepreneurship and new venture founding, which is our research

subject, is often lost in our search for general drivers and success factors. Then, before

we turn to the discussion of entrepreneurship and new venture founding in more

general and average terms reproaching the practice of the individual entrepreneur, we

present a fictive case – a story – highlighting a stereotypical image of an individual

entrepreneur during the initial phases of venture founding. In other words, we want to

experience the unique individual entrepreneur through an ‘ideal-type’ of an

entrepreneur during the initial phases of venture founding.

Like Max Weber’s use of the concept of ‘ideal-type’ (e.g. Weber 1949), the fictive

case is used as a methodological and especially heuristic tool for the enhancement of

distinctive and essential features of new venture founding. It is not meant to be a

description of reality or an ideal to evaluate reality by. It is a conceptual construct,

which is neither a historically correct reality nor even meant to be the ‘true’ reality.

The fictive entrepreneur does not exist in a pure form, but the elements forming the

picture of the entrepreneur are primarily taken from my constructions from the articles

on individual characteristics, social network characteristics, and financial

characteristics that follow in this thesis.

Page 29: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

29

Constructing an ideal-type is a four-fold process that equally serves four heuristic and

epistemological functions for both reader and writer (cf. Weber 1949):

1. It brings awareness to details in what was previously thought of as an

undifferentiated general experience (differentiation);

2. It systematically puts together differentiated parts of earlier experiences that

can be related to each other in various systematic ways (integration);

3. It separates characteristics of reality from specific objects or individuals, in

fact making the drawing of a stereotypic picture a challenging task

(abstraction);

4. It generalizes significant common meanings not to be changed by additional

experience (generalization).

The fictive case below seeks to perform these four functions for the reader as well as

the writer. Moreover, the fictive case is also meant as an appetizer for the reader in

terms of what to expect from the dissertation’s chapters on human, social, and

financial capital. Contrary to Weber, however, this ideal-type entrepreneurial story is

not thought of as a clear-cut conceptual scheme against which one could compare

empirical reality. In fact, the fictive case should not be compared to reality in any

way; it is basically a mental construction which is useful to understand and get closer

to the complex reality of entrepreneurship from the individual’s nexus of

opportunities. Furthermore, it is an attempt to see similarities between individual

entrepreneurs while staying as close as possible to their concrete particularity. In other

words, the fictive case is meant to give a brief illusion of closeness to the individual

entrepreneur while still allowing a degree of generality.

A fictive entrepreneur: Taking the first steps

What type of individual should we choose for this exercise? Clearly, the interest in

hairdressers and pizzeria owners is not as pronounced as the interest in new biotech

(ad) ventures and ‘dotcoms’. At least, this is the impression you get if you look at

empirical and theoretical work in the area of new venture founding. Thus, we will go

with my image of a typical dotcom ‘wannabe’ entrepreneur, Mr. Caruso.

Page 30: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

30

As suggested, a fundamental approach in this dissertation is to relate the behavioral

aspect of the process of new venture creation to different types of capital pertaining to

the individual entrepreneur. Hence, this short story will take Mr. Caruso through

phases of entrepreneurial intent, opportunity discovery, evaluation, and to different

phases of exploitation. The behavior in each phase will then be related to the

proposition put forth in the papers.

Entrepreneurial Intent

Caruso is a 42 year-old computer specialist programming special chips in a sound

hardware development company. He obtained his Master’s degree from the

University of Aarhus 15 years ago in information technology and has for the past

eight years been part of a product development team studying options for conducting

online computer network meetings. Caruso has a strong desire to be successful and is

not easily satisfied with current achievements. Moreover, he is confident that he has

the abilities it takes to create and run a new venture – not only obtained from his

education but also from observing his current employer, who is the founder and

owner of the company. Caruso’s personal network consists primarily of strong ties to

family members as well as strong ties to a couple of close friends and colleagues who

all know one another. Caruso is confident that his personal network will support him

financially as well as emotionally in a process of new venture creation. Finally, like

many other computer specialists, he has with great interest followed the success

stories in the press about individuals who succeed in starting their own dotcom

company, and he is very much alert to any business ideas and opportunities that

might show up.

Caruso’s human capital characteristics in the phase of new venture development relate

to the aspects of need for achievement and entrepreneurial self efficacy, which chapter

3 of this dissertation proposes are positively associated with entrepreneurial intent.

Moreover, Caruso’s personal network is relatively small, consisting mainly of strong

Page 31: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

31

cohesive ties, which are proposed in chapter 4 to be positively related to

entrepreneurial intent. This relationship is illustrated in figure 8.

Opportunity Discovery

As a result of his entrepreneurial motivation Caruso seeks to expand his personal

network to include entrepreneurs and potential buyers of products somehow related

to his capabilities in order to obtain information on possible opportunities. Caruso’s

sister plays the cello by profession. Knowing Caruso’s entrepreneurial intentions, she

one day expresses the demand for a real-time site to compose music online in

cooperation with fellow musicians; the demand seems to be shared by her close fellow

cellists. In fact, Caruso’s sister has talked a lot about this with other musicians; she is

confident that she knows exactly what features they want and that there is a demand

for this product. Suppose, for the sake of argument, that Caruso is actually a

specialist in this type of real-time sharing of online resources using a specific sound

device and a piece of software very much related to the type of requirements needed

Need for achievement

Entrepreneurial intent

Entrepreneurial self efficacy

Size

Strength

Density

Figure 8. Characteristics of human and social capital to entrepreneurial intent as explored in chapter 3 and 4

HUMAN CAPITAL SOCIAL CAPITAL

Page 32: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

32

in an online music project. To determine whether the new online music internet

service is indeed technically feasible and whether it has any value to potential

costumers he turns to some of his newly obtained weak relations in his personal

network and seeks contact with additional new relations – say people in the music

industry and people who distribute similar products. Although he trusts his sister’s

presumptions about the demand for such a product, he arranges a few meetings with

his sister and other musicians to check their potential demand and their requirements

regarding features, price range, etc. From these diverse personal relations Caruso

manages to discover and fine-tune an opportunity that appears to satisfy certain

needs in terms of demands, technical feasibility, and access to distribution channels.

Caruso is an ‘ideal-type’ entrepreneur; he is well connected to a network that has a

high level of expertise in a particular technology and to a second, completely

unrelated, network of actors with a problem that may be solved through application of

that particular technology. His deep understanding of both the technology and the

problem enables him to see the potential of this new combination. The aspects of

opportunity discovery presented above are mainly related to Caruso’s personal

network characteristics. From the phase of entrepreneurial intent Caruso has now

concentrated mainly on building a larger network from weak ties not connected to one

another in order to obtain a high degree of network diversity pertaining to availability

of information. He uses this diversity and larger network to redevelop and fine-tune

the initial idea of an opportunity put forth by his sister.

As chapter 4 proposes, we would expect a positive relationship between the size of the

personal network and in this particular case a negative relationship between the

strength of ties and density of ties as illustrated in figure 7 above.

Evaluation

Caruso is generally optimistic and thinks that his prospect for success in starting a

new venture is good, even though he realizes that the failure rate among dotcom

Page 33: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

33

ventures is relatively high. Moreover, Caruso is content that whether or not he

succeeds is entirely based on his skills and he is confident in his ability to control the

environment. Finally, he is still confident in his abilities to create and run a new

venture. Accordingly he does not perceive a high degree of uncertainty and risk and

decides to act on the opportunity instead of just talk about starting a new venture as

most of us tend to do occasionally.

Confronted with this potential opportunity, economists would expect Caruso to

conjecture whether there exists a positive probability that the future price of the new

online music service will exceed the cost, including opportunity costs, in producing

and bringing the new service to the market and that adequate future demand will exist.

However, predicting these things with certainty is definitely not as easy in practice as

in theory since, among other things, it requires Caruso to possess information that

does not exist ex ante. Furthermore, it is humanly impossible to weigh all possible

pros and cons in a completely new and highly complex situation, such as starting a

new venture with a completely new and untested product. Hence, as suggested in

chapter 3, the decision to act on an opportunity may be positively related to a

cognitive bias of risk perception. In order to infer on the antecedents of this cognitive

bias, chapter 3 proposes a positive relationship between the cognitive aspect of risk

perception and the individual’s predisposed degree of optimism, locus of control, and

entrepreneurial self efficacy as illustrated in figure 6 above.

Emergent exploitation

In the initial process of exploring his entrepreneurial opportunity, Caruso figures that

he needs to develop a prototype to test the different features and the ultimate

desirability of the product. Furthermore, if he wants to go any further with his new

venture, which is very time consuming, he realizes that he needs to quit his current

job. Although Caruso’s own savings are quite substantial, he still needs to acquire

additional resources to make a prototype. He first approaches the bank with his ideas,

looking for start-up finance. However, the validity of his idea or perception is

completely unknown; the bank has no information about his competences, the

Page 34: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

34

potential demand, the technical feasibility of the product and other elements needed to

make a qualified risk profile. He is lucky though; his sister and her husband trust him

and his idea, and they are willing to lend him some money or rather put up a personal

guarantee for a loan in the bank. His parents, who own a farm in Jutland, also put up

a personal guarantee for a loan in the local bank. Even though they have never

actually seen the internet and do not really understand the idea or need to write and

play music online, they somehow feel obliged to support their son.

Caruso is now ready to make his first prototype. He is able to make the necessary

programming without help from outsiders, but in order to produce some parts of the

initial hardware unit, he needs help from some of his former colleagues who are still

employed at the software development firm. Caruso is not interested in sharing the

ownership of his new venture so he persuades his former employer, who happens to

be one of his best friends from the university, to make the hardware prototype for a

fixed fee. If it turns out successfully, he promises to use the firm as the sole supplier of

that particular hardware. After three months, the first prototype is finished. To protect

his idea, he immediately spends his last financial resources on a patent.

Caruso’s initial expectations about emotional and financial support from his personal

network were correct. As expected from the pecking order described in Chapter 5 the

only available finance at this stage of emergence is based on a hierarchical

governance mechanism where personal trust from relatives and close friends is of

utmost importance.

Early growth

After testing his prototype on some potential customers and making some final

changes, Caruso once again lacks financial funds to market his product and he

approaches the bank with his newly produced patented prototype. Now, he needs

sufficient capital to put the hardware in production and to market the new product.

Once again he asks the bank for a long-term loan. Even though Caruso has obtained

a patent and apparently has a working prototype, the bank considers the risk

associated with the requested amount of capital to be high. However, they are willing

Page 35: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

35

to offer him a credit limit of 500,000 DKK mainly because of a personal relationship

with the banker that incurs a certain amount of calculated trust.

However, the credit limit is not even enough to put the prototype in production so

Caruso is somewhat desperate. An acquaintance, a trained accountant, advises him to

seek some kind of venture capital from a reasonably successful venture capitalist

located nearby, who knows the hardware and software industry rather well and also

offers his assistance in preparing a business proposal.

Now, Caruso needs to convince the venture capitalist or other potential investors that

this is in fact a good investment, that the prototype can be brought to the market place

at a profit, that there is an opportunity for quick and strong growth, and that Caruso

is trustworthy and competent to make it happen. Caruso is currently interested in

seeking enough money to market his product to a large share of potential customers

over the internet and in the biggest music instrument chains. Finally, he needs capital

to order the first 1,000 hardware units from his former employer. Reading different

handbooks on the subject, Caruso realizes that most venture capitalists prefer to read

only the summary and that the summary is where you should start. He follows the

headlines in the venture capital manual and ends up with this summary:

Page 36: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

36

Attached summary of business proposal

Contact:

Online Music Sharing (OMS)

Caruso, President of OMS

Type of Business:

Online and real-time sharing of music through the internet with specially developed hardware and

software.

Company Summary:

Through his job as a senior developer at the software development firm, Caruso has developed a

completely new method of sharing music in real time on the internet. The company already has a

working patented prototype that has been tested on several potential customers with overwhelmingly

positive responses. Every customer buys a special piece of hardware – a real-time card – as a

supplement to their already installed soundcard and a piece of software with several recording and

playback features. With a relatively fast internet connection, the customers are able to compose music

together in real time (max 6-10 people at a time depending on the available internet connection) from

their average home computer over the internet. The method will allow musicians with similar musical

interests from different parts of the world to gather and create music.

Management:

Caruso, president, has a Master’s degree from the University of Aarhus in information technology. He

has been working for the software development firm for the past eight years as a programmer and has

been in charge of a development unit working on different types of real-time software. He has been

working on the prototype for about one year.

Products and Competition:

The company will start offering the product online as well as through music instrument outlets. There

are no similar products on the market. However, once the hardware and software are available, other

music software developers may try to develop a similar product. The prototype and the general concept

are already patented.

Financial History:

Caruso has financed the building of the prototype and the testing with his own savings, approximately

400,000 DKK.

Page 37: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

37

Funds Requested:

The company seeks 1,000,000 DKK in common stock for a 30% ownership.

Use Proceeds:

700,000 DKK to begin the initial production of the hardware. 300,000 DKK to market the product in

music instrument stores, on the internet, and other relevant places.

Projections:

The first year we expect a revenue of around 200,000 DKK, and an income of around 50,000 DKK.

The second year, we expect a revenue of around 1,000,000 DKK, and an income of around 400,000

DKK. The third year, we expect a revenue of around 4,000,000 DKK, and an income of around

1,500,000 DKK.

Exits:

It is expected that the company has the potential to go public in 4 years. Alternatively, it is expected

that existing music software producers will be willing to pay a very good price for the company.

After finishing the summary, Caruso prepares the full business proposal making sure

that all necessary details are presented in an easily understandable way. Now, the

survival of the new venture is basically in the hands of the venture capitalist. If the

venture capitalist refuses the business proposal and has no interest in the new

combination, Caruso probably has no alternative but to sell his patent to an existing

company if possible. Perhaps he may even sell it to his former employer with

sufficient resources to market the new combination. However, with some luck, the

venture capitalist may agree to the terms and Caruso’s dream of becoming a success

in starting a new venture can live on, at least until the next round of financing. Of

course, the typical answer from the venture capitalist would be no. Caruso may then

try to obtain finance from other venture capitalists or other financial intermediaries,

possibly at a higher cost.

Page 38: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

38

Learning from Caruso

By using Caruso as an ideal-type entrepreneur, we get an idea of the different motives

that may drive the initial entrepreneurial process. We also sense the importance of

human and social capital in recognizing and exploiting entrepreneurial opportunities,

and finally we portray the difficulty in obtaining the financial support which is

necessary to take the final steps with the new venture. Chapters 3, 4, and 5 in this

dissertation deal with several of these issues.

Page 39: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

39

References

Ackroyd, S. 1992. Paradigms lost: Paradise Regained? In Rethinking Organizations. Edited by M. Reed and M. Hughes. London: Sage Publications.

Aldrich, H. 1999. Organizations evolving. Sage Publications.

Aldrich, H. and T. Baker. 1997. Blinded by the cites? Has there been progress in entrpreneurship research? In Entrepreneurship 2000. Edited by D. L. Sexton and R. W. Smilor. Chicago: Upstart Publishing.

Alvarez, S. A. and L. W. Busenitz, ”The entrepreneurship of resource-based theory,” Journal of Management 27 (6): 755-775 (2001).

Amit, R., L. Glosten, and E. Muller, ”Challenges to theory development in entrepreneurship research,” Journal of management studies 30: 815-834 (1993).

Arenius, P. and M. Minniti, ”Perceptual variables and nascent entrepreneurship,” Small Business Economics 24 (3): 233-247 (2005).

Audretsch, D. B. and M. Keilbach, ”Does entrepreneurship capital matter?,” Entrepreneurship-Theory and Practice 28 (5): 419-429 (2004).

Audretsch, D. B. and A. R. Thurik, ”What is new about the new economy: sources of growth in the managed and entrepreneurial economies?,” Industrial and Corporate Change 10: 267-315 (2001).

Baumol, W. J., ”Entrepreneurship in Economic Theory,” American Economic Review 58 (2): 64-71 (1968).

Bhave, M., “A process model of entrepreneurial venture creation”, Journal of Business Venturing 9: 223-241 (1994).

Birley, S., ”The role of new firms: Births, deaths and job generation,” Strategic Management Journal 7: 361-376 (1986).

Birley, S. and P. Westhead, ”A Taxonomy of Business Start-Up Reasons and Their Impact on Firm Growth and Size,” Journal of Business Venturing 9 (1): 7-31 (1994).

Bohman, J. 1991. New philosophy of social science. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

Bowman, E. H., ”Strategy history: through different mirrors,” Advances in strategic management 11A: 25-45 (1995).

Bull, I. and H. Thomas, ”A Perspective on Theory Building in Entrepreneurship,” Journal of Business Venturing 8 (3): 181-182 (1993).

Page 40: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

40

Bull, I. and G. E. Willard, ”Towards A Theory of Entrepreneurship,” Journal of Business Venturing 8 (3): 183-195 (1993).

Burell, G. and G. Morgan. 1979. Sociological Paradigm and Organizational analysis. London: Heinemann.

Burt, R. S. 1992. Structural holes the social structure of competition. Cambridge,

Mass: Harvard University Press.

Busenitz, L. W. et al., ”Entrepreneurship research in emergence: Past trends and

future directions,” Journal of Management 29 (3): 285-308 (2003).

Bygrave, W. D., ”Theory Building in the Entrepreneurship Paradigm,” Journal of Business Venturing 8 (3): 255-280 (1993).

Bygrave, W. and C. W. Hofer, ”Theorizing about Entrepreneurship,” Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 16: 13-22 (1991).

Carter, N. M., W. B. Gartner, and P. D. Reynolds, ”Exploring start-up event sequences,” Journal of Business Venturing 11 (3): 151-166 (1996).

Casson, M. 1982. The entrepreneur. An economic theory. Oxford: Martin Robertson.

Chandler, G. N. and D. W. Lyon, ”Issues of research design and construct measurement in entrepreneurship research: The past decade,” Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 26 (4): 101-113 (2001).

Clegg, S. 1990. Modern Organizations. Thousand Oaks: Sage.

Cooper, A. C., ”Challenges in Predicting New Firm Performance,” Journal of Business Venturing 8 (3): 241-253 (1993).

Covin, J. G., D. P. Slevin, and M. B. Heeley, ”Pioneers and followers: Competitive tactics, environment, and firm growth,” Journal of Business Venturing 15 (2): 175-210 (2000).

Davidsson, P. and M. Henrekson, ”Determinants of the prevalence of start-ups and high-growth firms,” Small Business Economics 19 (2): 81-104 (2002).

Davidsson, P. and B. Honig, ”The role of social and human capital among nascent entrepreneurs,” Journal of Business Venturing 18 (3): 301-331 (2003).

Davidsson, P. and J. Wiklund, ”Levels of analysis in entrepreneurship research: The past decade,” Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 25 (4) (2001).

Davidsson, P., M. B. Low, and M. Wright, ”Editor’s Introduction: Low and MacMilan Ten Years On: Achievements and Future Directions for

Page 41: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

41

Entrepreneurship Research,” Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 25 (4): 5-15 (2001).

de Koning, A. and D. Muzyka. 1996. The Convergence of Good Ideas: When and how do entrepreneurial managers recognize innovative business ideas? In Frontiers of Entrepreneurship Research. Edited by Churchill N. et al. Wesley: Babson College.

Delmar, F. and S. Shane, ”Does business planning facilitate the development of new ventures?,” Strategic Management Journal 24 (12): 1165-1185 (2003).

Derrida, J. 1988. Limited Inc. Evanston, IL: Northwestern University Press.

Durkheim, E. 1893. De la Division du Travail Social. Paris: Universitaires de France.

Eckhardt, J. T. and S. A. Shane, ”Opportunities and entrepreneurship,” Journal of Management 29 (3): 333-349 (2003).

Eckhardt, J. T., S. Shane, and F. Delmar, ”Multistage selection and the financing of new ventures,” Management Science 52 (2): 220-232 (2006).

Erhvervs- & Boligstyrrelsen (2003): “De nye virksomheder”

Gaglio, C. M. and J. A. Katz, ”The psychological basis of opportunity identification: Entrepreneurial alertness,” Small Business Economics 16 (2): 95-111 (2001).

Gartner, W. B., ”A conceptual framework for describing the phenomenon of new venture creation,” Academy of Management Review 10 (4): 696-706 (1985).

Gartner, W. B., ””Who is an entrepreneur?” Is the wrong question,” American Journal of Small Business 12 (4): 11-32 (1988).

Gartner, W. B., ”Some suggestions for research on entrepreneurial traits and characteristics,” Entrepreneurship, Theory and Practice 14 (1): 27-37 (1989).

Gartner, W. B., ”What Are We Talking About When We Talk About Entrepreneurship,” Journal of Business Venturing 5 (1): 15-28 (1990).

Gartner, W. B., ”Is there an elephant in entrepreneurship? Blind assumptions in theory development,” Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 24 (5) (2001).

Gartner, W. B. and N. M. Carter. 2003. Entrepreneurial behavior and firm organizing processes. In Handbook of Entrepreneurship Research. Edited by Z. J. Acs and D. B. Audretsch. Dordrecht, NL: Kluwer.

Gartner, W. B. and S. A. Shane, ”Measuring Entrepreneurship Over Time,” Journal of Business Venturing 10 (4): 283-301 (1995).

Page 42: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

42

Gartner, W. B., P. Davidsson, and S. A. Zahra, ”Are you talking to me? The nature of community in entrepreneurship scholarship,” Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 30 (3): 321-331 (2006).

Gartner, W. B., T. R. Mitchell, and K. H. Vesper, ”A Taxonomy of New Business Ventures,” Journal of Business Venturing 4 (3): 169-186 (1989).

Gartner, W. B., J. A. Starr, and S. Bhat, ”Predicting new venture survival: An analysis of ”Anatomy of a Start-up.” Cases from Inc. magazine,” Journal of Business Venturing 14 (2): 215-232 (1999).

Gatewood, E. J., K. G. Shaver, and W. B. Gartner, ”A Longitudinal-Study of Cognitive-Factors Influencing Start-Up Behaviors and Success at Venture Creation,” Journal of Business Venturing 10 (5): 371-391 (1995).

Hassard, J. 1993. Sociology and Organization theory. Positivism, Paradigms, and Postmodernity. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Hills, G. E., G. T. Lumpkin, and R. Singh. 1997. Opportunity Recognition: Perceptions and behaviors of entrepreneurs. In Frontiers of Entrepreneurship Research. Edited by Churchill N. et al. Wellesley, MA: Babson College.

Hitt, M. A. et al., ”Guest editors’ introduction to the special issue – Strategic entrepreneurship: Entrepreneurial strategies for wealth creation,” Strategic Management Journal 22 (6-7): 479-491 (2001).

Jackson, N. and P. Carter, ”In defense of incommensurability,” Organization Studies 12: 109-127 (1991).

Katz, J., ”The institution and infrastructure of entrepreneurship,” Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 15 (3): 85-102 (1991).

Kilduff, M. and A. Mehra, ”Postmodernism and organizational research,” Academy of Management Review 22 (2): 453-481 (1997).

Kirzner, I. M. 1973. Competition and Entrepreneurship. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Kirzner, I. M. 1979. Perceptions, Opportunities, and Profit. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Kirzner, I. M., ”Entrepreneurial discovery and the competitive market process: An Austrian approach,” Journal of Economic Literature 35 (1): 60-85 (1997).

Kuratko, D. F., ”The emergence of entrepreneurship education: Development, trends, and challenges,” Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 29 (5): 577-597 (2005).

Page 43: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

43

Lichtenstein, B. B., K. J. Dooley, and G. T. Lumpkin, ”Measuring emergence in the dynamics of new venture creation,” Journal of Business Venturing 21 (2): 153-175 (2006).

Little, D. 1991. Varieties of social explanation. Boulder, CO: Westview.

Low, B. S. and I. MacMillan, ”Entrepreneurship: Past research on future challenges,” Journal of Management 14: 139-161 (1988).

Low, M. B., ”The adolescence of entrepreneurship research: Specification of purpose,” Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 26 (4): 17-25 (2001).

Low, M. B. and E. Abrahamson, ”Movements, bandwagons, and clones: Industry evolution and the entrepreneurial process,” Journal of Business Venturing 12 (6): 435-457 (1997).

MacMillan, I. C., ”The Emerging Forum for Entrepreneurship Scholars,” Journal of Business Venturing 8 (5): 377-381 (1993).

McGrath, R. G., ”Falling forward: Real options reasoning and entrepreneurial failure,” Academy of Management Review 24 (1): 13-30 (1999).

Noorderhaven, N. et al., ”The role of dissatisfaction and per capita income in explaining self-employment across 15 European countries,” Entrepreneurship-Theory and Practice 28 (5): 447-466 (2004).

Parker, S. C. and W. B. Gartner, ”Special Issue on Entrepreneurship and New Venture Creation – Introduction,” Entrepreneurship-Theory and Practice 28 (5): 413-417 (2004).

Pfeffer, J., ”Barriers to the advance of organizational science: Paradigm Development as a dependent variable.,” Academy of Management Review 18: 599-620 (1993).

Reed, M. 1992. The Sociology of Organizations. Themes, Perspectives, and Prospects. New York: Harvester Wheatsheaf.

Reynolds, P. D., ”New Firms – Societal Contribution Versus Survival Potential,” Journal of Business Venturing 2 (3): 231-246 (1987).

Reynolds, P. D., ”Who starts new firms? – Preliminary explorations of firms-in-gestation,” Small Business Economics 9 (5): 449-462 (1997).

Reynolds, P. and B. Miller, ”New Firm Gestation – Conception, Birth, and Implications for Research,” Journal of Business Venturing 7 (5): 405-417 (1992).

Rocha, H. O., ”Entrepreneurship and development: The role of clusters,” Small Business Economics 23 (5): 363-400 (2004).

Page 44: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

44

Schultz, M. and M. J. Hatch, ”Living with multiple paradigms: The case of paradigm interplay in organizational culture studies,” Academy of Management Review 21 (2): 529-557 (1996).

Schumpeter, J. A. 1934. The theory of economic development. Cambridge: MA: Harvard University Press.

Schumpeter, J. A. 1942. Capitalism, socialism, and democracy. New York, London: Harper.

Shane, S., ”Explaining variation in rates of entrepreneurship in the United States: 1899-1988,” Journal of Management 22 (5): 747-781 (1996).

Shane, S. A., ”Who is publishing the entrepreneurship research?,” Journal of Management 23 (1): 83-95 (1997).

Shane, S. and S. Venkataraman, ”The promise of entrepreneurship as a field of research,” Academy of Management Review 25 (1): 217-226 (2000).

Shook, C. L., R. L. Priem, and J. E. Mcgee, ”Venture creation and the enterprising individual: A review and synthesis,” Journal of Management 29 (3): 379-399 (2003).

Smircich, L. and Ch. Stubbart, ”Strategic management in an enacted world,” Academy of Management Review 10: 724-736 (1985).

Sternberg, R. and S. Wennekers, ”Determinants and effects of new business creation using Global Entrepreneurship Monitor data,” Small Business Economics 24 (3): 193-203 (2005).

Thomas, H. and M. Pruett, ”Introduction to the special issue. Perspectives on theory building in strategic management.,” Journal of management studies 30: 3-10 (1993).

Thornton, P. H., ”The sociology of entrepreneurship,” Annu.Rev.Sociol. 25: 19-46 (1999).

Ucbasaran, D., P. Westhead, and M. Wright, ”The focus of entrepreneurial research:

Contextual and process issues,” Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 25 (4) (2001).

van Stel, A., M. Carree, and R. Thurik, ”The effect of entrepreneurial activity on national economic growth,” Small Business Economics 24 (3): 311-321 (2005).

VanMaanen, J., ”Style As Theory,” Organization Science 6 (1): 133-143 (1995).

Venkataraman, S. 1997. “The distinctive domain of entrepreneurship research: An editor’s perspective.” In J. Katz & R. Brockhaus (Eds.), Advances in

Page 45: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

45

entrepreneurship, firm emergence, and growth, Vol. 3: 119-138, Greenwich, CT, JAI Press

Weber, M. 1949. The Methodology of the Social Sciences. New York: Free Press.

Wennekers, S. and R. Thurik, ”Linking entrepreneurship and economic growth,” Small Business Economics 13 (1): 27-55 (1999).

Whitley, R. 2000. The intellectual and social organization of the sciences. New York: Oxford University Press Inc.

Willmott, H., ”Breaking the paradigm mentality,” Organization Studies 14: 681-719 (1993).

Wong, P. X., Y. P. Ho, and E. Autio, ”Entrepreneurship, innovation and economic growth: Evidence from GEM data,” Small Business Economics 24 (3): 335-350 (2005).

Zahra S. A. and G. G. Dess, ”Entrepreneurship as a field of research: encouraging dialogue and debate,” Acadamy of Management Review 26: 8-10 (2001).

Page 46: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

46

Status among Management Journals and the forum for

Entrepreneurship Research

Abstract

The purpose of this paper is twofold. First, a broad citation-based analysis of the field

of management is employed in order to uncover the status among a large group of

management journals. Instead of focusing on categories of journals that are defined by

their inner attributes in terms of raw citation counts, this paper uses a methodology

that focuses on the relations between journals. The raw citation counts are

transformed into three adjacency matrices, as used in social network theory, and

different measures of centrality are used to describe the status among the journals

during three periods of time. The network is then divided into five clusters of interest

on the basis of the citation pattern. Articles on entrepreneurship-related issues are then

related to these clusters and the status network among the management journals. It is

suggested that the field of entrepreneurship is gaining increasing legitimacy and status

in the general field of management.

Introduction

Scientific journals are the primary outlet for the creation and diffusion of knowledge.

They are also the means by which the scientific community can certify research areas

and additions to the body of already accepted knowledge and the means by which

researchers compete for prestige and recognition. The influence that these journals

exert on one another as well as the degree to which a particular journal is considered

as communicative and important within its immediate and complete network of

journals may be discerned by examining the citing pattern between journals (Garfield

1972; Gordon 1982; Salancik 1986; Extejt and Smith 1990; Johnson and Podsakoff

1994; Tahai and Meyer 1999; Busenitz et al. 2003; Baumgartner and Pieters 2003).

Understanding the impact and status of journals is important for two basic reasons.

First, universities and academic departments generally evaluate the qualities of job

and promotion candidates on the basis of publications in acknowledged scientific

Page 47: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

47

journals (Stahl, Leap, and Wei 1988; Pfeffer 1993; Tahai and Meyer 1999; Baden-

Fuller, Ravazzolo, and Schweizer 2000). Hence, rankings of universities and

academic departments, tenure positions, promotions, status among peers, and status

among different areas of research are highly dependent on access to high-status

journals.

Secondly, scientific journals generally decide the worth of particular research results

as well as research topics by admitting or excluding articles. For example, scholars

may determine the degree of contribution that specific journals have made to

advancing the body of academic knowledge in a certain field (Johnson and Podsakoff

1994), or scholars may seek information on the merits of research articles and topics

from the status of the journal in which the article or research topic is published (Tahai

and Meyer 1999). Thus, the status among journals is an important indicator of the

quality and status of a particular research topic (Garfield 1972; Gordon 1982; Extejt

and Smith 1990; Johnson and Podsakoff 1994; Tahai and Meyer 1999; Busenitz et al.

2003; Baumgartner and Pieters 2003; Podsakoff et al. 2005). In other words, if a

research topic is frequently recurring in high-status journals, we would expect the

particular topic to gain an increasing status and legitimacy among peers in the broader

discipline of management. The status among journals is thus of critical importance

when seeking information about where to publish a certain topic; what topic or area of

interest to publish in order to obtain a high status among peers, and who to cite in

order to obtain maximum visibility and status (Garfield 1972; Culnan 1987; Doreian

1988; Cote and Leong 1991; MacMillan I. 1991; MacMillan 1993; Everett 1994;

Tahai and Meyer 1999; Baumgartner and Pieters 2003).

The purpose of this paper is twofold. First of all, we seek to describe the status

network of management journals in the management discipline at large. Instead of

focusing on a relatively small segment of management, organization, or marketing

journals, as earlier studies have done (e.g. MacMillan I. 1991; Blackburn and Mitchell

1991; Johnson and Podsakoff 1994; Tahai and Meyer 1999; Baumgartner and Pieters

2003; Podsakoff et al. 2005), this study seeks to discuss a broad scope of journals

related to the entire field of management including aspects such as economics,

psychology, and sociology. Hence citations from a broad range of journals in the field

of management were obtained from a set of 73 source journals in management from

Page 48: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

48

three different two-year periods using the ICI Journal Citation Report and data

obtained from ‘Web of Science’.

Instead of using the raw citation counts to evaluate the status and citation pattern

among these journals as prior citation studies, this paper presents a novel

methodology to identify the status network of management journals in general. The

citation matrices were transformed into three adjacency matrices with absent, weak, or

strong ties between entities as used in social network theory. Two different measures

of centrality were then applied to the matrices to indicate the relative status of journals

in the social network of journals for the three periods. These measures are then

discussed and the status among management journals and changes in status over time

are considered.

Prior citation studies have treated the overall network of management journals as one

single network and have not considered subgroups in this network. Clearly, this is

needed since we are often less interested in the status of a given journal in

management in general than its status in a particular area within management.

Moreover, this procedure makes it possible to discern the importance of different

clusters of journals, or areas of research, to the field of entrepreneurship and not just

to single journals. Hence, the network is divided into sub-areas or clusters with a

relatively high citation activity inside the cluster, and each cluster is given a label

corresponding to the main area(s) of interest in this particular cluster. From these

procedures, we know which journals have the highest status among the broad range of

management journals as well as the areas of interests in these journals and the

subfields in the total network of management journals.

The second purpose of this paper is to assess the legitimacy and citation pattern of

entrepreneurship research from the mid-eighties. This is basically important because it

establishes whether or not entrepreneurship has established a theoretical platform of

its own (Landström and Johannisson 2001), and also whether entrepreneurship studies

can be considered a legitimate area of study in the domain of the dominating

management discourse (Busenitz et al. 2003). The field of entrepreneurship was

accorded division status in 1987 and has attracted an increasing interest among

scholars since then (Low and MacMillan 1988; Shane 1997; Chandler and Lyon 2001;

Busenitz et al. 2003). Alongside this growing interest, a number of scholars have

Page 49: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

49

considered the field of entrepreneurship as an object of study within management in

its own rights. The first study in this line of research appeared in Low and MacMillan

1988. They sought to define the forum of entrepreneurship research in terms of stated

preferences of respectable journals from a list of 20 tenured professors in the field.

Since then, a number of scholars have sought to define where issues on

entrepreneurship are published in scientific journals, how entrepreneurship is related

to other journals and topics in management and whether entrepreneurship is gaining

increased legitimacy in the wider field of management (e.g. MacMillan 1993,

Harrison and Leitch 1996, Romano and Ratnatunga 1996, Aldrich and Baker 1997,

Shane 1997, Huse and Landström 1998, Landström and Johannisson 2001, Busenitz

et al. 2003, and Fried 2003). However, the most encompassing citation study of

entrepreneurship publications in Busenitz et al. 2003 used only 7 source journals as

representatives of the field of management (all of them from the general management

group as will be discussed later on) as well as three journals solely devoted to

entrepreneurship topics.

This study, on the other hand, uses the broad range of management journals from

different research areas (and clusters) in management to improve representativeness

and facilitate comparisons of journals across research areas and subfields. From the

original status network of management journals, it is first assessed where issues of

entrepreneurship are typically published, i.e. in which journals entrepreneurship-

related research typically appears and the pattern over time. We then assess the

legitimacy of entrepreneurship research over time, taking into consideration the status

of the journals that publish issues on entrepreneurship. Finally, we seek to assess the

inspirational sources of entrepreneurship-related articles, i.e. which journals are cited

by entrepreneurship-related articles and the changing patterns over time.

Journal Selection

Management is a multifaceted academic research area, manifested in the huge amount

of research outlets covering a broad range of topics. As a proxy for this diversity, the

Academy of Management currently posseses 21 divisions covering a broad range of

research areas within the discipline at large. Hence, if we seek a broad description of

Page 50: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

50

the management discipline, we need to focus on a broad range of research outlets. The

source journals, where citations were extracted from, were initially obtained from the

2001 edition of the ISI Journal Citation Reports covered by the Social Science

Citation Index (SSCI). Journals with an impact factor above 0.5 were selected from

two relevant categories: ‘business’ and ‘management’, in total 55 journals. Only full-

length articles were considered. The impact factor measures the frequency with which

an average article in a journal has been cited in a particular year by all other journals

in the entire database; more specifically the number of current citations to articles

published in the previous two years divided by the total number of articles published

in the two previous years (Garfield 1972). The measure is used to indicate a particular

journal’s relative importance compared to others. Because of its simplicity, this

measure has become one of the most popular citation-based measures of journal

influence (Johnson and Podsakoff 1994; Baumgartner and Pieters 2003;). However,

the measure is not suitable to represent the status hierarchy among management

journals as we will discuss later on. Using the Web of Science database, cited

references were collected from each of these 55 journals in three different time

periods 1985-1986, 1993-1994, and 2001-2002. The reason for collecting data across

a two-year period was to avoid instability of citation patterns due to short-term

fluctuations (Tahai and Meyer 1999; Baumgartner and Pieters 2003). Some of the

journals do not appear in the database in every period, either because the journal did

not exist in the particular period or because some of the journals in the particular

period were not part of the SSCI database. From the collected data, the raw number of

citations (more than 500,000 total citations) was sorted and counted. Journals with

absolute high citation counts (above 750 raw citations) that were also included in the

SSCI database were included in the list. The reason for doing this was to capture

management or management-related journals with a relatively high raw number of

citations, i.e. an impact factor above 0.5, which were not included in the list of

journals labeled management or business in the SSCI database. Finally, to take into

consideration the inconsistency in use of abbreviations, the complete list was first

sorted alphabetically and checked to account for any consistency bias related to use of

wrong abbreviations. When adding these journals to the list, we get 73 journals, as

presented in Tables 1a to 1e, which have been divided into five clusters, or research

Page 51: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

51

areas, as will be discussed later on. Moreover, in each cluster, the journals have been

sorted by the highest Bonacich eigenvector centrality measure in the latest period,

which is a measure in which the centrality of a particular journal is recursively related

to the centralities of the journal(s) to which it is connected as discussed later on.

1985-1986 1993-1994 2001-2002

Table 1a: Economics and quantitatively oriented journals

Impact

Degree

Bonacich

Degree

Bonacich

Degree

Bonacich

Journal Of Business 1,357 51 229 52 205 55 169 American Economic Review Add 42 103 53 110 52 89 American Business Law Journal 1,172 0 31 0 58 0 72 Econometrica Add 38 112 37 86 43 71 Quarterly Journal Of Economics Add 26 65 35 74 35 69 Business History 0,935 0 15 0 58 0 69 Journal Of Common Market Studies 1,167 0 14 0 28 0 63 Journal Of Financial Economics Add 22 74 31 87 28 50 Journal Of Political Economy Add 31 78 30 68 33 48 Journal Of Finance Add 23 71 31 73 30 48 Operations Research Add 11 67 11 48 5 34 International Journal Of Forecasting 0,672 0 54 3 56 2 28 Journal Of Forecasting 0,582 5 73 2 46 2 24 Journal Of Productivity Analysis 0,926 0 0 0 0 2 18

1985-1986 1993-1994 2001-2002

Table 1b: Marketing oriented journals

Impact

Degree

Bonacich

Degree

Bonacich

Degree

Bonacich

Journal Of Marketing 2,403 34 183 39 162 50 153 Journal Of Marketing Research 1,671 30 163 38 133 42 134 Journal Of Product Innovation Management 0,673 2 86 7 91 10 100 Journal Of Consumer Research 1,821 19 112 29 104 32 93 Journal Of The Academy Of Marketing Science 1,844 0 0 3 3 0 85 Industrial Marketing Management 0,556 4 99 7 69 3 80 Marketing Science 1,83 9 24 15 77 24 77 Journal Of Retailing 0,826 8 114 7 63 14 55

Page 52: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

52

International Journal Of Research In Marketing 0,645 0 0 0 0 0 54 Journal Of Advertising Research 0,522 5 64 10 52 4 29 Journal Of Advertising 0,688 29 88 25 54 19 28 Advances In Consumer Research Add 14 100 15 54 14 19 Journal Of Public Policy & Marketing 0,941 0 68 4 37 3 14

1985-1986 1993-1994 2001-2002

Table 1c: Information and technology oriented journals

Impact

Degree

Bonacich

Degree

Bonacich

Degree

Bonacich

Sloan Management Review 1,698 23 142 30 155 39 155 MIS Quarterly 1,796 9 109 16 131 20 138 Decision Sciences 0,723 15 141 11 109 10 108 Communications Of The ACM Add 7 109 15 101 13 107 International Journal Of Operations & Production Management 0,638 0 0 0 0 2 88 Information Management 1,176 1 84 7 74 2 87 Journal Of Information Technology 0,545 0 0 0 46 0 76 International Journal Of Electronic Commerce 1,179 0 0 0 0 3 74 Journal Of Environmental Economics And Management 1,224 1 1 0 28 1 1

1985-1986 1993-1994 2001-2002

Table 1d: General management and sociology oriented journals

Impact

Degree

Bonacich

Degree

Bonacich

Degree

Bonacich

Academy Of Management Review 3,157 44 238 59 256 87 258 Academy Of Management Journal 2,831 52 256 58 251 87 253 Administrative Science Quarterly 3,98 58 270 65 253 80 243 Strategic Management Journal 2,682 22 166 50 216 73 240 Management Science 1,502 52 224 67 230 73 218 Organization Science 2,058 0 0 20 141 61 214 Journal Of Management 1,306 1 107 27 159 45 180 Human Relations 0,858 34 206 32 185 38 164 Harvard Business Review 2,465 58 217 76 173 81 161 California Management Review 1,352 12 133 21 132 34 158

Page 53: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

53

Journal Of International Business Studies 0,866 9 126 24 140 31 156 Journal Of Management Studies 0,634 11 129 19 131 28 147 American Sociological Review Add 39 176 42 142 46 135 Research Policy 1,289 4 100 15 111 23 133 American Journal Of Sociology Add 30 127 35 125 35 124 Journal Of Business Venturing 0,574 0 0 3 111 9 114 Organizational Studies 0,899 2 86 7 117 18 113 Human Resource Management 1,161 2 108 16 139 15 108 Organizational Dynamics 0,841 14 141 11 109 12 98 Management Learning 0,644 0 0 0 0 0 98 New Technology Work And Employment 0,8 0 0 0 80 0 90 Journal Of Management Inquiry 0,52 0 0 0 0 1 88 Journal Of World Business 0,583 0 0 0 0 1 86 Organization 0,607 4 7 0 0 10 82

1985-1986 1993-1994 2001-2002

Table 1e: Psychology and organization oriented journals

Impact

Degree

Bonacich

Degree

Bonacich

Degree

Bonacich

Journal Of Personality And Social Psychology Add 40 174 49 159 61 150 Organizational Behavior And Human Decision Processes 1,269 8 122 33 167 35 143 Psychological Bulletin Add 52 203 53 160 45 127 Personnel Psychology Add 18 153 18 130 24 106 Group & Organization Management 0,73 0 0 0 99 4 97 Leadership quarterly 2,511 0 0 0 0 2 85 American Psychologist Add 38 154 26 94 28 82 Research In Organizational Behavior Add 25 80 33 174 33 79 Negotiation journal – On The Process Of Dispute Settlement 0,5 0 67 0 112 0 74 Psychological Review Add 32 123 31 118 23 70 International Journal Of Selection And Assessment 0,667 0 0 0 0 0 46 Journal Of Applied Psychology Add 20 100 14 52 7 40 Journal Of Organizational Behavior Management 1,176 0 0 0 0 0 33

In each of the three periods, the collected data forms a matrix with the raw citation

counts. The typical form of citation analysis would be to examine the raw citation

count weighted with some measure of the particular journal’s citation practice in each

Page 54: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

54

of these three matrices (see e.g. Blackburn and Mitchell 1981 and Sharplin and

Marbry 1985). However, to be able to compare the citation pattern among the

different journals as a social network, the data was transformed using the following

criterion. For a “social” relation to be present between two journals, the number of

citations given to a particular journal (e.g. from Strategic Management Journal to

Academy of Management Journal) should be higher than the average raw citations

(excluding self citations) given from that particular journal to all other journals in the

list of 73 journals. If this was not the case, the relation was treated as “absent” (0s).

Furterhmore, the relations are divided into two groups; one group of “weak” relations

(1s) representing the third quartile above average and another group of “strong”

relations (2s) representing the forth quartile above the average number of raw

citations. Thus, instead of using the raw number of citations, these were transformed

into a social network of management journals where strength of ties, ranging from 0

to 2, explains where a particular journal is situated in the network of journals.

Journal Status in the Network

Seeking aspects of status between entities in a social network, we often turn to

measures of centrality (Bonacich 1972; Freeman 1979; Brass 1984; Bonacich 1987;

Wasserman and Galaskiewicz 1994; Wasserman and Faust 1994; Scott 2000). These

measures describe the positions of entities in a network relative to others, and some

centrality measures also describe the position in relation to the complete network. The

basic idea among all these measures is that high-status journals are the recipients of

many citations from other journals, i.e. they are in high demand and somewhat central

in the network of management journals. Journals that are more central are expected to

exert more influence on status by virtue of being intellectually linked with a large

number of other journals in the network. By the very nature of centrality, they are

equally more likely to be connected to other high-status journals, i.e. central journals,

in the network. In this paper, two measures of centrality, i.e. degree centrality and

Bonacich eigenvector centrality are used to describe the network of management

journals2.

2 For a general discussion on centrality measures, see e.g. Scott 2000 or Wasserman and Faust 1994.

Page 55: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

55

Degree Centrality

The simplest and perhaps most intuitive measure of centrality is degree centrality

(Freeman 1979; Wasserman and Faust 1994; Scott 2000). The degree centrality of a

particular journal is simply a measure for the number of other journals that the

particular journal has direct contact with, i.e. the number of journals to which a

journal is adjacent or connected to through their citations. A journal with a relatively

high degree of centrality is heavily involved in the network which is directly

surrounding the particular journal. It occupies a position permitting direct contact with

many other journals and is supposedly seen as a major channel of information,

legitimacy, and status. On the other hand, a journal with a relatively low degree of

centrality is often seen as peripheral and somehow isolated from direct contact with

most of the other journals in the network (Freeman 1979; Wasserman and Faust 1994;

Scott 2000). In this context, the degree measure can be seen as an index of a particular

journal’s communicative activity and its “cognitive” influence among the journals in

this particular journal’s immediate surroundings.

The social network software package UCINET VI was used to convert the adjacency

matrices into individual centrality scores (Borgatti, Everett, and Freeman 2002). In

order to preserve as much information as possible concerning journal status, the data

was kept asymmetrically. This means that, in computing centrality, sending (out-

degree) and receiving (in-degree) a citation are treated as distinct activities. Thus,

even though a particular journal may be citing other journals, only citations received

from other journals to that particular journal generate the status. Furthermore, the data

was also kept valued, i.e. the weight given to the strength of the relationship is

maintained and strong relationships count as 2 in-degrees accordingly.

The overall result of this maneuver is presented in Tables 1a to 1e.

The status among the journals is remarkably stabile in the three periods. This is

indicated by the relatively high Spearman rank correlation coefficients, ranging from

0.84 (between 1985-1986 and 2001-2002) to 0.96 (between 1993-1994 and 2001-

2002) among the 73 journals (p<0.0001) in the 3 periods. Moreover, the Herfindahl

index equally suggests that the distribution and concentration of in-degrees, or the

Page 56: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

56

share of received citations, is remarkably stable in the time period ranging from 308 in

the first period to 277 in the last period. Finally, the Cr5 index is stable at around 24%

in this period3. Thus, the status obtained from degree centrality is overall relatively

stable in the periods observed. However, a few notable changes have occurred. For

example, the four psychology journals: Psychological Bulletin, American

Psychologist, Journal of Applied Psychology, and Psychological Review lost status

over the period from 15.2% of the total amount of “in-degrees” in 1985-1986 to only

8.7% in 2001-2002. On the other hand, Journal Of International Business Studies,

Academy Of Management Review, Organizational Behavior and Human Decision

Processes, Strategic Management Journal, Journal of Management, and Organization

Science gained increasing status in the period from 7.4 % in 1985-1986 to 19.1% of

the in-degrees in 2001-2002. Although Organization Science is a relatively young

journal, it has relatively quickly acquired a high status in the field with a 1.4% share

of degrees in 1993-1994 to a 3.5 share in 2001-2002 (rank 4).

Bonacich Eigenvector Centrality

In an early study, Salancik 1986 used citation data to exemplify dependency

networks. According to Salancik, a journal is central to the extent that other journals

in the network cite from the journal (i.e. it receives in-degrees), but also to the extent

that the journal contributes to important other journals in the network. However, the

degree measures of centrality do not consider the fact that centrality of a particular

journal is dependent upon the centrality of the journals that it is connected to.

Basically, being cited by relatively higher status journals should add more to a

journal’s relative status than being cited by a journal without any in-degrees. Thus,

what we need is a measure in which the centrality of a particular journal is recursively

related to the centralities of the journal(s) to which it is connected. A measure with

these properties was initially introduced by (Bonacich 1972). He proposes an

eigenvector approach, in which – in this context – a journal’s centrality is its summed

connections to others, weighted by their centralities. Hence, contrary to the in-degree

3 In this context, the CR5 index measures the sum of the citation shares of the 5 largest journals in terms of received citations, whereas the Herfindahl index considers the distribution of all the journals’ citation shares, given by the formula: Σ Si2, where Si is the citation share of the journal.

Page 57: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

57

and the closeness centrality measures, the eigenvector approach pays less attention to

patterns of citations that are more local in nature than the degree centrality measure,

but concentrates instead on the overall structure of the network. However, a limitation

to this measure is that it does not allow asymmetric data (Bonacich 1987; Borgatti,

Everett, and Freeman 2002). In order to keep as much information as possible, the

matrices were first symmetrized by taking the average value of the relationships

between the different pairs of journals. Thus, the relations were assigned values from

0 to 2 accordingly. Journals without in-degrees were disregarded because they had no

influence on the status of the other journals in the network. Hence the matrices were

recoded by replacing all 0.5 relationships to absent relationships.

The rankings of journals from this measure, obtained from UCINET, are presented in

Table 1a to 1e. Once again, the rankings are relatively stable among the journals in the

three periods. The Spearman rank correlation ranges from 0.68 to 0,83 (n=57,

p<0,0001). Thus, the overall status of the network in terms of Bonacich centrality

scores is relatively stable in the period observed. However, Organization Science is

once again notable for its fast increase in centrality from a rank 17 in 1993-1994 to a

rank 6 in 2001-2002. On the other hand, Psychological Review and Research in

Organizational Behavior went from an average ranking of 17 in 1993-1004 to an

average ranking of 50 in 2001-2002.

Comparing Measures of Centrality

Both centrality measures show a high degree of stability over time. Now we want to

compare the centrality measures with each other as well as the impact factor. Table 2

below lists the rankings from the three different measures of status in 2001-2002 (that

is, the period where the impact factors are calculated). We would expect the impact

factor to be different from the centrality measures, especially the Bonacich centrality

measure, for a number of reasons. First of all, the impact factors are derived from

citation exchanges from all journals covered by the Social Science Citation Index,

regardless of subject or impact, whereas the degree as well as the Bonacich measures

in this paper are obtained from a relatively small (but high-status) group of journals.

Second, the impact factor only considers citations made in the past two years whereas

Page 58: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

58

the centrality measures used in this paper consider all citations made (see e.g. Tahai

and Meyer 1999 for a criticism of this aspect). Third, the impact factor focuses on the

influence of an average article in a particular journal, i.e. it takes into consideration

the number of articles in calculating “status” as discussed earlier on. Fourth, the

impact factor includes self-citations with the result that a journal that only cites itself

may have a relatively high impact factor. Fifth, the impact factor does not consider the

status of the citing journal like the Bonacich eigenvector measure does. Due to these

limitations, the impact measure is not suitable as a centrality measure and we would

expect it to be the least important correlate among the measures.

Rank # Impact Degree Bonacich

1 Administrative Science Quarterly Academy Of Management Review

Academy Of Management Journal

Academy Of Management

Review

2 Academy Of Management Review Harvard Business Review Academy Of Management

Journal

3 Academy Of Management Journal Administrative Science Quarterly Administrative Science

Quarterly

4 Strategic Management Journal Strategic Management Journal

Management Science Strategic Management Journal

5 Leadership Quarterly Organization Science

Journal of Personality and Social Psychology Management Science

6 Harvard Business Review Journal of Business Organization Science

7 Journal of Marketing American Economic Review Journal of Management

8 Organization Science Journal of Marketing Journal of Business

9

Journal of the Academy of Marketing

Science

American Sociological Review Human Relations

Page 59: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

59

10 Marketing Science Journal of Management

Psychological Bulletin Harvard Business review

11 Journal of Consumer Research Econometrica California Management

Review

12 MIS Quarterly Journal Of Marketing Research Journal Of International

Business Studies

13 Sloan Management Review Sloan Management Review Sloan Management Review

14 Journal of Marketing Research Human Relations Journal of Marketing

15 Management Science

Organizational Behavior And Human Decision

Processes

American Journal Of Sociology

Quarterly Journal Of Economics

Journal of Personality and

Social Psychology

Table 2 – Overview of the rankings in the 2001-2002 periods, with the different

measures of centrality and status.

From Table 2, it is evident that there is a relatively high overlap between the highest

ranked journals, which were obtained from the degree and Bonacich centrality

measures, which are equally consistent with the Spearman correlation coefficient of

0.83 (p<0.0001), which was obtained from the rankings of the journals4. As expected,

however, the Bonacich eigenvector centrality and the impact measure of centrality are

less correlated with a Spearman correlation coefficient of 0.53 (p<0.0004) for the

reasons described above. For example, Leadership Quarterly obtained a rank 5 in

impact, but is about rank 40 when using the Bonacich centrality measure and the

degree centrality measure.

Differences between the degree centrality and the Bonacich centrality are readily

interpretable. For example, Harvard Business Review is ranked as 3 in degree

centrality, but only obtains a rank 10 in Bonacich centrality. By the same token,

American Economic Review and American Sociological Review obtained a relatively

high degree ranking (7 and 9), whereas their Bonacich ranking is relatively low (35

and 19). These differences suggest that these journals are relatively central in their

immediate surroundings or among relatively low status journals. In other words, these

journals may appear as high-status journals in some clusters in the network, whereas

4 Calculating the Spearman measure, only journals from the ‘management’ or ‘business’ list in the ISI Journal Citation Report could be used in order to get a realistic comparison of impact measures.

Page 60: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

60

they are not high ranked by the total network. This is only natural since each field of

inquiry has a forum in which the work of scholars in that particular field should be

presented and in which new knowledge is accepted and considered respectable in this

particular community. Hence, if we seek status in the total network, we need to apply

the Bonacich measure whereas the degree measure is valuable in describing the

influence of a particular journal in a cluster or research topic in the total network.

Clusters of Related Journals

So far, we have considered the whole network of management journals (73 journals)

when calculating status. However, it should be evident that various sub-areas or

clusters in the network of management journals do exist. Furthermore, it should be

equally evident that the status of particular journals differs across various clusters, i.e.

one journal (for example Journal of Marketing) may be influential in one area

(marketing), but less influential in others (for example among sociology-oriented

journals). This was equally implied in the differences between the centrality degree

measure and the Bonacich measure of centrality. Moreover, in a network with

relatively dense clusters, it is difficult (if not impossible) to have a very high status in

all areas.

One common way of measuring the extent to which a network displays clustering is to

examine the local neighborhood of entities, in this case journals, and to calculate the

density in this neighborhood (Wasserman and Faust 1994; Scott 2000). The density of

a concrete neighborhood is simply the proportion of all possible ties that are actually

present in the neighborhood. After doing this for all journals in the whole network, we

can characterize the degree of clustering as an average of all the neighborhoods. To

perform this procedure, the cluster optimization procedure in UCINET, using the

maximum density as the fit criterion, was used to identify the clusters in the network

(Borgatti, Everett, and Freeman 2002). From this operation, 5 clusters with a

relatively high density inside each cluster were identified in the larger network of

management journals. The clustering of the journals is illustrated in Tables 1a to 1e.

Each cluster was given a rough label describing the content in each research area.

Page 61: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

61

These labels were obtained by reading the editorial policies of each of these journals

and by looking for possible overlaps in these.

This suggests that a very large proportion of the total number of journals are clustered

into 5 local neighborhoods or related sub-areas. Moreover, as indicated by the density

matrix below, the clusters in the network are differently related to each other. For

example, according to the density matrix, we should expect for example cluster 1 to

be more related to cluster 4 than to cluster 5.

Density matrix

1 2 3 4 5

1 0.990 0.022 0.016 0.202 0.049

2 0.110 0.864 0.068 0.285 0.225

3 0.071 0.385 0.901 0.606 0.197

4 0.152 0.093 0.106 0.941 0.292

5 0.027 0.030 0.017 0.340 1.036

These relational differences are illustrated in Figure 1 below, representing a

multidimensional scaling of the clustering and the connection between the clusters

using the program package ‘Pajek’ (Borgatti, Everett, and Freeman 2002). In the

multidimensional scaling, journals that have a relatively strong mutual citation

relationship are positioned relatively close to one another, whereas journals that are

distant have no or only a relatively weak citation relationship. Moreover, the journals

were given a number, matching the particular cluster that it represents, and lines were

removed between the journals to give the best visual representation of the clusters.

Page 62: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

62

Figure 1 – A multidimensional scaling of the 2001-2002 citation network and the

identified clusters

Figure 1 is readily interpretable. The (almost) horizontal dimension distinguishes

journals with an economic/quantitative orientation (the left side of the figure) from

those with a psychological and organizational orientation. The vertical dimension, on

the other hand, distinguishes journals with a marketing orientation (the upper half)

from journals with a more general management and sociology orientation (the middle

and lower half). The dominance of the forth cluster is equally indicated by the central

position in the network.

Finally, from this clustering, we can discern any changes in status in different areas of

research within management. Figure 2 depicts the average Bonacich measure of

centrality for each journal in the different cluster.

Page 63: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

63

Average journal status in each cluster

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

160

180

1985-1986 1993-1994 2001-2002

Period

Bon

acic

h M

easu

re Cluster 1

Cluster 2

Cluster 3

Cluster 4

Cluster 5

Figure 2 – Average journal status within clusters

The fourth cluster has experienced the highest increase in status from an average of

128 in the first period to an average of 153. Moreover, after a decrease in 1993-1994,

cluster 3 has experienced an increase in the average Bonacich score from 72 to 93.

Finally, journals with an economic or quantitative orientation as well as journals with

a marketing orientation have generally experienced a decrease in status among

management journals.

Entrepreneurship Research in Management

The final part of this paper seeks to depict how entrepreneurship is emerging as a field

of research in comparison to the network of management journals. The first question

we seek to answer is: which journals and clusters are now publishing issues of

entrepreneurship and have been since the mid-eighties? We then compare this to the

status network in order to see if entrepreneurship has gained increasing legitimacy and

status over time. We also examine where clusters issues on entrepreneurship have

generally been published? Finally, we collect citation data for three periods,

Page 64: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

64

corresponding to the periods used above, from articles published in the 73 source

journals on entrepreneurship issues. From these citations, we illustrate differences in

citation practice among entrepreneurship-related articles.

In order to obtain articles on entrepreneurship issues, a Boolean search was used in

the Web of Science among the 73 source journals. If the title, abstract, or keywords

contained the words entrepreneur* OR entrepreneurial OR entrepreneurship OR new

venture creation OR new venture emergence OR emerging ventures OR founder*,

these were included in the list. These search expressions are almost identical with

earlier search expressions used to search for entrepreneurship articles. For example,

the only difference between this search string and the search string used by Busenitz

et al. 2003 is the expression, ‘small business’, which was not included in this list

because the interest of this paper is on entrepreneurship research and not on small

businesses. Among the 73 journals in the period from 1985 to 2002, 751 articles on

entrepreneurship-related issues were published. Disregarding articles in Journal of

Business Venturing, since this might skew the results, the total number of articles

came to 485. Changes in this citation pattern over time in the different clusters are

illustrated below in Figure 3. This figure illustrates entrepreneurship-related articles

divided into clusters as a percentage of the total number of articles in the journals for

each period.

Page 65: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

65

Percentages of entrepreneurship related articles

0,00%

1,00%

2,00%

3,00%

4,00%

5,00%

6,00%

7,00%

8,00%

1985-1986

1987-1988

1989-1990

1991-1992

1993-1994

1995-1996

1997-1998

1999-2000

2001-2002

Cluster 1

Cluster 2

Cluster 3

Cluster 4

Cluster 5

Total

Figure 3 – Percentages of entrepreneurship-related articles divided into clusters of

research area

Beginning with the 1985-1986 period, the data shown in Figure 3 clearly indicate a

continuing increase in the number of entrepreneurship-related articles among the

source journals. If we compare the 1985-1992 period with the 1995-2002 period, the

share of entrepreneurship-related articles increased from 15.09% to 24.11%.

Moreover, it is evident that the primary target for entrepreneurship articles is the

general management and social cluster (cluster 4). This is, however, to be expected

since Journal of Business Venturing was also included in this cluster of research. How

is this distribution of entrepreneurship-related articles then related to the status among

management journals?

Table 3 shows the top 10 ranking of the Bonacich centrality measure in the 2001-2002

period and the corresponding percentages of entrepreneurship-related articles. As

suggested in the table, the appearance of entrepreneurship-related articles has

increased from an average of less than 2% in the period from 1985 to 1990 to about

5% on average in the five-year period 1996-2001. In fact, the only high-status journals

(top 15) in which entrepreneurship research does not appear are Journal of Business,

Journal of Personality and Social Psychology. The Spearman rank coefficient between

Page 66: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

66

the Bonacich rankings in 2001-2002 and the rankings of the appearance of

entrepreneurship articles in the whole period among all the source journals on 0.58

(p<0.001) equally suggests a positive relationship between the status of management

journals and the publication of entrepreneurship-related articles.

Share of

entrepreneurship-

related articles

1985

-1986

1987

-1988

1989

-1990

1991

-1992

1993

-1994

1995

-1996

1997

-1998

1999

-2000

2001

-2002

Ave

rage P

ercent

Academy Of Management

Review 1,98% 2,86% 0,00% 2,00% 0,00% 9,52% 4,55% 12,12% 21,43% 6,05%

Academy Of Management

Journal 0,00% 0,00% 0,00% 0,00% 0,00% 2,86% 3,28% 10,91% 10,64% 3,08%

Administrative Science

Quarterly 2,17% 0,00% 4,35% 6,82% 0,00% 0,00% 7,32% 9,76% 5,88% 4,03%

Strategic Management Journal 1,92% 1,15% 6,98% 6,00% 4,04% 4,04% 5,04% 3,42% 12,50% 5,01%

Management Science 0,00% 0,00% 0,00% 0,00% 0,00% 0,00% 0,37% 0,00% 0,00% 0,04%

Organization Science n/a n/a n/a 0,00% 1,47% 4,29% 2,41% 4,29% 2,90% 2,56%

Journal of Management 0,00% 2,94% 3,28% 5,00% 6,25% 2,56% 3,85% 3,23% 7,55% 3,85%

Journal Of Applied Psychology 0,00% 0,00% 0,56% 0,00% 0,56% 0,00% 1,31% 0,00% 0,00% 0,27%

Human Relations 0,00% 0,00% 0,00% 1,75% 1,49% 1,47% 0,76% 0,00% 1,35% 0,76%

Harvard Business Review 9,68% 2,99% 0,00% 5,42% 4,52% 3,13% 1,96% 5,49% 7,22% 4,49%

Average Percent 1,75% 1,10% 1,68% 2,70% 1,83% 2,79% 3,08% 4,92% 6,95%

Table 3 – Share of entrepreneurship-related articles among the top 10 status journals

Thus, these measures suggest that the legitimacy and status of the field of

entrepreneurship has increased since the mid-eighties. Moreover, the citation pattern

has equally changed in this period. The most significant change is related to the

distribution of articles, as suggested by the Herfindahl index depicted in Table 4.

According to the Herfindahl index, the concentration of entrepreneurship-related

articles has decreased. This suggests that the number of outlets for entrepreneurship

research has increased among the source journals at large and among the high-status

journals in particular.

Page 67: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

67

19

85-1

986

19

87-1

988

19

89-1

990

19

91-1

992

19

93-1

994

19

95-1

996

19

97-1

998

19

99-2

000

20

01-2

002

Herfindahl index

2500 1005 976 1016 1003 950 554 602 753

Who do they cite? The final question we seek to answer is: which authors do entrepreneurship-related

journals tend to cite for either intellectual ballast or status? Normally, a citation

analysis makes the assumption (or at least hopes, for the sake of science) that an

intellectual link does exist between the citing source and the reference article.

However, authors may cite an article from a high-status journal which they perhaps

have not even read only to enhance their own status (Baird and Oppenheim 1994). In

addition, people may cite a particular article if they find it provocative or out of bonds

with their own ideas. Moreover, the citation is only a subset of the total population of

influence (Tahai and Meyer 1999). For example, knowledge originally obtained from

a specific article may have become common knowledge in a field in the sense that

citations are no longer used. In other words, scholars in entrepreneurship may use

insight from for example psychology without citing any sources because it is an

integrated part of the canon in entrepreneurship. We need to keep this is mind when

we conclude from the citation pattern from entrepreneurship-oriented journals.

From the journals on entrepreneurship obtained from the Boolean search

(disregarding Journal of Business Venturing), data for the three periods (in period

2001-2002, this was more than 19,000 raw citations) was collected. Table 4 is an

extract of this procedure, showing the 15 journals that are on average the most cited in

entrepreneurship-related articles. This table suggests that Strategic Management

Journal is the most cited journal in the three periods with an average share of cites at

8.72% among the 72 journals (disregarding Journal of Business Venturing).

Moreover, on average these 15 journals obtained about 65% of the citations among

Page 68: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

68

the 72 source journals in the three periods even though the top 15 share of citations

has decreased from 71.3% to 61.5%.

1984

-1985

1993

-1994

2001

-2002

To

tal

Share/number Share/number Share/number Share

Strategic Management Journal

4,41% 6 8,99% 142 12,77% 551 8,72%

Administrative Science Quarterly

10,29% 14 6,65% 105 5,86% 253 7,60%

Harvard Business Review 11,76% 16 7,15% 113 3,29% 142 7,40% American Economic Review 10,29% 14 3,92% 62 5,17% 223 6,46% Academy Of Management

Journal 5,88% 8 5,44% 86 5,47% 236 5,60%

Academy Of Management Review

2,94% 4 5,32% 84 6,51% 281 4,92%

Management Science 4,41% 6 4,62% 73 2,64% 114 3,89% American Journal Of

Sociology 2,21% 3 3,16% 50 4,33% 187 3,23%

Journal Of Marketing 4,41% 6 2,22% 35 2,36% 102 3,00% California Management

Review 4,41% 6 2,15% 34 1,39% 60 2,65%

Journal Of Political Economy 4,41% 6 1,84% 29 1,34% 58 2,53% American Sociological

Review 0,74% 1 4,05% 64 2,64% 114 2,48%

Research Policy 2,21% 3 2,34% 37 2,34% 101 2,30% Quarterly Journal Of

Economics 2,21% 3 2,09% 33 2,48% 107 2,26%

Journal Of Management 0,74% 1 2,97% 47 2,94% 127 2,22% Total among the top 15 71,32% 97 62,91% 994 61,53% 2656 65,26%

Table 4 – The top 15 on average most cited journals by entrepreneurship articles

Page 69: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

69

Citations from Entrepreneurship related articles

0

500

1000

1500

2000

2500

3000

3500

4000

1984-1985 1993-1994 2001-2002

Period

Num

ber

Of c

itatio

ns

Cluster 1

Cluster 2

Cluster 3

Cluster 4

Cluster 5

Total

Figure 4 – Citations from entrepreneurship-related articles divided into clusters

As indicated in Figure 4, the citations from entrepreneurship-related articles are

primarily concentrated among the general management cluster, which is expected

because these are the journals that primarily deal with entrepreneurship issues.

However, a notable exception is American Economic Review with an average number

of citations at 6.5%. In fact, the economic and quantitatively oriented cluster is the

second most important source of inspiration even though entrepreneurship-related

articles do not appear more frequently in these journals when compared to journals

from the psychology, marketing, or technology clusters as suggested by Figure 3.

Finally, when comparing the share of citations to one of the 73 original source

journals relative to the total number of citations used in entrepreneurship-related

articles in the three periods, a notable difference appears. In the 1985-1986 period, the

share of citations for the 73 source journals was 15%. However, in the final period

(2001-2002), this share increased to 23%. This suggests that the citation pattern

among entrepreneurship-related articles is changing in the sense that citations are

increasingly given to high-status journals.

Page 70: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

70

Conclusion

This citation-based study uses a social network approach to discern the status among a

broad range of management journals. Using a Bonacich eigenvector centrality

measure, 5 journals were found to be particularly central in the network in the three

periods observed, i.e. Academy of Management Review, Academy of Management

Journal, Administrative Science Quarterly, Strategic Management Journal, and

Management Science. Moreover, the Herfindahl index as well as the Spearman rank

correlation coefficients suggest that the status and citation pattern among journals are

remarkably stable in the three periods. Using a network clustering procedure, 5

clusters were identified in the network; economic and quantitative oriented journals,

marketing oriented journals, information and technology oriented journals, general

management and sociology oriented journals, and psychology and organization

oriented journals. Among these clusters, the most central cluster and the cluster

experiencing the highest increase in status in the observed period were the general

management and sociology cluster. The information and technology journals also

experienced a small increase in centrality in the period, whereas the psychology-

oriented journals experienced a decrease in centrality in the period.

Looking at entrepreneurship-related journals among the source journals, the study

shows that articles dealing with aspects of entrepreneurship have experienced an

increase since the mid-eighties among the selected journals. This is even more

pronounced if we look at the journals with a relatively high status in the network. The

increasing number of entrepreneurship-related articles among the high-status journals

in management suggests that entrepreneurship as a field of study has increased in

status. In addition, it is shown that aspects of entrepreneurship are primarily dealt with

in the cluster labeled general management and sociology journals, and secondary

economic and quantitatively oriented journals. Finally, when discerning the citation

pattern from entrepreneurship articles, it is shown that the general management and

sociology oriented journals are the primary sources of intellectual ballast or status.

Page 71: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

71

References

Aldrich, H. and T Baker. 1997. Blinded by the cites? Has there been progress in

entrpreneurship research? In Entrepreneurship 2000. Edited by D. L.

Sexton and R. W. Smilor. Chicago: Upstart Publishing.

Baden-Fuller, C, F Ravazzolo, and T Schweizer, "Making and Measuring Reputations

- The Research Ranking of European Business Schools," Long Range

Planning 33 (5): 621-650 (2000).

Baird, L and C. Oppenheim, "Do Citations Matter?," Journal of Information Science

20 (1): 2-15 (1994).

Baumgartner, H. and R. Pieters, "The structural influence of marketing journals: A

citation analysis of the discipline and its subareas over time," Journal of

Marketing 67: 123-139 (2003).

Blackburn, R. S. and M Mitchell, "Citation Analysis in the Organization Sciences,"

Journal of Applied Psychology 66 (3): 337-342 (1981).

Bonacich, P. 1972. A technique for analyzing overlapping memberships. In

Sociological Methodology. Edited by H. Costner. San Francisco: Jossey

Bass.

Bonacich, P., "Power and Centrality: A family of measures," American Journal of

Sociology 92 (5): 1170-1182 (1987).

Borgatti, S. P., M. G. Everett, and L. C. Freeman. 2002. Ucinet 6 for windows:

Software for Social Network Analysis. Harvard: Analytical

Technologies.

Brass, D. J., "Being in the right place: A structural analysis of individual influence in

an organization," Administrative Science Quarterly 29 (518): 539 (1984).

Page 72: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

72

Busenitz, L. W. et al., "Entrepreneurship research in emergence: Past trends and

future directions," Journal of Management 29 (3): 285-308 (2003).

Burt, R. S. 1992. Structural holes the social structure of competition. Cambridge,

Mass: Harvard University Press.

Chandler, G. N. and D. W. Lyon, "Issues of research design and construct

measurement in entrepreneurship research: The past decade,"

Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 26 (4): 101-113 (2001).

Cote, J. A and S. M. Leong, "Assessing the Influence of Journal of Consumer

Resaerch: A citation analysis," Journal of Consumer Research 18 (69):

81 (1991).

Culnan, M. J., "Mapping the intellectual structure of MIS, 1980-1985: A co-citation

analysis," MIS Quarterly September: 341-353 (1987).

Doreian, P., "Measuring the relative standing of disciplinary journals," Information

Processing & Management 24: 45-56 (1988).

Everett, J. E., "The journal relations of human relations," Human Relations 47 (1): 1-

12 (1994).

Extejt, M. M. and J. E. Smith, "The behavioral sciences and management: An

evaluation of relevant journals," Journal of Management 16 (3): 539-551

(1990).

Freeman, L. C., "Centrality in Social Networks Conceptual Clarification," Social

Networks 1: 215-239 (1979).

Fried, V. H., "Defining a forum for entrepreneurship scholars," Journal of Business

Venturing 18 (1): 1-11 (2003).

Garfield, E., "Citation analysis as a tool in journal evaluation," Science 178: 471-479

(1972).

Page 73: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

73

Gordon, M. D., "Citation ranking verses subjective evaluation in the determination of

journal hierarchies in the social sciences," Journal of the American

Society for Information Science 34: 55-57 (1982).

Harrison, R. T. and C. M Leitch, "Discipline emergence in entrepreneurship:

Accumulative fragmentalism or paradigmatic science?,"

Entrepreneurship, Innovation, and Change 5 (2): 65-83 (1996).

Huse, M. and H. Landström, "European Entrepreneurship and Small Business

Research: Methodological Openness and Contextual Differences,"

International Studies of Management & Organization 27 (3): 3-12

(1998).

Johnson, J. L. and P. M. Podsakoff, "Journal influence in the field of management: An

analysis using Salancik's index in a dependency network," Academy of

Management Journal 37 (5): 1392-1407 (1994).

Landström, H. and B. Johannisson, "Theoretical foundations of Swedish entrepreneurship and small-business research," Scandinavian Journal of Management 17: 225-248 (2001).

Low, B. S. and I. MacMillan, "Entrepreneurship: Past research on future Challenges,"

Journal of Management 14: 139-161 (1988).

MacMillan, I. C., "The Emerging Forum for Entrepreneurship Scholars," Journal of

Business Venturing 8 (5): 377-381 (1993).

MacMillan I., "Delineating a forum for business policy scholars," Strategic

Management Journal 12 (3): 161-165 (1991).

MacMillan, I. C., "Delineating A Forum for Entrepreneurship Scholars," Journal of

Business Venturing 6 (2): 83-87 (1991).

Pfeffer, J., "Barriers to the advance of organizational science: Paradigm development

as a dependent variable.," Academy of Management Review 18: 599-620

(1993).

Page 74: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

74

Podsakoff, P. M. et al., "The Influence of Management Journals in the 1980s and

1990s," Strategic Management Journal 26: 473-488 (2005).

Romano, C. and J. Ratnatunga, "A citation analysis of the impact of journals on

contemporary small enterprise research," Entrepreneurship Theory and

Practice 20 (3): 7-21 (1996).

Salancik, G. R., "An index of Subgroup Influence in Dependency Networks,"

Administrative Science Quarterly 31: 194-211 (1986).

Scott, J. 2000. Social Network Analysis: A Handbook. 2nd ed. Thousand Oaks, CA:

Sage.

Shane, S. A., "Who is publishing the entrepreneurship research?," Journal of

Management 23 (1): 83-95 (1997).

Sharplin, A. D. and R. H. Marbry, "The relative importance of journals used in

mangement research: An alternative ranking," Human Relations 38 (2):

139-149 (1985).

Stahl, M. J., T. L. Leap, and Z. Z. Wei, "Publications in Leading Management

Journals as a Measure of Institutional Resaerch Productivity," Academy

of Management Journal 31 (1): 707-720 (1988).

Tahai, A. and M. W. Meyer, "A Revealed Preference Study of Management Journals

Direct Influence," Strategic Management Journal 20 (3): 279-296

(1999).

Wasserman, Stanley and Katherine Faust. 1994. Social network analysis methods and

applications. Cambridge, New York: Cambridge University Press.

Wasserman, Stanley and Joseph Galaskiewicz. 1994. Advances in social network

analysis research in the social and behavioral sciences. Thousand Oaks,

Calif: Sage Publications.

Page 75: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

75

Page 76: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

76

A REVITALIZATION OF PERSONAL TRAITS AS COMPLEMENTAR Y TO

THE COGNITIVE APPROACH IN ASPECTS OF NEW VENTURE

CREATION

ABSTRACT

This paper claim that the death sentence for the trait approach is premature and

mislead by an apparent empirical anomaly that builds on dubious assumptions

regarding the stability of personal traits. It is suggested that the traits that have

received the most attention in entrepreneurship seek to explain aspects of

entrepreneurial motivation or evaluation and not aspects of exploitation. On the

contrary, nearly all the empirical research conducted is based on samples of

entrepreneurs in already established new ventures. Moreover, it is suggested that the

cognitive approach that seek an explanation – among other things – on the same

aspects of motivation and evaluation should not be considered an alternative, but a

complementary approach. Finally, it is suggested how the two approaches may

complement each other on the aspect of evaluation.

INTRODUCTION

Early on, researchers suggested that entrepreneurs were somehow equipped with a

particular type of personality or a psychological profile. For example, according to

Say (1816) an entrepreneur is a [man] equipped with good judgment, perseverance,

and knowledge of the world and business. Schumpeter (1934) argued that new venture

creation was greatly dependent on individuals equipped with certain personal traits.

However, McClelland (1961) was the first to initiate research on these particular traits

which greatly turned focus to the question of “who is an entrepreneur?” in terms of

particular personal traits. His work spurred the interest of numerous scholars in

entrepreneurship bringing the personal trait studies to the center of entrepreneurial

research (Ronstadt et al. 1986; Gartner 1988, 1990; Gartner, Mitchell, and Vesper

Page 77: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

77

1989; Duchesneau and Gartner 1990; Shaver and Scott 1991; Herron and Robinson

1993; Gartner, Starr, and Bhat 1999; Stewart et al. 1999; Shane and Venkataraman

2000; Krueger, Reilly, and Carsrud 2000; Shook, Priem, and Mcgee 2003). However,

several empirical studies did not yield consistent results and in some cases even came

to contradictory conclusions leading a number of scholars to the conclusion that this

type of research was a ‘dead end’ (Chell 1985; Gartner 1988, 1989; Stuart and Abetti

1990; Shane and Venkataraman 2000; Carter et al. 2003). As a result of these

disappointing results, a relatively new line of research was set forth as a direct

alternative to the trait approach to explain entrepreneurial profiles in new venture

creation focusing on cognitive processes and variations in these (e.g. Krueger and

Brazeal 1994; Palich and Bagby 1995; Busenitz and Barney 1997; Baron 1998;

Forbes 1999; Simon, Houghton, and Aquino 2000; Shook, Priem, and Mcgee 2003).

A contemporary and fairly large stream of research in entrepreneurship agrees on a

definition of the entrepreneur as an individual who are motivated to recognition,

evaluate, and possibly exploit entrepreneurial opportunities (e.g. Kirzner 1979;

Bygrave 1993; Shane & Venkataraman 2000; Hitt et al. 2001; Zahra and Dess 2001;

Eckhardt and Shane 2003; Davidsson and Honig 2003; Shook, Priem, and Mcgee

2003). An important aspect with this definition is that the concept of an entrepreneur –

i.e. in terms of who is an entrepreneur – is not a static description of an individual as

the owner of a newly founded venture. It is not just an individual who relatively

recently recognized and exploited entrepreneurial opportunities. Instead, an

entrepreneur is an individual caught in a process that may analytically be split into

different phases. Moreover, each of these phases possesses unique individual and

strategic challenges as equally suggested by a number of organizational life cycle

models (e.g. Kazanjian, 1988; Reynolds and Miller, 1992; Reynolds, 1994; Greve

1995; Greve & Salaff 2003). Thus, if we seek an answer to the question “who is an

entrepreneur?” in terms of personal traits it would be natural to take these different

phases into consideration and to specify the dependent and independent variables

according to each individual phase we seek to explain.

Page 78: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

78

From a re-review of the traits that have received the most attention in the

entrepreneurship literature – i.e. need for achievement, locus of control, optimism,

entrepreneurial self-efficacy, and risk taking propensity – it is suggested that these

traits are concerned with either motivational mechanisms primarily related to a phase

of entrepreneurial intent or mechanisms related to the evaluation of entrepreneurial

opportunities – i.e. whether or not to proceed to the phase of exploitation. However,

with few exceptions the empirical evidence that shows support or no support for the

significance of these traits in new venture creation use existing new ventures (or some

performance measures in these) as the dependent variable. In other word they measure

the personality of entrepreneurs at the phase of exploitation which is not the

mechanism that these constructs initially seek to explain.

This particular aspect of personal trait studies in entrepreneurship has fundamentally

been ignored possibly due to an underlying premise that seem to overemphasize the

stability of traits across time inspired by what is sometimes referred to as the plaster

approach typically related to the work of McCrae and Costa (see e.g. McCrae and

Costa 1995, 1999). According to this tradition traits may be considered as:

“dimensions of individual differences in tendencies to show consistent patterns of

thoughts, feelings, and actions” (McCrae and Costa 1995:235). Moreover, it is

suggested that personality traits are “insulated from the direct effects of the

environment” (McCrae & Costa, 1999:144). Thus, once the personal traits are

established in adolescence they remain constant. However, empirical evidence

actually suggests that changes in social roles, life events, and social environments

may have important impact on personality traits (Srivastava, Gosling, and Potter

2003). In fact, longitudinal studies provide illustration of frequent subtle change and

of occasional very great changes in individuals’ personal traits often following

changes in role assumption and commitment as the individual takes on new

responsibilities and encounters changing demands (Clausen and Jones 1998). One

study actually suggested that changes in traits were often observed in men with more

disorderly careers (Clausen and Jones 1998). Hence, the trait consistency estimates

are not high enough to warrant the conclusion that no change occurs in time and in

particular changes accruing from events characterized by great tumult (Helson and

Page 79: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

79

Moane 1987; Levine, Resnick, and Higgins 1993; Heatherton and Weinberger 1994;

Bandura 1999; Roberts and DelVecchio 2000; Srivastava, Gosling, and Potter 2003;

Ravenna, Jones, and Kwan 2002; Cervone 2004). In other words, traits may indeed

change during different phases of the entrepreneurial process of new venture creation.

With only few exceptions (see e.g. Hansemark 2003) empirical research on traits in

the domain of entrepreneurship has largely ignored this aspect. Hence, this paper

claims that the death call for trait studies in new venture creation are based on wrong

assumptions and is foremost a result of debatable premises regarding the stability of

traits as well as fundamental problems of validity regarding the dependent variable in

discerning – who is an entrepreneur. What is new here is not that people changes

during the process of new venture creation (see e.g. Gartner 1989; Shook, Priem, and

Mcgee 2003). It is how these changes ultimately relate to the existing empirical

research on personality traits in new venture creation. The first conclusion is then, that

the trait approach does not have to be a dead end due to empirical anomalies.

The final purpose of this paper is actually a natural consequence of the first

conclusion. Since we have to grant at least a temporary pardon to the trait approach

we are somehow obliged to relate the cognitive approach to the revitalized trait

approach. From a re-review of the cognitive approach it is suggested that the central

cognitive characteristics related to intent or aspects of evaluation – analogous to the

“domains” of the trait theory – is the general characteristic of cognitive bias

associated with the aspect of evaluation. However, it is suggested that the cognitive

approach should not be considered as an alternative to the trait approach but as a

complementary approach that may in fact revitalize the description of the entrepreneur

in terms of certain personal characteristics. In particular it is suggested how the trait

approach may explain why certain individuals demonstrate cognitive bias. Hence re-

introducing the trait approach may help explain the source of entrepreneurial behavior

instead of merely describing behavior in terms of cognitive processes. To give an

overview of the discussion, figure 1 below shows the propositions made in this paper.

Page 80: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

80

Figure 1 Overview of Propositions

‘+’ indicate a positive and ‘-‘ a negative relationship among the proposed variables

in this paper.

P2B-

P2C-

P2A-

Optimism

Locus of control

Self-efficacy

Risk Perception Positive evaluation

P2B+

P1A+

Need for achievement

Entrepreneurial self-efficacy

Entrepreneurial intent

Opportunity recognition

Exploitation

Page 81: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

81

ENTREPRENEURIAL MOTIVATION

In a seminal book on entrepreneurship Kirzner argued that some individuals possess a

special alertness that predisposes them to be exceptionally perceptive about changes

in the market (Kirzner 1979). The important aspect is that some individuals are

predisposed – i.e. have certain traits important to fuel their perceptive interests in

discovering opportunities in the market – what we may refer to as being

entrepreneurial motivated. Moreover, it is interesting to note that Kirzner implicitly

suggest that the importance of traits is followed by the importance of perception and

cognitive abilities. Later on Bird (1988) introduced the concept of entrepreneurial

intentions. According to Bird (1988), intentions are the state of mind that directs

entrepreneurs’ attention and action toward a particular vocational or business goal.

These intentions are created as a result of a complex interplay between on one hand a

social, political, and economic context and on another hand the individual’s personal

history and abilities and current personality in terms of traits that underlies formal

business plans, opportunity analysis, and resource acquisitions. Thus, Kirzner as well

as Bird points to the importance of predispositions in determining the entrepreneurial

motivation that is central to fuel the rest of the entrepreneurial process of new venture

creation. These predispositions or intentions precede action in terms of opportunity

recognition but it directs attention toward the goal of entrepreneurial opportunity

recognition – often described as some kind of search process – and fundamentally the

exploitation of entrepreneurial opportunities (Herron and Sapienza 1992; Krueger,

Reilly, and Carsrud 2000).

The group of traits summarized as the ‘need for’ variables – i.e. need for

independence, autonomy, flexibility, and achievement –relate to these predispositions

for entrepreneurial intent. Also risk taking propensity and entrepreneurial self-efficacy

are related to intent in the sense that individuals may be drawn into areas that fulfill

there need for risk taking or into areas where they may expect to do well because of

their perceived competences (see e.g. Boyd and Vozikis 1994). Each of these traits

and their mechanisms related to entrepreneurial intent will be discussed in more detail

in the following. Moreover, the empirical evidence – or lack of empirical evidence

pertaining to each trait is discussed. Finally, it may be worth noticing that no

Page 82: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

82

cognitive mechanisms appear to exist in the literature on the aspect entrepreneurial

motivation.

NEED FOR ACHIEVEMENT

One of the earliest psychological traits related to the motivational aspect is the need

for achievement, which originated from the seminal work of (McClelland 1961).

People with a high need for achievement are expected to have a strong desire to be

successful and are not easily satisfied with current achievements. Hence, they are

motivated to improve their performance by setting challenging and distant goals and

standards for themselves (Jackson 1967). McClelland refer to prior studies contrasting

individuals with high and low achievement scores which suggest that individuals with

a relatively high achievement score are among other things more experimental, more

active in college and community activities and more resistant to social pressure. These

characteristics where then equated with the characteristics of entrepreneurs and what

McClelland refer to as entrepreneurial behavior. In order to show these connections

empirically, McClelland tested a group of student – i.e. non-entrepreneurs – for

different levels of achievement scores. Finally, the respondents were asked whether or

not they would consider an entrepreneurial occupation to suggest whether or not their

basic needs would motivate them into an entrepreneurial occupation. Finally,

McClelland came to the conclusion that need for achievement was significantly

related to entrepreneurial intent. A similar study on high school boys by Gould (1969)

shows similar results as to the effect of need for achievement on entrepreneurial

intent. On the contrary however, a study by Sexton & Bowman 1983 suggest that

research on students and their motivation for choosing certain majors, and their

intentions to become entrepreneurs or not, was not significantly related to need for

achievement (Sexton and Bowman 1983). However, the inconclusiveness of this

study may be due different operationalizations and convergent validity problems in

instrumentation (Johnson 1990).

Even though several other empirical studies use need for achievement as an

independent variable the majority use already existing new ventures in their samples.

For example, some studies support that entrepreneurs in already established new

Page 83: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

83

ventures generally have a higher need for achievement than non-entrepreneurs

(Hornaday & Bunker 1970; Smith and Miner 1984; Begley and Boyd 1987; Stewart et

al. 1999; Lee and Tsang 2001), whereas some studies point to more mixed results

concerning need for achievement (Brockhaus and Horwitz 1986; Hansemark 2003).

Would we expect need for achievement to increase or decrease during the process of

new venture creation? On one hand, need for achievement may be expected to

decrease because the individual existing frame of reference may have changes

compared to the individual’s own desire to achieve (McClelland 1990). On the other

hand, some individuals may also correct their desire to achieve – wanting more and

more. Whether it increases or decreases some research suggest that achievement

motivation is indeed a learned characteristic and do change over time (McClelland

1990; Hansemark 2003). Hence, we cannot discern the significance of need for

achievement from existing empirical evidence conducted in already established new

ventures. However, from the evidence that exists on entrepreneurial intent as well as

the mechanism the trait propose to describe we would suggest that need for

achievement is positively associated with entrepreneurial intent.

P1A: There is a positive relationship between need for achievement and

entrepreneurial intent.

RISK TAKING PROPENSITY

According to Jackson (1967), individuals with a high risk taking propensity enjoys

gambling and taking chances. Moreover, they willingly expose themselves to

situations, with uncertain and hazardous outcomes, without considering the potential

danger involved. This tendency to take actions that one considers to be risky is often

referred to in the entrepreneurship literature as a high degree of risk taking propensity.

The premise here is that individuals with a high risk taking propensity are drawn into

occupations with high risk and possibly high pay-off. Even though this may appear

intuitively sound there appear to be several different and somewhat easier ways for

people with high risk taking propensities to get in contact with their predisposed

desires - such as playing poker, betting, shop lifting, and possibly seeking a career as

Page 84: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

84

a pop-star. Hence, the fundamental motivational mechanism of risk taking propensity

appears equivocal. Another important anchor against risk taking propensity is that

new venture creation and entrepreneurship is basically not about risk taking but about

uncertainty and the perception of uncertainty as suggested in the seminal work of

(Knight 1921). In summary, it is unclear whether the mechanism of risk taking

propensity is related to entrepreneurial intent even though it has some intuitive appeal.

Some evidence suggests that entrepreneurs that already have a running company

indeed prefer at least intermediate levels of risk and that these entrepreneurs have a

higher risk taking propensity compared to non-entrepreneurs (Van de Ven, Hudson,

and Schroeder 1984; Stewart et al. 1999). However, comparing entrepreneurs in

already established new ventures with managers no significant difference was found,

even though entrepreneurs were generally believed to take more risks than managers

because they faces a more uncertain and ambiguous set of possibilities (Brockhaus

1980; Brockhaus and Horwitz 1986; Miner 1990; Kahneman and Lovallo 1994;

Palich and Bagby 1995; Busenitz and Barney 1997). Hence, the empirical results

regarding the relationship between new venture creation and risk taking propensity are

ambiguous. Finally, it is difficult to infer what happens with risk taking propensity

from the phase of intent to the phase of exploitation. In conclusion, it is suggested that

the mechanisms that relates risk taking propensity to entrepreneurial intent is

somewhat ambiguous so we would not expect any positive correlation. Moreover, it

appears that no empirical research on risk taking propensity at the phase of

entrepreneurial intent exists so we would generally assume that risk taking propensity

is not necessarily positively correlated with entrepreneurial intent compared to

managers or the rest of the population in general.

ENTREPRENEURIAL SELF-EFFICACY

Self-efficacy is an individual’s perception of his or her capabilities to mobilize the

necessary resources, skills, and competences needed to exercise control of a specific

task and/or event (Wood and Bandura 1989; Bandura 1997). In a sense it resembles

what we will later discuss as locus of control since it is ultimately also about control

over events. However, contrary to locus of control, self-efficacy is more concerned

Page 85: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

85

with skills related to a specific task or event (Gist 1987; Chen, Greene, and Crick

1998). Thus, it is actually possible to have a strong locus of control and a low self-

efficacy in performing a specific task. For example, an individual with a relatively

high internal locus of control may believe that outcomes are primarily related to his or

her behavior and skills, but at the same time – due to a low entrepreneurial self-

efficacy – know that he or she does not possess those particular skills associated with

performing the tasks of starting and running a new venture. Exactly due to its

dependence on a specific event or task we use the term entrepreneurial self-efficacy in

this context. More specifically then, the concept of entrepreneurial self-efficacy refers

to whether the individual believes that he or she is capable of successfully performing

the tasks of an entrepreneur (Boyd and Vozikis 1994; Chen, Greene, and Crick 1998).

This is also reflected in the measurement of entrepreneurial self-efficacy where

researchers have developed more or less detailed conceptual frameworks of task

requirements for creating new ventures and running them (Gist 1987; Chen, Greene,

and Crick 1998).

How is entrepreneurial self-efficacy then related to the question of entrepreneurial

intent? As we might expect, people generally tend to choose their jobs and careers

based upon their perception of self-efficacy (Wood and Bandura 1989; Chen, Greene,

and Crick 1998; Krueger, Reilly, and Carsrud 2000). Accordingly, we would expect

people with a high degree of entrepreneurial efficacy to have a high degree of

entrepreneurial intent. Empirical evidence comparing entrepreneurs in already

established new ventures with groups of managers or regular people equally suggest

that a high degree of entrepreneurial self-efficacy is positively related to new venture

creation (Krueger and Dickson 1993; Krueger and Brazeal 1994; Boyd and Vozikis

1994; Chen, Greene, and Crick 1998). However, once again it is difficult to infer on

the possible changes in entrepreneurial self-efficacy from intent to exploitation. We

might expect that if things turn out better than expected the perceived entrepreneurial

self-efficacy may enhance. Moreover, because of the inherent self selection among

already existing ventures we would not expect entrepreneurial self selection to fall

along the process. On the other hand, the awareness of the tremendous amount of

things that the entrepreneur need to take care of may perhaps decrease the individual’s

perceived entrepreneurial self-efficacy. Even though no empirical evidence appears to

Page 86: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

86

exist at this phase we would expect a positive relationship between entrepreneurial

self-efficacy and entrepreneurial intent.

P1B: There is a positive relationship between entrepreneurial self-efficacy and

entrepreneurial intent.

ENTREPRENEURIAL EVALUATION

Once the individual is predisposed and the entrepreneurial intent is formed we would

expect the process of opportunity recognition to progress (Krueger, Reilly, and

Carsrud 2000; Krueger, Reilly, and Carsrud 2000; Shook, Priem, and Mcgee 2003).

Even though this is clearly a central and relatively new aspect in terms of academic

interest of new venture creation (Shane and Venkataraman 2000; Shane 2000) there

do not appear to be any traits research so far that seek to explain any of these

mechanisms. Hence, so far this aspect of new venture creation is in the hands of the

cognitive approach. This does not suggest that traits and predisposition may be

irrelevant in the phase, only that research on traits have not focused on these aspects

so far.

Finally, once an opportunity is recognized or created (see. e.g. Kaish & Gilad 1991)

the individual need to figure out whether to exploit the opportunity – i.e. somehow act

on the opportunity – or not (Shane and Venkataraman 2000; Shook, Priem, and

Mcgee 2003). As with entrepreneurial intent, a number of traits have sought to explain

why some individuals may be predisposed to a positive valuation of an

entrepreneurial opportunity. These include traits such as locus of control, optimism,

entrepreneurial self-efficacy, and risk taking propensity. Especially the latter – i.e. risk

taking propensity – have been the preferred point of attack on the trait approach from

the cognitive approach (e.g. Baron 1998; Simon, Houghton, and Aquino 2000; Baron

2000; Simon and Hougton 2003; Baron and Ward 2004; Baron 2004a; Baron 2004b).

Instead of risk taking as a predisposition, the cognitive approach have introduce

different bases of biases that individuals exhibit in their decision making process. The

Page 87: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

87

basic premise of this research is that in order to get a positive evaluation the

individual need to experience a perceptual bias. However, as suggested, this bias may

fundamentally be related to the traits that seek to explain this particular aspect in new

venture creation. The next section will discuss each of these traits in more detail, the

mechanisms that these traits seek to explain, and the empirical research conducted on

these matters. Finally, the cognitive bias as a focal point in the cognitive approach on

entrepreneurial evaluation is discussed and related to the trait approach.

LOCUS OF CONTROL

Locus of control refers to individuals’ perception of their ability to influence events

encountered in their lives (Chen, Greene, and Crick 1998). External locus of control

refers to the belief or perception that rewards are controlled by outside factors

whereas internal locus of control suggests that rewards are perceived contingent on

the individual’s own skills and behavior (Rotter 1966). Thus, an individual with an

internal locus of control believes that outcomes are related to his or her behavior,

while an individual with external locus of control perceives life events as controlled

by luck, chance, fate, or powerful others. Basically it is expected that individuals who

do not believe in their ability to control the environment to a certain extent through

their actions – i.e. individuals with external locus of control or a low degree of

internal locus of control – are reluctant to start a new venture. On the other hand, it is

reasonable to expect that individuals with confidence in their ability to control the

events in their lives are more likely to pursue entrepreneurial opportunities

(Brockhaus 1980; Brockhaus and Horwitz 1986; Shaver and Scott 1991; Gatewood,

Shaver, and Gartner 1995; Lee and Tsang 2001). However, it is important to keep in

mind that locus of control is based upon a perception that may be inaccurate or simply

an illusion of control (Shaver and Scott 1991). Thus, some people may overemphasize

the extent to which their skills may control circumstances to the better when skills are

not necessarily the deciding factor (Duhaime and Schwenk 1985). This is why locus

of control is considered a predisposition possibly able to explain aspects of

entrepreneurial evaluation – not exploitation.

However, empirically relating locus of control to the aspect of entrepreneurial intent

appears to be missing in the literature. For most parts empirical evidence do suggests

Page 88: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

88

that there is a significant positive relationship between internal locus of control and

entrepreneurs in already established new ventures (Durand and Shea 1974; Begley

and Boyd 1987; Lee and Tsang 2001). The relationship between locus of control at

the level of intent compared to locus of control at the level of already established new

ventures appears ambiguous however. At one hand we might expect that locus of

control decrease in the course of new venture creation because the entrepreneur may

realize that several aspects are outside the scope of control. On the other hand, as

things work out (i.e. people start buying and financial issues are no longer critical) we

may expect the exact opposite to happen. Hence, we cannot discern the significance of

locus of control from existing empirical evidence conducted in already established

new ventures.

OPTIMISM

People with a predisposed high degree of optimism (also referred to as perceived

probability of success in McClelland 1961) think that their prospects for success are

better compared to other people’s, even though they have no apparent objective

reason for such optimism – i.e. they generally believe that the likelihood of

experiencing a positive outcome is much higher than “objective” data actually

suggest. Schumpeter (1942) actually suggested that entrepreneurs have a tendency to

overestimate their chances for success. It is often suggested that the reason for this

kind of over-optimism is that individuals with a high degree of optimism tend to base

their forecasts on plans and glowing images of the future, ignoring to a great extent

lessons of other people’s attempts or lessons from own experiences (Kahneman and

Lovallo 1993). Indeed, Cooper, Woo, and Dunkelberg (1988) observed that

entrepreneurs’ assessments of positive outcomes were not systematically related to the

backgrounds of the entrepreneurs or the nature of their ventures. Even though more

than 50% of all new ventures fail, 95% of the entrepreneurs believe that their new

ventures will most likely succeed (Cooper, Woo, and Dunkelberg 1988). They

referred to this characteristic as “entrepreneurial euphoria”. Comparing managers and

entrepreneurs in already established new ventures, Palich and Bagby (1995) found

that the latter was more likely to perceive strength and opportunities and less likely to

perceive weaknesses and threats suggesting that entrepreneurs were significantly more

Page 89: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

89

optimistic than non-entrepreneurs. However, once again these studies use already

existing new ventures as the dependent variable. Moreover, it is likely that problems

of self selection – i.e. choosing individuals who are already entrepreneurs in

established new ventures – may indeed distort the picture. Hence, we cannot discern

the significance of optimism from existing empirical evidence conducted in already

established new ventures. However, from the mechanism that the optimism trait

proposes to describe we would propose a positive relationship.

ENTREPRENEURIAL SELF-EFFICACY

It has already been suggested that self-efficacy is positively associated with

entrepreneurial intent. However, since the concept of entrepreneurial self-efficacy

refers to whether the individual believes that he or she is capable of successfully

performing the tasks of an entrepreneur we would equally expect that entrepreneurial

self-efficacy is also positively related to how the entrepreneur evaluates

entrepreneurial opportunities (see also Chen, Greene, and Crick 1998). Hence, even

though no evidence on entrepreneurial self-efficacy at the phase of evaluation exists

we would generally expect a positive relationship between entrepreneurial efficacy

and a positive evaluation of entrepreneurial opportunities.

EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE OF NASCENT ENTREPRENEURSHIP FROM THE

GEM- AND PSED DATABASES

In a recent paper by Davidsson (2006) it is suggested that the cross sectional panel

studies such as the GEM data and the PSED data aims to overcome selection biases as

well as hindsight bias resulting from asking survey questions about the start-up

process retrospectively, and to get a reasonable temporal order of measurement right

for causal analysis. A recent large scale study Carter et al. (2003) exactly uses the

PSED database in a comprehensive empirical study on the career reasons of nascent

entrepreneurs. At first glance, results from this empirical research appear to be a fatal

blow for some of the personal traits related to different aspects of new venture

creation. The overall conclusion is that nascent entrepreneurs are not qualitatively

Page 90: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

90

different from non-entrepreneurs and most importantly that this particular study based

on the PSED database should: “take precedence over any previous studies where

retrospective reasons for start-up were offered” (Carter et al. 2003:16). The authors

claim that contrary to previous studies the panel data give access to a group of

individual that is currently in the initial stages of forming a business. Accordingly,

they argue, the problem of retrospection does not exist which make the data on

vocation valid for interpretation.

However, looking at the selection of nascent entrepreneurs in this study it is still

difficult top assess the specific phase in which these nascent entrepreneurs is situated.

The first qualification to become part of the group of nascent entrepreneurs is that the

respondent is alone or with others now trying to start a business. Moreover, two

affirmative questions needed a positive answer: a) the respondent should anticipate

becoming an owner of the business and b) the respondent should have conducted

ongoing business organizing activities during the immediately preceding 12 months

while at the same time the respondents should not have received sufficient cash flow

for 3 months to pay expenses and the owner-manager’s salary. It appears that the 3

months cash flow is of central importance in distinguishing between the process of

motivation and evaluation on the one hand and exploitation on the other hand. The

divergence of new ventures and almost existing new ventures pertaining to these

criterions is however too wide to reasonably relate these nascent entrepreneurs to a

stage of motivation or evaluation. Moreover, it may be fruitful to say that this measure

is indeed a measure of nascent new ventures where the demarcation is the aspect of

cash flow. Hence, even though these studies suggest that they should take precedence

over past studies because it takes the process of new venture creation into

consideration – which is in fact the exact point of this paper – they are not able to

divide their sample into a phase of motivation or evaluation. Once again we may

conclude that these studies actually are conducted at the level of exploitation which

makes their significance difficult to infer.

Page 91: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

91

COGNITIVE BIAS AS A MEDIATOR OF PERSONALITY TRAITS

As suggested in the preceding sections we cannot claim that the trait approach is a

dead end due to empirical anomalies. Generally, no or little empirical evidence have

been conducted at the phase of motivation or evaluation that the mechanisms of the

particular traits initially seek to describe. Hence, if we cannot discharge the trait

approach on these grounds it appears fundamentally important to relate the proposed

alternative – i.e. the cognitive mechanisms – to the proposed traits to see if there is

any conflicting conclusions.

The cognitive tradition in entrepreneurship generally focuses on social cognitive

mediating processes that underlie and motivate behavior. The premise of this tradition

is that the pattern of situation-behavior relationships shown by an individual is in fact

the key to a description of individuality and personal coherence. This relationship

between the person (in terms of personal traits) and the specific situation is basically

neglected in the personal trait approach. The point is that entrepreneurs evaluate

identical situations differently from non-entrepreneurs so that they differ in their

perception of different situations. For example, a study by Corman et al. (1988)

suggests that around two thirds of high-tech entrepreneurs suspected of having a very

high failure rate actually asserted that they were not taking any risk.

Exactly the aspect of risk taking propensity and how the potential entrepreneur

evaluate whether or not to act on entrepreneurial opportunities has been the

cornerstones in the attack on the trait approach and in fact the only area in which the

cognitive approach is proposed as a direct alternative to the trait approach in a specific

phase of new venture creation (see e.g. Palich and Bagby 1995; Baron 1998; Forbes

1999; Simon, Houghton, and Aquino 2000; Baron 2000; Baron 2004a; Baron 2004b;

Forbes 2005). The major claim is that entrepreneurs take risky actions basically

because they perceive relatively less risk in the concrete situation and not necessarily

because they are equipped with a higher risk taking propensity (March and Shapira

Page 92: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

92

1987; Kahneman and Lovallo 1993; Palich and Bagby 1995; Simon, Houghton, and

Aquino 2000). This observation changes the focus away from the “objective” measure

of risk taking propensity associated with or embedded in the individual as a personal

psychological trait to differences in perception and how the perception of a low or

high risk is actually formed in a particular situation in terms of cognitive processes.

Early on researchers argued that limits in cognitive capacity to process and remember

all relevant information in complex decision situations forced people to use different

cognitive devices or heuristics (Simon 1948). These cognitive devises are necessary

short-cuts in our thinking to avoid overload of information and to minimize our

cognitive effort. The most important cognitive device involves matching observed

stimuli with a mental schema (Barsalou 1992; Walsh 1995). A mental schema is a

categorization or a template which individuals impose on an information environment

to give it form and meaning, which allows individuals to make inferences and form

opinions about complex situations that reveal less than complete information (Fiske

and Taylor 1991; Walsh 1995). However, using these simplifying cognitive devices

may lead to serious distortions and biases in the processing of information. This is

especially the case when individuals are confronted with more information than they

can possible process, when they face situations that are new and involve a high degree

of uncertainty, when emotions run high, and when individuals face a high time

pressure (Baron 1998). This actually suggests that cognitive biases are probably

particularly prevalent among entrepreneurs because they unintentionally simplify their

information processing to diminish the stress and ambiguity associated with making

very complex and uncertain decisions like starting a new venture (Shaver and Scott

1991; Mccarthy, Schoorman, and Cooper 1993; Palich and Bagby 1995; Busenitz and

Barney 1997; Baron 1998; Forbes 1999; Simon, Houghton, and Aquino 2000).

Moreover, if the mental schemes used in these decision processes vary systematically

between groups of people, then perceptions are likely to be similarly systematically

biased or skewed (Kahneman and Lovallo 1994). This suggests that the question

pertaining to whether or not an individual chose to act on an entrepreneurial

opportunity should include the basis for variation in cognitive bias among individuals

in search for an “entrepreneurial cognition” (Busenitz and Lau 1996; Baron 1998;

Forbes 1999).

Page 93: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

93

HOW IS THIS RELATED TO PERSONALITY TRAITS

According to Baron (1998), these differences in cognition do not stem primarily from

differences in personal traits, but rather from the fact that entrepreneurs operate in

situations of high uncertainty and complexity which maximize cognitive biases and

errors. However, this does not have to suggest that differences in cognition are not

somehow related to personality traits. For example, some scholars suggest redefining

traits in terms of cognitive schemes or mental processes – i.e. to figure out how these

traits produce, guide, create, or influence behavior (Langston and Sykes 1997;

Bandura 1999; Endler 2000;). The first step in this integration is to explore the

relationship between psychological traits and cognitive processes (Langston and

Sykes 1997; Endler 2000) – i.e. explore how individual differences in psychological

traits are related to individual differences in perception and cognitive processes which

then again relates to differences in behavior.

In fact some studies do suggest that the cognitive bias – in terms of giving a positive

evaluation to entrepreneurial opportunities – are possibly related to the engagement in

counterfactual thinking which make some people more likely to act upon perceived

opportunities (Baron 1998; Baron 2000), favorable interpretation of equivocal

situations (Busenitz and Lau 1996), susceptibility to the planning fallacy resulting in

overly confident predictions about future outcomes (Cooper, Woo, and Dunkelberg

1988; Palich and Bagby 1995; Baron 1998; Forbes 2005), and illusion of control in

the sense that individuals overemphasize the extent to which their skill can increase

performance in situation that are somewhat out of the individual’s control (Simon,

Houghton, and Aquino 2000). Even though these aspects are framed as being part of a

cognitive tradition they are in fact predispositions as suggested by Busenitz and Lau

(1996) very much related to some of the traits already described in this paper.

For example a highly optimistic individual is predisposed to see the world through

rose-colored glasses and consequently tends to evaluate everything as more favorable

than might otherwise have been true. This corresponds with the evidence suggesting

that entrepreneurs tend to be more susceptible to the planning fallacy resulting in

Page 94: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

94

overly confident predictions about future outcomes as well as a favorable

interpretations of equivocal situations (see e.g. Cooper, Woo, and Dunkelberg 1988;

Baron 1998; Palich and Bagby 1995; Busenitz and Barney 1997; Simon, Houghton,

and Aquino 2000; Forbes 2005). Accordingly, as suggested in proposition P2A in

figure 1, we would expect a negative relationship between optimism and risk

perception – i.e. the more optimistic the more perceptual bias the less risk perception.

P2A: Degree of optimism is positively related to a positive evaluation of

opportunities.

However, overconfidence also refers to people’s ability to estimate the accuracy of

their own knowledge in a certain area (Simon, Houghton, and Aquino 2000; Forbes

2005). In this respect then, entrepreneurial self-efficacy is equally an aspect when

referring to a degree of overconfidence even though the difference is that

overconfidence measures the accuracy of ability whereas entrepreneurial self-efficacy

measure what people believe about their ability (Forbes 2005). Hence we might

expect a negative relationship between entrepreneurial self-efficacy and risk

perception suggested by P2C in figure 1.

P2C: Entrepreneurial self-efficacy is positively related to a positive evaluation of

opportunities

Finally, the aspect of illusion of control suggests that individuals may overemphasize

the extent to which personal skills can increase performance in situations when skills

are not the deciding factor (Simon, Houghton, and Aquino 2000). Hence, this aspect is

not only an aspect of internal locus of control, but also an aspect of entrepreneurial

self-efficacy and believes in skills (see e.g. Boyd and Vozikis 1994). Hence, illusion

of control suggests that locus of control as well as entrepreneurial self-efficacy is

negatively related to risk perception as suggested by P2C and P2B in figure 1.

Page 95: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

95

P2B: There is a positive relationship between the positive evaluation of opportunities

and locus of control.

CONCLUSION

Inconclusive results, inconsistencies and serious methodological problems have

frustrated research on individual characteristics in entrepreneurship studies.

Reviewing numerous personal trait studies into the entrepreneurial phase that each

trait aims to explain, this paper revitalize the trait approach in suggesting that the only

major problem of trait studies is not the independent variables – i.e. the traits – but the

comparison of results across different dependent variables. Indeed it is suggested that

important traits such as need for achievement, entrepreneurial self-efficacy, optimism,

and locus of control pertaining to aspects of entrepreneurial motivation and evaluation

does not experience the ambiguity and equivocality as suggested by the highly quoted

death sentence on trait studies by Gartner (1988). On the other hand, there is nor solid

empirical evidence for these traits pertaining to the exact phase that these traits aims

at explaining. Hence, this conclusion underlines the need to empirically explore the

relevance of different psychological traits pertaining to different phases in the

entrepreneurial process.

Furthermore, the introduction of cognitive processes in entrepreneurship should not

automatically lead to a neglect of psychological traits (Bandura 1986; Cantor 1990;

Bandura 1999). The personal trait approach as well as the cognitive approach is both

concerned with individual differences. However, where the personal traits can serve

as the ‘having’ side of personality to explain the basic why-questions, the ‘doing’ side

may be considered the how-question as the cognitive expression of these traits (Endler

and Magnusson 1976; Epstein and O'Brian 1985; Endler 2000). In other words,

cognitive factors mediate the influence of trait factors on individuals’ decision to

become entrepreneurs (Katz 1992; Kolvereid 1997).

Page 96: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

96

Finally, it is proposed in this paper that entrepreneurial self-efficacy, locus of control,

and optimism is part of the fundamental having-side of the entrepreneur that explain

why certain individual perceive relatively less risk than others. In this sense,

psychological traits and cognitive processes are intertwined and we need to

understand this interdependence empirically as well as theoretically to advance our

knowledge. Thus more studies are needed that simultaneously investigate personal

traits and cognitive processes in relation to different phases of new venture creation

Page 97: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

97

References

Ajzen, I. 1988. Attitudes, personality, and behavior. Homewood, IL: Dorsey Press.

Aronson, R. L. 1991. Self-employment: A labor market perspective. Ithaca, NY: ILR

Press.

Bandura, A. 1986. Social foundations of thought and action. Englewood Cliffs, NJ:

Prentice Hall.

Bandura, A. 1997. Self-efficacy: The exercise of control. New York: Freeman.

Bandura, A. 1999. Social cognitive theory of personality. In Handbook of Personality:

Theory and research. 2nd ed. Edited by L. A. Pervin and O. P. John. New

York: Guilford.

Baron, R. A. and T. B. Ward, "Expanding entrepreneurial cognition's toolbox: Potential contributions from the field of cognitive science," Entrepreneurship-Theory and Practice 28 (6): 553-573 (2004).

Baron, R. A., "Cognitive mechanisms in entrepreneurship: Why and when

entrepreneurs think differently than other people," Journal of Business

Venturing 13 (4): 275-294 (1998).

Baron, R. A., "Counterfactual thinking and venture formation: The potential effects of thinking about "what might have been"," Journal of Business Venturing 15 (1): 79-91 (2000).

Baron, R. A., "Potential benefits of the cognitive perspective: expanding entrepreneurship's array of conceptual tools," Journal of Business Venturing 19 (2): 169-172 (2004a).

Baron, R. A., "The cognitive perspective: a valuable tool for answering entrepreneurship's basic "why" questions," Journal of Business Venturing 19 (2): 221-239 (2004b).

Barsalou, L. W. 1992. Cognitive Psychology: An Overview for Cognitive Scientists.

Hillsdale, NJ: Erlbaum.

Bates, T., "Self-Employment Entry Across Industry Groups," Journal of Business

Venturing 10 (2): 143-156 (1995).

Page 98: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

98

Begley, T. M. and D. P. Boyd, "A Comparison of Entrepreneurs and Managers of

Small Business Firms," Journal of Management 13 (1): 99-108 (1987a).

Begley, T. M. and D. P. Boyd, "Psychological Characteristics Associated with

Performance in Entrepreneurial Firms and Smaller Businesses," Journal of

Business Venturing 2 (1): 79-93 (1987b).

Bird, B., "Implementing entrepreneurial ideas: The case for intentions," Academy of

Management Review 13: 442-453 (1988).

Boyd, N. G. and G. S. Vozikis, "The influence on self-efficacy on the development of

entrepreneurial intentions and actions." Entrepreneurship, Theory and

Practice 18: 63-90 (1994).

Brockhaus, R. H. 1982. The psychology of the entrepreneur. In The encyclopedia of entrepreneurship. Edited by C. A. Kent, D. Sexton, and K. H. Vesper. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall.

Brockhaus, R. H. and P. S. Horwitz. 1986. The psychology of the entrepreneur. In The

art and science of entrepreneurship. Edited by D. Sexton and R. W. Smilor.

Cambridge, MA: Ballinger.

Brockhaus, R. H., "Risk-Taking Propensity of Entrepreneurs," Academy of

Management Journal 23 (3): 509-520 (1980).

Brüderl, J. and P. Preisendörfer, "Network support and the success of newly founded

businesses," Small Business Economics 10: 231-225 (1998).

Brush, C. G. and P. A. Vanderwerf, "A Comparison of Methods and Sources for

Obtaining Estimates of New Venture Performance," Journal of Business

Venturing 7 (2): 157-170 (1992).

Brush, C. G., "Research of women business owners: past trends, a new perspective,

future directions," Entrepreneurship, Theory and Practice 16 (4): 5-30 (1992).

Busenitz, L. W. and D. C. Lau, "A cross-cultural cognitive model of new venture

creation," Entrepreneurship, Theory and Practice 20: 25-39 (1996).

Page 99: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

99

Busenitz, L. W. and J. B. Barney, "Differences between entrepreneurs and managers in large organizations: Biases and heuristics in strategic decision-making," Journal of Business Venturing 12 (1): 9-30 (1997).

Cantor, N., "From Thought to Behavior - Having and Doing in the Study of Personality and Cognition," American Psychologist 45 (6): 735-750 (1990).

Carter, N. M. et al., "The career reasons of nascent entrepreneurs," Journal of

Business Venturing 18 (1): 13-39 (2003).

Carter, N. M., M. Williams, and P. D. Reynolds, "Discontinuance among new firms in

retail: The influence of initial resources, strategy, and gender," Journal of

Business Venturing 12 (2): 125-145 (1997).

Cervone, D., "The Architecture of Personality," Psychological Review 111 (1): 183-204 (2004).

Chell, E., "The Entrepreneurial Personality: A few ghosts laid to rest?," International Small Business Journal 3 (3): 43-54 (1985).

Chen, C. C., P. G. Greene, and A. Crick, "Does entrepreneurial self-efficacy

distinguish entrepreneurs from managers?" Journal of Business Venturing 13

(4): 295-316 (1998).

Clausen, J. A. and C. J Jones, "Predicting Personality Stability Across the Life Span: The Role of Competence and Work and Family Commitments," Journal of Adult Development 5 (2): 73-83 (1998).

Cooper, A. C. and W. C. Dunkelberg, "Entrepreneurial research: old questions, new

answers and methedological issues," American Journal of Small Business 11

(3): 11-21 (1987).

Cooper, A. C., C. Y. Woo, and W. C. Dunkelberg, "Entrepreneurs Perceived Chances

for Success," Journal of Business Venturing 3 (2): 97-108 (1988).

Cooper, A. C., F. J. Gimenogascon, and C. Y. Woo, "Initial Human and Financial Capital As Predictors of New Venture Performance," Journal of Business Venturing 9 (5): 371-395 (1994).

Cooper, A. C., T. B. Folta, and C. Woo, "Entrepreneurial Information Search,"

Journal of Business Venturing 10 (2): 107-120 (1995).

Page 100: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

100

Davidsson, P. and B. Honig, "The role of social and human capital among nascent

entrepreneurs," Journal of Business Venturing 18 (3): 301-331 (2003).

Davidsson, P., "Nascent Entrepreneurship: Empirical Studies and Developments," Foundations and Trends in Entrepreneurship 2 (1): 1-76 (2006).

DeMartino, R. and R. Barbato, "Differences between women and men MBA

entrepreneurs: exploring family flexibility and wealth creation as career

motivators," Journal of Business Venturing 18 (6): 815-832 (2003).

Duchesneau, D. A. and W. B. Gartner, "A Profile of New Venture Success and

Failure in An Emerging Industry," Journal of Business Venturing 5 (5): 297-

312 (1990).

Duhaime, I. M. and C. Schwenk, "Conjectures on cognitive simplification in

acquisition and divestment decision-making," Academy of Management

Review 10 (2): 287-295 (1985).

Durand, D. and D. Shea, "Entrepreneurial activity as a function of achievement

motivation and reinforcement control," Journal of Psychology 88: 57-63

(1974).

Endler, N. S. and D. Magnusson, "Toward an interactional psychology of

personality," Psychological Bulletin 33: 956-974 (1976).

Endler, N. S., "The interface between Personality and Cognition," European Journal

of Personality 14: 377-389 (2000).

Epstein, S. and E. J. O'Brian, "The person-situation debate in historical and current

perspective," Psychological Bulletin 98: 513-537 (1985).

Evans, D and L. Leighton, "Some empirical aspects of entrepreneurship," American

Economic Review 79: 519-535 (1986).

Fischer, E. M., A. R. Reuber, and L. S. Dyke, "A Theoretical Overview and Extension

of Research on Sex, Gender, and Entrepreneurship," Journal of Business

Venturing 8 (2): 151-168 (1993).

Page 101: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

101

Fiske, S. T. and S. Taylor. 1991. Social cognition. 2nd ed. New York: Random

House.

Forbes, D. P., "Are some entrepreneurs more overconfident than others?," Journal of Business Venturing 20 (5): 623-640 (2005).

Forbes, D. P., "Cognitive approaches to new venture creation," International Journal

of Management Reviews 1 (4): 415-439 (1999).

Gartner, W. B., ""Who is an entrepreneur?" Is the wrong question," American Journal of Small Business 12 (4): 11-32 (1988).

Gartner, W. B., "A conceptual framework for describing the phenomenon of new

venture creation," Academy of Management Review 10 (4): 696-706 (1985).

Gartner, W. B., "Some suggestions for research on entrepreneurial traits and

characteristics," Entrepreneurship, Theory and Practice 14 (1): 27-37 (1989).

Gartner, W. B., "What Are We Talking About When We Talk About

Entrepreneurship," Journal of Business Venturing 5 (1): 15-28 (1990).

Gartner, W. B., J. A. Starr, and S. Bhat, "Predicting new venture survival: An analysis

of "Anatomy of a Start-up." Cases from Inc. magazine," Journal of Business

Venturing 14 (2): 215-232 (1999).

Gartner, W. B., T. R. Mitchell, and K. H. Vesper, "A Taxonomy of New Business

Ventures," Journal of Business Venturing 4 (3): 169-186 (1989).

Gatewood, E. J., K. G. Shaver, and W. B. Gartner, "A Longitudinal-Study of

Cognitive-Factors Influencing Start-Up Behaviors and Success at Venture

Creation," Journal of Business Venturing 10 (5): 371-391 (1995).

Gimeno, J. et al., "Survival of the fittest? Entrepreneurial human capital and the

persistence of underperforming firms," Administrative Science Quarterly 42

(4): 750-783 (1997).

Gist, M. E., "Self-efficacy: Implications for organizational behavior and human

resource management," Academy of Management Journal 12: 472-485 (1987).

Page 102: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

102

Goffee, R. and R. Scase. 1985. Women in charge: The experiences of female

entrepreneurs.Allen & Unwin (London and Boston).

Hansemark, O. C., "Need for achievement, locus of control and the prediction of

business start-ups: A longitudinal study," Journal of Economic Psychology 24

(3): 301-319 (2003).

Heatherton, T. F. and J. L Weinberger. 1994. Can personality change?American Psychological Association.

Helson, R. and G. Moane, "Personality change in women from college to midlife," Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 53 (1): 176-186 (1987).

Herron, L. and H. Sapienza, "The entrepreneur and the initiation of new venture launch activitites," Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 17 (1): 49-55 (1992).

Herron, L. and R. B. Robinson, "A Structural Model of the Effects of Entrepreneurial

Characteristics on Venture Performance," Journal of Business Venturing 8 (3):

281-294 (1993).

Honig, B., "What determines success? Examining the human, financial, and social

capital of Jamaican microentrepreneurs," Journal of Business Venturing 13

(5): 371-394 (1998).

Hornaday, J. and J Aboud, "Characteristics of sucessful entrepreneurs," Personnel

Psychology (1971).

Jackson, D. N. 1967. Personality research form manual. New York: Research

Psychologists Press.

Johnson, B. R., "Toward a multidimensional model of entrepreneurship: The case of

achievement motivation and the entrepreneur," Entrepreneurship, Theory and

Practice: 39-54 (1990).

Kahneman, D and D Lovallo, "Timid choices and bold forecasts: A cognitive

perspective on risk taking," Management Science 39 (1): 17-31 (1993).

Page 103: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

103

Kalleberg, A. and K. T. Leicht, "Gender and organizational performance:

determinants of small business survival and success," Academy of

Management Journal 34 (1): 136-161 (1991).

Katz, J. and W. B. Gartner, "Properties of emerging organizations," Academy of

Management Review 13 (3): 429-441 (1988).

Katz, J., "A psychosocial cognitive model of employment status choice,"

Entrepreneurship, Theory and Practice 16: 29-37 (1992).

Kirzner, I. M. 1979. Perceptions, Opportunities, and Profit.Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Kirzner, I. M., "Entrepreneurial discovery and the competitive market process: An

Austrian approach," Journal of Economic Literature 35 (1): 60-85 (1997).

Knight, F.H. 1921. Risk uncertainty and profit.Kelley.

Kolvereid, L., "Organizational employment versus self-employment: reasons for

career choice intentions," Entrepreneurship, Theory and Practice 20: 23-31

(1997).

Krueger, N. F. and D. V. Brazeal, "Entrepreneurial potential and potential

entrepreneurs," Entrepreneurship, Theory and Practice Spring: 91-104 (1994).

Krueger, N. F. and P. R. Dickson, "Perceived Self-Efficacy and Perceptions of

Opportunity and Threat," Psychological Reports 72 (3): 1235-1240 (1993).

Krueger, N. F., M. D. Reilly, and A. L. Carsrud, "Competing models of

entrepreneurial intentions," Journal of Business Venturing 15 (5-6): 411-432

(2000).

Langston, C. A. and W. E. Sykes, "Beliefs and the big five: cognitive bases of broad

individual differences in personality," Journal of Research in Personality 31:

141-165 (1997).

Page 104: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

104

Lee, D. Y. and E. W. K. Tsang, "The effects of entrepreneurial personality,

background and network activities on venture growth," Journal of

management studies 38 (4): 583-602 (2001).

Levine, J. M., L. B. Resnick, and H. T. Higgins, "Social Foundations of Cognition," Annual Review of Psychology 44: 585-612 (1993).

Liles, P. R. 1974. New Business Ventures and the Entrepreneur. Homewood, Ill:

Richard D. Irwin.

March, J. G. and Z. Shapira, "Managerial perspectives on risk and risk taking,"

Management Science 33 (11): 1404-1418 (1987).

Mccarthy, A. M., F. D. Schoorman, and A. C. Cooper, "Reinvestment Decisions by

Entrepreneurs - Rational Decision-Making Or Escalation of Commitment,"

Journal of Business Venturing 8 (1): 9-24 (1993).

McClelland, D. C. 1961. The Achieving Society. New Jersey, Van Nostrand.

McClelland, D. C. 1990. Human Motivation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

McCrae, R. R. and P. T. Costa, "Trait explanations in personality psychology," European Journal of Personality 9: 231-252 (1995).

Mincer, J. 1974. Schooling, experience, and earnings. New York: Columbia

University Press.

Miner, J. B., "Entrepreneurs, High Growth Entrepreneurs, and Managers - Contrasting

and Overlapping Motivational Patterns," Journal of Business Venturing 5 (4):

221-234 (1990).

Palich, L. E. and D. R. Bagby, "Using Cognitive Theory to Explain Entrepreneurial

Risk-Taking - Challenging Conventional Wisdom," Journal of Business

Venturing 10 (6): 425-438 (1995a).

Ravenna, H., C. Jones, and V. S Kwan, "Personality change over 40 years of adulthood: hierarchical linear modelling analyses of two longitudinal samples," Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 83 (3): 752-766 (2002).

Page 105: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

105

Reynolds, P. D., "New Firms - Societal Contribution Versus Survival Potential,"

Journal of Business Venturing 2 (3): 231-246 (1987).

Reynolds, P. D., "Sociology and entrepreneurship: Concepts and Contributions,"

Entrepreneurship, Theory and Practice 16 (2): 47-70 (1991).

Roberts, B. W. and W. F. DelVecchio, "The Rank-Order Consistency of Personal Traits from Childhood to Old Age: A Quantitative Review of Longitudinal Studies," Psychological Bulletin 126 (1): 3-25 (2000).

Robinson, P. B. and E. A. Sexton, "The Effect of Education and Experience on Self-

Employment Success," Journal of Business Venturing 9 (2): 141-156 (1994).

Ronstadt, R. et al. 1986. Frontiers of Entrepreneurship Research. Wellesley, MA:

Babson College.

Rotter, J. B. 1966. Generalized expectancies for internal versus external control of

reinforcement.Psychological Monographs: General and Applied 80, Whole

No. 609.

Sapienza, H. and C. Grimm, "Founder characteristics, start-up process and

strategy/structure variables as predictors of shortline railroad performance,"

Entrepreneurship, Theory and Practice 22 (1): 45-67 (1997).

Say, J. A. 1816. A Treatise on Political Economy. London: Sherwood, Neeley and

Jones.

Schultz, T. M., "Investment in man: An economist's view," Social Service Review 33:

109-117 (1959).

Schumpeter, Joseph Alois. 1934. The theory of economic development. Cambridge:

MA: Harvard University Press.

Schumpeter, Joseph Alois. 1942. Capitalism, socialism, and democracy. New York,

London: Harper.

Sexton, D. L. and E. H. Bowman. 1983. Comparitive entrepreneurship characteristics

of students: Preliminary results. In Frontiers of Entrepreneurship Research.

Page 106: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

106

Edited by J. Hornaday, J. A. Timmons, and K. H. Vesper. Wellesley, MA:

Babson College.

Sexton, D. L. and N. Bowmanupton, "Female and Male Entrepreneurs - Psychological

Characteristics and Their Role in Gender-Related Discrimination," Journal of

Business Venturing 5 (1): 29-36 (1990).

Shane, S. and R. Khurana, "Bringing individuals back in: the effects of career

experience on new firm founding," Industrial and Corporate Change 12 (3):

519-543 (2003).

Shane, S. and S. Venkataraman, "The promise of entrepreneurship as a field of research," Academy of Management Review 25 (1): 217-226 (2000).

Shane, S., "Explaining variation in rates of entrepreneurship in the United States:

1899-1988," Journal of Management 22 (5): 747-781 (1996).

Shane, S., "Prior knowledge and the discovery of entrepreneurial opportunities,"

Organization Science 11 (4): 448-469 (2000).

Shaver, K. G. and L. R. Scott, "Person, process, choice: the psychology of new venture creation," Entrepreneurship, Theory and Practice 16: 23-42 (1991).

Shepperd, J. A., J. A. Ouellette, and J. K. Fernandez, "Abandoning unrealistic

optimism: Performance estimates and the temporal proximity of self-relevant

feedback," Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 70 (4): 844-855

(1996).

Shook, C. L., R. L. Priem, and J. E. Mcgee, "Venture creation and the enterprising

individual: A review and synthesis," Journal of Management 29 (3): 379-399

(2003).

Simon, Herbert A. 1948. Administrative behavior: a study of the decision-making process in administrative organization. New York : Macmillan, c1947.

Simon, M and S. M. Hougton, "The relationship between overconfidence and the introduction of risky products: Evidence from a field study," Academy of Management Journal 46 (2): 139-149 (2003).

Page 107: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

107

Simon, M., S. M. Houghton, and K. Aquino, "Cognitive biases, risk perception and

venture formation: How individuals decide to start companies," Journal of

Business Venturing 15 (2): 113-134 (2000).

Smith, N. R. and J. B. Miner. 1984. Motivational considerations in the success of

technologically innovative entrepreneurs. In Frontiers of Entrepreneurship

Research. Edited by J. Hornaday et al. Wellesley, MA: Babson Center for

Entrepreneurial Studies.

Srivastava, S., S. Gosling, and J. Potter, "Development of Personality in Early and Middle Adulthood: Set like Plaster or Persistent Change?," Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 84 (5): 1041-1053 (2003).

Stewart, W. H. et al., "A proclivity for entrepreneurship: A comparison of

entrepreneurs, small business owners, and corporate managers," Journal of

Business Venturing 14 (2): 189-214 (1999).

Stinchcombe, Arthur L. 1965. Social structure and organizations. In Handbook of

organizations. Edited by James G. March. Chicago: Rand McNally.

Stuart, R. W. and P. A. Abetti, "Impact of Entrepreneurial and Management

Experience on Early Performance," Journal of Business Venturing 5 (3): 151-

162 (1990).

Van de Ven, A. H., R. Hudson, and D. M. Schroeder, "Designing new business start-

ups: Entrepreneurial, Organizational, and ecological considerations," Journal

of Management 10: 89-107 (1984).

Walsh, J. P., "Managerial and Organizational Cognition - Notes from A Trip Down

Memory Lane," Organization Science 6 (3): 280-321 (1995).

Wood, R. and A. Bandura, "Social Cognitive Theory of Organizational Management,"

Academy of Management Review 14 (3): 361-384 (1989).

Page 108: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

108

Page 109: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

109

Personal networks in different phases of new

venture creation

Abstract

This paper takes stock of studies on the personal networks of entrepreneurs. It is

suggested that what appears to be empirical inconsistencies in the effect of personal

networks is a disregard of the important contingency of the entrepreneurial phase or

an oversimplified description of the needs in different phases of entrepreneurial

development as either a need for either information or resources. It is suggested how

needs for resources and information as well as the legitimacy of the new venture

change as the new venture develops from the phases of entrepreneurial intent to the

phase of early growth. These changes are then related to theoretical as well as

empirical evidence on the positive aspects of the personal network of the entrepreneur

in terms of personal network size, the strength of ties, and the density of the personal

network.

Introduction

The last twenty years of research on personal networks and new venture creation has

contributed to the investigation of a wide range of characteristics more or less

beneficial to new venture creation. The results of this endeavor are basically a

scattered collection of research with diverging concepts, techniques, and measures.

Despite broad agreement about the general importance of personal networks and

personal relations, there is considerably less agreement and more ambiguity about the

specific characteristics of personal networks that relate to success in creating new

ventures (Bloodgood et al. 1995; Rowley et al. 2000; Hite & Hesterly 2001; Elfring &

Hulsink 2003). Except for Hoang and Antoncic’s (2003) critical review of network-

based research in entrepreneurship in more general terms and Thornton’s (1999) even

Page 110: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

110

more general review of sociology and entrepreneurship, no one has attempted to

evaluate and review this body of research. This paper takes stock of the results of

these relatively divergent studies on personal networks conducted so far with the

single entrepreneur as the unit of research; this is often referred to as the

entrepreneur’s egocentric network.

The term ‘social network’ is frequently used to describe individuals’ informal or non-

work related networks. However, as suggested by Johannisson (2000) all networks are

per definition social. Instead, the term ‘personal network’ is used throughout to

include both social and business relations that may become intertwined in the

different processes of new venture creation (Johannisson 2000). As suggested by

Johannisson it is in fact this blending of ideological and affective commitment with

business-like calculated interests that fuels the process of new venture creation. Hence

personal networks are viewed as those that “reflect the personality of the

entrepreneur” and which carry “the generic sense-making process that guide the

entrepreneur…as a tool for realizing the venture” (Johannisson, 2000:371).

Within the literature on personal networks in entrepreneurship, a noticeable dispute in

theoretical as well as empirical research concerns the importance of density and

strength of ties, which in turn may also be related to the size of the personal network.

For example, several studies in entrepreneurship point to the benefits of dense

networks manifested in – by definition relatively few – strong cohesive ties in

obtaining the key resources needed for success in new venture creation (Larson 1991;

Larson & Starr 1993; Brüderl & Preisendörfer 1998; Bhide 1999). Another group of

researchers argue that entrepreneurs through weak ties in more sparsely connected

networks benefit from superior information access, timing, control, and referrals with

the possibility of recognizing new opportunities early from a diverse group of

relations (Burt 1992, 1997; Portes & Sensenbrenner 1993; Krackhardt 1995; Singh et

al. 1999; Baum et al. 2000). Hence, two types of personal network characteristics – a

bonding approach and a bridging approach – are competing for recognition in the

literature. However, it is often claimed that different types of networks have to be

developed as different functional and strategic needs change (Butler & Hansen 1988;

Gibb & Davies 1991). What constitutes an enabling personal network structure for

one set of actions may well be disabling for others (Podolny & Baron 1997; Burt

Page 111: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

111

2000). Hence, what appears to be contradictory theoretical and empirical implications

of personal networks in prior studies may to some extent be traced back to a disregard

of contingencies (Birley et al. 1991; Gibb & Davies 1991; Aldrich & Reese 1993;

Larson & Starr 1993; Hite & Hesterly 2001; Schutjens & Stam 2003).

This paper suggests that entrepreneurial phase as a contingency may reconcile these

opposing approaches to personal network theory. This is equally suggested by

empirical evidence indicating that the superiority of a particular type of personal

network varies with the entrepreneurial stage of development (Birley 1985; Birley et

al. 1991; Bloodgood et al. 1995; Schutjens & Stam 2003; Greve & Salaff 2003). For

example, several researchers suggest that strong ties manifested in a dense network

may play a more important role in the early stages of a new venture’s founding, while

weak ties – of a more professional character – in sparse networks tend to become

more beneficial later on (Birley 1985; Butler & Hansen 1988; Starr & MacMillan

1990; Birley et al. 1991; Bloodgood et al. 1995; Hite & Hesterly 2001).

The first section of this paper gives a short presentation of the different personal

network characteristics in terms of network size, strength of ties, and personal

network density that we will be referring to. Then, it is suggested how the process of

new venture creation may be split into phases of entrepreneurial intent, opportunity

discovery, emergent exploitation, and early growth. From this endeavor, it is

suggested how different needs for information, support, and resources accrue at each

stage. Empirical as well as theoretical studies on new venture creation and personal

networks are then related to these different phases, and the importance of different

types of personal networks in each stage of entrepreneurship is discussed. The

discussion as well as the propositions made in this paper are illustrated in figure 1

below.

Page 112: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

112

Figure 1. Propositions put forth in this paper.

Strength of ties P3a+

P1+

P1+

P1-

Personal network characteristics

Size

Density

Size

Strength of ties

Density

Entrepreneurial Intent

Opportunity Discovery

Nascent Exploitation

Ongoing Exploitation

P7+

P5+

P6-

P10-

P9-

P8+

P4-

P3b-

P2+

Page 113: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

113

Personal network measures

The paper primarily focuses on the theoretical and empirical aspects of a personal

network of the focal entrepreneur. The personal network is broadly defined as the

focal entrepreneur’s relations and contacts with others. Personal – or what is often

referred to as egocentric – networks are especially useful for collecting network data

from a target group, that is a small percentage of a population (minimum of overlap

between alters as well as entrepreneurs) whose relations are not concentrated in a

single personal structure (Wasserman & Faust 1994). This is exactly the case in

entrepreneurship (Greve & Salaff 2003). Moreover, collecting network data that go

beyond the egocentric network is a difficult and very demanding empirical task,

whereas the egocentric network data can be conveniently collected from a single

respondent.

A variety of measures have been drawn and utilized from this relatively simple

network structure to uncover different patterns that may be used for characterization

of the differential positions of entrepreneurs. One of the most basic measures is

network size, defined as the number of direct dyadic ties between the entrepreneur and

his/her alters. This number indicates how many people the entrepreneur talks to

during the process of new venture creation and measures the extent to which resources

and information can be accessed through the direct ties of the entrepreneur (Aldrich et

al. 1987; Greve 1995; Hansen 1995).

Measuring network size, the dyadic ties are treated as dichotomous, i.e. either present

or absent. However, we may also add value to the relational ties between

entrepreneurs and alters in the egocentric network to obtain more information about

the characteristics of the relationship and general network structure. Normally, this

valuation is referred to as the strength of the relationship, or strength of tie, suggesting

aspects such as degree of trust between parties, duration of relationship, and the

ability to transfer fine-grained or tacit knowledge (Granovetter 1973; Aldrich &

Zimmer 1986; Krackhardt 1992; Uzzi 1996; Rowley et al. 2000). Strength of ties may

Page 114: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

114

be specified on the basis of four criteria: emotional intensity, frequency of contacts,

degree of intimacy, and reciprocal commitment between relational parties

(Granovetter 1983, 1973). This suggests that relations can be gauged as either weak

(entailing a limited investment of time and intimacy, subsuming an array of formal or

informal personal acquaintances) or strong (often with relatives and close friends

entailing a high investment of time and intimacy as well as reciprocity). Krackhardt

(1992) uses the concept of ‘degrees of friendship’ as the measure of tie of strength. In

this analogy, a tie is defined as weak if it describes an acquaintance or a loose

acquaintance and strong if the focal person describes the relationship as a friendship

or a close friendship.

Finally, bringing in the relationship between alters shifts the reference from a sole

focus on the dyad to the triad, considering not only the direct communication between

the entrepreneur and his/her alters. This brings us to a third type of measure, namely

density and redundancy. Density describes the proportion of pairs of alters that are

connected, whereas redundancy describes the extent to which an ego’s contacts are

connected to each other as well the relative number of the entrepreneur’s direct dyadic

ties that are connected to each other (Burt 1992). In other words, it is a comparison of

the number of ties against the total number of actors in the network excluding the ego.

Hence, the central aspect is whether or not alters are interconnected. If two alters are

not interconnected, they span a structural hole; if alters are interconnected, one of

them is redundant (Burt 1992). The rest of this paper will relate these three measures

from a theoretical as well as an empirical point of view to the different phases of new

venture creation.

Entrepreneurial phases

Several scholars in entrepreneurship and new venture creation have suggested that

new venture creation may be split into different phases, recently paraphrased as

phases of opportunity discovery and exploitation (e.g. Kirzner 1979, 1997; Shane &

Page 115: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

115

Venkataraman 2000; Hitt et al. 2001; Zahra & Dess 2001; Eckhardt & Shane 2003;

Davidsson & Honig 2003). The next section combines this research with a few

insights gained from research on the organizational life cycle in order to explore the

different needs of emotional support, resources, and information in different phases

and how the needs change as the new venture progresses to the next phase (see e.g.

Kazanjian 1988 and Hite & Hesterly 2001). This endeavor will assist us in answering

questions such as which resources are important, why and when they are important,

and consequently how the entrepreneurs may obtain them from their personal

networks.

Most of these life cycle models, however, do not focus on the initial aspects of new

venture creation (e.g. Miller & Friesen 1984; Drazin & Kazanjian 1990). Even models

that explicitly position themselves in an entrepreneurial setting of new venture

creation often refer to the emergence stage as the stage where the organization is

legally created. This is basically the approach used by Dubini and Aldrich (1991),

who define entrepreneurship as the pursuit of entrepreneurial opportunities

disregarding the process of entrepreneurial opportunity creation. In other words, these

studies basically focus on the initial stages of new venture creation once the

entrepreneurial opportunity has been recognized or created maintaining its focus on

resource acquisition (e.g. Birley et al. 1991; Larson & Starr 1993; Bloodgood et al.

1995; Hite & Hesterly 2001). Hence, we need to obtain additional insights from

research in opportunity creation (e.g. Kirzner 1979, 1997; Kaish & Gilad 1991;

Busenitz & Lau 1996; Hills et al. 1999; Shane & Venkataraman 2000; Shane 2000;

Gaglio & Katz 2001; Krueger 2003; Ardichvili et al. 2003). A rather literal reading of

Shane and Venkataraman (2000) suggests that the phase of opportunity discovery

actually consists of at least two phases in terms of diverging needs from a personal

network: a phase of entrepreneurial intent followed by a phase of opportunity

discovery.

Page 116: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

116

ENTREPRENURIAL INTENT

As emphasized in a recent almost canonized definition of entrepreneurship by Shane

and Venkataraman (2000), entrepreneurship and new venture creation are about: “the

nexus of two phenomena: the presence of lucrative opportunities and the presence of

enterprising individuals” (200). The term ‘enterprising individual’ indicates that the

behavior of entrepreneurial individuals is not entirely determined by the outside

world, but is instead a result of autonomous individuals indicating that new ventures

are neither coerced into being nor randomly created as passive byproducts of

environmental circumstances. Instead, new ventures are the direct outcome of

individuals’ intentions and consequent actions (Katz & Gartner 1988). What is

important in this context is that personal networks are the context for action, but they

do not act themselves. Early on Kirzner (1979) argued that people need motivation

and support to fuel their perceptive interests in discovering opportunities in the market

– referred to as entrepreneurial alertness. Thus, any discovery of an entrepreneurial

opportunity by a prospective entrepreneur is preceded by a state of heightened

alertness to information (Ardichvili et al. 2003). This aspect is equally related to the

term ‘entrepreneurial intent’ as defined by Bird (1988) as the state of mind that directs

peoples’ attention and action toward a particular vocational or business goal. These

intentions are created as a result of a complex interplay between on the one hand a

social, political, and economic context and on the other hand the individual’s personal

history and abilities and current personality that underlies the opportunity analysis and

resource acquisitions (Bird 1988). Finally, Burt (1992) contends that the odds of

entrepreneurial behavior increase if someone is inclined towards entrepreneurial

behavior. Hence, intrinsic motivation, entrepreneurial alertness, or entrepreneurial

intent is often seen as an important inspiring factor and the first real step in the

process of new venture development (Kirzner 1979, 1997; Bird 1988; Kaish & Gilad

1991; Herron & Sapienza 1992; Bhave 1994).

Moreover, the heightened alertness to information and propensity to act on an

entrepreneurial opportunity are dependent upon the entrepreneur’s personal network.

For example, evidence suggests that the initial financial commitment, emotional

support as well as motivation are all factors that are influenced by strong ties in the

Page 117: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

117

network (Wellman 1981; Granovetter 1985; Krackhardt 1992; Brüderl &

Preisendörfer 1998). In their research on human and social capital, Davidsson and

Honig (2003) found evidence that encouragement from close friends and family – i.e.

strong ties – was strongly associated with the probability of new venture founding.

Moreover, Johannisson (1988) suggests that strong ties may help the entrepreneur

mobilize self-confidence as well as cognitive and emotive resources that are important

in new venture creation. In a Norwegian study, Jenssen and Koenig (2002) find

evidence that strong ties are significantly important for obtaining entrepreneurial

motivation. In fact, Zhao and Aram’s study (1995), which focuses specifically on

aspects of pre-founding, found that Chinese entrepreneurs seem to benefit from

intensity of networking as a proxy for strong ties. Finally, as suggested by Rousseau

et al. (1998), trust not only creates confident expectations but also makes the trusted

or trusting relation more comfortable about entering a vulnerable situation and

perhaps more likely to accept the risk associated with new venture creation. In other

words, if the individual believes that she can count and depend on the resources from

her personal network – including aspects of emotional support and concrete resources

– we would expect her to be more inclined towards entrepreneurial behavior – i.e.

become entrepreneurially intent.

From this reasoning, we would expect that a dense network with strong ties capable of

maximizing the level of trust in the personal network will be beneficial to obtain a

sufficient amount of entrepreneurial intent. Moreover, we would expect strong ties to

require more effort and intimacy, which as a natural consequence decrease their

occurrence influencing the size of the network (Granovetter 1985; Uzzi 1996). This

leads to the following proposition:

P1: Strength of ties and network density will be positively related and network size

will be negatively related to entrepreneurial intent.

Once the individual is predisposed and the entrepreneurial intent is formed we would

expect the process of opportunity search to progress (Krueger et al. 2000; Shook et al.

2003; Greve & Salaff 2003).

Page 118: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

118

OPPORTUNITY DISCOVERY

On the other side of the nexus is what Shane and Venkataraman (2000) refer to as the

presence of lucrative opportunities. The term ‘presence of’ indicates that opportunities

waiting to be discovered already exist independently of the individual very much

inspired by an Austrian tradition as explicated in Kirzner (1979, 1997). The premise

in this approach is that markets are in disequilibrium. However, opportunity-seeking

actors cannot start an active search process as the opportunity cannot be clearly

defined ex ante (Shane 2000). Even though they do not actively search,

entrepreneurially alert individuals are expected to see opportunities that are embedded

or latent, while non-entrepreneurially alert individuals simply see the environment as

it is. Opportunity identification is thus often related to situations of asymmetric

information, combined with the entrepreneur’s particular information sensitivity and

cognitive capacity that allows him to see opportunities even if he is not actively

searching for them (Kirzner 1997). Hence, what is of central importance is that the

entrepreneurially alert individuals keep their eyes and ears open (alertness) for yet

unspecified and undiscovered opportunities. This is actually consistent with

Schumpeter’s (1934) studies in the sense that people who have early access to new

information – what Schumpeter sees as a result of an exogenous shock – are more

likely to discover new combinations. Thus, we would generally expect that people

with access to more information are better at discovering entrepreneurial opportunities

(Shaver & Scott 1991; Kaish & Gilad 1991; Fiet 1996; Kirzner 1997).

The personal network is clearly of central importance in this process, acting as a

complex screening device keeping the individual up to date with information on

entrepreneurial opportunities even if the information tends to be fuzzy, inaccurate, and

diverse (Birley 1985; Coleman 1988; Burt 1992; Fiet 1996; Powell et al. 1996; Singh

et al. 1999). As argued by Burt (1992), opportunities jump out everywhere, but it is

the network that defines who gets to know about them and when they know.

Basically, “Who you know affects what you know” (Nahapiet & Ghoshal 1998:252).

Thus, only people occupying a certain position in the network are able to receive

Page 119: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

119

relevant information. In this way, the entrepreneurial network stimulates

entrepreneurship by creating opportunities that are not readily available for actors

outside or at different positions in the network. For example, in a US study Hills et al.

(1997) found that among 171 respondents, 50% claimed (ex post) that they discovered

their entrepreneurial opportunities through their personal network. The question is

how this relates to the structural characteristics of network size, strength of ties, and

personal network density.

As argued early on by Boissevain (1974), the number of relationships is the most

important property of egocentric networks because the amount of available

information increases with number of relationships. Generally, studies on network

size and opportunity recognition expect that a high number of contacts indicate the

possibility of receiving more, and possibly valuable, information. Thus, the more

people you have relationships with, the greater the chance of obtaining the

information needed for new venture creation. For example, a study on opportunity

recognition by Singh et al. (1999) found that network size significantly affected the

number of opportunities recognized by entrepreneurs. In this study, questionnaires

were obtained from 308 entrepreneurs who had recently founded consulting firms in

the information technology industry. The entrepreneurs were asked to report or recall

the number of new venture opportunities during a one-year period. However, even

though this study may indicate that network size is important in the initial stages of

new venture development, it did in fact measure the opportunity generation of existing

firms at a different stage of development. Finally, in two cross-sectional studies,

Greve (1995) and Greve and Salaff (2003) found that network size varied according to

entrepreneurial stage. In the initial stage of idea development, the network was

significantly smaller than in the later stages of organizing and running the firm.

However, the study does not say whether the network size of entrepreneurs is

generally larger than for non-entrepreneurs. Hence, the importance of network size in

this particular phase is not considered. Finally, focusing on existing firms, Shan et al.

(1994) and Ahuja (2000) found that the number of collaborative relationships formed

was positively related to innovative output, e.g. patents. Even though most of these

studies do not relate number of network contacts to opportunity search in this phase of

Page 120: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

120

new venture creation, we still expect a positive relationship between network size and

opportunity search.

P2: The size of the personal network will be positively related to the discovery of

opportunities.

The literature on strength of ties and entrepreneurial opportunity discovery mainly

focuses on the argument of ‘strength of weak ties’ as put forth in the seminal paper by

Granovetter (1973). Whereas the size of the network measures the amount of

information the entrepreneur can access, the aspect of strength of ties is expected to

measure access to a diversity of information. According to Granovetter (1973), weak

ties are often more important in spreading innovations and general knowledge

diffusion because they tend to serve as bridges between otherwise disconnected

groups of actors and pieces of information. The argument is that strong ties lead to

less efficient diffusion of information because people with whom the focal

entrepreneur has a strong relationship tend to know one another and have access to the

same information. This aspect is often referred to as the transitivity of networks.

Transitivity is the tendency that two individuals who are strongly connected to a third

party form mutual relationships over time. In other words, two individuals who both

have strong ties to a third individual are likely to be at least weakly tied to one

another. The main reason is that individuals strive to reduce inconsistencies in their

social and cognitive worlds and attempt to establish a balance in their interpersonal

relationships (Granovetter 1973; Burt 1992). As a consequence, the so-called

‘forbidden triad’ – where an individual has a strong tie to two individuals who are not

interconnected themselves – is unlikely to be a stable structure. Thus, those with

whom one is closest tend to move in similar social circles where information

circulates at a high velocity, suggesting that each person tends to know what the other

person knows. Consequently, information provided by strong ties is typically very

similar to the information the individual already has.

This rather simple assumption has far-reaching consequences for the large-scale

structure of the personal network and the availability of information. Most

Page 121: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

121

importantly, ties that bridge otherwise disconnected regions of a personal network are

likely to be weak, suggesting that weak ties are more likely to connect an individual to

diverse information. Thus, compared to strong ties, weak ties may come from multiple

and distant parts of the social system (Granovetter 1983). They represent local bridges

to disparate segments of the entrepreneur’s personal network that may otherwise be

disconnected and thus may open the door to new options (Granovetter 1973; Burt

1992). In this sense, weak ties are expected to be particularly beneficial for spotting

entrepreneurial opportunities because weak ties provide access to a diverse set of

topics and lead to a more varied set of information than strong ties (Bloodgood et al.

1995). In contrast, a network of homogeneous ties may be of limited value. As

suggested by Burt (1992), ties to more than one person with similar characteristics or

in similar social locations are redundant and of questionable value in providing new

information. Thus, a network of homogeneous ties will, according to Burt (1992), be

of limited value regarding generation of new information because people have access

to the same limited sources and tend to interpret the information in similar ways.

Like the empirical findings on network size, empirical studies relating opportunity

recognition to strength of ties in the actual phase of opportunity discovery in new

venture creation are sparse. However, some studies focusing on respondents at

another stage of new venture founding do indicate some support for the strength of

weak ties argument. For example, using a combined measure of patents and

trademarks with self-reported measures of innovation, Ruef (2002) found evidence

that entrepreneurs are more likely to engage in what they report as innovative activity

if they engage in information from weak rather than strong ties. However, none of the

respondents were actually in the first stage of new venture development. They were

either established entrepreneurs in later venture stages or failed entrepreneurs. Using

respondents from later stages as well, Singh et al. (1999) found support for the

importance of weak ties to opportunity recognition in the sense that they were

exposed to more opportunities that may be pursued or launched as new ventures.

Finally, a Norwegian study by Jenssen and Koenig (2002) indicates that weak ties

more often give access to information compared to strong ties, whereas strong ties

seem more important than weak ties in obtaining motivation and finance.

Page 122: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

122

In summary, although evidence on strength of ties and opportunity recognition is

relatively sparse, there are indications that weak ties give access to relatively more

diverse information than strong ties. However, evidence does not suggest whether

weak ties are relatively more beneficial in this stage of development than strong ties

because it only focuses on the aspects of diverse information access.

The premise that more diverse information is obtained through weak ties may,

however, be counterproductive as regards the discovery of entrepreneurial

opportunities because this may require access to tacit and complex information. A

central presumption in the strength of weak tie argument is that weak ties can

substitute for strong ties (Ahuja 2000). According to Burt (2000), it is not the strength

of ties that matters, but rather the position in the network. However, the

substitutability varies with the content transmitted through each type of tie. This does

not only accrue to the distinction between support and information, but also to types

of information. For example, if the transmitted content is simple, data transfer through

a weak tie may be adequate to obtain information from alters. However, if the content

of information is tacit and fine-grained, the entrepreneur needs strong ties (Krackhardt

1995; Uzzi 1997; Rowley et al. 2000; Hite 2003). As suggested by Johannisson

(2000), entrepreneurs in particular rely primarily on tacit knowledge mainly

transmitted through metaphors, hands-on demonstrations and mentorship like peer

entrepreneurs. Similarly, Kale et al. (2000) find a positive relationship between strong

ties and the degree of learning in inter-firm alliances. Moreover, as suggested by

Weick (1995), a dense network with strong ties is more adept at creating meaningful

information. Finally, as stressed by Johannisson (1988), quite a long time is needed to

develop a relationship based on trust and reciprocity that facilitates enactment

behavior and eventually opportunity creation.

In order to reconcile these differing approaches to the strength of weak or strong ties a

second type of contingency has been suggested in the literature: uncertainty in terms

of stabile or dynamic industries (see e.g. Rowley et al. 2000 and Elfring & Hulsink

2003). For example, Rowley et al. (2000) found that firms operating in industries

Page 123: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

123

requiring a relatively high rate of innovation activity – such as the semiconductor

industry in which alternative strategic decisions are demanded – would benefit from

weak ties, whereas firms operating in more stable industries – such as steel production

– would benefit from strong ties. As suggested by Rowley et al. (2000), this

contingency equally relates to the notion of exploitation versus exploration as put

forth by March (1991), i.e. whether or not the firm’s strategies are designed to exploit

existing technologies, skills, and information or whether the firm’s strategies are to

explore the environment for emerging innovations and other significant changes.

Finally, Elfring and Hulsink (2003) distinguish between incremental and radical

innovation in relation to degree of innovation. They propose that new ventures

pursuing incremental innovations benefit from using weak ties, whereas ventures

pursuing radical innovations tend to benefit from using a mix of strong and weak ties.

This leads to the following propositions on the strength of strong or weak ties:

P3a: Strength of ties is positively related to the discovery of opportunities in new

venture creation if the entrepreneur mainly seeks to refine and extend existing

competencies, technologies, and paradigms.

P3b: Strength of ties is negatively related to the discovery of opportunities in new

venture creation if the entrepreneur mainly seeks to explore the environment for

emerging innovations and other significant changes.

When focusing on the aspect of information access, the premise of these studies is that

a relatively dense network of contacts with a low amount of structural holes and a

high degree of redundancy is highly disadvantageous in relation to entrepreneurial

opportunity recognition because information will simply recirculate within the group:

“Contacts are redundant to the extent that they lead to the same people, and so provide

the same information benefits” (Burt 1992:17). The focus on activities within the

group creates structural holes in the information flow between groups. Some people

may belong to – or at least have contacts in – two or more different networks, giving

them the opportunity to break the flow of information between groups or across the

structural hole that integrates otherwise separated information or separated ways of

Page 124: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

124

thinking and behaving. Basically, an idea that is mundane in one group may be a

valuable insight in another. According to Burt (1992), it is this early access to diverse

information that makes entrepreneurs appear as gifted, creative people in the process

of opportunity discovery. In fact, Burt points out that the French word ‘entrepreneur’

initially comes from the French verb ‘entreprendre’. The verb ‘prende’ literally means

‘to take, grasp, or snatch’, while ‘entre’ means ‘between’ (Burt 1992). He uses this

parallel to illustrate that entrepreneurial opportunities typically arise when an

individual occupies a position in a network between otherwise unconnected

individuals.

Some of these arguments clearly resemble the arguments put forth as the strength of

weak ties. However, Burt (1992) points out that the causal agent in this phenomenon

is not the weakness of ties, but rather the structural holes that it spans. Thus weak ties

are only correlated with density, and weak ties are not a cause. The structural hole

generates the information benefit whether the tie is weak or strong. Thus, information

benefits travel across all bridges – weak as well as strong. However, weak ties are not

automatically bridges (Burt 1992). Additionally, the weak tie argument focuses only

on the amount of weak ties and not the degree to which alters are redundant or not.

There are few empirical studies on opportunity recognition in the actual phase of

opportunity discovery in new venture creation. Moreover, challenges in gathering data

on crosscutting relationships have forced researchers to use diversity in the personal

network as a proxy for density, i.e. the idea that alters bring about diverse information

(e.g. Van de Ven et al. 1984; Burt 1992; Kirzner 1997; Nahapiet & Ghoshal 1998;

McEvily & Zaheer 1999; Ahuja 2000; Baum et al. 2000; Renzulli et al. 2000; Ruef

2002). Taking this into consideration, some research on ventures in later stages

indicates a relationship between higher innovative rates in new ventures and network

redundancy (or diversity as a proxy), whereas other studies do not seem to find

significant differences. For example, studying small to medium-sized manufacturers,

McEvily and Zaheer (1999) found that firms with low density networks, i.e. networks

with a low degree of redundancy and a relatively high number of structural holes,

were associated with a greater acquisition of capabilities as an innovative capability

Page 125: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

125

important for firms. Looking at network diversity as a proxy for redundancy, Powell

et al. (1996) showed that established firms in the US biotech industry obtained a more

information-rich position from a more diverse set of relations. A study from the

Canadian biotech industry by Baum et al. (2000) on start-ups, i.e. established firms

that are no longer in the stage of conception, supports these findings. Focusing on the

diversity of alliance partners as a proxy for redundancy, network diversity was

significantly related to innovative capability (captured by patenting) as well as rates of

revenue. Moreover, evidence from a sample of 766 entrepreneurial teams who

attempted to start a new business venture supports the hypothesis that individuals

embedded in a diverse set of network ties comprising of strong ties, weak ties, and

advisors with no prior contact are relatively more innovative (in terms of patents and

trademarks as well as a subjective perception of innovation in nine categories by the

entrepreneur) than individuals relying on homogeneous ties (Ruef 2002). In fact,

evidence suggests that personal networks with complete heterogeneous ties encourage

innovation at almost three times the rate of networks with completely homogeneous

ties (Ruef 2002). Finally, Hargadon and Sutton (1997) show how a firm exploits its

position between two unconnected alters – i.e. using a structural hole – to develop

new products.

In contrast, Singh et al. (1999) did not find support for the importance of structural

holes to opportunity recognition in their study on information technology consulting

firms. This is somewhat surprising since they obtained significant results on the

relationship between weak ties and opportunity recognition as suggested earlier on.

However, in their study an ego-network method was employed allowing only five

alters and hence a maximum of ten structural holes. As equally suggested by Singh et

al., allowing only five alters may not be sufficient to fully assess the importance of

structural holes mainly because of a bias toward strong ties. Then, this approach may

underestimate the number of structural holes because strong ties tend to be mutually

connected as suggested by the theory of transitivity of networks. Moreover, using this

approach we will not be able to see the actual variation in number of structural holes

among different individuals. Finally, a longitudinal study by Ahuja (2000) in the

chemical industry shows that the amount of structural holes was actually negatively

Page 126: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

126

related to innovation output as measured by number of patents. According to Ahuja,

technological collaboration is a central feature in this particular industry, implying

that working with competitors or customers is a precondition for innovation in the

first place. Hence, it is difficult to relate aspects of this particular industry to

industries at large. The dubiousness of these contrary results leads to the following

proposition:

P4: Personal network density is negatively associated with the discovery of

opportunities in new venture creation.

EMERGENT EXPLOITATION

Once the decision to pursue a new venture is made and the opportunity is discovered,

action must translate intent into a new venture (Bird 1988). The central focus in this

phase of new venture creation is the accumulation of resources including aspects of

obtaining financial capital, setting up business deals, getting necessary knowledge,

and mobilizing resources in general (Greve 1995 and Greve & Salaff 2003). We

would not expect the entrepreneur to control all the resources required to develop the

market and eventually to profit from the opportunity. Hence, most of these resources

must come from other people and institutions (Venkatraman 1997). However, the

liabilities of newness in terms of a low degree of legitimacy and reputation combined

with a lack of necessary resources makes the new venture largely dependent upon its

network to obtain these necessary resources as an alternative to the market mechanism

in an arm’s length relationship (Butler & Hansen 1991; Hite & Hesterly 2001).

Whereas the fundamental dogma in the phase of opportunity discovery is related to

the aspect of opportunity recognition through weak ties spanning structural holes,

mainly associated with Granovetter (1973) and Burt (1992), the primary focus in this

emergent phase of exploitation is how network closure – mainly associated with

Coleman (1988, 1990) – fosters identification with a group of alters, which may

facilitate the emergence of effective norms and trust among individuals in the

network, which then again facilitates exchange of resources. According to Coleman,

Page 127: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

127

the optimal personal network structure is a dense, interconnected network in which

the entrepreneur’s alters are connected to each other. It is difficult and unproductive in

any context to make large joint investments, share knowledge, and combine skills and

resources without a certain amount of trust and a corresponding reduction of

opportunism in the relationship (Coleman 1988). Coleman (1990) states that

redundant ties among individuals result in a resolution to collective action problems.

This is done through improved coordination, which is supported by trust in a repeated

and relatively stable network. Trust is not merely an attitude held by one party toward

another, but is basically a characteristic of the relationship (Whitener et al. 1998),

largely formed and developed through repeated interaction where the entrepreneur

and the alter build positive expectations to each other over time (Blau 1964; Luhmann

1979; Larson 1992). Thus, strong ties reflect relatively intense, emotion-laden and

reciprocal relationships that require repeated and frequent meetings as well as energy

to create and maintain. On the other hand, the close contact and mutual dependency

between the parties furnish a great obligation as well as an exchange of resources

below market price (Starr & MacMillan 1990; Larson & Starr 1993; Jones et al.

1997). Hence, strong ties often provide trust, which is critical when dealing with

uncertainty and the procurement of resources particularly important in new venture

creation (Granovetter 1983; Johannisson 1988; Nelson 1989; Dubini & Aldrich 1991;

Krackhardt 1992).

Empirical evidence equally supports the importance of strong ties in this phase of

emergent exploitation. The studies by Birley (1985) and Birley et al. (1988)

distinguish between social (or informal) ties (e.g. family, friends, and acquaintances)

and professional (or formal) ties with whom the entrepreneur has a business-like

relationship (e.g. banks, accountants, and lawyers). An analysis of these networks

over time (using cross-sectional analyses) suggests that social ties of network support

based on strong ties were most important in the initial phases of new venture

development, whereas formal sources based on weak ties come to the fore: “… when

the elements of the firm are set and the entrepreneur is seeking to raise finance”

(Birley 1985:114). A study by Schutjens and Stam (2003) partly supports these

results. The shift from social to business contacts is found to be significant, but only

Page 128: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

128

holds for outsourcing, suppliers, and cooperative relationships, whereas down-stream

contacts (such as sales relationships) become increasingly social over time (Schutjens

& Stam 2003). Finally, a vast amount of evidence equally suggests that the wealth of

relatives and other strong relations plays a critical role in the initial resource

acquisition and financing of new ventures (see e.g. Starr & MacMillan 1990, Holmes

& Kent 1991, Norton 1991, Bhide 1992, Scherr et al. 1993, Petersen & Rajan 1994,

Fluck et al. 1998, and Avery et al. 1998). This leads to the following proposition:

P5: The strength of ties is positively associated with the successful exploitation of

opportunities in the emergent phase of new venture creation.

As mentioned, we would expect a network of primarily strong ties to require more

effort and intimacy, which as a natural consequence decreases their occurrence

influencing the size of the network (Granovetter 1985; Uzzi 1996). This aspect is

indicated in Greve (1995) and Greve and Salaff (2003). Their findings suggest that the

size of the personal network differed according to the entrepreneurial stage. In the

emergent phase (also referred to as the planning phase), the network was significantly

smaller than in the later stages of infancy (also referred to as the establishment phase).

However, the study does not say whether the network size of high performing

entrepreneurs is generally higher than that of low performing entrepreneurs or non-

entrepreneurs. Even so, these results support the hypothesis concerning the different

needs of the two stages of new venture founding; a small-size network is associated

with dense networks with relatively strong ties, whereas a relatively bigger network is

associated with a sparser network of weak ties.

Hence we would assume the following proposition:

P6: The size of the personal network is negatively associated with the successful

exploitation of opportunities in the emergent phase of new venture creation.

Page 129: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

129

Finally, the creation of trust and curbing of opportunism are highly facilitated in dense

networks, where sanctions for deviant behavior are more easily imposed since

information about actors diffuses rapidly to other related actors (Coleman 1988;

Walker et al. 1997; Rowley 1997). Furthermore, the sanctions are expected to be more

effective since the collective sanctions and the loss of reputation in the whole network

more often outweigh the benefits of opportunism. For example, according to the

rather well-developed literature on ethnic entrepreneurship the critical task of

obtaining financial support in the founding process is directly systemized as a rotating

credit relationship in dense ethnic networks (see e.g. Coleman 1988). Thus, personal

networks with a high density are often found relevant as a source of social and

economic support moderating different aspects of uncertainty by creating governance

mechanisms based on trust instead of market mechanisms (Coleman 1990; Uzzi 1996,

1999; Lorenzoni & Lipparini 1999).

P7: Personal network density is positively associated with the successful exploitation

of opportunities in the emergent phase of new venture creation.

EARLY GROWTH PHASE

It is expected that new ventures entering the early growth phase have obtained a

sufficient amount of fundamental resources as well as greater legitimacy and

reputation. The focus in this stage is turning from mere survival and viability to

detailed strategic decisions to intentionally grow in a certain direction (Hite &

Hesterly 2001). At this stage, the entrepreneur is confronted with two basic

challenges; resource availability and resource access under favorable terms of

exchange. As a consequence, the new firm requires a more extensive and specific set

of resources often only accessible outside the entrepreneur’s immediate network

(Butler & Hansen 1991; Hite & Hesterly 2001). Hence, during this stage of new

venture development, entrepreneurs are more likely to acquire their resources through

calculative networks. These networks are egocentric networks where the focal actor’s

ties are more business related and primarily motivated by expected economic

cost/benefit analysis (Hite & Hesterly 2001). Moreover, these networks contain

Page 130: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

130

mostly weak ties. Hence, the entrepreneur may access a wider range of resources,

which may not be available in the dense network based on strong ties to close friends

and relatives. According to Butler and Hansen (1991), the network in this stage is

gradually comprises individuals from the pre-existing personal networks and new

individuals as well as organizations such as suppliers, customers, and capital

providers directly linked to the new venture. These relatively sparse personal

networks facilitate the search for critical resource providers, such as business angels

or venture capitalists, who may offer the new venture further access to financial

resources, suppliers, distribution channels, and customers.

Moreover, the scarcity of personal network – i.e. the existence of structural holes – in

this phase of new venture creation not only relates to the information aspect as

suggested in the phase of opportunity discovery. Another important aspect with

structural holes is their ability to enjoy efficiency and brokerage advantages based on

the ability to arbitrage non-redundant information and resource exchange (Burt 1992).

In other words, the entrepreneur may act as an intermediary between otherwise

disconnected parties who then have to rely on the entrepreneur for exchange.

Except for the few studies that specifically distinguish between phases of new venture

creation, empirical evidence on new venture development in the early growth phase is

difficult to distinguish from evidence in the emergent phase of exploitation. A large

group of empirical evidence does consider both periods of new venture development

at the same time. However, since the needs change in these two periods of new

venture development, we would expect research that does not distinguish between

these phases to present insignificant results.

For example on the aspect of network size a study by Baum et al. (2000) on biotech

start-ups suggests that a larger alliance network to other ventures may improve start-

up performance. Particularly the number of alliances with other pharmaceutical

companies, universities and other research institutes as well as marketing alliances

was significantly related to performance. The respondents in this network were drawn

from a group of existing new ventures that all had grown to a stage in which strategic

Page 131: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

131

alliances were created. Thus, this evidence supports the need for a relatively big and

sparse network in the stage of infancy. As mentioned, evidence suggests that the size

of the personal network of entrepreneurs increases as the venture moves from the

emergent to the early growth phase (Greve 1995 and Greve & Salaff 2003). However,

evidence from a population of firms from both the emergent and early growth phase

of new venture development is more blurred. For example, Aldrich et al. (1987) found

that network size was significantly related to start-up success. However, a study by

Aldrich and Reese (1993) using data from the same area of North Carolina as the

initial study by Aldrich et al. (1987) found no significance when relating network size

to entrepreneurial success. The same goes for a Swedish study by Johannisson (1996),

which studied potential and actual founders using self-reported success as the

dependent variable. Finally, Ostgaard and Birley (1996) did not find any significant

relationship between network size and performance in terms of sales and profit

growth. They did, however, find that larger firms on average were more likely to have

large networks. This finding may indicate that firms in later stages (using firm size as

a dubious proxy) are more likely to have a larger network. This leads to the following

proposition:

P8: The size of the personal network is positively associated with the successful

exploitation of opportunities in the early growth phase of new venture creation.

As suggested, we expect that week ties and structural holes become increasingly

important in this phase of early growth, which is equally supported by the sparse

empirical evidence that exists on these matters. For example, from a sample of

Swedish entrepreneurs, Davidsson and Honig (2003) argue that – as the process of

new venture generation progressed – weak ties helped the entrepreneur connect to

specific knowledge and necessary information, which was not available in his/her

close network. They argue that bridging networks through weak ties comes more to

the fore as the entrepreneur moves to the stage of infancy. This evidence suggests the

importance not only of weak ties, but also of bridging – i.e. the importance of

structural holes.

Page 132: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

132

P9: The strength of ties is negatively related to the successful exploitation of

opportunities in the early growth phase of new venture creation.

P10: The density of the personal network is negatively related to the successful

exploitation of opportunities in the early growth phase of new venture creation.

However, once again it is noteworthy that evidence that does not distinguish between

the two phases tends to be equivocal. For example, from a sample of 159 relatively

new ventures (between two and ten years old) with less than 50 employees, Ostgaard

and Birley (1996) found that networks containing many strong ties as measured by the

percentage of strangers in the personal network were significantly more often

associated with new venture growth. However, when using a combined measure of

frequency of contact with number of years the entrepreneur has known the relation,

Ostgaard and Birley (1996) did not find any significant success for sales growth,

increase in number of employees, or in profitability. Thus, the result of strength of ties

in this study is blurred. The same goes for a Swedish study by Johannisson (1996), in

which neither frequency of exchange (daily, weekly, less frequent) nor degree of

friendship (well acquainted, acquainted, strangers, unknown) turned out to be

significant. However, none of these studies distinguish between stages of new venture

development.

CONCLUSION AND PERSPECTIVES

This paper suggests that most researchers do not consider the effect of stage of

development when measuring the success of different types of personal network

characteristics. Moreover, if these aspects are considered, researchers make a

simplified distinction between opportunity identification as the primary objective in

the initial stage manifested in weak ties and resource procurement as a primary object

in later stages manifested in strong ties. However, evidence suggests that equally

important to information on possible opportunities in the initial phases is financial and

emotional support. Moreover, the necessity of strong ties in transferring fine-grained

information, which may be important for opportunity identification, is equally not

Page 133: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

133

considered. Hence, both weak and strong ties often give access to information as well

as finance, suggesting that the information and procurement of resources go through

both types of ties in different phases of new venture creation.

This paper suggests how the success of certain personal network characteristics is

related to different phases of new venture creation – we may refer to this as a cross-

sectional review of personal network characteristics. Since we would expect at least

some entrepreneurs to succeed in each phase of new venture creation, we may

conclude that personal networks are not always fixed and need to change according to

the different contextual requirements. However, this paper and the vast amount of

research on structural characteristics of personal networks do not explain how the

personal network actually changes in density, size, and strength and importantly how

the entrepreneur can use his or her network strategically in the process of new venture

creation. In a seminal paper, Larson (1992) describes how exchange in a dyad may

become institutionalized. From qualitative studies, Larson and Starr (1993) seek a

description of the typical development of the personal network. For example, they

depict how personal relationships become more multiplex in the sense that informal

relations may become formal or the other way around. This aspect of multiplexity is

equally suggested in a longitudinal study by Johannisson (1996). Even though these

process perspectives do shed some light on how personal relations are born and how

the strength and formality of ties change, more research is needed to understand this

process in greater detail. Hence, whereas this paper seeks the grounds for the structure

aspect of personal networks, we still need a process perspective to describe how

entrepreneurs may use and change their personal network in a strategically sound

manner. In short, the ability to influence the personal network in a strategically sound

manner is likely to be a critical component in the success of new venture creation.

The relatively simple ways of measuring the structural aspects of personal networks in

terms of size, strength, and density do have some limitations, however. A central

presumption relating effects of personal networks to different aspects of new venture

creation is that entrepreneurial behavior is embedded in interpersonal networks, which

may facilitate or hinder the successful development of new ventures (Larson 1992;

Page 134: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

134

Hite & Hesterly 2001). Moreover, it is presumed that the personal network of the

entrepreneur is virtually synonymous with the new venture’s network, as network ties

initially exist on the interpersonal level (Birley 1985; Greve 1995; Hite & Hesterly

2001). However, studying new venture creation over time, it is increasingly difficult

to keep a clear demarcation between the entrepreneur’s relations and the relations to

the new venture and other employees in the new venture. Thus, using the network of

the entrepreneur as the only relational mechanism may be highly problematic as the

new venture develops.

Moreover, like other individuals, entrepreneurs differ in their competences in using

and utilizing their networks as well as their absorptive capacity (Cohen & Levinthal

1990). For example, Mcgee et al. (1995) show that positive effects of networks only

accrue to new ventures where the managers (or entrepreneurs) have a certain level of

know-how and experience with co-operation. This is further supported by Cooper et

al. (1991), who found that age and management experience were positively correlated

with the use of network ties for information that was relevant to the start-up of a new

venture. This suggests that the sheer size of the network may be secondary to the

competences of the entrepreneur including financial resources, level of education, and

work experience. Moreover, it has also been suggested that individuals differ in their

propensity and capability to form network connections in the first place (Burt et al.

1998).

Common to these structural studies on personal networks is the focus on the different

aspects of relations and not the specific resources accruing from these relationships

(Jenssen & Koenig 2002). Clearly we cannot treat every personal tie as equally

important in the process of new venture creation. Moreover, building a typology of

eight different types of relational embeddedness, Hite (2003) clearly illustrates that

relational ties are not homogeneous, but highly heterogeneously. Thus, even though a

few of these studies on network size focus on a group of alters that should be more

related to issues of new venture founding, the heterogeneity of these ties still makes

the sheer number of ties or density difficult to compare directly. Finally, evidence

suggests that we cannot assume network characteristics to be generic across borders

Page 135: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

135

(Dodd & Patra 2002) and across market context, such as extent of competition,

maturity of the industry, and size and growth rate of the market (Eisenhardt &

Schoonhoven 1996). For example, evidence suggests that US entrepreneurs have

significantly larger networks than Swedish entrepreneurs, who have significantly

larger networks than Norwegian and Italian entrepreneurs (Greve & Salaff 2003).

Page 136: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

136

REFERENCES

Ahuja, G., 2000, Collaboration Networks, Structural Holes, and Innovation: A

Longitudinal Study, Administrative Science Quarterly 45, 425-455.

Aldrich, H.E. and P.R. Reese, 1993, Does networking pay off? A panel study of

entrepreneurs in the research triangle, in N. Churchill et al., eds., Frontiers in

Entrepreneurship Research (Wellesley, MA: Babson College) 325-399.

Aldrich, H.E. and C. Zimmer, 1986, Entrepreneurship through social networks, in

H.E. Aldrich, ed., Population Perspectives on Organizations (Uppsala: Acta

Universitatis) 13-28.

Aldrich, H.E., B. Rosen, and W. Woodward, 1987, The Impact of Social Networks on

Business Founding and Profit, in N. Churchill et al., eds., Frontiers in

Entrepreneurship Research (Wellesley, MA: Babson College) 154-168.

Ardichvili, A., R. Cardozo, and S. Ray, 2003, A theory of entrepreneurial opportunity

identification and development, Journal of Business Venturing 18 (1): 105-123.

Baum, J.A.C., T. Calabresse, and B.S. Silverman, 2000, Don’t Go it Alone: Alliance

Network composition and startups’ performance in Canadian Biotechnology,

Strategic Management Journal 21, 267-294.

Bhave, M. P., 1994, A Process Model of Entrepreneurial Venture Creation, Journal of

Business Venturing 9 (3): 223-242.

Bhide, A., 1999, The origin and evolution of new businesses (Oxford: Oxford

University Press).

Bird, B., 1988, Implementing entrepreneurial ideas: The case for intentions, Academy

of Management Review 13: 442-453.

Page 137: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

137

Birley, S., 1985, The role of networks in the entrepreneurial process, Journal of

Business Venturing 1, 107-117.

Birley, S., S. Cromie, and A. Myers, 1988, Entrepreneurial Networks in Northern

Ireland (Belfast).

Birley, S., S. Cromie, and A. Myers, 1991, Entrepreneurial Networks: Their

Emergence in Ireland and Overseas, International Small Business Journal 9, 57-

74.

Blau, P.M., 1964, Exchange and Power in Social Life (New York: Wiley).

Bloodgood, J.M., H. Sapienza, and A.L. Carsrud, 1995, The dynamics of new

business start-ups: Person, context, and process, in J. Katz and R.H. Brockhaus,

eds., Advances in Entrepreneurship, Firm Emergence, and Growth (Greenwich:

Elsevier).

Boissevain, J., 1974, Friends of Friends, Networks, Manipulators and Coalitions

(Oxford).

Brüderl, J. and P. Preisendörfer, 1998, Network support and the success of newly

founded businesses, Small Business Economics 10, 231-225.

Burt, R.S., 1992, Structural holes: the social structure of competition (Cambridge,

MA: Harvard University Press).

Burt, R.S., 1997, The contingent value of social capital, Administrative Science

Quarterly 42, 339-365.

Burt, R.S., 2000, The network structure of social capital, in R.I. Sutton and B.M.

Staw, eds., Research in organizational behavior (Greenwich, CT: JAI Press)

345-423.

Page 138: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

138

Burt, R.S., J.E. Janotta, and J.T. Mahoney, 1998, Personality correlates of structural

holes, Social Networks 20: 63-88.

Busenitz, L.W. and D.C. Lau, 1996, A cross-cultural cognitive model of new venture

creation, Entrepreneurship, Theory and Practice 20: 25-39.

Butler, J.E. and G.S. Hansen, 1988, Managing Social Network Evolution and

Entrepreneurial Benefits, in B.A. Kirchhoff, ed., Frontiers of Entrepreneurship

Research (Wellesley, MA) 403-404.

Butler, J.E. and G.S. Hansen, 1991, Network Evolution, Entrepreneurial Success, and

Regional Development, Entrepreneurship and Regional Development 3, 1-16.

Cohen, W.M. and D.A. Levinthal, 1990, Absorbative capacity: A new perspective on

learning and innovation, Administrative Science Quarterly 35, 128-152.

Coleman, J.S., 1988, Social capital in the creation of human capital, American

Journal of Sociology 94, 95-120.

Coleman, J.S., 1990, Foundations of social theory (Cambridge, MA: Harvard

University Press).

Cooper, A.C., T.B. Folta, and C. Woo, 1991, Information acquisition and performance

by start-up firms, in N. Churchill et al., eds., Frontiers in Entrepreneurship

Research (Wellesley, MA: Babson College) 276-290.

Davidsson, P. and B. Honig, 2003, The role of social and human capital among

nascent entrepreneurs, Journal of Business Venturing 18, 301-331.

Dodd, S.D. and E. Patra, 2002, National Differences in entrepreneurial networking,

Entrepreneurship and Regional Development 14, 117-134.

Drazin, R. and R. Kazanjian, 1990, A Reanalysis of Miller and Friesen’s lifecycle

data, Strategic Management Journal 11, 319-325.

Page 139: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

139

Dubini, P. and H. Aldrich, 1991, Personal and Extended Networks Are Central to the

Entrepreneurial Process, Journal of Business Venturing 6, 305-313.

Eisenhardt, K.M. and C.B. Schoonhoven, 1996, Resource-based view of strategic

alliance formation: Strategic and social effects in entrepreneurial firms,

Organization Science 7, 136-150.

Elfring, T. and W. Hulsink, 2003, Networks in Entrepreneurship: The case of high-

technology firms, Small Business Economics 21, 409-422.

Fiet, J.O., 1996, The information basis of entrepreneurial discovery, Small Business

Economics 8, 419-430.

Gaglio, C.M. and J.A. Katz, 2001, The psychological basis of opportunity

identification: Entrepreneurial alertness, Small Business Economics 16 (2): 95-

111.

Gibb, A.A. and L.G. Davies, 1991, Methodological Problems in the Development and

Testing of a Growth Model of Business Enterprise Development, in L.G. Davies

and A.A. Gibb, eds., Recent Research in Entrepreneurship (Avebury) 286-323.

Granovetter, M.S., 1973, The strength of weak ties, American Journal of Sociology

78, 1360-1380.

Granovetter, M.S., 1983, The strength of weak ties: A network theory revisited, in R.

Collins, ed., Sociological Theory (San Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass) 201-233.

Granovetter, M.S., 1985, Economic action and social structure: The problem of

embeddedness, American Journal of Sociology 91, 481-510.

Greve, A., 1995, Networks and entrepreneurship – an analysis of social relations,

occupational background, and use of contacts during the establishment process,

Scandinavian Journal of Management 11, 1-24.

Page 140: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

140

Greve, A. and J.W. Salaff, 2003, Social Networks and Entrepreneurship,

Entrepreneurship, Theory and Practice Fall, 1-22.

Hansen, E.L., 1995, Entrepreneurial Network and New Organization Growth,

Entrepreneurship, Theory and Practice 19, 7-19.

Hargadon, A. and R. I. Sutton, 1997, Technology brokering and innovation in a

product development firm, Administrative Science Quarterly 42 (4): 716-749.

Herron, L. and H. Sapienza, 1992, The entrepreneur and the initiation of new venture

launch activitites, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 17 (1): 49-55.

Hills, G.E., G.T. Lumpkin, and R. Singh, 1997, Opportunity Recognition: Perceptions

and Behaviors of Entrepreneurs, in N. Churchill et al., eds., Frontiers in

Entrepreneurship Research (Wellesley, MA: Babson College).

Hite, J.M., 2003, Patterns of multidimensionality among embedded network ties: a

typology of relational embeddedness in emerging entrepreneurial firms,

Strategic Organization 1, 9-49.

Hite, J.M. and W.S. Hesterly, 2001, The evolution of firm networks: From emergence

to early growth of the firm, Strategic Management Journal 22, 275-286.

Hoang, H. and B. Antoncic, 2003, Network-based research in entrepreneurship – A

critical review, Journal of Business Venturing 18, 165-187.

Jenssen, J.I. and H.F. Koenig, 2002, The Effect of Social Networks on Resource

Access and Business Start-ups, European Planning Studies 10, 1039-1046.

Johannisson, B., 1988, Business formation – a network approach, Scandinavian

Journal of Management, 83-99.

Page 141: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

141

Johannisson, B., 1996, The dynamics of entrepreneurial networks, in P. Reynolds et

al., eds., Frontiers of Entrepreneurship Research (Wellesley, MA: Babson

College) 253-267.

Johannisson, B., 2000. Networking and Entrepreneurial Growth, in D. Sexton and H.

Landstrom, eds., Handbook of Entrepreneurship (Oxford, UK: Blackwell) 368-

386.

Jones, C., W.S. Hesterly, and S.P. Borgatti, 1997, A general theory of network

governance: Exchange conditions and social mechanisms, Academy of

Management Review 22, 911-945.

Kaish, S. and B. Gilad, 1991, Characteristics of Opportunities Search of

Entrepreneurs Versus Executives – Sources, Interests, General Alertness,

Journal of Business Venturing 6 (1): 45-61.

Kale, P., H. Singh, and H. Perlmutter, 2000, Learning and protection of proprietary

assets in strategic alliances: Building relational capital, Strategic Management

Journal 21 (3): 217-237.

Katz, J. and W.B. Gartner, 1988, Properties of emerging organizations, Academy of

Management Review 13, 429-441.

Kazanjian, R., 1988, Relation of Dominant Problems to Stages of Growth in

Technology-Based New Ventures, Academy of Management Journal 31, 257-

279.

Kirzner, I.M., 1979. Perceptions, Opportunities, and Profit (Chicago: University of

Chicago Press).

Kirzner, I.M., 1997, Entrepreneurial discovery and the competitive market process:

An Austrian approach, Journal of Economic Literature 35 (1): 60-85.

Page 142: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

142

Krackhardt, D., 1992, The strength of strong ties: The importance of philos in

organizations, in N. Nohria and R.G. Eccles, eds., Networks and Organizations:

Structure, Form, and Action (Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press) 215-

239.

Krackhardt, D., 1995, Structural Holes – the Social-Structure of Competition –

Burt,Rs, Administrative Science Quarterly 40, 350-354.

Larson, A., 1991, Partner Networks – Leveraging External Ties to Improve

Entrepreneurial Performance, Journal of Business Venturing 6, 173-188.

Larson, A., 1992, Network dyads in entrepreneurial settings: a study of the

governance of exchange relationships, Administrative Science Quarterly 37, 76-

104.

Larson, A.L. and J.A. Starr, 1993, A network model of organization formation,

Entrepreneurship, Theory and Practice 17, 5-15.

Lorenzoni, G. and A. Lipparini, 1999, The leveraging of interfirm relationships as a

distinctive organizational capability: a longitudinal study, Strategic

Management Journal 20, 317-338.

Luhmann, N., 1979, Trust and Power (New York: Chichester).

March, J., 1991, Exploration and exploitation in organizational learning, Organization

Science 2: 71-87.

McEvily, B. and A. Zaheer, 1999, Bridging ties: a source of firm heterogeneity in

competitive capabilities, Strategic Management Journal 20, 1133-1156.

Mcgee, J.E., M.J. Dowling, and W.L. Megginson, 1995, Cooperative strategy and

new venture performance: The role of business strategy and management

experience, Strategic Management Journal 16, 565-580.

Page 143: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

143

Miller, D. and P.H. Friesen, 1984, A longitudinal study of the corporate life cycle,

Management Science 30, 1161-1183.

Nahapiet, J. and S. Ghoshal, 1998, Social capital, intellectual capital and the

organizational advantage, Academy of Management Review 23, 242-266.

Nelson, R.E., 1989, The strength of strong ties: Social networks and intergroup

conflict in organization, Academy of Management Journal 2, 377-401.

Norton, E., 1991, Capital Structure and Small Public Firms, Journal of Business

Venturing 6, 287-303.

Ostgaard, T.A. and S. Birley, 1996, New venture growth and personal networks,

Journal of Business Research 36, 37-50.

Podolny, J.M. and J.N. Baron, 1997, Resources and relationships: Social networks

and mobility in the workplace, American Sociological Review 62, 673-693.

Portes, A. and J. Sensenbrenner, 1993, Embeddedness and immigration: notes on the

social determinants of economic action, American Journal of Sociology 98,

1320-1350.

Powell, W.W., K.W. Koput, and L. SmithDoerr, 1996, Interorganizational

collaboration and the locus of innovation: Networks of learning in

biotechnology, Administrative Science Quarterly 41, 116-145.

Renzulli, L.A., H.E. Aldrich, and J. Moody, 2000, Family matters: gender, family,

and entrepreneurial outcomes, Social Forces 79, 523-546.

Rousseau, D.M. et al., 1998, Not so different after all: A cross-discipline view of trust,

Academy of Management Review 23 (3): 393-404.

Rowley, T. J., 1997, Moving beyond dyadic ties: A network theory of stakeholder

influences, Academy of Management Review 22 (4): 887-910.

Page 144: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

144

Rowley, T., D. Behrens, and D. Krackhardt, 2000, Redundant governance structures:

An analysis of structural and relational embeddedness in the steel and

semiconductor industries, Strategic Management Journal 21, 369-386.

Ruef, M., 2002, Strong ties, weak ties and islands: structural and cultural predictions

of organizational innovation, Industrial and Corporate Change 11, 427-449.

Schumpeter, J.A., 1934, The theory of economic development (Cambridge: Harvard

University Press).

Schutjens, V. and E. Stam, 2003, The Evolution and Nature of Young Firm Networks:

A Longitudinal Perspective, Small Business Economics 21, 115-134.

Shan, W., G.B. Walker, and B. Kogut, 1994, Interfirm cooperation and startup

innovation in the biotechnology industry, Strategic Management Journal 15,

387-394.

Shane, S. and S. Venkataraman, 2000, The promise of entrepreneurship as a field of

research, Academy of Management Review 25, 217-226.

Shaver, K.G. and L.R. Scott, 1991, Person, process, choice: the psychology of new

venture creation, Entrepreneurship, Theory and Practice 16, 23-42.

Singh, R.G., R.C. Hybels, and G.T. Lumpkin, 1999, Opportunity recognition through

social network characteristics of entrepreneurs, in P. Reynolds et al., eds.,

Frontiers of Entrepreneurship Research (Wellesley, MA: Babson College).

Starr, J.A. and I.C. MacMillan, 1990, Resource cooptation and social contracting:

Resource acquisition strategies for new ventures, Strategic Management

Journal 11, 79-92.

Thornton, P.H., 1999, The sociology of entrepreneurship, Annu.Rev.Sociol. 25, 19-46.

Page 145: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

145

Uzzi, B., 1996, The sources and consequences of embeddedness for the economic

performance of organizations: the network effect, American Sociological

Review 61, 674-698.

Uzzi, B., 1997, Social structure and competition in interfirm networks: The paradox

of embeddedness, Administrative Science Quarterly 42, 35-67.

Uzzi, B., 1999, Embeddedness in the making of financial capital, American

Sociological Review 64, 481-505.

Van de Ven, A.H., R. Hudson, and D.M. Schroeder, 1984, Designing new business

start-ups: Entrepreneurial, organizational, and ecological considerations,

Journal of Management 10, 89-107.

Walker, G., B. Kogut, and W.J. Shan, 1997, Social capital, structural holes and the

formation of an industry network, Organization Science 8, 109-125.

Wasserman, S. and K. Faust, 1994, Social network analysis methods and applications

(Cambridge/New York: Cambridge University Press).

Weick, K.E., 1995, Sensemaking in organizations (Thousand Oaks: Sage

Publications).

Wellman, B., 1981, Applying network analysis to the study of social support, in B.

Gottlieb, ed., Social Network and Social Support (Beverly Hills, CA: Sage

Publications).

Whitener, E.M., S.E. Brodt, M.A. Korsgaard, and J.M. Werner, 1998, Managers as

initiators of trust: An exchange relationship framework for understanding

managerial trustworthy behavior, Academy of Management Review 23, 513-530.

Page 146: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

146

Page 147: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

147

Governance Mechanisms in the Pecking Order

of New Venture Finance

Abstract

This paper seeks to develop taxonomy of governance mechanisms in new venture

finance by introducing elements of transaction cost economics as well as elements of

the relational contracting literature. Contractual forms of governance are suggested to

be applicable only if exchange hazards are very low. If exchange hazards increase, the

exchange parties – i.e. the entrepreneur and the investor – need to rely on a

combination of formal contractual governance mechanisms and relational governance

mechanisms based on personal or calculated trust. Finally, these governance

mechanisms are related to the typical pecking order of new ventures and different

types of finance.

Introduction

Principal-agent theory has been the primary focus in new venture finance, (see e.g.

Amit, Glosten, and Muller 1990; Petersen and Rajan 1994; Cable and Shane 1997;

Wright and Robbie 1998; Manigart and Sapienza 2000; Amit, Brander, and Zott 2000;

Hellmann and Puri 2002). The central issue is how the investor (principal) motivates

the entrepreneur (agent) through different types of contractual relationships or

governance mechanisms to act on behalf of and in the interest of the investor in the

context of bounded rationality, uncertainty, information asymmetry, and opportunism

(Jensen and Meckling 1976; Eisenhardt 1989). Even though this stream of research

has provided insight into agency problems and has specified different contractual

solutions to a hierarchical relationship between investors and new ventures, agency

theory answers only a subset of the broader questions in new venture finance; if, how,

and under what circumstances investors can use formal contractual solutions to

mitigate problems of bounded rationality, information asymmetry, and opportunism in

a hierarchical setting (Cable and Shane 1997). However, the answers to these

Page 148: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

148

fundamental questions in the context of new venture finance appear to be overly

negative. It appears that even the fundamental ‘if’ question is hard to get by. Hence, it

is often suggested that new ventures face a financial gap due to severe agency

problems (Petersen and Rajan 1994; Wright and Robbie 1998; Manigart and Sapienza

2000; Amit, Brander, and Zott 2000). By the same token, acquiring finance is often

referred to as one of the most important problems for the creation of new ventures

(Scholtens 1999). As a consequence, most new ventures are financially constrained

and have to ‘bootstrap’ their new ventures to grow and survive in terms of finding

creative ways of acquiring finance without turning to bank or equity finance or

alternatively to minimize the need for financial resources by securing resources at a

low cost (Winborg and Landstrom 2001; Harrison, Mason, and Girling 2004; Ebben

and Johnson 2006).

Instead of a sole focus on the formal contractual options of investors, this paper

introduces the transactional relationship between the entrepreneur and the investor as

the primary unit of analysis. The transaction not only encompasses the exchange of

financial resources, but also any kind of information and social action establishing a

linkage between the parties. Focusing on the transaction, the primary research

question is where and how transactions should be governed under different

transactional circumstances in the context of new venture finance. This paper seeks to

answer this question by developing taxonomy of governance forms and a general

framework for understanding new venture finance in relation to different transactional

characteristics. Finally, these different forms and mechanisms of governance are

related to the typical pecking order of new ventures (Cosh and Hughes 1994; Petersen

and Rajan 1994; Berggren, Olofsson, and Silver 2000) and three fundamental

financial sources, including different types of bank finance, private equity finance,

and finance obtained from strong ties such as friends and relatives.

Governance – where and how?

A common framework for answering the where and how question – related to the

same neo-economic basis as agency theory – is based on transaction cost economics

(see e.g. Williamson 1979, 1985, 1991; Uzzi 1997; Poppo and Zenger 2002). A key

Page 149: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

149

feature of the transaction cost approach is the comparative analysis of different formal

contractual forms of governance and the selective match of these forms to the

characteristics of the concrete transactional situation (Williamson 1985, 1996). This

framework has traditionally been the primary theoretical focus from where to examine

the basic choice between integration (hierarchical governance) and arm’s length

market transaction, i.e. the essential make or buy decision, as well as the optimal

governance mechanisms in inter-firm alliances (Gulati 1995). In the context of new

venture finance, the entrepreneur as well as the investor are equally confronted with a

basic make or buy option. The entrepreneur needs to decide whether to make/procure

financial resources inside the firm if possible or buy financial resources from external

sources, whereas the investor needs to decide whether to make or buy an expected

stream of future payments. Moreover, the optimal answer to this decision may be

somewhere in between as a hybrid or an alliance between exchange parties. Insight

from this approach is used here to outline the basic characteristics of four generic

types of governances; hierarchies, equity based hybrids, non-equity based hybrids,

and markets.

Recently, however, transaction cost economics has been criticized for downplaying

the social and relational aspects of exchange in its primary focus on formal contracts

between anonymous legal units. As a consequence of this criticism, a number of

researchers have turned their focus towards the relational contracting literature as an

alternative or a complement to formal contracts as emphasized by transaction cost

economics (Gulati 1995, 1998; Uzzi 1997; Dyer and Singh 1998; Rowley, Behrens,

and Krackhardt 2000; Malhotra and Murnighan 2002; Poppo and Zenger 2002; Luo

2002; Lazzarini, Miller, and Zenger 2004). This paper incorporates the relational view

into the framework of transaction cost economics by introducing the relational

influence on behavioral as well as transactional characteristics. Contrary to the

traditional approach in transaction cost economics, prior relationships between the

entrepreneur and the investor or relationships developed in the course of transacting

are introduced in the analysis. These relational aspects are of critical importance if we

seek to understand the underlying mechanisms of exchange in the hybrid and

hierarchical types of governance in the context of new venture creation. Finally, this

Page 150: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

150

taxonomy is related to the characteristics of central financial sources in new venture

finance.

TRANSACTION COST ECONOMICS IN THE CONTEXT OF

NEW VENTURE CREATION

The central premise of the transaction cost approach is that different types of formal

contracts between the transacting parties facilitate governance of different types of

transactions5. Thus, in the context of new venture finance, transaction cost economics

suggests that transactions between entrepreneurs and different types of investors can

be governed through different types of formal contractual relations. Contracts in this

context is a formal agreement between the entrepreneur and the investor that

encompasses the sort of actions each is to take in different circumstances, flows of

payments between them, and dispute resolution mechanisms. Thus, in simple terms, it

represents promises of obligations to perform particular actions in the future. In the

event of default or disagreement, legal systems or other third parties are expected to

decide whether or not the entrepreneur, or the investor, fulfills the agreed range of

acceptable behaviors specified in the formal contract. Generally, by placing these

credibly enforceable limits on the actions of each party, formal contracts are

suggested to facilitate and constrain exchanges through the reduction of uncertainty,

the enhancement of control, and the mitigation of different types of transactional

hazards (Jensen and Meckling 1976; Williamson 1979, 1985).

Following the logic of transaction cost economics, different types of formal contracts

not only facilitate different types of transactions between the entrepreneur and the

investor, the choice of formal contracts equally affects the cost of contracting. This is

the basis for a central theoretical prediction; that of ‘discriminating alignment’, i.e.

simple transactions between parties should be matched with simple and economical

forms of contracts, whereas more complex transactions should be matched with more

costly and complex forms of contracts with increased amounts of safeguards

(Williamson 1985). Using simple forms of formal contracts to manage a complex

5 This paper does not intend a thorough introduction and description of transactions cost economics (see e.g. Williamson 1975, 1996) – only to relate it to new venture financing.

Page 151: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

151

transaction would incur a risk of contractual breakdown, whereas using complex

forms of formal contracts to manage simple transactions would be to incur costs

without gain. Thus, contingent on the characteristics of transactions to be organized

between the entrepreneur and the investor and their respective transaction costs, some

forms of contractual governance are superior to others. Notice, however, that the prior

relationship or relationships developing in the course of transaction between the

entrepreneur and the investor are not considered in this framework.

Sources of transaction costs in the context of new venture finance

The fundamental behavioral assumption of bounded rationality suggests that it is

infeasible for the investor and the entrepreneur to negotiate and write complete

contracts that fully describe each exchange party’s rights and responsibilities in all

conceivable future contingencies. Moreover, even though the investor may obtain

more detailed information on the private information held by the entrepreneur as well

as possible future scenarios in or outside the exchange relationship with the

entrepreneur or visa versa, the cost in time and resources may surpass the benefits of

this knowledge. Moreover, expecting the entrepreneur or the investor to act in

accordance with the spirit of the contract is not feasible due to the second behavioral

assumption of opportunism. Opportunism encompasses a wide range of behaviors

such as shirking, non-cooperative strategic bargaining, failure to share important

information, and failure to honor agreements and obligations (Williamson 1975). For

example, the entrepreneur or the investor may hide information regarding their own

and/or their co-workers abilities and willingness to work, knowledge of expected

future payoffs, and other types of negative information. This is akin to what is

referred to as adverse selection in principal-agent theory associated with ex ante costs

of contracting, where exchange partners may hide their private information and

misrepresent their true abilities and preferences (Eisenhardt 1989). In addition, the

entrepreneur may hire relatives or close friends who are not covered by or thought of

in the original contractual terms only to seize money from the investor. On the other

hand, the investor may seek to steal the ideas of the entrepreneur to appropriate the

potential economic profit in the transaction relationship. Hence, the entrepreneur may

be unwilling to share valuable, proprietary knowledge with the investor if the

Page 152: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

152

entrepreneur is not credibly assured that this knowledge will not be readily shared

with or exploited by potential competitors. In agency theory, this type of opportunistic

behavior is referred to as moral hazard (Eisenhardt 1989); an ex post contractual

agency problem that needs to be safeguarded ex ante in the contract.

Although not all entrepreneurs or investors are prone to opportunism, the assumption

of bounded rationality suggests that it is either too costly or plain impossible to

identify opportunistic individuals ex ante (Williamson 1996). Moreover, the

entrepreneur often has no prior track record or operational history, which makes it

even harder to disclose the propensity to act opportunistically (Sahlman 1990; Amit,

Brander, and Zott 2000). Thus, in this framework, the mere possibility for

opportunistic behavior combined with bounded rationality necessitates the

introduction of different kinds of costly safeguards to monitor and enforce the

contractual arrangement (Williamson 1985).

Characteristics of transactions in the context of new venture finance

Transaction cost scholars often define aspects of asset specificity, uncertainty, and

measurement difficulty as characteristics of transactions affecting transaction costs

and choice of governance in a transacting relationship. Asset specificity in this context

suggests that transactions between the investor and the entrepreneur entail transaction-

specific investments in time and resources in terms of physical as well as human

assets. These specific investments may include the costs of negotiating and writing a

customized contract between the entrepreneur and the investor, which to some degree

may be useless outside the specific transaction. Moreover, investors as well as

entrepreneurs often have to pay an ‘entry fee’ for initializing a relationship with

another party and obtaining a minimum of information about the transacting party.

For example, investors may need to spend time and energy analyzing business

proposals, assessing the competences and the trustworthiness of the entrepreneur, as

well as disclosing private information specific to the entrepreneur. On the other hand,

the entrepreneur may need to disclose some of the private information held by the

investor and develop a unique understanding of the investor’s investment procedures

and habits to obtain a satisfactory contractual agreement. Once again, these

Page 153: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

153

investments may be useless or at least not as valuable in another transactional

relationship. Finally, parties may be vulnerable to the negative signaling effects

following a breakup. Investors as well as entrepreneurs may be unwilling to engage in

future transactions with parties with a bad track record of breakups. In other words, if

asset specificity goes up, the potential exchange hazards and the necessary complexity

of the formal contract as well as the transaction costs associated with the exchange

will increase (Joskow 1988; Poppo and Zenger 2002).

Unanticipated changes in events such as unforeseeable changes in demand, supply,

technological environment and unexpected changes in the behavior of the

entrepreneur or the investor equally challenge the contractual governance of

transactions (Balakrishnan and Wernerfelt 1986; Heide and John 1990). The

uncertainty associated with new venture finance is almost per definition relatively

high, especially if the entrepreneur pursues commercial applications of new and

highly uncertain technologies (Aldrich and Fiol 1993; Moore 1994; Mason and

Harrison 2000). The core of the problem is that formal contracts are relatively

inflexible and therefore not well suited to handle transactions surrounded by a high

degree of uncertainty. Moreover, if contingencies that could not possibly have been

accounted for in the initial contract arise, the entrepreneur or the investor may

reinterpret the contractual terms to suit them as an aspect of opportunism. Thus, as the

degree of uncertainty rises so does the potential for opportunistic behavior as well as

expected costs of writing and enforcing a contingent claim contract (Williamson

1985).

Finally, the quality of effort put forth by transacting parties may be difficult or

impossible for the other party to measure, monitor, and enforce (Barzel 1982;

Demsetz 1988; Poppo and Zenger 1998). This is especially a problem if the

performance measures of transacting parties associated with the contractual terms are

ambiguous and not easily defined and if transacting parties seek opportunistic actions.

As suggested by Barzel (1982) observing the activities involved in transforming input

to output is often a reasonable proxy to outcome observation. However, if the mean-

end framework is difficult to ascertain, transacting parties may have incentives to

Page 154: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

154

behave opportunistically and limit their effort accordingly. Thus, as more information

is needed to evaluate behavior, more complex forms of governance are needed to

handle the transaction. Particularly, creative processes simply cannot be completely

specified in advance (Alchain and Demsetz 1972). This is most likely the case in

several processes of new venture creation. Thus, if problems of measurement are

numerous in a particular transaction, it is expected that the complexity of the contract

is equally high as well as the corresponding transaction costs in terms of writing,

monitoring, and safeguarding the transacting relationship.

Transactions between entrepreneurs and investors all differ along these

characteristics. The question is how do these transactional differences influence the

choice of formal contract and contractual governance? In other words, where and how

can transactions be governed between the entrepreneur and the investor, and

eventually, what types of financial sources fit these criteria?

Forms of governance in the context of new venture f inance

Transaction cost economics conceptualizes contractual forms in terms of three generic

types of contractual regimes: Market contracts, hybrids, and hierarchies (e.g.

Williamson 1991). Market contracts represent simple market or arm’s length

transactions based on relatively simple, formal, standardized contracts. In a market

contract, the individual transactions are easily and unambiguously enforced by the

legal system. Moreover, prices act as the only coordinating mechanism signaling all

relevant information to the transacting parties. Thus, exchange of information

between the transacting parties in a market contract is minimal and transactions can be

managed through relatively simple routines (Williamson 1985; Bradach and Eccles

1989; Dyer and Singh 1998). In this sense, arm’s length transactions require only

minimal investments in governance mechanisms and entail low transaction costs. This

type of contract is particularly optimal if faced with simple exchanges where the

exchange hazards in terms of asset specificity, measurement difficulties, and

uncertainty is relatively low (Williamson 1991). Among the available financial

sources to new ventures, finance based on collateral agreements corresponds

Page 155: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

155

particularly well to these characteristics. These include vehicle loans, equipment

loans, and commercial mortgages, which do not normally require additional guarantee

or collateral, but use the underlying asset as collateral instead (Petersen and Rajan

1994). Moreover, these types of loans are very popular among new ventures (Avery,

Bostic, and Samolyk 1998; Berger and Udell 1998). For example, according to the

ENSR Enterprise survey 1999, 33% of early stage ventures (<5 years) have bank

credit guaranteed by collateral. However, even though the market contract relying on

collateral to mitigate problems of exchange hazards is an important form of

governance between investors and entrepreneurs, most new ventures do not hold

adequate amounts of collateral to obtain the necessary resources to further the

development of the new venture (Petersen and Rajan 1994; Scholtens 1999). This is

especially true in industries with few tangible business assets such as professional

services firms, in very labor-intensive industries, and industries with very liquid assets

compared to fixed assets (Avery, Bostic, and Samolyk 1998; Scholtens 1999). In this

case, the entrepreneurs need other types of financial sources to ensure the continued

success of the new venture.

However, if/when finance based on different types of collateral with a low degree of

exchange hazards is no longer sufficient to continue the operations of the new

venture, the entrepreneur needs to find other financial sources: sources where

problems of asset specificity, uncertainty, and measurement difficulty may rise. In this

case, entrepreneurs as well as investors need to opt for more extensive and detailed

customized contracts in order to decrease the risk of contractual breakdown. Hence,

instead of relying on classical ‘anonymous’ contract law (as in market contracts), the

contractual parties may turn to hybrid types of governance and/or contracts relying on

neoclassical contract law and excuse doctrines where the identity of the transacting

parties is of critical importance (Williamson 1991). Moreover, hybrid or intermediate

forms of contracts use customized complex contracts outlining in greater details the

remedies for different contingencies and specifying processes for resolving

unforeseeable outcomes – and exchange of supplement prices as coordinating

mechanisms (Dyer and Singh 1998). In this sense, hybrids blend the elements of the

market and the hierarchy: thus suggesting that the entrepreneur and the investor may

Page 156: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

156

enter hybrid arrangements when the transaction costs associated with a transaction are

intermediate and not high enough to justify vertical integration or low enough to

justify a market contract (Williamson 1985; Bradach and Eccles 1989). Like alliances

between firms, these hybrid arrangements may include several formal contractual

arrangements between transacting parties such as a formal command structure and

authority systems, incentive systems facilitating short-term performance measures,

standard operating procedures, and dispute resolution mechanisms that may or may

not bypass court rules (Gulati and Singh 1998).

The hybrid form of governance represents a continuum reflected in the type of hybrid

governance. A dichotomous classification of hybrid governance structures is often

made on the basis of their possible use of equity-based ownership (Pisano 1989;

Gulati 1995; Lui and Ngo 2004). Non-equity hybrids are more akin to the market type

of governance, even though the contractual terms do not use classical ‘anonymous’

contract law, are more complex, and require relatively more communication,

monitoring, and transparency (Pisano 1989; Gulati 1995; Poppo and Zenger 2002).

However, if transaction hazards in terms of asset specificity, uncertainty, and

measurement difficulty are too high to justify non-equity hybrid governance, structure

parties may turn to equity-based hybrids. Equity-based ownership in the context of

new venture finance suggests that the investor takes an equity position in the new

venture. In this sense, equity-based hybrids are more akin to the hierarchy than the

market. Through the introduction of shared equity or ownership, the problems of

potential hold-ups decrease and the potential for addressing unforeseen contingency

increases (Williamson 1975; Gulati 1995; Poppo and Zenger 2002; Lui and Ngo

2004). These benefits need to be weighed against the increased cost of negotiation,

administration and possible very high exit costs (Pisano 1989; Gulati 1995; Lui and

Ngo 2004).

Finally, transaction hazards may ascend to a degree where markets as well as hybrid

types of governance are too expensive in terms of governance costs and too risky in

terms of contractual breakdown. In this case, the entrepreneur and the investor may

Page 157: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

157

chose to remove the transaction from the market and internalize it in the hierarchy. In

this sense, the hierarchic organization is considered a response to a market failure

(Williamson 1991), like the notion of a financial gap in new venture finance from a

principal-agency point of view (Cable and Shane 1997). In the transaction cost theory,

hierarchic governance forms rely on bureaucratic or administrative control and

evaluation through employment law to mitigate high levels of transaction hazards in

the market (Masten 1988; Williamson 1991). This type of governance provides access

to a broader and more flexible set of administrative control systems, which are subject

to an implicit law of forbearance where fiat is a central and often costly mechanism

without the ‘straitjacketing’ effect of contracts. In this context, however, this is only

the case if the investor takes over the new venture and hires the entrepreneur as a

‘simple’ employee. However, in most cases, removing the transaction from the market

or the hybrid suggests that the ‘traditional’ relationship between the new venture and

the investor is surpassed, whereas social relations and obligations between exchange

parties become the center stage.

RELATIONAL ASPECTS OF EXCHANGE IN THE CONTEXT OF

NEW VENTURE CREATION

The sole emphasis on a formal contractual apparatus and formal safeguards is only

applicable in competitive, idealized markets where buyers and sellers are in fact

anonymous to each other, like for instance the market exchange in the transaction cost

approach (Granovetter 1985). However, actors frequently act in a social context where

attempts at purposive economic action are embedded in concrete ongoing systems of

social relations using exchange protocols associated with noncommercial attachments

of social control such as trust, reputation, sanctions, and norms of reciprocity inherent

in long-term cooperation between exchange parties (Macneil 1980; Granovetter 1985;

Coleman 1990; Ring and Van de Ven 1992; Gulati 1995, 1998; Ghoshal and Moran

1996; Uzzi 1997, 1999; Zaheer, McEvily, and Perrone 1998; Dyer and Singh 1998;

Rowley, Behrens, and Krackhardt 2000; Poppo and Zenger 2002). Hence, on top of

the formal contractual arrangements between an investor and an entrepreneur, a more

informal type of relationship may emerge or may exist prior to the exchange

Page 158: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

158

agreement. Moreover, this embeddedness influences the behavioral as well as the

transactional characteristics of the transaction between the entrepreneur and the

investor, which is not considered in the transaction cost economics framework.

Particularly in the hierarchical type of governance – where exchange hazards are too

high to justify market or hybrid exchanges – the effect of embeddedness is the single

fundamental mechanism that allows the entrepreneur to obtain finance from investors

instead of a mere takeover. Thus, ignoring the effects of personal embeddedness prior

to the exchange agreement or the embeddedness developed in the course of exchange,

the transaction cost framework gives an inadequate description of the mechanism of

exchange in hybrid as well as hierarchical forms of governance between organizations

(e.g. Macneil 1980; Ring and Van de Ven 1994; Gulati 1995; Uzzi 1997; Dyer and

Singh 1998; Rowley, Behrens, and Krackhardt 2000; Gulati, Nohria, and Zaheer

2000; Poppo and Zenger 2002).

A central premise of the relational stream of research is that through personal

interaction the parties to the agreement may develop trust that helps mitigate the

problems of bounded rationality, opportunism, and incomplete contracts (Macneil

1980; Uzzi 1997; Dyer and Singh 1998). Thus, performing transactions with personal

contacts is more effective, because it embeds commercial exchanges in a web of

obligations (DiMaggio and Louch 1998). Moreover, the transacting parties may be

acquaintances, friends, or even relatives prior to the transaction, incurring a certain

amount and type of trust not considered in the traditional transaction cost economics

framework. Two types of trust can be identified in the literature ranging from the

highly calculative trust, where cooperation is maintained because it is in the self-

interest of the transacting parties given the repeated nature of the transaction, to the

altruistic or personal trust where generosity and kindness are at center stage, and

where the long-term payoff to cooperation is not considered (Williamson 1996).

In a strong relationship characterized by personal trust, the new venture and the

investment per se are not crucial points, but can be seen rather as an investment in a

social relationship between an entrepreneur and an investor. On the other hand, in a

Page 159: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

159

relationship based upon calculated trust, the investor trusts the entrepreneur because

the investor calculates that the entrepreneur’s short-run benefit from behaving

opportunistically is outweighed by the entrepreneur’s long-run benefit from continued

cooperation. In this sense ‘calculated trust’ is not necessarily tied to the personal

characteristics of the entrepreneur, such as trustworthiness and opportunistic

preferences. In the extreme case, even if the entrepreneur may be lying to the investor

and may appear untrustworthy, the investor may still trust the entrepreneur to do a

certain thing or act in a certain way. Here ‘calculated trust’ has to do with information

and expectations (Luhmann 1979).

According to March and Olson (1989), the core idea of trust is that it is not based on

an expectation of justification. They argue that if trust is justified by expectations of

positive reciprocal consequences, it is simply another version of economic exchange

that has nothing to do with real trust. Thus, this type of trust basically uses the same

underlying construct and governance mechanism as the formal contracts (Malhotra

and Murnighan 2002). However, even if it is just another version of economic

exchange, the personal interaction and embeddedness between the transacting parties

provide both sides with information on expected behavior in different circumstances,

which in turn mitigates problems of uncertainty, information asymmetry, bounded

rationality, and opportunism. In sum, the main distinction between these two types of

trust-based transactions is, in this context, the object of trust. In a relationship based

on calculated trust, the object of trust is related to the expectations surrounding the

concrete business proposal, whereas in a relationship based on personal trust, the

object is the entrepreneur or the investor and not the investment in the new venture

per se. Finally, we would expect that personal trust is only feasible between close

personal relations such as close friends and relatives, whereas calculated trust

develops in weak relations.

Evidence equally suggests that relational governance mechanisms between transacting

parties provide a number of beneficial outcomes such as lowering transaction costs

and opportunism in the exchange and reducing relational risk and uncertainty (Gulati

1995; Nooteboom, Berger, and Noorderhaven 1997). When ignoring these effects of

Page 160: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

160

social relations, transaction cost economics yields poor explanations and predictions

of non-market types of governance, like the hybrid and the hierarchy (Ring and Van

de Ven 1992; Uzzi 1997). Thus, the ‘a priori’ assumption of opportunism in the

transaction cost approach is only applicable if the transacting parties are and continue

to be anonymous to one another.

Personal embedded relationships promote distinctive governance mechanisms as an

alternative to formal contracts whether or not they are based on personal or calculated

trust. Moreover, personal embedded relationships have the potential to promote

transfer of fine-grained information between the transacting parties and occasionally

to create joint problem solving to overcome hurdles of information asymmetry and

paucity as well as increase the combined value of the investment (Gulati 1995; Uzzi

1997; Walker, Kogut, and Shan 1997; Kale, Singh, and Perlmutter 2000; Rowley et

al. 2001). Thus, the presumption of a fixed degree of information asymmetry and

bounded rationality in transaction cost economics does not hold if the economic

behavior of the entrepreneur and the investor is or becomes embedded in a personal

relation. In other words, the investor and the entrepreneur, through their relationship,

may disclose private information from their transacting parties from where to base

their future expectations. Moreover, the investor may provide benefits to the new

venture such as complementary competences and a good reputation besides the

invested money (Stuart, Hoang, and Hybels 1999; Thornton 1999).

COMBINING CONTRACTUAL AND RELATIONAL GOVERNANCE

MECHANISMS

In the traditional transaction cost economics framework, transactional characteristics

of the concrete transaction determine the optimal form of governance – i.e. where and

how transactions should be governed. In this framework, behavioral characteristics

such as bounded rationality and opportunism do not enter the picture, but are

considered uniformly distributed across transactions of diverging kinds. Thus, aspects

Page 161: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

161

of exchange hazards lead to different optimal forms of governance and their

corresponding formal contractual solutions.

If exchange hazards are relatively small, the market contract is the optimal solution.

The market contract in the context of new venture finance corresponds to a broad

range of straightforward formal contractual investments based on collateral. However,

if exchange hazards rise, hybrids may be necessary to avoid the danger of contractual

breakdown. In the hybrid type of governance, the relational characteristics – i.e. the

existing or developing embeddedness between the entrepreneur and the investor –

support the formal contractual solutions in the sense that they provide the transacting

parties with more or less fine-grained information which is not readily available to

outside investors. This information allows transacting parties to develop a sense of

calculated trust and refine their expectation in relation to their transacting party

accordingly. Thus, when entrepreneurs seek bank finance without guarantees and

collateral or private equity, such as venture or business angel capital, relational forms

of governance as well as formal contracts are used to govern the transaction between

the parties. Finally, if exchange hazards ascend even further, the optimal form of

governance may be to internalize the transaction in the hierarchy. In this context, this

suggests that the transaction between the entrepreneur (as a representative of the new

venture) and the investor is removed from the market. Instead, the transaction is solely

based on relational governance where personal and altruistic trust between the

investor and the entrepreneur becomes the central governance mechanism. These

aspects are illustrated in Figure 2 suggesting how relational and transactional

characteristics in combination points to different optimal forms of governance.

Page 162: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

162

Figure 1. Combining relational and contractual characteristics in defining forms of

governance

THE PECKING ORDER

The final part of this paper relates these different forms of governance to the typical

pecking order of new ventures. This will allow us to see not only the typical form of

governance at different stages of new venture founding but also the demands for

certain personal network characteristics at different stages of new venture founding

accruing from the specific governance mechanisms. The financial order of new

ventures has been shown to be consistent with the pecking order hypothesis in a large

- Prior relational embeddedness between exchange parties

- Embeddedness developing in the

- Uncertainty - Active

specificity - Measurement

difficulty

- Bounded

rationality - Opportunism

Relational characteristics

Transactional and behavioral characteristics

Optimal form of governance

Where? Market Hybrid Hierarchy

Governance mechanisms Formal contracts Formal contracts & Relational governance Relational governance

Capital forms - Bank and lending

finance with collateral - Private equity - Bank finance - Love Money

Page 163: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

163

and mature business context (Cosh and Hughes 1994; Petersen and Rajan 1994;

Berggren, Olofsson, and Silver 2000). In short, the pecking order hypothesis suggests

that firms have a hierarchy of financing preferences with internal finance on top

followed by external debt followed by external equity as a final resort. Translated to

the context of new ventures the pecking order suggests that new ventures first use

financial sources based on internal resources and then different kinds of loan

arrangements. However, contrary to the pecking order hypothesis in the context of

mature publicly listed companies only a relatively small number of new ventures have

access to external equity financing. Particularly, public equity is almost never

available to new ventures (Berger and Udell 1998). In sum, if we look at the financial

life cycle of a typical new venture the proportion of financing from insiders increases

to a certain point and then decreases as the fraction of first debt, and occasionally

private equity such as business angel capital and venture capital rises. The final part of

this paper suggests how the pecking order in terms of financial sources may be related

to governance mechanism and consequently changing relational requirements

between investors and entrepreneurs as the new venture unfolds.

Hierarchical governance

Besides the entrepreneur’s own money, evidence suggests that relatives and close

friends are the most important source of capital in the initial phases of new venture

founding, often referred to as love money (Holmes and Kent 1991; Norton 1991;

Bhide 1992; Scherr, Sugrue, and Ward 1993; Petersen and Rajan 1994; Fluck, Holtz-

Eakin, and Rosen 1998; Avery, Bostic, and Samolyk 1998). In their US study, Berger

and Udell (1998) found that the largest sources of finance for small businesses were

the principal owner(s) (including principal’s equity, loans, and credit card debt)

responsible for 31.33% of the total financing. Other US studies equally suggest that

new ventures (< two years) rely most heavily on ‘loans’ from the owner, co-founders,

and/or relatives (Petersen and Rajan 1994). Moreover, relatives and close friends

often provide personal collateral or guarantees to serve as security for different types

of bank debt (Petersen and Rajan 1994). These ‘loans’ are, however, in effect

hierarchically governed and should not be considered market or hybrid types of

Page 164: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

164

funding (Binks and Ennew 1997; Berger and Udell 1998). Thus, finance with

collateral in the personal wealth of relatives and friends are considered part of the

hierarchical finance of the new venture even though it is obtained through a market

contract.

The importance of this type of capital stems from the high degrees of transactional

hazards in new venture finance, particularly in the initial stages. Initially, the

entrepreneur and the new venture have no track record or reputation established in the

financial market. The degree of exchange hazards at this stage is extremely high,

especially in terms of uncertainty and difficulties measuring and benchmarking

performance (Bhide 1992; Fluck, Holtz-Eakin, and Rosen 1998). Evidence (or

signals) that the business concept works, that the entrepreneur is competent,

trustworthy, serious, emotionally and financially committed, and that customer

demand does exist in relation to the new combinations typically does not exist. Then,

the assumptions of bounded rationality and opportunism as well as a very high degree

of exchange hazards make it impossible for the transacting parties to rely on formal

contractual solutions. Instead, the transaction is removed from the market or the

hybrid to the hierarchy. Here the transacting parties are no longer the investor and the

entrepreneur, representatives of the new venture; instead friends and relatives and

social obligations take center stage. Thus, aspects of the underlying investment are not

the object of the transaction and do not enter the equation accordingly.

Hence, before turning to external financial sources the entrepreneur must first reduce

the degree of uncertainty and problems of moral hazard and adverse selection by

providing some kind of evidence or signals to potential external investors that the

business concept works, that the entrepreneur is competent, trustworthy, serious,

emotionally and financially committed, and possibly that customer demand exists in

relation to the new combinations and so on and so forth. The only way to do this

initially is to obtain finance from sources where the possibility of opportunism and

problems of informational asymmetry does not exist or at least is not important.

Page 165: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

165

Finally, recent research on new venture finance – labeled ‘financial bootstrapping’ –

points to at least two additional methods that entrepreneurs may use at this stage of

development where the only way of obtaining resources is through an internal mode

of resource acquisition (Winborg and Landstrom 2001; Harrison, Mason, and Girling

2004; Ebben and Johnson 2006). One way to bootstrap at this stage of venture

creation is by delaying payments to external actors to improve cash flow with the risk

of jeopardizing the external actors’ trust in the new venture and the entrepreneur. In

the same vein the entrepreneur may seek longer-term payments with suppliers or lease

equipment to delay upfront payments (Winborg and Landstrom 2001; Ebben and

Johnson 2006). Secondly, if the new venture is at a stage where it is already producing

a product, it may bootstrap through minimizing stocks even though this may result in

longer delivery times or alternatively use methods towards customers that improve

cash flow by obtaining advance payments, charging high interests on overdue

invoices, or delaying delivery to customers (Winborg and Landstrom 2001; Ebben

and Johnson 2006). These techniques all represent methods of obtaining finance

through an internal mode of resource acquisition – i.e. modes that are used as a result

of decisions in hierarchical governance.

Low risk market governance

As suggested by the pecking order hypothesis, new ventures generally turn to bank

financing after spending all possible sources of internal finance (Norton 1991; Holmes

and Kent 1991; Scherr, Sugrue, and Ward 1993; Petersen and Rajan 1994). Evidence

in both Europe and the US likewise indicates that commercial banks are the most

popular source of finance for new ventures (Riding and Swift 1990; Binks and Ennew

1997; Meyer 1998). Despite scant empirical evidence specifically related to new

venture financing, research on small and medium sized enterprises in Europe suggests

that 46% of the SMEs state that they use long- or short-term bank loans as a financial

source (2001 Exco Grant and Thornton survey of European SMEs). A US study

suggests that commercial banks are responsible for 18.75% of the total financing

among SMEs (Berger and Udell 1998).

Page 166: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

166

However, initially we would not assume that the entrepreneur has built a strong

relationship with the bank thus far. Of course, the entrepreneur may have been doing

business of a more private nature with the same bank and somehow proved

trustworthy prior to the establishment of the new venture. Generally, however, at the

initial stage of bank financing we would not expect trust to be a sufficient contractual

mechanism considering the very high degree of uncertainty and information

asymmetry. Even if the prospect has already turned into a new venture most likely

with the help of internal financial sources, it rarely possesses audited financial

statements, credit ratings or other relatively objective measures easily monitored by

the bank (Verheul and Thurik 2001).

As a result, banks normally rely on collateral or other kinds of relatively reliable

guarantees as governance mechanisms to mitigate the very high degree of uncertainty

and information asymmetry and possibly reduce the interest rate. Thus, the

availability of tangible assets to work as collateral or different kinds of reliable

guarantees is often essential in bank financing (Avery, Bostic, and Samolyk 1998;

Berger and Udell 1998). Some of the bank financing is relatively straightforward for

products such as vehicle loans, equipment loans, and commercial mortgages that

normally do not require any additional guarantee or collateral, but use the actual

collateral instead. However, apart from those types of relative straightforward loans,

most new ventures do not hold adequate amounts of collateral to obtain long- or short-

term loans (Petersen and Rajan 1994; Scholtens 1999). This is especially true in

industries with few tangible business assets such as professional services firms, in

very labor intensive industries, and industries with highly liquid assets compared to

fixed assets (Avery, Bostic, and Samolyk 1998). In other words, long and short-term

external bank finance (i.e. disregarding the straightforward type of loans just

mentioned) is typically not available to new ventures until they have achieved a

substantial level of tangible business assets to pledge as collateral (Berger and Udell

1998). According to the ENSR Enterprise survey 1999, 33% of early stage ventures

(<5 years) have bank credit guaranteed by collateral. The fixed assets of the venture

only account for 4% of this collateral, whereas the entrepreneur and/or relatives

account for 25%.

Page 167: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

167

Non-equity hybrid governance

After spending the financial resources of friends and relatives through personal trust,

and using every thinkable asset as collateral the entrepreneur typically turns to short-

or long-term non-equity bank loans (Cosh and Hughes 1994; Petersen and Rajan

1994; Berger and Udell 1998; Berggren, Olofsson, and Silver 2000; Verheul and

Thurik 2001).

Problems in relation to exchange hazards at this early stage of new venture finance

are, however, still a threat. Adequate information on the specific prospects of the new

venture is in general not available to uninformed investors when entrepreneurs with

fairly unproven, perhaps even highly technical, projects with no records of

profitability require non-equity finance. Even if the prospect has already turned into a

new venture, most likely with the help of hierarchically governed financial sources as

well as investments based on different types of guarantees and collateral, the new

venture rarely possesses audited financial statements, credit ratings or other relatively

objective measures that are easily monitored by the investor bank or other forms of

non-equity hybrid governance forms. On top of this, banks rarely posses the

competence to monitor and predict future streams of income in the first place

(Verheul and Thurik 2001). In other words, we would not expect the bank to be able

to assess the specific prospects of the new venture or whether the income stream

generated from the specific investment is sufficient to cover the interest and capital

repayments involved from publicly available information at this stage of new venture

development.

However, empirical evidence suggests that a close relationship between entrepreneur

and banker may potentially reduce some of these exchange hazards through increased

information sharing and often results in lower transaction costs, better credit

agreements and especially availability of credit for the entrepreneur (Meyer 1998;

Uzzi 1999; Brau 2002). For example, in their US study, Petersen and Rajan 1994

found that the loan amount – and whether the loan is granted at all – was significantly

correlated with the strength of the relationship between the new venture and the bank.

A study by Brau (2002) suggests that new ventures with banking relationships enjoy

Page 168: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

168

lower interest rates, whereas ventures with a large number of banks have to pay higher

rates. Thus, new ventures that borrow money from multiple banks are charged a

significantly higher interest rate (Petersen and Rajan 1994). In the same vain, Berger

and Udell (1998) found that the amount of collateral required decreased with the

strength of relationship between bank and entrepreneur. Finally, from a huge US

sample, Dunkelberg (1998) reports the importance of different characteristics in the

relationship between the entrepreneur and the bank. According to this, 79% of the

entrepreneurs rated ‘knows you and your business’ as very important – the most

important of all characteristics. Thus, as a relationship between the bank and the

entrepreneur develops over time, both parties will possibly be able to disclose some of

the private information held by the other party and obtain much more fine-grained

information and develop an increased amount of calculated trust to reduce haggling

and monitoring costs (Petersen and Rajan 1994; Uzzi 1999). For example, the bank

may be able to learn about the new venture sales by monitoring the cash flows of the

entrepreneur as well as the new venture. This is supported by the fact that new

ventures tend to concentrate their borrowings and a broad range of services including

transactions, deposit services, checking and savings accounts, etc. in a single bank

(Petersen and Rajan 1994).

Hence, the complex formal contractual solutions surrounding hybrid types of

governance are supported by refined expectations obtained from the transfer of fine-

grained information in the transactional relationship between bank and entrepreneur

(Meyer 1998). As suggested by Slovin, Sushka, and Polonchek (1993), the bank

serves as a repository of private information. Then, the relationship between the

entrepreneur and the investor reduces the need for collateral to mitigate problems of

exchange hazards combined with complex formal contracts.

Page 169: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

169

Equity-based hybrids

In the context of new venture finance, transactions based on equity positions are most

often associated with business angels and venture capital6. Since the eighties (and the

mid-nineties in Europe), these types of financial sources have obtained an

increasingly important position in new venture finance with notable success stories

such as Microsoft, Apple, and Intel (Thornton 1999; Manigart and Sapienza 2000).

Typically, the equity investor invests in common stocks in the new venture through

some kind of equity contract. Furthermore, capital is normally provided in several

investment rounds, ideally giving the entrepreneur and the new venture just enough

money to get to the next predefined investment round (Prowse 1998). Moreover, the

amount of funding in early rounds is relatively small because investors will not make

large financial commitments to entrepreneurial firms without more information to

base their expectations on (Gompers 1995). Then, with the option to abandon an

investment project at predefined stages investors minimize problems of exchange

hazards while at the same time disclosing private information from their transacting

party (Sahlman 1990; Gompers 1995; Podolny 2001).

After the investment is made, equity-based investors often serve on the board of

directors. In this position, the investor may provide the venture with a variety of

inputs such as operating services, access to new business contacts or better business

deals, additional financing, recruitment of knowledgeable board members, provision

of general business knowledge, financial and strategic discipline, as well as legitimacy

toward third parties (Gorman and Sahlman 1989; MacMillan, Kulow, and Khoylian

1989; Bygrave and Timmons 1992; Mason and Harrison 1994; Ehrlich et al. 1994;

Sapienza, Manigart, and Vermier 1996; Fried, Bruton, and Hisrich 1998; Prowse

1998; Lumme, Mason, and Suomi 1998; Stuart, Hoang, and Hybels 1999; Manigart

and Sapienza 2000; Lee, Lee, and Pennings 2001). Thus, the relational embeddedness

allows for joint problem solving arrangements which may not be considered in the

6 Venture capitalists and business angels are treated as one type of equity-based finance. For a detailed description of each type of private equity-based finance (see e.g. Prowse 1998, Amit, Brander, and Zott 1998; Manigart and Sapienza 2000; and Mason and Harrison 2000).

Page 170: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

170

traditional transaction cost approach (Uzzi 1997; Rowley, Behrens, and Krackhardt

2000).

Moreover, with the frequent contact, the investor may obtain fine-grained information

which is otherwise unavailable in the market by monitoring the daily operations of the

venture and by actively participating in board meetings. The ability to disclose private

information of the entrepreneur and obtain more general information about the new

venture’s future prospects is the reason equity-based investors, such as venture

capitalists and business angels, exist in the first place (Sahlman 1990; Amit, Brander,

and Zott 1998). Thus, equity-based hybrids are particularly important in situations

where asymmetric information and exchange hazards are especially significant.

Evidence suggests that equity-based financing is more prominent in industries where

exchange hazards as well as informational concerns are important. Such industries

include biotechnology, computer software, and other high-tech industries where

information about both the entrepreneurs and their products is a major concern and

where informational asymmetry is significant in contrast to more routine-based

investments in for example retail outlets and restaurants (Amit, Brander, and Zott

1998; Prowse 1998; Manigart et al. 2002). The latter may be more easily monitored

by conventional non-equity based financial intermediaries, such as conventional

banks, and does not require an expensive setup of equity finance (Amit, Brander, and

Zott 1998). Thus on top of the formal contractual aspects of equity finance, the

relational embeddedness between transacting parties allows the investor and the

entrepreneur to transfer fine-grained information and allows for joint problem solving

arrangements. Moreover, combining this with the aspect of investment rounds makes

this form of governance a possible mechanism at this stage of new venture finance.

Conclusion and perspectives

Except in the market type of transaction, entrepreneurs as well as new ventures

benefit from the individual dyadic relationships to investors through the development

of trust and the possible transfer of fine-grained information. However, using social

relations as a way to disclose private information and mitigate problems of

Page 171: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

171

opportunism is not without costs in terms of time and resources (Burt 1992; Larson

1992; Das and Teng 1998; Poppo and Zenger 2002). Thus, the entrepreneur should

invest in the development of relational governance only when significant exchange

hazards in terms of active specificity, uncertainty, and measurement difficulty are

present. Using the hierarchy in every circumstance then is to incur costs that are not

necessary in relation to the transactional characteristics. The cost of maintaining this

relational embeddedness should then be treated as the cost of fiat as in the transaction

cost framework. Thus, in order to obtain the optimal form of governance given the

relational, transactional, and behavioral characteristics of an exchange, we need to

balance the relational cost with the cost of using formal contractual mechanisms.

Moreover, as suggested in this paper the ability to obtain finance is primarily related

to the characteristics of the entrepreneur’s personal network as well as the networking

activities of the entrepreneur. The typical pecking order suggests that in the initial

stages of finance, the entrepreneur need to rely on what we have been referring to as

personal trust contrary to calculated trust. Indeed, the underlying transaction between

the investor and the entrepreneur in this phase is not the investment in the new

venture, but an investment in a personal relationship. Moreover, it has been suggested

that personal networks characterized by strong ties and cohesiveness are favorable in

this endeavor. The next step according to the pecking order is what was referred to as

low-risk market governance. This particular step relied heavily on collateral, which is

especially problematic for new ventures with few tangible assets. However, this

particular mode of governance typically does not require specific network

characteristics or individual characteristics but instead rely on institutional

characteristics outside the scope of the individual.

Following the collateralized stage of finance, the pecking order suggests that new

ventures primarily rely on short- and long-term bank loans referred to as non-equity

hybrid governance. Even though exchange hazards in this stage of new venture

finance is still high it is suggested that an embedded relationship with the bank (or

banker) has the potential to reduce some of these hazards through increased

information sharing and hence better credit availability. This particular form of

Page 172: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

172

governance suggests the importance of embedded ties with the banker. Finally, the

last stage of the pecking order for new firms is what is referred to as an equity-based

hybrid. It was suggested that on top of the formal contractual aspects of equity

finance, the relational embeddedness between the entrepreneur and the equity investor

allows the investor and the entrepreneur to transfer fine-grained information and

allows for joint problem solving arrangements. Moreover, combining this with the

aspect of investment rounds makes this form of governance a possible mechanism

even though the exchange hazards are still relatively high. Then once again the

importance of embedded ties and personal networking is manifested in the available

governance mechanisms in new venture finance.

Page 173: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

173

References

Adler, P. S., ”Market, hierarchy, and trust: The knowledge economy and the future of capitalism,” Organization Science 12 (2): 215-234 (2001).

Alchain, A and H. Demsetz, ”Production, information costs, and economic organization,” American Economic Review 62: 777-795 (1972).

Aldrich, H. E. and M. C. Fiol, ”Fools rush in? The institutional context of industry creation,” Acadamy of Management Review 19: 645-670 (1993).

Amit, R., J. Brander, and C. Zott, ”Why do venture capital firms exist? Theory and Canadian evidence,” Journal of Business Venturing 13 (6): 441-466 (1998).

Amit, R., J. Brander, and C. Zott. 2000. Venture capital financing of entrepreneurship: Theory, empirical evidence and a research agenda. In Handbook of Entrepreneurship. Edited by D. Sexton and H. Landström. Blackwell Publishers Ltd.

Amit, R., L. Glosten, and E. Muller, ”Entrepreneurial Ability, Venture Investments, and Risk Sharing,” Management Science 36 (10): 1232-1245 (1990).

Avery, R. B., R. W. Bostic, and K. A. Samolyk, ”The role of personal wealth in small business finance,” Journal of Banking and Finance 22: 1019-1061 (1998).

Balakrishnan, S. and B. Wernerfelt, ”Technical change, competition, and vertical integration,” Strategic Management Journal 7: 347-359 (1986).

Barzel, Y., ”Measurement costs and the organization of markets,” Journal of Law Economics & Organization 25: 27-48 (1982).

Berger, A. N. and G. F. Udell, ”The economies of small business finance: The roles of private equity and debt markets in the financial growth cycle,” Journal of Banking and Finance 22: 613-676 (1998).

Berggren, B., C. Olofsson and L. Silver, “Control aversion and the search for external financing in Swedish SMEs”, Small Business Economics 15(3), 233-42 (2000).

Bhide, A., ”The Art of Start-Ups,” Harvard Buisness Review 70 (6): 109-117 (1992).

Binks, M.R., Ennew, C.T. "The relationship between UK banks and their small business customers", Small Business Economics, Vol. 9 pp.167-78 (1997).

Bradach, Jeffrey and Robert G. Eccles, ”Price, authority, and trust: From ideal types to plural forms,” Annu.Rev.Sociol. 15: 97-118 (1989).

Page 174: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

174

Brau, J. C., ”Do Banks Price Owner-Manager Agency Costs? An Examination of Small Business Borrowing,” Journal of Small Business Management 40 (4): 273-286 (2002).

Burt, R. S. 1992. Structural holes the social structure of competition. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

Bygrave, W. D. and J. A. Timmons. 1992. Venture Capital at the Crossroads. Boston MA: Harvard Business School Press.

Cable, D. M. and S. Shane, ”A prisoner’s dilemma approach to entrepreneur-venture capitalist relationships,” Acadamy of Management Review 22 (1): 142-176 (1997).

Coleman, J. S. 1990. Foundations of social theory. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

Cosh, A. and A. Hughes, 1994, Size, financial structure and profitability: UK companies in the 1980s, in A. Hughes and D. J. Storey, eds., Finance and the small firm (Routledge, London).

Das, T. K. and B. S. Teng, ”Between trust and control: Developing confidence in partner cooperation in alliances,” Academy of Management Review 23 (3): 491-512 (1998).

Demsetz, H., ”The theory of the firm revisited,” Journal of Law Economics & Organization 4: 141-162 (1988).

DiMaggio, P. and H. Louch. “Socially Embedded Consumer Transactions: For What Kinds of Purchases do People Most Often Use Networks?”, American Sociological Review, 63 (5), 619-637 (1998).

Dunkelberg, W. C., ”Credit, banks and small business in America,” Journal of Banking and Finance 22: 1085-1088 (1998).

Dyer, J. H. and H. Singh, ”The relational view: Cooperative strategy and sources of interorganizational competitive advantage,” Academy of Management Review 23 (4): 660-679 (1998).

Ebben, J. and A. Johnson, ”Bootstrapping in small firms: An empirical analysis of change over time,” Journal of Business Venturing 21 (6): 851-865 (2006).

Ehrlich, S. B. et al., ”After the Cash Arrives – A Comparative-Study of Venture Capital and Private Investor Involvement in Entrepreneurial Firms,” Journal of Business Venturing 9 (1): 67-82 (1994).

Eisenhardt, K. M., ”Agency Theory: an assessment and review,” Acadamy of Management Review 14: 57-74 (1989).

Page 175: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

175

Fluck, Z., D. Holtz-Eakin, and H. Rosen, ”Where Does The Money Come From? The Financing of Small Entrepreneurial Enterprises,” Metropolitan Studies Program Series Occasional Paper No. 191 (1998).

Fried, V. H., G. D. Bruton, and R. D. Hisrich, ”Strategy and the board of directors in venture capital-backed firms,” Journal of Business Venturing 13 (6): 493-503 (1998).

Ghoshal, S. and P. Moran, ”Bad for practice: A critique of the transaction cost theory,” Academy of Management Review 21 (1): 13-47 (1996).

Gompers, P. A., ”Optimal investment, monitoring, and the staging of ventre capital,” Journal of Finance 50: 1461-1489 (1995).

Gorman, M. and W. A. Sahlman, ”What do Venture Capitalists do,” Journal of Business Venturing 4 (4): 231-248 (1989).

Granovetter, M. S., ”Economic action and social structure: The problem of embeddedness,” American Journal of Sociology 91: 481-510 (1985).

Gulati, R., ”Does Familiarity Breed Trust? The Implications of Repeated Ties for Contractual Choice in Alliances,” Academy of Management Journal 38 (1): 85-112 (1995).

Gulati, R., ”Alliances and networks,” Strategic Management Journal 19 (4): 293-317 (1998).

Gulati, R., N. Nohria, and A. Zaheer, ”Strategic networks,” Strategic Management Journal 21 (3): 203-215 (2000).

Gulati, R. and H. Singh, ”The architecture of cooperation: Managing coordination costs and appropriation concerns in strategic alliances,” Administrative Science Quarterly 43 (4): 781-814 (1998).

Harrison, R. T., C. M. Mason, and P. Girling, ”Financial bootstrapping and venture development in the software industry,” Entrepreneurship and Regional Development 16 (4): 307-333 (2004).

Heide, J. B. and G. John, ”Alliances in Industrial Purchasing: The Determinants of Joint Action in Buyer-Supplier Relationships,” Journal of Marketing Research 27 (1): 24-36 (1990).

Hellmann, T. and M. Puri, ”Venture Capital and the Professionalization of Start-up Firms: Empirical Evidence,” Journal of Finance 57 (1): 169-197 (2002).

Holmes, S. and P. Kent, ”An empirical analysis of the Financial Structure of Small and Large Australian Manufacturing Enterprises,” The Journal of Small Business Finance 1 (2): 141-154 (1991).

Page 176: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

176

Jensen, M. C. and W. H. Meckling, ”Theory of Firm – Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure,” Journal of Financial Economics 3 (4): 305-360 (1976).

Joskow, P., ”Asset specificity and the structure of vertical relationships: empirical evidence,” Journal of Law Economics & Organization 4: 95-118 (1988).

Kale, P., H. Singh, and H. Perlmutter, ”Learning and protection of proprietary assets in strategic alliances: Building relational capital,” Strategic Management Journal 21 (3): 217-237 (2000).

Larson, A., ”Network dyads in entrepreneurial settings: a study of the governance of exchange relationships,” Administrative Science Quarterly 37: 76-104 (1992).

Lazzarini, S. G., G. J Miller, and T. Zenger, ”Order with some law: Complementarity versus substitution of formal and informal arrangements,” Journal of Law Economics & Organization 20 (2): 261-298 (2004).

Lee, C., K. Lee, and J. M. Pennings, ”Internal capabilities, external networks, and performance: A study on technology-based ventures,” Strategic Management Journal 22 (6-7): 615-640 (2001).

Luhmann, N. 1979. Trust and Power. Chichester, New York: Wiley.

Lui, S. S. and H. Y. Ngo, ”The role of trust and contractual safeguards on cooperation in non-equity alliances,” Journal of Management 30 (4): 471-485 (2004).

Lumme, A., C. Mason, and M. Suomi. 1998. Informal venture capital: Investors, Investments and Policy issues in Finland. Dordrecht, Netherlands: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

Luo, Y. D., ”Contract, cooperation, and performance in international joint ventures,” Strategic Management Journal 23 (10): 903-919 (2002).

MacMillan, I. C., D. M. Kulow, and R. Khoylian, ”Venture Capitalists Involvement in Their Investments – Extent and Performance,” Journal of Business Venturing 4 (1): 27-47 (1989).

Macneil, I. R. 1980. The new social contract. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

Malhotra, D. and J. K. Murnighan, ”The effects of contracts on interpersonal trust,” Administrative Science Quarterly 47 (3): 534-559 (2002).

Manigart, S. et al., ”Determinants of required return in venture capital investments: a five-country study,” Journal of Business Venturing 17 (4): 291-312 (2002).

Manigart, S. and H. Sapienza. 2000. Venture capital and growth. In Handbook of Entrepreneurship. Edited by D. Sexton and H. Landström. Blackwell Publishers Ltd.

Page 177: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

177

March, J. G. and J. P. Olson (1989). The New Institutionalism: Organizational Factors in Political Life. New York: The Free Press.

Mason, C. and R. Harrison. 1994. Informal venture capital in the UK. In Finance and the Small Firm. Edited by A. Hughes and D. J. Storey. London: Routledge.

Mason, C. and R. Harrison. 2000. Informal Venture Capital and the Financing of Emergent Growth Businesses. In The Blackwell Handbook of the Entrepreneurship. Edited by D. Sexton and H. Landström. Blackwell Publishers.

Masten, S. E., ”A legal basis for the firm,” Journal of Law Economics & Organization 4 (spring): 181-198 (1988).

Meyer, L. H., ”The presbet and future roles of banks in small business finance,” Journal of Banking and Finance 22: 1109-1116 (1998).

Moore, B. 1994. Financial constraints to the growth and development of small high technology firms. In Finance and the Small Firm. Edited by A. Hughes and D. J. Storey. London: Routledge.

Nooteboom, B., Berger, H. and Noorderhaven, N.G ”Effects of trust and governance on relational risk.” Academy of Management Journal, Vol. 40, No.2, 308-338. (1997).

Norton, E., ”Capital Structure and Small Public Firms,” Journal of Business Venturing 6 (4): 287-303 (1991).

Petersen, M. and R. Rajan, ”The Benefit of lending relationships: Evidence from Small Business Data,” Journal of Finance 49 (2): 3-37 (1994).

Pisano, G. P., ”Using equity participation to support exchange: Evidence from the biotechnology industry,” Journal of Law Economics & Organization 5 (1): 109-126 (1989).

Podolny, J. M., ”Networks as the pipes and prisms of the market,” American Journal of Sociology 107 (1): 33-60 (2001).

Poppo, L. and T. Zenger, ”Testing alternative theories of the firm: transaction cost, knowledge-based, and measurement explanations for make-or-buy decisions in information services,” Strategic Management Journal 19 (9): 853-877 (1998).

Poppo, L. and T. Zenger, ”Do formal contracts and relational governance function as substitutes or complements?,” Strategic Management Journal 23 (8): 707-725 (2002).

Page 178: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

178

Prowse, S., ”Angel investors and the market for angel investments,” Journal of Banking & Finance 22: 785-792 (1998).

Ring, P. S. and A. H. Van de Ven, ”Structuring cooperative relationships between organizations,” Strategic Management Journal 13: 483-498 (1992).

Ring, P. S. and A. H. Van de Ven, ”Development processes of cooperative interorganizational relationships,” Acadamy of Management Review 19: 90-118 (1994).

Rowley, T., D. Behrens, and D. Krackhardt, ”Redundant governance structures: An analysis of structural and relational embeddedness in the steel and semiconductor industries,” Strategic Management Journal 21 (3): 369-386 (2000).

Sahlman, W., ”The structure and governance of Venture Capital Organizations,” Journal of Financial Economics 27: 473-521 (1990).

Sapienza, H. J., S. Manigart, and W. Vermier, ”Venture capitalist governance and value added in four countries,” Journal of Business Venturing 11 (6): 439-469 (1996).

Scherr, F. C., T. Sugrue, and J. Ward, ”Financing the Small Firm Start-Up: Determinants of debt use,” The Journal of Small Business Finance 3 11): 17-36 (1993).

Scholtens, B., ”Analytical Issues in External Financing Alternatives for SBEs,” Small Business Economics 12: 137-148 (1999).

Slovin, M. B., M. E. Sushka, and A. Polonchek, ”The value of bank durability: Borrowers as bank stakeholders,” Journal of Finance 42: 863-872 (1993).

Stuart, T. E., H. Hoang, and R. C. Hybels, ”Interorganizational endorsements and the performance of entrepreneurial ventures,” Administrative Science Quarterly 44 (2): 315-349 (1999).

Thornton, P. H., ”The sociology of entrepreneurship,” Annu.Rev.Sociol. 25: 19-46 (1999).

Uzzi, B., ”Social structure and competition in interfirm networks: The paradox of embeddedness,” Administrative Science Quarterly 42 (1): 35-67 (1997).

Uzzi, B., ”Embeddedness in the making of financial capital,” American Sociological Review 64: 481-505 (1999).

Verheul, I. and R. Thurik, ”Start-Up Capital: ”Does Gender Matter?”,” Small Business Economics 16: 329-345 (2001).

Page 179: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

179

Walker, G., B. Kogut, and W. J. Shan, ”Social capital, structural holes and the formation of an industry network,” Organization Science 8 (2): 109-125 (1997).

Williamson, O. E. 1975. Markets and hierarchies, analysis and antitrust implications a study in the economics of internal organization. New York: Free Press.

Williamson, O. E., ”Transaction-cost economics: the governance of contractual relations,” The Journal of Law and Economics 22: 3-61 (1979).

Williamson, O. E. 1985. The economic institutions of capitalism firms, markets, relational contracting. New York, London: Free Press. Collier Macmillan.

Williamson, O. E., ”Comparative Economic-Organization – the Analysis of Discrete Structural Alternatives,” Administrative Science Quarterly 36 (2): 269-296 (1991).

Williamson, O. E. 1996. The Mechanisms of Governance. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.

Winborg, J. and H. Landstrom, ”Financial bootstrapping in small businesses: Examining small business managers’ resource acquisition behaviors,” Journal of Business Venturing 16 (3): 235-254 (2001).

Wright, M. and K. Robbie, ”Venture capital and Private Equity: A Review and Synthesis,” Journal of Business Finance and Accounting 25 (5&6): 521-570 (1998).

Zaheer, A., B. McEvily, and V. Perrone, ”Does trust matter? Exploring the effects of interorganizational and interpersonal trust on performance,” Organization Science 9 (2): 141-159 (1998).

Page 180: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

180

Dansk resume (Danish summary)

Den første artikel i denne afhandling tager udgangspunkt i forskningen inden for

entrepreneurship som objekt for egen forskning under overskriften: Status blandt

tidsskrifter inden for management og forumet for forskningen inden for

entrepreneurship. Flere studier har forsøgt at sætte forskning inden for

entrepreneurship i relation til management-disciplinen som et svar på spørgsmål om

feltets status og hvorledes entrepreneurship er relateret til centrale videnskabelige

tidsskrifter inden for management. Med afsæt i social netværksmetode søger denne

artikel først at afdække statushierarkiet blandt en lang række tidsskrifter inden for

management, herunder at opdele disse tidsskrifter i klynger. Med udgangspunkt i dette

statushierarki søger artiklen dernæst at finde ud af, hvorledes forskning inden for

entrepreneurship er placeret i forhold til dette statushierarki. Det konkluderes bl.a., at

entrepreneurship har opnået en stigende legitimitet og status i den dominerende

diskurs i management-feltet igennem de sidste 20 år. Særligt inden for gruppen af

generelle management- og sociologi-tidsskrifter har interessen for entrepreneurship

været voksende.

Trods den stigende interesse fremstår feltet imidlertid fragmenteret og

usammenhængende, og ny forskning søges sjældent placeret i forhold til feltets

eksisterende forskningsresultater. Flere akademikere inden for feltet har derfor

argumenteret for, at feltet bør søge mod et fælles enhedsskabende paradigme, der med

epistemologisk, ontologisk og metodologisk ensretning kan styre feltet til en

integreret fælles forståelsesramme. Hvor besnærende en sådan tanke end måtte

fremstå, tvinger genstandsfeltets mange analyseniveauer og enheder, samt

kompleksiteten indenfor disse, feltet til at benytte en bred vifte af ontologier,

epistemologier og metodologier fra en lang række discipliner såsom psykologi,

sociologi og management. I stedet for at søge en indsnævring af feltet søger denne

afhandling at udvide forståelsen og kendskabet til skabelsen af nye virksomheder ved

at præsentere læseren for en systematisk gennemgang af en del af denne litteratur det

beskæftiger sig med – eller er relateret til – skabelsen af nye virksomheder.

Afhandlingen fokuserer på individet som analyseenhed i relation til skabelsen af nye

virksomheder. Hvert individ bringer tre grundlæggende typer af kapital i spil i relation

Page 181: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

181

til andre individer – human kapital, social kapital og finansiel kapital. Denne

afhandling diskuterer følgelig hver af disse typer af kapital i forhold til eksisterende

undersøgelser inden for feltet.

I den første af disse artikler diskuteres aspekter af human kapital i forhold til

skabelsen af nye virksomheder under overskriften: ”En revitalisering af

personlighedstræktilgangen som komplementær til den kognitive tilgang under ny

virksomhedsskabelse”. Hovedpåstanden i denne artikel er, at introduktionen af

processen i skabelsen af nye virksomheder som en kontingens kan genoplive

personlighedstræktilgangen indenfor feltet, der ellers har været udskældt som følge af

manglende empirisk gyldighed. Der argumenteres for, at denne manglende gyldighed

primært skyldes at personlighedstræk i overvejende grad, er blevet testet på

entrepreneurer i allerede eksisterende virksomheder, med en implicit antagelse om at

personlighedstræk er stabile under hele den entrepreneurielle skabelsesproces. Som et

resultat af den manglende empiriske gyldighed har dele af feltet forkastet hele

personlighedstræktraditionen til fordel for en kognitiv tilgang. Artiklen søger

efterfølgende at vise hvorledes de to tilgangen er komplementære og at de

repræsenterer forskellige faser og aspekter i skabelsen af nye virksomheder.

I den næste af disse artikler diskuteres aspekter af social kapital i forhold til skabelsen

af nye virksomheder under overskriften: ”Personlige netværk i forskellige faser i

skabelsen af nye virksomheder”. En gennemlæsning af litteraturen om personlige

netværkskarakteristika viser, at feltet er delt i to lejre såvel empirisk som teoretisk.

Den ene lejr finder teoretiske og empiriske argumenter for, at tætte netværk er

fordelagtige i forbindelse med den nødvendige ressourcefrembringelse i skabelsen af

nye virksomheder, hvorimod den anden lejr peger på vigtigheden af løse personlige

netværk i forhold til mulighedsidentifikation. Artiklen peger dels på, at vigtigheden af

tætte versus løse sociale netværk afhænger af, hvilken fase den nye virksomhed

befinder sig i, dels at tætte sociale netværk ligeledes er vigtige i forbindelse med

mulighedsidentifikation, såvel som løse sociale netværk kan være vigtige i

frembringelsen af ressourcer.

Page 182: CAPITAL FORMS AND THE ENTREPRENEUR - A contingency approach on …pure.au.dk/portal/files/98249623/cthranejensen.pdf · 2016-03-08 · Aarhus), especially Lone Niedziella and Annette

182

I den sidste artikel diskuteres aspekter af finansiel kapital i forhold til skabelsen af nye

virksomheder under overskriften: ”Governance-mekanismer i

finansieringsrækkefølgen af nye virksomheder”. Relationen mellem entrepreneur og

investor ses som en transaktion mellem to parter, og artiklen udvikler en taksonomi,

der søger at svare på, hvor og hvordan en transaktion skal reguleres under forskellige

transaktionskarakteristika. To overordnede kontraktformer identificeres – den ene er

baseret på kontraktuel regulering og den anden er baseret på relationel regulering,

hvor der i sidstnævnte sondres mellem relationel regulering med udgangspunkt i

personlig tillid versus kalkuleret tillid. Disse reguleringsformer relateres til de typiske

finansielle kilder for nye virksomheder, og der argumenteres for, at kontraktuel

regulering er optimal ved lav transaktionsusikkerhed, hvorimod relationel regulering

med afsæt i personlig tillid mellem parterne er optimal ved høj

transaktionsusikkerhed. Endelig relateres denne referenceramme til den typiske

finansieringsrækkefølge for nye virksomheder.