Buckland Neoliberal PE War

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    1/46

    Neoliberalism and the Political Economy of War

    By Bruce K. Guenther

    60.4100/3 Senior Seminar in International Development Studies

    Jerry Buckland

    Menno Simons CollegeUniversity of Winnipeg

    April 15, 2005

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    2/46

    2

    Neoliberalism and the Political Economy of War

    If somebody hides a thing behind a bush, seeks it again and finds it in the selfsame place, then there is notmuch to boast of, respecting this seeking and finding; thus, however matters stand with the seeking and

    finding of truth within the realm of reason. Friedrich Nietzshe, On Truth and Lie in an Extra-Moral

    Sense, 1911

    Violence always rides on the back of lies. Stanley Hauerwas, 2004

    Chapter 1: Neoliberalism SAPs and Conflict

    Though the topic of this essay is quite broad, its thesis emerges out of my

    practicum experience working for a human rights organization, Jamaicans for Justice, in

    Kingston, Jamaica. The main area of focus during my one year term through Mennonite

    Central Committee was responding to complaints of human rights violations by the state

    (i.e. police, military, prison officials). Dealing daily with the cycle of violence in Jamaica

    caused me to ask questions about the source of this pervasive violence.

    Though there are a variety of root causes associated with Jamaicas poverty and

    violence including the legacy of colonialism and the plantation system, many Kingston

    inner-city residents point to the 1970s as a time when a large shift occurred.1 In the 1970s

    to 1980s, the conditionality of Structural Adjustment Programs (SAPs) imposed by

    organizations such as the International Monetary Fund (IMF) shifted economic and social

    burdens on the poor through layoffs and less investment in social services.2 For inner-

    city residents this time period was characterized by a sharp increase in the cost of living

    (due to high inflation and currency devaluation) as well as high unemployment. 3 One

    1 Horace Levy, They Cry 'Respect'!: Urban Violence and Poverty in Jamaica, (Kingston, Jamaica:

    Centre for Population, Community and Social Change, University of the West Indies, 1996), 10.2 Anthony Harriott,Police and Crime Control: Problems of Reforming Ex-Colonial

    Constabularies, (Kingston, Jamaica: The University of the West Indies Press, 2000), 3.3 Levy, They Cry 'Respect'!: Urban Violence and Poverty in Jamaica,, 10. For an excellent

    documentary on the affects of the SAPs on Jamaica, see Life and Debt by Stephanie Black (New Yorker

    Video), 2001.

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    3/46

    3

    Jamaican academic, Anthony Harriot, describes SAPs as a globally dominant neoliberal

    paradigm which associates inequality and individualism with efficiency and economic

    progress.4 This neoliberal paradigm, through cuts in government spending, currency

    devaluation, trade and finance liberalization, caused polarization between the rich and the

    poor in Jamaica.5

    According to Harriot, this deregulation of the economy in Jamaica has a

    tendency towards rent-seeking rather than wealth creating activities. The consequence of

    this increased marginalization and inequality has generated powerful, socially

    destructive tendencies and induced the use of greater (but ineffective) coercive force by a

    weakened state in support of this mode of development.

    6

    Through studying the

    pervasive violence in Jamaica, he concluded that this high level of inequality and

    competitive individualism are associated with high rates of violent crime.7 It is this

    observation by both Jamaican academics and inner-city residents regarding the

    correlation between increases in violence and neoliberalism which has spurred me to

    further explore these linkages.

    Using a global political economy approach which attempts to analyze the power

    embedded in economic relationships, this essay will argue that neoliberal policies rather

    than fostering peace and prosperity, have actually created global instability by fuelling

    armed conflict. This happened in three significant ways: 1) the increasing influence of

    transnational corporations, 2) the widening of income inequality and 3) the dismantling

    of the state.

    4 Harriott,Police and Crime Control: Problems of Reforming Ex-Colonial Constabularies,, 4.5 Patrick Bryan,Inside Out and Outside In: Factors in the Creation of Contemporary Jamaica,

    (Kingston, Jamaica: Grace Kennedy Foundation, 2000), 81.6 Harriott,Police and Crime Control: Problems of Reforming Ex-Colonial Constabularies,

    xxviii..7 ibid., 4.

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    4/46

    4

    This is an essay about the causes of armed conflict, but I must be clear about what

    I am and am not saying. My argument is that neoliberalism and its policies such as

    Structural Adjustment Programs have in many cases engendered and fueled conflict. The

    intention of this paper is not to gloss over historical and contextual particularities but

    rather to explore the ways in which neoliberalism feeds armed conflict in the Global

    South. Nationalist, independence, political and ideological struggles, ethnic and religious

    divisions, as well as other historical grievances and marginalization, all play a role in

    contemporary conflict. Yet, it is my contention that often contemporary conflicts have

    more to do with struggles over resources and are thus related to neoliberal economic

    globalization.8

    In John Bowens article, The Myth of Global Ethnic Conflict, he argues

    that when conflict gets pinned on religious or ethnic differences we see those in conflict

    as tribal and less modern, making it easier for us to tolerate suffering because conflict

    is natural of a people or region: it distracts us from the central and difficult question of

    just how and why people are sometimes led to commit such horrifying deeds.9

    However, the North is involved in this process of neoliberal globalization often

    benefiting from this new imperialism. While benefiting the North, neoliberal policies

    continue to allow for the exploitation and marginalization of already peripheral regions

    causing further suffering and violence.

    It is also important to clarify that my intention is not to replace one universal

    claim for another that is, while neoliberal policies have been implemented in a one size

    fits all fashion, my argument is not that in every instance neoliberalism has led to

    8 John R. Bowen, "The myth of global ethnic conflict," Journal of Democracy 7, no. 4 (1996): 3.9 ibid.

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    5/46

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    6/46

    6

    approaches. Despite widespread criticism of these policies, these market-friendly

    reforms continue to be advocated by the international financial institutions.

    In the second chapter of this essay, the global political economy framework will

    be presented. This will be followed by the third chapter, where through using a political

    economy lens, we will analyze how neoliberalism has contributed to armed conflict. The

    fourth chapter will conclude with a reflection on neoliberal hegemony. Despite the

    narrowness of this pure economic approach for development and peace-building,

    proponents still point to the rationalism of neoliberal policies. Unfortunately, in many

    cases, the continual aggrandizement of market driven development breeds and fuels

    violence and conflict around the world.

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    7/46

    7

    Chapter 2: Global Political Economy

    The beginning of the global political economy discourse can be traced back to an

    influential article by Susan Strange entitled International Economics and International

    Relations: A Case of Mutual Neglect where she notes that there has been little

    interaction between the disciplines of international relations (politics) and economics.11

    Strange notes that a lack of developing a study of international political economy at the

    university is allowing the gulf between international economics and international

    politics to grow yearly wider and deeper and more unbridgeable than ever.12

    Martin

    Staniland, in outlining the political economy discussion states that the study of political

    economy generally arises out of the radically incompatible perspectives of economics and

    political science with economics (in its classical/neoclassical sense) emphasizing market

    and with politics emphasizing power: the assumptions and working logics of economics

    cannot easily accommodate, except as externalities, the phenomenon of coercive power,

    since they rest on the axiom of the freely choosing individual.13

    Recent literature also points to a continued lack of cooperation between

    disciplines, particularly between international development studies and economics. John

    Harris in his article The Case for Cross-Disciplinary Approaches in International

    Development, indicates that this cooperation between disciplines, as in the case of

    global political economy, is essential in order to save disciplines from themselves.14

    Harris points to the limitations of an economic methodology which is based on an

    11 Susan Strange, "International Economics and International Relations: A Case of Mutual

    Neglect," International Affairs (Royal Institute of International Affairs 1944-) 46, no. 2 (1970): 304-315.12 ibid., 307.13 Martin Staniland, What is Political Economy?: A Study of Social Theory and

    Underdevelopment, (New Haven, CO: Yale University Press, 1985), 4.14 John Harris, "The Case for Cross-Disciplinary Approaches in International Development,"

    World Development30, no. 3 (2002): 487.

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    8/46

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    9/46

    9

    traditional approaches to the discipline of international relations or, indeed, economics.19

    Recently however, a number of economics scholars have stated that political economy

    itself is just a methodology of formal economics that falls within the rational actor

    model; this is obviously inadequate in that it once again marginalizes political and non-

    economic factors.20

    In contrast, Robert Cox notes that the contribution of political

    economy has highlighted economic foundations of power.21 Political Economy or Global

    Political Economy, has not merely expanded the subject matter of international relations

    but has changed the way we think about power and the world order.22

    In discussing political economy, the literature typically compares it to three

    different theoretical frameworks: realism, liberalism and Marxism.23

    The realist tradition in international relations theory focuses primarily on the

    competition between state actors.24 Realism believes that nation-states pursue power and

    shape the economy to this end. Unlike Marxists and liberals, realists assume the primacy

    of politics over economics: the state is the dominant actor in the global political

    economy.25 For Realists, politics underlies economics. In the pursuit of power, nation-

    states shape the international economy to best serve their desired ends.26 The

    19 Geoffrey R. D. Underhill, "Conceptualizing the Changing Global Order," in Political Economy

    and the Changing Global Order, ed. Richard Stubbs and Geoffrey R.D. Underhill. (Toronto, ON: Oxford

    University Press, 2000), 3-21.20 Gilpin, The Nature of Political Economy, 1021 Robert W. Cox, "Political Economy and World Order: Problems of Power and Knowledge at

    the Turn of the Millenium," in Political Economy and the Changing Global Order, ed. Richard Stubbs and

    Geoffrey R.D. Underhill. (Toronto, ON: Oxford University Press, 2000), 32.22 ibid., 32.23 See Jeffry A. Frieden and David A. Lake, "International Politics and International Economics,"

    inInternational Political Economy: State-Market Relations in a Changing Global Order, ed. Goddard, C.

    Roe, Patrick Cronin and Kishore C. Dash. (Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2003), 25-7.;Underhill, Conceptualizing the Changing Global Order, 3-21.; Staniland, What is Political Economy?: A

    Study of Social Theory and Underdevelopment, 229.24 Underhill, Conceptualizing the Changing Global Order, 3-21., 9.25 Frieden and Lake,International Politics and International Economics, 30.26 ibid., 31

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    10/46

    10

    international system is anarchical under which nation-states are sovereign and, through

    rational self-interested actions, states maintain a balance of power. This stark

    separation between the political and economic factors contrasts a global political

    economy perspective which understands those spheres to be an integrated whole.27

    Security becomes the primary issue from a Realist perspective which clashes with a

    global political economy approach where security has just as much to do with economic

    factors of who gets what, when and how.28 In summary, realism is inadequate as it

    attempts to divorce the interplay between the state and the economy.

    A liberal approach, in contrast to the realist perspective, sees the individual, not

    the state, as the primary actor in society. Liberalism is thus permeated with a concern

    for enhancing the freedom and welfare of individuals; it proposes that humankind can

    employ reason better to develop a sense of harmony of interest among individual and

    groups within the wider community, domestic or international.29 The liberal approach

    assumes that individuals are rational, utility maximizing actors making cost-benefit

    calculations across a wide range of possible options. Individuals maximize their utility

    when they choose the result which yields the highest rate of subjective satisfaction.30 The

    interaction between individuals occurs within the economic sphere. If individuals are

    free to interact as economic agents, this will ensure the most beneficial distribution of

    wealth.31 The state exists primarily to facilitate the free exchange of goods between

    individuals within the market.32 At first glance, liberalism seems diametrically opposed

    27 Underhill, Conceptualizing the Changing Global Order, 10.28 ibid., 11.29 ibid., 13.30 Frieden and Lake,International Politics and International Economics, 26.31 Underhill, Conceptualizing the Changing Global Order, 13.32 Frieden and Lake,International Politics and International Economics, 27.

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    11/46

    11

    to realism however they share the same problematic assumption: that the realm of politics

    and economics are separate and governed by their own laws and relationships.33 Markets

    cannot be separated from the political institutions in which they exist and are formed.

    Moreover, one cannot understand the behaviour of economic agents outside of their

    particular socio-political location and their particular historical developments.34

    A neoliberal strategy flows logically from the liberal framework. Neoliberalism

    sees actions of the state as a market distortion which inhibits economic growth.

    Neoliberalism, as outlined in chapter 1, is characterized by the rise of transnational

    capital, the decline of the state and emphasis on global market-friendly policies.

    35

    Neoliberalism has become the dominant paradigm thus representing the context for our

    discussion of the global political economy of war.

    Marxism emerged as a response to liberalism in the late 19th century. Karl Marx

    developed a new discourse where capitalism and the market were seen as creating

    extremes of wealth for capitalists and poverty for workers.36 The basis of the capitalist

    economy is the exploitation of labour for the sake of capital. According to Marx

    capitalism is an inherently conflictual system that will be overthrown and replaced by the

    classless society.37 From a political economy perspective the principal strength of the

    Marxist approach, as opposed to that of liberalism and realism, is that it focuses

    precisely on the connection between the social and economic structures of the capitalist

    33 Underhill, Conceptualizing the Changing Global Order, 13.34 ibid., 14.35 See Jorge Nef and Wilder Robles, "Globalization, Neoliberalism, and the State of

    Underdevelopment in the New Periphery," Journal of Developing Socities 16, no. 1 (2000): 27-21.36 Frieden and Lake,International Politics and International Economics, 25-7., 28.37 ibid., 27

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    12/46

    12

    economic system, on the one hand and the exercise of the political power in the

    international system, on the other.38

    Just as Marxism arose in response to liberalism, the Dependency school arose

    alongside and in response to modernization theory articulated most clearly by Walt W.

    Rostow.39

    Dependency theorists postulated that development is not simply dependent on

    a countrys endowments and the ability of the economy to take off; rather, development

    and underdevelopment is determined by relationships of power. According to

    Dependency theory, development, or a lack of, is a product of those who set the rules of

    the international economic game: industrialized nations (the core/metropolis) expand at

    the expense of the developing world (the periphery/satellite).40

    What Marxism, Dependency and Neo-Marxist approaches contribute to the

    political economy approach is how intimately power is tied up with economic

    globalization. These approaches take into account the complex interdependence among

    states, their societies, and economic structures at domestic and global levels of analysis. 41

    It is in not questioning these global structures of power, where many approaches to

    development and peace-building fall short. A political economy approach sees power

    embedded in both economic and political spheres.

    It is thus interesting to look at approaches that have emerged as a result of

    widespread criticism of the neoliberal agenda. Doug Porter and Patrick Craig argue that

    neoliberalism has moved beyond its more market phase (as through Structural

    38 Underhill, Conceptualizing the Changing Global Order, 14.39 See Rostow, The Stages of Economic Growth: A Non-Communist Manifesto, 93. Though

    Rostow was a strong advocate of the linear growth model, he differs from neoliberals in that his approach is

    remains quite state-driven.40 Patrice Franko, The Puzzle of Latin American Economic Development, 2nded. (New York, NY:

    Rowman and Littlefield Publishers Inc., 2002), 53 & 74.41 Underhill, Conceptualizing the Changing Global Order, 19.

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    13/46

    13

    Adjustment Programmes) and has turned toward embedding, legitimizing and securing

    liberal reform by promoting an inclusive liberalism.42 In reaction to widespread

    distrust and angst toward neoliberal globalization, inclusive liberalism seeks to cloak its

    market policies under the veil of poverty alleviation, security, and participation. 43

    Instead of questioning the current power and exploitive nature of the current market

    system, like Marxists and radical political economy approaches, this liberal

    inclusiveness recommends policies which attempt to tweak and manage economic

    globalization (i.e. good governance and democratization).

    The Human Security approach, made popular by persons such as Lloyd

    Axworthy, is a good example of a theory firmly grounded in liberal thought which

    appeases our desire for more human globalization but does not question the underlying

    assumptions of liberalism and neoliberal economic globalization.44 Inclusive liberal

    strategies such as human security, represent a temporary pre-emptive, strategic

    inoculation, against a more broadly and socially contested double movement, the kind of

    political double movement arguably most feared by proponents of a wider liberal

    project.45 Liberalism, as articulated earlier, refuses to acknowledge the power dynamics

    and interconnectedness of the economy and the political environment in which it exists.

    Liberal perspectives are not alone in refusing to question fundamental

    assumptions, but a political economy framework can also fall into this trap. Though

    42 Doug Porter and David Craig, "The Third Way and the Third World: Poverty Reduction and

    Social Inclusion in the Rise of 'Inclusive' Liberalism," Review of International Political Economy 11, no. 2

    (2004): 390.43 ibid., 392.44 See Sakiko Fukuda-Parr, "New Threats to Human Security in the Era of Globalization," Journal

    of Human Development4, no. 2 (2003): 167.; Lloyd Axworthy, "Human Security and Global Governance:

    Putting People First," Global Governance 7, no. 1 (2001): 19.45 Porter and Craig, The Third Way and the Third World: Poverty Reduction and Social Inclusion

    in the Rise of 'Inclusive' Liberalism, 418.

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    14/46

    14

    political economy should be commended for its recognition of the interconnectedness of

    politics and economics, much of the literature falls short in continuing to assume that the

    state is the primary political actor.46 I agree with David Harvey in The New Imperialism

    when he states that, there is considerable evidence that the transition to capitalist

    development was and continues to be vitally contingent upon the stance of the state.

    And that, the development role of the state goes back a long way, keeping the territorial

    and capitalist logics of power always intertwined though not necessarily concordant.47

    Though I would make a departure from Harveys articulation that the only realistic

    answer to the current problems with neoliberalism is the reformulation of state power

    along more interventionist and state lines where the power of financial capital,

    oligopolies and monopolies is curbed.48 This is indeed an outcome that should be

    applauded if realized but it once again places the power of governance in the hands of

    nation-state and inter-national actors, discounting the importance of local communities

    and the political space located therein to make change.

    As articulated in Lydia Herbert-Cheshire and Geoffrey Lawrences essay

    Political Economy and the Challenge of Governance, power should not be relegated to

    state actors but:

    From a Foucauldian governmentality perspective, on the other hand, modernforms of power are seen to occur less through the formal structures of thenation state or for that matter, through supra-national authorities and morethrough a complex network of localized power relations. These relationscannot be reduced to any one way domination of one class by another, but are

    46 See Underhill, Conceptualizing the Changing Global Order, 3-21.; C. Roe Goddard, Patrick

    Cronin, and Kishore C. Dash eds.,International Political Economy: State-Market Relations in a Changing

    Global Order, , 2nd ed. (Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2003), 513.47 David Harvey, The New Imperialism, (New York, NY: Oxford University Press, 2003), 145.48 ibid., 209. This is similar to the critique stated by Porter & Craig.

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    15/46

    15

    made up of shifting alliances between individuals and groups, which fractureand re-form according to different issues and interests.49

    Power does not only lie within the function of the state but rather, power lies also within

    communities who mobilize, take action and embody the ethic that they wish to see in the

    world. The modern state should no longer be seen as the primary locus of where

    processes of change occur.50 This makes possible a new order where civil society or a

    network or organizationspresentrather than represent those interest which represent the

    people.51 This is particularly informative when looking at the political economy of war

    since many, if not the majority, of the political actors within contemporary conflicts are

    non-state actors.

    If political economy looks at the dynamics between the political and economic

    realms, a political economy of war perspective explores the role of economic factors

    which lead to state collapse, give rise to and sustain conflict, and complicate

    peacebuilding.52 A political economy of war perspective allows for a critical look at

    regional linkages and violent cross-border spillover.53 Michael Pugh and Neil Cooper

    acknowledge that traditionally, the effects of globalization and outside economic factors

    have not been considered as causes of conflict but rather conflict is caused by purely

    indigenous factors.54 Rather, globalization and economic and political liberalism are

    49 Lynda Herbert-Cheshire and Geoffrey Lawrence, "Political Economy and the Challenge of

    Governance," Journal of Australian Political Economy 0, no. 50 (2002): 141.50 Kenneth Surin, "Marxism(s) and "The Withering Away of the State"," Social Text, no. 27

    (1990): 35-54.51 ibid.52 Pugh, Michael and Neil Cooper, War Economies in a Regional Context, Challenges of

    Transformation, (Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner, 2004), 1.53 ibid., 2.54 ibid., 2.

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    16/46

    16

    primary causes of contemporary conflict.55 In discussing the political economy of war in

    Sub-Saharan Africa, Cramer notes that now that the classical liberal interpretation of

    war with its assumptions of war as exogenous and wholly negative in its socio-

    economic effects has been overtaken by more nuanced analyses of the dynamics of

    wartime economies and societies, it may well be that this area of research will expand

    productively in coming years.56 In contrast to a neo-classical economic framework (i.e.

    Collier), Cramer advocates for a political economy perspective which takes seriously

    social relations, material conditions, the drive for political power as well as an analysis of

    capital and class formation.

    57

    As already stated, this essay will intend to do just that,

    analyze the ways in which neoliberal policies have contributed to fuelling conflict and

    civil unrest. Through a global political economy framework, this discussion will explore

    three of the mechanisms by which neoliberalism has fueled conflict: the growing power

    of transnational corporations, widening income inequalities and the decline of the state.

    This will be supported by a review of the contemporary literature as well as through

    particular case studies.

    55 Timothy M. Shaw, "Peace-building partnerships and human security," in The Companion toDevelopment Studies, ed. Desai, Vendana and Robert B. Potter. (New York, NY: Oxford University Press,

    2002), 450.56 Chris Cramer, The Economics and Political Economy of Conflict in Sub-Saharan Africa,

    (London, UK: Center for Development Policy & Research, 1999), 20.57 C. Cramer, "Homo Economicus Goes to War: Methodological Individualism, Rational Choice

    and the Political Economy of War," World Development30, no. 11 (2002): 1856. The work of persons

    such as Collier will be discussed further in the next chapter.

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    17/46

    17

    Chapter 3: TNCs, Inequality and the Transformation of the State

    Using this global political economy which looks at the power embedded in

    economic relationships, this chapter will analyze how neoliberal policies rather than

    building peace, foster global instability by fuelling armed conflict. This has happened in

    three significant ways: 1) the increasing role of transnational corporations, 2) the

    widening of income inequality and 3) the dismantling of the state.

    The Rise of Transnational Corporations

    Michael Todaro and Stephen Smith note that few developments have played as

    critical a role in the extraordinary growth of international trade and capital flows during

    the past few decades as the rise of the transnational corporation (TNC).58 As a result of

    neoliberal policies, TNCs are free to move capital as well as goods and services on a

    global scale. Increasing foreign direct investment has been rapid during the past couple

    of decades rising from an annual rate of US$2.4 billion in 1962 to over US$185 billion in

    1999 in constant dollars.59 Recently, the role of TNCs in conflict situations has been

    highlighted by non-governmental organizations including Human Rights Watch,

    Amnesty International, Global Witness and International Alert.60 This private sector

    activity, both licit and illicit, is a significant factor influencing the shape and intensity of

    many conflicts.61 Recently, UN Secretary-General Kofi Annan pointed out the ways in

    which armed groups use TNCs to their benefit in a report to the Security Council on

    armed conflict:

    58 Todaro and Smith,Economic Development, 635.59 ibid.60 See www.amnesty.org, www.hrw.org, www.globalwitness.org, and www.internation-alert.org .61 Jessica Banfield, Virginia Haufler, and Damian Lilly, Transnational Corporations in Conflict

    Prone Zones: Public Policy Responses and a Framework for Action, (London, UK: International Alert,

    2003), 1-89.

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    18/46

    18

    The impact of the pursuit of economic interests in conflict areas hascome under increasingly critical scrutiny. Corporations have beenaccused of complicity with human rights abuses, and corporate tieshave continued to fuel civil wars. It has become commonknowledge that by selling diamonds and other valuable minerals,

    belligerents can supply themselves with small arms and lightweapons, thereby prolonging and intensifying the fighting andsuffering of civilians.62

    Moreover, nongovernmental organizations indicate that TNCs in countries as diverse as

    Colombia, Indonesia and Nigeria, continue to exacerbate conflict.63

    Paul Collier, at the University of Oxfords Centre for the Study of African

    Economies, has been at the forefront of the discussion regarding the role of resource

    exploitation in civil war.64 His analysis is helpful in pointing out the significance of

    TNCs and natural resources in civil conflict.65 The main thesis of his ongoing work is that

    grievance motives for conflict: inequality, political rights, ethnic polarization, and

    religious fractionalization are not significant motivators for conflict; but rather, civil

    conflict is motivated primarily by the availability of finance, what he calls the greed

    motive.66 Collier argues that countries which have a substantial share of their income

    (GDP) coming from the export of primary commodities are radically more at risk of

    conflict.67 Thus as a result of these commodities being used for extortion, makes civil

    62 Kofi Annan,Report to the Security Council on the protection of civilians in armed conflict,

    (New York, NY: UN, 2001).63 Banfield, Haufler, and Lilly, Transnational Corporations in Conflict Prone Zones: Public

    Policy Responses and a Framework for Action, 1-89.64 See, Paul Collier,Economic Causes of Civil Conflict and their Implications for Policy,

    (Washington, DC: Development Research Group, World Bank, 2000), 1-23.; Paul Collier and NicholasSambanis, "Understanding Civil War: A New Agenda," Journal of Conflict Resolution 46, no. 1 (2002): 3-

    13.; Paul Collier, Anne Hoeffler, and Mns Sderbom, "On the Duration of Civil War," Journal of PeaceResearch 41, no. 3 (2004): 253-273.; Paul Collier and Anne Hoeffler, "Greed and Grievance in Civil War,"

    Oxford Economic Papers 56, no. 4 (2004): 563-95.; Paul Collier, "Doing Well out of War: An EconomicPerspective," in Greed and Grievance: Economic Agendas in Civil Wars, eds. Mats Berdal and David M.

    Malone. (Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2000), 91-21.65 Later when discussing inequality we will look at the limits of Colliers analysis and conclusions.66 Collier and Hoeffler, Greed and Grievance in Civil War, 588.67 Collier,Economic Causes of Civil Conflict and their Implications for Policy , 6.

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    19/46

    19

    conflict both feasible and attractive.68 Collier writes: the true cause of much civil

    conflict is not the loud discourse of grievance but the silent force of greed.69 From a

    political economy perspective, the role of transnational corporations is crucial here as

    they play a major role in extracting and transporting these resources. Though Collier

    does not speak directly to the role of TNCs, many agencies including the UN and other

    NGOs as well as numerous academics point to the significance of TNCs in extracting

    these war-financing commodities (including conflict in Afganistan, Burma, Cambodia,

    Colombia, DRC, Indonesia (Aceh, Kalimatan and West Papau), Liberia, Nigeria, Papau

    New Guinea and Sierre Leone).

    70

    Cramer as well as Frynas and Wood share my thesis by

    questioning the neoliberal notion that increased trade flows will lead to peace; rather,

    they indicate that TNCs exacerbate conflict by allowing new opportunities for

    accumulation by elite segments.71 Moreover, citing Colliers analysis, Nafziger and

    Auvinen, point how rulers and warlords use exclusive contracts with foreign firms

    involved in resource extraction in order to consolidate power and secure income.72 They

    point particularly to how Charles Taylor used transnational commercial networks to

    amass power over Liberia as well as parts of Sierra Leone. Thus, Colliers contribution

    in highlighting the greed motive is important for our discussion.

    68 Collier and Hoeffler, Greed and Grievance in Civil War, 588.69

    Collier,Doing Well out of War: An Economic Perspective , 101.70 See Paula Richardson, Corporate Crime in a Globalized Economy: An Examination of the

    Corporate Legal Conundrum and Positive Prospects for Peace,Journal of Public and International Affairs

    15 (Spring 2004): 165-189.71 Jedrzej George Frynas and Geoffrey Wood, The Liberal View of the Trade-Peace Relationship

    Re-considered: Oil and Conflict in Angola, Paper presented at the VAD Conference 2002; Christopher

    Cramer, Capitalism, violence and war,Anti-capitalism: a Marxist introduction. ed. A. Saad-Filho.

    (London, UK: Pluto Press, 2002).72 E. Wayne Nafziger and Juha Auvinen, Economic Development, Inequality, War and State

    Violence, World Development30 (2002): 157-158.

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    20/46

    20

    International Alert, in a report on the operation of TNCs in conflict zones,

    indicates that there are two basic categories for the ways in which corporations contribute

    to violence: the impact on the local/micro level and the impact of foreign investment on

    the host countrys political/economic structures (macro-level).73 The micro-level impacts

    include the relationship between TNCs and local security forces, employment relations

    and community relations. Community relations and employment relations are defined as

    those activities both internal and within the community that may reinforce tensions and

    create further inequality with only certain people benefiting from the companys

    operation.

    74

    When it comes to security, companies contract either public or private

    security forces to protect their investments. Sometimes these security personnel can be

    repressive, violate human rights and can potentially play a role in the conflict.

    One example of this is found in a report by Amnesty International documenting

    human rights abuses by security personnel in the Democratic Republic of Congo.75 The

    mining company MIBA is a state run diamond corporation with transnational companies

    such as De Beers owning portions of the company. Government security personnel kill

    dozens of unarmed civilians each year in order to prevent stealing from diamond

    concessions.76

    Of more importance to this study however, are the macro impacts. In many

    conflict-prone regions the political economy is so weak that the disruption of the foreign

    73 Banfield, Haufler, and Lilly, Transnational Corporations in Conflict Prone Zones: PublicPolicy Responses and a Framework for Action, 18.

    74 ibid., 19-20.75Democratic Republic of Congo: Making a Killing - the diamond trade in government-

    controlled DRC, Amnesty International, 2002), 1-37.76 ibid.

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    21/46

    21

    investment has a huge impact.77 Foreign investment often targets specific regions which

    benefits some and disadvantages others; this inequality may reinforce existing tensions

    either ethnically or religiously. When natural resources are concentrated in one region of

    the country, as in the case of oil in Nigeria, residents do not receive a fair share of the

    benefits from the resource extraction but are left burdened with the environmental and

    resettlement consequences which may fuel violence.78 In some cases, bribery and

    corruption are common where either public officials or rebel groups seek self-

    aggrandizement, promising security and/or ease of operation.79 The existence of the TNC

    itself allows for combatants to have easy access to global markets whether illegally or

    legally. Because of increased liberalization through neoliberal globalization, diamonds,

    timber, oil and other resources move freely and quickly with the assistance of TNCs

    providing the financial income necessary for the purchase of armaments.

    Specifically, when one looks at the cases in Africa, war in Angola, Sierre Leone,

    Sudan and the DRC have all shown a high integration into the global economy through

    the operation of TNCs which have both intensified and prolonged the conflict.80 As

    already alluded to, De Beers has had a long history of buying conflict diamonds

    originating from areas such as Sierre Leone, DRC and Angola. Particularly in the DRC,

    there are a plethora of natural resources which continue to be exploited and thus fuel the

    war economy. According to Amnesty International the eastern regions of the DRC are

    77 Banfield, Haufler, and Lilly, Transnational Corporations in Conflict Prone Zones: Public

    Policy Responses and a Framework for Action, 1-89.78 James K. Boyce,Aid, Conditionality, and War Economies, (Amberst, MA: Political Economy

    Research Institute, University of Massachusetts Amhert, 2003), 5.79 Banfield, Haufler, and Lilly, Transnational Corporations in Conflict Prone Zones: Public

    Policy Responses and a Framework for Action, 1-89.80 Charles Cater, "The Political Economy of Conflict and UN Intervention: Rethinking the Critical

    Case of Africa," in The Political Economy of Armed Conflict: Beyond Greed and Grievance, eds. Karen

    Ballentine and Jake Sherman. (Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner, 2003), 19-26.

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    22/46

    22

    rich in gold, diamonds, coltan, cassiterite, copper, cobalt, wolfram, zinc and oil, as well

    as timber, coffee and palm oil. Moreover, considerable diamond deposits exist in

    Kisangani, Bafwasende and Watsa, high quality gold in Ituri, and coltan deposits

    throughout the eastern DRC.81 Amnesty points out that the UN Panel of Experts has

    documented various international connections with the exploitation of coltan in eastern

    DRC. In particular, the UN alleges the involvement of several European companies or

    individuals and one US Company in the coltan trade. Rebel leaders in the Goma area are

    estimated to raise approximately US$200,000 per month on the Coltan trade involving

    Northern TNCs.

    82

    Many of the companies named in the UN Panel reports, particularly in

    the final October 2002 report, have denied any involvement in contributing to the

    conflict.83

    However, the influence of transnational corporations and the overall world wide

    trade of primary commodities has not only been a factor in African conflicts but also in

    other regions. For example, the timber trade has played a large role in conflict in Asian

    countries such as Burma (Myanmar), Cambodia, Indonesia, and the Philippines.84

    Similarly, the ongoing conflict in Colombia has been fuelled by the illicit drug cultivation

    and trade which has both been made necessary and easier via the forces of economic

    globalization.85

    81Democratic Republic of the Congo: "Our brothers who help kill us" - economic exploitation

    and human rights abuses in the east. (London, UK: Amnesty International, 2003)82 Kent Hughes Butts and Arthur L. Bradshaw, Central African Security: Conflict in the Congo,

    (Carlisle Barracks, PA: Center for Strategic Leadership, U.S. Army War College, 2001),28 & 34.83Democratic Republic of the Congo: "Our brothers who help kill us" - economic exploitation

    and human rights abuses in the east.84 The Logs of War: The Timber Trade and Armed Conflict - Economies of Conflict: Private

    Sector Activity in Armed Conflict, (London, UK: Global Witness, Fafo Institute for Applied Social Science,

    2002), 1-65.85 Alexandra Guaqueta, "The Colombian Conflict: Political and Economic Dimensions," in The

    Political Economy of Armed Conflict: Beyond Greed and Grievance, eds. Karen Ballentine and Jake

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    23/46

    23

    The case of Angola provides one of the best examples of how corporate

    exploitation of natural resources fuels civil war. As Phillipe Le Billon points out, since

    the integration of Angola into the Western economy five hundred years ago, the

    demands placed on its wealth have been associated with repression and suffering.86 The

    country has been placed under continuous stress: Angolas people were shipped to

    Brazils plantations, colonists expropriated land for agricultural surpluses for Portugals

    provision, and the new industrial economy of the twentieth century, coupled with

    neoliberal globalization has facilitated the need for Angolas oil and diamonds. In

    Angola, the rival parties of the ruling Peoples Movement for the Liberation of Angola

    (MPLA) and the National Union for the Total Independence of Angola (UNITA) both

    benefited from the extraction of natural resources facilitated by TNCs: MPLA oil and

    UNITA diamonds.87 Oil exports from Angola have financed capital intensive

    militarization of the state while also filling the bank accounts of political elites through

    the operation of large TNCs such as ChevronTexaco and TotalFinaElf.88 These

    companies have been backed by both the French and U.S. governments facilitating state-

    backed loans, insurance, and corporate mercenary contracts as well as the French

    governments role in facilitating arms-for-oil.89 Oil revenue in 1999 for the government

    was estimated at US$ 2, 377 million.90

    Sherman. (Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner, 2003), 92. The example of Colombia will be discussed more fully

    in the next section.86 Philippe Le Billon, "Angola's political economy of war: The role of oil and diamonds, 1975

    2000," African Affairs 100, no. 398 (2001): 55.87 ibid., 57.88 Cater, The Political Economy of Conflict and UN Intervention: Rethinking the Critical Case of

    Africa, 32.89 ibid., 32.90 Le Billon,Angola's political economy of war: The role of oil and diamonds, 19752000, 62.

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    24/46

    24

    On the other hand, the diamond industry helped finance the rebel group, UNITA

    who controlled 60-70% of the diamond industry.91 Companies such as De Beers are both

    directly and indirectly buying from Angola. Though De Beers is upfront stating that

    there is no doubt that we buy many of those diamonds that emanate from the UNITA-

    held areas in Angola, second-hand in the markets of Antwerp and Tel Aviv, they deny

    the purchase of UNITA diamonds directly.92 Recently, in 2002, the Kimberly process

    was initiated in order to stop the flow of conflict diamonds; yet this process has been

    hindered by the implementation of the regulations with 83% (25 out of 30) companies

    surveyed falling short of implementing the protocols.

    93

    Though the conflict in Angola has killed 500,000 people with thousands more

    suffering from landmines, and other injuries, TNCs refuse to acknowledge their

    responsibility in the conflict. One oil company representative perhaps put it best when he

    stated: As our boss keeps telling us: we are not Jesus Christ . . .We came to this country

    to find oil and to make money. Thats our job.94

    Transnational Companies benefit significantly from the liberalization of global

    market and are thus able to take advantage of the South whose governments are desperate

    for their financial investment. Meanwhile, as we have seen from an extensive review of

    the literature and numerous examples (particularly the case of Angola), the operation of

    TNCs in conflict areas contributes to further suffering by helping fund insurgency and

    expanding military budgets. As Macartan Humphreys has pointed out, TNCs receive the

    91Broken Vows: Exposing the 'Loupe' Holes in the Diamond Industry's Effort to Prevent theTrade in Conflict Diamonds, Global Witness, 2004), 7.

    92 Le Billon,Angola's political economy of war: The role of oil and diamonds, 19752000, 76.93Broken Vows: Exposing the 'Loupe' Holes in the Diamond Industry's Effort to Prevent the

    Trade in Conflict Diamonds, 32.94 Le Billon,Angola's political economy of war: The role of oil and diamonds, 19752000, 77.

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    25/46

    25

    booty from war companies finance warring factions in exchange for the rights to the

    spoils of conflict.95

    Embedding Inequality

    Just as there is a reluctance to acknowledge the role of corporations in civil

    conflict, some neoliberal proponents continue to deny the increasing inequality created by

    such policies.96 According to recent research, and using numerous testing strategies, there

    is substantial evidence supporting the view that income inequality is rising globally.97

    The neoliberal growth model, not only produces an overabundance of goods available to

    western consumers and Southern elites but it also creates deeper inequality and economic

    exclusion.98

    Following neoliberal structural adjustment policies, we now have trickle up

    or recessive income distribution on a global scale. . .99 and the present structure of the

    neoliberal global economic order is transnational, centralized, concentric, and

    institutionalized at the top.100 In fact, it is well documented that market-oriented

    policies always tend toward disequilibria when one looks through a lens of class, income

    distribution and geographic location.101

    This growing gap has contributed substantially to armed conflict. According to a

    UNESCO report, agreement is growing on the effect of inequality and social exclusion

    on the creation and worsening of conditions leading to events that threaten peoples

    95 David Hecht, "Why war zones love monopolies," Fortune 149, no. 11 (2004): 66-68.96 See for example, Standing up for the global economy: key facts, figures and arguments in

    support of globalization, (Paris, France: International Chamber of Commerce, 2004).97

    Robert Hunter Wade, "The Rising Inequality of World Income Distribution," inDevelopmentand Underdevelopment: The Political Economy of Global Inequality, eds. Mitchell A. Seligson and John T.

    Passe-Smith. (Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner, 2003), 36.98 Gilbert Rist, The History of Development: from Western Origins to Global Faith, trans. Patrick

    Camiller. (New York, NY: Zed Books, 1997), 239.99 Nef and Robles, Globalization, Neoliberalism, and the State of Underdevelopment in the New

    Periphery, 32.100 ibid., 41.101 Victor Segesvary,From Illusion to Delusion: The Contradictions of the Late Modernity,

    (Lanham, MD: University Press of America, 2001), 237.

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    26/46

    26

    security, including violence. The recent report studying Human Security, Conflict

    Prevention and Peace, indicates that violence created by economic disparities is not just

    a question of poverty, but about how people perceive it in a context of increasing

    inequality of opportunity and social exclusion in societies which, at the same time,

    include them (only) symbolically in their development horizons, thus greatly raising their

    expectations.102 Other reports concur with this conclusion regarding the effects of

    inequality. According to Francis Stewart, economic differentiation among groups is of

    fundamental importance to group mobilization toward conflict.103

    This seems to contradict the basic findings of Paul Collier who indicates that

    factors such as inequality do not play a role in the engendering of civil armed conflict:

    Inequality, whether measured in terms of income or landownership, has no affect on the

    risk of conflict according to the data.104 For Collier, it is greed not grievance which

    motivates civil conflict. Collier acknowledges that this is surprising but states that the

    result cannot lightly be dismissed since his analysis with Anne Hoeffler has experimented

    with hundreds of variables in which inequality is never found as a significant cause of

    conflict (whereas primary commodity exports are always significant).105 In a discussion

    of the Economics and Political Economy of Conflict in Sub-Saharan Africa, by Chris

    Cramer, he summarizes Collier as one who ties the insight that there are economic

    factors involved in the origins of and motivations for conflict to a rigorous neo-classical

    framework, but that arguably what this analysis gains in the elegance of its formal

    102 Francisco Rojas Aravena and Moufida Goucha,Human Security, Conflict Prevention and

    Peace in Latin America and the Caribbean, (Santiago, Chile: UNESCO, 2001), 1-383.103 Frances Stewart, "The Root Causes of Humanitarian Emergencies," in The Origins of

    Humanitarian Emergencies: War and Displacement in Developing Countries, eds. E. Wayne Nafziger,

    Francis Stewart and Raimo Vayrynen. (Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press, forthcoming), 13.104 Collier,Doing Well out of War: An Economic Perspective, 97.105 ibid., 97-98.

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    27/46

    27

    model it loses in social understanding.106 As Cramer points out, there is the danger that

    economic motivations become too reductionist and simply replace one simplification

    (tribal or cultural difference) with another, such as economic opportunism.107 It is here

    that Colliers neo-classical framework falls short verses a more holistic political economy

    perspective. Though Colliers greed analysis is helpful in highlighting the relationship

    between resource access (such as diamonds, oil, timber) and armed conflict, he does not

    recognize how those factors contribute to further embedding horizontal and vertical

    inequality creating grievance both locally, nationally and regionally. It should also be

    noted that others have used the Gini measurement used by Collier and Hoeffler and have

    found a relationship between inequality and conflict.108

    A regression analysis by Nafziger

    and Auvinen using Gini coefficient data indicates that high Gini or income

    concentrations contribute to humanitarian emergencies.109 Christopher Cramer notes that

    any econometric analysis appears capable of supporting completely contrasting claims

    through modest changes in specification data.110 Cramer through a political economy

    analysis notes that economic inequality is hugely important in explaining civil conflict

    but only if the analysis is considered embedded within the social, political, cultural and

    historical, considering factors such as colonialism, ethnic and regional differences, and so

    on.111 Moreover, Collier also forgets that resource extraction by Transnational

    Corporations, during times of conflict and weak government control, almost guarantees

    that the benefits of this foreign investment will be distributed unequally resulting from

    106 Cramer, The Economics and Political Economy of Conflict in Sub-Saharan Africa, 15.107 Ibid.,16.108 Nafziger & Auvinen, Economic Development, Inequality, War and State Violence, 156.109 ibid., 156.110 Christopher Cramer, CDPR Discussion Paper 1501: Economic Inequalities and Civil

    Conflict, Centre for Development Policy & Research, School of Oriental and African Studies, University

    of London, 2002, 11.111 ibid., 18.

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    28/46

    28

    corruption between rebel groups, government and corporations as well as the significant

    regional differences in the location of these primary commodities.112

    In a book on the causes of humanitarian crises, Nafziger, Stewart and Vayrynen

    also point to the role that inequality plays in engendering conflict and the interplay with

    race and ethnicity: high rates of inequality are associated with a high propensity to

    conflict, especially if it reflects or contributes to high inequality among regional, ethnic

    or class groups.113 Chua indicates that whether it is deserved of not, market-dominated

    minorities, with access to capital, skills and business networks, drive global capitalism

    and foster not only a backlash against the dominant minorities but against the free

    markets themselves.114

    Rather than reinforcing the market liberalization and its apparent

    wealth production, this inequality and the frustration/empowerment of the poor threatens

    the peace and prosperity that proponents of the market envision.115 The inequality

    fostered by neoliberal globalization actually hurts market liberalization and efficiency by

    fuelling and instigating conflict.

    Colombia is an excellent example of how inequality fuels armed conflict. In

    Colombia, the guerrillas have historically claimed that they are fighting against

    systematic political and socioeconomic exclusion of the majority by the small urban

    elite.116 Inequality remains one of the primary causes of the conflict in Colombia and has

    been exacerbated in the past few decades despite the progress made in the 60s and 70s.

    112

    Banfield, Haufler, and Lilly, Transnational Corporations in Conflict Prone Zones: PublicPolicy Responses and a Framework for Action, 18-20.

    113 E. Wayne Nafziger, Francis Stewart, and Raimo Vayrynen, "Case Studies of Complex

    Humanitarian Emergencies," in The Origins of Humanitarian Emergencies: War and Displacement in

    Developing Countries, eds. E. Wayne Nafziger, Francis Stewart and Raimo Vayrynen. (Oxford, UK:Oxford University Press, forthcoming), 3.

    114 Amy Chua, World On Fire: How Exporting Free Market Democracy Breeds Ethnic Hatred

    and Global Instability, (Toronto, ON: Anchor Books, 2004), 261.115 ibid., 261.116 Guaqueta, The Colombian Conflict: Political and Economic Dimensions, 95.

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    29/46

    29

    Rural inequality has increased substantially due to neoliberal reforms and expanding

    capitalist agriculture.117 The well-being of small peasant property owners has steadily

    declined as a consequence of more open markets and lower protective tariffs.118 This

    rising inequality has undoubtedly aided the expansions of the guerilla movement and

    also led to an increase in the number of peasants with links to the illegal drug

    economy.119 The conflict has embedded these inequalities further as people are forcibly

    displaced and as drug traffickers land holdings increase.120

    The ongoing conflict and inequality has resulted in a large group of peasants

    relying on the drug economy. In addition to liberalization, the drop in coffee prices and

    other cash crops have made illicit crops the only viable alternative making up an industry

    of approximately 1.5-3 billion per year.121 Nazih Richani specifically points to the strong

    correlation between those areas which are dominated by violence and the high levels of

    inequality. Uneven economic development has led to high numbers of assassinations in

    areas where the agroindustry, raising of livestock, mining and textiles are concentrated.122

    The profits that the elite are able to make off of the war through extortion and the control

    of the drug trade, make peace a very expensive commodity.123 As a result of the

    uncertainty created by insurgents, narco-trafficking, peace negotiations, etc., there was

    little time for Colombians to oppose these neoliberal policies which have fed the conflict.

    117 Jason Thor Hagen,Agrarian Interests in a Liberalizing Economy: Colombia's Law 101 of

    1993, (Guadalajara, Mexico: Prepared for delivery at the Latin American Studies Association, 1997), 1 &7n. Whether inequality remains the sole motivation for the guerillas can definitely be debated considering

    the large profits that armed groups are making through trade and criminal activity.118 Nazih Richani, "The political economy of violence: The war-system in Colombia," Journal of

    Interamerican Studies & World Affairs 39, no. 2 (1997): 37.119 ibid.120 Guaqueta, The Colombian Conflict: Political and Economic Dimensions, 95.121 Richani, The political economy of violence: The war-system in Colombia, 37.122 ibid.123 ibid.

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    30/46

    30

    In fact, it has been suggested that President Gaviria used these issues as a distraction

    meanwhile deepening the liberalization process.124 The inequality created by the

    expansion of neoliberal policies through structural adjustment has not only led peasants

    into the arms of the guerillas but has also forced farmers into the illegal trade which funds

    the insurgency.

    It is clear that neoliberal policy imperatives and structural adjustment programs

    create increasing inequality entailing intensified impoverishment for the majority.125 The

    presence of this income inequality not only leads to poverty but enhances the potential for

    insurgency and armed conflict.

    126

    The Transformation of the State

    Not only are the operations of transnational corporations and rising inequality

    causes of instability but the retreat or hollowing out of state structures can also be a

    catalyst for violent conflict. Though the implementation of neoliberal macroeconomic

    policies through structural adjustment programs are said to facilitate adjustments to more

    positive economic realities, they often create increased political instability as public

    expenditure decreases and as the state loses control over economic decision making. The

    new structures of global governance (including international financial institutions such as

    the World Bank and the IMF) as well as the increased strength of local-global

    interconnections undermine state authority and democratic accountability.127 Neil Cooper

    points out in his discussion of the political economy of post-modern conflict that weak

    124 Hagen,Agrarian Interests in a Liberalizing Economy: Colombia's Law 101 of 1993, 1 & 7n.125 Shaw,Peace-building parnerships and human security, 450.126 Edward N. Muller and Mitchell A. Seligson, "Inequality and Insurgency," inDevelopment and

    Underdevelopment: The Political Economy of Global Inequality, eds. Mitchell A. Seligson and John T.

    Passe-Smith. (Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2003), 93-95.127 Angus Cameron and Ronen Palan, The Imagined Economies of Globalization, (London,

    Thousand Oaks, New Delhi: Sage Publication, 2004), 139.

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    31/46

    31

    states in the developing world have become virtual states where their autonomy has been

    destabilized by the influence of globalization, aid dependence and structural adjustment

    programs. These neoliberal influences have both reduced the authority and the

    legitimacy of the state.128 Looking particularly at conflicts in Sierra Leone, Congo and

    Liberia, Nafziger and Auvinen indicate that humanitarian crises, particularly conflict, are

    more likely to occur when the state is weak.129 Another study points out that the

    occurrence of civil conflict in Africa is intimately related to the failure of governments to

    deliver the type of public expenditures that the people want, i.e., with a strong

    redistributive component such as health and education.

    130

    Giving examples as diverse as

    Colombia, Kosovo, Afghanistan and the DRC, Neil Cooper point to how increased global

    free trade has contributed to the weakening of the state.131 I quote at length:

    When the structural violence created by these legitimate tradingnetworks is combined with the impacts of neo-liberal globalization,structural adjustment and aid dependence the effect is to produce aparticularly acute version of the crisis of the state which creates theconditions for, if not the inevitability of, collapse.132

    However, Nicolas van de Walle has difficulty with those who quickly point to the

    international financial institutions and SAPs as reasons for state failure.133 According to

    Van de Walle, there has not been a neoliberal assault in low-income Africa, but yet he

    128 Neil Cooper, "Warlords and Logo Warriors: The Political Economy of Post-Modern Conflict,"

    inArming the South: The Economics of Military Expenditure, Arms Production and Arms Trade in

    Developing Countries, eds. Jurgen Brauer and J. Paul Dunne. (New York, NY: Palgrave, 2002), 39.129

    Nafziger & Auvinen, Economic Development, Inequality, War and State Violence, 154.130 Jean-Paul Azam, The Redistributive State and Conflicts in Africa,Journal of Peace

    Research 38 (July 2001): 442.131 See Neil Cooper, State Collapse as Business: The Role of Conflict Trade and the Emerging

    Control Agenda,Development and Change 33 (2002): 935-955.132 ibid., 952.133 See Nicolas Van de Walle, "The economic Correlates of State Failure: Taxes, Foreign Aid and

    Policies," in , ed. Robert I. Rotberg. (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2004), 94-115; Nicolas

    Van de Walle,African Economies and the Politics of Permanent Crisis, 1979-1999, (Cambridge, UK:

    Cambridge University Press, 2001), 291.

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    32/46

    32

    acknowledges that structural adjustment processes have created instability.134 Speaking

    specifically about Africa, he states that initially the flow of resources to the area through

    multilateral lending helped to stabilize governments by providing an economic boost.

    While at the same time he points out that donor efforts have not helped to bring about the

    renewal of economic growth and that the persistence of economic crises for over two

    decades has had a negative effect on political stability.135 Moreover, though Van de

    Walle expresses reservation about those who make blanket statements in regards to SAPs

    and the IFIs, he concedes that:

    Local technocrats often take a back seat to semestrial missions fromthe Washington institutions. Economic decision-making power ismoved away from the ministries and their procedures to ad hocdonor-financed structures . . .which typically lack transparency andaccountability. National budgetary and planning structuresatrophy.136

    Joseph Stiglitz, former advisor to President Bill Clinton and chief economist at the World

    Bank, asserts that the Bretton Woods institutions have failed to bring about global

    stability but for many countries have made matters worse, crippling the developing

    world.137

    When we adopt a political economy framework, we see that this crippling of the

    state also fosters increasing inequality and creates an environment where transnational

    companies can operate with little accountability. This dislocation of conventional

    political structures thus permits further social exclusion.138 Inequality is further

    embedded as access to public services of education and health decrease and while weak

    134 Van de Walle, The economic Correlates of State Failure: Taxes, Foreign Aid and Policies,111.

    135 ibid.136 ibid.137 Joseph E. Stiglitz, Globalization and its discontents, (New York and London: Norton, 2002).138 Cameron and Palan, The Imagined Economies of Globalization, 139.

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    33/46

    33

    state elites (whether government or rebel leaders) use privatization and the presence of

    TNCs to exploit local resources and linkages with the global market place.139

    As the poor become increasingly frustrated during this phase of adjustment,

    there are often violent outbursts against the state. In fact, this negative perception of the

    state by the local population has a negative effect on the structural adjustment programs

    themselves because of social and political unrest.140 For example, privatization and

    liberalization was highly unpopular in Haiti as many argued that the problem was the

    political will to make public companies run efficiently.141 Moreover, IMF policies hurt

    Haitis rural population (70%) with the shift to export-orientation creating massive

    migration into urban slums which caused further discontent with the government.142

    Since there is no effective governance in Haiti, policies which further disenfranchise the

    population breed civil unrest continuing to whittle away at the state.

    A similar comparison can be made to the restructuring that occurred in Somalia

    prior to the crisis in 1991. Michel Chossudovsky argues that the Bretton Woods

    recommended fiscal reforms contributed to the collapsing of the state.143 Chossudovsky

    draws a direct correlation between SAPs and the formation of the famine because of its

    systematic undermining of the categories of economic activity which do not directly

    serve the interests of the global market system, specifically Somalias pastoral economy

    and the exchange between nomadic herdsmen and small agriculturalists:

    139

    Cooper, Warlords and Logo Warriors: The Political Economy of Post-Modern Conflict, 39.140 Eirin Mobekk and I . Spyrou, "Re-evaluation IMF Involvement in Low-Income Countries: The

    Case of Haiti," International Journal of Social Economics 29, no. 7-8 (2002): 527.141 ibid., 533. For further discussion on IMF involvement in Haiti see "Haiti's latest coup:

    Structural adjustment and the.." Multinational Monitor18, no. 5 (1997): 20.142 Mobekk and Spyrou,Re-evaluation IMF Involvement in Low-Income Countries: The Case of

    Haiti, 533.143 Michel Chossudovsky, "The Real Causes of Somalia's Faimine," in Justice Denied!: Human

    Rights and the International Financial Institutions (Geneva, Switzerland: Women's International League,

    1994), 27-33.

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    34/46

    34

    Import substituting industries for the internal market are dismantledas a result of the lifting of tariff barriers and the collapse of internalpurchasing power, small artisans are impoverished, and food farmingis undermined in favor of export crops. In turn, the State apparatusis undone through the imposition of fiscal austerity, civil society

    collapses, and the nation-State becomes politically fragmented.

    144

    Though, Somalia and Haiti are good examples of how already weak states became

    crippled by neoliberal policies, it is the case of Rwanda which is perhaps the most

    horrific and noteworthy.

    In an essay entitled How multilateral development assistance triggered the

    conflict in Rwanda, Regine Andersen notes that both multilateral and bilateral agencies

    promoted strategies of economic structural adjustment, democratization and peace in

    Rwanda.145 Though a multitude of factors contributed to the crisis (i.e. ethnic tensions,

    economic malaise, etc), the policies played a role in instigating the genocide. During and

    economic downswing, the Habyarimana regime was forced into negotiations with both

    the IMF and the World Bank on structural adjustment loans which in turn made a

    conditional link between aid and democratization, as well as the implementation of the

    Arusha Accords.146 Even Nicolas van de Walle agrees that aid contributed to the

    mobilization of ethnic minorities despite his reservations about such arguments.147 SAPs

    undermined the legitimacy of the government as perceived by the majority of the

    population as Rwandas currency was devalued numerous coupled with significant price

    increases which led to rapid inflation.148 Though exports increased, farm earnings

    144 ibid. 27 & 32.145 Regine Andersen, "How multilateral development assistance triggered the conflict in

    Rwanda," Third World Quarterly 21, no. 3 (2000): 442. In some ways this coupling of marketization anddemocratization echoes previous arguments in Chua, World On Fire: How Exporting Free Market

    Democracy Breeds Ethnic Hatred and Global Instability, 346.146 Andersen,How multilateral development assistance triggered the conflict in Rwanda, 450.147 Van de Walle,African Economies and the Politics of Permanent Crisis, 1979-1999, 291., 210.148 Andersen,How multilateral development assistance triggered the conflict in Rwanda, 448.

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    35/46

    35

    decreased sharply by 20%.149 Meanwhile the simultaneous multiparty democratization

    process led to the fragmentation of political groupings into new radical racist groups

    which further weakened the position of the government and led to the deterioration of the

    peace process.150 It was therefore the tensions between these economic and political

    processes which led to the weakening of the regime contributing to the formulation of the

    genocide.151

    The particular examples of Rwanda, Colombia and Angola along with the

    extensive review of the contemporary literature has revealed the numerous ways in which

    neoliberalism has contributed to civil conflict. By looking simultaneously at political and

    economic factors, one can see that dominance of TNCs, growing inequality and the

    retreat of the state has perpetuated and fuelled these violent conflicts.

    149 ibid.150 ibid., 452.151 ibid., 452.

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    36/46

    36

    Chapter 4: The Construction of the Neoliberal Hegemony

    In a recent report on globalization, the International Chamber of Commerce (ICC)

    argues that globalization, more particularly neoliberal globalization, is a much-

    misunderstood phenomena.152 The report insists that a more open economy and more

    accountable governance will lead to a higher standard of living for persons around the

    globe. The report defines globalization as the spread of market reforms and open trade

    policies. The benefits of globalization include: faster economic growth, a rise in living

    standards, easier access to capital and technology, high productivity and lower prices;

    while the challenges of globalization are listed as transition problems as well as social

    and cultural impacts.153

    As we have seen, Structural Adjustment Programs (SAPs) and neoliberalism have

    led to increasing global inequality which disputes the findings of this report which

    indicates that the inequality gap is closing.154 But perhaps the biggest inadequacy of the

    ICC Report on Globalization is its recommendation that it is conflict and bad

    governance which are holding countries back from reaping the benefits of economic

    globalization.155 What the report fails to recognize is how in many instances neoliberal

    globalization in fact undermines Southern governments as well as fuels global instability

    through increasing inequality. Moreover, the expansion of transnational corporations

    (TNCs) around the world has actually been associated with an increase in distributional

    152 Standing up for the global economy: key facts, figures and arguments in support of

    globalization, (Paris, France: International Chamber of Commerce, 2004).153 ibid.154 See for example: Frances Stewart and Albert Berry,Inequality, Globalization, and World

    Politics, (New York, NY: Oxford University Press, 1999) & Oscar Altimit, "Income Distribution and

    Poverty Through Crisis and Adjustment," inPoverty, Economic Reform, and Income Distribution in Latin

    America, ed. Albert Berry. (Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publishers, 1998), 43-80.155 Standing up for the global economy: key facts, figures and arguments in support of

    globalization,18.

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    37/46

    37

    conflicts around the globe with conflicts arising over oil, gas, minerals, etc.156 Similarly,

    neoliberal policies and the influence of the Washington Consensus by the International

    Financial Institutions have undermined local government authorities by imposing strict

    guidelines on public expenditure and fiscal policy. Though armed conflict is a concern

    for development, the ICC report seems to be confusing cause and effect.

    What this paper has argued from a political economy perspective is that in many

    cases it is precisely that neoliberal economic hegemony which has fueled conflict.

    Neoliberal policies allow for warring factions to fund their operations with the help of

    transnational corporations such as the case of Angola; radical liberalization causes further

    social polarization and inequality like in Colombia; and programs such as structural

    adjustment or the Washington Consensus have led to a hollowing out of the state in

    instances such as Somalia and Rwanda. What is needed and what is not explored in this

    work is an understanding of the types of macro-economic policies which foster peace-

    building and sustainable development. Some continue to advocate that liberalization,

    commercial freedom and the general promotion of capitalism will bring peace;157 but as

    we have seen from the literature and numerous examples, the idea that such pure market-

    based approaches bring peace is an illusion. We must seek alternatives to the

    Washington Consensus if development policy is going to promote peace. However, the

    development discourse remains fragmented with very little alternatives to the dominant

    neoliberal model.

    156 Joan Martinez-Alier, "Environmental Justice as a Force for Sustainability," in Global Futures:

    Shaping Globalization, ed. Jan Nederveen Pieterse. (New York, NY: Zed Books, 2000), 159.157 See Erich Weede, "The Diffusion of Prosperity and Peace by Globalization," Independent

    Review 9, no. 2 (2004): 165-186. & John A. Tures, "Economic Liberalization and International Order,"

    Cato Journal23, no. 3 (2004): 423-31.

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    38/46

    38

    It has become difficult to engage alternatives to the neoliberal model when the

    forces of economic globalization are so pervasive. Neoliberalisms linear growth model

    has not only led to a widening gap between the rich and the poor, given rise to large

    transnational capital flows and weakened the position of the state, but the shear

    dominance of this ideology has led to the fragmentation of development discourse.

    Growth is assumed and many of the so called alternatives only cloak themselves in a

    new language in an attempt to hide the same linear thinking.

    Because Marxs model is no longer considered viable due to the fall of Soviet

    communism, the neoliberal growth paradigm has become the governing model in the

    present ideological vacuum.

    If the South were to just follow the recipe for growth there would be

    development. Yet, the current neoliberal model has caused great hardship for the poor

    as a result of increasing global inequality. Neoliberal policies have created a world

    where the richest one percent receives as much income as the poorest 57 percent.158

    Gilbert Rist even argues that it is in the nature of development not only to make the

    overabundance of goods available to consumers but also to produce inequality and

    exclusion.159 The proponents of the growth ideology insist that the poor will eventually

    benefit as a result of the trickle-down effect; yet the benefits of this hyper-growth most

    often trickle up.160 The model assumed that once the pie gets big enough, then it can be

    158 Henry Veltmeyer, James Petras, and Steve Vieux,Neoliberalism and class conflict in LatinAmerica : a comparative perspective on the political economy of structural adjustment, (New York, NY:

    St. Martin's Press, 1997), 5.159 Rist, The History of Development: from Western Origins to Global Faith , 239.160 "A Critique of Corporate Globalization," inAlternatives to Economic Globalization: A Better

    World is Possible (San Francisco, CA: Berret-Koehler Publishers Inc., 2002), 21.

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    39/46

    39

    divided. The neoliberal growth paradigm maintains an inequitable social order, which is

    exclusionary, class-biased and thus fuels conflict.161

    While on the one hand, advocates indicate that this growth will eventually trickle

    down to the poor, there is an acknowledgement that before one reaches development

    there will be some growing pains. Inequality, the destruction caused by TNCs and cuts to

    government spending are then perhaps just necessary growing pains of this neoliberal

    agenda. Rist links the neoliberal model to Western Christian thought saying that

    neoliberalism, like any religion requires sacrifice.162 It appears then that armed conflict is

    not unexpected but that such hardship for the poor and marginalized is part of the

    turbulence required for the take off.

    Neoliberalism has become the dominant discourse because it has on its side all

    the forces of a world of relations of forces, a world that is contributes to making what it

    is.163 This discourse legitimates the elitist interests of national and international regimes

    such as transnational corporations and the international financial institutions and of

    course the economic policies of those very elites who benefit from such a regime.164 The

    globalization of this ideology has eroded political power by forcing nations to follow the

    logic of the market and the god of growth.165 Neoliberalism is a construction; yet this

    logic has become hegemonic because of the institutions which continue to preserve the

    same violent evolutionist creed. The need for economic growth continues to be the

    161 Nef and Robles, Globalization, Neoliberalism, and the State of Underdevelopment in the NewPeriphery, 35.

    162 Rist, The History of Development: from Western Origins to Global Faith, 240.163 See Pierre Bourdieu, The essence of neoliberalism: Utopia of endless exploitation,Le Monde

    Diplomatique (Dec 1998).164 See Ken Kempner and Loureiro Jurema, "The Global Politics of Education: Brazil and the

    World " Higher Education 43 (2002): 331-354.165 Rist, The History of Development: from Western Origins to Global Faith, 224.

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    40/46

    40

    imperative for every new development model proposed. Development discourses have

    become fragmented as a result of the neoliberal ideological empire.

    If there is going to be hope for the people of Colombia, Sudan, the DRC and

    Jamaica, then we are going to need to imagine alternatives to the existing paradigm. Our

    political economy approach teaches us that we cannot assume that a narrow neoliberal

    approach will bring peace and development. Perhaps more importantly as development

    practitioners and theorists, we must be conscious about how the construction of

    knowledge can initiate violence and promote the continued suffering of the global south.

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    41/46

    41

    Bibliography

    Broken Vows: Exposing the 'Loupe' Holes in the Diamond Industry's Effort to Prevent the

    Trade in Conflict Diamonds. Global Witness, 2004.

    Standing Up for the Global Economy: Key Facts, Figures and Arguments in Support ofGlobalization. Paris, France: International Chamber of Commerce, 2004.

    Democratic Republic of the Congo: "our Brothers Who Help Kill Us" - EconomicExploitation and Human Rights Abuses in the East. London, UK: AmnestyInternational, 2003.

    "A Critique of Corporate Globalization." InAlternatives to Economic Globalization: ABetter World is Possible. San Francisco, CA: Berret-Koehler Publishers Inc., 2002.

    Democratic Republic of Congo: Making a Killing - the Diamond Trade in Government-

    Controlled DRC. Amnesty International, 2002.

    The Logs of War: The Timber Trade and Armed Conflict - Economies of Conflict: Private

    Sector Activity in Armed Conflict. London, UK: Global Witness, Fafo Institute forApplied Social Science, 2002.

    "Haiti's Latest Coup: Structural Adjustment and the.." Multinational Monitor18, no. 5(1997): 20.

    Altimit, Oscar. "Income Distribution and Poverty through Crisis and Adjustment." In

    Poverty, Economic Reform, and Income Distribution in Latin America. Edited byAlbert Berry. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publishers, 1998, 43-80.

    Andersen, Regine. "How Multilateral Development Assistance Triggered the Conflict inRwanda." Third World Quarterly 21, no. 3 (2000): 441-456.

    Annan, Kofi.Report to the Security Council on the Protection of Civilians in ArmedConflict. New York, NY: UN, 2001.

    Aravena, Francisco Rojas, and Moufida Goucha.Human Security, Conflict Preventionand Peace in Latin America and the Caribbean. Santiago, Chile: UNESCO, 2001.

    Axworthy, Lloyd. "Human Security and Global Governance: Putting People First."Global Governance 7, no. 1 (2001): 19.

    Azam, Jean-Paul. The Redistributive State and Conflicts in Africa,Journal of PeaceResearch 38 (July 2001): 429-444.

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    42/46

    42

    Banfield, Jessica, Virginia Haufler, and Damian Lilly. Transnational Corporations inConflict Prone Zones: Public Policy Responses and a Framework for Action. London, UK: International Alert, 2003.

    Bourdieu, Pierre. The Essence of Neoliberalism: Utopia of Endless Exploitation.1998.

    Bowen, John R. "The Myth of Global Ethnic Conflict."Journal of Democracy 7, no. 4(1996): 3.

    Boyce, James K.Aid, Conditionality, and War Economies. Amberst, MA: PoliticalEconomy Research Institute, University of Massachusetts Amhert, 2003.

    Bryan, Patrick.Inside Out and Outside in: Factors in the Creation of ContemporaryJamaica. Kingston, Jamaica: Grace Kennedy Foundation, 2000.

    Butts, Kent Hughes, and Arthur L. Bradshaw. Central African Security: Conflict in theCongo. Carlisle Barracks, PA: Center for Strategic Leadership, U.S. Army War

    College, 2001.

    Cameron, Angus, and Ronen Palan. The Imagined Economies of Globalization. London,Thousand Oaks, New Delhi: Sage Publication, 2004.

    Cater, Charles. "The Political Economy of Conflict and UN Intervention: Rethinking theCritical Case of Africa." In The Political Economy of Armed Conflict: Beyond Greedand Grievance. Edited by Karen Ballentine and Jake Sherman. Boulder, CO: LynneRienner, 2003, 19-26.

    Chossudovsky, Michel. "The Real Causes of Somalia's Famine." InJustice Denied!:Human Rights and the International Financial Institutions. Geneva, Switzerland:Women's International League, 1994, 27-33.

    Chua, Amy. World on Fire: How Exporting Free Market Democracy Breeds EthnicHatred and Global Instability. Toronto, ON: Anchor Books, 2004.

    Collier, Paul. "Doing Well Out of War: An Economic Perspective." In Greed andGrievance: Economic Agendas in Civil Wars. Edited by Mats Berdal and David M.Malone. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2000, 91-112.

    Collier, Paul.Economic Causes of Civil Conflict and their Implications for Policy.Washington, DC: Development Research Group, World Bank, 2000.

    Collier, Paul, and Anne Hoeffler. "Greed and Grievance in Civil War." Oxford EconomicPapers 56, no. 4 (2004): 563-95.

    Collier, Paul, Anne Hoeffler, and Mns Sderbom. "On the Duration of Civil War."Journal of Peace Research 41, no. 3 (2004): 253-273.

  • 8/14/2019 Buckland Neoliberal PE War

    43/46

    43

    Collier, Paul, and Nicholas Sambanis. "Understanding Civil War: A New Agenda."Journal of Conflict Resolution 46, no. 1 (2002): 3-13.

    Cooper, Neil. "Warlords and Logo Warriors: The Political Economy of Post-ModernConflict." InArming the South: The Economics of Military Expenditure, ArmsProduction and Arms Trade in Developing Countries. Edited by Jurgen Brauer and J.Paul Dunne. New York, NY: Palgrave, 2002, 35-50.

    Cox, Robert W. "Political Economy and World Order: Problems of Power andKnowledge at the Turn of the Millenium." InPolitical Economy and the ChangingGlobal Order. Edited by Stubbs,Richard and Geoffrey R.D. Underhill. Toronto, ON:Oxford University Press, 2000, 25-49.

    Cramer, Christopher. Capitalism, violence and war,Anti-capitalism: a Marxistintroduction. ed. A. Saad-Filho. (London, UK: Pluto Press, 2002).

    Cramer, Christopher. The Economics and Political Economy of Conflict in Sub-Saharan

    Africa. London, UK: Center for Development Policy & Research, 1999.

    Cramer, Christopher. CDPR Discussion Paper 1501: Economic Inequalities and CivilConflict, Centre for Development Policy & Research, School of Oriental andAfrican Studies, University of London, 2002, 11.

    Cramer, Christopher. "Homo Economicus Goes to War: Methodological Individualism,Rational Choice and the Political Economy of War." World Development30, no. 11(2002): 1845.

    Franko, Patrice. The Puzzle of Latin American Economic Development. 2nd ed. New

    York, NY: Rowman and Littlefield Publishers Inc., 2002.

    Frieden, Jeffry A., and David A. Lake. "International Politics and InternationalEconomics." InInternational Political Economy: State-Market Relations in aChanging Global Order. Edited by Goddard, C. Roe, Patrick Cronin and Kishore C.Dash. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2003, 25-32.

    Frynas, Jedrzej George and Geoffrey Wood. The Liberal View of the Trade-PeaceRelationship Re-considered: Oil and Conflict in Angola, Paper presented at theVAD Conference 2002.

    Fukuda-Parr, Saki