30
CONSUMER AND CORPORATE DEBT IN A BASIC POST-KEYNESIAN MODEL OF GROWTH AND INCOME DISTRIBUTION Emilia Marsellou 1 Labor Institute of the General Confederation of Greek workers (INE/ GSEE) and UADPhilEcon Economics Department, University of Athens. Abstract: In this paper a basic Post-Keynesian model of growth and income distribution is developed incorporating consumer and corporate borrowing. Consumer borrowing is incorporated in the short-run and corporate borrowing is introduced in the long-run. Assuming a neoliberal regime, workers borrow to fill the consumption gap, and set targets for both living standard and interest payments. Capitalists borrow to finance investment. In the long-run model two cases are examined: the consumer debt-rate of accumulation relation and the consumer debt-corporate debt-rate of accumulation relation. In both cases the stable point corresponds to high growth and low workers’ debt-capital ratio and the saddle to low growth and high workers’ debt-capital ratio. Changes on parameters affect the volume of the stability of the system. INTRODUCTION Consumer debt and its role in business cycles and growth is much less investigated in formal models than corporate debt is. Palley (1996a, 1996b) and Dutt (2006) are exceptions. In particular, Palley (1996a) in a Kaleckian model of aggregate demand introduces inside debt and a generational structure and finds that workers’ borrowing and population growth serve to increase aggregate demand. However, increased borrowing by young workers has a negative impact on both the profit rate and share in order to preserve equilibrium between savings and investment. Palley (1996b) within a Minskyan framework developed three simple linear multiplier-accelerator models that incorporate the effects of debt on the business cycle and found that borrowing initially serves aggregate demand and output yet subsequently debt service payments tend to reduce them. Dutt (2006) extended a Steindlian model of growth and income distribution to incorporate consumer credit and showed that it has a favorable effect on aggregate demand in the short-run while in the long-run the effects are ambiguous. This is because, workers’ interest payments are equivalent to a redistribution of income towards the rich, who have a lower propensity to consume and this might contract growth. 1 I would like to thank A. Maniatis for the provision of data for the Hourly real wage index and Dr. Kotsios and Dr. Athanasiou for their helpful comments. Address for correspondence: 71A, Em. Benaki st., GR-10681, Athens tel: 0030 210 3327722 e-mail: [email protected]

Berlin Octorber 2011 Emilia Marsellou Consumer and corporate Debt

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    1

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Berlin Octorber 2011 Emilia Marsellou Consumer and corporate Debt

CONSUMER AND CORPORATE DEBT IN A BASIC POST-KEYNESIAN MODEL

OF GROWTH AND INCOME DISTRIBUTION

Emilia Marsellou1

Labor Institute of the General Confederation of Greek workers (INE/ GSEE) and UADPhilEcon

Economics Department, University of Athens.

Abstract: In this paper a basic Post-Keynesian model of growth and income distribution is developed incorporating consumer and corporate borrowing. Consumer borrowing is incorporated in the short-run and corporate borrowing is introduced in the long-run. Assuming a neoliberal regime, workers borrow to fill the consumption gap, and set targets for both living standard and interest payments. Capitalists borrow to finance investment. In the long-run model two cases are examined: the consumer debt-rate of accumulation relation and the consumer debt-corporate debt-rate of accumulation relation. In both cases the stable point corresponds to high growth and low workers’ debt-capital ratio and the saddle to low growth and high workers’ debt-capital ratio. Changes on parameters affect the volume of the stability of the system.

INTRODUCTION

Consumer debt and its role in business cycles and growth is much less investigated in

formal models than corporate debt is. Palley (1996a, 1996b) and Dutt (2006) are

exceptions. In particular, Palley (1996a) in a Kaleckian model of aggregate demand

introduces inside debt and a generational structure and finds that workers’ borrowing and

population growth serve to increase aggregate demand. However, increased borrowing by

young workers has a negative impact on both the profit rate and share in order to preserve

equilibrium between savings and investment. Palley (1996b) within a Minskyan framework

developed three simple linear multiplier-accelerator models that incorporate the effects of

debt on the business cycle and found that borrowing initially serves aggregate demand and

output yet subsequently debt service payments tend to reduce them. Dutt (2006) extended a

Steindlian model of growth and income distribution to incorporate consumer credit and

showed that it has a favorable effect on aggregate demand in the short-run while in the

long-run the effects are ambiguous. This is because, workers’ interest payments are

equivalent to a redistribution of income towards the rich, who have a lower propensity to

consume and this might contract growth.

                                                            1 I would like to thank A. Maniatis for the provision of data for the Hourly real wage index and Dr. Kotsios and Dr. Athanasiou for their

helpful comments. Address for correspondence: 71A, Em. Benaki st., GR-10681, Athens tel: 0030 210 3327722 e-mail: [email protected]

Page 2: Berlin Octorber 2011 Emilia Marsellou Consumer and corporate Debt

Recently, Bhaduri (2010) examined three interrelated facets of a financial crisis: the

evolution of a debt financed consumption boom supported by rising asset prices, a process

where consumer-borrowing driven by capital gains can lead to a ponzi borrowing and the

lack of short-term liquidity of the system as financial firms try to sell assets to cover the

defaulted loans. Charpe et al. (2009) in a Keynes-Goodwin model that incorporates

consumer debt investigate the stability conditions under different hypothesis about income

distribution, credit rationing and Central Bank’s policy against debt default. Charpe and

Flaschel (2011) investigate the conditions under which financial instability arises in the

event of household debt taking into account the functional income distribution and the

credit supply and they extend the analysis for the possibility of debt default and the role of

the adequacy ratio.

There is also a steadily growing empirical literature on households’ debt. Pollin (1988)

examined econometrically a series of demand-side explanations of the rise in net borrowing

to income and found that the latter had the major effect. Pollin (1990) and Blecker (1990)

provide further arguments that support these findings. Dabelle (2004) found that household

debt in a series of developed countries presents some common features such as the share of

the stock of debt increases with households’ income and wealth, the debt-income (wealth)

ratio is higher at the low and low-middle income (wealth) households, and the debt-service

ratio is higher for lower income households. The author concludes that rising household

debt makes households more sensitive to shocks to interest rates, income and asset prices.

Barba and Pivetti (2009) analyze household’s indebtedness in the US economy for the

period 1980-2005 and find the same features of household debt with Dabelle (2004). They

also find that it is stagnant wages combined with increasing inequality that caused the rise

in household debt and by that providing a solution to the problem of low demand within a

system which is based on unequal income distribution. By contrast, Maki (2000), based on

the standard life-cycle model, finds a positive correlation between consumer credit and

durable expenditures suggesting that consumer credit “is not primarily a bridge to get

household through tough times”. Maki and Palumbo (2001) argue that capital gains during

the 1990s contributed in large part to the rise in borrowing, since those upper-income

households that benefited the most from the rising prices of assets are those whose net

savings flows fell the most. These findings however are questioned by Barba and Pivetti

(2009) on the ground that even if wealth effects have led rich people to consume over their

rising incomes, which is quite implausible, this argument “is associated with the idea that

Page 3: Berlin Octorber 2011 Emilia Marsellou Consumer and corporate Debt

low and middle-income households would have nearly doubled their saving rate despite the

decline in the income share allotted to them”. Finally, Cynamon and Fazzari (2008),

explain the rise in household debt and in particular the tendency for higher consumption

expenditures, through the connection of the evolving social norms on which consumer

preferences are based with the changes in financial institutions that took place in the 1980s.

The authors argue that financial innovation in consumer finance along with consumerism

has shifted the locus of financial instability to the consumer sector. Contrary to the standard

life cycle model, the reason that the burst haven’t occurred until 2008 is the favorable

macroeconomic environment that sustained household debt obligations at reasonable levels

and not the rational smoothing of consumption during the last 25 years.

In this paper, we examine the short and long-run implications of consumer debt on income

distribution and growth. This model is an extension of Dutt’s (2006) model in several

ways. First, we capture the demand side explanation of households’ debt according to

which households borrow to sustain their standard of living in a period of growing

inequality and stagnant wages. Also, workers are assumed to set a ceiling of the debt

service burden they can afford and whenever their actual debt service burden exceeds it

they reduce borrowing. Second, we follow Marx’s analysis in Volume III of Capital (part

IV) and assume three classes: workers and industrial and financial capitalists. The latter

own commercial banks and their role is rather passive since their task is to collect interest

payments by workers and capitalists in order to provide new loans. Commercial banks are

the sole providers of credit. Third, we introduce corporate borrowing for investment

purposes.

Our economy is a mature monetary economy. Consumption and investment are partly

financed by borrowing and as a result borrowers accumulate debt. Credit is generated

endogenously. We deal only with consumer loans. Loans provided to industrial capitalists

are for investment purposes and assume away any other source of investment finance

(corporate bonds, share issuance). The only source of income for the working class is

wages, neglecting any dividends from ownership of shares of stock and interest income

accruing from deposits. Workers and industrial capitalists in every period repay some part

of their outstanding debt. Financial capitalists do not borrow.

In this basic model, we assume a closed economy without state intervention. The only

institution that intervenes is the Central Bank in the “passive” sense implied by the post-

Page 4: Berlin Octorber 2011 Emilia Marsellou Consumer and corporate Debt

Keynesian horizontalist2 monetary view. The CB sets the interest rate and provides the

necessary reserves for the financial sector when needed in pursuing its ultimate

responsibility of ensuring the liquidity of the system, implying that industrial capitalists and

workers always have access to credit. We assume away inflation and for simplicity a

common interest rate is applied for both consumption and corporate credit.

The rest of the paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 provides a brief review of the empirical

findings concerning the patterns of consumer debt in several counties and compares them

with the Greek case. Sections 3 and 4 outline the short-run and the long-run model,

respectively. In Section 5 we consider the implications of changes in the basic variables

and parameters. Section 6 concludes by considering the main results.

1. HOUSEHOLD BORROWING AND DEBT ACROSS COUNTRIES

Household indebtedness rose substantially in most developed countries over the past two or

three decades with a different timing and extent. For instance, Debelle (2004) finds that in

France, Japan, Italy and the United Kingdom household indebtedness grew more rapidly

during the 1980s, in Australia, the Netherlands and Denmark during the 1990s while in the

US it kept increasing steadily during the two decades. Several semi-industrialized

countries, such as India, have also experienced increases in consumer indebtedness (Dutt,

2006). Debelle (2004) for a number of developed countries and Barba and Pivetti (2009)

for the US find the following patterns of household debt: a) the share of the stock of debt

increases with households’ income and wealth, b) the debt-income (wealth) ratio is higher

at the low and low-middle income (wealth) households and c) the debt-service ratio is

higher for lower income households.

These patterns also characterize the household debt in Greece since 2000. Household

borrowing, consumer credit in particular which is our main interest, increased rapidly. It

took less than a decade to reach debt to income ratios that for other developed countries it

took several decades. As shown in Figure 1, in 1995 consumer debt was 1.5% of

households’ disposable income and 1.1% of GDP, in 2000 it was 4.9% and 3.4%,

respectively, while in 2009 the ratio more than quadrupled reaching 21.7% and 15.5%,

respectively.

                                                            2 The reader can trace the post-Keynesian ‘horizontalist’ monetary theory in Kaldor (1982, 1985), Lavoie (1992, 1996), Moore (1988, 1989) and Rousseas (1986).

Page 5: Berlin Octorber 2011 Emilia Marsellou Consumer and corporate Debt

Figure 1: Consumer Debt-Income Ratio, Greece. Source: CBG and AMECO (Net disposable income: households and NPISH).

These developments rely on both supply and demand side explanations. Financial

liberalization and the low interest rates that occurred with the adoption of Euro is definitely

the most prominent supply3 side explanation. The inability of Greece to raise its

competitiveness compared to the core European countries forced the Greek economy to

rely heavily on internal consumption and hence to consumer indebtedness.

Housing debt accounts for the most part of total household debt. The proportion of housing

to consumer debt was 3.5 in 1995. In the following decade this proportion fell and

stabilized around 2 implying that consumer credit was growing faster than housing. In

2011, during the Greek public debt crisis, the proportion increased slightly to 2.3 more

likely because it is easier to constrain consumer credit than to reduce the housing debt.

Table 1: Household debt as percentage of disposable income, GREECE

Total Outstanding

loans Housing Loans

Consumer Credit

Other Housing/Consumer

Loans

1995 6,6 5,1 1,5 3.5

2000 15,5 10,6 4,9 0,1 2.2

2005 47,0 30,6 15,2 1,2 2.0

2009 70,6 47,2 21,7 1,8 2.2 Source: CBG - AMECO (Net disposable income: h/h and NPISH). Authors’ Calculations.

Data from three surveys conducted by the Central Bank of Greece (CBG) in 2002, 2005

and 2007 show the aforementioned patterns of household’s indebtedness. In these surveys

the term “other loans” includes all non-housing bank loans, i.e. credit card borrowing and

                                                            3 The supply side explanations mostly concern the competition between financial institutions that induced banks to lower interest rates, relax credit rationing processes, remove debt burden ceilings, proliferate securitization etc.

0,02,55,07,5

10,012,515,017,520,022,525,0

Consumer Debt to Net Disposable Income (current prices)Consumer Debt to/Gross domestic product (current prices)

Page 6: Berlin Octorber 2011 Emilia Marsellou Consumer and corporate Debt

loans from private individuals with the latter being insignificant. In Figure 2, we observe

that the average consumer debt increases with income, while the median of consumer debt

as a percentage of household disposable income is negatively related to income-groups.

Figure 2: a) Average consumer debt by Income Group, b) Median of consumer debt as a % of disposable income by Income Group. Source: CBG, Sample Survey on household’s indebtedness 2002, 2005 and 2007.

Figure 3 below, shows for the years 2005 and 2007 (the only available data for this ratio)

the median of debt service to disposable income ratio by income group. The ratio increased

in all income groups and it is higher for lower income households. Note that it increased by

52.3% for the lower income group and only by 6.5% for the richer.

Figure 3: Median of debt service to disposable income ratio. Source: CBG, Sample Survey on household’s indebtedness 2005 and 2007.

 

It has been well documented that during the last 15-20 years many industrialized countries

have experienced increasing inequality as well as stagnant or anemically increasing wages.

These developments are seen as the demand-side causes for the rising household

indebtedness (Barba and Pivetty, 2009; Pollin 1988, 1990). In Figure 4 below we observe

the course of the hourly real wage index in Greece during the last 50 years. The index

0

2000

4000

6000

8000

10000

12000

7.500,00 7.501-15.000 15.001-25.00025.001-35.000 35.001+

2002 2005 2007

25,220,2

10,2 8,55,1

41,3

21,8

15,312,4 10,3

45,8

30,825,8

19,414,9

0,0

10,0

20,0

30,0

40,0

50,0

2002 2005 2007

28,3

21,6

15,8 14,210,7

43,1

24,1

18,2 17,8

11,4

0,0

10,0

20,0

30,0

40,0

50,0

<7500 7501-15000 15001-2500025001-35000 >35000

2005 2007

Page 7: Berlin Octorber 2011 Emilia Marsellou Consumer and corporate Debt

indicates that from 1985 to 1993 it fell by approximately 26.0% whereas it increased from

1994 until 2009, by 32.2%, only to reach the levels of 1985 in 2008. Meanwhile, the real

GDP grew almost twice this rate, by approximately 63.0%, during the period 1994-2008.

Thus, the picture that emerges is one in which workers even if they experienced increases

in real wages since 1995, they were in a worse financial position than they were more than

10 years before (1978-1985). This contradicts those suggesting that increasing household

indebtedness is the result of a rapidly rising income that led to a “consumption binge”, by

implying that for the period 1995-2008, during which the debt/income ratio rose (Figure 1),

real wages were not only below their historical high values but also below their trend-line

for a course that lasted almost 20 years.

Figure 4: Hourly Real Wage Index. Source: Hellenic Statistical Authority. National Accounts.

 

2. STRUCTURE OF THE MODEL

The economy produces a single good with two factors of production, homogeneous labour

(L) and capital (K). A fixed proportions production function is assumed and the production

coefficients are considered constant. The supply of labour grows at an exogenously given

rate. Firms function with excess capacity. Hence, since there is excess supply of labour,

output is constrained by the amount of the capital stock of the economy. The capital stock

is assumed fixed in the short-run and for simplicity there is no depreciation of capital.

Net National product, Y , is equal to the sum of consumption and investment and it is

distributed between wages, w L , and gross profits, .

( ) Pr n w IY wL wL iD Ind iD (1)

100103107110122

129137

146157

166174177

190190179

197

216

232

253250239

232

247240243

256

232

215223

224217

202195

189193198199

197208

201203

198

215219224224

233243

255263

75

100

125

150

175

200

225

250

275

19601962 196419661968 197019721974 197619781980 198219841986 198819901992 199419961998 200020022004 20062008

Hourly real wage index

Page 8: Berlin Octorber 2011 Emilia Marsellou Consumer and corporate Debt

with ( )nwL the net wage-income, wiD and IiD workers’ and industrial capitalists interest

payments, respectively, i the interest rate and PrInd the profits of enterprise. Financial

capitalists’ income at any point in time equals the sum of wiD and IiD . For simplicity, we

assume that financial capitalists save all their income in order to lend workers and

enterprises.

WORKERS

Workers borrow to finance part of their consumption. Thus, wage-income splits into net

wage-income and workers’ interest payments. Workers consume their entire net wage, so

workers’ consumption equals the sum of their net wage and the amount of new borrowing.

It follows that the propensity of workers’ consumption is larger than one. We denote with

wC workers borrowing-induced consumption.

(1 )w

w wdD

C Y iDdt

(2)

with Y

the share of gross profits. Another way of seeing (2) is by considering workers’

net borrowing, (1 ) ww wY

dDC iD

dt , as the difference between workers’ new

borrowing minus the interest payments which is equal to the level of consumption minus

the wage-income. A positive difference between consumption and wage-income must be

financed by an injection of credit, a negative difference implies that workers save in excess

of their interest payments while an equality implies that new borrowing equals interest

payments.

We assume that workers’ debt adjusts to new borrowing according to the following:

wW

dDB

dt (3)

Workers’ desired borrowing ( dWB ), is determined by the following partial adjustment

mechanism:

1 2(1 ) (1 )dW WB w L Y Y iD (4)

in which, 1 and 2 are two constant adjustment coefficients where 1 20 , 1 . These

coefficients are determined by workers’ behavior and reflect how quickly they set their

Page 9: Berlin Octorber 2011 Emilia Marsellou Consumer and corporate Debt

spending plans. If these coefficients are equal to unity, the adjustment of borrowing to

changes in current wages or in interest payments is instant. If they are less than unity,

borrowers adjust their borrowing demand gradually.

w is the wage target that workers set according to the socially determined standard of

living or in a similar way the “conventional wage”4. The wage target w is determined by

social conditions and in periods of intense income inequality together with conspicuous

consumption from the upper income class it tends to be higher than the real wage. This

induces workers to borrow in order to sustain their living standard5.

is the debt service to workers’ income ratio which is assumed constant and 0 1 .

determines workers’ maximum affordable interest payments as a percentage of their

income capturing workers’ prudency: a large represents a careless borrower while a low

a prudent one, given they do not face any borrowing constraints. In effect, it is workers

who set the ceilings on borrowing and initially they are all considered as creditworthy.

Equation (4) says that whenever the “conventional wage” exceeds current wage desired

borrowing by workers will increase as a result of workers struggle to sustain their living

standard, and vice versa. Similarly, whenever the “ceiling” of interest payments exceeds

the actual interest payments, workers will increase borrowing6. This ceiling however

depends on the level of current wage too and therefore changes in current wage affect both

terms of (4) towards the opposite direction (i.e. a potential fall in current wage will have a

positive effect on borrowing due to the increase of the difference between “conventional

wage” and current wage and a negative effect due to the fall in the “ceiling” of interest

payments). Rearranging (4) we take the following relation:

1 2 2 1( )(1 )dW W

wL

B Y iD w L (5)

                                                            4 We find this term in Marglin (1984) and it is similar to the subsistence wage used by classical economists such as Marx, Smith and Ricardo. This term takes into account the biological as well as the historical and cultural conditions of any period of time. 5 Pollin (1988, 1990) uses the term “necessitous demand for credit” to describe this phenomenon. Household’s tendency to sustain their living standard can also be traced back in the writings of Duesenberry (1949) as well as in Veblen (1899). 6 This formulation draws from empirical and experimental research on microfinance suggesting that the amount of borrowing demanded is affected differently by changes in income, interest rates and interest payments. In particular, interest payments (proxied by the loan maturity) have a much more significant effect on the borrowing demand than the cost of borrowing especially for the low and middle income borrowers (Karlan and Zinman, 2007; Attanasio et al., 2007).

Page 10: Berlin Octorber 2011 Emilia Marsellou Consumer and corporate Debt

where 1 2( ) is the sensitivity of workers’ borrowing to changes in current wages

where it is assumed 1 2 , and 1 2( )(1 ) expresses the additional amount of

workers’ borrowing due to a change in output. 2 now reflects the sensitivity of workers’

borrowing to changes in interest payments, while 1 shows the effect of any change in the

“conventional wage” on borrowing where the positive sign reflects their positive relation.

INDUSTRIAL CAPITALISTS

As noted before, gross profits are distributed to the owners of the capitalist firm as profits

of enterprise and to its lenders as interest payments. Industrial capitalists pay dividends to

the stakeholders of the company and they save the rest of the profits of the enterprise i.e.

the retained profits. The retention rate (or the business propensity to save), s, is assumed

constant. Retained profits are saved in order to finance future investment plans. In contrast,

dividends are used by their owners (members of the industrial capitalist class) for

consumption. For simplicity, we assume away any other source of income of financial

capitalists except from interest payments.

Pr

Pr (1 ) PrI I

Ind

R Div iD sInd s Ind iD , where Pr IInd iD (6)

where R denotes the retained profits, s the retention rate and Div are the dividends.

Industrial capitalists’ consumption function cC is given by:

(1 )( )IcC s id Y (7)

where Iid is the interest payments of industrial capitalists as a share of national income.

Investment demand in the short-run is assumed fixed. We denote the investment rate, that

is the growth rate of K , as:

Ig

K (8)

where I is gross and net investment since we ignore depreciation. However, in the long-run

we assume that industrial capitalists adjust their actual investment rate to their desired rate

of investment using the formula7 below:

                                                            7 This formulation is common in the Post-Keynesian literature (see for instance Jarsulic (1990), Dutt (2006, 1995), Charles (2008)).

Page 11: Berlin Octorber 2011 Emilia Marsellou Consumer and corporate Debt

ddgg g

dt (9)

where dg is the desired accumulation rate and is the adjustment speed where0 1 .

Formulation (9) implies that whenever the desired rate of accumulation is above the current

rate, the actual rate will rise.

The desired level of industrial capitalists’ borrowing is given by the following:

I IB b id Y , 0b (10)

where π is the gross profit share. Industrial capitalists’ level of borrowing is a fraction of

the profits of enterprise. For simplicity we abstract from any other financing costs except

from interest. Coefficient b can be taken as a proxy of the leverage ratio. This ratio can be

determined either by bank lending practices or by industrial capitalists’ decisions. The

latter allows for a consideration of b as capitalists’ propensity to borrow. Equation (10)

says that there is a positive relationship between firm’s borrowing and gross profits and a

negative to interest payments. This relation captures Kalecki’s (1937) principle of

increasing risk’ according to which diminished internal means of finance for real

investment purposes reduce access to external means of finance in imperfectly competitive

capital markets.

Note that industrial capitalists do not borrow in the short-run and hence their stock of debt

is fixed, i.e. 0 II

dDB

dt and thus b=0. However, following Hein (2006) and Lavoie

(1995) their debt-to-income ratio is taken into account because of past borrowing.

New borrowing IdD

dt has a positive impact on desired investment dI .

( ) ( )Id r I r I

dDI id Y b id

dt (11)

Where r , captures the sensitivity of desired investment to the profits of enterprise and

0 1r . Equation (11) reflects classical economists’ view of the centrality of the profits

of enterprise on investment decisions.

Page 12: Berlin Octorber 2011 Emilia Marsellou Consumer and corporate Debt

3. THE SHORT-RUN MODEL

In the short-run we assume that firms function with excess capacity so that the level of

output adjusts in response to aggregate demand. It is also assumed that the levels of debt,

capital stock and investment are given. So, short-run equilibrium is given by:

w cY C C I (12)

Assuming dW WB B and inserting 4 into 2 and then the resulting into 12, inserting 8 into 12

and then normalizing by K we get:

1 2 2 1(1 )(1 ) (1 ) (1 )( )W Iu u i w l s u i g (13)

with Yu =

K the rate of capacity utilization, 1 2(1 ) the sensitivity of workers’

consumption to changes in the wage-income and 1 20 1 1 for reasonable values

of * and 1w l reflecting the impact of conventional wage on workers’ consumption

which can also be seen as a proxy of workers’ autonomous consumption. Also, Ww

D

K is

the stock of worker’s debt-to-capital ratio and L

lK the fixed technological coefficient of

labor-capital ratio. If we solve for u we take the short-run equilibrium value of capacity

utilization u :

1 2

1 2

(1 ) (1 )

(1 )( )wg w l i s i

us

   (14)

The stability of the short-run equilibrium requires that the denominator in (14) is positive8.

To ensure that we always have a positive u we also require that the numerator in (14) is

positive. Moreover, the standard macroeconomic stability condition requires the savings

rate to respond more elastically to changes in capacity utilization than the investment rate

does. This implies that the denominator in (14) (which is the sensitivity of the saving rate to

changes in capacity utilization) must exceed the r term (which is the sensitivity of the

investment rate to changes in capacity utilization) derived by (11) after the normalization

by K and the differentiation with respect to u.

                                                            8 Obviously, all terms are positive.

Page 13: Berlin Octorber 2011 Emilia Marsellou Consumer and corporate Debt

Thus the stability condition in the goods market requires thatS Idg dg

du du is satisfied, i.e.:

1 2(1 )( ) rs (15)

We now examine the effects of changes in the variables and parameters of the model on the

short-run equilibrium level of the rate of capacity utilization. Through partial derivation of

(14) with respect to W , Id , g , 1 , 2 , w , , , s and i we have: 0gu , 0w

u ,

0u , 0du

, 0

wu , 0iu , 0su , 0u depending on 1 2( )s ,

10u

depending on * (1 )w l u and 2

0u depending on (1 ) Wi .

As expected for a demand-driven model the investment rate, g , the conventional wage w

and the interest burden on income have a positive effect on capacity utilization. In

contrast, workers’ debt-capital ratio, W , industrial capitalists’ debt-income ratio,

Id , the

interest rate, i , and the retention rate s have a negative impact on capacity utilization.

However, the two parameters 1 and

2 and the gross profit share may have either

positive or negative impact on capacity utilization.

First we consider an increase in worker’s debt-capital ratio. It has a contractionary effect on

u because it redistributes income from workers who consume to financial capitalists, who

neither consume nor invest. There are two channels through which a higher W affects

aggregate demand: it reduces the net wage and therefore consumption and curtails worker’s

borrowing that finance consumption. A similar effect on u has a rise in the interest rate.

The profits of enterprise are also negatively affected by an increase in the rate of interest

yet there is no impact on investment in the short-run but only a distributional outcome

toward financial capitalists’ income.

A higher industrial capitalist’s debt-output ratio Id also impacts negatively u because the

profits of enterprise (as well as the share of profits of enterprise) and thus the dividends

will decrease resulting to a fall in capitalists’ consumption. Again there is no investment

side effect but only a distributional one.

A fall (increase) in the retention rate has a positive (negative) impact on u reflecting the

Paradox of the thrift. This happens because part of retained profits that are saved to finance

future investment plans are directed to current consumption resulting to an increase in

aggregate demand.

Page 14: Berlin Octorber 2011 Emilia Marsellou Consumer and corporate Debt

As in Dutt (2006), in the short-run although changes in the capacity utilization have no

effect in the rate of accumulation and hence the growth of the economy, they do affect

income distribution. Thus, increases in u are not translated into investment yet the

accumulated profits that derive by increasing demand increase the share of profits (of

enterprise). This happens because with the stock of capital constant, industrial profits

increase and temporarily the profit share increases. Yet, in the long-run as K starts to

expand the profit share will return to its initial level.

For 1 depends on whether current wages are greater or lower than the conventional wages

while for 2 it depends on whether the maximum affordable part of wages that goes to

interest payments is greater or lower than the actual interest payments.

Finally, for it depends on whether the propensity to save out of profits, s, is greater than

workers’ propensity to borrow, 1 2 . If the former exceeds the later the effect of the

share of profits of enterprises on capacity utilization will be negative and vice versa. Note

that the term 1 2s expresses also the derivative of (Sdg

du) with respect to the share

of gross profits. This implies that if s is higher than the propensity of workers to borrow

then the increase in the saving rate with respect to capacity utilization will be increasing

while on the contrary, if s is lower than the propensity of workers to borrow the increase in

the saving rate will be decreasing. On the other hand, concerning the rate of investment, the

derivative of (Idg

du) with respect to the share of gross profits is equal to 0r . It follows

that other things being equal, the 1 2 s case will eventually lead to the failure of the

standard macroeconomic stability condition and therefore we assume 1 2 s .

4. THE LONG-RUN MODEL

The two dimensional case

In order to study the dynamics of the model we have to reduce the above equations into a

three-dimensional system of differential equations. We are interested on the dynamics of

the state variables g , w and I . However, the analysis first starts with the two dimension

case, in which we assume that industrial capitalists do not borrow so that b=0, and

concentrate on the g and w dynamics. For simplicity henceforth we use this notation:

*1 21 , *

1 2 1 A and 1 2(1 )( )s .

Page 15: Berlin Octorber 2011 Emilia Marsellou Consumer and corporate Debt

The differential equation describing the path of w (overhats denote growth rates) is

specified as follows,

w WD K

(16)

Inserting (3), (5) and (8) into (16) and assuming dW WB B we obtain:

*

1 2(1 )(1- )(1- ) ] (1- )(1- ) - - (1- )(1- )- [

Iw w wsg s i sd w

dt

A l A i A

(17)

The term (1- )(1- )A w is positive. Second, the term 2 - (1- )(1- )As is also positive and

reflects the relation between capitalists’ and workers’ contribution to savings due to

changes in capacity utilization. It’s plausible to assume that the capitalist class, as a whole,

has a higher tendency to save than workers’ do and this is assumed to hold even if β2 is

lower than one, provided that the term in question remains positive.

The dynamic path of the rate of accumulation is specified by (9), in which (11) normalized

by K and (14) are inserted. Then we get:

1 2(1 ) (1 )wr

dg

g

dt

g w l i s ii

(18)

where we have already assumed that the denominator r is positive as well as the

numerators of the intercept and the slope are.

The vertical asymptote of the 0wd

dt

isocline rests in the second quadrant and its

expression is given by (1 )(1 )

W

A

while the horizontal is 2- (1- )

0(1- )

gs A

which is below the horizontal axis but pretty close to it. Since our intention is to focus on

consumer credit and its effect on growth we concentrate only to the first quadrant and

specifically the area above the LIM line which represents the

1 2(1 ) (1 )wg w l i s i condition (see 14).

Given the above conditions, the paths of g and w are shown in the Figure 5 below. As we

can observe there are two equilibrium points A and B, the former corresponding to a

positive but low rate of accumulation combined with high workers’ debt-to-capital ratio

Page 16: Berlin Octorber 2011 Emilia Marsellou Consumer and corporate Debt

while the later corresponds to a combination of a positive and high rate of accumulation

with low levels of workers’ debt-to-capital ratio.

Figure 5: Dynamics of workers’ debt-to-capital ratio and the rate of accumulation

In what follows we deduce the stability properties of the dynamical system, consisting of

(17) and (18), algebraically. The stability requires that the Jacobian Matrix gives [ ] 0Det J

and [ ] 0tr J .

The Jacobian Matrix is the following:

2(1 )(1 ) (1 )(1

[

)

]

ww

w

g

r r g

g i A u A uJ

u u

(19)

Evaluating the determinant of the Jacobian at equilibrium point A9 we obtain

[ , ] 0

w

Det g , which means that it is a saddle point, since , and are

always positive.

Evaluating the Determinant at equilibrium point B we obtain:

[ , ] 0

w

Det g (20)

while the trace is given by the following expression which is always negative since all the

terms are positive10:

2 2[ ( , )][ (1 )(1 )(1 )]

w

rtr J gi

g

(21)

                                                            9 See Appendix 1. 10 See Appendix 1.

Page 17: Berlin Octorber 2011 Emilia Marsellou Consumer and corporate Debt

Hence the equilibrium point B is asymptotically stable.

Consequently, the economy will converge at B while if it reach A the economy will be

driven to negative values of growth and capacity utilization. Actually, this two-dimensional

case of the model suggests that structural instability is inherent to the model without the

need to rely in any special assumption about over-indebtedness. In essence, it shows that

the engagement of workers to borrowing as a result of their struggle to sustain their living

standards introduces instability into the system by itself. In other words, even if the real

side of the economy is stable, which is given by the standard macroeconomic stability

condition, financial variables may be sources of instability that destabilize the economy

(Dutt, 1995). Moreover, instability mostly appears there where the rate of growth is low11.

Note, also, that changes in the parameters of the system only change the volume of

structural stability12. Otherwise stated, whether equilibrium points tend to come closer,

instability increases because a sudden shock might produce oscillations able to move the

system from the stable to the unstable path, while when they become more distant

instability falls (Jarsulic, 1990). In Figure 6 below, the vector field of the system is

illustrated.

Figure 6: Phase Diagram

We first examine the area close to equilibrium point A. It is clear that no matter in which of

the sectors in the neighborhood of A the system begins, all the forces push the system away

from A and towards B. This happens even if a trajectory crosses from one sector into

another. Let us consider equilibrium point B. Starting from a point close to B, for instance

at the south-east of B. There the actual investment rate is less than the desired rate implying

                                                            11 Jarsulic (1990), Dutt (1995) and Charles (2008) also find the high-growth eq. point as the stable one. 12 This is also found in Jarsulic (1990).

B

A

-0.5 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0 2.5 3.0δω

-0.4

-0.2

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1.0g

Page 18: Berlin Octorber 2011 Emilia Marsellou Consumer and corporate Debt

that enterprises will tend to raise their actual investment rate. Aggregate demand, output

and capacity utilization will increase in consequence and this will make workers to reduce

the desired level of borrowing which will decelerate their stock of debt. Eventually, the

workers’ debt-to-capital ratio ( w ) will fall. However, this fall in workers’ debt, will

increase consumption, aggregate demand and capacity utilization which will increase the

desired rate of investment making the actual rate to rise even more. At the same time, the

abovementioned fall in workers’ debt will induce workers to increase the desired level of

borrowing and accelerate the accumulation of debt. Given that the slope of the 0dg

dt

isocline is lower than that of 0wd

dt

, the combined outcome will be that w

will increase.

The previous increase in workers’ debt will reduce the desired level of borrowing

decelerating the stock of debt. In the meanwhile, the actual rate of investment surpasses the

desired rate and thus the former will start to fall. As a consequence, w will rise.

Eventually, the increase in workers’ debt reduces workers’ consumption, aggregate

demand, capacity utilization and hence the desired rate of accumulation making the actual

rate to fall. As workers’ debt has already fallen (due to the fall of desired borrowing

resulting from the increased interest payments), w will start to fall again because the slope

of the 0wd

dt

isocline is higher than that of 0

dg

dt .

On the other hand, if we start from a point in the proximity of A, the economy will be

trapped in a downward spiral of increasing indebtedness, w , and falling rate of

accumulation that will eventually lead to zero levels of growth.

Sources of instability and macrodynamics

We can now examine the impact of changes in the parameters of the two dimensional

model on the long-run equilibrium points. We will examine changes in r , the interest rate

i , the adjustment coefficients 1 and 2 , the retention rate s, the profit share σ and the

debt service burden λ*.

Page 19: Berlin Octorber 2011 Emilia Marsellou Consumer and corporate Debt

Figure 7: Increase in γr Figure 8: Increase in the Interest Rate

Figure 9: Increase in β1 Figure 10: Increase in β2

Figure 11: Increase in the gross profit share π Figure 11: Increase in the retention rate s

Figure 12: Increase in λ*

Page 20: Berlin Octorber 2011 Emilia Marsellou Consumer and corporate Debt

Let us first consider an increase in r (the coefficient that shows the responsiveness of

investment to changes in the profit of enterprise). It will affect only the desired investment

function shifting upwards the 0dg

dt isocline, leaving the 0w

d

dt

isocline unaffected

(Figure 7). This implies that the long-run equilibrium point A moves slightly to the right

(Α’) while point B has a clear movement towards left (B’). This change implies that other

things equal if industrial capitalists invest a larger proportion of their profits of enterprise

they can achieve higher levels of growth ( g ) for any given level of workers’ debt-to-

capital ratio ( w ). Hence, in the region of low workers’ indebtedness, growth and income

distribution for workers (in relation to financial capitalists) improve. Note, however, that,

concerning the saddle point A, there is a slight deterioration of both growth and income

distribution. This is quite plausible since in the region of highly indebted workers capacity

utilization will be below some acceptable level and thus any increase in investment would

only expand excess capacity. This implies that if the economy reached the region of A an

increase in animal spirits would not be sufficient to move the economy towards the stable

path, on the contrary it will move the economy to an even worse position. Therefore, only a

strong state intervention might create an effective shock that will make the system jump

away from the unstable trajectory. The increase in r reduces the instability of the system

since it makes the two points more distant. However, note that if the economy is already at

the saddle point, the more distant it is from the stable path an increasingly stronger shock

will be needed for the economy to escape from its trajectory.

An increase in the interest rate shifts the 0wd

dt

isocline (not visible in Figure 8)

downward while it makes the 0dg

dt isocline steeper (Figure 8). B’ remains almost at the

same position ( g falls slightly and w increases slightly) but A’ corresponds to a lower w

and a higher g . Note, that by increasing i income distribution improves for workers at the

expense of financial capitalists because they reduce borrowing (although in the short-run

the opposite happens)13. The critical points move closer and therefore the instability of the

system increases.

                                                            13 This is also found in Dutt (2006).

Page 21: Berlin Octorber 2011 Emilia Marsellou Consumer and corporate Debt

An increase in 1 (workers’ borrowing responds less gradually to changes in wages) shifts

the 0wd

dt

isocline in a counter-clockwise direction and 0

dg

dt isocline becomes flatter

(Figure 9). A’ reflects a higher w and an ambiguous whereas negligible change in g , while

B’ a lower g while w changes slightly in an ambiguous direction depending on the

volume of the change in the 0wd

dt

isocline. At A’, the increase in w implies a definite

deterioration of income distribution for workers in relation to financial capitalists and a fall

in capacity utilization as a result of the relatively constant g and the increase in w . As far

as B’ is concerned, the affect on capacity utilization is negative because it is affected

negatively by g while w remains almost constant. The new equilibrium points become

more distant so the system reduces its instability.

An increase in 2 (workers’ borrowing responds less gradually to changes in interest

payments) shifts the 0wd

dt

isocline slightly in a clockwise direction and the 0

dg

dt

isocline becomes steeper (Figure 10). A’ reflects a lower w and a slightly higher g , and B’

reflects a higher g while the effect on w is ambiguous. At both A’ and B’ capacity

utilization and income distribution improve. The instability of the system increases because

A’B’ move towards a steeper region in the Figure and hence come closer.

An increase in (gross profit share) swifts upwards both the 0dg

dt

and the 0w

d

dt

isoclines (Figure 11). The new equilibrium point A’ reflects a higher w and a lower g ,

while B’ a higher g but an ambiguous change in w . So, the growth of the economy is

profit led at the area of B while it is wage led around the point A. At point A’, the increase

in w implies that income distribution and capacity utilization fall while at B’ the opposite

happens. The two new points become more distant so instability decreases14.

An increase in s (retention rate), swifts downwards the 0dg

dt isocline and upwards the

0wd

dt

(Figure 12). B’ corresponds to a lower g and a slightly higher w , while A’ to a

                                                            14 This is also found in Jarsulic (1990).

Page 22: Berlin Octorber 2011 Emilia Marsellou Consumer and corporate Debt

lower w and a slightly higher g . At B’ both income distribution and capacity utilization

deteriorate while the opposite happens at A. The two points move closer increasing the

instability of the system.

An increase in λ* (workers’ debt service burden ceiling) swifts upwards both the 0dg

dt

and the 0wd

dt

isoclines (Figure 13). B’ corresponds to a higher g while the effect on w

is ambiguous and small, and A’ to a higher w while the effect on g is ambiguous and

small. At B’ capacity utilization improves because g increases significantly while w

changes slightly whereas the status of income distribution is ambiguous. On the contrary, in

A’ capacity utilization deteriorates because w improves substantially while g roughly

changes, whereas income distribution exacerbates. Furthermore, note that the two points

become more distant decreasing the instability of the system, implying that higher

borrowing expands the stable region of B’. This is because it enhances growth and capacity

utilization which in turn creates higher profits of enterprise and retained earnings. In other

words the capital stock will grow at a sufficiently high rate to keep the w rate low.

The three dimensional case

In this section the three-dimensional case is considered, where the dynamics of workers’

and industrial capitalists’ debt and the rate of accumulation interact. Note that the dynamics

of workers’ debt and the rate of accumulation are the same as before with the only

difference that in (25) below 0b . The dynamics of corporate debt are given by:

I ID K

(22)

Inserting (8), (10) and (14) into (22) we obtain:

1 2(1 ) (1 )w II

db

dt

g wl i s ii g

(23)

The rest as said before are:

*

1 2(1 )(1- )(1- ) ] (1- )(1- ) - - (1- )(1- )- [

Iw w wsg s i sd w

dt

A l A i A

(24)

Page 23: Berlin Octorber 2011 Emilia Marsellou Consumer and corporate Debt

1 2(1 ) (1 )( ) w I

r

d

dg

g

t

g w l i s ib i

(25)

By solving this system we get three equilibrium points: one that corresponds to a

combination of a positive and high rate of accumulation with low levels of workers’ debt-

to-capital ratio and positive corporate-debt-to-capital ratio (A), one that corresponds to a

positive but low rate of accumulation combined with high workers’ debt-to-capital ratio

and positive corporate-debt-to-capital ratio (B) and one with zero capital accumulation

positive, positive workers’ debt-to-capital ratio and negative corporate-debt-to-capital ratio

(C). The stability of these critical points is examined by using the Routh—Hurwitz

Theorem. The Routh—Hurwitz conditions for the stability of the three-dimensional

dynamical system require that the Trace (J) < 0, det(J1) + det(J2) + det(J3) > 0, det(J) < 0

and -Trace(J)(detJ1+detJ2+detJ3)+ det(J)>0.

Plugging the critical points into the Routh-Hurwitz conditions we find that A is

asymptotically stable, and B and C are unstable15. These results show that the stability

characteristics of the two-dimensional system are sustained with the introduction of

industrial capitalists’ borrowing. As in the two dimensional case it is the high rates of

accumulation and the low level of consumer debt that ensures stability.

CONCLUSIONS

In this paper we introduced consumer credit in a basic post-Keynesian model of growth and

income distribution and examined its short-run and long-run effects. Workers set two

targets: one for their standard of living and borrow to fill the gap between their wage and

consumption and one for the level of interest payments which they consider they can

afford. In the short-run our findings are common with the other papers that deal with

household borrowing: it boosts consumer demand and capacity utilization yet the interest

payments decelerate this tendency. In the long run, however, consumer credit creates

endogenous instability by resulting to two equilibrium points: a stable and a saddle. We

then examined the effects of changes in the parameters of the system and found that r , 1 ,

and * reduce the instability of the system while i , 2 and s increase it. None of the

                                                            15 See Appendix 2.

Page 24: Berlin Octorber 2011 Emilia Marsellou Consumer and corporate Debt

parameters is sufficient to reverse the downward course of the economy or to jump to the

stable path once the system reaches the unstable path. Any policy that would push the

system from the unstable to the stable path is exogenous to the system. The only possible

effective intervention might be either a strong shock by public investments that would

create income without altering income distribution between workers and industrial

capitalists but would certainly reduce borrowing and thus the debt-income ratio while at the

same time the growth rate would increase rapidly or a massive “hair-cut” on workers’ debt

partially backed by the Central Bank so that there will be no lack of liquidity in the system

and the rate of accumulation will remain unaffected. Finally, the introduction of capitalists’

borrowing in the three dimensional system produces one stable equilibrium point which

corresponds to a high level of rate of accumulation and a low level of workers’ debt to

capital stock and two unstable points: one with a low level of rate of accumulation and a

high level of workers’ debt to capital stock and one with a zero level of rate of

accumulation, a positive level of workers’ debt to capital stock and a negative level of

capitalists’ debt to capital stock.

Appendix 1.

Equilibrium point A is of the following form:

*1 2 2

2

( ) [ (1 )(1 )] [ (1 ) ]

2 (1 )r r

w Ar

w l i i s i s

i

*1 2 2( ) [ (1 )(1 )] [ (1 ) ]

2[ ]r r

Ar

w l i i s i sg

and B:

*1 2 2

2

( ) [ (1 )(1 )] [ (1 ) ]

2 (1 )r r

wr

w l i i s i s

i

*1 2 2( ) [ (1 )(1 )] [ (1 ) ]

2[ ]r r

r

w l i i s i sg

Where Δ:

* *2 1 1

2*1 2 2 2

4 (1 ) (1 )(1 )[ (1 )] ( ) (1 )(1 )

( ) [ (1 )(1 )(1 )] [ (1 ) ]

r r I r

r r

i A w l i s w l A i

w l i i i s

We have assumed that Δ>0 so that the system (17)-(18) has two roots.

Page 25: Berlin Octorber 2011 Emilia Marsellou Consumer and corporate Debt

Numerical simulations give a positive sign for Δ (we set the following parameter values

γr=0,7, π=0,55, i=0,05, w*=0.50, β1=0.9, β2=1, Γ=0,720, Α=0,5, s=0.9 and dI=0.35) and we

obtain Δ=0.017, { w A Aδ =3.74, g =0.06 }, { w B Bδ =0.37, g =0.45 }.

Appendix 2.

The 3x3 dynamical system (23)-(25) has three equilibrium points.

The Jacobian of the dynamical system (23)-(25) is:

2 2

2

2

(1 )(1 )(1 ) (1 )(1 ) (1 )(1 )(1 )

( ) (1 ) ( ) (1 )( )

(1 ) (1 )

w

r rr

i i A A i A sg

i b b sJ b i

bi b sg bi

The Routh – Hurwitz necessary and sufficient conditions for the local asymptotic stability

are: Det(J)<0, Tr(J)<0, Det(J1)+Det(J2)+Det(J3)>0, –Tr(J)(DetJ1+DetJ2+DetJ3)+ Det(J)>0.

Equilibrium point A satisfies the Routh – Hurwitz necessary and sufficient conditions for the local asymptotic stability.

Proof:

2 * 2 2* * 1 2 2

2

2 1 2

( ) ( ) [ (1 )(1 )] [ (1 )]( )( , , ) ( ,

2 ( ) (1 )2

, )( ) (1 )(1 )(1 ) ( ) (1 ) [ ( )]

2( )[ ( ) ]

r

r r r

rr r

b w l i i s A i s brA g Aw I i b r

b

b

b i A w l b ib s i b

b b

The determinant of J at eq. point A is the following:

2 1 2

2

( ) (1 )(1 )(1 ) ( ) (1 ) [ ( )][ ]

2( ) [ ( ) ]

r r r

A

r

b i A w l b ib s i bDet J

b br

[ ]ADet J is negative if we want the eq. point A to reflect a positive g (along with a positive

w and I ). Obviously, 2 1 2(1 )(1 )(1 ) ( ) (1 ) [ ( )]r ri A w l b ib s i b .

The trace of the Jacobian at point A is equal to the following:

2(2 ) [ (1 )(1 )] [ (1 )] ( )

[ ] 0A r

A

g i s A ib s bTr J

Page 26: Berlin Octorber 2011 Emilia Marsellou Consumer and corporate Debt

We assume that 2

(2 ) [ (1 )(1 )] [ (1 )] ( )A r

g i s A ib s b so that the trace is negative. We now take the determinants of the three principal minors at point A which they come out to be positive and thus their sum is positive:

1

( ) (1 )( )

(1 )

r

r

A

A

A

b sb i

Jb s

g bi

2 1 2

1

( ) (1 )(1 )(1 ) ( ) (1 ) [ ( )][ ]

2( )

r r r

A

r

b i A w l b ib s i bDet J

b

which is positive since we have already assumed

2 1 2(1 )(1 )(1 ) ( ) (1 ) [ ( )]

r ri A w l b ib s i b .

2 2

2

2

(1 )(1 )(1 ) (1 )(1 )(1 )

(1 ) (1 )

A

A

i i A i A sg

Jbi s

g bi

Since a11<0, a33<0, a31<0 and a13>0 it comes out that 2[ ] 0ADet J .

3[ ] 0

( )A

r

Det Jb

The above imply that 1 2 3[ ] [ ] [ ] 0A A ADet J Det J Det J

Assuming a strong trace we obtain a positive sign for the last stability condition

1 2 3[ ] [ ] [ ] [ ] [ ] 0B B B B BTr J Det J Det J Det J Det J

This implies that according to the following relation Γ and s have to be large implying that the sensitivity of savings with respect to changes in capacity utilization is large and the propensity to save out of profits is also large

2(2 ) [ (1 )(1 )] [ (1 )] ( )A rg i s A ib s b . These assumptions

imply that industrial capitalists have a weak reliance on external finance.

Equilibrium point B fails to satisfy all the Routh – Hurwitz criteria so it is unstable.

Proof:

The equilibrium point B is the following:

Page 27: Berlin Octorber 2011 Emilia Marsellou Consumer and corporate Debt

2 * 2 2* * 1 2 2

2

*

2 2 1

( ) ( ) [ (1 )(1 )] [ (1 )]( )( , , ) ( ,

2 ( ) (1 )2

( ) [ ( )] [ (1 )] (1 )(1 )(1 ) ( ), )

2( )[ ( ) ]

r

w I

r r r

rr r

rb w l i i s A i s bB g B

i b r

b i b ib s i A w l b b

b b b

Equilibrium point B has to reflect a positive g, which implies

*2 2 1[ ( )] [ (1 )] (1 )(1 )(1 ) ( )r ri b ib s i A w l b .

From this it follows that:

*

2 2 1

2

( ) [ ( )] [ (1 )] (1 )(1 )(1 ) ( )[ ] 0

2( ) [ ( ) ]

r r r

Br r

b i b ib s i A wl bDet J

b b

This means that the Det(JB) < 0 requirement for stability fails.

Equilibrium point C fails to satisfy all the Routh – Hurwitz criteria so it is unstable.

Proof:

The equilibrium point C is the following:

* *

2 2

* *1 1

[(1 )(1 ) [ (1 ) ]] [(1 )(1 ) [ (1 ) ]]( , , ) ,0,w I

w l w l

i A i s s i A i s sC g C

The determinant and the trace of the Jacobian Matrix at equilibrium point C is negative since all the terms of the numerators are positive.

2 2 2 1

*[ (1 )(1 )(1 )] (1 ) ( )

[ ] 0r

c

i ib A ib s w l bDet J

2 2[ (1 )(1 )(1 )] [ (1 ) ] [ ( ) ]

[ ] 0rc

i A ib s bTr J

We now examine the determinants of the three principal minors at C:

1

( ) (1 )( )

(1 )

r

r

C

C

b sb i

Jb s

g bi

J21>0 is positive because C is negative: 2

*1 0

[(1 )(1 ) [ (1 ) ]]Cw l

i A i s s

, so we have that

J11<0, J22<0, J12<0 and J21>0 and thus 1 0J .

Page 28: Berlin Octorber 2011 Emilia Marsellou Consumer and corporate Debt

We have that the second principal minor of the Jacobian at C is positive and very low

(because of the very low term 2bi

and the fact that gc=0).

2

2 2[ ] (1 )(1 ) 0

c

biDet J A

From the third minor principal we have:

2 2

3

2

(1 )(1 )(1 ) (1 )(1 )

( ) (1 ) ( )

wC

C

r r

i i A Ag

Ji b b

where J11<0, J22<0, J12<0 and J21<0 which implies that the determinant is either positive or

negative. However, we now that at point C 2

*1 0

[(1 )(1 ) [ (1 ) ]]wCw l

i A i s s

is very high

while gc=0, so it is safe to consider this determinant as negative and high. Given the above considerations we can reach the conclusion that the sum of the determinants of the principal minors is negative:

3

1 2

1 2 2 2

2

[ ] [ ] [ ]

1 *( ) [ ] [ (1 )(1 )] [ (1 )(1 ) [ (1 ) ]] 0

r

Det J Det J Det J

b w l i bi A i s A b s

This means that the 3

1 2[ ] [ ] [ ] 0Det J Det J Det J condition fails which makes the

[ ] [ ] [ ] [ ] [ ] 01 2 3Tr J Det J Det J Det J Det JB BB B B condition to fail as well.

Simulations result to the same conclusions.

Table: Simulation Results  

Parameter set

i=0.05, λ*=0.3, b=0.1, β1=0.9, β2=Λ=1, Α=0.5, γr=0.7, π=0.55, Γ=0.720, w*l=0.5

Results:

Equilibrium Point A {δw=0.145, g=0.7, δΙ=0.125}

Det[J]= -0.161, Tr[J]= -1.754, Det[J1]+ Det[J2]+ Det[J3]= 0.966

-Tr[J]*(Det[J1]+ Det[J2]+ Det[J3])+ Det[J]= 1.54

Equilibrium Point B {δw=4.074, g=0.053, δΙ=0.125}

Det[J] = 0.0127, Tr[J]= -0.52, Det[J1]+ Det[J2]+ Det[J3]= -0.215

-Tr[J]*(Det[J1]+Det[J2]+Det[J3])+Det[J]= -0.098

Equilibrium Point C {δw=15.2308, g=0, δΙ=-15.2308}

Det[J] = -0.014 , Tr[J]= -0.413 , Det[J1]+ Det[J2]+ Det[J3]= -0.281

-Tr[J]*(Det[J1] + Det[J2] + Det[J3]) + Det[J]= -0.130

References

Page 29: Berlin Octorber 2011 Emilia Marsellou Consumer and corporate Debt

Attanasio O. P., Goldberg P. K., Kyriazidou E. (2007): ‘Credit Constraints in the Market for Consumer Durables: Evidence from Micro Data on Car Loans’, International Economic Review, 49(2), pp. 401–36.

Barba A., Pivetti M., (2009): ‘Rising household debt: Its causes and macroeconomic implications—a long-period analysis’, Cambridge Journal of Economics, No 33, pp. 113–137.

Blecker R. (1990): Are Americans on a consumption binge? The evidence reconsidered, Economic Policy Institute.

Bhaduri A. (2010): ‘A Contribution to the Theory of Financial Fragility and Crisis’, Working Paper No 593, The Levy Economics Institute.

Charles S. (2008): ‘A Post-Keynesian Model of Accumulation with a Minskyan Financial Structure’, Review of Political Economy, 20:3, 319-331.

Charpe M., Flaschel P., (2011): ‘Worker Debt, default and diversity of financial fragility’, Macroeconomic Policy Institute, Working Paper

Charpe M., Flaschel P., Proaňo Chr., Semmler W., (2009): ‘Overconsumption, Credit Rationing and Bailout Monetary Policy: A Miskyan Perspective’, Macroeconomic Policy Institute, Working Paper

Cynamon B. Z., Fazzari S. M., (2008): ‘Household Debt in the Consumer Age: Source of Growth—Risk of Collapse’, Capitalism and Society, 3, 2, Article 3

Debelle G. (2004): ‘Macroeconomic Implications of Rising Household Debt’, BIS Working Paper, No. 153

Duesenberry J. S. (1949): Income, Saving and the Theory of Consumer Behavior, Cambridge MA, Harvard University Press

Dutt A. K. (2006): ‘Maturity, stagnation and consumer debt: a Steindlian approach’, Metroeconomica 57:3, pp. 339–364

Dutt A.K. (1995): ‘Internal finance and monopoly power in capitalist economies: A reformulation of Steindl’s growth model’, Metroeconomica, 46, pp. 16-34.

Domovitz I., Sartain R.L., (1999): ‘Determinants of the Consumer Bankruptcy Decision’, Journal of Finance, 54: 403-420.

Foley D. (2003): ‘Financial fragility in developing economies’, in A. K. Dutt and Jamie Ros (ed.): Development Economics and Structuralist Macroeconomics, Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar

Hein E. (2006): ‘Interest, debt and capital accumulation-a Kaleckian approach’, International Review of Applied Economics, 20(3), 337-352.

Jacoby M.B., Sullivan T.A., Warren E. (2000): ‘Medical Problems and Bankruptcy Filings’ Norton Bankruptcy Law Adviser, 5: 1-12.

Jarsulic M. (1990): ‘Debt and macro stability’, Eastern Economic Journal, 15, pp. 91–100.

Kaldor N. (1982): The Scourge of Monetarism, Oxford University Press, Oxford.

Kaldor N. (1985): ‘How monetarism failed’, Challenge, May/June, pp. 4-13.

Kalecki M. (1937): ‘The Principle of Increasing’, Economica, 4(16), pp. 440-447.

Karlan D.S., Zinman, J. (2007): ‘Credit Elasticities in Less-Developed Economies: Implications for Microfinance’, Working Paper, Economic Growth Center, Yale University.

Lavoie M. (1992): Foundations of Post-Keynesian Economic Analysis, Edward Elgar, Aldershot.

Lavoie M. (1995): ‘Interest rates in post-Keynesian models of growth and distribution’, Metroeconomica, 46, 146-177.

Page 30: Berlin Octorber 2011 Emilia Marsellou Consumer and corporate Debt

Lima G.T., Meirelles A.J.A. (2006): ‘Debt, financial fragility and economic growth: a post-Keynesian macromodel’, Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 29(1), 93-115.

Maki D.M. (2000): ‘The growth of consumer credit and the household debt service burden’, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Working Paper No. 2000/12.

Maki D.M., Palumbo M.G. (2001): ‘Disentangling the Wealth Effect: A Cohort Analysis of Household Saving in the 1990s’, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Finance and Economics, Discussion Series no. 2001-21.

Marglin S.A. (1984): ‘Growth, Distribution and Inflation: A centennial synthesis’, Cambridge Journal of Economics, (8)2, 115-44.

Moore B.J. (1988): Horizontalists and Verticalists: The macroeconomics of credit money, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

Moore B.J. (1989): ‘The endogeneity of credit money’, Review of Political Economy, 1, pp. 65-93.

Palley T. (1996a): ‘Inside Debt, Aggregate Demand, and the Cambridge Theory of Distribution’, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 20, 465-74.

Palley T. (1996b): Post Keynesian Economics: Debt, Distribution, and the Macro Economy, Macmillan Press

Pollin R. (1988): ‘The Growth of U.S. Household Debt Demand Side Influences’, Journal of Macroeconomics, 10(2), pp. 231-248.

Pollin R. (1990): Deeper in Debt. The Changing Financial conditions of U.S. Households, Economic Policy Institute.

Rousseas S. (1986): Post Keynesian monetary economics, Houndmills: MacMillan

Sullivan T.A., Warren E., Westbrook J.L. (2000): The Fragile Middle Class: Americans in Debt, Yale University Press.

Veblen T. (1899): The Theory of the Leisure Class, Fairfield NJ, August M. Kelley 1991.