Bargaining for the American Dream

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/20/2019 Bargaining for the American Dream

    1/36  WWW.AMERICANPROGRESS.O

    Bargaining for the American Dream

    What Unions do for Mobility

    By Richard Freeman, Eunice Han, David Madland, and Brendan V. Duke September 2015

  • 8/20/2019 Bargaining for the American Dream

    2/36

    Bargaining for theAmerican DreamWhat Unions do for Mobility

    By Richard Freeman, Eunice Han, David Madland, and Brendan V. Duke

    September 2015

  • 8/20/2019 Bargaining for the American Dream

    3/36

      1 Introduction and summary

      4 Unions and intergenerational mobility by area

     10 Mobility in union and nonunion households

     14 Unions and stagnant intergenerational mobility

      16 Conclusion

     17 Appendix A: Area-level data

     20 Appendix B: Area-level analysis

     24 Appendix C: Individual household data and analysis

      31 Endnotes

    Contents

  • 8/20/2019 Bargaining for the American Dream

    4/36

    1 Center for American Progress |  Bargaining for the American Dream

    Introduction and summary

    One o he cenral challenges acing he Unied Saes on which boh progressives

    and conservaives can agree is he need o increase economic mobiliy. Upward

    mobiliy and opporuniy are he definiion o he American dream. Bu oday,

    he naion has less mobiliy and ewer opporuniies when compared o oher

    advanced economies. A U.S. child born in he botom 20 percen o he income

    disribuion, or example, has a 7.5 percen probabiliy o reaching he op 20

    percen as an adul, compared o 11.7 percen in Denmark and 13.4 percen in

    Canada.1 Increasing mobiliy, however, requires undersanding why i is low.

    Research by economiss Raj Chety o Sanord Universiy, Nahaniel Hendren

    o Harvard Universiy and Parick Kline and Emmanuel Saez o he Universiy o

    Caliornia, Berkeley, shows ha some regions o he Unied Saes have levels o

    mobiliyha is o say, he abiliy o improve upon he siuaion o one’s birh

    similar o Denmark and Canada. However, ha same research reveals ha oher

    U.S. areas have mobiliy levels ha are lower han any oher advanced economy

    or which daa are available. Te research o Chety and his ellow auhors also

    show ha five acors have he sronges geographical relaionshipposiive or

    negaivewih mobiliy: single moherhood raes, income inequaliy, high school

    dropou raes, social capial, and segregaion.2 

    Tis repor examines he relaionship beween mobiliy and anoher variable ha

    Chety and his co-auhors did no consider: union membership. Te analysis in

    his repor begins on he area level using he same mehodological approach as

    Chety and his co-auhors or heir five acors. Bu he analysis hen goes beyond

    his area-level analysis, using anoher daase ha maches parens wih children

    ha allows or he comparison o oucomes or children who grew up in oherwise

    similar union and nonunion households. Tis individual-level analysis is moreappropriae han he area-level analysis or examining wheher parens’ union

    membership acually influences mobiliy.

  • 8/20/2019 Bargaining for the American Dream

    5/36

    2 Center for American Progress |  Bargaining for the American Dream

    *All reference to “we,” “us,” and “our” refer to the authors of this report.

    Based on he research or his repor, i is clear ha here is a srong relaionship

     beween union membership and inergeneraional mobiliy. More specifically:

    • Areas with higher union membership demonstrate more mobility for low-

    income children. Using Chety and ohers’ daa, we* find ha low-income

    children rise higher in he income rankings when hey grow up in areas wihhigh-union membership. A 10 percenage poin increase in a geographic area’s

    union membership is associaed wih low-income children ranking 1.3 per-

    cenile poins higher in he naional income disribuion. Tis relaionship

     beween unions and he mobiliy o low-income children is a leas as srong

    as he relaionship beween mobiliy and high school dropou raesa acor

    ha is generally recognized as one o he mos imporan correlaes o eco-

    nomic mobiliy. Indeed, union densiy is one o he sronges predicors o an

    area’s mobiliy. Furhermore, unions remain a significan predicor o economic

    mobiliy even afer one conrols or several variables including race, ypes o

    indusries, inequaliy, and more.

    • Areas with higher union membership have more mobility as measured by

    all children’s incomes.  We also measure he geographic relaionship beween

    union membership and anoher measure o mobiliy: he income o all children

     who grew up in an area afer conrolling or heir parens’ incomes. According

    o our findings, a 10 percenage poin increase in union densiy is associaed

     wih a 4.5 percen increase in he income o an area’s children. Here again, union

    densiy compares quie avorable wih oher common predicors o an area’s

    mobiliy. In addiion, he relaionship beween unions and he mobiliy o all

    children remains srong afer adoping several addiional conrols.

    • Children who grow up in union households have better outcomes. Using a differ-

    en daase, we mach parens and children o compare he oucomes o children

     who grew up in oherwise similar union and nonunion households. Te findings

    show ha children growing up in union households end o have beter oucomes

    han children who grew up in nonunion households, especially when he parens

    are low skilled. For example, children o non-college-educaed ahers earn 28

    percen more i heir aher was in a labor union. Tis analysis helps provide evi-

    dence suggesing a link beween unions and economic mobiliy.

    Tese findings are new and illusrae a previously ignored acor ha could be

    essenial or promoing economic mobiliy. However, hey are no surprising, par-

    icularly given he exensive research ha has been done on unions and middle-

  • 8/20/2019 Bargaining for the American Dream

    6/36

    3 Center for American Progress |  Bargaining for the American Dream

    class incomes. Previous research by he CAP Acion Fund has ound a srong

    geographical relaionship beween union membership and inrageneraional

    mobiliyhe relaionship beween someone’s earnings when hey are 35 o 39

     years old and when hey are 45 o 49 years old.3 Our findings also coincide wih

    he findings o several sudies showing ha alling union membership has been a

    key driver in he rise o income inequaliy.4

     Mos recenly, Bruce Wesern and JakeRoseneld o Harvard and he Washingon Universiy a S. Louis, respecively,

    ound ha he decline o labor unions explains up o one-hird o he increase in

    male wage inequaliy beween 1973 and 2007.5

    Tere are srong reasons o believe ha unions may increase opporuniy. Firs,

    here are he direc effecs ha a paren’s union membership may have on heir

    children. Union workers make more money han comparable nonunion work-

    erswha economiss call he union premiumand when parens make more

    money, heir children end o make more moneywhich economiss reer o as

    he inergeneraional earnings elasiciy. In heory, unionized parens should passon a porion o he union premium o heir children. Tere may be oher chan-

    nels hrough which children whose parens were in a union have beter oucomes

    han oher children: union jobs may be more sable and predicable, which could

    produce a more sable living environmen or children, and union jobs are more

    likely o provide amily healh insurance.

    Bu here are also a series o oher ways ha unions could boos inergeneraional

    mobiliy or nonunion workers. I has been shown ha unions push up wages or

    nonunion workers, or example, and hese wage gains or nonunion members

    could be passed on o heir children.6 Children who grow up in nonunion house-

    holds may also display more mobiliy in highly unionized areas, or example,

     because hey may be able o join a union when hey ener he labor marke. Finally,

    unions generally advocae or policies ha benefi all working peoplesuch as

    minimum wage increases and increased expendiures on schools and public ser-

     vicesha may especially benefi low-income parens and heir children. A recen

    sudy on ineres groups and poliical influence ound ha mos o he naional

    groups ha suppored middle-class prioriies were unions.7 Anoher sudy ound

    ha saes wih higher union densiy also have higher minimum wages.8 

    In shor, here are many heoreical reasons o expec unions o go hand in hand

     wih economic mobiliy, and his paper provides empirical evidence ha his is

    indeed he case.

  • 8/20/2019 Bargaining for the American Dream

    7/36

    4 Center for American Progress |  Bargaining for the American Dream

    Unions and intergenerational

    mobility by area

    In 2013, Chety, Hendren, Kline, and Saez made headlines wih heir paper

    “Where is he Land o Opporuniy? Te Geography o Inergeneraional

    Mobiliy in he Unied Saes.” Using ederal ax records, hey were able o

    esimae he relaionship beween paren and child incomesinergeneraional

    mobiliywih more precision han previous daases. Measuring he variaion in

    mobiliy in areaswha hey call commuing zones, or CZsacross he counry,

    hey ound ha some areas such as Pitsburgh, Pennsylvania, and Minneapolis,

    Minnesoa, had much higher mobiliy han oher areas such as Charlote, NorhCarolina, and Alana, Georgia.

    Te main limiaion o using ax records, however, is he lack o deailed individual

    demographic and socioeconomic daa ha would allow scholars o examine par-

    ens’ and children’s characerisics ha have he closes associaions wih inergen-

    eraional mobiliy. Insead, Chety and his co-auhors combined he geographical

    mobiliy esimaes wih rich demographic and social saisics on commuing

    zones rom public daa sources o examine he geographical correlaion. Tey

    ound ha five acors had he sronges relaionship wih mobiliy across com-

    muing zones: he percen o children wih single mohers, social capial, income

    inequaliy, high school dropou raes, and a measure o residenial segregaion

    he percenage o workers wih less han 15 minue commues o heir jobs.

    Chety and his co-auhors righly emphasize ha he geographical correlaions

    hey find are no necessarily causal, bu raher serve as “a se o sylized acs o

    guide he search or causal deerminans and he developmen o new models o

    inergeneraional mobiliy.”9 Wha our geographical analysis does esablish is he

    sylized ac ha regions wih higher union membership exhibi higher inergener-

    aional mobiliy. Our analysis in he nex secion invesigaes his relaionship moreclosely, using survey daa o examine he relaionship beween individual parens’

    union saus and heir children’s mobiliy while conrolling or more acors.

  • 8/20/2019 Bargaining for the American Dream

    8/36

    5 Center for American Progress |  Bargaining for the American Dream

    Using wo geographic measures o mobiliy, we ollow he same approach as

    Chety and his co-auhors o examine heir relaionship wih unions: We calcu-

    lae he percen o workers in a commuing zone who are members o a union

    reerred o as union densiyand measure is correlaion wih mobiliy across

    commuing zones. o see how we consruced he union variable and he com-

    muing zones, see Appendix A.

    Mobility for low-income children

    Te main variable Chety and his co-auhors use o measure geographical mobil-

    iy is wha hey call absolue upward mobiliyhe expeced rank in he naional

    income disribuion o a 29- o 32-year-old whose parens were in he 25h

    percenile o he naional income disribuion. We use he same variable in heir

    analysis, bu call i “mobiliy or low-income children” o avoid conusion wih our

    oher mobiliy measure.

    In our sample’s average commuing zone, he average 29- o 32-year old whose

    parens were in he 25h percenile o he naional income disribuion ends up in

    he 40.7h percenile as an adul. We find a very srong correlaion beween unions

    and mobiliy across commuing zones: A 10 percenage poin increase in he

    share o workers in a union is associaed wih a 1.3 percenile increase in children’s

    rank. As a poin o comparison, he difference in mobiliy beween San Francisco,

    Caliornia and Alana, Georgiarespecively, one o he mos and one o he

    leas mobile o he 25 larges CZsis 7.1 percenile poins.

    Figure 2 compares he size o he correlaion beween areas’ union membership

    raes wih he five oher acors Chety and his co-auhors idenified as having he

    sronges correlaion wih mobiliy.10 Te relaionship beween unionizaion and

    mobiliy is abou he same as he relaionship beween residenial segregaion and

    high school dropou raes, wo commonly cied drivers o mobiliy. Even when

    one conrols or several variablesa commuing zone’s racial makeup, indusry

    makeup, Chety’s five acors, he number o children per amily, he child pov-

    ery rae, he median house value, he progressiviy o he ax code, and he share

    o amilies covered by a sae’s Earned Income ax Credi, or EIChe shareo workers in a union remains a significan correlae o mobiliy or low-income

    children. For deails on he analysis, see Appendix B.

  • 8/20/2019 Bargaining for the American Dream

    9/36

    6 Center for American Progress |  Bargaining for the American Dream

    FIGURE 1

    Union membership goes with economic mobility for low-income

    kids across regions

    Note: Dots represent union membership and mobility for low-income children by commuting zone. Labeled dots represent 15 mostpopulous commuting zones.

    Source: Authors' analysis using data from Raj Chetty and others, "Where is the Land of Opportunity? The Geography of Intergenerational

    Mobility in the United States," Quarterly Journal of Economics 129 (4) (2014): 1553–1623, available at http://www.equality-of-opportuni-ty.org; Data from Barry T. Hirsch and David A. Macpherson, "Union Membership and Coverage Database from the Current Population

    Survey: Note," Industrial and Labor Relations Review  56 (2) (2003): 349–54, available at http://www.unionstats.com.

    Expected income rank of low-income children by region

    0 10 20 30 40

    33

    37

    41

    45

    49

    Union membership, 1986

    Houston

    Dallas

    Atlanta

    Miami

    Boston

    Washington, D.C.Los Angeles

    Bridgeport

    Newark San Francisco

    Detroit

    New York Seattle

    Chicago

    Philadelphia

  • 8/20/2019 Bargaining for the American Dream

    10/36

    7 Center for American Progress |  Bargaining for the American Dream

    Mobility for all children

    How unions affec he mobiliy o children who grew up in he 25h percenile is

    imporan, bu perhaps even more imporan is how union membership affecs

    he income rajecories o all children in a geographic area. Using Chety and his

    co-auhors’ daa, we explore his quesion wih a variable ha we call mobiliy or

    all childrenhe average income o aduls who grew up in an area conrolling or

    he average income o heir parens.

    Imporanly, his measure avoids he issue o wha he opimal-level o social

    mobiliy is since higher incomes or all children in an area is unambiguously posi-

    ive. For he rank-based measure used or low-income children, on he oher hand,

    he opimal-level o mobiliy is unclear oher han he ac ha having i higherhan i is oday is preerable. Some associaion beween paren and children’s eco-

    nomic saus may be desirable or sociey as i provides an incenive or parens o

    inves in he human capial o heir children.

    FIGURE 2

    Union membership is strongly correlated with economic mobility

    for low-income children

    Absolute value of correlation between economic mobility for low-income children

    and union membership compared to Chetty and others' "five factors"

    Note: Correlation is estimate from regression, normalizing both dependent and independent variables so that univariate regressioncoefficients equal correlation coefficients. Unlike Chetty and his coauthors’ analysis, inequality is for the entire income distributioninstead of the bottom 99 percent resulting from issues in merging union and mobility data.

    Source: Authors' analysis using data from Raj Chetty and others, "Where is the Land of Opportunity? The Geography of IntergenerationalMobility in the United States," Quarterly Journal of Economics 129 (4) (2014): 1553–1623, available at http://www.equality-of-opportuni-

    ty.org; Data from Barry T. Hirsch and David A. Macpherson, "Union Membership and Coverage Database from the Current PopulationSurvey: Note," Industrial and Labor Relations Review  56 (2) (2003): 349–54, available at http://www.unionstats.com.

    0.0

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    Segregation Social capital Dropout rates

    Singlemotherhood

    Unionmembership

    0.255 0.270 0.274 0.333 0.367 0.626

    Inequality

  • 8/20/2019 Bargaining for the American Dream

    11/36

    8 Center for American Progress |  Bargaining for the American Dream

     Again, we find a srong relaionship beween mobiliy or all children and union

    membershipa 10 percenage poin increase in union densiy is associaed wih a

    4.5 percen increase in children’s incomesconrolling or heir parens’ incomes.

    Even afer inroducing he several conrols menioned above, a 10 percenage

    poin increase in an area’s union membership is sill associaed wih a 3 percen

    increase in children’s laer incomes.

    FIGURE 3

    Union membership goes with economic mobility for all kids

    across regions

    Note: Dots represent union membership and mobility for all children by commuting zone. Mobility for all children is displayed using theresidual from a regression of the log of the commuting zone's average children's income on the log of the commuting zone's averageparent's income. Labeled dots represent 15 most populous commuting zones.

    Source: Authors' analysis using data from Raj Chetty and others, "Where is the Land of Opportunity? The Geography of Intergenerational

    Mobility in the United States," Quarterly Journal of Economics 129 (4) (2014): 1553–1623, available at http://www.equality-of-opportuni-ty.org; Data from Barry T. Hirsch and David A. Macpherson, "Union Membership and Coverage Database from the Current Population

    Survey: Note," Industrial and Labor Relations Review  56 (2) (2003): 349–54, available at http://www.unionstats.com.

    0 10 20 30 40

    -0.2

    -0.1

    0.0

    0.1

    0.2

    Union membership, 1986

    Mobility for all children, 1980–1982 cohort

    Houston

    Dallas

    Atlanta

    Miami

    Boston

    Washington, D.C.

    Los Angeles

    Newark 

    San Francisco

    Detroit

    New York 

    Seattle

    Chicago

    Philadelphia

    Bridgeport

  • 8/20/2019 Bargaining for the American Dream

    12/36

    9 Center for American Progress |  Bargaining for the American Dream

    Discussion

    Tis analysis reveals ha areas wih higher union membership have higher mobil-

    iy no jus or low- income children, bu or all children. Tis relaionship holds

    even afer conrolling or several oher acors, some o which may serve as a chan-

    nel or how unions increase mobiliy. Our analysis, or example, conrols or ax

    progressiviy, which Chety and his co-auhors find has a posiive correlaion wih

    mobiliy. Unions, o course, are possibly he mos imporan advocaes in saes

    or progressive ax codes and ha may be one o he key ways ha unions increase

    mobiliy. By conrolling or ax progressiviy and oher variables such as social

    capial ha a region’s union membership likely influences, we have subjeced he

    union-mobiliy relaionship o a sringen es ha i appears o have passed.

    Neverheless, Chety and his co-auhors cauion ha he correlaions hey find

    such as he srongly negaive relaionship beween single moherhood raes and

    mobiliyshould be inerpreed as a se o correlaions and sylized acs raherhan a causal finding. Te same cavea applies o our findings abou he spaial

    relaionship beween unions and inergeneraional mobiliy. Wha is clear, how-

    ever, is ha mobiliy hrives in areas where unions hrive.

    Note: Correlation is estimate from regression, normalizing both dependent and independent variables so that univariate regression

    coefficients equal correlation coefficients

    Source: Authors' analysis using data from Raj Chetty and others, "Where is the Land of Opportunity? The Geography of IntergenerationalMobility in the United States," Quarterly Journal of Economics 129 (4) (2014): 1553–1623, available at http://www.equality-of-opportuni-

    ty.org; Data from Barry T. Hirsch and David A. Macpherson, "Union Membership and Coverage Database from the Current PopulationSurvey: Note," Industrial and Labor Relations Review  56 (2) (2003): 349–54, available at http://www.unionstats.com.

    FIGURE 4

    Union membership is strongly correlated with mobility for all children

    Absolute value of correlation between mobility for all children and union

    membership compared to Chetty and others' "five factors"

    0.00

    0.10

    0.20

    0.30

    Dropout rates

    Singlemotherhood

    Social capital SegregationUnion

    membership

    Inequality

    0.219 0.247 0.260 0.270 0.271 0.310

  • 8/20/2019 Bargaining for the American Dream

    13/36

    10 Center for American Progress |  Bargaining for the American Dream

    Mobility in union and

    nonunion households

    More confidence can be developed ha here is a srong relaionship beween

    unions and upward mobiliy by using household-level daa o compare he

    rajecories o children rom union and similar nonunion households. Ideally,

    randomized conrols could be perormed or a naural experimen could be ideni-

    fied where he assignmen o union membership is random and mobiliy could

     be measured. Unorunaely, ha is no plausible. Insead, we use survey daa and

    conrol or several observable characerisics o he parens, including race, educa-

    ion, indusry, occupaion, age, work saus, and urban saus.

    Te Panel Sudy o Income Dynamics, or PSID, is he bes daase or his work

     because i no only racks households, bu when children rom he original house-

    hold orm heir own household, i coninues o collec inormaion abou hem.

    Tereore, i is possible o combine he characerisics o 26- o 37-year olds in

    2011 wih he characerisics o heir parens in 1985 and compare he rajecories

    o children whose parens were oherwise similar excep or heir union saus. See

     Appendix C or more deails.

    Similar o he geographic analysis, we examine wheher parens’ union saus

     booss earnings or children overall and wheher i raises he earnings o he chil-

    dren o low-skilled parens relaive o he children o high-skilled parens. Unlike

    he previous analysis, which ocused on children whose parens’ incomes were

    he samein he 25h percenilewe ocus on measures o skilleducaion and

     blue- or whie-collar saussince one o he ways ha unions may boos relaive

    mobiliy is by increasing he incomes o low-skilled aduls via he union premium,

     which hese workers can hen pass on o heir children.

    Neverheless, when one conrols or income, here is sill a saisically significanposiive relaionship beween union membership and children’s mobiliy, sugges-

    ing channels or how parens’ union saus influences mobiliy independen o

    one year o income. We also examine wheher parens’ union saus affecs oher

    measures o well-being ouside o income, more specifically healh and educa-

    ionwhich can also lead o higher incomes laer in lie.

  • 8/20/2019 Bargaining for the American Dream

    14/36

    11 Center for American Progress |  Bargaining for the American Dream

    Effect of unions on children’s incomes

    o provide a firs look a he effec o unions on children’s income, we do a simple

    comparison o he labor incomes o ull-ime workers by he union saus o heir

    parens. Tis par o he analysis does no conrol or any o he many possible

    differences beween union and nonunion parens; insead, i does he comparisonseparaely or children wih a paren who graduaed college and children whose

    parens did no. Tis is o ensure ha any posiive effec o unions on children’s

    incomes acually increases opporuniy or hose who need i mos. Figure 5 pres-

    ens he average incomes o children in he sample differeniaed by heir parens’

    union saus and educaional saus.

     Among children whose parens did no graduae college, he average income o

    children wih a union paren exceeds he average income o children wih non-

    union parens by $6,300, or 16 percen, a difference ha is significan a he 1 per-

    cen level. For children who did have a paren who graduaed college, union saushad essenially no effec. Te resul or children whose parens graduaed college

    indicaes ha unions could increase inergeneraional mobiliy. Bu he resuls do

    no provide any insigh ino wheher hese differences reflec he direc impac o

    paren’s union saus on children’s incomes.

    *Difference is not statistically significant

    Note: Calculations are for 26- to 37-year-olds who work full time and who had at least one parent who worked full time in 1985.

    Source: Authors' analysis of the Panel Study of Income Dynamics 1985 and 2011 files, available at https://psidonline.isr.umich.edu/.

    FIGURE 5

    Children whose parents were in a union have higher earnings

    Average labor income of children by parents’ union and education status

    Parents did not graduate college At least one parent graduated college*

    Union parent

    Nonunion parents

    $0

    $20,000

    $40,000

    $60,000

    $46,000

    $39,000

    $53,000 $54,000

  • 8/20/2019 Bargaining for the American Dream

    15/36

    12 Center for American Progress |  Bargaining for the American Dream

    For his repor, we perorm a regression analysis ha conrols or several char-

    acerisics o he parens ha affec heir income o allow or an apples-o-apples

    comparison beween union and nonunion parens: race, ehniciy, marial saus,

    educaion, age, urbanizaion, occupaion, ull-ime saus, and indusry. We find

    ha he effec o having a aher in a union is an 18.7 percen increase in a child’s

    earnings, an effec ha is significan a he 1 percen level. Nex, we conrol or heincome o he parens o examine i here are oher ways ha parens’ union saus

    affecs mobiliy ouside o higher parenal incomes. Based on he findings, a union

    aher sill increases an offspring’s income by a saisically significan 16.4 percen.

     When he sample is divided ino sons and daughers, one finds ha union ahers

    have posiive effecs on boh sons and daughers. Union mohers, on he oher

    hand, have a posiive effec on daughers’ earnings bu have no effec on sons. We

    also find ha union membership o he parens raises he incomes o children

    independen o he child’s own union saus.

    Te ac ha unions increase he earnings o children does no necessarily meanhey boos inergeneraional mobiliy in relaive erms; he quesion is wheher

    unions boos he earnings o he children o higher-skilled or lower-skilled

    parens. We do his by dividing our sample ino approximaely equally sized skill

    groups based on he skill saus o he aher. Te firs comparison is or ahers

     who atended college and ahers who did no. Te second comparison is or

    ahers in blue-collar jobs and ahers in whie-collar jobs.

     We find ha he effecs o ahers’ union saus are concenraed among he chil-

    dren o lower-skilled ahers. For sons wih a aher who did no atend college,

    unions boos earnings by 27.5 percen, and children o a aher wih a blue-collar

     job see a 21.3 percen earnings increase. On he oher hand, unions do no have

    saisically significan effecs on children wih college-educaed ahers or whie-

    collar ahers. Te benefis o parens’ union saus are hus concenraed among

    he children o lower-skilled parens, implying ha unions increase relaive iner-

    generaional mobiliy.

     We also examine wo oher measures o mobiliyhe healh and educaion o

    he children. We measure educaion by years o school compleed and find ha a

    aher in a union is associaed wih compleing an addiional hal year o educa-ion. We measure he effec o unions on healh using a five-poin scale or sel-

    repored healh, 1 being lowes and 5 being highes. We find boh union ahers

    and mohers are associaed wih saisically significan increases o 0.14 and 0.16

    poins, respecively.11 

  • 8/20/2019 Bargaining for the American Dream

    16/36

    13 Center for American Progress |  Bargaining for the American Dream

    Discussion

    Our findings among households ell a similar sory o he findings among com-

    muing zones: union membership or parens has a posiive associaion wih

    children’s uure earnings. Imporanly, hese effecs are concenraed among he

    children o low-skill workers, which urns his inergeneraional union premium

    ino a orce or inergeneraional mobiliy. Tese findings are especially noewor-

    hy when combined wih he previous area-level analysis because he analyses

    come rom wo compleely differen daases on wo differen levelshe regional

    and household level.

    Te household-level findings sugges a srong relaionship exiss beween unions

    and mobiliy. Proving causaliy, however, is difficul wihou experimenal or quasi-

    experimenal daa, which have become he gold sandard in modern empirical eco-

    nomics. Bu he hope is ha hese findings will rigger urher research ino wheher

    a causal relaionship beween unions and inergeneraional mobiliy exiss.

    0%

    10%

    20%

    30%

    *Not statistically significant

    Note: Calculations are for 26- to 37-year-olds who work full time and lived with a father in 1985 who worked full time. Calculationscontrol for father’s age, race, marital status, industry, occupation, and the urban status of the household.

    Source: Authors' analysis of the Panel Study of Income Dynamics 1985 and 2011 files, available at https://psidonline.isr.umich.edu/ 

    FIGURE 6

    Unions increase the earnings of children with lower-skilled fathers

    Effect of father’s union status on labor incomes of children by father’s skill group

    No college education

    Blue collar

    White collar*

    At least somecollege education*

    27.5% 10.7% 21.3% 6.7%

  • 8/20/2019 Bargaining for the American Dream

    17/36

    14 Center for American Progress |  Bargaining for the American Dream

    Unions and stagnant

    intergenerational mobility

    I unions boos inergeneraional mobiliy and hey have declined so much over

    he pas 40 years, should economic mobiliy have allen? Chety and his co-

    auhors analyze he ime rend o anoher measure o mobiliyhe probabiliy

    ha a child born in he botom quinile would reach he op quinileand hey

    find ha i did no decline beween he 1973 and 1993 birh cohors, a period over

     which income inequaliy grew and unionizaion ell.12 A firs glance, his presens

    a puzzle or our finding ha unionizaion is associaed wih inergeneraional

    mobiliy, as well as or Chety and ohers’ finding wih respec o income equaliy.

    Bu his puzzle only exiss i one believes ha declining union membership and

    growing income inequaliy were he only rends ha affeced mobiliy over he

    pas 40 years. Chety and his co-auhors find ha high school dropou raes and

    racial segregaion have declined, offseting he decline in mobiliy one would

    predic based on rising inequaliy and single moherhood raes:

    We predict the trend in the rank-rank slope [relative mobility] implied by

    changes in the five key correlates over time … Te predicted changes are quite

    small because the factors move in opposing directions. For example, the increase

    in inequality and single parenthood rates in recent decades predict a small

    decline in mobility in recent decades. In contrast, the decline in racial segregation

    and high school dropout rates predict an increase in mobility of similar mag-

    nitude. Overall, the cross-sectional correlations documented here are consistent

    with the lack of a substantial time trend in mobility in recent decades.13

    Chety has also noed elsewhere ha mobiliy should have grown in a period

    o alling racial discriminaion and he War on Povery.14 Mobiliy did no rise

     beween he early 1970s and early 1990s despie rends ha Chety and his co-auhors’ daa sugges should have increased mobiliyincreasing educaional

    atainmen, declining segregaion, and ederal programs argeed a reducing pov-

    ery. I hese rends had no occurred, alling union membership along wih rising

    inequaliy and single moherhood raes would likely have pushed down mobiliy.

  • 8/20/2019 Bargaining for the American Dream

    18/36

    15 Center for American Progress |  Bargaining for the American Dream

    I is also imporan o examine he rend in mobiliy over a longer ime period

    since 20 years is a relaively shor span. In a recen Naional Bureau o Economic

    Research, or NBER, working paper, Brown Universiy economis Nahaniel

    Hilger examines educaional mobiliy using U.S. Census Bureau daa going all he

     way back o 1940.15 He also finds ha mobiliy as measured by child educaional

    atainmen did no change among 22- o 25-year olds beween 1980 and 2000, bu his comes afer 40 years o growing mobiliy beween 1940 and 1980.16 In

    oher words, he ailure o inergeneraional mobiliy o grow beween 1980 and

    2000 represens a change rom rising mobiliy in he decades beore. Moreover,

    as Harvard poliical scienis Rober Punam has argued, i may ake ime or he

    ull effecs o growing inequaliy o be refleced in mobiliy saisics i a causal

    relaionship exiss.17 Te same could be rue or unions.

    Our findings rom boh he area and household levels sugges ha he decline o

    union densiy over he pas 40 years along wih he increase in inequaliy and rise o

    single mohers played a role in prevening mobiliy rom rising. Wha his impliesabou he uure rend or economic mobiliy is discouraging unless one expecs

    a coninued decline in high school dropou raes and urher reducion in racial

    segregaion o offse he effecs o rising inequaliy and alling union membership.

  • 8/20/2019 Bargaining for the American Dream

    19/36

    16 Center for American Progress |  Bargaining for the American Dream

    Conclusion

    In his repor, we have shown ha parens’ union membership has a significan

    and posiive relaionship wih heir children’s well-being. Te adul offspring

    o unionized parens earn higher labor incomes compared o he offspring o

    nonunionized parens. Tey also atain higher levels o educaion, which can help

    hem achieve beter economic sandings. Tis inergeneraional union effec is

    sronger or less-educaed and less-skilled parens, making i a posiive orce or

    inergeneraional mobiliy. An associaion also appears on he area level: Localiies

     wih higher union membership are also areas where children o poor parens endup higher in he naional income disribuion and children hroughou he income

    disribuion earn more in hese areas.

    Te research in his repor is he firs o examine he relaionship beween unions

    and inergeneraional mobiliy, bu hopeully i will no be he las sudy on his

    opic. Researchers have produced a plehora o sudies on how alling union

    membership has increased income inequaliy, and his repor will hopeully inspire

    ohers o examine he relaionship beween unions and mobiliy in greaer deail.

    Tis repor also provides lessons or policymakers who have, a leas rheorically,

    embraced he concep o inergeneraional mobiliy. A serious policy agenda

    aimed a boosing inergeneraional mobiliy mus include policies ha will

    increase he bargaining power o workers. Te resuls rom his repor show ha

    unions are a powerul orce or improving he economic lives no jus o organized

     workers, bu o heir offspring as well. I is possible ha a srong union movemen

    is no simply sufficien or high levels o inergeneraional mobiliy, bu i may be

    necessary. I ha is he case, i will be difficul o meaningully increase inergen-

    eraional mobiliy wihou also rebuilding unions or some comparable worker-

     based organizaions.

  • 8/20/2019 Bargaining for the American Dream

    20/36

    17 Center for American Progress |  Bargaining for the American Dream

    Appendix A: Area-level data

    o perorm he analysis o unions and commuing zones, we linked wo area-

    level daases. Te firs comes rom he “Inergeneraional Mobiliy Saisics and

    Seleced Covariaes by Couny,” developed by Chety and his co-auhors rom

     which mobiliy or low-income and all children daa were obained (available a

     www.Equaliy-o-Opporuniy.org). Te second daase is Barry Hirsch and David

    McPherson’s Curren Populaion Survey-based esimaes o union densiy or

    meropolian saisical areas (available a www.UnionSas.com).

    Maching he wo daases involved some echnical complicaions. Te mobil-

    iy and income daa relae o counies and commuing zones, or CZs, which are

    hemselves collecions o counies. Te union daa are available on he meropoli-

    an saisical area, or MSA, level, which are also collecions o couniesexcep

    in New England, as described below. Te geographic analysis akes place on he

    CZ level. Te primary advanage o CZs over MSAs is ha he CZ file comes

     wih sae idenificaion, which allows or he use o sandard errors clusered a

    he sae level o accoun or spaial and sae-specific correlaions. Boh CZ and

    MSAs ofen cross sae boundariesor example, he Washingon, D.C., MSA

    and CZ cover counies in he Disric o Columbia, Virginia, and Maryland. Bu

    he MSAs do no have sae IDs, and hus we canno use sae clusered sandard

    errors wih hem. We assign o each couny he union densiy o he MSA o

     which i belongs and hen combines he counies ino CZs, dropping counies

    ha are no par o MSAs since here are no union daa or hem. Tis removes

    rural counies rom CZs and creaes some sligh differences in he covariaes rom

    he original daa eaured in Chety’s paper. Bu we do no believe his is a serious

    problem: he correlaion beween mobiliy or low-income children esimaes

    o our limied CZs and he whole CZs is 0.946. Addiionally, we reconsruc he

    covariaes on he CZ-level only or counies or which here are also union daa.Te correlaion beween he five acors in our limied CZs and he whole CZs

    ranges beween 0.937 and 0.980.

    http://www.equality-of-opportunity.org/http://www.unionstats.com/http://www.unionstats.com/http://www.equality-of-opportunity.org/

  • 8/20/2019 Bargaining for the American Dream

    21/36

    18 Center for American Progress |  Bargaining for the American Dream

     Anoher problem in orming he mobiliy/unionizaion area daase is ha he

    unionizaion daa or he New England saes differ rom hose o he res o

    he counry. Insead o MSAswhich are collecions o whole counieshey

    are really New England Ciy and own Areas, or NECAs, which are collec-

    ions o owns. Counies can hus belong o muliple NECAs. Fairfield Couny,

    Connecicu, or example, belongs o he Danbury, Samord-Norwalk, andBridgepor NECAs. o deal wih his problem, we ake he average o he union

    densiies o he NECAs o which each couny belongs rom UnionSas.com,

     weighed by he porion o heir 2000 populaion ha lived in each NECA. For

    Fairfield Couny, or example, we averaged he union densiies o he NECAs o

    Danbury (13.2 percen), Samord-Norwalk (12.9 percen), and Bridgepor (22.8

    percen) MSAs, weighed by heir 2000 populaions residing in Fairfield Couny

    (183,303, 353,556, and 345,708, respecively).

    Once we successully combined heir mobiliy and union daa a he couny level,

    he nex sep was linking hem o several oher couny-level covariaes beoreurning hem ino CZs. Mos covariaes come rom Chety’s publicly available

    older on www.Equaliy-o-Opporuniy.org: populaion; percen o children wih

    a single moher; commue ime; high school dropou raes; he Gini coefficien;

    social capial; a sae’s EIC coverage; and he progressiviy o he sae’s ax code.

    Te SAA code in he older was used o produce couny-level esimaes o

    hese variables, mached hem o he couny-level esimaes o mobiliy and union

    densiy, and hen ransormed hem ino CZs. Chety and his co-auhors ound

    ha he mos significan acors in heir analysis were single moherhood raes,

    dropou raes, commue imes, social capial, and inequaliy among he botom

    99 percen. We do no include he las covariaea Gini coefficien o he botom

    99 percen o he couny’s income disribuionbecause i is based on nonpublic

    ax daa and is no provided a he couny level. We use he overall Gini coefficien

    insead. We hen added oher covariaes: indusry since some indusries are more

    unionized han ohers, wih daa on indusries in Chety ’s raw daa older rom

    he 2000 Census: ”Sex by Indusry or he Employed Civilian Populaion 16 Years

    and Over.” We place he indusries ino five caegories.18 Muliple race variables

     were also creaed. Using race daa rom he 2000 Census in he Naional Hisorical

    Geographic Inormaion Sysem in Chety’s public daa older, variables or he

    percenage o he commuing zone ha is non-Hispanic whie, non-Hispanic black, non-Hispanic Asian, non-Hispanic “oher,” and Hispanic were creaed.

    Finally, we added U.S. Census daa rom 2000 on he child povery rae, average

    number o children per amily, and he median value o owner-occupied housing.

    http://www.equality-of-opportunity.org/http://www.equality-of-opportunity.org/

  • 8/20/2019 Bargaining for the American Dream

    22/36

    19 Center for American Progress |  Bargaining for the American Dream

    Once we combined union, mobiliy, and oher covariae daa on he couny level,

     we urned hem ino CZs. Lacking union daa ouside o MSAs, his analysis does

    no apply o rural areas. Te oal populaion o our CZs in 2000 was 207 million

    people compared o a U.S. populaion o 281 million in 2000.19 Tere is no way o

    obain unionizaion raes or rural areas o see wheher he resuls o his repor do

    or do no hold or hese areas.

  • 8/20/2019 Bargaining for the American Dream

    23/36

    20 Center for American Progress |  Bargaining for the American Dream

    Appendix B: Area-level analysis

    Tis repor uses he area-level daa or wo ypes o analysis.

    Firs, he repor uses Chety’s preerred “absolue upward mobiliy” variable,

     which measures he expeced rank in he 2011–2012 income disribuion o per-

    sons rom he 1980–1982 birh cohor whose parens’ 1996–2000 income placed

    hem in he 25h percenile o he naional income disribuion. Tis is reerred o

    as mobiliy or low-income children.

    Te ollowing model was used:

    (1) R25 iO = β0 + β1U i

     P + ∑ di X i + εi

    In his model, i indexes commuing zone (CZ), o indexes offspring, and p indexes

    heir parens. R25 iO measures he expeced rank o a 25h percenile child in 2011

    and 2012. U i P measures he CZ’s union densiy in 1986, which is when he young

    persons would have been 4 o 6 years old. Because union densiy by area is a sable

    saisic across areas in relaive erms, he resuls are similar or union densiy over

    oher ime periods. o reduce he poenial ha he effec o unionism will be con-

    ounded wih ha o oher area variables, he X i  vecor in he regression conrols

    or a large se o covariaes, including many ha could be channels or unionism o

    increase mobiliy: a commuing zone’s racial makeup, indusry makeup, Chety’s

    and his co-auhor’s five acors, he number o children per amily, he child

    povery rae, he median house value, he progressiviy o he ax code, and sae

    Earned Income ax Credi, or EIC, coverage.

     We firs perorm he univariae correlaion beween union densiy and mobiliy

    or low-income children displayed in column 1. o assess he relaive srengh ohis correlaion beween mobiliy or low-income children and union densiy, we

    compare i o he correlaion beween mobiliy or low-income children and he

    five acors ha Chety ound o have he sronges relaionship wih mobiliy or

    low-income children: he percen o children wih single mohers as parens; he

  • 8/20/2019 Bargaining for the American Dream

    24/36

    21 Center for American Progress |  Bargaining for the American Dream

    income-adjused dropou rae; he level o social capial; he percen o work-

    ers wih less han 15 minues commues, which is a measure o segregaion; and

    inequaliy as measured by he Gini coefficien. As menioned in Appendix A and

    endnoe 10, we use he overall Gini coefficien while Chety and ohers use he

    Gini or he botom 99 percen. As done by Chety and his co-auhors, we normal-

    ize all covariaes and mobiliy or low-income children so ha hey have a meano zero and sandard deviaion o one or beter comparison. Columns 2 hrough

    7 show ha he correlaion beween mobiliy and union densiy is a leas as large

    as he correlaion beween mobiliy and dropou raes, social capial, or segrega-

    ion. Columns 8 and 9 repor he coefficiens rom he mulilevel regression o he

    mobiliy or low-income children on union densiy and he oher covariaes. In

    column 8, even afer conrolling or all five acors, union densiy sill shows a sig-

    nificanly posiive associaion wih mobiliy or low-income children. In column 9,

     we conrol or he five acors and several oher covariaes: race; indusry; median

    housing value; he number o children per amily; ax progressiviy; he sae’s

    EIC coverage; and he share o children living below he povery line. In hisspecificaion, union densiy sill remains significan.

    Nex, we esimae he effec o union densiy in a commuing zone on he 2011–

    2012 income o persons rom he 1980–1982 birh cohor who had resided in ha

    zone by he ollowing model:

    (2) LogȲ iO = β0 + β1U i

     P + β2 LogȲ i P + ∑ di X i + εi

    In his model, i indexes commuing zone (CZ), o indexes offspring, and p indexes

    heir parens. Ȳ i P measures he average income o parens in he ih CZ rom 1996

    o 2000, and Ȳ iO measures he average income o offspring who grew up in he same

    CZ. As beore, he X i  vecor in he regression conrols or a large se o covariaes.

     As above, column 1 shows he relaionship beween union membership and

    mobiliy or all children. A 10 percenage poin increase in union densiy is associ-

    aed wih a 4.5 percen increase in children’s incomes. Columns 2 hrough 7 com-

    pare he correlaions beween mobiliy or all children, union densiy, and he five

    acors. Union densiy has a leas as large o a correlaion as he oher variables

     wih he excepion o inequaliy. I also mainains a srong correlaion in each ohe mulivariae analyses in columns 8 and 9.

  • 8/20/2019 Bargaining for the American Dream

    25/36

    22 Center for American Progress |  Bargaining for the American Dream

    TABLE A1

    Unions, the five factors, and mobility for low-income children

    Mobility for

    low-income

    children

    Mobility for

    low-income

    children,

    normalized

    Mobility for

    low-income

    children,

    normalized

    Mobility for

    low-income

    children,

    normalized

    Mobility for

    low-income

    children,

    normalized

    Mobility for

    low-income

    children,

    normalized

    Mobility for

    low-income

    children,

    normalized

    Mobility for

    low-income

    children,

    normalized

    Mobi

    low-i

    chil

    norm

    (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (

    Union density12.90***

    (4.579)

    Union density,

    normalized

    0.333*** 0.386*** 0.2

    (0.118) (0.131) (0.0

    Percentage of

    workers with a

    commute under

    15 minutes,

    normalized

    0.255*** 0.214** 0.1

    (0.090) (0.090) (0.0

    Overall Gini

    coefficient,normalized

    -0.367*** 0.123 -0.1

    (0.112) (0.113) (0.0

    Dropout rate,

    income adjusted

    and normalized

    -0.274** -0.047 -0.1

    (0.110) (0.088) (0.0

    Social capital,

    normalized

    0.270** 0.044 -0.0

    (0.132) (0.084) (0.0

    Percentage of kids

    with single mother,

    normalized

    -0.626*** -0.576*** -0.

    (0.061) (0.078) (0.1

    Other covariates No No No No No No No No Y

    State clusteredstandard errors

      Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Y

    Observations 203 203 203 203 163 201 203 161 1

    R-squared 0.111 0.111 0.065 0.135 0.070 0.073 0.392 0.540 0.7

    Note: Cluster robust standard errors in parentheses. *** p

  • 8/20/2019 Bargaining for the American Dream

    26/36

    23 Center for American Progress |  Bargaining for the American Dream

    TABLE A2

    Unions, the five factors, and mobility for all children

    Log child

    income

    Log child

    income,

    normalized

    Log child

    income,

    normalized

    Log child

    income,

    normalized

    Log child

    income,

    normalized

    Log child

    income,

    normalized

    Log child

    income,

    normalized

    Log child

    income

    Log

    inc

    (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

    Log parent income0.442*** 3.424*** 3.921*** 3.392*** 3.647*** 3.120*** 3.232*** 0.422*** 0.

    (0.033) (0.258) (0.285) (0.272) (0.313) (0.254) (0.269) (0.050) (0.0

    Union density0.449*** 0.451*** 0.

    (0.107) (0.124) (0.

    Union density,

    normalized

    0.271***

    (0.065)

    Percentage of

    workers with

    commute under 15

    minutes, normalized

    0.270*** 0.021** 0.

    (0.051) (0.009) (0.

    Overall Ginicoefficient,

    normalized

    -0.310*** -0.011 -0.

    (0.059) (0.011) (0.

    Dropout rate,

    normalized

    -0.219*** -0.010 -0.

    (0.078) (0.009) (0.

    Social Capital,

    normalized

    0.260*** 0.002 -0.

    (0.085) (0.012) (0.

    Percentage of kids

    with single mother,

    normalized

    -0.247*** -0.019* 0.

    (0.053) (0.010) (0.

    Other covariates No No No No No No No No

    State clustered

    standard errors  Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

    Observations 203 203 203 203 163 201 203 161

    R-squared 0.687 0.687 0.687 0.709 0.656 0.668 0.668 0.803 0.

    Note: Cluster robust standard errors in parentheses. *** p

  • 8/20/2019 Bargaining for the American Dream

    27/36

    24 Center for American Progress |  Bargaining for the American Dream

    Appendix C: Individual household

    data and analysis

    Te Panel Sudy o Income Dynamics, or PSID, provides deail on he characeris-

    ics o amilies, including he labor income and union saus o he head o house-

    hold and o he head’s spouse and he comparable characerisics o heir adul

    offspring when hey orm heir own households. o obain a sample o parens

    and heir adul offspring, we mached he 1985 and 2011 PSID files by individual

    and creaed a new file limied o individuals who were children or sepchildren o

    he head o a household in 1985 and were hemselves heads o household or he

    spouses o household heads in 2011. We also resric he sample o hose youngerhan 38 years old in 2011younger han 12 years old in 1985so ha hey are

     young enough o be direcly influenced by parens’ economic saus. We creaed a

    new se o 2011 offspring variables o characerize his group: characerisics o he

    household heads i he individual was he head o household and characerisics o

    he wives i he individual was he married or unmarried parner o he household

    head. Tese offspring variables are designed o ocus on he relaionships beween

    parens and heir children raher han beween parens and he spouses o heir

    children. Because we limi heir analysis o heads o household and spouses, he

    daa exclude children who were no heads o household or spouses, which consis

    primarily o hose living wih heir parens in 2011.

     We regress he log o offspring income on he log o heir parenal income and

    oher parenal characerisics using he ollowing orm:

    (3) LogY  jk = β0 + β1U k P + β2 LogY k

     P + ∑ dk X k P + ε jk

    In his model, j indexes offspring and k indexes heir parens. Y is offspring’s labor

    income.20 UP is heir parens’ union saus, where 1 means he parens are union-

    ized and 0 ha hey are no in a union. Y P

     is parens’ amily income and X P

     rep-resens oher parenal atribues: parens’ age; race and ehniciy; heir ull-ime

    saus; educaion; marial saus; indusry and occupaions; and he urban saus

    o he household. I UP is significanly posiive, hen on average, he offspring o

    union parens earn higher incomes han he offspring o nonunion parens.

  • 8/20/2019 Bargaining for the American Dream

    28/36

    25 Center for American Progress |  Bargaining for the American Dream

    able 3 gives he resuls o he regressions o he log o offspring income on par-

    ens’ atribues, including parens’ amily income.21 Te coefficien on he log o

    amily income in column 1 is he inergeneraional income elasiciy, or IGE, ha

    measures he associaion beween parens’ income and heir offspring’s income.22 

    Te esimaed coefficien o 0.326 indicaes ha i parens’ income increases by

    10 percen, offspring’s labor income increases by 3.3 percen or all persons in hesample.23 Te addiion o he covariaes or parenal atribues reduces he coe-

    ficien o 0.239 in column 2.

    Column 3 examines he effec o having union parens on offspring income

    absen amily income bu wih inclusion o oher parenal covariaes and deliv-

    ers our main finding rom he individual-level daa: he aher’s union saus has a

    significan effec on child income wih a magniude o 0.187, which implies ha

    he adul offspring o unionized ahers earn 18.7 percen higher income han he

    adul offspring o nonunionized ahers. Te addiion o parenal amily income in

    column 4 reduces he coefficien on he union saus o parenal-household heado 0.164. Tis implies ha he effec o parens’ unionism goes beyond heir higher

    income due o he union premium.

    Finally, in columns 5 and 6, we add a dummy variable indicaing wheher he

    offspring are unionized. Te esimaed coefficiens on parenal union saus and

    parenal income do no change much afer we include offspring’s union saus,

     which suggess ha parens’ union saus has an independenly posiive impac on

    heir children’s income beyond wheher heir children join a union. Te esimaed

    coefficien on children’s union saus shows ha hey earn a subsanial union pre-

    mium. Compared o children whose parens and hemselves have no connecion

    o unionism, children whose parens are unionized and hemselves are also union-

    ized earn abou 37 percen (18.5 percen + 18.6 percen) higher labor incomes.

     We also analyzed he effec o parens’ unionism conrolling or separae labor

    incomes o household heads and heir spouses raher han conrolling or paren’s

    amily income, and we find an even higher efficien coefficien on union ahers.24 

     We also examine he effecs o mohers’ and ahers’ union saus on daughers and

    sons separaely in ables 4 and 5. Te relaionship is less precisely esimaed han

    he above regressions since he sample size is abou hal. Te poin esimaes or heeffec o ahers’ union saus on sons are slighly smaller han in he pooled samples

     while, mohers’ union saus appears o have no effec on sons’ labor incomes. For

    daughers, we find he effecs o ahers’ union saus are larger han hose or sons,

    and he effec o mohers’ union saus is also posiive bu no quie significan.

  • 8/20/2019 Bargaining for the American Dream

    29/36

    26 Center for American Progress |  Bargaining for the American Dream

    Given he many pahways ha educaed and skilled workers are likely o have o

    pass on heir economic advanages o heir children, i is imporan o deermine

     wheher he union parens’ effec on heir offspring’s income is sronger among

    less-educaed and less-skilled workers han among more-educaed and more-

    skilled workers. In he ormer case, he union effec would reduce relaive social

    mobiliy while in he later case he union effec would increase relaive mobiliy.

    o examine his issue, we divided heir sample by level o educaionahers

     wih no college educaion and hose wih a leas some college educaionand

     by naure o workahers in blue-collar occupaions compared o ahers in

     whie-collar occupaionsand esimaed equaion 3 and 4 or hese groups. We

    only examine ahers in order o avoid he complicaions o marriages where one

    parner has a college educaion or a whie-collar job while he oher has no college

    educaion or a blue-collar job. We used a leas some college as he cuoff because

    roughly hal o ahers had some college educaion, and he cuoff hus maximizes

    sample size or boh groups. Te resuls, summarized in able 6 show ha heunion effec in raising he income o offspring is concenraed among ahers wih

    less educaion and among ahers in blue-collar jobs. While one poenial explana-

    ion is he large union wage premium or low-skilled workers, he inclusion o he

    parenal household income variable, which should reflec he wage premium, sill

    leaves a sizable independen union effec.

    Our final research quesion in he individual-level daa is wha exen does he

    effec o parens’ unionism show up in oher measures o socioeconomic well-

     being? We examine his quesion by esimaing varians o equaions 3 and 4 ha

    replace children’s labor income wih measures o educaional progresshighes

    grade compleedand healh, as repored by individuals on a 1 o 5 scale wih 5

    as he bes healh and 1 as he wors healh saus.

    For he healh and educaion regressions, we condiion on a head o household

     who works ull ime raher han a head o household or wie ha works ull ime

    as in he oher regressions. Tis is in order o capure unions’ poenial role on

    moher’s well-being hrough beter maerniy leave since a moher on maerniy

    leave would no be couned as working ull ime. Unlike all he oher resuls

    including he educaion resulshe healh resuls are sensiive o his adjusmenand do no display significan effecs i we condiion on eiher he household head

    or wie working ull ime. We also drop he requiremen or he healh regressions

    ha he children work ull ime since he beneficial effecs o unions on children’s

    healh should no depend on heir labor marke saus. Te healh resuls are posi-

  • 8/20/2019 Bargaining for the American Dream

    30/36

    27 Center for American Progress |  Bargaining for the American Dream

    ive bu no significan when we condiion on he child working ull ime and/or

    condiion on a head o household or wie working ull ime. Columns 1 and 2 o

    able 7 give he resuls or he educaion measure. Tey show ha having a union

    aher increases highes grade compleed even or persons wih he same amily

    income.25 Columns 3 and 4 o able 7 give he resuls or he healh measure o

    offspring. Te healh saus o offspring is associaed wih boh heir moher’s andaher’s union saus. And, as in he calculaions or he highes grade compleed,

    he resul or union ahers holds wih he addiion o amily income, implying

    ha unionism improves offspring’s healh hrough mechanisms beyond parens’

    income. Tis may reflec he beter healh care benefis ha unions provide mem-

     bers and heir amilies.

    TABLE A3

    Unions and children’s earnings

    Log childlabor income

    Log childlabor income

    Log childlabor income

    Log childlabor income

    Log childlabor income

    Log chlabor in

    (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

    Log of family income, 19850.326*** 0.239*** 0.224*** 0.23

    (0.074) (0.068) (0.070) (0.07

    Union Father, 19850.187*** 0.164** 0.185*** 0.16

    (0.062) (0.064) (0.060) (0.06

    Union Mother, 19850.073 0.023 0.060 0.00

    (0.087) (0.085) (0.085) (0.08

    Union child

    0.186*** 0.20

    (0.059) (0.05

    Other covariates No Yes Yes Yes Yes Ye

    State clustered standard errors Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Ye

    Observations 1,068 1,068 1,068 1,068 1,068 1,06

    R-squared 0.066 0.188 0.179 0.193 0.186 0.20

    Note: Cluster robust standard errors in parentheses. *** p

  • 8/20/2019 Bargaining for the American Dream

    31/36

    28 Center for American Progress |  Bargaining for the American Dream

    TABLE A4

    Effect of parents’ union status on sons’ earnings

    Log child

    labor income

    Log child

    labor income

    Log child

    labor income

    Log child

    labor income

    Log child

    labor income

    Log ch

    labor in

    (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

    Log parent income

    0.313*** 0.205 0.201 0.212

    (0.098) (0.125) (0.129) (0.126

    Union father0.142 0.125 0.133 0.115

    (0.087) (0.087) (0.083) (0.083

    Union mother-0.017 -0.054 -0.014 -0.053

    (0.137) (0.137) (0.133) (0.132

    Union child0.247** 0.260

    (0.073) (0.07

    Other covariates No Yes Yes Yes Yes Ye

    State clustered standard errors Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Ye

    Observations 566 566 566 566 566 56R-squared 0.060 0.238 0.231 0.241 0.242 0.25

    Note: Cluster robust standard errors in parentheses. *** p

  • 8/20/2019 Bargaining for the American Dream

    32/36

    29 Center for American Progress |  Bargaining for the American Dream

    TABLE A6

    Unions and mobility by fathers’ educational and occupational group

    Noncollege-

    educated

    father

    Noncollege-

    educated

    father

    College-

    educated

    father

    College-

    educated

    father

    Blue collar

    father

    Blue collar

    father

    White collar

    father

    White

    fat

    Log child

    labor income

    Log child

    labor income

    Log child

    labor income

    Log child

    labor income

    Log child

    labor income

    Log child

    labor income

    Log child

    labor income

    Log

    labor i

    (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8

    Union father0.275*** 0.195** 0.107 0.104 0.213*** 0.146** 0.067 0.

    (0.083) (0.088) (0.086) (0.085) (0.075) (0.069) (0.100) (0.

    Log father labor

    income

    0.284*** 0.059 0.293*** 0.

    (0.066) (0.097) (0.069) (0.

    Other covariates Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

    State clustered

    standard errors  Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

    Observations 435 435 479 478 498 497 416

    R-squared 0.234 0.263 0.059 0.060 0.194 0.230 0.047 0.

    Note: Cluster robust standard errors in parentheses. *** p

  • 8/20/2019 Bargaining for the American Dream

    33/36

    30 Center for American Progress |  Bargaining for the American Dream

    About the authors

    Richard Freeman holds he Herber Ascherman chair in economics a Harvard

    Universiy and is a research associae a he Naional Bureau o Economic

    Research in Cambridge, Massachusets.

    Eunice Han is a proessor o economics a Wellesley College and a research ellow

    a he Naional Bureau o Economic Research. Her research covers opics in labor

    economics and he economics o educaion wih an emphasis on insiuions and

    legal sysems. She currenly ocuses on he impac o unionism on he local labor

    marke, especially wih regards o income inequaliy and economic mobiliy. She

    received her Ph.D. in economics rom Harvard Universiy in 2013.

    David Madland is he Managing Direcor o he Economic Policy eam and he

    Direcor o he American Worker Projec a Cener or American Progress. He has

     writen exensively abou he economy and American poliics on a range o opics,including he middle class, economic inequaliy, reiremen policy, labor unions,

    and workplace sandards such as he minimum wage. His book, Hollowed Out:

    Why the Economy Doesn’t Work without a Strong Middle Class , was published by he

    Universiy o Caliornia Press in June 2015. Madland has a docorae in govern-

    men rom Georgeown Universiy and received his bachelor’s degree rom he

    Universiy o Caliornia, Berkeley.

    Brendan V. Duke is a Policy Analys or he Cener or American Progress’ Middle-

    Ou Economics projec. His research ocuses on economic inequaliy and eco-

    nomic growh. He holds a maser’s degree in economics and public policy rom

    Princeon Universiy’s Woodrow Wilson School o Public and Inernaional Affairs.

  • 8/20/2019 Bargaining for the American Dream

    34/36

    31 Center for American Progress |  Bargaining for the American Dream

    Endnotes

    1 Raj Chetty, Nathaniel Hendren, Patrick Kline, and Em-manuel Saez, “Where is the Land of Opportunit y? TheGeography of Intergenerational Mobility in the UnitedStates,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 129 (4) (2014):1553–1623.

      2 Ibid.

      3 David Madland and Nick Bunker, “Unions BoostEconomic Mobility in U.S. States” (Washington: Centerfor American Progress Action Fund, 2012), available athttps://www.americanprogressaction.org/issues/labor/report/2012/09/20/38624/unions-boost-economic-mobility-in-u-s-states/.

      4 Bruce Western and Jake Rosenfeld, “How Much HasDe-Unionisation Contributed to the Rise in Male Earn-ings Inequality,” The American Sociological Review  4 (76)(2011): 513–537; David Card, Thomas Lemieux, and W.Craig Riddell, “Unions and Wage I nequality,” Journalof Labor Research 25 (2004); John DiNardo, Nicole M.Fortin, and Thomas Lemieux, “Labor Market Institu-tions and the Distribution of Wages, 1973–1992: ASemiparametric Approach,” Econometrica 5 (64) (1996):1001-1004; Richard B. Freeman, “How Much Has De-Unionisation Contributed to the Rise in Male EarningsInequality?” In Sheldon Danziger and Peter Gottschalk(eds.), Uneven Tides (New York: Sage Press, 1992), pp.133–163.

      5 Western and Rosenfeld, “How Much Has De-Unionisa-tion Contributed to the Rise in Male Earnings Inequal-ity.”

      6 Unions’ tendency to raise wages for nonunion workersbecause firms try to avoid unionization is called thethreat effect. Unions could also reduce wages fornonunion workers if union wages and benefits reducedemployment in the union sector, increasing the laborsupply in nonunion work; this is called the crowdingeffect. Evidence suggests that the threat effect domi-nates the crowding effect and that unions raise wagesfor nonunion workers. See Henry S. Farber, “NonunionWage Rates and the Threat of Unionization,” ILR Review  28 (3) (2005): 335–352.

      7 Martin Gilens, Affluence and Influence: EconomicInequality and Political Power in America (Princeton, NJ:Princeton University Press, 2013), pp. 154–160.

      8 James Cox and Ronald L. Oaxaca, “The Political Econo-my of Minimum Wage Legislation,” Economic Inquiry  20(4) (1982): 533–555.

      9 Chetty, Hendren, Kline, and Saez, “Where is the Land ofOpportunity?”

      10 Chetty and others, “Where is the Land of Opportunity?”finds a Gini coefficient of just the bottom 99 percent ofhouseholds has a stronger negative association withmobility than an overall Gini does and uses this bottom99 percent Gini as one of its five factors. We use theoverall Gini, however, because they do not provide abottom 99 percent Gini by county (which we need to

    include it in our analysis because of the complicationsof combining with the union data), and it comes fromtheir federal tax data, so public data could not be used.See Appendix A for more details.

      11 As described in the appendix, the health results aresensitive to the population analyzed. We find positiveand statistically significant results when we do not con-dition on the child working full time and only condition

    on the head of household working full time (the latterto include union mothers on maternity leave). Thehealth results are positive but not sign ificant when wecondition on the child working full time and/or condi-tion on a head of household or wife working full time.

      12 Raj Chetty and others, “Is the United States Still a Landof Opportunity? Recent Trends in IntergenerationalMobility,” American Economic Review Papers and Pro-ceedings 104 (5) (2014): 141–147.

      13 Chetty, Hendren, Kline, and Saez, “Where is the Land ofOpportunity?”

      14 Danny Vinik, “Is It Inequality or Mobility? Neither Econo-mists nor GOP Candidates Can Decide,” New Republic ,April 7, 2015, available at http://www.newrepublic.com/article/121465/2016-presidential-candidates-face-challenge-talking-about-inequality.

    15 Nathaniel G. Hilger, “The Great Escape: Intergenera-tional Mobility Sin ce 1940.” Working Paper 21217 (Cam-bridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research,2015).

      16 Ibid.

     17 Robert D. Putnam, Our Kids (New York: Simon & Schus-ter, 2015), p. 228.

      18 Sectors are based on Zoltan Kenessey, “The Primary,Secondary, Tertiary And Quaternary Sectors Of TheEconomy,” Review of Income and Wealth 33 (4) (1987):359–385. Analysis with major industry categories yieldssimilar results.

      19 Marc J. Perry and Paul J. Mackun, “Population Changeand Distribution” (Washington: U.S. Bureau of theCensus, 2001), available at https://www.census.gov/prod/2001pubs/c2kbr01-2.pdf.

      20 To measure the direct effect of parents’ unionism onoffspring income, the authors focus on offspring’slabor income rather than the combined family incomeof married couples. The use of labor income drops

    children who are self-employed status or out of laborforce.

      21 The full results for all of the authors’ regression analysesare available upon request.

    22 It is commonly understood that the higher value ofIGE, the lower the intergenerational mobility is. In oneextreme case, the IGE would be equal to zero if thereexists no relationship between family background andthe adult offspring income. Children born into a poorfamily would have the same likelihood of earning ahigh income as children born into a rich family.

      23 Although the authors used labor income rather thanfamily income of offspring, this estimate is consistentwith literature. See Chetty and others, “Where is theLand of Opportunity?”; Chul-In Lee and Gary Solon,“Trends in Intergenerational Income M obility,” Review

    of Economics and Statistics 91 (4) (2009): 766-772;Bhashkar Mazumder, “Fortunate Sons: New Es timatesof Intergenerational Mobility in the United States UsingSocial Security Earnings Data,”The Review of Economicsand Statistics 87 (2) (2005): 235-255. This literaturestates that the estimated IGE could be subject to theattenuation bias if the data focus on short-term periodsdue to the long-lasting transitory shocks to income.

    http://www.newrepublic.com/article/121465/2016-presidential-candidates-face-challenge-talking-about-inequalityhttp://www.newrepublic.com/article/121465/2016-presidential-candidates-face-challenge-talking-about-inequalityhttp://www.newrepublic.com/article/121465/2016-presidential-candidates-face-challenge-talking-about-inequalityhttp://www.newrepublic.com/article/121465/2016-presidential-candidates-face-challenge-talking-about-inequalityhttp://www.newrepublic.com/article/121465/2016-presidential-candidates-face-challenge-talking-about-inequalityhttp://www.newrepublic.com/article/121465/2016-presidential-candidates-face-challenge-talking-about-inequality

  • 8/20/2019 Bargaining for the American Dream

    35/36

    32 Center for American Progress |  Bargaining for the American Dream

      24 If we control for separate labor incomes of bothparents, the coefficients on union father in Model 4, forexample, is 0.25 and is statistically significant at the 1percent of significance level. The coefficient on unionmothers remain insignificant.

      25 In regressions with high school graduation as themeasure of schooling, the father’s unionism raises sons’high school graduation rate by a statistically significant4.4 percentage points.

     

  • 8/20/2019 Bargaining for the American Dream

    36/36

    Our Mission

     The Center for American

    Progress is an independent,

    nonpartisan policy institute

    that is dedicated to improving

    the lives of all Americans,

    through bold, progressive

    ideas, as well as strongleadership and concerted

    action. Our aim is not just to

    change the conversation, but

    to change the country.

    Our Values

    As progressives, we believe

    America should be a land of

    boundless opportunity, where

    people can climb the ladder

    of economic mobility. We

    believe we owe it to future

    generations to protect theplanet and promote peace

    and shared global prosperity.

    And we believe an effective

    government can earn the

    trust of the American people,

    champion the common

    good over narrow self-interest,

    and harness the strength ofour diversity.

    Our Approach

    We develop new policy ideas

    challenge the media to cover

    the issues that truly matter,

    and shape the national debat

    With policy teams in major

    issue areas, American Progres

    can think creatively at thecross-section of traditional

    boundaries to develop ideas

    for policymakers that lead to

    real change. By employing an

    extensive communications

    and outreach effort that we

    adapt to a rapidly changing

    media landscape, we move

    our ideas aggressively in thenational policy debate.