Alex Parkinson - Dissertation

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/4/2019 Alex Parkinson - Dissertation

    1/57

    A Model for an Anthropological Economy:

    Beyond the Universal and the Particular

    A dissertation submitted to the University of Manchester for the degree of

    Master of Arts in the Faculty of Humanities

    2010

    Alexander Parkinson

    School of Social Sciences

  • 8/4/2019 Alex Parkinson - Dissertation

    2/57

    1

    List of Contents

    Introduction ......................................................................................................................................................................... 5

    Introducing the Eye of Providence Economic Model ........................................................................................... 7

    Why the Great Transformation Today? ............................................................................................................... 7

    Outlining the Eye of Providence Methodology .................................................................................................. 8

    Dialectical Interconnectivity of Components ................................................................................................. 11

    Bridging the Intellectual Divide? ......................................................................................................................... 12

    Theorising with the Eye of Providence Model ..................................................................................................... 14

    Political Economy ...................................................................................................................................................... 14

    Local Expressions, Global Forces, and Elite Interests ............................................................................15

    An Interpretative Theory of Value ...................................................................................................................... 18

    The Problem of Economic Value ..................................................................................................................19

    The Values of Price ................................................................................................................................................21Wall Street in an Anthropological Economy ....................................................................................................... 23

    The Economy, The Whitehouse, Wall Street, and High Financiers ...................................................23

    The Politics of Shareholder Value in a Finance-led Economy .............................................................27

    Masters of a Symbolic Universe of Value .....................................................................................................30

    Summary ...................................................................................................................................................................33

    Migrant Remittances in an Anthropological Economy ................................................................................... 34

    What the Economists Say ................................................................................................................................... 34

    Remittances and Microeconomics ..................................................................................................................35

    Remittances and Macroeconomics .................................................................................................................37

    Remittances and the Eye of Providence Model ............................................................................................... 41

    Transnational Dynamics of Remittances .....................................................................................................42

    Articulations of Value Realms ..........................................................................................................................45

    Summary ...................................................................................................................................................................47

    Conclusion ......................................................................................................................................................................... 49

    Word count: 17,594

    List of Diagrams

    The Eye of Providence model10

  • 8/4/2019 Alex Parkinson - Dissertation

    3/57

    2

    ABSTRACT

    This paper critiques the privileged place of economic expertise in contemporary societyand introduces the Eye of Providence model - intended for economic anthropology - thatdirectly engages and challenges knowledge from the discipline of economics. The formaland substantive elements of the economy are situated in dialectically embedded

    relationships with individuals, institutions, and ruling powers.

    I exemplify how an anthropological approach to value is useful when highlighting thelimits of economic knowledge. This is achieved theoretically by blending ideas frompolitical economy with perspectives from interpretive or symbolic anthropology. Theresult is an approach that, on the one hand, pays careful attention to wider systems ofpower, such as those embodied by the term neoliberalism, and how these articulatewith local political contexts. On the other hand, it uses the concept of value or values toprobe the social, political, and cultural dynamics of economic value and to interpretmeaningfully how values shape economic action from the perspective of economicactors.

    The model is tested comparatively, firstly with financiers that operate in a formallyinstituted market environment but that are shown to also function throughinstitutionalised culture and forces of political power. Secondly, it is tested on the case ofremittance makers that operate more informally through gift exchanges with their kin.This allows me to contrast the place of economic expertise in a market environment familiar ground for economists with a context that does not sit so comfortably with itsmethods.

    I argue for a more humanistic approach to the economy and highlight specific points ofcollaboration with economics. I also emphasise that anthropologists should pay more

    attention to the processes through which economics ideologically represents the world,rather than channelling efforts into disproving the universality of economic models.

  • 8/4/2019 Alex Parkinson - Dissertation

    4/57

    3

    No portion of the work referred to in the dissertation has been submitted in support of

    an application for another degree or qualification of this or any other university or other

    institute of learning.

    COPYRIGHT STATEMENT

    i. Copyright in text of this dissertation rests with the author. Copies (by any process)

    either in full, or of extracts, may be made only in accordance with instructions given by

    the author. Details may be obtained from the appropriate Graduate Office. This page

    must form part of any such copies made. Further copies (by any process) of copies made

    in accordance with such instructions may not be made without the permission (in

    writing) of the author.

    ii. The ownership of any intellectual property rights which may be described in this

    dissertation is vested in the University of Manchester, subject to any prior agreement to

    the contrary, and may not be made available for use by third parties without the written

    permission of the University, which will prescribe the terms and conditions of any such

    agreement.

    iii. Further information on the conditions under which disclosures and exploitation maytake place is available from the Head of the School of Social Sciences.

  • 8/4/2019 Alex Parkinson - Dissertation

    5/57

    4

    The Author

    I obtained a Bachelor of Arts with First Class Honours in Corporate Communication from

    Manchester Metropolitan University in 2006. This included two years of study at

    Indiana-Purdue University Fort Wayne.

    I worked as a stockbroker and investment manager in Manchester, UK, from 2006 to

    2009, obtaining the Certificate in Investment Securities in 2007 and the Certificate in

    Investment Management in 2008 from the Securities and Investment Institute.

    In September 2009, I embarked on the Master of Arts (taught) in Social Anthropology at

    Manchester University and began specialising in economic anthropology over the

    summer of 2010.

    With special thanks to Karen Sykes, Mia, David, Jarle, Irene, and Jennifer.

    For Mr Alan Cave

  • 8/4/2019 Alex Parkinson - Dissertation

    6/57

    5

    Introduction

    The astounding dominance of the discipline of economics over the other social

    sciences is all too well known in anthropology. The Economic and Social Research

    Council (2009) granted less than one-fifth of the number of research awards to social

    anthropology than it did to economics in 2009 and it received just over a quarter of the

    number of applications (p. 64). In response to the trend that William Milberg (2009) has

    described as intellectual imperialism and in order to problematize the current status

    that economists occupy as the high priests of our [Western] culture (Wilk 1996, p. 33),

    this paper asks what are the implications of privileging one form of knowledge over

    another? What is economic expertise? In what ways and in which places can we study

    the economy? How might an anthropological perspective enable a greater

    understanding of contemporary economic life? In what ways can it engage

    constructively with economics, not only to challenge the axioms upon which the

    discipline rests but to provide new insights that connect with its understandings? Given

    the centrality of economic thought in modern social and political spheres, in my view,

    these are among the big questions of today, for anthropologists and for us all.

    In this thesis, I will present a critique of the high value placed on economic

    expertise in contemporary Western society and, in doing so, emphasise, and hopefully

    enhance, the value of anthropological expertise. To this end, I introduce what I shall

    refer to as the Eye of Providence economic model that offers methodological and

    theoretical guidance for the subdiscipline of economic anthropology. It is here that

    questions about the value of knowledge meet questions about value more generally.

    What is at stake in answering these questions is an anthropology of value that

    overcomes the current rule of economics as the queen of those social sciences that judge

    what is good, which as a matter of no coincidence, also includes judgements made

    regarding the disciplines own brand of knowledge. Indeed, by arguing for the

    importance of understanding dimensions of power in relation to value, I reveal howcertain interests are served by value structures that pattern such judgements. An

    anthropology of value can mark out the limitations of economic expertise embedded

    ideologically in our social knowledge and practice by negotiating those areas of life

    that currently fall outside of the rubric of the discipline of economics but nonetheless

    influence and constitute our economic lives.

  • 8/4/2019 Alex Parkinson - Dissertation

    7/57

    6

    It became apparent to me while developing the overall framework of method

    and of theory that I should avoid reiterating the conceptual dichotomy of the

    universal and the particular that seems to echo through so many connected debates.

    Thus, I believe that we must go beyond simply arguing that the world everywhere is

    different and that universal principles do not hold up in reality. Rather than merely

    refuting economic expertise, I hope to engage it directly to highlight potential areas of

    connection between economic knowledge and anthropological knowledge. In addition to

    this, I argue that anthropology should focus on the ways in which economics

    (mis)represents the world and should vie for a more humanistic intellectual perspective

    on the economy. In the space between economic representation and economic reality

    lies a distinct opportunity for anthropological analyses to highlight social, cultural, and

    political dynamics that can draw the two disciplines closer together.

    The opening section outlines the methodological areas of the Eye of Providence

    model, which situates the economy as a set of both ideas and functionings in relation

    to individuals, institutions, and ruling powers. To add theoretical direction, the second

    part considers how the model relates to political economy and interpretative

    approaches to the anthropology of value. I do not suggest that these two theoretical

    perspectives are the only ones compatible with my model; however, for the purposes of

    this paper, they should be considered part and parcel of the conceptual apparatus.

    The remainder of the paper endeavours to emphasise the importance of this specificblend of prescriptions for an anthropological economy theoretical, methodological,

    and epistemological in a more concrete fashion and across two very different contexts.

    Hence, the third section reinterprets ethnographic research conducted with finance

    workers to reveal the influence of culture in a formally instituted environment. The final

    part investigates the less-instituted practices of international money transfers

    undertaken by remittance-makers to contrast economists understandings with that of

    anthropologists. This comparative analysis not only shows anthropologically how

    people live economic lives in spaces of divergent degrees of (in)formality. More

    importantly, it also enables me to contrast the nature and place of economic expertise

    vis--vis anthropological expertise, as well as the place and role of money in each social

    setting.

  • 8/4/2019 Alex Parkinson - Dissertation

    8/57

    7

    Introducing the Eye of Providence Economic Model

    Why the Great Transformation Today?

    The inspiration for my model initially came from Hann and Harts (2009)

    rethinking of Polanyi in a contemporary context. Polanyi was principally concerned with

    the relationship between the market and society, particularly with tracing how the

    former became central to the latter and emphasising the destructive social

    consequences that ensue when self-regulating markets form the bases of societies.

    Importantly, he showed that this was achieved through political power rather than

    natural social evolution, contradicting common belief. He was not opposed to the

    utilisation of markets to allocate goods and services from a more marginal position in

    society but to the dominant position that self-regulated markets can come to occupy

    when the market principle reigns supreme. Hann and Hart (2009) have similar concernstoday, characterising unrestrained markets as engines of inequality and arguing that

    the notion of markets as a natural force beyond social regulation serves also to

    legitimize [sic] wealth and even to make poverty seem deserved (p. 3). In structuring

    my model, I have largely drawn on the idea of the interplay between the market1 and

    society,2 as well as Polanyis notion of embeddedness.3

    Polanyi believed that the market fundamentalism to which he was opposed

    would ultimately lead to a political reaction and a withdrawal to more socially sensitive

    economic practices. Certainly, his fears may have been quelled with the rise to

    dominance of the U.S. as an economic superpower, enabled through market expansion

    (Hart 2000). However, with the global spread of neoliberal ideology since the 1980s,

    perpetuated by market fundamentalists epitomised by Reagan and Thatcher, Keynesian

    and socialist forms of economic management were dislodged; consequently, a situation

    has arisen that Polanyi did not envisage when writing in the 1940s but that has

    nonetheless imbued his ideas with a new resurgence (Hann & Hart 2009). There are

    1 I take the market to be both an economic idea and a functioning of the economy. I conflate the termsmarket, finance, and economy throughout the paper.2 In the model, I have split society into individuals, institutions, and ruling powers.3 Although it has been argued that embeddedness is not one of Polanyis main concepts and that it wasactually transformed by sociologists into the mainstream of the discipline (Beckert 2009), it is the re-thinking of Polanyis ideas that I am concerned with here, rather than tracing a genealogy of ideas. I hopeto show that Gudemans (2009a) concept of dialectical embeddedness is useful when understandingcontemporary economies.

  • 8/4/2019 Alex Parkinson - Dissertation

    9/57

    8

    parallels between Polanyis description of European societies during The Great

    Transformation and the current revival of self-regulating markets through neoliberal

    globalisation, as the market is once again considered vital to the functioning of society

    (Servet 2009, pp. 72-74). With the focus on market relations, itcertainly seems that a

    quest for a better understanding of contemporary economic life4

    Hann and Hart (2009) argue that the discipline of economics has mainly

    concerned itself with individuals assumed to be economic decision-makers and market

    participants. Yet peopleper se do not feature in their calculations; hence, the idea of an

    economy with humans has been left for other social scientists to pursue. The baton was

    partly carried by sociologists whose interest was invigorated from the late 1970s due to

    the perceived rise in the importance of understanding economic concerns in relation to

    social integration (Beckert 2009, pp. 38-41). Anthropologists, too, have felt obligated to

    address the main views of economists, as economics became the ideological and

    practical arm of global capitalism (Hann & Hart 2009, p. 12). The editors (2009) call for

    more anthropologists to directly challenge economists at their own game of national and

    global economic analysis in order to assess the world economy in whole and by part

    and investigate further whether or not capitalist economy rests on human principles of

    universal validity (p. 13). The remainder of this section and the one that follows lay the

    conceptual groundwork for this type of study by offering a model for economicanthropology. My work is not based on research experience and is thus restricted by the

    walls of a library-based study. However, I hope to still set out specific research

    objectives, as well as some general questions to be explored.

    should begin by riding

    this resurgent wave of Polanyian (re)thinking.

    Outlining the Eye of Providence Methodology

    The model, as outlined in figure 1 below, has within its triangular enclosure a

    component for economy that encompasses both economic ideasper se and the actual

    functionings of an economy that occur out there in the world. The world of ideas, for

    instance, would consist of neoclassic theories ranging from hypotheses of efficient

    markets to notions of individual rationality but also more socially sensitive concepts,

    4 I use the term economic life to incorporate the perspectives of production, distribution, exchange, andconsumption.

  • 8/4/2019 Alex Parkinson - Dissertation

    10/57

    9

    such as the domestic moral economy. The physical functionings are the substance of the

    market. They would, for example, consist of the actual buying and selling that occurs in a

    marketplace, such as that on the London Stock Exchange, as well as activity in the

    housing market, which is perhaps more loosely enacted through the market principle

    than through a physical marketplace. I have situated the economy within this enclosed

    area to illustrate the dialectical embeddedness (discussed below) with the other

    components at each of the three points of the triangle.

    The top point of the model the pyramids tip represents the ruling powers

    and their rulings and interests. It may, for instance, reflect modern capitalist state

    agendas to protect the economy from inflation through monetary policy. The component

    of the model that points to institutions and their knowledges and practices does

    not simply signify economic phenomena relating to organisations or to economic

    institutions themselves but also includes institutions, such as the household or family.

    Finally, the point of the model that incorporates individuals and their thoughts and

    actions highlights the importance of considering peoples economic agency and the

    meaning that they attach to their economic lives. In accordance to the Polanyian

    rethinking that I have outlined above, these four main elements of the framework

    represent the fundamental perspectives from which I believe social scientists should try

    to understand economic life.

    I have named my economic model the Eye of Providence for two reasons. Firstly,its structure resembles the symbol of the Eye of Providence, which is probably most

    ubiquitously represented on the Great Seal of the U.S. one dollar bill and that has the

    words Annuit Coeptis God favours our undertakings placed above it. Taken

    together, these signs are said to refer to the many divine interventions for the American

    cause (U.S. Department of State 2003, pp. 6 & 15). Given that the all-seeing eye can be

    interpreted as God watching over all of humanity, it is rather fitting with a central tenet

    of this paper; namely, that the economy, or the eye, has become so important to modern

    capitalist societies that we can think of this Great Transformation as an apotheosis. The

    state may intervene but it acts only in the divine name of a Capitalist Democratic

    Economy. Therefore, my second motive for labelling my model this way is to invoke the

    metaphor of the eye. I use it interchangeably with the economy in order to

  • 8/4/2019 Alex Parkinson - Dissertation

    11/57

    10

    emphasise the piety towards, and the power emanating from, the associated ideas and

    functionings.

    Figure 1 The Eye of Providence Economic Model:

    * The borders on each component are intentionally dashed to emphasise the crossover

    between the concepts.

    ** All connections are dialectical.

    *** Economic ideas discussed in this essay are mapped onto the sub-component box in

    the following order: 1. Market economy; 2. Marketplace; 3. Domestic Moral Economy; 4.

    Remittances. I have ordered the examples in every sub-component box of the model

    correspondingly.

    ***

    *

    **

    RulingsMonetary policy

    De-regulation

    Confer chiefly title

    Force state

    governments to act

    InterestsControl inflation

    Reduce trade barriers

    Increase chiefly power

    Encourage investment

    of remittances

    IndividualsInstitutions

    Ruling Power

    Economy

    IdeasA market economy

    Marketplace

    Domestic Moral Economy

    Remittance phenomenon

    FunctioningsCapitalist transactions

    Banking deals

    Cycling gift system

    Total remittances

    KnowledgesEconomic reports

    Analyst reports

    Services rendered

    Kinship ties

    PracticesIMF policy pressure

    Raise capital

    Serve chief and kin

    Remit to kin

    ActionsSell labour

    Buy stock

    Share food with kin

    Migrate and remit

    ThoughtsAccumulate money

    Make a profit

    Value sharing

    Value family

  • 8/4/2019 Alex Parkinson - Dissertation

    12/57

    11

    Dialectical Interconnectivity of Components

    Having outlined the main components of the framework, I now depict the

    relationship between the parts. Polanyi emphasises how the economy became

    disembedded from existing social relations as the Western world made the transition to

    industrial society. Neoclassic economists would happily leave things there, perceiving

    any embeddedness as a flaw to the ideal functioning of the economy. Even the New

    Institutional Economists overlook the a priori relationships that constitute actors,

    despite observing the emergence and form of economic institutions (Gudeman 2009a,

    pp. 32-34). To rectify this, Gudeman (2009a) argues for a dialectical approach to society

    and the market as both embedded and disembedded and considers the two different

    value realms that surround each. On the one hand, people are only connected through

    market trade by alienating and impersonal contracts. On the other, there is a mutual

    economic base of shared interests and holdings of people who are themselves products

    of others within the base. Gudeman (2009a) argues that this division is a continuing

    dialectic in all economies, where it assumes different historical forms and degrees of

    tension (p. 37). Mutuality is essential to the existence of all economies, even those that

    have become submerged in the market, but it is also undermined by the very market

    practices and models that it supports, while this dependency link is itself erased. This is

    exemplified when companies mystify downsizing by presenting themselves as

    communities to the employees on which they depend, while the downsizing itself

    undermines mutuality and holds wages down, despite the rhetoric of increased

    productivity (Gudeman 2009a, pp. 28 & 29). My model supports the illumination of such

    dynamics.

    We could posit further that the relationship between all four elements of the

    model is characterised by dialectical mutual constitution. Berger and Luckman (1966)

    depict the social order as an ongoing human production where action becomes

    patterned and the patterning eventually becomes habitually typified into institutions(pp. 69-78). This world is then objective and antecedent to individuals, as the product

    acts back upon the producers in a dialectical relationship whereby: Society is a human

    product. Society is an objective reality. Man is a social product (p. 79). Once this first-

    order of social institutionalisation has been established, it must be made plausible by a

    second-order process of legitimisation, for which Berger and Luckman (1966) identify

  • 8/4/2019 Alex Parkinson - Dissertation

    13/57

    12

    four distinct and ascending levels (pp. 110-122). Reinterpreted for a neoliberal capitalist

    economy, one could say that these are: incipient transmission of a vocabulary of self-

    interest, such as you have to think of yourself in business; basic theoretical

    propositions that explain sets of meanings, such as the economic proverb a rising tide

    lifts all boats; explicit theories of an institutional sector with a separate stock of

    knowledge, such as economics; and finally, at the highest level, the symbolic universe

    that amalgamates discrete provinces of meaning and encompasses the institutional

    order, such as a universe of value.

    Bridging the Intellectual Divide?

    As I alluded to in the introduction, a great intellectual split can be discerned when

    considering the history of economic anthropology. Having outlined my model, I can now

    explore this a little further. The divide was perhaps most pronounced when it

    manifested as the opposing force between the two schools of thought that comprised

    The Great Debate. I do not revisit the formalist-substantivist debate but invoke it only

    to demonstrate the models capacity to draw together these divergent views. Wilk

    (1996) believes that the debates disengagement derives from each partys starting

    point, which he claims made the perspectives mutually exclusive. The formalists begin

    with individuals, considered to be rational self-interested maximizers, while the

    substantivists start at the level of societies, the institutions of which they say act as

    structures for economic life (pp. 1-13). Thus, the methodology of the former view

    assumes the universality of the individual and the latter implies the particularity of each

    social context.

    The roots of the intellectual dichotomy at the heart of the formalist-substantivist

    debate run much deeper and farther back. Carrier (2009a) traces the universal-

    particular divide back respectively to the individual contract posited by Spencer and the

    social contextualisation of Durkheim. The divide continued to the primitive acquisitive

    tendency that Malinowski identified in the Trobrianders against the social and historical

    context of self-interest that Mauss argued for (pp. 20-22). Disputes between those that

    saw a world of ideas and those who tried to understand things as they are date back

    even to the time of Plato and Aristotle (Blavatsky 1939). I assume that in reality the

    divide is more of an intellectual continuum than a dichotomous split and that there are

    truths in either view that are worth exploring. This leaves me with one caveat and one

  • 8/4/2019 Alex Parkinson - Dissertation

    14/57

    13

    challenge. Firstly, I must avoid the pitfalls of adhering too strongly to either perspective;

    namely, by positing that everything is like this or that everything is different.

    Secondly, I should aspire, where possible, to productively reconcile this age-old

    epistemological separation. Indeed, my model is designed to encourage adherence to

    these prescriptions.

  • 8/4/2019 Alex Parkinson - Dissertation

    15/57

    14

    Theorising with the Eye of Providence Model

    The Eye of Providence economic model, as outlined so far, is more methodological

    in that it highlights four conceptual areas where researchers might examine the

    economy. Although it does include some theoretical discussion, such as dialectics and

    embeddedness, it is necessary to further elaborate the theoretical account in line with

    the aspirations of the paper. Navigating through the notions of the universal and the

    particular, of representation and reality, and of anthropological and economic expertise,

    will take more than conceptual cartography. We also need a theoretical compass to

    direct our way. As I mentioned at the outset, in developing an anthropological theory of

    value, I have chosen to invoke political economy and interpretive approaches to value,

    which are key themes from Hann and Harts (2009) edited volume, because they

    generally differ with respect to their orientations to society and to the individual. The

    theoretical apparatus of political economy lends itself to studies of the ruling powers

    and institutions, whereas interpretative value theory is generally more applicable to

    the element for individuals. These complementary perspectives, though, are not

    exclusive to the stated domains, allowing me to interweave the theoretical analysis and

    open up the economic realm in a unified fashion. I now introduce the two lines of

    investigation that constitute the final parts of my model and that I will later apply to the

    cases of finance workers and remittance makers.

    Political Economy

    At the societal level, I have opted for a view of political economy, rather than say

    emphasising a Durkheimian functional approach, to allow for a political slant when

    connecting with economics (Wilk 1996, p. 83). This may seem at odds with Steiners

    (2009) criticism of Polanyi vis--vis the Durkheimians for not attending to the

    functioning of the market, assuming market mentality to be obsolete, and for endorsing

    rather than challenging its economic assumptions (pp. 68-71). Indeed, Steiners (2009)

    stress on [a] more accurate study of the interplay between economic thought,

    institutions, and the economy does seem to superimpose comfortably onto the

    framework of my model (p. 71). Moreover, his discussion of the importance of the

    teaching of economics, which is powerfully employed to extend the market, and on how

    economic knowledge is embodied by market tools and apparatus, such as the use of

  • 8/4/2019 Alex Parkinson - Dissertation

    16/57

    15

    economic models in contemporary financial markets, seems to link well with the

    dialectical interconnectivity of the model (pp. 68-71). While this approach may also fit

    my model, I develop a more Marxist stance on this occasion to emphasise the political

    and power dimensions of economic life rather than simply observing the functional

    aspects of an economy, as if it were a component of something that derives from a

    unified structure (Wilk 1996, pp. 83-93). Nevertheless, by dealing with economic ideas

    and functionings directly, I clearly do not ignore Steiners (2009) concerns.

    Local Expressions, Global Forces, and Elite Interests

    I begin with a less extreme case of political power, which nonetheless shows that

    investigating the dynamic relationship between political powers and economic forms is

    vital if we wish to comprehend the latter. Even in situations where the connection may

    ostensibly be trivial, power is prevalent. Carrier (2009b) augments this point when he

    compares our current moment of neoliberalism to Polanyis notion of the self-regulating

    market growing free and expanding to other areas of life, as money itself becomes the

    measure and value of individuals. He argues that neoliberalism permeates many aspects

    of life that are not ostensibly economic; thus, in order to understand these phenomena,

    we must attend to economic beliefs, motivations, institutions, and practices (pp. 240-

    242). To exemplify this, Carrier (2009b) discusses his research of environmental

    conservation in Jamaica. In a political economic milieu where the heavily indebted

    government, owing to the International Monetary Fund (IMF), had no money for

    conservation, activists had to appeal to the commercial advantages of protecting the

    coastal areas through an emphasis on tourism. This was not simply a consequence of the

    self-regulating market model but an outcome of the way the environmental activists had

    to operate through extending the market principle to commodify the coastal land and

    local labour force. Nevertheless, the market reach was largely realised as park

    management eventually became reduced to the financial bottom line and a goodenvironment came to mean a profitable space for attracting tourists, a profitable

    space, that is, for large overseas corporations (Carrier 2009b, pp. 242-255).

    I revisit this case briefly below but for now wish to note that it raises an

    important point about how ethnographers should think about engaging with political

    economy, since it essentially represents a local expression of global and national forces.

  • 8/4/2019 Alex Parkinson - Dissertation

    17/57

    16

    Marcus and Fischer (1986) call for ethnographic fieldwork to represent external

    systems[through] their thoroughly local definition and penetration, and [that] are

    formative of the symbols and shared meanings within the most intimate life-worlds of

    ethnographic subjects (p. 39). However, it is not sufficient to simply reveal these

    expressionsper se, as we must also consider the broader scale of political economy. For

    Marcus and Fischer (1986), these political economic forces should be the object of study

    for anthropology, even if this macrosystem perspective entails traversing multiple field

    sites (pp. 90-95).5

    David Harvey (2005) offers a particularly Marxist view of these broader

    processes, interpreting neoliberalism a sweeping abstraction that he invokes to

    describe a plethora of different actions as a political project that creates the conditions

    for elites to accumulate capital. Combining his arguments with Carriers (2009b)

    research in Jamaica, we could posit that the neoliberal ideology forcefully circulated

    through the IMF allowed it to continue charging crippling interest payments to an

    indebted country and force the reduction of trade barriers and capital flows to allow

    foreign tourism corporations and investors to gain capital opportunistically within the

    countrys borders. From Harveys (2005) standpoint, the unlikelihood of Jamaica simplydefaulting on its debt and its inability to negotiate more socially-friendly terms would be

    attributed to neoliberal reforms that made the borrower take the losses on defaults (p.

    29), the precedent set by the New York fiscal crisis that favoured a good business

    climate over social well-being (p. 48), and the full authority given to the IMF in cases of

    default, whereby it will always protect financial firms (p. 73). Indeed, when the

    Jamaican government accepted stringent fiscal controls in order to obtain a U.S.$240

    million IMF loan in 1978, those opposed to the move predicted lower wages for

    Jamaican workers and higher profits for multinationals (Bolles 1983, p. 138). The

    calamitous consequences of this from the Jamaican perspective are perhaps most

    passionately communicated in Stephanie Blacks documentary Life and Debt(2001).

    By connecting economic forms and individuals to the forces of

    institutions and ruling powers that shape them, my model notably advocates the kind of

    research that the authors envisage. But what might this type of macrosystem view be

    and how can it complement an understanding of local economic forms?

    5 At the time of their writing, this was perhaps a more innovative statement than if it were made now. Thenotion of a multi-sited ethnography has indeed become part of the mainstream in anthropology.

  • 8/4/2019 Alex Parkinson - Dissertation

    18/57

    17

    While Harvey (2005) offers a rather radical perspective of political economy, it is

    nonetheless instructive in showing the importance of attending to the ways in which

    external influences can forcefully shape a given locale. This is particularly crucial even if

    we only partially accept Harveys (2005) depiction of the uneven spread of

    neoliberalism around the globe. Graebers (2009) depiction of our current era as the

    empire of debt does seem to echo these concerns. It is characterised, he says, by

    electronic consumer transactions, national economies driven by consumer debt, and

    financialisation that is increasingly detached from direct relations to commerce or

    production. Not only are we seemingly devoid of the social controls in place to curtail

    debt but this age has also witnessed the establishment of the first effective planetary

    administrative system, operating through the IMF, the World Bank, corporations, and

    other financial institutions, largely in order to protect the interests of creditors against

    debtors (p. 130). I am not suggesting that neoliberalism is the only broad systemic

    force to be reckoned with, nor am I ignoring alternative views of it that de-emphasise its

    homogenising and hegemonic character (Ong 2006). I have merely chosen to utilise the

    abstraction because it exemplifies my point about external forces. However, since it is

    usually employed to encompass notions of market fundamentalism and processes of

    global spread, tracing the influences of neoliberal ruling powers that operate through

    neoliberal institutions such as the World Bank and the IMF may be a decent

    starting-point when thinking about external influences on economic forms, especiallythose that we would usually refer to as capitalist.

    The dynamics of political economy can also be fathomed by unpacking economic

    ideas themselves. Graeber (2009) emphasises this point when he argues that drawing

    boundaries or making models is problematic since what we call social or economic

    systems are, in reality, an endless interweaving of dyadic relations that often operate

    according to completely different principles (p. 131). He argues that the market:

    is a model created by isolating certain principles within a complex system [] and thencreating a totalizing model within which the books all balance and all debts and

    credits ultimately cancel one another out (pp. 131-132).

    If markets, like societies, are ideological gestures that do not exist out there in the

    world but rather are a specific way in which a society represents itself, it is important to

    look at whose interests a particular model is serving and question the types of value that

  • 8/4/2019 Alex Parkinson - Dissertation

    19/57

    18

    are being realised. As Graeber (2009) illustrates, a market sells a house, where as the

    market justifies capitalist principles (p. 132), such as the commodification of Jamaica or

    of humans and nature more broadly.

    If we accept Graebers (2009) argument, it indicates that anthropologists must

    attempt to understand more than the functioning of a market and probe the influences

    and interests of political powers and their effects on that facet of the economy. This may

    even entail challenging the raison d'tre of existing ideas about the latter. In short, it

    means asking whythis is happening, rather than justwhatis going on. My point is that it

    would be insufficient, for instance, to argue abstractly that defaults on subprime

    mortgages can be understood as what Stuart Kirsch (2006) might refer to as

    unrequited reciprocity rather than, say, failed market exchange. We also require a

    better comprehension of the positioning of different actors in such practices, the

    institutional context that enabled the loans to take place, and the states neoliberal

    agenda that promoted less regulation. In our empire of debt, it was quite acceptable

    for greedy opportunistic creditors to loan money to people who could not afford to pay

    it back. In sum, we must aspire to interpret the interplay between the local and the

    external political influences on economic actors and institutions, as well as the internal

    political dynamics that constitute economic ideas themselves. This is a holistic ambition

    that may not be truly achievable in modern ethnography; however, it is a step towards a

    better understanding of the forces that shape economic life and a further opportunityfor interdisciplinary dialogue.

    An Interpretative Theory of Value

    Leaving things there would do no justice to the dialectical relationships that I

    have depicted above. Economic life would simply be a socio-political product and the

    inherent meanings would be left unexamined. If the previous section brought the

    individual into the picture as an activist within a Jamaican political economic system,this part tries to reveal the picture as seen from the individual. This allows us to enter

    the world of minds and presents the possibility of revealing a more Weberian view of

    economics as something that is embedded deeply in culture and belief, rather than vice-

    versa with a Marxist take (Wilk 1996, p. 110). To achieve this, I probe the meaning of

    value(s) in different contexts to effectively map out a symbolic structure of meaning,

  • 8/4/2019 Alex Parkinson - Dissertation

    20/57

    19

    thus, extending the concept of an anthropological theory of value and its connection to

    forms of economic life. By meshing symbolic anthropology with the dynamics of political

    economy, the Eye of Providence model should hopefully encourage [a]n interpretative

    anthropology [that is] fully accountable to its historical and political-economy

    implications (Marcus & Fischer 1986, p. 86).

    The Problem of Economic Value

    Developing a symbolic theory of value takes us far beyond thinking about value

    in the purely rational economic terms of labour, scarcity, and utility, and considers

    instead how value is determined through relations between different groups. In doing

    so, it becomes apparent that there are alternatives to our current world configuration,

    which was manufactured by economists and based on relations of self-interest (Servet

    2009, pp. 87-89). Economic theories of value were developed through the myth of value

    as natural and isolated from politics and where exchange counterparts in the market

    could have complete freedom to make choices, maintain an equal standing to one

    another, and have the ability to act with full rationality. Servet (2009) argues that these

    theories were:

    objective [since] they rationalized the relationship between a person (conceived of as

    by nature an egotistical individual) and a world of things where others exist only

    through competition for access to those things (pp. 89).

    This conflicts with the notion of humanity as having the potential for solidarity,

    interdependence as a community, and being obligated to future societies. Classical

    economists, positing their world of self-interest, could not resolve this problem, which

    Polanyi made explicit, of recognising both the needs of the individual and of society (pp.

    89-90). This is something that I hope an anthropological theory of value will achieve.

    To understand the problems surrounding past and current theories of value(s),

    we must venture much deeper than these logics of exchange. For instance, what kinds ofexpertise do we miss by assuming a narrow view of value? Graeber (2005) maintains

    that contemporary economists have limited the focus of their discipline to the

    production of mathematical models of resource allocation for profit or consumer

    preferences; consequently, questions of value, which were central to economics at the

    birth of the discipline, have been sidelined and left for anthropologists and other

  • 8/4/2019 Alex Parkinson - Dissertation

    21/57

    20

    scholars to explore. Moreover, he highlights that it was questions of value that set

    neoclassic economists apart from their predecessors, as the meaning of value

    transcended the physical altogether, and became simply a subjective measure of desire

    (p. 440). From here on, the price and value of objects became increasingly

    indistinguishable from one another. Adam Smith developed the labour theory of value to

    explain the difference between the exchange value and use value of objects. Ricardo

    identified the problem of depressed wages. Marx critiqued the wage system,

    characterising it as destructive of all that is worthwhile and meaningful. However, this

    kind of intellectual insight was swept aside by the marginalist revolution that redefined

    economics as a discipline devoted to studying the formation of price (pp. 441-443).

    I kindly ask for the readers patience here, as one may recognise that I am

    traversing material to which some scholars dedicate an entire career. My point is,

    however, that there was a fundamental change, a paradigm shift perhaps, that makes

    this whole process work. Was this shift in economic expertise simply down to myopia? I

    suspect probably not. Maybe it can be better viewed as a constructive distinction that

    was produced largely through political power when making the shift in perspective

    away from the theorists mentioned above, one that followed on historical changes in the

    key economic activities of men and women; that is, the movement from mid-nineteenth

    century U.K. production to consumption at the turn of the following century. While the

    underlying dynamics of the change are important because they allow us to see howeconomic ideas change vis--vis economic functionings, so too is the state of the present

    situation. Significantly, a contemporary study of value would typically surpass what we

    would usually refer to as economics, for it leads us into moral, aesthetic and symbolic

    territory that is very hard to reduce to rational calculation and science (Graeber 2005,

    p. 453). Grasping the particular is not a calculative act but judging the universal is.

    So how else can we theorise about value(s)? When questioning the existence of

    an anthropological theory of value, Graeber (2005) outlines three uses of the term:

    values in the socio-philosophical sense, value in the economic usage, and value in

    the Saussurean linguistic sense. If one considers these terms to essentially be instances

    of the same thing, it implies a common foundation for the three meanings, a symbolic

    system of value that defines the world in terms of what is important, meaningful,

    desirable or worthwhile in it (Graeber 2005, p. 439). In the sections below, I will

  • 8/4/2019 Alex Parkinson - Dissertation

    22/57

    21

    attempt to delineate such a system by analysing different usages of value(s). With

    regards to the latter of the three usages, the Saussauran approach to value as meaningful

    difference, I specifically investigate Graebers (2005) claim that it may be able to

    mediate understandings between individuals and systems. Moreover, Graeber (2005)

    invokes Dumonts notion of classic structuralist ideas as values that are hierarchical and

    able to become inverted at different levels. This may be especially pertinent to this

    paper since, as he argues, Dumont believed Western society is no longer hierarchical,

    not because Westerners value equality but because the supreme value is now the

    individual, which has allowed the market, as a sphere of individual self-realisation, to

    become the highest sphere (pp. 447-50).

    The Values of Price

    If value is conflated with price in our current economic world, then perhaps it

    will pay to also scratch below the surface of commodity prices to reveal the social

    processes behind them and popular understandings of them. Guyers (2009) work on

    price provides a suitable account with which to close this section because it

    amalgamates an expanded notion of value with an awareness of the concealment of

    political power. She shows how, in the twenty-first century, economic actors are

    increasingly aware that composite elements constitute prices, rather than simply

    assuming prices to be singular wholes. As shrewd consumers, we are now reminded ofthe fabrications of prices, such as those encompassed by currency exchanges. The

    outcome, Guyer (2009) claims, is a moral economy of transparently composite prices,

    which nevertheless retain the mystery of their components (p. 205). Thus, she argues

    that we should investigate the components encompassed by prices that are diffusely

    hidden amongst the traditional elements (pp. 203-205).

    Guyer (2009) demonstrates this through a case where the price of gasoline in the

    U.S. rose sharply by a dollar and rocked the projections of budgets from households to

    corporations. Forced to explain the rise, petroleum companies claimed that despite the

    rise in the nominal price of oil, there was a steady proportional return and they

    distinguished between crude oil costs, taxes, refining costs and profits, and distribution

    and marketing. They did not include profit on capital as a composite category, which

    made costs of finance imperceptible; thus, the public representation of price was as

  • 8/4/2019 Alex Parkinson - Dissertation

    23/57

    22

    proportions of the retail price that was itself based on market actors from producers to

    retailers. Furthermore, financial speculation on the commodity through futures

    contracts, driving up the price, was the composite component that was eventually

    determined to be the impetus behind the rise, which itself created further incentives to

    invest in oil. However, these factors, and indeed the great resulting profits made from

    investment banks, can only constitute part of the market price of crude from the view

    presented to consumers. Risk management and consulting costs, from which the great

    benefactors seem to be investment banks, are diffusely hidden (pp. 208-210).

    Guyers (2009) analysis may be useful here not only because it suggests that

    values are composite and allows us to investigate them as such. It also portrays a case

    where companies produced socially important economic expertise by (mis)representing

    the very factors that they were supposed to explain. Beyond the singular numerical

    aspects of numbers lies an array of social dynamics that affect their composition. If our

    task involves working with economic numbers or with theories that imply that

    numbers are wholes then Guyer (2009) shows that an understanding of their

    composite structure and how it is negotiated is crucial if we are to probe the concealed

    interests, motivations, and forces that are masked by these public ideologies of price. So

    it is not just economic models that we must unpack but also the numbers that are fed

    into them. If numbers cannot simply be taken at economic face value, this presents a

    clear point-of-entry for anthropology to interpret their associated social, cultural, andpolitical aspects.

  • 8/4/2019 Alex Parkinson - Dissertation

    24/57

    23

    Wall Street in an Anthropological Economy

    Having set out the conceptual framework of this paper, I now reinterpret Karen

    Hos (2009) monograph of high finance6

    on Wall Street through the lens of the Eye of

    Providence model and pursue the theoretical approaches of value and political economy.

    Ho (2009) offers a unique view of Wall Street, having initially worked there as a

    management consultant and later through probing her network of financial and

    economic actors when conducting fieldwork. Her ethnography allows us to understand

    an aspect of capitalism from the perspective of financial market actors and institutions

    that possess a considerable degree of economic and political agency. With this influence

    in mind, a broader view can also be attained of the effects on both the trends in the

    economy and in the structure of corporate America. For Ho (2009), the divorce of what

    is in the best interests of corporations from that of employees is a new feature of

    capitalism, whereby long-term social institutions have transformed into short-term

    liquid spaces under the dictates of Wall Street. Thus, we can investigate how people

    actually use and produce economic ideas and functionings not only on-the-ground but

    on a Street that is a well-instituted environment and an icon of modern market

    capitalism.

    The Economy, The Whitehouse, Wall Street, and High Financiers

    If we accept the notion of the market being disembedded from society, it implies

    that the labour market in high finance operates freely from stringent social ties, a

    meritocracy that is based on individuals competing fairly and equally for such highly

    remunerative and prestigious places in todays society; however, such an assumption

    would amount to a grave neglect of the organisational mutuality that governs this

    process. As Ho (2009) shows, Wall Street institutions and elite universities maintain

    huge feeder relationships that naturalise banking careers as the main destinations for

    top graduates of any discipline. The investment banks actually operate a quota systemfor the schools, with a huge bias to recruiting students from Harvard and Princeton.

    Candidates are actively poached from these two schools regardless of whether they can

    demonstrate technical banking ability, whereas candidates from other universities lack

    6 As with the market, I consider finance and financial markets to be both an idea and a functioning ofthe economy.

  • 8/4/2019 Alex Parkinson - Dissertation

    25/57

    24

    the socio-cultural capital and must prove themselves otherwise. Moreover, that

    intelligence is not considered a quality of a person but a currency that proves a persons

    worth attests to the mutual ties that underlie the dealings in this currency (pp. 39-72).

    On the one side, investment bankers are recruited and constructed through

    embedded ties of mutuality and are patterned into Wall Streets culture of smartness,

    hard work, and compensation. Furthermore, these connections also influence the

    success that one may have once hired, as there are better opportunities to meet with

    directors who themselves graduated from these elite schools. This is exemplified by the

    case of a talented black woman who left banking because she felt alienated for having

    attended a non-elite school (pp. 61 & 62). Despite the culture of hard work where green

    is supposedly the only colour, Ho (2009) shows how ethnicity greatly determines career

    paths. African-Americans generally assumed roles that required less networking and

    harder work, while Asians normally ended up in technical or product-focused positions.

    The privileged client-facing roles with the large bonuses were mostly earmarked for

    white upper-class males (pp. 106-121). Such filtering could not take place without pre-

    existing social ties and dispositions being transposed as conduits onto the supposedly

    neutral marketplace. Peoples way on the Street is largely already paved by social

    relations and institutions, although it does seem that money can still buy status for those

    that can afford an elite education.

    On the other side, one could argue for the disembeddedness of the actions ofthese market actors given that their greed almost reduced the Street to rubble in the

    latest crisis, never mind helping to engender a global recession. Meanwhile, the bonuses

    that bankers collected were still astronomically large and unfair (p. 225). The labour

    force might recruit through strong ties of mutuality but, once operational, bankers were

    only able to accrue such high levels of risk and large amounts of wealth by functioning as

    disembedded from concern for society at large. This was largely enabled through acts of

    deregulation by the ruling power7

    7 A contrast can be made with this Western view to Hertzs (1998) monograph of stock market traders inShanghai. She shows that the traders interpret the market in political terms, thus in China, you cannotlook at economics without looking at politics (p. 26). The market is more overtly embedded in the rulingsand interests of the ruling power. In Hos (2009) book, the lines between what constitutes the rulingpowers and the financial institutions are much fuzzier.

    that instantiated a greater degree of

    disembeddedness. Ho (2009) alludes to this process by mentioning the rollback of the

    Glass-Steagall act in the late 1990s that allowed deposit-taking banks and casino banks

  • 8/4/2019 Alex Parkinson - Dissertation

    26/57

    25

    to operate as one (p. 7). She also mentions how the takeover movement of the 1980s

    could only occur through deregulation and favouring of private ownership (p. 136).

    While Ho (2009) purports that a finance capital-led version of capitalismis not so

    much about disembedding as it is about power relations (p. 34), I would note that

    disembedding describes a process, where as power relations suggest how this process

    may have been enacted. Whatever the case, my model clearly highlights the need to

    attend to both the cause, as the political power through institutions, and effect, as shifts

    in the dialectical embeddedness.

    The dialectical mutual constitution of the elements of the model can also be

    discerned from Hos (2009) monograph. This is perhaps most evident in her illustration

    of the interplay between economic ideas and functionings and institutions knowledge

    and practices. A major theme of her book is how the institutions of Wall Street have

    incredible influence over those of corporate America through encouraging their

    downsizing and realigning them to the short-term. This does not engender productive

    growth but short-term mortgaged productivity that leads to broader economic booms

    and busts (p. 293). Economic and financial expertise is used by one group in society to

    realign social relations throughout the country. This is achieved by both acting out and

    perpetuating particular ideas about the way in which the economy should function. If we

    also consider that investment bankers are paid huge sums for their services, an image of

    economic expertise as a prized asset that can be exchanged for wealth usually in themoney form begins to emerge.

    More specifically, through her focus on employment, Ho (2009) analyses the

    nexus of investment banking culture and strategy and the intersections with

    corporations, markets, and economies (pp. 213-215). On the one side, employment

    decisions bear a relation to, but do not mirror, the stock market, and shareholder value

    (p. 227). While Wall Street prides itself on reacting much more quickly to market

    movements than other corporations (p. 229), these corporations are also pressured

    from the cultural dynamics of Wall Street to adopt downsizing as the general model for

    workplaces (p. 247). Any tension deriving from bankers self-concern or concern for

    others was reconciled by them resorting to market externalisations as economic ideas

    to rationalise the prevalence of rampant downsizing. In this case, it was not the

    company intentionally promoting itself as a community that mystified downsizing but

  • 8/4/2019 Alex Parkinson - Dissertation

    27/57

    26

    the institutional culture and individual beliefs of bankers. Like some sort of religious

    doctrine, people actually refer to economic ideas when justifying the undermining of

    mutuality and of themselves. Moreover, that investment banks actually get enrolled in

    their own hype, and the market trends that they help to engender, further attests to

    notion of the creation acting back upon the creators (pp. 318-324).

    For Ho (2009), this fetishization of the invisible hand obscures what happens on

    the other side of the dialectic; to wit, the role of investment banks in constructing

    unstable financial markets and jobs (pp. 234 & 235). Threatened with job cuts even

    during boom times, perhaps to protect the bonus pools of elites (p. 240), bankers are

    compelled to extract whatever they can out of the present regardless of the cost to

    society (p. 233). In addition to past crises, Ho (2009) discusses the substantial role of

    investment banks in engendering the subprime boom and the disastrous social

    consequences that came with the bust. Through generating a global market for

    mortgages by creating various sophisticated instruments, hyping them, and peddling

    them around the globe to investors (pp. 297-302), Wall Street eventually created a

    global web of risk that they themselves could not decipher (p. 321). Future ideas about

    economies and present functionings of economies are shaped by the collective agency of

    those acting within, and dually transforming, the institution of investment banking.

    Hos (2009) ethnography is intriguing because it shows that the economic actors

    within the well-instituted hub of the worlds financial markets actually operate largelythrough culture. Hence, she argues that we should look behind abstracted notions of

    the market since bankers appeals to naturalized market cycles must also be

    understood as particular cultural self-representations borne out of everyday Wall Street

    work life, not reification of market dominance (p. 242). She re-imagines the market as a

    space of human values, emotions, and institutional standards, a site of everyday

    practices as opposed to an abstract concept. Wall Street has not simply reconstructed

    the world to its image of shareholder value but has actualised a model that is [in fact]

    the bankers cultural model of themselves as coeval and identified with the market (p.

    252, italics in original). In this case, the market principle has become submerged into the

    organisational structure of investment banking compensation schemes (p. 260), while

    also expressed through the culture of Wall Street whose members are socialised into

    this elite world of market-centricity, short-termism, and rampant-insecurity. The high

  • 8/4/2019 Alex Parkinson - Dissertation

    28/57

    27

    financiers of Wall Street are humans with culture, not just machines with calculators. Ho

    (2009) emphasises the importance of anthropological insight in examining these forces.

    This cultural understanding is clearly beyond the repertoire of neoclassical

    economics. In fact, the notion of economic cycles being produced by Wall Street would

    not fit into any of the economic models of market cycles that I have come across, since

    there is no place in them for the human factor. When I became qualified as a

    stockbroker and investment manager, I was taught how to conduct a combination of

    technical and fundamental analysis8

    but was never shown where to look on the graph to

    watch for the excesses of Wall Street culture. I spent three years looking at charts of

    share prices and share indexes to try and establish where the prices were going but

    ignored the actions of Wall Street that allegedly caused the whole market to bottom out.

    Nonetheless, Ho (2009) does not explore the huge implications of her argument for the

    economy and for economics from the perspective of her informants. It would have been

    fascinating if she had elicited their take on her theory by perhaps asking whether they

    considered economic and financial market models and formulas to be relevant,

    fascinating to also consider that she did not decide to pursue this research. Asking

    investments bankers what they thought about the relationship between the actions of

    Wall Street and the economy at large could have yielded interesting results. The same

    could also be said for their views on the notion of a jobless recovery.

    The Politics of Shareholder Value in a Finance-led Economy

    Having discussed the ethnography from the different methodological

    perspectives of the model, I can now turn to the first of the theoretical approaches. In

    keeping with the Marxist stance that I have highlighted for political economy, I read Hos

    (2009) ethnography as an account of financial hegemony and competition over access to

    the new modes of production in the age of neoliberal financialisation. The distance

    between the ideal of shareholder value and the particular version of it that investmentbankers perform reiterates the need to look beyond the models themselves to the

    interests that are being served, as I mentioned above. Ho (2009) unpacks the notion of

    shareholder value to show that it is part of a wider scheme on Wall Street to promote its

    8 For an accurate and accessible explanation of these two financial strategies see (Janssen, Langager, and

    Murphy 2010).

  • 8/4/2019 Alex Parkinson - Dissertation

    29/57

    28

    benefits to the economy at large, perpetuated by an origin myth where investment

    banks provided the capital to allow corporate America to grow. These self-serving

    narratives (discussed in more detail below) re-signify the business landscape in a

    manner that promotes inequality and prevents a more democratic approach to business

    in the U.S. (pp. 26-30).

    During her fieldwork, Ho (2009) maintains that shareholder value was beginning

    to engulf U.S. culture as the central reasoning and explanation for the restructuring of

    firms, shifting concepts of inequality and wealth, and the condition of the U.S. economy

    at large. To understand this phenomenon, Ho (2009) unpacks the ethnographic present,

    which leads her to the takeover movement in the 1980s when Wall Street hardened its

    grip over corporate America. Essentially, this entailed supplanting existing values in

    the plural sociological sense and establishing values that are more market-oriented.

    The shift was from the old concept of the firm as a social institution, valued for its

    permanency and role in the community, to the new notion of the corporation as a

    network of liquid investors, now measured by efficiency, liquidity, and short-term

    profits. While one could interpret this as an instance of the market undermining the

    mutuality upon which it rests, as Gudeman (2009a) might posit, for Hos (2009)

    informants, the championing of shareholder value was mission-driven and considered

    economically and morally the correct thing to do. Even when increasing shareholder

    value means cutting jobs, the tension is averted because the company has becomedefined by its owners and not its employees (pp. 122-129). The dependency link of the

    market to society is rendered imperceptible.

    I would suspect that bankers would instead perceive this unfortunate scenario as

    a necessary evolutionary progression from stakeholder value-orientations to

    shareholder value-orientations. I am referring to the contrast of values that can be

    discerned between the stakeholder economies of Japan and Western Europe, where

    company profits go to long-serving employees, with the shareholder economies of the

    U.K. and U.S., where profits go to the owners of the companies shares. Thus, the former

    rewards for loyalty and the latter for individual gain. The institutional loyalties of the

    stakeholder economies create social attachments to firms, which surpasses a mere

    economic relationship. This loyalty is reciprocated from the companies, who in turn

    offer more than simply a market rate wage. There is a greater inherent valuation for

  • 8/4/2019 Alex Parkinson - Dissertation

    30/57

    29

    group ties, as rewards are given for occupancy and role within the firm, rather than

    individual achievement and ability (Blim 2005, pp. 314-316). Ostensibly, the economists

    and financiers of today have learned well from their counterparts of the marginalist

    revolution. Just as values, such as these, were abandoned for price back then, today the

    composites of shareholder value were packaged together and represented in one

    economic usage of the term as a market valued share price that ignores and conceals

    any conflicting values.

    The benefits of this configuration for the few can be discerned when Ho (2009)

    calls forth the case of Safeway to show the real purpose of creating shareholder value in

    these contexts. The company had been operating competitively with plans for growth

    until a leveraged buyout (LBO) led to massive downsizing, lower wages, and a reduction

    in capital improvement plans. Essentially, this enacted a significant transfer of wealth

    from the firm to top company executives, investment banks, and the private equity firm,

    while the company itself was saddled with a monumental amount of debt. Thus, Ho

    (2009) argues that takeovers should be understood as power struggles over cultural

    values and practices that are hierarchical and diverging. Contrary to the worldview of

    her informants, who believed that Wall Street unlocked value and improved efficiency in

    corporate America, Ho (2009) argues that the takeover movement of the 1980s and the

    mergers and acquisitions prevalent in the 1990s were really about high financiers

    capitalising on the downturn of the previous decade to align corporate values to those ofthe stock market and Wall Street. To counter the perceived inefficiencies of managerial

    capitalism, managers were made into shareholders through LBOs so that the interests of

    the firm became their interests (pp. 129-153).

    These revolutions in the name of shareholder value often, paradoxically, caused a

    long term decline in the value of the target company, as Ho (2009) illustrates with the

    example of Daimler-Benz and Chrysler. Hence, she argues that shareholder value must

    be viewed as a political tactic to monopolise control over corporations and to support

    the demands of short-term financial profiteering. Moreover, the way that her informants

    explain this tension, as advocates of shareholder value, highlights the representational

    power of economic ideas and their utility as political tools. Although some informants

    were more hesitant over the benefits of shareholder value, downsizing, and efficiency,

    none robustly challenged their assumptions and resorted instead to neoclassic

  • 8/4/2019 Alex Parkinson - Dissertation

    31/57

    30

    rationalisations (pp. 153-168). This interpretation of events sits rather comfortably with

    the Marxist analysis of political economy changes that I outlined above. Elites created

    the conditions for financial accumulation through the financialisation of corporate

    America and by perpetuating neoclassic ideologies that became so pervasive that the

    very actors who currently carry the flag for shareholder value do not recognise their

    contributions to these unequal transfers of wealth. In this view, we also begin to see why

    economic expertise is perhaps such a valued service, since it allows an enormous

    amount of wealth to be transferred to those who access it.

    From the standpoint of investment bankers, the use of the share price as the

    primary measure of a company was about restoring the correct harmony between

    control and ownership of firms. Here, shareholder value enables investment bankers to

    package their values into a single number and fight for elite interests by forcing market-

    centric short-term decisions on corporations. Ho (2009) purports that part of the

    discursive power of the market derives from these abstract, flexible representations and

    allows Wall Street to maintain its current position as producer of U.S. hegemony (pp. 35-

    38). As she argues, Wall Street also maintains its own hegemony through [t]he culture

    of smartness [which] begets global spread, justifies global financial influence,

    naturalizes imperialist practices, and produces financial dominance (p. 72). If the ruling

    powers and institutions have cultivated the market economy to their benefit, then how

    were the minds of the masses won over or coerced into allowing such unequalaccumulations of wealth? Combining these transformations with an interpretative

    theory of value may throw light upon these questions, as we travel deeper into the realm

    of the human economic mind.

    Masters of a Symbolic Universe of Value

    The manner in which investment banks and their worldview of shareholder value

    became institutionalised and then legitimated resonates clearly with the levels oflegitimacy that Berger and Luckman (1966) outline. The explicit theories of an

    institutional sector, in this case comprised of economists and financiers, brewed its own

    stock of knowledge to support shareholder value through what Ho (2009) shows to be

    a crude reinterpretation of the historical relationships between corporate America, the

    stock market, and investors, but also on decontexualized extrapolations (and new

  • 8/4/2019 Alex Parkinson - Dissertation

    32/57

    31

    adaptations) from neoclassic and classic economic thought (p. 169). Accordingly, to

    denaturalise bankers worldview of shareholder value, Ho (2009) contests the myth

    upon which its legitimacy rests whereby the shareholder was situated as the original

    fund provider and controller of corporations. She points out that corporations raised

    funds predominantly through bonds issues for most of the twentieth-century and

    funded the vast majority of their capital expenditure from internal resources up until the

    early 1970s (pp. 179 & 202), while it was actually corporations that financed the growth

    of the stock market (p. 343). Although shareholder value is in reality a socially

    constructed justification for institutional practice, the manner in which bankers selected

    axioms to fit their worldview indicates how it was able to reach and maintain such a

    high level of legitimacy.

    None of these changes could have taken place if they did not occur within a

    symbolic universe of value, a fourth level of legitimacy that also suggests the existence of

    a system of meaning that Graeber (2005) alludes to. There are numerous indications

    that such a phenomenon exists. Firstly, this universe is characterised by Dumontian

    hierarchy, which is perhaps best exemplified when Ho (2009) recounts an interview

    with an analyst that moved from investment bank Morgan Stanley to Pepsi Corporation.

    Her informant describes Wall Street as a fighter plane when making decisions in

    comparison to other corporations. As Ho (2009) points out, this implies a value

    hierarchy where Wall Streets quick adaptation and flexibility are favoured over slowand rigid firms, bankers are superior to the average worker, and liquidity is preferred to

    illiquidity (pp. 243-248). The values in a sociological sense of trust, commitment, and

    loyalty are abandoned for shareholder value that, in spite of the single number

    represented on the stock exchange, is a composite that includes notions of liquidity,

    flexibility, and short-termism. This notably contains and conceals the dimensions of

    power that my discussion in the previous section crystallised.

    Secondly, the hierarchy above implies that there are different segregations or

    spheres of value encompassed by the modern universe. Ho (2009) offers us a vignette of

    these realms when she shows that the stock market was historically constructed to

    separate control from ownership in order to create liquidity. This contradicts general

    beliefs about corporate history that saw control returned to the shareholder, who in

    reality never had it. Ho (2009) finds this alarming since the stock price is used as a

  • 8/4/2019 Alex Parkinson - Dissertation

    33/57

    32

    measure of corporate success and value yet the value realm of liquidity which affects

    the share price is ill suited to the operations of the firm, while the share price itself is

    not historically or culturally connected to the practices of the company. Against Wall

    Streets claims, stocks are not merely representations since they belong to a divergent

    social construction that functions apart from corporations (pp. 183-188). For instance, a

    retail company could be making lots of sales and performing well but this would not

    prevent general market fear operating in a different value sphere from depressing

    the price and attracting pressure from investors, which might lead to downsizing.

    Thirdly, these segmented hierarchies of value may be imagined to have varying

    degrees of attachment to a broader social order. Dumont (1986) claims that in the non-

    modern view, the values of the right hand and left hand which he invokes to exemplify

    an idea and a pair of values is rooted in relation to the whole body or a higher level of

    existence (pp. 248-250). In the modern view, determining the values of the pair would

    only entail a look at each of the hands. Applying this to shareholder value suggests the

    possibility of alternative configurations. Rather than determining share price based

    solely on cash flows and the like, market mechanisms could be established that increase

    share value in relation to some broader social measure, such as contributions to

    charitable causes or the level of carbon emissions. This may be a step to fixing the

    modern formation that has arisen from the break between the element and the whole.

    Certainly, Dumonts (1986) claim that [t]he whole has become a heap resonates withour current economic crisis (pp. 262 & 263).

    Fourthly, if as Dumont (1986) argues, the scientific is replacing the moral in our

    contemporary consciousness, then Hos (2009) informants have used the scientific, or

    the economic, to directly realign and then justify what should be considered moral.

    The more that shareholder value gains legitimacy and begins to take on the form of an

    ideology if indeed it has not already the previous hierarchical universe[becomes]

    fanned out into a collection of flat views of this kind (Dumont 1986, p. 249). At that

    point, there is no inversion of values at different levels since everything is measured

    against share price. Whatever the context, we do not even make the value judgement

    over left or right. Finally, we need not look beyond the very structure of the phrase

    shareholder value, which clearly denotes the superiority of the shareholder by placing

    the word first. It makes the inversion, valued shareholders, conceptually harder to

  • 8/4/2019 Alex Parkinson - Dissertation

    34/57

    33

    imagine. Hence, there can be no value in who the shareholders are, long-term or short-

    term, nurturing or predatory, forgiving or relentless. It seems that the masters of the

    universe, as the name implies, are capable of manipulating and oscillating these value

    structures by asserting a particular type of economic expertise into configurations

    that best suit their financial and monetary interests.

    Summary

    I have tried to show how the Eye of Providence model is useful when interpreting

    existing ethnographic research on powerful market actors and institutions. I chose to

    examine a single ethnography in significant detail because it largely conforms to my

    framework. This has enabled me to think through the key perspectives of this paper in

    specific relation to the economic lives of investment bankers. Wall Street is a place

    where people go to make money as individuals; money is central to peoples being on

    the Street and is also the key product that the financial institutions are structured to

    manufacture. This is all made possible through the rendering of instituted financial and

    economic expertise that has essentially liquidated social relations both individual and

    institutional on the Street and far beyond.

    Whether or not one chooses to accept the hegemonic view of the institutions and

    the ruling powers, it is hard to doubt that they play a significant role in perpetuating the

    worldview of shareholder value; thus, these elements of the framework cannot be leftunattended. The concept of value that I have been developing appears to have universal

    applicability ostensibly due to its interpretive flexibility yet the manifestations of it

    appear to assume endless forms. On the one hand, there appears to be a realm of value

    out there informing bankers decisions and guiding their preferences towards

    shareholder value. Institutional and political influences played an instrumental role in

    crafting these values. On the other, one could argue that all bankers are really just acting

    out of universal self-interested rationality. While the universal-particular debate

    continues into the section below, I have verified that interpretive value theory can speak of

    both individuals and of societies in the same breath, while political economy unearths the

    dynamics that motivate them.

  • 8/4/2019 Alex Parkinson - Dissertation

    35/57

    34

    Migrant Remittances in an Anthropological Economy

    I began this paper by drawing on theories about the relation of the market to

    society and later critiqued an ethnography that offers a view of this relationship from

    the market itself, or at least from the perspective of very influential market actors. In

    addition to the cultural influences, investment banking is very much an institutionalised

    arena for economic rationality. Investment bankers were shown to largely talk in its

    language and think in its logic. But what happens when we step away from market

    institutions and toward economic life that flourishes in an entirely different social

    sphere? To address this question, I turn the optic to the case of international cash

    transfers that are sent by migrant workers to recipients who have remained in their

    origin country. The migrant-remittance phenomenon is perhaps the most significant9

    and for some potentially the most important10

    example of economic activity that

    operates to principles other than those that we might consider to come under the rubric

    of the market economy. Assuming that remittances are less of a formally

    institutionalised economic function, I suspect that the transferring agents are much

    more distant from the discipline of economics than financiers. Thus, I first examine how

    economists try to build expert knowledge about the remittance phenomenon, since it

    entails dealing with peoples actions that operate outside the disciplines comfort zone. I

    then contrast this with an anthropological perspective through the conceptual

    framework of this paper.

    What the Economists Say

    I begin with a summary and critique ofRapoport and Docquiers (2005)

    discussion of migrant-remittance economics.11

    9 Against other international flows, even just the recordedtransfers were estimated to be only second toForeign Direct Investment and were much more resilient during the global downturn (Ratha, Mohapatra& Silwal 2010, p. 3).

    To introduce remittances, the authors

    point out that since the 1980s, there has been increasing acknowledgement in

    microeconomics of the familial and strategic motives behind remittances, while in

    macroeconomics there has been a shift of focus from the short-run effects of transfers to

    their long-run role in development and reducing inequality (p. 4). The authors recognise

    10 Given the development potential of $316 billion+.11 The work was prepared for an independent non-profit organisation that researches labour and waslater published in a handbook for economics. See Rapoport and Docquier (2006).

  • 8/4/2019 Alex Parkinson - Dissertation

    36/57

    35

    that poor data quality circumscribes the macro analyses of remittances and that the

    difficulty in discriminating between competing microeconomic theories makes their

    study more challenging; however, they argue for further investigation since remittances

    often significantly increase GNP, are a major source of foreign exchange, and constitute a

    large portion of GDP in many of the developing countries to which they are sent (p. 5).

    Moreover, they emphasise that the method of conducting household surveys from

    various countries has revealed that a signi